SlideShare a Scribd company logo
S t u d i a i A n a l i z y 
S t u d i e s & A n a l y s e s 
C e n t r u m A n a l i z 
S p o ł e c z n o – E k o n o m i c z n y c h 
C e n t e r f o r S o c i a l 
a n d E c o n o m i c R e s e a r c h 
2 5 3 
Jacek Rostowski 
When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
Wa r s a w , O c t o b e r 2 0 0 3
Materials published here have a working paper character. They can be subject to further 
publication. The views and opinions expressed here reflect the author(s) point of view and not 
necessarily those of the CASE. 
The paper was prepared within the research project entitled: Strategie przystapienia do 
Europejskiej Unii Gospodarczej i Walutowej: analiza porównawcza moliwych scenariuszy 
(Strategies for Joining the European Economic and Monetary Union: a Comparative Analysis of 
Possible Scenarios) financed by the State Committee for Scientific Research. 
Keywords: currency unions, currency areas, monetary policy, economic growth, economic 
union, monetary union, European Union, enlargement, 
© CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw 2003 
Graphic Design: Agnieszka Natalia Bury 
ISSN 1506-1701, ISBN: 83-7178-308-6 
Publisher: 
CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research 
12 Sienkiewicza, 00-944 Warsaw, Poland 
tel.: (48 22) 622 66 27, 828 61 33, fax: (48 22) 828 60 69 
e-mail: case@case.com.pl 
http://www.case.com.pl/
Contents 
Abstract ..............................................................................................................................5 
1. Introduction....................................................................................................................6 
2. Risks of Macroeconomic Instability Outside the EMU...............................................6 
3. Optimum Currency Area Considerations ....................................................................8 
4. Is there a trade-off between Real and Nominal Convergence? ...............................12 
5. Should rapid catch-up disqualify CEECs from EMU membership?........................13 
6. EMU institutional issues .............................................................................................18 
7. Conclusion ...................................................................................................................20 
REFERENCES ..................................................................................................................22
Jacek Rostowski 
Jacek Rostowski is Professor of Economics at the Central European University, Budapest, a 
trustee of the CASE Foundation, Warsaw, an adviser to the Governor of the National Bank of 
Poland, and an associate of the International Economics Programme at the Royal Institute for 
International Affairs.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
5 
Abstract 
The paper first considers why central European countries wish to join EMU soon. The main 
reasons are the risk of macroeconomic instability they face outside the euro zone if they wish to 
grow quickly. At the same time, Central Europe is highly integrated as regards trade with EMU, so 
it is little exposed to asymmetric shocks that would require a realignment of exchange rates. 
Finally, it is argued that there is no cost in terms of slower growth from EMU accession, so that 
there is no trade-off, as has been claimed, between nominal convergence to EMU and real 
convergence to EU average GDP levels. Second, the paper assesses whether Central European 
accession to EMU would be disadvantageous to current members. It concludes that accession 
cannot increase inflationary pressure on existing EMU members, as has been claimed, but that 
slow growing members of EMU might suffer increased unemployment, unless they increase the 
flexibility of their labour markets. Incumbent members may also be unwilling to share power with 
Central Europeans in EMU institutions.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
1. Introduction1 
With EU accession now assured, the candidate countries are actively considering when to join 
the EMU. Unlike Britain and Denmark the new members will not have an “opt-out” - the right to 
remain outside the EMU indefinitely. The question is therefore only one of timing. A number of 
countries have already declared that they want to join EMU as soon as possible after EU 
accession. The costs of such a move are minimal for Estonia and Lithuania, which already have 
their currencies “hard-pegged” to the euro through a currency board [Sulling 2002]2. Hungary and 
Poland have also announced that their aim is to satisfy the Maastricht criteria for EMU accession in 
2005, which would allow them to join during 2006 or January 2007. On the other hand, the Czech 
government has declared that it does not foresee early EMU accession3. The European 
Commission [Financial Times, 10 Oct. 2002] and the Bundesbank [Bratkowski and Rostowski 
2002, Financial Times, 26 Sept. 2000] have also made clear their lack of enthusiasm for new 
members joining the EMU quickly. 
What are the reasons pushing many applicant countries towards early EMU entry, and why are 
some key players in Western Europe opposed to it? We divide the discussion into seven sections. 
Section 2 describes the macroeconomic risks to which central European countries are exposed 
while they remain outside the EMU. Section 3 assesses the standard optimum currency area 
(OCA) criteria for whether these countries are ready for EMU accession. Section 4 considers 
whether there is a trade-off for central Europeans between joining EMU and real economic 
convergence with the EU. Section 5 addresses some arguments which claim that Central 
European accession to EMU would be bad for current EMU members. Section 6 considers 
institutional issues and Section 7 concludes. 
2. Risks of Macroeconomic Instability Outside the EMU 
In earlier papers we have analysed the difficulties faced by the more advanced central and 
east European countries (CEECs) in achieving macroeconomic stability in the run-up to EU and 
EMU membership [Rostowski 2000], and have presented the case for unilateral euroization as a 
1 I wish to thank a referee for very useful comments. 
2 Estonia has argued that it should be able to join EMU earlier than 2006, since it has satisfied the Maastricht 
Treaty’s exchange rate criterion ever since the ratification of the Treaty and the interest rate criterion for many years. 
These are the two criteria which need to be satisfied for two years. The exchange rate criterion requires that the value of 
the applicant country’s currency remain within the range required by the ERM2 relative to the central parity (plus or 
minus 15%) for a period of two years, without a devaluation of the central parity. The interest rate criterion requires that 
interest rates on long term (ten year) government bonds not exceed the average of the three countries with the lowest 
inflation by more than 2 percentage points. The remaining criteria are: (1) that inflation should not exceed the average of 
that in the three best performing members of the EMU by more than 1.5% for one year; (2) that the fiscal deficit should 
not exceed 3% of GDP, and (3) that gross public debt should not exceed 60% of GDP. 
3 This is because of the government’s desire to maintain fiscal deficits above 3% of GDP.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
solution to these problems [Bratkowski and Rostowski, 2000]. At present, unilateral euroization 
seems unlikely to be adopted by any of the front runners for EU accession in 2004. Nevertheless, 
the problems we have identified remain, and in the absence of unilateral euroization, rapid 
adoption of the euro becomes the best remedy. 
The argument goes as follows: successful market reforms in the transition applicant 
countries (CEECs) and the perspective of EU accession leads to expectations of rapid economic 
growth. This in turn means that domestic residents wish to save less so as to smooth consumption, 
while foreign investors are willing to provide the financing needed to bridge the gap between 
savings and investment. The result is high capital account surpluses and their corollary high 
current account deficits. This, in turn, makes the CEECs very susceptible to capital inflow “stops” 
(reversals are not necessary) possibly leading to currency crises. In the case of Poland the current 
account deficit has been around 4-8% GDP over the last four years, which is usually considered 
well within the “danger zone” in which a currency “stop” may threaten due to fears of un-sustainability 
7 
by investors. 
We also argue that neither monetary nor fiscal policies can be counted on to keep these 
developments in check. Under a floating exchange rate regime, contractionary monetary policy will 
cause the domestic currency to appreciate, which may increase the CA deficit even further. In fact, 
very contractionary monetary policy has led to a significant reduction in the current account deficit 
in Poland over the last three years. Our argument is not that this cannot happen, merely that it 
cannot be counted on to happen. Furthermore, the reduction in the CA deficit has occurred at a 
very high cost in foregone output (growth had to fall sharply so as to reduce the motive for 
consumption smoothing). Expansionary monetary policy will lead to faster inflation and is likely to 
make the achievement of the Maastricht criteria impossible. Under a fixed exchange rate, 
monetary policy is not available as an instrument. Turning to fiscal policy (which can be used with 
either floating or fixed exchange rate regimes), this may also prove ineffective in improving the CA. 
A tightening of the fiscal stance may simply make foreign lenders more willing to lend to domestic 
private sector borrowers (we know that foreign investors do nowadays look at the overall 
4 
indebtedness of a country’s residents, both public and private) 
. In any event, even assuming a 
very high (one to one) correspondence between fiscal and current account changes, reducing a 
current account deficit by three percentage points would involve a politically improbably large fiscal 
adjustment. Expansionary fiscal policy would, in the traditional way, increase aggregate demand 
and thus tend to increase the CA deficit. 
Given the difficulty of reducing high CA deficits, many CEECs are very exposed to the risk 
of a sharp depreciation of their currency, commonly called a currency crisis. In countries with high 
levels of “liability euroization” [Calvo, 1998] such crises will lead to increases in the real debt 
burden and to depression (Indonesia post-1997 is a recent example). Many CEECs do not have a 
very high level of liability euroization (e.g. the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland) but even in these 
4 The US experience in the 1990s is instructive in this context.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
the need to offset the inflationary effect of a sharp depreciation through higher interest rates could 
well lead to a strongly recessionary effect. In the absence of unilateral euroization, rapid accession 
to EMU is the only way of escaping the choice between slow growth and high exposure to the risk 
of currency crisis (possibly followed by a prolonged period of slow growth, as occurred in the 
Czech Republic after the 1996 crisis)5. 
Thus, the period before CEECs have joined the EMU exposes potentially fast growing 
applicant countries to either a high risk of currency crisis, or forces them to grow far more slowly 
than they could. Since real convergence is one of the purposes of EU accession for the CEECs, 
the orthodox path is at variance with the ultimate goal, something which cannot be desirable. This 
is the crux of my argument for early EMU accession for CEECs. 
3. Optimum Currency Area Considerations 
Asymmetric shocks are a danger if a country and the monetary union it proposes joining are 
not part of an optimum currency area (OCA). Our view is that many CEECs satisfy the OCA 
conditions to the same degree as present members of EMU, or are very close to doing so. Since 
the CEECs are committed by their acceptance of the acquis communautaire to joining the EMU at 
some stage, what is good enough for the EMU's current members should be good enough for the 
CEECs. Even if some of the CEECs satisfy OCA conditions a little less than current EMU 
members, this merely exposes them to slightly higher risks from idiosyncratic shocks than current 
EMU members are exposed to. In making a choice on EMU accession, these slightly higher risks 
must be set against the very high costs described above of keeping one's national currency in the 
pre-accession period. 
The main reason we think that many CEECs are close to satisfying OCA requirements to a 
similar degree as current EMU members is their very high level of trade integration with EMU 
countries. Trade with other members of a currency area as a share of GDP is a good indication of 
the extent to which idiosyncratic shocks to a country's economy are likely to be amortized by its 
trade with the rest of the currency area. Table 1 shows that in 1999 all of the CEECs traded a 
higher share of their GDP with EMU countries than six of the current 12 EMU members (including 
the four largest Germany, France, Italy and Spain) in the year preceding the launching of the 
euro6. Trade with other members of a currency area as a share of total trade is a good indication of 
5 For a balanced assessment of the benefits of “hard peg” exchange rate regimes such as currency boards or 
dollarization see Ghosh et al. 2000. 
6 Most of the CEECs are small countries in terms of population and very small in terms of GDP, and small countries 
tend to have less diversified foreign trade. With the exception of Finland and Greece it is the larger EMU members that 
have lower levels of international trade (and therefore of EMU trade/GDP). They may, therefore offset their lower levels 
of trade with higher levels of diversification. However, it is not clear whether in CEECs the extent of diversification 
depends on GDP or population. Also, small countries may be less affected by a given asymmetric shock than large ones. 
Usually OCA theory assumes that all goods produced by a given sector are identical, irrespective of which country they 
were produced in. However, if there are specificities to the goods produced by different countries, each country will face 
a somewhat downward sloping demand curve for its exports. Such demand curves are likely to be more elastic in the 
case of smaller countries, since they supply a smaller share of the market for their own produce and that of close
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
the extent to which a country would be exposed to movements in the exchange rate of the 
common currency against the currencies of third countries: all of the CEECs traded a higher 
share of their total trade with EMU countries than two EMU members, and six of the CEECs traded 
a higher share of total trade with EMU than all but two current EMU members. Thus, if these 
ratios were the only criteria for satisfying OCA requirements, we could already conclude that many 
CEECs satisfy them7. 
It is argued [e.g. Fidrmuc and Schardax, 2000] that a higher share of intra-industry (II) trade 
within a currency area will lead to more synchronous business cycles, because industry specific 
supply or demand shocks are then more likely to be symmetric across countries. We therefore 
measure intra-industry trade with EMU/GDP for EMU members and applicant countries, and find 
that seven CEECs have a share of II trade with EMU/GDP which is higher than that of three EMU 
members. 
competitors. A negative asymmetric supply shock to one sector can be compensated by an expansion in a country’s 
other exports, and this is likely to be easier in the case a smaller country. Further empirical study of this question is 
needed. This problem is likely to have less relevance for the second measure of trade with EMU/total trade, where it is 
the largest CEECs which score highest, and they do so against almost all EMU members. 
7 CEECs’ scores on both measures would be somewhat higher if we were considering their exposure to shocks after 
all of them had joined EMU, since CEECs also trade with each other. I am grateful to a referee for this and the preceding 
point. 
9
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
Table 1. Degree of trade integration of CEECs with EMU compared to that of EMU countries 
EMU trade/GDP Intra-industry EMU 
trade/GDP(estimated)* 
EMU trade/total 
trade 
Belgium-Lux. 81.4 59 56.8 
Hungary 73.2 43 68.7 
Czech Republic 65.1 43 61.7 
Estonia 62.0 24 45.1 
Slovenia 61.8 37 67.1 
Slovakia 58.9 29 56.8 
Netherlands 48.8 38 47.9 
Ireland 44.2 22 33.2 
Bulgaria 39.3 13 54.2 
Portugal 38.5 19 67.1 
Austria 37.6 26 63.2 
Romania 34.7 10 66.4 
Latvia 30.9 7 46.8 
Poland 27.6 12 58.5 
Lithuania 26.5 6 36.0 
Spain 25.5 17 58.3 
France 21.7 18 51.9 
Germany 20.8 17 43.8 
Finland 20.7 10 34.0 
Italy 19.5 12 49.3 
Greece 17.4 5 53.4 
Source: Eurostat. Data is 1999 for accession countries and 1998 for EMU countries. 
* The shares of intra-industry (II) trade with EMU countries in GDP were estimated by taking the 1997 shares of II trade 
with the EU in Fidrmuc and Schardax [2000] and applying them to columns 2 and 4.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
Intra-industry trade is often classified as coming in one of two varieties. “Horizontal II trade” 
where almost identical goods are exchanged between two trading partners and “vertical II trade”, 
where the goods traded although they come under the same IST classification, differ in some 
important respects. It is usually assumed that a given amount “vertical intra-industry trade” assures 
less correlation between business cycles than the same amount of “horizontal intra-industry trade” 
of almost identical goods. This is not clear for two reasons: (1) if vertical trade depends on the 
supply of components by one side and of finished products by the other, then the two countries’ 
trade and output flows are likely to be very highly correlated indeed; (2) if vertical trade depends on 
exchanging similar products of differing quality, then if CEECs export the lower quality, cheaper 
variants, the income elasticity of demand for these is likely to be lower than for that of the 
corresponding EMU country products. In that case, aggregate or sectoral demand shocks in EMU 
economies are likely to affect CEECs less (falls in demand in the EMU will result in smaller falls in 
demand for CEECs exports, increases in demand in EMU will result in smaller increases in 
demand for CEEC exports). Thus thanks to “vertical II integration” of this kind, CEECs would be 
less affected by EMU demand shocks than equally II integrated EMU members 
11 
8 
. 
Moreover, it needs to be remembered that inter-industry trade also contributes to the 
convergence of business cycles in a currency area in the presence of aggregate shocks, be they 
supply or demand shocks. Thus, an increase in aggregate demand in EMU (but not in a particular 
CEEC) will spill over to the CEEC through increased demand for its exports, whatever the nature of 
these. And an asymmetric increase in aggregate costs, constituting a negative aggregate 
idiosyncratic supply shock (for instance as a result of increased energy prices which affects the 
CEEC more than EMU) will be partly cushioned by the smaller fall in EMU output and therefore 
demand9. 
Thus, it is hardly surprising that studies show that business cycles are more correlated 
between the advanced CEECs and Germany than between important EMU members. Boone and 
Maurel [1999], using de-trended unemployment, show that between 55% (Poland) and 86% 
(Hungary) of the advanced CEECs' cycles are explained by German cycles, whereas only 43% of 
Spanish and 18% of Italian cycles can be explained in this way. Fidrmuc and Schardax [2000] find 
that Poland's industrial production is as closely correlated with Germany's as is Austria's, and more 
so than those of Switzerland or Italy. Hungary and Slovenia's industrial outputs are more closely 
correlated with Germany's than is that of Italy, although those of the Czech Republic and Slovakia 
are far less correlated. 
More recent work by Karhonen and Fidrmuc [2001] improves on previous research by 
correlating EMU members’ and CEECs’ supply and demand shocks with those of the EMU as a 
8 On the reasonable assumption that any monetary policy response to such a shock for the EMU as a whole would 
not fully offset the effects of the shock. 
9 This is not to deny that the effects of such a shock might be even more muted if the CEEC’s currency could 
depreciate in such a situation. But we are not talking here of the choice between accession or not for the CEECs, but 
rather about whether they are less suited to accession than current EMU members. It is in this context that it is important 
to remember the role of inter-industry trade in muting the effects of shocks even in a currency union.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
whole10. The research shows that Hungary and Estonia seem to have least to loose by giving up 
their domestic currency, followed by Poland. The remaining CEECs either have very low 
correlations on both kinds of shock, or reasonable ones on one kind of shock but negative ones of 
a similar size on the other kind. Finally, Lithuania seems to have quite large negative correlations 
on both kinds of shock. However, much of the data used in the research comes from quite a few 
years ago, and since trade integration has proceeded apace, one may suppose that the correlation 
of CEECs’ shocks to EMU shocks (of both kinds) has increased. 
4. Is there a trade-off between Real and Nominal Convergence? 
It is clear that if countries were able to use national monetary policy to mitigate the effects of 
demand shocks (both negative and positive) and to use exchange rate policy to mitigate the effects 
of negative supply shocks, the path of GDP would be smoother (which would increase welfare 
somewhat), and the trend rate of growth might even be somewhat higher (less risk could 
encourage higher investment). 
Nevertheless, in general, catch-up is a pretty long-term phenomenon. Convergence 
between similar regions (US states, Japanese prefectures, European regions) proceeds at 
between 2% and 4% of the initial gap per annum [Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1998], which implies a 
half-life for the productivity gap of between 18 and 36 years. This is not a period over which the 
availability or otherwise of tools for flexible macro policy is likely to be decisive, even if one were to 
assume that macro policy smoothes fluctuations rather than augmenting them. 
But this is exactly where the “rub” lies. Monetary policy in robust young democracies with 
strong populist movements and limited human capital at the central bank can easily be pro-cyclical 
rather than anti-cyclical. Exchange rate movements can also be more of a “shock generator” than a 
shock absorber. A recent study [Habib 2002] finds that emerging market risk premia had a 
significant impact on exchange rates in the Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland during the period 
mid-1997 – mid- 2001, and on interest rates in the Czech Republic and Hungary. The volatility of 
the Czech and Polish exchange rates was also affected by “volatility contagion” coming from the 
emerging markets and there was also some “volatility contagion” of Czech interest rates. Csermely 
and Vonnak [2002] show that in Hungary the main reason for exchange rate and real interest rate 
movements has been changes in the risk premium Hungary has had to pay. These changes were 
due to world market increases in the premium required of emerging markets, an effect which would 
very largely disappear after EMU accession. 
Thus, I would argue that a monetary union which eliminated the risk of “emerging market 
contagion” and made a higher level of capital inflow safe, while at the same time providing a 
strong, externally guaranteed anti-inflationary framework (which might in turn encourage a higher 
10 The period covered depends on the availability of statistics, but for EMU countries it is for 1991 Q3 – 2000 Q3 or 
Q4. For CEECs it ends in 2000 Q4 (except for Slovakia, which ends in 2000 Q3) and begins as early as 1992 Q1 
(Romania) or as late as 1995 Q2 (Estonia, Hungary, Latvia and Lithuania).
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
level of domestic savings), might be expected to increase the long term rate of growth of the 
CEECs, rather than reduce it. 
Another argument which has been put forward is that CEECs need to run fiscal deficits in 
excess of the limit set by the Maastricht criterion and of the requirements of the Stability and 
Growth Pact. One justification for this view is that CEECs have poor physical infrastructures, that 
infrastructural investment can often boost economic growth, and that therefore a higher level of 
borrowing for public investment needs is justified in the case of CEECs [European Economy, 2002, 
Part V]. This is an argument for a certain kind of public expenditure rather than for financing that 
expenditure through borrowing. Such investment can also be financed by reducing other 
expenditure or increasing taxation. However, if we were to accept that borrowing was the best way 
of financing under the special circumstances which CEECs face, then rather than require that they 
choose between EMU membership and an optimal investment/financing mix, it is the Maastricht 
fiscal deficit criterion which should be altered11. Finally, it needs to be remembered that the 
requirements for fiscal prudence in the Treaties apply to non-EMU-participating EU member states 
as well12. 
5. Should rapid catch-up disqualify CEECs from EMU membership? 
Prominent ESCB officials have argued that not just nominal but also “real” convergence should 
be required of CEECs before they join EMU. Thus Hans Reckers, a Bundesbank Board member, 
has argued that CEECs should not be allowed to join EMU before they had achieved GDP per 
capita levels equivalent to 70% of the EU average [Financial Times, 26 Sept. 2000]. In fact, the 
value or stability of a currency has nothing to do with the income of the people who use it. Were 
this the case, West European currencies would have been much more stable in the 1970s than in 
the 1870s, whereas the opposite was the case13. 
11 A variant of this argument is that the EU itself requires various expenditures (for instance on environmental 
protection). These can be thought of as the “admission price” to the EU, which is worth paying because other aspects of 
accession will boost growth in such a way as to more than compensate for it. If the optimal method of financing these 
expenditures were borrowing, then rather than excluding the CEECs from EMU or forcing them to finance the admission 
price in a sub-optimal way, it would again be better to adjust the fiscal deficit criterion appropriately. 
12 All EU members are obliged to avoid excessive deficits (defined as those in excess of 3% of GDP) under the 
Maastricht Treaty, whether they are EMU members or not (the sole exception is once again the UK, which is only obliged 
to “attempt to avoid” an excessive deficit). Only EMU members can be fined for failing, but the legal requirement 
nevertheless remains. Furthermore, any member state which has an excessive deficit should be unable to obtain 
financing for any new projects under the EU Cohesion Fund, something which is of great importance for some CEECs, 
such as Poland [Ecofin 1999, Art 2, Para 4 and Art 6, Para 1]. Finally, all EU members are obliged to achieve “a fiscal 
position close to balance or in surplus” in accordance with the Stability and Growth Pact. Neither EMU nor non-EMU 
members can be fined for failing to fulfil this requirement either, although again both will loose access to the Cohesion 
Fund if they are found by the Council to be in breach of the Pact [Ecofin 1999, Art 1, Para 1]. 
13 It may be the case that a certain minimum level of income is required for a society to be able to support various 
sophisticated institutions, such as advanced forms of banking supervision, which may be helpful in protecting the political 
system from demands for inflationary finance. However, the more advanced CEECs already have such institutions in 
place. 
13
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
One argument that has been made is that the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson (H-B-S) effect 
means that CEECs are likely to have inflation rates 0%-2% above the average of the present EMU. 
On top of this there may be a demand effect resulting from the demand for non-tradeables being 
more income elastic than the demand for tradeables. As incomes rise, demand for non-tradeables 
rises faster, and unless productivity in the sector rises faster than in the whole economy (which is 
unlikely) non-tradeable prices will rise faster than tradeable prices. This phenomenon of “growth 
related relative price changes” also happens in current EMU members, but with faster income 
growth, it would presumably happen faster in CEECs. Adding faster growing countries with higher 
H-B-S and “demand effect” inflation to EMU must increase EMU inflation for any given degree of 
tightness of monetary policy it is argued. This seems to confront the EMU with an unpleasant 
dilemma: if the 2% ceiling on inflation is to be maintained for the EMU as a whole, interest rates will 
have to be higher and inflation in slow growing countries will need to be lower than at present. On 
the other hand, abandoning the 2% ceiling on inflation and allowing CEECs to have inflation rates 
well above the average of present EMU members (without reducing inflation in the current member 
states) would, it is claimed, undermine price stability in the whole zone. 
However, we have to take a number of other considerations into account. 
First, both the H-B-S effect proper and the demand effect, are as likely to occur in any 
rapidly growing economy as in a CEEC. Indeed, these effects have appeared quite strongly in 
Ireland, and to a lesser extent in Spain. They are not particularly the effect of catch-up, but simply 
of faster growth in the country concerned than the EMU on average. Thus, in order to prevent 
these effects from raising the average inflation rate in the EMU, members should not only refuse to 
accept CEECs, but they should also prevent current members from unilaterally undertaking 
structural reforms which would accelerate their growth14. Indeed, such a moratorium on reform 
would be particularly important since the CEECs represent only about 6.5% of EMU GDP. Thus, 
structural reforms that increased the growth rate by half in France and Italy (which together 
account for about 40% of EMU GDP) would be likely to have a much larger effect on EMU inflation 
than the accession of the CEECs. 
Therefore, unless the EMU wishes to remain a low growth zone, there can be no argument 
for excluding CEECs on such a basis. Indeed, it may be in recognition of this fact, that the 
Maastricht inflation criterion only needs to be fulfilled for one year. Although the reduction in 
inflation does need to be sustainable to satisfy the MIC, it is hard to imagine that expectations of 
“growth generated relative price changes” of the kind we are discussing after the conclusion of the 
“reference period”, could be held to violate this condition 
15 
. 
14 This would be particularly vital if countries are to avoid the “demand effect”. 
15 The “reference period” is that for which the conformity of a country with the criteria is assessed. What could be 
targeted by the sustainability requirement, would be various tricks such as “delaying” administered price or negotiated 
wage increases into “post-examination” years, or the fulfilment of the criterion thanks to an unsustainable nominal 
appreciation.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
Second, the CEECs are so small economically that their accession to EMU would not in fact 
require any change in the ECB’s inflation target, even if their “growth inflation” were relatively high. 
Thus, if CEEC inflation were an improbably high 3 percentage points above the average of current 
EMU members, this would mean an increase in enlarged EMU inflation of 0.2%, on the assumption 
that there were no offsetting effects. If France and Italy increased their long-term growth rate by 
half, the effect could be twice as large (if we assume that the inflation effect of a growth 
acceleration would be about half of the acceleration)16. Of course, even if the EMU-wide inflation 
target were adjusted upwards to take “growth inflation” in parts of the zone into account, there 
would not be any need to adjust the ECB’s monetary policy, and therefore there should not be any 
effect on the inflation rate in slow growing countries. 
Third, it is not in fact clear that either the H-B-S effect or the demand effect on non-tradeables 
prices in the faster growing countries, would in fact increase the inflation rate in EMU as a whole, 
once we take the impact of the higher growth on the nominal exchange rate of the euro into 
account. 
To see this, let us imagine that all EMU countries increase their growth rates by half. Would 
this lead to higher inflation within EMU? Assuming a stability- oriented monetary policy there are 
four ways of thinking about what would happen: 
·  To the extent that the higher growth was mainly generated by productivity increases in 
the traded sector (leading to an H-B-S effect), it would lead to a nominal appreciation 
of the euro against other currencies (we assume that the growth acceleration would be 
limited to the EMU). Domestic EMU prices of tradeables would fall (or fall more rapidly 
than they are in any case doing before the acceleration), compensating for the 
increase in the prices of non-tradeables and overall inflation would remain roughly 
constant17. 
·  To the extent to which the productivity growth occurred in non-tradeables, prices in this 
15 
sector would not rise in the first place18. 
·  To the extent to which we have a shift in the structure of demand from tradeables to 
non-tradeables, the euro zone’s balance of payments will improve ceteris paribus, 
leading to nominal appreciation of the euro, reducing the euro price of tradeables and 
thus compensating for the increase in non-tradeables prices19. The nominal 
appreciation also increases the marginal costs of producing tradeables in the EMU 
16 The same assumption applied to an excess of CEEC inflation of 3 percentage points above the EMU average 
inflation during 2000-2002 of 2.5%, would imply improbably high CEEC-wide growth rates of 7-8% per annum. 
17 As long as the domestic price elasticity of demand for both categories of goods (tradeables and non-tradeables) 
were the same. 
18 As long as the “structure of demand” effect on the demand for non-tradeables, resulting from the higher income 
the accelerated growth brings, is not larger than the growth in productivity in non-tradeables. 
19 The shift is in the structure of demand, so euro zone demand for tradeables is likely to grow in absolute terms. 
This is because the shift itself results from overall growth in the economy.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
relative to their world price (in dollars) and leads to resources being transferred inside 
the euro area to non-tradeables production. 
·  To the extent to which higher growth is balanced across sectors and there is no 
“demand effect”, prices of non-tradeables would not rise. However, higher growth 
would lead to pressure for higher real interest rates, which would also lead to nominal 
appreciation of the euro, which would cause the price of tradeables to decline, and 
overall inflation actually to fall. 
We can now consider what happens when the increase in growth is not EMU-wide. In the case 
when it is limited only to France and Italy, we would have weaker H-B-S or “demand effect” 
impacts on EMU-wide non-tradeables prices, more or less compensated by an equivalently weaker 
nominal appreciation of the euro. In the last case above, of “fully balanced” growth acceleration20 
in France and Italy, the real interest rate effect on tradeables prices would also be weaker than in 
the case of an equally large EMU-wide growth acceleration. 
In all of these scenarios the impact of such a “geographically unbalanced” growth acceleration 
on slower growing countries within EMU could nevertheless be quite unpleasant. Nominal 
appreciation of the euro would make some part of their tradeables output non-competitive at 
previously expected wages. We can see this if we initially assume the existence a single 
homogeneous tradeable good, for which world demand and world supply are perfectly elastic. This 
good is produced in different currency areas of the world according to production functions which 
differ between areas in the short term, and which generate increasing marginal costs in production. 
Area output is determined at the level at which the world price PT = MCT (domestic marginal cost). 
Resources (at least two factors) used in the production of the tradeable good are also used in the 
production of each area’s non-tradeable good. An increase in productivity in the production of the 
tradeable good in an area leads to an increase in area income and therefore to a change in the 
structure of demand. Assuming that this causes a greater increase in demand for the non-tradeable 
good in the area than for the tradeable, the price of the non-tradeable good will rise. This 
implies a real appreciation of the area’s currency, and in a non-inflationary environment, a nominal 
appreciation of the currency as well. Resources are then transferred from production of the 
tradeable to the non-tradeable good, which will additionally benefit the suppliers of the factors of 
production which are used more intensively in the production of the non-tradeable good (by the 
Rybczynski Theorem). 
“Regions” within the currency area (in the EMU case these could be countries such as 
Germany) in which productivity in the production of the tradeable good does not increase, will find 
that with nominal appreciation, domestic PT will fall. If domestic factor prices are flexible in such a 
region, this may cause a fall in nominal returns to factors of production which are relatively 
immobile out of the region (labour). If domestic factor prices are downwardly sticky, it will cause a 
fall in the output of the tradeable good in the region, and a reduction in employment. Thus, in order 
20 Fully balanced on both the demand and supply sides in both sectors.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
to avoid an increase in unemployment, expected wage increases might have to be foregone, or in 
the case of a relatively strong effect, real (or even nominal) wages might have to fall. This latter 
case is made the more likely by the low level of the ECB’s inflation target. 
Of course, on average even the inhabitants of slow growing EMU-members will benefit from 
faster growth anywhere in EMU (or indeed in the world). But these gains are likely to be unevenly 
distributed, with consumers of tradeable goods benefiting more than their producers. Thus, if we 
assume two tradeable goods are produced in the world, the currency area and the region we have 
been considering, and that productivity increases in the production of only one of the two tradeable 
goods in one of the regions of our area (but not in the other region or the rest of the world) then we 
get the following effects: (1) the area’s currency still appreciates; (2) in the region in which 
productivity has increased, resources are transferred from the production of the both tradeable 
goods to the non-tradeable good; (3) in the region in which productivity has not increased, there 
are two rounds of effects. The first round involves, as before, a reduction in the profit maximizing 
level of output of both tradeable goods at given factor prices. This requires either a fall in output 
and an increase in unemployment, or a fall in regional factor prices (relative to other regions and in 
nominal terms in a non-inflationary environment). The second round is a consequence of the 
overall currency area growth which has resulted from the increased productivity in the production 
of one of the tradeable goods in the other region of the area. This increases area demand for the 
other tradeable good (in whose production productivity has not increased), which increases 
demand for the factors used intensively in the production of this second tradeable good. The non-growing 
region should benefit from this, as it can increase exports of the second tradeable good to 
the growing region. Which of these two (first or second round) effects will predominate depends on 
the size of the slow growing region relative to the area and on the various elasticities involved. If 
factor prices are highly flexible downwards, then the region will not loose from the first round effect 
and will gain (albeit maybe only slightly) from the second round effect. 
In the case of CEEC accession and subsequent catch up, the direction of the effects on EMU 
slow growers would be the same as in the two cases examined above, but their magnitude is likely 
to be far smaller21. Thus, to summarise, the problem with CEEC accession to EMU is not that it will 
cause higher inflation in the whole euro zone, but rather that it may cause higher unemployment in 
slow growing countries such as Germany if they fail to increase the flexibility of their labour 
markets. 
21 Throughout the analysis we assume that the EMU does not face a downward sloping demand curve for its 
products. If it does, then productivity growth in the tradeables sector will lead to a nominal depreciation of the euro 
rather than an appreciation, whether it is balanced by equal productivity growth in non-tradeables or not. Nominal 
depreciation will put upward pressure on EMU inflation, which would need to be offset by higher nominal interest rates. If 
the tradeable goods produced by all EMU countries were homogeneous, producers in countries with slow productivity 
growth would be hit by competition from their neighbours and by higher real interest rates. To the extent to which the 
tradeables produced by different countries differed, producers in slower growing EMU countries would face only the 
second problem of higher real exchange rates. However, only areas with largely undiversified exports (such as raw 
materials producers) are likely to face demand curves which are downward sloping in the medium to long term (the time 
horizon which concerns us, as we are considering issues of differential growth rates). 
17
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
6. EMU institutional issues 
One reason for the Maastricht criteria for EMU accession is that EMU membership gives a 
country voting rights in the ECB and the Eurogroup of the Ecofin, and existing members would not 
want countries that have not demonstrated a commitment to low inflation to have such a vote. 
This is especially important in the case of the ECB. Although the ECB is supposed to make 
policy for the EMU as a whole, and therefore small economies should have a small weight in its 
considerations, each member of the interest rate setting ECB Governing Council (GC) has one 
vote at present. Apart from the six Executive Board (EB) members, the governors of all the NCBs 
are members of the Governing Council (giving a total of 18 members in the GC). This is a concern 
given that there are at present 12 potential new members from central, eastern and southern 
Europe. The Nice summit of December 2000 asked the ECB to make proposals for the 
restructuring of the Governing Council, and the ECB has now done this. 
The current member states of the EMU may be concerned that most of the potential new 
members have recent histories of far higher inflation than Western Europe. The fear could be that 
they would not have the same commitment to price stability as existing members. We have called 
this the “price-stability culture problem” [Bratkowski and Rostowski, 2002]. This problem is partly 
offset by the fact that central bankers are not as a breed prone to be inflation lovers. Second, all 
European System of Central Banks (ESCB) member banks now have to be highly independent for 
countries to qualify for EU, let alone EMU, accession. Indeed, the opposite fear has also been 
expressed: central bankers of CEECs might vote for short-term interest rates which kept inflation 
under control in their own countries, but were too high for core countries such as Germany. 
It has also been claimed that a Governing Council of 28 members would be far too large for 
serious discussion of the merits of monetary policy issues, which are best decided in a small 
group. It is said that in the ECB the tradition has been not to vote but to reach consensus and, it 
has been argued, reaching consensus in a group of twenty odd could be time consuming. Neither 
of these arguments seems to have any real merit. It is impossible to believe that consensus is at 
present arrived at in the 18 member Council through general discussion. What seems far more 
likely is that there is a smaller group with a clear view, and the rest go along with that. Compared to 
this, voting at least has the advantage of transparency. Moreover, the practical irrelevance of this 
argument has been demonstrated by the ECB’s own proposal for the reform, which foresees a GC 
of 21 voting members, and that all “National Central Bank Governors will continue to participate in 
the discussions of the Governing Council and attend the meetings…” - which implies up to 33 
participants [ECB, 2002]. 
Third, there is the serious matter of the unfairness of the present arrangement, which with its 
“one governor one vote” principle, favours small countries enormously, even if all the members of 
the executive board were drawn from large countries (which has not been the case). The 
admission of the present applicant countries merely exacerbates and highlights the problem. 
Nevertheless, this problem has now been largely solved by the ECB’s proposal for the reform of
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
the GC. This envisions 6 board members and 15 rotating country representatives. The 5 largest 
countries in terms of their shares of GDP will have 4 votes rotating among them22. The remaining 
countries will be divided into two groups as follows: the next largest one half of all the EMU-participating 
countries by GDP will have 8 votes to rotate amongst themselves, while all the 
19 
remaining countries will have 3 votes to rotate among themselves23. 
Membership in the eurogroup of the Ecofin Council of Finance Ministers may therefore be a 
more sensitive issue for some within the present EU. The European Commission (EC) and the 
twelve eurozone members have put forward proposals to the EU’s Constitutional Convention that 
the eurogroup should cease being an informal forum for discussion, and should be allowed to take 
binding executive decisions and pass legislation for the eurozone in the same way that the wider 
Ecofin does for the EU as whole [Financial Times June 10, 2003]. Indeed, one might expect that as 
regards macroeconomic issues the importance of the decisions that would be taken by the new 
“EMU-Ecofin” may prove to be even greater than those that are at present taken by the EU-wide 
Ecofin. Thus, it has been argued that, because it shares a single currency, the EMU needs a far 
greater degree of co-ordination of fiscal policies than does the EU as whole [Jacquet and Pisani- 
Ferry, 1999]. If CEECs were admitted to the EMU they would be entitled to participate in any 
strengthened “EMU-Ecofin”. Voting rights in Ecofin are roughly determined according to population, 
with an additional advantage being given to smaller countries24. There are also quirks in the 
allocation of voting rights. Thus, according to the rules adopted in the Treaty of Nice, Poland will 
have 27 votes compared to Germany’s 29 in all the “chambers” of the Council of the European 
Union”, despite having half of its population and a tenth of its national income25. These proportions 
would hold within any “EMU-Ecofin” as well. Thus it is not surprising that large and rich states 
within EMU might not be enthusiastic about poor states, that would contribute a small proportion of 
EMU GDP, joining EMU. 
Furthermore, the European Commission wants to have the “EMU-Ecofin” granted legislative 
and executive powers for two reasons. First, this may be the only way in which it would be possible 
to establish a central authority for making fiscal policy decisions which could be made binding on 
EMU member states, as these might be unwilling to see non-EMU members participating in such 
decisions within the wider, presently existing Ecofin [Financial Times, 2003]. Second, the 
constitutional principle in the EU is that the Council of the Union (of which Ecofin is an embodiment 
and an “EMU-Ecofin” would be) votes usually on proposals put before it by the Commission. 
22 The actual criterion is a composite indicator of each country’s supposed “representativeness” of the EMU 
economy as a whole. This indicator is composed in 5/6 of GDP and in 1/6 of the total assets of the aggregated balance 
sheet of monetary financial institutions (TABS-MFI). It is unlikely that TABS-MFI will significantly affect the allocation of 
Member States to the three groups. 
23 The third group will only come into existence when the number of states participating in EMU reaches 22. 
24 Since the voting rules are laid down by treaty it would be extremely hard to change them, so as to take account of 
GDP for example (as we suggested could be done in the case of the ECB by weighting votes by members shares in ECB 
capital). Such a move would also be seen as profoundly anti-democratic. 
25 Economics and Finance (Ecofin), Agriculture, Environment, Foreign Affairs, etc.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
Empowering “EMU-Ecofin” is therefore probably a necessary step for empowering the Commission 
itself in the sphere of EMU wide fiscal policy making, and therefore also fiscal policy co-ordination 
within EMU26. Thus, the expectation that CEECs will be admitted to the EMU and therefore to the 
“EMU-Ecofin” undermines the likelihood of large and rich EMU members agreeing to the creation 
of a powerful “EMU-Ecofin”. Knowledge of this may well lie at the root of Commission antipathy to 
EMU accession by CEECs27. However, this antipathy may decline once the Constitutional 
Convention finishes its work28. 
It should also be pointed out that whereas it is not in fact very dangerous, from the point of 
view of maintaining the commitment to price stability, to admit CEEC central bankers to the ECB 
Governing Council (given central bankers usual preferences), the same cannot necessarily be said 
as regards the effects on sound public finance of admitting CEEC finance ministers to a powerful 
“EMU-Ecofin”. The risk of doing so may be perceived as even greater if the Stability and Growth 
Pact is seriously watered down29. 
7. Conclusion 
Thus, the balance of the argument appears to lie definitely on the side of EMU accession when 
we look at it from the perspective of the CEECs’ interests. However, from the perspective of 
incumbent EMU members’ interests, although we can state that many of the arguments put 
forward against early EMU accession have been overblown, we cannot avoid the conclusion that 
the arguments are more finely balanced. This is especially the case when we analyse the situation 
of slow growing incumbents, who are also likely to be members of any “core” grouping, and that of 
a Commission that is eager to expand its powers into fiscal policy and fiscal policy co-ordination. 
Given the opposing interests between the two sides, and the fact that it is impossible to forbid EU 
members from joining EMU if they fulfil the Maastricht criteria, we can expect to see an intensified 
effort by the Commission and certain incumbent Member States to dissuade CEECs from joining 
26 The latter becomes all the more important as the “Stability and Growth Pact” which was supposed to provide a 
framework for such co-ordination comes under increasing strain. 
27 Strangely, Germany does not seem to oppose the strengthened role of the Commission in EMU fiscal policy, 
even though under the Nice Treaty the role of small countries in the Commission will be further dramatically 
strengthened, as not only will 9 new small countries join (and only 1 large country) join, but also all countries (large and 
small) will have only 1 Commissioner (until now large countries have had 2 Commissioners). Nevertheless, this 
increased influence may be offset by the influence of the large countries within the Commission’s bureaucracy, 
developing a more hierarchical structure for the Commission (with more power for its President and - probably large 
country - Vice-Presidents), and by ensuring the appointment of a large country Commissioner to the crucial Economics 
and Finance Directorate-General. I am grateful to Fabrizio Coricelli for these points. 
28 If the Convention rejects the Commission’s proposal. If instead the proposal is accepted, we may expect 
continued Commission opposition to CEEC accession to EMU until the new EU constitution, which would have to 
incorporate the proposal, is ratified. 
29 Recent suggestions for watering down the Stability and Growth Pact include: (1) using cyclically adjusted deficits; 
(2) excluding net investment spending from the deficit; (3) providing an allowance for low public debt/GDP levels; (4) 
being more lenient towards countries with low inflation; (5) excluding defence spending [The Business, 10/11 November 
2002, p.11, London].
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
EMU. There may even be an attempt to return to the idea of tightening the accession criteria, 
although this would be hard to square with the principle of “equality between present and future 
Member States”30. 
30 This principle is claimed to be the basis for the Commission’s opposition to unilateral euroization [European 
21 
Commission, 2000].
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 
REFERENCES 
Barro, R. and X.Sala-i-Martin [1998] Economic Growth, MIT Press, Cambridge Mass., pp. 583. 
Boone,L. and M.Maurel [1999] An Optimal Currency Area Perspective of the EU Enlargement to 
the CEECs, Discussion Paper 2119, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London. 
Bratkowski, A. and J.Rostowski [2000] “Unilateral Adoption of the Euro by EU Applicant Countries: 
the Macroeconomic Aspects”, in Ten Years of Transition, ed. L.Orlowski, Edward Elgar. 
Bratkowski, A. and J.Rostowski [2002] “The EU Attitude to Unilateral Euroization: 
Misunderstandings, real concerns and sub-optimal admission criteria”, Economics of Transition, 
Vol.10, No.2, pp.445-468. 
Calvo,G. [1999] On Dollarization available online at: http://www.bsos.umd.edu/econ/ciecpn5.pdf 
Csermely, A. and B.Vonnak [2002] “The role of the exchange rate in the transmission mechanism 
in Hungary”, paper presented at the research meeting on Monetary Policy Transmission in the 
Euro Area and the Accession Countries, 3 October 2002, National Bank of Hungary, Budapest. 
ECB [2002] “Governing Council Prepares for Enlargement”, Press Release, 20 December, 
European Central Bank, Frankfurt. 
Ecofin [1999] Council Regulation (EC) No 1264/1999, Official Journal of the European 
Communities, L161/57, 26.6.1999. 
European Commission [2000] “Exchange rate regimes for applicant countries”, Note for the 
Economic and Financial Committee, August, Brussels, mimeo, August 22, ECFIN/521/2000-EN, 
18pp. 
European Economy [June 2002] “Public Finances in EMU 2002”, 
http://europa.eu.int/comm/economy_finance/publications/european_economy/2002/ee402en.pdf 
Fidrmuc,J. and F.Schardax [2000] “More ‘Pre-Ins’ Ante Portas? Euro Area Enlargement, Optimum 
Currency Area, and Nominal Convergence”, Transition, 2000:2, pp28-47, Oesterrichisches 
Nazionalbank, Vienna. 
Financial Times, 26 September 2000, “EU hopefuls likely to suffer if Danes vote ‘no’”. 
Financial Times, 10 October 2002, p.2, “Commission warns applicants on EMU”. 
Financial Times, 10 June 2003, p.1 “Eurogroup seeks more economic control”. 
Financial Times, 14 January 2003, “EU reform heads Paris talks”. 
Habib, M. [2002] “Financial contagion, interest rates and the role of the exchange rate as a shock 
absorber in Central and Eastern Europe”, Discussion Paper No. 7, pp. 42, Bank of Finland 
Institute for Economies in Transition, BOFIT. 
Jacquet,P. and J.Pisani-Ferry [1999] “Economic Policy Co-ordination in the Eurozone: What has 
been achieved? What should be done?” www.sei.ac.uk/pdfs/wp40.pdf 
Karhonen,I. And J.Fidrmuc [2001] “Similarity of Demand and Supply Shocks Between the Euro 
Area and the Accession Countries” Focus on Transition, 2/2001, pp. 26-42, National Bank of 
Austria, Vienna.
Studies  Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 
Rostowski, J. [2000] “The approach to EU and EMU membership: the implications for 
macroeconomic policy in the applicant countries”, in The Eastern Enlargement of the European 
Union eds. M.Dabrowski and J.Rostowski, Kluwer Academic Publishers, New York. 
23 
Sulling,A. [2002] “Should Estonia Euroize”, Economics of Transition, Vol.10, No.2, pp.469-480.

More Related Content

PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 266 - Exchange Rate Regimes and the Nominal...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 270 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Alter...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 275 - The Stability and Growth Pact - Essen...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 450 - Macroeconomic Preconditions of the Re...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 260 - Do Acceding Countries Need Higher Fis...
PDF
Intellectual capital paradox
PDF
Macroeconomic Developments Report, December 2017
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 277 - Fiscal Costs of Delaying the EMU Acce...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 266 - Exchange Rate Regimes and the Nominal...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 270 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Alter...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 275 - The Stability and Growth Pact - Essen...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 450 - Macroeconomic Preconditions of the Re...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 260 - Do Acceding Countries Need Higher Fis...
Intellectual capital paradox
Macroeconomic Developments Report, December 2017
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 277 - Fiscal Costs of Delaying the EMU Acce...

What's hot (20)

PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 212 - Poland's Accession to the EMU
PDF
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 09/2017
PDF
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 12/2017
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 257 - Uneven Growth in a Monetary Union: on...
PDF
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 07/2017
PDF
Baltic Outlook January 2009
PDF
Macroeconomic Developments Report, June 2017
PDF
"Macroeconomic Developments Report", January 2014
PDF
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 08/2017
PDF
Macroeconomic Developments Report. June 2016
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 423 - Fiscal policy in the EU in the crisis...
PDF
PDF
Macroeconomic Developments Report. December 2014
PDF
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 12/2016
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 330 - Rethinking balance-of-payments constr...
PDF
Swedbank Economic Outlook - 2010, September 21
PDF
"Macroeconomic Developments Report", October 2013
PDF
Monthly Newsletter 5/2013
PPT
2006. Laszlo Akar. Medium-term Economic Trends and Perspectives for Hungary. ...
PPT
Financila markets in russia
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 212 - Poland's Accession to the EMU
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 09/2017
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 12/2017
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 257 - Uneven Growth in a Monetary Union: on...
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 07/2017
Baltic Outlook January 2009
Macroeconomic Developments Report, June 2017
"Macroeconomic Developments Report", January 2014
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 08/2017
Macroeconomic Developments Report. June 2016
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 423 - Fiscal policy in the EU in the crisis...
Macroeconomic Developments Report. December 2014
Latvijas Banka Monthly Newsletter 12/2016
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 330 - Rethinking balance-of-payments constr...
Swedbank Economic Outlook - 2010, September 21
"Macroeconomic Developments Report", October 2013
Monthly Newsletter 5/2013
2006. Laszlo Akar. Medium-term Economic Trends and Perspectives for Hungary. ...
Financila markets in russia
Ad

Viewers also liked (20)

PPS
Cosas de cementerios
PDF
neotvlab2014-diseñar el medio-bertolotti
PDF
Logical Standby
PPTX
Almum de imágenes
PDF
Sintesis informativa 20 03 2013
PPTX
Cloud services
DOCX
Pengaruh deformasi dingin trhdp kekerasan a'lim abror (13504241062)
PDF
Horarios empleados semana 46
PPTX
2 programa de_radio_de_musica_(10_minutos)_36f (1)
PDF
Learninig Analytics Special Track: A cluster-based analisys to diagnose stude...
PDF
Summer 2009 10 Common Slot Timetable
PPT
Langkah ppm
DOCX
Kirsten delay reference 2014
PPS
Subprime Primer
PPTX
PDF
Convocatoria para proeever el cargo de secretario (a) general del concejo mun...
DOCX
Native american lesson plan
PDF
IGDD n.209 _Il guizzo e la griglia_ Antonio Macchi Cassia
PDF
청년 체인지메이커 아카데미 ㅡ 3강 오가니제이션 요리, 커뮤니티 기반의 신사업 구상 - 한영미 외
DOC
Cosas de cementerios
neotvlab2014-diseñar el medio-bertolotti
Logical Standby
Almum de imágenes
Sintesis informativa 20 03 2013
Cloud services
Pengaruh deformasi dingin trhdp kekerasan a'lim abror (13504241062)
Horarios empleados semana 46
2 programa de_radio_de_musica_(10_minutos)_36f (1)
Learninig Analytics Special Track: A cluster-based analisys to diagnose stude...
Summer 2009 10 Common Slot Timetable
Langkah ppm
Kirsten delay reference 2014
Subprime Primer
Convocatoria para proeever el cargo de secretario (a) general del concejo mun...
Native american lesson plan
IGDD n.209 _Il guizzo e la griglia_ Antonio Macchi Cassia
청년 체인지메이커 아카데미 ㅡ 3강 오가니제이션 요리, 커뮤니티 기반의 신사업 구상 - 한영미 외
Ad

Similar to CASE Network Studies and Analyses 253 - When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? (20)

PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 443 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy Determinan...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 258 - Exchange Rate Variability and Foreign...
DOC
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 290 - A Strategy for EMU Enlargement
PDF
CASE Network E-briefs 9.2009 - The Baltic Conundrum
PDF
A minimal moral hazard central stabilization capacity for the EMU based on wo...
PDF
CASE Network E-brief 9.2010 - Euro Crisis or Debt Crisis?
PDF
Pub 4542 financial_transaction_tax
PDF
Pub 4542 financial_transaction_tax
PDF
20130905 sapirwolff final
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 412 - The Sustainability of Public Finances...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 286 - New Member States' Trading Potential ...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 262
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 262 - ECB Decision-making and the Status of...
DOCX
60 sergey savchenko1 olena sukach2 volume 29 (5),
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 200 - Institutional arrangements of Currenc...
PDF
Democracy and Legitimacy in an Economic Union
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 466 - Fiscal or Bailout Union: Where Is the...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 269 - The EMU Enlargement and the Choice of...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 256 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Spain...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 443 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy Determinan...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 258 - Exchange Rate Variability and Foreign...
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 290 - A Strategy for EMU Enlargement
CASE Network E-briefs 9.2009 - The Baltic Conundrum
A minimal moral hazard central stabilization capacity for the EMU based on wo...
CASE Network E-brief 9.2010 - Euro Crisis or Debt Crisis?
Pub 4542 financial_transaction_tax
Pub 4542 financial_transaction_tax
20130905 sapirwolff final
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 412 - The Sustainability of Public Finances...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 286 - New Member States' Trading Potential ...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 262
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 262 - ECB Decision-making and the Status of...
60 sergey savchenko1 olena sukach2 volume 29 (5),
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 200 - Institutional arrangements of Currenc...
Democracy and Legitimacy in an Economic Union
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 466 - Fiscal or Bailout Union: Where Is the...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 269 - The EMU Enlargement and the Choice of...

More from CASE Center for Social and Economic Research (20)

PDF
In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...
PDF
Praca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencje
PDF
The retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economy
PDF
Problems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economy
PDF
Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...
PDF
Informal employment and wages in Poland
PDF
The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...
PDF
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final Report
PDF
Increasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to Go
PDF
Is the economy doomed to a long recession?
PDF
mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...
PDF
Nasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii Europejskiej
PDF
Our Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European Union
PDF
The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....
PDF
The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...
PDF
30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus
PDF
Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?
PDF
Estonian corporate tax: Lessons for Poland
PDF
Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...
PDF
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final Report
In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...
Praca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencje
The retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economy
Problems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economy
Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...
Informal employment and wages in Poland
The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final Report
Increasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to Go
Is the economy doomed to a long recession?
mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...
Nasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii Europejskiej
Our Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European Union
The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....
The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...
30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus
Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?
Estonian corporate tax: Lessons for Poland
Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final Report

Recently uploaded (20)

PPT
features and equilibrium under MONOPOLY 17.11.20.ppt
PDF
3CMT J.AFABLE Flexible-Learning ENTREPRENEURIAL MANAGEMENT.pdf
PDF
Lundin Gold Corporate Presentation August 2025
PPTX
Group Presentation Development Econ and Envi..pptx
PPTX
PROFITS AND GAINS OF BUSINESS OR PROFESSION 2024.pptx
PDF
Truxton Capital: Middle Market Quarterly Review - August 2025
PPTX
ML Credit Scoring of Thin-File Borrowers
PPTX
Q1 PE AND HEALTH 5 WEEK 5 DAY 1 powerpoint template
PPTX
Machine Learning (ML) is a branch of Artificial Intelligence (AI)
PPTX
Grp C.ppt presentation.pptx for Economics
PPTX
General-Characteristics-of-Microorganisms.pptx
PDF
The Right Social Media Strategy Can Transform Your Business
PDF
Unkipdf.pdf of work in the economy we are
DOCX
BUSINESS PERFORMANCE SITUATION AND PERFORMANCE EVALUATION OF FELIX HOTEL IN H...
PDF
How to join illuminati agent in Uganda Kampala call 0782561496/0756664682
PDF
Buy Verified Payoneer Accounts for Sale - Secure and.pdf
PPTX
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
PDF
Pension Trustee Training (1).pdf From Salih Shah
PDF
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
PPTX
INDIAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM (Financial institutions, Financial Markets & Services)
features and equilibrium under MONOPOLY 17.11.20.ppt
3CMT J.AFABLE Flexible-Learning ENTREPRENEURIAL MANAGEMENT.pdf
Lundin Gold Corporate Presentation August 2025
Group Presentation Development Econ and Envi..pptx
PROFITS AND GAINS OF BUSINESS OR PROFESSION 2024.pptx
Truxton Capital: Middle Market Quarterly Review - August 2025
ML Credit Scoring of Thin-File Borrowers
Q1 PE AND HEALTH 5 WEEK 5 DAY 1 powerpoint template
Machine Learning (ML) is a branch of Artificial Intelligence (AI)
Grp C.ppt presentation.pptx for Economics
General-Characteristics-of-Microorganisms.pptx
The Right Social Media Strategy Can Transform Your Business
Unkipdf.pdf of work in the economy we are
BUSINESS PERFORMANCE SITUATION AND PERFORMANCE EVALUATION OF FELIX HOTEL IN H...
How to join illuminati agent in Uganda Kampala call 0782561496/0756664682
Buy Verified Payoneer Accounts for Sale - Secure and.pdf
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
Pension Trustee Training (1).pdf From Salih Shah
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
INDIAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM (Financial institutions, Financial Markets & Services)

CASE Network Studies and Analyses 253 - When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU?

  • 1. S t u d i a i A n a l i z y S t u d i e s & A n a l y s e s C e n t r u m A n a l i z S p o ł e c z n o – E k o n o m i c z n y c h C e n t e r f o r S o c i a l a n d E c o n o m i c R e s e a r c h 2 5 3 Jacek Rostowski When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? Wa r s a w , O c t o b e r 2 0 0 3
  • 2. Materials published here have a working paper character. They can be subject to further publication. The views and opinions expressed here reflect the author(s) point of view and not necessarily those of the CASE. The paper was prepared within the research project entitled: Strategie przystapienia do Europejskiej Unii Gospodarczej i Walutowej: analiza porównawcza moliwych scenariuszy (Strategies for Joining the European Economic and Monetary Union: a Comparative Analysis of Possible Scenarios) financed by the State Committee for Scientific Research. Keywords: currency unions, currency areas, monetary policy, economic growth, economic union, monetary union, European Union, enlargement, © CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw 2003 Graphic Design: Agnieszka Natalia Bury ISSN 1506-1701, ISBN: 83-7178-308-6 Publisher: CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research 12 Sienkiewicza, 00-944 Warsaw, Poland tel.: (48 22) 622 66 27, 828 61 33, fax: (48 22) 828 60 69 e-mail: case@case.com.pl http://www.case.com.pl/
  • 3. Contents Abstract ..............................................................................................................................5 1. Introduction....................................................................................................................6 2. Risks of Macroeconomic Instability Outside the EMU...............................................6 3. Optimum Currency Area Considerations ....................................................................8 4. Is there a trade-off between Real and Nominal Convergence? ...............................12 5. Should rapid catch-up disqualify CEECs from EMU membership?........................13 6. EMU institutional issues .............................................................................................18 7. Conclusion ...................................................................................................................20 REFERENCES ..................................................................................................................22
  • 4. Jacek Rostowski Jacek Rostowski is Professor of Economics at the Central European University, Budapest, a trustee of the CASE Foundation, Warsaw, an adviser to the Governor of the National Bank of Poland, and an associate of the International Economics Programme at the Royal Institute for International Affairs.
  • 5. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski 5 Abstract The paper first considers why central European countries wish to join EMU soon. The main reasons are the risk of macroeconomic instability they face outside the euro zone if they wish to grow quickly. At the same time, Central Europe is highly integrated as regards trade with EMU, so it is little exposed to asymmetric shocks that would require a realignment of exchange rates. Finally, it is argued that there is no cost in terms of slower growth from EMU accession, so that there is no trade-off, as has been claimed, between nominal convergence to EMU and real convergence to EU average GDP levels. Second, the paper assesses whether Central European accession to EMU would be disadvantageous to current members. It concludes that accession cannot increase inflationary pressure on existing EMU members, as has been claimed, but that slow growing members of EMU might suffer increased unemployment, unless they increase the flexibility of their labour markets. Incumbent members may also be unwilling to share power with Central Europeans in EMU institutions.
  • 6. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 1. Introduction1 With EU accession now assured, the candidate countries are actively considering when to join the EMU. Unlike Britain and Denmark the new members will not have an “opt-out” - the right to remain outside the EMU indefinitely. The question is therefore only one of timing. A number of countries have already declared that they want to join EMU as soon as possible after EU accession. The costs of such a move are minimal for Estonia and Lithuania, which already have their currencies “hard-pegged” to the euro through a currency board [Sulling 2002]2. Hungary and Poland have also announced that their aim is to satisfy the Maastricht criteria for EMU accession in 2005, which would allow them to join during 2006 or January 2007. On the other hand, the Czech government has declared that it does not foresee early EMU accession3. The European Commission [Financial Times, 10 Oct. 2002] and the Bundesbank [Bratkowski and Rostowski 2002, Financial Times, 26 Sept. 2000] have also made clear their lack of enthusiasm for new members joining the EMU quickly. What are the reasons pushing many applicant countries towards early EMU entry, and why are some key players in Western Europe opposed to it? We divide the discussion into seven sections. Section 2 describes the macroeconomic risks to which central European countries are exposed while they remain outside the EMU. Section 3 assesses the standard optimum currency area (OCA) criteria for whether these countries are ready for EMU accession. Section 4 considers whether there is a trade-off for central Europeans between joining EMU and real economic convergence with the EU. Section 5 addresses some arguments which claim that Central European accession to EMU would be bad for current EMU members. Section 6 considers institutional issues and Section 7 concludes. 2. Risks of Macroeconomic Instability Outside the EMU In earlier papers we have analysed the difficulties faced by the more advanced central and east European countries (CEECs) in achieving macroeconomic stability in the run-up to EU and EMU membership [Rostowski 2000], and have presented the case for unilateral euroization as a 1 I wish to thank a referee for very useful comments. 2 Estonia has argued that it should be able to join EMU earlier than 2006, since it has satisfied the Maastricht Treaty’s exchange rate criterion ever since the ratification of the Treaty and the interest rate criterion for many years. These are the two criteria which need to be satisfied for two years. The exchange rate criterion requires that the value of the applicant country’s currency remain within the range required by the ERM2 relative to the central parity (plus or minus 15%) for a period of two years, without a devaluation of the central parity. The interest rate criterion requires that interest rates on long term (ten year) government bonds not exceed the average of the three countries with the lowest inflation by more than 2 percentage points. The remaining criteria are: (1) that inflation should not exceed the average of that in the three best performing members of the EMU by more than 1.5% for one year; (2) that the fiscal deficit should not exceed 3% of GDP, and (3) that gross public debt should not exceed 60% of GDP. 3 This is because of the government’s desire to maintain fiscal deficits above 3% of GDP.
  • 7. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski solution to these problems [Bratkowski and Rostowski, 2000]. At present, unilateral euroization seems unlikely to be adopted by any of the front runners for EU accession in 2004. Nevertheless, the problems we have identified remain, and in the absence of unilateral euroization, rapid adoption of the euro becomes the best remedy. The argument goes as follows: successful market reforms in the transition applicant countries (CEECs) and the perspective of EU accession leads to expectations of rapid economic growth. This in turn means that domestic residents wish to save less so as to smooth consumption, while foreign investors are willing to provide the financing needed to bridge the gap between savings and investment. The result is high capital account surpluses and their corollary high current account deficits. This, in turn, makes the CEECs very susceptible to capital inflow “stops” (reversals are not necessary) possibly leading to currency crises. In the case of Poland the current account deficit has been around 4-8% GDP over the last four years, which is usually considered well within the “danger zone” in which a currency “stop” may threaten due to fears of un-sustainability 7 by investors. We also argue that neither monetary nor fiscal policies can be counted on to keep these developments in check. Under a floating exchange rate regime, contractionary monetary policy will cause the domestic currency to appreciate, which may increase the CA deficit even further. In fact, very contractionary monetary policy has led to a significant reduction in the current account deficit in Poland over the last three years. Our argument is not that this cannot happen, merely that it cannot be counted on to happen. Furthermore, the reduction in the CA deficit has occurred at a very high cost in foregone output (growth had to fall sharply so as to reduce the motive for consumption smoothing). Expansionary monetary policy will lead to faster inflation and is likely to make the achievement of the Maastricht criteria impossible. Under a fixed exchange rate, monetary policy is not available as an instrument. Turning to fiscal policy (which can be used with either floating or fixed exchange rate regimes), this may also prove ineffective in improving the CA. A tightening of the fiscal stance may simply make foreign lenders more willing to lend to domestic private sector borrowers (we know that foreign investors do nowadays look at the overall 4 indebtedness of a country’s residents, both public and private) . In any event, even assuming a very high (one to one) correspondence between fiscal and current account changes, reducing a current account deficit by three percentage points would involve a politically improbably large fiscal adjustment. Expansionary fiscal policy would, in the traditional way, increase aggregate demand and thus tend to increase the CA deficit. Given the difficulty of reducing high CA deficits, many CEECs are very exposed to the risk of a sharp depreciation of their currency, commonly called a currency crisis. In countries with high levels of “liability euroization” [Calvo, 1998] such crises will lead to increases in the real debt burden and to depression (Indonesia post-1997 is a recent example). Many CEECs do not have a very high level of liability euroization (e.g. the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland) but even in these 4 The US experience in the 1990s is instructive in this context.
  • 8. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? the need to offset the inflationary effect of a sharp depreciation through higher interest rates could well lead to a strongly recessionary effect. In the absence of unilateral euroization, rapid accession to EMU is the only way of escaping the choice between slow growth and high exposure to the risk of currency crisis (possibly followed by a prolonged period of slow growth, as occurred in the Czech Republic after the 1996 crisis)5. Thus, the period before CEECs have joined the EMU exposes potentially fast growing applicant countries to either a high risk of currency crisis, or forces them to grow far more slowly than they could. Since real convergence is one of the purposes of EU accession for the CEECs, the orthodox path is at variance with the ultimate goal, something which cannot be desirable. This is the crux of my argument for early EMU accession for CEECs. 3. Optimum Currency Area Considerations Asymmetric shocks are a danger if a country and the monetary union it proposes joining are not part of an optimum currency area (OCA). Our view is that many CEECs satisfy the OCA conditions to the same degree as present members of EMU, or are very close to doing so. Since the CEECs are committed by their acceptance of the acquis communautaire to joining the EMU at some stage, what is good enough for the EMU's current members should be good enough for the CEECs. Even if some of the CEECs satisfy OCA conditions a little less than current EMU members, this merely exposes them to slightly higher risks from idiosyncratic shocks than current EMU members are exposed to. In making a choice on EMU accession, these slightly higher risks must be set against the very high costs described above of keeping one's national currency in the pre-accession period. The main reason we think that many CEECs are close to satisfying OCA requirements to a similar degree as current EMU members is their very high level of trade integration with EMU countries. Trade with other members of a currency area as a share of GDP is a good indication of the extent to which idiosyncratic shocks to a country's economy are likely to be amortized by its trade with the rest of the currency area. Table 1 shows that in 1999 all of the CEECs traded a higher share of their GDP with EMU countries than six of the current 12 EMU members (including the four largest Germany, France, Italy and Spain) in the year preceding the launching of the euro6. Trade with other members of a currency area as a share of total trade is a good indication of 5 For a balanced assessment of the benefits of “hard peg” exchange rate regimes such as currency boards or dollarization see Ghosh et al. 2000. 6 Most of the CEECs are small countries in terms of population and very small in terms of GDP, and small countries tend to have less diversified foreign trade. With the exception of Finland and Greece it is the larger EMU members that have lower levels of international trade (and therefore of EMU trade/GDP). They may, therefore offset their lower levels of trade with higher levels of diversification. However, it is not clear whether in CEECs the extent of diversification depends on GDP or population. Also, small countries may be less affected by a given asymmetric shock than large ones. Usually OCA theory assumes that all goods produced by a given sector are identical, irrespective of which country they were produced in. However, if there are specificities to the goods produced by different countries, each country will face a somewhat downward sloping demand curve for its exports. Such demand curves are likely to be more elastic in the case of smaller countries, since they supply a smaller share of the market for their own produce and that of close
  • 9. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski the extent to which a country would be exposed to movements in the exchange rate of the common currency against the currencies of third countries: all of the CEECs traded a higher share of their total trade with EMU countries than two EMU members, and six of the CEECs traded a higher share of total trade with EMU than all but two current EMU members. Thus, if these ratios were the only criteria for satisfying OCA requirements, we could already conclude that many CEECs satisfy them7. It is argued [e.g. Fidrmuc and Schardax, 2000] that a higher share of intra-industry (II) trade within a currency area will lead to more synchronous business cycles, because industry specific supply or demand shocks are then more likely to be symmetric across countries. We therefore measure intra-industry trade with EMU/GDP for EMU members and applicant countries, and find that seven CEECs have a share of II trade with EMU/GDP which is higher than that of three EMU members. competitors. A negative asymmetric supply shock to one sector can be compensated by an expansion in a country’s other exports, and this is likely to be easier in the case a smaller country. Further empirical study of this question is needed. This problem is likely to have less relevance for the second measure of trade with EMU/total trade, where it is the largest CEECs which score highest, and they do so against almost all EMU members. 7 CEECs’ scores on both measures would be somewhat higher if we were considering their exposure to shocks after all of them had joined EMU, since CEECs also trade with each other. I am grateful to a referee for this and the preceding point. 9
  • 10. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? Table 1. Degree of trade integration of CEECs with EMU compared to that of EMU countries EMU trade/GDP Intra-industry EMU trade/GDP(estimated)* EMU trade/total trade Belgium-Lux. 81.4 59 56.8 Hungary 73.2 43 68.7 Czech Republic 65.1 43 61.7 Estonia 62.0 24 45.1 Slovenia 61.8 37 67.1 Slovakia 58.9 29 56.8 Netherlands 48.8 38 47.9 Ireland 44.2 22 33.2 Bulgaria 39.3 13 54.2 Portugal 38.5 19 67.1 Austria 37.6 26 63.2 Romania 34.7 10 66.4 Latvia 30.9 7 46.8 Poland 27.6 12 58.5 Lithuania 26.5 6 36.0 Spain 25.5 17 58.3 France 21.7 18 51.9 Germany 20.8 17 43.8 Finland 20.7 10 34.0 Italy 19.5 12 49.3 Greece 17.4 5 53.4 Source: Eurostat. Data is 1999 for accession countries and 1998 for EMU countries. * The shares of intra-industry (II) trade with EMU countries in GDP were estimated by taking the 1997 shares of II trade with the EU in Fidrmuc and Schardax [2000] and applying them to columns 2 and 4.
  • 11. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski Intra-industry trade is often classified as coming in one of two varieties. “Horizontal II trade” where almost identical goods are exchanged between two trading partners and “vertical II trade”, where the goods traded although they come under the same IST classification, differ in some important respects. It is usually assumed that a given amount “vertical intra-industry trade” assures less correlation between business cycles than the same amount of “horizontal intra-industry trade” of almost identical goods. This is not clear for two reasons: (1) if vertical trade depends on the supply of components by one side and of finished products by the other, then the two countries’ trade and output flows are likely to be very highly correlated indeed; (2) if vertical trade depends on exchanging similar products of differing quality, then if CEECs export the lower quality, cheaper variants, the income elasticity of demand for these is likely to be lower than for that of the corresponding EMU country products. In that case, aggregate or sectoral demand shocks in EMU economies are likely to affect CEECs less (falls in demand in the EMU will result in smaller falls in demand for CEECs exports, increases in demand in EMU will result in smaller increases in demand for CEEC exports). Thus thanks to “vertical II integration” of this kind, CEECs would be less affected by EMU demand shocks than equally II integrated EMU members 11 8 . Moreover, it needs to be remembered that inter-industry trade also contributes to the convergence of business cycles in a currency area in the presence of aggregate shocks, be they supply or demand shocks. Thus, an increase in aggregate demand in EMU (but not in a particular CEEC) will spill over to the CEEC through increased demand for its exports, whatever the nature of these. And an asymmetric increase in aggregate costs, constituting a negative aggregate idiosyncratic supply shock (for instance as a result of increased energy prices which affects the CEEC more than EMU) will be partly cushioned by the smaller fall in EMU output and therefore demand9. Thus, it is hardly surprising that studies show that business cycles are more correlated between the advanced CEECs and Germany than between important EMU members. Boone and Maurel [1999], using de-trended unemployment, show that between 55% (Poland) and 86% (Hungary) of the advanced CEECs' cycles are explained by German cycles, whereas only 43% of Spanish and 18% of Italian cycles can be explained in this way. Fidrmuc and Schardax [2000] find that Poland's industrial production is as closely correlated with Germany's as is Austria's, and more so than those of Switzerland or Italy. Hungary and Slovenia's industrial outputs are more closely correlated with Germany's than is that of Italy, although those of the Czech Republic and Slovakia are far less correlated. More recent work by Karhonen and Fidrmuc [2001] improves on previous research by correlating EMU members’ and CEECs’ supply and demand shocks with those of the EMU as a 8 On the reasonable assumption that any monetary policy response to such a shock for the EMU as a whole would not fully offset the effects of the shock. 9 This is not to deny that the effects of such a shock might be even more muted if the CEEC’s currency could depreciate in such a situation. But we are not talking here of the choice between accession or not for the CEECs, but rather about whether they are less suited to accession than current EMU members. It is in this context that it is important to remember the role of inter-industry trade in muting the effects of shocks even in a currency union.
  • 12. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? whole10. The research shows that Hungary and Estonia seem to have least to loose by giving up their domestic currency, followed by Poland. The remaining CEECs either have very low correlations on both kinds of shock, or reasonable ones on one kind of shock but negative ones of a similar size on the other kind. Finally, Lithuania seems to have quite large negative correlations on both kinds of shock. However, much of the data used in the research comes from quite a few years ago, and since trade integration has proceeded apace, one may suppose that the correlation of CEECs’ shocks to EMU shocks (of both kinds) has increased. 4. Is there a trade-off between Real and Nominal Convergence? It is clear that if countries were able to use national monetary policy to mitigate the effects of demand shocks (both negative and positive) and to use exchange rate policy to mitigate the effects of negative supply shocks, the path of GDP would be smoother (which would increase welfare somewhat), and the trend rate of growth might even be somewhat higher (less risk could encourage higher investment). Nevertheless, in general, catch-up is a pretty long-term phenomenon. Convergence between similar regions (US states, Japanese prefectures, European regions) proceeds at between 2% and 4% of the initial gap per annum [Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1998], which implies a half-life for the productivity gap of between 18 and 36 years. This is not a period over which the availability or otherwise of tools for flexible macro policy is likely to be decisive, even if one were to assume that macro policy smoothes fluctuations rather than augmenting them. But this is exactly where the “rub” lies. Monetary policy in robust young democracies with strong populist movements and limited human capital at the central bank can easily be pro-cyclical rather than anti-cyclical. Exchange rate movements can also be more of a “shock generator” than a shock absorber. A recent study [Habib 2002] finds that emerging market risk premia had a significant impact on exchange rates in the Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland during the period mid-1997 – mid- 2001, and on interest rates in the Czech Republic and Hungary. The volatility of the Czech and Polish exchange rates was also affected by “volatility contagion” coming from the emerging markets and there was also some “volatility contagion” of Czech interest rates. Csermely and Vonnak [2002] show that in Hungary the main reason for exchange rate and real interest rate movements has been changes in the risk premium Hungary has had to pay. These changes were due to world market increases in the premium required of emerging markets, an effect which would very largely disappear after EMU accession. Thus, I would argue that a monetary union which eliminated the risk of “emerging market contagion” and made a higher level of capital inflow safe, while at the same time providing a strong, externally guaranteed anti-inflationary framework (which might in turn encourage a higher 10 The period covered depends on the availability of statistics, but for EMU countries it is for 1991 Q3 – 2000 Q3 or Q4. For CEECs it ends in 2000 Q4 (except for Slovakia, which ends in 2000 Q3) and begins as early as 1992 Q1 (Romania) or as late as 1995 Q2 (Estonia, Hungary, Latvia and Lithuania).
  • 13. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski level of domestic savings), might be expected to increase the long term rate of growth of the CEECs, rather than reduce it. Another argument which has been put forward is that CEECs need to run fiscal deficits in excess of the limit set by the Maastricht criterion and of the requirements of the Stability and Growth Pact. One justification for this view is that CEECs have poor physical infrastructures, that infrastructural investment can often boost economic growth, and that therefore a higher level of borrowing for public investment needs is justified in the case of CEECs [European Economy, 2002, Part V]. This is an argument for a certain kind of public expenditure rather than for financing that expenditure through borrowing. Such investment can also be financed by reducing other expenditure or increasing taxation. However, if we were to accept that borrowing was the best way of financing under the special circumstances which CEECs face, then rather than require that they choose between EMU membership and an optimal investment/financing mix, it is the Maastricht fiscal deficit criterion which should be altered11. Finally, it needs to be remembered that the requirements for fiscal prudence in the Treaties apply to non-EMU-participating EU member states as well12. 5. Should rapid catch-up disqualify CEECs from EMU membership? Prominent ESCB officials have argued that not just nominal but also “real” convergence should be required of CEECs before they join EMU. Thus Hans Reckers, a Bundesbank Board member, has argued that CEECs should not be allowed to join EMU before they had achieved GDP per capita levels equivalent to 70% of the EU average [Financial Times, 26 Sept. 2000]. In fact, the value or stability of a currency has nothing to do with the income of the people who use it. Were this the case, West European currencies would have been much more stable in the 1970s than in the 1870s, whereas the opposite was the case13. 11 A variant of this argument is that the EU itself requires various expenditures (for instance on environmental protection). These can be thought of as the “admission price” to the EU, which is worth paying because other aspects of accession will boost growth in such a way as to more than compensate for it. If the optimal method of financing these expenditures were borrowing, then rather than excluding the CEECs from EMU or forcing them to finance the admission price in a sub-optimal way, it would again be better to adjust the fiscal deficit criterion appropriately. 12 All EU members are obliged to avoid excessive deficits (defined as those in excess of 3% of GDP) under the Maastricht Treaty, whether they are EMU members or not (the sole exception is once again the UK, which is only obliged to “attempt to avoid” an excessive deficit). Only EMU members can be fined for failing, but the legal requirement nevertheless remains. Furthermore, any member state which has an excessive deficit should be unable to obtain financing for any new projects under the EU Cohesion Fund, something which is of great importance for some CEECs, such as Poland [Ecofin 1999, Art 2, Para 4 and Art 6, Para 1]. Finally, all EU members are obliged to achieve “a fiscal position close to balance or in surplus” in accordance with the Stability and Growth Pact. Neither EMU nor non-EMU members can be fined for failing to fulfil this requirement either, although again both will loose access to the Cohesion Fund if they are found by the Council to be in breach of the Pact [Ecofin 1999, Art 1, Para 1]. 13 It may be the case that a certain minimum level of income is required for a society to be able to support various sophisticated institutions, such as advanced forms of banking supervision, which may be helpful in protecting the political system from demands for inflationary finance. However, the more advanced CEECs already have such institutions in place. 13
  • 14. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? One argument that has been made is that the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson (H-B-S) effect means that CEECs are likely to have inflation rates 0%-2% above the average of the present EMU. On top of this there may be a demand effect resulting from the demand for non-tradeables being more income elastic than the demand for tradeables. As incomes rise, demand for non-tradeables rises faster, and unless productivity in the sector rises faster than in the whole economy (which is unlikely) non-tradeable prices will rise faster than tradeable prices. This phenomenon of “growth related relative price changes” also happens in current EMU members, but with faster income growth, it would presumably happen faster in CEECs. Adding faster growing countries with higher H-B-S and “demand effect” inflation to EMU must increase EMU inflation for any given degree of tightness of monetary policy it is argued. This seems to confront the EMU with an unpleasant dilemma: if the 2% ceiling on inflation is to be maintained for the EMU as a whole, interest rates will have to be higher and inflation in slow growing countries will need to be lower than at present. On the other hand, abandoning the 2% ceiling on inflation and allowing CEECs to have inflation rates well above the average of present EMU members (without reducing inflation in the current member states) would, it is claimed, undermine price stability in the whole zone. However, we have to take a number of other considerations into account. First, both the H-B-S effect proper and the demand effect, are as likely to occur in any rapidly growing economy as in a CEEC. Indeed, these effects have appeared quite strongly in Ireland, and to a lesser extent in Spain. They are not particularly the effect of catch-up, but simply of faster growth in the country concerned than the EMU on average. Thus, in order to prevent these effects from raising the average inflation rate in the EMU, members should not only refuse to accept CEECs, but they should also prevent current members from unilaterally undertaking structural reforms which would accelerate their growth14. Indeed, such a moratorium on reform would be particularly important since the CEECs represent only about 6.5% of EMU GDP. Thus, structural reforms that increased the growth rate by half in France and Italy (which together account for about 40% of EMU GDP) would be likely to have a much larger effect on EMU inflation than the accession of the CEECs. Therefore, unless the EMU wishes to remain a low growth zone, there can be no argument for excluding CEECs on such a basis. Indeed, it may be in recognition of this fact, that the Maastricht inflation criterion only needs to be fulfilled for one year. Although the reduction in inflation does need to be sustainable to satisfy the MIC, it is hard to imagine that expectations of “growth generated relative price changes” of the kind we are discussing after the conclusion of the “reference period”, could be held to violate this condition 15 . 14 This would be particularly vital if countries are to avoid the “demand effect”. 15 The “reference period” is that for which the conformity of a country with the criteria is assessed. What could be targeted by the sustainability requirement, would be various tricks such as “delaying” administered price or negotiated wage increases into “post-examination” years, or the fulfilment of the criterion thanks to an unsustainable nominal appreciation.
  • 15. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski Second, the CEECs are so small economically that their accession to EMU would not in fact require any change in the ECB’s inflation target, even if their “growth inflation” were relatively high. Thus, if CEEC inflation were an improbably high 3 percentage points above the average of current EMU members, this would mean an increase in enlarged EMU inflation of 0.2%, on the assumption that there were no offsetting effects. If France and Italy increased their long-term growth rate by half, the effect could be twice as large (if we assume that the inflation effect of a growth acceleration would be about half of the acceleration)16. Of course, even if the EMU-wide inflation target were adjusted upwards to take “growth inflation” in parts of the zone into account, there would not be any need to adjust the ECB’s monetary policy, and therefore there should not be any effect on the inflation rate in slow growing countries. Third, it is not in fact clear that either the H-B-S effect or the demand effect on non-tradeables prices in the faster growing countries, would in fact increase the inflation rate in EMU as a whole, once we take the impact of the higher growth on the nominal exchange rate of the euro into account. To see this, let us imagine that all EMU countries increase their growth rates by half. Would this lead to higher inflation within EMU? Assuming a stability- oriented monetary policy there are four ways of thinking about what would happen: · To the extent that the higher growth was mainly generated by productivity increases in the traded sector (leading to an H-B-S effect), it would lead to a nominal appreciation of the euro against other currencies (we assume that the growth acceleration would be limited to the EMU). Domestic EMU prices of tradeables would fall (or fall more rapidly than they are in any case doing before the acceleration), compensating for the increase in the prices of non-tradeables and overall inflation would remain roughly constant17. · To the extent to which the productivity growth occurred in non-tradeables, prices in this 15 sector would not rise in the first place18. · To the extent to which we have a shift in the structure of demand from tradeables to non-tradeables, the euro zone’s balance of payments will improve ceteris paribus, leading to nominal appreciation of the euro, reducing the euro price of tradeables and thus compensating for the increase in non-tradeables prices19. The nominal appreciation also increases the marginal costs of producing tradeables in the EMU 16 The same assumption applied to an excess of CEEC inflation of 3 percentage points above the EMU average inflation during 2000-2002 of 2.5%, would imply improbably high CEEC-wide growth rates of 7-8% per annum. 17 As long as the domestic price elasticity of demand for both categories of goods (tradeables and non-tradeables) were the same. 18 As long as the “structure of demand” effect on the demand for non-tradeables, resulting from the higher income the accelerated growth brings, is not larger than the growth in productivity in non-tradeables. 19 The shift is in the structure of demand, so euro zone demand for tradeables is likely to grow in absolute terms. This is because the shift itself results from overall growth in the economy.
  • 16. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? relative to their world price (in dollars) and leads to resources being transferred inside the euro area to non-tradeables production. · To the extent to which higher growth is balanced across sectors and there is no “demand effect”, prices of non-tradeables would not rise. However, higher growth would lead to pressure for higher real interest rates, which would also lead to nominal appreciation of the euro, which would cause the price of tradeables to decline, and overall inflation actually to fall. We can now consider what happens when the increase in growth is not EMU-wide. In the case when it is limited only to France and Italy, we would have weaker H-B-S or “demand effect” impacts on EMU-wide non-tradeables prices, more or less compensated by an equivalently weaker nominal appreciation of the euro. In the last case above, of “fully balanced” growth acceleration20 in France and Italy, the real interest rate effect on tradeables prices would also be weaker than in the case of an equally large EMU-wide growth acceleration. In all of these scenarios the impact of such a “geographically unbalanced” growth acceleration on slower growing countries within EMU could nevertheless be quite unpleasant. Nominal appreciation of the euro would make some part of their tradeables output non-competitive at previously expected wages. We can see this if we initially assume the existence a single homogeneous tradeable good, for which world demand and world supply are perfectly elastic. This good is produced in different currency areas of the world according to production functions which differ between areas in the short term, and which generate increasing marginal costs in production. Area output is determined at the level at which the world price PT = MCT (domestic marginal cost). Resources (at least two factors) used in the production of the tradeable good are also used in the production of each area’s non-tradeable good. An increase in productivity in the production of the tradeable good in an area leads to an increase in area income and therefore to a change in the structure of demand. Assuming that this causes a greater increase in demand for the non-tradeable good in the area than for the tradeable, the price of the non-tradeable good will rise. This implies a real appreciation of the area’s currency, and in a non-inflationary environment, a nominal appreciation of the currency as well. Resources are then transferred from production of the tradeable to the non-tradeable good, which will additionally benefit the suppliers of the factors of production which are used more intensively in the production of the non-tradeable good (by the Rybczynski Theorem). “Regions” within the currency area (in the EMU case these could be countries such as Germany) in which productivity in the production of the tradeable good does not increase, will find that with nominal appreciation, domestic PT will fall. If domestic factor prices are flexible in such a region, this may cause a fall in nominal returns to factors of production which are relatively immobile out of the region (labour). If domestic factor prices are downwardly sticky, it will cause a fall in the output of the tradeable good in the region, and a reduction in employment. Thus, in order 20 Fully balanced on both the demand and supply sides in both sectors.
  • 17. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski to avoid an increase in unemployment, expected wage increases might have to be foregone, or in the case of a relatively strong effect, real (or even nominal) wages might have to fall. This latter case is made the more likely by the low level of the ECB’s inflation target. Of course, on average even the inhabitants of slow growing EMU-members will benefit from faster growth anywhere in EMU (or indeed in the world). But these gains are likely to be unevenly distributed, with consumers of tradeable goods benefiting more than their producers. Thus, if we assume two tradeable goods are produced in the world, the currency area and the region we have been considering, and that productivity increases in the production of only one of the two tradeable goods in one of the regions of our area (but not in the other region or the rest of the world) then we get the following effects: (1) the area’s currency still appreciates; (2) in the region in which productivity has increased, resources are transferred from the production of the both tradeable goods to the non-tradeable good; (3) in the region in which productivity has not increased, there are two rounds of effects. The first round involves, as before, a reduction in the profit maximizing level of output of both tradeable goods at given factor prices. This requires either a fall in output and an increase in unemployment, or a fall in regional factor prices (relative to other regions and in nominal terms in a non-inflationary environment). The second round is a consequence of the overall currency area growth which has resulted from the increased productivity in the production of one of the tradeable goods in the other region of the area. This increases area demand for the other tradeable good (in whose production productivity has not increased), which increases demand for the factors used intensively in the production of this second tradeable good. The non-growing region should benefit from this, as it can increase exports of the second tradeable good to the growing region. Which of these two (first or second round) effects will predominate depends on the size of the slow growing region relative to the area and on the various elasticities involved. If factor prices are highly flexible downwards, then the region will not loose from the first round effect and will gain (albeit maybe only slightly) from the second round effect. In the case of CEEC accession and subsequent catch up, the direction of the effects on EMU slow growers would be the same as in the two cases examined above, but their magnitude is likely to be far smaller21. Thus, to summarise, the problem with CEEC accession to EMU is not that it will cause higher inflation in the whole euro zone, but rather that it may cause higher unemployment in slow growing countries such as Germany if they fail to increase the flexibility of their labour markets. 21 Throughout the analysis we assume that the EMU does not face a downward sloping demand curve for its products. If it does, then productivity growth in the tradeables sector will lead to a nominal depreciation of the euro rather than an appreciation, whether it is balanced by equal productivity growth in non-tradeables or not. Nominal depreciation will put upward pressure on EMU inflation, which would need to be offset by higher nominal interest rates. If the tradeable goods produced by all EMU countries were homogeneous, producers in countries with slow productivity growth would be hit by competition from their neighbours and by higher real interest rates. To the extent to which the tradeables produced by different countries differed, producers in slower growing EMU countries would face only the second problem of higher real exchange rates. However, only areas with largely undiversified exports (such as raw materials producers) are likely to face demand curves which are downward sloping in the medium to long term (the time horizon which concerns us, as we are considering issues of differential growth rates). 17
  • 18. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? 6. EMU institutional issues One reason for the Maastricht criteria for EMU accession is that EMU membership gives a country voting rights in the ECB and the Eurogroup of the Ecofin, and existing members would not want countries that have not demonstrated a commitment to low inflation to have such a vote. This is especially important in the case of the ECB. Although the ECB is supposed to make policy for the EMU as a whole, and therefore small economies should have a small weight in its considerations, each member of the interest rate setting ECB Governing Council (GC) has one vote at present. Apart from the six Executive Board (EB) members, the governors of all the NCBs are members of the Governing Council (giving a total of 18 members in the GC). This is a concern given that there are at present 12 potential new members from central, eastern and southern Europe. The Nice summit of December 2000 asked the ECB to make proposals for the restructuring of the Governing Council, and the ECB has now done this. The current member states of the EMU may be concerned that most of the potential new members have recent histories of far higher inflation than Western Europe. The fear could be that they would not have the same commitment to price stability as existing members. We have called this the “price-stability culture problem” [Bratkowski and Rostowski, 2002]. This problem is partly offset by the fact that central bankers are not as a breed prone to be inflation lovers. Second, all European System of Central Banks (ESCB) member banks now have to be highly independent for countries to qualify for EU, let alone EMU, accession. Indeed, the opposite fear has also been expressed: central bankers of CEECs might vote for short-term interest rates which kept inflation under control in their own countries, but were too high for core countries such as Germany. It has also been claimed that a Governing Council of 28 members would be far too large for serious discussion of the merits of monetary policy issues, which are best decided in a small group. It is said that in the ECB the tradition has been not to vote but to reach consensus and, it has been argued, reaching consensus in a group of twenty odd could be time consuming. Neither of these arguments seems to have any real merit. It is impossible to believe that consensus is at present arrived at in the 18 member Council through general discussion. What seems far more likely is that there is a smaller group with a clear view, and the rest go along with that. Compared to this, voting at least has the advantage of transparency. Moreover, the practical irrelevance of this argument has been demonstrated by the ECB’s own proposal for the reform, which foresees a GC of 21 voting members, and that all “National Central Bank Governors will continue to participate in the discussions of the Governing Council and attend the meetings…” - which implies up to 33 participants [ECB, 2002]. Third, there is the serious matter of the unfairness of the present arrangement, which with its “one governor one vote” principle, favours small countries enormously, even if all the members of the executive board were drawn from large countries (which has not been the case). The admission of the present applicant countries merely exacerbates and highlights the problem. Nevertheless, this problem has now been largely solved by the ECB’s proposal for the reform of
  • 19. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski the GC. This envisions 6 board members and 15 rotating country representatives. The 5 largest countries in terms of their shares of GDP will have 4 votes rotating among them22. The remaining countries will be divided into two groups as follows: the next largest one half of all the EMU-participating countries by GDP will have 8 votes to rotate amongst themselves, while all the 19 remaining countries will have 3 votes to rotate among themselves23. Membership in the eurogroup of the Ecofin Council of Finance Ministers may therefore be a more sensitive issue for some within the present EU. The European Commission (EC) and the twelve eurozone members have put forward proposals to the EU’s Constitutional Convention that the eurogroup should cease being an informal forum for discussion, and should be allowed to take binding executive decisions and pass legislation for the eurozone in the same way that the wider Ecofin does for the EU as whole [Financial Times June 10, 2003]. Indeed, one might expect that as regards macroeconomic issues the importance of the decisions that would be taken by the new “EMU-Ecofin” may prove to be even greater than those that are at present taken by the EU-wide Ecofin. Thus, it has been argued that, because it shares a single currency, the EMU needs a far greater degree of co-ordination of fiscal policies than does the EU as whole [Jacquet and Pisani- Ferry, 1999]. If CEECs were admitted to the EMU they would be entitled to participate in any strengthened “EMU-Ecofin”. Voting rights in Ecofin are roughly determined according to population, with an additional advantage being given to smaller countries24. There are also quirks in the allocation of voting rights. Thus, according to the rules adopted in the Treaty of Nice, Poland will have 27 votes compared to Germany’s 29 in all the “chambers” of the Council of the European Union”, despite having half of its population and a tenth of its national income25. These proportions would hold within any “EMU-Ecofin” as well. Thus it is not surprising that large and rich states within EMU might not be enthusiastic about poor states, that would contribute a small proportion of EMU GDP, joining EMU. Furthermore, the European Commission wants to have the “EMU-Ecofin” granted legislative and executive powers for two reasons. First, this may be the only way in which it would be possible to establish a central authority for making fiscal policy decisions which could be made binding on EMU member states, as these might be unwilling to see non-EMU members participating in such decisions within the wider, presently existing Ecofin [Financial Times, 2003]. Second, the constitutional principle in the EU is that the Council of the Union (of which Ecofin is an embodiment and an “EMU-Ecofin” would be) votes usually on proposals put before it by the Commission. 22 The actual criterion is a composite indicator of each country’s supposed “representativeness” of the EMU economy as a whole. This indicator is composed in 5/6 of GDP and in 1/6 of the total assets of the aggregated balance sheet of monetary financial institutions (TABS-MFI). It is unlikely that TABS-MFI will significantly affect the allocation of Member States to the three groups. 23 The third group will only come into existence when the number of states participating in EMU reaches 22. 24 Since the voting rules are laid down by treaty it would be extremely hard to change them, so as to take account of GDP for example (as we suggested could be done in the case of the ECB by weighting votes by members shares in ECB capital). Such a move would also be seen as profoundly anti-democratic. 25 Economics and Finance (Ecofin), Agriculture, Environment, Foreign Affairs, etc.
  • 20. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? Empowering “EMU-Ecofin” is therefore probably a necessary step for empowering the Commission itself in the sphere of EMU wide fiscal policy making, and therefore also fiscal policy co-ordination within EMU26. Thus, the expectation that CEECs will be admitted to the EMU and therefore to the “EMU-Ecofin” undermines the likelihood of large and rich EMU members agreeing to the creation of a powerful “EMU-Ecofin”. Knowledge of this may well lie at the root of Commission antipathy to EMU accession by CEECs27. However, this antipathy may decline once the Constitutional Convention finishes its work28. It should also be pointed out that whereas it is not in fact very dangerous, from the point of view of maintaining the commitment to price stability, to admit CEEC central bankers to the ECB Governing Council (given central bankers usual preferences), the same cannot necessarily be said as regards the effects on sound public finance of admitting CEEC finance ministers to a powerful “EMU-Ecofin”. The risk of doing so may be perceived as even greater if the Stability and Growth Pact is seriously watered down29. 7. Conclusion Thus, the balance of the argument appears to lie definitely on the side of EMU accession when we look at it from the perspective of the CEECs’ interests. However, from the perspective of incumbent EMU members’ interests, although we can state that many of the arguments put forward against early EMU accession have been overblown, we cannot avoid the conclusion that the arguments are more finely balanced. This is especially the case when we analyse the situation of slow growing incumbents, who are also likely to be members of any “core” grouping, and that of a Commission that is eager to expand its powers into fiscal policy and fiscal policy co-ordination. Given the opposing interests between the two sides, and the fact that it is impossible to forbid EU members from joining EMU if they fulfil the Maastricht criteria, we can expect to see an intensified effort by the Commission and certain incumbent Member States to dissuade CEECs from joining 26 The latter becomes all the more important as the “Stability and Growth Pact” which was supposed to provide a framework for such co-ordination comes under increasing strain. 27 Strangely, Germany does not seem to oppose the strengthened role of the Commission in EMU fiscal policy, even though under the Nice Treaty the role of small countries in the Commission will be further dramatically strengthened, as not only will 9 new small countries join (and only 1 large country) join, but also all countries (large and small) will have only 1 Commissioner (until now large countries have had 2 Commissioners). Nevertheless, this increased influence may be offset by the influence of the large countries within the Commission’s bureaucracy, developing a more hierarchical structure for the Commission (with more power for its President and - probably large country - Vice-Presidents), and by ensuring the appointment of a large country Commissioner to the crucial Economics and Finance Directorate-General. I am grateful to Fabrizio Coricelli for these points. 28 If the Convention rejects the Commission’s proposal. If instead the proposal is accepted, we may expect continued Commission opposition to CEEC accession to EMU until the new EU constitution, which would have to incorporate the proposal, is ratified. 29 Recent suggestions for watering down the Stability and Growth Pact include: (1) using cyclically adjusted deficits; (2) excluding net investment spending from the deficit; (3) providing an allowance for low public debt/GDP levels; (4) being more lenient towards countries with low inflation; (5) excluding defence spending [The Business, 10/11 November 2002, p.11, London].
  • 21. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski EMU. There may even be an attempt to return to the idea of tightening the accession criteria, although this would be hard to square with the principle of “equality between present and future Member States”30. 30 This principle is claimed to be the basis for the Commission’s opposition to unilateral euroization [European 21 Commission, 2000].
  • 22. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – When Should the Central Europeans Join EMU? REFERENCES Barro, R. and X.Sala-i-Martin [1998] Economic Growth, MIT Press, Cambridge Mass., pp. 583. Boone,L. and M.Maurel [1999] An Optimal Currency Area Perspective of the EU Enlargement to the CEECs, Discussion Paper 2119, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London. Bratkowski, A. and J.Rostowski [2000] “Unilateral Adoption of the Euro by EU Applicant Countries: the Macroeconomic Aspects”, in Ten Years of Transition, ed. L.Orlowski, Edward Elgar. Bratkowski, A. and J.Rostowski [2002] “The EU Attitude to Unilateral Euroization: Misunderstandings, real concerns and sub-optimal admission criteria”, Economics of Transition, Vol.10, No.2, pp.445-468. Calvo,G. [1999] On Dollarization available online at: http://www.bsos.umd.edu/econ/ciecpn5.pdf Csermely, A. and B.Vonnak [2002] “The role of the exchange rate in the transmission mechanism in Hungary”, paper presented at the research meeting on Monetary Policy Transmission in the Euro Area and the Accession Countries, 3 October 2002, National Bank of Hungary, Budapest. ECB [2002] “Governing Council Prepares for Enlargement”, Press Release, 20 December, European Central Bank, Frankfurt. Ecofin [1999] Council Regulation (EC) No 1264/1999, Official Journal of the European Communities, L161/57, 26.6.1999. European Commission [2000] “Exchange rate regimes for applicant countries”, Note for the Economic and Financial Committee, August, Brussels, mimeo, August 22, ECFIN/521/2000-EN, 18pp. European Economy [June 2002] “Public Finances in EMU 2002”, http://europa.eu.int/comm/economy_finance/publications/european_economy/2002/ee402en.pdf Fidrmuc,J. and F.Schardax [2000] “More ‘Pre-Ins’ Ante Portas? Euro Area Enlargement, Optimum Currency Area, and Nominal Convergence”, Transition, 2000:2, pp28-47, Oesterrichisches Nazionalbank, Vienna. Financial Times, 26 September 2000, “EU hopefuls likely to suffer if Danes vote ‘no’”. Financial Times, 10 October 2002, p.2, “Commission warns applicants on EMU”. Financial Times, 10 June 2003, p.1 “Eurogroup seeks more economic control”. Financial Times, 14 January 2003, “EU reform heads Paris talks”. Habib, M. [2002] “Financial contagion, interest rates and the role of the exchange rate as a shock absorber in Central and Eastern Europe”, Discussion Paper No. 7, pp. 42, Bank of Finland Institute for Economies in Transition, BOFIT. Jacquet,P. and J.Pisani-Ferry [1999] “Economic Policy Co-ordination in the Eurozone: What has been achieved? What should be done?” www.sei.ac.uk/pdfs/wp40.pdf Karhonen,I. And J.Fidrmuc [2001] “Similarity of Demand and Supply Shocks Between the Euro Area and the Accession Countries” Focus on Transition, 2/2001, pp. 26-42, National Bank of Austria, Vienna.
  • 23. Studies Analyses CASE No. 253 – Jacek Rostowski Rostowski, J. [2000] “The approach to EU and EMU membership: the implications for macroeconomic policy in the applicant countries”, in The Eastern Enlargement of the European Union eds. M.Dabrowski and J.Rostowski, Kluwer Academic Publishers, New York. 23 Sulling,A. [2002] “Should Estonia Euroize”, Economics of Transition, Vol.10, No.2, pp.469-480.