Adams, J. (1999). Policy divergence in multicandidate probabilistic spatial voting. Public Choice, 100, 103–22.
Ansolabehere, S., & Snyder, J. M, Jr. (2000). Valence politics and equilibrium in spatial election models. Public Choice, 103, 327–336.
Ansolabehere, S., Leblanc, W., & Snyder, J. M, Jr. (2012). When parties are not teams: Party positions in single-member district and proportional representation systems. Economic Theory, 49(3), 521–547.
- Aragonès, E., & Palfrey, T. R. (2002). Mixed strategy equilibrium in a Downsian model with a favored candidate. Journal of Economic Theory, 103, 131–161.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Aragonès, E., & Palfrey, T. R. (2005). Social choice and strategic decisions. In D. Austen-Smith & J. Duggan (Eds.), Spatial competition between two candidates of different quality: The effects of candidate ideology and private information. Berlin: Springer.
Aragonès, E., & Xefteris, D. (2012). Candidate quality in a Downsian model with a continuous policy space. Games and Economic Behavior, 75(2), 464–480.
Aragonès, E., & Xefteris, D. (2017a). Imperfectly informed voters and strategic extremism. International Economic Review, 58(2), 439–471.
Aragonès, E., & Xefteris, D. (2017b). Voters’ private valuation of candidates’ quality. Journal of Public Economics, 156, 121–130.
Aragones, E., & Palfrey, T. R. (2004). The effect of candidate quality on electoral equilibrium: An experimental study. American Political Science Review, 98(1), 77–90.
Ashworth, S., & de Mesquita, E. B. (2009). Elections with platform and valence competition. Games and Economic Behavior, 67, 191–216.
Baye, M. R., Kovenock, D., & De Vries, C. G. (1996). The all-pay auction with complete information. Economic Theory, 8(2), 291–305.
Bernheim, B. D., & Kartik, N. (2014). Candidates, character, and corruption. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 6, 205–246.
Brusco, S., & Roy, J. (2011). Aggregate uncertainty in the citizen candidate model yields extremist parties. Social Choice and Welfare, 36(1), 83–104.
Buisseret, P. (2017). Electoral competition with entry under non-majoritarian run-off rules. Games and Economic Behavior, 104, 494–506.
Cadigan, J. (2005). The citizen candidate model: An experimental analysis. Public Choice, 123(1–2), 197–216.
Callander, S. (2005). Electoral competition in heterogeneous districts. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), 1116–1145.
- Callander, S., & Wilson, C. H. (2007). Turnout, polarization, and Duverger’s law. Journal of Politics, 69(4), 1047–1056.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- Carillo, J. D., & Castanheria, M. (2008). Information and strategic political polarisation. Economic Journal, 118, 845–874.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Collins, R., & Sherstyuk, K. (2000). Spatial competition with three firms: An experimental study. Economic Inquiry, 38(1), 73–94.
Crutzen, B. S., Castanheira, M., & Sahuguet, N. (2009). Party organization and electoral competition. The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 26(2), 212–242.
Degan, A. (2007). Candidate valence: Evidence from consecutive presidential elections. International Economic Review, 48(2), 457–482.
Dellis, A. (2009). Would letting people vote for multiple candidates yield policy moderation? Journal of Economic Theory, 144(2), 772–801.
Dix, M., & Santore, R. (2002). Candidate ability and platform choice. Economics Letters, 76, 189–194.
Eaton, B. C., & Lipsey, R. G. (1975). The principle of minimum differentiation reconsidered: Some new developments in the theory of spatial competition. Review of Economic Studies, 42(1), 27–49.
- Elbittar, A. & Gomberg, A. (2009). An experimental study of the citizen-candidate model. In E. Aragonès, C. Beviá, H. Lllavador, & N. Schofield (Eds.), The political economy of democracy. Fundación BBVA conference proceedings.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Erikson, R. S., & Palfrey, T. R. (2000). Equilibria in campaign spending games: Theory and data. American Political Science Review, 94, 595–609.
Evrenk, H., & Kha, D. (2011). Three-candidate spatial competition when candidates have valence: Stochastic voting. Public Choice, 147, 421–438.
Greenberg, J., & Shepsle, K. (1987). The effect of electoral rewards in multiparty competition with entry. American Political Science Review, 81, 525–537.
- Groseclose, T. (2001). A model of candidate location when one candidate has a valence advantage. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 862–86.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Grosser, J., & Palfrey, T. R. (2014). Candidate entry and political polarization: An antimedian voter theorem. American Journal of Political Science, 58(1), 127–143.
- Grosser, J., & Palfrey, T. R. (2017). Candidate entry and political polarization: An experimental study. New York: Mimeo.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Herrera, H., Levine, D., & Martinelli, C. (2008). Policy platforms, campaign spending and voter participation. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 501–513.
Hummel, P. (2010). On the nature of equilibriums in a Downsian model with candidate valence. Games and Economic Behavior, 70(2), 425–445.
Kartik, N., & McAfee, R. P. (2007). Signaling character in electoral competition. American Economic Review, 97, 852–870.
Kim, K. (2005). Valence characteristics and entry of a third party. Economics Bulletin, 4, 1–9.
Krasa, S., & Polborn, M. (2012). Political competition between differentiated candidates. Games and Economic Behavior, 76(1), 249–271.
Laussel, D., & Le Breton, M. (2002). Unidimensional Downsian politics: Median, utilitarian, or what else? Economics Letters, 76, 351–356.
Loertscher, S., & Muehlheusser, G. (2011). Sequential location games. The RAND Journal of Economics, 42(4), 639–663.
- Meirowitz, A. (2008). Electoral contests, incumbency advantages and campaign finance. Journal of Politics, 70(3), 681–699.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Osborne, M. J. (1993). Candidate positioning and entry in a political competition. Games and Economic Behavior, 5(1), 133–151.
Osborne, M. J., & Pitchik, C. (1986). The Nature of equilibrium in a location model. International Economic Review, 27(1), 223–237.
Osborne, M. J., & Slivinski, A. (1996). A model of political competition with citizen-candidates. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1), 65–96.
Palfrey, T. R. (1984). Spatial equilibrium with entry. Review of Economic Studies, 51, 139–56.
Pastine, I., & Pastine, T. (2012). Incumbency advantage and political campaign spending limits. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 20–32.
Schofield, N. J. (2007). The mean voter theorem: Necessary and sufficient conditions for convergent equilibrium. The Review of Economic Studies, 74, 965–980.
- Serra, G. (2010). Polarization of what? A model of elections with endogenous valence. Journal of Politics, 72(2), 426–437.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
Shaked, A. (1982). Existence and computation of mixed strategy Nash equilibrium for 3-firms location problem. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 31, 93–96.
Shapoval, A., Weber, S., & Zakharov, A. (2015). Valence influence in electoral competition with rank objectives. New York: Mimeo.
Stokes, D. E. (1963). Spatial models of party competition. American Political Science Review, 57, 368–77.
Tsakas, N., & Xefteris, D. (2018). Electoral competition with third party entry in the lab. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 148, 121–134.
Weber, S. (1992). On hierarchical spatial competition. The Review of Economic Studies, 59(2), 407–425.
Weber, S. (1997). Entry deterrence in electoral spatial competition. Social Choice and Welfare, 15(1), 31–56.
Xefteris, D. (2012). Mixed strategy equilibrium in a Downsian model with a favored candidate: A comment. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(1), 393–396.
Xefteris, D. (2014). Mixed equilibriums in a three-candidate spatial model with candidate valence. Public Choice, 158, 101–120.
Zakharov, A. (2009). A model of candidate location with endogenous valence. Public Choice, 138, 347–366.