SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Models with Multiple
Explanatory Variables
Chapter 2 assumed that the dependent variable (Y) is affected by only ONE
explanatory variable (X).
Sometimes this is the case.
Example: Age = Days Alive/365.25
Usually, this is not the case.
Example: midterm mark depends on:
 how much you study
 how well you study
 intelligence, etc
1
4. Multi Variable Examples:
Demand = f( price of good, price of substitutes, income, price of compliments)
Consumption = f( income, tastes, wages)
Graduation rates = f( tuition, school quality, student quality)
Christmas present satisfaction = f (cost, timing, knowledge of person, presence of
card, age, etc.)
2
4. The Partial Derivative
It is often impossible analyze ONE variable’s impact if ALL variables are changing.
Instead, we analyze one variable’s impact, assuming ALL OTHER VARIABLES
REMAIN CONSTANT
We do this through the partial derivative.
This chapter uses the partial derivative to expand the topics introduced in chapter
2.
3
4. Calculus and Applications involving More
than One Variable
4.1 Derivatives of Functions of More Than One
Variable
4.2 Applications Using Partial Derivatives
4.3 Partial and Total Derivatives
4.4 Unconstrained Optimization
4.5 Constrained Optimization
4
4.1 Partial Derivatives
Consider the function z=f(x,y). As this function takes into account 3 variables, it
must be graphed on a 3-dimensional graph.
A partial derivative calculates the slope of a
2-dimensional “slice” of this 3-dimensional graph.
The partial derivative ∂z/∂x asks how x affects z while y is held constant (ceteris
paribus).
5
4.1 Partial Derivatives
In taking the partial deriv
ative, all other variables are kept constant and hence treated as constants (the
derivative of a constant is 0).
There are a variety of ways to indicate the partial derivative:
1) ∂y/∂x
2) ∂f(x,z)/∂x
3) fx(x,z)
Note: dy=dx is equivalent to ∂y/∂x if y=f(x); ie: if y only has x as an explanatory
variable.
(Therefore often these are used interchangeably in economic shorthand)
6
4.1 Partial Derivatives
Let y = 2x2
+3xz+8z2
∂y/ ∂x = 4x+3z+0
∂y/ ∂z = 0+3x+16z
(0’s are dropped)
Let y = xln(zx)
∂ y/ ∂ x = ln(zx) + zx/zx
= ln(zx) + 1
∂ y/ ∂ z = x(1/zx)x
=x/z
7
4.1 Partial Derivatives
Let y = 3x2
z+xz3
-3z/x2
∂ y/ ∂ z=3x2
+3xz2
-3/x2
∂ y/ ∂ x=6xz+z3
+6z/x3
Try these:
z=ln(2y+x3
)
Expenses=sin(a2
-ab)+cos(b2
-ab)
8
4.1.1 Higher Partial Derivatives
Higher order partial derivates are evaluated exactly like normal higher order
derivatives.
It is important, however, to note what variable to differentiate with respect to:
From before:
Let y = 3x2
z+xz3
-3z/x2
∂ y/ ∂ z=3x2
+3xz2
-3/x2
∂ 2
y/ ∂ z2
=6xz
∂ 2
y/ ∂ z ∂ x=6x+3z2
+6/x3
9
4.1.1 Young’s Theorem
From before:
Let y = 3x2
z+xz3
-3z/x2
∂ y/ ∂ x=6xz+z3
+6z/x3
∂ 2
y/ ∂ x2
=6z-18z/x4
∂ 2
y/ ∂ x ∂ z=6x+3z2
+6/x3
Notice that ∂2
y/∂x∂z=∂2
y/∂z∂x
This is reflected by YOUNG’S THEOREM: order of differentiation doesn’t matter
for higher order partial derivatives
10
4.2 Applications using Partial Derivatives
As many real-world situations involve many variables, Partial Derivatives can be
used to analyze our world, using tools including:
 Interpreting coefficients
 Marginal Products
11
4.2.1 Interpreting Coefficients
Given a function a=f(b,c,d), the dependent variable a is determined by a variety of
explanatory variables b, c, and d.
If all dependent variables change at once, it is hard to determine if one dependent
variables has a positive or negative effect on a.
A partial derivative, such as ∂ a/ ∂ c, asks how one explanatory variable (c), affects
the dependent variable, a, HOLDING ALL OTHER DEPENDENT VARIABLES
CONSTANT (ceteris paribus)
12
4.2.1 Interpreting Coefficients
A second derivative with respect to the same variable discusses curvature.
A second cross partial derivative asks how the impact of one explanatory variable
changes as another explanatory variable changes.
Ie: If Happiness = f(food, tv),
∂ 2
h/ ∂ f ∂tv asks how watching more tv affects food’s effect on happiness (or how
food affects tv’s effect on happiness). For example, watching TV may not
increase happiness if someone is hungry.
13
4.2.1 Corn Example
Consider the following formula for corn production:
Corn = 500+100Rain-Rain2
+50Scare*Fertilizer
Corn = bushels of corn
Rain = centimeters of rain
Scare=number of scarecrows
Fertilizer = tonnes of fertilizer
Explain this formula
14
4.2.1 Corny Example
1) Intercept = 500
-if it doesn’t rain, there are no scarecrows and no fertilizer, the farmer will
harvest 500 bushels
2) ∂Corn/∂Rain=100-2Rain
-each additional cm of rain changes corn production by 100-2Rain
-positive impact if rain < 50 cm
-negative impact if rain > 50 cm
15
4.2.1 Corny Example
3) ∂2
Corn/∂Rain2
=-2<0, (concave)
-More rain has a DECREASING impact on the corn harvest
-More rain DECREASES rain’s impact on the corn harvest by 2
4) ∂Corn/∂Scare=50Fertilizer
-More scarecrows will increase the harvest 50 for every tonne of fertilizer
-if no fertilizer is used, scarecrows are useless
16
4.2.1 Corny Example
5) ∂ 2
Corn/∂Scare2
=0 (straight line, no curvature)
-Additional scarecrows have a CONSTANT impact on corn’s harvest
6) ∂ 2
Corn/∂Scare∂Fertilizer=50
-Additional fertilizer increases scarecrow’s impact on the corn harvest by 50
17
4.2.1 Corny Example
7) ∂Corn/∂Fertilizer=50Scare
-More fertilizer will increase the harvest 50 for every scarecrow
-if no scarecrows are used, fertilizer is useless
8) ∂ 2
Corn/∂Fertilizer2
=0, (straight line)
-Additional fertilizer has a CONSTANT impact on corn’s harvest
18
4.2.1 Corny Example
9) ∂ 2
Corn/∂Fertilizer ∂Scare =50
-Additional scarecrows increase fertilizer’s impact on the corn harvest by 50
19
4.2.2 Partial Derivatives and
Marginal Product
Consider the function Q=f(L,K,)
The partial derivative is the change in output if one input (labour or capital)
increases by one.
 The partial derivative IS the MARGINAL PRODUCT of an production function
∂ Q/ ∂ L=Marginal Product of Labour (MPL)
∂ Q/ ∂ K=Marginal Product of Capital (MPK)
20
4.2.2 Cobb-Douglas Production Function
A favorite function of economists is the Cobb-Douglas Production Function of the
form
Q=aLb
Kc
Of
Where L=labour, K=Capital, and O=Other (education, technology, government,
etc.)
This is an attractive function because if b+c+f=1, the demand function is
homogeneous of degree 1. (Doubling all inputs doubles outputs…a happy
concept)
21
4.2.2 Cobb-Douglas University
Consider a production function for university degrees:
Q=aLb
Kc
Af
Where
L=Labour (ie: professors),
K=Capital (ie: classrooms)
A=Administration
22
4.2.2 Average and Marginal Products
Finding partial derivatives:
∂ Q/ ∂ L =abLb-1
Kc
Af
=b(aLb
Kc
Af
)/L
=b(Q/L) OR
=b* average product of labour
-in other words, adding an additional professor will contribute a fraction of the
average product of each current professor
-this partial derivative gives us the MARGINAL PRODUCT of labour
23
4.2.2 Cobb-Douglas Professors
For example, if 20 professors are employed by the department, and 500
students graduate yearly, and b=0.5:
∂ Q/ ∂ L =0.5(500/20)
=12.5
Ie: Hiring another professor will graduate 12.5 more students. The marginal
product of labour is 12.5
24
4.3 Total Derivatives
Often in econometrics, one variable is influenced by a variety of other variables.
Ie: Happiness =f(sun, driving)
Ie: Productivity = f(labor, effectiveness)
Using TOTAL DERIVATIVES, we can examine how growth of one variable is caused by growth in all other variables
The following formulae will combine x’s impact on y (dy/dx) with x’s impact on y, with other variables held constant
(δy/δx)
25
4.3 Total Derivatives
Assume you are increasing the square footage of a house where
AREA = LENGTH X WIDTH
A=LW
If you increase the length,
the change in area is equal
to the increase in length
times the current width:
26
Length
Area
dL
Notice that:
δA/δL=W, (partial derivative, since width is constant)
Therefore the increase in area is equal to:
dA=(δA/δL)dL
4.3 Total Derivatives
A=LW
If you increase the width,
the change in area is equal
to the increase in width
times the current length:
27
Length
Area
dW
Notice that:
δA/δW=L, (partial derivative, since length is constant)
Therefore the increase in area is equal to:
dA=(δA/δW)dW
Next we combine the two effects:
4.3 Total Derivatives
A=LW
An increase in both length
and width has the following
impact on area:
28
Length
Area
dW
Now we have:
dA=(δA/δL)dL+(δA/δW)dW+(dW)dL
But since derivatives always deal with instantaneous slope
and small changes, (dW)dL is small and ignored, resulting in:
dA=(δA/δL)dL+(δA/δW)dW
dL
4.3 Total Derivatives
29
Length
Area
dW
dA=(δA/δL)dL+(δA/δW)dW
Effectively, we see that change in the dependent variable (A),
comes from changes in the independent variables (W and L).
In general, given the function z=f(x,y) we have:
dL
dy
y
z
dx
x
z
dy
y
y
x
f
dx
x
y
x
f
dz












)
,
(
)
,
(
The key advantage of the total derivative is it takes variable
interaction into account.
The partial derivative (δz/δx) examines the effect of x on z if
y doesn’t change. This is the DIRECT EFFECT.
However, if x affects y which then affects z, we might want
to measure this INDIRECT EFFECT.
We can modify the total derivative to do this:
4.3 Total Derivative Final Form
30
dx
dy
y
z
x
z
dx
dy
y
z
dx
dx
x
z
dx
dz
dy
y
z
dx
x
z
dy
y
y
x
f
dx
x
y
x
f
dz
























)
,
(
)
,
(
4.3 Total Derivative Extension
31
dx
dy
y
z
x
z
dx
dy
y
z
dx
dx
x
z
dx
dz
dy
y
z
dx
x
z
dy
y
y
x
f
dx
x
y
x
f
dz
























)
,
(
)
,
(
Here we see that x’s total impact on z is broken up into two
parts:
1)x’s DIRECT impact on z (through the partial derivative)
2)x’s INDIRECT impact on z (through y)
Obviously, if x and y are unrelated, (δy/δx)=0, then the total
derivative collapses to the partial derivative
4.3 Total Derivative Example
32
Assume Happiness=Candy+3(Candy)Money+Money2
h=c+3cm+m2
Furthermore, Candy=3+Money/4 (c=3+m/4)
The total derivative of happiness with regards to money:
m
c
dm
dh
m
m
c
dm
dh
dm
dc
c
h
m
h
dm
dh
75
.
2
3
25
.
0
)]
4
/
1
)(
3
1
[(
]
2
3
[













4.3 Total Derivative and Elasticity
33
Total derivatives can also give us the relationship between
elasticity and revenue that we found in Chapter 2.2.3:
demand)
of
elasticity
price
is
(where
)
1
(
)
1
(















Q
dP
dTR
dP
dQ
Q
P
Q
dP
dTR
dP
dQ
P
dP
dP
Q
dP
dTR
dQ
Q
TR
dP
P
TR
dTR
PQ
TR
4.4 Unconstrained Optimization
Unconstrained optimization falls into two categories:
1) Optimization using one variable (ie: changing wage to
increase productivity, working conditions are constant)
2) Optimization using two (or more) variables (ie: changing
wage and working conditions to maximize productivity)
34
4.4 Simple Unconstrained Optimization
For a multivariable case where only one variable is
controlled, optimization steps are easy:
Consider the function z=f(x)
1) FOC:
Determine where δz/δx=0 (necessary condition)
2) SOC:
δ2
z/δx2
<0 is necessary for a maximum
δ2
z/δx2
>0 is necessary for a minimum
3) Determine max/min point
Substitute the point in (2) back into the original equation.
35
4.4 Simple Unconstrained Optimization
Let productivity = -wage2
+10wage(working conditions)2
P(w,c)=-w2
+10wc2
If working conditions=2, find the wage that maximizes productivity
P(w,c)=-w2
+40w
1) FOC:
δp/δw =-2w+40=0
w=20
2) SOC:
δ2
p/δw2
= -2 < 0, a maximum exists
36
4.4 Simple Unconstrained Optimization
P(w,c)=-w2
+10wc2
w=20 (maximum confirmed)
3) Find Maximum
P(20,4)=-202
+10(20)(2)2
P(20,4)=-400+800
P(20,4)=400
Productivity is maximized at 400 when wage is 20.
37
4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization
For a multivariable case where only two variable are
controlled, optimization steps are more in-depth:
Consider the function z=f(x,y)
1) FOC:
Determine where δz/δx=0 (necessary condition)
And
Determine where δz/δy=0 (necessary condition)
38
4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization
For a multivariable case where only two variable are
controlled, optimization steps harder:
Consider the function z=f(x,y)
2) SOC:
δ2
z/δx2
<0 and δ2
z/δy2
<0 are necessary for a maximum
δ2
z/δx2
>0 and δ2
z/δy2
>0 are necessary for a minimum
Plus, the cross derivatives can’t be too large compared to the
own second partial derivatives:
39
0
2
2
2
2
2
2

































y
x
z
y
z
x
z
4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization
If this third SOC requirement is not fulfilled, a SADDLE POINT
occurs, where z is a maximum with regards to one
variable but a minimum with regards to the other. (ie:
wage maximizes productivity while working conditions
minimizes it)
Vaguely, even though both variables work to increase z,
their interaction with each other outweighs this
maximizing effect
40
0
2
2
2
2
2
2

































y
x
z
y
z
x
z
4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization
Let P(w,c)=-w2
+wc-c2
+9c , maximize productivity
1) FOC:
δp/δw =-2w+c=0
2w=c
δp/δc=w-2c+9=0
w=2c-9
w=2(2w)-9
-3w=-9
w=3
2w=c
6=c
41
4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization
P(w,c)=-w2
+wc-c2
+9c
δp/δw =-2w+c=0
δp/δc=w-2c+9=0
w=3, c=6 (possible max/min)
2) SOC:
δ2
p/δw2
= -2 < 0
δ2
p/δc2
= -2 < 0, possible max
42
0
3
1
)
2
)(
2
(
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2






































































c
w
p
c
p
w
p
c
w
p
c
p
w
p Maximum confirmed
4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization
P(w,c)=-w2
+wc-c2
+9c
w=3, c=6 (confirmed max)
3) Find productivity:
43
27
)
,
(
54
36
18
9
)
,
(
)
6
(
9
6
6
)
3
(
3
)
,
(
9
)
,
(
2
2
2
2
















c
w
p
c
w
p
c
w
p
c
c
wc
w
c
w
p
Productivity is maximized at 27 when wage=3 and working
conditions=6.
4.5 Constrained Optimization
Typically constrained optimization consists of maximizing or minimizing an objective function with regards
to a constraint, or
Max/min z=f(x,y)
Subject to (s.t.): g(x,y)=k
Where k is a constant
44
4.5 Constrained Optimization
Often economic agents are not free to make any decision they would like. They are
CONSTRAINED by factors such as income, time, intelligence, etc.
When optimizing with constraints, we have two general methods:
1) Internalizing the constraint
2) Creating a Lagrangeian function
45
4.5 Internalizing Constraints
If the constraint can be substituted into the
equation to be optimized, we are left with an
unconstrained optimization problem:
Example:
Bob works a full week, but every Saturday he has
seven hours left free, either to watch TV or read.
He faces the constrained optimization problem:
Max. Utility=7TV-TV2
+Read (U=7TV-TV2
+R)
s.t. 7=TV+Read (7=TV+R)
46
4.5 Internalizing Constraints
Max. U=7TV-TV2
+R
s.t. 7=TV+R
We can solve the constraint:
R=7-TV
And substitute into the objective function:
U=-TV2
+7TV+(7-TV)
U=-TV2
+6TV+7
47
4.5 The Lagrangian
L=z*=z(x,y)+λ(k-g(x,y))
After finding FOC’s, to confirm a maximum or minimum, the SOC is employed.
This SOC must be negative for a maximum and positive for a minimum
Note that for more terms, this function becomes exponentially complicated.
SOC’s:
48























































δxδy
z
δ
δy
δg
δx
δg
2
δx
z
δ
δy
δg
δy
z
δ
δx
δg 2
2
2
2
2
2
2
SOC
4.5 Lagrangian example
Max. U=7TV-TV2
+R
s.t. 7=TV+R
L=z*=z(x,y)+λ(k-g(x,y))
L=7TV-TV2
+R+λ(7-TV-R)
FOC:
49
2TV
-
7
0
-
2TV
-
7







TV
L
1
0
-
1







R
L
R
V
T




T
7
0
R
-
V
-
7

L
4.5 Lagrangian example
50
R
TV 



7
)
3
(
1
)
2
(
2TV
-
7
)
1
(


3
1
2
7
)
2
(
)
1
(




TV
TV
R
R
R
V





4
3
7
T
7
:
)
3
(
4.5 Lagrangian Example
51
           
0
2
0
1
1
2
2
-
1
0
1
δTVδR
z
δ
δR
δg
δTV
δg
2
δTV
z
δ
δR
δg
δR
z
δ
δTV
δg
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2

























































SOC
SOC
SOC
Since the second order condition is negative, the points
found are a maximum.
Notice that we found the same answers as internalizing the
constraint.
4.5 The Lagrange Multiplier
The Lagrange Multiplier, λ, provides a measure of how much of an impact
relaxing the constraint would make, or how the objective function
changes if k of g(x,y)=k is marginally increased.
The Lagrange multiplier answers how much the maximum or minimum
changes when the constraint g(x,y)=k increases slightly to g(x,y)=k+δ
52
4.5 Lagrangian example
53
1
2(3)
-
7
2TV
-
7
4
3
2TV
-
7








R
TV
This means that if Bob gets an extra hour, his maximum utility
will increase by approximately 1.
(Alternately, if Bob loses an hour of leisure, his maximum
utility will decrease by approximately 1.)
Check:
If 8=TV+R, TV=3.5, R=4.5, U=16.75
(utility increases by approximately 1)
Constrained Optimization
So far we have discussed optimizing functions without
placing restrictions upon the values that the independent
variables can assume. Such problems are often referred to as
free maxima and minima or free optima.
However, in the real world, often
restrictions or constraints
are placed upon values of the independent
variables.
These problems are referred to as
constrained optima or constrained optimization.
Constrained Optimization
constraint
Constrained
maximum
Free
maximu
m
Graphically, the difference between the free optima
and the constrained optima can be shown as:
• The free optima occurs at the peak of the
surface.
• If we specify a specific relationship between
variables and (a constraint) then the
search for an optimum is restricted to a slice
of the surface. The constrained maximum
occurs at the peak of the slice.
constraint
Constrained
maximum
Free
maximu
m
Constrained Optimization
• Since economists deal with the allocation of
scarce resources among alternative uses, the
concept of constraints or restrictions is
important.
• There are two approaches to solving
constrained optima problems:
(i) substitution method
(ii) Lagrange multipliers
Substitution Method
• Consider a firm producing commodity with
the following production function:
• Without any constraints, the firm can produce
an unlimited quantity by utilizing an unlimited
amount
of and .
Substitution Method
• But suppose the firm has a budget constraint:
Let
• For simplicity, assume that the maximum
amount the firm can spend on these two inputs
is $100.
• So we have the following constraint:
Substitution Method
• Suppose the economic question facing this firm
is maximizing production subject to this budget
constraint.
• The solution via the substitution method is to
substitute:
• First, write the constraint in terms of :
Substitution Method
• Then substitute this value into the production
function, such that:
• With this substitution, the constrained
maxima problem is reduced to a free maxima
problem with one independent variable.
Substitution Method
• Now apply the usual optimization procedure:
(critical value)
Substitution Method
◦ The method of substitution is one way to
solve constrained optima problems. This is
manageable in some cases. In others, the
constraint may be very complicated and
substitution becomes complex.
Lagrange Multipliers
 The constrained optima problem can be
stated as finding the extreme value of
subject to .
 So Lagrange (a mathematician) formed the
augmented function.
denotes augmented function
will behave like the function if the constraint is foll
Lagrange Multipliers
• Given the augmented function, the first order
condition for optimization (where the
independent variables are , and λ) is as
follows:
Lagrange Multipliers
 Using the previous example:
note:
to be on the budget
line
Lagrange Multipliers
• Solving these 3 equations simultaneously:
Lagrange Multipliers
• Solving these 3 equations simultaneously
(cont’d):
Lagrange Multipliers
• Solving these 3 equations simultaneously
(cont’d):
Lagrange Multipliers
• If , then
• This solution yields the same answer as the substitution
method, i.e., and .
Lagrange Multipliers
• Economists prefer using the Lagrange technique
over the substitution method, because:
Namely for (ii), the value of λ has an
economic interpretation. (There is no
counterpart to this variable in the substitution
method).
(i) easier to handle for most cases and
(ii) provides additional information.
Lagrange Multipliers
 Given,
where C is the level of expenditures
(budget = $100 in this example).
here the Lagrange multiplier measures the
sensitivity of to changes in the constraint
(C ).
Lagrange Multipliers
 2nd
order conditions
Given
 1st
order conditions for extremum:
Lagrange Multipliers
• 2nd
order conditions involve second order partial
derivatives expressed in the form of a
determinant.
• In the constraint case, we will utilize the
bordered Hessian – which is the Hessian of the
free optima case surrounded by the partial
derivatives with respect to the Lagrange
multiplier λ.
Lagrange Multipliers
 2nd
order partials:
Lagrange Multipliers
 2nd
order partials:
Lagrange Multipliers
 2 explanatory variables and 1 constraint is the largest
size bordered Hessian we will consider for this class.
Note: partials with respect to Lagrange
multiplier (λ) form the border
Lagrange Multipliers
 So the 2nd
order condition is:
 Let’s now return to our previous example:
◦ Recall the critical values of ,
and .
Lagrange Multipliers
• What about the 2nd
order conditions?
Lagrange Multipliers
Find
Lagrange Multipliers
Expand by 1st
row:
Lagrange Multipliers
represents a rel max.
represents a rel max.

More Related Content

PDF
fouriertransform.pdf
PPTX
Applications of partial differentiation
PDF
Direct Variation.ppt.pdf type of variations
PPTX
partialderivatives
PPTX
3.6 applications in optimization
PPT
equationandinequalities-131007011741-phpapp01.ppt
PDF
Partial diferential good
PPT
209759095-Technique-of-Differentiation-Ppt-03.ppt
fouriertransform.pdf
Applications of partial differentiation
Direct Variation.ppt.pdf type of variations
partialderivatives
3.6 applications in optimization
equationandinequalities-131007011741-phpapp01.ppt
Partial diferential good
209759095-Technique-of-Differentiation-Ppt-03.ppt

Similar to Integrations with applications for engineering students (20)

PPTX
solve wordproblems Direct-Variation.pptx
PPTX
Direct Variation.ppt.pptx YYY
PPT
Lec5_Product & Quotient Rule.ppt
PPT
Equation and inequalities
PPTX
CALCULUS PRESENTATION.pptx.ecnomic and finance course
DOCX
Limits and continuity[1]
PPTX
CO-1 SESSIOuiopyhrtgjkhntgkljhnrtgN-4.pptx
PDF
Formulas
PPTX
Kalkulus - 20 Oct Introduction to Derivative.pptx
PDF
mathspresentation-160419194459.pdf
PPT
Direct variation power point
PPT
5.2 Directvariation
PPT
Cost function
PPTX
Derivatives and their Applications
PDF
AppsDiff3c.pdf
PDF
Average value by integral method
PDF
poster2
PPTX
5.6 solving exponential and logarithmic equations
solve wordproblems Direct-Variation.pptx
Direct Variation.ppt.pptx YYY
Lec5_Product & Quotient Rule.ppt
Equation and inequalities
CALCULUS PRESENTATION.pptx.ecnomic and finance course
Limits and continuity[1]
CO-1 SESSIOuiopyhrtgjkhntgkljhnrtgN-4.pptx
Formulas
Kalkulus - 20 Oct Introduction to Derivative.pptx
mathspresentation-160419194459.pdf
Direct variation power point
5.2 Directvariation
Cost function
Derivatives and their Applications
AppsDiff3c.pdf
Average value by integral method
poster2
5.6 solving exponential and logarithmic equations
Ad

Recently uploaded (20)

PPTX
Engineering Ethics, Safety and Environment [Autosaved] (1).pptx
PDF
PRIZ Academy - 9 Windows Thinking Where to Invest Today to Win Tomorrow.pdf
PDF
PPT on Performance Review to get promotions
PPTX
Geodesy 1.pptx...............................................
PDF
Well-logging-methods_new................
PPTX
Current and future trends in Computer Vision.pptx
PDF
The CXO Playbook 2025 – Future-Ready Strategies for C-Suite Leaders Cerebrai...
PPTX
Lecture Notes Electrical Wiring System Components
PDF
Unit I ESSENTIAL OF DIGITAL MARKETING.pdf
PDF
TFEC-4-2020-Design-Guide-for-Timber-Roof-Trusses.pdf
PPTX
Internet of Things (IOT) - A guide to understanding
DOCX
573137875-Attendance-Management-System-original
PDF
Mohammad Mahdi Farshadian CV - Prospective PhD Student 2026
PPTX
additive manufacturing of ss316l using mig welding
PPTX
Safety Seminar civil to be ensured for safe working.
PPTX
FINAL REVIEW FOR COPD DIANOSIS FOR PULMONARY DISEASE.pptx
PPTX
Artificial Intelligence
PDF
Operating System & Kernel Study Guide-1 - converted.pdf
PDF
Automation-in-Manufacturing-Chapter-Introduction.pdf
PPTX
OOP with Java - Java Introduction (Basics)
Engineering Ethics, Safety and Environment [Autosaved] (1).pptx
PRIZ Academy - 9 Windows Thinking Where to Invest Today to Win Tomorrow.pdf
PPT on Performance Review to get promotions
Geodesy 1.pptx...............................................
Well-logging-methods_new................
Current and future trends in Computer Vision.pptx
The CXO Playbook 2025 – Future-Ready Strategies for C-Suite Leaders Cerebrai...
Lecture Notes Electrical Wiring System Components
Unit I ESSENTIAL OF DIGITAL MARKETING.pdf
TFEC-4-2020-Design-Guide-for-Timber-Roof-Trusses.pdf
Internet of Things (IOT) - A guide to understanding
573137875-Attendance-Management-System-original
Mohammad Mahdi Farshadian CV - Prospective PhD Student 2026
additive manufacturing of ss316l using mig welding
Safety Seminar civil to be ensured for safe working.
FINAL REVIEW FOR COPD DIANOSIS FOR PULMONARY DISEASE.pptx
Artificial Intelligence
Operating System & Kernel Study Guide-1 - converted.pdf
Automation-in-Manufacturing-Chapter-Introduction.pdf
OOP with Java - Java Introduction (Basics)
Ad

Integrations with applications for engineering students

  • 1. Models with Multiple Explanatory Variables Chapter 2 assumed that the dependent variable (Y) is affected by only ONE explanatory variable (X). Sometimes this is the case. Example: Age = Days Alive/365.25 Usually, this is not the case. Example: midterm mark depends on:  how much you study  how well you study  intelligence, etc 1
  • 2. 4. Multi Variable Examples: Demand = f( price of good, price of substitutes, income, price of compliments) Consumption = f( income, tastes, wages) Graduation rates = f( tuition, school quality, student quality) Christmas present satisfaction = f (cost, timing, knowledge of person, presence of card, age, etc.) 2
  • 3. 4. The Partial Derivative It is often impossible analyze ONE variable’s impact if ALL variables are changing. Instead, we analyze one variable’s impact, assuming ALL OTHER VARIABLES REMAIN CONSTANT We do this through the partial derivative. This chapter uses the partial derivative to expand the topics introduced in chapter 2. 3
  • 4. 4. Calculus and Applications involving More than One Variable 4.1 Derivatives of Functions of More Than One Variable 4.2 Applications Using Partial Derivatives 4.3 Partial and Total Derivatives 4.4 Unconstrained Optimization 4.5 Constrained Optimization 4
  • 5. 4.1 Partial Derivatives Consider the function z=f(x,y). As this function takes into account 3 variables, it must be graphed on a 3-dimensional graph. A partial derivative calculates the slope of a 2-dimensional “slice” of this 3-dimensional graph. The partial derivative ∂z/∂x asks how x affects z while y is held constant (ceteris paribus). 5
  • 6. 4.1 Partial Derivatives In taking the partial deriv ative, all other variables are kept constant and hence treated as constants (the derivative of a constant is 0). There are a variety of ways to indicate the partial derivative: 1) ∂y/∂x 2) ∂f(x,z)/∂x 3) fx(x,z) Note: dy=dx is equivalent to ∂y/∂x if y=f(x); ie: if y only has x as an explanatory variable. (Therefore often these are used interchangeably in economic shorthand) 6
  • 7. 4.1 Partial Derivatives Let y = 2x2 +3xz+8z2 ∂y/ ∂x = 4x+3z+0 ∂y/ ∂z = 0+3x+16z (0’s are dropped) Let y = xln(zx) ∂ y/ ∂ x = ln(zx) + zx/zx = ln(zx) + 1 ∂ y/ ∂ z = x(1/zx)x =x/z 7
  • 8. 4.1 Partial Derivatives Let y = 3x2 z+xz3 -3z/x2 ∂ y/ ∂ z=3x2 +3xz2 -3/x2 ∂ y/ ∂ x=6xz+z3 +6z/x3 Try these: z=ln(2y+x3 ) Expenses=sin(a2 -ab)+cos(b2 -ab) 8
  • 9. 4.1.1 Higher Partial Derivatives Higher order partial derivates are evaluated exactly like normal higher order derivatives. It is important, however, to note what variable to differentiate with respect to: From before: Let y = 3x2 z+xz3 -3z/x2 ∂ y/ ∂ z=3x2 +3xz2 -3/x2 ∂ 2 y/ ∂ z2 =6xz ∂ 2 y/ ∂ z ∂ x=6x+3z2 +6/x3 9
  • 10. 4.1.1 Young’s Theorem From before: Let y = 3x2 z+xz3 -3z/x2 ∂ y/ ∂ x=6xz+z3 +6z/x3 ∂ 2 y/ ∂ x2 =6z-18z/x4 ∂ 2 y/ ∂ x ∂ z=6x+3z2 +6/x3 Notice that ∂2 y/∂x∂z=∂2 y/∂z∂x This is reflected by YOUNG’S THEOREM: order of differentiation doesn’t matter for higher order partial derivatives 10
  • 11. 4.2 Applications using Partial Derivatives As many real-world situations involve many variables, Partial Derivatives can be used to analyze our world, using tools including:  Interpreting coefficients  Marginal Products 11
  • 12. 4.2.1 Interpreting Coefficients Given a function a=f(b,c,d), the dependent variable a is determined by a variety of explanatory variables b, c, and d. If all dependent variables change at once, it is hard to determine if one dependent variables has a positive or negative effect on a. A partial derivative, such as ∂ a/ ∂ c, asks how one explanatory variable (c), affects the dependent variable, a, HOLDING ALL OTHER DEPENDENT VARIABLES CONSTANT (ceteris paribus) 12
  • 13. 4.2.1 Interpreting Coefficients A second derivative with respect to the same variable discusses curvature. A second cross partial derivative asks how the impact of one explanatory variable changes as another explanatory variable changes. Ie: If Happiness = f(food, tv), ∂ 2 h/ ∂ f ∂tv asks how watching more tv affects food’s effect on happiness (or how food affects tv’s effect on happiness). For example, watching TV may not increase happiness if someone is hungry. 13
  • 14. 4.2.1 Corn Example Consider the following formula for corn production: Corn = 500+100Rain-Rain2 +50Scare*Fertilizer Corn = bushels of corn Rain = centimeters of rain Scare=number of scarecrows Fertilizer = tonnes of fertilizer Explain this formula 14
  • 15. 4.2.1 Corny Example 1) Intercept = 500 -if it doesn’t rain, there are no scarecrows and no fertilizer, the farmer will harvest 500 bushels 2) ∂Corn/∂Rain=100-2Rain -each additional cm of rain changes corn production by 100-2Rain -positive impact if rain < 50 cm -negative impact if rain > 50 cm 15
  • 16. 4.2.1 Corny Example 3) ∂2 Corn/∂Rain2 =-2<0, (concave) -More rain has a DECREASING impact on the corn harvest -More rain DECREASES rain’s impact on the corn harvest by 2 4) ∂Corn/∂Scare=50Fertilizer -More scarecrows will increase the harvest 50 for every tonne of fertilizer -if no fertilizer is used, scarecrows are useless 16
  • 17. 4.2.1 Corny Example 5) ∂ 2 Corn/∂Scare2 =0 (straight line, no curvature) -Additional scarecrows have a CONSTANT impact on corn’s harvest 6) ∂ 2 Corn/∂Scare∂Fertilizer=50 -Additional fertilizer increases scarecrow’s impact on the corn harvest by 50 17
  • 18. 4.2.1 Corny Example 7) ∂Corn/∂Fertilizer=50Scare -More fertilizer will increase the harvest 50 for every scarecrow -if no scarecrows are used, fertilizer is useless 8) ∂ 2 Corn/∂Fertilizer2 =0, (straight line) -Additional fertilizer has a CONSTANT impact on corn’s harvest 18
  • 19. 4.2.1 Corny Example 9) ∂ 2 Corn/∂Fertilizer ∂Scare =50 -Additional scarecrows increase fertilizer’s impact on the corn harvest by 50 19
  • 20. 4.2.2 Partial Derivatives and Marginal Product Consider the function Q=f(L,K,) The partial derivative is the change in output if one input (labour or capital) increases by one.  The partial derivative IS the MARGINAL PRODUCT of an production function ∂ Q/ ∂ L=Marginal Product of Labour (MPL) ∂ Q/ ∂ K=Marginal Product of Capital (MPK) 20
  • 21. 4.2.2 Cobb-Douglas Production Function A favorite function of economists is the Cobb-Douglas Production Function of the form Q=aLb Kc Of Where L=labour, K=Capital, and O=Other (education, technology, government, etc.) This is an attractive function because if b+c+f=1, the demand function is homogeneous of degree 1. (Doubling all inputs doubles outputs…a happy concept) 21
  • 22. 4.2.2 Cobb-Douglas University Consider a production function for university degrees: Q=aLb Kc Af Where L=Labour (ie: professors), K=Capital (ie: classrooms) A=Administration 22
  • 23. 4.2.2 Average and Marginal Products Finding partial derivatives: ∂ Q/ ∂ L =abLb-1 Kc Af =b(aLb Kc Af )/L =b(Q/L) OR =b* average product of labour -in other words, adding an additional professor will contribute a fraction of the average product of each current professor -this partial derivative gives us the MARGINAL PRODUCT of labour 23
  • 24. 4.2.2 Cobb-Douglas Professors For example, if 20 professors are employed by the department, and 500 students graduate yearly, and b=0.5: ∂ Q/ ∂ L =0.5(500/20) =12.5 Ie: Hiring another professor will graduate 12.5 more students. The marginal product of labour is 12.5 24
  • 25. 4.3 Total Derivatives Often in econometrics, one variable is influenced by a variety of other variables. Ie: Happiness =f(sun, driving) Ie: Productivity = f(labor, effectiveness) Using TOTAL DERIVATIVES, we can examine how growth of one variable is caused by growth in all other variables The following formulae will combine x’s impact on y (dy/dx) with x’s impact on y, with other variables held constant (δy/δx) 25
  • 26. 4.3 Total Derivatives Assume you are increasing the square footage of a house where AREA = LENGTH X WIDTH A=LW If you increase the length, the change in area is equal to the increase in length times the current width: 26 Length Area dL Notice that: δA/δL=W, (partial derivative, since width is constant) Therefore the increase in area is equal to: dA=(δA/δL)dL
  • 27. 4.3 Total Derivatives A=LW If you increase the width, the change in area is equal to the increase in width times the current length: 27 Length Area dW Notice that: δA/δW=L, (partial derivative, since length is constant) Therefore the increase in area is equal to: dA=(δA/δW)dW Next we combine the two effects:
  • 28. 4.3 Total Derivatives A=LW An increase in both length and width has the following impact on area: 28 Length Area dW Now we have: dA=(δA/δL)dL+(δA/δW)dW+(dW)dL But since derivatives always deal with instantaneous slope and small changes, (dW)dL is small and ignored, resulting in: dA=(δA/δL)dL+(δA/δW)dW dL
  • 29. 4.3 Total Derivatives 29 Length Area dW dA=(δA/δL)dL+(δA/δW)dW Effectively, we see that change in the dependent variable (A), comes from changes in the independent variables (W and L). In general, given the function z=f(x,y) we have: dL dy y z dx x z dy y y x f dx x y x f dz             ) , ( ) , (
  • 30. The key advantage of the total derivative is it takes variable interaction into account. The partial derivative (δz/δx) examines the effect of x on z if y doesn’t change. This is the DIRECT EFFECT. However, if x affects y which then affects z, we might want to measure this INDIRECT EFFECT. We can modify the total derivative to do this: 4.3 Total Derivative Final Form 30 dx dy y z x z dx dy y z dx dx x z dx dz dy y z dx x z dy y y x f dx x y x f dz                         ) , ( ) , (
  • 31. 4.3 Total Derivative Extension 31 dx dy y z x z dx dy y z dx dx x z dx dz dy y z dx x z dy y y x f dx x y x f dz                         ) , ( ) , ( Here we see that x’s total impact on z is broken up into two parts: 1)x’s DIRECT impact on z (through the partial derivative) 2)x’s INDIRECT impact on z (through y) Obviously, if x and y are unrelated, (δy/δx)=0, then the total derivative collapses to the partial derivative
  • 32. 4.3 Total Derivative Example 32 Assume Happiness=Candy+3(Candy)Money+Money2 h=c+3cm+m2 Furthermore, Candy=3+Money/4 (c=3+m/4) The total derivative of happiness with regards to money: m c dm dh m m c dm dh dm dc c h m h dm dh 75 . 2 3 25 . 0 )] 4 / 1 )( 3 1 [( ] 2 3 [             
  • 33. 4.3 Total Derivative and Elasticity 33 Total derivatives can also give us the relationship between elasticity and revenue that we found in Chapter 2.2.3: demand) of elasticity price is (where ) 1 ( ) 1 (                Q dP dTR dP dQ Q P Q dP dTR dP dQ P dP dP Q dP dTR dQ Q TR dP P TR dTR PQ TR
  • 34. 4.4 Unconstrained Optimization Unconstrained optimization falls into two categories: 1) Optimization using one variable (ie: changing wage to increase productivity, working conditions are constant) 2) Optimization using two (or more) variables (ie: changing wage and working conditions to maximize productivity) 34
  • 35. 4.4 Simple Unconstrained Optimization For a multivariable case where only one variable is controlled, optimization steps are easy: Consider the function z=f(x) 1) FOC: Determine where δz/δx=0 (necessary condition) 2) SOC: δ2 z/δx2 <0 is necessary for a maximum δ2 z/δx2 >0 is necessary for a minimum 3) Determine max/min point Substitute the point in (2) back into the original equation. 35
  • 36. 4.4 Simple Unconstrained Optimization Let productivity = -wage2 +10wage(working conditions)2 P(w,c)=-w2 +10wc2 If working conditions=2, find the wage that maximizes productivity P(w,c)=-w2 +40w 1) FOC: δp/δw =-2w+40=0 w=20 2) SOC: δ2 p/δw2 = -2 < 0, a maximum exists 36
  • 37. 4.4 Simple Unconstrained Optimization P(w,c)=-w2 +10wc2 w=20 (maximum confirmed) 3) Find Maximum P(20,4)=-202 +10(20)(2)2 P(20,4)=-400+800 P(20,4)=400 Productivity is maximized at 400 when wage is 20. 37
  • 38. 4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization For a multivariable case where only two variable are controlled, optimization steps are more in-depth: Consider the function z=f(x,y) 1) FOC: Determine where δz/δx=0 (necessary condition) And Determine where δz/δy=0 (necessary condition) 38
  • 39. 4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization For a multivariable case where only two variable are controlled, optimization steps harder: Consider the function z=f(x,y) 2) SOC: δ2 z/δx2 <0 and δ2 z/δy2 <0 are necessary for a maximum δ2 z/δx2 >0 and δ2 z/δy2 >0 are necessary for a minimum Plus, the cross derivatives can’t be too large compared to the own second partial derivatives: 39 0 2 2 2 2 2 2                                  y x z y z x z
  • 40. 4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization If this third SOC requirement is not fulfilled, a SADDLE POINT occurs, where z is a maximum with regards to one variable but a minimum with regards to the other. (ie: wage maximizes productivity while working conditions minimizes it) Vaguely, even though both variables work to increase z, their interaction with each other outweighs this maximizing effect 40 0 2 2 2 2 2 2                                  y x z y z x z
  • 41. 4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization Let P(w,c)=-w2 +wc-c2 +9c , maximize productivity 1) FOC: δp/δw =-2w+c=0 2w=c δp/δc=w-2c+9=0 w=2c-9 w=2(2w)-9 -3w=-9 w=3 2w=c 6=c 41
  • 42. 4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization P(w,c)=-w2 +wc-c2 +9c δp/δw =-2w+c=0 δp/δc=w-2c+9=0 w=3, c=6 (possible max/min) 2) SOC: δ2 p/δw2 = -2 < 0 δ2 p/δc2 = -2 < 0, possible max 42 0 3 1 ) 2 )( 2 ( 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2                                                                       c w p c p w p c w p c p w p Maximum confirmed
  • 43. 4.4 Complex Unconstrained Optimization P(w,c)=-w2 +wc-c2 +9c w=3, c=6 (confirmed max) 3) Find productivity: 43 27 ) , ( 54 36 18 9 ) , ( ) 6 ( 9 6 6 ) 3 ( 3 ) , ( 9 ) , ( 2 2 2 2                 c w p c w p c w p c c wc w c w p Productivity is maximized at 27 when wage=3 and working conditions=6.
  • 44. 4.5 Constrained Optimization Typically constrained optimization consists of maximizing or minimizing an objective function with regards to a constraint, or Max/min z=f(x,y) Subject to (s.t.): g(x,y)=k Where k is a constant 44
  • 45. 4.5 Constrained Optimization Often economic agents are not free to make any decision they would like. They are CONSTRAINED by factors such as income, time, intelligence, etc. When optimizing with constraints, we have two general methods: 1) Internalizing the constraint 2) Creating a Lagrangeian function 45
  • 46. 4.5 Internalizing Constraints If the constraint can be substituted into the equation to be optimized, we are left with an unconstrained optimization problem: Example: Bob works a full week, but every Saturday he has seven hours left free, either to watch TV or read. He faces the constrained optimization problem: Max. Utility=7TV-TV2 +Read (U=7TV-TV2 +R) s.t. 7=TV+Read (7=TV+R) 46
  • 47. 4.5 Internalizing Constraints Max. U=7TV-TV2 +R s.t. 7=TV+R We can solve the constraint: R=7-TV And substitute into the objective function: U=-TV2 +7TV+(7-TV) U=-TV2 +6TV+7 47
  • 48. 4.5 The Lagrangian L=z*=z(x,y)+λ(k-g(x,y)) After finding FOC’s, to confirm a maximum or minimum, the SOC is employed. This SOC must be negative for a maximum and positive for a minimum Note that for more terms, this function becomes exponentially complicated. SOC’s: 48                                                        δxδy z δ δy δg δx δg 2 δx z δ δy δg δy z δ δx δg 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 SOC
  • 49. 4.5 Lagrangian example Max. U=7TV-TV2 +R s.t. 7=TV+R L=z*=z(x,y)+λ(k-g(x,y)) L=7TV-TV2 +R+λ(7-TV-R) FOC: 49 2TV - 7 0 - 2TV - 7        TV L 1 0 - 1        R L R V T     T 7 0 R - V - 7  L
  • 50. 4.5 Lagrangian example 50 R TV     7 ) 3 ( 1 ) 2 ( 2TV - 7 ) 1 (   3 1 2 7 ) 2 ( ) 1 (     TV TV R R R V      4 3 7 T 7 : ) 3 (
  • 51. 4.5 Lagrangian Example 51             0 2 0 1 1 2 2 - 1 0 1 δTVδR z δ δR δg δTV δg 2 δTV z δ δR δg δR z δ δTV δg 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2                                                          SOC SOC SOC Since the second order condition is negative, the points found are a maximum. Notice that we found the same answers as internalizing the constraint.
  • 52. 4.5 The Lagrange Multiplier The Lagrange Multiplier, λ, provides a measure of how much of an impact relaxing the constraint would make, or how the objective function changes if k of g(x,y)=k is marginally increased. The Lagrange multiplier answers how much the maximum or minimum changes when the constraint g(x,y)=k increases slightly to g(x,y)=k+δ 52
  • 53. 4.5 Lagrangian example 53 1 2(3) - 7 2TV - 7 4 3 2TV - 7         R TV This means that if Bob gets an extra hour, his maximum utility will increase by approximately 1. (Alternately, if Bob loses an hour of leisure, his maximum utility will decrease by approximately 1.) Check: If 8=TV+R, TV=3.5, R=4.5, U=16.75 (utility increases by approximately 1)
  • 54. Constrained Optimization So far we have discussed optimizing functions without placing restrictions upon the values that the independent variables can assume. Such problems are often referred to as free maxima and minima or free optima. However, in the real world, often restrictions or constraints are placed upon values of the independent variables. These problems are referred to as constrained optima or constrained optimization.
  • 55. Constrained Optimization constraint Constrained maximum Free maximu m Graphically, the difference between the free optima and the constrained optima can be shown as:
  • 56. • The free optima occurs at the peak of the surface. • If we specify a specific relationship between variables and (a constraint) then the search for an optimum is restricted to a slice of the surface. The constrained maximum occurs at the peak of the slice. constraint Constrained maximum Free maximu m
  • 57. Constrained Optimization • Since economists deal with the allocation of scarce resources among alternative uses, the concept of constraints or restrictions is important. • There are two approaches to solving constrained optima problems: (i) substitution method (ii) Lagrange multipliers
  • 58. Substitution Method • Consider a firm producing commodity with the following production function: • Without any constraints, the firm can produce an unlimited quantity by utilizing an unlimited amount of and .
  • 59. Substitution Method • But suppose the firm has a budget constraint: Let • For simplicity, assume that the maximum amount the firm can spend on these two inputs is $100. • So we have the following constraint:
  • 60. Substitution Method • Suppose the economic question facing this firm is maximizing production subject to this budget constraint. • The solution via the substitution method is to substitute: • First, write the constraint in terms of :
  • 61. Substitution Method • Then substitute this value into the production function, such that: • With this substitution, the constrained maxima problem is reduced to a free maxima problem with one independent variable.
  • 62. Substitution Method • Now apply the usual optimization procedure: (critical value)
  • 63. Substitution Method ◦ The method of substitution is one way to solve constrained optima problems. This is manageable in some cases. In others, the constraint may be very complicated and substitution becomes complex.
  • 64. Lagrange Multipliers  The constrained optima problem can be stated as finding the extreme value of subject to .  So Lagrange (a mathematician) formed the augmented function. denotes augmented function will behave like the function if the constraint is foll
  • 65. Lagrange Multipliers • Given the augmented function, the first order condition for optimization (where the independent variables are , and λ) is as follows:
  • 66. Lagrange Multipliers  Using the previous example: note: to be on the budget line
  • 67. Lagrange Multipliers • Solving these 3 equations simultaneously:
  • 68. Lagrange Multipliers • Solving these 3 equations simultaneously (cont’d):
  • 69. Lagrange Multipliers • Solving these 3 equations simultaneously (cont’d):
  • 70. Lagrange Multipliers • If , then • This solution yields the same answer as the substitution method, i.e., and .
  • 71. Lagrange Multipliers • Economists prefer using the Lagrange technique over the substitution method, because: Namely for (ii), the value of λ has an economic interpretation. (There is no counterpart to this variable in the substitution method). (i) easier to handle for most cases and (ii) provides additional information.
  • 72. Lagrange Multipliers  Given, where C is the level of expenditures (budget = $100 in this example). here the Lagrange multiplier measures the sensitivity of to changes in the constraint (C ).
  • 73. Lagrange Multipliers  2nd order conditions Given  1st order conditions for extremum:
  • 74. Lagrange Multipliers • 2nd order conditions involve second order partial derivatives expressed in the form of a determinant. • In the constraint case, we will utilize the bordered Hessian – which is the Hessian of the free optima case surrounded by the partial derivatives with respect to the Lagrange multiplier λ.
  • 77. Lagrange Multipliers  2 explanatory variables and 1 constraint is the largest size bordered Hessian we will consider for this class. Note: partials with respect to Lagrange multiplier (λ) form the border
  • 78. Lagrange Multipliers  So the 2nd order condition is:  Let’s now return to our previous example: ◦ Recall the critical values of , and .
  • 79. Lagrange Multipliers • What about the 2nd order conditions?
  • 82. Lagrange Multipliers represents a rel max. represents a rel max.