- Afriat, Sydney N. The construction of utility functions from expenditure data. International Economic Review 8, no. 1 (1967): 67-77.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Agranov, Marina, and Pietro Ortoleva. Stochastic choice and preferences for randomization. Journal of Political Economy 125, no. 1 (2017): 40-68.
Allred, S., Duffy, S. and Smith, J., 2016. Cognitive load and strategic sophistication. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 125, pp.162-178.
Almlund, M., Duckworth, A.L., Heckman, J. and Kautz, T., 2011. Personality psychology and economics. In Handbook of the Economics of Education (Vol. 4, pp. 1-181). Elsevier.
Andersson, Ola, Håkan J. Holm, Jean-Robert Tyran, and Erik Wengström. Risk aversion relates to cognitive ability: Preferences or Noise? Journal of the European Economic Association 14, no. 5 (2016): 1129-1154.
- Barrouillet, Pierre, Sophie Bernardin, Sophie Portrat, Evie Vergauwe, and Valérie Camos. Time and cognitive load in working memory. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition 33, no. 3 (2007): 570.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Benjamin, D. J., Brown, S. A., & Shapiro, J. M. (2013). Who is ‘behavioral’? Cognitive ability and anomalous preferences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(6), 1231-1255.
Camerer, Colin F. An experimental test of several generalized utility theories. Journal of Risk and uncertainty 2, no. 1 (1989): 61-104.
Carpenter, Jeffrey, Michael Graham, and Jesse Wolf. Cognitive ability and strategic sophistication. Games and Economic Behavior 80 (2013): 115-130.
Dave, Chetan, Catherine C. Eckel, Cathleen A. Johnson, and Christian Rojas. Eliciting risk preferences: When is simple better? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 41, no. 3 (2010): 219-243.
Deck, Cary, and Salar Jahedi. The effect of cognitive load on economic decision making: A survey and new experiments. European Economic Review 78 (2015): 97-119.
Dohmen, Thomas, Armin Falk, David Huffman, and Uwe Sunde. On the relationship between cognitive ability and risk preference. Journal of Economic Perspectives 32, no. 2 (2018): 115-34.
Dohmen, Thomas, Armin Falk, David Huffman, Uwe Sunde, Jürgen Schupp, and Gert G. Wagner. Individual risk attitudes: Measurement, determinants, and behavioral consequences. Journal of the European Economic Association 9, no. 3 (2011): 522-550.
Duffy, Sean, and John Smith. Cognitive load in the multi-player prisoner's dilemma game: Are there brains in games? Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics 51 (2014): 47-56.
Eckel, C., & Grossman, P. (2002). Sex differences and statistical stereotyping in attitudes toward financial risk. Evolution and Human Behavior, 23(4), 281–295.
Eckel, C., & Grossman, P. (2008). Forecasting risk attitudes: An experimental study using actual and forecast gamble choices. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 68(1), 1–17.
Falk, A., Kosse, F., Pinger, P., Schildberg-Hörisch, H., & Deckers, T. (2019). Socio-economic status and inequalities in children’s IQ and economic preferences. Journal of Political Economy (forthcoming).
Filippin, Antonio, and Paolo Crosetto. A reconsideration of gender differences in risk attitudes. Management Science 62, no. 11 (2016): 3138-3160.
Fischbacher, Urs. z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental economics 10, no. 2 (2007): 171-178.
Frederick, Shane. Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19, no. 4 (2005): 25-42.
Gerhardt, Holger, Guido P. Biele, Hauke R. Heekeren, and Harald Uhlig. Cognitive load increases risk aversion. No. 2016-011. SFB 649 Discussion Paper, 2016.
Greiner, Ben. Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association 1, no. 1 (2015): 114-125.
Gul, Faruk, and Wolfgang Pesendorfer. Random expected utility. Econometrica 74, no. 1 (2006): 121-146.
Heckman, James J. and Edward Vytlacil. 2001. “Identifying the Role of Cognitive Ability in Explaining the Level of and Change in the Return to Schooling.†Review of Economics and Statistics 83 (1):1–12.
Hey, John D. Why we should not be silent about noise. Experimental Economics 8, 4 (2005): 325345.
Hey, John D., and Chris Orme. Investigating generalizations of expected utility theory using experimental data. Econometrica (1994): 1291-1326.
Hey, John D., and Enrica Carbone. Stochastic choice with deterministic preferences: An experimental investigation. Economics Letters 47, no. 2 (1995): 161-167.
- Houthakker, Hendrik S. Revealed preference and the utility function. Economica 17, no. 66 (1950): 159-174.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Jacobson, Sarah, and Ragan Petrie. Learning from mistakes: What do inconsistent choices over risk tell us?. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 38, no. 2 (2009): 143-158.
Krajbich, I., Oud, B. and Fehr, E., 2014. Benefits of neuroeconomic modeling: new policy interventions and predictors of preference. American Economic Review, 104(5), pp.501-06.
Lohse, J., 2016. Smart or selfish–When smart guys finish nice. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 64, pp.28-40.
McFadden, Daniel. Economic choices. American Economic Review 91, 3 (2001): 351-378.
Rabin, Matthew, and Georg Weizsäcker. Narrow bracketing and dominated choices. American Economic Review 99, 4 (2009): 1508-43.
Rabin, Matthew, and Richard H. Thaler. Anomalies: risk aversion. Journal of Economic perspectives 15, 1 (2001): 219-232.
- Samuelson, Paul A. Consumption theory in terms of revealed preference. Economica 15, 60 (1948): 243-253.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Schmidt, Frank L. and John E. Hunter. 2004. “General Mental Ability in the World of Work: Occupational Attainment and Job Performance.†Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 86 (1):162–73.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Shiv Baba and Alexander Fedorikhin. “Heart and Mind in Conflict: The Interplay of Affect and Cognition in Consumer Decision Making.†Journal of Consumer Research 26, (1999): 278–292.
Starmer, Chris, and Robert Sugden. Probability and juxtaposition effects: An experimental investigation of the common ratio effect. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 2, no. 2 (1989): 159-178.
- Toplak, Maggie E., Richard F. West, and Keith E. Stanovich. Assessing miserly information processing: An expansion of the Cognitive Reflection Test. Thinking & Reasoning 20, no. 2 (2014): 147-168.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Tversky, Amos. Intransitivity of preferences. Psychological review 76, no. 1 (1969): 31.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Whitney, Paul, Christa A. Rinehart, and John M. Hinson. Framing effects Under Cognitive Load: The Role of Working Memory in Risky Decisions. Psychonomic Bulletin & Review 15(6), (2008): 1179-1184. Online Appendix (not intended for print publication)
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now