NBER Summer Institute Econometrics
        Methods Lecture:
 GMM and Consumption-Based Asset Pricing


   Sydney C. Ludvigson, NYU and NBER



                          July 14, 2010




    Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes
    Why care about consumption-based models?




           Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes
    Why care about consumption-based models?
    True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in
    nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset
    prices are derived endogenously from these.




           Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes
    Why care about consumption-based models?
    True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in
    nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset
    prices are derived endogenously from these.
    Some cons-based models work better than others, but...




           Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes
    Why care about consumption-based models?
    True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in
    nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset
    prices are derived endogenously from these.
    Some cons-based models work better than others, but...
    ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro
    variables often measured with error. Therefore:




           Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes
    Why care about consumption-based models?
    True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in
    nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset
    prices are derived endogenously from these.
    Some cons-based models work better than others, but...
    ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro
    variables often measured with error. Therefore:
      1   move away from specification tests of perfect fit (given
          sampling error),




             Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes
    Why care about consumption-based models?
    True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in
    nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset
    prices are derived endogenously from these.
    Some cons-based models work better than others, but...
    ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro
    variables often measured with error. Therefore:
      1   move away from specification tests of perfect fit (given
          sampling error),
      2   toward estimation and testing that recognize all models are
          misspecified,




             Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes
    Why care about consumption-based models?
    True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in
    nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset
    prices are derived endogenously from these.
    Some cons-based models work better than others, but...
    ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro
    variables often measured with error. Therefore:
      1   move away from specification tests of perfect fit (given
          sampling error),
      2   toward estimation and testing that recognize all models are
          misspecified,
      3   toward methods permit comparison of magnitude of
          misspecification among multiple, competing macro models.


             Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes
    Why care about consumption-based models?
    True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in
    nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset
    prices are derived endogenously from these.
    Some cons-based models work better than others, but...
    ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro
    variables often measured with error. Therefore:
      1   move away from specification tests of perfect fit (given
          sampling error),
      2   toward estimation and testing that recognize all models are
          misspecified,
      3   toward methods permit comparison of magnitude of
          misspecification among multiple, competing macro models.
    Themes are important in choosing which methods to use.
             Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline


     GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA
     utility model




            Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline


     GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA
     utility model

     Incorporating conditioning information: scaled
     consumption-based models




            Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline


     GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA
     utility model

     Incorporating conditioning information: scaled
     consumption-based models

     Generalizations of CRRA utility: recursive utility




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline


     GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA
     utility model

     Incorporating conditioning information: scaled
     consumption-based models

     Generalizations of CRRA utility: recursive utility

         Semi-nonparametric minimum distance estimators:
         unrestricted LOM for data




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline


     GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA
     utility model

     Incorporating conditioning information: scaled
     consumption-based models

     Generalizations of CRRA utility: recursive utility

         Semi-nonparametric minimum distance estimators:
         unrestricted LOM for data
         Simulation methods: restricted LOM




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline


     GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA
     utility model

     Incorporating conditioning information: scaled
     consumption-based models

     Generalizations of CRRA utility: recursive utility

         Semi-nonparametric minimum distance estimators:
         unrestricted LOM for data
         Simulation methods: restricted LOM


     Consumption-based asset pricing: concluding thoughts


             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)


     Economic model implies set of r population moment
     restrictions

                                  E{h (θ, wt )} = 0
                                      (r × 1 )




            Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)


     Economic model implies set of r population moment
     restrictions

                                   E{h (θ, wt )} = 0
                                       (r × 1 )



     wt is an h × 1 vector of variables known at t




             Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)


     Economic model implies set of r population moment
     restrictions

                                   E{h (θ, wt )} = 0
                                       (r × 1 )



     wt is an h × 1 vector of variables known at t

     θ is an a × 1 vector of coefficients




             Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)


     Economic model implies set of r population moment
     restrictions

                                   E{h (θ, wt )} = 0
                                       (r × 1 )



     wt is an h × 1 vector of variables known at t

     θ is an a × 1 vector of coefficients

     Idea: choose θ to make the sample moment as close as
     possible to the population moment.


             Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)
     Sample moments:
                                        T
                     g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) ,
                                       t= 1
                        (r × 1 )




           Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)
     Sample moments:
                                                  T
                       g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) ,
                                                 t= 1
                          (r × 1 )

           ′    ′          ′         ′
     yT ≡ wT , wT −1 , ...w1             is a T · h × 1 vector of observations.




             Sydney C. Ludvigson              Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)
     Sample moments:
                                                       T
                       g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) ,
                                                      t= 1
                          (r × 1 )

           ′    ′          ′         ′
     yT ≡ wT , wT −1 , ...w1             is a T · h × 1 vector of observations.

     The GMM estimator θ minimizes the scalar
                                                       ′
                  Q (θ; yT ) = [g(θ; yT )] WT [g(θ; yT )],                               (1)
                                           ( 1× r )        (r×r)   ( r × 1)

          ∞
     {WT }T =1 a sequence of r × r positive definite matrices
     which may be a function of the data, yT .



             Sydney C. Ludvigson                Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)
     Sample moments:
                                                       T
                       g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) ,
                                                      t= 1
                          (r × 1 )

           ′    ′          ′         ′
     yT ≡ wT , wT −1 , ...w1             is a T · h × 1 vector of observations.

     The GMM estimator θ minimizes the scalar
                                                       ′
                  Q (θ; yT ) = [g(θ; yT )] WT [g(θ; yT )],                               (1)
                                           ( 1× r )        (r×r)   ( r × 1)

          ∞
     {WT }T =1 a sequence of r × r positive definite matrices
     which may be a function of the data, yT .
     If r = a, θ estimated by setting each g(θ; yT ) to zero.

             Sydney C. Ludvigson                Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)
     Sample moments:
                                                       T
                       g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) ,
                                                      t= 1
                          (r × 1 )

           ′    ′          ′         ′
     yT ≡ wT , wT −1 , ...w1             is a T · h × 1 vector of observations.

     The GMM estimator θ minimizes the scalar
                                                       ′
                  Q (θ; yT ) = [g(θ; yT )] WT [g(θ; yT )],                               (1)
                                           ( 1× r )        (r×r)   ( r × 1)

          ∞
     {WT }T =1 a sequence of r × r positive definite matrices
     which may be a function of the data, yT .
     If r = a, θ estimated by setting each g(θ; yT ) to zero.
     GMM refers to use of (1) to estimate θ when r > a.
             Sydney C. Ludvigson                Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)


     Asym. properties (Hansen 1982): θ consistent, asym.
     normal.




            Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)


     Asym. properties (Hansen 1982): θ consistent, asym.
     normal.

     Optimal weighting WT = S−1

                                                                           
                        ∞
                                  
                                                                           
                                                                            
                                                                        ′
             S =
             r×r
                       ∑     E
                                  
                                      [h (θo , wt )] h θo , wt−j
                                                                            
                                                                                .
                     j=− ∞                                                 
                                          r×1               1× r




            Sydney C. Ludvigson              Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)


     Asym. properties (Hansen 1982): θ consistent, asym.
     normal.

     Optimal weighting WT = S−1

                                                                            
                         ∞
                                   
                                                                            
                                                                             
                                                                         ′
              S =
             r×r
                        ∑     E
                                   
                                       [h (θo , wt )] h θo , wt−j
                                                                             
                                                                                 .
                      j=− ∞                                                 
                                           r×1               1× r




     In many asset pricing applications, it is inappropriate to
     use WT = S−1 (see below).


             Sydney C. Ludvigson              Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)

     ST depends on θT which depends on ST . Employ an
     iterative procedure:




            Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Review (Hansen, 1982)

     ST depends on θT which depends on ST . Employ an
     iterative procedure:

                                               (1)
      1   Obtain an initial estimate of θ = θT , by minimizing
          Q (θ; yT ) subject to arbitrary weighting matrix, e.g., W = I.


                (1)                                       (1)
      2   Use θT to obtain initial estimate of S = ST .

                                                                (1 )
      3   Re-minimize Q (θ; yT ) using initial estimate ST ; obtain
                             (2)
          new estimate θT .

      4   Continue iterating until convergence, or stop. (Estimators
          have same asym. dist. but finite sample properties differ.)



              Sydney C. Ludvigson     Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Classic Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Investors maximize utility

                                    ∞
                           max Et
                             Ct
                                    ∑ β i u (C t + i )
                                    i= 0




            Sydney C. Ludvigson       Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Classic Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Investors maximize utility

                                      ∞
                             max Et
                              Ct
                                      ∑ β i u (C t + i )
                                      i= 0


     Power (isoelastic) utility
                                            1− γ
                          u (C ) =
                                       Ct
                                                    γ>0
                               t        1− γ
                                                                                 (2)
                         
                         
                              u (Ct ) = ln(Ct ) γ = 1




             Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Classic Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Investors maximize utility

                                      ∞
                             max Et
                              Ct
                                      ∑ β i u (C t + i )
                                      i= 0


     Power (isoelastic) utility
                                            1− γ
                          u (C ) =
                                       Ct
                                                    γ>0
                               t        1− γ
                                                                                 (2)
                         
                         
                              u (Ct ) = ln(Ct ) γ = 1

     N assets => N first-order conditions
             −γ                        −γ
           Ct     = βEt (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) Ct+1                 i = 1, ..., N.        (3)


             Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Re-write moment conditions
                                                        −γ
                                                     Ct + 1
                 0 = Et       1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 )       −γ        .             (4)
                                                      Ct




            Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Re-write moment conditions
                                                         −γ
                                                      Ct + 1
                  0 = Et       1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 )       −γ        .             (4)
                                                       Ct

     2 params to estimate: β and γ, so θ = ( β, γ) ′ .




             Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Re-write moment conditions
                                                         −γ
                                                      Ct + 1
                  0 = Et       1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 )       −γ        .             (4)
                                                       Ct

     2 params to estimate: β and γ, so θ = ( β, γ) ′ .
      ∗
     xt denotes info set of investors

                                        −γ      −γ         ∗
     0=E      1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) Ct+1 /Ct               |xt           i = 1, ...N
                                                                               (5)




             Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Re-write moment conditions
                                                           −γ
                                                         Ct + 1
                  0 = Et       1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 )         −γ      .             (4)
                                                         Ct

     2 params to estimate: β and γ, so θ = ( β, γ) ′ .
      ∗
     xt denotes info set of investors

                                        −γ          −γ       ∗
     0=E      1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) Ct+1 /Ct                 |xt
                                                      i = 1, ...N
                                                              (5)
           ∗ . Conditional model (5) => unconditional model:
     xt ⊂ xt
                                               −γ
                                             Ct + 1
       0=E        1−       β (1 + ℜi,t+1 )     −γ        xt        i = 1, ...N
                                             Ct
                                                                                 (6)
             Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Let xt be M × 1. Then r = N · M and,
                                               −γ
                                                                    
                                              C +1
                          1 − β (1 + ℜ1,t+1 ) t−γ             xt 
                                              Ct
                                                                 
                                               −γ
                                              Ct+1                
                          1 − β (1 + ℜ2,t+1 ) −γ              xt 
                                             Ct                  
                                                                 
                         
            h (θ, wt ) =              ·                                   (7)
                                                                  
               r×1                    ·                          
                                                                 
                                      ·                          
                                                                 
                                               −γ
                                               C +1               
                           1 − β (1 + ℜN,t+1 ) t−γ             xt
                                                     Ct




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Let xt be M × 1. Then r = N · M and,
                                               −γ
                                                                    
                                              C +1
                          1 − β (1 + ℜ1,t+1 ) t−γ             xt 
                                              Ct
                                                                 
                                               −γ
                                              Ct+1                
                          1 − β (1 + ℜ2,t+1 ) −γ              xt 
                                             Ct                  
                                                                 
                         
            h (θ, wt ) =              ·                                   (7)
                                                                  
               r×1                    ·                          
                                                                 
                                      ·                          
                                                                 
                                               −γ
                                               C +1               
                           1 − β (1 + ℜN,t+1 ) t−γ             xt
                                                     Ct


     Model can be estimated, tested as long as r ≥ 2.




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Let xt be M × 1. Then r = N · M and,
                                               −γ
                                                                     
                                              C +1
                          1 − β (1 + ℜ1,t+1 ) t−γ              xt 
                                              Ct
                                                                  
                                               −γ
                                              Ct+1                 
                          1 − β (1 + ℜ2,t+1 ) −γ               xt 
                                             Ct                   
                                                                  
                         
            h (θ, wt ) =              ·                                    (7)
                                                                   
               r×1                    ·                           
                                                                  
                                      ·                           
                                                                  
                                               −γ
                                               C +1                
                           1 − β (1 + ℜN,t+1 ) t−γ              xt
                                                       Ct


     Model can be estimated, tested as long as r ≥ 2.
     Take sample mean of (7) to get g(θ; yT ), minimize
                                             ′
                min Q (θ; yT ) = [g(θ; yT )] WT [g(θ; yT )]
                  θ                              r×r
                                     1× r               r×1
             Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions:
                                       a
                            TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a)




             Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions:
                                       a
                            TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a)


     HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and
     industry returns, NDS expenditures.
     Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity
     premium puzzle! But....




             Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions:
                                       a
                            TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a)


     HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and
     industry returns, NDS expenditures.
     Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity
     premium puzzle! But....
     ...model is strongly rejected according to OID test.




             Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions:
                                       a
                            TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a)


     HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and
     industry returns, NDS expenditures.
     Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity
     premium puzzle! But....
     ...model is strongly rejected according to OID test.
     Campbell, Lo, MacKinlay (1997): OID rejections stronger
     whenever stock returns and commercial paper are
     included as test returns. Why?




             Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions:
                                       a
                            TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a)


     HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and
     industry returns, NDS expenditures.
     Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity
     premium puzzle! But....
     ...model is strongly rejected according to OID test.
     Campbell, Lo, MacKinlay (1997): OID rejections stronger
     whenever stock returns and commercial paper are
     included as test returns. Why?
     Model cannot capture predictable variation in excess
     returns over commercial paper ⇒

             Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982)
     Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions:
                                       a
                            TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a)


     HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and
     industry returns, NDS expenditures.
     Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity
     premium puzzle! But....
     ...model is strongly rejected according to OID test.
     Campbell, Lo, MacKinlay (1997): OID rejections stronger
     whenever stock returns and commercial paper are
     included as test returns. Why?
     Model cannot capture predictable variation in excess
     returns over commercial paper ⇒
     Researchers have turned to other models of preferences.
             Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors
     Results in HS use conditioning info xt –scaled returns.




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors
     Results in HS use conditioning info xt –scaled returns.
     Another limitation with classic CCAPM: large
     unconditional Euler equation (pricing) errors even when
     params freely chosen.




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors
     Results in HS use conditioning info xt –scaled returns.
     Another limitation with classic CCAPM: large
     unconditional Euler equation (pricing) errors even when
     params freely chosen.
     Let Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ . Define Euler equation errors:
                               j                j
                               eR ≡ E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] − 1

                           j                j         f
                         eX ≡ E[Mt+1 (Rt+1 − Rt+1 )]




             Sydney C. Ludvigson         Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors
     Results in HS use conditioning info xt –scaled returns.
     Another limitation with classic CCAPM: large
     unconditional Euler equation (pricing) errors even when
     params freely chosen.
     Let Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ . Define Euler equation errors:
                                j                    j
                               eR ≡ E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] − 1

                           j                     j            f
                         eX ≡ E[Mt+1 (Rt+1 − Rt+1 )]

                             ′
     Choose params: min β,γ gT WT gT where jth element of gT
                                                              j
                               gj,t (γ, β) =     1
                                                 T   ∑T=1 eR,t
                                                      t

                                                          j
                                gj,t (γ) =   1
                                             T   ∑T=1 eX,t
                                                  t

             Sydney C. Ludvigson             Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Unconditional Euler Equation Errors, Excess Returns

           j                                         j            f
          eX ≡ E[ β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ (Rt+1 − Rt+1 )]                                  j = 1, ..., N
                                            j                                                 j           f
          RMSE =              1
                              N   ∑N 1 [eX ]2 ,
                                   j=                    RMSR =            1
                                                                           N
                                                                                N
                                                                               ∑j=1 [E(Rt+1 − Rt+1 )]2




  Source: Lettau and Ludvigson (2009). Rs is the excess return on CRSP-VW index over 3-Mo T-bill rate. Rs & 6 FF
  refers to this return plus 6 size and book-market sorted portfolios provided by Fama and French. For each value of
  γ, β is chosen to minimize the Euler equation error for the T-bill rate. U.S. quarterly data, 1954:1-2002:1.


                        Sydney C. Ludvigson                    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors
     Magnitude of errors large, even when parameters are
     freely chosen to minimize errors.
     Unlike the equity premium puzzle of Mehra and Prescott
     (1985), large Euler eq. errors cannot be resolved with high
     risk aversion.




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors
     Magnitude of errors large, even when parameters are
     freely chosen to minimize errors.
     Unlike the equity premium puzzle of Mehra and Prescott
     (1985), large Euler eq. errors cannot be resolved with high
     risk aversion.
     Lettau and Ludvigson (2009): Leading consumption-based
     asset pricing theories fail to explain the mispricing of
     classic CCAPM.




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors
     Magnitude of errors large, even when parameters are
     freely chosen to minimize errors.
     Unlike the equity premium puzzle of Mehra and Prescott
     (1985), large Euler eq. errors cannot be resolved with high
     risk aversion.
     Lettau and Ludvigson (2009): Leading consumption-based
     asset pricing theories fail to explain the mispricing of
     classic CCAPM.
     Anomaly is striking b/c early evidence (e.g., Hansen &
     Singleton) that the classic model’s Euler equations were
     violated provided the impetus for developing these newer
     models.



             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors
     Magnitude of errors large, even when parameters are
     freely chosen to minimize errors.
     Unlike the equity premium puzzle of Mehra and Prescott
     (1985), large Euler eq. errors cannot be resolved with high
     risk aversion.
     Lettau and Ludvigson (2009): Leading consumption-based
     asset pricing theories fail to explain the mispricing of
     classic CCAPM.
     Anomaly is striking b/c early evidence (e.g., Hansen &
     Singleton) that the classic model’s Euler equations were
     violated provided the impetus for developing these newer
     models.
     Results imply data on consumption and asset returns not
     jointly lognormal!
             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997


        Asset pricing applications often require WT               S−1 . Why?




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997


        Asset pricing applications often require WT               S−1 . Why?

        One reason: assessing specification error, comparing
        models.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997


        Asset pricing applications often require WT               S−1 . Why?

        One reason: assessing specification error, comparing
        models.
        Consider two estimated models of SDF, e.g.,
                             (1)
           1   CCAPM: Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ , OID restricts not rejected
                           (2)
           2   CAPM: Mt+1 = a + bRm,t+1 , OID restricts rejected




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997


        Asset pricing applications often require WT               S−1 . Why?

        One reason: assessing specification error, comparing
        models.
        Consider two estimated models of SDF, e.g.,
                             (1)
           1   CCAPM: Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ , OID restricts not rejected
                           (2)
           2   CAPM: Mt+1 = a + bRm,t+1 , OID restricts rejected

        May we conclude Model 1 is superior?




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997


        Asset pricing applications often require WT               S−1 . Why?

        One reason: assessing specification error, comparing
        models.
        Consider two estimated models of SDF, e.g.,
                             (1)
           1   CCAPM: Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ , OID restricts not rejected
                           (2)
           2   CAPM: Mt+1 = a + bRm,t+1 , OID restricts rejected

        May we conclude Model 1 is superior?

        No. Hansen’s J-test of OID restricts depends on model
        specific S: J = gT S−1 gT .
                        ′




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997


        Asset pricing applications often require WT               S−1 . Why?

        One reason: assessing specification error, comparing
        models.
        Consider two estimated models of SDF, e.g.,
                             (1)
           1   CCAPM: Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ , OID restricts not rejected
                           (2)
           2   CAPM: Mt+1 = a + bRm,t+1 , OID restricts rejected

        May we conclude Model 1 is superior?

        No. Hansen’s J-test of OID restricts depends on model
        specific S: J = gT S−1 gT .
                        ′


        Model 1 can look better simply b/c the SDF and pricing
        errors gT are more volatile, not b/c pricing errors are lower.
                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997

        HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric:

                                                                                  T
                                                                             1
          DistT (θ) =        mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ),
                                         −
                                                                   GT ≡          ∑ Rt Rt′
                               θ                                             T   t= 1
                                                                                        N ×N
                                          T
                                     1
                            gT (θ) ≡
                                     T   ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ]
                                         t= 1




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997

        HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric:

                                                                                  T
                                                                             1
          DistT (θ) =        mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ),
                                         −
                                                                   GT ≡          ∑ Rt Rt′
                               θ                                             T   t= 1
                                                                                        N ×N
                                          T
                                     1
                            gT (θ) ≡
                                     T   ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ]
                                         t= 1


        DistT does not reward SDF volatility => suitable for
        model comparison.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997

        HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric:

                                                                                  T
                                                                             1
          DistT (θ) =        mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ),
                                         −
                                                                   GT ≡          ∑ Rt Rt′
                               θ                                             T   t= 1
                                                                                        N ×N
                                          T
                                     1
                            gT (θ) ≡
                                     T   ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ]
                                         t= 1


        DistT does not reward SDF volatility => suitable for
        model comparison.
        DistT is a measure of model misspecification:




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997

        HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric:

                                                                                  T
                                                                             1
          DistT (θ) =        mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ),
                                         −
                                                                   GT ≡          ∑ Rt Rt′
                               θ                                             T   t= 1
                                                                                        N ×N
                                          T
                                     1
                            gT (θ) ≡
                                     T   ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ]
                                         t= 1


        DistT does not reward SDF volatility => suitable for
        model comparison.
        DistT is a measure of model misspecification:
              Gives distance between Mt (θ) and nearest point in space of
              all SDFs that price assets correctly.



                  Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997

        HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric:

                                                                                  T
                                                                             1
          DistT (θ) =        mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ),
                                         −
                                                                   GT ≡          ∑ Rt Rt′
                               θ                                             T   t= 1
                                                                                        N ×N
                                          T
                                     1
                            gT (θ) ≡
                                     T   ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ]
                                         t= 1


        DistT does not reward SDF volatility => suitable for
        model comparison.
        DistT is a measure of model misspecification:
              Gives distance between Mt (θ) and nearest point in space of
              all SDFs that price assets correctly.
              Gives maximum pricing error of any portfolio formed from
              the N assets.
                  Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997




        Appeal of HJ Distance metric:




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997




        Appeal of HJ Distance metric:

              Recognizes all models are misspecified.

              Provides method for comparing models by assessing which
              is least misspecified.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997




        Appeal of HJ Distance metric:

              Recognizes all models are misspecified.

              Provides method for comparing models by assessing which
              is least misspecified.


        Important problem: how to compare HJ distances
        statistically?




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997




        Appeal of HJ Distance metric:

              Recognizes all models are misspecified.

              Provides method for comparing models by assessing which
              is least misspecified.


        Important problem: how to compare HJ distances
        statistically?

        One possibility developed in Chen and Ludvigson (2009):
        White’s reality check method.



                  Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009

         Chen and Ludvigson (2009) compare HJ distances among
         K competing models using White’s reality check method.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009

         Chen and Ludvigson (2009) compare HJ distances among
         K competing models using White’s reality check method.
           1   Take benchmark model, e.g., model with smallest squared
               distance d1,T ≡ min{d2 }K 1 .
                         2
                                    j,T j=

           2   Null: d2 − d2 ≤ 0, where d2 is competing model with
                       1,T     2,T          2,T
               the next smallest squared distance.
                                   √
           3   Test statistic T W = T (d2 − d2,T ).
                                        1,T
                                                2

           4   If null is true, test statistic should not be unusually large,
               given sampling error.
           5   Given distribution for T W , reject null if historical value T W
               is > 95th percentile.




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009

         Chen and Ludvigson (2009) compare HJ distances among
         K competing models using White’s reality check method.
           1   Take benchmark model, e.g., model with smallest squared
               distance d1,T ≡ min{d2 }K 1 .
                         2
                                    j,T j=

           2   Null: d2 − d2 ≤ 0, where d2 is competing model with
                       1,T     2,T          2,T
               the next smallest squared distance.
                                   √
           3   Test statistic T W = T (d2 − d2,T ).
                                        1,T
                                                2

           4   If null is true, test statistic should not be unusually large,
               given sampling error.
           5   Given distribution for T W , reject null if historical value T W
               is > 95th percentile.

         Method applies generally to any stationary law of motion
         for data, multiple competing possibly nonlinear, SDF
         models.
                   Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009



         Distribution of T W is computed via block bootstrap.

              T W has complicated limiting distribution.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009



         Distribution of T W is computed via block bootstrap.

              T W has complicated limiting distribution.

         Bootstrap works only if have a multivariate, joint,
         continuous, limiting distribution under null.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009



         Distribution of T W is computed via block bootstrap.

              T W has complicated limiting distribution.

         Bootstrap works only if have a multivariate, joint,
         continuous, limiting distribution under null.

         Proof of limiting distributions exists for applications to
         most asset pricing models:




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009



         Distribution of T W is computed via block bootstrap.

              T W has complicated limiting distribution.

         Bootstrap works only if have a multivariate, joint,
         continuous, limiting distribution under null.

         Proof of limiting distributions exists for applications to
         most asset pricing models:

              For parametric models (Hansen, Heaton, Luttmer ’95)
              For semiparametric models (Ai and Chen ’07).



                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Reasons to use identity matrix: econometric problems




                                              −       −
         Econometric problems: near singular ST 1 or GT 1 .

              Asset returns are highly correlated.

              We have large N and modest T.

              If T < N covariance matrix for N asset returns is singular.
              Unless T >> N, matrix can be near-singular.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Reasons to use identity matrix: economically interesting portfolios


         Original test assets may have economically meaningful
         characteristics (e.g., size, value).




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson       Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Reasons to use identity matrix: economically interesting portfolios


         Original test assets may have economically meaningful
         characteristics (e.g., size, value).

                     −       −
         Using WT = ST 1 or GT 1 same as using WT = I and doing
         GMM on re-weighted portfolios of original test assets.

               Triangular factorization S−1 = (P′ P), P lower triangular

                                  min gT S−1 gT ⇔ (gT P′ )I(PgT )
                                       ′            ′




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Reasons to use identity matrix: economically interesting portfolios


         Original test assets may have economically meaningful
         characteristics (e.g., size, value).

                     −       −
         Using WT = ST 1 or GT 1 same as using WT = I and doing
         GMM on re-weighted portfolios of original test assets.

               Triangular factorization S−1 = (P′ P), P lower triangular

                                  min gT S−1 gT ⇔ (gT P′ )I(PgT )
                                       ′            ′


         Re-weighted portfolios may not provide large spread in
         average returns.




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Reasons to use identity matrix: economically interesting portfolios


         Original test assets may have economically meaningful
         characteristics (e.g., size, value).

                     −       −
         Using WT = ST 1 or GT 1 same as using WT = I and doing
         GMM on re-weighted portfolios of original test assets.

               Triangular factorization S−1 = (P′ P), P lower triangular

                                  min gT S−1 gT ⇔ (gT P′ )I(PgT )
                                       ′            ′


         Re-weighted portfolios may not provide large spread in
         average returns.

         May imply implausible long and short positions in test
         assets.

                   Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Reasons not to use WT = I: objective function dependence on test asset choice



         Using WT = [ET (R′ R)]−1 , GMM objective function is
         invariant to initial choice of test assets.




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Reasons not to use WT = I: objective function dependence on test asset choice



         Using WT = [ET (R′ R)]−1 , GMM objective function is
         invariant to initial choice of test assets.

         Form a portfolio, AR from initial returns R. (Note,
         portfolio weights sum to 1 so A1N = 1N ).

                                              −1
                 [E (MR) − 1N ]′ E RR′             [E (MR − 1N )]
                                         ′              −1
            = [E (MAR) − A1N ] E ARR′ A                      [E (MAR − A1N )] .




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson       Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting
Reasons not to use WT = I: objective function dependence on test asset choice



         Using WT = [ET (R′ R)]−1 , GMM objective function is
         invariant to initial choice of test assets.

         Form a portfolio, AR from initial returns R. (Note,
         portfolio weights sum to 1 so A1N = 1N ).

                                              −1
                 [E (MR) − 1N ]′ E RR′             [E (MR − 1N )]
                                         ′              −1
            = [E (MAR) − A1N ] E ARR′ A                      [E (MAR − A1N )] .


         With WT = I or other fixed weighting, GMM objective
         depends on choice of test assets.


                   Sydney C. Ludvigson       Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More Complex Preferences: Scaled
Consumption-Based Models
     Consumption-based models may be approximated:
                    Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 ,     ct+1 ≡ ln(Ct+1 )




             Sydney C. Ludvigson         Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More Complex Preferences: Scaled
Consumption-Based Models
     Consumption-based models may be approximated:
                    Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 ,     ct+1 ≡ ln(Ct+1 )
     Example: Classic CCAPM with CRRA utility
                              1− γ
                             Ct
                u ( Ct ) =       ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β − βγ ∆ct+1
                             1−γ
                                                at = a0   bt = b0




             Sydney C. Ludvigson         Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More Complex Preferences: Scaled
Consumption-Based Models
     Consumption-based models may be approximated:
                     Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 ,                 ct+1 ≡ ln(Ct+1 )
     Example: Classic CCAPM with CRRA utility
                                1− γ
                              Ct
                 u ( Ct ) =       ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β − βγ ∆ct+1
                              1−γ
                                                             at = a0     bt = b0

     Model with habit and time-varying risk aversion: Campbell and
     Cochrane ’99, Menzly et. al ’04
                                       ( Ct S t ) 1 − γ                   C t − Xt
                    u ( Ct , S t ) =                    ,     St + 1 ≡
                                          1−γ                                 Ct

            ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β 1 − γ (φ − 1)(st − s) − γ (1 + ψ (st )) ∆ct+1
                                               at                          bt




              Sydney C. Ludvigson                     Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
More Complex Preferences: Scaled
Consumption-Based Models
     Consumption-based models may be approximated:
                     Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 ,                 ct+1 ≡ ln(Ct+1 )
     Example: Classic CCAPM with CRRA utility
                                1− γ
                              Ct
                 u ( Ct ) =       ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β − βγ ∆ct+1
                              1−γ
                                                             at = a0     bt = b0

     Model with habit and time-varying risk aversion: Campbell and
     Cochrane ’99, Menzly et. al ’04
                                       ( Ct S t ) 1 − γ                   C t − Xt
                    u ( Ct , S t ) =                    ,     St + 1 ≡
                                          1−γ                                 Ct

            ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β 1 − γ (φ − 1)(st − s) − γ (1 + ψ (st )) ∆ct+1
                                               at                          bt
     Proxies for time-varying risk-premia should be good proxies for
     time-variation in at and bt .
              Sydney C. Ludvigson                     Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
     Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1
     Empirical specification: Lettau and Ludvigson (2001a, 2001b):
          at = a0 + a1 zt , bt = b0 + b1 zt
          zt = cayt ≡ ct − αa at − αy yt , (cointegrating residual)
          cayt related to log consumption-(aggregate) wealth ratio.
          cayt strong predictor of excess stock market returns




              Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
     Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1
     Empirical specification: Lettau and Ludvigson (2001a, 2001b):
          at = a0 + a1 zt , bt = b0 + b1 zt
          zt = cayt ≡ ct − αa at − αy yt , (cointegrating residual)
          cayt related to log consumption-(aggregate) wealth ratio.
          cayt strong predictor of excess stock market returns
     Other examples: including housing consumption
                                 1
                              1− σ                                            ε
                            Ct                    ε −1               ε −1   ε −1
            U(Ct , Ht ) =           1
                                        Ct = χCt    ε
                                                         + (1 − χ) Ht  ε
                                                                                   ,
                            1−      σ

                                                                             pC Ct
                                                                              t
      ⇒ ln Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 + dt ∆ ln St+1 ,          St + 1 ≡
                                                                         pC Ct
                                                                          t      + pH Ht
                                                                                    t
     Lustig and Van Nieuwerburgh ’05 (incomplete markets):
          at = a0 + a1 zt , bt = b0 + b1 zt , dt = d0 + d1 zt
          zt = housing collateral ratio (measures quantity of risk
          sharing)

              Sydney C. Ludvigson          Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Two kinds of conditioning are often confused.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Two kinds of conditioning are often confused.
         Euler equation: E Mt+1 Rt+1 |zt = 1
         Unconditional version: E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Two kinds of conditioning are often confused.
         Euler equation: E Mt+1 Rt+1 |zt = 1
         Unconditional version: E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1
         Two forms of conditionality:
           1   scaling returns: E Mt+1 Ri,t+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′ = 1
           2   scaling factors ft+1 , e.g., ft+1 = ∆ ln Ct+1 :
                                            ′
                            Mt+1         = bt ft+1 with bt = b0 + b1 zt
                                         = b′ ft+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Two kinds of conditioning are often confused.
         Euler equation: E Mt+1 Rt+1 |zt = 1
         Unconditional version: E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1
         Two forms of conditionality:
           1   scaling returns: E Mt+1 Ri,t+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′ = 1
           2   scaling factors ft+1 , e.g., ft+1 = ∆ ln Ct+1 :
                                            ′
                            Mt+1         = bt ft+1 with bt = b0 + b1 zt
                                         = b′ ft+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′

         Scaled consumption-based models are conditional in sense
         that Mt+1 is a state-dependent function of ∆ ln Ct+1
              ⇒ scaled factors




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Two kinds of conditioning are often confused.
         Euler equation: E Mt+1 Rt+1 |zt = 1
         Unconditional version: E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1
         Two forms of conditionality:
           1   scaling returns: E Mt+1 Ri,t+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′ = 1
           2   scaling factors ft+1 , e.g., ft+1 = ∆ ln Ct+1 :
                                            ′
                            Mt+1         = bt ft+1 with bt = b0 + b1 zt
                                         = b′ ft+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′

         Scaled consumption-based models are conditional in sense
         that Mt+1 is a state-dependent function of ∆ ln Ct+1
              ⇒ scaled factors
         Scaled consumption-based models have been tested on
         unconditional moments, E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1
              ⇒ NO scaled returns.
                   Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence


         Scaled CCAPM turns a single factor model with
         state-dependent weights into multi-factor model ft with
         constant weights:


             Mt+1 = (a0 + a1 zt ) + (b0 + b1 zt ) ∆ ln Ct+1
                  = a0 + a1 zt +b0 ∆ ln Ct+1 +b1 (zt ∆ ln Ct+1 )
                                        f1,t+1        f2,t+1                f3,t+1




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence


         Scaled CCAPM turns a single factor model with
         state-dependent weights into multi-factor model ft with
         constant weights:


             Mt+1 = (a0 + a1 zt ) + (b0 + b1 zt ) ∆ ln Ct+1
                  = a0 + a1 zt +b0 ∆ ln Ct+1 +b1 (zt ∆ ln Ct+1 )
                                        f1,t+1        f2,t+1                f3,t+1

                                ′
         Multiple risk factors ft ≡ (zt , ∆ ln Ct+1 , zt ∆ ln Ct+1 ).




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence


         Scaled CCAPM turns a single factor model with
         state-dependent weights into multi-factor model ft with
         constant weights:


             Mt+1 = (a0 + a1 zt ) + (b0 + b1 zt ) ∆ ln Ct+1
                  = a0 + a1 zt +b0 ∆ ln Ct+1 +b1 (zt ∆ ln Ct+1 )
                                        f1,t+1        f2,t+1                f3,t+1

                                ′
         Multiple risk factors ft ≡ (zt , ∆ ln Ct+1 , zt ∆ ln Ct+1 ).

         Scaled consumption models have multiple, constant betas
         for each factor, rather than a single time-varying beta for
         ∆ ln Ct+1 .

                  Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Deriving the “beta”-representation
  Let F = (1 f′ )′ , M = b′ F, ignore time indices
              1      = E[MRi ]
                     = E[Ri F′ ]b ⇒ unconditional moments
                     = E[Ri ]E[F′ ]b + Cov(Ri , F′ )b ⇒

                            1 − Cov(Ri , F′ )b
            E[Ri ]    =
                                 E [F′ ]b
                            1 − Cov(Ri , f′ )b
                      =
                                 E [F′ ]b
                            1 − Cov(Ri , f′ )Cov(f, f′ )−1 Cov(f, f′ )b
                      =
                                              E [F′ ]b
                      = R0 − R0 β′ Cov(f, f′ )b
                      = R0 − β′ λ ⇒ multiple, constant betas

       Estimate cross-sectional model using Fama-MacBeth (see Brandt
       lecture).
                  Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Fama-MacBeth Methodology: Preview–See Brandt


       Step 1: Estimate β’s in time-series regression for each
               portfolio i:

                          βi ≡ Cov(ft+1 , ft+1 )−1 Cov(ft+1 , Ri,t+1 )
                                           ′


       Step 2: Cross-sectional regressions (T of them):

                                     Ri,t+1 − R0,t = αi,t + βi′ λt

                         T                                 T
           λ = 1/T ∑ λt ;               σ2 (λ) = 1/T ∑ (λt − λ)2
                       t= 1                               t= 1

  Note: report Shanken t-statistics (corrected for estimation error
  of betas in first stage)


               Sydney C. Ludvigson           Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Scaled models: conditioning done in SDF:
                                 Mt+1 = at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 ,
         not in Euler equation: E(MR) = 1N .




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Scaled models: conditioning done in SDF:
                                 Mt+1 = at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 ,
         not in Euler equation: E(MR) = 1N .
         Gives rise to a restricted conditional consumption beta
         model:
                     Ri = a + β ∆c ∆ct + β ∆c,z ∆ct zt−1 + βz zt−1
                      t




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson        Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Scaled models: conditioning done in SDF:
                                 Mt+1 = at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 ,
         not in Euler equation: E(MR) = 1N .
         Gives rise to a restricted conditional consumption beta
         model:
                     Ri = a + β ∆c ∆ct + β ∆c,z ∆ct zt−1 + βz zt−1
                      t

         Rewrite as
                       Ri = a + ( βc + βc,z zt−1 ) ∆ct + βz zt−1
                        t
                                        time-varying beta




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson             Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Scaled models: conditioning done in SDF:
                                 Mt+1 = at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 ,
         not in Euler equation: E(MR) = 1N .
         Gives rise to a restricted conditional consumption beta
         model:
                     Ri = a + β ∆c ∆ct + β ∆c,z ∆ct zt−1 + βz zt−1
                      t

         Rewrite as
                       Ri = a + ( βc + βc,z zt−1 ) ∆ct + βz zt−1
                        t
                                        time-varying beta


         Unlikely the same time-varying beta as obtained from
         modeling conditional mean Et (Mt+1 Rt+1 ) = 1.
                  Sydney C. Ludvigson             Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Distinction is important.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Distinction is important.
         Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance:
              typically a few variables that capture risk-premia.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Distinction is important.
         Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance:
              typically a few variables that capture risk-premia.

         Conditioning in Euler eqn: model joint dist. (Mt+1 Rt+1 ).




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Distinction is important.
         Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance:
              typically a few variables that capture risk-premia.

         Conditioning in Euler eqn: model joint dist. (Mt+1 Rt+1 ).
         Latter may require variables beyond a few that capture
         risk-premia.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Distinction is important.
         Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance:
              typically a few variables that capture risk-premia.

         Conditioning in Euler eqn: model joint dist. (Mt+1 Rt+1 ).
         Latter may require variables beyond a few that capture
         risk-premia.
         Approximating condition mean well requires large
         number of instruments (misspecified information sets)
              Results sensitive to chosen conditioning variables, may fail
              to span information sets of market participants.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence

         Distinction is important.
         Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance:
              typically a few variables that capture risk-premia.

         Conditioning in Euler eqn: model joint dist. (Mt+1 Rt+1 ).
         Latter may require variables beyond a few that capture
         risk-premia.
         Approximating condition mean well requires large
         number of instruments (misspecified information sets)
              Results sensitive to chosen conditioning variables, may fail
              to span information sets of market participants.

         Partial solution: summarize information in large number
         of time-series with few estimated dynamic factors (e.g.,
         Ludvigson and Ng ’07, ’09).
                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence




         Bottom lines:




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence




         Bottom lines:

           1   Conditional moments of Mt+1 Rt+1 difficult to model ⇒
               reason to focus on unconditional moments
               E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] = 1.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence




         Bottom lines:

           1   Conditional moments of Mt+1 Rt+1 difficult to model ⇒
               reason to focus on unconditional moments
               E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] = 1.

           2   Models are misspecified: interesting question is whether
               state-dependence of Mt+1 on consumption growth ⇒ less
               misspecification than standard, fixed-weight CCAPM.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Scaled Consumption-Based Models
Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence




         Bottom lines:

           1   Conditional moments of Mt+1 Rt+1 difficult to model ⇒
               reason to focus on unconditional moments
               E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] = 1.

           2   Models are misspecified: interesting question is whether
               state-dependence of Mt+1 on consumption growth ⇒ less
               misspecification than standard, fixed-weight CCAPM.

           3   As before, can compare models on basis of HJ distances,
               using White ”reality check” method to compare statistically.




                  Sydney C. Ludvigson      Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive
     preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW).




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive
     preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW).

     Two reasons recursive utility is of interest:




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive
     preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW).

     Two reasons recursive utility is of interest:

         More flexibility as regards attitudes toward risk and
         intertemporal substitution.




             Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive
     preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW).

     Two reasons recursive utility is of interest:

         More flexibility as regards attitudes toward risk and
         intertemporal substitution.

         Preferences deliver an added risk factor for explaining asset
         returns.




             Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive
     preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW).

     Two reasons recursive utility is of interest:

         More flexibility as regards attitudes toward risk and
         intertemporal substitution.

         Preferences deliver an added risk factor for explaining asset
         returns.


     But, only a small amount of econometric work on
     recursive preferences ⇒ gap in the literature.



             Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models:




            Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models:

       1   For general stationary, consumption growth and cash flow
           dynamics: Chen, Favilukis, Ludvigson ’07.




              Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models:

       1   For general stationary, consumption growth and cash flow
           dynamics: Chen, Favilukis, Ludvigson ’07.

       2   When restricting cash flow dynamics (e.g., “long-run risk”):
           Bansal, Gallant, Tauchen ’07.




              Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models:

       1   For general stationary, consumption growth and cash flow
           dynamics: Chen, Favilukis, Ludvigson ’07.

       2   When restricting cash flow dynamics (e.g., “long-run risk”):
           Bansal, Gallant, Tauchen ’07.


     In (1) DGP is left unrestricted, as is joint distribution of
     consumption and returns (distribution-free estimation
     procedure).




              Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences


     Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models:

       1   For general stationary, consumption growth and cash flow
           dynamics: Chen, Favilukis, Ludvigson ’07.

       2   When restricting cash flow dynamics (e.g., “long-run risk”):
           Bansal, Gallant, Tauchen ’07.


     In (1) DGP is left unrestricted, as is joint distribution of
     consumption and returns (distribution-free estimation
     procedure).

     In (2) DGP and distribution of shocks explicitly modeled.



              Sydney C. Ludvigson    Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstein-Zin-Weil basics

         Recursive utility (Epstein, Zin (’89, ’91) & Weil (’89)):
                                                                            1
                                         1− ρ
                                                + β R t ( Vt + 1 ) 1 − ρ
                                                                           1− ρ
                     Vt = ( 1 − β ) Ct
                                                                    1
                                            1−                     1− θ
                            Rt (Vt+1 ) = E Vt+1θ |Ft




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson          Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstein-Zin-Weil basics

         Recursive utility (Epstein, Zin (’89, ’91) & Weil (’89)):
                                                                            1
                                         1− ρ
                                                + β R t ( Vt + 1 ) 1 − ρ
                                                                           1− ρ
                     Vt = ( 1 − β ) Ct
                                                                    1
                                            1−                     1− θ
                            Rt (Vt+1 ) = E Vt+1θ |Ft


         Vt+1 is continuation value, θ is RRA, 1/ρ is EIS.




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson          Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstein-Zin-Weil basics

         Recursive utility (Epstein, Zin (’89, ’91) & Weil (’89)):
                                                                              1
                                         1− ρ
                                                + β R t ( Vt + 1 ) 1 − ρ
                                                                             1− ρ
                     Vt = ( 1 − β ) Ct
                                                                     1
                                            1−                      1− θ
                            Rt (Vt+1 ) = E Vt+1θ |Ft


         Vt+1 is continuation value, θ is RRA, 1/ρ is EIS.
         Rescale utility function (Hansen, Heaton, Li ’05):
                                                                                1
                                                                      1− ρ     1− ρ
                   Vt                               Vt + 1 Ct + 1
                      = ( 1 − β ) + β Rt
                   Ct                               Ct + 1 Ct



                   Sydney C. Ludvigson          Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstein-Zin-Weil basics

         Recursive utility (Epstein, Zin (’89, ’91) & Weil (’89)):
                                                                              1
                                         1− ρ
                                                + β R t ( Vt + 1 ) 1 − ρ
                                                                             1− ρ
                     Vt = ( 1 − β ) Ct
                                                                     1
                                            1−                      1− θ
                            Rt (Vt+1 ) = E Vt+1θ |Ft


         Vt+1 is continuation value, θ is RRA, 1/ρ is EIS.
         Rescale utility function (Hansen, Heaton, Li ’05):
                                                                                1
                                                                      1− ρ     1− ρ
                   Vt                               Vt + 1 Ct + 1
                      = ( 1 − β ) + β Rt
                   Ct                               Ct + 1 Ct

                                                                                      C1−θ
         Special case: ρ = θ ⇒ CRRA separable utility Vt = β 1−θ .
                                                              t


                   Sydney C. Ludvigson          Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics

         The MRS is pricing kernel (SDF) with added risk factor:
                                                     ρ−θ
                                          Vt+1 Ct+1
                            Ct + 1 − ρ   Ct+1 Ct    
               Mt + 1 = β
                             Ct          R Vt+1 Ct+1
                                               t   Ct+1 Ct




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics

         The MRS is pricing kernel (SDF) with added risk factor:
                                                     ρ−θ
                                          Vt+1 Ct+1
                            Ct + 1 − ρ   Ct+1 Ct    
               Mt + 1 = β
                             Ct          R Vt+1 Ct+1
                                               t   Ct+1 Ct

         Difficulty: MRS a function of V/C, unobservable, embeds
         Rt (·).




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics

         The MRS is pricing kernel (SDF) with added risk factor:
                                                     ρ−θ
                                          Vt+1 Ct+1
                            Ct + 1 − ρ   Ct+1 Ct    
               Mt + 1 = β
                             Ct          R Vt+1 Ct+1    t      Ct+1 Ct

         Difficulty: MRS a function of V/C, unobservable, embeds
         Rt (·).
         Epstein-Zin ’91 use alt. rep. of SDF, uses agg. wealth
         return Rw,t :
                                                        1− θ                θ −ρ
                                                  −ρ    1− ρ
                                         Ct + 1                     1       1− ρ
                    Mt + 1 =        β
                                          Ct                     Rw,t+1

         where Rw,t proxied by stock market return.


                   Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics

         The MRS is pricing kernel (SDF) with added risk factor:
                                                     ρ−θ
                                          Vt+1 Ct+1
                            Ct + 1 − ρ   Ct+1 Ct    
               Mt + 1 = β
                             Ct          R Vt+1 Ct+1    t      Ct+1 Ct

         Difficulty: MRS a function of V/C, unobservable, embeds
         Rt (·).
         Epstein-Zin ’91 use alt. rep. of SDF, uses agg. wealth
         return Rw,t :
                                                        1− θ                θ −ρ
                                                  −ρ    1− ρ
                                         Ct + 1                     1       1− ρ
                    Mt + 1 =        β
                                          Ct                     Rw,t+1

         where Rw,t proxied by stock market return.
         Problem: Rw,t+1 represents a claim to future Ct , itself
         unobservable.
                   Sydney C. Ludvigson            Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics


      1   If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series
          process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution.




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics


      1   If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series
          process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution.
      2   If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk
          premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between
          returns, and news about current and future Ct growth.




                   Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics


      1   If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series
          process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution.
      2   If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk
          premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between
          returns, and news about current and future Ct growth.

          But....




                    Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics


      1   If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series
          process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution.
      2   If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk
          premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between
          returns, and news about current and future Ct growth.

          But....
               EIS=1 ⇒ consumption-wealth ratio is constant,
               contradicting statistical evidence.




                    Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics


      1   If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series
          process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution.
      2   If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk
          premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between
          returns, and news about current and future Ct growth.

          But....
               EIS=1 ⇒ consumption-wealth ratio is constant,
               contradicting statistical evidence.
               Joint lognormality strongly rejected in quarterly data.




                    Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
EZW Recursive Preferences
Epstien-Zin-Weil basics


      1   If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series
          process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution.
      2   If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk
          premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between
          returns, and news about current and future Ct growth.

          But....
               EIS=1 ⇒ consumption-wealth ratio is constant,
               contradicting statistical evidence.
               Joint lognormality strongly rejected in quarterly data.

          Points to need for estimation method feasible under less
          restrictive assumptions.

                    Sydney C. Ludvigson   Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models

More Related Content

PDF
Signal Processing Course : Approximation
PDF
Fin econometricslecture
PDF
Pages from fin econometrics brandt_1
PDF
"Correlated Volatility Shocks" by Dr. Xiao Qiao, Researcher at SummerHaven In...
PDF
PhD Proposal St. Andrews University
PDF
Optimal Transport vs. Fisher-Rao distance between Copulas
PDF
Maxentropic and quantitative methods in operational risk modeling
PDF
Monash University short course, part II
Signal Processing Course : Approximation
Fin econometricslecture
Pages from fin econometrics brandt_1
"Correlated Volatility Shocks" by Dr. Xiao Qiao, Researcher at SummerHaven In...
PhD Proposal St. Andrews University
Optimal Transport vs. Fisher-Rao distance between Copulas
Maxentropic and quantitative methods in operational risk modeling
Monash University short course, part II

More from NBER (20)

PDF
FISCAL STIMULUS IN ECONOMIC UNIONS: WHAT ROLE FOR STATES
PDF
Business in the United States Who Owns it and How Much Tax They Pay
PDF
Redistribution through Minimum Wage Regulation: An Analysis of Program Linkag...
PDF
The Distributional E ffects of U.S. Clean Energy Tax Credits
PDF
An Experimental Evaluation of Strategies to Increase Property Tax Compliance:...
PDF
Nbe rtopicsandrecomvlecture1
PDF
Nbe rcausalpredictionv111 lecture2
PDF
Nber slides11 lecture2
PPTX
Recommenders, Topics, and Text
PPTX
Machine Learning and Causal Inference
PDF
Introduction to Supervised ML Concepts and Algorithms
PDF
Jackson nber-slides2014 lecture3
PDF
Jackson nber-slides2014 lecture1
PDF
Acemoglu lecture2
PDF
Acemoglu lecture4
PPTX
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Joshua Gans
PPTX
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Claudia Goldin
PPT
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - James Poterba
PPTX
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Scott Stern
PDF
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Glenn Ellison
FISCAL STIMULUS IN ECONOMIC UNIONS: WHAT ROLE FOR STATES
Business in the United States Who Owns it and How Much Tax They Pay
Redistribution through Minimum Wage Regulation: An Analysis of Program Linkag...
The Distributional E ffects of U.S. Clean Energy Tax Credits
An Experimental Evaluation of Strategies to Increase Property Tax Compliance:...
Nbe rtopicsandrecomvlecture1
Nbe rcausalpredictionv111 lecture2
Nber slides11 lecture2
Recommenders, Topics, and Text
Machine Learning and Causal Inference
Introduction to Supervised ML Concepts and Algorithms
Jackson nber-slides2014 lecture3
Jackson nber-slides2014 lecture1
Acemoglu lecture2
Acemoglu lecture4
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Joshua Gans
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Claudia Goldin
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - James Poterba
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Scott Stern
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Glenn Ellison
Ad

Ludvigson methodslecture 1

  • 1. NBER Summer Institute Econometrics Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Asset Pricing Sydney C. Ludvigson, NYU and NBER July 14, 2010 Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 2. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes Why care about consumption-based models? Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 3. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes Why care about consumption-based models? True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset prices are derived endogenously from these. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 4. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes Why care about consumption-based models? True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset prices are derived endogenously from these. Some cons-based models work better than others, but... Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 5. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes Why care about consumption-based models? True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset prices are derived endogenously from these. Some cons-based models work better than others, but... ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro variables often measured with error. Therefore: Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 6. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes Why care about consumption-based models? True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset prices are derived endogenously from these. Some cons-based models work better than others, but... ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro variables often measured with error. Therefore: 1 move away from specification tests of perfect fit (given sampling error), Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 7. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes Why care about consumption-based models? True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset prices are derived endogenously from these. Some cons-based models work better than others, but... ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro variables often measured with error. Therefore: 1 move away from specification tests of perfect fit (given sampling error), 2 toward estimation and testing that recognize all models are misspecified, Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 8. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes Why care about consumption-based models? True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset prices are derived endogenously from these. Some cons-based models work better than others, but... ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro variables often measured with error. Therefore: 1 move away from specification tests of perfect fit (given sampling error), 2 toward estimation and testing that recognize all models are misspecified, 3 toward methods permit comparison of magnitude of misspecification among multiple, competing macro models. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 9. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Themes Why care about consumption-based models? True systematic risk factors are macroeconomic in nature–derived from IMRS over consumption–asset prices are derived endogenously from these. Some cons-based models work better than others, but... ...emphasize here: all models are misspecified, and macro variables often measured with error. Therefore: 1 move away from specification tests of perfect fit (given sampling error), 2 toward estimation and testing that recognize all models are misspecified, 3 toward methods permit comparison of magnitude of misspecification among multiple, competing macro models. Themes are important in choosing which methods to use. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 10. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA utility model Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 11. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA utility model Incorporating conditioning information: scaled consumption-based models Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 12. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA utility model Incorporating conditioning information: scaled consumption-based models Generalizations of CRRA utility: recursive utility Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 13. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA utility model Incorporating conditioning information: scaled consumption-based models Generalizations of CRRA utility: recursive utility Semi-nonparametric minimum distance estimators: unrestricted LOM for data Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 14. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA utility model Incorporating conditioning information: scaled consumption-based models Generalizations of CRRA utility: recursive utility Semi-nonparametric minimum distance estimators: unrestricted LOM for data Simulation methods: restricted LOM Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 15. GMM and Consumption-Based Models: Outline GMM estimation of classic representative agent, CRRA utility model Incorporating conditioning information: scaled consumption-based models Generalizations of CRRA utility: recursive utility Semi-nonparametric minimum distance estimators: unrestricted LOM for data Simulation methods: restricted LOM Consumption-based asset pricing: concluding thoughts Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 16. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Economic model implies set of r population moment restrictions E{h (θ, wt )} = 0 (r × 1 ) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 17. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Economic model implies set of r population moment restrictions E{h (θ, wt )} = 0 (r × 1 ) wt is an h × 1 vector of variables known at t Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 18. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Economic model implies set of r population moment restrictions E{h (θ, wt )} = 0 (r × 1 ) wt is an h × 1 vector of variables known at t θ is an a × 1 vector of coefficients Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 19. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Economic model implies set of r population moment restrictions E{h (θ, wt )} = 0 (r × 1 ) wt is an h × 1 vector of variables known at t θ is an a × 1 vector of coefficients Idea: choose θ to make the sample moment as close as possible to the population moment. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 20. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Sample moments: T g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) , t= 1 (r × 1 ) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 21. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Sample moments: T g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) , t= 1 (r × 1 ) ′ ′ ′ ′ yT ≡ wT , wT −1 , ...w1 is a T · h × 1 vector of observations. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 22. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Sample moments: T g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) , t= 1 (r × 1 ) ′ ′ ′ ′ yT ≡ wT , wT −1 , ...w1 is a T · h × 1 vector of observations. The GMM estimator θ minimizes the scalar ′ Q (θ; yT ) = [g(θ; yT )] WT [g(θ; yT )], (1) ( 1× r ) (r×r) ( r × 1) ∞ {WT }T =1 a sequence of r × r positive definite matrices which may be a function of the data, yT . Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 23. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Sample moments: T g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) , t= 1 (r × 1 ) ′ ′ ′ ′ yT ≡ wT , wT −1 , ...w1 is a T · h × 1 vector of observations. The GMM estimator θ minimizes the scalar ′ Q (θ; yT ) = [g(θ; yT )] WT [g(θ; yT )], (1) ( 1× r ) (r×r) ( r × 1) ∞ {WT }T =1 a sequence of r × r positive definite matrices which may be a function of the data, yT . If r = a, θ estimated by setting each g(θ; yT ) to zero. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 24. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Sample moments: T g(θ; yT )≡ (1/T ) ∑ h (θ, wt ) , t= 1 (r × 1 ) ′ ′ ′ ′ yT ≡ wT , wT −1 , ...w1 is a T · h × 1 vector of observations. The GMM estimator θ minimizes the scalar ′ Q (θ; yT ) = [g(θ; yT )] WT [g(θ; yT )], (1) ( 1× r ) (r×r) ( r × 1) ∞ {WT }T =1 a sequence of r × r positive definite matrices which may be a function of the data, yT . If r = a, θ estimated by setting each g(θ; yT ) to zero. GMM refers to use of (1) to estimate θ when r > a. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 25. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Asym. properties (Hansen 1982): θ consistent, asym. normal. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 26. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Asym. properties (Hansen 1982): θ consistent, asym. normal. Optimal weighting WT = S−1   ∞     ′ S = r×r ∑ E  [h (θo , wt )] h θo , wt−j  . j=− ∞   r×1 1× r Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 27. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) Asym. properties (Hansen 1982): θ consistent, asym. normal. Optimal weighting WT = S−1   ∞     ′ S = r×r ∑ E  [h (θo , wt )] h θo , wt−j  . j=− ∞   r×1 1× r In many asset pricing applications, it is inappropriate to use WT = S−1 (see below). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 28. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) ST depends on θT which depends on ST . Employ an iterative procedure: Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 29. GMM Review (Hansen, 1982) ST depends on θT which depends on ST . Employ an iterative procedure: (1) 1 Obtain an initial estimate of θ = θT , by minimizing Q (θ; yT ) subject to arbitrary weighting matrix, e.g., W = I. (1) (1) 2 Use θT to obtain initial estimate of S = ST . (1 ) 3 Re-minimize Q (θ; yT ) using initial estimate ST ; obtain (2) new estimate θT . 4 Continue iterating until convergence, or stop. (Estimators have same asym. dist. but finite sample properties differ.) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 30. Classic Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Investors maximize utility ∞ max Et Ct ∑ β i u (C t + i ) i= 0 Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 31. Classic Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Investors maximize utility ∞ max Et Ct ∑ β i u (C t + i ) i= 0 Power (isoelastic) utility  1− γ  u (C ) =  Ct γ>0 t 1− γ (2)   u (Ct ) = ln(Ct ) γ = 1 Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 32. Classic Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Investors maximize utility ∞ max Et Ct ∑ β i u (C t + i ) i= 0 Power (isoelastic) utility  1− γ  u (C ) =  Ct γ>0 t 1− γ (2)   u (Ct ) = ln(Ct ) γ = 1 N assets => N first-order conditions −γ −γ Ct = βEt (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) Ct+1 i = 1, ..., N. (3) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 33. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Re-write moment conditions −γ Ct + 1 0 = Et 1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) −γ . (4) Ct Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 34. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Re-write moment conditions −γ Ct + 1 0 = Et 1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) −γ . (4) Ct 2 params to estimate: β and γ, so θ = ( β, γ) ′ . Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 35. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Re-write moment conditions −γ Ct + 1 0 = Et 1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) −γ . (4) Ct 2 params to estimate: β and γ, so θ = ( β, γ) ′ . ∗ xt denotes info set of investors −γ −γ ∗ 0=E 1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) Ct+1 /Ct |xt i = 1, ...N (5) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 36. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Re-write moment conditions −γ Ct + 1 0 = Et 1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) −γ . (4) Ct 2 params to estimate: β and γ, so θ = ( β, γ) ′ . ∗ xt denotes info set of investors −γ −γ ∗ 0=E 1 − β (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) Ct+1 /Ct |xt i = 1, ...N (5) ∗ . Conditional model (5) => unconditional model: xt ⊂ xt −γ Ct + 1 0=E 1− β (1 + ℜi,t+1 ) −γ xt i = 1, ...N Ct (6) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 37. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Let xt be M × 1. Then r = N · M and,  −γ  C +1  1 − β (1 + ℜ1,t+1 ) t−γ xt  Ct    −γ Ct+1   1 − β (1 + ℜ2,t+1 ) −γ xt   Ct     h (θ, wt ) =  ·  (7)  r×1  ·     ·     −γ C +1  1 − β (1 + ℜN,t+1 ) t−γ xt Ct Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 38. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Let xt be M × 1. Then r = N · M and,  −γ  C +1  1 − β (1 + ℜ1,t+1 ) t−γ xt  Ct    −γ Ct+1   1 − β (1 + ℜ2,t+1 ) −γ xt   Ct     h (θ, wt ) =  ·  (7)  r×1  ·     ·     −γ C +1  1 − β (1 + ℜN,t+1 ) t−γ xt Ct Model can be estimated, tested as long as r ≥ 2. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 39. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Let xt be M × 1. Then r = N · M and,  −γ  C +1  1 − β (1 + ℜ1,t+1 ) t−γ xt  Ct    −γ Ct+1   1 − β (1 + ℜ2,t+1 ) −γ xt   Ct     h (θ, wt ) =  ·  (7)  r×1  ·     ·     −γ C +1  1 − β (1 + ℜN,t+1 ) t−γ xt Ct Model can be estimated, tested as long as r ≥ 2. Take sample mean of (7) to get g(θ; yT ), minimize ′ min Q (θ; yT ) = [g(θ; yT )] WT [g(θ; yT )] θ r×r 1× r r×1 Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 40. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions: a TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 41. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions: a TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a) HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and industry returns, NDS expenditures. Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity premium puzzle! But.... Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 42. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions: a TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a) HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and industry returns, NDS expenditures. Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity premium puzzle! But.... ...model is strongly rejected according to OID test. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 43. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions: a TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a) HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and industry returns, NDS expenditures. Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity premium puzzle! But.... ...model is strongly rejected according to OID test. Campbell, Lo, MacKinlay (1997): OID rejections stronger whenever stock returns and commercial paper are included as test returns. Why? Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 44. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions: a TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a) HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and industry returns, NDS expenditures. Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity premium puzzle! But.... ...model is strongly rejected according to OID test. Campbell, Lo, MacKinlay (1997): OID rejections stronger whenever stock returns and commercial paper are included as test returns. Why? Model cannot capture predictable variation in excess returns over commercial paper ⇒ Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 45. Asset Pricing Example: Hansen and Singleton (1982) Test of Over-identifying (OID) restrictions: a TQ θ; yT ∼ χ2 (r − a) HS use lags of cons growth and returns in xt ; index and industry returns, NDS expenditures. Estimates of β ≈ .99, RRA low = .35 to .999. No equity premium puzzle! But.... ...model is strongly rejected according to OID test. Campbell, Lo, MacKinlay (1997): OID rejections stronger whenever stock returns and commercial paper are included as test returns. Why? Model cannot capture predictable variation in excess returns over commercial paper ⇒ Researchers have turned to other models of preferences. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 46. More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors Results in HS use conditioning info xt –scaled returns. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 47. More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors Results in HS use conditioning info xt –scaled returns. Another limitation with classic CCAPM: large unconditional Euler equation (pricing) errors even when params freely chosen. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 48. More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors Results in HS use conditioning info xt –scaled returns. Another limitation with classic CCAPM: large unconditional Euler equation (pricing) errors even when params freely chosen. Let Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ . Define Euler equation errors: j j eR ≡ E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] − 1 j j f eX ≡ E[Mt+1 (Rt+1 − Rt+1 )] Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 49. More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors Results in HS use conditioning info xt –scaled returns. Another limitation with classic CCAPM: large unconditional Euler equation (pricing) errors even when params freely chosen. Let Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ . Define Euler equation errors: j j eR ≡ E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] − 1 j j f eX ≡ E[Mt+1 (Rt+1 − Rt+1 )] ′ Choose params: min β,γ gT WT gT where jth element of gT j gj,t (γ, β) = 1 T ∑T=1 eR,t t j gj,t (γ) = 1 T ∑T=1 eX,t t Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 50. Unconditional Euler Equation Errors, Excess Returns j j f eX ≡ E[ β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ (Rt+1 − Rt+1 )] j = 1, ..., N j j f RMSE = 1 N ∑N 1 [eX ]2 , j= RMSR = 1 N N ∑j=1 [E(Rt+1 − Rt+1 )]2 Source: Lettau and Ludvigson (2009). Rs is the excess return on CRSP-VW index over 3-Mo T-bill rate. Rs & 6 FF refers to this return plus 6 size and book-market sorted portfolios provided by Fama and French. For each value of γ, β is chosen to minimize the Euler equation error for the T-bill rate. U.S. quarterly data, 1954:1-2002:1. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 51. More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors Magnitude of errors large, even when parameters are freely chosen to minimize errors. Unlike the equity premium puzzle of Mehra and Prescott (1985), large Euler eq. errors cannot be resolved with high risk aversion. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 52. More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors Magnitude of errors large, even when parameters are freely chosen to minimize errors. Unlike the equity premium puzzle of Mehra and Prescott (1985), large Euler eq. errors cannot be resolved with high risk aversion. Lettau and Ludvigson (2009): Leading consumption-based asset pricing theories fail to explain the mispricing of classic CCAPM. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 53. More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors Magnitude of errors large, even when parameters are freely chosen to minimize errors. Unlike the equity premium puzzle of Mehra and Prescott (1985), large Euler eq. errors cannot be resolved with high risk aversion. Lettau and Ludvigson (2009): Leading consumption-based asset pricing theories fail to explain the mispricing of classic CCAPM. Anomaly is striking b/c early evidence (e.g., Hansen & Singleton) that the classic model’s Euler equations were violated provided the impetus for developing these newer models. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 54. More GMM results: Euler Equation Errors Magnitude of errors large, even when parameters are freely chosen to minimize errors. Unlike the equity premium puzzle of Mehra and Prescott (1985), large Euler eq. errors cannot be resolved with high risk aversion. Lettau and Ludvigson (2009): Leading consumption-based asset pricing theories fail to explain the mispricing of classic CCAPM. Anomaly is striking b/c early evidence (e.g., Hansen & Singleton) that the classic model’s Euler equations were violated provided the impetus for developing these newer models. Results imply data on consumption and asset returns not jointly lognormal! Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 55. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Asset pricing applications often require WT S−1 . Why? Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 56. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Asset pricing applications often require WT S−1 . Why? One reason: assessing specification error, comparing models. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 57. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Asset pricing applications often require WT S−1 . Why? One reason: assessing specification error, comparing models. Consider two estimated models of SDF, e.g., (1) 1 CCAPM: Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ , OID restricts not rejected (2) 2 CAPM: Mt+1 = a + bRm,t+1 , OID restricts rejected Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 58. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Asset pricing applications often require WT S−1 . Why? One reason: assessing specification error, comparing models. Consider two estimated models of SDF, e.g., (1) 1 CCAPM: Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ , OID restricts not rejected (2) 2 CAPM: Mt+1 = a + bRm,t+1 , OID restricts rejected May we conclude Model 1 is superior? Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 59. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Asset pricing applications often require WT S−1 . Why? One reason: assessing specification error, comparing models. Consider two estimated models of SDF, e.g., (1) 1 CCAPM: Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ , OID restricts not rejected (2) 2 CAPM: Mt+1 = a + bRm,t+1 , OID restricts rejected May we conclude Model 1 is superior? No. Hansen’s J-test of OID restricts depends on model specific S: J = gT S−1 gT . ′ Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 60. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Asset pricing applications often require WT S−1 . Why? One reason: assessing specification error, comparing models. Consider two estimated models of SDF, e.g., (1) 1 CCAPM: Mt+1 = β(Ct+1 /Ct )−γ , OID restricts not rejected (2) 2 CAPM: Mt+1 = a + bRm,t+1 , OID restricts rejected May we conclude Model 1 is superior? No. Hansen’s J-test of OID restricts depends on model specific S: J = gT S−1 gT . ′ Model 1 can look better simply b/c the SDF and pricing errors gT are more volatile, not b/c pricing errors are lower. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 61. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric: T 1 DistT (θ) = mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ), − GT ≡ ∑ Rt Rt′ θ T t= 1 N ×N T 1 gT (θ) ≡ T ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ] t= 1 Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 62. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric: T 1 DistT (θ) = mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ), − GT ≡ ∑ Rt Rt′ θ T t= 1 N ×N T 1 gT (θ) ≡ T ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ] t= 1 DistT does not reward SDF volatility => suitable for model comparison. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 63. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric: T 1 DistT (θ) = mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ), − GT ≡ ∑ Rt Rt′ θ T t= 1 N ×N T 1 gT (θ) ≡ T ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ] t= 1 DistT does not reward SDF volatility => suitable for model comparison. DistT is a measure of model misspecification: Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 64. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric: T 1 DistT (θ) = mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ), − GT ≡ ∑ Rt Rt′ θ T t= 1 N ×N T 1 gT (θ) ≡ T ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ] t= 1 DistT does not reward SDF volatility => suitable for model comparison. DistT is a measure of model misspecification: Gives distance between Mt (θ) and nearest point in space of all SDFs that price assets correctly. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 65. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 HJ: compare models Mt (θ) using distance metric: T 1 DistT (θ) = mingT (θ)′ GT 1 gT (θ), − GT ≡ ∑ Rt Rt′ θ T t= 1 N ×N T 1 gT (θ) ≡ T ∑ [Mt (θ)Rt − 1N ] t= 1 DistT does not reward SDF volatility => suitable for model comparison. DistT is a measure of model misspecification: Gives distance between Mt (θ) and nearest point in space of all SDFs that price assets correctly. Gives maximum pricing error of any portfolio formed from the N assets. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 66. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Appeal of HJ Distance metric: Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 67. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Appeal of HJ Distance metric: Recognizes all models are misspecified. Provides method for comparing models by assessing which is least misspecified. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 68. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Appeal of HJ Distance metric: Recognizes all models are misspecified. Provides method for comparing models by assessing which is least misspecified. Important problem: how to compare HJ distances statistically? Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 69. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Comparing specification error: Hansen and Jagannathan, 1997 Appeal of HJ Distance metric: Recognizes all models are misspecified. Provides method for comparing models by assessing which is least misspecified. Important problem: how to compare HJ distances statistically? One possibility developed in Chen and Ludvigson (2009): White’s reality check method. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 70. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009 Chen and Ludvigson (2009) compare HJ distances among K competing models using White’s reality check method. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 71. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009 Chen and Ludvigson (2009) compare HJ distances among K competing models using White’s reality check method. 1 Take benchmark model, e.g., model with smallest squared distance d1,T ≡ min{d2 }K 1 . 2 j,T j= 2 Null: d2 − d2 ≤ 0, where d2 is competing model with 1,T 2,T 2,T the next smallest squared distance. √ 3 Test statistic T W = T (d2 − d2,T ). 1,T 2 4 If null is true, test statistic should not be unusually large, given sampling error. 5 Given distribution for T W , reject null if historical value T W is > 95th percentile. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 72. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009 Chen and Ludvigson (2009) compare HJ distances among K competing models using White’s reality check method. 1 Take benchmark model, e.g., model with smallest squared distance d1,T ≡ min{d2 }K 1 . 2 j,T j= 2 Null: d2 − d2 ≤ 0, where d2 is competing model with 1,T 2,T 2,T the next smallest squared distance. √ 3 Test statistic T W = T (d2 − d2,T ). 1,T 2 4 If null is true, test statistic should not be unusually large, given sampling error. 5 Given distribution for T W , reject null if historical value T W is > 95th percentile. Method applies generally to any stationary law of motion for data, multiple competing possibly nonlinear, SDF models. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 73. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009 Distribution of T W is computed via block bootstrap. T W has complicated limiting distribution. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 74. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009 Distribution of T W is computed via block bootstrap. T W has complicated limiting distribution. Bootstrap works only if have a multivariate, joint, continuous, limiting distribution under null. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 75. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009 Distribution of T W is computed via block bootstrap. T W has complicated limiting distribution. Bootstrap works only if have a multivariate, joint, continuous, limiting distribution under null. Proof of limiting distributions exists for applications to most asset pricing models: Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 76. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Statistical comparison of HJ distance: Chen and Ludvigson, 2009 Distribution of T W is computed via block bootstrap. T W has complicated limiting distribution. Bootstrap works only if have a multivariate, joint, continuous, limiting distribution under null. Proof of limiting distributions exists for applications to most asset pricing models: For parametric models (Hansen, Heaton, Luttmer ’95) For semiparametric models (Ai and Chen ’07). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 77. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Reasons to use identity matrix: econometric problems − − Econometric problems: near singular ST 1 or GT 1 . Asset returns are highly correlated. We have large N and modest T. If T < N covariance matrix for N asset returns is singular. Unless T >> N, matrix can be near-singular. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 78. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Reasons to use identity matrix: economically interesting portfolios Original test assets may have economically meaningful characteristics (e.g., size, value). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 79. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Reasons to use identity matrix: economically interesting portfolios Original test assets may have economically meaningful characteristics (e.g., size, value). − − Using WT = ST 1 or GT 1 same as using WT = I and doing GMM on re-weighted portfolios of original test assets. Triangular factorization S−1 = (P′ P), P lower triangular min gT S−1 gT ⇔ (gT P′ )I(PgT ) ′ ′ Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 80. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Reasons to use identity matrix: economically interesting portfolios Original test assets may have economically meaningful characteristics (e.g., size, value). − − Using WT = ST 1 or GT 1 same as using WT = I and doing GMM on re-weighted portfolios of original test assets. Triangular factorization S−1 = (P′ P), P lower triangular min gT S−1 gT ⇔ (gT P′ )I(PgT ) ′ ′ Re-weighted portfolios may not provide large spread in average returns. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 81. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Reasons to use identity matrix: economically interesting portfolios Original test assets may have economically meaningful characteristics (e.g., size, value). − − Using WT = ST 1 or GT 1 same as using WT = I and doing GMM on re-weighted portfolios of original test assets. Triangular factorization S−1 = (P′ P), P lower triangular min gT S−1 gT ⇔ (gT P′ )I(PgT ) ′ ′ Re-weighted portfolios may not provide large spread in average returns. May imply implausible long and short positions in test assets. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 82. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Reasons not to use WT = I: objective function dependence on test asset choice Using WT = [ET (R′ R)]−1 , GMM objective function is invariant to initial choice of test assets. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 83. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Reasons not to use WT = I: objective function dependence on test asset choice Using WT = [ET (R′ R)]−1 , GMM objective function is invariant to initial choice of test assets. Form a portfolio, AR from initial returns R. (Note, portfolio weights sum to 1 so A1N = 1N ). −1 [E (MR) − 1N ]′ E RR′ [E (MR − 1N )] ′ −1 = [E (MAR) − A1N ] E ARR′ A [E (MAR − A1N )] . Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 84. GMM Asset Pricing With Non-Optimal Weighting Reasons not to use WT = I: objective function dependence on test asset choice Using WT = [ET (R′ R)]−1 , GMM objective function is invariant to initial choice of test assets. Form a portfolio, AR from initial returns R. (Note, portfolio weights sum to 1 so A1N = 1N ). −1 [E (MR) − 1N ]′ E RR′ [E (MR − 1N )] ′ −1 = [E (MAR) − A1N ] E ARR′ A [E (MAR − A1N )] . With WT = I or other fixed weighting, GMM objective depends on choice of test assets. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 85. More Complex Preferences: Scaled Consumption-Based Models Consumption-based models may be approximated: Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 , ct+1 ≡ ln(Ct+1 ) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 86. More Complex Preferences: Scaled Consumption-Based Models Consumption-based models may be approximated: Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 , ct+1 ≡ ln(Ct+1 ) Example: Classic CCAPM with CRRA utility 1− γ Ct u ( Ct ) = ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β − βγ ∆ct+1 1−γ at = a0 bt = b0 Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 87. More Complex Preferences: Scaled Consumption-Based Models Consumption-based models may be approximated: Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 , ct+1 ≡ ln(Ct+1 ) Example: Classic CCAPM with CRRA utility 1− γ Ct u ( Ct ) = ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β − βγ ∆ct+1 1−γ at = a0 bt = b0 Model with habit and time-varying risk aversion: Campbell and Cochrane ’99, Menzly et. al ’04 ( Ct S t ) 1 − γ C t − Xt u ( Ct , S t ) = , St + 1 ≡ 1−γ Ct ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β 1 − γ (φ − 1)(st − s) − γ (1 + ψ (st )) ∆ct+1 at bt Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 88. More Complex Preferences: Scaled Consumption-Based Models Consumption-based models may be approximated: Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 , ct+1 ≡ ln(Ct+1 ) Example: Classic CCAPM with CRRA utility 1− γ Ct u ( Ct ) = ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β − βγ ∆ct+1 1−γ at = a0 bt = b0 Model with habit and time-varying risk aversion: Campbell and Cochrane ’99, Menzly et. al ’04 ( Ct S t ) 1 − γ C t − Xt u ( Ct , S t ) = , St + 1 ≡ 1−γ Ct ⇒ Mt+1 ≈ β 1 − γ (φ − 1)(st − s) − γ (1 + ψ (st )) ∆ct+1 at bt Proxies for time-varying risk-premia should be good proxies for time-variation in at and bt . Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 89. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 Empirical specification: Lettau and Ludvigson (2001a, 2001b): at = a0 + a1 zt , bt = b0 + b1 zt zt = cayt ≡ ct − αa at − αy yt , (cointegrating residual) cayt related to log consumption-(aggregate) wealth ratio. cayt strong predictor of excess stock market returns Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 90. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ct+1 Empirical specification: Lettau and Ludvigson (2001a, 2001b): at = a0 + a1 zt , bt = b0 + b1 zt zt = cayt ≡ ct − αa at − αy yt , (cointegrating residual) cayt related to log consumption-(aggregate) wealth ratio. cayt strong predictor of excess stock market returns Other examples: including housing consumption 1 1− σ ε Ct ε −1 ε −1 ε −1 U(Ct , Ht ) = 1 Ct = χCt ε + (1 − χ) Ht ε , 1− σ pC Ct t ⇒ ln Mt+1 ≈ at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 + dt ∆ ln St+1 , St + 1 ≡ pC Ct t + pH Ht t Lustig and Van Nieuwerburgh ’05 (incomplete markets): at = a0 + a1 zt , bt = b0 + b1 zt , dt = d0 + d1 zt zt = housing collateral ratio (measures quantity of risk sharing) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 91. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Two kinds of conditioning are often confused. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 92. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Two kinds of conditioning are often confused. Euler equation: E Mt+1 Rt+1 |zt = 1 Unconditional version: E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1 Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 93. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Two kinds of conditioning are often confused. Euler equation: E Mt+1 Rt+1 |zt = 1 Unconditional version: E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1 Two forms of conditionality: 1 scaling returns: E Mt+1 Ri,t+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′ = 1 2 scaling factors ft+1 , e.g., ft+1 = ∆ ln Ct+1 : ′ Mt+1 = bt ft+1 with bt = b0 + b1 zt = b′ ft+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′ Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 94. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Two kinds of conditioning are often confused. Euler equation: E Mt+1 Rt+1 |zt = 1 Unconditional version: E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1 Two forms of conditionality: 1 scaling returns: E Mt+1 Ri,t+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′ = 1 2 scaling factors ft+1 , e.g., ft+1 = ∆ ln Ct+1 : ′ Mt+1 = bt ft+1 with bt = b0 + b1 zt = b′ ft+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′ Scaled consumption-based models are conditional in sense that Mt+1 is a state-dependent function of ∆ ln Ct+1 ⇒ scaled factors Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 95. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Two kinds of conditioning are often confused. Euler equation: E Mt+1 Rt+1 |zt = 1 Unconditional version: E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1 Two forms of conditionality: 1 scaling returns: E Mt+1 Ri,t+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′ = 1 2 scaling factors ft+1 , e.g., ft+1 = ∆ ln Ct+1 : ′ Mt+1 = bt ft+1 with bt = b0 + b1 zt = b′ ft+1 ⊗ (1 zt )′ Scaled consumption-based models are conditional in sense that Mt+1 is a state-dependent function of ∆ ln Ct+1 ⇒ scaled factors Scaled consumption-based models have been tested on unconditional moments, E Mt+1 Rt+1 = 1 ⇒ NO scaled returns. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 96. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Scaled CCAPM turns a single factor model with state-dependent weights into multi-factor model ft with constant weights: Mt+1 = (a0 + a1 zt ) + (b0 + b1 zt ) ∆ ln Ct+1 = a0 + a1 zt +b0 ∆ ln Ct+1 +b1 (zt ∆ ln Ct+1 ) f1,t+1 f2,t+1 f3,t+1 Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 97. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Scaled CCAPM turns a single factor model with state-dependent weights into multi-factor model ft with constant weights: Mt+1 = (a0 + a1 zt ) + (b0 + b1 zt ) ∆ ln Ct+1 = a0 + a1 zt +b0 ∆ ln Ct+1 +b1 (zt ∆ ln Ct+1 ) f1,t+1 f2,t+1 f3,t+1 ′ Multiple risk factors ft ≡ (zt , ∆ ln Ct+1 , zt ∆ ln Ct+1 ). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 98. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Scaled CCAPM turns a single factor model with state-dependent weights into multi-factor model ft with constant weights: Mt+1 = (a0 + a1 zt ) + (b0 + b1 zt ) ∆ ln Ct+1 = a0 + a1 zt +b0 ∆ ln Ct+1 +b1 (zt ∆ ln Ct+1 ) f1,t+1 f2,t+1 f3,t+1 ′ Multiple risk factors ft ≡ (zt , ∆ ln Ct+1 , zt ∆ ln Ct+1 ). Scaled consumption models have multiple, constant betas for each factor, rather than a single time-varying beta for ∆ ln Ct+1 . Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 99. Deriving the “beta”-representation Let F = (1 f′ )′ , M = b′ F, ignore time indices 1 = E[MRi ] = E[Ri F′ ]b ⇒ unconditional moments = E[Ri ]E[F′ ]b + Cov(Ri , F′ )b ⇒ 1 − Cov(Ri , F′ )b E[Ri ] = E [F′ ]b 1 − Cov(Ri , f′ )b = E [F′ ]b 1 − Cov(Ri , f′ )Cov(f, f′ )−1 Cov(f, f′ )b = E [F′ ]b = R0 − R0 β′ Cov(f, f′ )b = R0 − β′ λ ⇒ multiple, constant betas Estimate cross-sectional model using Fama-MacBeth (see Brandt lecture). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 100. Fama-MacBeth Methodology: Preview–See Brandt Step 1: Estimate β’s in time-series regression for each portfolio i: βi ≡ Cov(ft+1 , ft+1 )−1 Cov(ft+1 , Ri,t+1 ) ′ Step 2: Cross-sectional regressions (T of them): Ri,t+1 − R0,t = αi,t + βi′ λt T T λ = 1/T ∑ λt ; σ2 (λ) = 1/T ∑ (λt − λ)2 t= 1 t= 1 Note: report Shanken t-statistics (corrected for estimation error of betas in first stage) Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 101. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Scaled models: conditioning done in SDF: Mt+1 = at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 , not in Euler equation: E(MR) = 1N . Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 102. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Scaled models: conditioning done in SDF: Mt+1 = at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 , not in Euler equation: E(MR) = 1N . Gives rise to a restricted conditional consumption beta model: Ri = a + β ∆c ∆ct + β ∆c,z ∆ct zt−1 + βz zt−1 t Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 103. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Scaled models: conditioning done in SDF: Mt+1 = at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 , not in Euler equation: E(MR) = 1N . Gives rise to a restricted conditional consumption beta model: Ri = a + β ∆c ∆ct + β ∆c,z ∆ct zt−1 + βz zt−1 t Rewrite as Ri = a + ( βc + βc,z zt−1 ) ∆ct + βz zt−1 t time-varying beta Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 104. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Scaled models: conditioning done in SDF: Mt+1 = at + bt ∆ ln Ct+1 , not in Euler equation: E(MR) = 1N . Gives rise to a restricted conditional consumption beta model: Ri = a + β ∆c ∆ct + β ∆c,z ∆ct zt−1 + βz zt−1 t Rewrite as Ri = a + ( βc + βc,z zt−1 ) ∆ct + βz zt−1 t time-varying beta Unlikely the same time-varying beta as obtained from modeling conditional mean Et (Mt+1 Rt+1 ) = 1. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 105. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Distinction is important. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 106. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Distinction is important. Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance: typically a few variables that capture risk-premia. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 107. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Distinction is important. Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance: typically a few variables that capture risk-premia. Conditioning in Euler eqn: model joint dist. (Mt+1 Rt+1 ). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 108. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Distinction is important. Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance: typically a few variables that capture risk-premia. Conditioning in Euler eqn: model joint dist. (Mt+1 Rt+1 ). Latter may require variables beyond a few that capture risk-premia. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 109. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Distinction is important. Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance: typically a few variables that capture risk-premia. Conditioning in Euler eqn: model joint dist. (Mt+1 Rt+1 ). Latter may require variables beyond a few that capture risk-premia. Approximating condition mean well requires large number of instruments (misspecified information sets) Results sensitive to chosen conditioning variables, may fail to span information sets of market participants. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 110. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Distinction is important. Conditioning in SDF: theory provides guidance: typically a few variables that capture risk-premia. Conditioning in Euler eqn: model joint dist. (Mt+1 Rt+1 ). Latter may require variables beyond a few that capture risk-premia. Approximating condition mean well requires large number of instruments (misspecified information sets) Results sensitive to chosen conditioning variables, may fail to span information sets of market participants. Partial solution: summarize information in large number of time-series with few estimated dynamic factors (e.g., Ludvigson and Ng ’07, ’09). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 111. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Bottom lines: Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 112. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Bottom lines: 1 Conditional moments of Mt+1 Rt+1 difficult to model ⇒ reason to focus on unconditional moments E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] = 1. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 113. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Bottom lines: 1 Conditional moments of Mt+1 Rt+1 difficult to model ⇒ reason to focus on unconditional moments E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] = 1. 2 Models are misspecified: interesting question is whether state-dependence of Mt+1 on consumption growth ⇒ less misspecification than standard, fixed-weight CCAPM. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 114. Scaled Consumption-Based Models Distinguishing two types of conditioning, or state dependence Bottom lines: 1 Conditional moments of Mt+1 Rt+1 difficult to model ⇒ reason to focus on unconditional moments E[Mt+1 Rt+1 ] = 1. 2 Models are misspecified: interesting question is whether state-dependence of Mt+1 on consumption growth ⇒ less misspecification than standard, fixed-weight CCAPM. 3 As before, can compare models on basis of HJ distances, using White ”reality check” method to compare statistically. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 115. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 116. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW). Two reasons recursive utility is of interest: Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 117. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW). Two reasons recursive utility is of interest: More flexibility as regards attitudes toward risk and intertemporal substitution. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 118. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW). Two reasons recursive utility is of interest: More flexibility as regards attitudes toward risk and intertemporal substitution. Preferences deliver an added risk factor for explaining asset returns. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 119. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Growing interest in asset pricing models with recursive preferences, e.g., Epstein and Zin ’89, ’91, Weil ’89, (EZW). Two reasons recursive utility is of interest: More flexibility as regards attitudes toward risk and intertemporal substitution. Preferences deliver an added risk factor for explaining asset returns. But, only a small amount of econometric work on recursive preferences ⇒ gap in the literature. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 120. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models: Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 121. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models: 1 For general stationary, consumption growth and cash flow dynamics: Chen, Favilukis, Ludvigson ’07. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 122. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models: 1 For general stationary, consumption growth and cash flow dynamics: Chen, Favilukis, Ludvigson ’07. 2 When restricting cash flow dynamics (e.g., “long-run risk”): Bansal, Gallant, Tauchen ’07. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 123. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models: 1 For general stationary, consumption growth and cash flow dynamics: Chen, Favilukis, Ludvigson ’07. 2 When restricting cash flow dynamics (e.g., “long-run risk”): Bansal, Gallant, Tauchen ’07. In (1) DGP is left unrestricted, as is joint distribution of consumption and returns (distribution-free estimation procedure). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 124. Asset Pricing Models With Recursive Preferences Here discuss two examples of estimating EZW models: 1 For general stationary, consumption growth and cash flow dynamics: Chen, Favilukis, Ludvigson ’07. 2 When restricting cash flow dynamics (e.g., “long-run risk”): Bansal, Gallant, Tauchen ’07. In (1) DGP is left unrestricted, as is joint distribution of consumption and returns (distribution-free estimation procedure). In (2) DGP and distribution of shocks explicitly modeled. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 125. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstein-Zin-Weil basics Recursive utility (Epstein, Zin (’89, ’91) & Weil (’89)): 1 1− ρ + β R t ( Vt + 1 ) 1 − ρ 1− ρ Vt = ( 1 − β ) Ct 1 1− 1− θ Rt (Vt+1 ) = E Vt+1θ |Ft Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 126. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstein-Zin-Weil basics Recursive utility (Epstein, Zin (’89, ’91) & Weil (’89)): 1 1− ρ + β R t ( Vt + 1 ) 1 − ρ 1− ρ Vt = ( 1 − β ) Ct 1 1− 1− θ Rt (Vt+1 ) = E Vt+1θ |Ft Vt+1 is continuation value, θ is RRA, 1/ρ is EIS. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 127. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstein-Zin-Weil basics Recursive utility (Epstein, Zin (’89, ’91) & Weil (’89)): 1 1− ρ + β R t ( Vt + 1 ) 1 − ρ 1− ρ Vt = ( 1 − β ) Ct 1 1− 1− θ Rt (Vt+1 ) = E Vt+1θ |Ft Vt+1 is continuation value, θ is RRA, 1/ρ is EIS. Rescale utility function (Hansen, Heaton, Li ’05): 1 1− ρ 1− ρ Vt Vt + 1 Ct + 1 = ( 1 − β ) + β Rt Ct Ct + 1 Ct Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 128. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstein-Zin-Weil basics Recursive utility (Epstein, Zin (’89, ’91) & Weil (’89)): 1 1− ρ + β R t ( Vt + 1 ) 1 − ρ 1− ρ Vt = ( 1 − β ) Ct 1 1− 1− θ Rt (Vt+1 ) = E Vt+1θ |Ft Vt+1 is continuation value, θ is RRA, 1/ρ is EIS. Rescale utility function (Hansen, Heaton, Li ’05): 1 1− ρ 1− ρ Vt Vt + 1 Ct + 1 = ( 1 − β ) + β Rt Ct Ct + 1 Ct C1−θ Special case: ρ = θ ⇒ CRRA separable utility Vt = β 1−θ . t Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 129. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics The MRS is pricing kernel (SDF) with added risk factor:   ρ−θ Vt+1 Ct+1 Ct + 1 − ρ  Ct+1 Ct  Mt + 1 = β Ct R Vt+1 Ct+1 t Ct+1 Ct Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 130. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics The MRS is pricing kernel (SDF) with added risk factor:   ρ−θ Vt+1 Ct+1 Ct + 1 − ρ  Ct+1 Ct  Mt + 1 = β Ct R Vt+1 Ct+1 t Ct+1 Ct Difficulty: MRS a function of V/C, unobservable, embeds Rt (·). Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 131. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics The MRS is pricing kernel (SDF) with added risk factor:   ρ−θ Vt+1 Ct+1 Ct + 1 − ρ  Ct+1 Ct  Mt + 1 = β Ct R Vt+1 Ct+1 t Ct+1 Ct Difficulty: MRS a function of V/C, unobservable, embeds Rt (·). Epstein-Zin ’91 use alt. rep. of SDF, uses agg. wealth return Rw,t : 1− θ θ −ρ −ρ 1− ρ Ct + 1 1 1− ρ Mt + 1 = β Ct Rw,t+1 where Rw,t proxied by stock market return. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 132. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics The MRS is pricing kernel (SDF) with added risk factor:   ρ−θ Vt+1 Ct+1 Ct + 1 − ρ  Ct+1 Ct  Mt + 1 = β Ct R Vt+1 Ct+1 t Ct+1 Ct Difficulty: MRS a function of V/C, unobservable, embeds Rt (·). Epstein-Zin ’91 use alt. rep. of SDF, uses agg. wealth return Rw,t : 1− θ θ −ρ −ρ 1− ρ Ct + 1 1 1− ρ Mt + 1 = β Ct Rw,t+1 where Rw,t proxied by stock market return. Problem: Rw,t+1 represents a claim to future Ct , itself unobservable. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 133. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics 1 If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 134. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics 1 If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution. 2 If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between returns, and news about current and future Ct growth. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 135. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics 1 If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution. 2 If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between returns, and news about current and future Ct growth. But.... Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 136. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics 1 If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution. 2 If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between returns, and news about current and future Ct growth. But.... EIS=1 ⇒ consumption-wealth ratio is constant, contradicting statistical evidence. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 137. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics 1 If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution. 2 If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between returns, and news about current and future Ct growth. But.... EIS=1 ⇒ consumption-wealth ratio is constant, contradicting statistical evidence. Joint lognormality strongly rejected in quarterly data. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models
  • 138. EZW Recursive Preferences Epstien-Zin-Weil basics 1 If EIS=1, and ∆ log Ct+1 follows a loglinear time-series process, log(V/C) has an analytical solution. 2 If returns, Ct are jointly lognormal and homoscedastic, risk premia are approx. log-linear functions of COV between returns, and news about current and future Ct growth. But.... EIS=1 ⇒ consumption-wealth ratio is constant, contradicting statistical evidence. Joint lognormality strongly rejected in quarterly data. Points to need for estimation method feasible under less restrictive assumptions. Sydney C. Ludvigson Methods Lecture: GMM and Consumption-Based Models