SlideShare a Scribd company logo
 
 
Why does food cost much more today than it did a few years ago?  One reason is that we now use part of our corn crop to produce ethanol, a clean biofuel substitute for gasoline. Another reason is that drought in some parts of the world has decreased global grain production.  We use an economic model—the production possibilities frontier—to learn why ethanol production and drought have increased the cost of producing food.  We also use this model to study how we can expand our production possibilities; how we gain by trading with others; and why the social institutions have evolved.
Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost The  production possibilities frontier  ( PPF ) is the boundary between those combinations of goods and services that can be produced and those that cannot. To illustrate the  PPF , we focus on two goods at a time and hold the quantities of all other goods and services constant. That is, we look at a model economy in which everything remains the same ( ceteris paribus ) except the two goods we’re considering.
Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost  Production Possibilities Frontier Figure 2.1 shows the  PPF  for two goods: cola and pizza.  Any point  on  the frontier such as  E  and any point  inside  the  PPF  such as  Z  are attainable. Points outside the  PPF  are unattainable.
Production Efficiency We achieve  production efficiency  if we cannot produce more of one good without producing less of some other good. Points on the frontier are  efficient . Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
Any point inside the frontier, such as  Z , is  inefficient . At such a point, it is possible to produce more of one good without producing less of the other good. At  Z , resources are either unemployed or misallocated. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
Tradeoff Along the  PPF Every choice along the  PPF  involves a  tradeoff . On this  PPF,  we must give up some cola to get more pizzas or give up some pizzas to get more cola. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
Opportunity Cost As we move down along the  PPF, we  produce more pizzas, but the quantity of cola we can produce decreases. The opportunity cost of a pizza is the cola forgone. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
In moving from  E  to  F,  the quantity of pizzas increases by 1 million. The quantity of cola decreases by 5 million cans. The opportunity cost of the fifth 1 million pizzas is 5 million cans of cola. One of these pizzas costs 5 cans of cola. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
In moving from  F  to  E , the quantity of cola produced increases by 5 million. The quantity of pizzas decreases by 1 million. The opportunity cost of the first 5 million cans of cola is 1 million pizzas. One of these cans of cola costs 1/5 of a pizza. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
Note that the opportunity cost of a can of cola is the  inverse  of the opportunity cost of a pizza. One pizza costs 5 cans of cola. One can of cola costs 1/5 of a pizza. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
Because resources are not equally productive in all activities, the  PPF  bows outward—is concave. The outward bow of the  PPF  means that as the quantity produced of each good increases, so does its opportunity cost. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
All the points along the  PPF  are efficient. To determine which of the alternative efficient quantities to produce, we compare costs and benefits. The  PPF  and Marginal Cost The  PPF  determines opportunity cost. The  marginal cost  of a good or service is the opportunity cost of producing  one more unit  of it.  Using Resources Efficiently
Figure 2.2 illustrates the marginal cost of pizza. As we move along the  PPF  in part (a), the opportunity cost of a pizza increases. The opportunity cost of producing one more pizza is the marginal cost of a pizza. Using Resources Efficiently
Using Resources Efficiently  In part (b) of Fig. 2.2, the bars illustrate the increasing opportunity cost of pizza. The black dots and the line  MC  show the marginal cost of pizza. The  MC  curve passes through the center of each bar.
Preferences and Marginal Benefit Preferences  are a description of a person’s likes and dislikes. To describe preferences, economists use the concepts of marginal benefit and the marginal benefit curve. The  marginal benefit  of a good or service is the benefit received from consuming one more unit of it. We measure marginal benefit by the amount that a person is  willing to pay  for an additional unit of a good or service. Using Resources Efficiently
It is a general principle that the more we have of any good, the smaller is its marginal benefit and the less we are willing to pay for an additional unit of it. We call this general principle the  principle of decreasing marginal benefit .  The  marginal benefit curve  shows the relationship between the marginal benefit of a good and the quantity of that good consumed. Using Resources Efficiently
Figure 2.3 shows a marginal benefit curve. The curve slopes downward to reflect the principle of decreasing marginal benefit. Using Resources Efficiently  At point  A , with pizza production at 0.5 million, people are willing to pay 5 cans of cola for a pizza.
Using Resources Efficiently  At point  B , with pizza production at 1.5 million, people are willing to pay 4 cans of cola for a pizza. At point  E , with pizza production at 4.5 million, people are willing to pay 1 can of cola for a pizza.
Allocative Efficiency When we cannot produce more of any one good without giving up some other good, we have achieved  production efficiency. We are producing at a point  on  the  PPF . When we cannot produce more of any one good without giving up some other good  that we value more highly , we have achieved  allocative efficiency .  We are producing at  the  point on the  PPF  that we prefer above all other points. Using Resources Efficiently
Figure 2.4 illustrates allocative efficiency. The point of allocative efficiency is the point on the  PPF  at which marginal benefit equals marginal cost. Using Resources Efficiently  This point is determined by the quantity at which the marginal benefit curve intersects the marginal cost curve.
Using Resources Efficiently  We get more value from our resources by producing more pizzas. On the  PPF  at point  A , we are producing too much cola, and we are better off moving along the  PPF  to produce more pizzas. If we produce fewer than 2.5 million pizzas, marginal benefit exceeds marginal cost.
Using Resources Efficiently  We get more value from our resources by producing fewer pizzas. On the  PPF  at point  C , we are producing too many pizzas, and we are better off moving along the  PPF  to produce fewer pizzas. If we produce more than 2.5 million pizzas, marginal cost exceeds marginal benefit.
Using Resources Efficiently  We cannot get more value from our resources. On the  PPF  at point  B , we are producing the efficient quantities of cola and pizzas. If we produce exactly 2.5 million pizzas, marginal cost equals marginal benefit.
The expansion of production possibilities—and increase in the standard of living—is called  economic growth . Two key factors influence economic growth: Technological change Capital accumulation Technological change  is the development of new goods and of better ways of producing goods and services. Capital accumulation  is the growth of capital resources, which includes  human capital . Economic Growth
The Cost of Economic Growth To use resources in research and development and to produce new capital, we must decrease our production of consumption goods and services. So economic growth is not free. The opportunity cost of economic growth is less current consumption. Economic Growth
Figure 2.5 illustrates the tradeoff we face. We can produce pizzas or pizza ovens along  PPF 0 . By using some resources to produce pizza ovens today, the  PPF  shifts outward in the future. Economic Growth
Gains from Trade Comparative Advantage and Absolute Advantage A person has a  comparative advantage  in an activity if that person can perform the activity at a lower opportunity cost than anyone else. A person has an  absolute advantage  if that person is more productive than others. Absolute advantage involve comparing productivities while comparative advantage involves comparing opportunity costs. Let’s look at Liz and Joe who operate smoothie bars.
Gains from Trade Liz's opportunity cost of producing 1 salad is 1 smoothie. Liz’s customers buy salads and smoothies in equal number, so she produces 15 smoothies and 15 salads an hour.  Liz's Smoothie Bar In an hour, Liz can produce 30 smoothies or 30 salads. Liz's opportunity cost of producing 1 smoothie is 1 salad.
Gains from Trade Joe's opportunity cost of producing 1 smoothie is 5 salads. Joe's opportunity cost of producing 1 salad is 1/5 smoothie.  Joe's Smoothie Bar In an hour, Joe can produce 6 smoothies or 30 salads. Joe’s spend 10 minutes making salads and 50 minutes making smoothies, so he produces 5 smoothies and 5 salads an hour .
Liz’s Absolute Advantage Liz is three times as productive as Joe. Liz can produce 15 smoothies and 15 salads an hour whereas Joe can produce only 5 smoothies and 5 salads an hour. Liz has an absolute advantage in producing smoothies and salads. Gains from Trade
Liz’s Comparative Advantage Liz’s opportunity cost of a smoothie is 1 salad. Joe’s opportunity cost of a smoothie is 5 salads. Liz’s opportunity cost of a smoothie is less than Joe’s. So Liz has a comparative advantage in producing smoothies. Gains from Trade
Joe’s Comparative Advantage Joe’s opportunity cost of a salad is 1/5 smoothie. Liz’s opportunity cost of a salad is 1 smoothie. Joe’s opportunity cost of a salad is less than Liz’s. So Joe has a comparative advantage in producing salads. Gains from Trade
Achieving Gains from Trade Liz and Joe produce the good in which they have a comparative advantage:  Liz produces 30 smoothies and 0 salads. Joe produces 30 salads and 0 smoothies. Gains from Trade
Liz and Joe trade: Liz sells Joe 10 smoothies and buys 20 salads. Joe sells Liz 20 salads and buys 10 smoothies. After trade: Liz has 20 smoothies and 10 salads. Joe has 20 smoothies and 10 salads. Gains from Trade
Gains from trade: Liz gains 5 smoothies and  5 salads an hour Joe gains 5 smoothies and 5 salads an hour Gains from Trade
Gains from Trade Figure 2.6 shows the gains from trade. Joe initially produces at point  A  on his  PPF. Liz initially produces at point  A  on her  PPF.
Gains from Trade Joe’s opportunity cost of producing a salad is less than Liz’s . So Joe has a comparative advantage in producing salad .
Gains from Trade Liz’s opportunity cost of producing a smoothie is less than Joe’s . So Liz has a comparative advantage in producing smoothies.
Gains from Trade Joe specializes in producing salad and he produces  30 salads an hour at point  B  on his  PPF.
Gains from Trade Liz specializes in producing smoothies and produces  30 smoothies an hour at point  B  on her  PPF.
Gains from Trade They trade salads for smoothies along the red “Trade line.”  The price of a salad is 2 smoothies or the price of a smoothie is ½ of a salad.
Gains from Trade Joe buys smoothies from Liz and moves to point  C —a point  outside  his  PPF . Liz buys salads from Joe and moves to point  C —a point  outside  her  PPF .
Dynamic Comparative Advantage Learning-by-doing  occurs when a person (or nation) specializes and by repeatedly producing a particular good or service becomes more productive in that activity and lowers its opportunity cost of producing that good over time. Dynamic comparative advantage  occurs when a person (or nation) gains a comparative advantage from learning-by-doing. Gains from Trade
To reap the gains from trade, the choices of individuals must be coordinated. To make coordination work, four complimentary social institutions have evolved over the centuries: Firms  Markets Property rights Money Economic Coordination
A  firm  is an economic unit that hires factors of production and organizes those factors to produce and sell goods and services. A  market  is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business with each other. Property rights  are the social arrangements that govern ownership, use, and disposal of resources, goods or services. Money  is any commodity or token that is generally acceptable as a means of payment. Economic Coordination
Circular Flows Through Markets Figure 2.7 illustrates how households and firms interact in the market economy. Factors of production and goods and services flow in one direction. Money flows in the opposite direction. Economic Coordination
Coordinating Decisions Markets coordinate individual  decisions through price adjustments. Economic Coordination

More Related Content

PPT
Ch08
PPT
Chapter 8 lecture presentation
PPT
Ch06
PPT
Ch03
PPT
Ch10
PPT
Ch04
PPT
Ch05
PPT
Ch01
Ch08
Chapter 8 lecture presentation
Ch06
Ch03
Ch10
Ch04
Ch05
Ch01

Viewers also liked (16)

PPT
Ch07
ODP
Economic systems
PPTX
Southern and Eastern Asian Economic Systems
PPT
Ch11
PPT
Ch09
PPT
Strategy implementation
PPTX
Elasticity - AS Economics
PPTX
Elasticity
PPT
Price Elasticity of Demand
PPT
Economic efficiency
PPT
Economic efficiency
PPTX
Price System
PPS
Elasticity+and+its+application
PPT
Elasticity Concepts
PPT
How do economic systems answer the basic economic questions
Ch07
Economic systems
Southern and Eastern Asian Economic Systems
Ch11
Ch09
Strategy implementation
Elasticity - AS Economics
Elasticity
Price Elasticity of Demand
Economic efficiency
Economic efficiency
Price System
Elasticity+and+its+application
Elasticity Concepts
How do economic systems answer the basic economic questions
Ad

Similar to Ch02 (20)

PPT
Intro macro ch02-1
PPT
Variebles in macroeconomics and how worikings in macro market
PPTX
Chapter 2 Lecture Presentation (THE ECONOMIC PROBLEM)
PPT
Chapter 2 lecture presentation
PPTX
Lec 04 Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
PPTX
PARKIN12E_ECONOMICS_Ch02.pptx , IOBM UNIVERSITY
PDF
Macroeconomics Australia 7th Edition McTaggart Solutions Manual
PPTX
CFO_POE12_ppt_02 (1).pptx
PPTX
ECONOMICS_02_Choice+in+a+World+of+Scarcity.pptx
PPT
ch2_powerpoint_hunter.ppt
PPT
The Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice
PPTX
PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCIAL PROBLEMS
PPT
Prinecomi lectureppt ch02
PPTX
1.1.4 Production possibility frontiers.pptx
PDF
ppc lectures nangati marshal 2017
PPT
Chapter 02 presentation
PPT
Unit 1 review_session
PDF
Methods of Philosophizing-Distinguishing Opinion from Truth
PPT
What is - Production Possibility (1).ppt
PDF
4 5-basic economic concepts to pharmacy
Intro macro ch02-1
Variebles in macroeconomics and how worikings in macro market
Chapter 2 Lecture Presentation (THE ECONOMIC PROBLEM)
Chapter 2 lecture presentation
Lec 04 Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
PARKIN12E_ECONOMICS_Ch02.pptx , IOBM UNIVERSITY
Macroeconomics Australia 7th Edition McTaggart Solutions Manual
CFO_POE12_ppt_02 (1).pptx
ECONOMICS_02_Choice+in+a+World+of+Scarcity.pptx
ch2_powerpoint_hunter.ppt
The Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice
PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCIAL PROBLEMS
Prinecomi lectureppt ch02
1.1.4 Production possibility frontiers.pptx
ppc lectures nangati marshal 2017
Chapter 02 presentation
Unit 1 review_session
Methods of Philosophizing-Distinguishing Opinion from Truth
What is - Production Possibility (1).ppt
4 5-basic economic concepts to pharmacy
Ad

Ch02

  • 1.  
  • 2.  
  • 3. Why does food cost much more today than it did a few years ago? One reason is that we now use part of our corn crop to produce ethanol, a clean biofuel substitute for gasoline. Another reason is that drought in some parts of the world has decreased global grain production. We use an economic model—the production possibilities frontier—to learn why ethanol production and drought have increased the cost of producing food. We also use this model to study how we can expand our production possibilities; how we gain by trading with others; and why the social institutions have evolved.
  • 4. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost The production possibilities frontier ( PPF ) is the boundary between those combinations of goods and services that can be produced and those that cannot. To illustrate the PPF , we focus on two goods at a time and hold the quantities of all other goods and services constant. That is, we look at a model economy in which everything remains the same ( ceteris paribus ) except the two goods we’re considering.
  • 5. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost Production Possibilities Frontier Figure 2.1 shows the PPF for two goods: cola and pizza. Any point on the frontier such as E and any point inside the PPF such as Z are attainable. Points outside the PPF are unattainable.
  • 6. Production Efficiency We achieve production efficiency if we cannot produce more of one good without producing less of some other good. Points on the frontier are efficient . Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
  • 7. Any point inside the frontier, such as Z , is inefficient . At such a point, it is possible to produce more of one good without producing less of the other good. At Z , resources are either unemployed or misallocated. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
  • 8. Tradeoff Along the PPF Every choice along the PPF involves a tradeoff . On this PPF, we must give up some cola to get more pizzas or give up some pizzas to get more cola. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
  • 9. Opportunity Cost As we move down along the PPF, we produce more pizzas, but the quantity of cola we can produce decreases. The opportunity cost of a pizza is the cola forgone. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
  • 10. In moving from E to F, the quantity of pizzas increases by 1 million. The quantity of cola decreases by 5 million cans. The opportunity cost of the fifth 1 million pizzas is 5 million cans of cola. One of these pizzas costs 5 cans of cola. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
  • 11. In moving from F to E , the quantity of cola produced increases by 5 million. The quantity of pizzas decreases by 1 million. The opportunity cost of the first 5 million cans of cola is 1 million pizzas. One of these cans of cola costs 1/5 of a pizza. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
  • 12. Note that the opportunity cost of a can of cola is the inverse of the opportunity cost of a pizza. One pizza costs 5 cans of cola. One can of cola costs 1/5 of a pizza. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
  • 13. Because resources are not equally productive in all activities, the PPF bows outward—is concave. The outward bow of the PPF means that as the quantity produced of each good increases, so does its opportunity cost. Production Possibilities and Opportunity Cost
  • 14. All the points along the PPF are efficient. To determine which of the alternative efficient quantities to produce, we compare costs and benefits. The PPF and Marginal Cost The PPF determines opportunity cost. The marginal cost of a good or service is the opportunity cost of producing one more unit of it. Using Resources Efficiently
  • 15. Figure 2.2 illustrates the marginal cost of pizza. As we move along the PPF in part (a), the opportunity cost of a pizza increases. The opportunity cost of producing one more pizza is the marginal cost of a pizza. Using Resources Efficiently
  • 16. Using Resources Efficiently In part (b) of Fig. 2.2, the bars illustrate the increasing opportunity cost of pizza. The black dots and the line MC show the marginal cost of pizza. The MC curve passes through the center of each bar.
  • 17. Preferences and Marginal Benefit Preferences are a description of a person’s likes and dislikes. To describe preferences, economists use the concepts of marginal benefit and the marginal benefit curve. The marginal benefit of a good or service is the benefit received from consuming one more unit of it. We measure marginal benefit by the amount that a person is willing to pay for an additional unit of a good or service. Using Resources Efficiently
  • 18. It is a general principle that the more we have of any good, the smaller is its marginal benefit and the less we are willing to pay for an additional unit of it. We call this general principle the principle of decreasing marginal benefit . The marginal benefit curve shows the relationship between the marginal benefit of a good and the quantity of that good consumed. Using Resources Efficiently
  • 19. Figure 2.3 shows a marginal benefit curve. The curve slopes downward to reflect the principle of decreasing marginal benefit. Using Resources Efficiently At point A , with pizza production at 0.5 million, people are willing to pay 5 cans of cola for a pizza.
  • 20. Using Resources Efficiently At point B , with pizza production at 1.5 million, people are willing to pay 4 cans of cola for a pizza. At point E , with pizza production at 4.5 million, people are willing to pay 1 can of cola for a pizza.
  • 21. Allocative Efficiency When we cannot produce more of any one good without giving up some other good, we have achieved production efficiency. We are producing at a point on the PPF . When we cannot produce more of any one good without giving up some other good that we value more highly , we have achieved allocative efficiency . We are producing at the point on the PPF that we prefer above all other points. Using Resources Efficiently
  • 22. Figure 2.4 illustrates allocative efficiency. The point of allocative efficiency is the point on the PPF at which marginal benefit equals marginal cost. Using Resources Efficiently This point is determined by the quantity at which the marginal benefit curve intersects the marginal cost curve.
  • 23. Using Resources Efficiently We get more value from our resources by producing more pizzas. On the PPF at point A , we are producing too much cola, and we are better off moving along the PPF to produce more pizzas. If we produce fewer than 2.5 million pizzas, marginal benefit exceeds marginal cost.
  • 24. Using Resources Efficiently We get more value from our resources by producing fewer pizzas. On the PPF at point C , we are producing too many pizzas, and we are better off moving along the PPF to produce fewer pizzas. If we produce more than 2.5 million pizzas, marginal cost exceeds marginal benefit.
  • 25. Using Resources Efficiently We cannot get more value from our resources. On the PPF at point B , we are producing the efficient quantities of cola and pizzas. If we produce exactly 2.5 million pizzas, marginal cost equals marginal benefit.
  • 26. The expansion of production possibilities—and increase in the standard of living—is called economic growth . Two key factors influence economic growth: Technological change Capital accumulation Technological change is the development of new goods and of better ways of producing goods and services. Capital accumulation is the growth of capital resources, which includes human capital . Economic Growth
  • 27. The Cost of Economic Growth To use resources in research and development and to produce new capital, we must decrease our production of consumption goods and services. So economic growth is not free. The opportunity cost of economic growth is less current consumption. Economic Growth
  • 28. Figure 2.5 illustrates the tradeoff we face. We can produce pizzas or pizza ovens along PPF 0 . By using some resources to produce pizza ovens today, the PPF shifts outward in the future. Economic Growth
  • 29. Gains from Trade Comparative Advantage and Absolute Advantage A person has a comparative advantage in an activity if that person can perform the activity at a lower opportunity cost than anyone else. A person has an absolute advantage if that person is more productive than others. Absolute advantage involve comparing productivities while comparative advantage involves comparing opportunity costs. Let’s look at Liz and Joe who operate smoothie bars.
  • 30. Gains from Trade Liz's opportunity cost of producing 1 salad is 1 smoothie. Liz’s customers buy salads and smoothies in equal number, so she produces 15 smoothies and 15 salads an hour. Liz's Smoothie Bar In an hour, Liz can produce 30 smoothies or 30 salads. Liz's opportunity cost of producing 1 smoothie is 1 salad.
  • 31. Gains from Trade Joe's opportunity cost of producing 1 smoothie is 5 salads. Joe's opportunity cost of producing 1 salad is 1/5 smoothie. Joe's Smoothie Bar In an hour, Joe can produce 6 smoothies or 30 salads. Joe’s spend 10 minutes making salads and 50 minutes making smoothies, so he produces 5 smoothies and 5 salads an hour .
  • 32. Liz’s Absolute Advantage Liz is three times as productive as Joe. Liz can produce 15 smoothies and 15 salads an hour whereas Joe can produce only 5 smoothies and 5 salads an hour. Liz has an absolute advantage in producing smoothies and salads. Gains from Trade
  • 33. Liz’s Comparative Advantage Liz’s opportunity cost of a smoothie is 1 salad. Joe’s opportunity cost of a smoothie is 5 salads. Liz’s opportunity cost of a smoothie is less than Joe’s. So Liz has a comparative advantage in producing smoothies. Gains from Trade
  • 34. Joe’s Comparative Advantage Joe’s opportunity cost of a salad is 1/5 smoothie. Liz’s opportunity cost of a salad is 1 smoothie. Joe’s opportunity cost of a salad is less than Liz’s. So Joe has a comparative advantage in producing salads. Gains from Trade
  • 35. Achieving Gains from Trade Liz and Joe produce the good in which they have a comparative advantage: Liz produces 30 smoothies and 0 salads. Joe produces 30 salads and 0 smoothies. Gains from Trade
  • 36. Liz and Joe trade: Liz sells Joe 10 smoothies and buys 20 salads. Joe sells Liz 20 salads and buys 10 smoothies. After trade: Liz has 20 smoothies and 10 salads. Joe has 20 smoothies and 10 salads. Gains from Trade
  • 37. Gains from trade: Liz gains 5 smoothies and 5 salads an hour Joe gains 5 smoothies and 5 salads an hour Gains from Trade
  • 38. Gains from Trade Figure 2.6 shows the gains from trade. Joe initially produces at point A on his PPF. Liz initially produces at point A on her PPF.
  • 39. Gains from Trade Joe’s opportunity cost of producing a salad is less than Liz’s . So Joe has a comparative advantage in producing salad .
  • 40. Gains from Trade Liz’s opportunity cost of producing a smoothie is less than Joe’s . So Liz has a comparative advantage in producing smoothies.
  • 41. Gains from Trade Joe specializes in producing salad and he produces 30 salads an hour at point B on his PPF.
  • 42. Gains from Trade Liz specializes in producing smoothies and produces 30 smoothies an hour at point B on her PPF.
  • 43. Gains from Trade They trade salads for smoothies along the red “Trade line.” The price of a salad is 2 smoothies or the price of a smoothie is ½ of a salad.
  • 44. Gains from Trade Joe buys smoothies from Liz and moves to point C —a point outside his PPF . Liz buys salads from Joe and moves to point C —a point outside her PPF .
  • 45. Dynamic Comparative Advantage Learning-by-doing occurs when a person (or nation) specializes and by repeatedly producing a particular good or service becomes more productive in that activity and lowers its opportunity cost of producing that good over time. Dynamic comparative advantage occurs when a person (or nation) gains a comparative advantage from learning-by-doing. Gains from Trade
  • 46. To reap the gains from trade, the choices of individuals must be coordinated. To make coordination work, four complimentary social institutions have evolved over the centuries: Firms Markets Property rights Money Economic Coordination
  • 47. A firm is an economic unit that hires factors of production and organizes those factors to produce and sell goods and services. A market is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business with each other. Property rights are the social arrangements that govern ownership, use, and disposal of resources, goods or services. Money is any commodity or token that is generally acceptable as a means of payment. Economic Coordination
  • 48. Circular Flows Through Markets Figure 2.7 illustrates how households and firms interact in the market economy. Factors of production and goods and services flow in one direction. Money flows in the opposite direction. Economic Coordination
  • 49. Coordinating Decisions Markets coordinate individual decisions through price adjustments. Economic Coordination