SlideShare a Scribd company logo
THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE FOREST SECTOR IN URUGUAY:

                                A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS

                                               by

                                VIRGINIA MORALES OLMOS

                             (Under the Direction of Jacek P. Siry)

                                          ABSTRACT



       Uruguay is a South American country surrounded by Argentina and Brazil. Its economy

has traditionally been based on agriculture. Since the 1960s, the government has been

encouraging forestry as an alternative use for marginal agricultural lands in an effort to promote

economic development, diversification, and environmental services. The Forestry Law of 1987

introduced subsidies and tax exonerations for the development of forest plantations and wood

manufacturing industries. As a result, the new forest sector has been growing rapidly, attracting

foreign investment. While several studies have examined the impact of individual forest firms,

no study to date has examined the impact of the forest sector from the point of view of the entire

economy. This research project evaluated the impact of the new forest sector by conducting a

Cost-Benefit Analysis. The results indicate a positive net impact when compared with livestock:

the Net Present Value for the forest sector was 630.2 million US$, and the Internal Rate of

Return was 36.4%.



INDEX WORDS: Policy Evaluation, Uruguay, Forest Sector, Cost-Benefit Analysis.
THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE FOREST SECTOR IN URUGUAY:

                              A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS




                                             by



                              VIRGINIA MORALES OLMOS

               Lic. en Economía, Universidad de la República, Uruguay, 2002




A Thesis Submitted to the Graduate Faculty of The University of Georgia in Partial Fulfillment

                             of the Requirements for the Degree




                                  MASTER OF SCIENCE



                                    ATHENS, GEORGIA

                                            2007
© 2007

Virginia Morales Olmos

 All Rights Reserved
THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE FOREST SECTOR IN URUGUAY:

                               A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS




                                         by



                               VIRGINIA MORALES OLMOS




                                              Major Professor:   Jacek P. Siry

                                              Committee:         David H. Newman
                                                                 Warren Kriesel




Electronic Version Approved:

Maureen Grasso
Dean of the Graduate School
The University of Georgia
May 2007
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS



       Three years ago I was invited to participate in a discussion on Forest Economics at INIA

with Dr. Brooks Mendell from The University of Georgia, who was at that time visiting

Uruguay. While I had never heard about the discipline before, the forest sector was developing

rapidly. Since I wanted to learn more about it, I attended the meeting. There I started the

adventure of studying Forest Economics. Many people accompanied me in this adventure with

Forest Economics, and I would like to thank them for making it possible.

       I thank my advisor, Dr. Jacek Siry, for giving me the opportunity to study in the United

States, and for his guidance and supervision. He was always open to new ideas in this process, to

my questions, and to my last minute concerns. Thank you for pushing me further but with the

doses of compassion that we all need, and for taking the time to continuously read the drafts of

the thesis and correct them, and, especially, for your support during the last days of writing.

       I thank my Committee Members, Dr. David Newman and Dr. Warren Kriesel, who have

been open to my research ideas and accepted the changes with patience and helpful suggestions.

Dr. Newman was always ready for my questions and concerns; I really enjoyed our

conversations and discussions about the Third World and South America. Gracias, Dr. Newman.

Dr. Kriesel was always supportive during the Committee Meetings, making valuable comments

and suggestions.

       I thank all the people in Uruguay for providing me with the information about the

Forestry Sector and Uruguay statistics, and for discussing with me policy evaluation methods,

including Mr. Lorenzo Balerio (FYMNSA), Mr. Javier Otegui (COFUSA), Mr. José Obes

(BOTNIA), Mr. Ricardo Methol (FOSA), Mr. Carlos Faroppa (BOTNIA), Mr. Enrique Ramos




                                                 iv
(COLONVADE), Mr. Raúl Pazos (EUFORES), Mr. Gustavo Balmelli (INIA Tacuarembó), Mr.

Pedro Barrenechea, Mr. Carlos Voulminot (Industrias Forestales Arazatí), Ms. Paola Zubillaga

(SPF), Mr. Héctor Pastori (UDELAR), Mr. Alberti, Mr. Roni Swedzki (CIU), Ms. Elena

Cuadrado (BCU), Ms. Lucía Pittaluga (IE), Mr. Michael Borchardt (MEF), Mr. Jerónimo Rocca,

Mr. Bruno Lanfranco (INIA), Mr. Rafael De La Torre (CELFOR). Special thanks to the Forest

Division of Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay: Mr. Daniel San San Román and Mr. Andrés

Berterreche, Mr. Juan Pablo Nebel for the information on Native Forest. Special thanks to Ms.

Verónica Durán (OPYPA) who was always willingly answering my questions and with whom I

first discussed the topic of this thesis. Thank you Verónica, your help has been invaluable. I

thank my colleague Mercedes, who shared discussions on line and has been of great support

since we met in Tacuarembó.

       I thank the Latin American and Caribbean Student Institute (LACSI) for facilitating this

research by providing travel funds to conduct my interviews in Uruguay.

       I thank Dr. Brooks Mendell, the “first person responsible” for my trip to Athens. Thank

you for providing all the information that I needed and for being there even though we did not

met very often during these two years. It was a pleasure working with you.

       I thank the staff of the Warnell School of Forestry and Natural Resources. Special thanks

to Ms. Rosemary Wood who was always ready to answer any questions with kindness and

patience, and to the students and professors in the fifth floor of Building 4. Thank you for always

encouraging me, especially during the last months of my writing.

       I thank my officemates: Tony, Matt, Iris and Tiffany. In different ways, you were always

there for me. Thank you, Tony for listening to my complaints for a year and for your friendship

and support. To Gay Mac Cormack, my English professor, who became an expert in Forest




                                                v
Economics and Uruguay after a year working together. Thank you for the coffee that we shared

in the English Department.

          I thank my friends in Athens, the ones who already left and the ones that are still here,

who became my extended family during this time far from Uruguay.

          Finally, I thank my family. Without their support, I could not have completed this

degree.

          In memorian of my colleague Mariana, with whom I started to like the forests.




                                                 vi
TABLE OF CONTENTS

                                                                                                                                    Page

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS........................................................................................................... iv

LIST OF TABLES....................................................................................................................... viii

LIST OF FIGURES ....................................................................................................................... xi

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION ....................................................................................................1

CHAPTER 2: POLICY ANALYSIS ...............................................................................................5

CHAPTER 3: URUGUAY’S FOREST SECTOR ........................................................................24

CHAPTER 4: METHODS, RESULTS AND DISCUSSION .......................................................52

CHAPTER 5: CONCLUSIONS ....................................................................................................91

REFERENCES ..............................................................................................................................95

APPENDICES

                    I. SURVEY RESULTS.........................................................................................105

                    II. SURVEY FORMS ...........................................................................................113

                    III. CBA TABLES ................................................................................................128




                                                                   vii
LIST OF TABLES

                                                                                                                   Page

TABLE 1. FOREST AREA IN CHILE (1,000 HA) …………………………………………….19

TABLE 2. FOREST AREA IN BRAZIL (1,000 HA)...................................................................19

TABLE 3.GDP AS PERCENTAGE OF AGRICULTURAL GDP ..............................................40

TABLE 4. URUGUAY FOREST RESOURCES..........................................................................40

TABLE 5. CONEAT INDEX FOR FOREST LANDS .................................................................42

TABLE 6. FOREST FARMS BY AREA......................................................................................43

TABLE 7. URUGUAY FOREST EXPORTS SHARE IN TOTAL EXPORTS...........................43

TABLE 8. URUGUAY EXPORTS IN VALUE AND VOLUME ...............................................44

TABLE 9. PAPER AND CARDBOARD EXPORTS PRICE INDEX.........................................46

TABLE 10. WOOD EXPORT UNIT VALUES (1,000 US$/M3)................................................47

TABLE 11. SAW TIMBER EXPORT PRICE INDEX ................................................................48

TABLE 12. URUGUAY FOREST IMPORTS (MILLION US$ FOB) ........................................49

TABLE 13. GDP FOREST INDUSTRIES AS PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL GDP (2003) .........49

TABLE 14. CIIU PRODUCTION INDEX, BASE 100=2002......................................................50

TABLE 15. GDP FOREST INDUSTRIES AND MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY

(CONSTANT MILLION 2002 US$).............................................................................................50

TABLE 16. SAWMILLS AND PULP AND PAPER INDUSTRIES SHARE IN INDUSTRY

PRODUCT AND INDUSTRY WAGES.......................................................................................51

TABLE 17. SHADOW PRICES RELATIONS FOR URUGUAY...............................................81

TABLE 18. UNEMPLOYMENT RATES FOR URUGUAY.......................................................82

TABLE 19. URUGUAY BLV (2005) ...........................................................................................83




                                                          viii
TABLE 20. EUCALYPTUS GROWTH, YIELDS AND MANAGEMENT ASSUMPTIONS...83

TABLE 21. PINE GROWTH, YIELDS AND MANAGEMENT ASSUMPTIONS....................84

TABLE 22. PLANTATION COSTS STRUCTURE.....................................................................85

TABLE 23. FOREST PRODUCTION COSTS (2005).................................................................86

TABLE 24. INDUSTRIAL COSTS STRUCTURE (2005) ..........................................................87

TABLE 25. TRANSPORTATION COSTS COEFFICIENTS......................................................87

TABLE 26. FOREST LAND PRICES VS LIVESTOCK LAND PRICES ..................................88

TABLE 27. COST BENEFIT ANALYSIS RESULTS.................................................................89

TABLE 28. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: WOOD PRICES .........................................................90

TABLE 29. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: YIELDS ......................................................................90

TABLE 30. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: TRANSPORTATION COSTS ...................................91

TABLE 31. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: LAND PRICE.............................................................91

TABLE 32. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: HARVESTING, THINNING AND MANAGEMENT

COSTS ...........................................................................................................................................91

TABLE 33. COMPANIES CLASSIFIED ACCORDING TO THE ORIGIN OF THE

CAPITAL.....................................................................................................................................113

TABLE 34. AREA BY COMPANIES ........................................................................................113

TABLE 35. AREA BY SPECIES (IN HA) .................................................................................113

TABLE 36. ROTATION AGES AND GROWTH RATES .......................................................113

TABLE 37. TOTAL EXTRACTION EUCALYPTUS (1,000 M3)............................................129

TABLE 38. TOTAL EXTRACTION PINE (1,000 M3).............................................................130

TABLE 39. BASIC ASSUMPTIONS .........................................................................................131

TABLE 40. INVESTMENTS IN LAND (MILLION US$)........................................................132




                                                                        ix
TABLE 41. INDUSTRY INVESTMENTS (MILLION US$) ....................................................133

TABLE 42. EXPORTS................................................................................................................134

TABLE 43. TRANSPORTATION COSTS (MILLION US$)....................................................136

TABLE 44. LIVESTOCK TRANSPORTATION COSTS .........................................................137

TABLE 45. INDUSTRY COSTS ................................................................................................138

TABLE 46. PRODUCTION COSTS ..........................................................................................142

TABLE 47. LABOR COSTS EXPORTS (MILLION US$) .......................................................144

TABLE 48. PRUNING AND THINNING COSTS (MILLION US$)........................................144

TABLE 49. ADMINISTRATION AND MANAGEMENTE COSTS (MILLION US$)...........145

TABLE 50. HARVESTING COSTS...........................................................................................145

TABLE 51. NURSERY COSTS..................................................................................................146




                                                                 x
LIST OF FIGURES

                                                                    Page

FIGURE 1. BASIC POLICY ANALYSIS PROCESS…………………………………………..21

FIGURE 2. CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS……………………………………...22

FIGURE 3. TAXATION AND DEADWEIGHT LOSS………………………………………...22

FIGURE 4. URUGUAY GDP BY SECTORS (2005)…………………………………………..40

FIGURE 5. URUGUAY FOREST PRIORITY SOILS………………………………………….41

FIGURE 6. AREA PLANTED BY SPECIES (CUMULATIVE)……………………………….42

FIGURE 7. PAPER AND CARBOARD EXPORTS BY REGION (US$ FOB, 2005)…………45

FIGURE 8. WOOD AND WOOD PRODUCTS EXPORTS BY REGION (US$ FOB, 2005)....45




                                   xi
CHAPTER 1

                                       INTRODUCTION



       Incentives promoting investment in the development of forest plantations and wood

manufacturing industries have been a controversial policy issue in recent decades. Most of the

arguments rely on the misuse and depletion of natural resources due to government failures.

Ineffective forest policies, the absence of logging controls, and external pressures such as rapid

population growth have frequently resulted in resource decline and deforestation (Hyde et al.

1987; Repetto & Gillis 1988; Ascher & Healy 1990; Clapp 1995; Dore & Guevara 2000; Clapp

2001; Guldin 2003; Bacha 2004; Silva 2004). Some studies pointed out that economic incentives

such as tax breaks, tax exonerations, subsidies, credit concessions, and pricing policies resulted

in the misuse of forest resources as well (Repetto & Gillis 1988). One of the most important

consequences of these failures is deforestation as many developing countries experience high

deforestation rates (Repetto & Gillis 1988; Haltia & Keipi 1997; FAO 2005).

       Unlike many developing countries experiencing deforestation, forest cover in Uruguay

has been increasing (Nebel 2003). The majority of the land in Uruguay is privately owned and

population growth is slow (INE 2006). In addition, the landholding concentration is not high. As

a result, Uruguay does not have the characteristics that have led to deforestation in other

countries. Further, Uruguay has used economic incentives to promote the development of forest

plantations and wood manufacturing industries. Whether these incentives will result in

deforestation or resource decline seems to be a non-controversial issue since effective regulations

protecting native forest exists. In addition, forest plantations have been established on

agricultural lands. Nevertheless, environmental groups have argued that monocultures composed




                                                1
of either eucalyptus or pine will cause severe damage to the native forest (Guayubira 2006). In

addition, those organizations claim that the forest sector does not generate economic benefits

while providing low-quality employment (Carrere 2002).

       The forest sector in Uruguay has been rapidly developing since the passage of the

Forestry Law 15939 in 1987 (Durán 2004; Forest Division 2005). The Law established subsidies

and tax incentives to support the development of forest plantations and wood manufacturing

industries. This development is part of a broader trend in South America, where countries such

as Brazil and Chile have long used economic incentives to attract domestic and foreign

investment into their forestry sectors.



               1.1     Objective

       The objective of the project is to evaluate the impact of the new forest sector on the

Uruguayan Economy by considering the costs and benefits associated with the policy that started

with the Forestry Law 15939 promulgated in 1987.



               1.2     Justification

       The rationale for Law 15939 as discussed by members of Parliament was that the project

will contribute to environmental, economic and social goals of the country. The existing studies

have attempted to evaluate the policy and its impacts from the point of view of the government

by focusing on fiscal impacts (González Posse & Barrenechea 1996); estimating tax balance,

unemployment balance and product balance (Vázquez Platero 1996; Ramos & Cabrera 2001), or

by studying individual firms (Metsa-Botnia 2004; World Bank 2005). These studies do not

reflect the opportunity cost for the Uruguayan society of the resources used in the forest activity.




                                                 2
The current study uses a Cost-Benefit Analysis (CBA) to determine the impact of the new

forest sector on the Uruguayan economy. It approaches the analysis from the point of view of the

society, using shadow prices and a social discount rate.

        The results of this project will be important for assessing the impact of a policy on the

whole economy. The results will help in determination of whether (1) the incentives were

efficiently used, (2) the incentives should be now terminated as the forest sector has already

developed, or (3) the incentives should be refocused on different agents in the sector, i.e., small

producers. In addition, the analysis of the sector will help in assessing further information needs.

Finally, the discussion of forest policy evaluation methods from the standpoint of the country’s

economy will contribute to future studies.

        The second chapter describes the methods of policy evaluation and discusses CBA along

with the Social Choice theory and Welfare economics theories. In this framework, the rationale

for establishing forest policies is discussed, and two South American forest sectors are briefly

described: Chile and Brazil.

         The third chapter describes the Uruguayan forest sector and examines forest laws and

regulations. The silvicultural sub-sector has increased its share in agricultural GDP between

1990 and 2002, from 3.8% to 13.40%; and sawmills increased from nearly 0% of the

manufacturing industry GDP1 to 1.44% in 2003. Then a description of exports and imports is

presented, with the emphasis on forest exports and its share in Uruguay’s total exports, as most

of the total production is exported. Favorable laws and regulations were key factors attracting

foreing investor into the country.




1
 The GDP for sawmills was not included in the country’s statistics before 2001 because its sharing in the industry’s
GDP was negligible.


                                                         3
The fourth chapter presents the analytical method, results and discussion. The CBA is

discussed along with data and assumptions. The chapter addresses major issues with the use in

the current study, including shadow pricing and its application for Uruguay, with emphasis in

land and labor valuation. Finally, the CBA results are presented and discussed.

       The fifth chapter summarizes the results and provides policy. Finally, several future

research opportunities identified during this research are presented.




                                                 4
CHAPTER 2

                                       POLICY ANALYSIS



       Policy analysis considers a complex set of factors and therefore there are several ways to

define the analysis (Patton & Sawicki 1993; Dunn 2004). Policy analysis is both descriptive and

normative, because it has to describe the objectives, instruments, and results of the policy, and

has to provide instruments to select the best policy. The choice of objectives and results involves

balancing opposite interests and values such as efficiency, equity, security, and development

(Dunn 2004). Furthermore, given their scarcity, the resources have to be allocated in order to

consider different interests (Cubbage et al. 1993; Patton & Sawicki 1993). This allocation

implies tradeoffs involved in following one policy or another.

       A basic policy analysis process can be summarized in six steps: define the problem,

establish the evaluation criteria, identify alternative policies, evaluate the policies, implement the

policy, and monitor the implemented policy (Figure 1). First, the analyst has to define the

problem, a process, which assumes that a problem exists and describe it with a focus on the

central, critical factors. Problem structuring is the description and definition of the problem to be

solved by the policy (Cubbage et al. 1993; Boardman 2001; Dunn 2004). Second, the analyst has

to establish the criteria to evaluate alternative policies. The evaluation criteria chosen depend on

the objectives of the policy and its effects on the population. The most common criteria used to

evaluate a policy include cost, net benefit, effectiveness, efficiency, equity, legality, and

administrative ease. Third, the analyst has to identify alternative polices according to their

objectives and specific values and interests. A list of alternatives, including a thorough definition

of each one, can reveal aspects of the problem not considered before. This description can lead to




                                                  5
a reformulation of the problem and return to the beginning of the policy analysis. Fourth, after

selecting the alternatives, the analyst has to evaluate, with technical criteria, which alternative

best achieves the objectives of the policy defined at the beginning of the policy analysis.

Evaluation is the systematic assessment of the outcomes of a policy compared with a set of

standards (Weiss 1998 in Bisang & Zimmermann 2006; Dunn 2004). It consists of the evaluation

of the content of the policy, which includes programs and instruments (Bisang & Zimmermann

2006). The types of evaluation depend on the problem: the analyst can use quantitative methods

of evaluation, qualitative methods of evaluation, or a combination of both. At this point, the

analyst can find that there is information missing from the problem description, and then has to

go back and redefine the problem. Fifth, after evaluating the alternatives and choosing the best

one, this policy has to be implemented. Finally, the implemented policy has to be monitored in

order to assess whether the policy worked properly and, if not, to identify the problems and

correct them. Monitoring is the observation of previously defined indicators and produces

information on the outcomes of the policy (Dunn 2004; Bisang & Zimmermann 2006).

       The policy analysis is an iterative process: at each step there is feedback from the other

steps, and the final step, to monitor the implemented policy, will be compared with the first step.



               2.1     Policy Evaluation

               2.1.1. History of Policy Evaluation

       Formal policy evaluation began in the 1930s. On a systematic basis policies have been

evaluated from the mid 1960s (Zerbe & Dively 1994; Rossi et al. 1999; Bisang & Zimmermann

2006). At that time the United States established two programs to fight poverty: the War on

Poverty-Great Society initiative and the Executive Order establishing the Planning Programming




                                                 6
Budgeting (PPB) system, both programs mandated policy evaluation (Haveman 1987 in Rossi et

al 1999; Rossi et al 1999; Bisang & Zimmermann 2006). The US General Accounting Office

(GAO) was put in charge of these evaluation studies (GAO 1991 in Bisang & Zimmermann

2006). The Government Performance and Results Act, passed in 1993, required US executive

agencies to evaluate their programs.

       International institutions, such as the World Bank and the United Nations, also require

evaluations of their projects (Dasgupta et al. 1972; Squire & van der Tak 1975; Nas 1996);

Chelimsky & Shadish 1997 in Bisang & Zimmerman 2006). The World Bank requires an impact

evaluation of its projects. It provides evaluation guidelines, recognizing that there is no single

standard approach to conduct an impact evaluation, and that each evaluation has to consider the

project, the country and institutional context and the actors involved. The Bank recognizes that

there are different times in project evaluation: (1) evaluations for the Bank have to be timed with

mid-term review and closing of the project; (2) evaluations for the government have to be timed

with government discussions, i.e., budget, political context. Government participation in the

project is considered a key element to the success of a policy. The role of the government is to

identify the relevant policy questions, to ensure the integrity of the evaluation, and to incorporate

the results in future policy choices (World Bank 2006).

       Since the World Bank is an important lending source for developing countries, these

developments had numerous impacts on project evaluations in Latin America.               In Europe,

program evaluations were introduced in the 1970s in Sweden, Germany and the UK. The

practice of policy evaluation has expanded to other countries in the 1990s, making it a common

practice nowadays (Leeuw 2004 in Bisang & Zimmermann 2006).




                                                 7
2.1.2. Types of evaluation

           Policy evaluation methods can be classified in different ways: quantitative and

qualitative, social choice and “implementable”2, rationalist and social. A classification according

to the objective of the evaluation criteria has been widely discussed in the literature. These

methods range from qualitative methods (Dunn 2004) to quantitative methods (Dasgupta et al.

1972; Squire & van der Tak 1975; Ray 1984; Pleskovic & Treviño 1985; Stone 1985;

Chowdhury & Kirkpatrick 1994; Zerbe & Dively 1994; Nas 1996), and a combination of both

(Slee 2006).

           Quantitative methods can be grouped in three categories: Input-Output models (I-O),

Computable General Equilibrium models (CGE) and Cost-Benefit analyses (CBA). An I-O

model uses a matrix to represent a nation’s economy in terms of the linkages between sectors,

households and the government (Pleskovic & Treviño 1985; Chowdhury & Kirkpatrick 1994).

Multipliers are calculated from the matrix to estimate the change in total economic activity

attributable to sector activity. A CGE model simulates a market economy by considering the

abstract general equilibrium structure formalized by Arrow and Debreu (Bergman & Henrekson

2003; Wing 2004). A CBA estimates the costs and benefits associated with the new activity or

policy. This approach differs from I-O and CGE models since it does not consider the economy

as a whole.

           Qualitative models include focus groups and in-depth interviews with the populations

affected by the policy (Dunn 2004; Slee 2006). They aim to reveal stakeholders´ response to the

policy under evaluation (Slee 2006). Most of these methods do not allow immediate

quantification, and qualitative statistical methods should be adopted.



2
    The term “implementable” refers to a policy that can be put in practice.


                                                            8
A combination of quantitative and qualitative methods to policy evaluation has been

proposed by Slee (2006). The method is called a multidimensional approach and it includes four

elements: economic linkages, regional impacts, non-market benefits, and social analysis

(Slee et al. 2003). The consideration of these elements will allow measuring the spillovers

associated with a forest project, such as non-market benefits and local and regional development

of the population around the forest.

        Mendes classified policy evaluation methods into two general approaches. The first one

is used when the policy maker has defined a set of objectives the policy should achieve and

evaluates their achievement. The second approach takes performance criteria as given and

assesses if the desirable outcomes can be put in practice implemented (Mendes 2000 in Carvalho

Mendes 2006). The first group of methods is based on social choice theories, and the second

group on implementation theory (Carvalho Mendes 2006). The social choice theories started

with the General Possibility Theorem established by Arrow (1951). He proved that any social

choice rule that satisfies a basic set of fairness conditions could produce an intransitive social

order leading to a non-Pareto Optimal solution (Boardman 2001). The implementation method

examines whether the policy targets were achieved, and if they were not, it investigates whether

the goals were “implementable”. The author proposes three types of implementation constraints:

“feasibility, individual rationality, and incentive compatible constraints“, and associates these

constraints with three facts of policy making: resources availability, decisions decentralization,

and imperfect information about the stakeholders (Carvalho Mendes 2006).

        Finally, two groups of approaches resulted from the discussion at a symposium on Forest

Policy Evaluation held in France in 20043. One group is the rationalist, as the methods included


3
 EFI (European Forest Institute)-ENGREF (French Institute of Forestry, Agricultural and Environmental
Engineering)-IUFRO (International Union of Forest Research Organizations) International Symposium. June, 2004.


                                                      9
here use a rationalist framework to evaluate a policy. The theories included the social choice

theory, as explained above; the implementation theory, previously mentioned in the classification

conducted by Carvalho Mendes; and the systemic theory, which considers the sector as groups of

actors interrelated among them and with different institutions. Another group considers the

context in which the policy is evaluated, including social and policy considerations rather than

using rationalist schemes (Forest Policy and Economics Editorial 2006).



              2.2      Cost Benefit Analysis

              2.2.1.   Social choice

       According to the social choice theory, the government intervenes in the economy in

response to market failures, which prevent an optimal resource allocation in society. These

failures may include imperfect competition, asymmetric information, inability to provide public

goods, or externalities. The policies of the government are driven by a goal of reaching income

distribution and improving public welfare (Zerbe & Dively 1994; Dunn 2004). The policies will

affect prices and then consumer welfare.

       A convenient way to measure the change in the social welfare is the consumer surplus.

The willingness to pay measured by the compensating and equivalent variations would be the

correct way to measure welfare changes. However, in practice, the measures are difficult to

obtain since deriving compensated demand curves requires holding utility levels constant.

Therefore, demand curves in which income is held constant are used. The welfare measured

using these demand curves, called ordinary demand curves are called consumer and producer

surplus (Varian 1984; Zerbe & Dively 1994).




                                               10
Consumer surplus (CS) is approximately the amount one would pay for the good over

what one does have to pay. It is the usual measure of welfare change in CBA benefit cost

analysis. The CS is represented by the area under the ordinary demand curve, but above the price

(Figure 2). Producer surplus (PS) is an analogous concept to consumer surplus. It is the amount

that can be taken from the producer or input supplier without diminishing the amount supplied.

PS is measured along a supply curve just as CS is measured along a demand curve, so it is the

area below the price and above the supply curve.

       However, policy questions do not generally concern a single individual only. A central

problem of any social welfare or social value theory is the problem of aggregation over

individuals to obtain society’s welfare (Zerbe & Dively 1994; Boardman 2001). The use of the

Pareto Optimality criterion usually allows measuring society’s welfare. This criterion is an

efficiency norm describing the conditions necessary to achieve optimality in resource allocation.

The Pareto Optimality criterion establishes that no one can be made better off without

simultaneously making at least one other person worse off (Dunn 2004). The criterion is an

efficiency norm criterion and three efficiency conditions are associated with it: production

efficiency, exchange efficiency, and allocative efficiency. Production efficiency represents a

resource allocation where it is no longer possible to increase the output of one good without

reducing the output of another. Exchange efficiency represents a resource allocation where is

impossible to make one individual better off without making one other individual worse off.

Allocative efficiency is attained when production and exchange efficiency are both attained: the

rate at which commodities are substituted in production equals the rate at which commodities are

exchanged in consumption. Pareto Optimality criterion distinguishes between optimal and non-




                                               11
optimal solutions but does not provide a conceptual framework for comparing two solutions that

are efficient.

        The problem of locating the optimal point on the utility frontier is a problem of social

choice. Economists approach to the social choice problem by postulating a social welfare

function. A social welfare function is a decision rule for making choices in which the welfare of

more than one person or agent is affected. A social welfare function is a function of the utilities

of n individuals:

                       W= W (U1, U2,…,Un)

                       Where: W= society’s welfare

                               Un = utility of individual n

                               n= number of individuals in the society



        While the Pareto Optimality indicates an efficient resource allocation, in the real word is

difficult to attain. Consequently a more flexible criterion is used: the Potential Pareto

improvement also called the Kaldor-Hicks criterion. According to this criterion, those

individuals who benefit from reallocation could compensate those individuals who lose (Zerbe &

Dively 1994; Boardman 2001).

        The value of a resource allocation change can be measured by considering consumer and

producer surpluses. Examples of factors affecting welfare include externalities, supply changes,

and other market distortions. Social welfare can be affected by a policy, such as new taxation or

subsidies. Figure 3 provides an example of how new taxes affect three sectors of the economy:

consumers, producers and government. The supply curve shifts backward, and the price paid by

the household changes from p0 to pd while the price received by the producer is ps. The loss in CS




                                                12
equals area A plus area B while PS loses area C plus area D. The revenue received by the

government equals area A plus area D. The difference between the revenue received by the

government and the households’ and producers’ loss is called deadweight loss, consisting of area

B plus area D.



                 2.3   Forest Policy

       There are several reasons for policy interventions in the forest sector. First, forests

provide non-market services such as soil conservation, aesthetic values, recreation, and carbon

storage (Chappelle 1971; Ellefson 1988; Dore & Guevara 2000; Clapp 2001; Clark 2004;

Richards & Stokes 2004). Second, forest investments are long-term investments. They require

the maintenance of a large capital stock, which makes the opportunity cost of capital tied up in

growing stock high.

       Meijerink (1997 in Enters et al. 2003) proposed that incentives should be applied to

public goods only. Where plantations provide environmental services such as soil or watershed

protection, prevention of land degradation or carbon sequestration, incentives are appropriate

because private net returns are often lower than overall social returns. Enters et al. (2003)

proposed incentives to projects that provide employment, especially to new forest industries in

countries with competitive advantages, ensuring reliable supplies of strategic timber resources,

and alleviating rural poverty. Scherr and Current (1999 in Enters et al 2003) stated that

incentives might be particularly justified to accelerate the pace of plantation development in

cases where a developing industry requires a minimum supply of raw material. Clapp (1995 in

Enters et al 2003) stated that commodity industries such as pulp and paper need economies of

scale to be competitive, then a subsidy to start their activities may be necessary. Cubbage et al.




                                               13
(1993) mentioned that reducing income taxes by providing tax deductions or tax credits for

timber growing is a way of favoring timber investments.

       On the other hand, some authors claimed that incentives represent a misallocation of

public-sector resources and are not needed when the private returns from plantation management

exceed those from other land uses (Forestry Law 13723 1968; Haltia & Keipi 1997).

Furthermore, in a number of instances government forestry policies have aggravated problems

such as deforestation (Repetto & Gillis 1988). The deforestation of Brazilian Amazon, the

inefficient use of resources in Philippines, and illegal logging in Indonesia are the most common

examples of these negative effects (Repetto 1988; Repetto & Gillis 1988; Berck et al. 2003;

Bacha 2004).



               2.4       Latin American Policy

       In Latin America, the use of incentive mechanisms promoting forest investments started

in the 1970s and was broadly adopted in the 1980s. Chile, Argentina, Brazil and Uruguay

introduced subsidies, tax breaks and tax exonerations to promote the development of forest

plantations and wood manufacturing industries, with different results. Colombia, Ecuador and

Paraguay took the Chilean model to establish subsidies.



               2.4.1. Chile

               2.4.1.1       Regulation

       The development of the forest sector in Chile began with the Decree Law 701 that

created the Forestry National Corporation (CONAF). The objective of the policy was:

“…to promote plantations, reforest, rationalize the exploitation and attain the optimum




                                                 14
management of the forest” (Sabag Villalobos 1984). Management plans are required for native

forest, forest plantations, afforestation projects, and harvesting operations (FAO 2006). The

instruments applied consisted of subsidies and tax exonerations (Sabag Villalobos 1984; Silva

2004; FAO 2006). Currently subsidies are not in force and tax exonerations are the only

incentive still available. Policy results were positive. The area of pine and eucalyptus plantations

increased substantially (FAO 2006).

       Small producers were not included in the incentives schemes established by the Decree

Law 701 (Silva 2004). The reestablishment of a democratic government led to several reforms of

the forest policy. These reforms included the debate of the Native Forest Bill in 1990, and the

reform of the Decree Law 701 between 1994 and 2000 (Silva 1999 in Silva 2004). The Native

Forest Bill was one of the first environmental initiatives of the government. The Native Forest

Bill aimed to protect native forests that were under pressure from invading pine plantations.

Several political issues and opposite interests arose in the debate, with the president and the

Agricultural Ministry supporting the Bill, and the Economy Ministry, part of the legislature, and

the timber corporations opposing it. The Native Forest Bill is still under deliberation and has not

yet been approved. The reform of the Decree Law 701 aimed to redirect the subsidies from large

corporations to small producers. Following negotiations, large corporations received an

extension of tax exonerations but did not gain access to the subsidies.



               2.4.1.2   Forest Resources

       Chile’s forest area has grown over the past 15 years as a result on increased planting. At

the same time, native forest area has been stable. The total forest area reached 16 million

hectares (ha) by 2005 (Table 1). Between 1998 and 2004, about 40,000 ha were planted




                                                15
annually. The country is divided into 13 regions. Native forests are located in Regions IX

through XII and forest plantations are concentrated in Regions VII through IX (Lara & Veblen

1993). In 1994 radiata pine covered 75.5% of the total planted area, and eucalyptus 16.9%. By

2004 the share of radiata pine declined to 47% and while that of eucalyptus rose to 40% (Paredes

1999; Southern Hemisphere 2006). The value of forest production increased more than four

times between 1984 and 1997. During this period, 74% of the production was exported (Paredes

1999). Wood pulp production reached 3.4 million ton in 2004, as much as 2.5 million were

exported. Pulpwood consumption also increased, and there is a concern regarding future pulp

wood availability for new projects. Paper exports increased by 78% between 1986 and 2004.

Paper exports increased in 2004 compared to 2003 by 31% (Southern Hemisphere 2006).

       Lumber production has also increased reaching 8.6 million m3 in 2004, with 2.4 million

m3 exported. On the other hand, local lumber consumption has also increased due to the growth

of the construction sector (Paperloop 2005; Southern Hemisphere 2006).



              2.4.1.3    Industry

       The Chilean forest industry is one of the most rapidly growing in the world (Clapp 2001;

Silva 2004). The pulp industry is highly concentrated. rauco and CMPC Celulosa are the most

important companies (Paperloop 2005; Southern Hemisphere 2006). Arauco owns four pulpmills

in Chile and one in Argentina (Southern Hemisphere 2006). The solid wood sector is also highly

concentrated: nine companies account for 90% of the production. The most important companies

are the same as in the pulp sector: Arauco and CMPC Celulosa (Southern Hemisphere 2006).




                                              16
2.4.2     Brazil

              2.4.2.1      Regulation

       Between 1967 and 1986, Brazil has provided incentives for establishing forest

plantations. The first law was established in 1966 and included tax incentives to plantations

(Keugen 2001; Flynn 2005). To be included in this program the owner had to present a plan to

the Brazilian Institute for Forestry Development (IBDF), which had to approve it, and then the

plantation and maintenance costs were deducted from the income taxes for the first three years of

the operation, up to a maximum of 50% of the income tax. During the 1970s the law was revised

restricting the tax exonerations to legal entities, and reducing gradually the percentage of tax

deduction. In 1987, the percentage was reduced to 10% and restricted to the Northeast of the

country (Flynn 2005). A controversial issue was the use of agricultural lands for forestry. In

1976 the regulation established “Priority Regions for Reforestation and/or Forest Industry

Districts” for planting. Currently, the federal government has two programs that provide

incentives to small and medium sized landowners to plant trees.

       Regarding the industry, the Brazilian Government has encouraged the establishment of

specific programs to develop the industrial forest sector. The Wood and Furniture Forum is led

by the Ministry of Development and Foreign Trade and was established to promote growth in the

sector. The BNDES has financed studies which indicate that more plantations are needed in

order to provide wood for the new industries. Therefore, the BNDES has been financing forest

plantations projects. PROMOVEL is the Brazilian Program for Increasing Furniture Exports. It

was created in 1998 by the Brazilian Furniture Association (Flynn 2005).




                                               17
There are some protective tariffs to the wood products industry. On one hand, taxes on

wood imports have been decreasing. On the other hand, imported equipment has high tariffs in

order to encourage the use of local machinery (Flynn 2005).

       Another law requires that at least 20% of every forest area must be maintained in “natural

vegetation”(Flynn 2005).



               2.4.2.2     Forest Resources

       Today, Brazil has nearly 6 million ha covered with forest plantations, and the total area of

natural forest is more than 550 million ha as is shown in Table 2 (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005;

FAO 2006; Southern Hemisphere 2006). Eucalyptus accounted for 63% of total planted area and

pine for 31%. Eucalyputs growth rates differ according to states and companies, ranging from 30

to 50 m3/ha/year. Annual harvest is estimated in 60-70 million m3, and it is projected to increase

to 106 million m3. Consumption is divided into pulp mills (50%), charcoal and energy (40%),

panels (6%), and lumber (4%) (Flynn 2005).

       Pine plantations are located mainly in the state of Parana, 682,000 ha, and were planted

between 1967 and 1998 (Southern Hemisphere 2006). The ownership is not very concentrated as

12 companies own 18.4% of the total (Flynn 2005). Rotations are on average 22 years in the

South, with a first thinning at 12 years and a second thinning at 17 years. If pines are managed

for pulp, rotations are 16 years (Flynn 2005). Pine harvest is divided among sawmills (60%),

pulpmills (22%), plywood (10%) and composite wood panels (8%).




                                               18
2.4.2.3    Industry

       Brazil is the 7th largest producer of pulp in the world and the 11th largest producer of

paper and paperboard in the world (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005). Pulp production has been

expanding since the 1990s (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005). Aracruz is the most important pulp

company with a pulp production capacity of 2.25 million metric tons in 2003. The reminder is

divided among five companies (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005).

       Another growth industry is packaging. The largest packaging producer is Klabin which

has a capacity of 150,000 ton/year (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005).



               2.4.2.4     Exports

       The value of sawn wood exports increased 23% between 2003 and 2004. The growth in

the following year was much smaller. The exports increased by 5% only due to the Real

devaluation (Southern Hemisphere 2006). The most important export markets were United States

and China.

       Pulp and paper exports have been increasing reaching 1.187 billion US$ in 2004. The

main destinations for pulp were Europe (47%), Asia (29%) and North America (21%); on the

other hand, paper went to Latin America, Europe (18%) and North America (16%) (Flynn 2005).



               2.5       Summary

       The design of a public policy implies the choice of objectives that considers scarce

resources and opposite interests. The last objective behind any public policy is to increase the

welfare of the society, i.e., to make a group of persons better off without making anyone else

worse off. This is known as the Pareto Optimality criteria.




                                                19
In Latin America, many countries started forest programs with different results. Chile and

Brazil can be characterized as the most successful, even though their policies and strategies have

been different. Chile has a highly concentrated forest industry while Brazil has less concentrated

industry. Both countries rely on exotic species.




                                                   20
1. Define
                                            the
                                         problem

         6. Monitor the                                 2. Establish
          implemented                                    evaluation
             policy                                        criteria


           5. Implement
                                                        3. Identify
             the Policy
                                                        alternative
                                                         policies




                                       4. Evaluate
                                       alternative
                                         policies




  Source: Adapted from Patton and Sawicki, 1993.




Figure 1. Basic Policy Analysis Process



                                                   21
Price                              Supply



                       CS
           Po         PS
                                            Demand


                                                     Quantity
                              Qo
Figure 2. Consumer and Producer Surplus




         Price                     Supply 2          Supply 1



                 Pd
                      A        B
                 P0
                               D            Demand
                          C
                 Ps
                              Q1       Qo            Quantity


Figure 3. Taxation and Deadweight Loss




                                                 22
Table 1. Forest area in Chile (1,000 ha)

     FRA 2005 Categories            1990       2000       2005
     Primary                        4,152      4,145      4,142
     Modified natural               9,344      9,309      9,292
     Semi-natural                     26        26         26
     Sub total                     13,522     13,480     13,460
     Productive plantation          1,741      2,354      2,661
     Protective plantation             0         0          0
     Total                         15,263     15,834     16,121
     Source: FAO, Global Forest Resources Assessment 2005.



Table 2. Forest area in Brazil (1,000 ha)
     FRA 2005 Categories             1990       2000       2005
     Primary                       460,513    433,220    415,890
     Modified natural               54,444     54,714     56,424
     Semi-natural                      -          -          -
     Sub total                     514,957    487,934    472,314
     Productive plantation           5,070      5,279      5,384
     Protective plantation             -          -          -
     Total                         520,027    493,213    477,698
     Source: FAO, Global Forest Resources Assessment 2005.




                                                   23
CHAPTER 3

                                  URUGUAY’S FOREST SECTOR



        Uruguay is a small South American country located between Argentina and Brazil. It has

a Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of 18 billion US$ (Central Bank of Uruguay 2005). The most

important sector of the economy is Manufacturing Industries, which accounts for 22.9% of GDP.

Another important sector is Agriculture, including livestock, which contributed 8.7% to the GDP

(Figure 4). The silviculture sub-sector (forest plantations) has increased its share in the

Agricultural GDP between 1990 and 2002 to 13.4% (Table 3).

        The Uruguayan Economy has been relatively stable during the last 25 years, except for

two financial crises in 1982 and in 2002. In 1982, the exchange rate system collapsed leading to

a currency devaluation and a financial crisis. This resulted in a decline in the agricultural sector,

which had debt denoted in US$ and was multiplied by the devaluation effect. After a period of

high growth in the 1990s, the economy began to contract in 1998, and the 2002 financial crisis

reinforced this phenomena. However, in 2003 the GDP increased 1% versus a 10% decline the

year before. This reversal can be explained by growing exports and by substituting imports with

domestic production. The trade balance in Uruguay was negative between 2000 and 2005 with

the exception of 2003. The main export is beef, which accounts for 33% of total exports. Even

though in 2005 exports increased by 16.2%, imports increased 24.4%, resulting in a trade deficit

of 474 million US$. A one-time special purchase of 243 million US$ of Venezuelan oil was part

of the deficit.




                                                 24
The Uruguayan exchange rate regime4 has changed from pegged exchange rates within

horizontal bands in the 1990s to a floating system in 2002, after a 93% devaluation that year. The

devaluation has increased the competitiveness of domestic production and exports grew. At the

same time, imports declined due to a contraction in consumption (Economic Institute 2003).



                 3.1      Description of the Uruguayan Forest Sector

                 3.1.1    Area

        Forest area is in Uruguay reaches almost 1.5 million ha, constituting 9% of the country’s

land base (Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay 2000; Ramos & Cabrera 2001). Forests are

classified as either plantations or natural forests. Natural forests cover 740,000 ha, representing

4% of the country’s land area (Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay 2000; Ramos & Cabrera 2001).

Plantations cover 751,000 ha and their area has grown rapidly from between 1990 and 2005

(Table 4).

        The last Agricultural Census, CGA 2000, shows a significant increase in the forest area

(Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay 2000). Planted forest area reached 661 thousand ha in 2000.

That represented a nearly 4-fold increase from the preceding Census of 1990. According to the

Forest Division of the Agricultural Ministry, between 1990 and 2002, 590,000 ha were planted

under the incentives of the Forestry Law (Durán 2003).

        The law provided fiscal incentives for the development of commercial forests plantations

on priority soils, generally marginal agricultural (Figure 5). The CONEAT5 index measures the

productivity of the land by soil type, location, and productivity. The base index is 100; lands

4
 The exchange rate considered here is the price of a dollar in terms of Uruguayan Peso ($U). The US$ is the
currency used by the Uruguayan Government to set the exchange rate and the exchange rate regime.
5
 CONEAT stands for the National Commission of Agronomic Study of the Land. This Commission depends on the
Renewable Resources Division (RENARE) which depends on the Agricultural and Livestock Ministry (MGAP).


                                                        25
with an index higher than 100 are considered very well for livestock and agriculture; lands with

an index lower than 100 are considered poor lands. Ramos and Cabrera built a weighted average

CONEAT index for forest lands and estimated that between 1989 and 1999 the index was 69.6

(Ramos & Cabrera 2001) (Table 5).



               3.1.2   Species

       Plantation incentives were provided for particular tree species. As a consequence,

eucalyptus species account for 76% of planted areas greater than 10, and pine for 22%

(Figure 6). While pine has been more frequently planted in recent years, eucalyptus still accounts

for the majority of the planted area,



               3.1.3   Location

       Forested areas are geographically concentrated in the north of the country (the provinces

of Rivera and Tacuarembó). The remainder is found in the west (the provinces of Paysandú and

Río Negro), and in the southwest (the provinces of Lavalleja and Maldonado). Currently, forest

area is Cerro Largo also growing. Rivera is the province with the largest forest area (115,000 ha,

which represents 13.1% of the total agricultural area of the province). It is followed by

Tacuarembó (97,300 ha, 6.6% of the total agricultural area of the province); and Paysandú

(93,000 ha, 6.9% of the total area of the province). Nearly a half of the forest planted area is

located in those three provinces, Rivera, Tacuarembó and Paysandú (Durán 2003).




                                               26
3.1.4   Ownership

       The saw timber and paper sectors have begun developing rapidly in the 1990s. As the

first forest plantations neared their first harvest, international investors have discovered

Uruguay’s forest sector as an attractive investment opportunity. Traditionally, the sector

concentrated on paper and lumber production manufactures. These lumber manufacturers were

small local firms (Durán 2004). The Forestry Law has recently attracted new, primarily foreign,

investors who focus on plantations development and paper and lumber manufacturing. The

forest sector today is characterized by the coexistence of large, vertically integrated firms with

many small scale primary producers and a substantial presence of foreign investors. Production

and export activities are the domain of a few large firms (Durán 2003; Mendell et al. 2007).

       Even though there are more than 19,000 farms with at least one forested ha, the forest

plantation estate is highly concentrated: 96% of the farms have less than 100 ha planted and they

control only 17.3% of the forest area. Most of these small farms use plantations for shelter and

shadow for livestock or for other non-commercial purposes. On the other hand, 62.8% of the

plantation area is in farms with forest areas greater than 500 ha. Intermediate farms (planted

areas between 100 and 500 ha) account for only 9% the total forest planted area (Table 6).

According to DIEA assessment, in 2000 there were 64 farms with planted area between 1,000

and 10,000 ha and 9 farms with forest planted areas larger than 10,000 ha (Durán 2003).



               3.1.5   Forest Income

       The development of plantations and growing production of wood products have

transformed the forest sector into an important source of income. According to the Agricultural

Census 2000, out of 57,131 farms, 1,015 listed forestry as their main source of income. The




                                               27
forest sector employs 2,962 workers, from a total of 157,000 employees in the agricultural

sector. In addition, a large number of workers serve the forest sector by performing harvesting,

pruning, and thinning operations. The Forest Division estimated that in 2000 the sector had

approximately 14,000 employees in the forest plantations (Durán 2003).



               3.1.6   Wood harvest, manufacturing, and exports

       Growing wood harvest fueled a rapid growth in wood exports. The harvest volume

increased 27% between 2000 and 2003, rising from 2.9 million to 3.7 million m3 (cubic meters)

(DIEA 2004). Pulpwood production increased from 893,000 to 1.6 million cum, a gain of 83%,

and fuel wood production increased from 1.4 to 1.6 million cum, a gain of 13%. Much of the

harvest, except fuel wood, is designated for export (Forest Division 2005).

       While export growth has been rapid, its share in the Trade Balance remains low. Forest

products exports account only for 5% of the country’s total exports, and in the period 1989-2004

the share has oscillated between 2 to 7% (Table 7). At the same time, forest products imports

account for 3.5% of the total imports (ALADI 2006). It is expected, however, that maturing

plantations will increase wood harvest which would promote export-oriented production. The

two most important export groups are (1) saw timber (2) paper and cardboard, and pulpwood has

been increasing in the last years (Table 8). If paper and cardboard exports are not considered,

forest exports account for 4% of the country’s total exports.

       Since 1990 pulpwood production increased dramatically. About 50% of the production is

exported. Saw timber and lumber production also increased. Since domestic consumption of

these products has been stable, their export continues to grow. In 2000, about 100 thousand cum

of lumber were exported. That accounts for a fifth of the total lumber production. Paper and




                                                28
cardboard exports also increased, reaching more than 50,000 tons in 1999, or 40% of the total

production. That year the total forest exports were less than 100 million US$, 4.4% of the total

exports in Uruguay. By 2004, pulpwood exports reached 92.5 million US$, lumber exports 18.1

million US$, and paper and cardboard 31.6 million US$.

         During the 1990s pulp logs exports went to Europe: Spain, Norway, Finland and

Portugal. Lumber was sold to Italy, USA and Japan (Figures 7 and 8).



                  3.1.7    Export Prices

         Between 1989 and 1999, exports grew in volume but not in value. The Central Bank of

Uruguay (BCU) constructs an index for Paper and Cardboard (Series X). The Index is a Paasche

Index with base in the previous year on FOB6 values, and it is available from 1994 to 2004. The

index shows that prices increased between 1994 and 1995, but started declining in 1996

(Table 9).

         The Forest Division provides export information by value, volume, and item, allowing

the estimation of unitary values. This information is available for years from 1980 and 2005, for

hardwood and softwood saw timber and pulpwood. The results indicate that hardwood saw

timber unit values were more stable than softwood saw timber ones (Table 10). Hardwood prices

varied from 27 to 314 US$/m3 in the period7; while softwood unit values oscillated from 99 to

115 US$/ m3. Softwood pulpwood pries were stable at around 40 US$/ m3 8.

         The Association of Industries of Uruguay (CIU) constructs a Paasche index for the entire

sector (saw timber, pulp, paper, cardboard, printing, etc.) based on the National Customs

Administration (DNA) data. The index is also calculated for saw timber, but not for pulpwood

6
  Free on Board.
7
  In 1990, the average unit value was 5 US$/cum, a value that probably does not reflect the real price.
8
  There is no information about pulp prices before 1989.


                                                         29
because its share in Uruguay’s total exports is low. The weights are not fixed as the index base is

the preceding year. Three products are included: pine wood, eucalyptus wood, and other species

wood (Table 11). The results from 2000 to 2006 with 2000 as a base year show that prices had

decreased until 2002 and after that started growing again.



                 3.1.8    Imports

        Forest products imports increased in the 1990s: paper purchases increased four-fold,

representing 60% of the total forest imports in value; lumber represented 18% of the total;

remanufactured wood purchases represented 5% of the total. Pulp purchases doubled in value

and tripled in volume, reaching more than 10% of the total. Between 1995 and 2005, forest

imports9 were on average US$ 47 million annually (Table 12).

        Two thirds of the Uruguayan purchases of paper and cardboard came from the region,

mainly from Argentina and Brazil, 15% came from North America, and the rest from Europe.

The regions are the source for 70% of pulpwood imports.



                 3.1.9    Forest Industries

        The National Institute of Statistics (INE) collects information for industries using the

Uniform International Industrial Classification (CIIU). According to its estimates, based on INE

and BCU data, sawmills and pulp and paper industries constituted 1.36% of Uruguay’s GDP in

2003 (Table 13). This percentage will be higher after new facilities currently under construction

are included. Botnia, which will have completed a pulp and paper mill investment of one billion




9
 Not all the products were considered. Ramos and Cabrera (2001) considered all the products and indicated that
between 1989 and 2000, the forest imports averaged 75 million US$ annually.


                                                       30
US$ this year. The mill construction began in the third quarter of 2005. Other companies, such

Urupanel and Colonvade in Tacuarembó also completed their investments after 2003.

       The CIIU 2 was used until 2002. Then it was replaced the CIIU 3. In CIIU 2, the pulp

and paper industry was considered together with newspapers, printing, etc. In CIIU 3, they are

separate items, and the wood and wood manufacturing industry includes new items as well.

Therefore, the production values of each subgroup cannot be compared for those years. The

Association of Industries of Uruguay (CIU) constructs a Production Index (PI) for the industry

using the CIIU 3 codes from 1993 to 2006 based on INE data, which was used to convert the

values from current US$ to constant 2002 US$ (Table 14).

       Pulp and Paper Industry GDP increased 6% between 1998 and 1999, measured in

constant US$ of 2002, and then declined (Table 15). In 2002, the INE changed the classification

system and the Pulp and Paper sub sector does not include printing; therefore, the results cannot

be compared easily. However, after adjusting the data, the results show that the GDP in US$

increased. If only pulp and paper industry is considered, between 2002 and 2003, its GDP

increased 30%; sawmills GDP increased by 67%; meanwhile, manufacturing industry GDP

decreased. There are no records of sawmills GDP before 2002.

       Analyzing the share of forest industries in total manufacturing GDP, only sawmills

increased their share significantly between 2002 and 2003 (Table 16). This is consistent with the

current situation in the forest sector: the new projects that just have been completed or are about

to be completed are not included in the GDP.

       The number of sawmills decreased, indicating the industry concentrated. By 2000, the

number of sawmills declined to about than 50, down from 113 in 1988. The sawmills operated

primarily in Montevideo (45%), San José and Paysandú (20% each) and Rivera and Tacuarembó




                                                31
(15% of the total) (Ramos & Cabrera 2001). In the 1990s, the production of pulp wood and

recycled paper increased, as well as the pulp and cardboard production, to lesser degree, but the

employment in those sub sectors was reduced to half (Ramos & Cabrera 2001).

       Currently, five firms are key players in the forest sector in Uruguay: Botnia, Colonvade,

Fymnsa, Cofusa-Urufor, and Urupanel. Two firms invest heavily in pulp manufacturing: Ence

and Stora Enso. Botnia, is constructing a pulp mill in the North of the country, which involves

the largest single investment in the country’s history, with a value of one billion US$. The mill

will be operational the third quarter of 2007. Ence has partnerships with several local firms and

had been planning a pulp mill. Due to a dispute with Argentina, Ence has been forced to change

the mill’s location and that decision is still under consideration. Stora Enso has just arrived in

the country and is also planning to build a pulp mill. In the saw timber and plywood sector, the

leading firms include Fymnsa and Urufor (domestic) and Weyerhaeuser and Urupanel (foreign).

Colonvade is constructing a plywood facility and plans to build five to eight more plants in

Tacuarembó, Rivera and Paysandú. Fymnsa, one of the oldest and biggest domestic companies

located in Rivera, is constructing a sawmill. Cofusa and Urufor operate in the North of Uruguay

and produce high quality eucalyptus grandis timber. Urupanel is a Chilean lumber company

located in Tacuarembó.



               3.2    Forest Policy

       Even though there was a general agreement when the Forestry Law was approved in

1987, controversies soon followed. The Forestry Law in Uruguay was controversial for several

reasons including subsidies and regionalization. Regarding subsidies, the main issues were: (1)

whether the subsidies were necessary to attract investments, (2) whether to subsidize other,




                                               32
already established, sectors of the economy and (3) whether the subsidies should be in effect for

regions which determined that better alternative uses exist for lands allocated to forest

development. Regarding regionalization, the argument focused on the designation of forest

priority lands as it was argued that not all lands included were low productivity lands.



               3.2.1   Background and Previous Regulation

       In the 1950s, the potential to increase forest production in Uruguay was studied. At the

same time, the country’s soils were classified according to their productivity (CIDE 1963). The

classification had five soil groups, and the country was divided into thirteen soils zones for

management and conservation (Berreta 2003).

       In 1968, the first Forestry Law was approved (Forestry Law 13723 1968), and the forest

sector became the only economic sector with a Promotion Policy (Gabriel San Román Policy

Director, Forest Division. Personal Communication, July 2006). The objective was to increase

the forest area. The instruments used included tax exonerations, tax reinvestments in plantations,

and credit extended by the BROU.

       The Law did not achieve its objectives for a variety of reasons. The law was incomplete,

funds were not allocated for the Forest Fund, and priority zones were not defined. Furthermore

the credit extension was not designed according to the long term characteristics of a forest

investment (Forestry Law 13723/54-56). Forestry loans were offered by the BROU for a period

of only 10 years (Forestry Law 13723/53), and timber rotations range from 15 to 25 years.




                                                33
3.2.2   Forestry Law 15939: objectives and instruments

           The second Forestry Law was approved in 1987 (Forestry Law 15939 1988) by all

members of the Parliament, even though some members expressed their concerns about some

areas10.

           The parliament passed the law to generate to environmental, economic, and social

benefits for the country. The main objectives of the 1987 Forestry Law were to increase planted

area and to protect native forests. The specific objectives were to increase forest cover through

the introduction of fast-growing species in regions with poor soils, to promote industrial

development in non-industrialized regions, and to increase and diversify exports.

           The Forestry Law 15939 is the framework for the current forestry policy, but, as the

sector has been developing, new regulations have been developed in several decrees and

resolutions. Some of these regulations were designed to implement certain parts of the Law (i.e.

soils priority zones, tax exonerations, subsidies, Forest Fund); others were developed to consider

new factors that emerged during the development of the forest sector (e.g. species productivity);

and finally some were developed to modify original resolutions that needed updating (e.g. soils

priority zones, subsidies).

           The policy instruments used include regionalization, tax exonerations, subsidies, and

credit. Regionalization consisted of defining forestry priority zones in the country. Forestlands

are defined and zones classified according to soil type in Decree 452/88. Soils classified as

priority soils in Forestry Law 15939 and following decrees (Decree 452/88-Article 2; Decree

26/93) are located mainly in the North, Northwest and Northeast of the country. To be classified

as the forest priority soil, the site has to be characterized by a low natural fertility but offer good

10
  The Forest Producers Society summarized the history and discussion of the Forestry Law 15939 in an internal
report that was obtained during the author’s visit to Uruguay, but they date when the report was prepared was not
known.


                                                        34
forest growth conditions (Decree 452/88-Article 3). The minimum area to be considered a forest

was set at 2,500 square meters (Decree 452/88-Article 1).

         The definition of priority zones also included “supplementary soils” that could be planted

up to 40% of the total area11 (Decree 333/90). This decree was revoked in 2005 (Decree 154/05).

Currently, forest planting requires an associated management plan, and to plant in accessory

soils, an environmental plan (Decree 191/06; Decree 220/06). These changes have only a limited

impact on forest investment decisions as they do not affect the management of lands where most

forest plantations have been developed 12 (Personal Communication with Forest Companies, July

2006).

         Tax exonerations for forestlands and taxes and tariff exonerations for goods and inputs

used for forestry activities also were established. Tax exonerations included land tax, which is

1.25% on the land value and will vary according to soil productivity13; rural property taxes; the

exoneration of the Global Tariff Rate and Value Added Tax (IVA) for the imports14 by forest

companies for 15 years. While the last exoneration expired in 2002; property tax exonerations

are still in force. To benefit from the exonerations, the plantations have to be qualified as

protective and production forests and they have to be located in forest priority zones.

         Law 16002 established a subsidy of up to 30% of the cost of plantation but this

percentage was later increased to 50% (Law 16.170, Article 251; Decree 212/97, Article 1).

Currently subsidies are not in force. Another change is that forest priority soils and species are

under revision, but projects previously approved are not affected.



11
   In Decree 452/98 it was allowed to plant in “supplementary soils” up to 10% of the total area.
12
   Other groups of soils affected are: 2.11a, 2.12, 5.01c, 5.02a, 7, 8 (not all) (Decree 191/06).
13
   The value used to calculate the tax is the CONEAT Index.
14
   Activities are listed in Decree 457/989 and include: fertilizers, chemical products, vehicles, machines, equipment
for fire prevention, etc.


                                                         35
Credit is another tool used by the Government to promote forest investments. The

Republic of Uruguay Bank (BROU) finances nurseries and different stages of the forest

production. It provided financing of up to 80% of the project’s value, not considering land value;

the credits are in US$, and payment begin up to 10 years later.

            The ability to create Joint Stock Corporations with bearer shares was one of the changes

introduced by the new Forestry Law. Join Stock corporations with bearer shares were not

allowed in the Agricultural Sector, but the Forestry Sector was the exception. Today, they are

allowed in the Agricultural Sector as well.

            Wood manufacturing industries benefit from other laws as well15. Investments Promotion

and Protection Law and associated decrees, and Free Trade Zone Companies regulations all help

in developing wood processing. Investments Promotion and Protection Law (Law 16906 1998),

establishes tax exonerations and tax breaks for investments that are considered as National

Interest Projects. To receive the benefits introduced in the Law the project has to be declared by

the Government as National Interest Project. The project has to be presented to the Customer

Office at the Tourism Ministry. The requirements include presenting a note describing the fiscal

incentives requested, an investment project containing a description of its costs and benefits, and

an environmental impact study when necessary and a proof of origin of the capital.

            Industries can choose to develop a Free Trade Zone. Two international forest companies

had adopted this regime: Botnia and Ence16. To be considered under this scheme, the company

has to present a project to the government describing the economic viability of the project and

the benefits it will generate for the country. After obtaining the authorization, the company has to


15
     These laws are in force for all industries, not just for forest industries.
16
  By October 2006, Ence announced a change in the mill construction plans. The mill would be relocated and
therefore, the construction is delayed.


                                                               36
pay either a one-time fee or a periodic fee. The benefits include tax exonerations. All the national

taxes are exonerated except for social security contributions. In addition, the entrance of goods

and the services rendered within the free trade zone is exempt from all taxes. Goods inbound to

the zone from Uruguay are considered to be exports and goods outbound from the zone are

exempt from all taxes. However, if the goods are moved into Uruguayan territory they are

considered imports. The company that operates in a tax free zone is not allowed to have activities

in the rest of the country (Tourism Ministry 2006).



                    3.3      Native Forests

           Native species represent 3.7% of the country’s land area. They are composed of 140

species. The species distribution varies with geographical location, particularly with soil

conditions. Native forests can be into five groups: gallery forests, mountain forests, park forests,

ravine forests and palms.

           Traditionally, native forest has been used for fuel wood. Fuel wood consumption has

been constant at around 35,000 to 40,000 tons annually. The sellers are controlled by the

Government and are required to report their stocks every four months.

           The native forests also have non-timber uses. The species present in Uruguay can be used

for medicine, carbon storage, cosmetics (essential oils), fruits17, and ornaments (Escudero 2004).

The ecotourism has been proposed as an interesting alternative use for native forests and is

currently developing in the country.

           Some studies have attempted to estimate the returns of managing native woods

(Cubbage et al. 2006). By considering three different management regimes, the study analyzes

different species in the Southern Cone of Latin America and in the Southern United States.
17
     The Agricultural School of the University of Republic in Uruguay has attempted to work in this field.


                                                           37
Natural stand returns in Latin America were much lower than those of plantations. The average

natural forest growth rates were estimated at 1 cubic meter per hectare per year (m3/ha/yr),

resulting in a low internal rate of return (IRR). The immediate harvest of native species would be

more attractive financially, but is not likely to be sustainable without good management.

       The unsustainable use and exploitation of the native forests worldwide is a widespread

problem. There are three different approaches to the management of the native forests:

exploitation, preservation and conservation. Exploitation refers to the use of the resource,

without considering its conservation. Preservation does not allow any resource utilization.

Finally the intermediate approach would be the conservation approach, which refers to the

regulated use of the forests.

       The Uruguayan government has taken the conservation approach, along with the

preservation of some specific areas. The harvest of native wood is only allowed in the forests

subject to management plans that need to be approved by the Forest Division of the Agricultural

Ministry. In addition, the commercialization and transport of the native wood is controlled by the

government, as described above.

       The Uruguayan Government considered the definition proposed by the World

Conservation Union (IUCN) to design the native forest policy. They consider that the

conservation is positive and involves the preservation, the sustainable management and the

improvement of the natural environment. The Uruguayan government as well as some

institutions has signed agreements with international organizations to implement projects that

protect the native forests, e.g., BIRF Projects UR (3131, 3697), Cooperation Agreement with the

European Union (1994-1995).




                                               38
3.4     Summary

       The Forestry Law promoted the rapid development of forest plantations. Between 1989

and 1999 the area planted increased by 491 thousand ha. The annual planting reached its peak in

1998. The plantations are concentrated in the provinces of Rivera, Paysandú, Tacuarembó, Río

Negro and Cerro Largo, all located in the North of the country (Forest Division 2004). The

Forestry Law attracted new, primarily foreign, firms into the forest sector. These new firms

invested in wood growing and lumber and pulp.

       The incentives were offered because the forest sector has long-term investments and the

returns are not immediate. In addition, if industries are expected to invest in the country, it will

be necessary to have a sizeable forest area in order to meet their raw material needs. Even though

environmental issues such as the protection of native forest protection were considered, they

were not the center of the debate.

       Regionalization was another controversial issue related to the new forest policy. It was

argued that soils that can be used for livestock would be used for forestry. In such cases agro-

forestry systems have been adapted by most of the forest firms.




                                                39
Agriculture and
                                         Other Services             Livestock
                                            8.90%                     8.69%
                                                                               Fisheries
                                                                                0.38%
                                                                                           Minery
                Government Services
                                                                                           0.28%
                      8.22%


                                                                                              Manufacturer Industries
               Assets and services to                                                               22.95%
                    companies
                      11.70%



                                                                                           Electricity, Gas and
                                                                                                  Water
                   Financial Business,
                                                                                                  4.61%
                     Insurances, etc
                         7.54%
                                                                                     Construction
                                   T ransportation                                     4.19%
                                        9.56%
                                                             Commerce, Restaurants
                                                                 and Hotels
                                                                  12.97%

Source: Central Bank of Uruguay 2007.

Figure 4. Uruguay GDP by sectors (2005)


Table 3. GDP as Percentage of Agricultural GDP

    Sub sectors           1990            2002
    Agriculture           23.40           21.00
    Silviculture           3.80           13.40
     Livestock            72.80           65.60
       Total             100.00          100.00
 Source: Central Bank of Uruguay.



Table 4. Uruguay Forest Resources (1,000 ha)

 FRA 2005 Categories                     1990        2000      2005
 Primary                                 591          296       296
 Modified natural                        465          444       444
 Semi-natural                              -            -         -
 Sub total                               704          740       740
 Productive plantation                   197          655       751
 Protective plantation                     4           14        15
 Total                                   905         1,409     1,506
 Source: FAO, Global Forest Resources Assessment 2005.




                                                             40
Uruguay: Forest Priority Soils



                                                          CONEAT Groups




                                                        Agricultural and Livestock Ministry
                                                         Renewable Resources Division
                                                        Geographical Information System




Figure 5. Uruguay Forest Priority Soils




                                          41
Table 5. CONEAT Index for Forest Lands

 Province                                             Ha                   CONEAT Index
 Artigas                                              193                      70.5
 Canelones                                           2,753                     32.4
 Cerro Largo                                        20,941                     65.4
 Colonia                                            1,325                      55.3
 Durazno                                            31,951                     72.4
 Flores                                               426                       69
 Florida                                            23,786                     61.2
 Lavalleja                                          42,960                     65.6
 Maldonado                                          10,247                     65.6
 Montevideo                                           137                       4.5
 Paysandu                                           56,348                     80.1
 Rio Negro                                          77,668                     68.2
 Rivera                                             74,305                      69
 Rocha                                              10,316                     55.5
 Salto                                                437                      41.1
 San Jose                                            2,406                     47.2
 Soriano                                            21,784                     80.9
 Tacuarembo                                         68,113                     71.4
 Treinta y Tres                                      4,823                     63.2
 Total                                             450,917                     69.6
Source: Ramos and Cabrera 2001.




               800,000
               700,000
               600,000
    Hectares




               500,000
                                                                                          Pine
               400,000
                                                                                          Eucalyptus
               300,000
               200,000
               100,000
                    0
                   19 9
                   19 0
                   19 1
                   19 2
                   19 3
                   19 4
                   19 5
                   19 6
                   19 7
                   19 8
                   20 9
                   20 0
                   20 1
                  20 02
                  20 3*
                  20 4*
                       *
                    05
                     8
                     9
                     9
                     9
                     9
                     9
                     9
                     9
                     9
                     9
                     9
                     0
                     0
                   19




                    0
                    0




                                                 Year

(*) For years 2003 and 2004 the official data was not updated, but the total area by 2005 was 751,000 ha, then the
area for each species was assigned according to secondary information.
Source: Forest Division

Figure 6. Area Planted by Species (Cumulative)


                                                         42
Table 6. Forest Farms by Area

  Plantation area             Total
      (in ha)            Number             %
       Total              19,402           100
         <3               11,248            58
        3-10               5,139           26.5
       11-20               1,071           5.5
       21-50                832            4.3
      51-100                362            1.9
     101-500                558            2.9
       >500                 192             1
Source: Agricultural Census 2000.

Table 7. Uruguay Forest Exports Share in Total Exports

                 1989    1990       1991    1992    1993   1994    1995   1996   1997   1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003   2004
 Total
 Exports        1,599 1,693 1,605 1,703 1,645 1,913 2,106 2,397 2,726 2,771 2,242 2,302 2,061 1,861 2,198 2,922
 Forest
 Exports        101.7 103.1         114     117.4 113.5 120.6 142.6 152.4 172.2 171.4 176.3           84.7   82.9   86.7   94.9   146.2
 Share in
 total            6%      6%        7%       7%     7%     6%      7%      6%    6%     6%     8%     4%     4%     5%     4%      5%
    Forest
  Exports (2)     95      94.7      97.2    101.5   98.9   106.1   127    131.4 139.7 138.7 144.8     48.1   49.9   53.9   63.3   114.6
 Share in
 total            6%      6%        6%       6%     6%     6%      6%      5%    5%     5%     6%     2%     2%     3%     3%      4%
 (2) Excludes paper and cardboard
Sources: Forest Division and Central Bank of Uruguay.




                                                                          43
Table 8. Exports in Value and Volume

In volume (1,000 m3)
Product             89     90       91      92      93       94     95     96     97     98     99    00      01     02       03      04      05
Pulpwood           114     83      145 149          88      215    457    510    690    623    702    840    907    1,097   1,369   1,611   1,490
Chips                                                                                                 17     25      12      262     836    1,298
Sawtimber           0       2        2      15      22       28    36     43     64     57     56     72      58     77       96     120     140
Panels                                                                                                 *      *       *       *       *       3
Pulp                3       1        0       1       1        1     2      0      0      *      *      0      1       *       *       *       *
Paper and
Cardboard           7      12       22      22      21       20    15     20     32     35     38     39     36      44      43      42      41
In value (million US$)
Product             89     90       91      92      93       94    95      96     97     98     99     00     01     02       03      04      05
Pulpwood           4.5     3.5      5.8    7.3      3.4      7.9   25     27.6   34.8   31.6   35.7   40.3   41.5   43.1     47.5   56.53   55.73
Chips               0       0        0       0       0        0     0       0     0      0      0     0.42   0.67   0.67    10.86   32.69   62.28
Sawtimber           0      0.2      0.3    1.7      2.1      3.8   5.5     7.8   7.9    9.1    10.1    7.8     7     8.8     12.8    18.1    22.7
Panels              0       0        0       0       0        0     0       0     0      0      *       *      *    0.09     0.04   0.01    0.559
Pulp               1.8      1       0.1    0.5      0.4      0.4   1.5      0     0      0      0     0.02   0.71     *     0.03    0.02      *
Paper and
Cardboard          6.4     8.4 16.8 15.9           14.6     14.5   15.6   21     32.5   32.7   31.5   36.6   33     32.8    31.6    31.6    30.6
(*) Missing information
Source: Forest Division (Statistics Bulletin 2004 and web site)




                                                                          44
Europe
                              Others
                                        0.26%
                              14.30%

                    M exico
                    2.44%



                Chile
               14.23%


                      US
                    1.31%                               M ERCOSUR
                                                        (Argentina and
                                                           Brazil)
                                                           67.46%


Source: ALADI, 2006.

Figure 7. Paper and Cardboard Exports by Region (US$ FOB, 2005)




                     Others
                     24.28%


                                                        Europe
                                                        44.27%




            Asia
           16.72%

                 M exico
                 0.94%                           M ERCOSUR
                                Chile   US          1.04%
                               1.12%  11.63%



       Note: ALADI classification does not include pulpwood. Source: ALADI, 2006.

Figure 8. Wood and Wood Products Exports by Region (US$ FOB, 2005)




                                                   45
Table 9. Paper and Paper Cardboard Exports Price Index

       Year            Price Index
        94                104.2
        95                128.7
        96                 85.1
        97                 90.6
        98                 95.8
        99                 89.3
        00                103.5
        01                 99.8
        02                 83.4
        03                 97.1
        04                103.0
Source: Wood Pastes, Paper and Cardboard (NCM-Section X). Paasche Exports Price Index Base 100=previous
year. Central Bank of Uruguay.




                                                    46
Table 10. Wood Export Unit Values (1,000 US$/m3)

                           Saw timber                          Pulp
  Year        Hardwood         Softwood         Total        Softwood
  1980            -              0.369          0.369
  1981            -              0.410          0.410            -
  1982            -                -              -              -
  1983            *              0.056          0.063            -
  1984          0.086            0.058          0.067          0.032
  1985            -              0.150          0.150            -
  1986            -                -              -              -
  1987          0.100            0.500          0.464            -
  1988          0.150            0.231          0.195            -
  1989          0.139            0.097          0.119          0.042
  1990          0.005            0.099          0.098          0.040
  1991            -              0.115          0.115          0.042
  1992          0.044            0.120          0.114          0.040
  1993          0.140            0.095          0.099          0.046
  1994          0.241            0.123          0.132          0.039
  1995          0.314            0.139          0.151          0.037
  1996          0.027            0.155          0.075          0.055
  1997          0.103            0.149          0.121          0.054
  1998          0.216            0.129          0.160          0.050
  1999          0.049            0.132          0.063          0.049
  2000          0.105            0.117          0.108          0.049
  2001          0.118            0.131          0.121          0.046
  2002          0.129            0.112          0.114          0.039
  2003          0.197            0.098          0.133          0.035
  2004          0.284            0.107          0.151          0.034
  2005          0.240            0.139          0.162          0.037
Source: Based on Forest Division data (Volume and Exports in value).




                                                     47
Table 11. Saw timber Export Price Index

             Year                                 CIU
             2000                                92.71
             2001                                93.98
             2002                                93.15
             2003                                82.58
            2004 (1)                             101.59
             2005                                111.47
(1)
  The CIU calculates the Index as a Paasche Index with base 100=2004. However, when the index is calculated for
year 2004 as a simple average of the monthly indexes, the index is different from 100.
 Source: CIU.




                                                      48
Table 12. Uruguay Forest Imports (million US$ FOB)

               1989 1990        1991   1992    1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
 Wood          0.015 0.048        0      0     0.248 0.118 0.178 0.271 0.011 0.247 0.237 0.226 0.183 0.051 0.116 0.281 0.554
 Saw
 timber    4.936 4.999 5.926 5.597 6.641 9.173 9.552 7.3 14.15 15.2 12.9     9.3 8.985 4.2 3.478 6.589 8.074
 Panels    0.667 0.612 1.36 1.784 2.276 3.228 3.764 4.354 5.942 6.642 5.9 4.963 4.281 2.459 2.701 3.571 5.149
 Paper and
 Cardboard 12.01 13.45 19.65 26.28 30.1 36.29 48.96 46.77 41.31 47.41 44.78 50.8 61.24 30.9 20.84 13.35 45.47
Source: Forest Division 2006.



Table 13. GDP Forest Industries as Percentage of Total GDP (2003)

                                             2003
 GDP Industry/GDP Total                    18.57%
 GDP SW/GDP Industry                        1.44%
 GDP P&P/GDP Industry                       5.90%

 GDP SW/GDP Total                             0.27%
 GDP P&P/GDP Total                            1.10%

 GDP SW and P&P/GDP Total                     1.36%
SW=sawmills, P&P= pulp and paper industries
Source: Own estimations based on INE and BCU data.




                                                                  49
Table 14. CIIU Production Index, base 100=2002

         Year               Sawmills (1)                  Pulp and Paper (2)
         1993                   nd                                69
         1994                   nd                                75
         1995                   nd                                59
         1996                   nd                                84
         1997                   nd                                94
         1998                   nd                                98
         1999                   nd                               101
         2000                   nd                               100
         2001                   nd                                96
         2002                  100                               100
         2003                  201                               103
         2004                  120                               111
         2005                  111                               109
      Jan-Aug 05               103                               104
      Jan-Aug 06               134                               112
Source: CIU based on INE data.



Table 15. GDP Forest Industries and Manufacturing Industry
(constant million 2002 US$)

                            1998          1999          2000         2001          2002          2003
                                                                                          (*)
 Pulp and Paper             101.3         108.3        104.8          99.2        106.3         122.1(*)
 Sawmills                      -            -             -             -           18.8         58.0
 Industry                  2,146.7       1,802.4      1,780.3       1,715.7       1,921.9       1,887.7
(*)
   In 2002, INE changed the classification system from to CIIU 2 to CIIU 3. These results were estimated adding the
information for pulp and paper and printing press (sub sectors 21 and 22 according to CIIU 3 classification) in order
to compare the results.
Source: INE.




                                                         50
Table 16. Sawmills and Pulp and Paper Industries Share in Industry Product
and Industry Wages

                               1998         1999     2000     2001     2002     2003
          GNP
     Pulp and Paper          6.12%         7.28%    6.86%     5.98%    4.97%    4.47%
        Sawmills                -             -        -         -     0.82%    1.01%
    Slaughter Houses         42.26%        42.96%   41.74%   42.68%   43.97%   45.54%
    Wool, cotton and
         leather             12.21%        11.45%   11.42%   11.26%   14.06%   13.82%
          GDP
     Pulp and Paper          6.58%         7.44%    7.50%     7.13%    5.53%    5.90%
        Sawmills                -             -        -         -     0.98%    1.44%
    Slaughter Houses         35.36%        37.91%   37.91%   38.45%   38.59%   39.29%
    Wool, cotton and
         leather             10.16%        9.54%     9.53%   8.73%    9.63%    11.68%
        Salaries
     Pulp and Paper          10.06%        11.04%   10.10%    9.82%    9.44%    8.42%
        Sawmills                -             -        -         -     1.11%    1.09%
    Slaughter Houses         38.07%        39.07%   39.81%   40.76%   42.54%   42.63%
    Wool, cotton and
         leather             14.66%        13.72%   13.09%   12.04%   11.88%   13.15%
Source: Own estimates based on INE data.




                                                    51
CHAPTER 4
                          METHODS, RESULTS, AND DISCUSSION



        The objective of the research was to evaluate the impact of the new forest sector on the

Uruguayan economy by considering the costs and benefits of the policy that started with the

Forestry Law 15939 in 1987. Different approaches to policy evaluation were discussed in

Chapter 2. Considering the aim of the study and data availability, a CBA was chosen for this

research. The analytical process included the following steps: (1) identifying the costs, benefits

and investments associated with the policy; (2) quantifying them; and (3) evaluating the overall

impact of the policy on the national economy.

        Different studies that attempted to measure the economic impact of the forest sector in

Uruguay comparing the economy with and without the forest sector (Vázquez Platero 1996;

Ramos & Cabrera 2001). They considered plantations as well as industrial activities, and both

concluded that the impact will be positive. The limitations for the sector would be related with

high costs in US$, especially fuel, and a low exchange rate which leads to a competitiveness

loss.

        Vázquez Platero (1996) evaluated the forest policy estimating Fiscal Balance,

employment, and costs (including plantations and sawmills), and compared the forestry activity

with livestock. He uses market prices and includes subsidies and taxes. Investments were not

considered and plantations from 1989 to 1994 were included. The results showed a Net Present

Value (NPV) for the forest sector equals to 26 million US$, using a 10% discount rate. The

internal rate of return (IRR) was 29.8%. Ramos and Cabrera (2001) using the same approach,

evaluate the forest policy considering the plantations between 1989 and 1999. They estimated a




                                                52
NPV equals to 730 million US$, and an IRR equals to 38.7%. The total subsidies accrued

between 1989 and 1999 were 29 million US$ which gives an average subsidy of 181 US$/ha.

        The Forest Division estimates the cost of the policy at 149 million US$ (Forest Division

 2006). This analysis conducted by Forest Division considered tax exoneration and subsidies to

 plantations. It is estimated that 2.86 jobs were created by 1,000 ha planted.

       No studies that consider direct and indirect impacts of the forest sector in Uruguay have

been done, however a study for BOTNIA, a Finnish Company that is building a pulp mill in

Uruguay, estimated the impact of the new mill on the Uruguayan Economy using an I-O model

(Metsa-Botnia 2004). The study used elements from C-B analysis and I-O models to describe

two scenarios: one assessing the Uruguayan Economy without the mill project and the other

assessing the Uruguayan Economy with the project. The study determined the main variables of

the economy as well as the activities more related with the forest sector from 2004 to 2016.

Direct and indirect impacts were measured. Direct impacts referred to “…the effects of the pulp

mill investment and production on output and employment in those sectors, which are directly

connected to the investment and production process”. The study estimated that the new pulp mill

will increase the GDP by 1.4% by year 2016, and it will increase employment in 2200 new jobs.

However, the impact on labor fluctuates according to which stage of the construction/ operation

of the mill was considered. Although the trade balance is positive for the period considered,

imports will increase at the beginning due to the mill construction. Indirect impacts referred to

the impacts induced by increasing the activity in the forest sector that leads to increase

consumption, income and employment. In addition, development impacts were summarized

grouping them into: population and sociology, forest sector, regional economy and national




                                                53
economy. The study located the effects on three different state economies involved: Río Negro,

Soriano and Paysandú.



               4.1.     Methods: CBA

       While CBA is generally similar to Cost-Effectiveness Analysis (CEA), there are several

differences (Little & Mirrlees 1974; Nas 1996). First, taxes and subsidies are not included in the

CBA because they are transfers between agents within the economy. Second, some benefits or

costs resulting from the project’s operation do not appear as inputs or outputs in the ordinary

accounts. Third, the discount rate used to evaluate the project is usually different from the market

interest rate which might be used by a private firm.

       CBA is a very comprehensive procedure as it considers all potential gains and losses

from a policy and it is particularly designed for the evaluation of public projects. The project

outcome is always evaluated in CBA on the basis of public interest. Prices in CBA are corrected

for market distortions. Costs and benefits are measured in terms of social utility gains and losses

rather than cash or revenue flows, and external costs and benefits are invariably included in the

evaluation (Nas 1996). CBA may be used to recommend policy actions, in which case it is

applied prospectively (ex ante). It may also be used to evaluate policy performance. This

approach is applied retrospectively (ex post) in this study.



               4.1.1   Shadow Prices

       Shadow prices are defined as the increase in welfare resulting from any marginal change

in the availability of commodities of factors of production (Squire & van der Tak 1975).

“A shadow price is a measure of the welfare effects of marginal changes in the supply or demand




                                                 54
of good or services” (Londero & Cervini 2003). As it was discussed in the previous chapter,

CBA is based in welfare economics as is shadow prices theory (Londero & Cervini 2003). An

important assumption in applied welfare economics is the use of economic shadow prices to

appraise investments (Harou 1987). The analytical method uses a partial equilibrium approach: it

is assumed that all prices other than that of the good being studied remain unchanged. Individual

markets are studied in isolation, as if they were independent from other markets, reflecting the

expectation that a price change in one market does not have significant repercussions in other

markets (Londero & Cervini 2003). In this study this assumption is not too restrictive as forestry

accounts only for small part of the national economy.

       One approach to estimate shadow prices is the efficiency analysis, in which equal weights

are assigned to the marginal income changes, not considering differences among income levels.

Another approach assigns the same valuation in welfare function to all that have the same

income level. The most important authors in this group include UNIDO (1972), Little and

Mirrlees (1974), and Squire and van der Tak (1975) (Londero & Cervini 2003). Little and

Mirrlees (1974) proposed the “accounting prices” to conduct social cost-benefit analysis

(Little & Mirrlees 1974). The UNIDO (1972) approach distinguishes between “weights” which

are political value judgments, and the shadow prices derived from these judgments and technical

information (Marglin 1977). UNIDO Guidelines propose a ”bottom-up” procedure in which the

weights are generated by the formulation and evaluation procedure itself (Dasgupta et al. 1972).

Squire and van der Tak (1975) proposed the use of distribution weights, which may be derived

from an explicitly specified welfare function. The choice of a numeraire (unit of account) is basic

to the determination of weights, insofar as the numeraire determines the absolute level of weights

(Squire & van der Tak 1975). However, the conclusions would not change if the numeraire




                                                55
changes (Londero & Cervini 2003). In LMST, the value of public investment in border18 prices

is expressed in relation to the value of consumption in border prices. In the Squire van der Tak

system the value of public investment in border prices is expressed in relation to the value of

consumption in domestic prices (Ray 1984).

         The technique of shadow prices consists of several steps. First, goods or services are

classified in several ways according to how additional demand is met. According to Londero and

Cervini, goods or services can be classified considering how additional demand is met: fixed

supply goods, where it is met from withdrawals from other uses; produced goods, when it is met

by additional production; and socially traded goods; when it is met by additional imports or

reduced exports (Londero & Cervini 2003). According to Squire and van der Tak goods and

services can be classified considering whether they are tradable or not tradable: goods imported

or exported at the margin with infinite elasticity, goods imported or exported at the margin with

less than infinite elasticity, goods not currently traded but ought to be traded, and goods not

currently traded and ought not to be traded (Squire & van der Tak 1975). Second, several

techniques can be used to estimate the shadow prices: input-output matrices (Londero & Cervini

2003), linear programming (Harou 1987), and welfare functions (Squire & van der Tak 1975).

         Shadow pricing of forestry projects was proposed in the 50s (Duerr and Vaux 1953) but

started to be applied in the 70s (Watt 1973, FAO 1979, Harou 1981). The methodology has been

developed for industrial investments (OECD 1968, UNIDO 1972, Squire and Van Der Tak 1976,

UNIDO 1979) and agricultural projects (Gittinger 1983 in Harou 1987). In forestry projects,



18
   Border prices are the prices of imports or exports of a commodity. Import prices usually are calculated as CIF
prices (it is the price paid by the buyer, which includes: Cost, Insurance and Freight) and export prices are calculated
as FOB prices (Free on Board) refers to the price received by the seller, who pays the transportation from the port of
origin to the country.




                                                          56
most outputs can be expressed in shadow prices. On the other hand, major input such as land,

labor, and machinery may or may not be considered for shadow pricing. Whether or not it is

actually worth shadow pricing a particular input depends on the magnitude of the estimated

difference between its market price and its economic value19 (Gregersen & Contreras 1979;

Harou 1987).

           There are some difficulties in estimating the shadow price of land by measuring the

compensating variation of those affected by the change in the demand (supply) of land. First, the

market price of land is determined by the present value of the associated rent. When moving to

forestry from alternative uses it is necessary to estimate the effects of the change and to compute

their future values. Second, the use of land could have significant external effects that could or

could not impact other markets. These difficulties may be further related to different land

qualities, different land locations, and the existence of taxes. Therefore, simplified approaches

are used to estimate the shadow price of land (Londero & Cervini 2003). The appropriate

measure of value for land is the highest net return that actually has been obtained from the land

in the absence of the project (Gregersen & Contreras 1979; Londero & Cervini 2003).

           The objective in valuing labor is to arrive at a measure of the benefits foregone by

employing labor in the project rather than in its next best alternative use. If labor is hired away

from other productive activity and there is little unemployment in the project region, the value of

labor in the other activity, or the market wage, provides an acceptable measure of opportunity

cost for the economic analysis (Dasgupta et al. 1972; Little & Mirrlees 1974; Marglin 1977;

Gregersen & Contreras 1979; Londero & Cervini 2003).

           The shadow price ratio (SPR) for labor is the ratio of its efficiency cost to its market cost:

the reduction in production per unit of withdrawn value, multiplied by the amount of labor
19
     In the text, the economic value is referred sometimes as “efficiency price” that is defined in the next pages.


                                                             57
withdrawn (Londero & Cervini 2003). The difference between the efficiency salary and the

market salary depends on the characteristic of the labor market. This topic has been extensively

discussed in the literature (Dasgupta et al. 1972; Little & Mirrlees 1974; Squire & van der Tak

1975; Marglin 1977; Gregersen & Contreras 1979; Ray 1984; Harou 1987; Londero & Cervini

2003). Labor markets can be classified in different ways. According to Londero and Cervini

(2003), (1) labor can be withdrawn from the production of traded goods; (2) dual urban markets

can exist where there is a group of workers protected by labor legislation and/or represented by

unions; and (3) rural urban migration can be caused by the new activity.

       The efficiency price of foreign exchange, like any other efficiency price, is defined as the

sum of the compensating variations attributable to a unit change in the demand or supply of

foreign exchange. Its SPR would be the ratio of that shadow price to the market price, the

prevailing exchange rate (Londero & Cervini 2003).



             4.1.2    Discount Rate

       Discounting is based on the idea that a given amount of resources available for use in the

future is worth less than the same amount of resources available today. Through investments, one

can transform resources that are currently available for use into a greater amount of resources in

the future (Boardman 2001). The selection of the most appropriate rate of discount is related to

the weights that the society should apply to consumption that occurs in future periods relative to

the same amount of consumption in the current period. These weights represent how much of the

current consumption the society is willing to give up now in order to obtain a given increase in

future consumption.




                                               58
The choice of the social rate of return is based on the preferences of individuals in the

society. In order to compare the costs and benefits associated with the policy they have to be

weighted (Dasgupta et al. 1972). The weights ( w j ) are related to the discount rate (i) as follows:

                      1
           wj =
                  (1 + i ) n


           where:

           n= number of periods,

            i= discount rate



           These weights can be determined if the consumers’ preferences are known and markets

do not have imperfections. In addition, there should not be any distortions such are taxes, risk,

and transaction costs20 (Dasgupta et al. 1972; Boardman et al. 1997). An approach to measure

transaction costs for Uruguay can be found in the report present by the World Bank where 175

countries are measured according several indicators that measure “…business regulation and the

protection of property rights and their effect on businesses” (World Bank 2006) in order to

establish the average period of time that takes starting a business in a country. Uruguay ranked

70 in 200521 and 64 in 2006. While the country has similar indicators to the region22 in some

cases in other they are similar to OECD countries.




20
   Transactions costs are defined as the costs incurred in the exchange process as transaction fees, gather
information, move products (Chavas & Bouamra Mechemache 2006)
21
     A complete report of the ranking can be found at: www.doingbusiness.org
22
     Uruguay is included in Latin America and Caribbean.


                                                           59
Regarding risk, the “country risk”23 is measured in Uruguay using an indicator called

Uruguay Bond Index (UBI) that measures the spread between the returns on Uruguayan bonds

and USA bonds. The UBI was 3,100 basis points during the 2002 and financial crisis, and it is

167 points today, reaching the lowest value in the last six years. According to Adamodar

(Hagler 2007) Uruguay pays a 5.25% of risk premium while in the region Chile pays 1.05%,

Brazil 3.75%, and Argentina 6.75%.

            Taxes in Uruguay are the main source of income for the Government. In the last two

decades the taxes went from 62.5% of the Government income in 1990 to 71.3% in 2002; and

taxes went from 17.8% of the GDP in 1990 to 22.1% in 2002. Compared with other countries,

the share of taxes in the GDP is lower than developed countries but higher than the average in

Latin America; compared with the region, Uruguay is between Argentina and Brazil (Lorenzo et

al. 2005).

            The discount rate used in this project was 6%, as this is the social interest rate that is

being used in the country to evaluate local development projects.



                     4.1.3     “Before and After” Approach versus “With and Without” Approach to

            CBA.

            The “With and Without” approach to analyze the effects of a policy is not the same as

comparing the situation “Before and After” its implementation.

            The “Before and After” analysis compares the economy before the project is established

with the economy after the project is established. The “Before and After” approach would not

give information about the changes that may occur without the policy because it does not

describes the same economy (Boardman 2001).
23
     The country risk is defined as an index that reflects the risk that a country has for foreign investments.


                                                             60
The “With and Without” analysis consists of estimating the net marginal benefit induced

by the new policy (Harou 1987). In this project, the “With and Without” approach will be used.

The “With” situation is defined as the situation where the Forestry Policy has been established in

1989; the “Without” situation is defined as the situation where the Forestry Policy has not been

established. The “With” situation describes what happened in the economy after the Forestry

Law. Therefore, plantations from 1989 onward were considered and, according to the

management regimes, forest industries were considered from the first year when wood harvest

was processed into manufactured wood products. The “Without” situation describes what would

have happened to the economy if the Forestry Policy had not been established. It was assumed

that if the lands were not used for forestry, they would have been used for livestock. Therefore,

slaughter houses, tanning leather and wool industries would have been developed.



                  4.1.4 Sensitivity Analysis

        Uncertainty about the magnitude of the results is always present as there is uncertainty

about the values we assign to the costs and benefits associated to the policy evaluated. Sensitivity

analysis acknowledges this uncertainty and allows analysts to identify how sensitive the results

are to the assumptions made. The analysis also helps to identify the key variables that affect the

policy results.

        Three approaches can be taken in order to conduct a sensitivity analysis: partial

sensitivity analysis, worst and best case analysis, and Monte Carlo simulations. Partial sensitivity

analysis consists of estimating how net benefits change as one variable is changed and the others

remain constant. Worst and best case analysis consists of changing some assumptions in order to

identify the assumptions or a combination of assumptions that would change the analysis’




                                                61
results. Monte Carlo sensitivity analysis consists of assigning probability distribution functions

to some key assumptions and evaluating how changes of these assumptions would affect the net

results (Boardman 2001).

           In this study, a partial sensitivity analysis will be conducted in order to identify the

variables that most affect the results obtained.



                    4.1.5 Terminal Value

           Forestry investments are usually long-term investments; therefore, some corporations

have unlimited planning horizons and anticipate managing their forests forever. To evaluate an

asset that produces cash flows over an infinite time frame, it is necessary to have a procedure for

calculating the present value of an infinite series of cash flows (Clutter et al. 1983). There are

several indicators to evaluate forest investments, some based on yield criteria, and others on

economic criteria (Clutter et al. 1983; Newman 1988; Perman et al. 2003). Those based on yield

criteria are maximum single-rotation physical yield; maximum single-rotation annual yield, also

called Mean Annual Increment (MAI); and Maximum Sustainable Yield (MSY). Those based on

economic criteria are maximization of discounted net revenues from a single rotation;

maximization of the discount net revenues from an infinite series of like rotations, also called

soils expectation value (SEV) or bare land value (BLV); maximization of annual net revenues,

also called forest rent; and internal rate of return (Clutter et al. 1983; Newman 1988; Perman et

al. 2003).

           However, the discussion of the optimum rotation length for a forest stand has not been a

simple issue24 (Newman 1988). Faustman’s Formula (1849) is the first rule used to evaluate the

optimal rotation age, and was based in the maximization of discounted net revenues (Perman et
24
     A very good discussion on the literature referring to Optimal Forest Rotation can be found in Newman (1988).


                                                          62
al. 2003). Even though it is important, the formula contains simplified assumptions that have

been changed in the following years, allowing the development of a great number of theories and

practices (Newman 1988). Newman discusses six criteria for an optimal rotation age: Maximum

Gross Yield, Maximum Sustained Yield, Present Net Worth, Soil Rent, Forest Rent, and Internal

Rate of Return (Newman 1988).

           In this study, BLV criterion was used to estimate the terminal value of the plantations’

investments and the land value in order to compare it with land market prices. BLV, associated

with a given rotation age, is the present value of the net returns from all the rotations in the

continuing series. This is the present value of all cash flows produced by an infinite series of

rotations using a rotation age of t years (Clutter et al. 1983).

           Cash flows for continuing series of plantations for each alternative were calculated, and

the present value of each alternative was maximized. The maximum present value is

accomplished with the rotation age with maximum BLV, and this rotation age is called the

optimum economic rotation (Clutter et al. 1983). BLV was used because it estimates the net

present value of the land in infinite rotations and it is a good approach of the opportunity cost of

land.



                    4.2.     Data and Assumptions

           Costs, investments and benefits25 were estimated from primary and secondary

information. Primary information was obtained from a survey conducted in Uruguay in July

200626. Secondary information was obtained from the Forest Division (DF), the Agricultural

Planning and Policy Office (OPYPA), the Agricultural Statistics Division (DIEA), the Forest


25
     The tables with the assumptions for the period of analysis are presented in Appendix III.
26
     The questionnaire and the Survey’s results are presented in Appendices I and II.


                                                            63
Producers Society (SPF), the National Institute of Statistics (INE), the Central Bank of Uruguay

(BCU), the Association of Industries of Uruguay (CIU), the Agricultural and Livestock Plan

Office (IPA), and the National Colonization Institute (INC). In addition, estimates on plantations

and sawmills data were taken from two previous studies: Vázquez Platero (1996) and Ramos and

Cabrera (2001). Taxes estimates were obtained from Ramos and Cabrera (2001). Growth rates

and management plans were compared with those obtained from the survey and with SPF

information.

       Market prices were converted to shadow prices according to two studies: Fernández

Gaeta (1995) and Pereyra (2004). Both studies considered the income as numeraire and defined

the SPR as:


       spri = spi/pi

       where:

        spri =shadow price ratio of the good i,

       spi = shadow price of good i,

        pi = market price of good i



       From 1989 to 2001, Fernández Gaeta (Fernandez Gaeta 1995) estimates for 1995 were

used. From 2001 to 2005, Pereyra estimates from 2004 (Pereyra 2004) were used because the

major change in the economy occurred in 2002 after the devaluation of the Uruguayan currency

and Pereyra estimates reflected those changes. The first study provided estimates of all the

shadow prices of the economy except for imports; while the second provided estimates for only a

few items related to infrastructure projects.




                                                  64
Labor SPR has been less than one in the period 1989-2005. Estimates for 1995 showed

that the SPR for skilled labor was 0.98 and for non-skilled and semi-skilled labor was 0.8,

meaning that the market wage for skilled labor was similar to the opportunity cost of it. On the

other hand, the market wage for non-skilled and semi-skilled labor was higher than its

opportunity costs. Labor SPR estimates for 2004 showed that the SPR for skilled labor had not

changed significantly, but the SPR for non-skilled and semi-skilled labor had dropped to 0.6

(Table 17). These results reflect the increase in the unemployment rate which went from 7% in

1989 to 12% in 2005 (Table 18). The unemployment rate estimates includes only cities with

more than 5,000 habitants, therefore the rural unemployment was not included. However, the

analysis of the provinces where plantations were established, indicate that the unemployment has

decreased. Therefore the question: What does the rest of the economy ultimately lose when a

person joins the project? becomes crucial for the analysis of the situation in Uruguay where two

opposite phenomena occur. On one hand, a high level of unemployment in the cities and lower in

rural areas, and a high demand for semi-skilled labor in the new industries that in some cases has

been difficult to meet. The states of Río Negro and Tacuarembó are examples of the changes in

the opportunity cost of semi-skilled and skilled labor. In Río Negro, Botnia is constructing a pulp

mill and the province state did not have enough labor available to meet the needs. In

Tacuarembó, Colonvade27 and Urupanel28 are building plywood facilities and the demand semi-

skilled and skilled labor has also been growing and attracting labor from other states. In those

cases, the companies started training programs and they are encouraging technical teaching

institutes to adapt their programs to the new industries requirements.



27
   Colonvade is a company with partnership between Weyerhaeuser and Global Partners with facilities located in
Tacuarembó and Rivera.
28
   Urupanel is a Chilean company with facilities located in Tacuarembó.


                                                       65
Therefore, despite the high level of unemployment in the Uruguayan economy, the

opportunity cost of labor in the forest sector is not zero because some resources are being

withdrawn from other sectors.

        One of the most important effects of the new Forestry Law was the increase in land

prices. As the demand for land increased, prices rose. Average prices presented by the DIEA

which calculates the price in US$/ha as an average of the transactions in the period, do not reflect

the prices of the transactions accurately because data from INC shows that land prices are higher

than those reported by DIEA. The INC shows that, during the first semester of 2006, the average

price land was 1354.30 US$/ha; if this average is standardized according to productivity indexes,

it was 1465.06 US$/ha CONEAT 100 (Colonization National Institute 2006). In 1995, Fernández

Gaeta estimated that the SPR for land was 1.19, meaning that the market prices under value the

land. Fernández Gaeta estimated the land price considering the net present value of the most

important outputs for year 1992, when the agricultural and livestock sector had a different

structure. Based on the CGA information, he assumed that the total area was distributed as

follows: 76.9% livestock, 7.7% dairy production, 3.9% rice and 11.5% other cereals production.

The sector structure was different from today’s structure, where the forest sector has small

participation.

        To fill this lack of information, BLV for land were estimated. The BLV were divided

into three activities: land designated for eucalyptus plantations, land designated for pine

plantations, and land designated for livestock. As it was discussed in Chapter 3, land designated

for forestry has a site productivity index of 69 in average; therefore the BLV was estimated for

these sites.




                                                66
The results show that the market prices are lower than shadow prices estimated

(Table 19). The SPR showed that for forestlands designated for eucalyptus it is 1.20, for

forestlands designated for pine is 1.42 and for lands designated for livestock is 1.25. These

results show the BLV in 2005, but a complete series could not be estimated. As the changes have

been important in the period of analysis, 1989-2005, the opportunity cost of the land might have

been changing. Therefore for the CBA, market prices were used and a sensitivity analysis was

conducted.

       Exports and imports values were corrected by the foreign exchange SPR (SPRf).

Considering the 1993 Uruguay’s trade structure, the 1993 Trade Commercial Balance and the

equilibrium and observed exchange rate, Fernández Gaeta estimated a SPRf of 1.31. Pereyra,

using the same approach but including 2003 data, estimated SPRf of 1.01 (Pereyra 2004).



       SPRf = (Eq. ER/Obs. ER) * [(Imports*(1+Taxes and Tariffs) +

                Exports (1+Subsidies)]/(Imports +Exports)

       where:

       Eq. ER=Equilibrium Exchange Rate,

       Obs. ER= Observed Exchange Rate



       The exchange rate he used was 30 Uruguayan Pesos per US$ ($U/US$), and currently the

ER is 25 $U/US$, then the shadow price does not reflect the current currency value but it is the

most updated version of shadow prices estimation.

       The analysis covered the period from 1989 through 2005, in order to consider the

plantations that were established as a result of the Forestry Law 15939.




                                                67
Two indicators were calculated to determine the value of the project for the society:

NPV, using a 6% discount rate, and IRR. Both were calculated at year 1989.



              4.2.1 Production

              4.2.1.1.       Forest Management Plans

       Several forest management plans have been designed in the past decades. Vázquez

Platero (1996) assumed a management plan consisting of two prunings, four thinnings and final

harvest for pine for saw timber; two prunings, two thinnings and final harvest for eucalyptus for

sawtimber; and a final at year eight for eucalyptus for pulpwood (Vázquez Platero 1996).

       Ramos and Cabrera (2001) proposed six different models and six different management

plans according to wood destination and regions. Eucalyptus management plans included one

thinning and the final harvest if the wood was grown for pulp, or two thinnings and the final

harvest if the wood was grown for saw timber. Pine plantations management plans included two

or three thinnings, and a final harvest at age 22 or 24. Pine plantations were grown for saw

timber (saw logs, plywood logs, sawn wood).In the survey conducted in Uruguay, rotation ages

varied according to the final product of the company. Therefore, in Pine grown for saw timber

was managed on rotations 22 to 25 year long. On the other hand, information on rotation ages for

eucalyptus differed among plantations: plantations grown for saw timber had rotation ages from

15 to 20 years, and plantations grown for pulpwood had rotation ages around 10 years.

       This study assumed that 70% of the eucalyptus plantation area was grown for pulp and

30% for saw timber. The rotation age for pulp was 9 years and for saw timber 18 years with two

intermediate thinnings, at 9 and 13. Both thinnings produced pulpwood. The assumptions are

presented in Table 21 and volume estimations are based on Methol’s model (Methol 2003). For




                                               68
pine it was assumed that 100% of the plantations are grown for saw timber. The rotation age was

22 years with three intermediate thinnings, at years 4, 12 and 18, and two prunings. The

assumptions are shown in Table 21 and were based on Ramos and Cabrera model for Pine in the

North29 (Ramos & Cabrera 2001).



                   4.2.1.2.          Growth rates

           Growth rates have been adjusted after first plantations were established. Vázquez Platero

(1996), according to producers, estimated growth rates ranging from 22 to 36 cubic cu m/yr/ha

on average30 for eucalyptus and 17 to 26 m3/yr/ha for pine according to the location.

            Ramos and Cabrera (2001) estimated different growth rates by location, products and

species. For eucalyptus plantations grown for saw timber, MAI varies from 28 to 32 m3/yr/ha,

and for pulp from 18 to 23 m3/year. For pine plantations MAI can be from 19 to 24 m3/yr/ha.

According to the survey conducted in Uruguay, growth rates vary from 20 m3/yr/ha for Pine to

20 to 25 m3/yr/ha for eucalyptus with an average of 22 m3/yr/ha.

           In this research the following growth rates were assumed: 24 m3/yr/ha for Pine, and

30 m3/yr/ha for eucalyptus.



                   4.2.2 Inputs

                   4.2.2.1.          Production Costs

                               4.2.2.1.1.    Plantations

           Plantation costs vary with management plans and species. Management plans have been

changing since expertise was gained in the field. Before the Forestry Law 15939 was established,

29
     In Ramos and Cabrera study, these assumptions correspond to Model 2.
30
     This is the Mean Annual Increment (MAI) which designs the average production per year.


                                                         69
plantations were oriented towards fuel wood or saw timber production for local companies, with

some exceptions.

       Plantation costs were based on Ramos and Cabrera estimates (Ramos & Cabrera 2001).

They include fencing, soil preparation, ant control, fertilization, plants, plantation, and other

minor costs. Each item includes the labor required for the activity, and only imported items were

included. On average, labor costs are 16% of plantations costs meanwhile imports account for

10%. Shadow prices were assigned according to the share of each component in total costs; taxes

were not considered (Table 22).

                         4.2.2.1.2.   Pruning and Thinning

       The most important component in these activities is labor. Labor used varies according to

the management plan: pruning and thinning ages.

       In this study, it was assumed that eucalyptus plantations grown for pulp are not pruned or

thinned; eucalyptus plantations growth for saw timber are thinned at year 9; and pine plantations

growth for saw timber are pruned at years 4, 6 and 8 and thinned at years 4, 12 and 18. It was

assumed a cost of 60 US$/ha for pruning and 8 US$/ha for thinning (Table 23).

                         4.2.2.1.3.   Harvesting

       For pulp, labor requirements were estimated in 0.289 daily wages/ m3 for pulp and 0.222

daily wages/ m3 for saw timber according to Ramos and Cabrera based on SPF information

(Ramos & Cabrera 2001). The costs structure for final harvest is as follows: 55% labor, 30%

fuel, and the other costs are 15% of the total cost. These costs were corrected using shadow

prices, which where assigned according to the weight of each item in the total cost.




                                                70
4.2.2.1.4.   Industry

       For the case with project, sawmills were included in the analysis. Costs in thousand

US$/ m3 of wood processed were obtained from Ramos and Cabrera based on INE data, from

1999 the coefficients were considered constant. Wood manufacturing costs, included wood, were

estimated at 119 US$/ m3 of wood processed in 1989 and in 67 US$/ m3 from 1999. Several

factors could explain this drop: a decrease in equipment maintenance after 1993 and the

disappearance of the cost of fuel wood in the last three years. On the other hand, salary costs

remained stable in US$ despite increasing 70 to 80% in $U. Wood processed was obtained from

the eucalyptus and pine models described above.

       For the case without the project, slaughter houses, wool and leather industries were

considered. The productivity indexes for these industries were considered from Ramos and

Cabrera between 1989 and 1999, from IPA between 2000 and 2005, and thereafter assumed

constant until 2010. These costs were corrected using the same criteria as in the previous item

(Table 24).

                            4.2.2.1.5.   Transportation

       Transportation costs were based on figures provided by Ramos and Cabrera (2001) by

region, species and product. Costs were estimated by tons and divided into pulp and saw timber

products. Harvested wood could be destined for either the mill or the seaport. Transportation

costs included costs from the plantation to the mill and from the mill to the final destination

(Table 25). Wood designated for final consumption either in the local markets or abroad, had

other transportation costs associated. Then, transportation costs were first calculated for the

distance between the plantation and the mills. Costs from the mill to the final destination were

assigned to the industry.




                                                    71
For the case without the project, the livestock that would have been transported if

forestland were used for livestock production was estimated.

                          4.2.2.1.6.   Export Costs

       Export costs include labor costs for activities in the port, and these costs were based on

Ramos and Cabrera estimates. They assumed that 0.022 daily wages/day/m3 was needed to

prepare wood for export from the port.



               4.2.3 Investments

               4.2.3.1.       Plantations

       Investments in plantations were calculated as the total area declared in the Forest

Division multiplied by the land price of the same year. Land price series were taken from DIEA

and a sensitivity analysis was conducted to address the differences between market and shadow

prices (Table 26).



               4.2.3.2.       Industry

       Investments in the industry were based on the survey data, and only sawmills were

considered because information regarding pulp mill investments was not available. According to

the survey, 85% of the investments in equipment in the industry are imported, and the companies

have tax exonerations for imports to the industry. Therefore, it was assumed that 85% of the

investments were imported and that the information did not include taxes.




                                                72
4.2.4 Outputs

       Wood exports are the output considered in the analysis as they represent income

generated in the country. For the case with project, total wood exports were estimated according

to the level of production, and the value was estimated considering average stumpage prices

obtained from the Forest Division. In the model, the wood can be used to produce either pulp or

saw timber. As of 2006, there were not pulp mills in the country; therefore, it was assumed that

until that year all wood for pulp was exported.

       For the situation without project, exports from alternative activities were estimated based

on production levels and producers prices, as most of the production is destined for exports

(Ramos & Cabrera 2001). To estimate the percentage of the production exported each year, CIU

estimations and IPA information were used. Between 1988 and 1998, CIU estimated that leather

and wool were sub-sectors that exported more than 50% of their production, while slaughter

houses exported from 11% to 50% of their production. The slaughter houses accounted for most

of the total value of the alternative products considered here, it was assumed that between 1989

and 2000 50% of the total production was exported. In 2001, the foot-and-mouth disease caused

beef exports to drop until 2002. Based on IPA data, for 2001 it was assumed that 40% of the

production was exported as the outbreak began in October of that year; for 2002 and 2003 it was

assumed that 30% of the production was exported; and for 2004 and 2005 it was assumed that

60% of the production. From 1999 to 2005, leather and wool industries decreased their exports

and slaughter houses increased them, becoming one of the most important sectors in the total

exports of the country.




                                                  73
4.3.    Results

       The results show that the forest sector compared with an alternative production, livestock,

had a net positive impact on the Uruguayan economy in the period 1989-2005. The NPV for the

forest sector compared with livestock in year 1989 equals 630.2 million US$, using a 6%

discount rate. The IRR for the forest sector was 36.4% (Table 27). Since the project’s products

are mostly exported, all economic project’s outputs are included. On the other hand, only inputs

including imported items and labor are included. In addition, SPRs are lower than one for inputs

and equal or higher to one for outputs. Therefore the results are more positive than evaluating the

policy at market prices.

       The alternative industries costs savings were high. The livestock production is an annual

activity, and therefore costs associated with the industry will occur every year. On the other

hand, forestry is a periodic activity and industry costs will start when the first wood harvested is

processed. In the model, forest industries started to operate 9 years after the plantations were

established; as a result, there is a 9-year period where there no forestry industry costs.

       Sensitivity analyses were conducted on wood prices, yields, transportation costs, land

prices and thinning, administration and harvesting costs. The results are presented as variations

of NPV and IRR in percentage. Wood markets are a key factor for the analysis as its results are

sensitive to changes in wood prices. Results are more sensitive to changes in pulpwood prices

than in saw timber prices (Table 28). These results can be explained by the fact that pulpwood

accounts for most of wood output. Between 1989 and 2005 a total of 72.2 million of cum of

pulpwood were produced versus 22.7 million of cum of sawn wood.

       Since the prices considered were FOB Montevideo, freight costs to final destinations

were not included. According to the industries’ survey, the oceanic freight costs increased 60%




                                                 74
between 2002 and 2006. It is expected that wood consumption would continue to rise, but the

real price of products will increase slightly. The biggest effect would be on trade rather than on

production, with a shift on trade toward processed products (Prestemon et al. 2003). This

increasing demand represents an opportunity to Uruguayan products; however, an analysis of

price trends and markets would be important to obtain benefits.

       The results are very sensitive to changes in yields: if both plantations yields decreased

20%, the IRR would decrease more than 7% and the NPV would decrease nearly 100%. A

reduction in eucalyptus yields has more impact on NPV and IRR than a reduction in pine yields.

This result can be explained by the different areas covered by pine and eucalyptus.

Approximately 75% of the area is covered with eucalyptus and the rest by pine. With most land

owned by private investors, the investors’ management decisions are the key factor influencing

the provision of forest benefits to the society. The idea that private forest management is less

socially responsible and characterized by lower environmental standards has proved to be not

always true; forest certification and private management plans analysis are two elements that

support this outcome (Siry et al. 2005).

       Transportation costs at the beginning of the project represent a saving in costs because

there is no wood transported. However, after wood processing begins, these costs will be

included. A decrease or increase in transportation costs rangin from 10 to 20%, change the IRR

less than 1% point, meanwhile the NPV will increase or decrease by 3% when the costs vary by

20% (Table 31). This result does not conform with the private investors’ view that transportation

is an important factor in their production operations.

       Results were very sensitive to changes in land prices, a drop of 20% in land prices, will

result in a 21% increase in the IRR and a 9.5% in the NPV. On the other hand, a 20% increase




                                                75
will lower the IRR by 8% and the NPV by 11% (Table 32). The IRR is not very sensitive to

changes in management costs: a change of 10% in thinning, harvesting and management costs

changes the IRR by less than 1% (Table 33). Results show that land prices are still lower than

shadow prices. If the demand for land was driven by timber prices, an analysis of the products

and markets where Uruguay plans to export would be necessary. Even though the land price in

Uruguay has increased in the last thirty years, historically, it has been lower than the land prices

in Argentina and Brazil. Considering the same quality land, average prices per hectare in

Argentina and Brazil have been higher than the Uruguay’s average land price between 1994 and

2003 (Sáder Neffa 2004). Current land prices in Uruguay are similar to land prices in Brazil and

in Argentina. Lower land price can be considered as another factor attracting foreign investors to

the Uruguayan forest sector.

       Forestry generally provides more jobs than the livestock on the same land base.

Considering the primary production costs in both alternatives, forestry costs are higher. Labour

accounts for much of the costs; therefore, the forest activity has a positive impact on

employment. Results show that, on average, labor costs in US$/ha in forest plantations were four

times higher than labor costs in livestock activities. If pruning, thinning, management,

administration, and harvesting costs are added, labor costs are twenty times higher than those in

livestock activities. These results are consistent with those estimated by the Forest Division and

Ramos and Cabrera (Ramos & Cabrera 2001; San Roman 2005). The Forest Division estimated

that the employment generated in the forest sector is higher than the employment generated in

the livestock sector. First, they considered only the permanent employees in plantations and the

results were that 2 to 9 jobs were created per 1,000 ha. Second, they DIEA adjusted these results

considering the labor hired by third parties, and they estimated that the sector generates




                                                76
7 jobs/ 1,000 ha. Third, based on CGA 2000 results, DF estimated that the forest sector generated

7.98 jobs/1,000 ha, that is, four times the employment generated in the livestock sector (DIEA

estimates that the livestock activity generates 1.96 to 2.65 jobs/1,000 ha). The Forest Division

estimates salaries in plantations at 130% of the minimum national wage. In addition, salaries

paid in the forest sector are higher than those paid in the livestock sector.

           Finally non-market benefits were not included in the evaluation as this assessment

exceeded the objectives of this research. Other benefits associated with the forests are carbon

storage, recreational, bird watching, hiking, and wildlife. In addition, forests decrease erosion,

diminish urban migration, and promote industrial development. These impacts are difficult to

quantify but they will increase the social net return of the policy.

           One underlying objective of forest management is maintaining a variety and valuable

supply of forest products while at the same time ensuring that production and harvesting are

sustainable in the long run and do not compromise the consumption of generations.

           Uruguay has also attempted to evaluate the alternative use of forests31. The country

ratified the Kyoto Protocol in 2001, and has been promoting participation in the Clean

Development Mechanism (CDM) for forestry and agricultural projects. The Environmental




31
     Some of the activities and publications regarding CS developed by the Uruguayan Government include:

       -   Host Country approval for CDM projects in Uruguay Applications on sustainability Tool Assessment.
           August 2003.

       -   Research to support the appliance to CDM for the Kyoto Protocol for Uruguay. May 2002. MVOTMA.

       -   Meeting Climate Change: CDM application in Uruguay. Montevideo, 24- 25 April 2003.

       -   National Capacity Proposal No 15.



                                                         77
Ministry (MVOTMA) is in charge of the research and activities related to the evaluation of CDM

projects 32.

          In addition, the Agricultural and Livestock Ministry (MGAP) established an office to

analyze the possibilities of producing alternative energy from biomass (Methol 2004; Souto &

Methol 2005). The Agricultural Projects of Climate Change Unit (UPACC) was established in

February 2001and started their activities in 200433. The Forest Division integrates the UPCC

along with other Divisions.

          Currently the Forest Division is analyzing the feasibility of horse and cattle breeding

along with forest activities (Seminar: Opinions on the Forest Policy – Forest Division Director

Andrés Berterreche- July 20 2006). This alternative has been part of a strategy of the new

government to combine the two most important activities in the country. Most of the companies

have been developing agroforestry projects which minimize fire risk because animal grazing

reduces fuel loads in forests (COFUSA 2006).

          The most important forest companies have programs to preserve native flora and fauna in

their forests. Ence has two conservation areas: M’Bopicuá and Santo Domingo (Ence 2006).

M’Bopicuá Conservation Area is located on the banks of the Uruguay River in Río Negro,

covering 150 ha. It comprises “…the breeding station, the Nature Trail for appreciating native

flora and an area of special historic interest. The aim is to preserve species of native flora and

fauna, reproduce certain species that are in danger of extinction and then re-introduce them back

into their natural habitat and contribute to environmental education in schools in the area”. The

Santo Domingo conservation area of 7,000 ha is located in Paysandú. Since 1996 plans have



32
     www.cambioclimatico.gub.uy

33
     Law 17296.


                                                78
been developed for preserving palm trees, wetlands and native fauna. This is the first developed

wetland restoration project in the country. Native species threatened with extinction (coati and

caiman) have been reintroduced to this area. A project for improving the numbers of the natural

population of caimans is also being developed.




                                                 79
Table 17. Shadow Prices Relations for Uruguay

 Category                                    1995    2004
 Non-skilled and semi-skilled labor           0.8     0.6
 Qualified labor                              0.8      1
 Foreign Exchange                            1.31    1.01
 Land                                        1.19      -
 Ground transportation                        0.77   0.77
 Investments                                 0.98    0.77
 Sources: Fernández Gaeta (1995), Pereyra (2004).




                                                     80
Table 18. Unemployment Rate in Uruguay

                 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
 Total (Urban)     8    9    9    9    8    9   10   12   11   10   11   14   15   17   17   13   12

  Montevideo       9      9      9       9      8       9     11      12     12    10   12   14   16   17   17   13   12
  Provinces        7      8      9       9      8       9     10      11     11    10   11   13   15   17   17   13   13
    Artigas       19     12      14     14      15     20     13      16     15    13   13   17   20   15   17   13   15
  Canelones        9      9      8       9      9      10      9      13     14    12   12   14   15   19   21   16   14
 Cerro Largo       7      7      9       8      7       7      8      10     12    10   12   11   12   14   10    5    9
   Colonia         5      6      10     12      8       8      8       9     11    8    14   16   20   20   18   12   10
   Durazno         9      8      8      3       5       6     11      10     13    8    17   22   24   25   22   14   13
    Flores         8      5      10      5      6       4     10       8     15    14   19   20   16   18   16   14   17
   Florida         9     10      10      9      6       8     10      10     15    11   11   15   21   23   22   19   16
   Lavalleja       9     10      11     11      8       9      7      9       9    9    7    11   13   17   16   10   16
  Maldonado       4      8       8       9      7      9      12      13     13    8    11   17   20   24   23   20   18
  Paysandú        7      7       8      10      7      8      9       12     9     9    9    11   13   13   19   16   13
  Río Negro       13     11      17      9      11     12     16      26     13    13   12    6    9    6    7    4    8
   Rivera         6      6       11     11      10     16     13      11      7    6     3    8    6    6    3    4    4
    Rocha          9      7      7       8      7       9     13      10     12    8    10   12   16   18   18   13   14
     Salto         5      9      5       5      5       4      3      2       1    1    4    2    6    8    7    6    12
   San José        4      2      6       6      7       8      8      9       6    10   9    10   12   14   12   10   13
   Soriano         6      7      10     10      10     6      10      12     11    15   14   18   19   21   18   17   12
 Tacuarembó        8      8       9      9       9     10     11      11     12    10    8   15   14   17   13   11    8
Treinta y Tres     5       5       13      11    14   13      17     14       15   13   14   13   17   17   25   15   18
Note: The provinces marked in bold are the provinces with higher forest area.
Source: National Institute of Statistics (2006).




                                                                      81
Table 19. Uruguay BLV (2005)

Market Prices                 US$/ha
Pine                           1,028
Eucalyptus                     1,493
Livestock                       420

Shadow Prices                 US$/ha
Pine                           1,460
Eucalyptus                     1,785
Livestock                       523

Source: Own estimates.



Table 20. Eucalyptus Growth, Yields and Management Assumptions

              Pulp (70% area)
Growth rate (m3/ha/year)                 30
Rotation age (years)                     9
Initial Density (trees/ha)             1,000
Final Density (trees/ha)                800
Extraction (m3/ha)                      250

         Saw timber (30% area)
Growth rate (m3/ha/year)                30
Rotation age (years)                    18
Extraction (m3/ha)                    m3/ha     Product     Year
           1st Thinning                 50        Pulp       9
           2nd Thinning                140        Pulp       13
          Final Harvest                340     Saw timber    18

Source: Own estimates based on Methol (2001)




                                                  82
Table 21. Pine Growth, Yields and Management Assumptions

Saw timber
Growth rate (m3/ha/year)             24
Rotation age (years)                 22
Initial Density (trees/ha)         1,000    -
     1st Thinning Density          1,000   600
     2nd Thinning Density           600    400
     3rd Thinning Density           400    200
   Final Density (trees/ha)         200     0

                                                   Saw    Fuel    No
Extraction                         m3/ha Year    timber   wood   Value
         1st Thinning               11    4        0%      0%    100%
        2nd Thinning                 93   12      50%     50%     0%
        3rd Thinning                188   18      70%     30%     0%
        Final Harvest               255   22      85%     15%     0%

Source: Ramos and Cabrera (2001)




                                                 83
Table 22. Plantation Costs Structure

        Items                Share of Total Costs          Taxes        %
 Fences                              9%
 Posts                               47%                 Exonerated
 Wire                                30%                 Exonerated
 Labor                               24%                    BPS        11.5%
 Soil Preparation                   16%
 Fuel                                56%                   IMESI       34%
 Lubricants                           8%                   IMESI       26%
 Machinery                           25%                 Exonerated
 Labor                               11%                    BPS        12%
 Ants control                        3%
 Inputs                              55%                    IVA        17%
 Labor                               45%                    BPS        12%
 Fertilization                       6%
 Inputs                              61%                  Exonerated
 Labor                               39%                     BPS       12%
 Plants                             40%                  IVA pending
 Plantation
 Labor                                7%                    BPS        12%
 Reposition                          9%
 Plants                              85%                 IVA pending
 Labor                               15%                    BPS        12%
 Miscellaneous                       9%                   IVA Basic    17%
 Source: Adapted from Ramos and Cabrera (2001)




                                                    84
Table 23. Forest Production Costs (2005)

 Export Costs
                                                             3
 Total Labor Costs/volume of wood exported (1,000 US$/1,000 m )     0.38

 Pruning (1,000 US$/ha)                                            0.060

 Thinning (1,000 US$/ha)                                           0.008

 Administration and Management

 Ants Control (1,000 US$/ha)                                       0.007
 Year 1

 Wage days/ha                                                      1.25
 1 day wage (1,000 US$)                                            0.015
 Years 1 and 2

 Paths
 Daily wages/ha                                                     0.3
 Daily wage (1,000 US$)                                            0.015
 Annual

 Administration
 Daily wages/ha                                                      3

 Harvest
                                                                             Sawn
                                                                   Pulp      wood
 Daily wages (# daily wages/m3)                                    0.289     0.222
 Salaries US$ (130% minimum national wage )
 1 day salary (1,000 US$)                                         0.015385

 Cost Structure
 Labor                                                             55%
 Fuel                                                              30%
 Rest                                                              15%
 Total Costs                                                       100%
Source: Own estimations based on Ramos and Cabrera (2001).




                                                    85
Table 24. Industrial Costs Structure (2005)

                          Beef      Wool     Leather     Wood
 Total Costs             100%       99%       100%       100%
 Inputs                   65%       44%        42%        77%
 Production Costs         35%       54%        58%        23%

 Imports and Labor as percentage of total costs
                     Imports Labor
 Wood                  8%       35%
 Leather               3%       15%
 Slaughter Houses      4%       12%
 Wool                  3%       15%
 Sources: Own estimates based on Ramos and Cabrera (2001) and INE.



Table 25. Transportation Costs Coefficients

 Wood Transportation

 Coefficients
 Pulpwood transportation/Pulpwood extracted                  0.90
 Sawn wood transportation/Sawn wood extracted                0.80
 Total Costs US$/ tons                                         9
 Saw timber transported/Saw timber                           0.45

 Livestock Transportation
 Transportation Costs (1,000 US$/ha)                     0.0009
                              1989
 Livestock production (kg/ha)                             43
 Total Area                                              6575
 Livestock production total (tons)                        285
 Livestock production (ton/ha)                           0.043
 # trips (total tons/13 tons)                             22

 Transportation fees (US$/km-1 trip=13 tons)                 1.15

 US$/km/ton                                                  0.08
 Km/trip                                                     250
Source: Own estimations based on Ramos and Cabrera (2001).




                                                    86
Table 26. Forest Land Prices vs. Livestock Land Prices

                               US$/ha
 Year
          Average       Forest    Livestock        Difference
 1999       530           617        486              132
 2000       473           624        415              209
 2001       421           565        349              217
 2002       362           460        283              177
 2003       434           584        385              199
 2004       689          871         599              271
 2005       807          1015        692              323
 Source: DIEA based on INC




                                              87
Table 27. Cost Benefit Analysis Results
                       89      90     91     92     93     94      95      96      97     98     99     00      01      02      03      04      05

INPUTS                 0.3     0.3    1.0    1.5    2.4    2.6    3.3     3.0     3.7     13.2   13.0   24.5   42.6    55.9    69.4    100.6   116.6

Production Costs       0.3     0.3    1.0    1.6    2.4    2.7    3.5     3.2     4.0      8.9    8.2   12.6   19.7    10.2    22.1    41.3     59.3
Plantations            0.1     0.1     0.2    0.4    0.6    0.6    0.7     0.4    0.7     0.5    -0.2   -1.2   -1.4    -3.2    -1.9    -2.1     -2.7
Nurseries              0.2     0.2    0.6    1.0     2.0    2.2    2.7    2.7     3.2     3.4    1.9     2.2    1.9     0.5     0.8     1.6      2.6
Pruning and Thinning   0.0     0.0    0.0    0.0     0.0    0.0   0.1     0.1     0.2     0.3     0.4    0.5    0.8     1.9     2.2     2.7      2.9
Management and Adm     0.2     0.3    1.0    1.4     2.1    2.7    3.6    3.7     4.4     5.3     5.0    4.3    3.4     0.7     1.1     2.4      5.8
Harvesting             0.0     0.0    0.0    0.0     0.0    0.0    0.0    0.0     0.0     4.3    4.5    10.6   18.7    12.3    22.0    39.8     55.0
Industry               0.0     0.0    -0.1   -0.2   -0.4   -0.6   -0.8    -1.0    -1.2    -1.5   -1.5   -1.6   -1.8    -1.5    -1.3    -1.5     -1.6
Transportation         0.0     0.0    0.0    0.0    -0.1   -0.1   -0.2    -0.2    -0.3     4.1    4.6   11.5   22.1    43.7    45.3    56.7     54.8
Export Costs           0.0     0.0    0.0    0.0    0.0    0.0    0.0     0.0     0.0      0.2    0.2    0.4    0.8     1.9     2.0     2.6      2.5

INVESTMENTS            0.0     0.9    2.0    3.1    5.1    5.4    20.8    7.1     8.9     16.6   12.5   16.2   14.9     5.2    16.1    20.9     55.7

Plantations            0.0     0.9    2.0    3.1    5.1    5.4    7.1     7.1     8.9     16.6   12.5   16.2   14.9     5.2     5.5    10.3     13.8
Industry               0.0     0.0    0.0    0.0    0.0    0.0    13.8    0.0     0.0      0.0    0.0   0.0    0.0      0.0    10.6    10.6     41.9

OUTPUTS                -0.2    -0.2   -0.4   -0.6   -1.0   -1.0   -1.8    -1.8    -2.4    23.4   31.1   60.6   114.7   187.4   214.5   274.8   297.1

Exports                -0.2    -0.2   -0.4   -0.6   -1.0   -1.0   -1.8    -1.8    -2.4    23.4   31.1   60.6   114.7   187.4   214.5   274.8   297.1

Terminal Value                                                                                                                                 1164.5

CASH FLOW              -0.4    -1.4   -3.4   -5.2   -8.4   -8.9   -26.0   -11.9   -15.0   -6.3   5.6    19.9   57.2    126.3   129.0   153.3   1289.3

IRR                           36.4%
NPV (6%) mill US$ 1989        630.2




                                                                                  88
Table 28. Sensitivity Analysis: Wood Prices

IRR                                       Pulpwood                                                                   Pulpwood
                      -20%      -10%         0%       10%       20%                              -20%      -10%         0%       10%        20%
               -10%   33.38%    34.81%     36.17%    37.46%    38.69%                     -10%   -3.01%    -1.58%      -0.22%    1.07%     2.30%
  Saw timber




                                                                           Saw timber
               0%     33.63%    35.05%    36.39%     37.67%    38.89%                      0%    -2.76%    -1.34%       0.00%    1.28%     2.50%
               10%    33.88%    35.28%     36.61%    37.88%    39.09%                     10%    -2.51%    -1.11%       0.22%    1.49%     2.70%
               20%    34.13%    35.52%     36.83%    38.09%    39.28%                     20%    -2.26%    -0.87%       0.44%    1.70%     2.89%

NPV                                       Pulpwood                                                                   Pulpwood
                       -20%      -10%        0%       10%       20%                               -20%       -10%         0%     10%        20%
               -10%   564,972   579,189    621,762   664,334   706,907                    -10%   -11.55%    -8.81%     -1.36%    5.14%     10.85%
 Saw timber




                                                                         Saw timber
               0%     545,061   587,663    630,206   672,778   715,350                    0%     -15.62%    -7.24%      0.00%    6.33%     11.90%
               10%    553,505   596,077    638,649   681,222   723,794                    10%    -13.86%    -5.73%      1.32%    7.49%     12.93%
               20%    561,948   604,521    647,093   689,666   732,238                    20%    -12.15%    -4.25%      2.61%    8.62%     13.93%

Table 29. Sensitivity Analysis: Yields

IRR                                         Pine                                                                        Pine
                      -20%      -10%        0%        10%       20%                               -20%      -10%        0%        10%        20%
               -20%   29.02%    29.70%     30.35%    30.97%    31.57%                     -20%   -7.37%    -6.69%      -6.04%    -5.42%     -4.82%
  Eucalyptus




                                                                           Eucalyptus
               -10%   32.67%    33.19%     33.70%    34.19%    34.66%                     -10%   -3.72%    -3.20%      -2.69%    -2.20%     -1.73%
               0%     35.55%    35.98%    36.39%     36.80%    37.19%                      0%    -0.84%    -0.41%       0.00%    0.41%      0.80%
               10%    37.94%    38.30%     38.66%    39.00%    39.34%                     10%     1.55%    1.91%       2.27%     2.61%      2.95%
               20%    40.00%    40.31%     40.62%    40.92%    41.21%                     20%     3.61%    3.92%       4.23%     4.53%      4.82%

NPV                                         Pine                                                                         Pine
                       -20%      -10%       0%        10%       20%                                -20%      -10%        0%       10%         20%
               -20%   321,701   343,506    365,312   387,117   408,922                    -20%   -95.90%   -83.46%     -72.51%   -62.79%    -54.11%
 Eucalyptus




                                                                             Eucalyptus




               -10%   454,148   475,953    497,759   519,564   541,369                    -10%   -38.77%   -32.41%     -26.61%   -21.30%    -16.41%
               0%     586,595   608,400    630,206   652,011   673,816                     0%     -7.43%    -3.58%      0.00%     3.34%      6.47%
               10%    719,042   740,847    762,653   784,458   806,264                     10%   12.35%    14.93%      17.37%    19.66%     21.84%
               20%    851,489   873,294    895,100   916,905   938,711                     20%   25.99%    27.84%      29.59%    31.27%     32.86%


                                                                         89
Table 30. Sensitivity Analysis: Transportation Costs

IRR                     Wood                                                                                Wood
                        -20%        -10%         0%         10%       20%                                   -20%        -10%       0%        10%        20%
              -20%      36.96%      36.66%      36.35%     36.05%    35.73%                     -20%        0.26%      -0.04%     -0.35%    -0.65%     -0.97%
  Livestock




                                                                                Livestock
              -10%      36.98%      36.68%      36.37%     36.07%    35.75%                     -10%        0.28%      -0.02%     -0.33%    -0.63%     -0.95%
              0%        37.00%      36.70%      36.39%     36.09%    35.77%                     0%          0.30%       0.00%     -0.31%    -0.61%     -0.93%
              10%       37.02%      36.72%      36.41%     36.11%    35.80%                     10%         0.32%       0.02%     -0.29%    -0.59%     -0.90%
              20%       37.04%      36.74%      36.43%     36.13%    35.82%                     20%         0.34%       0.04%     -0.27%    -0.57%     -0.88%

NPV                     Wood                                                                                 Wood
                        -20%        -10%         0%         10%       20%                                    -20%       -10%        0%        10%       20%
              -20%      650,415     640,078     629,740    619,403   609,066                    -20%        3.11%       1.54%     -0.07%    -1.74%     -3.47%
  Livestock




                                                                                    Livestock
              -10%      650,647     640,310     629,973    619,636   609,299                    -10%        3.14%       1.58%     -0.04%    -1.71%     -3.43%
              0%        650,880     640,543     630,206    619,868   609,531                     0%         3.18%       1.61%      0.00%    -1.67%     -3.39%
              10%       651,113     640,775     630,438    620,101   609,764                     10%        3.21%       1.65%      0.04%    -1.63%     -3.35%
              20%       651,345     641,008     630,671    620,334   609,996                     20%        3.25%       1.69%      0.07%    -1.59%     -3.31%

Table 31. Sensitivity Analysis: Land Price

                                        Land Price                                                                           Land Price
               -20%        -10%        0%       10%          20%      50%                            -20%       -10%       0%      10%         20%       50%
                                                                                                                                                           -
 IRR          57.50%      43.38%      36.39%     31.71%     28.18%   20.94%       IRR             21.11%        6.99%     0.00%    -4.68%    -8.21%     15.45%
                                                                                                                                                           -
 NPV          698,946     664,576     630,206    595,835   561,465   458,354     NPV              9.83%         5.17%     0.00%    -5.77%    -12.24%    37.49%

Table 32. Sensitivity Analysis: Harvesting, Thinning and Management Costs

                                        Land Price                                                                           Land Price
               -20%        -10%        0%       10%          20%      50%                            -20%       -10%       0%      10%         20%        50%
 IRR          57.50%      43.38%      36.39%     31.71%     28.18%   20.94%       IRR             21.11%        6.99%     0.00%    -4.68%     -8.21%    -15.45%
 NPV          698,946     664,576     630,206    595,835   561,465   458,354     NPV               9.83%        5.17%     0.00%    -5.77%    -12.24%    -37.49%



                                                                               90
CHAPTER 5

                                        CONCLUSIONS


       The forest policy in Uruguay was developed to promote economic growth and generate

environmental benefits. The government considered it as a tool to transform marginal

agricultural lands, offering good forest growth conditions, into a thriving, globally competitive

forest sector. The government thought that effective policies will help in developing a higher-

value land use while promoting economic development, creating employment, attracting foreign

investment, and increasing exports. While the development of the forest policy benefited from

broad support in the legislature, it still was controversial. Subsidies proved to be particularly

contentious. The main issues were: (1) whether the subsidies were necessary to attract

investments, (2) whether to subsidize other, already established, sectors of the economy, and (3)

whether the subsidies should be in effect for regions which determined that better alternative

uses exist for lands allocated to forest development.

       This study evaluated the forest policy in Uruguay nearly twenty years after it was

developed. It used a CBA approach that has not been used before. While some studies had tried

to evaluate the impact of the new forest sector on Uruguay’s economy, they had focused on

fiscal impacts and individual projects, not on the sector as a whole. This study compares the new

forest sector with alternative activities that would have been developed if the project would have

not been implemented. Livestock was assumed to be the alternative land use, corresponding

closely to what has been observed on the ground. The CBA model had to make an extensive use

of secondary information and own estimates. Linkages with other sectors of the economy,

excluding direct transportation costs, were not considered due to data limitations. The current

area of forest priority soils is 3 million ha; forests are already planted on 750 thousand ha. This



                                                91
indicates that the forest planted area can still grow substantially, followed by further growth of

wood manufacturing industries.

       The results indicate a positive net impact of the newly developed forest sector on the

Uruguayan economy when compared with agriculture and livestock. The NPV for the forest

sector equals 630.2 million US$, using a 6% discount rate. The IRR for the forest sector

development is 36.4%. These results are somewhat sensitive to changes in wood prices and

growth rates and harvest yields. This indicates that market conditions and forest management

operations are important variables in the evaluation of impacts that the sector has on the

country’s economy.

       Forest policy in Uruguay has been successful in several ways. It has increased exports,

which improved the balance of payments. It has found more productive uses for poor quality

lands while attracting foreign investment, generating income and employment, and providing

environmental benefits. Still, some aspects of the forest policy are a subject of a heated debate.

       One of the most contentious issues is the increased competition for land. The

development of the forest sector has brought about higher land prices. It has been harder and

more expensive to purchase land, rising dissent in some circles of the society. There are only

limited investment opportunities in Uruguay, and land has traditionally been considered as an

important low risk investment. Current land prices are on par with prices in neighboring Brazil

and Argentina. In the past, they had been lower. While not mentioned by forest investors, the

lower land prices were one of the factors that attracted foreign investment. In addition, some

farmers complained about the necessity of moving livestock to new areas once traditional

pastures were converted to forestry. Since this process has been gradual, the cost is not expected

to be high.




                                                 92
Other contentious issue regarding the forest policy was the use of subsidies to support the

development of forest plantations and wood manufacturing industries. It has been shown that the

even though subsidies the subsidy were important to attract investments, they were not the key

factor. The discussion of whether to subsidize other sectors of the economy can be addressed

with the positive net results obtained from evaluating the cost and benefits of the forest activity

compared with an alternative production.

       One may ask: Why the impacts of the forest policy in Uruguay have been uniformly

positive? After all, there are numerous examples of countries that tried and failed in developing

their forest sectors in an efficient and sustainable way (Repetto 1988; Repetto & Gillis 1988).

Certainly, Uruguay has growth conditions suitable for forestry. Factors that may have decided

the successes of the policy include a stable economic policy and investment polices that truly

encourage foreign capital to invest to the country.

        Throughout the course of this research project, several opportunities for further research

have been identified. First, an extension of this CBA analysis should be conducted in a few years

time. This is because large wood manufacturing facilities, including two paper mills, are nearing

completion and will start operating in the next few years. Their massive, value-added products

targeting global wood and paper markets will have a major impact on the country’s economy and

the evaluation of the forest policy.

       Second, it would be worthwhile to estimate shadow prices for the forest sector, in

particular for land and labor. Shadow prices for land in forestry uses have not been developed in

Uruguay as suggested in the forest research literature. Labor treatment has been long a

controversial issue. Unemployment is high in Uruguay, and large numbers of workers migrate in

search for employment opportunities. While employment generation has not been a major




                                                93
policy’s objective, it has been an important argument in debating and defending it. A

comprehensive assessment of labor issues would certainly help in informing this and future

policy debates.

       Third, the use of a more comprehensive evaluation method may also cast more

information on the policy’s impacts. Three approaches are generally used to evaluate forest

policies. They include the Computable General Equilibrium (CGE), Input-Output (I-O) and

Cost-Benefit Analysis (CBA), which was used in this study. CGE requires estimation of

macroeconomic equations which was beyond the scope of this project. The second approach

requires an updated I-O matrix. The rationale for a more comprehensive approach is that in a

small country such as Uruguay, the forest sector, once large mills become operable, will have a

substantial impact on the country’s economy.

       Finally, further research should incorporate non-market variables. They include a range

of environmental services that are provided by forest plantations. Environmental values are

increasingly important in policy debates, and Uruguay is no exception. While the plantations

have been criticized on environmental grounds, they appear to put less stress on the environment

than agriculture and livestock. These impacts too need to be evaluated to inform policy debates

and permit rational land use decision-making.




                                                94
REFERENCES


Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay, 2000. Agricultural Census 2000, Montevideo, Uruguay.

ALADI, 2006. Regional Trade Statistics. ALADI (Latin American Integration Association). In
www.aladi.com. Last accessed: March 2006.

Ascher, W., Healy, R., 1990. Natural resource policymaking in developing countries:
       Environment, economic growth, and income distribution. Duke University Press, Durham
       and London.

Bacha, C.J.C., 2004. The Use of Forest Resources and Brazilian Economic Policies. A Partial
       and Historical Vision of a Development Process. Economic Studies 34, Pages 393-426.

Berck, P., Costello, C., Fortmann, L., Hoffmann, S., 2003. Poverty and employment in forest-
       dependent counties. Forest Science 49, 763-777

Bergman, L., Henrekson, M., 2003. CGE Modeling of Environmental Policy and Resource
       Management.

Berreta, E., 2003. Country Pasture Profiles: Uruguay. Available at:
http://fao.org/ag/Agp/agpc/doc/pasture/forage.htm. Last accessed: October 2006.

Bisang, K., Zimmermann, W., 2006. Key concepts and methods of programme evaluation and
       conclusions from forestry practice in Switzerland. Forest Policy and Economics 8, 502-
       511

Boardman, A.E., 2001. Cost-benefit analysis: concepts and practice. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle
       River, NJ.

Boardman, A.E., Greenberg, D.H., Vining, A.R., Weimer, D.L., 1997. Plug-in shadow price
       estimates for policy analysis. Annals of Regional Science 31, 299




                                               95
Carrere, R., 2002. Uruguay: the Absurd Injustice Behind the Forestry [Uruguay: la absurda
       injusticia detrás de la forestación] Revista del Sur 133. Available at: www.guayubira.com
       Last accessed: December 2006.

Carvalho Mendes, A.M.S., 2006. Implementation analysis of forest programmes: Some
       theoretical notes and an example. Forest Policy & Economics 8, 512-528

Central Bank of Uruguay, 2005. GDP Statistics. Serie Nº 19135: GDP. Central Bank of
Uruguay. Montevideo, Uruguay. At www.bcu.gub.uy. Last Accessed: February 2007.

Chappelle, D.E., 1971. Forestry, Public Pressures, and Economic Development: Discussion.
       American Journal of Agricultural Economics 53, 896

Chavas, J.-P., Bouamra Mechemache, Z., 2006. Efficiency measurements and the gains from
       trade under transaction costs. J Prod Analysis (2006) 26:67–85. Published online: 19 July
       2006.

Chowdhury, A., Kirkpatrick, C.H., 1994. Development policy and planning : an introduction to
       models and techniques. Routledge, London ; New York.

CIDE, 1963. Uruguayan Soils: Use and Management. Investment and Economic Development
       Comission, FAO. Montevideo, Uruguay

Clapp, R.A., 1995. Creating competitive advantage: Forest policy as industrial policy in Chile.
       Economic Geography 71, 273

Clapp, R.A., 2001. Tree Farming and Forest Conservation in Chile: Do Replacement Forests
       Leave Any Originals Behind? Society and Natural Resources 14, 341-356

Clark, J., 2004. Forest policy for sustainable commodity wood production: an examination
       drawing on the Australian experience. Ecological Economics 50, 219-232

Clutter, J.L., Fortson, J.C., Pienaar, L.V., Brister, G.H., Bailey, R.L., 1983. Timber management
       : a quantitative approach . New York, N.Y. : Wiley, c1983.



                                               96
COFUSA, 2006. www.cofusa.com.uy Last accessed: April 2007.

Colonization National Institute, 2006. www.colonizacion.com.uy. Last accessed: March 2007.

Cubbage, F., Mac Donagh, P., Sawinski Júnior, J., Rubilar, R., Donoso, P., Ferreira, A., Hoeflich
       V., Morales Olmos, V., Ferreira, G., Balmelli, G., Siry, J., Báez, M.N., Alvarez, J., 2006.
       Timber Investment Returns for Selected Plantation and Native Forests in South America
       and the Southern United States. New Forests (In press)

Cubbage, F.W., O’Laughlin, J., Bullock, C.S., 1993. Forest Resource Policy. Chapters 1, 2, 3, 5,
       18.

Dasgupta, P., Sen, A.K., Marglin, S.A., 1972. Guidelines for project evaluation, New York.

Decrees: 452/88, 457/989/, 330/90, 26/93, 212/97 (Art. 1), 191/06, 220/06. Montevideo,
       Uruguay.

Dewar, R.C., 1991. An analytical model of carbon storage in the trees. Tree Physiology. 8, 239–
       258.

DIEA, 2004. Agricultural Statistics. Agricultural Planning and Programming Office/Agricultural
Ministry. In: www.mgap.gub.uy/opypa. Last accessed: February 2006.

Dore, M.H.I., Guevara, R.e., 2000. Sustainable forest management and global climate change:
       Selected case studies from the Americas. Elgar, Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton,
       Mass.

Dunn, W.N., 2004. Public policy analysis: an introduction. Pearson/Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle
       River, N.J.

Durán, V., 2003. Forest Sector: A Characterization. Yearbook OPYPA 2003. Montevideo,
       Uruguay.

Durán, V., 2004. In 2003 forest sector industrialization took off. National wood availability,
       would be enough? Yearbook OPYPA 2004. Montevideo, Uruguay


                                               97
Economic Institute, 2003. Uruguayan Economy Report 2003. Trends and Outlook. Economic
       Institute (Ed.), Montevideo, Uruguay

El Espectador Radio, 2005. Interview with Marvin Risco (Weyerhaeuser Manager for South
       America). Montevideo, Uruguay.

Ellefson, P.V., 1988. Forestry issues as a focus for forest economics and policy research : a
       review of selected issue defining documents. College of Forestry and the Agricultural
       Experiment Station Institute of Agriculture Forestry and Home Economics University of
       Minnesota, St. Paul, Minn.

Ence, 2006. Ence in Uruguay. Brochure. Montevideo, Uruguay.

Escudero, R., 2004. GEFR/IBRD Project. Component: Native Forest. Montevideo, Uruguay.

FAO, 2005. Global Resources Assessment 2005.

FAO, 2006. www.fao.org.uy. Last accessed: February 2007.

Fernandez Gaeta, R., 1995. Accounting Prices Estimation for Uruguay [Actualizacion de precios
       de cuenta para el Uruguay]. Budgeting and Planning Office. Montevideo, Uruguay.

Flynn, B., 2005. Brazil's Forest Industry: Background Fact Book for the 2005 Plantation Forestry
       Study Tour. April 03-10, 2005.

Forest Division, 2005. Strategy Report. Forest Division/Agricultural Ministry, Montevideo,
       Uruguay

Forest Division, 2006. Estimation of the Costs of the Forestry Policy. Report. Montevideo,
       Uruguay

Forest Policy and Economics Editorial, 2006. Forest Policy and Economics Journal 8 (2006)

Forest Producers Society, 2006. Mision and Objectives. In www.spf.com.uy. Last accessed:
       December 2006.


                                              98
Forestry Law 13723, 1968. Montevideo, Uruguay.

Forestry Law 15939, 1988. Montevideo, Uruguay.

González Posse, E., Barrenechea, P., 1996. Study on the Forest Promotion Fiscal Effects.
       Montevideo, Uruguay.

Gregersen, H.M., Contreras, A.H., 1979. Economic analysis of forestry projects. Food and
       Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome, Italy.

Guldin, R.W., 2003. Forest science and forest policy in the Americas: building bridges to a
       sustainable future. Forest Policy & Economics 5, 329.

Hagler, R., 2007. The Risks and Returns of International Timberland Investing. Presented at: The
       Timberland Asset: Reliable and Renewable Conference. March 28-30, 2007. Lake
       Oconee, Georgia, USA.

Haltia, O., Keipi, K., 1997. Financing Forest Investments in Latin America: The Issue of
       Incentives. IDB. No ENV-113. Washington, D.C.

Harou, P.A.W., 1987. Essays in forestry economics: appraisal and evaluation of forestry
       investments, programs, and policies Wissenschaftsverlag Vauk, Kiel.

www.guayubira.com.uy. Last accessed: December 2006.

Hyde, W.F., Boyd, R.G., Daniels, B.L., 1987. The Impacts of Public Interventions: An
       Examination of the Forestry Sector. Journal of Policy Analysis & Management 7, 40-61

INE, 2006. www.ine.gub.uy. Last accessed: December 2006.

Karjalainen, T., 1996. Dynamics and potentials of carbon sequestration in managed stands and
       wood products in Finlandunder changing climatic conditions. For. Ecol. Manage.
       80,113–132.




                                              99
Keugen, S., 2001. The Brazilian Forest Policy: A Historical Perspective. SIAGEF, Porto Seguro,
       4-7 July 2001.

Lara, A., Veblen, T.T., 1993. Forest Plantations in Chile: a successful model? in Afforestation:
       Policies, Planning and Progress. Edited by Alexander Mather. Belhaven Press. United
       Kingdom. .

Law 16906, 1998. Investments, Promotion and Protection. Montevideo, Uruguay

Lim, B., Brown, S., Schlamadinger, B., 1999. Carbon accounting for forest harvesting and wood
       products. Review and evaluation of different approaches. Environmental Science and
       Policy 2, p. 207-216.

Little, I.M.D., Mirrlees, J.A., 1974. Project Appraisal and Planning in Developing Countries.
       Basic Books, Inc., Publishers New York.

Londero, E., Cervini, H., 2003. Shadow prices for project appraisal: theory and practice
       Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA: E. Elgar.

Lorenzo, F., Berreta, N., Laens, S., Perelmuter, N., Osimani, R., Paolino, C., Pessano, O., 2005.
       Industrial and Investment Policy in Uruguay. IADBF. Reference Notes (RE1-RN-05-
       006).

Marglin, S.A., 1977. The Essentials of the UNIDO Approach to Benefit-Cost Analysis in Cost-
       Benefit Analysis and Project Design. Edited by John D. Donahue. Indiana University,
       Bloomington, Indiana, USA.

Mendell, B., Morales, V., Bennadji, Z., Moreno, A., Siry, J., 2007. Financing Uruguay’s Forestry
       Sector: Survey and Case Study. Journal of Forestry [In press].

Methol, M., 2004. Activities in environmental policy and natural resources management.
       Yearbook OPYPA 2004. Montevideo, Uruguay




                                              100
Methol, R., 2003. SAG Grandis: Support System to Eucalyptus Grandis Plantations Management
       [SAG grandis: Sistema de Apoyo a la Gestión de Plantaciones de Eucalyptus grandis].
       Agricultural Research National Institute (INIA). Serie Técnica No 131. Tacuarembó,
       Uruguay.

Metsa-Botnia, 2004. Socioeconomic Study of the Impacts of Botnia SA Pulp Mill Project in
       Uruguay. Executive Summary. Montevideo, Uruguay

Nas, T.F., 1996. Cost-benefit analysis: theory and application. Sage Publications,, Thousand
       Oaks, California.

Nebel, P., 2003. Conservation of the Native Forest: the Uruguayan Strategy. Unpublished.
       Montevideo, Uruguay.

Newman, D.H., 1988. The Optimal Forest Rotation: A Discussion and Annotated Bibliography.
       p. 47. US Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Southeastern Forest Experiment
       Station, Asheville, North Carolina

Paperloop, 2005. Pulp and Paper Global Fact & Price Book 2005.

Paredes, G.V., 1999. Chilean Forestry: Wood Products from an Exporting Industry. In Global
       Concerns for Forest Resource Utilization. Sustainable Use and Management. Edited by
       A. Yoshimoto and K. Yukutake. Kluwer Academic Publishers. The Netherlands.

Patton, C., Sawicki, D.S., 1993. Basic Methods of Policy Analysis and Planning. Prentice Hall.

Pereyra, A., 2004. Accounting Prices Estimation for the Economic Evaluation of Local
       Development Projects Program IV- Final Report. Planning and Budgeting Office/Local
       Development Program. Montevideo, Uruguay.

Perman, R., Ma, Y., McGilvray, J., Common, M., 2003. Natural Resource and Environmental
       Economics (Chapter 10). Addison-Wesley.




                                              101
Pleskovic, B., Treviño, G., 1985. The use of a social accounting matrix framework for public
       sector analysis : the case study of Mexico. International Center for Public Enterprises in
       Developing Countries, Ljubljana, Yugoslavia.

Prestemon, J.P., Buongiorno, J., Wear, D.N., Siry, J.P., 2003. International Trade in Forest
       Products (Chapter 11). In: Sills EO & Lee Abt K (eds.) Forests in a Market Economy.
       Series: Forestry Sciences, Vol. 72.

Ramos, A., Cabrera, R., 2001. Uruguay Forest Sector Impact. p. 99, Montevideo, Uruguay

Ray, A., 1984. Cost-benefit analysis: issues and methodologies. Published for the World Bank
       [by] Johns Hopkins University Press.

Repetto, R., 1988. The forest for the trees? Government policies and the misuse of forest
       resources. World Resources Institute, Washington, D.C.

Repetto, R.C., Gillis, M., 1988. Public policies and the misuse of forest resources. Cambridge
       University Press, Cambridge [Cambridgeshire]; New York

Richards, K.R., Stokes, C., 2004. A review of forest carbon sequestration cost studies: A dozen
       years of research. Climatic Change 63, 1-48

Rossi, P.H., Freeman, H.E., Lipsey, M.W., 1999. Evaluation: a systematic approach. Sage
       Publications, Thousand Oaks, California.

Sabag Villalobos, P.H., 1984. Forestry Promotion Policy. An Economical Analysis: 1974-1983.
       Thesis. Universidad Austral de Chile. Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y
       Administrativas. Escuela de Ingeniería Comercial. Valdivia, Chile.

Sáder Neffa, M., 2004. Characteristics of the Investments in Land (Características de la inversión
       en tierra). OPYPA Yearbook 2004. Montevideo, Uruguay.

San Román, D., 2005. Review of Forest Sector Employment - Internal Report. Montevideo,
       Uruguay.



                                               102
Silva, E., 2004. The political economy of forest policy in Mexico and Chile. Singapore Journal
       of Tropical Geography 25, 261-280.

Siry, J.P., Cubbage, F., Newman, D.H., 2005. Who Owns World's Forests? Implications for
       Forest Production, Management and Protection. Presented at IUFRO World Congress.
       8-13 August 2005. Brisbane, Australia.

Slee, B., 2006. The socio-economic evaluation of the impact of forestry on rural development: A
       regional level analysis. Forest Policy and Economics 8, 542-554.

Slee, W., Evans, R., Roberts, D., 2003. Understanding Forestry in Rural Development: Report to
       the Forestry Commission. Forestry Commission, England.

Southern Hemisphere, 2006. Forest Industry Yearbook. 2005-06 Edition. Trade and Media
       Services Ltd. New Zealand.

Souto, G., Methol, M., 2005. Energy and Agricultural Sector. OPYPA Yearbook 2005.
       Montevideo, Uruguay.

Squire, L., van der Tak, H.G., 1975. Economic analysis of projects. Published for the World
       Bank [by] Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.

Stone, R., 1985. The Disaggregation of the Household Sector in the National Accounts. In:
       Social accounting matrices: a basis for planning. World Bank, Washington, DC, pp. 145-
       185.

Tourism Ministry, 2006. www.turismo.gub.uy. Last accessed: December 2006.

Varian, H.R., 1984. Microeconomic analysis, New York.

Vázquez Platero, R., 1996. Evaluation of the Forest Development in Uruguay Forest Producers
       Society/Rural Association of Uruguay, Montevideo, Uruguay.

Wing, I.S., 2004. Computable General Equilibrium Models and Their Use in Economy-Wide
       Policy Analysis: Everything You Ever Wanted to Know (But Were Afraid to Ask).


                                                103
World Bank, 2005. Uruguay Pulp Mills-Cumulative Impact Study- Draft. In:
http://www/ifc.org/ifcext/lac/nsf/Content/Uruguay. Last accessed: November 2006.

World Bank, 2006. Doing Business in Uruguay: Methodology. Available at:
http://www.doingbusiness.org/MethodologySurveys/. Last accessed: April 2007.

Zerbe, R.O., Dively, D., 1994. Benefit-cost analysis in theory and practice. HarperCollins
       College Publishers, New York.




                                            104
APPENDIX I

SURVEY RESULTS




     105
THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE FOREST SECTOR IN URUGUAY:

                                      SURVEY RESULTS



    A survey to institutions and companies in the forest sector was conducted in July 2006 in

Uruguay. The institutions selected were the Forest Producers Society (SPF), the Economic

Institute of the Social Sciences Faculty of the Republic of Uruguay University, the Forest

Division and the Agricultural Planning and Policy Office (OPYPA) of the Agricultural Ministry.

Selected companies included were Botnia, Eufores, Colonvade, Fymnsa and Cofusa.

    The Forest Producers Society (SPF) is a private association that represents the forest

business sector in Uruguay. It is made up of technicians, producers, and companies, both local

and foreign. Its objective is to promote a sustainable forest sector in Uruguay by promoting

forest plantations and contributing to the conservation of the natural forests in the country (Forest

Producers Society 2006).

    The Economic Institute of the Social Sciences Faculty of the Republic of Uruguay

University is a research institute which research areas include: econometric, industrial

organization, business, microeconomics, macroeconomics, finance and labor economic.

    The Forest Division of the Agricultural Ministry is in charge of the Forest Policy (Forestry

Law 15939 1988). The main activities are to promote the forest activity, to design and to analyze

management plans for public and private lands, to assist the institutions on the forest

management and to coordinate activities related with the forestry.

    OPYPA of the Agricultural Ministry is the office in charge of advising the government in

the design, execution and control of the agricultural policies.




                                                106
The companies were selected for the following reasons: first, they include both local and

foreign companies; second, all together they own 30% of the plantations and the rest is

fragmented; third, they produce a spectrum of products (two, wood for pulp; two, saw timber;

one, plywood); fourth, each of the companies is in a different stage of development; fifth, they

have different types of organization according to capital, species and timber management. Some

of the companies have different names for their plantation’s firm and for their manufacturing

firm; furthermore, some companies have different names from the name they use in their country

of origin (Table 33).

    Botnia is constructing a pulp mill in the North of the country, which involves the largest

single investment in the country’s history: a one billion US$ investment. It consumes 3.5 million

cum of pulpwood when operating at full capacity (Metsa-Botnia 2004). Its main product is

bleached eucalyptus Kraft pulp, and their estimated production capacity will be one million tons

per year. Its capital originates from Finland and was used to purchase the Uruguayan company,

FOSA, which owned the forest plantations. The company is located in Río Negro and Paysandú.

    Colonvade is a branch of the US company Weyerhaeuser. It is constructing a plywood

facility and plans to construct five to eight more plants in Tacuarembó, Rivera and Paysandú. Its

total investment is between $500 and $800 million, depending on the number of plants it will

construct. It has already made a $270 million investment in 131,000 hectares of land for

plantations, of which 85,000 were already planted. Its first commercial thinning was planned for

the current year, and it expected to obtain 16,000 m3 wood. By 2012 it expects to extract 2.5

million m3 per year, from which it would obtain 900,000 m3 in products to export. The main

products are: plywood, saw timber, MDF (medium density board) and LVL (laminated veneer

lumber) (El Espectador Radio 2005).




                                              107
Ence, a Spanish company that has partnerships with several local companies, was planning

to construct a pulp mill by the end of the current year. Eufores is the local branch of the

company. At M’Bopicuá Logistic Terminal, Ence invested $622 million in a chip plant with a

production capacity of 500,000 cum per year. Maserlit, an Uruguayan sawmill that Ence

controls, produces 35,000 cum per year of kiln dried wood to produce Eucalyptus Grandis

lumber. By the time of the interview, Ence estimated that by the year 2008 they will be operating

at full capacity. However, these days it has been subsequently announced the relocation of the

mill and the information of when they are going to begin the construction is not known.

    Fymnsa, which produces saw logs, is one of the oldest and biggest local companies and is

building a sawmill in Rivera (northern Uruguay). It is producing 18,000 tons of chips per year

and it has 13,000 ha of plantations.

    Cofusa and Urufor are two forestry companies that belong to the same economic group.

They are located in the North of Uruguay and produce high quality Eucalyptus Grandis timber.

Cofusa owns 25,000 haof plantations and Urufor owns a sawmill.

    The survey for institutions had semi structured questions on topics which differed according

to the institution. SPF was asked about regulation, their studies on forest sector impact and

policy evaluation and limitations for the sector’s development; the Economic Institute of Social

Sciences Faculty was asked about macroeconomic data availability to use in the research; Forest

Division was asked about the Forest Policy history and the current regulation in force as well as

about their future actions; and OPYPA was asked about the situation of the forest sector in

Uruguay and its possible impacts in the economy.




                                              108
The survey for companies had open and structured questions. The companies had to fill out

two different forms: one for its plantation activities and the other for its industrial activities, as

some companies has separate corporations for each activity.

        Each plantation company was asked about location, origin of the capital, production (forest

area, harvest, and rotation age), costs and investments, labor, certification programs and future

plans. Each industry was asked questions dealing with location, origin of the capital, production

(products, markets, sales, and plants’ capacity), investment and costs, labor, regulation,

certification programs and future plans. Each company was also asked for the reasons it started

its activities in Uruguay.

        Institutions interviewed evaluated the impact of the forest sector in Uruguay as positive.

There is an agreement that the sector is just starting its development and it is going to grow fast

in the next years when plantations start to be harvested. Opinions on regulation differed: the SPF

said that regulation is good, and people in the Forest Division said that current regulation needs

to be adjusted. Institutions are weaker than at the beginning of the forest sector development.

        The SPF had evaluated the impact of the new forest sector using cost benefit analysis. Two

private consultants compared the Uruguayan economy with and without the forest sector

(Vázquez Platero 1996; Ramos & Cabrera 2001). They considered plantations as well as

industrial activities, and both concluded that the impact will be positive. The limitations for the

sector would be related with high costs in US dollars, specially fuel, and a low exchange rate34

which leads to a competitiveness loss.

        The Forest Division described the origin and objectives of the current Forest Policy in force.

Regarding the institution itself, two factors have a negative impact on their activities: first, an


34
     Currently the exchange rate is 24 $U/ 1 US$.



                                                    109
increasing number of technicians are going to the private sector, and second, more resources are

going to the Environmental Ministry to evaluate forest projects.

     The companies are located in the North and Northwest of the country, and one is expanding

their activities to the Northeast. The companies’ capital is originated in different countries:

Spain, Finland, USA and Uruguay. All the companies together have a forest area that represents

30% of the country’s forest area. They have more than 50% of their land planted; meanwhile this

ratio for the country is only 4.3%. These results show that the companies will buy new land to

increase the plantations area (Table 34).

     Even though Eucalyptus is the most important specie planted, Pine is increasing its

participation reaching 77,265 hectares in 2004 (Table 35). Eucalyptus is mostly managed for

pulp with the exception of one company that is managing it for hardwood. Pine is managed for

saw timber and plywood.

     Rotation ages vary from 22 to 25 for Pine according to the final product, and 10 to 20 years

for Eucalyptus. On average, this represents 23 years for Pine and 15 years for Eucalyptus

(Table 36).

     Investments vary from each company according to their stage of development. By 2008,

four companies’ total investments35 will be approximately 1,900 million US$36. This amount

includes investments that the companies have been done in land and investments they planned to

do in industries. There are important differences in amount, as one company is planning to invest

1 billion US $ in its pulp mill. The most important investments are from the foreign companies.



35
  One company did not give information about its total investments, and another did not give information before
2005.
36
  These days, one of the companies announced that an 800million US $ investment planned will be delayed. If this
investment were not considered, the total amount would be 1.100 billion US $.


                                                       110
All the companies are involved in Certification Programs: four of them have Forest

Stewardship Council (FSC) certification and one has International Organization for

Standardization 14001 (ISO 14001) certification.

    The regulation is good, but labor regulation is needed. Plantation workers are regulated

under agricultural laws without considering the specific characteristics of the forest sector, such

are safety issues. The general opinion is that the sector started developing because of the Forestry

Law 15939 and subsidies were an important part of the incentives’ package.

    All the companies have plans to grow in the future, either to increase the area planted, to

export, to build new mills or to increase their current capacity. Two companies are already

building their second sawmill.

    The companies mentioned several reasons for starting their activities in Uruguay. All of

them mentioned soils and growth rates as key elements to go to the country. They also pointed

put that a good economy’s performance, economy’s stability and a good regulation in the Forest

Sector were factors that contribute to this decision.

    Labor’s skills were a problem at the beginning, but the problem was quickly solved by

training the labor in the skills needed. Training programs were offered by companies to their

labor force and most of the companies said that Uruguayan workers are open to learn.




                                                111
Table 33. Companies classified according to the origin of the capital

           Uruguayan Entity                   International       Origin of (Foreign)
  Manufacturing      Forest Plantations      Firm in Control            Capital
     Botnia                Fosa              Oy Metsa Botnia              Finland
     Eufores              Eufores                  Ence                    Spain
   Colonvade            Colonvade              Weyerhaeuser             United States
     Fymnsa               Fymnsa                     -                    Uruguay
     Urufor               Cofusa                     -                    Uruguay


Table 34. Area by companies

                                                                                         Planted/
                              Planted Area (ha)              Land Area (ha)             Land Area
   Total 5 Companies                220,893                      391,000                 56.49%
     Total Uruguay                  714,000                     16,666,670               4.30%
          % Total
 (5 Companies/Uruguay)               30.94%


Table 35. Area by species (in ha)

 Euc.       Pinus      Euc.         Pinus       Pinus         Total
Grandis     Taeda    Globulus       Patula      Elliotti      Area
 38,120     77,265    105,000        129         379         220,893


Table 36. Rotation ages and Growth rates

     Estimations                     Pine                             Eucalyptus
    Rotation Age                    23 years                           15 years
    Growth Rates                   20 m3/year                         22 m3/year




                                                       112
APPENDIX II

SURVEY FORMS




     113
The Impact of the Forest Sector on the Uruguayan Economy
                               Master of Science Thesis Research
                     Warnell School of Forestry and Natural Resources
                                     University of Georgia
                                     Survey - Plantations


                                          July, 2006




I.      General Information


     1. Company Name: _________________________________________________________

     2. Contact Information:

        Address/ Phone Number/E-mail address:

        ________________________________________________________________________

        ________________________________________________________________________

        ________________________________________________________________________

     3. Name and Position of the Person who answer the survey:

        ________________________________________________________________________

        ________________________________________________________________________

     4. Type of business organization: Domestic         Foreign

        Sole Proprietorship      Domestic Partnership        Corporation

     5. Origin of foreign capital (if applicable): _____________________________________




                                             114
II.       Production

6. Area of Forest Land:


         Species         Total Land Area         Planted Area            Location




          Total


7. Harvest:


          Product                 Tons
       Saw timber
       Chip and Saw
       Pulpwood


8. Rotation: which is the average rotation by specie or by product?

___________________________________________________________________________

___________________________________________________________________________



III.      Investments and Costs


9. Investments: Which are the estimated investments per year?


              Category            Amount (in dollars)     Year        Imported (%)




                                           115
10. Total costs

           Year        Amount
           2000
           2001
           2002
           2003
           2004
           2005

11. Costs as percentage of the total:


                  Concept                  Amount (in dollars) Year
   Raw material (timber)
   Transportation
   Services, maintenance and repair
   Equipment
   Wages
   Insurance
   Supplies
   Contractual Services
   Fuels
   Utilities (Water, Electricity, Phone)
   Taxes
   Other administrative expenses
   Others (describe)




                                           116
IV.    Employment


12. Indicate number of employees by part of the company.
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________

V.     Environmental, certification and other programs
13. Does the company have environmental programs? If yes, please describe them briefly.
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


14. Does the company participate in any certification programs? If yes, in which ones?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


15. In which other programs does the company participate?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________




                                          117
VI.      Future Plans


16. What are the company’s plans for the following years?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


17. Which are the most important limitations that, in your opinion, the company would face
      in the following years? E.g.: transport, financing, labor, markets.
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
18. Which are the growth rates expected by species?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
19. How much production is expected for the next years?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________




                                              118
The Impact of the Forest Sector on the Uruguayan Economy
                           Master of Science Thesis Research
                  Warnell School of Forestry and Natural Resources
                                 University of Georgia
                                   Survey Industry


                                      July 2006




I.      General Information


1. Company Name: _________________________________________________________

2. Contact Information:

     Address/ Phone Number/E-mail address:

     ________________________________________________________________________

     ________________________________________________________________________

     ________________________________________________________________________

3. Name and Position of the Person who answer the survey:

     ________________________________________________________________________

     ________________________________________________________________________

4. Type of business organization: Domestic           Foreign

     Sole Proprietorship     Domestic Partnership        Corporation

5. Origin of foreign capital (if applicable): _____________________________________




                                         119
II.      Production

6. Products:

                                  Destination
              Product             (markets)          % of the total sales
      Fuel wood
      Chips
      Plywood
      Boards
      Pulp
      Paper
      Others (specify)




7. Total Sales of Forest Products: indicate the approximate amount of sales per year.


            Year              Amount
            2000
            2001
            2002
            2003
            2004
            2005




                                         120
8. Does the company buy wood (timber) from other companies? Yes            No        . If yes,
   fill in the following table:


                Seller               % of total timber consumed          Specie(s)
   Farmer(s)
   Other companies
   (1) ___________________
   (2) ___________________
   (3) ___________________
   (4) ___________________
   (5) ___________________

9. Mill capacity. Indicate current and expected annual capacity of your mill(s) in cum.


        Plant                Year           Capacity          Product      Location




                                          121
III.   Investments and Costs


10. Investments: Which are the estimated investments per year?


            Concept              Amount (in dollars)      Year   Imported (%)




11. Total costs: how much are the total costs per year?


          Year            Amount
          2000
          2001
          2002
          2003
          2004
          2005




                                           122
12. Costs as percentage of the total:


                      Concept                   Amount (in dollars) Year
        Raw material (timber)
        Transportation
        Services, maintenance and repair
        Equipment
        Wages
        Insurance
        Supplies
        Contractual Services
        Fuels
        Utilities (Water, Electricity, Phone)
        Taxes
        Other administrative expenses
        Others (describe)



  IV.       Employment


  13. Indicate number of employees by part of the company. If the company has more than one
        plant, please use different tables.


  Plant: _____________________________________


                                                      Years
   Concept
Construction
Operation




                                                123
Plant: _____________________________________


                                                    Years
   Concept
Construction
Operation

Plant: _____________________________________


                                                    Years
   Concept
Construction
Operation



Plant: _____________________________________


                                                    Years
   Concept
Construction
Operation




   14. Which external services do you hire?
   ___________________________________________________________________________
   ___________________________________________________________________________
   ___________________________________________________________________________
   ___________________________________________________________________________
   ___________________________________________________________________________




                                              124
V.      Regulation


15. Why did the company choose Uruguay to run the business?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


16. If the subsidies and tax exonerations were not established, would you have chosen the
     country to invest?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


17. How do you evaluate the regulation in the Forest Sector in Uruguay?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


18. Do you consider the Law No. 16906 (National Interest Investments) an important
     incentive to invest in the country?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________



                                           125
19. Which elements (or regulation) will be necessary to improve the developing of the sector
      in the next years?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________




VI.      Environmental, certification and other programs


20. Does the company have programs to monitor environmental effects? If yes, which kind of
      programs?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


21. Does the company participate in any certification programs? If yes, in which one(s)?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


22. Does the company participate in Chain of Custody certification programs?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________




                                          126
23. In which other programs the company participates?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


VII.   Future Plans


24. What are the company’s plans for the following years? E.g.: increase capacity, buy new
   land, and explore new markets.
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


25. Which are the most important limitations that, in your opinion, the company would face
   in the following years? E.g.: transport, financing, wood supply, labor, markets.
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________


26. What are the perspectives you see on the development of the forest sector in Uruguay?
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________
___________________________________________________________________________




                                          127
APPENDIX III
CBA TABLES




      128
Table 37. Total Extraction Eucalyptus (1,000 m3)

            1989    1990    1991     1992     1993     1994     1995     1996      1997     1998       1999       2000     2001     2002    2003    2004     2005

Effective
Area
(in ha)     3,817   4,208   10,070   16,473   25,707   26,736   35,651   34,671    41,683   38,274     28,865     22,778   19,988   8,807   8,620   19,808   17,873


Pulp                                                                                         668        736       1,762    2,883    4,499   4,679   6,239    6,067

Saw
timber
  Pulp
   1st
Thinning                                                                                          57         63     151      247     386     401      535      520
   2nd
Thinning                                                                                                                            1,080   1,123    1,497    1,456
   Saw
 timber

Total
Pulp         0       0        0        0        0        0        0      0           0       725        799       1,913    3,130    5,964   6,203   8,271    8,044
Total
Saw
timber       0       0        0        0        0        0        0          0       0        0          0          0        0       0       0        0        0




                                                                             129
Table 38. Total Extraction Pine (1,000 m3)

                1989   1990   1991     1992     1993     1994      1995      1996      1997       1998     1999     2000     2001     2002     2003    2004    2005
 Effective
 Area (in ha)   602    914    1,172    1,352    3,359    4,005     5,231     6,465     9,514      20,885   22,104   17,719   16,306   11,955   9,975   6,788   11,915
     Total
  Extraction
 No Value

 1st Thinning                                    7        10        13        15         37        45       58       72       106      233     246     198      182

   2nd Thin                                                                                                                    -        -          -       -     -

  3rd Thin.                                                                                                                    -        -          -       -     -
   Harvest
 Fuel wood

 1st Thinning                                        -         -         -         -          -     -        -        -        -        -          -       -     -

  2nd Thin.                                                                                                                   442      970     1,027   823      758
  3rd Thin.
   Harvest
 Saw timber

 1st Thinning                                        -         -         -         -          -     -        -        -        -        -          -       -     -

  2nd Thin.                                                                                                                   442      970     1,027   823      758
  3rd Thin.
   Harvest
 Total Pulp      0      0      0        0        0        0         0         0          0          0        0        0        0        0        0      0        0
 Total SW        0      0      0        0        0        0         0         0          0          0        0        0       442      970     1,027   823      758
 Total Fuel
 wood            0      0      0        0        0        0         0         0          0          0        0        0       442      970     1,027   823      758
 Total No
 Value           -      -          -        -    7        10        13        15         37        45       58       72       106      233     246     198      182




                                                                                   130
Table 39. Basic Assumptions

Forest Area (in 1,000 ha)

                  1989      1990    1991    1992    1993    1994    1995    1996    1997    1998    1999    2000    2001    2002    2003    2004    2005
Annual 1989-
1999               7         8       16      26      42     44      59      59      73      85      73      58      52      30      27      38      43
Cumulative         7         14      31      56      98     143     201     260     333     418     491     549     601     631     657     695      738

                                                                                                    0.2
With Project Production-Model (1,000 m3/ha)

                  1989      1990    1991    1992    1993    1994    1995    1996    1997    1998    1999    2000    2001    2002    2003    2004    2005
TOTAL              0         0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0      725     799     1,913   3,572   6,934   7,230   9,094   8,801
Pulpwood           0         0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0       725     799    1,913   3,130   5,964   6,203   8,271   8,044
Sawn wood           0         0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0      442     970    1,027    823     758
Saw timber          0         0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0       0      199     437     462     370     341


Prices (1,000 US$/m3)
Saw timber
price            0.084      0.084   0.084   0.084   0.084   0.084   0.084   0.084   0.084   0.084   0.084   0.084   0.084   0.112   0.112   0.112   0.112
Pulpwood
prices           0.020      0.020   0.020   0.020   0.020   0.020   0.020   0.020   0.020   0.028   0.032   0.025   0.023   0.023   0.026   0.028   0.032




                                                                            131
Table 40. Investments in Land (million US$)

 Plantations       1989    1990    1991    1992    1993    1994    1995    1996    1997    1998    1999    2000    2001    2002    2003    2004    2005
 With
 Market Land
 Price (1,000
 US$/ha)           0.361   0.528   0.580   0.637   0.658   0.716   0.749   0.760   0.734   0.796   0.630   0.650   0.590   0.460   0.593   0.871   1.871

 SPR land         1.19    1.19      1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19   1       1       1       1
 Investments Land million
 US$/ha
   Market Prices 2.37     4.02     9.48    16.37   27.62   31.73   43.85   44.74   53.70   67.49   46.00   37.71   30.65   13.66   15.77   33.09   43.21
  Shadow Prices 2.82      4.79     11.28   19.48   32.86   37.75   52.18   53.24   63.91   80.31   54.73   44.87   36.48   13.66   15.77   33.09   43.21

 Without
 Market Land
 Price (1,000
 US$/ha)
      Livestock    0.361   0.426   0.478   0.535   0.556   0.614   0.647   0.658   0.632   0.632   0.486   0.415   0.349   0.283   0.385   0.599   0.599
 SPR land
           Land    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.19    1.00    1.00    1.00    1.00
 Investments
 Land million
 US$/ha
   Market Prices   2.37    3.25    7.81    13.75   23.35   27.22   37.89   38.75   46.26   53.58   35.47   24.08   18.11   8.41    10.23   22.77   29.44
  Shadow Prices    2.82    3.86    9.30    16.37   27.78   32.39   45.09   46.12   55.05   63.76   42.20   28.65   21.55   8.41    10.23   22.77   29.44

 Incremental
 Market Prices     0.00    0.78    1.66    2.61    4.27    4.51    5.96    5.99    7.44    13.91   10.53   13.63   12.55   5.25    5.54    10.31   13.77
 Shadow
 Prices            0.00    0.92    1.98    3.11    5.08    5.36    7.09    7.13    8.86    16.55   12.53   16.22   14.93   5.25    5.54    10.31   13.77




                                                                           132
Table 41. Industry Investments (million US$)

                  1989   1990   1991   1992   1993   1994   1995    1996   1997    1998   1999   2000   2001   2002   2003    2004    2005

 Investments
 (with Project)    0      0      0      0      0      0     10.50    0         0    0      0      0      0      0     10.50   10.50   41.50
 Saw timber                                                 10.50                                                     10.50   10.50   41.50
 Pulp


 Investments
 (without
 Project)          0      0      0      0      0      0      0       0         0    0      0      0      0      0      0       0       0
 Incremental
 Investments
 market prices     0      0      0      0      0      0     10.50    0         0    0      0      0      0      0     10.50   10.50   41.50
 Incremental
 Investments
 shadow Prices     0      0      0      0      0      0     13.76    0         0    0      0      0      0      0     10.61   10.61   41.92




                                                                         133
Table 42. Exports

                                     1989    1990    1991          1992   1993    1994     1995     1996     1997
With
Cumulative area
(1,000 ha)                           6.58    14.2    30.55     56.25      98.24   142.57   201.14   260.04   333.23
Forest Area (1,000 ha)               6.58    7.62    16.35     25.71      41.99   44.33    58.57     58.9     73.2

Total Exports                         0       0       0             0      0        0        0        0        0
Saw timber                            0       0       0             0      0        0        0        0        0
Pulpwood                              0       0       0             0      0        0        0        0        0
Without
Total Exports (million
US $)                                0.13    0.13    0.27          0.44   0.75     0.75     1.4      1.36     1.84
Alternative Productions (total
production)                          0.22    0.22    0.46          0.74   1.24     1.25     2.33     2.26     2.83
Alt. Prod. (exports)                 0.13    0.13    0.27          0.44   0.75     0.75     1.4      1.36     1.84

Incremental market prices (million
US$)                                 -0.13   -0.13   -0.27     -0.44      -0.75   -0.75     -1.4    -1.36    -1.84
Incremental shadow prices (million
US$)                                 -0.17   -0.17   -0.36     -0.58      -0.98   -0.99    -1.83    -1.78    -2.41




                                                             134
Table 42 (cont) Exports


                                 1998     1999     2000     2001     2002      2003    2004     2005
With
Cumulative area
(1,000 ha)                       418.01   491.02   549.03   600.99   630.72   657.31   695.31   737.86
Forest Area (1,000 ha)           84.78    73.01    58.01    51.96    29.73     26.59   37.99    42.55

Total Exports                    20.31    25.58    47.83    88.64    185.9    212.84   272.93   295.44
Saw timber                         0        0        0      16.65    48.73    51.57    41.34    38.05
Pulpwood                         20.31    25.58    47.83    71.99    137.17   161.27   231.59   257.4
Without
Total Exports (million
US $)                             2.43     1.81     1.55     1.08     0.35     0.47     0.85     1.28
Alternative Productions (total
production)                       3.74     2.79     2.38     1.66     0.54     0.72     1.22     1.83
Alt. Prod. (exports)              2.43     1.81     1.55     1.08     0.35     0.47     0.85     1.28

Incremental market prices
(million US$)                    17.88    23.77    46.28    87.56    185.55   212.38   272.08   294.16
Incremental shadow prices
(million US$)                    23.42    31.14    60.63    114.7    187.41    214.5   274.8    297.1




                                                                         135
Table 43. Transportation Costs (million US$)

                   1989   1990   1991   1992   1993   1994   1995   1996    1997   1998   1999   2000    2001    2002    2003    2004    2005
 With
 Transportation
 (in 1,000 tons)
 Pulpwood           0      0      0      0      0      0      0      0       0     653    720    1722    2817    5368    5582    7444    7239
 Sawn wood          0      0      0      0      0      0      0      0       0      0      0       0      354     776     822     659     606
 Saw timber         0      0      0      0      0      0      0      0       0      0      0       0      90      196     208     167     153
 Total Volume       0      0      0      0      0      0      0      0       0     653    720    1722    3260    6340    6612    8269    7999

 Total Wood
 Transportation
 Costs             0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00    0.00   5.87   6.48   15.50   29.34   57.06   59.51   74.42   71.99
 Total
 Livestock
 Transportation
 Costs             0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00    0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00    0.00    0.00    0.00    0.00    0.00
  Total Transp.
 Costs
 Market Prices     0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00    0.00   5.87   6.48   15.50   29.34   57.06   59.51   74.42   71.99
 Shadow
 Prices            0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00    0.00   4.52   4.99   11.93   22.59   43.94   45.82   57.31   55.43
 Without
 Livestock not
 transported
 (million US$)     0.01   0.01   0.03   0.05   0.08   0.13   0.21   0.28    0.42   0.51   0.54   0.61    0.67    0.27    0.73    0.77    0.82
 Total Costs in
 shadow prices     0.00   0.01   0.02   0.04   0.06   0.10   0.16   0.22    0.33   0.40   0.42   0.47    0.51    0.21    0.56    0.59    0.63
  Incremental
 Market              -      -      -      -      -      -      -      -       -
 prices            0.01   0.01   0.03   0.05   0.08   0.13   0.21   0.28    0.42   5.36   5.93   14.89   28.67   56.79   58.78   73.65   71.17
 Shadow                     -      -      -      -      -      -      -       -
 prices            0.00   0.01   0.02   0.04   0.06   0.10   0.16   0.22    0.33   4.13   4.57   11.46   22.08   43.73   45.26   56.71   54.80




                                                                           136
Table 44. Livestock Transportation Costs

                                          1989      1990      1991      1992      1993      1994      1995      1996      1997
 Without
 Livestock production (kg/ha)              43        43         45        45        45        45        45        45       50
 Total Area                               6,575    14,199    30,545    56,251    98,242    142,572   201,140   260,037   333,232
 Livestock production total (tons)         285      616       1,381     2,543     4,441     6,444     9,092    11,754    16,696
 Livestock production (ton/ha)            0.04      0.04      0.05      0.05      0.05      0.05      0.05      0.05      0.05
 # trips (total tons/13 tons)              22        47        106       196       342       496       699       904      1,284
 Transportation fees (US$/km-1 trip=13
 tons)                                    1.15      1.30      1.24      1.11      1.07      1.14      1.31      1.40      1.47

 US$/km/ton                               0.08      0.09      0.09      0.08      0.07      0.08      0.09      0.10      0.10
 Km/trip                                  250       250       250       250       250       250       250       250       250
 Transportation Costs (million US$)       0.02      0.05      0.11      0.20      0.34      0.50      0.70      0.90      1.28

                                          1998      1999      2000      2001      2002      2003      2004      2005
 Without
 Livestock production (kg/ha)              52        51        51        51         20       51        51        51
 Total Area                              418,009   491,017   549,030   600,986   630,716   657,311   695,305   737,860
 Livestock production total (tons)       21,817    25,003    27,957    30,602    12,614    33,470    35,405    37,572
 Livestock production (ton/ha)            0.05      0.05      0.05      0.05      0.02      0.05      0.05      0.05
 # trips (total tons/13 tons)             1,678     1,923     2,151     2,354      970      2,575     2,723     2,890
 Transportation fees (US$/km-1 trip=13
 tons)                                    1.36      1.26      1.26      1.26      1.26      1.26      1.26      1.26

 US$/km/ton                               0.09      0.09      0.09      0.09      0.09      0.09      0.09      0.09
 Km/trip                                  250       250       250       250       250       250       250       250
 Transportation Costs (million US$)       1.68      1.92      2.15      2.35      0.97      2.57      2.72      2.89




                                                                       137
Table 45. Industry Costs

                      1989       1990       1991      1992      1993      1994      1995      1996      1997
 Production Costs (imports) 1,000 US$/ha
 Slaughter Houses 0.00025 0.00027          0.00028   0.00029   0.00030   0.00031   0.00037   0.00034   0.00038
      Wool           0.00012 0.00012       0.00012   0.00012   0.00012   0.00013   0.00013   0.00013   0.00011
     Leather         0.00005 0.00005       0.00005   0.00005   0.00005   0.00005   0.00005   0.00005   0.00006
 Wood (1,000
        3
 US$/m )             0.00225 0.00209       0.00210   0.00146   0.00148   0.00133   0.00130   0.00127   0.00127

 Labor
 Slaughter Houses    0.0013    0.0014      0.0015    0.0015    0.0015    0.0016    0.0019    0.0017    0.0020
       Wool           0.004     0.004       0.004     0.004     0.004     0.004     0.004     0.004     0.003
      Leather        0.0002    0.0002      0.0002    0.0002    0.0002    0.0002    0.0002    0.0002    0.0002
 Wood (1,000
        3
 US$/m )             0.02639   0.02451     0.02468   0.01713   0.01736   0.01556   0.01529   0.01489   0.01489
  In market prices
                      1989      1990        1991      1992      1993      1994      1995      1996      1997
 With Project          0         0           0         0         0         0         0         0         0

 Labor
 Alternative
 Productions           0         0           0         0         0         0         0         0         0
 Saw timber            0         0           0         0         0         0         0         0         0
 Production Costs
 (imports)
 Alternative
 Productions           0         0           0         0         0         0         0         0         0
 Saw timber            0         0           0         0         0         0         0         0         0

 Without Project       29        62         141       261       457       705       1017      1300      1536

 Labor
 Alternative
 Productions           26        56         127       235       410       634       906       1164      1350

 Production Costs
 (imports)
 Alternative
 Productions           3         6           14        26        46        71       111       136       186




                                                      138
Table 45 (cont) Industry Costs Production and Labor

   Shadow Prices
                       1989      1990      1991       1992    1993    1994    1995    1996    1997
 With Project           0         0         0          0       0       0       0       0       0
 Labor
 Saw timber              0         0         0         0       0       0       0       0       0

 Without Project        23        50        113       209     365     564     813     1040    1229
 Labor
 Alternative
 Productions            21        45        102       188     328     507     725     931     1080

 Production Costs
 (imports)
 Alternative
 Productions             2         5        11         21      37      57      89     109     149

 Incremental in
 SPR (million US$)     -0.02     -0.05     -0.11      -0.21   -0.37   -0.56   -0.81   -1.04   -1.23

 DATA
                        1989      1990      1991      1992    1993    1994    1995    1996    1997
 Production
 (kg/ha)
 Beef                    35         35        36       36      36      36      36      36      41
 Lamb                     8         8         9         9       9       9       9       9       6
 Wool                     4         4         5        5       5       5       5       5       4
 Leather                  4          4         4        4       4       4       4       4       5
 Total Costs Alternative Industries (1,000 US$/kg)
 Beef                  0.001      0.001     0.001     0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001
 Lamb                  0.000      0.000     0.000     0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001
 Wool                  0.002      0.001     0.002     0.002   0.002   0.003   0.003   0.003   0.003
 Leather               0.001      0.001     0.001     0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001
                                       3
 Total Costs Sawmills (1,000 US$/ m )
 Wood                  0.119      0.111     0.112     0.078   0.079   0.070   0.069   0.067   0.067




                                                     139
Table 45 (cont) Industry Costs Production and Labor

                                1998     1999      2000      2001      2002      2003      2004      2005
 Production Costs (imports) 1,000
 US$/ha
     Slaughter Houses         0.00043   0.00037   0.00037   0.00037   0.00017   0.00029   0.00037   0.00037
           Wool               0.00011   0.00008   0.00008   0.00008   0.00008   0.00008   0.00008   0.00008
          Leather             0.00007   0.00007   0.00007   0.00007   0.00001   0.00003   0.00007   0.00007
                     3
 Wood (1,000 US$/m )          0.00127   0.00127   0.00127   0.00127   0.00127   0.00127   0.00127   0.00127
 Labor
     Slaughter Houses          0.0023   0.0020    0.0020    0.0020    0.0009    0.0016    0.0020    0.0020
           Wool                 0.003    0.003     0.003    0.003      0.003     0.003     0.003     0.003
          Leather              0.0002   0.0002    0.0002    0.0002    0.0000    0.0001    0.0002    0.0002

                     3
 Wood (1,000 US$/m )          0.01489   0.01489   0.01489   0.01489   0.01489   0.01489   0.01489   0.01489
     In market prices
                               1998      1999      2000      2001      2002      2003      2004      2005
 With Project                   0         0         0         0         0         0         0         0
 Labor
 Alternative Productions        0         0         0         0         0         0         0         0
 Saw timber                     0         0         0         0         1         1         0         0

 Production Costs (imports)
 Alternative Productions        0         0         0         0         0         0         0         0
 Saw timber                     0         0         0         3         7         7         6         5

 Without Project               1859      1814      2028      2220      1926      2211      2568      2726
 Labor
 Alternative Productions       1608      1558      1742      1906      1758      1945      2206      2341
 Production Costs (imports)
 Alternative Productions       252       256       287       314       168       266       363       385




                                                    140
Table 45 (cont) Industry Costs Production and Labor

      Shadow Prices
                              1998      1999      2000     2001    2002    2003    2004    2005
 With Project                  0          0         0       3       6       7       5       5
 Saw timber                     0         0         0       3       6       7       5       5

 Without Project              1487       1451      1622    1776    1541    1327    1541    1635
 Labor
 Alternative Productions      1286       1246      1393    1525    1407    1167    1323    1404

 Production Costs (imports)
 Alternative Productions       201       205       229     251     134     160     218     231
 Incremental in shadow
 prices(million US$)          -1.49     -1.45     -1.62    -1.77   -1.53   -1.32   -1.54   -1.63

 DATA
                              1998      1999      2000     2001    2002    2003    2004    2005
 Production (kg/ha)
 Beef                          43         44        44      44      20      34      44      44
 Lamb                          7          5         5       5       2       5       5       5
 Wool                          4          3         3       3       3       3       3       3
 Leather                       5          5         5       5       1       2       5       5

 Total Costs Alternative Industries (1,000 US$/kg)
 Beef                         0.001      0.001     0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001
 Lamb                         0.001      0.001     0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001
 Wool                         0.002      0.001     0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001
 Leather                      0.001      0.001     0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001   0.001
                                      3
 Total Costs Sawmills (1,000 US$/ m )
 Wood                         0.067      0.067     0.067   0.067   0.067   0.067   0.067   0.067




                                                    141
Table 46. Production Costs

Market Prices
                          1989    1990     1991     1992       1993       1994      1995      1996      1997
With Project
   Plantation Costs       0.027   0.026    0.033    0.042      0.042      0.049     0.05      0.053     0.056
        Labor             0.011   0.011    0.013    0.017      0.017      0.019     0.02      0.021     0.022
        Import            0.016   0.016     0.02    0.025      0.025      0.029     0.03      0.032     0.034
         Area             6,575   7,624    16,346   25,706     41,991    44,330    58,568    58,897    73,195
    Effective Area        4,931   5,718    12,260   19,280     31,493    33,248    43,926    44,173    54,896
Plantation Costs (mill.
         US$)             0.133   0.151    0.399     0.81      1.317      1.614     2.182     2.361     3.094


   Without Project
    Alternative
    Productions
     Area (in ha)         6,575   14,199   30,545   56,251     98,242    142,572   201,140   260,037   333,232
        Labor             0.003   0.003    0.004    0.004      0.004      0.005     0.005     0.005     0.005
        Import            0.001   0.001    0.002    0.001      0.001      0.002     0.002     0.002     0.002
     Prod Costs           0.03     0.06     0.16     0.28       0.52      0.92      1.36      1.83      2.28

 Incremental (mill.
       US$)                0.1     0.09     0.23     0.53          0.8    0.69      0.82      0.53      0.82
Shadow Prices
    With Project
   Plantation Costs       0.021   0.021    0.026    0.034      0.033      0.039     0.04      0.043     0.045
        Labor             0.009   0.008     0.01    0.013      0.013      0.015     0.016     0.017     0.018
        Import            0.013   0.013    0.016     0.02       0.02      0.023     0.024     0.026     0.027
         Area             6,575   7,624    16,346   25,706     41,991    44,330    58,568    58,897    73,195
   Effective Area         4,931   5,718    12,260   19,280     31,493    33,248    43,926    44,173    54,896
Total Plantation Costs    0.11     0.12     0.32     0.65       1.05      1.29      1.75      1.89      2.48
  Production Costs
 With (million US$)       0.11     0.12     0.32     0.65       1.05      1.29      1.75      1.89      2.48


   Without Project
  Prod Costs (1,000
      US$/ha)              0        0        0        0            0      0.01      0.01      0.01      0.01
        Labor             0.003   0.003    0.003    0.003      0.003      0.004     0.004     0.004     0.004
        Import            0.001   0.001    0.001    0.001      0.001      0.001     0.002     0.002     0.002
    Area (in ha)          6,575   14,199   30,545   56,251     98,242    142,572   201,140   260,037   333,232
  Total Prod. Costs
    (mill. US$)           0.02     0.05     0.13     0.22       0.42      0.74      1.09      1.46      1.82
 Incremental (mill.
        US$)              0.08     0.07     0.19     0.42       0.64      0.55      0.66      0.43      0.65




                                                             142
Table 46 (Cont) Production Costs

Market Prices
                    1998      1999      2000      2001       2002      2003      2004      2005
With Project
  Plantation
     Costs          0.056     0.056     0.051     0.051      0.037     0.045     0.037     0.037
     Labor          0.022     0.022     0.02      0.02       0.015     0.018     0.015     0.015
    Import          0.034     0.034     0.031     0.031      0.022     0.027     0.022     0.022
     Area          84,777    73,008    58,013    51,956     29,730    26,595    37,995    42,555
 Effective Area    63,583    54,756    43,510    38,967     22,298    19,946    28,496    31,916
   Plantation
  Costs (mill.
     US$)           3.591     3.047     2.224     1.979      0.831     0.895     1.052     1.178


Without Project
 Alternative
 Productions
  Area (in ha)     418,009   491,017   549,030   600,986    630,716   657,311   695,305   737,860
     Labor          0.005     0.005     0.005     0.004      0.006     0.004     0.005     0.006
    Import          0.002     0.002     0.002     0.002      0.002     0.002     0.002     0.002
  Prod Costs        2.94      3.33      3.69      3.76       4.79       4         4.6      5.67

 Incremental
  (mill. US$)       0.65      -0.28     -1.47     -1.78      -3.96     -3.11     -3.55     -4.49


  With Project
   Plantation
     Costs          0.045     0.045     0.041     0.041      0.03      0.027     0.022     0.022
     Labor          0.018     0.018     0.016     0.016      0.012     0.011     0.009     0.009
    Import          0.027     0.027     0.025     0.024      0.018     0.016     0.013     0.013
     Area          84,777    73,008    58,013    51,956     29,730    26,595    37,995    42,555
Effective Area     63,583    54,756    43,510    38,967     22,298    19,946    28,496    31,916
Total Plantation
     Costs          2.87      2.44      1.78      1.58       0.67      0.54      0.63      0.71
  Production
  Costs With
 (million US$)      2.87      2.44      1.78      1.58       0.67      0.54      0.63      0.71
Without Project
  Prod Costs
(1,000 US$/ha)      0.006     0.005     0.005     0.005      0.006     0.004     0.004     0.005
     Labor          0.004     0.004     0.004     0.003      0.004     0.002     0.003     0.003
    Import          0.002     0.002     0.002     0.002      0.002     0.001     0.001     0.001
  Area (in ha)     418,009   491,017   549,030   600,986    630,716   657,311   695,305   737,860
  Total Prod.
  Costs (mill.
     US$)           2.35      2.66      2.95      3.01       3.83       2.4      2.76       3.4
 Incremental
  (mill. US$)       0.52      -0.22     -1.17     -1.43      -3.17     -1.86     -2.13     -2.7




                                                           143
Table 47. Labor Costs Exports (million US$)

 With
                        1989   1990    1991     1992      1993   1994   1995     1996      1997      1998    1999     2000   2001    2002   2003   2004   2005
 Wood Exported
 (1,000 m3)             0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.00   0.00   0.00      0.00      0.00     0.73     0.80    1.91    3.33   6.40   6.66   8.64   8.38
 Total Costs market
 prices                 0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.00   0.00   0.00      0.00      0.00     0.28     0.30    0.73    1.26   2.43   2.53   3.28   3.19
 Total Costs
 shadow prices          0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.00   0.00   0.00      0.00      0.00     0.17     0.18    0.44    0.76   1.95   2.03   2.63   2.55



Table 48. Pruning and Thinning Costs (million US$)

 With
                 1989   1990   1991      1992      1993      1994   1995   1996          1997      1998     1999     2000    2001    2002   2003   2004   2005
 Pruning
 (million US$)   0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.02      0.03   0.10       0.13      0.38      0.46     0.72     0.87    1.34    2.32   2.72   3.33   3.54
 1,000 US$/ha    0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.04      0.04   0.06       0.06      0.07      0.07     0.07     0.07    0.07    0.07   0.07   0.07   0.07
 Total (1,000
 US$)
      First      0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00       22        34     65         75       248       296      386      477     703     1542   1632   1308   1204
    Second       0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.00      0.00    33         51        87       100      248      296     386      477    703   1542   1632
     Third       0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.00      0.00   0.00       0.00       44        67      87       100     248      296   386     477    703
  Thinning
 (million US$)   0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.00      0.00   0.00       0.00      0.00      0.00     0.00     0.00    0.01    0.03   0.03   0.03   0.03

 Total Costs
 market prices
 (million US$)   0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.02      0.03   0.10       0.13      0.38      0.46     0.72     0.87    1.35    2.34   2.75   3.36   3.57
 Total Costs
 shadow
 prices
 (million US$)   0.00   0.00    0.00     0.00      0.01      0.02   0.06       0.08      0.23      0.28     0.43     0.52    0.81    1.88   2.20   2.69   2.85




                                                                               144
Table 49. Administration and Management Costs (million US$)

 Administration and Management Costs

 With
                           1989   1990   1991   1992   1993   1994   1995      1996   1997   1998   1999   2000   2001     2002    2003    2004   2005
 Management                0.00   0.09   0.19   0.32   0.57   0.92   1.18      1.41   1.61   1.82   2.15   2.11   1.71     1.05    0.61    0.69   1.19
 Ants Control              0.00   0.03   0.04   0.08   0.12   0.20   0.22      0.29   0.29   0.36   0.41   0.34   0.26     0.11    0.11    0.14   0.28
 Paths                     0.00   0.02   0.02   0.05   0.08   0.13   0.14      0.19   0.19   0.24   0.27   0.23   0.17     0.07    0.07    0.09   0.19
 Administration            0.21   0.24   0.53   0.84   1.37   1.45   1.93      1.94   2.42   2.79   2.36   1.84   1.60     0.42    0.65    1.34   2.14

 Total Costs market
 prices                    0.21   0.26   0.99   1.38   2.18   2.74   3.64      3.81   4.49   5.37   5.08   4.35   3.49     0.72    1.07    2.42   5.78
 Total Costs shadow
 prices                    0.20   0.25   0.97   1.35   2.14   2.69   3.57      3.73   4.40   5.26   4.98   4.26   3.42     0.72    1.07    2.42   5.78



Table 50. Harvesting Costs

 With
                        1989   1990   1991   1992   1993   1994   1995   1996     1997   1998   1999   2000    2001      2002     2003    2004    2005
 Labor                  0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00     0.00   3.06   3.21   7.55    13.35     10.08    18.00   32.60   44.99
               Pulp     0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00     0.00   3.06   3.21   7.55    11.94     8.65     15.40   29.60   41.06
          Sawn wood     0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00     0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00    1.41      1.43     2.60    3.00    3.94
 Fuel                   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00     0.00   1.67   1.75   4.12     7.28     5.50     9.82    17.78   24.54
 Rest                   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00     0.00   0.84   0.88   2.06    3.64      2.75     4.91    8.89    12.27

 Total Costs market
 prices (million US$)   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00    0.00    0.00   5.57   5.84   13.72   24.26     18.33    32.73   59.27   81.81
 Total Costs shadow
 prices (million US$)   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00   0.00    0.00    0.00   4.30   4.50   10.58   18.72     12.31    21.99   39.83   54.97




                                                                         145
Table 51. Nursery Costs

                               1989     1990      1991     1992     1993     1994     1995     1996     1997
Labor                          87%      94%       94%      94%      94%      94%      94%      94%      94%
Imports                        13%       6%        6%       6%       6%       6%       6%       6%       6%
Area planted (ha)              4,419    5,121    11,241   17,825   29,065   30,741   40,882   41,136   51,197

Costs (1,000 US$/ha)           0.043    0.048    0.061    0.067     0.08    0.081    0.077    0.077    0.072
Average Costs (1,000 US$/ha)   0.065

Total Costs market prices
(mill.US$)                      0.19     0.25     0.69     1.2      2.32     2.49     3.16     3.15     3.71

Total Costs shadow prices
(mill. US$)                     0.16     0.21     0.59     1.03      2       2.15     2.73     2.73     3.21



                                1998     1999     2000     2001     2002     2003     2004     2005
Labor                           94%      94%      94%      94%      94%      94%      94%      94%
Imports                          6%       6%       6%       6%       6%       6%       6%       6%
Area planted (ha)              59,159   50,969   40,497   36,294   20,763   18,595   26,596   29,788

Costs (1,000 US$/ha)           0.067    0.043    0.063    0.061    0.028    0.048    0.069    0.099
Average Costs (1,000 US$/ha)

Total Costs market prices
(mill.US$)                      3.94     2.19     2.54     2.2      0.58     0.9      1.85     2.95

Total Costs shadow prices
(mill. US$)                     3.41     1.89     2.2      1.9      0.51     0.78     1.6      2.55




                                                          146

More Related Content

PDF
Regional Newsletter (Summer 2015)
PPT
Digital design chap 3
PPTX
Day2 session3 multi-criteria-analysis
PDF
Policy analysis
PPT
Cost-benefit analysis
PDF
Morales&siry 2009
PDF
Environmental accounting as a means of promoting sustainable
Regional Newsletter (Summer 2015)
Digital design chap 3
Day2 session3 multi-criteria-analysis
Policy analysis
Cost-benefit analysis
Morales&siry 2009
Environmental accounting as a means of promoting sustainable

Similar to Final version resub (20)

PDF
Is Carbon gender neutral? Adaptation mitigation gendered linkages in the dry ...
PDF
MSc Thesis: Ecosystem Services of Tropical Silvopastoral Systems
PDF
Economics of Green Care in Agriculture
PPTX
The New CGIAR Research Program on Forests, Trees, and Agroforestry: Opportuni...
PPTX
Wfc unep forest economics update africa september 2015
PDF
Waiting For Rain Agriculture And Ecological Imbalance In Cape Verde Mark Lang...
PDF
Key Determinants of Forest-dependent Guyanese’ Willingness to Contribute to F...
PDF
Ecosystem services for biodiversity conservation and sustainable agriculture
PDF
Economic analysis of forestry projects en
PDF
US- Inidana IFRI Report 2013
DOC
Investment Project
PPT
Presentacion Mibosque Ingles Carp
PDF
REDD+ in Kolo Hills: impacts on forest governance and livelihoods
PPTX
Linking adaptation and mitigation to achieve climate compatible development i...
PDF
An analysis on the investment of forestland modelling using the agroforestry...
PDF
American Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Review
PDF
Forest, Trees and Agroforestry - Manuel Guariguata
PDF
Montenegro forest management reform study
PDF
Redd+ & agricultural drivers of deforestation
PPTX
Nature’s anonymous donor: The hidden contribution of forests to rural liveli...
Is Carbon gender neutral? Adaptation mitigation gendered linkages in the dry ...
MSc Thesis: Ecosystem Services of Tropical Silvopastoral Systems
Economics of Green Care in Agriculture
The New CGIAR Research Program on Forests, Trees, and Agroforestry: Opportuni...
Wfc unep forest economics update africa september 2015
Waiting For Rain Agriculture And Ecological Imbalance In Cape Verde Mark Lang...
Key Determinants of Forest-dependent Guyanese’ Willingness to Contribute to F...
Ecosystem services for biodiversity conservation and sustainable agriculture
Economic analysis of forestry projects en
US- Inidana IFRI Report 2013
Investment Project
Presentacion Mibosque Ingles Carp
REDD+ in Kolo Hills: impacts on forest governance and livelihoods
Linking adaptation and mitigation to achieve climate compatible development i...
An analysis on the investment of forestland modelling using the agroforestry...
American Journal of Multidisciplinary Research and Review
Forest, Trees and Agroforestry - Manuel Guariguata
Montenegro forest management reform study
Redd+ & agricultural drivers of deforestation
Nature’s anonymous donor: The hidden contribution of forests to rural liveli...
Ad

Recently uploaded (20)

PDF
Mobile App Security Testing_ A Comprehensive Guide.pdf
PDF
Blue Purple Modern Animated Computer Science Presentation.pdf.pdf
PDF
Machine learning based COVID-19 study performance prediction
PDF
Optimiser vos workloads AI/ML sur Amazon EC2 et AWS Graviton
PDF
cuic standard and advanced reporting.pdf
PDF
7 ChatGPT Prompts to Help You Define Your Ideal Customer Profile.pdf
PDF
Architecting across the Boundaries of two Complex Domains - Healthcare & Tech...
PDF
Empathic Computing: Creating Shared Understanding
PPTX
Understanding_Digital_Forensics_Presentation.pptx
PDF
Diabetes mellitus diagnosis method based random forest with bat algorithm
PPTX
20250228 LYD VKU AI Blended-Learning.pptx
PDF
Network Security Unit 5.pdf for BCA BBA.
PDF
How UI/UX Design Impacts User Retention in Mobile Apps.pdf
PDF
Encapsulation_ Review paper, used for researhc scholars
PPTX
Detection-First SIEM: Rule Types, Dashboards, and Threat-Informed Strategy
PPTX
Big Data Technologies - Introduction.pptx
PDF
Encapsulation theory and applications.pdf
PDF
Build a system with the filesystem maintained by OSTree @ COSCUP 2025
PDF
Agricultural_Statistics_at_a_Glance_2022_0.pdf
PPTX
Effective Security Operations Center (SOC) A Modern, Strategic, and Threat-In...
Mobile App Security Testing_ A Comprehensive Guide.pdf
Blue Purple Modern Animated Computer Science Presentation.pdf.pdf
Machine learning based COVID-19 study performance prediction
Optimiser vos workloads AI/ML sur Amazon EC2 et AWS Graviton
cuic standard and advanced reporting.pdf
7 ChatGPT Prompts to Help You Define Your Ideal Customer Profile.pdf
Architecting across the Boundaries of two Complex Domains - Healthcare & Tech...
Empathic Computing: Creating Shared Understanding
Understanding_Digital_Forensics_Presentation.pptx
Diabetes mellitus diagnosis method based random forest with bat algorithm
20250228 LYD VKU AI Blended-Learning.pptx
Network Security Unit 5.pdf for BCA BBA.
How UI/UX Design Impacts User Retention in Mobile Apps.pdf
Encapsulation_ Review paper, used for researhc scholars
Detection-First SIEM: Rule Types, Dashboards, and Threat-Informed Strategy
Big Data Technologies - Introduction.pptx
Encapsulation theory and applications.pdf
Build a system with the filesystem maintained by OSTree @ COSCUP 2025
Agricultural_Statistics_at_a_Glance_2022_0.pdf
Effective Security Operations Center (SOC) A Modern, Strategic, and Threat-In...
Ad

Final version resub

  • 1. THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE FOREST SECTOR IN URUGUAY: A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS by VIRGINIA MORALES OLMOS (Under the Direction of Jacek P. Siry) ABSTRACT Uruguay is a South American country surrounded by Argentina and Brazil. Its economy has traditionally been based on agriculture. Since the 1960s, the government has been encouraging forestry as an alternative use for marginal agricultural lands in an effort to promote economic development, diversification, and environmental services. The Forestry Law of 1987 introduced subsidies and tax exonerations for the development of forest plantations and wood manufacturing industries. As a result, the new forest sector has been growing rapidly, attracting foreign investment. While several studies have examined the impact of individual forest firms, no study to date has examined the impact of the forest sector from the point of view of the entire economy. This research project evaluated the impact of the new forest sector by conducting a Cost-Benefit Analysis. The results indicate a positive net impact when compared with livestock: the Net Present Value for the forest sector was 630.2 million US$, and the Internal Rate of Return was 36.4%. INDEX WORDS: Policy Evaluation, Uruguay, Forest Sector, Cost-Benefit Analysis.
  • 2. THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE FOREST SECTOR IN URUGUAY: A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS by VIRGINIA MORALES OLMOS Lic. en Economía, Universidad de la República, Uruguay, 2002 A Thesis Submitted to the Graduate Faculty of The University of Georgia in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree MASTER OF SCIENCE ATHENS, GEORGIA 2007
  • 3. © 2007 Virginia Morales Olmos All Rights Reserved
  • 4. THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE FOREST SECTOR IN URUGUAY: A COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS by VIRGINIA MORALES OLMOS Major Professor: Jacek P. Siry Committee: David H. Newman Warren Kriesel Electronic Version Approved: Maureen Grasso Dean of the Graduate School The University of Georgia May 2007
  • 5. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Three years ago I was invited to participate in a discussion on Forest Economics at INIA with Dr. Brooks Mendell from The University of Georgia, who was at that time visiting Uruguay. While I had never heard about the discipline before, the forest sector was developing rapidly. Since I wanted to learn more about it, I attended the meeting. There I started the adventure of studying Forest Economics. Many people accompanied me in this adventure with Forest Economics, and I would like to thank them for making it possible. I thank my advisor, Dr. Jacek Siry, for giving me the opportunity to study in the United States, and for his guidance and supervision. He was always open to new ideas in this process, to my questions, and to my last minute concerns. Thank you for pushing me further but with the doses of compassion that we all need, and for taking the time to continuously read the drafts of the thesis and correct them, and, especially, for your support during the last days of writing. I thank my Committee Members, Dr. David Newman and Dr. Warren Kriesel, who have been open to my research ideas and accepted the changes with patience and helpful suggestions. Dr. Newman was always ready for my questions and concerns; I really enjoyed our conversations and discussions about the Third World and South America. Gracias, Dr. Newman. Dr. Kriesel was always supportive during the Committee Meetings, making valuable comments and suggestions. I thank all the people in Uruguay for providing me with the information about the Forestry Sector and Uruguay statistics, and for discussing with me policy evaluation methods, including Mr. Lorenzo Balerio (FYMNSA), Mr. Javier Otegui (COFUSA), Mr. José Obes (BOTNIA), Mr. Ricardo Methol (FOSA), Mr. Carlos Faroppa (BOTNIA), Mr. Enrique Ramos iv
  • 6. (COLONVADE), Mr. Raúl Pazos (EUFORES), Mr. Gustavo Balmelli (INIA Tacuarembó), Mr. Pedro Barrenechea, Mr. Carlos Voulminot (Industrias Forestales Arazatí), Ms. Paola Zubillaga (SPF), Mr. Héctor Pastori (UDELAR), Mr. Alberti, Mr. Roni Swedzki (CIU), Ms. Elena Cuadrado (BCU), Ms. Lucía Pittaluga (IE), Mr. Michael Borchardt (MEF), Mr. Jerónimo Rocca, Mr. Bruno Lanfranco (INIA), Mr. Rafael De La Torre (CELFOR). Special thanks to the Forest Division of Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay: Mr. Daniel San San Román and Mr. Andrés Berterreche, Mr. Juan Pablo Nebel for the information on Native Forest. Special thanks to Ms. Verónica Durán (OPYPA) who was always willingly answering my questions and with whom I first discussed the topic of this thesis. Thank you Verónica, your help has been invaluable. I thank my colleague Mercedes, who shared discussions on line and has been of great support since we met in Tacuarembó. I thank the Latin American and Caribbean Student Institute (LACSI) for facilitating this research by providing travel funds to conduct my interviews in Uruguay. I thank Dr. Brooks Mendell, the “first person responsible” for my trip to Athens. Thank you for providing all the information that I needed and for being there even though we did not met very often during these two years. It was a pleasure working with you. I thank the staff of the Warnell School of Forestry and Natural Resources. Special thanks to Ms. Rosemary Wood who was always ready to answer any questions with kindness and patience, and to the students and professors in the fifth floor of Building 4. Thank you for always encouraging me, especially during the last months of my writing. I thank my officemates: Tony, Matt, Iris and Tiffany. In different ways, you were always there for me. Thank you, Tony for listening to my complaints for a year and for your friendship and support. To Gay Mac Cormack, my English professor, who became an expert in Forest v
  • 7. Economics and Uruguay after a year working together. Thank you for the coffee that we shared in the English Department. I thank my friends in Athens, the ones who already left and the ones that are still here, who became my extended family during this time far from Uruguay. Finally, I thank my family. Without their support, I could not have completed this degree. In memorian of my colleague Mariana, with whom I started to like the forests. vi
  • 8. TABLE OF CONTENTS Page ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS........................................................................................................... iv LIST OF TABLES....................................................................................................................... viii LIST OF FIGURES ....................................................................................................................... xi CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION ....................................................................................................1 CHAPTER 2: POLICY ANALYSIS ...............................................................................................5 CHAPTER 3: URUGUAY’S FOREST SECTOR ........................................................................24 CHAPTER 4: METHODS, RESULTS AND DISCUSSION .......................................................52 CHAPTER 5: CONCLUSIONS ....................................................................................................91 REFERENCES ..............................................................................................................................95 APPENDICES I. SURVEY RESULTS.........................................................................................105 II. SURVEY FORMS ...........................................................................................113 III. CBA TABLES ................................................................................................128 vii
  • 9. LIST OF TABLES Page TABLE 1. FOREST AREA IN CHILE (1,000 HA) …………………………………………….19 TABLE 2. FOREST AREA IN BRAZIL (1,000 HA)...................................................................19 TABLE 3.GDP AS PERCENTAGE OF AGRICULTURAL GDP ..............................................40 TABLE 4. URUGUAY FOREST RESOURCES..........................................................................40 TABLE 5. CONEAT INDEX FOR FOREST LANDS .................................................................42 TABLE 6. FOREST FARMS BY AREA......................................................................................43 TABLE 7. URUGUAY FOREST EXPORTS SHARE IN TOTAL EXPORTS...........................43 TABLE 8. URUGUAY EXPORTS IN VALUE AND VOLUME ...............................................44 TABLE 9. PAPER AND CARDBOARD EXPORTS PRICE INDEX.........................................46 TABLE 10. WOOD EXPORT UNIT VALUES (1,000 US$/M3)................................................47 TABLE 11. SAW TIMBER EXPORT PRICE INDEX ................................................................48 TABLE 12. URUGUAY FOREST IMPORTS (MILLION US$ FOB) ........................................49 TABLE 13. GDP FOREST INDUSTRIES AS PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL GDP (2003) .........49 TABLE 14. CIIU PRODUCTION INDEX, BASE 100=2002......................................................50 TABLE 15. GDP FOREST INDUSTRIES AND MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY (CONSTANT MILLION 2002 US$).............................................................................................50 TABLE 16. SAWMILLS AND PULP AND PAPER INDUSTRIES SHARE IN INDUSTRY PRODUCT AND INDUSTRY WAGES.......................................................................................51 TABLE 17. SHADOW PRICES RELATIONS FOR URUGUAY...............................................81 TABLE 18. UNEMPLOYMENT RATES FOR URUGUAY.......................................................82 TABLE 19. URUGUAY BLV (2005) ...........................................................................................83 viii
  • 10. TABLE 20. EUCALYPTUS GROWTH, YIELDS AND MANAGEMENT ASSUMPTIONS...83 TABLE 21. PINE GROWTH, YIELDS AND MANAGEMENT ASSUMPTIONS....................84 TABLE 22. PLANTATION COSTS STRUCTURE.....................................................................85 TABLE 23. FOREST PRODUCTION COSTS (2005).................................................................86 TABLE 24. INDUSTRIAL COSTS STRUCTURE (2005) ..........................................................87 TABLE 25. TRANSPORTATION COSTS COEFFICIENTS......................................................87 TABLE 26. FOREST LAND PRICES VS LIVESTOCK LAND PRICES ..................................88 TABLE 27. COST BENEFIT ANALYSIS RESULTS.................................................................89 TABLE 28. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: WOOD PRICES .........................................................90 TABLE 29. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: YIELDS ......................................................................90 TABLE 30. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: TRANSPORTATION COSTS ...................................91 TABLE 31. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: LAND PRICE.............................................................91 TABLE 32. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: HARVESTING, THINNING AND MANAGEMENT COSTS ...........................................................................................................................................91 TABLE 33. COMPANIES CLASSIFIED ACCORDING TO THE ORIGIN OF THE CAPITAL.....................................................................................................................................113 TABLE 34. AREA BY COMPANIES ........................................................................................113 TABLE 35. AREA BY SPECIES (IN HA) .................................................................................113 TABLE 36. ROTATION AGES AND GROWTH RATES .......................................................113 TABLE 37. TOTAL EXTRACTION EUCALYPTUS (1,000 M3)............................................129 TABLE 38. TOTAL EXTRACTION PINE (1,000 M3).............................................................130 TABLE 39. BASIC ASSUMPTIONS .........................................................................................131 TABLE 40. INVESTMENTS IN LAND (MILLION US$)........................................................132 ix
  • 11. TABLE 41. INDUSTRY INVESTMENTS (MILLION US$) ....................................................133 TABLE 42. EXPORTS................................................................................................................134 TABLE 43. TRANSPORTATION COSTS (MILLION US$)....................................................136 TABLE 44. LIVESTOCK TRANSPORTATION COSTS .........................................................137 TABLE 45. INDUSTRY COSTS ................................................................................................138 TABLE 46. PRODUCTION COSTS ..........................................................................................142 TABLE 47. LABOR COSTS EXPORTS (MILLION US$) .......................................................144 TABLE 48. PRUNING AND THINNING COSTS (MILLION US$)........................................144 TABLE 49. ADMINISTRATION AND MANAGEMENTE COSTS (MILLION US$)...........145 TABLE 50. HARVESTING COSTS...........................................................................................145 TABLE 51. NURSERY COSTS..................................................................................................146 x
  • 12. LIST OF FIGURES Page FIGURE 1. BASIC POLICY ANALYSIS PROCESS…………………………………………..21 FIGURE 2. CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS……………………………………...22 FIGURE 3. TAXATION AND DEADWEIGHT LOSS………………………………………...22 FIGURE 4. URUGUAY GDP BY SECTORS (2005)…………………………………………..40 FIGURE 5. URUGUAY FOREST PRIORITY SOILS………………………………………….41 FIGURE 6. AREA PLANTED BY SPECIES (CUMULATIVE)……………………………….42 FIGURE 7. PAPER AND CARBOARD EXPORTS BY REGION (US$ FOB, 2005)…………45 FIGURE 8. WOOD AND WOOD PRODUCTS EXPORTS BY REGION (US$ FOB, 2005)....45 xi
  • 13. CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION Incentives promoting investment in the development of forest plantations and wood manufacturing industries have been a controversial policy issue in recent decades. Most of the arguments rely on the misuse and depletion of natural resources due to government failures. Ineffective forest policies, the absence of logging controls, and external pressures such as rapid population growth have frequently resulted in resource decline and deforestation (Hyde et al. 1987; Repetto & Gillis 1988; Ascher & Healy 1990; Clapp 1995; Dore & Guevara 2000; Clapp 2001; Guldin 2003; Bacha 2004; Silva 2004). Some studies pointed out that economic incentives such as tax breaks, tax exonerations, subsidies, credit concessions, and pricing policies resulted in the misuse of forest resources as well (Repetto & Gillis 1988). One of the most important consequences of these failures is deforestation as many developing countries experience high deforestation rates (Repetto & Gillis 1988; Haltia & Keipi 1997; FAO 2005). Unlike many developing countries experiencing deforestation, forest cover in Uruguay has been increasing (Nebel 2003). The majority of the land in Uruguay is privately owned and population growth is slow (INE 2006). In addition, the landholding concentration is not high. As a result, Uruguay does not have the characteristics that have led to deforestation in other countries. Further, Uruguay has used economic incentives to promote the development of forest plantations and wood manufacturing industries. Whether these incentives will result in deforestation or resource decline seems to be a non-controversial issue since effective regulations protecting native forest exists. In addition, forest plantations have been established on agricultural lands. Nevertheless, environmental groups have argued that monocultures composed 1
  • 14. of either eucalyptus or pine will cause severe damage to the native forest (Guayubira 2006). In addition, those organizations claim that the forest sector does not generate economic benefits while providing low-quality employment (Carrere 2002). The forest sector in Uruguay has been rapidly developing since the passage of the Forestry Law 15939 in 1987 (Durán 2004; Forest Division 2005). The Law established subsidies and tax incentives to support the development of forest plantations and wood manufacturing industries. This development is part of a broader trend in South America, where countries such as Brazil and Chile have long used economic incentives to attract domestic and foreign investment into their forestry sectors. 1.1 Objective The objective of the project is to evaluate the impact of the new forest sector on the Uruguayan Economy by considering the costs and benefits associated with the policy that started with the Forestry Law 15939 promulgated in 1987. 1.2 Justification The rationale for Law 15939 as discussed by members of Parliament was that the project will contribute to environmental, economic and social goals of the country. The existing studies have attempted to evaluate the policy and its impacts from the point of view of the government by focusing on fiscal impacts (González Posse & Barrenechea 1996); estimating tax balance, unemployment balance and product balance (Vázquez Platero 1996; Ramos & Cabrera 2001), or by studying individual firms (Metsa-Botnia 2004; World Bank 2005). These studies do not reflect the opportunity cost for the Uruguayan society of the resources used in the forest activity. 2
  • 15. The current study uses a Cost-Benefit Analysis (CBA) to determine the impact of the new forest sector on the Uruguayan economy. It approaches the analysis from the point of view of the society, using shadow prices and a social discount rate. The results of this project will be important for assessing the impact of a policy on the whole economy. The results will help in determination of whether (1) the incentives were efficiently used, (2) the incentives should be now terminated as the forest sector has already developed, or (3) the incentives should be refocused on different agents in the sector, i.e., small producers. In addition, the analysis of the sector will help in assessing further information needs. Finally, the discussion of forest policy evaluation methods from the standpoint of the country’s economy will contribute to future studies. The second chapter describes the methods of policy evaluation and discusses CBA along with the Social Choice theory and Welfare economics theories. In this framework, the rationale for establishing forest policies is discussed, and two South American forest sectors are briefly described: Chile and Brazil. The third chapter describes the Uruguayan forest sector and examines forest laws and regulations. The silvicultural sub-sector has increased its share in agricultural GDP between 1990 and 2002, from 3.8% to 13.40%; and sawmills increased from nearly 0% of the manufacturing industry GDP1 to 1.44% in 2003. Then a description of exports and imports is presented, with the emphasis on forest exports and its share in Uruguay’s total exports, as most of the total production is exported. Favorable laws and regulations were key factors attracting foreing investor into the country. 1 The GDP for sawmills was not included in the country’s statistics before 2001 because its sharing in the industry’s GDP was negligible. 3
  • 16. The fourth chapter presents the analytical method, results and discussion. The CBA is discussed along with data and assumptions. The chapter addresses major issues with the use in the current study, including shadow pricing and its application for Uruguay, with emphasis in land and labor valuation. Finally, the CBA results are presented and discussed. The fifth chapter summarizes the results and provides policy. Finally, several future research opportunities identified during this research are presented. 4
  • 17. CHAPTER 2 POLICY ANALYSIS Policy analysis considers a complex set of factors and therefore there are several ways to define the analysis (Patton & Sawicki 1993; Dunn 2004). Policy analysis is both descriptive and normative, because it has to describe the objectives, instruments, and results of the policy, and has to provide instruments to select the best policy. The choice of objectives and results involves balancing opposite interests and values such as efficiency, equity, security, and development (Dunn 2004). Furthermore, given their scarcity, the resources have to be allocated in order to consider different interests (Cubbage et al. 1993; Patton & Sawicki 1993). This allocation implies tradeoffs involved in following one policy or another. A basic policy analysis process can be summarized in six steps: define the problem, establish the evaluation criteria, identify alternative policies, evaluate the policies, implement the policy, and monitor the implemented policy (Figure 1). First, the analyst has to define the problem, a process, which assumes that a problem exists and describe it with a focus on the central, critical factors. Problem structuring is the description and definition of the problem to be solved by the policy (Cubbage et al. 1993; Boardman 2001; Dunn 2004). Second, the analyst has to establish the criteria to evaluate alternative policies. The evaluation criteria chosen depend on the objectives of the policy and its effects on the population. The most common criteria used to evaluate a policy include cost, net benefit, effectiveness, efficiency, equity, legality, and administrative ease. Third, the analyst has to identify alternative polices according to their objectives and specific values and interests. A list of alternatives, including a thorough definition of each one, can reveal aspects of the problem not considered before. This description can lead to 5
  • 18. a reformulation of the problem and return to the beginning of the policy analysis. Fourth, after selecting the alternatives, the analyst has to evaluate, with technical criteria, which alternative best achieves the objectives of the policy defined at the beginning of the policy analysis. Evaluation is the systematic assessment of the outcomes of a policy compared with a set of standards (Weiss 1998 in Bisang & Zimmermann 2006; Dunn 2004). It consists of the evaluation of the content of the policy, which includes programs and instruments (Bisang & Zimmermann 2006). The types of evaluation depend on the problem: the analyst can use quantitative methods of evaluation, qualitative methods of evaluation, or a combination of both. At this point, the analyst can find that there is information missing from the problem description, and then has to go back and redefine the problem. Fifth, after evaluating the alternatives and choosing the best one, this policy has to be implemented. Finally, the implemented policy has to be monitored in order to assess whether the policy worked properly and, if not, to identify the problems and correct them. Monitoring is the observation of previously defined indicators and produces information on the outcomes of the policy (Dunn 2004; Bisang & Zimmermann 2006). The policy analysis is an iterative process: at each step there is feedback from the other steps, and the final step, to monitor the implemented policy, will be compared with the first step. 2.1 Policy Evaluation 2.1.1. History of Policy Evaluation Formal policy evaluation began in the 1930s. On a systematic basis policies have been evaluated from the mid 1960s (Zerbe & Dively 1994; Rossi et al. 1999; Bisang & Zimmermann 2006). At that time the United States established two programs to fight poverty: the War on Poverty-Great Society initiative and the Executive Order establishing the Planning Programming 6
  • 19. Budgeting (PPB) system, both programs mandated policy evaluation (Haveman 1987 in Rossi et al 1999; Rossi et al 1999; Bisang & Zimmermann 2006). The US General Accounting Office (GAO) was put in charge of these evaluation studies (GAO 1991 in Bisang & Zimmermann 2006). The Government Performance and Results Act, passed in 1993, required US executive agencies to evaluate their programs. International institutions, such as the World Bank and the United Nations, also require evaluations of their projects (Dasgupta et al. 1972; Squire & van der Tak 1975; Nas 1996); Chelimsky & Shadish 1997 in Bisang & Zimmerman 2006). The World Bank requires an impact evaluation of its projects. It provides evaluation guidelines, recognizing that there is no single standard approach to conduct an impact evaluation, and that each evaluation has to consider the project, the country and institutional context and the actors involved. The Bank recognizes that there are different times in project evaluation: (1) evaluations for the Bank have to be timed with mid-term review and closing of the project; (2) evaluations for the government have to be timed with government discussions, i.e., budget, political context. Government participation in the project is considered a key element to the success of a policy. The role of the government is to identify the relevant policy questions, to ensure the integrity of the evaluation, and to incorporate the results in future policy choices (World Bank 2006). Since the World Bank is an important lending source for developing countries, these developments had numerous impacts on project evaluations in Latin America. In Europe, program evaluations were introduced in the 1970s in Sweden, Germany and the UK. The practice of policy evaluation has expanded to other countries in the 1990s, making it a common practice nowadays (Leeuw 2004 in Bisang & Zimmermann 2006). 7
  • 20. 2.1.2. Types of evaluation Policy evaluation methods can be classified in different ways: quantitative and qualitative, social choice and “implementable”2, rationalist and social. A classification according to the objective of the evaluation criteria has been widely discussed in the literature. These methods range from qualitative methods (Dunn 2004) to quantitative methods (Dasgupta et al. 1972; Squire & van der Tak 1975; Ray 1984; Pleskovic & Treviño 1985; Stone 1985; Chowdhury & Kirkpatrick 1994; Zerbe & Dively 1994; Nas 1996), and a combination of both (Slee 2006). Quantitative methods can be grouped in three categories: Input-Output models (I-O), Computable General Equilibrium models (CGE) and Cost-Benefit analyses (CBA). An I-O model uses a matrix to represent a nation’s economy in terms of the linkages between sectors, households and the government (Pleskovic & Treviño 1985; Chowdhury & Kirkpatrick 1994). Multipliers are calculated from the matrix to estimate the change in total economic activity attributable to sector activity. A CGE model simulates a market economy by considering the abstract general equilibrium structure formalized by Arrow and Debreu (Bergman & Henrekson 2003; Wing 2004). A CBA estimates the costs and benefits associated with the new activity or policy. This approach differs from I-O and CGE models since it does not consider the economy as a whole. Qualitative models include focus groups and in-depth interviews with the populations affected by the policy (Dunn 2004; Slee 2006). They aim to reveal stakeholders´ response to the policy under evaluation (Slee 2006). Most of these methods do not allow immediate quantification, and qualitative statistical methods should be adopted. 2 The term “implementable” refers to a policy that can be put in practice. 8
  • 21. A combination of quantitative and qualitative methods to policy evaluation has been proposed by Slee (2006). The method is called a multidimensional approach and it includes four elements: economic linkages, regional impacts, non-market benefits, and social analysis (Slee et al. 2003). The consideration of these elements will allow measuring the spillovers associated with a forest project, such as non-market benefits and local and regional development of the population around the forest. Mendes classified policy evaluation methods into two general approaches. The first one is used when the policy maker has defined a set of objectives the policy should achieve and evaluates their achievement. The second approach takes performance criteria as given and assesses if the desirable outcomes can be put in practice implemented (Mendes 2000 in Carvalho Mendes 2006). The first group of methods is based on social choice theories, and the second group on implementation theory (Carvalho Mendes 2006). The social choice theories started with the General Possibility Theorem established by Arrow (1951). He proved that any social choice rule that satisfies a basic set of fairness conditions could produce an intransitive social order leading to a non-Pareto Optimal solution (Boardman 2001). The implementation method examines whether the policy targets were achieved, and if they were not, it investigates whether the goals were “implementable”. The author proposes three types of implementation constraints: “feasibility, individual rationality, and incentive compatible constraints“, and associates these constraints with three facts of policy making: resources availability, decisions decentralization, and imperfect information about the stakeholders (Carvalho Mendes 2006). Finally, two groups of approaches resulted from the discussion at a symposium on Forest Policy Evaluation held in France in 20043. One group is the rationalist, as the methods included 3 EFI (European Forest Institute)-ENGREF (French Institute of Forestry, Agricultural and Environmental Engineering)-IUFRO (International Union of Forest Research Organizations) International Symposium. June, 2004. 9
  • 22. here use a rationalist framework to evaluate a policy. The theories included the social choice theory, as explained above; the implementation theory, previously mentioned in the classification conducted by Carvalho Mendes; and the systemic theory, which considers the sector as groups of actors interrelated among them and with different institutions. Another group considers the context in which the policy is evaluated, including social and policy considerations rather than using rationalist schemes (Forest Policy and Economics Editorial 2006). 2.2 Cost Benefit Analysis 2.2.1. Social choice According to the social choice theory, the government intervenes in the economy in response to market failures, which prevent an optimal resource allocation in society. These failures may include imperfect competition, asymmetric information, inability to provide public goods, or externalities. The policies of the government are driven by a goal of reaching income distribution and improving public welfare (Zerbe & Dively 1994; Dunn 2004). The policies will affect prices and then consumer welfare. A convenient way to measure the change in the social welfare is the consumer surplus. The willingness to pay measured by the compensating and equivalent variations would be the correct way to measure welfare changes. However, in practice, the measures are difficult to obtain since deriving compensated demand curves requires holding utility levels constant. Therefore, demand curves in which income is held constant are used. The welfare measured using these demand curves, called ordinary demand curves are called consumer and producer surplus (Varian 1984; Zerbe & Dively 1994). 10
  • 23. Consumer surplus (CS) is approximately the amount one would pay for the good over what one does have to pay. It is the usual measure of welfare change in CBA benefit cost analysis. The CS is represented by the area under the ordinary demand curve, but above the price (Figure 2). Producer surplus (PS) is an analogous concept to consumer surplus. It is the amount that can be taken from the producer or input supplier without diminishing the amount supplied. PS is measured along a supply curve just as CS is measured along a demand curve, so it is the area below the price and above the supply curve. However, policy questions do not generally concern a single individual only. A central problem of any social welfare or social value theory is the problem of aggregation over individuals to obtain society’s welfare (Zerbe & Dively 1994; Boardman 2001). The use of the Pareto Optimality criterion usually allows measuring society’s welfare. This criterion is an efficiency norm describing the conditions necessary to achieve optimality in resource allocation. The Pareto Optimality criterion establishes that no one can be made better off without simultaneously making at least one other person worse off (Dunn 2004). The criterion is an efficiency norm criterion and three efficiency conditions are associated with it: production efficiency, exchange efficiency, and allocative efficiency. Production efficiency represents a resource allocation where it is no longer possible to increase the output of one good without reducing the output of another. Exchange efficiency represents a resource allocation where is impossible to make one individual better off without making one other individual worse off. Allocative efficiency is attained when production and exchange efficiency are both attained: the rate at which commodities are substituted in production equals the rate at which commodities are exchanged in consumption. Pareto Optimality criterion distinguishes between optimal and non- 11
  • 24. optimal solutions but does not provide a conceptual framework for comparing two solutions that are efficient. The problem of locating the optimal point on the utility frontier is a problem of social choice. Economists approach to the social choice problem by postulating a social welfare function. A social welfare function is a decision rule for making choices in which the welfare of more than one person or agent is affected. A social welfare function is a function of the utilities of n individuals: W= W (U1, U2,…,Un) Where: W= society’s welfare Un = utility of individual n n= number of individuals in the society While the Pareto Optimality indicates an efficient resource allocation, in the real word is difficult to attain. Consequently a more flexible criterion is used: the Potential Pareto improvement also called the Kaldor-Hicks criterion. According to this criterion, those individuals who benefit from reallocation could compensate those individuals who lose (Zerbe & Dively 1994; Boardman 2001). The value of a resource allocation change can be measured by considering consumer and producer surpluses. Examples of factors affecting welfare include externalities, supply changes, and other market distortions. Social welfare can be affected by a policy, such as new taxation or subsidies. Figure 3 provides an example of how new taxes affect three sectors of the economy: consumers, producers and government. The supply curve shifts backward, and the price paid by the household changes from p0 to pd while the price received by the producer is ps. The loss in CS 12
  • 25. equals area A plus area B while PS loses area C plus area D. The revenue received by the government equals area A plus area D. The difference between the revenue received by the government and the households’ and producers’ loss is called deadweight loss, consisting of area B plus area D. 2.3 Forest Policy There are several reasons for policy interventions in the forest sector. First, forests provide non-market services such as soil conservation, aesthetic values, recreation, and carbon storage (Chappelle 1971; Ellefson 1988; Dore & Guevara 2000; Clapp 2001; Clark 2004; Richards & Stokes 2004). Second, forest investments are long-term investments. They require the maintenance of a large capital stock, which makes the opportunity cost of capital tied up in growing stock high. Meijerink (1997 in Enters et al. 2003) proposed that incentives should be applied to public goods only. Where plantations provide environmental services such as soil or watershed protection, prevention of land degradation or carbon sequestration, incentives are appropriate because private net returns are often lower than overall social returns. Enters et al. (2003) proposed incentives to projects that provide employment, especially to new forest industries in countries with competitive advantages, ensuring reliable supplies of strategic timber resources, and alleviating rural poverty. Scherr and Current (1999 in Enters et al 2003) stated that incentives might be particularly justified to accelerate the pace of plantation development in cases where a developing industry requires a minimum supply of raw material. Clapp (1995 in Enters et al 2003) stated that commodity industries such as pulp and paper need economies of scale to be competitive, then a subsidy to start their activities may be necessary. Cubbage et al. 13
  • 26. (1993) mentioned that reducing income taxes by providing tax deductions or tax credits for timber growing is a way of favoring timber investments. On the other hand, some authors claimed that incentives represent a misallocation of public-sector resources and are not needed when the private returns from plantation management exceed those from other land uses (Forestry Law 13723 1968; Haltia & Keipi 1997). Furthermore, in a number of instances government forestry policies have aggravated problems such as deforestation (Repetto & Gillis 1988). The deforestation of Brazilian Amazon, the inefficient use of resources in Philippines, and illegal logging in Indonesia are the most common examples of these negative effects (Repetto 1988; Repetto & Gillis 1988; Berck et al. 2003; Bacha 2004). 2.4 Latin American Policy In Latin America, the use of incentive mechanisms promoting forest investments started in the 1970s and was broadly adopted in the 1980s. Chile, Argentina, Brazil and Uruguay introduced subsidies, tax breaks and tax exonerations to promote the development of forest plantations and wood manufacturing industries, with different results. Colombia, Ecuador and Paraguay took the Chilean model to establish subsidies. 2.4.1. Chile 2.4.1.1 Regulation The development of the forest sector in Chile began with the Decree Law 701 that created the Forestry National Corporation (CONAF). The objective of the policy was: “…to promote plantations, reforest, rationalize the exploitation and attain the optimum 14
  • 27. management of the forest” (Sabag Villalobos 1984). Management plans are required for native forest, forest plantations, afforestation projects, and harvesting operations (FAO 2006). The instruments applied consisted of subsidies and tax exonerations (Sabag Villalobos 1984; Silva 2004; FAO 2006). Currently subsidies are not in force and tax exonerations are the only incentive still available. Policy results were positive. The area of pine and eucalyptus plantations increased substantially (FAO 2006). Small producers were not included in the incentives schemes established by the Decree Law 701 (Silva 2004). The reestablishment of a democratic government led to several reforms of the forest policy. These reforms included the debate of the Native Forest Bill in 1990, and the reform of the Decree Law 701 between 1994 and 2000 (Silva 1999 in Silva 2004). The Native Forest Bill was one of the first environmental initiatives of the government. The Native Forest Bill aimed to protect native forests that were under pressure from invading pine plantations. Several political issues and opposite interests arose in the debate, with the president and the Agricultural Ministry supporting the Bill, and the Economy Ministry, part of the legislature, and the timber corporations opposing it. The Native Forest Bill is still under deliberation and has not yet been approved. The reform of the Decree Law 701 aimed to redirect the subsidies from large corporations to small producers. Following negotiations, large corporations received an extension of tax exonerations but did not gain access to the subsidies. 2.4.1.2 Forest Resources Chile’s forest area has grown over the past 15 years as a result on increased planting. At the same time, native forest area has been stable. The total forest area reached 16 million hectares (ha) by 2005 (Table 1). Between 1998 and 2004, about 40,000 ha were planted 15
  • 28. annually. The country is divided into 13 regions. Native forests are located in Regions IX through XII and forest plantations are concentrated in Regions VII through IX (Lara & Veblen 1993). In 1994 radiata pine covered 75.5% of the total planted area, and eucalyptus 16.9%. By 2004 the share of radiata pine declined to 47% and while that of eucalyptus rose to 40% (Paredes 1999; Southern Hemisphere 2006). The value of forest production increased more than four times between 1984 and 1997. During this period, 74% of the production was exported (Paredes 1999). Wood pulp production reached 3.4 million ton in 2004, as much as 2.5 million were exported. Pulpwood consumption also increased, and there is a concern regarding future pulp wood availability for new projects. Paper exports increased by 78% between 1986 and 2004. Paper exports increased in 2004 compared to 2003 by 31% (Southern Hemisphere 2006). Lumber production has also increased reaching 8.6 million m3 in 2004, with 2.4 million m3 exported. On the other hand, local lumber consumption has also increased due to the growth of the construction sector (Paperloop 2005; Southern Hemisphere 2006). 2.4.1.3 Industry The Chilean forest industry is one of the most rapidly growing in the world (Clapp 2001; Silva 2004). The pulp industry is highly concentrated. rauco and CMPC Celulosa are the most important companies (Paperloop 2005; Southern Hemisphere 2006). Arauco owns four pulpmills in Chile and one in Argentina (Southern Hemisphere 2006). The solid wood sector is also highly concentrated: nine companies account for 90% of the production. The most important companies are the same as in the pulp sector: Arauco and CMPC Celulosa (Southern Hemisphere 2006). 16
  • 29. 2.4.2 Brazil 2.4.2.1 Regulation Between 1967 and 1986, Brazil has provided incentives for establishing forest plantations. The first law was established in 1966 and included tax incentives to plantations (Keugen 2001; Flynn 2005). To be included in this program the owner had to present a plan to the Brazilian Institute for Forestry Development (IBDF), which had to approve it, and then the plantation and maintenance costs were deducted from the income taxes for the first three years of the operation, up to a maximum of 50% of the income tax. During the 1970s the law was revised restricting the tax exonerations to legal entities, and reducing gradually the percentage of tax deduction. In 1987, the percentage was reduced to 10% and restricted to the Northeast of the country (Flynn 2005). A controversial issue was the use of agricultural lands for forestry. In 1976 the regulation established “Priority Regions for Reforestation and/or Forest Industry Districts” for planting. Currently, the federal government has two programs that provide incentives to small and medium sized landowners to plant trees. Regarding the industry, the Brazilian Government has encouraged the establishment of specific programs to develop the industrial forest sector. The Wood and Furniture Forum is led by the Ministry of Development and Foreign Trade and was established to promote growth in the sector. The BNDES has financed studies which indicate that more plantations are needed in order to provide wood for the new industries. Therefore, the BNDES has been financing forest plantations projects. PROMOVEL is the Brazilian Program for Increasing Furniture Exports. It was created in 1998 by the Brazilian Furniture Association (Flynn 2005). 17
  • 30. There are some protective tariffs to the wood products industry. On one hand, taxes on wood imports have been decreasing. On the other hand, imported equipment has high tariffs in order to encourage the use of local machinery (Flynn 2005). Another law requires that at least 20% of every forest area must be maintained in “natural vegetation”(Flynn 2005). 2.4.2.2 Forest Resources Today, Brazil has nearly 6 million ha covered with forest plantations, and the total area of natural forest is more than 550 million ha as is shown in Table 2 (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005; FAO 2006; Southern Hemisphere 2006). Eucalyptus accounted for 63% of total planted area and pine for 31%. Eucalyputs growth rates differ according to states and companies, ranging from 30 to 50 m3/ha/year. Annual harvest is estimated in 60-70 million m3, and it is projected to increase to 106 million m3. Consumption is divided into pulp mills (50%), charcoal and energy (40%), panels (6%), and lumber (4%) (Flynn 2005). Pine plantations are located mainly in the state of Parana, 682,000 ha, and were planted between 1967 and 1998 (Southern Hemisphere 2006). The ownership is not very concentrated as 12 companies own 18.4% of the total (Flynn 2005). Rotations are on average 22 years in the South, with a first thinning at 12 years and a second thinning at 17 years. If pines are managed for pulp, rotations are 16 years (Flynn 2005). Pine harvest is divided among sawmills (60%), pulpmills (22%), plywood (10%) and composite wood panels (8%). 18
  • 31. 2.4.2.3 Industry Brazil is the 7th largest producer of pulp in the world and the 11th largest producer of paper and paperboard in the world (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005). Pulp production has been expanding since the 1990s (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005). Aracruz is the most important pulp company with a pulp production capacity of 2.25 million metric tons in 2003. The reminder is divided among five companies (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005). Another growth industry is packaging. The largest packaging producer is Klabin which has a capacity of 150,000 ton/year (Flynn 2005; Paperloop 2005). 2.4.2.4 Exports The value of sawn wood exports increased 23% between 2003 and 2004. The growth in the following year was much smaller. The exports increased by 5% only due to the Real devaluation (Southern Hemisphere 2006). The most important export markets were United States and China. Pulp and paper exports have been increasing reaching 1.187 billion US$ in 2004. The main destinations for pulp were Europe (47%), Asia (29%) and North America (21%); on the other hand, paper went to Latin America, Europe (18%) and North America (16%) (Flynn 2005). 2.5 Summary The design of a public policy implies the choice of objectives that considers scarce resources and opposite interests. The last objective behind any public policy is to increase the welfare of the society, i.e., to make a group of persons better off without making anyone else worse off. This is known as the Pareto Optimality criteria. 19
  • 32. In Latin America, many countries started forest programs with different results. Chile and Brazil can be characterized as the most successful, even though their policies and strategies have been different. Chile has a highly concentrated forest industry while Brazil has less concentrated industry. Both countries rely on exotic species. 20
  • 33. 1. Define the problem 6. Monitor the 2. Establish implemented evaluation policy criteria 5. Implement 3. Identify the Policy alternative policies 4. Evaluate alternative policies Source: Adapted from Patton and Sawicki, 1993. Figure 1. Basic Policy Analysis Process 21
  • 34. Price Supply CS Po PS Demand Quantity Qo Figure 2. Consumer and Producer Surplus Price Supply 2 Supply 1 Pd A B P0 D Demand C Ps Q1 Qo Quantity Figure 3. Taxation and Deadweight Loss 22
  • 35. Table 1. Forest area in Chile (1,000 ha) FRA 2005 Categories 1990 2000 2005 Primary 4,152 4,145 4,142 Modified natural 9,344 9,309 9,292 Semi-natural 26 26 26 Sub total 13,522 13,480 13,460 Productive plantation 1,741 2,354 2,661 Protective plantation 0 0 0 Total 15,263 15,834 16,121 Source: FAO, Global Forest Resources Assessment 2005. Table 2. Forest area in Brazil (1,000 ha) FRA 2005 Categories 1990 2000 2005 Primary 460,513 433,220 415,890 Modified natural 54,444 54,714 56,424 Semi-natural - - - Sub total 514,957 487,934 472,314 Productive plantation 5,070 5,279 5,384 Protective plantation - - - Total 520,027 493,213 477,698 Source: FAO, Global Forest Resources Assessment 2005. 23
  • 36. CHAPTER 3 URUGUAY’S FOREST SECTOR Uruguay is a small South American country located between Argentina and Brazil. It has a Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of 18 billion US$ (Central Bank of Uruguay 2005). The most important sector of the economy is Manufacturing Industries, which accounts for 22.9% of GDP. Another important sector is Agriculture, including livestock, which contributed 8.7% to the GDP (Figure 4). The silviculture sub-sector (forest plantations) has increased its share in the Agricultural GDP between 1990 and 2002 to 13.4% (Table 3). The Uruguayan Economy has been relatively stable during the last 25 years, except for two financial crises in 1982 and in 2002. In 1982, the exchange rate system collapsed leading to a currency devaluation and a financial crisis. This resulted in a decline in the agricultural sector, which had debt denoted in US$ and was multiplied by the devaluation effect. After a period of high growth in the 1990s, the economy began to contract in 1998, and the 2002 financial crisis reinforced this phenomena. However, in 2003 the GDP increased 1% versus a 10% decline the year before. This reversal can be explained by growing exports and by substituting imports with domestic production. The trade balance in Uruguay was negative between 2000 and 2005 with the exception of 2003. The main export is beef, which accounts for 33% of total exports. Even though in 2005 exports increased by 16.2%, imports increased 24.4%, resulting in a trade deficit of 474 million US$. A one-time special purchase of 243 million US$ of Venezuelan oil was part of the deficit. 24
  • 37. The Uruguayan exchange rate regime4 has changed from pegged exchange rates within horizontal bands in the 1990s to a floating system in 2002, after a 93% devaluation that year. The devaluation has increased the competitiveness of domestic production and exports grew. At the same time, imports declined due to a contraction in consumption (Economic Institute 2003). 3.1 Description of the Uruguayan Forest Sector 3.1.1 Area Forest area is in Uruguay reaches almost 1.5 million ha, constituting 9% of the country’s land base (Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay 2000; Ramos & Cabrera 2001). Forests are classified as either plantations or natural forests. Natural forests cover 740,000 ha, representing 4% of the country’s land area (Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay 2000; Ramos & Cabrera 2001). Plantations cover 751,000 ha and their area has grown rapidly from between 1990 and 2005 (Table 4). The last Agricultural Census, CGA 2000, shows a significant increase in the forest area (Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay 2000). Planted forest area reached 661 thousand ha in 2000. That represented a nearly 4-fold increase from the preceding Census of 1990. According to the Forest Division of the Agricultural Ministry, between 1990 and 2002, 590,000 ha were planted under the incentives of the Forestry Law (Durán 2003). The law provided fiscal incentives for the development of commercial forests plantations on priority soils, generally marginal agricultural (Figure 5). The CONEAT5 index measures the productivity of the land by soil type, location, and productivity. The base index is 100; lands 4 The exchange rate considered here is the price of a dollar in terms of Uruguayan Peso ($U). The US$ is the currency used by the Uruguayan Government to set the exchange rate and the exchange rate regime. 5 CONEAT stands for the National Commission of Agronomic Study of the Land. This Commission depends on the Renewable Resources Division (RENARE) which depends on the Agricultural and Livestock Ministry (MGAP). 25
  • 38. with an index higher than 100 are considered very well for livestock and agriculture; lands with an index lower than 100 are considered poor lands. Ramos and Cabrera built a weighted average CONEAT index for forest lands and estimated that between 1989 and 1999 the index was 69.6 (Ramos & Cabrera 2001) (Table 5). 3.1.2 Species Plantation incentives were provided for particular tree species. As a consequence, eucalyptus species account for 76% of planted areas greater than 10, and pine for 22% (Figure 6). While pine has been more frequently planted in recent years, eucalyptus still accounts for the majority of the planted area, 3.1.3 Location Forested areas are geographically concentrated in the north of the country (the provinces of Rivera and Tacuarembó). The remainder is found in the west (the provinces of Paysandú and Río Negro), and in the southwest (the provinces of Lavalleja and Maldonado). Currently, forest area is Cerro Largo also growing. Rivera is the province with the largest forest area (115,000 ha, which represents 13.1% of the total agricultural area of the province). It is followed by Tacuarembó (97,300 ha, 6.6% of the total agricultural area of the province); and Paysandú (93,000 ha, 6.9% of the total area of the province). Nearly a half of the forest planted area is located in those three provinces, Rivera, Tacuarembó and Paysandú (Durán 2003). 26
  • 39. 3.1.4 Ownership The saw timber and paper sectors have begun developing rapidly in the 1990s. As the first forest plantations neared their first harvest, international investors have discovered Uruguay’s forest sector as an attractive investment opportunity. Traditionally, the sector concentrated on paper and lumber production manufactures. These lumber manufacturers were small local firms (Durán 2004). The Forestry Law has recently attracted new, primarily foreign, investors who focus on plantations development and paper and lumber manufacturing. The forest sector today is characterized by the coexistence of large, vertically integrated firms with many small scale primary producers and a substantial presence of foreign investors. Production and export activities are the domain of a few large firms (Durán 2003; Mendell et al. 2007). Even though there are more than 19,000 farms with at least one forested ha, the forest plantation estate is highly concentrated: 96% of the farms have less than 100 ha planted and they control only 17.3% of the forest area. Most of these small farms use plantations for shelter and shadow for livestock or for other non-commercial purposes. On the other hand, 62.8% of the plantation area is in farms with forest areas greater than 500 ha. Intermediate farms (planted areas between 100 and 500 ha) account for only 9% the total forest planted area (Table 6). According to DIEA assessment, in 2000 there were 64 farms with planted area between 1,000 and 10,000 ha and 9 farms with forest planted areas larger than 10,000 ha (Durán 2003). 3.1.5 Forest Income The development of plantations and growing production of wood products have transformed the forest sector into an important source of income. According to the Agricultural Census 2000, out of 57,131 farms, 1,015 listed forestry as their main source of income. The 27
  • 40. forest sector employs 2,962 workers, from a total of 157,000 employees in the agricultural sector. In addition, a large number of workers serve the forest sector by performing harvesting, pruning, and thinning operations. The Forest Division estimated that in 2000 the sector had approximately 14,000 employees in the forest plantations (Durán 2003). 3.1.6 Wood harvest, manufacturing, and exports Growing wood harvest fueled a rapid growth in wood exports. The harvest volume increased 27% between 2000 and 2003, rising from 2.9 million to 3.7 million m3 (cubic meters) (DIEA 2004). Pulpwood production increased from 893,000 to 1.6 million cum, a gain of 83%, and fuel wood production increased from 1.4 to 1.6 million cum, a gain of 13%. Much of the harvest, except fuel wood, is designated for export (Forest Division 2005). While export growth has been rapid, its share in the Trade Balance remains low. Forest products exports account only for 5% of the country’s total exports, and in the period 1989-2004 the share has oscillated between 2 to 7% (Table 7). At the same time, forest products imports account for 3.5% of the total imports (ALADI 2006). It is expected, however, that maturing plantations will increase wood harvest which would promote export-oriented production. The two most important export groups are (1) saw timber (2) paper and cardboard, and pulpwood has been increasing in the last years (Table 8). If paper and cardboard exports are not considered, forest exports account for 4% of the country’s total exports. Since 1990 pulpwood production increased dramatically. About 50% of the production is exported. Saw timber and lumber production also increased. Since domestic consumption of these products has been stable, their export continues to grow. In 2000, about 100 thousand cum of lumber were exported. That accounts for a fifth of the total lumber production. Paper and 28
  • 41. cardboard exports also increased, reaching more than 50,000 tons in 1999, or 40% of the total production. That year the total forest exports were less than 100 million US$, 4.4% of the total exports in Uruguay. By 2004, pulpwood exports reached 92.5 million US$, lumber exports 18.1 million US$, and paper and cardboard 31.6 million US$. During the 1990s pulp logs exports went to Europe: Spain, Norway, Finland and Portugal. Lumber was sold to Italy, USA and Japan (Figures 7 and 8). 3.1.7 Export Prices Between 1989 and 1999, exports grew in volume but not in value. The Central Bank of Uruguay (BCU) constructs an index for Paper and Cardboard (Series X). The Index is a Paasche Index with base in the previous year on FOB6 values, and it is available from 1994 to 2004. The index shows that prices increased between 1994 and 1995, but started declining in 1996 (Table 9). The Forest Division provides export information by value, volume, and item, allowing the estimation of unitary values. This information is available for years from 1980 and 2005, for hardwood and softwood saw timber and pulpwood. The results indicate that hardwood saw timber unit values were more stable than softwood saw timber ones (Table 10). Hardwood prices varied from 27 to 314 US$/m3 in the period7; while softwood unit values oscillated from 99 to 115 US$/ m3. Softwood pulpwood pries were stable at around 40 US$/ m3 8. The Association of Industries of Uruguay (CIU) constructs a Paasche index for the entire sector (saw timber, pulp, paper, cardboard, printing, etc.) based on the National Customs Administration (DNA) data. The index is also calculated for saw timber, but not for pulpwood 6 Free on Board. 7 In 1990, the average unit value was 5 US$/cum, a value that probably does not reflect the real price. 8 There is no information about pulp prices before 1989. 29
  • 42. because its share in Uruguay’s total exports is low. The weights are not fixed as the index base is the preceding year. Three products are included: pine wood, eucalyptus wood, and other species wood (Table 11). The results from 2000 to 2006 with 2000 as a base year show that prices had decreased until 2002 and after that started growing again. 3.1.8 Imports Forest products imports increased in the 1990s: paper purchases increased four-fold, representing 60% of the total forest imports in value; lumber represented 18% of the total; remanufactured wood purchases represented 5% of the total. Pulp purchases doubled in value and tripled in volume, reaching more than 10% of the total. Between 1995 and 2005, forest imports9 were on average US$ 47 million annually (Table 12). Two thirds of the Uruguayan purchases of paper and cardboard came from the region, mainly from Argentina and Brazil, 15% came from North America, and the rest from Europe. The regions are the source for 70% of pulpwood imports. 3.1.9 Forest Industries The National Institute of Statistics (INE) collects information for industries using the Uniform International Industrial Classification (CIIU). According to its estimates, based on INE and BCU data, sawmills and pulp and paper industries constituted 1.36% of Uruguay’s GDP in 2003 (Table 13). This percentage will be higher after new facilities currently under construction are included. Botnia, which will have completed a pulp and paper mill investment of one billion 9 Not all the products were considered. Ramos and Cabrera (2001) considered all the products and indicated that between 1989 and 2000, the forest imports averaged 75 million US$ annually. 30
  • 43. US$ this year. The mill construction began in the third quarter of 2005. Other companies, such Urupanel and Colonvade in Tacuarembó also completed their investments after 2003. The CIIU 2 was used until 2002. Then it was replaced the CIIU 3. In CIIU 2, the pulp and paper industry was considered together with newspapers, printing, etc. In CIIU 3, they are separate items, and the wood and wood manufacturing industry includes new items as well. Therefore, the production values of each subgroup cannot be compared for those years. The Association of Industries of Uruguay (CIU) constructs a Production Index (PI) for the industry using the CIIU 3 codes from 1993 to 2006 based on INE data, which was used to convert the values from current US$ to constant 2002 US$ (Table 14). Pulp and Paper Industry GDP increased 6% between 1998 and 1999, measured in constant US$ of 2002, and then declined (Table 15). In 2002, the INE changed the classification system and the Pulp and Paper sub sector does not include printing; therefore, the results cannot be compared easily. However, after adjusting the data, the results show that the GDP in US$ increased. If only pulp and paper industry is considered, between 2002 and 2003, its GDP increased 30%; sawmills GDP increased by 67%; meanwhile, manufacturing industry GDP decreased. There are no records of sawmills GDP before 2002. Analyzing the share of forest industries in total manufacturing GDP, only sawmills increased their share significantly between 2002 and 2003 (Table 16). This is consistent with the current situation in the forest sector: the new projects that just have been completed or are about to be completed are not included in the GDP. The number of sawmills decreased, indicating the industry concentrated. By 2000, the number of sawmills declined to about than 50, down from 113 in 1988. The sawmills operated primarily in Montevideo (45%), San José and Paysandú (20% each) and Rivera and Tacuarembó 31
  • 44. (15% of the total) (Ramos & Cabrera 2001). In the 1990s, the production of pulp wood and recycled paper increased, as well as the pulp and cardboard production, to lesser degree, but the employment in those sub sectors was reduced to half (Ramos & Cabrera 2001). Currently, five firms are key players in the forest sector in Uruguay: Botnia, Colonvade, Fymnsa, Cofusa-Urufor, and Urupanel. Two firms invest heavily in pulp manufacturing: Ence and Stora Enso. Botnia, is constructing a pulp mill in the North of the country, which involves the largest single investment in the country’s history, with a value of one billion US$. The mill will be operational the third quarter of 2007. Ence has partnerships with several local firms and had been planning a pulp mill. Due to a dispute with Argentina, Ence has been forced to change the mill’s location and that decision is still under consideration. Stora Enso has just arrived in the country and is also planning to build a pulp mill. In the saw timber and plywood sector, the leading firms include Fymnsa and Urufor (domestic) and Weyerhaeuser and Urupanel (foreign). Colonvade is constructing a plywood facility and plans to build five to eight more plants in Tacuarembó, Rivera and Paysandú. Fymnsa, one of the oldest and biggest domestic companies located in Rivera, is constructing a sawmill. Cofusa and Urufor operate in the North of Uruguay and produce high quality eucalyptus grandis timber. Urupanel is a Chilean lumber company located in Tacuarembó. 3.2 Forest Policy Even though there was a general agreement when the Forestry Law was approved in 1987, controversies soon followed. The Forestry Law in Uruguay was controversial for several reasons including subsidies and regionalization. Regarding subsidies, the main issues were: (1) whether the subsidies were necessary to attract investments, (2) whether to subsidize other, 32
  • 45. already established, sectors of the economy and (3) whether the subsidies should be in effect for regions which determined that better alternative uses exist for lands allocated to forest development. Regarding regionalization, the argument focused on the designation of forest priority lands as it was argued that not all lands included were low productivity lands. 3.2.1 Background and Previous Regulation In the 1950s, the potential to increase forest production in Uruguay was studied. At the same time, the country’s soils were classified according to their productivity (CIDE 1963). The classification had five soil groups, and the country was divided into thirteen soils zones for management and conservation (Berreta 2003). In 1968, the first Forestry Law was approved (Forestry Law 13723 1968), and the forest sector became the only economic sector with a Promotion Policy (Gabriel San Román Policy Director, Forest Division. Personal Communication, July 2006). The objective was to increase the forest area. The instruments used included tax exonerations, tax reinvestments in plantations, and credit extended by the BROU. The Law did not achieve its objectives for a variety of reasons. The law was incomplete, funds were not allocated for the Forest Fund, and priority zones were not defined. Furthermore the credit extension was not designed according to the long term characteristics of a forest investment (Forestry Law 13723/54-56). Forestry loans were offered by the BROU for a period of only 10 years (Forestry Law 13723/53), and timber rotations range from 15 to 25 years. 33
  • 46. 3.2.2 Forestry Law 15939: objectives and instruments The second Forestry Law was approved in 1987 (Forestry Law 15939 1988) by all members of the Parliament, even though some members expressed their concerns about some areas10. The parliament passed the law to generate to environmental, economic, and social benefits for the country. The main objectives of the 1987 Forestry Law were to increase planted area and to protect native forests. The specific objectives were to increase forest cover through the introduction of fast-growing species in regions with poor soils, to promote industrial development in non-industrialized regions, and to increase and diversify exports. The Forestry Law 15939 is the framework for the current forestry policy, but, as the sector has been developing, new regulations have been developed in several decrees and resolutions. Some of these regulations were designed to implement certain parts of the Law (i.e. soils priority zones, tax exonerations, subsidies, Forest Fund); others were developed to consider new factors that emerged during the development of the forest sector (e.g. species productivity); and finally some were developed to modify original resolutions that needed updating (e.g. soils priority zones, subsidies). The policy instruments used include regionalization, tax exonerations, subsidies, and credit. Regionalization consisted of defining forestry priority zones in the country. Forestlands are defined and zones classified according to soil type in Decree 452/88. Soils classified as priority soils in Forestry Law 15939 and following decrees (Decree 452/88-Article 2; Decree 26/93) are located mainly in the North, Northwest and Northeast of the country. To be classified as the forest priority soil, the site has to be characterized by a low natural fertility but offer good 10 The Forest Producers Society summarized the history and discussion of the Forestry Law 15939 in an internal report that was obtained during the author’s visit to Uruguay, but they date when the report was prepared was not known. 34
  • 47. forest growth conditions (Decree 452/88-Article 3). The minimum area to be considered a forest was set at 2,500 square meters (Decree 452/88-Article 1). The definition of priority zones also included “supplementary soils” that could be planted up to 40% of the total area11 (Decree 333/90). This decree was revoked in 2005 (Decree 154/05). Currently, forest planting requires an associated management plan, and to plant in accessory soils, an environmental plan (Decree 191/06; Decree 220/06). These changes have only a limited impact on forest investment decisions as they do not affect the management of lands where most forest plantations have been developed 12 (Personal Communication with Forest Companies, July 2006). Tax exonerations for forestlands and taxes and tariff exonerations for goods and inputs used for forestry activities also were established. Tax exonerations included land tax, which is 1.25% on the land value and will vary according to soil productivity13; rural property taxes; the exoneration of the Global Tariff Rate and Value Added Tax (IVA) for the imports14 by forest companies for 15 years. While the last exoneration expired in 2002; property tax exonerations are still in force. To benefit from the exonerations, the plantations have to be qualified as protective and production forests and they have to be located in forest priority zones. Law 16002 established a subsidy of up to 30% of the cost of plantation but this percentage was later increased to 50% (Law 16.170, Article 251; Decree 212/97, Article 1). Currently subsidies are not in force. Another change is that forest priority soils and species are under revision, but projects previously approved are not affected. 11 In Decree 452/98 it was allowed to plant in “supplementary soils” up to 10% of the total area. 12 Other groups of soils affected are: 2.11a, 2.12, 5.01c, 5.02a, 7, 8 (not all) (Decree 191/06). 13 The value used to calculate the tax is the CONEAT Index. 14 Activities are listed in Decree 457/989 and include: fertilizers, chemical products, vehicles, machines, equipment for fire prevention, etc. 35
  • 48. Credit is another tool used by the Government to promote forest investments. The Republic of Uruguay Bank (BROU) finances nurseries and different stages of the forest production. It provided financing of up to 80% of the project’s value, not considering land value; the credits are in US$, and payment begin up to 10 years later. The ability to create Joint Stock Corporations with bearer shares was one of the changes introduced by the new Forestry Law. Join Stock corporations with bearer shares were not allowed in the Agricultural Sector, but the Forestry Sector was the exception. Today, they are allowed in the Agricultural Sector as well. Wood manufacturing industries benefit from other laws as well15. Investments Promotion and Protection Law and associated decrees, and Free Trade Zone Companies regulations all help in developing wood processing. Investments Promotion and Protection Law (Law 16906 1998), establishes tax exonerations and tax breaks for investments that are considered as National Interest Projects. To receive the benefits introduced in the Law the project has to be declared by the Government as National Interest Project. The project has to be presented to the Customer Office at the Tourism Ministry. The requirements include presenting a note describing the fiscal incentives requested, an investment project containing a description of its costs and benefits, and an environmental impact study when necessary and a proof of origin of the capital. Industries can choose to develop a Free Trade Zone. Two international forest companies had adopted this regime: Botnia and Ence16. To be considered under this scheme, the company has to present a project to the government describing the economic viability of the project and the benefits it will generate for the country. After obtaining the authorization, the company has to 15 These laws are in force for all industries, not just for forest industries. 16 By October 2006, Ence announced a change in the mill construction plans. The mill would be relocated and therefore, the construction is delayed. 36
  • 49. pay either a one-time fee or a periodic fee. The benefits include tax exonerations. All the national taxes are exonerated except for social security contributions. In addition, the entrance of goods and the services rendered within the free trade zone is exempt from all taxes. Goods inbound to the zone from Uruguay are considered to be exports and goods outbound from the zone are exempt from all taxes. However, if the goods are moved into Uruguayan territory they are considered imports. The company that operates in a tax free zone is not allowed to have activities in the rest of the country (Tourism Ministry 2006). 3.3 Native Forests Native species represent 3.7% of the country’s land area. They are composed of 140 species. The species distribution varies with geographical location, particularly with soil conditions. Native forests can be into five groups: gallery forests, mountain forests, park forests, ravine forests and palms. Traditionally, native forest has been used for fuel wood. Fuel wood consumption has been constant at around 35,000 to 40,000 tons annually. The sellers are controlled by the Government and are required to report their stocks every four months. The native forests also have non-timber uses. The species present in Uruguay can be used for medicine, carbon storage, cosmetics (essential oils), fruits17, and ornaments (Escudero 2004). The ecotourism has been proposed as an interesting alternative use for native forests and is currently developing in the country. Some studies have attempted to estimate the returns of managing native woods (Cubbage et al. 2006). By considering three different management regimes, the study analyzes different species in the Southern Cone of Latin America and in the Southern United States. 17 The Agricultural School of the University of Republic in Uruguay has attempted to work in this field. 37
  • 50. Natural stand returns in Latin America were much lower than those of plantations. The average natural forest growth rates were estimated at 1 cubic meter per hectare per year (m3/ha/yr), resulting in a low internal rate of return (IRR). The immediate harvest of native species would be more attractive financially, but is not likely to be sustainable without good management. The unsustainable use and exploitation of the native forests worldwide is a widespread problem. There are three different approaches to the management of the native forests: exploitation, preservation and conservation. Exploitation refers to the use of the resource, without considering its conservation. Preservation does not allow any resource utilization. Finally the intermediate approach would be the conservation approach, which refers to the regulated use of the forests. The Uruguayan government has taken the conservation approach, along with the preservation of some specific areas. The harvest of native wood is only allowed in the forests subject to management plans that need to be approved by the Forest Division of the Agricultural Ministry. In addition, the commercialization and transport of the native wood is controlled by the government, as described above. The Uruguayan Government considered the definition proposed by the World Conservation Union (IUCN) to design the native forest policy. They consider that the conservation is positive and involves the preservation, the sustainable management and the improvement of the natural environment. The Uruguayan government as well as some institutions has signed agreements with international organizations to implement projects that protect the native forests, e.g., BIRF Projects UR (3131, 3697), Cooperation Agreement with the European Union (1994-1995). 38
  • 51. 3.4 Summary The Forestry Law promoted the rapid development of forest plantations. Between 1989 and 1999 the area planted increased by 491 thousand ha. The annual planting reached its peak in 1998. The plantations are concentrated in the provinces of Rivera, Paysandú, Tacuarembó, Río Negro and Cerro Largo, all located in the North of the country (Forest Division 2004). The Forestry Law attracted new, primarily foreign, firms into the forest sector. These new firms invested in wood growing and lumber and pulp. The incentives were offered because the forest sector has long-term investments and the returns are not immediate. In addition, if industries are expected to invest in the country, it will be necessary to have a sizeable forest area in order to meet their raw material needs. Even though environmental issues such as the protection of native forest protection were considered, they were not the center of the debate. Regionalization was another controversial issue related to the new forest policy. It was argued that soils that can be used for livestock would be used for forestry. In such cases agro- forestry systems have been adapted by most of the forest firms. 39
  • 52. Agriculture and Other Services Livestock 8.90% 8.69% Fisheries 0.38% Minery Government Services 0.28% 8.22% Manufacturer Industries Assets and services to 22.95% companies 11.70% Electricity, Gas and Water Financial Business, 4.61% Insurances, etc 7.54% Construction T ransportation 4.19% 9.56% Commerce, Restaurants and Hotels 12.97% Source: Central Bank of Uruguay 2007. Figure 4. Uruguay GDP by sectors (2005) Table 3. GDP as Percentage of Agricultural GDP Sub sectors 1990 2002 Agriculture 23.40 21.00 Silviculture 3.80 13.40 Livestock 72.80 65.60 Total 100.00 100.00 Source: Central Bank of Uruguay. Table 4. Uruguay Forest Resources (1,000 ha) FRA 2005 Categories 1990 2000 2005 Primary 591 296 296 Modified natural 465 444 444 Semi-natural - - - Sub total 704 740 740 Productive plantation 197 655 751 Protective plantation 4 14 15 Total 905 1,409 1,506 Source: FAO, Global Forest Resources Assessment 2005. 40
  • 53. Uruguay: Forest Priority Soils CONEAT Groups Agricultural and Livestock Ministry Renewable Resources Division Geographical Information System Figure 5. Uruguay Forest Priority Soils 41
  • 54. Table 5. CONEAT Index for Forest Lands Province Ha CONEAT Index Artigas 193 70.5 Canelones 2,753 32.4 Cerro Largo 20,941 65.4 Colonia 1,325 55.3 Durazno 31,951 72.4 Flores 426 69 Florida 23,786 61.2 Lavalleja 42,960 65.6 Maldonado 10,247 65.6 Montevideo 137 4.5 Paysandu 56,348 80.1 Rio Negro 77,668 68.2 Rivera 74,305 69 Rocha 10,316 55.5 Salto 437 41.1 San Jose 2,406 47.2 Soriano 21,784 80.9 Tacuarembo 68,113 71.4 Treinta y Tres 4,823 63.2 Total 450,917 69.6 Source: Ramos and Cabrera 2001. 800,000 700,000 600,000 Hectares 500,000 Pine 400,000 Eucalyptus 300,000 200,000 100,000 0 19 9 19 0 19 1 19 2 19 3 19 4 19 5 19 6 19 7 19 8 20 9 20 0 20 1 20 02 20 3* 20 4* * 05 8 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 0 0 19 0 0 Year (*) For years 2003 and 2004 the official data was not updated, but the total area by 2005 was 751,000 ha, then the area for each species was assigned according to secondary information. Source: Forest Division Figure 6. Area Planted by Species (Cumulative) 42
  • 55. Table 6. Forest Farms by Area Plantation area Total (in ha) Number % Total 19,402 100 <3 11,248 58 3-10 5,139 26.5 11-20 1,071 5.5 21-50 832 4.3 51-100 362 1.9 101-500 558 2.9 >500 192 1 Source: Agricultural Census 2000. Table 7. Uruguay Forest Exports Share in Total Exports 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Total Exports 1,599 1,693 1,605 1,703 1,645 1,913 2,106 2,397 2,726 2,771 2,242 2,302 2,061 1,861 2,198 2,922 Forest Exports 101.7 103.1 114 117.4 113.5 120.6 142.6 152.4 172.2 171.4 176.3 84.7 82.9 86.7 94.9 146.2 Share in total 6% 6% 7% 7% 7% 6% 7% 6% 6% 6% 8% 4% 4% 5% 4% 5% Forest Exports (2) 95 94.7 97.2 101.5 98.9 106.1 127 131.4 139.7 138.7 144.8 48.1 49.9 53.9 63.3 114.6 Share in total 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% 5% 5% 5% 6% 2% 2% 3% 3% 4% (2) Excludes paper and cardboard Sources: Forest Division and Central Bank of Uruguay. 43
  • 56. Table 8. Exports in Value and Volume In volume (1,000 m3) Product 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 Pulpwood 114 83 145 149 88 215 457 510 690 623 702 840 907 1,097 1,369 1,611 1,490 Chips 17 25 12 262 836 1,298 Sawtimber 0 2 2 15 22 28 36 43 64 57 56 72 58 77 96 120 140 Panels * * * * * 3 Pulp 3 1 0 1 1 1 2 0 0 * * 0 1 * * * * Paper and Cardboard 7 12 22 22 21 20 15 20 32 35 38 39 36 44 43 42 41 In value (million US$) Product 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 Pulpwood 4.5 3.5 5.8 7.3 3.4 7.9 25 27.6 34.8 31.6 35.7 40.3 41.5 43.1 47.5 56.53 55.73 Chips 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.42 0.67 0.67 10.86 32.69 62.28 Sawtimber 0 0.2 0.3 1.7 2.1 3.8 5.5 7.8 7.9 9.1 10.1 7.8 7 8.8 12.8 18.1 22.7 Panels 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 * * * 0.09 0.04 0.01 0.559 Pulp 1.8 1 0.1 0.5 0.4 0.4 1.5 0 0 0 0 0.02 0.71 * 0.03 0.02 * Paper and Cardboard 6.4 8.4 16.8 15.9 14.6 14.5 15.6 21 32.5 32.7 31.5 36.6 33 32.8 31.6 31.6 30.6 (*) Missing information Source: Forest Division (Statistics Bulletin 2004 and web site) 44
  • 57. Europe Others 0.26% 14.30% M exico 2.44% Chile 14.23% US 1.31% M ERCOSUR (Argentina and Brazil) 67.46% Source: ALADI, 2006. Figure 7. Paper and Cardboard Exports by Region (US$ FOB, 2005) Others 24.28% Europe 44.27% Asia 16.72% M exico 0.94% M ERCOSUR Chile US 1.04% 1.12% 11.63% Note: ALADI classification does not include pulpwood. Source: ALADI, 2006. Figure 8. Wood and Wood Products Exports by Region (US$ FOB, 2005) 45
  • 58. Table 9. Paper and Paper Cardboard Exports Price Index Year Price Index 94 104.2 95 128.7 96 85.1 97 90.6 98 95.8 99 89.3 00 103.5 01 99.8 02 83.4 03 97.1 04 103.0 Source: Wood Pastes, Paper and Cardboard (NCM-Section X). Paasche Exports Price Index Base 100=previous year. Central Bank of Uruguay. 46
  • 59. Table 10. Wood Export Unit Values (1,000 US$/m3) Saw timber Pulp Year Hardwood Softwood Total Softwood 1980 - 0.369 0.369 1981 - 0.410 0.410 - 1982 - - - - 1983 * 0.056 0.063 - 1984 0.086 0.058 0.067 0.032 1985 - 0.150 0.150 - 1986 - - - - 1987 0.100 0.500 0.464 - 1988 0.150 0.231 0.195 - 1989 0.139 0.097 0.119 0.042 1990 0.005 0.099 0.098 0.040 1991 - 0.115 0.115 0.042 1992 0.044 0.120 0.114 0.040 1993 0.140 0.095 0.099 0.046 1994 0.241 0.123 0.132 0.039 1995 0.314 0.139 0.151 0.037 1996 0.027 0.155 0.075 0.055 1997 0.103 0.149 0.121 0.054 1998 0.216 0.129 0.160 0.050 1999 0.049 0.132 0.063 0.049 2000 0.105 0.117 0.108 0.049 2001 0.118 0.131 0.121 0.046 2002 0.129 0.112 0.114 0.039 2003 0.197 0.098 0.133 0.035 2004 0.284 0.107 0.151 0.034 2005 0.240 0.139 0.162 0.037 Source: Based on Forest Division data (Volume and Exports in value). 47
  • 60. Table 11. Saw timber Export Price Index Year CIU 2000 92.71 2001 93.98 2002 93.15 2003 82.58 2004 (1) 101.59 2005 111.47 (1) The CIU calculates the Index as a Paasche Index with base 100=2004. However, when the index is calculated for year 2004 as a simple average of the monthly indexes, the index is different from 100. Source: CIU. 48
  • 61. Table 12. Uruguay Forest Imports (million US$ FOB) 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Wood 0.015 0.048 0 0 0.248 0.118 0.178 0.271 0.011 0.247 0.237 0.226 0.183 0.051 0.116 0.281 0.554 Saw timber 4.936 4.999 5.926 5.597 6.641 9.173 9.552 7.3 14.15 15.2 12.9 9.3 8.985 4.2 3.478 6.589 8.074 Panels 0.667 0.612 1.36 1.784 2.276 3.228 3.764 4.354 5.942 6.642 5.9 4.963 4.281 2.459 2.701 3.571 5.149 Paper and Cardboard 12.01 13.45 19.65 26.28 30.1 36.29 48.96 46.77 41.31 47.41 44.78 50.8 61.24 30.9 20.84 13.35 45.47 Source: Forest Division 2006. Table 13. GDP Forest Industries as Percentage of Total GDP (2003) 2003 GDP Industry/GDP Total 18.57% GDP SW/GDP Industry 1.44% GDP P&P/GDP Industry 5.90% GDP SW/GDP Total 0.27% GDP P&P/GDP Total 1.10% GDP SW and P&P/GDP Total 1.36% SW=sawmills, P&P= pulp and paper industries Source: Own estimations based on INE and BCU data. 49
  • 62. Table 14. CIIU Production Index, base 100=2002 Year Sawmills (1) Pulp and Paper (2) 1993 nd 69 1994 nd 75 1995 nd 59 1996 nd 84 1997 nd 94 1998 nd 98 1999 nd 101 2000 nd 100 2001 nd 96 2002 100 100 2003 201 103 2004 120 111 2005 111 109 Jan-Aug 05 103 104 Jan-Aug 06 134 112 Source: CIU based on INE data. Table 15. GDP Forest Industries and Manufacturing Industry (constant million 2002 US$) 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 (*) Pulp and Paper 101.3 108.3 104.8 99.2 106.3 122.1(*) Sawmills - - - - 18.8 58.0 Industry 2,146.7 1,802.4 1,780.3 1,715.7 1,921.9 1,887.7 (*) In 2002, INE changed the classification system from to CIIU 2 to CIIU 3. These results were estimated adding the information for pulp and paper and printing press (sub sectors 21 and 22 according to CIIU 3 classification) in order to compare the results. Source: INE. 50
  • 63. Table 16. Sawmills and Pulp and Paper Industries Share in Industry Product and Industry Wages 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 GNP Pulp and Paper 6.12% 7.28% 6.86% 5.98% 4.97% 4.47% Sawmills - - - - 0.82% 1.01% Slaughter Houses 42.26% 42.96% 41.74% 42.68% 43.97% 45.54% Wool, cotton and leather 12.21% 11.45% 11.42% 11.26% 14.06% 13.82% GDP Pulp and Paper 6.58% 7.44% 7.50% 7.13% 5.53% 5.90% Sawmills - - - - 0.98% 1.44% Slaughter Houses 35.36% 37.91% 37.91% 38.45% 38.59% 39.29% Wool, cotton and leather 10.16% 9.54% 9.53% 8.73% 9.63% 11.68% Salaries Pulp and Paper 10.06% 11.04% 10.10% 9.82% 9.44% 8.42% Sawmills - - - - 1.11% 1.09% Slaughter Houses 38.07% 39.07% 39.81% 40.76% 42.54% 42.63% Wool, cotton and leather 14.66% 13.72% 13.09% 12.04% 11.88% 13.15% Source: Own estimates based on INE data. 51
  • 64. CHAPTER 4 METHODS, RESULTS, AND DISCUSSION The objective of the research was to evaluate the impact of the new forest sector on the Uruguayan economy by considering the costs and benefits of the policy that started with the Forestry Law 15939 in 1987. Different approaches to policy evaluation were discussed in Chapter 2. Considering the aim of the study and data availability, a CBA was chosen for this research. The analytical process included the following steps: (1) identifying the costs, benefits and investments associated with the policy; (2) quantifying them; and (3) evaluating the overall impact of the policy on the national economy. Different studies that attempted to measure the economic impact of the forest sector in Uruguay comparing the economy with and without the forest sector (Vázquez Platero 1996; Ramos & Cabrera 2001). They considered plantations as well as industrial activities, and both concluded that the impact will be positive. The limitations for the sector would be related with high costs in US$, especially fuel, and a low exchange rate which leads to a competitiveness loss. Vázquez Platero (1996) evaluated the forest policy estimating Fiscal Balance, employment, and costs (including plantations and sawmills), and compared the forestry activity with livestock. He uses market prices and includes subsidies and taxes. Investments were not considered and plantations from 1989 to 1994 were included. The results showed a Net Present Value (NPV) for the forest sector equals to 26 million US$, using a 10% discount rate. The internal rate of return (IRR) was 29.8%. Ramos and Cabrera (2001) using the same approach, evaluate the forest policy considering the plantations between 1989 and 1999. They estimated a 52
  • 65. NPV equals to 730 million US$, and an IRR equals to 38.7%. The total subsidies accrued between 1989 and 1999 were 29 million US$ which gives an average subsidy of 181 US$/ha. The Forest Division estimates the cost of the policy at 149 million US$ (Forest Division 2006). This analysis conducted by Forest Division considered tax exoneration and subsidies to plantations. It is estimated that 2.86 jobs were created by 1,000 ha planted. No studies that consider direct and indirect impacts of the forest sector in Uruguay have been done, however a study for BOTNIA, a Finnish Company that is building a pulp mill in Uruguay, estimated the impact of the new mill on the Uruguayan Economy using an I-O model (Metsa-Botnia 2004). The study used elements from C-B analysis and I-O models to describe two scenarios: one assessing the Uruguayan Economy without the mill project and the other assessing the Uruguayan Economy with the project. The study determined the main variables of the economy as well as the activities more related with the forest sector from 2004 to 2016. Direct and indirect impacts were measured. Direct impacts referred to “…the effects of the pulp mill investment and production on output and employment in those sectors, which are directly connected to the investment and production process”. The study estimated that the new pulp mill will increase the GDP by 1.4% by year 2016, and it will increase employment in 2200 new jobs. However, the impact on labor fluctuates according to which stage of the construction/ operation of the mill was considered. Although the trade balance is positive for the period considered, imports will increase at the beginning due to the mill construction. Indirect impacts referred to the impacts induced by increasing the activity in the forest sector that leads to increase consumption, income and employment. In addition, development impacts were summarized grouping them into: population and sociology, forest sector, regional economy and national 53
  • 66. economy. The study located the effects on three different state economies involved: Río Negro, Soriano and Paysandú. 4.1. Methods: CBA While CBA is generally similar to Cost-Effectiveness Analysis (CEA), there are several differences (Little & Mirrlees 1974; Nas 1996). First, taxes and subsidies are not included in the CBA because they are transfers between agents within the economy. Second, some benefits or costs resulting from the project’s operation do not appear as inputs or outputs in the ordinary accounts. Third, the discount rate used to evaluate the project is usually different from the market interest rate which might be used by a private firm. CBA is a very comprehensive procedure as it considers all potential gains and losses from a policy and it is particularly designed for the evaluation of public projects. The project outcome is always evaluated in CBA on the basis of public interest. Prices in CBA are corrected for market distortions. Costs and benefits are measured in terms of social utility gains and losses rather than cash or revenue flows, and external costs and benefits are invariably included in the evaluation (Nas 1996). CBA may be used to recommend policy actions, in which case it is applied prospectively (ex ante). It may also be used to evaluate policy performance. This approach is applied retrospectively (ex post) in this study. 4.1.1 Shadow Prices Shadow prices are defined as the increase in welfare resulting from any marginal change in the availability of commodities of factors of production (Squire & van der Tak 1975). “A shadow price is a measure of the welfare effects of marginal changes in the supply or demand 54
  • 67. of good or services” (Londero & Cervini 2003). As it was discussed in the previous chapter, CBA is based in welfare economics as is shadow prices theory (Londero & Cervini 2003). An important assumption in applied welfare economics is the use of economic shadow prices to appraise investments (Harou 1987). The analytical method uses a partial equilibrium approach: it is assumed that all prices other than that of the good being studied remain unchanged. Individual markets are studied in isolation, as if they were independent from other markets, reflecting the expectation that a price change in one market does not have significant repercussions in other markets (Londero & Cervini 2003). In this study this assumption is not too restrictive as forestry accounts only for small part of the national economy. One approach to estimate shadow prices is the efficiency analysis, in which equal weights are assigned to the marginal income changes, not considering differences among income levels. Another approach assigns the same valuation in welfare function to all that have the same income level. The most important authors in this group include UNIDO (1972), Little and Mirrlees (1974), and Squire and van der Tak (1975) (Londero & Cervini 2003). Little and Mirrlees (1974) proposed the “accounting prices” to conduct social cost-benefit analysis (Little & Mirrlees 1974). The UNIDO (1972) approach distinguishes between “weights” which are political value judgments, and the shadow prices derived from these judgments and technical information (Marglin 1977). UNIDO Guidelines propose a ”bottom-up” procedure in which the weights are generated by the formulation and evaluation procedure itself (Dasgupta et al. 1972). Squire and van der Tak (1975) proposed the use of distribution weights, which may be derived from an explicitly specified welfare function. The choice of a numeraire (unit of account) is basic to the determination of weights, insofar as the numeraire determines the absolute level of weights (Squire & van der Tak 1975). However, the conclusions would not change if the numeraire 55
  • 68. changes (Londero & Cervini 2003). In LMST, the value of public investment in border18 prices is expressed in relation to the value of consumption in border prices. In the Squire van der Tak system the value of public investment in border prices is expressed in relation to the value of consumption in domestic prices (Ray 1984). The technique of shadow prices consists of several steps. First, goods or services are classified in several ways according to how additional demand is met. According to Londero and Cervini, goods or services can be classified considering how additional demand is met: fixed supply goods, where it is met from withdrawals from other uses; produced goods, when it is met by additional production; and socially traded goods; when it is met by additional imports or reduced exports (Londero & Cervini 2003). According to Squire and van der Tak goods and services can be classified considering whether they are tradable or not tradable: goods imported or exported at the margin with infinite elasticity, goods imported or exported at the margin with less than infinite elasticity, goods not currently traded but ought to be traded, and goods not currently traded and ought not to be traded (Squire & van der Tak 1975). Second, several techniques can be used to estimate the shadow prices: input-output matrices (Londero & Cervini 2003), linear programming (Harou 1987), and welfare functions (Squire & van der Tak 1975). Shadow pricing of forestry projects was proposed in the 50s (Duerr and Vaux 1953) but started to be applied in the 70s (Watt 1973, FAO 1979, Harou 1981). The methodology has been developed for industrial investments (OECD 1968, UNIDO 1972, Squire and Van Der Tak 1976, UNIDO 1979) and agricultural projects (Gittinger 1983 in Harou 1987). In forestry projects, 18 Border prices are the prices of imports or exports of a commodity. Import prices usually are calculated as CIF prices (it is the price paid by the buyer, which includes: Cost, Insurance and Freight) and export prices are calculated as FOB prices (Free on Board) refers to the price received by the seller, who pays the transportation from the port of origin to the country. 56
  • 69. most outputs can be expressed in shadow prices. On the other hand, major input such as land, labor, and machinery may or may not be considered for shadow pricing. Whether or not it is actually worth shadow pricing a particular input depends on the magnitude of the estimated difference between its market price and its economic value19 (Gregersen & Contreras 1979; Harou 1987). There are some difficulties in estimating the shadow price of land by measuring the compensating variation of those affected by the change in the demand (supply) of land. First, the market price of land is determined by the present value of the associated rent. When moving to forestry from alternative uses it is necessary to estimate the effects of the change and to compute their future values. Second, the use of land could have significant external effects that could or could not impact other markets. These difficulties may be further related to different land qualities, different land locations, and the existence of taxes. Therefore, simplified approaches are used to estimate the shadow price of land (Londero & Cervini 2003). The appropriate measure of value for land is the highest net return that actually has been obtained from the land in the absence of the project (Gregersen & Contreras 1979; Londero & Cervini 2003). The objective in valuing labor is to arrive at a measure of the benefits foregone by employing labor in the project rather than in its next best alternative use. If labor is hired away from other productive activity and there is little unemployment in the project region, the value of labor in the other activity, or the market wage, provides an acceptable measure of opportunity cost for the economic analysis (Dasgupta et al. 1972; Little & Mirrlees 1974; Marglin 1977; Gregersen & Contreras 1979; Londero & Cervini 2003). The shadow price ratio (SPR) for labor is the ratio of its efficiency cost to its market cost: the reduction in production per unit of withdrawn value, multiplied by the amount of labor 19 In the text, the economic value is referred sometimes as “efficiency price” that is defined in the next pages. 57
  • 70. withdrawn (Londero & Cervini 2003). The difference between the efficiency salary and the market salary depends on the characteristic of the labor market. This topic has been extensively discussed in the literature (Dasgupta et al. 1972; Little & Mirrlees 1974; Squire & van der Tak 1975; Marglin 1977; Gregersen & Contreras 1979; Ray 1984; Harou 1987; Londero & Cervini 2003). Labor markets can be classified in different ways. According to Londero and Cervini (2003), (1) labor can be withdrawn from the production of traded goods; (2) dual urban markets can exist where there is a group of workers protected by labor legislation and/or represented by unions; and (3) rural urban migration can be caused by the new activity. The efficiency price of foreign exchange, like any other efficiency price, is defined as the sum of the compensating variations attributable to a unit change in the demand or supply of foreign exchange. Its SPR would be the ratio of that shadow price to the market price, the prevailing exchange rate (Londero & Cervini 2003). 4.1.2 Discount Rate Discounting is based on the idea that a given amount of resources available for use in the future is worth less than the same amount of resources available today. Through investments, one can transform resources that are currently available for use into a greater amount of resources in the future (Boardman 2001). The selection of the most appropriate rate of discount is related to the weights that the society should apply to consumption that occurs in future periods relative to the same amount of consumption in the current period. These weights represent how much of the current consumption the society is willing to give up now in order to obtain a given increase in future consumption. 58
  • 71. The choice of the social rate of return is based on the preferences of individuals in the society. In order to compare the costs and benefits associated with the policy they have to be weighted (Dasgupta et al. 1972). The weights ( w j ) are related to the discount rate (i) as follows: 1 wj = (1 + i ) n where: n= number of periods, i= discount rate These weights can be determined if the consumers’ preferences are known and markets do not have imperfections. In addition, there should not be any distortions such are taxes, risk, and transaction costs20 (Dasgupta et al. 1972; Boardman et al. 1997). An approach to measure transaction costs for Uruguay can be found in the report present by the World Bank where 175 countries are measured according several indicators that measure “…business regulation and the protection of property rights and their effect on businesses” (World Bank 2006) in order to establish the average period of time that takes starting a business in a country. Uruguay ranked 70 in 200521 and 64 in 2006. While the country has similar indicators to the region22 in some cases in other they are similar to OECD countries. 20 Transactions costs are defined as the costs incurred in the exchange process as transaction fees, gather information, move products (Chavas & Bouamra Mechemache 2006) 21 A complete report of the ranking can be found at: www.doingbusiness.org 22 Uruguay is included in Latin America and Caribbean. 59
  • 72. Regarding risk, the “country risk”23 is measured in Uruguay using an indicator called Uruguay Bond Index (UBI) that measures the spread between the returns on Uruguayan bonds and USA bonds. The UBI was 3,100 basis points during the 2002 and financial crisis, and it is 167 points today, reaching the lowest value in the last six years. According to Adamodar (Hagler 2007) Uruguay pays a 5.25% of risk premium while in the region Chile pays 1.05%, Brazil 3.75%, and Argentina 6.75%. Taxes in Uruguay are the main source of income for the Government. In the last two decades the taxes went from 62.5% of the Government income in 1990 to 71.3% in 2002; and taxes went from 17.8% of the GDP in 1990 to 22.1% in 2002. Compared with other countries, the share of taxes in the GDP is lower than developed countries but higher than the average in Latin America; compared with the region, Uruguay is between Argentina and Brazil (Lorenzo et al. 2005). The discount rate used in this project was 6%, as this is the social interest rate that is being used in the country to evaluate local development projects. 4.1.3 “Before and After” Approach versus “With and Without” Approach to CBA. The “With and Without” approach to analyze the effects of a policy is not the same as comparing the situation “Before and After” its implementation. The “Before and After” analysis compares the economy before the project is established with the economy after the project is established. The “Before and After” approach would not give information about the changes that may occur without the policy because it does not describes the same economy (Boardman 2001). 23 The country risk is defined as an index that reflects the risk that a country has for foreign investments. 60
  • 73. The “With and Without” analysis consists of estimating the net marginal benefit induced by the new policy (Harou 1987). In this project, the “With and Without” approach will be used. The “With” situation is defined as the situation where the Forestry Policy has been established in 1989; the “Without” situation is defined as the situation where the Forestry Policy has not been established. The “With” situation describes what happened in the economy after the Forestry Law. Therefore, plantations from 1989 onward were considered and, according to the management regimes, forest industries were considered from the first year when wood harvest was processed into manufactured wood products. The “Without” situation describes what would have happened to the economy if the Forestry Policy had not been established. It was assumed that if the lands were not used for forestry, they would have been used for livestock. Therefore, slaughter houses, tanning leather and wool industries would have been developed. 4.1.4 Sensitivity Analysis Uncertainty about the magnitude of the results is always present as there is uncertainty about the values we assign to the costs and benefits associated to the policy evaluated. Sensitivity analysis acknowledges this uncertainty and allows analysts to identify how sensitive the results are to the assumptions made. The analysis also helps to identify the key variables that affect the policy results. Three approaches can be taken in order to conduct a sensitivity analysis: partial sensitivity analysis, worst and best case analysis, and Monte Carlo simulations. Partial sensitivity analysis consists of estimating how net benefits change as one variable is changed and the others remain constant. Worst and best case analysis consists of changing some assumptions in order to identify the assumptions or a combination of assumptions that would change the analysis’ 61
  • 74. results. Monte Carlo sensitivity analysis consists of assigning probability distribution functions to some key assumptions and evaluating how changes of these assumptions would affect the net results (Boardman 2001). In this study, a partial sensitivity analysis will be conducted in order to identify the variables that most affect the results obtained. 4.1.5 Terminal Value Forestry investments are usually long-term investments; therefore, some corporations have unlimited planning horizons and anticipate managing their forests forever. To evaluate an asset that produces cash flows over an infinite time frame, it is necessary to have a procedure for calculating the present value of an infinite series of cash flows (Clutter et al. 1983). There are several indicators to evaluate forest investments, some based on yield criteria, and others on economic criteria (Clutter et al. 1983; Newman 1988; Perman et al. 2003). Those based on yield criteria are maximum single-rotation physical yield; maximum single-rotation annual yield, also called Mean Annual Increment (MAI); and Maximum Sustainable Yield (MSY). Those based on economic criteria are maximization of discounted net revenues from a single rotation; maximization of the discount net revenues from an infinite series of like rotations, also called soils expectation value (SEV) or bare land value (BLV); maximization of annual net revenues, also called forest rent; and internal rate of return (Clutter et al. 1983; Newman 1988; Perman et al. 2003). However, the discussion of the optimum rotation length for a forest stand has not been a simple issue24 (Newman 1988). Faustman’s Formula (1849) is the first rule used to evaluate the optimal rotation age, and was based in the maximization of discounted net revenues (Perman et 24 A very good discussion on the literature referring to Optimal Forest Rotation can be found in Newman (1988). 62
  • 75. al. 2003). Even though it is important, the formula contains simplified assumptions that have been changed in the following years, allowing the development of a great number of theories and practices (Newman 1988). Newman discusses six criteria for an optimal rotation age: Maximum Gross Yield, Maximum Sustained Yield, Present Net Worth, Soil Rent, Forest Rent, and Internal Rate of Return (Newman 1988). In this study, BLV criterion was used to estimate the terminal value of the plantations’ investments and the land value in order to compare it with land market prices. BLV, associated with a given rotation age, is the present value of the net returns from all the rotations in the continuing series. This is the present value of all cash flows produced by an infinite series of rotations using a rotation age of t years (Clutter et al. 1983). Cash flows for continuing series of plantations for each alternative were calculated, and the present value of each alternative was maximized. The maximum present value is accomplished with the rotation age with maximum BLV, and this rotation age is called the optimum economic rotation (Clutter et al. 1983). BLV was used because it estimates the net present value of the land in infinite rotations and it is a good approach of the opportunity cost of land. 4.2. Data and Assumptions Costs, investments and benefits25 were estimated from primary and secondary information. Primary information was obtained from a survey conducted in Uruguay in July 200626. Secondary information was obtained from the Forest Division (DF), the Agricultural Planning and Policy Office (OPYPA), the Agricultural Statistics Division (DIEA), the Forest 25 The tables with the assumptions for the period of analysis are presented in Appendix III. 26 The questionnaire and the Survey’s results are presented in Appendices I and II. 63
  • 76. Producers Society (SPF), the National Institute of Statistics (INE), the Central Bank of Uruguay (BCU), the Association of Industries of Uruguay (CIU), the Agricultural and Livestock Plan Office (IPA), and the National Colonization Institute (INC). In addition, estimates on plantations and sawmills data were taken from two previous studies: Vázquez Platero (1996) and Ramos and Cabrera (2001). Taxes estimates were obtained from Ramos and Cabrera (2001). Growth rates and management plans were compared with those obtained from the survey and with SPF information. Market prices were converted to shadow prices according to two studies: Fernández Gaeta (1995) and Pereyra (2004). Both studies considered the income as numeraire and defined the SPR as: spri = spi/pi where: spri =shadow price ratio of the good i, spi = shadow price of good i, pi = market price of good i From 1989 to 2001, Fernández Gaeta (Fernandez Gaeta 1995) estimates for 1995 were used. From 2001 to 2005, Pereyra estimates from 2004 (Pereyra 2004) were used because the major change in the economy occurred in 2002 after the devaluation of the Uruguayan currency and Pereyra estimates reflected those changes. The first study provided estimates of all the shadow prices of the economy except for imports; while the second provided estimates for only a few items related to infrastructure projects. 64
  • 77. Labor SPR has been less than one in the period 1989-2005. Estimates for 1995 showed that the SPR for skilled labor was 0.98 and for non-skilled and semi-skilled labor was 0.8, meaning that the market wage for skilled labor was similar to the opportunity cost of it. On the other hand, the market wage for non-skilled and semi-skilled labor was higher than its opportunity costs. Labor SPR estimates for 2004 showed that the SPR for skilled labor had not changed significantly, but the SPR for non-skilled and semi-skilled labor had dropped to 0.6 (Table 17). These results reflect the increase in the unemployment rate which went from 7% in 1989 to 12% in 2005 (Table 18). The unemployment rate estimates includes only cities with more than 5,000 habitants, therefore the rural unemployment was not included. However, the analysis of the provinces where plantations were established, indicate that the unemployment has decreased. Therefore the question: What does the rest of the economy ultimately lose when a person joins the project? becomes crucial for the analysis of the situation in Uruguay where two opposite phenomena occur. On one hand, a high level of unemployment in the cities and lower in rural areas, and a high demand for semi-skilled labor in the new industries that in some cases has been difficult to meet. The states of Río Negro and Tacuarembó are examples of the changes in the opportunity cost of semi-skilled and skilled labor. In Río Negro, Botnia is constructing a pulp mill and the province state did not have enough labor available to meet the needs. In Tacuarembó, Colonvade27 and Urupanel28 are building plywood facilities and the demand semi- skilled and skilled labor has also been growing and attracting labor from other states. In those cases, the companies started training programs and they are encouraging technical teaching institutes to adapt their programs to the new industries requirements. 27 Colonvade is a company with partnership between Weyerhaeuser and Global Partners with facilities located in Tacuarembó and Rivera. 28 Urupanel is a Chilean company with facilities located in Tacuarembó. 65
  • 78. Therefore, despite the high level of unemployment in the Uruguayan economy, the opportunity cost of labor in the forest sector is not zero because some resources are being withdrawn from other sectors. One of the most important effects of the new Forestry Law was the increase in land prices. As the demand for land increased, prices rose. Average prices presented by the DIEA which calculates the price in US$/ha as an average of the transactions in the period, do not reflect the prices of the transactions accurately because data from INC shows that land prices are higher than those reported by DIEA. The INC shows that, during the first semester of 2006, the average price land was 1354.30 US$/ha; if this average is standardized according to productivity indexes, it was 1465.06 US$/ha CONEAT 100 (Colonization National Institute 2006). In 1995, Fernández Gaeta estimated that the SPR for land was 1.19, meaning that the market prices under value the land. Fernández Gaeta estimated the land price considering the net present value of the most important outputs for year 1992, when the agricultural and livestock sector had a different structure. Based on the CGA information, he assumed that the total area was distributed as follows: 76.9% livestock, 7.7% dairy production, 3.9% rice and 11.5% other cereals production. The sector structure was different from today’s structure, where the forest sector has small participation. To fill this lack of information, BLV for land were estimated. The BLV were divided into three activities: land designated for eucalyptus plantations, land designated for pine plantations, and land designated for livestock. As it was discussed in Chapter 3, land designated for forestry has a site productivity index of 69 in average; therefore the BLV was estimated for these sites. 66
  • 79. The results show that the market prices are lower than shadow prices estimated (Table 19). The SPR showed that for forestlands designated for eucalyptus it is 1.20, for forestlands designated for pine is 1.42 and for lands designated for livestock is 1.25. These results show the BLV in 2005, but a complete series could not be estimated. As the changes have been important in the period of analysis, 1989-2005, the opportunity cost of the land might have been changing. Therefore for the CBA, market prices were used and a sensitivity analysis was conducted. Exports and imports values were corrected by the foreign exchange SPR (SPRf). Considering the 1993 Uruguay’s trade structure, the 1993 Trade Commercial Balance and the equilibrium and observed exchange rate, Fernández Gaeta estimated a SPRf of 1.31. Pereyra, using the same approach but including 2003 data, estimated SPRf of 1.01 (Pereyra 2004). SPRf = (Eq. ER/Obs. ER) * [(Imports*(1+Taxes and Tariffs) + Exports (1+Subsidies)]/(Imports +Exports) where: Eq. ER=Equilibrium Exchange Rate, Obs. ER= Observed Exchange Rate The exchange rate he used was 30 Uruguayan Pesos per US$ ($U/US$), and currently the ER is 25 $U/US$, then the shadow price does not reflect the current currency value but it is the most updated version of shadow prices estimation. The analysis covered the period from 1989 through 2005, in order to consider the plantations that were established as a result of the Forestry Law 15939. 67
  • 80. Two indicators were calculated to determine the value of the project for the society: NPV, using a 6% discount rate, and IRR. Both were calculated at year 1989. 4.2.1 Production 4.2.1.1. Forest Management Plans Several forest management plans have been designed in the past decades. Vázquez Platero (1996) assumed a management plan consisting of two prunings, four thinnings and final harvest for pine for saw timber; two prunings, two thinnings and final harvest for eucalyptus for sawtimber; and a final at year eight for eucalyptus for pulpwood (Vázquez Platero 1996). Ramos and Cabrera (2001) proposed six different models and six different management plans according to wood destination and regions. Eucalyptus management plans included one thinning and the final harvest if the wood was grown for pulp, or two thinnings and the final harvest if the wood was grown for saw timber. Pine plantations management plans included two or three thinnings, and a final harvest at age 22 or 24. Pine plantations were grown for saw timber (saw logs, plywood logs, sawn wood).In the survey conducted in Uruguay, rotation ages varied according to the final product of the company. Therefore, in Pine grown for saw timber was managed on rotations 22 to 25 year long. On the other hand, information on rotation ages for eucalyptus differed among plantations: plantations grown for saw timber had rotation ages from 15 to 20 years, and plantations grown for pulpwood had rotation ages around 10 years. This study assumed that 70% of the eucalyptus plantation area was grown for pulp and 30% for saw timber. The rotation age for pulp was 9 years and for saw timber 18 years with two intermediate thinnings, at 9 and 13. Both thinnings produced pulpwood. The assumptions are presented in Table 21 and volume estimations are based on Methol’s model (Methol 2003). For 68
  • 81. pine it was assumed that 100% of the plantations are grown for saw timber. The rotation age was 22 years with three intermediate thinnings, at years 4, 12 and 18, and two prunings. The assumptions are shown in Table 21 and were based on Ramos and Cabrera model for Pine in the North29 (Ramos & Cabrera 2001). 4.2.1.2. Growth rates Growth rates have been adjusted after first plantations were established. Vázquez Platero (1996), according to producers, estimated growth rates ranging from 22 to 36 cubic cu m/yr/ha on average30 for eucalyptus and 17 to 26 m3/yr/ha for pine according to the location. Ramos and Cabrera (2001) estimated different growth rates by location, products and species. For eucalyptus plantations grown for saw timber, MAI varies from 28 to 32 m3/yr/ha, and for pulp from 18 to 23 m3/year. For pine plantations MAI can be from 19 to 24 m3/yr/ha. According to the survey conducted in Uruguay, growth rates vary from 20 m3/yr/ha for Pine to 20 to 25 m3/yr/ha for eucalyptus with an average of 22 m3/yr/ha. In this research the following growth rates were assumed: 24 m3/yr/ha for Pine, and 30 m3/yr/ha for eucalyptus. 4.2.2 Inputs 4.2.2.1. Production Costs 4.2.2.1.1. Plantations Plantation costs vary with management plans and species. Management plans have been changing since expertise was gained in the field. Before the Forestry Law 15939 was established, 29 In Ramos and Cabrera study, these assumptions correspond to Model 2. 30 This is the Mean Annual Increment (MAI) which designs the average production per year. 69
  • 82. plantations were oriented towards fuel wood or saw timber production for local companies, with some exceptions. Plantation costs were based on Ramos and Cabrera estimates (Ramos & Cabrera 2001). They include fencing, soil preparation, ant control, fertilization, plants, plantation, and other minor costs. Each item includes the labor required for the activity, and only imported items were included. On average, labor costs are 16% of plantations costs meanwhile imports account for 10%. Shadow prices were assigned according to the share of each component in total costs; taxes were not considered (Table 22). 4.2.2.1.2. Pruning and Thinning The most important component in these activities is labor. Labor used varies according to the management plan: pruning and thinning ages. In this study, it was assumed that eucalyptus plantations grown for pulp are not pruned or thinned; eucalyptus plantations growth for saw timber are thinned at year 9; and pine plantations growth for saw timber are pruned at years 4, 6 and 8 and thinned at years 4, 12 and 18. It was assumed a cost of 60 US$/ha for pruning and 8 US$/ha for thinning (Table 23). 4.2.2.1.3. Harvesting For pulp, labor requirements were estimated in 0.289 daily wages/ m3 for pulp and 0.222 daily wages/ m3 for saw timber according to Ramos and Cabrera based on SPF information (Ramos & Cabrera 2001). The costs structure for final harvest is as follows: 55% labor, 30% fuel, and the other costs are 15% of the total cost. These costs were corrected using shadow prices, which where assigned according to the weight of each item in the total cost. 70
  • 83. 4.2.2.1.4. Industry For the case with project, sawmills were included in the analysis. Costs in thousand US$/ m3 of wood processed were obtained from Ramos and Cabrera based on INE data, from 1999 the coefficients were considered constant. Wood manufacturing costs, included wood, were estimated at 119 US$/ m3 of wood processed in 1989 and in 67 US$/ m3 from 1999. Several factors could explain this drop: a decrease in equipment maintenance after 1993 and the disappearance of the cost of fuel wood in the last three years. On the other hand, salary costs remained stable in US$ despite increasing 70 to 80% in $U. Wood processed was obtained from the eucalyptus and pine models described above. For the case without the project, slaughter houses, wool and leather industries were considered. The productivity indexes for these industries were considered from Ramos and Cabrera between 1989 and 1999, from IPA between 2000 and 2005, and thereafter assumed constant until 2010. These costs were corrected using the same criteria as in the previous item (Table 24). 4.2.2.1.5. Transportation Transportation costs were based on figures provided by Ramos and Cabrera (2001) by region, species and product. Costs were estimated by tons and divided into pulp and saw timber products. Harvested wood could be destined for either the mill or the seaport. Transportation costs included costs from the plantation to the mill and from the mill to the final destination (Table 25). Wood designated for final consumption either in the local markets or abroad, had other transportation costs associated. Then, transportation costs were first calculated for the distance between the plantation and the mills. Costs from the mill to the final destination were assigned to the industry. 71
  • 84. For the case without the project, the livestock that would have been transported if forestland were used for livestock production was estimated. 4.2.2.1.6. Export Costs Export costs include labor costs for activities in the port, and these costs were based on Ramos and Cabrera estimates. They assumed that 0.022 daily wages/day/m3 was needed to prepare wood for export from the port. 4.2.3 Investments 4.2.3.1. Plantations Investments in plantations were calculated as the total area declared in the Forest Division multiplied by the land price of the same year. Land price series were taken from DIEA and a sensitivity analysis was conducted to address the differences between market and shadow prices (Table 26). 4.2.3.2. Industry Investments in the industry were based on the survey data, and only sawmills were considered because information regarding pulp mill investments was not available. According to the survey, 85% of the investments in equipment in the industry are imported, and the companies have tax exonerations for imports to the industry. Therefore, it was assumed that 85% of the investments were imported and that the information did not include taxes. 72
  • 85. 4.2.4 Outputs Wood exports are the output considered in the analysis as they represent income generated in the country. For the case with project, total wood exports were estimated according to the level of production, and the value was estimated considering average stumpage prices obtained from the Forest Division. In the model, the wood can be used to produce either pulp or saw timber. As of 2006, there were not pulp mills in the country; therefore, it was assumed that until that year all wood for pulp was exported. For the situation without project, exports from alternative activities were estimated based on production levels and producers prices, as most of the production is destined for exports (Ramos & Cabrera 2001). To estimate the percentage of the production exported each year, CIU estimations and IPA information were used. Between 1988 and 1998, CIU estimated that leather and wool were sub-sectors that exported more than 50% of their production, while slaughter houses exported from 11% to 50% of their production. The slaughter houses accounted for most of the total value of the alternative products considered here, it was assumed that between 1989 and 2000 50% of the total production was exported. In 2001, the foot-and-mouth disease caused beef exports to drop until 2002. Based on IPA data, for 2001 it was assumed that 40% of the production was exported as the outbreak began in October of that year; for 2002 and 2003 it was assumed that 30% of the production was exported; and for 2004 and 2005 it was assumed that 60% of the production. From 1999 to 2005, leather and wool industries decreased their exports and slaughter houses increased them, becoming one of the most important sectors in the total exports of the country. 73
  • 86. 4.3. Results The results show that the forest sector compared with an alternative production, livestock, had a net positive impact on the Uruguayan economy in the period 1989-2005. The NPV for the forest sector compared with livestock in year 1989 equals 630.2 million US$, using a 6% discount rate. The IRR for the forest sector was 36.4% (Table 27). Since the project’s products are mostly exported, all economic project’s outputs are included. On the other hand, only inputs including imported items and labor are included. In addition, SPRs are lower than one for inputs and equal or higher to one for outputs. Therefore the results are more positive than evaluating the policy at market prices. The alternative industries costs savings were high. The livestock production is an annual activity, and therefore costs associated with the industry will occur every year. On the other hand, forestry is a periodic activity and industry costs will start when the first wood harvested is processed. In the model, forest industries started to operate 9 years after the plantations were established; as a result, there is a 9-year period where there no forestry industry costs. Sensitivity analyses were conducted on wood prices, yields, transportation costs, land prices and thinning, administration and harvesting costs. The results are presented as variations of NPV and IRR in percentage. Wood markets are a key factor for the analysis as its results are sensitive to changes in wood prices. Results are more sensitive to changes in pulpwood prices than in saw timber prices (Table 28). These results can be explained by the fact that pulpwood accounts for most of wood output. Between 1989 and 2005 a total of 72.2 million of cum of pulpwood were produced versus 22.7 million of cum of sawn wood. Since the prices considered were FOB Montevideo, freight costs to final destinations were not included. According to the industries’ survey, the oceanic freight costs increased 60% 74
  • 87. between 2002 and 2006. It is expected that wood consumption would continue to rise, but the real price of products will increase slightly. The biggest effect would be on trade rather than on production, with a shift on trade toward processed products (Prestemon et al. 2003). This increasing demand represents an opportunity to Uruguayan products; however, an analysis of price trends and markets would be important to obtain benefits. The results are very sensitive to changes in yields: if both plantations yields decreased 20%, the IRR would decrease more than 7% and the NPV would decrease nearly 100%. A reduction in eucalyptus yields has more impact on NPV and IRR than a reduction in pine yields. This result can be explained by the different areas covered by pine and eucalyptus. Approximately 75% of the area is covered with eucalyptus and the rest by pine. With most land owned by private investors, the investors’ management decisions are the key factor influencing the provision of forest benefits to the society. The idea that private forest management is less socially responsible and characterized by lower environmental standards has proved to be not always true; forest certification and private management plans analysis are two elements that support this outcome (Siry et al. 2005). Transportation costs at the beginning of the project represent a saving in costs because there is no wood transported. However, after wood processing begins, these costs will be included. A decrease or increase in transportation costs rangin from 10 to 20%, change the IRR less than 1% point, meanwhile the NPV will increase or decrease by 3% when the costs vary by 20% (Table 31). This result does not conform with the private investors’ view that transportation is an important factor in their production operations. Results were very sensitive to changes in land prices, a drop of 20% in land prices, will result in a 21% increase in the IRR and a 9.5% in the NPV. On the other hand, a 20% increase 75
  • 88. will lower the IRR by 8% and the NPV by 11% (Table 32). The IRR is not very sensitive to changes in management costs: a change of 10% in thinning, harvesting and management costs changes the IRR by less than 1% (Table 33). Results show that land prices are still lower than shadow prices. If the demand for land was driven by timber prices, an analysis of the products and markets where Uruguay plans to export would be necessary. Even though the land price in Uruguay has increased in the last thirty years, historically, it has been lower than the land prices in Argentina and Brazil. Considering the same quality land, average prices per hectare in Argentina and Brazil have been higher than the Uruguay’s average land price between 1994 and 2003 (Sáder Neffa 2004). Current land prices in Uruguay are similar to land prices in Brazil and in Argentina. Lower land price can be considered as another factor attracting foreign investors to the Uruguayan forest sector. Forestry generally provides more jobs than the livestock on the same land base. Considering the primary production costs in both alternatives, forestry costs are higher. Labour accounts for much of the costs; therefore, the forest activity has a positive impact on employment. Results show that, on average, labor costs in US$/ha in forest plantations were four times higher than labor costs in livestock activities. If pruning, thinning, management, administration, and harvesting costs are added, labor costs are twenty times higher than those in livestock activities. These results are consistent with those estimated by the Forest Division and Ramos and Cabrera (Ramos & Cabrera 2001; San Roman 2005). The Forest Division estimated that the employment generated in the forest sector is higher than the employment generated in the livestock sector. First, they considered only the permanent employees in plantations and the results were that 2 to 9 jobs were created per 1,000 ha. Second, they DIEA adjusted these results considering the labor hired by third parties, and they estimated that the sector generates 76
  • 89. 7 jobs/ 1,000 ha. Third, based on CGA 2000 results, DF estimated that the forest sector generated 7.98 jobs/1,000 ha, that is, four times the employment generated in the livestock sector (DIEA estimates that the livestock activity generates 1.96 to 2.65 jobs/1,000 ha). The Forest Division estimates salaries in plantations at 130% of the minimum national wage. In addition, salaries paid in the forest sector are higher than those paid in the livestock sector. Finally non-market benefits were not included in the evaluation as this assessment exceeded the objectives of this research. Other benefits associated with the forests are carbon storage, recreational, bird watching, hiking, and wildlife. In addition, forests decrease erosion, diminish urban migration, and promote industrial development. These impacts are difficult to quantify but they will increase the social net return of the policy. One underlying objective of forest management is maintaining a variety and valuable supply of forest products while at the same time ensuring that production and harvesting are sustainable in the long run and do not compromise the consumption of generations. Uruguay has also attempted to evaluate the alternative use of forests31. The country ratified the Kyoto Protocol in 2001, and has been promoting participation in the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) for forestry and agricultural projects. The Environmental 31 Some of the activities and publications regarding CS developed by the Uruguayan Government include: - Host Country approval for CDM projects in Uruguay Applications on sustainability Tool Assessment. August 2003. - Research to support the appliance to CDM for the Kyoto Protocol for Uruguay. May 2002. MVOTMA. - Meeting Climate Change: CDM application in Uruguay. Montevideo, 24- 25 April 2003. - National Capacity Proposal No 15. 77
  • 90. Ministry (MVOTMA) is in charge of the research and activities related to the evaluation of CDM projects 32. In addition, the Agricultural and Livestock Ministry (MGAP) established an office to analyze the possibilities of producing alternative energy from biomass (Methol 2004; Souto & Methol 2005). The Agricultural Projects of Climate Change Unit (UPACC) was established in February 2001and started their activities in 200433. The Forest Division integrates the UPCC along with other Divisions. Currently the Forest Division is analyzing the feasibility of horse and cattle breeding along with forest activities (Seminar: Opinions on the Forest Policy – Forest Division Director Andrés Berterreche- July 20 2006). This alternative has been part of a strategy of the new government to combine the two most important activities in the country. Most of the companies have been developing agroforestry projects which minimize fire risk because animal grazing reduces fuel loads in forests (COFUSA 2006). The most important forest companies have programs to preserve native flora and fauna in their forests. Ence has two conservation areas: M’Bopicuá and Santo Domingo (Ence 2006). M’Bopicuá Conservation Area is located on the banks of the Uruguay River in Río Negro, covering 150 ha. It comprises “…the breeding station, the Nature Trail for appreciating native flora and an area of special historic interest. The aim is to preserve species of native flora and fauna, reproduce certain species that are in danger of extinction and then re-introduce them back into their natural habitat and contribute to environmental education in schools in the area”. The Santo Domingo conservation area of 7,000 ha is located in Paysandú. Since 1996 plans have 32 www.cambioclimatico.gub.uy 33 Law 17296. 78
  • 91. been developed for preserving palm trees, wetlands and native fauna. This is the first developed wetland restoration project in the country. Native species threatened with extinction (coati and caiman) have been reintroduced to this area. A project for improving the numbers of the natural population of caimans is also being developed. 79
  • 92. Table 17. Shadow Prices Relations for Uruguay Category 1995 2004 Non-skilled and semi-skilled labor 0.8 0.6 Qualified labor 0.8 1 Foreign Exchange 1.31 1.01 Land 1.19 - Ground transportation 0.77 0.77 Investments 0.98 0.77 Sources: Fernández Gaeta (1995), Pereyra (2004). 80
  • 93. Table 18. Unemployment Rate in Uruguay 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Total (Urban) 8 9 9 9 8 9 10 12 11 10 11 14 15 17 17 13 12 Montevideo 9 9 9 9 8 9 11 12 12 10 12 14 16 17 17 13 12 Provinces 7 8 9 9 8 9 10 11 11 10 11 13 15 17 17 13 13 Artigas 19 12 14 14 15 20 13 16 15 13 13 17 20 15 17 13 15 Canelones 9 9 8 9 9 10 9 13 14 12 12 14 15 19 21 16 14 Cerro Largo 7 7 9 8 7 7 8 10 12 10 12 11 12 14 10 5 9 Colonia 5 6 10 12 8 8 8 9 11 8 14 16 20 20 18 12 10 Durazno 9 8 8 3 5 6 11 10 13 8 17 22 24 25 22 14 13 Flores 8 5 10 5 6 4 10 8 15 14 19 20 16 18 16 14 17 Florida 9 10 10 9 6 8 10 10 15 11 11 15 21 23 22 19 16 Lavalleja 9 10 11 11 8 9 7 9 9 9 7 11 13 17 16 10 16 Maldonado 4 8 8 9 7 9 12 13 13 8 11 17 20 24 23 20 18 Paysandú 7 7 8 10 7 8 9 12 9 9 9 11 13 13 19 16 13 Río Negro 13 11 17 9 11 12 16 26 13 13 12 6 9 6 7 4 8 Rivera 6 6 11 11 10 16 13 11 7 6 3 8 6 6 3 4 4 Rocha 9 7 7 8 7 9 13 10 12 8 10 12 16 18 18 13 14 Salto 5 9 5 5 5 4 3 2 1 1 4 2 6 8 7 6 12 San José 4 2 6 6 7 8 8 9 6 10 9 10 12 14 12 10 13 Soriano 6 7 10 10 10 6 10 12 11 15 14 18 19 21 18 17 12 Tacuarembó 8 8 9 9 9 10 11 11 12 10 8 15 14 17 13 11 8 Treinta y Tres 5 5 13 11 14 13 17 14 15 13 14 13 17 17 25 15 18 Note: The provinces marked in bold are the provinces with higher forest area. Source: National Institute of Statistics (2006). 81
  • 94. Table 19. Uruguay BLV (2005) Market Prices US$/ha Pine 1,028 Eucalyptus 1,493 Livestock 420 Shadow Prices US$/ha Pine 1,460 Eucalyptus 1,785 Livestock 523 Source: Own estimates. Table 20. Eucalyptus Growth, Yields and Management Assumptions Pulp (70% area) Growth rate (m3/ha/year) 30 Rotation age (years) 9 Initial Density (trees/ha) 1,000 Final Density (trees/ha) 800 Extraction (m3/ha) 250 Saw timber (30% area) Growth rate (m3/ha/year) 30 Rotation age (years) 18 Extraction (m3/ha) m3/ha Product Year 1st Thinning 50 Pulp 9 2nd Thinning 140 Pulp 13 Final Harvest 340 Saw timber 18 Source: Own estimates based on Methol (2001) 82
  • 95. Table 21. Pine Growth, Yields and Management Assumptions Saw timber Growth rate (m3/ha/year) 24 Rotation age (years) 22 Initial Density (trees/ha) 1,000 - 1st Thinning Density 1,000 600 2nd Thinning Density 600 400 3rd Thinning Density 400 200 Final Density (trees/ha) 200 0 Saw Fuel No Extraction m3/ha Year timber wood Value 1st Thinning 11 4 0% 0% 100% 2nd Thinning 93 12 50% 50% 0% 3rd Thinning 188 18 70% 30% 0% Final Harvest 255 22 85% 15% 0% Source: Ramos and Cabrera (2001) 83
  • 96. Table 22. Plantation Costs Structure Items Share of Total Costs Taxes % Fences 9% Posts 47% Exonerated Wire 30% Exonerated Labor 24% BPS 11.5% Soil Preparation 16% Fuel 56% IMESI 34% Lubricants 8% IMESI 26% Machinery 25% Exonerated Labor 11% BPS 12% Ants control 3% Inputs 55% IVA 17% Labor 45% BPS 12% Fertilization 6% Inputs 61% Exonerated Labor 39% BPS 12% Plants 40% IVA pending Plantation Labor 7% BPS 12% Reposition 9% Plants 85% IVA pending Labor 15% BPS 12% Miscellaneous 9% IVA Basic 17% Source: Adapted from Ramos and Cabrera (2001) 84
  • 97. Table 23. Forest Production Costs (2005) Export Costs 3 Total Labor Costs/volume of wood exported (1,000 US$/1,000 m ) 0.38 Pruning (1,000 US$/ha) 0.060 Thinning (1,000 US$/ha) 0.008 Administration and Management Ants Control (1,000 US$/ha) 0.007 Year 1 Wage days/ha 1.25 1 day wage (1,000 US$) 0.015 Years 1 and 2 Paths Daily wages/ha 0.3 Daily wage (1,000 US$) 0.015 Annual Administration Daily wages/ha 3 Harvest Sawn Pulp wood Daily wages (# daily wages/m3) 0.289 0.222 Salaries US$ (130% minimum national wage ) 1 day salary (1,000 US$) 0.015385 Cost Structure Labor 55% Fuel 30% Rest 15% Total Costs 100% Source: Own estimations based on Ramos and Cabrera (2001). 85
  • 98. Table 24. Industrial Costs Structure (2005) Beef Wool Leather Wood Total Costs 100% 99% 100% 100% Inputs 65% 44% 42% 77% Production Costs 35% 54% 58% 23% Imports and Labor as percentage of total costs Imports Labor Wood 8% 35% Leather 3% 15% Slaughter Houses 4% 12% Wool 3% 15% Sources: Own estimates based on Ramos and Cabrera (2001) and INE. Table 25. Transportation Costs Coefficients Wood Transportation Coefficients Pulpwood transportation/Pulpwood extracted 0.90 Sawn wood transportation/Sawn wood extracted 0.80 Total Costs US$/ tons 9 Saw timber transported/Saw timber 0.45 Livestock Transportation Transportation Costs (1,000 US$/ha) 0.0009 1989 Livestock production (kg/ha) 43 Total Area 6575 Livestock production total (tons) 285 Livestock production (ton/ha) 0.043 # trips (total tons/13 tons) 22 Transportation fees (US$/km-1 trip=13 tons) 1.15 US$/km/ton 0.08 Km/trip 250 Source: Own estimations based on Ramos and Cabrera (2001). 86
  • 99. Table 26. Forest Land Prices vs. Livestock Land Prices US$/ha Year Average Forest Livestock Difference 1999 530 617 486 132 2000 473 624 415 209 2001 421 565 349 217 2002 362 460 283 177 2003 434 584 385 199 2004 689 871 599 271 2005 807 1015 692 323 Source: DIEA based on INC 87
  • 100. Table 27. Cost Benefit Analysis Results 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 INPUTS 0.3 0.3 1.0 1.5 2.4 2.6 3.3 3.0 3.7 13.2 13.0 24.5 42.6 55.9 69.4 100.6 116.6 Production Costs 0.3 0.3 1.0 1.6 2.4 2.7 3.5 3.2 4.0 8.9 8.2 12.6 19.7 10.2 22.1 41.3 59.3 Plantations 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.4 0.7 0.5 -0.2 -1.2 -1.4 -3.2 -1.9 -2.1 -2.7 Nurseries 0.2 0.2 0.6 1.0 2.0 2.2 2.7 2.7 3.2 3.4 1.9 2.2 1.9 0.5 0.8 1.6 2.6 Pruning and Thinning 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.8 1.9 2.2 2.7 2.9 Management and Adm 0.2 0.3 1.0 1.4 2.1 2.7 3.6 3.7 4.4 5.3 5.0 4.3 3.4 0.7 1.1 2.4 5.8 Harvesting 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 4.3 4.5 10.6 18.7 12.3 22.0 39.8 55.0 Industry 0.0 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 -1.0 -1.2 -1.5 -1.5 -1.6 -1.8 -1.5 -1.3 -1.5 -1.6 Transportation 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 -0.1 -0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.3 4.1 4.6 11.5 22.1 43.7 45.3 56.7 54.8 Export Costs 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.8 1.9 2.0 2.6 2.5 INVESTMENTS 0.0 0.9 2.0 3.1 5.1 5.4 20.8 7.1 8.9 16.6 12.5 16.2 14.9 5.2 16.1 20.9 55.7 Plantations 0.0 0.9 2.0 3.1 5.1 5.4 7.1 7.1 8.9 16.6 12.5 16.2 14.9 5.2 5.5 10.3 13.8 Industry 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 13.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 10.6 10.6 41.9 OUTPUTS -0.2 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -1.0 -1.0 -1.8 -1.8 -2.4 23.4 31.1 60.6 114.7 187.4 214.5 274.8 297.1 Exports -0.2 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -1.0 -1.0 -1.8 -1.8 -2.4 23.4 31.1 60.6 114.7 187.4 214.5 274.8 297.1 Terminal Value 1164.5 CASH FLOW -0.4 -1.4 -3.4 -5.2 -8.4 -8.9 -26.0 -11.9 -15.0 -6.3 5.6 19.9 57.2 126.3 129.0 153.3 1289.3 IRR 36.4% NPV (6%) mill US$ 1989 630.2 88
  • 101. Table 28. Sensitivity Analysis: Wood Prices IRR Pulpwood Pulpwood -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -10% 33.38% 34.81% 36.17% 37.46% 38.69% -10% -3.01% -1.58% -0.22% 1.07% 2.30% Saw timber Saw timber 0% 33.63% 35.05% 36.39% 37.67% 38.89% 0% -2.76% -1.34% 0.00% 1.28% 2.50% 10% 33.88% 35.28% 36.61% 37.88% 39.09% 10% -2.51% -1.11% 0.22% 1.49% 2.70% 20% 34.13% 35.52% 36.83% 38.09% 39.28% 20% -2.26% -0.87% 0.44% 1.70% 2.89% NPV Pulpwood Pulpwood -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -10% 564,972 579,189 621,762 664,334 706,907 -10% -11.55% -8.81% -1.36% 5.14% 10.85% Saw timber Saw timber 0% 545,061 587,663 630,206 672,778 715,350 0% -15.62% -7.24% 0.00% 6.33% 11.90% 10% 553,505 596,077 638,649 681,222 723,794 10% -13.86% -5.73% 1.32% 7.49% 12.93% 20% 561,948 604,521 647,093 689,666 732,238 20% -12.15% -4.25% 2.61% 8.62% 13.93% Table 29. Sensitivity Analysis: Yields IRR Pine Pine -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% 29.02% 29.70% 30.35% 30.97% 31.57% -20% -7.37% -6.69% -6.04% -5.42% -4.82% Eucalyptus Eucalyptus -10% 32.67% 33.19% 33.70% 34.19% 34.66% -10% -3.72% -3.20% -2.69% -2.20% -1.73% 0% 35.55% 35.98% 36.39% 36.80% 37.19% 0% -0.84% -0.41% 0.00% 0.41% 0.80% 10% 37.94% 38.30% 38.66% 39.00% 39.34% 10% 1.55% 1.91% 2.27% 2.61% 2.95% 20% 40.00% 40.31% 40.62% 40.92% 41.21% 20% 3.61% 3.92% 4.23% 4.53% 4.82% NPV Pine Pine -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% 321,701 343,506 365,312 387,117 408,922 -20% -95.90% -83.46% -72.51% -62.79% -54.11% Eucalyptus Eucalyptus -10% 454,148 475,953 497,759 519,564 541,369 -10% -38.77% -32.41% -26.61% -21.30% -16.41% 0% 586,595 608,400 630,206 652,011 673,816 0% -7.43% -3.58% 0.00% 3.34% 6.47% 10% 719,042 740,847 762,653 784,458 806,264 10% 12.35% 14.93% 17.37% 19.66% 21.84% 20% 851,489 873,294 895,100 916,905 938,711 20% 25.99% 27.84% 29.59% 31.27% 32.86% 89
  • 102. Table 30. Sensitivity Analysis: Transportation Costs IRR Wood Wood -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% 36.96% 36.66% 36.35% 36.05% 35.73% -20% 0.26% -0.04% -0.35% -0.65% -0.97% Livestock Livestock -10% 36.98% 36.68% 36.37% 36.07% 35.75% -10% 0.28% -0.02% -0.33% -0.63% -0.95% 0% 37.00% 36.70% 36.39% 36.09% 35.77% 0% 0.30% 0.00% -0.31% -0.61% -0.93% 10% 37.02% 36.72% 36.41% 36.11% 35.80% 10% 0.32% 0.02% -0.29% -0.59% -0.90% 20% 37.04% 36.74% 36.43% 36.13% 35.82% 20% 0.34% 0.04% -0.27% -0.57% -0.88% NPV Wood Wood -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% -20% 650,415 640,078 629,740 619,403 609,066 -20% 3.11% 1.54% -0.07% -1.74% -3.47% Livestock Livestock -10% 650,647 640,310 629,973 619,636 609,299 -10% 3.14% 1.58% -0.04% -1.71% -3.43% 0% 650,880 640,543 630,206 619,868 609,531 0% 3.18% 1.61% 0.00% -1.67% -3.39% 10% 651,113 640,775 630,438 620,101 609,764 10% 3.21% 1.65% 0.04% -1.63% -3.35% 20% 651,345 641,008 630,671 620,334 609,996 20% 3.25% 1.69% 0.07% -1.59% -3.31% Table 31. Sensitivity Analysis: Land Price Land Price Land Price -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% 50% -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% 50% - IRR 57.50% 43.38% 36.39% 31.71% 28.18% 20.94% IRR 21.11% 6.99% 0.00% -4.68% -8.21% 15.45% - NPV 698,946 664,576 630,206 595,835 561,465 458,354 NPV 9.83% 5.17% 0.00% -5.77% -12.24% 37.49% Table 32. Sensitivity Analysis: Harvesting, Thinning and Management Costs Land Price Land Price -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% 50% -20% -10% 0% 10% 20% 50% IRR 57.50% 43.38% 36.39% 31.71% 28.18% 20.94% IRR 21.11% 6.99% 0.00% -4.68% -8.21% -15.45% NPV 698,946 664,576 630,206 595,835 561,465 458,354 NPV 9.83% 5.17% 0.00% -5.77% -12.24% -37.49% 90
  • 103. CHAPTER 5 CONCLUSIONS The forest policy in Uruguay was developed to promote economic growth and generate environmental benefits. The government considered it as a tool to transform marginal agricultural lands, offering good forest growth conditions, into a thriving, globally competitive forest sector. The government thought that effective policies will help in developing a higher- value land use while promoting economic development, creating employment, attracting foreign investment, and increasing exports. While the development of the forest policy benefited from broad support in the legislature, it still was controversial. Subsidies proved to be particularly contentious. The main issues were: (1) whether the subsidies were necessary to attract investments, (2) whether to subsidize other, already established, sectors of the economy, and (3) whether the subsidies should be in effect for regions which determined that better alternative uses exist for lands allocated to forest development. This study evaluated the forest policy in Uruguay nearly twenty years after it was developed. It used a CBA approach that has not been used before. While some studies had tried to evaluate the impact of the new forest sector on Uruguay’s economy, they had focused on fiscal impacts and individual projects, not on the sector as a whole. This study compares the new forest sector with alternative activities that would have been developed if the project would have not been implemented. Livestock was assumed to be the alternative land use, corresponding closely to what has been observed on the ground. The CBA model had to make an extensive use of secondary information and own estimates. Linkages with other sectors of the economy, excluding direct transportation costs, were not considered due to data limitations. The current area of forest priority soils is 3 million ha; forests are already planted on 750 thousand ha. This 91
  • 104. indicates that the forest planted area can still grow substantially, followed by further growth of wood manufacturing industries. The results indicate a positive net impact of the newly developed forest sector on the Uruguayan economy when compared with agriculture and livestock. The NPV for the forest sector equals 630.2 million US$, using a 6% discount rate. The IRR for the forest sector development is 36.4%. These results are somewhat sensitive to changes in wood prices and growth rates and harvest yields. This indicates that market conditions and forest management operations are important variables in the evaluation of impacts that the sector has on the country’s economy. Forest policy in Uruguay has been successful in several ways. It has increased exports, which improved the balance of payments. It has found more productive uses for poor quality lands while attracting foreign investment, generating income and employment, and providing environmental benefits. Still, some aspects of the forest policy are a subject of a heated debate. One of the most contentious issues is the increased competition for land. The development of the forest sector has brought about higher land prices. It has been harder and more expensive to purchase land, rising dissent in some circles of the society. There are only limited investment opportunities in Uruguay, and land has traditionally been considered as an important low risk investment. Current land prices are on par with prices in neighboring Brazil and Argentina. In the past, they had been lower. While not mentioned by forest investors, the lower land prices were one of the factors that attracted foreign investment. In addition, some farmers complained about the necessity of moving livestock to new areas once traditional pastures were converted to forestry. Since this process has been gradual, the cost is not expected to be high. 92
  • 105. Other contentious issue regarding the forest policy was the use of subsidies to support the development of forest plantations and wood manufacturing industries. It has been shown that the even though subsidies the subsidy were important to attract investments, they were not the key factor. The discussion of whether to subsidize other sectors of the economy can be addressed with the positive net results obtained from evaluating the cost and benefits of the forest activity compared with an alternative production. One may ask: Why the impacts of the forest policy in Uruguay have been uniformly positive? After all, there are numerous examples of countries that tried and failed in developing their forest sectors in an efficient and sustainable way (Repetto 1988; Repetto & Gillis 1988). Certainly, Uruguay has growth conditions suitable for forestry. Factors that may have decided the successes of the policy include a stable economic policy and investment polices that truly encourage foreign capital to invest to the country. Throughout the course of this research project, several opportunities for further research have been identified. First, an extension of this CBA analysis should be conducted in a few years time. This is because large wood manufacturing facilities, including two paper mills, are nearing completion and will start operating in the next few years. Their massive, value-added products targeting global wood and paper markets will have a major impact on the country’s economy and the evaluation of the forest policy. Second, it would be worthwhile to estimate shadow prices for the forest sector, in particular for land and labor. Shadow prices for land in forestry uses have not been developed in Uruguay as suggested in the forest research literature. Labor treatment has been long a controversial issue. Unemployment is high in Uruguay, and large numbers of workers migrate in search for employment opportunities. While employment generation has not been a major 93
  • 106. policy’s objective, it has been an important argument in debating and defending it. A comprehensive assessment of labor issues would certainly help in informing this and future policy debates. Third, the use of a more comprehensive evaluation method may also cast more information on the policy’s impacts. Three approaches are generally used to evaluate forest policies. They include the Computable General Equilibrium (CGE), Input-Output (I-O) and Cost-Benefit Analysis (CBA), which was used in this study. CGE requires estimation of macroeconomic equations which was beyond the scope of this project. The second approach requires an updated I-O matrix. The rationale for a more comprehensive approach is that in a small country such as Uruguay, the forest sector, once large mills become operable, will have a substantial impact on the country’s economy. Finally, further research should incorporate non-market variables. They include a range of environmental services that are provided by forest plantations. Environmental values are increasingly important in policy debates, and Uruguay is no exception. While the plantations have been criticized on environmental grounds, they appear to put less stress on the environment than agriculture and livestock. These impacts too need to be evaluated to inform policy debates and permit rational land use decision-making. 94
  • 107. REFERENCES Agricultural Ministry of Uruguay, 2000. Agricultural Census 2000, Montevideo, Uruguay. ALADI, 2006. Regional Trade Statistics. ALADI (Latin American Integration Association). In www.aladi.com. Last accessed: March 2006. Ascher, W., Healy, R., 1990. Natural resource policymaking in developing countries: Environment, economic growth, and income distribution. Duke University Press, Durham and London. Bacha, C.J.C., 2004. The Use of Forest Resources and Brazilian Economic Policies. A Partial and Historical Vision of a Development Process. Economic Studies 34, Pages 393-426. Berck, P., Costello, C., Fortmann, L., Hoffmann, S., 2003. Poverty and employment in forest- dependent counties. Forest Science 49, 763-777 Bergman, L., Henrekson, M., 2003. CGE Modeling of Environmental Policy and Resource Management. Berreta, E., 2003. Country Pasture Profiles: Uruguay. Available at: http://fao.org/ag/Agp/agpc/doc/pasture/forage.htm. Last accessed: October 2006. Bisang, K., Zimmermann, W., 2006. Key concepts and methods of programme evaluation and conclusions from forestry practice in Switzerland. Forest Policy and Economics 8, 502- 511 Boardman, A.E., 2001. Cost-benefit analysis: concepts and practice. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ. Boardman, A.E., Greenberg, D.H., Vining, A.R., Weimer, D.L., 1997. Plug-in shadow price estimates for policy analysis. Annals of Regional Science 31, 299 95
  • 108. Carrere, R., 2002. Uruguay: the Absurd Injustice Behind the Forestry [Uruguay: la absurda injusticia detrás de la forestación] Revista del Sur 133. Available at: www.guayubira.com Last accessed: December 2006. Carvalho Mendes, A.M.S., 2006. Implementation analysis of forest programmes: Some theoretical notes and an example. Forest Policy & Economics 8, 512-528 Central Bank of Uruguay, 2005. GDP Statistics. Serie Nº 19135: GDP. Central Bank of Uruguay. Montevideo, Uruguay. At www.bcu.gub.uy. Last Accessed: February 2007. Chappelle, D.E., 1971. Forestry, Public Pressures, and Economic Development: Discussion. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 53, 896 Chavas, J.-P., Bouamra Mechemache, Z., 2006. Efficiency measurements and the gains from trade under transaction costs. J Prod Analysis (2006) 26:67–85. Published online: 19 July 2006. Chowdhury, A., Kirkpatrick, C.H., 1994. Development policy and planning : an introduction to models and techniques. Routledge, London ; New York. CIDE, 1963. Uruguayan Soils: Use and Management. Investment and Economic Development Comission, FAO. Montevideo, Uruguay Clapp, R.A., 1995. Creating competitive advantage: Forest policy as industrial policy in Chile. Economic Geography 71, 273 Clapp, R.A., 2001. Tree Farming and Forest Conservation in Chile: Do Replacement Forests Leave Any Originals Behind? Society and Natural Resources 14, 341-356 Clark, J., 2004. Forest policy for sustainable commodity wood production: an examination drawing on the Australian experience. Ecological Economics 50, 219-232 Clutter, J.L., Fortson, J.C., Pienaar, L.V., Brister, G.H., Bailey, R.L., 1983. Timber management : a quantitative approach . New York, N.Y. : Wiley, c1983. 96
  • 109. COFUSA, 2006. www.cofusa.com.uy Last accessed: April 2007. Colonization National Institute, 2006. www.colonizacion.com.uy. Last accessed: March 2007. Cubbage, F., Mac Donagh, P., Sawinski Júnior, J., Rubilar, R., Donoso, P., Ferreira, A., Hoeflich V., Morales Olmos, V., Ferreira, G., Balmelli, G., Siry, J., Báez, M.N., Alvarez, J., 2006. Timber Investment Returns for Selected Plantation and Native Forests in South America and the Southern United States. New Forests (In press) Cubbage, F.W., O’Laughlin, J., Bullock, C.S., 1993. Forest Resource Policy. Chapters 1, 2, 3, 5, 18. Dasgupta, P., Sen, A.K., Marglin, S.A., 1972. Guidelines for project evaluation, New York. Decrees: 452/88, 457/989/, 330/90, 26/93, 212/97 (Art. 1), 191/06, 220/06. Montevideo, Uruguay. Dewar, R.C., 1991. An analytical model of carbon storage in the trees. Tree Physiology. 8, 239– 258. DIEA, 2004. Agricultural Statistics. Agricultural Planning and Programming Office/Agricultural Ministry. In: www.mgap.gub.uy/opypa. Last accessed: February 2006. Dore, M.H.I., Guevara, R.e., 2000. Sustainable forest management and global climate change: Selected case studies from the Americas. Elgar, Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, Mass. Dunn, W.N., 2004. Public policy analysis: an introduction. Pearson/Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, N.J. Durán, V., 2003. Forest Sector: A Characterization. Yearbook OPYPA 2003. Montevideo, Uruguay. Durán, V., 2004. In 2003 forest sector industrialization took off. National wood availability, would be enough? Yearbook OPYPA 2004. Montevideo, Uruguay 97
  • 110. Economic Institute, 2003. Uruguayan Economy Report 2003. Trends and Outlook. Economic Institute (Ed.), Montevideo, Uruguay El Espectador Radio, 2005. Interview with Marvin Risco (Weyerhaeuser Manager for South America). Montevideo, Uruguay. Ellefson, P.V., 1988. Forestry issues as a focus for forest economics and policy research : a review of selected issue defining documents. College of Forestry and the Agricultural Experiment Station Institute of Agriculture Forestry and Home Economics University of Minnesota, St. Paul, Minn. Ence, 2006. Ence in Uruguay. Brochure. Montevideo, Uruguay. Escudero, R., 2004. GEFR/IBRD Project. Component: Native Forest. Montevideo, Uruguay. FAO, 2005. Global Resources Assessment 2005. FAO, 2006. www.fao.org.uy. Last accessed: February 2007. Fernandez Gaeta, R., 1995. Accounting Prices Estimation for Uruguay [Actualizacion de precios de cuenta para el Uruguay]. Budgeting and Planning Office. Montevideo, Uruguay. Flynn, B., 2005. Brazil's Forest Industry: Background Fact Book for the 2005 Plantation Forestry Study Tour. April 03-10, 2005. Forest Division, 2005. Strategy Report. Forest Division/Agricultural Ministry, Montevideo, Uruguay Forest Division, 2006. Estimation of the Costs of the Forestry Policy. Report. Montevideo, Uruguay Forest Policy and Economics Editorial, 2006. Forest Policy and Economics Journal 8 (2006) Forest Producers Society, 2006. Mision and Objectives. In www.spf.com.uy. Last accessed: December 2006. 98
  • 111. Forestry Law 13723, 1968. Montevideo, Uruguay. Forestry Law 15939, 1988. Montevideo, Uruguay. González Posse, E., Barrenechea, P., 1996. Study on the Forest Promotion Fiscal Effects. Montevideo, Uruguay. Gregersen, H.M., Contreras, A.H., 1979. Economic analysis of forestry projects. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome, Italy. Guldin, R.W., 2003. Forest science and forest policy in the Americas: building bridges to a sustainable future. Forest Policy & Economics 5, 329. Hagler, R., 2007. The Risks and Returns of International Timberland Investing. Presented at: The Timberland Asset: Reliable and Renewable Conference. March 28-30, 2007. Lake Oconee, Georgia, USA. Haltia, O., Keipi, K., 1997. Financing Forest Investments in Latin America: The Issue of Incentives. IDB. No ENV-113. Washington, D.C. Harou, P.A.W., 1987. Essays in forestry economics: appraisal and evaluation of forestry investments, programs, and policies Wissenschaftsverlag Vauk, Kiel. www.guayubira.com.uy. Last accessed: December 2006. Hyde, W.F., Boyd, R.G., Daniels, B.L., 1987. The Impacts of Public Interventions: An Examination of the Forestry Sector. Journal of Policy Analysis & Management 7, 40-61 INE, 2006. www.ine.gub.uy. Last accessed: December 2006. Karjalainen, T., 1996. Dynamics and potentials of carbon sequestration in managed stands and wood products in Finlandunder changing climatic conditions. For. Ecol. Manage. 80,113–132. 99
  • 112. Keugen, S., 2001. The Brazilian Forest Policy: A Historical Perspective. SIAGEF, Porto Seguro, 4-7 July 2001. Lara, A., Veblen, T.T., 1993. Forest Plantations in Chile: a successful model? in Afforestation: Policies, Planning and Progress. Edited by Alexander Mather. Belhaven Press. United Kingdom. . Law 16906, 1998. Investments, Promotion and Protection. Montevideo, Uruguay Lim, B., Brown, S., Schlamadinger, B., 1999. Carbon accounting for forest harvesting and wood products. Review and evaluation of different approaches. Environmental Science and Policy 2, p. 207-216. Little, I.M.D., Mirrlees, J.A., 1974. Project Appraisal and Planning in Developing Countries. Basic Books, Inc., Publishers New York. Londero, E., Cervini, H., 2003. Shadow prices for project appraisal: theory and practice Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA: E. Elgar. Lorenzo, F., Berreta, N., Laens, S., Perelmuter, N., Osimani, R., Paolino, C., Pessano, O., 2005. Industrial and Investment Policy in Uruguay. IADBF. Reference Notes (RE1-RN-05- 006). Marglin, S.A., 1977. The Essentials of the UNIDO Approach to Benefit-Cost Analysis in Cost- Benefit Analysis and Project Design. Edited by John D. Donahue. Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana, USA. Mendell, B., Morales, V., Bennadji, Z., Moreno, A., Siry, J., 2007. Financing Uruguay’s Forestry Sector: Survey and Case Study. Journal of Forestry [In press]. Methol, M., 2004. Activities in environmental policy and natural resources management. Yearbook OPYPA 2004. Montevideo, Uruguay 100
  • 113. Methol, R., 2003. SAG Grandis: Support System to Eucalyptus Grandis Plantations Management [SAG grandis: Sistema de Apoyo a la Gestión de Plantaciones de Eucalyptus grandis]. Agricultural Research National Institute (INIA). Serie Técnica No 131. Tacuarembó, Uruguay. Metsa-Botnia, 2004. Socioeconomic Study of the Impacts of Botnia SA Pulp Mill Project in Uruguay. Executive Summary. Montevideo, Uruguay Nas, T.F., 1996. Cost-benefit analysis: theory and application. Sage Publications,, Thousand Oaks, California. Nebel, P., 2003. Conservation of the Native Forest: the Uruguayan Strategy. Unpublished. Montevideo, Uruguay. Newman, D.H., 1988. The Optimal Forest Rotation: A Discussion and Annotated Bibliography. p. 47. US Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Southeastern Forest Experiment Station, Asheville, North Carolina Paperloop, 2005. Pulp and Paper Global Fact & Price Book 2005. Paredes, G.V., 1999. Chilean Forestry: Wood Products from an Exporting Industry. In Global Concerns for Forest Resource Utilization. Sustainable Use and Management. Edited by A. Yoshimoto and K. Yukutake. Kluwer Academic Publishers. The Netherlands. Patton, C., Sawicki, D.S., 1993. Basic Methods of Policy Analysis and Planning. Prentice Hall. Pereyra, A., 2004. Accounting Prices Estimation for the Economic Evaluation of Local Development Projects Program IV- Final Report. Planning and Budgeting Office/Local Development Program. Montevideo, Uruguay. Perman, R., Ma, Y., McGilvray, J., Common, M., 2003. Natural Resource and Environmental Economics (Chapter 10). Addison-Wesley. 101
  • 114. Pleskovic, B., Treviño, G., 1985. The use of a social accounting matrix framework for public sector analysis : the case study of Mexico. International Center for Public Enterprises in Developing Countries, Ljubljana, Yugoslavia. Prestemon, J.P., Buongiorno, J., Wear, D.N., Siry, J.P., 2003. International Trade in Forest Products (Chapter 11). In: Sills EO & Lee Abt K (eds.) Forests in a Market Economy. Series: Forestry Sciences, Vol. 72. Ramos, A., Cabrera, R., 2001. Uruguay Forest Sector Impact. p. 99, Montevideo, Uruguay Ray, A., 1984. Cost-benefit analysis: issues and methodologies. Published for the World Bank [by] Johns Hopkins University Press. Repetto, R., 1988. The forest for the trees? Government policies and the misuse of forest resources. World Resources Institute, Washington, D.C. Repetto, R.C., Gillis, M., 1988. Public policies and the misuse of forest resources. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge [Cambridgeshire]; New York Richards, K.R., Stokes, C., 2004. A review of forest carbon sequestration cost studies: A dozen years of research. Climatic Change 63, 1-48 Rossi, P.H., Freeman, H.E., Lipsey, M.W., 1999. Evaluation: a systematic approach. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks, California. Sabag Villalobos, P.H., 1984. Forestry Promotion Policy. An Economical Analysis: 1974-1983. Thesis. Universidad Austral de Chile. Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y Administrativas. Escuela de Ingeniería Comercial. Valdivia, Chile. Sáder Neffa, M., 2004. Characteristics of the Investments in Land (Características de la inversión en tierra). OPYPA Yearbook 2004. Montevideo, Uruguay. San Román, D., 2005. Review of Forest Sector Employment - Internal Report. Montevideo, Uruguay. 102
  • 115. Silva, E., 2004. The political economy of forest policy in Mexico and Chile. Singapore Journal of Tropical Geography 25, 261-280. Siry, J.P., Cubbage, F., Newman, D.H., 2005. Who Owns World's Forests? Implications for Forest Production, Management and Protection. Presented at IUFRO World Congress. 8-13 August 2005. Brisbane, Australia. Slee, B., 2006. The socio-economic evaluation of the impact of forestry on rural development: A regional level analysis. Forest Policy and Economics 8, 542-554. Slee, W., Evans, R., Roberts, D., 2003. Understanding Forestry in Rural Development: Report to the Forestry Commission. Forestry Commission, England. Southern Hemisphere, 2006. Forest Industry Yearbook. 2005-06 Edition. Trade and Media Services Ltd. New Zealand. Souto, G., Methol, M., 2005. Energy and Agricultural Sector. OPYPA Yearbook 2005. Montevideo, Uruguay. Squire, L., van der Tak, H.G., 1975. Economic analysis of projects. Published for the World Bank [by] Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. Stone, R., 1985. The Disaggregation of the Household Sector in the National Accounts. In: Social accounting matrices: a basis for planning. World Bank, Washington, DC, pp. 145- 185. Tourism Ministry, 2006. www.turismo.gub.uy. Last accessed: December 2006. Varian, H.R., 1984. Microeconomic analysis, New York. Vázquez Platero, R., 1996. Evaluation of the Forest Development in Uruguay Forest Producers Society/Rural Association of Uruguay, Montevideo, Uruguay. Wing, I.S., 2004. Computable General Equilibrium Models and Their Use in Economy-Wide Policy Analysis: Everything You Ever Wanted to Know (But Were Afraid to Ask). 103
  • 116. World Bank, 2005. Uruguay Pulp Mills-Cumulative Impact Study- Draft. In: http://www/ifc.org/ifcext/lac/nsf/Content/Uruguay. Last accessed: November 2006. World Bank, 2006. Doing Business in Uruguay: Methodology. Available at: http://www.doingbusiness.org/MethodologySurveys/. Last accessed: April 2007. Zerbe, R.O., Dively, D., 1994. Benefit-cost analysis in theory and practice. HarperCollins College Publishers, New York. 104
  • 118. THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF THE FOREST SECTOR IN URUGUAY: SURVEY RESULTS A survey to institutions and companies in the forest sector was conducted in July 2006 in Uruguay. The institutions selected were the Forest Producers Society (SPF), the Economic Institute of the Social Sciences Faculty of the Republic of Uruguay University, the Forest Division and the Agricultural Planning and Policy Office (OPYPA) of the Agricultural Ministry. Selected companies included were Botnia, Eufores, Colonvade, Fymnsa and Cofusa. The Forest Producers Society (SPF) is a private association that represents the forest business sector in Uruguay. It is made up of technicians, producers, and companies, both local and foreign. Its objective is to promote a sustainable forest sector in Uruguay by promoting forest plantations and contributing to the conservation of the natural forests in the country (Forest Producers Society 2006). The Economic Institute of the Social Sciences Faculty of the Republic of Uruguay University is a research institute which research areas include: econometric, industrial organization, business, microeconomics, macroeconomics, finance and labor economic. The Forest Division of the Agricultural Ministry is in charge of the Forest Policy (Forestry Law 15939 1988). The main activities are to promote the forest activity, to design and to analyze management plans for public and private lands, to assist the institutions on the forest management and to coordinate activities related with the forestry. OPYPA of the Agricultural Ministry is the office in charge of advising the government in the design, execution and control of the agricultural policies. 106
  • 119. The companies were selected for the following reasons: first, they include both local and foreign companies; second, all together they own 30% of the plantations and the rest is fragmented; third, they produce a spectrum of products (two, wood for pulp; two, saw timber; one, plywood); fourth, each of the companies is in a different stage of development; fifth, they have different types of organization according to capital, species and timber management. Some of the companies have different names for their plantation’s firm and for their manufacturing firm; furthermore, some companies have different names from the name they use in their country of origin (Table 33). Botnia is constructing a pulp mill in the North of the country, which involves the largest single investment in the country’s history: a one billion US$ investment. It consumes 3.5 million cum of pulpwood when operating at full capacity (Metsa-Botnia 2004). Its main product is bleached eucalyptus Kraft pulp, and their estimated production capacity will be one million tons per year. Its capital originates from Finland and was used to purchase the Uruguayan company, FOSA, which owned the forest plantations. The company is located in Río Negro and Paysandú. Colonvade is a branch of the US company Weyerhaeuser. It is constructing a plywood facility and plans to construct five to eight more plants in Tacuarembó, Rivera and Paysandú. Its total investment is between $500 and $800 million, depending on the number of plants it will construct. It has already made a $270 million investment in 131,000 hectares of land for plantations, of which 85,000 were already planted. Its first commercial thinning was planned for the current year, and it expected to obtain 16,000 m3 wood. By 2012 it expects to extract 2.5 million m3 per year, from which it would obtain 900,000 m3 in products to export. The main products are: plywood, saw timber, MDF (medium density board) and LVL (laminated veneer lumber) (El Espectador Radio 2005). 107
  • 120. Ence, a Spanish company that has partnerships with several local companies, was planning to construct a pulp mill by the end of the current year. Eufores is the local branch of the company. At M’Bopicuá Logistic Terminal, Ence invested $622 million in a chip plant with a production capacity of 500,000 cum per year. Maserlit, an Uruguayan sawmill that Ence controls, produces 35,000 cum per year of kiln dried wood to produce Eucalyptus Grandis lumber. By the time of the interview, Ence estimated that by the year 2008 they will be operating at full capacity. However, these days it has been subsequently announced the relocation of the mill and the information of when they are going to begin the construction is not known. Fymnsa, which produces saw logs, is one of the oldest and biggest local companies and is building a sawmill in Rivera (northern Uruguay). It is producing 18,000 tons of chips per year and it has 13,000 ha of plantations. Cofusa and Urufor are two forestry companies that belong to the same economic group. They are located in the North of Uruguay and produce high quality Eucalyptus Grandis timber. Cofusa owns 25,000 haof plantations and Urufor owns a sawmill. The survey for institutions had semi structured questions on topics which differed according to the institution. SPF was asked about regulation, their studies on forest sector impact and policy evaluation and limitations for the sector’s development; the Economic Institute of Social Sciences Faculty was asked about macroeconomic data availability to use in the research; Forest Division was asked about the Forest Policy history and the current regulation in force as well as about their future actions; and OPYPA was asked about the situation of the forest sector in Uruguay and its possible impacts in the economy. 108
  • 121. The survey for companies had open and structured questions. The companies had to fill out two different forms: one for its plantation activities and the other for its industrial activities, as some companies has separate corporations for each activity. Each plantation company was asked about location, origin of the capital, production (forest area, harvest, and rotation age), costs and investments, labor, certification programs and future plans. Each industry was asked questions dealing with location, origin of the capital, production (products, markets, sales, and plants’ capacity), investment and costs, labor, regulation, certification programs and future plans. Each company was also asked for the reasons it started its activities in Uruguay. Institutions interviewed evaluated the impact of the forest sector in Uruguay as positive. There is an agreement that the sector is just starting its development and it is going to grow fast in the next years when plantations start to be harvested. Opinions on regulation differed: the SPF said that regulation is good, and people in the Forest Division said that current regulation needs to be adjusted. Institutions are weaker than at the beginning of the forest sector development. The SPF had evaluated the impact of the new forest sector using cost benefit analysis. Two private consultants compared the Uruguayan economy with and without the forest sector (Vázquez Platero 1996; Ramos & Cabrera 2001). They considered plantations as well as industrial activities, and both concluded that the impact will be positive. The limitations for the sector would be related with high costs in US dollars, specially fuel, and a low exchange rate34 which leads to a competitiveness loss. The Forest Division described the origin and objectives of the current Forest Policy in force. Regarding the institution itself, two factors have a negative impact on their activities: first, an 34 Currently the exchange rate is 24 $U/ 1 US$. 109
  • 122. increasing number of technicians are going to the private sector, and second, more resources are going to the Environmental Ministry to evaluate forest projects. The companies are located in the North and Northwest of the country, and one is expanding their activities to the Northeast. The companies’ capital is originated in different countries: Spain, Finland, USA and Uruguay. All the companies together have a forest area that represents 30% of the country’s forest area. They have more than 50% of their land planted; meanwhile this ratio for the country is only 4.3%. These results show that the companies will buy new land to increase the plantations area (Table 34). Even though Eucalyptus is the most important specie planted, Pine is increasing its participation reaching 77,265 hectares in 2004 (Table 35). Eucalyptus is mostly managed for pulp with the exception of one company that is managing it for hardwood. Pine is managed for saw timber and plywood. Rotation ages vary from 22 to 25 for Pine according to the final product, and 10 to 20 years for Eucalyptus. On average, this represents 23 years for Pine and 15 years for Eucalyptus (Table 36). Investments vary from each company according to their stage of development. By 2008, four companies’ total investments35 will be approximately 1,900 million US$36. This amount includes investments that the companies have been done in land and investments they planned to do in industries. There are important differences in amount, as one company is planning to invest 1 billion US $ in its pulp mill. The most important investments are from the foreign companies. 35 One company did not give information about its total investments, and another did not give information before 2005. 36 These days, one of the companies announced that an 800million US $ investment planned will be delayed. If this investment were not considered, the total amount would be 1.100 billion US $. 110
  • 123. All the companies are involved in Certification Programs: four of them have Forest Stewardship Council (FSC) certification and one has International Organization for Standardization 14001 (ISO 14001) certification. The regulation is good, but labor regulation is needed. Plantation workers are regulated under agricultural laws without considering the specific characteristics of the forest sector, such are safety issues. The general opinion is that the sector started developing because of the Forestry Law 15939 and subsidies were an important part of the incentives’ package. All the companies have plans to grow in the future, either to increase the area planted, to export, to build new mills or to increase their current capacity. Two companies are already building their second sawmill. The companies mentioned several reasons for starting their activities in Uruguay. All of them mentioned soils and growth rates as key elements to go to the country. They also pointed put that a good economy’s performance, economy’s stability and a good regulation in the Forest Sector were factors that contribute to this decision. Labor’s skills were a problem at the beginning, but the problem was quickly solved by training the labor in the skills needed. Training programs were offered by companies to their labor force and most of the companies said that Uruguayan workers are open to learn. 111
  • 124. Table 33. Companies classified according to the origin of the capital Uruguayan Entity International Origin of (Foreign) Manufacturing Forest Plantations Firm in Control Capital Botnia Fosa Oy Metsa Botnia Finland Eufores Eufores Ence Spain Colonvade Colonvade Weyerhaeuser United States Fymnsa Fymnsa - Uruguay Urufor Cofusa - Uruguay Table 34. Area by companies Planted/ Planted Area (ha) Land Area (ha) Land Area Total 5 Companies 220,893 391,000 56.49% Total Uruguay 714,000 16,666,670 4.30% % Total (5 Companies/Uruguay) 30.94% Table 35. Area by species (in ha) Euc. Pinus Euc. Pinus Pinus Total Grandis Taeda Globulus Patula Elliotti Area 38,120 77,265 105,000 129 379 220,893 Table 36. Rotation ages and Growth rates Estimations Pine Eucalyptus Rotation Age 23 years 15 years Growth Rates 20 m3/year 22 m3/year 112
  • 126. The Impact of the Forest Sector on the Uruguayan Economy Master of Science Thesis Research Warnell School of Forestry and Natural Resources University of Georgia Survey - Plantations July, 2006 I. General Information 1. Company Name: _________________________________________________________ 2. Contact Information: Address/ Phone Number/E-mail address: ________________________________________________________________________ ________________________________________________________________________ ________________________________________________________________________ 3. Name and Position of the Person who answer the survey: ________________________________________________________________________ ________________________________________________________________________ 4. Type of business organization: Domestic Foreign Sole Proprietorship Domestic Partnership Corporation 5. Origin of foreign capital (if applicable): _____________________________________ 114
  • 127. II. Production 6. Area of Forest Land: Species Total Land Area Planted Area Location Total 7. Harvest: Product Tons Saw timber Chip and Saw Pulpwood 8. Rotation: which is the average rotation by specie or by product? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ III. Investments and Costs 9. Investments: Which are the estimated investments per year? Category Amount (in dollars) Year Imported (%) 115
  • 128. 10. Total costs Year Amount 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 11. Costs as percentage of the total: Concept Amount (in dollars) Year Raw material (timber) Transportation Services, maintenance and repair Equipment Wages Insurance Supplies Contractual Services Fuels Utilities (Water, Electricity, Phone) Taxes Other administrative expenses Others (describe) 116
  • 129. IV. Employment 12. Indicate number of employees by part of the company. ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ V. Environmental, certification and other programs 13. Does the company have environmental programs? If yes, please describe them briefly. ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 14. Does the company participate in any certification programs? If yes, in which ones? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 15. In which other programs does the company participate? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 117
  • 130. VI. Future Plans 16. What are the company’s plans for the following years? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 17. Which are the most important limitations that, in your opinion, the company would face in the following years? E.g.: transport, financing, labor, markets. ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 18. Which are the growth rates expected by species? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 19. How much production is expected for the next years? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 118
  • 131. The Impact of the Forest Sector on the Uruguayan Economy Master of Science Thesis Research Warnell School of Forestry and Natural Resources University of Georgia Survey Industry July 2006 I. General Information 1. Company Name: _________________________________________________________ 2. Contact Information: Address/ Phone Number/E-mail address: ________________________________________________________________________ ________________________________________________________________________ ________________________________________________________________________ 3. Name and Position of the Person who answer the survey: ________________________________________________________________________ ________________________________________________________________________ 4. Type of business organization: Domestic Foreign Sole Proprietorship Domestic Partnership Corporation 5. Origin of foreign capital (if applicable): _____________________________________ 119
  • 132. II. Production 6. Products: Destination Product (markets) % of the total sales Fuel wood Chips Plywood Boards Pulp Paper Others (specify) 7. Total Sales of Forest Products: indicate the approximate amount of sales per year. Year Amount 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 120
  • 133. 8. Does the company buy wood (timber) from other companies? Yes No . If yes, fill in the following table: Seller % of total timber consumed Specie(s) Farmer(s) Other companies (1) ___________________ (2) ___________________ (3) ___________________ (4) ___________________ (5) ___________________ 9. Mill capacity. Indicate current and expected annual capacity of your mill(s) in cum. Plant Year Capacity Product Location 121
  • 134. III. Investments and Costs 10. Investments: Which are the estimated investments per year? Concept Amount (in dollars) Year Imported (%) 11. Total costs: how much are the total costs per year? Year Amount 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 122
  • 135. 12. Costs as percentage of the total: Concept Amount (in dollars) Year Raw material (timber) Transportation Services, maintenance and repair Equipment Wages Insurance Supplies Contractual Services Fuels Utilities (Water, Electricity, Phone) Taxes Other administrative expenses Others (describe) IV. Employment 13. Indicate number of employees by part of the company. If the company has more than one plant, please use different tables. Plant: _____________________________________ Years Concept Construction Operation 123
  • 136. Plant: _____________________________________ Years Concept Construction Operation Plant: _____________________________________ Years Concept Construction Operation Plant: _____________________________________ Years Concept Construction Operation 14. Which external services do you hire? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 124
  • 137. V. Regulation 15. Why did the company choose Uruguay to run the business? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 16. If the subsidies and tax exonerations were not established, would you have chosen the country to invest? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 17. How do you evaluate the regulation in the Forest Sector in Uruguay? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 18. Do you consider the Law No. 16906 (National Interest Investments) an important incentive to invest in the country? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 125
  • 138. 19. Which elements (or regulation) will be necessary to improve the developing of the sector in the next years? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ VI. Environmental, certification and other programs 20. Does the company have programs to monitor environmental effects? If yes, which kind of programs? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 21. Does the company participate in any certification programs? If yes, in which one(s)? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 22. Does the company participate in Chain of Custody certification programs? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 126
  • 139. 23. In which other programs the company participates? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ VII. Future Plans 24. What are the company’s plans for the following years? E.g.: increase capacity, buy new land, and explore new markets. ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 25. Which are the most important limitations that, in your opinion, the company would face in the following years? E.g.: transport, financing, wood supply, labor, markets. ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 26. What are the perspectives you see on the development of the forest sector in Uruguay? ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________ 127
  • 141. Table 37. Total Extraction Eucalyptus (1,000 m3) 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Effective Area (in ha) 3,817 4,208 10,070 16,473 25,707 26,736 35,651 34,671 41,683 38,274 28,865 22,778 19,988 8,807 8,620 19,808 17,873 Pulp 668 736 1,762 2,883 4,499 4,679 6,239 6,067 Saw timber Pulp 1st Thinning 57 63 151 247 386 401 535 520 2nd Thinning 1,080 1,123 1,497 1,456 Saw timber Total Pulp 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 725 799 1,913 3,130 5,964 6,203 8,271 8,044 Total Saw timber 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 129
  • 142. Table 38. Total Extraction Pine (1,000 m3) 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Effective Area (in ha) 602 914 1,172 1,352 3,359 4,005 5,231 6,465 9,514 20,885 22,104 17,719 16,306 11,955 9,975 6,788 11,915 Total Extraction No Value 1st Thinning 7 10 13 15 37 45 58 72 106 233 246 198 182 2nd Thin - - - - - 3rd Thin. - - - - - Harvest Fuel wood 1st Thinning - - - - - - - - - - - - - 2nd Thin. 442 970 1,027 823 758 3rd Thin. Harvest Saw timber 1st Thinning - - - - - - - - - - - - - 2nd Thin. 442 970 1,027 823 758 3rd Thin. Harvest Total Pulp 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total SW 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 442 970 1,027 823 758 Total Fuel wood 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 442 970 1,027 823 758 Total No Value - - - - 7 10 13 15 37 45 58 72 106 233 246 198 182 130
  • 143. Table 39. Basic Assumptions Forest Area (in 1,000 ha) 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Annual 1989- 1999 7 8 16 26 42 44 59 59 73 85 73 58 52 30 27 38 43 Cumulative 7 14 31 56 98 143 201 260 333 418 491 549 601 631 657 695 738 0.2 With Project Production-Model (1,000 m3/ha) 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 TOTAL 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 725 799 1,913 3,572 6,934 7,230 9,094 8,801 Pulpwood 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 725 799 1,913 3,130 5,964 6,203 8,271 8,044 Sawn wood 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 442 970 1,027 823 758 Saw timber 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 199 437 462 370 341 Prices (1,000 US$/m3) Saw timber price 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.084 0.112 0.112 0.112 0.112 Pulpwood prices 0.020 0.020 0.020 0.020 0.020 0.020 0.020 0.020 0.020 0.028 0.032 0.025 0.023 0.023 0.026 0.028 0.032 131
  • 144. Table 40. Investments in Land (million US$) Plantations 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 With Market Land Price (1,000 US$/ha) 0.361 0.528 0.580 0.637 0.658 0.716 0.749 0.760 0.734 0.796 0.630 0.650 0.590 0.460 0.593 0.871 1.871 SPR land 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1 1 1 1 Investments Land million US$/ha Market Prices 2.37 4.02 9.48 16.37 27.62 31.73 43.85 44.74 53.70 67.49 46.00 37.71 30.65 13.66 15.77 33.09 43.21 Shadow Prices 2.82 4.79 11.28 19.48 32.86 37.75 52.18 53.24 63.91 80.31 54.73 44.87 36.48 13.66 15.77 33.09 43.21 Without Market Land Price (1,000 US$/ha) Livestock 0.361 0.426 0.478 0.535 0.556 0.614 0.647 0.658 0.632 0.632 0.486 0.415 0.349 0.283 0.385 0.599 0.599 SPR land Land 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 Investments Land million US$/ha Market Prices 2.37 3.25 7.81 13.75 23.35 27.22 37.89 38.75 46.26 53.58 35.47 24.08 18.11 8.41 10.23 22.77 29.44 Shadow Prices 2.82 3.86 9.30 16.37 27.78 32.39 45.09 46.12 55.05 63.76 42.20 28.65 21.55 8.41 10.23 22.77 29.44 Incremental Market Prices 0.00 0.78 1.66 2.61 4.27 4.51 5.96 5.99 7.44 13.91 10.53 13.63 12.55 5.25 5.54 10.31 13.77 Shadow Prices 0.00 0.92 1.98 3.11 5.08 5.36 7.09 7.13 8.86 16.55 12.53 16.22 14.93 5.25 5.54 10.31 13.77 132
  • 145. Table 41. Industry Investments (million US$) 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Investments (with Project) 0 0 0 0 0 0 10.50 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 10.50 10.50 41.50 Saw timber 10.50 10.50 10.50 41.50 Pulp Investments (without Project) 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Incremental Investments market prices 0 0 0 0 0 0 10.50 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 10.50 10.50 41.50 Incremental Investments shadow Prices 0 0 0 0 0 0 13.76 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 10.61 10.61 41.92 133
  • 146. Table 42. Exports 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 With Cumulative area (1,000 ha) 6.58 14.2 30.55 56.25 98.24 142.57 201.14 260.04 333.23 Forest Area (1,000 ha) 6.58 7.62 16.35 25.71 41.99 44.33 58.57 58.9 73.2 Total Exports 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Saw timber 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Pulpwood 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Without Total Exports (million US $) 0.13 0.13 0.27 0.44 0.75 0.75 1.4 1.36 1.84 Alternative Productions (total production) 0.22 0.22 0.46 0.74 1.24 1.25 2.33 2.26 2.83 Alt. Prod. (exports) 0.13 0.13 0.27 0.44 0.75 0.75 1.4 1.36 1.84 Incremental market prices (million US$) -0.13 -0.13 -0.27 -0.44 -0.75 -0.75 -1.4 -1.36 -1.84 Incremental shadow prices (million US$) -0.17 -0.17 -0.36 -0.58 -0.98 -0.99 -1.83 -1.78 -2.41 134
  • 147. Table 42 (cont) Exports 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 With Cumulative area (1,000 ha) 418.01 491.02 549.03 600.99 630.72 657.31 695.31 737.86 Forest Area (1,000 ha) 84.78 73.01 58.01 51.96 29.73 26.59 37.99 42.55 Total Exports 20.31 25.58 47.83 88.64 185.9 212.84 272.93 295.44 Saw timber 0 0 0 16.65 48.73 51.57 41.34 38.05 Pulpwood 20.31 25.58 47.83 71.99 137.17 161.27 231.59 257.4 Without Total Exports (million US $) 2.43 1.81 1.55 1.08 0.35 0.47 0.85 1.28 Alternative Productions (total production) 3.74 2.79 2.38 1.66 0.54 0.72 1.22 1.83 Alt. Prod. (exports) 2.43 1.81 1.55 1.08 0.35 0.47 0.85 1.28 Incremental market prices (million US$) 17.88 23.77 46.28 87.56 185.55 212.38 272.08 294.16 Incremental shadow prices (million US$) 23.42 31.14 60.63 114.7 187.41 214.5 274.8 297.1 135
  • 148. Table 43. Transportation Costs (million US$) 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 With Transportation (in 1,000 tons) Pulpwood 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 653 720 1722 2817 5368 5582 7444 7239 Sawn wood 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 354 776 822 659 606 Saw timber 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 90 196 208 167 153 Total Volume 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 653 720 1722 3260 6340 6612 8269 7999 Total Wood Transportation Costs 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 5.87 6.48 15.50 29.34 57.06 59.51 74.42 71.99 Total Livestock Transportation Costs 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Total Transp. Costs Market Prices 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 5.87 6.48 15.50 29.34 57.06 59.51 74.42 71.99 Shadow Prices 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 4.52 4.99 11.93 22.59 43.94 45.82 57.31 55.43 Without Livestock not transported (million US$) 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.05 0.08 0.13 0.21 0.28 0.42 0.51 0.54 0.61 0.67 0.27 0.73 0.77 0.82 Total Costs in shadow prices 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.10 0.16 0.22 0.33 0.40 0.42 0.47 0.51 0.21 0.56 0.59 0.63 Incremental Market - - - - - - - - - prices 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.05 0.08 0.13 0.21 0.28 0.42 5.36 5.93 14.89 28.67 56.79 58.78 73.65 71.17 Shadow - - - - - - - - prices 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.10 0.16 0.22 0.33 4.13 4.57 11.46 22.08 43.73 45.26 56.71 54.80 136
  • 149. Table 44. Livestock Transportation Costs 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Without Livestock production (kg/ha) 43 43 45 45 45 45 45 45 50 Total Area 6,575 14,199 30,545 56,251 98,242 142,572 201,140 260,037 333,232 Livestock production total (tons) 285 616 1,381 2,543 4,441 6,444 9,092 11,754 16,696 Livestock production (ton/ha) 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 # trips (total tons/13 tons) 22 47 106 196 342 496 699 904 1,284 Transportation fees (US$/km-1 trip=13 tons) 1.15 1.30 1.24 1.11 1.07 1.14 1.31 1.40 1.47 US$/km/ton 0.08 0.09 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.10 0.10 Km/trip 250 250 250 250 250 250 250 250 250 Transportation Costs (million US$) 0.02 0.05 0.11 0.20 0.34 0.50 0.70 0.90 1.28 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Without Livestock production (kg/ha) 52 51 51 51 20 51 51 51 Total Area 418,009 491,017 549,030 600,986 630,716 657,311 695,305 737,860 Livestock production total (tons) 21,817 25,003 27,957 30,602 12,614 33,470 35,405 37,572 Livestock production (ton/ha) 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.05 # trips (total tons/13 tons) 1,678 1,923 2,151 2,354 970 2,575 2,723 2,890 Transportation fees (US$/km-1 trip=13 tons) 1.36 1.26 1.26 1.26 1.26 1.26 1.26 1.26 US$/km/ton 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 Km/trip 250 250 250 250 250 250 250 250 Transportation Costs (million US$) 1.68 1.92 2.15 2.35 0.97 2.57 2.72 2.89 137
  • 150. Table 45. Industry Costs 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Production Costs (imports) 1,000 US$/ha Slaughter Houses 0.00025 0.00027 0.00028 0.00029 0.00030 0.00031 0.00037 0.00034 0.00038 Wool 0.00012 0.00012 0.00012 0.00012 0.00012 0.00013 0.00013 0.00013 0.00011 Leather 0.00005 0.00005 0.00005 0.00005 0.00005 0.00005 0.00005 0.00005 0.00006 Wood (1,000 3 US$/m ) 0.00225 0.00209 0.00210 0.00146 0.00148 0.00133 0.00130 0.00127 0.00127 Labor Slaughter Houses 0.0013 0.0014 0.0015 0.0015 0.0015 0.0016 0.0019 0.0017 0.0020 Wool 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.003 Leather 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 Wood (1,000 3 US$/m ) 0.02639 0.02451 0.02468 0.01713 0.01736 0.01556 0.01529 0.01489 0.01489 In market prices 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 With Project 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Labor Alternative Productions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Saw timber 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Production Costs (imports) Alternative Productions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Saw timber 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Without Project 29 62 141 261 457 705 1017 1300 1536 Labor Alternative Productions 26 56 127 235 410 634 906 1164 1350 Production Costs (imports) Alternative Productions 3 6 14 26 46 71 111 136 186 138
  • 151. Table 45 (cont) Industry Costs Production and Labor Shadow Prices 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 With Project 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Labor Saw timber 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Without Project 23 50 113 209 365 564 813 1040 1229 Labor Alternative Productions 21 45 102 188 328 507 725 931 1080 Production Costs (imports) Alternative Productions 2 5 11 21 37 57 89 109 149 Incremental in SPR (million US$) -0.02 -0.05 -0.11 -0.21 -0.37 -0.56 -0.81 -1.04 -1.23 DATA 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Production (kg/ha) Beef 35 35 36 36 36 36 36 36 41 Lamb 8 8 9 9 9 9 9 9 6 Wool 4 4 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 Leather 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 Total Costs Alternative Industries (1,000 US$/kg) Beef 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 Lamb 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 Wool 0.002 0.001 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 Leather 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 3 Total Costs Sawmills (1,000 US$/ m ) Wood 0.119 0.111 0.112 0.078 0.079 0.070 0.069 0.067 0.067 139
  • 152. Table 45 (cont) Industry Costs Production and Labor 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Production Costs (imports) 1,000 US$/ha Slaughter Houses 0.00043 0.00037 0.00037 0.00037 0.00017 0.00029 0.00037 0.00037 Wool 0.00011 0.00008 0.00008 0.00008 0.00008 0.00008 0.00008 0.00008 Leather 0.00007 0.00007 0.00007 0.00007 0.00001 0.00003 0.00007 0.00007 3 Wood (1,000 US$/m ) 0.00127 0.00127 0.00127 0.00127 0.00127 0.00127 0.00127 0.00127 Labor Slaughter Houses 0.0023 0.0020 0.0020 0.0020 0.0009 0.0016 0.0020 0.0020 Wool 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 Leather 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0000 0.0001 0.0002 0.0002 3 Wood (1,000 US$/m ) 0.01489 0.01489 0.01489 0.01489 0.01489 0.01489 0.01489 0.01489 In market prices 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 With Project 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Labor Alternative Productions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Saw timber 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 Production Costs (imports) Alternative Productions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Saw timber 0 0 0 3 7 7 6 5 Without Project 1859 1814 2028 2220 1926 2211 2568 2726 Labor Alternative Productions 1608 1558 1742 1906 1758 1945 2206 2341 Production Costs (imports) Alternative Productions 252 256 287 314 168 266 363 385 140
  • 153. Table 45 (cont) Industry Costs Production and Labor Shadow Prices 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 With Project 0 0 0 3 6 7 5 5 Saw timber 0 0 0 3 6 7 5 5 Without Project 1487 1451 1622 1776 1541 1327 1541 1635 Labor Alternative Productions 1286 1246 1393 1525 1407 1167 1323 1404 Production Costs (imports) Alternative Productions 201 205 229 251 134 160 218 231 Incremental in shadow prices(million US$) -1.49 -1.45 -1.62 -1.77 -1.53 -1.32 -1.54 -1.63 DATA 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Production (kg/ha) Beef 43 44 44 44 20 34 44 44 Lamb 7 5 5 5 2 5 5 5 Wool 4 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 Leather 5 5 5 5 1 2 5 5 Total Costs Alternative Industries (1,000 US$/kg) Beef 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 Lamb 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 Wool 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 Leather 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 3 Total Costs Sawmills (1,000 US$/ m ) Wood 0.067 0.067 0.067 0.067 0.067 0.067 0.067 0.067 141
  • 154. Table 46. Production Costs Market Prices 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 With Project Plantation Costs 0.027 0.026 0.033 0.042 0.042 0.049 0.05 0.053 0.056 Labor 0.011 0.011 0.013 0.017 0.017 0.019 0.02 0.021 0.022 Import 0.016 0.016 0.02 0.025 0.025 0.029 0.03 0.032 0.034 Area 6,575 7,624 16,346 25,706 41,991 44,330 58,568 58,897 73,195 Effective Area 4,931 5,718 12,260 19,280 31,493 33,248 43,926 44,173 54,896 Plantation Costs (mill. US$) 0.133 0.151 0.399 0.81 1.317 1.614 2.182 2.361 3.094 Without Project Alternative Productions Area (in ha) 6,575 14,199 30,545 56,251 98,242 142,572 201,140 260,037 333,232 Labor 0.003 0.003 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.005 0.005 0.005 0.005 Import 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 Prod Costs 0.03 0.06 0.16 0.28 0.52 0.92 1.36 1.83 2.28 Incremental (mill. US$) 0.1 0.09 0.23 0.53 0.8 0.69 0.82 0.53 0.82 Shadow Prices With Project Plantation Costs 0.021 0.021 0.026 0.034 0.033 0.039 0.04 0.043 0.045 Labor 0.009 0.008 0.01 0.013 0.013 0.015 0.016 0.017 0.018 Import 0.013 0.013 0.016 0.02 0.02 0.023 0.024 0.026 0.027 Area 6,575 7,624 16,346 25,706 41,991 44,330 58,568 58,897 73,195 Effective Area 4,931 5,718 12,260 19,280 31,493 33,248 43,926 44,173 54,896 Total Plantation Costs 0.11 0.12 0.32 0.65 1.05 1.29 1.75 1.89 2.48 Production Costs With (million US$) 0.11 0.12 0.32 0.65 1.05 1.29 1.75 1.89 2.48 Without Project Prod Costs (1,000 US$/ha) 0 0 0 0 0 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 Labor 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.004 Import 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.002 0.002 Area (in ha) 6,575 14,199 30,545 56,251 98,242 142,572 201,140 260,037 333,232 Total Prod. Costs (mill. US$) 0.02 0.05 0.13 0.22 0.42 0.74 1.09 1.46 1.82 Incremental (mill. US$) 0.08 0.07 0.19 0.42 0.64 0.55 0.66 0.43 0.65 142
  • 155. Table 46 (Cont) Production Costs Market Prices 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 With Project Plantation Costs 0.056 0.056 0.051 0.051 0.037 0.045 0.037 0.037 Labor 0.022 0.022 0.02 0.02 0.015 0.018 0.015 0.015 Import 0.034 0.034 0.031 0.031 0.022 0.027 0.022 0.022 Area 84,777 73,008 58,013 51,956 29,730 26,595 37,995 42,555 Effective Area 63,583 54,756 43,510 38,967 22,298 19,946 28,496 31,916 Plantation Costs (mill. US$) 3.591 3.047 2.224 1.979 0.831 0.895 1.052 1.178 Without Project Alternative Productions Area (in ha) 418,009 491,017 549,030 600,986 630,716 657,311 695,305 737,860 Labor 0.005 0.005 0.005 0.004 0.006 0.004 0.005 0.006 Import 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 Prod Costs 2.94 3.33 3.69 3.76 4.79 4 4.6 5.67 Incremental (mill. US$) 0.65 -0.28 -1.47 -1.78 -3.96 -3.11 -3.55 -4.49 With Project Plantation Costs 0.045 0.045 0.041 0.041 0.03 0.027 0.022 0.022 Labor 0.018 0.018 0.016 0.016 0.012 0.011 0.009 0.009 Import 0.027 0.027 0.025 0.024 0.018 0.016 0.013 0.013 Area 84,777 73,008 58,013 51,956 29,730 26,595 37,995 42,555 Effective Area 63,583 54,756 43,510 38,967 22,298 19,946 28,496 31,916 Total Plantation Costs 2.87 2.44 1.78 1.58 0.67 0.54 0.63 0.71 Production Costs With (million US$) 2.87 2.44 1.78 1.58 0.67 0.54 0.63 0.71 Without Project Prod Costs (1,000 US$/ha) 0.006 0.005 0.005 0.005 0.006 0.004 0.004 0.005 Labor 0.004 0.004 0.004 0.003 0.004 0.002 0.003 0.003 Import 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.001 Area (in ha) 418,009 491,017 549,030 600,986 630,716 657,311 695,305 737,860 Total Prod. Costs (mill. US$) 2.35 2.66 2.95 3.01 3.83 2.4 2.76 3.4 Incremental (mill. US$) 0.52 -0.22 -1.17 -1.43 -3.17 -1.86 -2.13 -2.7 143
  • 156. Table 47. Labor Costs Exports (million US$) With 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Wood Exported (1,000 m3) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.73 0.80 1.91 3.33 6.40 6.66 8.64 8.38 Total Costs market prices 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.28 0.30 0.73 1.26 2.43 2.53 3.28 3.19 Total Costs shadow prices 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.17 0.18 0.44 0.76 1.95 2.03 2.63 2.55 Table 48. Pruning and Thinning Costs (million US$) With 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Pruning (million US$) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.03 0.10 0.13 0.38 0.46 0.72 0.87 1.34 2.32 2.72 3.33 3.54 1,000 US$/ha 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.06 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.07 Total (1,000 US$) First 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 22 34 65 75 248 296 386 477 703 1542 1632 1308 1204 Second 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 33 51 87 100 248 296 386 477 703 1542 1632 Third 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 44 67 87 100 248 296 386 477 703 Thinning (million US$) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.03 Total Costs market prices (million US$) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.03 0.10 0.13 0.38 0.46 0.72 0.87 1.35 2.34 2.75 3.36 3.57 Total Costs shadow prices (million US$) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.06 0.08 0.23 0.28 0.43 0.52 0.81 1.88 2.20 2.69 2.85 144
  • 157. Table 49. Administration and Management Costs (million US$) Administration and Management Costs With 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Management 0.00 0.09 0.19 0.32 0.57 0.92 1.18 1.41 1.61 1.82 2.15 2.11 1.71 1.05 0.61 0.69 1.19 Ants Control 0.00 0.03 0.04 0.08 0.12 0.20 0.22 0.29 0.29 0.36 0.41 0.34 0.26 0.11 0.11 0.14 0.28 Paths 0.00 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.08 0.13 0.14 0.19 0.19 0.24 0.27 0.23 0.17 0.07 0.07 0.09 0.19 Administration 0.21 0.24 0.53 0.84 1.37 1.45 1.93 1.94 2.42 2.79 2.36 1.84 1.60 0.42 0.65 1.34 2.14 Total Costs market prices 0.21 0.26 0.99 1.38 2.18 2.74 3.64 3.81 4.49 5.37 5.08 4.35 3.49 0.72 1.07 2.42 5.78 Total Costs shadow prices 0.20 0.25 0.97 1.35 2.14 2.69 3.57 3.73 4.40 5.26 4.98 4.26 3.42 0.72 1.07 2.42 5.78 Table 50. Harvesting Costs With 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Labor 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 3.06 3.21 7.55 13.35 10.08 18.00 32.60 44.99 Pulp 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 3.06 3.21 7.55 11.94 8.65 15.40 29.60 41.06 Sawn wood 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.41 1.43 2.60 3.00 3.94 Fuel 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.67 1.75 4.12 7.28 5.50 9.82 17.78 24.54 Rest 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.84 0.88 2.06 3.64 2.75 4.91 8.89 12.27 Total Costs market prices (million US$) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 5.57 5.84 13.72 24.26 18.33 32.73 59.27 81.81 Total Costs shadow prices (million US$) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 4.30 4.50 10.58 18.72 12.31 21.99 39.83 54.97 145
  • 158. Table 51. Nursery Costs 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Labor 87% 94% 94% 94% 94% 94% 94% 94% 94% Imports 13% 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% Area planted (ha) 4,419 5,121 11,241 17,825 29,065 30,741 40,882 41,136 51,197 Costs (1,000 US$/ha) 0.043 0.048 0.061 0.067 0.08 0.081 0.077 0.077 0.072 Average Costs (1,000 US$/ha) 0.065 Total Costs market prices (mill.US$) 0.19 0.25 0.69 1.2 2.32 2.49 3.16 3.15 3.71 Total Costs shadow prices (mill. US$) 0.16 0.21 0.59 1.03 2 2.15 2.73 2.73 3.21 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Labor 94% 94% 94% 94% 94% 94% 94% 94% Imports 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% 6% Area planted (ha) 59,159 50,969 40,497 36,294 20,763 18,595 26,596 29,788 Costs (1,000 US$/ha) 0.067 0.043 0.063 0.061 0.028 0.048 0.069 0.099 Average Costs (1,000 US$/ha) Total Costs market prices (mill.US$) 3.94 2.19 2.54 2.2 0.58 0.9 1.85 2.95 Total Costs shadow prices (mill. US$) 3.41 1.89 2.2 1.9 0.51 0.78 1.6 2.55 146