Ågren, H., Dahlberg, M., & Mörk, E. (2007). Do politicians’ preferences correspond to those of the voters? An investigation of political representation. Public Choice, 130(1/2), 137–162.
Ai, C., & Norton, E. C. (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters, 80(1), 123–129.
Alesina, A., & Drazen, A. (1991). Why are stabilizations delayed? American Economic Review, 81(5), 1170–1188.
Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1989). Partisan cycles in congressional elections and the macroeconomy. American Political Science Review, 83(2), 373–398.
Bender, B., & Lott, J. R. (1996). Legislator voting and shirking: A critical review of the literature. Public Choice, 87(1–2), 67–100.
Besley, T., & Coate, S. (2008). Issue unbundling via citizens’ initiatives. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 3(4), 379–397.
- Brennan, G. (2011). The political economy of public debt. Mimeo. Duke University & Australian National University.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Brunner, E. J.; Ross, S. L. & Washington, E. L. (2011). Does less income mean less representation? Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Working Papers, WP No. 16835.
Carey, J. M. (2007). Competing principals political institutions, and party unity in legislative voting. American Journal of Political Science, 51, 92–107.
Denzau, A. T., & Munger, M. C. (1986). Legislators and interest groups: How unorganized interests get represented. The American Political Science Review, 80(1), 89–106.
- Dow, J. K. (2001). A comparative spatial analysis of majoritarian and proportional elections. Electoral Studies, 20(1), 109–125.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.
Drazen, A., & Grilli, V. (1993). The benefit of crises for economic reforms. American Economic Review, 83(3), 598–607.
Eusepi, G., & Wagner, R. E. (2012). Indebted state versus intermediary state: Who owes what to whom? Mimeo. George Mason University.
Feld, L. P., & Matsusaka, J. G. (2003). Budget referendums and government spending: Evidence from Swiss cantons. Journal of Public Economics, 87(12), 2703–2724.
Frey, B. S. (1994). Direct democracy: Politico-economic lessons from swiss experience. American Economic Review, 84(2), 338–342.
Garrett, T. A. (1999). A test of shirking under legislative and citizen vote: The case of state lottery adoption. Journal of Law and Economics, 42(1), 189–208.
- Gerber, E. R. (1996). Legislative response to the threat of popular initiatives. American Journal of Political Science, 40(1), 99–128.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Gerber, E. R., & Lewis, J. B. (2004). Beyond the median: Voter preferences district heterogeneity, and political representation. Journal of Political Economy, 112(6), 1364–1383.
Golder, M., & Stramski, J. (2010). Ideological congruence and electoral institutions. American Journal of Political Science, 54(1), 90–106.
- Grofman, B. (2004). Downs and two-party convergence. Annual Review of Political Science, 7, 25–46.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Hersch, P. L., & McDougall, G. S. (1988). Voting for ‘sin’ in Kansas. Public Choice, 57(2), 127–139.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Kau, J. B., & Rubin, P. H. (1978). Voting on minimum wages: A time-series analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 86(2), 337–342.
Kau, J. B., & Rubin, P. H. (1979). Self-interest ideology, and logrolling in congressional voting. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 365–384.
Kenny, L., & Lotfinia, B. (2005). Evidence on the importance of spatial voting models in presidential nominations and elections. Public Choice, 123(3), 439–462.
Krehbiel, K. (1993). Constituency characteristics and legislative preferences. Public Choice, 76(1–2), 21–37.
- López, E., & RamÃrez, C. (2008). Mr. Smith and the economy: The influence of economic conditions on individual legislator voting. Public Choice, 136(1), 1–17.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Levitt, S. D. (1996). How do senators vote? Disentangling the role of voter preferences, party affiliation, and senator ideology. The American Economic Review, 86(3), 425–441.
Lott, J. R., & Davis, M. L. (1992). A critical review and an extension of the political shirking literature. Public Choice, 74(4), 461–484.
Matsusaka, J. G. (1995). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative: Evidence from the last 30 years. Journal of Political Economy, 103(3), 587–623.
Matsusaka, J. G. (2010). Popular control of public policy: A quantitative approach. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 5(2), 133–167.
Portmann, M., Stadelmann, D., & Eichenberger, R. (2012). District magnitude and representation of the majority’s preferences: Quasi-experimental evidence from popular and parliamentary votes. Public Choice, 151(3–4), 585–610.
- Schneider, F., Pommerehne, W. W., & Frey, B. S. (1981). Politico-economic interdependence in a direct democracy: The case of Switzerland. In Douglas A. Hibbs & Heino Fassbender (Eds.), Contemporary political economy, studies on the interdependence of politics and economics. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Stadelmann, D., Portmann, M., & Eichenberger, R. (2012a). Evaluating the median voter model’s explanatory power. Economics Letters, 114(3), 312–314.
Stadelmann, D., Portmann, M., & Eichenberger, R. (2012b). Quantifying parliamentary representation of constituents' preferences with quasi-experimental data. Journal of Comparative Economics (forthcoming).
Stratmann, T. (1992). Are contributors rational? Untangling strategies of political action committees. The Journal of Political Economy, 100(3), 647–664.
Stratmann, T. (1995). Campaign contributions and congressional voting: does the timing of contributions matter? Review of Economics and Statistics, 77(1), 127–136.