SlideShare a Scribd company logo
The Importance of Parameter Constancy for Endogenous Growth with Externality
Kelly Yiyu Lin*
BMO Financial Group, U.S.A.
email:yiyu@msn.com
Wenti Du**
Akita International University, Japan
email:wenti.du@gmail.com
Abstract
The economic model of endogenous growth has been commonly discussed. It has been
specified by econometric models by Robert Barro (1986, 1990, and 1994) and Xavier Sala-
i-Martin (2003) but it is challenging to keep parameter constancy in the model. This paper
demonstrates how to find the stable growth rate converging to the steady state and the
optimal capital level at the steady state with parameter constancy. This paper also finds
the economy would converge to a stable steady state when the co-integration holds
between annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita. We take an empirical
study of selected five countries (Indonesia, India, US, France and Japan) from 1960 to 2016
and specify econometric models of endogenous growth with externality and to test the
convergence.
JEL Codes: O11, O47
Keywords: externality, production function, endogenous growth, convergence, parameter
constancy
1
1. Introduction
Technology generates positive externalities and contributes to long-term growth in an
economy. The economic model of endogenous growth has been commonly discussed, for
example, see Romer (1986, 1990, 1994), Benhabib and Jovanovic (1989), Mankiw (1995);
however, it is challenging to keep parameter constancy. In this paper, we take an
empirical study of selected countries to specify an econometric model of endogenous
growth with externality and to test the convergence. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2003)
propose the concepts of β convergence and σ convergence to specify the econometric
models for the rate of convergence. However, parameter constancy is the challenge in
their model. In order to find the stable growth rate converging to the steady state and
the optimal capital level at the steady state, this paper applies impulse indicators to
keep parameter constancy in the face of exogenous shocks.
The new technology generates one-time shock that affects economies. We assume that
such impact of new technology is exogenous and constant, which could be viewed as an
externality in an economy. Also, technology innovation contributes to creating more
physical capital and human capital in an economy. In the face of exogenous shocks, the
significant impulse indicators of the model demonstrate the current economy is
converging to a stable steady state if the co-integration relationship holds between
endogenous variables; otherwise, the economy will diverge to a saddle point (unstable
steady state). Our findings show that technology innovation has a different impact on
developed countries (France, Japan, and the U.S.) and developing countries (India and
Indonesia).
The effect of new technology on developed countries is insignificant, while the impact of
new technology on developing countries is shown to be significant. Moreover, our results
suggest that the rates of convergence in developed countries are lower than those in
developing countries. In particular, among our sample countries, the Indian economy
diverges to an unstable steady state, also known as “saddle point” because the co-
integration relationship does not hold between annual growth rate of GDP per capita and
GDP per capita. This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 analyzes economies in
Indonesia, India, U.S., France and the Japan. Section 3 explains the data we use and
specify the econometric model we adopt. Section 4 presents the empirical results. Section
5 discusses the AK model and the case in Indonesia. Section 6 concludes our research.
2
2. An Overview of the relationship between GDP per capita and Human Capital
After World War II, the analysis of economic growth became a topic of high priority
because of decolonization in Asia. The neo-classical, Solow growth theory (1956) was
embraced by economists, which explains long-run economic growth by focusing on
physical capital accumulation. However, economic growth could not only rely on physical
capital. While the ratio of the growth of physical capital to the growth of human capital
exceeds the equilibrium ratio, the rate of economic growth declines. Thus, human capital
is the crucial variable for economic growth. The innovation of technology is the critical
shock for economic growth. To obtain the best available technology, the economy needs
skilled labor force, which leads to thinking about human capital in economic growth. The
advances in endogenous growth theory from Paul Romer (1986) have been the ability to
formalize this idea. This section provides the economic analysis to precede the research of
the endogenous growth model for Indonesia, India, U.S., France and Japan.
The main topic of endogenous growth is human capital accumulation. Human capital
could produce output in production, and human capital could produce human capital
endogenously. GDP per capita is highly co-integrated with human capital index and also
the index of physical capital, so GDP per capita can apply as the aggregate impacts of
physical capital and human capital in modeling. The human capital and physical capital in
developed countries are higher than they are in developing countries. However, the Inada
rule indicates the poor economies have small capital stocks, and the marginal product of
capital should be high. Thus, capital should have the incentive to flow from rich countries
to emerging countries. The poor economies have the tendency to grow more rapidly than
rich economies. Human capital accumulation of endogenous growth is caused by the
shock of technology. Technology is kind of positive externality of the economy with
governmental intervention, and the one-time shock of technology can create the
permanent change of the economy. This paper will focus on the endogenous growth with
externality and test for the convergence of selected countries.
3
Graph 2.1 GDP per Capita and Human Capital Index
As shown in Graph 2.1, GDP per capita is co-integrated with Human Capital Index for
Indonesia, India, U.S., France and Japan. Because GDP per capita for the selected four
4
countries are highly co-integrated with human capital indexes of all selected countries,
GDP per capita could be the proxy of human capital.
Graph 2.2 Human Capitals Index
Moreover, during the period both GDP per Capita and human capitals of developed
countries (Japan, U.S, and France) are higher than those of developing countries (India and
Indonesia) as shown in Graph 2.2.
5
Graph 2.3 Annual Growths of GDP per Capita and Population
6
However, as illustrated in Graph 2.3, the annual growth rate of GDP per capita increases
when population growth rate decreases for all selected countries from 1961 to 2016. In
general, human capital increases when population growth decreases for developed
countries (Indonesia, U.S, France and Japan), while India is an exception (Graph 2.4). In the
case of India, the human capital increases along with the population growth rate before
1983, but afterward it increases with the decline of population growth rate. Thus, human
capital does not have a constant negative relationship with population growth rate.
Graph 2.4 the Relationship between Human Capital and Population Growth Rate
7
Graph 2.5 Results of Convergence Tests
8
Results from conditional convergence test suggest that the long-run growth of Japan, U.S.,
and France converge to stable steady states (Graph 2.5). However, there are divergences
for long-run growth of India, in particular; the economy of India would diverge to an
unstable steady state (saddle point). The intercept shift of annual growth of GDP per
capita will be explained in detail in the model specification in Section three. The result of
conditional convergence test of Indonesia is close to AK model. This paper will discuss the
case of Indonesia in section five.
3. Data and Model Specification
3.1 Data
The sample size of data is annual data from 1961 to 2016. The data of annual growth of
GDP per capita comes from the World Bank database. The data of GDP per capita comes
from Federal Reserve's Bank. Constant GDP per capita is selected for gross domestic
product divided by midyear population. GDP is the sum of gross value added by all
resident producers in the economy plus any product taxes and minus any subsidies not
included in the value of the products.
3.2 Model Specification
Romer (1986) introduces the externality into the production function. The institution of
Romer model indicates that firms increase capital (physical capital and human capital) for
new technology, and this creates an externality. The externality is the impact of the
invention of technology. People believe the new technology will promote the production
significantly, so government encourages firms to invest more physical capital in new
technology and skill training to increase the human capital to operate new technology.
The technology generates positive externality to capital, so the externality to each firm is
determined by GDP per capita (Romer model with Lucas modification). Because GDP per
capita is highly co-integrated with human capital and physical capital, GDP per capita
should include the impacts of physical capital and human capital.
The invention of new technology creates the impacts of the one-time shock of the
economy (externality) and causes the permanent change of the economy. From 1961 to
2016, the innovate technology is "computer”. The invention of the computer changes our
lives permanently. Government establishes computer courses in schools and also
encourages firms to invest more in physical capital and human capital to promote the
industries. In economic theory section, we discuss how the impacts of one-time shocks
could cause the permanent change of the economy with externalities. In the model
9
specification, we will introduce the economic model first and then specify the
econometric models to test for convergence to find the optimal level of capital per capita
at the steady state and the rate of convergence back to steady state for selected
countries.
3.3 Economic Model
The theory of endogenous growth demonstrates the concerns of convergence and the
perfect competition in aggregate level. Graph 2.5 reflects the sample data (1961 to 2016)
supports the convergence for the economies of Japan, U.S and France, and the sample
data also supports the divergence for the economies of India. The invention of technology
would generate the one-time shock impacts to cause the permanent change of the
economy. The effects of new technology are exogenous and later change peoples'
economic activities permanently, so we assume technology is exogenous and constant in
the model. To investigate the impacts (size) of externality on the economy, we will discuss
the model in following three cases.
The production function of Romer model is defined as follows:
Y = AKα
L1−α
Ҟη
Y: production
A: constant technology
Ҟ: externality
𝝶: size of the externality
𝝶 increases -> externality is more significant and important
𝝶=0, production, Y, is Cobb-Douglas function
For Romer, Ҟ=K investment increases -> K increases
For Lucas, Ҟ= ƙ = K/L -> Romer model with Lucas modification
Y = AKα
L1−α
Ҟη
= AKα
L1−α
Kη
L−η
= AKα+η
L1−α−η
Y = AKα+η
L1−α−η
y = Y/L , ƙ= K/L -> y= Aƙα+η
Ќ = s·Y - δ·K
10
ƙ = K/L -> ln ƙ = ln K - ln L
ќ/ƙ = Ќ/K - Ľ/L
Ľ/L = n
n: population growth; population growth is exogenous
ќ/ƙ = (s·Y - δ·K )/K - n -> ќ = sy - (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ)·ƙ = s Aƙα+η
- (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ)·ƙ
ɣƙ = ќ/ƙ = s Aƙα+η−1
- (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ) -> the growth rate of ƙ, ɣƙ, depends on (α+δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1)
𝝶 > 0, ɣƙ >0, 0< s<1, s: saving rate; saving rate is exogenous
(α +δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1) decides if the model has a stable steady state, unstable steady state or no steady
state (AK model). The following three cases demonstrate the endogenous models with
different size of externalities.
Case 1: (α+δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1) <0 -> the impacts of externalities are not significant
-> Y is Neo-Classical production function
(the market is competitive)
-> there is a positive stable steady state
Graph 3.1 Convergence of the Endogenous Growth Model.
ɣƙ = ќ/ƙ = s Aƙ
α+η−1
- (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ) = 0
ƙ
ss
=[
sA
n+δ
]
1/(1−α−η)
11
Case 2: (α+δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1)>0 -> the impacts of externalities are very significant
-> Y is not Neo-Classical production function
(the market is not competitive)
-> there is a unique, positive unstable steady state
(saddle point)
Graph 3.2 Divergence of the Endogenous Growth Model.
ɣƙ = ќ/ƙ = s Aƙ
α+η−1
- (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ) = 0
ƙ
ss
=[
sA
n+δ
]
1/(1−α−η)
Case 3: (α+δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1)=0 -> the impacts of externalities are significant, stable and
consistent (𝝶 needs to be a specific value, 𝝶>0)
-> Y is not Neo-Classical production function
-> the market is perfectly competitive (constant return to scale holds)
-> AK model
12
-> there is no steady state
ɣƙ = sA - (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ)
Graph 3.3 AK model of the Endogenous Growth Model.
The AK-type endogenous growth models, (named for the production function Y = AK),
including those of Romer (1986, 1987), Lucas (1988), and Rebelo (1991), suggest that
investment in the broadly defined capital has a positive long-run effect on growth. One
primary concern about the AK model is that it is based on a simple one-sector linear
production function without transitional dynamics. The diminishing returns of physical
capital trade off the increasing return of human capital. An essential property of the AK
model is the global absence of diminishing returns of capital (physical and human capital).
The AK model implies that the broadly defined rate of investment exerts a positive effect
on the long-run rate of growth. Because the constant return to scale holds in AK model,
AK growth model satisfies perfect competitive models.
In the endogenous growth model, the accumulation of human capital encounters the
diminishing returns. AK model (Y=AK) occurs when the increasing return of human capital
trades off the diminishing return of physical capital. AK model exhibits constant returns to
scale in the accumulated factors of production, so the market is competitive; this model
can generate perpetual (permanent) growth without the assumption of exogenous shifts
in the production function.
Case 1 and case 2 indicates the steady state exists when the annual growth of capital per
capita is equal to zero (ɣƙ =0). Graph 2.5, Graph 3.1 and Graph3.2 indicate there are
intercept shifts in Y-axis of scatter plots when the annual growth of capital per capita is
equal to zero (ɣƙ =0). In economic theory, the intercept shift is equal to population growth
13
rate plus the depreciation rate of capital. The steady-state level of capital per capita (ƙss
=
[
sA
n+δ
]
1/(1−α−η)
) is equal to the function of all exogenous parameters (saving rate, constant
technology, population growth rate and depreciation rate of capital). The economic model
of endogenous growth is easy to demonstrate in the discussion. However, how to specify
the econometric model of endogenous growth for application is the major topic of this
paper.
3.4 Econometric Model
Econometric modeling in this paper would demonstrate how to find the capital per capita
at steady state and the rate of convergence for selected countries. Graph 2.5 indicates
there are intercept shifts in Y-axis when the annual growth rates of capital per capita for
selected countries are equal to zero (ɣƙ =0). In an economic model, the intercept shifts in
Y-axis is equal to population growth rate plus depreciation rate of capital. For India and
Indonesia, population growth rates decline dynamically within the sample size (1961 to
2016). For developed countries (Japan, U.S, and France), population growth rates keep as
low constant rates. Depreciation rate should include the aggregate impacts of physical
capital and human capital. However, it is not difficult to find the precise depreciation rates
of all selected countries. Population growth rates and depreciation rates change
dynamically. We are not able to calculate the capital per capita at the steady state and
find out the rate of convergence by using algebra.
In econometric modeling, the intercept shifts in Y-axis come from the aggregate impact of
exogenous parameters such as population growth rate and depreciation rate of capital. In
econometric modeling, the shifts of intercept on Y-axis of scatter plots could be
incorporated in the constant term of the regression model if the aggregate impact of
exogenous shock generates recursive activities with endogenous variables. If the
aggregate effect of the exogenous shock generates a constant impact on annual growth
rate per capita, we should transform the dependent variable as the annual growth rate of
GDP per capita minus average of the annual growth rate of GDP per capita. There are two
steps for econometric modeling of endogenous growth. In the first step, we have to
specify the models for all selected countries by using OLS methodology to find the GDP
per capita at the steady state. We also have to do Granger co-integration test for all
models. After we obtain the capital per capita at the steady state, we would pursue the
second step to find the rates of convergence.
3.4.1 Step One
14
We regress the annual growth rates of GDP per capita on the GDP per capita by using OLS
methodology and then test the co-integration relationship for all models. Graph 2.4
demonstrates all selected countries experienced the impacts of exogenous shocks from
the invention of new technology, governmental policy changes and financial crises within
the sample period. Although the innovation technology is one time shock and generates
consistent externality of the economy. The economy still experiences other shocks
dynamically. We have to impose the impulse indicators to capture the hit-and-run impacts
from the exogenous shocks and stabilize the parameters. Hendry (2005) states impulse
indicators simplify the dummy variables and stabilize parameters in the face of exogenous
shocks to avoid the misspecification of the model.
ɣƙ = ќ/ƙ = s Aƙα+η−1
- (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ) --------Equation 3.1
ɣƙ = C +δ)·ƙ = s βƙ +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation 3.2
ɣƙ = C +δ)·ƙ = s βƙ +δ)·ƙ = s ϵ -------Equation 3.3
ɣ= ɣƙ - Ʀ = C +δ)·ƙ = s βƙ +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation 3.4
ɣ=ɣƙ - Ʀ = C +δ)·ƙ = s βƙ +δ)·ƙ = s ϵ --------Equation3.5
ɣƙ: the annual growth rate of capital per capita
C: constant term (intercept)
ɸ: impulse indicators to capture hit-and-run impacts of exogenous shocks
Ԑ: error term of the estimated equation of annual growth rate of GDP per capita; Ԑ has to
be white noise
ϵ: error term of co-integration equation; ϵ has to be stationary
Ʀ: an average of the annual growth rate of GDP per capita
The economic model demonstrates the annual growth rate of capital per capita (ɣƙ) in
Equation 3.1, and then we specify the econometric model as Equation 3.2 that shows the
econometric model to estimate the endogenous growth model for Japan, India, and, U.S.
The intercept of Equation 3.2 incorporates the shift of the annual growth rate of capital
per capita in Graph 2.5.
Equation 3.2 provides stable and efficient parameters with white noise error terms to
demonstrate the economic interaction between the annual growth rate of GDP per capita
and GDP per capita. The significant impulse indicators mean the state of the economy is
15
deviating from the steady state in the face of impacts of exogenous shocks. Equation 3.3
demonstrates the co-integration equation (steady state) between the annual growth rate
of GDP per capita and GDP per capita. The definition of co-integration is that the
endogenous variables are not necessary to be stationary but the first differences of
endogenous variables have to be stationary, and the error term of the co-integration
equation has to be stationary. We applied Augmented Dickey-Fuller test to test for the
stationarity of endogenous variables, and the results are demonstrated in (Table4.1, Table
4.2, Table4.3, Table4.4, and Table4.5). The co-integration of endogenous variables
indicates the existence of the stable steady state of endogenous variables. However,
without the impulse indicators, the parameter of co-integration equation is not stable and
efficient enough to interpret the economic interaction of endogenous variables. The
significant impulse indicators of Equation 3.2 and Equation 3.4 demonstrate the current
economy is converging to steady state with stable growth rate if co-integration
relationship holds between endogenous variables; otherwise, the economy will diverge to
a saddle point (unstable steady state).
Equation 3.4 demonstrates the econometric model to estimate the endogenous growth
model for France. Equation 3.5 demonstrates the co-integration equation of endogenous
growth model of France. The aggregate impacts of exogenous parameters of France
approach a fixed constant. Thus, the constant term of an econometric model is not able to
incorporate the aggregate effects of exogenous parameters. Graph 2.5 demonstrates the
intercept shift of annual growth of GDP per capita of France is close to the average annual
growth of GDP per capita of France. The transformed annual growth rate of France should
be the annual growth rate of GDP per capita minus the average of the annual growth rate
of GDP per capita of France (2.14%).
The regression results of Equation 3.2 and Equation 3.4 demonstrate the economic
interaction between the annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita. ɣƙ is
equal to zero at steady state so we can obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady state
based on the regression results. We will demonstrate the results in Section 4 (Empirical
Results). As long as we obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady state, we can pursue
to the second step to specify the econometric model for the rate of convergence for the
selected countries.
3.4.2 Step Two
We specify the econometric model of the rate of convergence based on the paper of
Mankiw (1995). The model is specified as follows:
16
ќ = λ· (ƙ - ƙss
) +δ)·ƙ = s e-------Equation3.6
ќ: the first difference of GDP per capita; ƙss
: GDP per capita at steady state
e: the error term of estimation equation of rate of convergence; e has to be white noise
We have obtained the optimal GDP per capita at steady state in the first step, and then we
could specify a model for the rate of convergence as Equation 3.6. Equation 3.6
demonstrates the econometric model to estimate the rates of convergence for all selected
countries. λ is the convergence rate of GDP per capita. λ measures how quickly the
economy approach to the steady state.
4. Empirical Results
The previous section demonstrates the framework of econometric models for endogenous
growth. However, this section displays all results of the econometric models and explains
the results in detail. According to the framework of econometric models in Section 3, we
demonstrate the empirical results in two steps. The first step would describe how to
obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady state for all well-specified models and also
demonstrate the importance of co-integration tests for all models. The second step would
apply the optimal GDP per capita at steady states to specify the models for rates of
convergence.
4.1 The First Step
The first step would demonstrate how to obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady
states, and we also found the results of co-integration tests in relation to convergence,
which means the results of co-integration tests would support the models that converge
to a stable steady state. If the co-integration relation does not hold between endogenous
variables, the model should diverge to an unstable steady state (saddle point).
ɣJapan = 4.51394 -0.00015671·JAPANGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation4.1
ɣIndia = -1.97814 +δ)·ƙ = s 0.00241· INDIAGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation4.2
ɣUS = 2.50773 - 0.00007282 · USGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation4.3
ɣFRANCE = 3.4563 - 0.00011781· FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation4.4
ɣFRANCE = annual growth rate of GDP per capita of France - GDP per capita of France
(2.14%)
ɣFRANCE: the transformed annual growth rate of GDP per capita of France
17
ɸ: impulse indicators
The above equations demonstrate stable and efficient parameters to interpret economic
interactions between endogenous variables at steady states for selected countries,
although the current economic states are approaching to steady states. The error terms of
Equation4.1, Equation4.2, Equation4.3, and Equation4.4 are white noise, and the detail
regression results are demonstrated elaborately in Appendix. The results demonstrate
negative relationships between annual growth rates of GDP per capita and GDP per capita
for Japan, US, and France, which means the economies of Japan, US and France would
converge to stable steady states. The regression results show the positive relationship
between Indian annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita, which indicates
that the economy of India would diverge to an unstable steady state (saddle point). The
regression results are consistent with the scatter plot results of Graph 2.5.
At steady states, the expected values of annual growth rates of GDP per capita of all
selected countries are equal to zero without impulse indicators (ɸ). Thus, we obtain the
following results with stable and efficient parameters:
0 = 4.51394 - 0.00015671·JAPANGDPPERCAPITAss
-> JAPANGDPPERCAPITAss
= 28804.42
0 = -1.97814 +δ)·ƙ = s 0.00241· INDIAGDPPERCAPITAss
-> INDIAGDPPERCAPITAss
= 820.8
0 = 2.50773 - 0.00007282 · USGDPPERCAPITAss
-> USGDPPERCAPITAss
= 34437.38
0 = 2.50773 - 0.00007282· FRANCEGDPPERCAPITAss
-> FRANCEGDPPERCAPITAss
=29337.92
4.1.1 Co-integration Results
The definition of co-integration states the endogenous variables are not necessary to be
stationary1
(Table 4.2, Table 4.3). But the first differences of endogenous variables2
(Table
1
Table 4.2 demonstrates annual growth rate of Japan is almost stationary; annual growth rates of GDP per
capita for other selected countries are stationary. Table 4.3 demonstrates GDP per capita for selected
countries are not stationary (P-value > 5%) by using Augmented Dickey-Fuller test.
18
4.4, Table 4.5) are stationary, and the error terms of co-integration equations are
stationary (Table 4.1). The co-integration equations are demonstrated as followings:
ɣJapan = 9.37562 - 0.00019393·JAPANGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s e-------Equation4.5
ɣIndia = 0.6191 +δ)·ƙ = s 0.00401· INDIAGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = se-------Equation4.6
ɣUS = 4.06853 - 0.00005759· USGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s e -------Equation4.7
ɣFRANCE = 4.3147 - 0.0001423· FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = se-------Equation4.8
ɣFRANCE = annual growth of GDP per capita of France - GDP per capita of France (2.14%)
e: the error terms of co-integration equations
Table 4.1 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for Residuals
1
2
3
4
5 <.0001 <.0001 0.9999 <.0001
P-Value
Augmented Dickey-FullerUnit Root Tests for the Residuals ofCo-integration Equation (Ho: Nonstationary )
<.0001 0.0001 0.0001 <.0001
<.0001 0.0001 0.0001 <.0001
<.0001 <.0001 <.0001 <.0001
<.0001 <.0001 0.0001 <.0001
Lags
Japan (Zero Mean) India (Zero Mean) US (Zero Mean) France (Zero Mean)
Table 4.2 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for the Annual Growth Rates of GDP per Capita
1
2
3
4
5
P-Value
AugmentedDickey-FullerUnitRootTests forAnnualGrowthRate PerCapita( Ho: Nonstationary)
0.2202 0.4773 0.0004 0.0001
0.3451 0.2071 0.0004 0.0001
0.1479 0.0235 0.0005 <.0001
0.0517 0.0167 0.0005 <.0001
0.0042 0.0005 0.0005 <.0001
Lags
Japan(Single Mean) India(Single Mean) US(Single Mean) France (Trend)
Table 4.3 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for GDP per Capita
2
Table 4.5 demonstrates the first differences of GDP per capita for Japan, U.S., and France are stationary but
not India.
19
1
2
3
4
5
P-Value
AugmentedDickey-FullerUnit RootTests forGDP PerCapita( Ho: Nonstationary)
0.8726 0.9999 0.0036 0.9741
0.9191 0.9999 0.1415 0.9399
0.9413 0.9999 0.1586 0.9276
0.9536 0.9999 0.1126 0.9622
0.9378 0.9999 0.0903 0.9042
Lags
Japan(Trend) India (Trend) US(Trend) France (Trend)
Table 4.4 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for the First Difference of the Annual Growth
Rates of GDP per Capita
1
2
3
4
5
P-Value
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Unit Root Tests forthe First Difference ofAnnual Growth Rate PerCapita (Ho: Nonstationary )
0.99990.9999 0.9999 0.9999
0.9999
0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999
0.9999 0.9999 0.9999
0.0001
0.9999 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001
0.0001 0.0001 0.0001
Lags
Japan (Zero Mean) India (Zero Mean) US (Zero Mean) France (Zero Mean)
Table 4.5 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for the First Difference of GDP per Capita
1
2
3
4
5 0.014
P-Value
AugmentedDickey-FullerUnitRootTests forthe FirstDifference ofGDPPerCapita(Ho:Nonstationary)
0.0087 0.9972 0.0001
0.0004
0.003 0.9962 0.0001 0.0004
0.0004 0.9933 0.0001
0.0005
0.0005 0.9816 0.0005 0.0005
0.0005 0.6007 0.0005
Lags
Japan(Single Mean) India(Single Mean) US(Single Mean) France (Single Mean)
The results of co-integration test demonstrate the co-integration relationships hold for the
endogenous models of Japan, US, and France; however, the co-integration relationship
does not hold for the endogenous model of India. The co-integration relationship of
endogenous variables ensures the models would converge to stable steady states. The co-
integration relationship does not hold for the model of India. The model of India diverges
to an unstable steady state (saddle point). Thus, the co-integration ensures the stability of
endogenous variables.
Although the co-integration ensures the stability of endogenous variables to approach to a
stable steady state, the parameters of co-integration equation are not stable and efficient
because the error terms of co-integration equations are not white noise. The parameters
20
of co-integration equations are not able to interpret economic interactions of endogenous
variables at steady states. Thus, we have to apply the parameters of Equarion4.1,
Equation4.2, Equation4.3, and Equation4.4 to interpret the economic activities at steady
states and then obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady states for all selected
countries.
4.2 The Second Step
Equation 3.6 demonstrates the framework of the rate of convergence3
. After we obtain
the optimal value of GDP per capita at steady state, we can estimate the rate of
convergence as followings:
DJAPANGDPPERCAPITA = λ · (JAPAGDPPERCAPITA - JAPANGDPPERCAPITAss
) +δ)·ƙ = s e---
Equation4.9
DINDIAGDPPERCAPITA =λ· (INDIAGDPPERCAPITA - INDIAGDPPERCAPITAss
) +δ)·ƙ = s e---
Equation4.10
DUSGDPPERCAPITA = λ· (USGDPPERCAPITA - USGDPPERCAPITAss
) +δ)·ƙ = s e-------
Equation4.11
DFGDPPERCAPITA =λ· (FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA-FRANCEGDPPERCAPITAss
) +δ)·ƙ = s e----
Equation4.12
Note: JAPANGDPPERCAPITAss
=28804.42, INDIAGDPPERCAPITAss
=820.8,
USGDPPERCAPITAss
=34437.38, FRANCEGDPPERCAPITAss
=29337.92
DJAPANGDPPERCAPITA: the first difference of GDP per capita of Japan
DINDIAGDPPERCAPITA: the first difference of GDP per capita of India
DUSGDPPERCAPITA: the first difference of GDP per capita of US
DFGDPPERCAPITA: the first difference of GDP per capita of France
Table4.6 Regression Results for GDP per Capita at the Steady States and the Rate of
Convergence for Selected Countries
3
Table4.6 demonstrates the regression results for GDP per capita at steady states and the rates of
convergence for all selected countries.
21
COUNTRY JAPAN INDIA US FRANCE
GDP at Steady State 28804.42 820.8 34437.38 29337.92
The Rate of Convergence -1.54% 5.95% -0.57% -2.69%
Graph 2.5 provides the simple scatter plots between annual growth rates of GDP per
capita and GDP per capita, which provides the outline to judge the convergence or
divergence of the economies. The empirical results provide the overall results of the test
of convergence, which include how to obtain the optimal GDP per capita ate steady states,
judge if the models would converge to a stable steady state or diverge to a saddle point,
and estimate the rate of convergence for all selected countries. The economies of Japan,
US, and France converge to stable steady states. The impacts of the invention of new
technology are insignificant. The markets of these countries are perfectly competitive. The
rate of convergence of these countries is lower than the rate of convergence of
developing countries. The economies of these countries are consistent with Case 1 of
economic model in Section 3. The economy of India would diverge to an unstable steady
state (saddle point), and the impacts of the invention of technology would be significant.
The market of Indian is a monopoly with market power. The rate of convergence of India
is higher than the rate of convergence of other developed countries (Japan, US, and
France). The economy of India is consistent with Case 2 of the economic model in Section
3.
5. A Brief Discussion of the AK Model
Economists have been discussing the existence of AK model of endogenous growth for
several decades. The AK model could occur when the diminishing return rate of physical
capital trade off the increasing return rate of human capital. The accumulation of human
capital encounters the diminishing returns. The market is perfectly competitive because
AK model exhibits constant returns to scale in the accumulated factors of production; this
model can generate perpetual (permanent) growth without the assumption of exogenous
shifts in the production function. We will discuss AK model of endogenous growth by using
the economy of Indonesia.
Graph 5.1 shows the economy of Indonesia would barely diverge to an unstable steady
state, while Graph 5.2 illustrates that the economy of Indonesia has no steady state in the
22
aggregate level of the annual growth rate of GDP in relation to GDP per capita. The
aggregate level of the annual growth rate of GDP in relation to GDP per capita would
demonstrate the economy of Indonesia would approach to AK model, which can generate
perpetual (permanent) growth without the assumption of exogenous shifts in the
production function. Because there is no steady state in AK models, we are not able to
apply econometric model to obtain the GDP at the steady state and the rate of
convergence to steady state.
Graph 5.1 Test for Convergence of Indonesia (1)
Graph 5.2 Test for Convergence of Indonesia (2)
Looking at the annual growth of Indonesia’s GDP, we notice that the global financial crisis
(2008) did not affect Indonesia severely (Graph 5.3). The annual growth of aggregate GDP
of Indonesia and annual growth of GDP per capita have the same movement. The impacts
of Asian financial crisis (1997) hit the economy of Indonesia seriously.
23
Graph 5.3 Annual Growth of GDP of Indonesia
We discuss AK model in this section. We believe the AK model and Indonesia should be a
topic for further research papers. Indonesia and other Asian countries suffer from Asian
financial crisis severely. However, Indonesia got better recovery than other countries. AK
model can generate perpetual (permanent) growth without the assumption of exogenous
shifts in the production function, which might assist Indonesia to get out of the recession
from Asian financial crisis efficiently. The market of Indonesia should turn from monopoly
to perfect competition. However, there is no transitional dynamic and steady state for AK
model at current economic state for Indonesia. As long as Indonesia accumulate sufficient
physical capital and human capital, GDP per capita of Indonesia would obtain significantly
improved, the impacts of externality would not be significant. The economy of Indonesia
might converge to stable steady state as well as the neo-classical model.
6. Conclusion
In the history, there are industrial revolutions with the new invention of technologies.
New technology changes our lives and then becomes part of our lives. We could say new
technology generates one-time shock impacts of the economy and we assume the effects
24
of new technology are exogenous and constant, which are externalities of the economy.
The new technology generates more physical capital and human capital in the economy.
The new technology creates different impacts for developed countries and developing
countries. For developed countries, the physical capital and human capital of developed
are a lot higher than developing countries. Developing countries have small capital stocks.
Although developed countries have higher human capital stocks, the increasing return of
human capital of developed nations is not as high as emerging ones. The marginal
production of the capital of developing countries is higher than developed countries,
which makes capital flows from developed countries to developing countries. Thus, the
growth rates of developing countries are higher than developed countries.
Romer (1986) proposed new endogenous growth model with externality to demonstrate
the impacts of new technology on the economy. For developed countries (Japan, US, and
France), the effects of externalities are insignificant; the economies are close to neo-
classical economies and converge to stable steady states. The markets are perfectly
competitive. For developing countries, the impacts of externalities are significant. The
economies diverge to an unstable steady state (saddle point) with imperfect completive
markets, or the economies could have no steady state with the perfectly competitive
market (AK model). If the increasing return of human capital dominates the decreasing
return of physical capital, the economy of developing country will diverge to a saddle
point. If the increasing returns of human capital trade-off the decreasing return of
physical capital, the economy of developing country would approach AK model. This paper
confirms when the co-integration relation holds between the annual growth rate of GDP
per capita and GDP per capita; the economy would converge to a steady state; if it does
not hold, the economy will diverge to a saddle point. This paper demonstrates the results
of convergence test including how to obtain GDP per capita and convergence rates at
steady states for selected countries in detail and also discuss the economy of Indonesia
could be the case of AK model. We accomplish our work to dedicate the contribution of
economists to the endogenous growth model.
25
Appendix:
India
Step 1: Find the optimal GDP per capita at the steady state of India.
Dependent variable is annual growth rate of GDP per capita of India.
Root MSE 0.64386 R-Square 0.9638
Dependent Mean 3.3379 Adj R-Sq 0.9602
CoeffVar 19.28934
Parameter Standard
Estimate Error Standard
Error
Intercept 1 -1.97814 0.27052 -7.31 <.0001 0.20896 -9.47 <.0001 0
INDIAGDPPERCAPITA 1 0.00241 0.00021631 11.15 <.0001 0.00018742 12.87 <.0001 1.09086
IDUM1 1 3.73002 0.29652 12.58 <.0001 0.21669 17.21 <.0001 1.29906
IDUM2 1 -1.55698 0.18408 -8.46 <.0001 0.16105 -9.67 <.0001 1.12099
IDUM3 1 2.73219 0.18883 14.47 <.0001 0.17058 16.02 <.0001 1.19806
IDUM4 1 -5.18208 0.49409 -10.49 <.0001 0.3357 -15.44 <.0001 1.1357
Variable t Value Pr > |t|
Parameter Estimates for Model of India
Heteroscedasticity Consistent
DF t Value Pr > |t|
Variance
Inflation
The steady state INDIAGDPPERCAPITA= (1.97814/0.00241)= 820.8
Durbin-Watson D 1.932
Number of Observations 56
1st Order Autocorrelation 0.015
Parameter Symbol Estimate
Mean Mu 0
Std Dev Sigma 0.613896
Test
Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.09513858 Pr > D >0.150
Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.06131651 Pr > W-Sq >0.250
Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.40615653 Pr > A-Sq >0.250
p ValueStatistic
Parameters for Normal Distribution
Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution
Step 2: Find the stable growth rate of GDP per capita of India
26
Root MSE 4.48661 R-Square 0.9831
Dependent Mean 28.22067 Adj R-Sq 0.9814
CoeffVar 15.89832
Parameter Standard
Estimate Error Standard
Error
Intercept 1 20.91507 1.46528 14.27 <.0001 1.55237 13.47 <.0001 0
INDIASS 1 0.0595 0.00159 37.5 <.0001 0.00167 35.69 <.0001 1.19146
RIDUM1 1 15.07383 1.71336 8.8 <.0001 1.87688 8.03 <.0001 1.36819
RIDUM2 1 -8.7521 1.27478 -6.87 <.0001 1.18793 -7.37 <.0001 1.09205
RIDUM3 1 10.32725 1.51605 6.81 <.0001 1.09638 9.42 <.0001 1.56945
RIDUM4 1 21.56937 2.26909 9.51 <.0001 2.41325 8.94 <.0001 1.36726
Parameter Estimates for Model of India
Variance
InflationVariable DF t Value Pr > |t|
Heteroscedasticity Consistent
t Value Pr > |t|
The stable growth rate diverging to a saddle point (unstable steady state) of India is
0.0595.
Durbin-Watson D 1.903
Number of Observations 55
1st Order Autocorrelation 0.02
Parameter Symbol Estimate
Mean Mu 0
Std Dev Sigma 4.273854
Test
Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.071525 Pr > D >0.150
Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.043183 Pr > W-Sq >0.250
Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.403768 Pr > A-Sq >0.250
Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution
Parameters for Normal Distribution
Statistic p Value
US:
Step 1: Find the optimal GDP percapita at the steady state of US.
Dependent variable is annual growth rate of GDP per capita of US.
Root MSE 0.57928 R-Square 0.9223
Dependent Mean 2.03883 Adj R-Sq 0.9162
CoeffVar 28.41235
27
Parameter Standard
Estimate Error Standard
Error
Intercept 1 2.50773 0.30731 8.16 <.0001 0.4441 5.65 <.0001 0
USGDPPERCAPITA 1 -0.00007282 7.5E-06 -9.72 <.0001 7.88E-06 -9.24 <.0001 1.08544
UDUM1 1 3.14008 0.21141 14.85 <.0001 0.26328 11.93 <.0001 1.17727
UDUM2 1 -1.76926 0.17445 -10.14 <.0001 0.1846 -9.58 <.0001 1.22916
UDUM3 1 2.30261 0.20665 11.14 <.0001 0.15063 15.29 <.0001 1.39756
Variable DF t Value Pr > |t|
Heteroscedasticity Consistent
t Value Pr > |t|
Parameter Estimates for Model of US
Variance
Inflation
The steady state USGDPPERCAPITA= (2.50773/0.00007282) =34437.37984
Durbin-Watson D 1.987
Number of Observations 56
1st Order Autocorrelation -0.026
Parameter Symbol Estimate
Mean Mu 0
Std Dev Sigma 0.557818
Test
Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.09084667 Pr > D >0.150
Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.06583806 Pr > W-Sq >0.250
Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.41040077 Pr > A-Sq >0.250
Statistic p Value
Parameters for Normal Distribution
Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution
Step 2: Find the stable growth rate of GDP per capita of US
Root MSE 108.2639 R-Square 0.9736
Dependent Mean 637.3217 Adj R-Sq 0.9709
CoeffVar 16.98732
Parameter Standard
Estimate Error Standard
Error
Intercept 1 8.9137 44.93412 0.2 0.8436 49.00046 0.18 0.8564 0
USSS 1 -0.00572 0.0014 -4.09 0.0002 0.00132 -4.32 <.0001 1.02649
RUDUM1 1 843.08977 44.24133 19.06 <.0001 42.2722 19.94 <.0001 1.1416
RUDUM2 1 -394.9506 30.44639 -12.97 <.0001 34.11445 -11.58 <.0001 1.05833
RUDUM3 1 587.84322 33.06683 17.78 <.0001 36.55981 16.08 <.0001 1.12961
RUDUM4 1 -1324.58677 80.92743 -16.37 <.0001 24.4364 -54.21 <.0001 1.07688
Parameter Estimates for Model of US
Variance
Inflation
Variable DF t Value Pr > |t|
Heteroscedasticity Consistent
t Value Pr > |t|
The stable growth rate converging to a stable steady state of US is 0.00572.
28
Durbin-Watson D 1.994
Number of Observations 55
1st Order Autocorrelation -0.037
Parameter Symbol Estimate
Mean Mu 0
Std Dev Sigma 103.1299
Test
Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.078349 Pr > D >0.150
Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.060356 Pr > W-Sq >0.250
Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.463017 Pr > A-Sq >0.250
Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution
Parameters for Normal Distribution
Statistic p Value
France:
Step 1: Find the optimal GDP percapita at the steady state of France.
Dependent variable is annual growth rate of GDP per capita of France.
Root MSE 0.39871 R-Square 0.9591
Dependent Mean -0.00459 Adj R-Sq 0.9559
CoeffVar -8677.73562
Parameter Standard
Estimate Error Standard
Error
Intercept 1 3.4563 0.20401 16.94 <.0001 0.17738 19.49 <.0001 0
FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA 1 -0.00011781 0.00000627 -18.8 <.0001 0.00000541 -21.77 <.0001 1.08382
FDUM1 1 1.82828 0.11031 16.57 <.0001 0.10407 17.57 <.0001 1.04967
FDUM2 1 -0.99143 0.12043 -8.23 <.0001 0.09472 -10.47 <.0001 1.25112
FDUM3 1 -2.72724 0.20186 -13.51 <.0001 0.2833 -9.63 <.0001 1.16718
Variance
Inflation
ParameterEstimates forModel of France
Variable DF tValue Pr>|t|
HeteroscedasticityConsistent
tValue Pr>|t|
The steady state FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA= (3.4563/0.00011781)=29337.91698
Durbin-Watson D 2.07
Number of Observations 56
1st Order Autocorrelation -0.037
Parameter Symbol Estimate
Mean Mu 0
Std Dev Sigma 0.383937
Test
Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.07460072 Pr > D >0.150
Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.02673638 Pr > W-Sq >0.250
Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.24623075 Pr > A-Sq >0.250
Statistic p Value
Parameters for Normal Distribution
Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution
Step 2: Find the stable growth rate of GDP per capita of France
29
Root MSE 108.33758 R-Square 0.9503
Dependent Mean 517.97885 Adj R-Sq 0.9452
CoeffVar 20.91544
Parameter Standard
Estimate Error Standard
Error
Intercept 1 446.15411 25.24861 17.67 <.0001 21.81685 20.45 <.0001 0
FRANCESS 1 -0.02693 0.00178 -15.09 <.0001 0.00178 -15.14 <.0001 1.11228
RFDUM1 1 421.67458 33.50593 12.59 <.0001 30.24962 13.94 <.0001 1.31475
RFDUM2 1 -218.67875 30.16153 -7.25 <.0001 23.57055 -9.28 <.0001 1.06539
RFDUM3 1 386.15133 44.73396 8.63 <.0001 38.85144 9.94 <.0001 1.28338
RFDUM4 1 -1015.97424 66.93262 -15.18 <.0001 144.3399 -7.04 <.0001 1.08263
Parameter Estimates for Model of France
Variance
Inflation
Variable DF t Value Pr > |t|
Heteroscedasticity Consistent
t Value Pr > |t|
The stable growth rate converging to a stable steady state of France is 0.02693.
Durbin-Watson D 1.959
Number of Observations 55
1st Order Autocorrelation 0
Parameter Symbol Estimate
Mean Mu 0
Std Dev Sigma 103.2001
Test
Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.06989321 Pr > D >0.150
Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.03544269 Pr > W-Sq >0.250
Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.27073916 Pr > A-Sq >0.250
Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution
Parameters for Normal Distribution
Statistic p Value
Japan:
Step 1: Find the optimal GDP percapita of Japan at the steady state.
Dependent variable is annual growth rate of GDP per capita of Japan.
Root MSE 0.79714 R-Square 0.9543
Dependent Mean 3.16207 Adj R-Sq 0.9507
CoeffVar 25.20954
30
Intercept 1 4.51394 0.44526 10.14 <.0001 0.55259 8.17 <.0001 0
JGDPPERCAPITA 1 -0.00015671 0.0000098 -15.99 <.0001 0.00000826 -18.97 <.0001 1.19319
JDUM1 1 4.44399 0.33213 13.38 <.0001 0.4576 9.71 <.0001 1.06331
JDUM2 1 -2.49876 0.23595 -10.59 <.0001 0.22325 -11.19 <.0001 1.21253
JDUM3 1 5.01378 0.29817 16.82 <.0001 0.29856 16.79 <.0001 1.39664
Heteroscedasticity Consistent
t Value Pr >|t|
Variance
Inflation
Standard ERROR
Standard ERROR
Variable t Value Pr >|t|Parameter ERROR
Parameter Estimates for Model of Japan
DF
The steady state JGDPPERCAPITA= (4.51394/0.00015671)=28804.4158
Durbin-Watson D 2.017
Number of Observations 56
1st Order Autocorrelation -0.022
Parameter Symbol Estimate
Mean Mu 0
Std Dev Sigma 0.767609
Test
Shapiro-Wilk W 0.988035 Pr < W 0.8513
Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.068691 Pr > D >0.1500
Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.044715 Pr > W-Sq >0.2500
Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.255122 Pr > A-Sq >0.2500
Tests for Normality
Statistic p Value
Parameters for Normal Distribution
Step 2: Find the stable growth rate of GDP per capita of Japan
Root MSE 183.94301 R-Square 0.9485
Dependent Mean 694.75365 Adj R-Sq 0.9432
CoeffVar 26.476
Parameter Standard
Estimate Error Standard
Error
Intercept 1 -12.23152 80.81876 -0.15 0.8803 80.31201 -0.15 0.8796 0
JAPANSS 1 -0.01536 0.00219 -7.01 <.0001 0.00181 -8.48 <.0001 1.04418
RJDUM1 1 984.55057 81.58071 12.07 <.0001 79.77229 12.34 <.0001 1.20167
RJDUM2 1 -551.97999 50.8594 -10.85 <.0001 50.03882 -11.03 <.0001 1.04806
RJDUM3 1 952.16883 60.33682 15.78 <.0001 59.27475 16.06 <.0001 1.06814
RJDUM4 1 -1663.35318 201.397 -8.26 <.0001 81.10363 -20.51 <.0001 1.17698
Parameter Estimates for Model of Japan
Variance
Inflation
Variable DF t Value Pr > |t|
Heteroscedasticity Consistent
t Value Pr > |t|
The stable growth rate converging to a stable steady state of Japan is 0.01536.
31
Durbin-Watson D 1.967
Number of Observations 55
1st Order Autocorrelation 0.009
Parameter Symbol Estimate
Mean Mu 0
Std Dev Sigma 175.2203
Test
Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.046394 Pr > D >0.150
Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.013809 Pr > W-Sq >0.250
Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.120663 Pr > A-Sq >0.250
Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution
Parameters for Normal Distribution
Statistic p Value
Compliance with Ethical Standards:
Conflict of Interest:
I _____KELLY YIYU LIN_______________- as corresponding author, certify that all authors
contributed significantly to the manuscript and no other authors were involved and were not part
of the team that created this manuscript. All used data are correct and results are based on
authors’ calculations. Author(s) is/are solely responsible for the entire content and results of the
paper published in the journal.
I certify that no part of this manuscript has been published before or is not under consideration for
publication elsewhere.
I certified that this manuscript was used as working paper only.
Title of the
manuscript
The Importance of Parameter Constancy for Endogenous
Growth with Externality
Authors’ name / affiliation / official email address Percentage
of
contributio
n
1. KELLY YIYU LIN 70%
2.WENTI DU 30%
32
Ethical Approval: This article does not contain any study
References
Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1990). A model of growth through creative destruction.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Benhabib, J., & Jovanovic, B. (1989). Externalities and Growth Accounting. Working Paper
No. 3190.
Engle, R. F. & Granger, C. W. J. (1987). Co-integration and error correction:
Representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica, 55(2), 251–276.
Ertur, C., & Koch, W. (2007). Growth, technological interdependence and spatial
externalities: theory and evidence. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22(6), 1033-1062.
Granger, C. (1981). Some properties of time series data and their use in econometric
model specification. Journal of Econometrics, 16(1), 121-130.
Hendry, David.F & Santos, Carlos (2005), Regression Models with Data-Based Indicators
Variables. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Volume 67, Issue 5, 571-595.
Li, D. (2002). Is the AK model still alive? The long-run relation between growth and
investment re-examined. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne
d`Economique, 35(1), 92-114.
Mankiw, N. G. (1995). The Growth of Nations. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1,
275-326.
33
Rivera-Batiz, L., & Romer, P. (1991). Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2), 531-555.
Robert J. Barro and Xavier I. Sala-i-Martin, Economic Growth, Second Edition, The MIT
Press, October 2003.
Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. Journal of Political
Economy, 94(5), 1002-1037.
Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of Political Economy,
98(5), S71-S102.
Romer, P. M. (1994). The Origins of Endogenous Growth. The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 8(1), 3-22.
34

More Related Content

PDF
Business mentoring and domestic entrepreneurship in nigeria’s
PDF
4.[29 38]human capital development and economic growth in nigeria
PDF
unemployment, Abdulkadir
PDF
PDF
Human capital development in technical vocational education (tve) for sustain...
PDF
Government assisted programs and unemployment reduction in developing economi...
PDF
Human capital development and economic growth in nigeria
PDF
11.human capital development and economic growth in nigeria
Business mentoring and domestic entrepreneurship in nigeria’s
4.[29 38]human capital development and economic growth in nigeria
unemployment, Abdulkadir
Human capital development in technical vocational education (tve) for sustain...
Government assisted programs and unemployment reduction in developing economi...
Human capital development and economic growth in nigeria
11.human capital development and economic growth in nigeria

What's hot (20)

PDF
Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...
PPTX
My power point
PDF
Descriptive Analysis of Inflation and Unemployment in Indian Econonmy
PDF
Ethiopia-paper
PDF
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR RURAL EMPLOYMENT GENERATION IN INDIA
PDF
The impact of government agricultural expenditure on economic growth in zimbabwe
PDF
2 adaramola anthony olugbenga 9-19
PDF
Government Expenditure and Economic Growth in Nigeria, 1981-2013: A Bound Tes...
PDF
Education and economic growth in the mena region some new evidence
PDF
J3108086
PDF
Capital Accumulation and Labour Productivity Growth in Nigeria
PDF
Labour-Entrepreneurship Substitution Mechanism: Determining Growth, Employmen...
PPTX
Unempolyment in india
PDF
Growth determinants of micro and small enterprises evidence from northern et...
PDF
3.[18 28]government expenditure and economic development empirical evidence f...
PDF
Jobless and Wageless Recovery in Nigeria: Matters Arising and Way Forward
PDF
Investment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in Nigeria
PDF
An analysis of the effect of real gross domestic product on unemployment in n...
PDF
Guidence of business environment
Economic growth and social development an empirical study on selected states ...
My power point
Descriptive Analysis of Inflation and Unemployment in Indian Econonmy
Ethiopia-paper
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR RURAL EMPLOYMENT GENERATION IN INDIA
The impact of government agricultural expenditure on economic growth in zimbabwe
2 adaramola anthony olugbenga 9-19
Government Expenditure and Economic Growth in Nigeria, 1981-2013: A Bound Tes...
Education and economic growth in the mena region some new evidence
J3108086
Capital Accumulation and Labour Productivity Growth in Nigeria
Labour-Entrepreneurship Substitution Mechanism: Determining Growth, Employmen...
Unempolyment in india
Growth determinants of micro and small enterprises evidence from northern et...
3.[18 28]government expenditure and economic development empirical evidence f...
Jobless and Wageless Recovery in Nigeria: Matters Arising and Way Forward
Investment in Education Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth in Nigeria
An analysis of the effect of real gross domestic product on unemployment in n...
Guidence of business environment
Ad

Similar to The Importance of Parameter Constancy for Endogenous Growth with Externality (20)

PDF
Analysis of HRD Problems in the Developing Country
PDF
Human capital and development
PDF
A Literature Review Of Human Capital And Economic Growth
DOCX
Economic Development and Growth Glossary
PDF
The Influence of Economic Growth on Poverty, Investment, and Human Developmen...
PDF
An evaluation of_the_relevance_of_the_ak
PPTX
Class-2 Measurment of Economic Development.
PDF
CASE Network E-briefs 4.2013 - When will the global economy return to rapid g...
PDF
Assessment on economic growth of development indicators in asean
PPTX
Chandraketutripathi_world 2050-1
PPTX
Making a Miracle
PPTX
AS Macro: Introduction to Economic Development
PDF
Education Expenditures, Inequality and Economic Growth: Empirical Analysis o...
PDF
Public Expenditure on Education; A Measure for Promoting Economic Development
PDF
International Journal of Humanities and Social Science Invention (IJHSSI)
DOCX
Indicators of Development (Economic, Social and Environmental)
PDF
The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...
DOCX
IntroductionThe physical to human capital proportion is compos.docx
PDF
The role of education in economic development
PDF
Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth in Nigeria “Endogenous Growth Approach”
Analysis of HRD Problems in the Developing Country
Human capital and development
A Literature Review Of Human Capital And Economic Growth
Economic Development and Growth Glossary
The Influence of Economic Growth on Poverty, Investment, and Human Developmen...
An evaluation of_the_relevance_of_the_ak
Class-2 Measurment of Economic Development.
CASE Network E-briefs 4.2013 - When will the global economy return to rapid g...
Assessment on economic growth of development indicators in asean
Chandraketutripathi_world 2050-1
Making a Miracle
AS Macro: Introduction to Economic Development
Education Expenditures, Inequality and Economic Growth: Empirical Analysis o...
Public Expenditure on Education; A Measure for Promoting Economic Development
International Journal of Humanities and Social Science Invention (IJHSSI)
Indicators of Development (Economic, Social and Environmental)
The impact of interest rates on the development of an emerging market empiric...
IntroductionThe physical to human capital proportion is compos.docx
The role of education in economic development
Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth in Nigeria “Endogenous Growth Approach”
Ad

Recently uploaded (20)

PDF
1a In Search of the Numbers ssrn 1488130 Oct 2009.pdf
PDF
financing insitute rbi nabard adb imf world bank insurance and credit gurantee
PPTX
The discussion on the Economic in transportation .pptx
PDF
Understanding University Research Expenditures (1)_compressed.pdf
PPTX
Session 3. Time Value of Money.pptx_finance
PDF
Copia de Minimal 3D Technology Consulting Presentation.pdf
PDF
ssrn-3708.kefbkjbeakjfiuheioufh ioehoih134.pdf
PDF
Circular Flow of Income by Dr. S. Malini
PPTX
Session 11-13. Working Capital Management and Cash Budget.pptx
PDF
Dialnet-DynamicHedgingOfPricesOfNaturalGasInMexico-8788871.pdf
PDF
Mathematical Economics 23lec03slides.pdf
PPTX
Basic Concepts of Economics.pvhjkl;vbjkl;ptx
PDF
HCWM AND HAI FOR BHCM STUDENTS(1).Pdf and ptts
PDF
ECONOMICS AND ENTREPRENEURS LESSONSS AND
PDF
Spending, Allocation Choices, and Aging THROUGH Retirement. Are all of these ...
PDF
CLIMATE CHANGE AS A THREAT MULTIPLIER: ASSESSING ITS IMPACT ON RESOURCE SCARC...
PPT
KPMG FA Benefits Report_FINAL_Jan 27_2010.ppt
PPTX
Antihypertensive_Drugs_Presentation_Poonam_Painkra.pptx
PDF
How to join illuminati agent in Uganda Kampala call 0782561496/0756664682
PDF
illuminati Uganda brotherhood agent in Kampala call 0756664682,0782561496
1a In Search of the Numbers ssrn 1488130 Oct 2009.pdf
financing insitute rbi nabard adb imf world bank insurance and credit gurantee
The discussion on the Economic in transportation .pptx
Understanding University Research Expenditures (1)_compressed.pdf
Session 3. Time Value of Money.pptx_finance
Copia de Minimal 3D Technology Consulting Presentation.pdf
ssrn-3708.kefbkjbeakjfiuheioufh ioehoih134.pdf
Circular Flow of Income by Dr. S. Malini
Session 11-13. Working Capital Management and Cash Budget.pptx
Dialnet-DynamicHedgingOfPricesOfNaturalGasInMexico-8788871.pdf
Mathematical Economics 23lec03slides.pdf
Basic Concepts of Economics.pvhjkl;vbjkl;ptx
HCWM AND HAI FOR BHCM STUDENTS(1).Pdf and ptts
ECONOMICS AND ENTREPRENEURS LESSONSS AND
Spending, Allocation Choices, and Aging THROUGH Retirement. Are all of these ...
CLIMATE CHANGE AS A THREAT MULTIPLIER: ASSESSING ITS IMPACT ON RESOURCE SCARC...
KPMG FA Benefits Report_FINAL_Jan 27_2010.ppt
Antihypertensive_Drugs_Presentation_Poonam_Painkra.pptx
How to join illuminati agent in Uganda Kampala call 0782561496/0756664682
illuminati Uganda brotherhood agent in Kampala call 0756664682,0782561496

The Importance of Parameter Constancy for Endogenous Growth with Externality

  • 1. The Importance of Parameter Constancy for Endogenous Growth with Externality Kelly Yiyu Lin* BMO Financial Group, U.S.A. email:yiyu@msn.com Wenti Du** Akita International University, Japan email:wenti.du@gmail.com Abstract The economic model of endogenous growth has been commonly discussed. It has been specified by econometric models by Robert Barro (1986, 1990, and 1994) and Xavier Sala- i-Martin (2003) but it is challenging to keep parameter constancy in the model. This paper demonstrates how to find the stable growth rate converging to the steady state and the optimal capital level at the steady state with parameter constancy. This paper also finds the economy would converge to a stable steady state when the co-integration holds between annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita. We take an empirical study of selected five countries (Indonesia, India, US, France and Japan) from 1960 to 2016 and specify econometric models of endogenous growth with externality and to test the convergence. JEL Codes: O11, O47 Keywords: externality, production function, endogenous growth, convergence, parameter constancy 1
  • 2. 1. Introduction Technology generates positive externalities and contributes to long-term growth in an economy. The economic model of endogenous growth has been commonly discussed, for example, see Romer (1986, 1990, 1994), Benhabib and Jovanovic (1989), Mankiw (1995); however, it is challenging to keep parameter constancy. In this paper, we take an empirical study of selected countries to specify an econometric model of endogenous growth with externality and to test the convergence. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2003) propose the concepts of β convergence and σ convergence to specify the econometric models for the rate of convergence. However, parameter constancy is the challenge in their model. In order to find the stable growth rate converging to the steady state and the optimal capital level at the steady state, this paper applies impulse indicators to keep parameter constancy in the face of exogenous shocks. The new technology generates one-time shock that affects economies. We assume that such impact of new technology is exogenous and constant, which could be viewed as an externality in an economy. Also, technology innovation contributes to creating more physical capital and human capital in an economy. In the face of exogenous shocks, the significant impulse indicators of the model demonstrate the current economy is converging to a stable steady state if the co-integration relationship holds between endogenous variables; otherwise, the economy will diverge to a saddle point (unstable steady state). Our findings show that technology innovation has a different impact on developed countries (France, Japan, and the U.S.) and developing countries (India and Indonesia). The effect of new technology on developed countries is insignificant, while the impact of new technology on developing countries is shown to be significant. Moreover, our results suggest that the rates of convergence in developed countries are lower than those in developing countries. In particular, among our sample countries, the Indian economy diverges to an unstable steady state, also known as “saddle point” because the co- integration relationship does not hold between annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita. This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 analyzes economies in Indonesia, India, U.S., France and the Japan. Section 3 explains the data we use and specify the econometric model we adopt. Section 4 presents the empirical results. Section 5 discusses the AK model and the case in Indonesia. Section 6 concludes our research. 2
  • 3. 2. An Overview of the relationship between GDP per capita and Human Capital After World War II, the analysis of economic growth became a topic of high priority because of decolonization in Asia. The neo-classical, Solow growth theory (1956) was embraced by economists, which explains long-run economic growth by focusing on physical capital accumulation. However, economic growth could not only rely on physical capital. While the ratio of the growth of physical capital to the growth of human capital exceeds the equilibrium ratio, the rate of economic growth declines. Thus, human capital is the crucial variable for economic growth. The innovation of technology is the critical shock for economic growth. To obtain the best available technology, the economy needs skilled labor force, which leads to thinking about human capital in economic growth. The advances in endogenous growth theory from Paul Romer (1986) have been the ability to formalize this idea. This section provides the economic analysis to precede the research of the endogenous growth model for Indonesia, India, U.S., France and Japan. The main topic of endogenous growth is human capital accumulation. Human capital could produce output in production, and human capital could produce human capital endogenously. GDP per capita is highly co-integrated with human capital index and also the index of physical capital, so GDP per capita can apply as the aggregate impacts of physical capital and human capital in modeling. The human capital and physical capital in developed countries are higher than they are in developing countries. However, the Inada rule indicates the poor economies have small capital stocks, and the marginal product of capital should be high. Thus, capital should have the incentive to flow from rich countries to emerging countries. The poor economies have the tendency to grow more rapidly than rich economies. Human capital accumulation of endogenous growth is caused by the shock of technology. Technology is kind of positive externality of the economy with governmental intervention, and the one-time shock of technology can create the permanent change of the economy. This paper will focus on the endogenous growth with externality and test for the convergence of selected countries. 3
  • 4. Graph 2.1 GDP per Capita and Human Capital Index As shown in Graph 2.1, GDP per capita is co-integrated with Human Capital Index for Indonesia, India, U.S., France and Japan. Because GDP per capita for the selected four 4
  • 5. countries are highly co-integrated with human capital indexes of all selected countries, GDP per capita could be the proxy of human capital. Graph 2.2 Human Capitals Index Moreover, during the period both GDP per Capita and human capitals of developed countries (Japan, U.S, and France) are higher than those of developing countries (India and Indonesia) as shown in Graph 2.2. 5
  • 6. Graph 2.3 Annual Growths of GDP per Capita and Population 6
  • 7. However, as illustrated in Graph 2.3, the annual growth rate of GDP per capita increases when population growth rate decreases for all selected countries from 1961 to 2016. In general, human capital increases when population growth decreases for developed countries (Indonesia, U.S, France and Japan), while India is an exception (Graph 2.4). In the case of India, the human capital increases along with the population growth rate before 1983, but afterward it increases with the decline of population growth rate. Thus, human capital does not have a constant negative relationship with population growth rate. Graph 2.4 the Relationship between Human Capital and Population Growth Rate 7
  • 8. Graph 2.5 Results of Convergence Tests 8
  • 9. Results from conditional convergence test suggest that the long-run growth of Japan, U.S., and France converge to stable steady states (Graph 2.5). However, there are divergences for long-run growth of India, in particular; the economy of India would diverge to an unstable steady state (saddle point). The intercept shift of annual growth of GDP per capita will be explained in detail in the model specification in Section three. The result of conditional convergence test of Indonesia is close to AK model. This paper will discuss the case of Indonesia in section five. 3. Data and Model Specification 3.1 Data The sample size of data is annual data from 1961 to 2016. The data of annual growth of GDP per capita comes from the World Bank database. The data of GDP per capita comes from Federal Reserve's Bank. Constant GDP per capita is selected for gross domestic product divided by midyear population. GDP is the sum of gross value added by all resident producers in the economy plus any product taxes and minus any subsidies not included in the value of the products. 3.2 Model Specification Romer (1986) introduces the externality into the production function. The institution of Romer model indicates that firms increase capital (physical capital and human capital) for new technology, and this creates an externality. The externality is the impact of the invention of technology. People believe the new technology will promote the production significantly, so government encourages firms to invest more physical capital in new technology and skill training to increase the human capital to operate new technology. The technology generates positive externality to capital, so the externality to each firm is determined by GDP per capita (Romer model with Lucas modification). Because GDP per capita is highly co-integrated with human capital and physical capital, GDP per capita should include the impacts of physical capital and human capital. The invention of new technology creates the impacts of the one-time shock of the economy (externality) and causes the permanent change of the economy. From 1961 to 2016, the innovate technology is "computer”. The invention of the computer changes our lives permanently. Government establishes computer courses in schools and also encourages firms to invest more in physical capital and human capital to promote the industries. In economic theory section, we discuss how the impacts of one-time shocks could cause the permanent change of the economy with externalities. In the model 9
  • 10. specification, we will introduce the economic model first and then specify the econometric models to test for convergence to find the optimal level of capital per capita at the steady state and the rate of convergence back to steady state for selected countries. 3.3 Economic Model The theory of endogenous growth demonstrates the concerns of convergence and the perfect competition in aggregate level. Graph 2.5 reflects the sample data (1961 to 2016) supports the convergence for the economies of Japan, U.S and France, and the sample data also supports the divergence for the economies of India. The invention of technology would generate the one-time shock impacts to cause the permanent change of the economy. The effects of new technology are exogenous and later change peoples' economic activities permanently, so we assume technology is exogenous and constant in the model. To investigate the impacts (size) of externality on the economy, we will discuss the model in following three cases. The production function of Romer model is defined as follows: Y = AKα L1−α Ҟη Y: production A: constant technology Ҟ: externality 𝝶: size of the externality 𝝶 increases -> externality is more significant and important 𝝶=0, production, Y, is Cobb-Douglas function For Romer, Ҟ=K investment increases -> K increases For Lucas, Ҟ= ƙ = K/L -> Romer model with Lucas modification Y = AKα L1−α Ҟη = AKα L1−α Kη L−η = AKα+η L1−α−η Y = AKα+η L1−α−η y = Y/L , ƙ= K/L -> y= Aƙα+η Ќ = s·Y - δ·K 10
  • 11. ƙ = K/L -> ln ƙ = ln K - ln L ќ/ƙ = Ќ/K - Ľ/L Ľ/L = n n: population growth; population growth is exogenous ќ/ƙ = (s·Y - δ·K )/K - n -> ќ = sy - (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ)·ƙ = s Aƙα+η - (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ)·ƙ ɣƙ = ќ/ƙ = s Aƙα+η−1 - (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ) -> the growth rate of ƙ, ɣƙ, depends on (α+δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1) 𝝶 > 0, ɣƙ >0, 0< s<1, s: saving rate; saving rate is exogenous (α +δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1) decides if the model has a stable steady state, unstable steady state or no steady state (AK model). The following three cases demonstrate the endogenous models with different size of externalities. Case 1: (α+δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1) <0 -> the impacts of externalities are not significant -> Y is Neo-Classical production function (the market is competitive) -> there is a positive stable steady state Graph 3.1 Convergence of the Endogenous Growth Model. ɣƙ = ќ/ƙ = s Aƙ α+η−1 - (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ) = 0 ƙ ss =[ sA n+δ ] 1/(1−α−η) 11
  • 12. Case 2: (α+δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1)>0 -> the impacts of externalities are very significant -> Y is not Neo-Classical production function (the market is not competitive) -> there is a unique, positive unstable steady state (saddle point) Graph 3.2 Divergence of the Endogenous Growth Model. ɣƙ = ќ/ƙ = s Aƙ α+η−1 - (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ) = 0 ƙ ss =[ sA n+δ ] 1/(1−α−η) Case 3: (α+δ)·ƙ = s 𝝶-1)=0 -> the impacts of externalities are significant, stable and consistent (𝝶 needs to be a specific value, 𝝶>0) -> Y is not Neo-Classical production function -> the market is perfectly competitive (constant return to scale holds) -> AK model 12
  • 13. -> there is no steady state ɣƙ = sA - (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ) Graph 3.3 AK model of the Endogenous Growth Model. The AK-type endogenous growth models, (named for the production function Y = AK), including those of Romer (1986, 1987), Lucas (1988), and Rebelo (1991), suggest that investment in the broadly defined capital has a positive long-run effect on growth. One primary concern about the AK model is that it is based on a simple one-sector linear production function without transitional dynamics. The diminishing returns of physical capital trade off the increasing return of human capital. An essential property of the AK model is the global absence of diminishing returns of capital (physical and human capital). The AK model implies that the broadly defined rate of investment exerts a positive effect on the long-run rate of growth. Because the constant return to scale holds in AK model, AK growth model satisfies perfect competitive models. In the endogenous growth model, the accumulation of human capital encounters the diminishing returns. AK model (Y=AK) occurs when the increasing return of human capital trades off the diminishing return of physical capital. AK model exhibits constant returns to scale in the accumulated factors of production, so the market is competitive; this model can generate perpetual (permanent) growth without the assumption of exogenous shifts in the production function. Case 1 and case 2 indicates the steady state exists when the annual growth of capital per capita is equal to zero (ɣƙ =0). Graph 2.5, Graph 3.1 and Graph3.2 indicate there are intercept shifts in Y-axis of scatter plots when the annual growth of capital per capita is equal to zero (ɣƙ =0). In economic theory, the intercept shift is equal to population growth 13
  • 14. rate plus the depreciation rate of capital. The steady-state level of capital per capita (ƙss = [ sA n+δ ] 1/(1−α−η) ) is equal to the function of all exogenous parameters (saving rate, constant technology, population growth rate and depreciation rate of capital). The economic model of endogenous growth is easy to demonstrate in the discussion. However, how to specify the econometric model of endogenous growth for application is the major topic of this paper. 3.4 Econometric Model Econometric modeling in this paper would demonstrate how to find the capital per capita at steady state and the rate of convergence for selected countries. Graph 2.5 indicates there are intercept shifts in Y-axis when the annual growth rates of capital per capita for selected countries are equal to zero (ɣƙ =0). In an economic model, the intercept shifts in Y-axis is equal to population growth rate plus depreciation rate of capital. For India and Indonesia, population growth rates decline dynamically within the sample size (1961 to 2016). For developed countries (Japan, U.S, and France), population growth rates keep as low constant rates. Depreciation rate should include the aggregate impacts of physical capital and human capital. However, it is not difficult to find the precise depreciation rates of all selected countries. Population growth rates and depreciation rates change dynamically. We are not able to calculate the capital per capita at the steady state and find out the rate of convergence by using algebra. In econometric modeling, the intercept shifts in Y-axis come from the aggregate impact of exogenous parameters such as population growth rate and depreciation rate of capital. In econometric modeling, the shifts of intercept on Y-axis of scatter plots could be incorporated in the constant term of the regression model if the aggregate impact of exogenous shock generates recursive activities with endogenous variables. If the aggregate effect of the exogenous shock generates a constant impact on annual growth rate per capita, we should transform the dependent variable as the annual growth rate of GDP per capita minus average of the annual growth rate of GDP per capita. There are two steps for econometric modeling of endogenous growth. In the first step, we have to specify the models for all selected countries by using OLS methodology to find the GDP per capita at the steady state. We also have to do Granger co-integration test for all models. After we obtain the capital per capita at the steady state, we would pursue the second step to find the rates of convergence. 3.4.1 Step One 14
  • 15. We regress the annual growth rates of GDP per capita on the GDP per capita by using OLS methodology and then test the co-integration relationship for all models. Graph 2.4 demonstrates all selected countries experienced the impacts of exogenous shocks from the invention of new technology, governmental policy changes and financial crises within the sample period. Although the innovation technology is one time shock and generates consistent externality of the economy. The economy still experiences other shocks dynamically. We have to impose the impulse indicators to capture the hit-and-run impacts from the exogenous shocks and stabilize the parameters. Hendry (2005) states impulse indicators simplify the dummy variables and stabilize parameters in the face of exogenous shocks to avoid the misspecification of the model. ɣƙ = ќ/ƙ = s Aƙα+η−1 - (n+δ)·ƙ = sδ) --------Equation 3.1 ɣƙ = C +δ)·ƙ = s βƙ +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation 3.2 ɣƙ = C +δ)·ƙ = s βƙ +δ)·ƙ = s ϵ -------Equation 3.3 ɣ= ɣƙ - Ʀ = C +δ)·ƙ = s βƙ +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation 3.4 ɣ=ɣƙ - Ʀ = C +δ)·ƙ = s βƙ +δ)·ƙ = s ϵ --------Equation3.5 ɣƙ: the annual growth rate of capital per capita C: constant term (intercept) ɸ: impulse indicators to capture hit-and-run impacts of exogenous shocks Ԑ: error term of the estimated equation of annual growth rate of GDP per capita; Ԑ has to be white noise ϵ: error term of co-integration equation; ϵ has to be stationary Ʀ: an average of the annual growth rate of GDP per capita The economic model demonstrates the annual growth rate of capital per capita (ɣƙ) in Equation 3.1, and then we specify the econometric model as Equation 3.2 that shows the econometric model to estimate the endogenous growth model for Japan, India, and, U.S. The intercept of Equation 3.2 incorporates the shift of the annual growth rate of capital per capita in Graph 2.5. Equation 3.2 provides stable and efficient parameters with white noise error terms to demonstrate the economic interaction between the annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita. The significant impulse indicators mean the state of the economy is 15
  • 16. deviating from the steady state in the face of impacts of exogenous shocks. Equation 3.3 demonstrates the co-integration equation (steady state) between the annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita. The definition of co-integration is that the endogenous variables are not necessary to be stationary but the first differences of endogenous variables have to be stationary, and the error term of the co-integration equation has to be stationary. We applied Augmented Dickey-Fuller test to test for the stationarity of endogenous variables, and the results are demonstrated in (Table4.1, Table 4.2, Table4.3, Table4.4, and Table4.5). The co-integration of endogenous variables indicates the existence of the stable steady state of endogenous variables. However, without the impulse indicators, the parameter of co-integration equation is not stable and efficient enough to interpret the economic interaction of endogenous variables. The significant impulse indicators of Equation 3.2 and Equation 3.4 demonstrate the current economy is converging to steady state with stable growth rate if co-integration relationship holds between endogenous variables; otherwise, the economy will diverge to a saddle point (unstable steady state). Equation 3.4 demonstrates the econometric model to estimate the endogenous growth model for France. Equation 3.5 demonstrates the co-integration equation of endogenous growth model of France. The aggregate impacts of exogenous parameters of France approach a fixed constant. Thus, the constant term of an econometric model is not able to incorporate the aggregate effects of exogenous parameters. Graph 2.5 demonstrates the intercept shift of annual growth of GDP per capita of France is close to the average annual growth of GDP per capita of France. The transformed annual growth rate of France should be the annual growth rate of GDP per capita minus the average of the annual growth rate of GDP per capita of France (2.14%). The regression results of Equation 3.2 and Equation 3.4 demonstrate the economic interaction between the annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita. ɣƙ is equal to zero at steady state so we can obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady state based on the regression results. We will demonstrate the results in Section 4 (Empirical Results). As long as we obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady state, we can pursue to the second step to specify the econometric model for the rate of convergence for the selected countries. 3.4.2 Step Two We specify the econometric model of the rate of convergence based on the paper of Mankiw (1995). The model is specified as follows: 16
  • 17. ќ = λ· (ƙ - ƙss ) +δ)·ƙ = s e-------Equation3.6 ќ: the first difference of GDP per capita; ƙss : GDP per capita at steady state e: the error term of estimation equation of rate of convergence; e has to be white noise We have obtained the optimal GDP per capita at steady state in the first step, and then we could specify a model for the rate of convergence as Equation 3.6. Equation 3.6 demonstrates the econometric model to estimate the rates of convergence for all selected countries. λ is the convergence rate of GDP per capita. λ measures how quickly the economy approach to the steady state. 4. Empirical Results The previous section demonstrates the framework of econometric models for endogenous growth. However, this section displays all results of the econometric models and explains the results in detail. According to the framework of econometric models in Section 3, we demonstrate the empirical results in two steps. The first step would describe how to obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady state for all well-specified models and also demonstrate the importance of co-integration tests for all models. The second step would apply the optimal GDP per capita at steady states to specify the models for rates of convergence. 4.1 The First Step The first step would demonstrate how to obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady states, and we also found the results of co-integration tests in relation to convergence, which means the results of co-integration tests would support the models that converge to a stable steady state. If the co-integration relation does not hold between endogenous variables, the model should diverge to an unstable steady state (saddle point). ɣJapan = 4.51394 -0.00015671·JAPANGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation4.1 ɣIndia = -1.97814 +δ)·ƙ = s 0.00241· INDIAGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation4.2 ɣUS = 2.50773 - 0.00007282 · USGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation4.3 ɣFRANCE = 3.4563 - 0.00011781· FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s ɸ +δ)·ƙ = s Ԑ -------Equation4.4 ɣFRANCE = annual growth rate of GDP per capita of France - GDP per capita of France (2.14%) ɣFRANCE: the transformed annual growth rate of GDP per capita of France 17
  • 18. ɸ: impulse indicators The above equations demonstrate stable and efficient parameters to interpret economic interactions between endogenous variables at steady states for selected countries, although the current economic states are approaching to steady states. The error terms of Equation4.1, Equation4.2, Equation4.3, and Equation4.4 are white noise, and the detail regression results are demonstrated elaborately in Appendix. The results demonstrate negative relationships between annual growth rates of GDP per capita and GDP per capita for Japan, US, and France, which means the economies of Japan, US and France would converge to stable steady states. The regression results show the positive relationship between Indian annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita, which indicates that the economy of India would diverge to an unstable steady state (saddle point). The regression results are consistent with the scatter plot results of Graph 2.5. At steady states, the expected values of annual growth rates of GDP per capita of all selected countries are equal to zero without impulse indicators (ɸ). Thus, we obtain the following results with stable and efficient parameters: 0 = 4.51394 - 0.00015671·JAPANGDPPERCAPITAss -> JAPANGDPPERCAPITAss = 28804.42 0 = -1.97814 +δ)·ƙ = s 0.00241· INDIAGDPPERCAPITAss -> INDIAGDPPERCAPITAss = 820.8 0 = 2.50773 - 0.00007282 · USGDPPERCAPITAss -> USGDPPERCAPITAss = 34437.38 0 = 2.50773 - 0.00007282· FRANCEGDPPERCAPITAss -> FRANCEGDPPERCAPITAss =29337.92 4.1.1 Co-integration Results The definition of co-integration states the endogenous variables are not necessary to be stationary1 (Table 4.2, Table 4.3). But the first differences of endogenous variables2 (Table 1 Table 4.2 demonstrates annual growth rate of Japan is almost stationary; annual growth rates of GDP per capita for other selected countries are stationary. Table 4.3 demonstrates GDP per capita for selected countries are not stationary (P-value > 5%) by using Augmented Dickey-Fuller test. 18
  • 19. 4.4, Table 4.5) are stationary, and the error terms of co-integration equations are stationary (Table 4.1). The co-integration equations are demonstrated as followings: ɣJapan = 9.37562 - 0.00019393·JAPANGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s e-------Equation4.5 ɣIndia = 0.6191 +δ)·ƙ = s 0.00401· INDIAGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = se-------Equation4.6 ɣUS = 4.06853 - 0.00005759· USGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = s e -------Equation4.7 ɣFRANCE = 4.3147 - 0.0001423· FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA +δ)·ƙ = se-------Equation4.8 ɣFRANCE = annual growth of GDP per capita of France - GDP per capita of France (2.14%) e: the error terms of co-integration equations Table 4.1 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for Residuals 1 2 3 4 5 <.0001 <.0001 0.9999 <.0001 P-Value Augmented Dickey-FullerUnit Root Tests for the Residuals ofCo-integration Equation (Ho: Nonstationary ) <.0001 0.0001 0.0001 <.0001 <.0001 0.0001 0.0001 <.0001 <.0001 <.0001 <.0001 <.0001 <.0001 <.0001 0.0001 <.0001 Lags Japan (Zero Mean) India (Zero Mean) US (Zero Mean) France (Zero Mean) Table 4.2 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for the Annual Growth Rates of GDP per Capita 1 2 3 4 5 P-Value AugmentedDickey-FullerUnitRootTests forAnnualGrowthRate PerCapita( Ho: Nonstationary) 0.2202 0.4773 0.0004 0.0001 0.3451 0.2071 0.0004 0.0001 0.1479 0.0235 0.0005 <.0001 0.0517 0.0167 0.0005 <.0001 0.0042 0.0005 0.0005 <.0001 Lags Japan(Single Mean) India(Single Mean) US(Single Mean) France (Trend) Table 4.3 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for GDP per Capita 2 Table 4.5 demonstrates the first differences of GDP per capita for Japan, U.S., and France are stationary but not India. 19
  • 20. 1 2 3 4 5 P-Value AugmentedDickey-FullerUnit RootTests forGDP PerCapita( Ho: Nonstationary) 0.8726 0.9999 0.0036 0.9741 0.9191 0.9999 0.1415 0.9399 0.9413 0.9999 0.1586 0.9276 0.9536 0.9999 0.1126 0.9622 0.9378 0.9999 0.0903 0.9042 Lags Japan(Trend) India (Trend) US(Trend) France (Trend) Table 4.4 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for the First Difference of the Annual Growth Rates of GDP per Capita 1 2 3 4 5 P-Value Augmented Dickey-Fuller Unit Root Tests forthe First Difference ofAnnual Growth Rate PerCapita (Ho: Nonstationary ) 0.99990.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.9999 0.0001 0.9999 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 Lags Japan (Zero Mean) India (Zero Mean) US (Zero Mean) France (Zero Mean) Table 4.5 Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests for the First Difference of GDP per Capita 1 2 3 4 5 0.014 P-Value AugmentedDickey-FullerUnitRootTests forthe FirstDifference ofGDPPerCapita(Ho:Nonstationary) 0.0087 0.9972 0.0001 0.0004 0.003 0.9962 0.0001 0.0004 0.0004 0.9933 0.0001 0.0005 0.0005 0.9816 0.0005 0.0005 0.0005 0.6007 0.0005 Lags Japan(Single Mean) India(Single Mean) US(Single Mean) France (Single Mean) The results of co-integration test demonstrate the co-integration relationships hold for the endogenous models of Japan, US, and France; however, the co-integration relationship does not hold for the endogenous model of India. The co-integration relationship of endogenous variables ensures the models would converge to stable steady states. The co- integration relationship does not hold for the model of India. The model of India diverges to an unstable steady state (saddle point). Thus, the co-integration ensures the stability of endogenous variables. Although the co-integration ensures the stability of endogenous variables to approach to a stable steady state, the parameters of co-integration equation are not stable and efficient because the error terms of co-integration equations are not white noise. The parameters 20
  • 21. of co-integration equations are not able to interpret economic interactions of endogenous variables at steady states. Thus, we have to apply the parameters of Equarion4.1, Equation4.2, Equation4.3, and Equation4.4 to interpret the economic activities at steady states and then obtain the optimal GDP per capita at steady states for all selected countries. 4.2 The Second Step Equation 3.6 demonstrates the framework of the rate of convergence3 . After we obtain the optimal value of GDP per capita at steady state, we can estimate the rate of convergence as followings: DJAPANGDPPERCAPITA = λ · (JAPAGDPPERCAPITA - JAPANGDPPERCAPITAss ) +δ)·ƙ = s e--- Equation4.9 DINDIAGDPPERCAPITA =λ· (INDIAGDPPERCAPITA - INDIAGDPPERCAPITAss ) +δ)·ƙ = s e--- Equation4.10 DUSGDPPERCAPITA = λ· (USGDPPERCAPITA - USGDPPERCAPITAss ) +δ)·ƙ = s e------- Equation4.11 DFGDPPERCAPITA =λ· (FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA-FRANCEGDPPERCAPITAss ) +δ)·ƙ = s e---- Equation4.12 Note: JAPANGDPPERCAPITAss =28804.42, INDIAGDPPERCAPITAss =820.8, USGDPPERCAPITAss =34437.38, FRANCEGDPPERCAPITAss =29337.92 DJAPANGDPPERCAPITA: the first difference of GDP per capita of Japan DINDIAGDPPERCAPITA: the first difference of GDP per capita of India DUSGDPPERCAPITA: the first difference of GDP per capita of US DFGDPPERCAPITA: the first difference of GDP per capita of France Table4.6 Regression Results for GDP per Capita at the Steady States and the Rate of Convergence for Selected Countries 3 Table4.6 demonstrates the regression results for GDP per capita at steady states and the rates of convergence for all selected countries. 21
  • 22. COUNTRY JAPAN INDIA US FRANCE GDP at Steady State 28804.42 820.8 34437.38 29337.92 The Rate of Convergence -1.54% 5.95% -0.57% -2.69% Graph 2.5 provides the simple scatter plots between annual growth rates of GDP per capita and GDP per capita, which provides the outline to judge the convergence or divergence of the economies. The empirical results provide the overall results of the test of convergence, which include how to obtain the optimal GDP per capita ate steady states, judge if the models would converge to a stable steady state or diverge to a saddle point, and estimate the rate of convergence for all selected countries. The economies of Japan, US, and France converge to stable steady states. The impacts of the invention of new technology are insignificant. The markets of these countries are perfectly competitive. The rate of convergence of these countries is lower than the rate of convergence of developing countries. The economies of these countries are consistent with Case 1 of economic model in Section 3. The economy of India would diverge to an unstable steady state (saddle point), and the impacts of the invention of technology would be significant. The market of Indian is a monopoly with market power. The rate of convergence of India is higher than the rate of convergence of other developed countries (Japan, US, and France). The economy of India is consistent with Case 2 of the economic model in Section 3. 5. A Brief Discussion of the AK Model Economists have been discussing the existence of AK model of endogenous growth for several decades. The AK model could occur when the diminishing return rate of physical capital trade off the increasing return rate of human capital. The accumulation of human capital encounters the diminishing returns. The market is perfectly competitive because AK model exhibits constant returns to scale in the accumulated factors of production; this model can generate perpetual (permanent) growth without the assumption of exogenous shifts in the production function. We will discuss AK model of endogenous growth by using the economy of Indonesia. Graph 5.1 shows the economy of Indonesia would barely diverge to an unstable steady state, while Graph 5.2 illustrates that the economy of Indonesia has no steady state in the 22
  • 23. aggregate level of the annual growth rate of GDP in relation to GDP per capita. The aggregate level of the annual growth rate of GDP in relation to GDP per capita would demonstrate the economy of Indonesia would approach to AK model, which can generate perpetual (permanent) growth without the assumption of exogenous shifts in the production function. Because there is no steady state in AK models, we are not able to apply econometric model to obtain the GDP at the steady state and the rate of convergence to steady state. Graph 5.1 Test for Convergence of Indonesia (1) Graph 5.2 Test for Convergence of Indonesia (2) Looking at the annual growth of Indonesia’s GDP, we notice that the global financial crisis (2008) did not affect Indonesia severely (Graph 5.3). The annual growth of aggregate GDP of Indonesia and annual growth of GDP per capita have the same movement. The impacts of Asian financial crisis (1997) hit the economy of Indonesia seriously. 23
  • 24. Graph 5.3 Annual Growth of GDP of Indonesia We discuss AK model in this section. We believe the AK model and Indonesia should be a topic for further research papers. Indonesia and other Asian countries suffer from Asian financial crisis severely. However, Indonesia got better recovery than other countries. AK model can generate perpetual (permanent) growth without the assumption of exogenous shifts in the production function, which might assist Indonesia to get out of the recession from Asian financial crisis efficiently. The market of Indonesia should turn from monopoly to perfect competition. However, there is no transitional dynamic and steady state for AK model at current economic state for Indonesia. As long as Indonesia accumulate sufficient physical capital and human capital, GDP per capita of Indonesia would obtain significantly improved, the impacts of externality would not be significant. The economy of Indonesia might converge to stable steady state as well as the neo-classical model. 6. Conclusion In the history, there are industrial revolutions with the new invention of technologies. New technology changes our lives and then becomes part of our lives. We could say new technology generates one-time shock impacts of the economy and we assume the effects 24
  • 25. of new technology are exogenous and constant, which are externalities of the economy. The new technology generates more physical capital and human capital in the economy. The new technology creates different impacts for developed countries and developing countries. For developed countries, the physical capital and human capital of developed are a lot higher than developing countries. Developing countries have small capital stocks. Although developed countries have higher human capital stocks, the increasing return of human capital of developed nations is not as high as emerging ones. The marginal production of the capital of developing countries is higher than developed countries, which makes capital flows from developed countries to developing countries. Thus, the growth rates of developing countries are higher than developed countries. Romer (1986) proposed new endogenous growth model with externality to demonstrate the impacts of new technology on the economy. For developed countries (Japan, US, and France), the effects of externalities are insignificant; the economies are close to neo- classical economies and converge to stable steady states. The markets are perfectly competitive. For developing countries, the impacts of externalities are significant. The economies diverge to an unstable steady state (saddle point) with imperfect completive markets, or the economies could have no steady state with the perfectly competitive market (AK model). If the increasing return of human capital dominates the decreasing return of physical capital, the economy of developing country will diverge to a saddle point. If the increasing returns of human capital trade-off the decreasing return of physical capital, the economy of developing country would approach AK model. This paper confirms when the co-integration relation holds between the annual growth rate of GDP per capita and GDP per capita; the economy would converge to a steady state; if it does not hold, the economy will diverge to a saddle point. This paper demonstrates the results of convergence test including how to obtain GDP per capita and convergence rates at steady states for selected countries in detail and also discuss the economy of Indonesia could be the case of AK model. We accomplish our work to dedicate the contribution of economists to the endogenous growth model. 25
  • 26. Appendix: India Step 1: Find the optimal GDP per capita at the steady state of India. Dependent variable is annual growth rate of GDP per capita of India. Root MSE 0.64386 R-Square 0.9638 Dependent Mean 3.3379 Adj R-Sq 0.9602 CoeffVar 19.28934 Parameter Standard Estimate Error Standard Error Intercept 1 -1.97814 0.27052 -7.31 <.0001 0.20896 -9.47 <.0001 0 INDIAGDPPERCAPITA 1 0.00241 0.00021631 11.15 <.0001 0.00018742 12.87 <.0001 1.09086 IDUM1 1 3.73002 0.29652 12.58 <.0001 0.21669 17.21 <.0001 1.29906 IDUM2 1 -1.55698 0.18408 -8.46 <.0001 0.16105 -9.67 <.0001 1.12099 IDUM3 1 2.73219 0.18883 14.47 <.0001 0.17058 16.02 <.0001 1.19806 IDUM4 1 -5.18208 0.49409 -10.49 <.0001 0.3357 -15.44 <.0001 1.1357 Variable t Value Pr > |t| Parameter Estimates for Model of India Heteroscedasticity Consistent DF t Value Pr > |t| Variance Inflation The steady state INDIAGDPPERCAPITA= (1.97814/0.00241)= 820.8 Durbin-Watson D 1.932 Number of Observations 56 1st Order Autocorrelation 0.015 Parameter Symbol Estimate Mean Mu 0 Std Dev Sigma 0.613896 Test Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.09513858 Pr > D >0.150 Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.06131651 Pr > W-Sq >0.250 Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.40615653 Pr > A-Sq >0.250 p ValueStatistic Parameters for Normal Distribution Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution Step 2: Find the stable growth rate of GDP per capita of India 26
  • 27. Root MSE 4.48661 R-Square 0.9831 Dependent Mean 28.22067 Adj R-Sq 0.9814 CoeffVar 15.89832 Parameter Standard Estimate Error Standard Error Intercept 1 20.91507 1.46528 14.27 <.0001 1.55237 13.47 <.0001 0 INDIASS 1 0.0595 0.00159 37.5 <.0001 0.00167 35.69 <.0001 1.19146 RIDUM1 1 15.07383 1.71336 8.8 <.0001 1.87688 8.03 <.0001 1.36819 RIDUM2 1 -8.7521 1.27478 -6.87 <.0001 1.18793 -7.37 <.0001 1.09205 RIDUM3 1 10.32725 1.51605 6.81 <.0001 1.09638 9.42 <.0001 1.56945 RIDUM4 1 21.56937 2.26909 9.51 <.0001 2.41325 8.94 <.0001 1.36726 Parameter Estimates for Model of India Variance InflationVariable DF t Value Pr > |t| Heteroscedasticity Consistent t Value Pr > |t| The stable growth rate diverging to a saddle point (unstable steady state) of India is 0.0595. Durbin-Watson D 1.903 Number of Observations 55 1st Order Autocorrelation 0.02 Parameter Symbol Estimate Mean Mu 0 Std Dev Sigma 4.273854 Test Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.071525 Pr > D >0.150 Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.043183 Pr > W-Sq >0.250 Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.403768 Pr > A-Sq >0.250 Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution Parameters for Normal Distribution Statistic p Value US: Step 1: Find the optimal GDP percapita at the steady state of US. Dependent variable is annual growth rate of GDP per capita of US. Root MSE 0.57928 R-Square 0.9223 Dependent Mean 2.03883 Adj R-Sq 0.9162 CoeffVar 28.41235 27
  • 28. Parameter Standard Estimate Error Standard Error Intercept 1 2.50773 0.30731 8.16 <.0001 0.4441 5.65 <.0001 0 USGDPPERCAPITA 1 -0.00007282 7.5E-06 -9.72 <.0001 7.88E-06 -9.24 <.0001 1.08544 UDUM1 1 3.14008 0.21141 14.85 <.0001 0.26328 11.93 <.0001 1.17727 UDUM2 1 -1.76926 0.17445 -10.14 <.0001 0.1846 -9.58 <.0001 1.22916 UDUM3 1 2.30261 0.20665 11.14 <.0001 0.15063 15.29 <.0001 1.39756 Variable DF t Value Pr > |t| Heteroscedasticity Consistent t Value Pr > |t| Parameter Estimates for Model of US Variance Inflation The steady state USGDPPERCAPITA= (2.50773/0.00007282) =34437.37984 Durbin-Watson D 1.987 Number of Observations 56 1st Order Autocorrelation -0.026 Parameter Symbol Estimate Mean Mu 0 Std Dev Sigma 0.557818 Test Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.09084667 Pr > D >0.150 Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.06583806 Pr > W-Sq >0.250 Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.41040077 Pr > A-Sq >0.250 Statistic p Value Parameters for Normal Distribution Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution Step 2: Find the stable growth rate of GDP per capita of US Root MSE 108.2639 R-Square 0.9736 Dependent Mean 637.3217 Adj R-Sq 0.9709 CoeffVar 16.98732 Parameter Standard Estimate Error Standard Error Intercept 1 8.9137 44.93412 0.2 0.8436 49.00046 0.18 0.8564 0 USSS 1 -0.00572 0.0014 -4.09 0.0002 0.00132 -4.32 <.0001 1.02649 RUDUM1 1 843.08977 44.24133 19.06 <.0001 42.2722 19.94 <.0001 1.1416 RUDUM2 1 -394.9506 30.44639 -12.97 <.0001 34.11445 -11.58 <.0001 1.05833 RUDUM3 1 587.84322 33.06683 17.78 <.0001 36.55981 16.08 <.0001 1.12961 RUDUM4 1 -1324.58677 80.92743 -16.37 <.0001 24.4364 -54.21 <.0001 1.07688 Parameter Estimates for Model of US Variance Inflation Variable DF t Value Pr > |t| Heteroscedasticity Consistent t Value Pr > |t| The stable growth rate converging to a stable steady state of US is 0.00572. 28
  • 29. Durbin-Watson D 1.994 Number of Observations 55 1st Order Autocorrelation -0.037 Parameter Symbol Estimate Mean Mu 0 Std Dev Sigma 103.1299 Test Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.078349 Pr > D >0.150 Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.060356 Pr > W-Sq >0.250 Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.463017 Pr > A-Sq >0.250 Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution Parameters for Normal Distribution Statistic p Value France: Step 1: Find the optimal GDP percapita at the steady state of France. Dependent variable is annual growth rate of GDP per capita of France. Root MSE 0.39871 R-Square 0.9591 Dependent Mean -0.00459 Adj R-Sq 0.9559 CoeffVar -8677.73562 Parameter Standard Estimate Error Standard Error Intercept 1 3.4563 0.20401 16.94 <.0001 0.17738 19.49 <.0001 0 FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA 1 -0.00011781 0.00000627 -18.8 <.0001 0.00000541 -21.77 <.0001 1.08382 FDUM1 1 1.82828 0.11031 16.57 <.0001 0.10407 17.57 <.0001 1.04967 FDUM2 1 -0.99143 0.12043 -8.23 <.0001 0.09472 -10.47 <.0001 1.25112 FDUM3 1 -2.72724 0.20186 -13.51 <.0001 0.2833 -9.63 <.0001 1.16718 Variance Inflation ParameterEstimates forModel of France Variable DF tValue Pr>|t| HeteroscedasticityConsistent tValue Pr>|t| The steady state FRANCEGDPPERCAPITA= (3.4563/0.00011781)=29337.91698 Durbin-Watson D 2.07 Number of Observations 56 1st Order Autocorrelation -0.037 Parameter Symbol Estimate Mean Mu 0 Std Dev Sigma 0.383937 Test Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.07460072 Pr > D >0.150 Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.02673638 Pr > W-Sq >0.250 Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.24623075 Pr > A-Sq >0.250 Statistic p Value Parameters for Normal Distribution Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution Step 2: Find the stable growth rate of GDP per capita of France 29
  • 30. Root MSE 108.33758 R-Square 0.9503 Dependent Mean 517.97885 Adj R-Sq 0.9452 CoeffVar 20.91544 Parameter Standard Estimate Error Standard Error Intercept 1 446.15411 25.24861 17.67 <.0001 21.81685 20.45 <.0001 0 FRANCESS 1 -0.02693 0.00178 -15.09 <.0001 0.00178 -15.14 <.0001 1.11228 RFDUM1 1 421.67458 33.50593 12.59 <.0001 30.24962 13.94 <.0001 1.31475 RFDUM2 1 -218.67875 30.16153 -7.25 <.0001 23.57055 -9.28 <.0001 1.06539 RFDUM3 1 386.15133 44.73396 8.63 <.0001 38.85144 9.94 <.0001 1.28338 RFDUM4 1 -1015.97424 66.93262 -15.18 <.0001 144.3399 -7.04 <.0001 1.08263 Parameter Estimates for Model of France Variance Inflation Variable DF t Value Pr > |t| Heteroscedasticity Consistent t Value Pr > |t| The stable growth rate converging to a stable steady state of France is 0.02693. Durbin-Watson D 1.959 Number of Observations 55 1st Order Autocorrelation 0 Parameter Symbol Estimate Mean Mu 0 Std Dev Sigma 103.2001 Test Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.06989321 Pr > D >0.150 Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.03544269 Pr > W-Sq >0.250 Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.27073916 Pr > A-Sq >0.250 Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution Parameters for Normal Distribution Statistic p Value Japan: Step 1: Find the optimal GDP percapita of Japan at the steady state. Dependent variable is annual growth rate of GDP per capita of Japan. Root MSE 0.79714 R-Square 0.9543 Dependent Mean 3.16207 Adj R-Sq 0.9507 CoeffVar 25.20954 30
  • 31. Intercept 1 4.51394 0.44526 10.14 <.0001 0.55259 8.17 <.0001 0 JGDPPERCAPITA 1 -0.00015671 0.0000098 -15.99 <.0001 0.00000826 -18.97 <.0001 1.19319 JDUM1 1 4.44399 0.33213 13.38 <.0001 0.4576 9.71 <.0001 1.06331 JDUM2 1 -2.49876 0.23595 -10.59 <.0001 0.22325 -11.19 <.0001 1.21253 JDUM3 1 5.01378 0.29817 16.82 <.0001 0.29856 16.79 <.0001 1.39664 Heteroscedasticity Consistent t Value Pr >|t| Variance Inflation Standard ERROR Standard ERROR Variable t Value Pr >|t|Parameter ERROR Parameter Estimates for Model of Japan DF The steady state JGDPPERCAPITA= (4.51394/0.00015671)=28804.4158 Durbin-Watson D 2.017 Number of Observations 56 1st Order Autocorrelation -0.022 Parameter Symbol Estimate Mean Mu 0 Std Dev Sigma 0.767609 Test Shapiro-Wilk W 0.988035 Pr < W 0.8513 Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.068691 Pr > D >0.1500 Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.044715 Pr > W-Sq >0.2500 Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.255122 Pr > A-Sq >0.2500 Tests for Normality Statistic p Value Parameters for Normal Distribution Step 2: Find the stable growth rate of GDP per capita of Japan Root MSE 183.94301 R-Square 0.9485 Dependent Mean 694.75365 Adj R-Sq 0.9432 CoeffVar 26.476 Parameter Standard Estimate Error Standard Error Intercept 1 -12.23152 80.81876 -0.15 0.8803 80.31201 -0.15 0.8796 0 JAPANSS 1 -0.01536 0.00219 -7.01 <.0001 0.00181 -8.48 <.0001 1.04418 RJDUM1 1 984.55057 81.58071 12.07 <.0001 79.77229 12.34 <.0001 1.20167 RJDUM2 1 -551.97999 50.8594 -10.85 <.0001 50.03882 -11.03 <.0001 1.04806 RJDUM3 1 952.16883 60.33682 15.78 <.0001 59.27475 16.06 <.0001 1.06814 RJDUM4 1 -1663.35318 201.397 -8.26 <.0001 81.10363 -20.51 <.0001 1.17698 Parameter Estimates for Model of Japan Variance Inflation Variable DF t Value Pr > |t| Heteroscedasticity Consistent t Value Pr > |t| The stable growth rate converging to a stable steady state of Japan is 0.01536. 31
  • 32. Durbin-Watson D 1.967 Number of Observations 55 1st Order Autocorrelation 0.009 Parameter Symbol Estimate Mean Mu 0 Std Dev Sigma 175.2203 Test Kolmogorov-Smirnov D 0.046394 Pr > D >0.150 Cramer-von Mises W-Sq 0.013809 Pr > W-Sq >0.250 Anderson-Darling A-Sq 0.120663 Pr > A-Sq >0.250 Goodness-of-Fit Tests for Normal Distribution Parameters for Normal Distribution Statistic p Value Compliance with Ethical Standards: Conflict of Interest: I _____KELLY YIYU LIN_______________- as corresponding author, certify that all authors contributed significantly to the manuscript and no other authors were involved and were not part of the team that created this manuscript. All used data are correct and results are based on authors’ calculations. Author(s) is/are solely responsible for the entire content and results of the paper published in the journal. I certify that no part of this manuscript has been published before or is not under consideration for publication elsewhere. I certified that this manuscript was used as working paper only. Title of the manuscript The Importance of Parameter Constancy for Endogenous Growth with Externality Authors’ name / affiliation / official email address Percentage of contributio n 1. KELLY YIYU LIN 70% 2.WENTI DU 30% 32
  • 33. Ethical Approval: This article does not contain any study References Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1990). A model of growth through creative destruction. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Benhabib, J., & Jovanovic, B. (1989). Externalities and Growth Accounting. Working Paper No. 3190. Engle, R. F. & Granger, C. W. J. (1987). Co-integration and error correction: Representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica, 55(2), 251–276. Ertur, C., & Koch, W. (2007). Growth, technological interdependence and spatial externalities: theory and evidence. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22(6), 1033-1062. Granger, C. (1981). Some properties of time series data and their use in econometric model specification. Journal of Econometrics, 16(1), 121-130. Hendry, David.F & Santos, Carlos (2005), Regression Models with Data-Based Indicators Variables. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Volume 67, Issue 5, 571-595. Li, D. (2002). Is the AK model still alive? The long-run relation between growth and investment re-examined. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d`Economique, 35(1), 92-114. Mankiw, N. G. (1995). The Growth of Nations. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 275-326. 33
  • 34. Rivera-Batiz, L., & Romer, P. (1991). Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2), 531-555. Robert J. Barro and Xavier I. Sala-i-Martin, Economic Growth, Second Edition, The MIT Press, October 2003. Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002-1037. Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S71-S102. Romer, P. M. (1994). The Origins of Endogenous Growth. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(1), 3-22. 34