Contemporary Business 16th Edition Boone Solutions Manual
1. Contemporary Business 16th Edition Boone Solutions
Manual download pdf
https://testbankdeal.com/product/contemporary-business-16th-edition-
boone-solutions-manual/
Visit testbankdeal.com today to download the complete set of
test banks or solution manuals!
2. We have selected some products that you may be interested in
Click the link to download now or visit testbankdeal.com
for more options!.
Contemporary Business 16th Edition Boone Test Bank
https://testbankdeal.com/product/contemporary-business-16th-edition-
boone-test-bank/
Contemporary Marketing 16th Edition Boone Solutions Manual
https://testbankdeal.com/product/contemporary-marketing-16th-edition-
boone-solutions-manual/
Contemporary Marketing Update 2015 16th Edition Boone
Solutions Manual
https://testbankdeal.com/product/contemporary-marketing-
update-2015-16th-edition-boone-solutions-manual/
Essentials of Management 9th Edition DuBrin Test Bank
https://testbankdeal.com/product/essentials-of-management-9th-edition-
dubrin-test-bank/
3. Contemporary Issues in Accounting 2nd Edition Rankin
Solutions Manual
https://testbankdeal.com/product/contemporary-issues-in-
accounting-2nd-edition-rankin-solutions-manual/
Microeconomics 3rd Edition Hubbard Solutions Manual
https://testbankdeal.com/product/microeconomics-3rd-edition-hubbard-
solutions-manual/
Hydrologic Analysis and Design 4th Edition McCuen
Solutions Manual
https://testbankdeal.com/product/hydrologic-analysis-and-design-4th-
edition-mccuen-solutions-manual/
Canadian Business and the Law 5th Edition Duplessis
Solutions Manual
https://testbankdeal.com/product/canadian-business-and-the-law-5th-
edition-duplessis-solutions-manual/
Principles of Economics 7th Edition Taylor Test Bank
https://testbankdeal.com/product/principles-of-economics-7th-edition-
taylor-test-bank/
21. himself.[624] But why attack property, then? Property is attacked
because it gives to the proprietor a right to an income for which he
has not worked. It is not property as such, but the right of escheat,
that forms the butt of Proudhon’s attack; and following the lead of
Owen and other English socialists, as well as the Saint-Simonians, he
directs his charges against that right of escheat which, according to
circumstances and the character of the revenue, is variously known
as rent, discount, money interest, agricultural privilege, sinecure,
etc.[625]
Like every socialist, Proudhon considered that labour alone was
productive.[626] Land and capital without labour were useless. Hence
the demand of the proprietor for a share of the produce as a return
for the service which his capital has yielded is radically false. It is
based upon the supposition that capital by itself is productive,
whereas the capitalist in taking payment for it literally receives
something for nothing.[627]
All this is simply theft. His own definition of property is, “The right
to enjoy the fruits of industry, or of the labour of others, or to
dispose of those fruits to others by will.”[628]
The theme is not new, and the line of thought will be resumed—
by Rodbertus among others. The originality of the work consists not
so much in the idea as in the brilliance of the exposition, the
vehemence of the style, and the verve of the polemics hurled
against the old arguments which based property upon labour, upon
natural right, or upon occupation. A German writer[629] has said
that, published in Germany or in England, the book would have
passed unnoticed, because in both those countries the defence of
property had been much more scientific than in France.[630]
The whole force of the work lies, not in itself, but in the weakness
of the opposing arguments, and this fact is quite sufficient to give it
a certain permanent value. The treatise sent an echo through the
whole world, and its author may be said to have done for French
22. socialism what Lassalle did for German. The ideas set forth are not
new, but they are expressed in phrases of wonderful penetration.
There is also a wealth of ingenious remarks, which, if not,
perhaps, true, deserve retention because of their originality. How
such spoliation on the part of capitalists and proprietors can
continue without a revolt of the working men is a question which has
been asked by every writer on theoretical socialism, without its full
import ever being realised. Is there not something very improbable
in this? The problem is a curious one, indeed, and requires much
ingenuity for its solution. Marx disposed of it by his theory of surplus
value. Rodbertus in a simpler fashion showed the opposition
between economic distribution as realised in exchange and the social
distribution which lurks behind it. Proudhon has his own solution.
There is, says he, between master and men continual miscalculation.
[631] The master pays each workman in proportion to the value of
his own individual labour, but reserves for himself the product which
results from the collective force of all—a product which is altogether
superior to that yielded by the sum of their individual efforts. This
excessive product represents profits. “It is said that the capitalist
pays his workmen by the day. But to be more exact we ought to say
that he pays a per diem wage multiplied by the number of workmen
employed each day—which is not the same thing. For that immense
force which results from union and from the harmonious
combination of simultaneous efforts he has paid nothing. Two
hundred grenadiers can deck the base of the Louqsor statue in a few
hours, a task which would be quite impossible for one man though
he worked two hundred days. According to the capitalist reckoning
the wages paid in both cases would be the same.”[632] “And so the
worker is led to believe that he is paid for his work, whereas in
reality he is only partly paid for it. Even after receiving his wage he
still retains a right of property in the things which he has
produced.”[633] His explanation, though very subtle, is none the less
erroneous.
24. existing economic forces, but also their equilibration.[639] He never
contemplated “the extinction of such economic forces as division of
labour, collective effort, competition, credit, property, or even
economic liberty.”[640] His chief concern was to preserve them, but
at the same time to suppress the conflict that exists between them.
The socialists aim merely at destruction. For competition they would
substitute an associative organisation of labour; instead of private
property they would set up community of goods[641] or collectivism;
instead of the free play of personal interest they would, according to
Fourier, substitute love, or love and devotion, as the Saint-Simonians
put it, or the fraternity of Cabet. But none of these satisfies
Proudhon.
He dismisses association and organisation as being detrimental to
the liberty of the worker.[642] Labour’s power is just the result of
“collective force and division of labour.” Liberty is the economic force
par excellence. “Economic perfection lies in the absolute
independence of the workers, just as political perfection consists in
the absolute independence of the citizens.”[643] “Liberty,” he remarks
in an address delivered to the electors of the department of the
Seine in 1848, “is the sum total of my system—liberty of conscience,
freedom of the press, freedom of labour, of commerce, and of
teaching, the free disposal of the products of labour and industry—
liberty, infinite, absolute, everywhere and for ever.” He adds that his
is “the system of ’89,” and that he is preaching the doctrines of
Quesnay, of Turgot, and of Say. Indeed, it would not be difficult to
imagine ourselves reading the Classical rhapsodies concerning the
advantages of Free Trade over again.[644]
Communism as a juridical system is rejected no less energetically.
There is no suggestion of suppressing private property, which is the
necessary stimulant of labour, the basis of family life, and
indispensable to all true progress. His chief concern is to make it
harmless and to place it at the disposal of everyone.[645]
“Communism is merely an inverted form of private property.
27. Socialists of all shades of opinion, who from 1830 to 1840 had
been advocating radical reforms, were given a unique opportunity of
putting their theories to the test during the Revolution of 1848.
During the four months (February to June) which preceded the
terrible ruin of the socialist Republic by the bourgeoisie projects of
all kinds which for many years had been discussed in books and
newspapers appeared to be on the point of bearing fruit. For a
number of weeks nothing seemed impossible. “The right to work,”
“organisation of labour,” and “association,” instead of being so many
formulas, were by a mere stroke of the magic wand to be translated
into realities.
Enthusiasts were not wanting to attempt this task of
transformation, but, alas! only to find every scheme tumble into
ruins. Every formula, when put to the test, was found to be void.
The malevolence of some people, the impatience of others, the
awkwardness and haste of the promoters even, made the
experiments odious and ridiculous. Public opinion was at last
thoroughly wearied and all the reformers were indiscriminately
condemned.
The year 1848 is accordingly a memorable one in the history of
social ideas. The idealistic socialism of Louis Blanc, of Fourier, and of
Saint-Simon was definitely discredited. Bourgeois writers thought
that it was utterly destroyed. Reybaud, who contributed the article
on Socialism to the Dictionnaire d’Économie politique (edited by
Coquelin and Guillaumin) in 1852, writes as follows: “To speak of
socialism nowadays is to deliver a funeral oration. It has exhausted
itself. The vein is worked out. Should the human mind in its vertigo
ever take it up again it will be in a different form and under the
influence of other illusions.”
It fared scarcely better at the hands of subsequent socialists. Marx
referred to all his predecessors under the rather misleading title of
Utopians, and against their fantastic dreams he set up the “scientific
socialism” of Das Kapital. Between the two epochs lies a distinct
cleavage, marked by the Revolution of 1848. We must briefly see
29. the socialistic tendencies of the Luxembourg Commission, then
presided over by Louis Blanc. The workshops were placed under the
management of Émile Thomas, the engineer, who was an avowed
opponent of the scheme. In his Histoire des Ateliers nationaux,
written in 1849, he tells us how they were controlled by him in
accordance with the wishes of the anti-socialist majority of the
Provisional Government.[655]
But they were mistaken in their calculations. Those who thought
that the national workshops could be used for their own political
ends were soon undeceived. The Revolution greatly increased the
number of idlers, already fairly considerable as the result of the
economic crisis of 1847. Moreover, the opening of the workshops
brought the workmen from the provinces into Paris. Instead of the
estimated 10,000, 21,000 had been enrolled by the end of March,
and by the end of April there were 99,400. They were paid two
francs a day while at work, and a franc when there was no work for
them. In a very short time it became impossible to find employment
for so many. The majority of them, whatever their trade, were
employed upon useless earthworks, and even these soon proved
inadequate. Discontent soon became rife among this army of
unfortunate workers, humiliated by the nature of the ridiculous
labour upon which they were employed, and scarcely satisfied with
the moderate salary which they received. The wages paid, however,
were more than enough for the kind of work that was being done.
The workshops became centres of political agitation, and the
Government, thoroughly alarmed, and acting under pressure from
the National Assembly, was constrained to abandon them.
Suddenly, on June 21, a summons was executed upon all men
between seventeen and twenty-five enrolled in the shops, ordering
them to join the army or to leave for the country, where more
digging awaited them. The exasperated workmen rose in revolt.
Rioting broke out on June 23, but it was crushed in three days.
Hundreds of the workers died in the struggle, and the country was
terrorised into reaction.
33. combine together before they could secure the full benefit of their
labour. The moment Louis Blanc attained to power he sought to
guide the energies of the commission in this direction. The
“Association” was to be of the nature of a co-operative productive
society, supported by the State. Under the influence of Buchez, an
old Saint-Simonian, a Republican Catholic and the founder of the
newspaper called L’Atelier, there had been formed in 1834 an
association of jewellers and goldsmiths.[661] But it was a solitary
exception.
Louis Blanc was more fortunate. He successively founded
associations of tailors, of saddlers, of spinners and lace-makers, and
he secured Government orders for tunics, saddles, and epaulettes
for them. Other associations followed, and by July 5 the National
Assembly was sufficiently interested in these experiments to vote the
sum of three millions to their credit. A good portion of this sum
passed into the hands of mixed associations of masters and men
formed with the sole purpose of benefiting by the Government’s
liberality. The workmen’s associations pure and simple, however,
received more than a million, and there was not a sou of it left by
1849.
The first co-operative movement inspired by the ideas of Louis
Blanc was of short duration. The National Assembly took good care
to place the new societies under Ministerial control by appointing a
Conseil d’Encouragement, nominated by the Ministry to fix the
conditions under which loans should be granted. The Conseil
hastened to publish model regulations which left the associations
little scope for internal organisation. So stringent were the rules that
several of them were immediately jeopardised, and every society
which failed to conform to one of the three models outlined in Article
19 of the Commercial Code was obliged to dissolve. This meant
every society which was not nominally a collective society, a joint
stock or a limited liability company. By 1855, according to the
testimony of Reybaud, there remained only nine out of those
subsidised in 1848. Consumers’ co-operative societies, that is, the
34. societies which aimed at securing cheap commodities, established at
Paris, Lille, Nantes, and Grenoble, were also dissolved.
And so all these experiments—the only ones that had not already
brought reformers into discredit—were destined to fail in their turn.
Their extinction was partly due to political causes, partly to their
founders, who had not yet been trained in the difficult task of
building up such associations.
The social experiments of 1848 one after another foundered,
bringing a distrust of theories in their train. There still remained one
other experiment connected with Proudhon’s name—that of free
credit. But it also was destined to fail like the rest.
III: THE EXCHANGE BANK THEORY
The Revolution of 1848 did not take Proudhon quite unawares,
although he considered the outbreak was rather sudden. He was
soon convinced that the real problem to be determined was
economic rather than political, but he also realised that the
education of the masses was too backward to permit of a peaceful
solution. Proudhon, in this matter at one with his French confrères,
had hoped for such a solution.[662] He thought the February
Revolution was a child prematurely born.[663] In a striking article in
the columns of Le Peuple he gave wistful expression to his fears as
he foresaw the Revolution impending. Its solution had been
delivered to none and its interpretation baffled the ingenuity of all.
“I have wept over the poor workman, whose daily bread is already
sufficiently uncertain and who has now suffered misery for many
years. I have undertaken his defence, but I find that I am powerless
to succour him. I have mourned over the bourgeois, whose ruin I
have witnessed and who has been driven to bankruptcy and goaded
to opposition of the proletariat. My personal inclination is to
sympathise with the bourgeois, but a natural antagonism to his ideas
and the play of circumstance have made me his opponent. I have
gone in mourning and paid penance for the spirit of the old Republic
36. suppression of money interest would enable the worker to borrow
capital gratuitously, and would give him immediate control over all
useful capital instead of renting it. All attempts to hold up capital for
the sake of receiving interest without labour would thus be
frustrated. The right of property would be reduced to mere
possession. Exchange would be reciprocal, and the worker would
secure all the produce of his labour without having to share it with
others. In short, economic justice would be secured.
This is all very well, but how can the necessary money be
obtained without paying interest? Everything depends upon that.
Proudhon invites us to consider what money really is. It is a mere
medium of exchange which is designed to facilitate the circulation of
goods. Proudhon, who had hitherto regarded money as capital par
excellence, now treats it as a mere instrument of exchange. “Money
by itself is of no use to me. I merely take it in order to part with it. I
can neither consume it nor cultivate it.”[667] It is a mere medium of
exchange, and the interest paid merely covers this cost of
circulation.[668] But paper money will fulfil this function quite as well
and much more cheaply. Banks advance money in exchange for
commodities or supply bills which are immediately transferable into
cash. In exchange for this service the banker receives a discount
which goes to remunerate the shareholders who have supplied the
capital. Why not establish a bank without any capital which, like the
Bank of France, will discount goods with bills—either circulation or
exchange notes? The bills would be inconvertible, and consequently
would cost scarcely anything, and there would be no capital to
remunerate.
The service given would be equal to that given by the banks, but
would cost a great deal less. All that would be required to ensure the
circulation of the bills would be an understanding on the part of the
clientèle of the new bank that they would accept them as payment
for goods. The bearer would thus be certain that they were always
immediately exchangeable, just as if they were cash. The clients
would lose nothing by accepting them, for the statutes would decree
37. that the bank should never trade in anything except goods actually
delivered or under promise of delivery. The notes in circulation would
never exceed the demands of commerce. They would always
represent goods already produced and actually sold, but not yet paid
for.[669] Following the example of other banks, the bank would
advance to the seller of the goods a sum of money which it would
subsequently recover from the buyer. The merchants and
manufacturers would obtain not only their circulating capital without
payment of interest, but also the fixed capital necessary for the
founding of new industries. These advances obtained without
interest would enable them to buy and not merely to rent the
instruments of production which they needed.[670]
The consequences of a reform of this kind cannot be easily
enumerated. Not only would capital be freely placed at the disposal
of everyone, but every class distinction would disappear[671] as soon
as the worker ceased selling his products at cost price[672] and
government itself would become useless. The aim of all government
is to check the oppression of the weak by the strong.[673] But the
moment fair exchange becomes possible, free contract is sufficient
to secure this; there is no longer anyone who is oppressed. All are
equally favoured, for the cause of contention has been removed.
“Once capital and labour are identified, society will subsist of its own
accord, and there will no longer be any need for government.”
Government has “its origin and its whole being immersed in the
economic system.” Proudhon’s system means anarchy—the absence
of government.[674]
Such is Proudhon’s plan, and such its consequences. To
understand its full significance we must inquire whether (1) the
substitution of exchange notes for bank-notes payable at sight is
practicable, and, (2) supposing it to be practicable, if it is likely to
have the effects anticipated by its author.
Proudhon states that his system merely involves the universal
adoption of exchange notes.[675] The Exchange Bank would merely
38. append the manager’s signature against the particular commodity
discounted. But the issue of bank-notes at the present time involves
nothing more than this. Instead of the bill of exchange which it now
buys, and which enjoys only a limited circulation because the
signatories have only a very limited credit, it is proposed that the
Bank of France should substitute a note bearing its own signature,
which is universally known and testifies to an illimitable amount of
credit. In what respects, then, does Proudhon’s circulating medium
differ from a bank-note? It differs simply in the fact that the
signature of the Bank of France involves a promise of reimbursement
in metallic money, a commodity universally accepted and demanded,
while Proudhon’s Exchange Bank enters into no such definite
agreement, but merely undertakes to accept it in lieu of payment.
Theoretically, perhaps, the difference may appear insignificant,
since the signatures are the only guarantee of the solvency of the
notes of the Bank of France and the Exchange Bank alike. But in
practice it is enormous. The certainty that the note can be
exchanged for money gives it a wide currency and makes it
acceptable to many people who rely implicitly upon their confidence
in the bank. They need give no thought to the question of its
solvency. A mere circulating medium, on the other hand, in addition
to transferring a claim to certain goods belonging to clients of the
bank, involves a certain amount of confidence in the solvency of
those clients—a confidence not always easily justified. A note of this
kind will only circulate among the bank’s clientèle. It will never reach
the general public as the bank-note actually does. The clients
themselves will keep their engagements just so long as the bank
continues to discount goods that have actually been delivered and
never refuses payment when it falls due. Failing this, the exchange
notes, instead of regularly returning to the bank, will remain in
circulation. A slight crisis or a little tension, and many of the clients
will become insolvent. The total nominal value of the exchange notes
will quickly surpass the actual value of the goods which they
represent. There will be a rapid depreciation, and clients even will
refuse to take them.
39. It is just possible to conceive of the circulation of such exchange
notes, but the area of circulation will be a very limited one, and it
will be utterly impossible if all the clients are not perfectly solvent.
Let us, however, suppose that the practical difficulties have been
overcome, and that the exchange notes are already in circulation.
Interest will not disappear even then, and herein lies the essential
weakness of the system.
Why does the Bank of France charge a discount? Is it, as
Proudhon suggests, because it supplies cash in return for a bill of
exchange, so that “the seigneurial right of discount”[676] would
disappear with the adoption of a non-metallic currency? The bank
charges discount simply because it gives a certain quantity of
merchandise immediately exchangeable in return for a bill of
exchange falling due some months hence. It gives a tangible
commodity in exchange for a promise—a present good for a future.
What the bank takes is the difference between the present value of
the bill of exchange and its value when it falls due. It is not the mere
whim of the banker or the employment of a particular kind of money
that gives rise to discount. It belongs to the very nature of things.
Proudhon notwithstanding, a sale for cash and a sale with future
payment must remain two different operations,[677] at least as long
as the actual possession of a good is judged to be more
advantageous than its future possession.
This difference, even in the case of the Exchange Bank, would
very soon reappear. The exchange notes would represent goods
which were to be sold at a certain date. Although the Bank may
refuse to discount, this will not lessen the advantage enjoyed by
those merchants who are paid in cash. In order to secure this
advantage they will enter into agreement with those buyers who pay
cash either in the form of goods or of precious metals (which are,
after all, commodities), granting a slight rebate on the paper price.
There would thus be two sets of prices, the paper prices of goods
sold for future payment and the money price of goods sold for cash.
The first would be higher than the second, and the difference—
40. refused by the banks—would be pocketed by the sellers. Money
interest would then reappear under a new form.
To this Proudhon would reply that the clients of the bank, under
the terms of their agreement, are debarred from taking any such
premiums. Of course, if they remained faithful to their promises
interest or discount would be suppressed; but this would result, not
from the organisation of the Exchange Bank, but because of mutual
agreement. This would be a purely moral reform requiring no
banking contrivance to aid it, but one in which progress must
inevitably be very slow.
The Bank of Exchange failing to suppress discount, or to check the
right of escheat in general, Proudhon’s other conclusions fall to the
ground.
His theoretical error consists in his treating money at one moment
as capital par excellence, at another as a mere medium of exchange
having no value. He forgets that money is desired not merely for
purposes of exchange, but also as a store of value, as the proper
instrument for hoarding and saving; and although the exchange
notes may replace it in one respect, they fail in another. We may
increase the circulating media at pleasure, but we cannot multiply
our capital. Money may be replaced by goods, but this will not add a
single franc to the capital which already exists in society, of which
money itself is a part. Nor will it lessen the superior value of present
as compared with future goods—a superiority which gives rise to the
phenomenon of interest. The only result of multiplying the exchange
notes without increasing the amount of social capital would be to
raise prices as a whole, the price of land, houses, and machinery as
well as the price of consumption goods. Capital would be lent as
before, and being less plentiful the high rate of interest or rent
would tend to maintain the high level of prices, and these would in
turn be still further increased—a strange outcome of a reform
intended to lower them! Proudhon, having exaggerated the evil
effects of gold, now accepts Say’s formula too literally. J. B. Say
allowed himself to be led into error by his own formula that “Goods
41. exchange for goods,” and it is interesting to note that the Exchange
Bank is the logical, though somewhat paradoxical, outcome of the
reaction against the Mercantilist ideas concerning money which can
be traced to Adam Smith and the Physiocrats.
This does not imply that Proudhon’s idea is devoid of truth. The
false ideal of free credit contains the germ of a true ideal, namely,
mutual credit. The Bank of France is a society of capitalists whose
credit is established by the public who accept their notes. They really
deal in public credit. Proudhon saw clearly enough that their notes
are ultimately guaranteed by the public. The public are the true
signatories of these commercial goods. Were the public insolvent the
bank would never recover its advances, which really constitute the
security for the bills. The shareholders’ capital is only a
supplementary guarantee. The Comte Mollien, the Financial Minister
of Napoleon I, declared that in theory a bank of issue should be able
to operate without any capital. The public lends money to itself
through the intermediary, the bank. Why not operate without the
intermediary? Why not eliminate the entrepreneur of credit just as
the industrial or commercial entrepreneur is eliminated in the case of
the co-operative society? Discount would not disappear altogether,
perhaps, but the rate of discount for borrowers would be diminished
in proportion to the extent to which they stood to gain as lenders.
This is the principle of the mutual credit society, where the initial
capital is almost entirely superseded, its place being taken by the
joint liability of the co-operators. Proudhon’s initial conception seems
to be reducible to this very simple idea.[678]
It seems that Proudhon was merely following the idea of a co-
operative credit bank, just as in other parts of the work he copies
other forms of co-operation without ever showing much sympathy
for the principle itself.[679]
In addition to a correct conception of the value of mutual credit,
there runs throughout his whole system a more fundamental idea
which helps to distinguish it from other forms of official socialism
which arose either before or after his time. This is his profound
42. belief in individual liberty as the indispensable motive of economic
activity in industrial societies. He realised better than any of his
predecessors that economic liberty is a definite acquisition of
modern societies, and that every true reform must be based on
liberty. He has estimated the strength of spontaneous economic
forces more clearly than anyone else. He has demonstrated their
pernicious effects, but at the same time he has recognised, as Adam
Smith had done, that this was the most powerful lever of progress.
His passionate love of justice explains his hatred of private property,
and his jealous belief in liberty aroused his hostility to socialism.
Despite his famous formula, Destruam et ædificabo, he destroyed
more than he built. His liberalism rested on his profound hold of
economic realities, and the social problem of to-day, as Proudhon
clearly saw, is how to combine justice with liberty.
Proudhon’s project for an Exchange Bank must not be confused
with analogous schemes that have appeared either before or after
his day. All these schemes have a common basis in a reform of
exchange as a remedy for social inequalities. Apart from this one
idea the resemblance is frequently superficial, and the economic
bases differ considerably.
(1) Proudhon’s idea has often been contrasted with Robert Owen’s
labour notes, and with the scheme prepared by Mr. Bray in 1839, in
a work entitled Labour’s Wrongs and Labour’s Remedy,[680] as well
as with the later system outlined by Rodbertus. Proudhon’s
circulating notes have nothing in common with the labour notes
described by these writers. The circulating notes represent
commercial goods produced for the purpose of private exchange.
Prices are freely fixed by buyer and seller, and they bear no relation
to the labour time, as is the case with the labour notes. The final
result, doubtless, was expected to be the same. Proudhon hoped
that in this way the price of goods, now that it was no longer
burdened with interest on capital, would equal cost of production.
This result was to be obtained indirectly. The economic errors in the
two cases are also different. Proudhon’s error lay in his failure to
43. realise that metallic money is a merchandise as well as an
instrument of circulation. The error of Owen, of Bray, and of
Rodbertus consisted of a failure to see that the price of goods
includes something more than the mere amount of labour which
they have cost to produce—an error which Proudhon at any rate did
not commit.
(2) Proudhon’s bank has also been confused with other banks of
exchange which are really quite different. The ideas underlying such
schemes had become prominent before Proudhon’s days, and
numerous practical experiments had been attempted along the lines
indicated. These banks aimed, not at the suppression of interest, but
at a gradual rapprochement between producer and consumer, the
goods offered for sale being bought by the bank, and paid for in
exchange notes upon an agreed basis of calculation. Buyers in their
turn would come to the bank to obtain the necessaries of life, paying
for them in exchange notes. An experiment of this kind was made by
a certain Fulcrand Mazel in 1829.[681] In this case the bank was
merely an entrepĂ´t which facilitated the marketing of the goods
produced. Such a system is open to the objection that the value of
the notes issued in payment for goods would necessarily vary with
the fluctuations in the value of these goods during the interval which
would elapse between the time they are taken in by the bank and
their eventual purchase by consumers. Proudhon’s plan was to
discount the goods already bought or actually delivered. The bank
would only advance what was actually promised, but would make no
charge for accommodation. Depreciation could only arise if the buyer
were insolvent. It could never result from a fall in price as a result of
a diminished demand for the product. Proudhon renounced all
dealings with solidarity when he dismissed Mazel’s project.[682]
(3) M. Solvay, a Belgian entrepreneur, has recently elaborated a
scheme of “social accounting.” He also proposes the suppression of
metallic money and the introduction of a perfect system of payment.
Here, however, the analogy ends.
44. What Solvay proposed was the replacement of metallic money, not
by bank-notes, but by a system of cheques and clearing-houses. His
plan owes its inspiration to the modern development of the clearing-
house system. Solvay thought that the system might be so extended
as to make the employment of money entirely unnecessary. To every
such clearing-house the State would hand over a cheque-book,
covering a sum varying with the amount of real or personal property
which the house possessed. This cheque-book was to have two
columns, one for receipts, the other for expenditure. Whenever any
commodity was sold, the liquidation of debt would be effected by
the buyer’s stamping the book on the receipt side and the seller’s
stamping it on the expenditure side. As soon as the total value of
these transactions equalled the initial sum which the cheque-book
was supposed to represent the book would be returned to the State
bureau, where each individual account would be made up. “In this
way everybody’s receipts and expenditure will always be known with
absolute clearness.”[683]
The advantage of such a system would in the first place consist in
the economy of metallic money. In the second place it would furnish
the State with information as to the extent of everybody’s fortune.
The State would then be in possession of the information necessary
for setting up an equable scheme of succession duties which would
gradually suppress the hereditary transmission of acquired fortune.
Such gradual suppression would result in the total extinction of the
fundamental injustice of modern society, namely, the inequality of
opportunity.[684] It would also help the application of that other
principle of distributive justice, namely, “to each according as he
produces.” The idea is Saint-Simon’s rather than Proudhon’s.
The scope of the proposed reform is quite clear. Social accounting,
according to Solvay, is a mere element in a more general conception,
that of “productivism,” which in various ways is to result in
increasing productivity to its maximum.[685]
In all this it is impossible to see anything of Proudhon’s ideas.
With the exception of the suggestion of suppressing metallic money
45. the fundamental conceptions are utterly different. M. Solvay makes
no pretence to ability to suppress interest, and he never imagines
that money is the cause of interest. The cheque and clearing system
is a mere device for facilitating cash payment. It has nothing in
common with the Proudhonian system, whereby circulating notes
are supposed to place credit sales and cash payments on an equal
footing.[686]
The most serious objection to Solvay’s system lies in the fact that
the suppression of money as a circulating medium must also involve
its suppression as a measure of value. It seems difficult to imagine
that the universal cheque bank with no monetary support would not
result in a rapid inflation of prices because of the superabundance of
paper. But although the particular process advocated by Solvay is
open to criticism there can be no objection to his desire to diminish
the quantity of metallic money or to further the ideal of equal
opportunity for all.
The project was never successfully put into practice. Like the
cognate ideas of “the right to work,” “the organisation of labour,” and
“working men’s associations,” the idea of “free credit” has left behind
it a mere memory of a sudden check.
On January 31, 1849, Proudhon, in the presence of a notary, set
up a society known as the People’s Bank, with a view to showing the
practicability of free credit. The actual organisation differs
considerably from the theoretical outline of the Exchange Bank. The
Exchange Bank was to have no capital: the People’s Bank had a
capital of 5,000,000 francs, divided into shares of the value of 5
francs each. The Exchange Bank was to suppress metallic money:
the People’s Bank had to be content with issuing notes against
certain kinds of commercial goods only. The Exchange Bank was to
suppress interest: the People’s Bank fixed it at 2 per cent., expecting
that it could be reduced to a minimum of ÂĽ per cent.
Despite these important changes the bank would not work. At the
end of three months the subscribed capital was only 18,000 francs,
although the number of subscribers was almost 12,000. Just at that
47. Welcome to our website – the perfect destination for book lovers and
knowledge seekers. We believe that every book holds a new world,
offering opportunities for learning, discovery, and personal growth.
That’s why we are dedicated to bringing you a diverse collection of
books, ranging from classic literature and specialized publications to
self-development guides and children's books.
More than just a book-buying platform, we strive to be a bridge
connecting you with timeless cultural and intellectual values. With an
elegant, user-friendly interface and a smart search system, you can
quickly find the books that best suit your interests. Additionally,
our special promotions and home delivery services help you save time
and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
Join us on a journey of knowledge exploration, passion nurturing, and
personal growth every day!
testbankdeal.com