SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Social Security Policy In A Changing Environment
Jeffrey R Brown Editor Jeffrey B Liebman Editor
David A Wise Editor download
https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-policy-in-a-
changing-environment-jeffrey-r-brown-editor-jeffrey-b-liebman-
editor-david-a-wise-editor-51440648
Explore and download more ebooks at ebookbell.com
Here are some recommended products that we believe you will be
interested in. You can click the link to download.
Social Security Policy In Hong Kong From British Colony To Chinas
Special Administrative Region Chak Kwan Chan
https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-policy-in-hong-kong-
from-british-colony-to-chinas-special-administrative-region-chak-kwan-
chan-49058862
Social Security In The Balkans Volume 3 An Overview Of Social Policy
In Serbia And Kosovo Marzena Akowska Editor
https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-in-the-balkans-
volume-3-an-overview-of-social-policy-in-serbia-and-kosovo-marzena-
akowska-editor-53629856
Social Security In The Balkans Volume 1 An Overview Of Social Policy
In Croatia Albania Bosnia And Hercegovina Greece Romania And Bulgaria
Marzena Akowska
https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-in-the-balkans-
volume-1-an-overview-of-social-policy-in-croatia-albania-bosnia-and-
hercegovina-greece-romania-and-bulgaria-marzena-akowska-35011102
Labor Markets And Social Security Issues And Policy Options In The Us
And Europe 2nd Edition John T Addison
https://ebookbell.com/product/labor-markets-and-social-security-
issues-and-policy-options-in-the-us-and-europe-2nd-edition-john-t-
addison-4520432
Social Security And Wage Poverty Historical And Policy Aspects Of
Supplementing Wages In Britain And Beyond Chris Grover Auth
https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-and-wage-poverty-
historical-and-policy-aspects-of-supplementing-wages-in-britain-and-
beyond-chris-grover-auth-5612368
Labor Policy To Promote Good Jobs In Tunisia Revisiting Labor
Regulation Social Security And Active Labor Market Programs 1st
Edition Anne Hilger Arvo Kuddo Jan Rutkowski World Bank
https://ebookbell.com/product/labor-policy-to-promote-good-jobs-in-
tunisia-revisiting-labor-regulation-social-security-and-active-labor-
market-programs-1st-edition-anne-hilger-arvo-kuddo-jan-rutkowski-
world-bank-51741448
The Politics Of Policy Change Welfare Medicare And Social Security
Reform In The United States Daniel Beland And Alex Waddan
https://ebookbell.com/product/the-politics-of-policy-change-welfare-
medicare-and-social-security-reform-in-the-united-states-daniel-
beland-and-alex-waddan-5102374
How Social Security Works An Introduction To Benefits In Britain Paul
Spicker
https://ebookbell.com/product/how-social-security-works-an-
introduction-to-benefits-in-britain-paul-spicker-51810050
What Future For Social Security Debates And Reforms In National And
Crossnational Perspective Jochen Clasen
https://ebookbell.com/product/what-future-for-social-security-debates-
and-reforms-in-national-and-crossnational-perspective-jochen-
clasen-51808666
Social Security Policy In A Changing Environment Jeffrey R Brown Editor Jeffrey B Liebman Editor David A Wise Editor
Social Security Policy In A Changing Environment Jeffrey R Brown Editor Jeffrey B Liebman Editor David A Wise Editor
Social Security Policy in a
Changing Environment
A National Bureau
of Economic Research
Conference Report
National Bureau of Economic Research
Conference on Research in Income and Wealth
Social Security Policy in a
Changing Environment
Edited by Jeffrey R. Brown,
Jeffrey Liebman, and
David A. Wise
The University of Chicago Press
Chicago and London
Jeffrey R. Brown is the William G. Karnes Professor of Finance at
the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, and a research
associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Jeffrey
Liebman is the Malcolm Wiener Professor of Public Policy at the
John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and a
research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
David A. Wise is the John F. Stambaugh Professor of Political
Economy at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard
University, and director of the program on the economics of aging at
the National Bureau of Economic Research.
The University of Chicago Press, Chicago 60637
The University of Chicago Press, Ltd., London
© 2009 by the National Bureau of Economic Research
All rights reserved. Published 2009
Printed in the United States of America
18 17 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 09 1 2 3 4 5
ISBN-13: 978-0-226-07648-5 (cloth)
ISBN-10: 0-226-07648-2 (cloth)
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Social security policy in a changing environment / edited by Jeffrey R.
Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise.
p. cm. — (A National Bureau of Economic Research conference
report)
“This volume consists of papers presented at a conference held in
Woodstock, Vermont in October 2006”—Acknowledgments.
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN-13: 978-0-226-07648-5 (cloth : alk. paper)
ISBN-10: 0-226-07648-2 (cloth : alk. paper) 1. Social security—
Government policy—United States I. Brown, Jeffrey R. II.
Liebman, Jeffrey B. III. Wise, David A.
HD7125.S599286 2008
368.4′300973—dc22
2008031051
o The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements
of the American National Standard for Information Sciences—
Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials, ANSI Z39.48-1992.
National Bureau of Economic Research
Officers
Directors at Large
Directors by University Appointment
Directors by Appointment of Other Organizations
Directors Emeriti
Andrew Brimmer
Carl F. Christ
George Hatsopoulos
Lawrence R. Klein
Franklin A. Lindsay
Paul W. McCracken
Peter G. Peterson
Richard N. Rosett
Eli Shapiro
Arnold Zellner
Jean-Paul Chavas, American Agricultural
Economics Association
Gail D. Fosler, The Conference Board
Martin Gruber, American Finance
Association
Timothy W. Guinnane, Economic History
Association
Arthur B. Kennickell, American Statistical
Association
Thea Lee, American Federation of Labor
and Congress of Industrial Organizations
William W. Lewis, Committee for Economic
Development
Robert Mednick, American Institute of
Certified Public Accountants
Angelo Melino, Canadian Economics
Association
Harvey Rosenblum, National Association
for Business Economics
John J. Siegfried, American Economic
Association
George Akerlof, California, Berkeley
Jagdish Bhagwati, Columbia
Glen G. Cain, Wisconsin
Ray C. Fair, Yale
Franklin Fisher, Massachusetts Institute
of Technology
Mark Grinblatt, California, Los Angeles
Saul H. Hymans, Michigan
Marjorie B. McElroy, Duke
Joel Mokyr, Northwestern
Andrew Postlewaite, Pennsylvania
Uwe E. Reinhardt, Princeton
Nathan Rosenberg, Stanford
Craig Swan, Minnesota
David B. Yoffie, Harvard
Arnold Zellner (Director Emeritus),
Chicago
Peter C. Aldrich
Elizabeth E. Bailey
Richard B. Berner
John H. Biggs
John S. Clarkeson
Don R. Conlan
Kathleen B. Cooper
Charles H. Dallara
George C. Eads
Jessica P. Einhorn
Mohamed El-Erian
Jacob A. Frenkel
Judith M. Gueron
Robert S. Hamada
Karen N. Horn
John Lipsky
Laurence H. Meyer
Michael H. Moskow
Alicia H. Munnell
Rudolph A. Oswald
Robert T. Parry
James M. Poterba
John S. Reed
Marina v. N. Whitman
Martin B. Zimmerman
John S. Clarkeson, chairman
Kathleen B. Cooper, vice-chairman
James M. Poterba, president and chief
executive officer
Robert Mednick, treasurer
Kelly Horak, controller and assistant
corporate secretary
Alterra Milone, corporate secretary
Gerardine Johnson, assistant corporate
secretary
Relation of the Directors to the
Work and Publications of the
National Bureau of Economic Research
1. The object of the NBER is to ascertain and present to the economics profession, and to
the public more generally, important economic facts and their interpretation in a scientific
manner without policy recommendations. The Board of Directors is charged with the respon-
sibility of ensuring that the work of the NBER is carried on in strict conformity with this ob-
ject.
2. The President shall establish an internal review process to ensure that book manuscripts
proposed for publication DO NOT contain policy recommendations. This shall apply both to
the proceedings of conferences and to manuscripts by a single author or by one or more co-
authors but shall not apply to authors of comments at NBER conferences who are not NBER
affiliates.
3. No book manuscript reporting research shall be published by the NBER until the Presi-
dent has sent to each member of the Board a notice that a manuscript is recommended for pub-
lication and that in the President’s opinion it is suitable for publication in accordance with the
above principles of the NBER. Such notification will include a table of contents and an ab-
stract or summary of the manuscript’s content, a list of contributors if applicable, and a re-
sponse form for use by Directors who desire a copy of the manuscript for review. Each manu-
script shall contain a summary drawing attention to the nature and treatment of the problem
studied and the main conclusions reached.
4. No volume shall be published until forty-five days have elapsed from the above notifica-
tion of intention to publish it. During this period a copy shall be sent to any Director request-
ing it, and if any Director objects to publication on the grounds that the manuscript contains
policy recommendations, the objection will be presented to the author(s) or editor(s). In case
of dispute, all members of the Board shall be notified, and the President shall appoint an ad
hoc committee of the Board to decide the matter; thirty days additional shall be granted for
this purpose.
5. The President shall present annually to the Board a report describing the internal manu-
script review process, any objections made by Directors before publication or by anyone after
publication, any disputes about such matters, and how they were handled.
6. Publications of the NBER issued for informational purposes concerning the work of the
Bureau, or issued to inform the public of the activities at the Bureau, including but not limited
to the NBER Digest and Reporter, shall be consistent with the object stated in paragraph 1.
They shall contain a specific disclaimer noting that they have not passed through the review
procedures required in this resolution. The Executive Committee of the Board is charged with
the review of all such publications from time to time.
7. NBER working papers and manuscripts distributed on the Bureau’s web site are not
deemed to be publications for the purpose of this resolution, but they shall be consistent with
the object stated in paragraph 1. Working papers shall contain a specific disclaimer noting that
they have not passed through the review procedures required in this resolution. The NBER’s
web site shall contain a similar disclaimer. The President shall establish an internal review pro-
cess to ensure that the working papers and the web site do not contain policy recommenda-
tions, and shall report annually to the Board on this process and any concerns raised in con-
nection with it.
8. Unless otherwise determined by the Board or exempted by the terms of paragraphs 6 and
7, a copy of this resolution shall be printed in each NBER publication as described in para-
graph 2 above.
Contents
vii
Acknowledgments xi
Introduction 1
Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and
David A. Wise
I. Innovative Approaches to Social Security Reform
1. Removing the Disincentives in Social Security
for Long Careers 21
Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and
Sita Nataraj Slavov
Comment: Erzo F. P. Luttmer
2. Notional Defined Contribution Pension Systems
in a Stochastic Context: Design and Stability 43
Alan J. Auerbach and Ronald Lee
Comment: Jeffrey Liebman
3. Reforming Social Security with Progressive
Personal Accounts 73
John Geanakoplos and Stephen P. Zeldes
Comment: Jason Furman
II. Retirement Plan Choice
4. Who Chooses Defined Contribution Plans? 131
Jeffrey R. Brown and Scott J. Weisbenner
Comment: Brigitte C. Madrian
5. The Importance of Default Options for
Retirement Saving Outcomes: Evidence from
the United States 167
John Beshears, James J. Choi,
David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian
Comment: Jeffrey R. Brown
III. Reducing Financial Market Risk in Personal
Retirement Accounts
6. Reducing the Risk of Investment-Based
Social Security Reform 201
Martin Feldstein
Comment: David W. Wilcox
7. Pricing Personal Account Benefit Guarantees:
A Simplified Approach 229
Andrew Biggs, Clark Burdick, and
Kent Smetters
Comment: George G. Pennacchi
8. Reducing Social Security PRA Risk at the
Individual Level: Life-Cycle Funds and
No-Loss Strategies 255
James M. Poterba, Joshua Rauh,
Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise
Comment: Douglas W. Elmendorf
9. Changing Progressivity as a Means of
Risk Protection in Investment-Based
Social Security 299
Andrew A. Samwick
Comment: Michael Hurd
IV. Demographics, Asset Flows, and Macroeconomic Markets
10. The Decline of Defined Benefit Retirement
Plans and Asset Flows 333
James M. Poterba, Steven F. Venti, and
David A. Wise
Comment: Jonathan Skinner
viii Contents
11. Demographic Change, Relative Factor Prices,
International Capital Flows, and Their
Differential Effects on the Welfare
of Generations 385
Alexander Ludwig, Dirk Krüger, and
Axel Börsch-Supan
Comment: James M. Poterba
V. Mortality Projections
12. Is the U.S. Population Behaving Healthier? 423
David M. Cutler, Edward L. Glaeser, and
Allison B. Rosen
Comment: James P. Smith
Contributors 447
Author Index 451
Subject Index 455
Contents ix
Social Security Policy In A Changing Environment Jeffrey R Brown Editor Jeffrey B Liebman Editor David A Wise Editor
Acknowledgments
xi
This volume consists of papers presented at a conference held in Wood-
stock, VT in October 2006. Most of the research was conducted as part of
the NBER Retirement Research Center with financial support from the
U.S. Social Security Administration (SSA) through grant #10-P-98363-1 to
the National Bureau of Economic Research as part of the SSA Retirement
Research Consortium. Additional funding sources are noted in individual
papers.
The findings and conclusions expressed in this volume are those of the re-
spective authors and do not represent the views of SSA, any agency of the
federal government, or the National Bureau of Economic Research.
Social Security Policy In A Changing Environment Jeffrey R Brown Editor Jeffrey B Liebman Editor David A Wise Editor
Introduction
Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
1
This volume compiles selected studies conducted through the National Bu-
reau of Economic Research (NBER) Center for Retirement Research. The
center was created in 2003 with funding from the U.S. Social Security Ad-
ministration and is structured to provide analysis that can inform Social
Security policy. In setting our research agenda, we have been guided by
three principles. First, reform must recognize the changing and uncertain
environment in which the Social Security system will operate. Second, sev-
eral alternative routes to sustainable solvency should be explored. Third,
the potential routes to solvency should be evaluated for “resiliency” to fu-
ture uncertain demographic, economic, and social trends.
While some of the center’s research focuses directly on Social Security
reform, other research aims to inform Social Security policy by analyzing
the changing economic environment in which future Social Security ben-
eficiaries will live. For example, several of our center’s projects have stud-
ied trends in private-sector retirement saving—particularly the shift from
defined benefit (DB) to defined contribution (DC) pension plans—be-
cause the “optimal” Social Security replacement rate may evolve as the
structure of private retirement savings changes over time. We have also
studied trends in health care costs because decisions about Social Secu-
rity benefits, and indeed how much of society’s resources to devote to So-
Jeffrey R. Brown is the William G. Karnes Professor of Finance at the University of Illinois
at Urbana-Champaign, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Re-
search. Jeffrey Liebman is the Malcolm Wiener Professor of Public Policy at the John F.
Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and a research associate of the Na-
tional Bureau of Economic Research. David A. Wise is the John F. Stambaugh Professor of
Political Economy at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and
director of the program on the economics of aging at the National Bureau of Economic Re-
search.
cial Security, may depend in part on health care costs. And we have stud-
ied the uncertain nature of future demographic, economic, and social
trends—such as the age structure of the population, marriage and divorce
rates, women’s labor force participation, productivity, market rates of re-
turn, and the like.
The volume is organized into five parts. Part I introduces several inno-
vative approaches to Social Security reform. Part II examines individual
behavior in making retirement saving decisions, such as how much to save
or how to allocate savings among alternative investment options. Part III
analyzes different approaches to reducing the financial market risk faced
by individuals who invest in personal retirement accounts. Part IV looks
at aggregate trends in retirement asset flows and their effect on macro-
economic markets. Part V considers health trends and their projected
effects on future mortality. This introduction summarizes each of the chap-
ters, drawing heavily on the authors’ own summaries.
Innovative Approaches to Social Security Reform
In recent years, the debate about Social Security reform in the United
States has focused on a limited range of proposals, a fact which may have
contributed to the partisan nature of reform discussions. An important
aim of our center is to expand the range of approaches considered and to
assess the resiliency of alternative proposals to uncertain future demo-
graphic, financial, and other trends. The first three chapters in this volume
analyze new ideas for Social Security reform. The first considers reforms
that would remove the disincentive in Social Security for long careers. The
second analyzes notional defined contribution social security systems and
evaluates their ability to self-adjust to uncertain future circumstances, and
thus to retain their financial stability over the long term. The third devel-
ops a reform proposal based on progressive personal accounts, which
blend characteristics of funded personal accounts with some of the core
objectives of traditional social security policy.
In chapter 1, “Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long
Careers,” Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov ex-
plore the relationship between Social Security policy and labor market be-
havior at older ages. Since Social Security was instituted in 1935, life ex-
pectancy at age twenty has increased from sixty-six to seventy-six for men
and from sixty-nine to eighty for women. Health at older ages has also im-
proved. Such dramatic advances in health and longevity mean that people
have the physical and mental capability to work until older ages. Yet people
are retiring younger, even as they live longer and healthier lives. Indeed, the
duration of retirement has grown by even more than the increase in life ex-
pectancy at retirement.
Godi, Shoven, and Slavov consider the role of Social Security policy in
2 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
influencing—or, more precisely, distorting—the work and retirement de-
cisions of older workers. They highlight the features of Social Security that
discourage long careers, discourage work at older ages, and increase the
number of years in retirement. The main finding of the chapter is that So-
cial Security imposes high implicit tax rates on workers late in their careers.
As a result of this distortion, the duration of retirement is suboptimally
long, compounding the financial stress on public and private retirement
support systems.
One example of the distortion in Social Security is how benefits are cal-
culated based on the highest thirty-five years of earnings. This means that
the thirty-third, thirty-fourth, and thirty-fifth years of work noticeably im-
prove retirement benefits by replacing a “zero” in the benefit calculation
formula. The thirty-sixth year of work, on the other hand, may or may not
count, and if it does, it will replace a lower year of earnings and not a zero
in the calculation. Thus, the benefit formula discourages careers of more
than thirty-five years. Another aspect of the benefit formula offers dispro-
portionately higher benefits to workers with short careers, treating them
with the same redistributive advantages as if they were lower earners. Both
characteristics of the benefit formula lead to high implicit tax rates at older
ages and for longer careers.
The authors suggest three reforms that would reduce the distortionary
impact of Social Security at older ages. First, they propose using forty
years, rather than thirty-five, in benefit computation. Second, they propose
disentangling career length and progressivity in the benefit formula. And
third, they propose to establish a “paid-up” category of workers who have
more than forty years of contributions, who would no longer be subject to
the payroll tax. The study finds that these proposed changes would elimi-
nate most of the large positive tax rates for older workers. They would also
reduce the association between age and tax rate and move tax rates closer
to zero for most workers in most years of their lives. With these changes,
the implicit tax rates associated with Social Security remain roughly con-
stant over a worker’s life, resulting in less distortion of career length
choices. The authors find, in addition, that the proposed reforms need not
affect the overall progressivity of the Social Security system. However, by
reallocating benefits from those with shorter careers to those with longer
careers, the reforms would result in less insurance against adverse shocks
that cause people to work for fewer years.
The study concludes that by eliminating the disincentives against work-
ing longer careers, we can capitalize on the good fortunes of increasing life
expectancy and favorable health status by paving the way for those in good
health to stay in the labor force longer.
In chapter 2, “Notional Defined Contribution Pension Systems in a Sto-
chastic Context: Design and Stability,” Alan J. Auerbach and Ronald Lee
explore a new approach to Social Security reform that is known as “No-
Introduction 3
tional Defined Contribution” or “Nonfinancial Defined Contribution”
(NDC). Sweden was the first country to introduce an NDC system. A num-
ber of other countries have introduced NDC plans, including Italy, Poland,
Latvia, Mongolia, and the Kyrgyz Republic, and proposed plans for
France and Germany have NDC aspects.
The NDC programs differ in detail, but the basic principle is that they
mimic defined contribution plans without actually setting aside financial
assets. Thus, some of the benefits of fully funded defined contribution
plans can be achieved—particularly the improved labor supply incentives
from a more transparent link between current taxes and future retirement
benefits—while avoiding the transitional difficulties of converting from
an unfunded pay-as-you-go (PAYGO) system. Under an NDC program, a
“notional” capital account is maintained for each participant. Balances in
this account earn a rate of return that is declared by the pension plan each
year, and notional payments into this account are made over the entire life
history to mirror actual taxes or contributions by plan participants. After
a designated age such as sixty-two, a participant can begin to draw bene-
fits, which is done by using the account to purchase an annuity from the
pension plan. The terms of the annuity will depend on mortality risk at that
time and on a rate of return stipulated by the pension plan.
While NDC plans are seen as having various potential advantages over
traditional PAYGO systems, the focus of this chapter is on their financial
stability over the long term. The stability results from three factors. First,
the rate of return in the notional accounts reflects the underlying PAYGO
nature of the program and is based on what is expected to be affordable
over time. Second, the annuity structure should buffer the system from the
uncertain costs of rising longevity. And third, in the event that the pro-
gram’s finances move toward imbalance, a braking mechanism can be in-
corporated that automatically modifies the rate of return to help restore
the plan to financial health. Given the political difficulties of making fre-
quent changes in PAYGO pension programs, the attractiveness of an in-
herently stable and self-adjusting system is clear.
In this chapter, Auerbach and Lee use a stochastic macroeconomic
model for forecasting and simulating the long-term finances of NDC-type
public pension programs in the context of demographic and economic
trends in the United States. Because future patterns of demographic and
economic change are uncertain, the model generates a probability distri-
bution of outcomes (benefit flows and rates of return) for generations of
plan participants for the NDC program, as well as for the overall financial
stability of the NDC system.
The study finds that an NDC system similar to that currently in use in
Sweden, which bases rates of return on the growth rate of average wages
and utilizes a brake to adjust the rate of return during periods of financial
stress, effectively eliminates the accumulation of debt in the Social Security
4 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
system, even under the most adverse demographic and economic circum-
stances. Thus, the system is effective in preventing inadequate funding of
Social Security obligations over the long term.
What this version of an NDC system does not do is adjust automatically
to situations when there is excess money accumulating in the system. Put
differently, the braking mechanism is asymmetric, automatically making
corrections when the financial balances of the system move toward in-
creased debt, but without correction when the financial balances move to-
ward asset accumulation. Only a symmetric brake, which raises rates of re-
turn during periods of financial strength, avoids large accumulations of
financial assets.
Other findings from the simulations are first, that the brake can be more
gradual than under the Swedish system and still provide a stable distribu-
tion of outcomes; second, that an NDC system in which rates of return are
based on total rather than per capita economic growth is inherently more
stable; and third, that a considerable share of the volatility in the financial
performance of NDC systems is attributable to economic uncertainty,
rather than demographic uncertainty.
In chapter 3, “Reforming Social Security with Progressive Personal Ac-
counts,” John Geanakoplos and Stephen P. Zeldes develop yet another ap-
proach to Social Security reform. Their reform plan is designed to preserve
the core objectives of the current Social Security system and, at the same
time, gain the benefits of personal accounts.
Advocates for retaining the current system argue that Social Security
should redistribute wealth from those who have earned more over their
whole working lives to those who have earned less. They also suggest that
different generations should share in the risks and benefits of macroeco-
nomic growth. So if real wages go up over time, retirees should get some
benefit from those macroeconomic gains, even though they are no longer
working. Advocates for personal accounts, on the other hand, support
ownership by individuals of tangible assets that cannot be revoked by a fu-
ture government. They also like the idea that people know the current mar-
ket valuation of their retirement resources, as they are accrued over time,
so that rational planning for retirement can take place outside of Social Se-
curity.
Geanakoplos and Zeldes seek to find a common ground between these
two approaches and to develop a plan that preserves the core goals of each
one. They demonstrate that it is possible to convert Social Security into a
system of personal accounts with irrevocable ownership of market priced
assets, while at the same time redistributing benefits based on lifetime in-
come and sharing macroeconomic gains across generations. They refer to
the plan as progressive personal accounts.
The proposed system uses the payroll tax to buy assets in a personal re-
tirement account for each Social Security recipient. Income-based redis-
Introduction 5
tribution is accomplished through a variable government match (or tax) on
these Social Security contributions. High lifetime earners receive lower
matches (or a tax) on contributions to their personal account, while low
lifetime earners receive a higher government match. Risk sharing across
generations is accomplished through the creation of a new kind of deriva-
tive security whose payoffs depend on the average earnings of those work-
ing at a specific point in time. So if younger workers are doing well and re-
ceiving high wages, the old will get higher payoffs from their investment
in the derivative security. Every year a worker would pay the Old-Age and
Survivors Insurance (OASI) payroll tax and receive a certain number of
these securities in the worker’s account.
According to the authors, it is possible to create a system of progressive
personal accounts that exactly mimics the promised taxes and payouts of
the current Social Security system. The resulting system would preserve
some of the core goals of Social Security, as it is structured today, but
would also improve upon it due to the increased transparency, enhanced
property rights, and lower political risk (of legislation removing benefits)
that naturally come with individual accounts. Chapter 3 lays out the me-
chanics of such a system in detail.
Retirement Plan Choice
With the growth of 401(k)-type plans, retirement saving is becoming an
increasingly important complement to Social Security as a component of
financial support in retirement. In addition, some Social Security reform
proposals would supplement the defined benefits provided by the current
U.S. Social Security system with either voluntary or mandatory personal
retirement accounts (PRAs). The increasing importance of individually-
owned retirement savings accounts, whether integrated within the Social
Security system or outside the system, will make decision making by indi-
viduals a more important aspect of retirement planning in the future. The
next two chapters in the volume look at how people make decisions about
retirement plans when individual decisions need to be made.
In chapter 4, “Who Chooses Defined Contribution Plans?,” Jeffrey R.
Brown and Scott J. Weisbenner analyze the decisions made by a group of
50,000 workers who currently have a choice between a defined benefit (DB)
and a defined contribution (DC) pension system. Their study is based on
the experience of employees in the State Universities Retirement System
(SURS) of Illinois, where workers make a one-time, lifetime, irrevocable
choice among three retirement plans: (1) a traditional formula-based DB
plan; (2) a “portable DB plan,” which is slightly less generous than the tra-
ditional DB program if one retires from the system, but more generous if
the worker takes an early lump-sum distribution; and (3) a completely self-
managed DC plan. Individuals who fail to make an active choice within the
6 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
first six months of employment are automatically defaulted into the tradi-
tional DB plan.
Other aspects of the SURS experience are also relevant to the study.
First, the wages of individuals earned from SURS-covered employment
are not also covered by Social Security. So for most, the decision made is a
decision about people’s primary source of income in retirement. Second,
the combined employer/employee retirement contributions to the SURS
system are at least 14.6 percent of annual salary, which is larger than the
payroll tax paid by those in the Social Security system. Therefore, the
SURS system looms large as part of a participant’s lifetime financial plan.
And third, the choice of retirement programs is available to employees with
diverse job characteristics and earnings, including campus administrators,
faculty members, clerical staff, university police and fire protection work-
ers, and others.
There are two major findings from the study. First, despite initial pro-
jections that a majority of new employees would actively select the self-
managed DC plan or portable DB plan, the evidence is that a majority of
new employees never makes an active pension choice and, thus, are de-
faulted into the traditional DB plan. The proportion of new employees not
making a choice among plans, and hence defaulting into the traditional
DB plan, has been roughly three-fifths over the period 2001 to 2004.
Second, approximately 15 percent of new employees choose the self-
managed DC plan, despite the fact that the DC plan is likely inferior to the
portable DB plan, given the financial features of the various plans and rea-
sonable assumptions about future financial market returns. Interestingly,
individuals are more likely than average to choose the self-managed DC
plan if they are more highly educated, have higher earnings, are married,
and work in a location where a higher fraction of other employees also
chose the self-managed plan. The findings suggest that these “educated,
high earning, young professionals” have a strong preference for DC plans,
even when the financial terms are unfavorable. For example, among the 650
individuals in the sample who are full-time, aged thirty to thirty-nine, aca-
demics at a university, married, have earnings in excess of $50,000, and are
still active employees as of spring 2006, 52 percent of them chose the self-
managed DC plan, compared with 15 percent in the sample as a whole.
The analysis raises the question of why some individuals appear to make
suboptimal choices. The authors speculate that there are at least five rea-
sons why they may do so. First, participants may simply have difficulty pro-
cessing the complex information that they are provided when making this
choice, due either to time constraints or some form of bounded rationality.
Second, the information provided by SURS may not be optimally designed
to facilitate meaningful comparisons between the self-managed DC plan
and the portable benefits package. Third, individuals may understand the
rules, but may overestimate their investment abilities, or the expected mar-
Introduction 7
ket return of the DC plan. Fourth, individuals may believe there is politi-
cal risk in the traditional or portable benefit plans, arising from the chronic
underfunding of the SURS system. Fifth, individuals may place a high
value on choice for its own sake. In continuing research, the authors are ex-
ploring these alternative hypotheses using a survey of current SURS par-
ticipants.
In chapter 5, “The Importance of Default Options for Retirement Sav-
ing Outcomes: Evidence from the United States,” John Beshears, James J.
Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian look at a very similar issue
in the context of 401(k) plans. In this case, the worker’s decision is about
whether to enroll in the 401(k) plan, what portion of their income to allo-
cate to the plan, and how to invest it among the various investment options
offered in the plan. Much like the previous chapter, a core finding is that de-
faults matter a lot. Many people avoid making an active decision about
their retirement saving, and so the default provisions of their 401(k) plan
are what people end up doing “by default.”
The chapter summarizes a breadth of empirical evidence on how the de-
fault provisions of retirement saving plans impact savings behavior along
multiple dimensions, such as savings plan participation, savings rates, as-
set allocation, and postretirement savings distributions. The findings are
that defaults impact savings outcomes at every step along the way. For ex-
ample, some 401(k) plans have automatic enrollment, requiring employees
to explicitly “opt-out” of the plan. Others require eligible employees to ac-
tively enroll in the plan, or “opt-in.” Automatic enrollment is found to dra-
matically raise participation rates.
When the 401(k) plan has a default savings rate and a default investment
allocation, employees are much more likely to choose those defaults, rather
than to specify an alternative. As a result, the higher the default contribu-
tion rate, the higher the savings rate among those participating. Defaults
even matter when employees leave their jobs, and their 401(k) balances
may be left in the account, or they may be distributed to employees with the
option to roll over the funds to another retirement plan. When the funds
are distributed (which happens automatically in most smaller accounts),
they are much more likely to be removed permanently from retirement sav-
ing, while undistributed funds tend to be left in the plans.
The findings of this study are relevant not only to the design of a com-
pany’s 401(k) plan, but also to how one would structure a personal account
system within Social Security. For example, a voluntary PRA system
within Social Security would lead to higher participation and higher sav-
ing if it has automatic enrollment (rather than requiring active enrollment)
and if the default savings rate is higher. The findings on asset allocation are
also relevant and suggest careful attention to the investment options made
available to participants as well as to the default allocations among them.
A clear conclusion of this research is that defaults are not neutral—they
8 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
can either facilitate or hinder better savings outcomes. The authors em-
phasize that current public policies toward saving include examples of
both.
Reducing Financial Market Risk in Personal Retirement Accounts
The next section of the volume also relates to the increasing importance
of individual retirement saving and, particularly, to the potential implica-
tions of a PRA component in Social Security. A significant concern, par-
ticularly if PRAs were to become part of Social Security, is with the impo-
sition of investment risk on plan participants. The concern is that the
economic well-being of some retirees could be undermined by poor invest-
ment returns. There is, therefore, great interest in strategies that could re-
duce the riskiness of PRAs while preserving the other features of PRAs.
While the chapters in this section are focused on reducing the risk of PRAs,
the results are also relevant to retirement saving taking place in 401(k)
plans and other financial accounts that are separate from Social Security.
The first chapter in this section considers financial market products that
cap downside market risk. The second analyzes an approach in which the
government would guarantee a minimum investment return. The third
studies the extent to which life-cycle investment strategies could reduce the
variance in retirement income levels. The fourth investigates the extent to
which increased progressivity in the traditional Social Security system
could be used to buffer lower-income retirees against PRA market risk.
In chapter 6, “Reducing the Risk of Investment-Based Social Security
Reform,” Martin Feldstein presents a market-based approach to reducing
the risk of investment-based Social Security that could be tailored to indi-
vidual risk preferences. With this new form of risk reduction, substituting
an investment-based PRA for the traditional pure PAYGO plan could
achieve both a significantly higher expected retirement income and a very
high probability that the investment-based annuity would be at least as
large as the PAYGO benefit. A key feature of the approach developed in the
chapter is a guarantee that the individual would not lose any of the real
value of each year’s PRA savings and might be guaranteed to earn at least
some minimum real rate of return.
In one example of such a plan, the current 12.4 percent PAYGO tax is
compared with a mixed plan that has a 6.2 percent PAYGO tax and 6.2 per-
cent annual PRA savings. This new mixed plan, when fully phased in,
would have the following desirable characteristics: (1) The median value of
the combined retirement income (i.e., the sum of the PAYGO benefit and
the PRA annuity) would be 147 percent of the traditional PAYGO benefit.
(2) There would be a 95 percent probability that the combined retirement
income (the PAYGO benefit and the PRA annuity) exceeds the traditional
PAYGO benefit. (3) There would be less than one chance in 100 that the
Introduction 9
combined retirement income would be less than 96 percent of the tradi-
tional PAYGO benefit. (4) Each year’s PRA saving would be guaranteed to
earn at least a 1 percent real rate of return between the time that it is saved
and its value at age sixty-six. It is, therefore, referred to in the chapter as a
“No Lose” plan. (5) The variable annuity purchased at age sixty-six would
have a similar “No Lose” feature, that is, a guaranteed real rate of return
of at least 1 percent.
The “No Lose” concepts developed in the chapter rely on financial in-
struments already available in the marketplace. The idea is that the amount
saved in a PRA each year would be guaranteed to retain at least its real
value by age sixty-six. The simplest way to achieve such a No Lose PRA ac-
count would be to combine Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities (TIPS,
which have a guaranteed real return) with equities. The fraction of the an-
nual PRA saving that would have to be invested in TIPS to guarantee that
the annual PRA saving would retain its real value by age sixty-six depends
on the age of the saver and the rate of return on the TIPS of the relevant
maturity. For example, if the saver is twenty-one years old and the real re-
turn on TIPS is 2 percent, a $1,000 PRA saving would be divided between
$410 in TIPS and the remaining $590 in equities. The 2 percent real return
and the forty-five-year investment period imply that the $410 would accu-
mulate to $1,000 at the initial price level by age sixty-six. Even if the equity
portion became completely worthless, the PRA account would be worth
the initial $1,000 real dollars.
At older working ages, there are fewer years for the TIPS to accumulate
and, therefore, a larger fraction of the initial saving must be invested in
TIPS. For example, a forty-year-old would have to invest $598 out of each
$1,000 of new saving in TIPS to guarantee the $1,000 value of the account
at age sixty-six with the remaining $402 invested in equities. In practice, of
course, the value at age sixty-six of the annual PRA saving would be worth
substantially more than the guaranteed amount because the equity portion
of the account would add additional value. Indeed, the likelihood (based
on past market returns) is that the equity portion would add very substan-
tial additional value.
The chapter considers a range of “No Lose” options with varying trade-
offs between the guaranteed minimum return and the distribution of pos-
sible higher returns. For example, the approach can be easily modified to
increase the guarantee from a zero real return (No Lose) to a 1 percent real
rate of return. Indeed, different trade-offs might be more or less desirable
to different individuals, based on their particular risk preferences. These
options are then evaluated relative to the baseline values that would be pro-
vided through a traditional PAYGO Social Security system. Simulations
are used to derive the probability distributions of retirement incomes rela-
tive to the “benchmark” benefits specified in current law. Calculations of
expected utility show that the risk reduction techniques developed in the
10 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
chapter can raise expected utility relative to investment-based plans with
no guarantees. Finally, the chapter shows how these approaches might be
applied to deal with the aging of the population without the large rise in the
payroll tax that would otherwise be required.
In closely related work reported in chapter 7, “Pricing Personal Account
Benefit Guarantees: A Simplified Approach,” Andrew Biggs, Clark Bur-
dick, and Kent Smetters develop a methodology for estimating the market
cost of return guarantees. Given the size of Social Security benefit en-
titlements and the market risks inherent in personal account investing,
guarantees constitute a significant contingent liability to the guarantee
provider.
Most of the existing research on guarantees has estimated their cost,
based on a probability distribution of possible investment outcomes, and
then used the distribution to calculate an “expected” cost of the minimum
guarantee. According to the authors, however, this approach does not re-
flect fully how guarantees would be priced in the financial marketplace. In
particular, it ignores the greater valuation placed by the market on losses
relative to the expected value of the losses. Indeed, the total “market cost”
of a benefit guarantee, including the associated cost of market risk, could
be several times larger than its “expected cost.” This chapter demonstrates
how a model for calculating the expected cost of a benefit guarantee can be
modified to present the market price of personal account guarantees as a
supplement to expected cost valuations. The simplified method for esti-
mating the market price of a guarantee is shown to produce results equiv-
alent to the Black-Scholes model.
The approach is illustrated using a Social Security reform proposal from
Senator John Sununu (R-NH) and Representative Paul Ryan (R-WI). This
proposal would introduce personal accounts investing from 5 to 10 percent
of wages, depending upon the worker’s earnings level. At retirement, indi-
viduals would receive either the proceeds of their personal account or their
currently scheduled benefit, whichever is greater. Thus, this plan effectively
guarantees that accounts would produce benefits no lower than those
scheduled for the current program. In the illustrative policy, the “expected
cost” valuation of the proposed guarantee is calculated to be 11.3 percent
of total benefits to new retirees in 2050, while the “market value” cost is
calculated to be 28.2 percent of benefits.
In chapter 8, “Reducing Social Security PRA Risk at the Individual
Level: Life-Cycle Funds and No-Loss Strategies,” James M. Poterba,
Joshua Rauh, Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise explore the implications
for asset accumulation of different investment strategies. In a Social Secu-
rity system with a personal retirement account (PRA) component, retire-
ment savers would have to decide how to allocate their PRA portfolios
across a broad range of asset classes and financial products. Asset alloca-
tion decisions have important consequences for retirement wealth accu-
Introduction 11
mulation because they affect the expenses of investing as well as the risk of
low returns. The goal of this study is to assess the relative risk associated
with alternative asset allocation strategies in PRAs, though it also offers in-
sight on the consequences of different asset allocation rules in 401(k)-type
plans.
The approach used in the study is to simulate the distribution of balances
in PRA retirement saving accounts under various assumptions about the
asset allocation strategies that investors may choose. In addition to a range
of age-invariant strategies, such as an all-bond and an all-stock strategy,
the chapter considers several different “life-cycle funds” that automatically
alter the investor’s mix of assets as he or she ages. These funds allocate a
higher fraction of an investor’s portfolio to stocks at the beginning of a
working career and then gradually decrease the equity fraction as the
worker approaches retirement. The authors also consider a “no lose” allo-
cation strategy for retirement saving, in which households purchase
enough riskless bonds at each age to ensure that they will have no less than
their nominal contribution when they reach retirement age and then invest
the balance in corporate stock. This strategy combines a riskless floor for
retirement income with some upside investment potential, along the lines
of what is described in chapter 6.
The best asset allocation strategy—the one with the highest expected
utility to the investor—is found to depend on the relative importance of
four issues: the expected return on stocks, the risk aversion of the investing
household, the amount of financial wealth held outside the PRA, and the
expenses associated with different investment options. At modest levels of
risk aversion, or when the household has access to substantial non-PRA
wealth at retirement, the historical pattern of stock and bond returns im-
plies that an all-stock investment strategy brings higher expected utility
than any of the more conservative strategies. When the expected return on
stocks is reduced, however, other strategies may dominate the all-equity
allocation for investors with high levels of relative risk aversion. In these
circumstances, the value of a mix of stocks and inflation-indexed bonds
(TIPS) or an inexpensive life-cycle product may be higher than an all-stocks
strategy.
The findings also underscore the importance of avoiding high expense
ratios. Many of the available life-cycle products have higher expense ratios
than could be achieved by the household simply holding a stock index fund
and some TIPS (or bonds) and either holding them in fixed proportions
throughout their lifetime or rebalancing toward TIPS (or bonds) as they
get older. Households who are unable to do this on their own will not do
terribly in life-cycle funds, but they will lose money relative to what they
could get if they executed very simple investing strategies on their own.
A very different approach to reducing PRA risk is explored in chapter 9,
“Changing Progressivity as a Means of Risk Protection in Investment-
12 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
Based Social Security,” by Andrew A. Samwick. This chapter analyzes
changes in the progressivity of the Social Security benefit formula as an al-
ternative means of lessening the overall risk for lower-income Social Secu-
rity beneficiaries. Because Social Security benefits provide a larger share of
retirement income for lower-income households, Samwick argues, the
most direct way to make sure that they do not fall into poverty in old age is
to increase the progressivity of the benefit formula. Doing so would lessen
the need to provide insurance against the possibility of low returns in the
PRAs because low-income retirees would depend less on their PRAs to
stay out of poverty.
In the illustrative reform plans studied by Samwick, individual PRA ac-
counts are created with contributions of 2 percent of covered earnings per
year. At the same time, traditional Social Security benefits are reduced by
40 percent. Samwick evalues four different approaches to the 40 percent
aggregate benefit cut, each with a different degree of progressivity in the
benefit formula. The least progressive version would maintain the progres-
sivity of Social Security benefits at its current level, but reduced all benefits
by 40 percent. The most progressive version would provide an equal re-
tirement benefit to everyone, regardless of past earnings. The other two
scenarios are in between, offering moderate increases in benefit progres-
sivity.
A series of simulations are conducted to analyze the implications of these
policy alternatives on the economic well-being of lower income households,
as well as to evaluate the optimal allocation of PRA assets among different
asset classes. The key finding is that under baseline parameters, a flat Social
Security benefit independent of earnings (the most progressive option) al-
lows the bottom 30 percent of the earnings distribution to achieve a higher
expected utility than under the proportional reductions to the current ben-
efit formula even with no investments in equity. An additional 30 percent of
earners can lessen their equity investments without loss of welfare relative
to those available under the scaled-back current formula. Under more real-
istic and less extreme changes to the traditional benefit, about half of the eq-
uity risk can be eliminated for the lowest earnings decile, and some equity
risk can be eliminated for the bottom six deciles.
The optimal allocation to equities in the PRA is not particularly sensi-
tive to the progressivity of the reductions in the traditional benefits—in
most simulations, the optimal share in equities increases slightly for low
earners and decreases slightly for higher earners with more progressive re-
ductions in the traditional benefits.
Demographics, Asset Flows, and Macroeconomic Markets
Many analysts have suggested that population aging will adversely affect
the assets of baby boomers when they retire. These analysts argue that
Introduction 13
when a large population cohort is working and accumulating resources for
retirement, their demand for investments is high, thereby increasing asset
prices. Conversely, when a large cohort retires, they are more likely to sell
their assets to finance consumption and thereby drive down asset prices.
This argument suggests that the rapidly increasing population of older
people in the United States and around the world might lead to lower re-
turns in financial markets in the decades ahead.
The extent to which these predictions will be realized is difficult to pre-
dict. It is particularly difficult in an international context, where macro-
economic markets are interrelated, and where financial capital flows freely
across countries. The next two chapters in the volume consider the effects
of population aging on asset markets, one focused on retirement saving in
the United States and one on global financial markets.
Chapter 10 is part of a series of investigations by James M. Poterba,
Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise aimed at forecasting the flow of funds
into and out of retirement-related asset holdings in the United States. In
“The Decline of Defined Benefit Retirement Plans and Asset Flows,” these
investigators focus on the flow of funds into and out of “traditional” de-
fined benefit (DB) pension plans. A companion study, also referenced in
the chapter, focuses on the flow of funds into and out of 401(k)-type sav-
ings plans. Together, these studies project the direction and magnitude of
asset flows for a very significant portion of retirement-related investments.
These analyses provide quantitative documentation, as well as future
forecasting, of a fundamental transition in saving for retirement in the
United States. What we have experienced over the last twenty-five years is
a massive shift from saving through employer-managed defined benefit
(DB) pensions to saving in individually managed defined contribution
(DC) retirement plans, particularly 401(k) plans. Thus, to understand the
effect of demographic trends on the demand for retirement assets in the
coming decades, it is important to evaluate the likely flows into and out of
both 401(k)-type plans and DB plans.
The projections in the chapter suggest that the average (over all people)
of the present value of real DB benefits at age sixty-five attained an histor-
ical maximum in 2003, when the value was about $73,000. The present
value declines after 2003, as the proportion of new retirees covered by DB
plans declines. The projections also suggest that the average value of 401(k)
assets at age sixty-five surpasses the average present value of DB benefits at
age sixty-five in about 2010. Thereafter, the value of 401(k) assets grows
rapidly, attaining levels much greater than the maximum present value of
DB benefits. If equity returns between 2006 and 2040 are comparable to
those observed historically, by 2040 average projected 401(k) assets will be
over six times larger than the historical maximum level of DB benefits at
age sixty-five, attained in 2003. Even if equity returns average 300 basis
points below their historical value, the authors project that average 401(k)
14 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
assets in 2040 would be 3.7 times as large as the value of DB benefits in
2003.
The offsetting and dominating influence of 401(k)-type saving, com-
pared with flows in DB assets, is the central conclusion of the analysis. Fo-
cusing on DB assets alone suggests that an aging population, in conjunc-
tion with a shift away from DB plans, will lead to a decline in the real value
of pension assets averaged across all retirees in future cohorts. When com-
bining projected 401(k) assets with projected DB assets, however, the study
finds that real pension assets not only increase, but increase substantially,
in future decades.
These results underscore the need for further analysis of the factors
that determine the diffusion of 401(k) plans across corporations, especially
small companies with low-wage workers, as well as the contribution
behavior and withdrawal behavior of 401(k) participants. The growing role
of 401(k)-type plans in the retirement landscape suggests that understand-
ing asset accumulation and drawdown in these plans is a critical com-
ponent of any analysis of the effect of demographic change on financial
markets.
Chapter 11 extends the analysis of demographic change and asset mar-
kets from the United States to international financial markets. In “Demo-
graphic Change, Relative Factor Prices, International Capital Flows, and
Their Differential Effects on the Welfare of Generations,” Alexander Lud-
wig, Dirk Krüger, and Axel Börsch-Supan develop a simulation model to
analyze the impact of demographic change on macroeconomic markets
around the world.
While the size, rate of growth, and age distribution of the population is
changing worldwide, the magnitude of demographic changes and the tim-
ing and character of those changes differ significantly across countries and
across regions of the world. There is variation in aggregate population
growth rates and trends, variation in the ratio of the working-age popula-
tion to the total adult population, and variation in the portion of the pop-
ulation at older ages. These demographic variations, and the varying paths
of demographic change over time, affect international flows of capital and
other resources. And these flows, in conjunction with the demographic
changes themselves, affect the macroeconomic characteristics of different
countries and the welfare of different generations within them.
The authors present the following intuitive explanation, which plays out
in their more rigorous macroeconomic modeling. First, changes in the
population structure will alter aggregate labor supply and aggregate sav-
ings that, in turn, alter the prices for labor and capital. As the working age
population declines, for example, labor will become scarcer, relative to cap-
ital; real wages will increase; and real rates of return to capital will de-
crease. Second, as countries reform their PAYGO pension systems to par-
tially funded systems, the additional supply of capital from those reforms
Introduction 15
reinforces the downward pressure on the rate of return to capital. The wel-
fare implications of changing factor prices differ across generations, as
younger generations gain from wage increases and older generations lose
from lower capital returns.
The goal of this study is to quantify these effects in an international con-
text, accounting for international flows of resources across countries.
Much of the work leading up to this study has been in developing an eco-
nomic model to make these calculations.
The study finds that the rate of return to capital decreases by roughly 80
to 90 basis points if capital is allowed to flow freely across regions. The sim-
ulations indicate that capital flows from rapidly aging regions to the rest of
the world will initially be substantial, but that trends are reversed subse-
quently. However, because long-term demographic trends are highly cor-
related across Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD) countries, the capital flows across countries do not affect much
the long-run decrease in the rate of return on capital. In other words, the
impact of open markets in moderating the macroeconomic impact of de-
mographic change within countries is less important because of the simi-
larities in demographic change across countries in the long term.
In terms of the generational welfare effects, the simulations suggest that
for younger households with few capital assets, increases in wages will
dominate the decline in rates of return on capital. For example, abstracting
from Social Security and its reform, the cohort born in 2005 will gain about
0.6 to 0.9 percent in terms of lifetime consumption. Older, asset-rich indi-
viduals, on the other hand, tend to lose because of the decline in interest
rates on capital. However, if demographic changes necessitate reforms in
Social Security, then reduced benefits or increased taxes will moderate the
welfare gains to the younger generation.
Mortality Projections
The financial footing of the Social Security system depends importantly
on the longevity of program participants. In the past several decades,
longevity in the United States has increased substantially, adding to the fi-
nancial burden on the Social Security program. What the future holds is
less clear and requires the consideration of multiple factors. In chapter 12,
“Is the U.S. Population Behaving Healthier?,” David M. Cutler, Edward L.
Glaeser, and Allison B. Rosen compare the risk factor profile of the popu-
lation in the early 1970s with that of the population in the early 2000s
and consider the implications of recent trends for future reductions in mor-
tality.
The first part of the chapter estimates the impact of demographics,
smoking, drinking, obesity, blood pressure, and cholesterol on ten-year
mortality rates, comparing the predicted ten-year mortality in the two time
16 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
periods. For the population aged twenty- to seventy-four, the ten-year
probability of death fell from 9.8 percent in 1971 to 1975 to 8.4 percent in
1999 to 2002. For the population aged fifty-five to seventy-four, the ten-
year risk of death falls from 25.7 percent to 21.7 percent. The largest con-
tributors to these changes are reductions in smoking and better control of
blood pressure.
While overall health has improved, not all risk factor trends have been
in a positive direction. Smoking rates have fallen by more than a third
since 1960, and alcohol consumption has declined by 20 percent since
1980, both leading to better health. Demographically, the population is bet-
ter educated, and better-educated people live longer than less-educated
people. On the other hand, obesity rates have doubled in the past two
decades, and diabetes has increased as a result.
The second part of the analysis considers the impact on mortality if cur-
rent trends continue. The mortality forecast integrates together several of
the most important risk factors associated with mortality. Smoking and
obesity are found to be the most important and offsetting components of
the forecast. Based on reduced smoking, the mortality risk for the entire
population aged twenty-five and older would be expected to decline by 8
percent. Increasing obesity, however, with current treatment rates—leads
to increased hypertension and high cholesterol—and a 13 percent increase
in mortality risk.
While suggestive, the authors emphasize that there is considerable un-
certainty in making health projections for the future. For example, two-
thirds of the U.S. population is overweight or obese. As a result, continued
increases in weight from current levels have a bigger impact on health than
did increases in weight from lower levels of body mass index (BMI). At the
same time, however, the detrimental impact of BMI on health can be mod-
erated dramatically by controlling hypertension and high cholesterol. So
the question is not just whether weight will continue to increase. Also crit-
ical is the extent to which those who are overweight or obese take medica-
tions to control the health risks associated with high BMI. That, too, is
highly uncertain. Understanding how to improve utilization of and adher-
ence to recommended medications are key issues.
Introduction 17
Social Security Policy In A Changing Environment Jeffrey R Brown Editor Jeffrey B Liebman Editor David A Wise Editor
21
1.1 Introduction
When Social Security was instituted in 1935, the period life expectancy
at age twenty for males was sixty-six and for females sixty-nine. Today,
twenty-year-old males have a period life expectancy of seventy-six and fe-
males eighty. This increase in life expectancy has been accompanied by a
corresponding improvement in health at all ages. Cutler, Liebman, and
Smyth (2007) find that, in terms of mortality, men at age sixty-eight in 2000
have roughly the same mortality risk as men at age sixty-two in 1960. Thus,
at a same age, men in the year 2000 are roughly six years younger. In terms
of self-assessed health status, they find that the difference is even larger, ap-
proximately ten years. Their bottom line is, “Our best guess is that people
aged 62 in the 1960s are in equivalent health to people aged 70 or more to-
day” (p. 14). In related work, Shoven (2004) suggests that the age of elderly
people is more appropriately measured by remaining life expectancy than
by years since birth.
These improvements in life expectancy and health status enable individ-
uals to prolong their careers and delay retirement. However, the length of
retirement has actually grown by more than the increase in life expectancy
1
Removing the Disincentives in Social
Security for Long Careers
Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and
Sita Nataraj Slavov
Gopi Shah Goda is a Robert Wood Johnson Scholar in Health Policy Research at Harvard
University. John B. Shoven is the Charles R. Schwab Professor of Economics at Stanford Uni-
versity, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Sita Nataraj
Slavov is an assistant professor of economics at Occidental College.
This research was supported by the U.S. Social Security Administration (SSA) through
grant #10-P-98363-1-01 to the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) as part of the
SSA Retirement Research Consortium. The opinions and conclusions expressed are solely
those of the authors and do not represent the opinions or policy of SSA or any agency of the
Federal Government.
at retirement. Figure 1.1 shows labor force participation rates by age in
1965 and 2003. Both early retirees and median retirees are retiring earlier
in 2003 than they were in 1965. Figure 1.2 displays labor force participa-
tion rates by remaining life expectancy rather than age and shows that the
average length of retirement for men has increased almost 50 percent since
1965. In 1965, the average length of retirement for the median male retiree
was thirteen years. By 2003, it was nineteen years. Roughly half of the ad-
ditional years were due to improvements in life expectancy, and half were
due to earlier retirement.
Individuals may choose to use increases in their life expectancy for ad-
ditional leisure or additional consumption, and it is possible that the shift
toward longer retirements is optimal. However, there are a number of fea-
tures of Social Security that distort incentives toward increased retirement
length by imposing high implicit tax rates on longer careers and working
at older ages. For example, Social Security benefits are computed based on
the average of an individual’s highest thirty-five years of earnings. An in-
dividual with fewer than thirty-five years of earnings has a relatively strong
incentive to work for an additional year as the additional earnings clearly
raise the average upon which the benefit is based. On the other hand, an
individual who has already worked for thirty-five years has a diminished
incentive to work an additional year—the earnings from that year will, at
best, replace one of the previous highest thirty-five in the benefit computa-
22 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov
Fig. 1.1 Labor force participation of men by age, 1965 and 2003
tion. Thus, the benefit formula encourages careers of thirty-five years or
less. Several other features of the benefit computation—which we will dis-
cuss in detail in the following—contribute to the disincentives for long ca-
reers.
In this chapter, we examine the disincentives for long careers created by
Social Security. Our main finding is that the structure of these programs
imposes high implicit tax rates on workers late in their careers. As a result
of this distortion, we believe retirements are suboptimally long. The con-
sequences of this distortion are significant: a lot of the stress on public and
private pension systems is caused by the increased length of retirement. We
also outline ways to reduce or eliminate the implicit taxes on long careers
and working at older ages. The potential benefits of a larger work force for
Social Security and Medicare (and gross domestic product [GDP]) are
large.
1.2 Work Incentives in U.S. Social Security
In this section, we investigate the impact of Old Age and Survivors In-
surance (OASI) on the career-length incentives of both stylized and actual
workers. In each year of their working life, we compute the workers’ pres-
ent value of Social Security taxes minus benefits under the assumption that
Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 23
Fig. 1.2 Labor force participation of men by remaining life expectancy, 1965
and 2003
they stop working after the current year (i.e., they accumulate no further
earnings). The implicit Social Security tax rate is defined as the increase in
the net tax burden from working an additional year as a percentage of the
current year’s earnings. In other words, this is the additional net tax the
worker incurs by prolonging his or her career by one year. This variable
captures the worker’s incentive to continue working for an additional year
as opposed to retiring. Throughout our analysis, OASI benefits are com-
puted under 2005 law. That is, we sum each worker’s highest thirty-five
years of wage-indexed earnings that fall below the earnings cap and divide
this amount by 420 months to get the worker’s average indexed monthly
earnings (AIME). We then compute the worker’s primary insurance
amount (PIA): the PIA is equal to 90 percent of the first $x of AIME, plus
32 percent of the amount between $x and $y, plus 15 percent of the re-
mainder of AIME, where x and y are the constructed bend points for the
appropriate retirement year.1
The worker receives the PIA—indexed for in-
flation—every month from retirement until death. A minimum of ten years
of work is required to qualify for any benefits. In computing taxes and ben-
efits, we assume an aggregate wage growth rate of 3.5 percent, an inflation
rate of 2.5 percent, and a discount rate of 4.5 percent. The OASI tax rate is
assumed to be 10.6 percent applied to capped earnings using the historical
earnings caps. Benefit streams are discounted for mortality using the So-
cial Security Administration’s intermediate scenario mortality rates.
Our analysis is similar to that of Feldstein and Samwick (1992). Feld-
stein and Samwick compute marginal net tax rates for stylized workers
who vary by gender, income, and marital status. They show that the addi-
tional tax paid on an additional dollar of income varies significantly across
workers and over a worker’s lifetime—in particular, marginal tax rates are
significantly higher for single workers and for younger workers. Their find-
ing that marginal tax rates decline with age comes from the fact that as a
worker approaches retirement, the present value of the additional benefit
received increases. However, they only compute marginal tax rates for
workers between ages twenty-five and sixty, and each year of earnings over
this thirty-five-year period is assumed to count in the benefit computation.
This assumption overlooks a major disincentive for long careers: after a
worker has accumulated thirty-five years of earnings, additional years are
likely to have little, if any, impact on benefits. As we will show in the fol-
lowing, taking account of this fact implies that older workers face signifi-
cantly higher implicit tax rates than younger workers.
1.2.1 A Stylized Computation
To illustrate our argument, we compute implicit tax rates for a set of four
male stylized workers under current law. Three of our stylized workers re-
24 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov
1. The 2005 bendpoints ($627 and $3,779) were multiplied by the appropriate wage adjust-
ment factor to be in line with the year in which the worker retires.
ceive simulated earnings profiles equal to either the average, 10th per-
centile, or 90th percentile earnings for their age group. In order to simulate
wage histories, we use Outgoing Rotation Groups from the 2001 and 2002
Current Population Survey to compute the wage for each of the three earn-
ings levels within each age group. We then divide this by the aggregate av-
erage wage across all age groups. This ratio is multiplied by the historical
average wage in each year of the worker’s life to arrive at a wage for the
worker. For example, consider an average male thirty-year-old worker in
1950. The national average annual wage in 1950 was $2,763. According to
our computations, a thirty-year-old male earns 1.13 times the national av-
erage; therefore, his simulated wage would be $2,763  1.13  $3,122. A
fourth stylized worker earns the historical earnings cap in each year.
We assume that all stylized workers start work at age twenty and retire
at the normal retirement age. The implicit Social Security tax rate for a
given career length is calculated as described previously. The results of this
exercise are shown in figure 1.3. Note that for less than ten years of work,
the worker is not yet vested in the system and, therefore, faces an implicit
tax rate of the full 10.6 percent. (These years are not shown in figure 1.3.)
Two points should be clear from the graph. First, all workers experience
a sharp increase in their implicit tax rate at thirty-five years of work. The
reason for this increase is that Social Security benefits are calculated based
Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 25
Fig. 1.3 Implicit tax rates by career length
on the highest thirty-five years of indexed annual earnings. This means that
the thirty-third, thirty-fourth, and thirty-fifth year of work noticeably im-
prove retirement benefits because the earnings of that year replace a zero
in the calculation of average indexed monthly earnings (AIME). On the
other hand, the thirty-sixth year of work may or may not enter the calcu-
lation, and if it does, it will replace a lower year of earnings and not a zero
in the calculation. The marginal incentive to work for the thirty-sixth year
and beyond is much lower than for the first thirty-five years. Part-time
work after a career of thirty-five years or more will, in particular, usually
have no impact on subsequent benefits, and, therefore, the 10.6 percent
OASI payroll tax is simply a tax and has no component of deferred bene-
fits. For people who enter the workforce immediately after high school and
who do not leave the labor force for an extended period, thirty-five years of
earnings will be accumulated by the age of fifty-three.
Second, the median and low earners each experience a sharp increase
in their implicit tax rate earlier in their careers—for the middle-income
earner, after twelve years of work, and for the low-income earner, after
twenty-two years of work. This increase results from the fact that the PIA
formula is sharply progressive, combined with the fact that the AIME cal-
culation does not distinguish between workers with lower earnings and
those with higher earnings but shorter covered careers. At the beginning of
their careers, workers tend to have a low AIME because they have signifi-
cantly fewer than thirty-five years of positive earnings. The benefit com-
putation replaces the missing years of earnings with zeros, and these work-
ers appear to be in a lower income group than their true lifetime earnings
would imply. The progressivity of the PIA formula translates this low
AIME into a disproportionately high monthly benefit. As workers accu-
mulate positive earnings years, the benefit computation begins to treat
them as if they have higher lifetime incomes. A sharp increase in the im-
plicit tax rate occurs when a worker accumulates enough positive earnings
years to cross a PIA bend point. Thus, the current formula favors workers
with short careers by treating them as if they were low earners. In some
cases, for instance, where the short career was necessitated by poor health,
that may be appropriate. In most cases, however, the current treatment
seems inappropriate and blunts the incentive to work long careers. This
effect is most pronounced for low-income workers, who face the sharpest
increase in their implicit tax rate.
These distortions lead us to evaluate the following three reforms:
1. Use forty years, rather than thirty-five, in the AIME computation.
If forty years were used instead of thirty-five, this would remove some of
the discouragement currently built into the system for staying in the work-
force. An extra five years of work would count toward the calculation of re-
tirement benefits.
26 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov
2. Disentangle career length and progressivity.
Average indexed monthly earnings could be calculated only for the
months with covered earnings (eliminating the zeros from the computation
and dividing by the number of months of nonzero earnings rather than
420). The PIA would be calculated using this modified AIME formula.
However, a single person would only get the full PIA at the Normal Re-
tirement Age (NRA) if they worked a full career (currently thirty-five
years, proposed to be forty years under the first reform). If they worked
fewer years, their benefits would be reduced proportionately. For example,
consider how we currently treat someone with a ten-year high-income ca-
reer. Their benefits are determined as if they were a relative low earner with
the twenty-five years of zeros in the earnings calculation. The alternative
would be to give them 10/35ths of the PIA of a high earner. This would re-
sult in a reduction of benefits for short career workers. This reform is illus-
trated in figure 1.4.
3. Establish a “paid-up” category of workers who have more than forty
years of contributions.
Under the first proposed reform, the number of years in the benefit cal-
culation is forty. A complementary policy is to only collect forty years of
payroll taxes from workers. After forty years of covered employment, the
worker would be declared “paid-up” for Social Security. This should be rel-
atively easy to administer—conceivably an indicator would be added to
the individual’s Social Security number reflecting the fact that paid-up
Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 27
Fig. 1.4 PIA under current and proposed law
status had been achieved. A related idea was mentioned in Burtless and
Quinn (2002), namely allowing workers who reach the NRA to opt out of
additional Social Security contributions.
There is a theoretical justification for these policies. The intuition of op-
timal tax theory would be to place heavier taxes on more inelastic supply
(and demand) and lighter taxes or no taxes on highly elastic behavior. Our
hypothesis is that the forty-first and forty-second years of work, for in-
stance, are far more sensitive to incentives than the twenty-first and
twenty-second years of work. The practical significance of these three re-
forms is to make employment of veteran workers more attractive for both
the employee and the employer.
Taken together, these three proposals result in a benefit cut. In order to
compensate for this and keep the reforms benefit-neutral in aggregate, we
increase retirement benefits proportionately in order to keep aggregate
benefits constant before and after the reforms.2
Assuming no behavioral
changes, the adjustment needed is a 19.4 percent increase in benefits. The
proposals also result in redistribution from those with shorter careers to
those with longer ones. Figure 1.5 illustrates this by depicting our stylized
average earner’s PIA, as a function of career length, under both the current
and the proposed law. Under the proposed law, a worker’s PIA would rise
more sharply as he or she accumulated years of work—that is, benefits are
more responsive to a decision to delay retirement. Workers with fewer than
thirty-one years of covered earnings would receive a smaller PIA than un-
der the current system; however, as their career length extends beyond
thirty-one years, their PIA rises above the current level. A similar result
holds for the low and high earners.
On the revenue side, introducing the “paid-up” category of workers who
have worked forty years constitutes a reduction in the amount of tax rev-
enues the system receives. We estimate that at most 4.35 percent of OASI
revenue comes from income that was earned after an individual worked
forty years.3
Thus, instituting the “paid-up” reform would require a payroll
tax increase of 0.5 percent, changing the current OASI tax from 10.6 per-
cent to 11.1 percent. All future calculations of the impact of the three pro-
posed reforms account for the tax and benefit adjustments to ensure bene-
fit- and revenue-neutrality.
28 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov
2. The revenue effects are estimated using the Social Security Benefits and Earnings Public-
Use File described in the following section.
3. The estimate of the fraction of OASI revenue earned in years 41 comes from the Social
Security Benefits and Earnings Public-Use File, 2004, described in more detail in the follow-
ing section. The beneficiaries’ earnings were indexed to 2003 using the historical Social Secu-
rity average wage index. This estimate is biased upward because the data set only includes
earnings below the taxable maximum, which has increased significantly over the period 1951
to 2003. This implies the program has expanded over this time period, and earnings in the ear-
lier part of this period are underrepresented.
We repeat our implicit tax rate computations for the four stylized work-
ers under the proposed reforms. The results are shown in figure 1.6 and la-
beled “Proposed Law.” Current Law results are also shown for comparison
purposes. Note that implicit tax rates remain roughly constant over each
worker’s life, resulting in less distortion of career length choices. Moreover,
implicit tax rates for all income groups are closer to zero. The decreasing
trend arises from the present value of future benefits increasing as a worker
gets closer to the NRA. At forty years of work, all workers enter the “paid-
up” category and no longer participate in the system.
The proposed reforms do not affect the overall progressivity of the So-
cial Security system as is shown in table 1.1. At the thirty-five-year career
length, the average income earner’s internal rates of return (IRRs) are con-
stant before and after the reforms at 1.17 percent. The three policies do not
change the relative position of the low- and high-income earners. After an
individual has worked thirty-five years, he or she is always better off under
the proposed reforms.
1.2.2 Data and Results
The drawback of using stylized workers is, of course, that they do not re-
flect the diversity of actual workers’ labor market experiences. In particu-
lar, the stylized workers’ ages and career lengths are perfectly correlated.
This makes it difficult to capture the experience of, for example, a woman
who takes time out of the labor force to raise children. Thus, we repeat our
computations using the Social Security Benefits and Earnings Public-Use
Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 29
Fig. 1.5 Monthly primary insurance amount under current and proposed law: Av-
erage income earner
Fig. 1.6 Implicit tax rates by career length under current and proposed laws
Table 1.1 Internal rates of return for workers with 35-year career (%)
Current law Proposed law
Low-income earner 2.47 2.46
Average-income earner 1.17 1.17
High-income earner 0.66 0.66
File, 2004, which contains benefit and earnings data on a 1 percent ran-
dom, representative sample entitled to receive a Social Security benefit in
December 2004. The full sample contains data on 473,366 beneficiaries.
Unfortunately, this data set provides no way to link couples; therefore, we
include only workers who are receiving benefits based on their own earn-
ings records. We limit our attention to beneficiaries receiving retirement
benefits who started working in 1951 or later, which leaves 123,552 indi-
viduals born between 1910 and 1942.4
We continue to use Social Security
intermediate scenario assumptions for mortality.
For the actual worker computations under the proposed law, we intro-
duce an earnings threshold: years in which earnings are less than 5 percent
of the earnings cap are not counted toward the years of work calculation,
but are subject to payroll taxes.5
The rationale for the earnings threshold
is that many individuals—particularly as they get older—have years in
which they work a small number of hours. Without an earnings threshold,
these individuals’ benefits would increase disproportionately (given the
modified AIME computation and the progressivity of the PIA formula),
and they would accumulate years of credit toward the paid-up status. The
result is that many older individuals in the sample would face large nega-
tive implicit tax rates. The earnings threshold reduces this distortion. Of
course, this means that years where earnings were under the threshold face
the full tax, unless the individual had attained paid-up status by working
more than forty years. On balance, however, we find that distortions are
significantly less with the earnings threshold. (This issue did not arise with
the stylized workers as our simulated earnings profiles never fell below the
5 percent threshold.)
In order to illustrate the complexity of patterns that actual individuals
face, we plot histograms of the ages at which individuals attain ten years of
covered earnings (vesting age at which individuals become eligible for ben-
efits), thirty-five years of covered earnings (the current number used in the
benefit computation), and forty years of covered earnings (the proposed
number to be used in the benefit computation). The results are broken
down by gender and appear as figures 1.7 to 1.9.
While workers tend to reach ten years of work at age thirty, thirty-five
years at age fifty-five, and forty years at age sixty (like our stylized work-
ers), there is considerable individual variation, particularly for females. A
sizeable number of females reach these experience levels considerably later
than assumed in our stylized example. These figures illustrate the impor-
Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 31
4. Only aggregate earnings are recorded for years 1937 to 1950.
5. This is not unlike the earnings needed to obtain a quarter of coverage in the current sys-
tem, $920 in 2005. To receive four quarters of coverage, an individual would need $3,680 in
earnings, approximately 4 percent of the 2005 earnings cap of $90,000. Earnings below this
level are subject to the payroll tax even though benefits are not increased.
tance of using actual workers to study the career length incentives created
by the system, particularly if we are interested in the impact on women.
Figures 1.10 and 1.11 show our calculations of the average implicit tax
rate broken down by career length (figure 1.10), age (figure 1.11), and gen-
der. The current law computations exhibit the same features as did those
for stylized workers. Workers face increases in their implicit tax rates un-
der current law as they age and increase their career length. This is a result
of moving from one PIA bend point to the next and from accumulating
thirty-five years of earnings. This result occurs for both male and female
32 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov
Fig. 1.7 Distribution of vesting age: Graphs by gender
Fig. 1.8 Distribution of thirty-five-year career age: Graphs by gender
workers, and it is present whether we look at means or medians (not
shown).
Under the proposed law, male workers’ implicit tax rates move closer to
zero for all age and experience groups. There is also a much smaller asso-
ciation between implicit tax rate and age. Most of the large, positive im-
plicit tax rates—which occur late in their careers—are eliminated. Those
that remain are faced by individuals who earn less than the earnings
threshold and, therefore, are being subject to the full OASI tax rate of 10.6
percent. Individuals with earnings below the threshold drive up the aver-
Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 33
Fig. 1.9 Distribution of forty-year career age: Graphs by gender
Fig. 1.10 Average implicit Social Security tax rates, by career length:
Graphs by gender
age implicit tax rates faced under the proposed reforms at older ages; how-
ever, the average annual income earned by people who face the full OASI
tax rate is only $1,115. One of the main differences between the treatment
under the current law and the proposed law is the sharp decrease in the
number of people and the amount of income facing the full tax rate under
the three reforms.
The changes redistribute from short-careered workers to long-careered
workers as shown in figure 1.12. Individuals who work more than forty
years and are thus subject to the paid-up policy reform no longer see ear-
lier earnings years being replaced by later, potentially higher earning years.
While this could lead to a decrease in their calculated PIA, the IRR would
be higher under the proposed reforms because the added benefit from re-
placing a year of earnings in the current calculation is small relative to the
amount of taxes paid.
Females tend to experience a larger subsidy under both current law and
the proposed policies due to the fact that the system is progressive and fe-
males in the sample have lower earnings, and also because their mortality
probabilities are more favorable, making the expected future additional
benefits larger. We define the Gender Gap to be the difference between av-
erage male and female implicit Social Security tax rates. Table 1.2 summa-
rizes calculations of the Gender Gap under different mortality assump-
tions and shows that approximately 40 percent of the difference between
male and female implicit tax rates is due to more favorable female mortal-
ity; the remaining is attributed to differences in underlying earnings levels.
The reforms may disproportionately penalize women, who are more
likely to take time out of the labor force for child or elderly care and expe-
34 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov
Fig. 1.11 Average implicit Social Security tax rates, by age: Graphs by gender
rience shorter careers. Benefit levels are 0.89 percent higher for males but
1.45 percent lower for females under the three reforms. One possible pol-
icy to alleviate this effect would be to give women an across-the-board
credit for working of one, two, or three years. This policy is similar to the
treatment of individuals who take time out of the labor force to raise chil-
dren in countries such as Germany. In the German system, a child-raising
parent is treated as though he or she earned the average wage until the
child’s third birthday. The differences between the PIA in the current sys-
Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 35
Fig. 1.12 Percentage change in PIA by career length
Table 1.2 Average implicit Social Security tax (ISST) rates under different
mortality assumptions (%)
Average ISST Gender gap
Current law
Males 0.90
Females using female mortality 3.99 4.89
Females using male mortality 2.18 3.08
Portion of gender gap explained
by mortality differences 37
Proposed law
Males 0.93
Females using female mortality 5.33 4.40
Females using male mortality 3.34 2.41
Portion of gender gap explained
by mortality differences 45
tem and the PIA under the proposed reforms along with a credit for women
are given in table 1.3. Note that offering a credit to women of even one year
has a substantial effect on the level of benefits.
Our calculations of mean implicit tax rates mask a considerable amount
of variation across workers. To illustrate this variation, we plot individual
implicit tax rates as a function of age for a small subsample of individuals
under both current law and the proposed reforms. These are shown in fig-
ures 1.13 (current law) and 1.14 (proposed law). Most individuals experi-
ence features similar to the stylized workers: under current law, there are
sharp increases in implicit tax rate as they cross PIA bend points and an-
other sharp increase when they accumulate thirty-five years of work. There
is considerable variation across workers in the timing of these increases.
The proposed law eliminates most of the large positive tax rates for older
workers. It also reduces the association between age and tax rate and
moves tax rates closer to zero for most workers in most years of their lives.
However, many of the workers experience single years with large negative
implicit tax rates. These are years in which earnings are low—these years
36 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov
Table 1.3 Percentage change in primary insurance amount by gender and years of
credit given for women (%)
No credit 1-year credit 2-year credit 3-year credit
Male benefits 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.89
Female benefits 1.45 1.69 4.73 7.67
Total 0.02 1.20 2.39 3.53
Fig. 1.13 Current law: Graphs by gender
disproportionately increase PIA (due to the progressivity of the formula)
and contribute toward paid up status.
1.3 Conclusion
The U.S. labor market has proved to be very flexible in absorbing new
workers as evidenced by its ability to accommodate large numbers of work-
ers as women entered the labor force in the past several decades, and the
economy has benefited greatly as a result of the larger workforce. By elim-
inating the disincentives against working longer careers, we can capitalize
on the good fortunes of increasing life expectancy and favorable health sta-
tus by paving the way for more capable individuals to stay in the labor
force.
References
Burtless, Gary, and Joseph Quinn. 2002. Is working longer the answer for an aging
workforce? Center for Retirement Research. Issue in Brief no. 11. Center for Re-
tirement Research at Boston College.
Butrica, Barbara A., Richard W. Johnson, Karen E. Smith, and Eugene Steuerle.
2006. The implicit tax on work at older ages. National Tax Journal 59:211–34.
Cutler, David M., Jeffrey B. Liebman, and Seamus Smyth. 2007. How fast should
the Social Security eligibility age rise? NBER Retirement Research Center
Working Paper no. NB04-05. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 37
Fig. 1.14 Proposed law: Graphs by gender
Feldstein, Martin, and Andrew Samwick. 1992. Social Security rules and marginal
tax rates. National Tax Journal 45 (1): 1–22.
Fenge, Robert, Silke Uebelmesser, and Martin Werding. 2002. Second-best prop-
erties of implicit Social Security taxes: Theory and evidence. CESifo Working
Paper no. 743.
Gruber, Jonathan, and David A. Wise. 1997. Social Security and retirement around
the world. NBER Working Paper no. 6134. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau
of Economic Research, August.
Shoven, John B. 2004. The impact of major improvement in life expectancy on the
financing of Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid. In Coping with Methuse-
lah: The impact of molecular biology on medicine and society, ed. Henry J. Aaron
and William B. Schwartz, 166–97. Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
Comment Erzo F. P. Luttmer
This chapter tackles the important question of how the Social Security
benefit formula can be adjusted so that it generates fewer incentives for in-
dividuals to retire early. Social Security provides retirement incentives
when the additional Social Security taxes paid by postponing retirement
for a year exceed the increase in the present value of future Social Security
benefits from working this additional year. Goda, Shoven, and Slavov re-
fer to this difference, when expressed as a fraction of earnings, as the im-
plicit Social Security tax. Two features in the current Social Security law
cause this implicit Social Security tax to be high for individuals with long
careers. First, the current Social Security law bases benefits on the average
of the thirty-five highest years of indexed earnings. Thus, current earnings
will increase this average less for individuals who already have worked for
thirty-five years than for individuals who have not yet worked thirty-five
years because for the former group the current year’s earnings crowd out a
prior year’s earnings in the benefit formula. Second, the progressivity of
Social Security benefits depends on the average indexed earnings of the
highest thirty-five years of earnings (including years with zero earnings)
rather than basing this average only on those years with positive earnings.
As a result, Social Security redistributes from workers with long careers to
those with short careers even if these two groups have the same earnings
per year worked. This redistribution further raises the implicit Social Se-
curity tax on those with longer careers.
Goda, Shoven, and Slavov analyze a reform proposal that would reduce
the implicit early retirement incentives in the Social Security benefit rules.
This reform would base benefits on the average of the forty highest years of
38 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov
Erzo F. P. Luttmer is an associate professor at the John F. Kennedy School of Government,
Harvard University, and a faculty research fellow of the National Bureau of Economic Re-
search.
positive indexed earnings (i.e., excluding years with zero earnings) and re-
duce benefits pro rata based on the number of years with positive earnings
for people who have fewer than forty years of positive earnings. For ex-
ample, a person with twenty years of positive earnings would receive half
the benefits of someone who has the same average earnings based on forty
years of positive earnings. Finally, after forty years of positive earnings,
one would become “paid-up,” that is, exempt from paying any further So-
cial Security taxes. Under this proposal, Social Security benefits and the
Social Security tax rate are adjusted such that average benefits and average
Social Security tax revenue are the same as under the current law.
Using data on a 1 percent random sample of Social Security beneficiar-
ies in 2004 who started working after or during 1951 and claim benefits
based on their own earnings record, Goda, Shoven, and Slavov carefully
evaluate the reform proposal’s impact on the Social Security incentive to
retire as well as its distributional impact. They find that this reform would
lead to a sharp reduction in retirement incentives: the implicit Social Se-
curity tax rate would fall substantially, typically by 4 to 7 percentage
points, for men and women between the ages of fifty and seventy. As a re-
sult, Social Security would no longer provide this group of workers with an
incentive to retire early. By design, this proposal would increase benefits
for those with longer careers at the expense of those with shorter careers.
However, the reform does not substantially affect the overall progressivity
of the Social Security system. The proposed reform would reduce the av-
erage benefits of women relative to those of men, but this can be fixed with
a minor adjustment.
Goda, Shoven, and Slavov analyze one of three implicit marginal Social
Security taxes, namely the implicit Social Security tax “on postponing re-
tirement by one year.” In other words, it is the implicit tax on working this
year when the counterfactual is retiring in the following year. This is prob-
ably the most plausible counterfactual for older workers. The second im-
plicit Social Security tax is the tax on the extensive margin of working this
year holding labor supply constant in the future years. In other words, it is
the incentive to take one year off from working, for example, for child care
or schooling reasons. This margin is probably the more relevant one for
younger workers. Finally, there is the implicit Social Security tax on the in-
tensive margin: the effect of earning one extra dollar on expected Social Se-
curity benefits net of taxes holding earnings in all other years constant.
Feldstein and Samwick (1992) also calculate implicit Social Security
taxes and find, in apparent contradiction to Goda, Shoven, and Slavov’s
findings, that these tax rates fall with age. Goda, Shoven, and Slavov attri-
bute this difference to the fact that Feldstein and Samwick only calculate
implicit marginal Social Security tax rates for workers with at most thirty-
five years of earnings. This, however, is not the reason why Feldstein and
Samwick obtain different results. The difference in findings arises because
Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 39
Random documents with unrelated
content Scribd suggests to you:
the hierophants came and led him away to be of their company till
his death: the ceremony was ended. My attendants, arrayed as the
goddesses Hathor and Nut, conducted me from the shrine. I was
unrobed of my sacred panoplies and once more from a goddess
became a woman, and as a woman I sought my couch and wept
and wept.
For had I not at the first temptation in my heart broken the law
and betrayed the trust of her who, as then I believed, is and was
and shall be; her whose veil no mortal man had lifted, the Mother of
the sun and all its stars?
CHAPTER V
The Summons
None knew my fault. Yet I knew, and what is known to one soul is
known to all souls, since one is all and all are one. Moreover, it was
known to That which begets souls, That from which they come and
to which they return again, again to come, as Plato, the great
philosopher, who died before my day, has taught us in his writings.
Also it was known to that accursed priest who was the cause and
partner of my crime. I was overcome; I was eaten up with shame, I
who thought myself purer than the mountain snows, as indeed I was
and, in the flesh, to this hour have remained.
Soon I could no longer bear my torment. To Noot I went, Noot
the high-priest, my counsellor and master, and in a secret place
kneeling on my knees, there I told him all.
He hearkened with a little smile upon his withered face, then
answered,
“Daughter, in your honesty you do but reveal that which I knew
—how I knew it matters not. And now take comfort, since the blame
is not altogether yours, or even that of this new-made priest, whose
foot was caught in the same snare. You worship Isis, as I do, but
what is Isis whom we portray on earth as a woman glorious above
all women? Is she not Nature’s self, the universal Mother, the
Supreme in whom all gods and goddesses have a part? She wars on
Aphrodite, it is true, yet does not that mean that in verity she wars
upon herself? And are we not as Isis is, not one but many poured
into a single mould, for do we not all war upon ourselves? Believe
me, Daughter, the human heart is a great battleground where the
higher and the lower parts of us fight with spiritual spears and
arrows, till one side or the other wins victory and hoists the banner
of good or evil, of Isis or of Set. Only out of struggle comes
perfectness; that which has never struggled is a dead creature from
whom little may be hoped. The ore must be melted in the fire and
lo! the most of it is dross, refuse to be thrown away. Had it never
known the fire, there could be no pure gold to adorn the brows of
Heaven, nor even copper and iron to shape the swords of men.
Rejoice, then, that you have felt the hurt of fire.”
“Master,” I answered, “Lord of Wisdom to whom alone Ayesha
bows the knee, your words are true and comfortable, yet bethink
you, and if it is permitted, interpret me this riddle. I dreamed a
dream of the time before my earthly days—you know it well for I
have told it to you. I dreamed of a place in Heaven and of two
goddesses matched against each other and of a command that was
laid upon me to bring woe upon those who had deserted the one
and turned to the other. Now if they were parts of a single whole,
why should this command be laid upon me?”
“Daughter, in your dream you were ordained to be a Sword of
Vengeance, not because the Egyptians turned from one part of the
holy Unity to another part of that Unity, but because they have
become corrupt and faithless, worshipping no gods save themselves
and following after that which is low, not that which is high. Such is
my answer, yet of the truth or the falsehood of that dream I say
nothing. Perchance it was but a dream.”
“Perchance, Master. Yet in that dream, true or false, I saw a
face, and lo! a few nights gone I, draped as Isis in the shrine, I saw
that face again and knew it; knew also that with it my fate is
intertwined. What of this?”
“Daughter, who are we that we should read the mysteries of
Fate, we who know not whence we come nor whither we go, nor
what we have been, nor why we are? It may be that you have some
mission toward the spirit that is clothed in the flesh of yonder man.
It may be that you are destined to uplift that spirit, and in so doing
yourself to be trodden down. If so, I say that in the end you shall
rise again and bear him upward with you.”
He paused, and I knelt silent, pondering the prophecy, for such
I knew it well to be. Then again he spoke,
“You heard a laughter in the shrine, yet there was no laughter
save that of the evil in your own heart, mocking and triumphant.
Such laughter mayhap you will often hear, but while you can hear it
and repent, be not dismayed. When the ears of the soul grow deaf
then utter loss is near; while they are open, hope remains. Those
who still strive can never wholly fall. Fate rules us every one, yet
within the circle of that Fate power is given to us to work out our
redemption. I have finished. Ask me no more.”
“What punishment, Master?” I asked.
“Daughter, this. For a while look no more upon that man. I say
for a while, since with you I hold that his destiny and yours are
intertwined. I have a command for you: that presently you
accompany me hence to lands beyond the seas. Now, go rest, and in
rest find forgetfulness.”
So I went, wondering yet comforted, though I knew well that
Noot the Holy had not told me all, no, nor yet the half of what he
knew. For often those to whom the gods give vision are forbid to
speak it, lest, as in the old Hebrew parable, men should eat of the
tree of knowledge and grow like to them. Or perchance they cannot
speak it, since it comes to them in a tongue which may not be
rendered in the words that the passer-by would understand. So
indeed it is with me to-day.
Thus it came about that soon I and my master, Noot, left Philæ
and as before travelled the Nile disguised. Never since then have my
eyes looked upon that island and its holy fane which Holly, who has
visited it, tells me is now a ruin with stark, Hathor-headed columns
standing here and there amongst the tumbled stones. He says,
moreover, that his people who rule the land to-day purpose to sink it
beneath the Nile that the lands below may be enriched and
multiplied. Herein I see an allegory; the temples of Isis are drowned
and the learning they held is lost in order that more food may grow
to feed the common and the ignorant. Yet to what end, seeing that
if there is more food, more men will come to eat it, all of them
common and ignorant, while Isis and her wisdom are swallowed in
the slime. Thus has it ever been in Egypt, and doubtless elsewhere,
for such is Nature’s law. Food breeds multitudes and where carrion
is, there are flies, while in the deserts both are lacking. Yet I think
that the deserts and the few that wander on them beneath the sun
and stars are nearer far to God.
Once more disguised as merchants, I and Noot, my master, took
ship and visited far lands to see their state and gather wisdom. We
visited Rome, then breaking her shackles and rising to her
greatness. They were a great people, those Romans that Noot out of
his foresight told me would one day rule the world. Or perhaps it
was I who told Noot, judging them by their qualities; I am not sure.
At least I loved them not, because of their rude natures, their lack of
arts and their love of power and gain. Therefore when I had studied
their language and their politics I passed on.
We came to Greece and tarried there awhile, studying
philosophies and other things. The Greeks I did love, because they
were beautiful and called forth beauty from all they touched. Also
they were brave who defied the Persian might and had they but
stood together, might have queened it on the earth. But they would
not, for ever State tore out the throat of State, so that in the end all
were undone and overwhelmed by a multitude of commoner folk
who held Greece before them, for such was their destiny. Moreover,
they worshipped gods made like themselves, with all the faults of
men grown greater and more vile, and told fables concerning them
fit to please children, which I thought strange in a people that could
produce such philosophers and poets. Yet those gods had come
down to them from their fathers, and it is hard to shake off the yoke
of gods until some greater god appears and breaks it with the
hammer of war.
Here in Greece it was that I posed to its most famous sculptor
for a statue of Aphrodite, or rather it was as a mould of perfect
Womanhood that I posed, desiring that this sculptor, who pleased
me, should have one flawless model to copy in his future work, for
which he blessed me, naming that statue “Beauty’s Self.” Yet when I
visited him a while afterward I found that he had changed this name
to Aphrodite.
I was angered who did not desire that my loveliness should be
accredited to mine enemy and that of Isis whom I served, and asked
him why this had been done.
He answered, humbly enough, because of a dream in which the
Paphian had appeared to him and threatened him with blindness
unless he gave her own name to so divine a face and form.
Moreover, being in the thrall of superstition he prayed me, even with
tears, that thus it might remain, since otherwise he must break that
statue and as he thought, be blinded as well. So out of pity I let him
have his way and even gave him my hand to kiss in token of
forgiveness.
Thus it comes about that Aphrodite unashamed throughout the
ages has taken the tribute of a million eyes, clothed in a borrowed
loveliness. So be it, since what she has stolen is but a fraction of the
truth. No sculptor, however great, can mould the perfect out of
frozen stone.
From Greece, still disguised as a merchant and his daughter, we
wandered to Jerusalem, feigning to trade in pearls and gems, since
there I would study the religion of the Jews whereof I had heard so
much. The “City of Peace” it was called among the Egyptians of old
times, or so they interpreted its name, but never found I one in
which there was less of peace. Fierce-faced were those Jews and
quarrelsome; revengeful too and ever waging war, public and
private, upon one another. A peculiar people, as they name
themselves, full of hate, particularly of the stranger within their
gates. To trade with them was scarcely possible, because he who
sold them wares was always left the loser, though for this I who
sought their philosophy, not their gold, cared nothing.
So I turned myself to the study of their faith, and found that
God, as they interpreted Him, was well-nigh as fierce as were his
worshippers. Yet this I will say, that He was one God, not many, and
a true God also, since otherwise how could his prophets have written
so gloriously concerning Him? Moreover, it was their belief that He
would come to earth and lead them to the conquest of the world.
This, Holly tells me, has chanced though not in the shape they
hoped, since the King who came would have led them but to the
conquest of the evil that is in the hearts of men and to the
knowledge of a life to be, in which they had small faith. Therefore
they persecuted and slew Him as a malefactor after their cruel
fashion, and what is now accepted by millions, so says Holly, they
still reject.
I preached to them, for my heart burned in me at the sight of
their sacrifices. Yes, I preached to them against the shedding of
blood, telling them of a higher philosophy of gentleness and mercy.
For a while they listened, then took up stones and stoned me, so
that had I and Noot not been protected by Heaven, we should have
been slain. After this affront I turned my back upon Jerusalem and
its hook-nosed, fierce-eyed people, and went to Cyprus where I
debated with the lewd priests of Aphrodite at Paphos. Thence I got
me back to Egypt whence I had been absent many years.
At Naukratis priests of Isis who knew of our coming, how I
cannot tell, perchance Noot had told them by messenger, or in a
dream as he could do, met us and conducted us up the Nile to the
temple of Isis at Memphis. Here we were received in state in the
great hall of the temple and lo! at the head of those who welcomed
us was the Greek Kallikrates, now by his holiness and zeal risen high
in the service of the goddess.
When I saw him, beauteous as of old, my heart stood still and
the blood rushed to my brow.
Yet I gave no sign, treating him as a stranger on whom my eyes
had never fallen until that hour. He for his part stared at me with a
puzzled air, then shook his head as one does who sees a face that
he believes he has met in dream and yet is doubtful. For be it
remembered, this man had looked on me but once, when robed as
Isis I received him into the company of her priests at Philæ, and
then but for a moment in the light of the moon. Perchance he still
thought that it was the goddess herself whom he saw thus and not a
mortal. At the least he did not know that I, the beauteous
prophetess who came to Memphis after wandering through the
world, was the same as she who had sat upon the throne of Isis at
Philæ and whom by chance he had kissed upon the lips. Mayhap
even he did not remember the kiss, or if he remembered, set it
down as part of the ceremonial. Thus, if I knew him but too well, to
him I was a stranger.
I bethought me of flight, knowing in my heart that to me this
man was as the fabled sword that hung above the head of
Damocles, though what harm I had to fear from him, I did not know.
Again I sought the counsel of Noot who smiled and answered,
“Have I not told you, Daughter, that perils must be faced since
those from which we flee will be swift to overtake us? If Destiny has
brought you and this man together, be certain that it is for its own
purposes. Surely you have learned your lesson and steeled your soul
against all fleshly vanities.”
“Yes, my Father,” I answered proudly, “I have learned my lesson
and steeled my soul. Moreover, your thought is my thought, nor will
I turn my back on any man. Here I bide, defying woman’s weakness
and all the wiles of evil gods.”
“Well spoken,” answered Noot, and blessed me in the ancient
words. Yet as he did so I noted that he sighed and shook his head.
For many a moon, I know not how many who, having all time at
my command, seem to have lost its petty count, I remained there in
the temple at Memphis of which soon I became the prophetess and
the head of the priestesses. Ere long the fame of my divinations
spread far and wide, so that from all the land those who sought
wisdom or knowledge of the future would come to consult me,
bringing great gifts to the goddess, though not one gem or piece of
gold did Noot or I keep for ourselves, who indeed had no need of
such common dross.
So I sat in a carven chair in the sanctuary, my diviner’s bowl at
my side, and uttered dark sayings like to those of the famous oracles
of the Greeks at Delphi, many of which fulfilled themselves. For in
truth, I think that there was a spirit in me—whether it came from
the Heavens or elsewhere I do not know—which enabled me to read
much that was passing upon the earth and even sometimes that
which had not yet happened upon the earth. So the renown of the
Lady Isis spread till I became a power in the land. Moreover, thus I
learned many things, for those who consult an oracle, like those who
seek the help of a physician, lay bare their souls, keeping no secret
back.
Now at this time Egypt and all the countries round seethed with
war like a pot boiling on the flames. For years Egypt had beaten off
the attacks of the Persians, but now the Pharaoh Nectanebes, the
second of that name who then sat upon the throne, the last native
king who reigned upon the Nile, was threatened by Artaxerxes, that
one of this accursed race who was named Ochus. This Persian
Ochus had gathered a mighty force to subdue Egypt, hundreds of
thousands of men, tens of thousands of horsemen, hundreds of
triremes and of transport ships.
The last act of the tragedy had begun of which the end was to
be the crushing of Egypt who never more should know a Pharaoh of
her own blood and choosing. Of all these things I learned through
those who came to consult the oracle of Isis, and much did I talk of
them with Noot.
Now of myself during these long years of quiet and preparation
for great events, I will say that ever my spirit grew in purity and
strength. I put the things of earth behind me, I grew nearer to the
Divine, and in the night time I communed with my soul which
seemed to have become a part of that which is above the world. The
Greek, Kallikrates, I saw continually, but no word passed between us
save such as had to do with matters of our faith and of the worship
of Isis in whose service he now stood high. Never did we
interchange a touch or a look of love. He was apart from me and I
from him. And yet always in my heart I feared this man, this
beautiful man, the warrior who had become a priest, for some
prescience told me that he would bring disaster on my head, or I
should bring it upon his, I knew not which.
So there we sat in the sanctuary, Noot the wise and aged, who
yet never seemed to change, Kallikrates the priest, and I, and alone
or together gave counsel to kings and captains, or uttered oracles.
Clear seemed our sky and free from trouble, yet on the far horizon in
my spirit I discerned the tempest clouds arising, the terrible clouds
in which the lightnings played like the swords of Destiny that in a
day to come were doomed to overwhelm and pierce us through.
Nectanebes the second, the Pharaoh, came to his palace at
Memphis to gather troops from Upper Egypt and made great
offerings to the gods, seeking their favour in the coming war. Now I
saw him for the first time, a gray-haired, fat, heavy-jowled man,
bald-headed, large-nosed, with great eyes like to those of an ox.
Such was Nectanebes, the magician, the consorter with familiar
spirits, named the Destroyer, a title which the gods who hated him
must have given him in irony since himself he was doomed to be
destroyed. But one good thing can I say of this Nectanebes, that he
was a lover of the arts and raised glorious buildings to the gods.
Learning that I, the high-priestess, had dwelt at Philæ, he came to
consult me as to the beautiful temple with the Hathor-headed
columns which he built there and through my counsel it was made
perfect, for I drew its plans, or at least those of its adornments.
Holly tells me that even as a ruin, although so small, there is no
lovelier building in all Egypt.
Now this Pharaoh thought me a Greek and did not know that I
was Arab and the daughter of him of Ozal in Yaman, whom his
father, the first Nectanebes, had brought to his death because once
long ago I had been refused as a wife to himself or to this son of his
who now had succeeded him. Of these things doubtless he
remembered little or nothing, since that was one of the smallest of
Egypt’s wars. But I, I remembered and swore that in payment for
my father’s blood I would bring his accursed House to ruin. Always
also I received him veiled since I did not desire that he should look
upon my beauty and inquire concerning my history; therefore, as a
prophetess had a right to do, I received the Pharaoh veiled.
Often he came to visit me because he had learned that I was a
mistress of Magic and he who practised magic much hoped that I
would teach him secrets he did not know, and show him how to lay
spells upon his enemies. This indeed I did, but the secrets that I
taught him were evil and the spells were spears that when he threw
them would fall back upon his head.
So the scene was set, and at length came the summons to
begin the play with the watching world for audience.
A writing sealed with Pharaoh’s seal was brought to the temple
of Isis, commanding Noot the high-priest, and me, Ayesha, who now
was named Oracle-of-Isis, and the Greek Kallikrates, Chief of the
Ceremonies, whose office it was to assist me in my divinations, to
attend the court of Pharaoh and there declare to him the future of
the war as it should be revealed to us by the great goddess whom
we served. At first we refused to go, whereon there came another
message which said that if we continued to refuse, we should be
brought. The Pharaoh wished to offer no affront to Isis, the
messenger declared, but the matter was urgent, as great things
hung upon the revelations which we alone could make, and some of
the kings and generals who were gathered in the temple as allies of
Nectanebes, being the worshippers of other gods, could not set foot
in the holy shrine of Isis.
Then, there being no help for it, we answered that we would
come that very night at the rising of the moon.
Hastily consulting together we planned the words of an oracle,
double-edged words that yet prophesied good to Nectanebes and
encouraged him to war; for thus we believed we should most quickly
bring about his downfall.
Yet as those words were never spoken I will not write them
down.
CHAPTER VI
The Divination
Accompanied by the priests and priestesses of Isis clad in their robes
and chanting the holy songs, I was borne veiled to the palace of the
Pharaoh in a litter, with its curtains drawn. On my right hand walked
Noot the high-priest, white-bearded, venerable; and on my left the
Greek Kallikrates, Master of the Rites.
Thus we came to the palace of which the outer courts were
filled with Grecian soldiers of the guard, some of whom in past years
Kallikrates had once commanded, although as a shaven priest of
Isis, disguised in his white robes, they knew him no more. These
men stared at us, ready to mock and yet afraid, as did Phœnicians,
Sidonians, men of Cyprus, and others who were gathered in the
courts as though awaiting some great event.
In an outer hall a captain of the guard bade our escort of priests
and priestesses to await our return, but we three, that is I, Ayesha,
Noot, and Kallikrates, were summoned to the small banqueting
chamber where Nectanebes with a few of the most highly placed of
his guests sat at their feast. Among these were the King of Sidon,
two more kings from Cyprus, three Grecian generals, some great
nobles of Egypt, and others. Also certain royal ladies were present,
and among them one who instantly drew my eyes to her. She was
younger than I—perchance there may have been ten years between
us, tall, slender, and lovely in her dark fashion, with a strong, quiet
face and large brooding eyes, soft as a deer’s and rather blue than
black in colour.
Suddenly as we entered I, who note all, saw these eyes grow
frightened like to those of one who sees some spirit returned from
the halls of Death; saw also the rich-hued face turn pale, then grow
red again as the blood flowed back; saw the breast heave beneath
the jewelled robes, so sharply that a flower fell from them, and the
lips of coral part as though to utter some remembered name.
Wondering what had thus disturbed this beauteous royalty since
I, being veiled, it could not have been the vision of myself, I glanced
round and perceived that Kallikrates, who was on my left, but a little
behind me, had become pale as a dead man and stood like one
frozen into stone.
“Who is that royal woman?” I whispered to Noot through my
veil, for royal I knew her to be by the Uræus circlet she wore upon
her raven hair.
“Pharaoh’s daughter, Amenartas,” he whispered back, “whom
the Greeks call The Maiden because she will take no man in
marriage.”
Then I remembered a certain confession that once I had heard
sitting on the throne of the goddess Isis at Philæ, of how the
penitent had loved a girl of the royal House of Egypt, and for her
sake killed his own dear brother; remembered also that this penitent
was none other than the priest Kallikrates. Now I understood all, and
though Kallikrates was naught to me save a fellow servant of the
goddess, I hated that Amenartas and became aware that between
her and me there was war unending, though how and why I knew
not.
Next I looked at a man clad in kingly robes who sat on
Pharaoh’s right. He was a large man of about five and forty years of
age with dark, handsome face and shifting eyes; one with a jovial
aspect which yet I felt to be but a mask covering a heart full of evil
schemes. From his purple robe sewn with pearls and the style of his
attire and headdress I guessed that this must be Tenes the
Phœnician, King of the city of Sidon that was reported the wealthiest
in the world, which city, having revolted, had joined Egypt in its war
against the Persians. Instantly I weighed that man in the balance of
my mind and wrote him down as an ambitious rogue who was also a
coward and, as I judged from the many charms he wore, full of
superstition.
The others I had no time to study for at once the Pharaoh
began to speak.
“Greeting, Prophetess,” he said, rising from his chair and bowing
to us, or rather to me, “Greeting, High-priest of Isis, Queen of
Heaven, Mistress of the World; greeting also, Priest, Master of the
Rites of Isis. Pharaoh thanks you all for thus promptly answering to
his summons, since this night Egypt needs your wisdom more
perchance than ever before in all the ages of its history.”
“Be pleased, O Pharaoh, to set out what you desire of us, the
servants of the eternal goddess,” said Noot.
“This, High-priest: that you should declare the future to us.
Hearken! As you know, the great war has begun. The mighty Tenes
here, King of Sidon, my ally, by the help of the Greeks I sent him,
has defeated the Persians and against these Cyprus also is in revolt.
But now Artaxerxes Ochus has seized the throne of Persia, having
murdered all who stood between it and him, with the help of Bagoas
the eunuch, his counsellor and general. He has raised a countless
host and is pouring down upon Sidon and upon Egypt. Therefore we
would learn how the war shall go and to what gods we must
sacrifice to secure the victory.”
“O Pharaoh,” answered Noot, “in bygone years when your father
sat upon the throne and I was the Kherheb, yes, the first magician
of Egypt, he asked me such questions as these, and having prayed
to my goddess, I answered him in the words that she commanded.
None heard those words save your father himself, for he and I were
alone together. Yet there was that in them which made him wroth so
that he sought to kill me, and to save my life I fled out of Egypt,
going whither the goddess led me. Afterward I was called back to
Egypt where once more I am high-priest of Isis though the office of
Kherheb is filled by another. How know I, Pharaoh, if I obey you as I
obeyed your father, and again the goddess should utter prophecies
which are not pleasing to the ears of kings, that once more my life
may not be sought in payment?”
“I swear, High-priest,” answered Nectanebes eagerly, “that
whatever may be revealed by the goddess, you shall take no harm. I
swear it by the name and throne of the holy Isis, to whom I will
make great gifts, and all this company are witnesses of the oath. If
it be broken, may the curse of Isis and of all the gods of Egypt fall
upon the head of me and mine. Draw nigh now that I may touch you
with my sceptre, thereby forgiving all that you have said or shall say
against me or my House, and restoring to you your office of Kherheb
of Egypt, whereof my father, who to-day is gathered in Osiris,
robbed you.”
So Noot drew near and Pharaoh touched him with his sceptre, a
cedar wand surmounted with a little golden image of Horus, which
he always carried because of his throne-name which signified
“Horus-of-Gold.” Moreover, he re-created him Kherheb and in token
of it set upon his shoulders the gold chain from his own neck, and
swore to him his place and power for life and the gift of an alabaster
coffin wherein to lie after life was done. This sarcophagus, however,
Noot refused, saying darkly that it was fated that he should sleep his
last sleep far away from Egypt. Then he, Noot, drew back and as he
went I saw Pharaoh’s daughter rise and whisper awhile in her
father’s ear. He listened and nodded. Then he said,
“Come hither, priest who is named ‘Lover-of-Isis’ and Master of
her rites, the royal Lady of Egypt says to me that in bygone days
when she was scarce a woman, she thinks that before you were a
priest, you held some command amongst the Greeks of my guard,
as from your stature and bearing I can well believe. She says also
that if her memory serves her, you slew some man in a quarrel and
for this reason fled away and sought refuge with Isis. If such things
happened I have forgotten them, nor do I ask concerning them. Let
them lie. Yet, lest you should be afraid that old tales may be told
against you or vengeance wrought upon you, come hither also and
receive pardon for the past, and protection and advancement for the
future and with these a gift from Pharaoh.”
Now I marvelled at this lady’s foresight and cunning which
showed her how to take advantage of Pharaoh’s mood and
safeguard one who once had loved her, all of which told me that she
must be a wise woman as well as beauteous. Also it told me that the
worship of this man had been pleasing to her. Then Kallikrates drew
near and was touched with the sceptre. Moreover, Pharaoh spoke to
him in like words that he had spoken to Noot, pardoning him all and
promising him much. Moreover, in token of his favour he gave him a
gold cup of Grecian workmanship having two handles, that was
chased about with the story of the loves of Aphrodite and Adonis,
and bordered with a wreath of those anemones which were fabled to
have sprung from his blood. This glorious, flower-like cup from
which the guests, when we entered, were pledging themselves in
wine of Cyprus, Pharaoh lifted from the board and sent to
Kallikrates, a great gift which made it clear to me how deeply he
desired to propitiate the goddess in the persons of her servants.
Lastly the private scribe was commanded to write down these
decrees that he had spoken, which he did forthwith, sealing them
with Pharaoh’s seal and giving one copy to Noot whilst keeping the
other to be filed among the records.
Thus Noot and Kallikrates were protected from all things, but to
me, the Prophetess, nothing was said, as I thought for two reasons,
first because I was known to Pharaoh, who as I have told, had often
consulted me upon matters of magic, and secondly because as the
“voice of the goddess” I was holy and above reward or punishment
at the hands of man. Thus I thought, with how much truth shall be
seen.
The gifts were received, the papyrus had been hidden away in
the robe of Noot, and there was silence in the chamber. To me,
Ayesha, this heavy silence was full of omen. My soul, made keen and
fine with ceaseless contemplation of things that are above the earth,
in that silence seemed to hear the breath of the watching gods of
Egypt. To me it was as though they had gathered there to listen to
the fate of this their ancient home on earth. Yes, I felt them about
me; or at the least I felt a spirit stirring.
The company at the table drank no more wine and ceased from
speech. They sat still staring in front of them and notwithstanding
the glitter of the ornaments that proclaimed their royalty or rule, to
me they were as dead men in a tomb. Only the Princess of Egypt,
Amenartas, seemed to be alive and outside the circle of this doom,
for I noted that her splendid eyes sought the face, the perfect,
carven face of the priest Kallikrates and that though he stood with
folded arms and gaze fixed upon the ground, he knew it, for now
and again covertly he glanced back at her.
At length one of those guests could bear no more, and spoke.
He was a close-lipped, war-worn Grecian general who afterward I
learned was named Kleinios of Cos, the commander of Pharaoh’s
mercenary forces.
“By Zeus!” he cried, “are we men or are we stones, or are we
shades in Hades? Let these diviners divine and have done, for I
would get me to my wine again.”
“Aye,” broke in Tenes, King of Sidon. “Bid them divine, Pharaoh,
since we have much to agree upon ere I sail at dawn.”
Then all the company cried, “Divine! Divine!” save Amenartas
only, who searched the face of Kallikrates with her eyes, as though
she would learn what lay behind its cold and priestly mask.
“So be it,” said Noot, “but first I pray Pharaoh to bid all mean
men depart.”
Pharaoh waved his sceptre and the butlers and attendants
bowed and went. Then Noot motioned to Kallikrates, who thereon
shook the sistrum that he bore and, in his rich, low voice, uttered a
chant to the goddess, that which was used to summon her
presence.
He ended his chant and Noot began to pray.
“Hear me, thy prophet, O thou who wast and art and shalt be,
thou in whose bosom is locked all the wisdom of heaven and earth,”
he prayed. “These kings and great ones desire knowledge, declare it
unto them according to thy will. They desire truth—let them learn
the truth in such fashion as thou shalt decree.”
Then he was silent. None spoke, yet it seemed that a command
came to the three of us, for suddenly Noot looked at the priest
Kallikrates, a very strange look. Next the priest Kallikrates, rising
from his knees, laid down the sistrum and taking the beautiful cup
that Pharaoh had given him, went to the table and washed it with
pure water from a silver ewer, then filled it to the brim from the
ewer and brought it to me, Ayesha. Now I knew that I was
commanded to gaze into that cup and to say what things I saw.
So I set it on the ground in front of me and kneeling, threw my
veil over it and gazed into the water in the shallow golden cup.
For a little while I saw nothing, till presently a face formed in
the water, the face of the royal lady, Amenartas, which stared up at
me out of the cup. Yes, it stared hard and seemed to threaten me,
for in its eyes were hate and vengeance. Then another face came
and covered it, the face of Kallikrates the priest, and in its eyes were
trouble and desire.
Now I knew that the goddess Isis, or perchance another, she of
the Greeks, spoke to me of matters that had to do with myself and
not with the fate of Egypt. In my heart I prayed to the Queen of
Heaven to rid me of these visions, though to give me others I did
not pray her, since it was my design to speak certain politic words
which we had prepared.
Yet other visions came unsought, for some spirit possessed me,
a spirit of truth and destiny. They were many and all of them
terrible. I saw battlefields; I saw men fall in thousands, I saw cities
in flames. I saw that false-eyed king, Tenes, dead. I saw the
General, Kleinios of Cos, also dead, lying on a heap of Grecian slain.
I saw the Pharaoh Nectanebes flying up Nile upon a boat—I knew it
was up Nile because the current rippled against the prow of his ship,
I saw him seized by black savages and throttled with a rope till his
tongue hung out and the great round eyes started from his head. I
saw the temples of Egypt burning and a fierce-faced, drunken king
hacking at the statues of the gods with a Persian sword and
butchering the priests upon the altar. Then I saw no more but a
voice called in my ears,
“Death to Egypt! Death and desolation! Death to her king, death
to her priests, death to her gods! Finished, finished, all is finished!”
I cast the bowl from me. It overset but lo! there flowed from it
not water but blood, or dark-hued wine, staining the white marble of
the pavement. I stared at it! All stared at this god-sent horror!
“A trick!” cried the Princess Amenartas. “She has coloured the
water behind the shelter of her veil.”
The others too, especially the Greeks, took up the cry, echoing,
“A trick, a brazen trick!”
Only I noted that Pharaoh was silent, Pharaoh who knew that
Ayesha, named Isis-come-to-Earth, did not deal in tricks; Pharaoh
who himself practised magic and had seen such omens sent by Set.
Lo! Pharaoh looked afraid and spoke no word, only glared with his
great eyes at the stain upon the marble.
“What answer did the goddess give to your prayer, Prophetess,”
asked Amenartas, sneering at me.
“This answer, royal Lady of Egypt,” and I pointed to the marble,
“the answer of blood.”
“Blood! Whose blood? That of the Persians?”
“Nay, Lady, that of many who sit at this feast and who ere long
shall sit at the table of Osiris, and of thousands who cling to them.
Yet be comforted, Lady, not your blood. I think that you have much
mischief to work ere you sit also at the table of Osiris, or mayhap at
that of Set,” I added, giving thrust for thrust.
“Declare then their names, Seeress.”
“Nay, I declare them not. Go, seek them for yourself, Lady, or
let Pharaoh your father seek, for is he not a magician? though what
god gives him vision I do not know. You name me cheat, or rather
you name the goddess cheat. Therefore the goddess is dumb and
her prophetess is dumb.”
“Aye, I name you cheat,” she cried, who in her heart was mad
with fear, “and cheat you are. Now let this temple hag who hides her
hideousness behind a silken screen unveil that we may see her as
she is, and let her be searched and the vase of dye be taken from
her bosom or her robes.”
“Aye, let her be searched,” shouted the guests who were also
afraid.
“No need to search, high lords,” I said in a quavering voice, as
though I too were overcome with fear. “I will obey the Princess. I
will unveil, yet I beseech you all, make not a mock of me when you
see me as I am. Once I was perchance as fair as that royal Lady
who commands, but years of abstinence and the sleepless search for
wisdom mar the features and wither the frame. Moreover, time
touches the locks, such of them as remain to me, since these too
grow thin with age. Yet I will unveil and the vase of precious dye
shall be the prize of him who first can snatch it from my bosom or
my robe.”
“Aye,” said one of them, it was the king Tenes, “and in payment
for her trick we will make her drink what remains of it to give colour
to her poor old carcase.”
“Aye,” I answered, “and I will drink what remains of it for I think
the stuff is harmless. Oh! be not angry because a poor conjurer
plays her tricks.”
Now Noot stared at me as though he were about to speak. Then
his face changed like to that of a man who of a sudden receives a
command that others cannot hear. He let fall his eyes, remaining
silent, and I, watching, knew that it was the will of the goddess, or
at least Noot’s will, that I should unveil.
I glanced at the priest Kallikrates but he stood still, looking like
Apollo’s self frozen into stone.
During this play I had loosened the fastenings of my veil and
hood and now of a sudden I cast them from me, revealing myself
clad as Isis, that is in little save a transparent, clinging robe fastened
about my middle. On my breast, hanging from a chain of pearls,
were her holy symbols carved in gems and gold, and on my head
her vulture cap beneath which my tresses hung almost to my feet,
having the golden feathers of the cap adorned with sapphires and
with rubies and the uræus rising from it fashioned of glittering
diamonds.
Aye, I unveiled and stood before them, my arms folded upon
the jewelled girdle beneath my breast.
“Behold! Kings and Lords,” I said, “the temple hag stands before
you in such poor shape as it has pleased the gods to fashion her.
Now let him who can see it, come, take the vase that hides this
unveiled trickster’s dye.”
For a moment there was silence while those brutal men
devoured my white loveliness with their eyes, taking count of every
beauty of my perfect face and form. Amenartas stared at me and
her ruddy cheeks went pale; yes, even the coral faded from her rich
lips. Then from between those lips there burst these words:
“This is not a woman! This is the very goddess. Beware of her,
ye men, for she is terrible.”
“Nay, nay,” I answered humbly, “I am but a poor mortal, not
even royal like to yourself, Lady—but a poor mortal with some wits
and wisdom, though perchance Isis for a while to your sight has
touched me with her splendour. Come, take the vase ere I veil
myself again.”
Then those men went mad, all save Pharaoh, who sat brooding.
“Goddess or woman,” they cried, “give her to us who
henceforward can never look upon the beauty of another.”
King Tenes rose, his coarse face afire and his shifting eyes fixed
upon me greedily.
“By Baal and by Ashtoreth!” he cried, “goddess or woman, never
have I seen such an one as this prophetess of Isis. Hearken,
Pharaoh, before the feast we disputed together concerning a great
sum of gold and in the end it was confessed by you that it was due
to me in aid of my costs of war although, so you said, it could not be
found in Egypt save by raiding the rich treasury of Isis. Perchance
the goddess learned of this design of yours and by way of answer
sent us an evil oracle. I know not, but this I do know, that she sent
you also a means to pay the debt without cost to yourself or the
robbing of her sacred treasury. Give me this fair priestess to comfort
me with her wisdom and otherwise”—here the company laughed
coarsely—“and I will talk no more of the matter of that gold.”
Pharaoh listened without raising his head, then looked on me
with rolling eyes and answered:
“Which would anger the goddess most, King Tenes—to lose her
gold or her prophetess?”
“The former as I think, Pharaoh, seeing that gold is scarce, and
prophetesses—true or false—are many. Give her to me, I say.”
“I cannot for my oath’s sake, King Tenes.”
“You swore an oath to yonder high-priest and to yonder man,
who looks like a Grecian god clad in a priest’s robe and is called
Master-of-the-Rites, but to this lady you swore none.”
“I swore the oath to Isis, King Tenes, and if I break it doubtless
she will be avenged upon me. Go your way; the gold shall follow you
to the last ounce, but the prophetess is not mine to give.”
Now Tenes stared at me again and I, who hated him with all my
soul, gave him back his stare with interest, though this did but seem
to inflame him the more. Then he turned on Pharaoh furiously and
answered in a cold voice,
“Hear me, Pharaoh. It is but a small matter, yet my mind is set
upon this woman who knows the heart of the gods and can pour
their wisdom into my ears. Therefore make your choice:
“In Sidon there are two factions of almost equal strength. One
of them says ‘Make an alliance with Egypt and fight the Persian
Ochus whom already you have defeated once.’ The other says ‘Make
an alliance with Ochus and as reward in a day to come sit on
Pharaoh’s throne!’ I have taken the first counsel as you know. Yet it
is not too late to change that counsel for a second which perchance
would prove the wiser, if there be aught in yonder divination,” and
he pointed to the blood-stain upon the marble floor. Then he went
on:
“Moreover, I have my captains about me at this board and those
that serve me wait without with all my fleet, and therefore should it
be changed I need not fear to tell you so and to your face. So I say
to you that if you will not please me in this small matter, presently
my ambassadors go forth to Susa with a message for the ear of
Ochus to which it would rejoice you to listen, seeing that without the
strong aid of Sidon and her fleets Egypt cannot conquer in this war.”
Thus Tenes spoke and laid his hand upon the pommel of his
short Phœnician sword.
Now the face of Pharaoh, bearded thus in his own city and at
his own board, grew red with rage and I saw that he was about to
answer this outland king, defying him as many of the great
monarchs who filled his throne before him would have done. But ere
he could speak his royal daughter Amenartas whispered in his ear
and although I could not hear her words, I read their purport in her
face. They were—“Tenes speaks truth. Without Sidon you cannot
stand against the Persians and Egypt is lost. Let the woman go. Isis,
understanding, will forgive, who otherwise must see the Persian Holy
Fire burning on her altars.”
Pharaoh heard and the anger written in his eyes was changed to
trouble. Rolling them in his fashion he looked on Noot and said to
him as one who asks a question,
“I swore an oath to you, Kherheb, and to yonder priest, but to
the prophetess I swore no oath and perchance Egypt’s fate hangs
upon this business.”
The old high-priest paused awhile like a man who awaits a
message. If so, it seemed to come, for presently he answered in a
quiet voice,
“Pharaoh is right; Egypt’s fate hangs upon this business; also
Pharaoh’s fate; also that of King Tenes and many others. The only
fate which is not touched, whether it be finished in this way or in
that, is the fate of yonder seeress who is named Isis-come-to-Earth,
since the goddess will protect her own. Settle the matter as you will,
Pharaoh. Only settle it swiftly, because under our rule it is time that I
and my company who wait without should return to the temple to
make our nightly prayer and offerings to the goddess, the Queen of
all the earth, the Queen of Pharaoh and of Egypt; the Queen of the
King of Sidon, and in the end the Queen also of Artaxerxes Ochus,
the Persian, as one day surely he shall learn.”
Thus spoke Noot unconcernedly and hearing him, I laughed, for
now I was sure that I had nothing to fear from Tenes or from any
other man upon the earth. Therefore I laughed, which that company
thought strange in one who was about to be borne away a slave,
and bade Kallikrates give me my veil and hood, also the cloak that I
had thrown off when I entered the banqueting hall.
He obeyed, and while he was assisting me to cover up my
beauty in the folds of that veil, I noted that alone among all the men
here present, this beauty did not seem to stir him at all. Had he
been clothing a marble or an ivory image of the goddess, as every
day it was his duty to do at sunrise, anointing it with perfumes and
garlanding it with flowers, he could not have been less moved. Or
perhaps so truly had the priest in him overcome the man that he
had learned to cloak all the feelings of a man. Or perhaps it was
because that royal Amenartas watched his every movement with her
eyes. I know not, but this I do know, that his calm angered me and
it came into my mind that were I not the head-priestess of Isis and
sworn to her, there should be a different tale to tell. Yes, even in
that moment of destiny this came into my mind, which shows that in
my soul I had not forgotten the meeting of our lips in yonder shrine
at Philæ. At least I have often thought so since, I, who have had
much time for thought.
“Priestess, you are mine,” cried King Tenes in triumph. “Make
ready to sail with me for Sidon within an hour.”
“Do you think that I am yours, King Tenes?” I asked in a musing
voice as I fastened the folds of my veil and arranged the hood. “If
so, I hold otherwise. I hold that I, Ayesha, a free-born lady of the
ancient Arab blood, am not the slave of any Phœnician who for a
little while chances to be a king, but of her who is the Queen of
kings, Isis the Mother. Nay, Tenes, I am more, I am Isis herself, Isis-
come-to-Earth. It seems that go with you I must, since such is the
will of the goddess, but, Phœnician, take heed. Should you dare to
befoul me even with a touch, I tell you that I have strength at my
command and that ere long Sidon shall lack a king and Set shall gain
a subject. For your own sake therefore and for that of Sidon, think
again and let me be!”
Now the great jaws of Tenes fell and he stared at me open-
mouthed.
“Yet you shall go with me,” he muttered thickly, “and for the rest
Ashtoreth rules in Sidon, not Isis, for know that there are two
Queens of Heaven.”
“Aye, Tenes, a false queen and a true, and let the false beware
of the true.”
Then I turned to Nectanebes and said,
“Is it still your command, O Pharaoh, that I accompany this ally
of yours to Sidon? Bethink you ere you answer, since much hangs
upon your words.”
“Yea, Priestess, it must be so. I have spoken and my decree is
recorded. The fate of Egypt is more than that of any priestess and
doubtless King Tenes will treat you well. If not, you say that you
have strength to defend yourself against him.”
Now as I answered, I laughed lightly and the sound of my
laughter was like the tinkle of falling silver.
“So be it, Pharaoh. To me it is nothing; indeed I would see
Sidon, the glorious city, while she still is Sidon, home of merchants,
mistress of the seas. Still ere I go, shall I tell you something,
Pharaoh, of what was shewn to me in yonder bowl before its water
was turned to blood—by dye from that vase which none of you has
found? If I remember right, for as you who practise magic, know,
Pharaoh, such visions fade quickly like dreams at dawn—I say that if
I remember right, it had to do with the fate of a great king. Have
you ever seen a king, O Pharaoh, when in place of the chain of
royalty a collar of rope is set about his throat and drawn hard till the
tongue is thrust from the royal mouth and the royal eyes start from
their sockets? Nay? Then shall I draw his picture? Perchance in days
to come you would know it again?”
“Witch, accursed witch!” shouted Pharaoh. “Take her, Tenes, and
begone, though sooner would I nurture a viper in my bosom,” and
rising from the board, he turned and fled away.
Again I laughed as I answered,
“I must go, but it seems that Pharaoh has gone first. Royal
Amenartas, watch the good god, your father, for I think that he is
too superstitious and that which men believe fulfils itself upon them.”
Then I went to Noot and spoke with him—few words for already
the guards were advancing upon me.
“Fear nothing, Daughter,” he said, “you are safe.”
“I know that I am safe, Master, yet be ready to come to my aid
when I call, as my spirit tells me that call I shall.”
He bent his head and the guards came up. As I went I glanced
at the priest Kallikrates, who taking no note of me or of my fate, still
stood staring at the royal Amenartas like a statue cut in stone, while
she stared back at him.
CHAPTER VII
The Quelling of the Storm
They set me on board a great ship, on the prow of which were
images of certain gods of the Phœnicians, called by the Greeks
Pataeci, not unlike to that which the Egyptians worshipped by the
name of Bes, before which images burned fire. There was a royal
cabin in that ship which was given to me, and with it splendid robes
and furnishings of gold for my table.
At dawn we cast off from the quay of the white-walled city while
thousands of the worshippers of Isis who learned that I was being
taken from them, stood upon the quay and wailed, crying that the
Mouth-of-Isis was sent away to slavery and that where her “Mouth”
went, there the goddess would follow, leaving vengeance to fall
upon their heads. For that the head-priestess of Isis should be given
into the hands of barbarians and their foreign gods was such a crime
as had not been known in Egypt.
Therefore they wailed, prophesying evil, and I stood upon the
stern alone in my white robes, veiled, and hearkened to them, for
none dared to come near to me. Yes, I hearkened and blessed them
with my hands, whereat they knelt and wailed the more.
When at last we had passed down the Nile and were out upon
the great sea, sailing swiftly for Sidon over quiet waters, I, Ayesha,
having taken counsel of the goddess and of my woman’s craft, sent
for King Tenes, who was also on board the ship, and received him in
his own cabin that had been given up to me.
For my heart was black with rage against him, and against
Nectanebes, Pharaoh of Egypt, who had betrayed me, and in my
heart I swore that I would destroy them both. Yes, there I, the
captive, sat and received the captor king in his own cabin, purposing
his doom, though how this was to be accomplished as yet I did not
know.
“O King,” I said, “I, your slave who, when not a slave, was high-
priestess of Isis in Egypt and her seeress, into whose breast the
goddess poured her wisdom and her secrets, as indeed still she
does, would speak with you, and since I could not come to you
among so many men, have prayed your Majesty to come to me.
What would you do with me, King Tenes, since it has pleased you to
force Pharaoh to give me into your keeping? Is it an oracle that you
desire concerning your fate or that of your country in the war? If so,
I will——”
“Nay, Priestess,” he broke in hurriedly, “of your oracles I and
others have had enough. They are bitter bread for daily food. Keep
them, I pray you, to nurture your own soul.”
“What would you of me then, King Tenes, that you have been at
such pains to steal me away from Egypt, even threatening Pharaoh
to break your solemn pact with him if he did not give me into your
hands, me, the snared bird, who by chance was left out of his oath
to the high-priest and Isis’s officer, the Greek.”
“Lady Ayesha,” blurted out Tenes, “that I have learned to be by
birth, daughter of Yarab, once ruler of Ozal, upon whom, with the
Egyptians, I made war in the past and brought to his death, because
of you, Lady, tell me, you who are wise, what would any man of you
who had beheld your beauty as I saw it some nights gone?”
“Man, being man, that is, a ravening beast fashioned like a god
in shape but not in soul, would make me his prey, Tenes. Such at
least was the desire of the first Nectanebes whom you aided with
the ships of Sidon to destroy my father, and of many since his time.”
“Good. Well, I who am a man and something more, being not a
god indeed, but a great king, would make you my prey, as you say,
for to tell truth, having once looked on you I seek no other woman
in the whole world.”
Now I threw back my veil and studied him with my eyes.
“So you would take me for your queen, Tenes? Indeed I
guessed as much. But what would your other queen, for doubtless
you have one, say to this, O King?”
“My queen!” he said in an astonished voice, “my queen?”
“Surely, Tenes, you would scarcely dare to proffer less than
queenship to such a one as I?”
“May be not. Well, let us say that I would make you my queen,
since in Sidon it is not difficult to be rid of others of whom one may
be weary; that is, it is not difficult to a king who also is high-priest of
Baal and of Ashtoreth. Yes, yes, I am sure that I would make you my
queen. I will offer it to you in writing if you desire.”
“Aye, I do desire it, King, and that there may be no faults or
traps in it, I myself will draw up the writing for you to sign. Only I
doubt much whether I shall accept the offer if it is made.”
“Why not, Lady? Is it a small thing to be Queen of Sidon?”
“For Ayesha, daughter of Yarab, high-priestess and prophetess
of Isis, the wisest and most beauteous woman in the world, one who
has never turned to look on man, it is a very small thing indeed,
King Tenes. It is so small a thing that I will not deign to accept that
proffered crown of yours, unless——”
“Unless what, Lady?”
“Unless it is made larger, King, so large and wide that she who
wears it holds rule over all the earth.”
“By Baal, Ashtoreth, and Moloch, all three of them, what mean
you, Woman?”
“What I say, Man. I mean that when you are monarch, not of
Sidon only, but of Egypt, Cyprus, Persia, and all the East, then
perchance I will marry you, unless my fancy changes, as it may do,
but certainly not before.”
“Surely you are mad,” he gasped. “How can I gather all these
diadems upon a single brow? It is impossible.”
“Aye, for you it is impossible, King Tenes, but for me it is
possible. I can gather them and set them on your brow and on my
own, I who have within me all the wisdom of the earth and much of
the strength of Heaven. Understand that if I desire it and you follow
my counsel, I can crown you emperor of the world, no less, but the
question is, do I desire it and will you follow my counsel?”
“Lady, I swear that you are mad, unless in truth you are a
goddess as they say in Egypt.”
“Perchance I am somewhat of a goddess, and being so, marvel
whether for any reward that can be given I shall debase myself by
taking such a one as you to husband, King Tenes. Now, first, look on
me well and answer whether you do indeed desire me and are ready
to win me through toil and danger, or whether you will let me be.
For know, Tenes, that though I seem to be your captive, you cannot
snare me or do me violence. Lay but a finger on me against my will,
and it shall be your death, since I have those to aid me whom you
cannot see. Now look—and answer.”
He looked, devouring me with his greedy eyes, then said,
“Of a truth I desire you more than anything on the earth, and
since I may not do so otherwise, for I perceive that you are too
strong for me, will take you at your own price. Yea, even if I must
wait for years, still I will take you. Now tell me, most beauteous and
most wise, what I must do, and swear to me that when I am king of
all things you will wed me.”
“Aye, Tenes, I swear that when you are king of all things I will
wed you,” I answered gently, laughing in my heart as I remembered
that the first and last of all things, the greatest of all things, is—
Death. “Hearken. You shall bring me to Sidon, not as a captive but
as a strange goddess who has come to aid you and your people, and
with honour shall you receive me in Sidon, causing your priests and
priestesses to offer me worship and incense.”
“And if so, what then?”
“Then, when I have studied your people and your preparations
for war, we will take counsel together and I will show you how you
may prevail. Tell me, Tenes, do you love Pharaoh Nectanebes?”
“Nay, Lady, I hate him who asks too much and gives too little,
as I hated his father before him. Still we sleep in the same bed and
prop up the same wall, and if one of us ceases to support the wall,
the Persians will push it down on both.”
“I understand. Yet even so it comes into my mind that
perchance you would have been safer had you been pushing at the
wall with the Persian Ochus and not holding it up with the Egyptian
Nectanebes.”
He glanced at me with his shifting eyes and answered,
“I have had that thought, as you know well, but having rebelled
against Ochus, defeated his satraps, and slain thousands of his
soldiers, or rather those of his father, if I climb the wall I might find
spears waiting for me on the farther side. Lady, it is too late.”
“Yes, King Tenes, perhaps it is too late; I will consider of the
matter in your interest and my own. But first send me papyrus and
writing tools that I may set down our pact. When you have approved
and signed it, then I will consider of this and other matters and not
before. For the while, farewell.”
He rose and went unwillingly enough and when I was alone in
the cabin I laughed in my heart. This fish had been easy to hook,
but he was a large fish and strong, and I must beware lest he pull
me into the deep sea where both might drown together. Moreover,
the man was hateful to me, more so even than that ox-eyed, heavy-
jowled Pharaoh, and his presence seemed to poison the air I
breathed. Yet if I entered into this pact with him doubtless I must
breathe it often, which vexed me who shrank from men and their
desires, and above all from this man. Yet he had done me wrong
and insult; he had helped the Egyptians to make war upon my
people and he had taken me as a slave, me, Ayesha, thinking to
make of me his woman, and cost what it might, I would pay him
back as I would pay back Nectanebes who sold me.
The papyrus was brought to me by a slave and on it I wrote
such a contract as I think was never signed by a king before. It was
brief and ran thus:—
“Ayesha, daughter of Yarab, high-priestess of Isis, prophetess of
Isis, known in Heaven and among her servants as Isis-come-to-
Earth, and Child of Wisdom, to Tenes, King of Sidon.
“When you, Tenes, are king not only of Sidon but of Egypt,
Cyprus, Persia, and the East, as I can make you, if you obey me in
all things, then I, Ayesha, vow myself to you as your sole wife and
queen. But if, ere this dignity is mine and yours, you dare even to
touch my robe, then in the name of Isis and speaking with the voice
of Isis, I, Ayesha, vow to you shame and death in the world and
after it all the torments of hell and the jaws of the Devourer that
await the judgment of Thoth on perjured souls beyond the Sun.
“Accepted and sealed by Ayesha, daughter of Yarab and by
Tenes, King of Sidon.”
Having copied this writing, I sent it to Tenes by the slave that
he might study it. Awhile later he asked audience of me, and
entering, said in a thick voice that only a madman would set his seal
to such words.
I looked at him and answered that it was nothing to me
whether he sealed or did not seal them; indeed that considering all,
I should be better pleased if he let the bargain be.
He stared at me and rage took hold of him who was inflamed
with wine.
“Who are you,” he said, “that dare to talk thus to Tenes the
King? You are but a woman clad in the robes of a priestess who
pretend to powers you have not. Why should I not take you and
have done?”
Now I mocked him, answering,
“Because I think you love to sit upon a throne better than to lie
in a grave, Tenes, even in a king’s coffin. Still, as you desire to know
more particularly, I will put your question to the goddess, who is not
far from me even on this ship, and to-morrow when the sun is up I
will pass on her words to you—that is, if you live to look upon to-
morrow’s sun, King Tenes,” I added, staring him in the eyes.
These words seemed to sober him, for he turned pale and left
the cabin, making a sign to avert the evil eye, but as I noted, taking
the writing with him. Yet me he left perplexed and afraid, for my
heart was not so bold as my mouth!
Now that night, whether by chance or by the will of Heaven, a
great tempest sprang up suddenly. The captain of the trireme, a
Greek or a half-Greek of Naukratis, Philo by name, whom now upon
this ship I met for the first time, came himself to warn me, and to
make sure that all was fast in my cabin. He was a quick-brained
man, very active in his body and pleasant-faced, with a brown,
pointed beard, who had seen some five and thirty years upon the
earth. I had made inquiries concerning him from a certain slave who
attended me, and was told that although he pretended to timidity,
this Philo was in truth a great warrior and one of the best handlers
of a bow upon the mouths of Nile, since that which he aimed at he
always hit, even if it were a fowl in flight. Moreover, he was a very
good seaman and, it was said, faithful to those he served and a
worshipper of the gods.
“If so,” I answered to that old slave, “how comes it that this
Philo, instead of a humble captain, is not the first general or admiral
among the Greeks, as a man of such quality should be?”
“Because, divine Lady, of certain faults,” answered the slave,
“such faults as have made of me what I am instead of the Count of
a Nome upon the Nile as I should have been. This Philo has always
thought more of the welfare of others than of his own, which is a
very evil weakness; also he has loved women too much, which is a
worse.”
“Vile sins indeed,” I said, “more particularly the second. The
wise always think of themselves first, and the holy never love more
than one woman, and her not too much, which perhaps is why the
wise and the holy are so hateful and so dull. Bring this Philo to me;
he is one whom I should wish to know.”
In the end Philo came, though whether because my message
had reached him, or because of the advancing storm, I am not
certain. At least he came, and as he bowed before me, made a
certain secret sign whereby I knew that he was a worshipper of Isis
and one of high degree, though not of the highest, since when I
tried him with that sign he could not answer. Still his rank in our
great company was enough, and thenceforward we spoke to each
other under the seal of the goddess, or as our phrase went in those
days “within the shadow of her wings,” as brother and sister might,
or rather as mother and son.
That is, we did this after I had proved him further and brought
to his mind the fate of those who betray the goddess and her
ministers upon earth.
This Philo told me in few words, that although the trireme was
Egyptian and named Hapi after the god of Nile, for this voyage she
was under charter to Tenes and for the most part manned with
Sidonians, also with low fellows from Cyprus and the coast-ports.
Welcome to our website – the perfect destination for book lovers and
knowledge seekers. We believe that every book holds a new world,
offering opportunities for learning, discovery, and personal growth.
That’s why we are dedicated to bringing you a diverse collection of
books, ranging from classic literature and specialized publications to
self-development guides and children's books.
More than just a book-buying platform, we strive to be a bridge
connecting you with timeless cultural and intellectual values. With an
elegant, user-friendly interface and a smart search system, you can
quickly find the books that best suit your interests. Additionally,
our special promotions and home delivery services help you save time
and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
Join us on a journey of knowledge exploration, passion nurturing, and
personal growth every day!
ebookbell.com

More Related Content

PDF
Analyses In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise Editor
PDF
Social Security Programs And Retirement Around The World Reforms And Retireme...
PDF
Social Security Programs And Retirement Around The World Working Longer Court...
PDF
Political Arithmetic Simon Kuznets And The Empirical Tradition In Economics R...
PDF
Reforming The Welfare State Recovery And Beyond In Sweden Richard B Freeman E...
PDF
Perspectives On The Economics Of Aging David A Wise Editor
PDF
Corruption and Reform Lessons from America s Economic History Edward L. Glaeser
PDF
Perspectives on the Economics of Aging 1st Edition David A. Wise
Analyses In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise Editor
Social Security Programs And Retirement Around The World Reforms And Retireme...
Social Security Programs And Retirement Around The World Working Longer Court...
Political Arithmetic Simon Kuznets And The Empirical Tradition In Economics R...
Reforming The Welfare State Recovery And Beyond In Sweden Richard B Freeman E...
Perspectives On The Economics Of Aging David A Wise Editor
Corruption and Reform Lessons from America s Economic History Edward L. Glaeser
Perspectives on the Economics of Aging 1st Edition David A. Wise

Similar to Social Security Policy In A Changing Environment Jeffrey R Brown Editor Jeffrey B Liebman Editor David A Wise Editor (20)

PDF
Research Findings In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise Editor
PDF
Demography And The Economy John B Shoven Editor
PDF
Corruption and Reform Lessons from America s Economic History Edward L. Glaeser
PDF
Growth And Productivity In East Asia Takatoshi Ito Editor Andrew K Rose Editor
PDF
Corruption and Reform Lessons from America s Economic History Edward L. Glaeser
PDF
Corruption and Reform Lessons from America s Economic History Edward L. Glaeser
PDF
Investigations In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise
PDF
Investigations In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise
PDF
Economics Of Meanstested Transfer Programs In The United States Volume Ii Rob...
PDF
Science And Engineering Careers In The United States An Analysis Of Markets A...
PDF
The Economic Consequences Of Demographic Change In East Asia Takatoshi Ito Ed...
PDF
Human Capital In History The American Record Leah Platt Boustan Editor Carola...
PDF
Economic Regulation And Its Reform What Have We Learned Nancy L Rose Editor
PDF
Measuring Wealth And Financial Intermediation And Their Links To The Real Eco...
PDF
The Changing Frontier Rethinking Science And Innovation Policy Adam B Jaffe E...
PDF
Measuring Capital In The New Economy Carol Corrado Editor John Haltiwanger Ed...
PDF
Economics Of Meanstested Transfer Programs In The United States Volume I Robe...
PDF
Developments In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise Editor
PDF
Nber Macroeconomics Annual 2005 1st Edition Mark Gertler Kenneth Rogoff
PDF
Controlling Crime Strategies And Tradeoffs Philip J Cook Editor Jens Ludwig E...
Research Findings In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise Editor
Demography And The Economy John B Shoven Editor
Corruption and Reform Lessons from America s Economic History Edward L. Glaeser
Growth And Productivity In East Asia Takatoshi Ito Editor Andrew K Rose Editor
Corruption and Reform Lessons from America s Economic History Edward L. Glaeser
Corruption and Reform Lessons from America s Economic History Edward L. Glaeser
Investigations In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise
Investigations In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise
Economics Of Meanstested Transfer Programs In The United States Volume Ii Rob...
Science And Engineering Careers In The United States An Analysis Of Markets A...
The Economic Consequences Of Demographic Change In East Asia Takatoshi Ito Ed...
Human Capital In History The American Record Leah Platt Boustan Editor Carola...
Economic Regulation And Its Reform What Have We Learned Nancy L Rose Editor
Measuring Wealth And Financial Intermediation And Their Links To The Real Eco...
The Changing Frontier Rethinking Science And Innovation Policy Adam B Jaffe E...
Measuring Capital In The New Economy Carol Corrado Editor John Haltiwanger Ed...
Economics Of Meanstested Transfer Programs In The United States Volume I Robe...
Developments In The Economics Of Aging David A Wise Editor
Nber Macroeconomics Annual 2005 1st Edition Mark Gertler Kenneth Rogoff
Controlling Crime Strategies And Tradeoffs Philip J Cook Editor Jens Ludwig E...
Ad

Recently uploaded (20)

PPTX
PPT- ENG7_QUARTER1_LESSON1_WEEK1. IMAGERY -DESCRIPTIONS pptx.pptx
PDF
VCE English Exam - Section C Student Revision Booklet
PPTX
Introduction-to-Literarature-and-Literary-Studies-week-Prelim-coverage.pptx
PDF
A GUIDE TO GENETICS FOR UNDERGRADUATE MEDICAL STUDENTS
PDF
Chinmaya Tiranga quiz Grand Finale.pdf
PPTX
Lesson notes of climatology university.
PDF
01-Introduction-to-Information-Management.pdf
PPTX
GDM (1) (1).pptx small presentation for students
PDF
102 student loan defaulters named and shamed – Is someone you know on the list?
PDF
O5-L3 Freight Transport Ops (International) V1.pdf
PDF
Abdominal Access Techniques with Prof. Dr. R K Mishra
PDF
Supply Chain Operations Speaking Notes -ICLT Program
PDF
Chapter 2 Heredity, Prenatal Development, and Birth.pdf
PDF
3rd Neelam Sanjeevareddy Memorial Lecture.pdf
PDF
Black Hat USA 2025 - Micro ICS Summit - ICS/OT Threat Landscape
PDF
The Lost Whites of Pakistan by Jahanzaib Mughal.pdf
PDF
GENETICS IN BIOLOGY IN SECONDARY LEVEL FORM 3
PDF
Computing-Curriculum for Schools in Ghana
PPTX
IMMUNITY IMMUNITY refers to protection against infection, and the immune syst...
PPTX
1st Inaugural Professorial Lecture held on 19th February 2020 (Governance and...
PPT- ENG7_QUARTER1_LESSON1_WEEK1. IMAGERY -DESCRIPTIONS pptx.pptx
VCE English Exam - Section C Student Revision Booklet
Introduction-to-Literarature-and-Literary-Studies-week-Prelim-coverage.pptx
A GUIDE TO GENETICS FOR UNDERGRADUATE MEDICAL STUDENTS
Chinmaya Tiranga quiz Grand Finale.pdf
Lesson notes of climatology university.
01-Introduction-to-Information-Management.pdf
GDM (1) (1).pptx small presentation for students
102 student loan defaulters named and shamed – Is someone you know on the list?
O5-L3 Freight Transport Ops (International) V1.pdf
Abdominal Access Techniques with Prof. Dr. R K Mishra
Supply Chain Operations Speaking Notes -ICLT Program
Chapter 2 Heredity, Prenatal Development, and Birth.pdf
3rd Neelam Sanjeevareddy Memorial Lecture.pdf
Black Hat USA 2025 - Micro ICS Summit - ICS/OT Threat Landscape
The Lost Whites of Pakistan by Jahanzaib Mughal.pdf
GENETICS IN BIOLOGY IN SECONDARY LEVEL FORM 3
Computing-Curriculum for Schools in Ghana
IMMUNITY IMMUNITY refers to protection against infection, and the immune syst...
1st Inaugural Professorial Lecture held on 19th February 2020 (Governance and...
Ad

Social Security Policy In A Changing Environment Jeffrey R Brown Editor Jeffrey B Liebman Editor David A Wise Editor

  • 1. Social Security Policy In A Changing Environment Jeffrey R Brown Editor Jeffrey B Liebman Editor David A Wise Editor download https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-policy-in-a- changing-environment-jeffrey-r-brown-editor-jeffrey-b-liebman- editor-david-a-wise-editor-51440648 Explore and download more ebooks at ebookbell.com
  • 2. Here are some recommended products that we believe you will be interested in. You can click the link to download. Social Security Policy In Hong Kong From British Colony To Chinas Special Administrative Region Chak Kwan Chan https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-policy-in-hong-kong- from-british-colony-to-chinas-special-administrative-region-chak-kwan- chan-49058862 Social Security In The Balkans Volume 3 An Overview Of Social Policy In Serbia And Kosovo Marzena Akowska Editor https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-in-the-balkans- volume-3-an-overview-of-social-policy-in-serbia-and-kosovo-marzena- akowska-editor-53629856 Social Security In The Balkans Volume 1 An Overview Of Social Policy In Croatia Albania Bosnia And Hercegovina Greece Romania And Bulgaria Marzena Akowska https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-in-the-balkans- volume-1-an-overview-of-social-policy-in-croatia-albania-bosnia-and- hercegovina-greece-romania-and-bulgaria-marzena-akowska-35011102 Labor Markets And Social Security Issues And Policy Options In The Us And Europe 2nd Edition John T Addison https://ebookbell.com/product/labor-markets-and-social-security- issues-and-policy-options-in-the-us-and-europe-2nd-edition-john-t- addison-4520432
  • 3. Social Security And Wage Poverty Historical And Policy Aspects Of Supplementing Wages In Britain And Beyond Chris Grover Auth https://ebookbell.com/product/social-security-and-wage-poverty- historical-and-policy-aspects-of-supplementing-wages-in-britain-and- beyond-chris-grover-auth-5612368 Labor Policy To Promote Good Jobs In Tunisia Revisiting Labor Regulation Social Security And Active Labor Market Programs 1st Edition Anne Hilger Arvo Kuddo Jan Rutkowski World Bank https://ebookbell.com/product/labor-policy-to-promote-good-jobs-in- tunisia-revisiting-labor-regulation-social-security-and-active-labor- market-programs-1st-edition-anne-hilger-arvo-kuddo-jan-rutkowski- world-bank-51741448 The Politics Of Policy Change Welfare Medicare And Social Security Reform In The United States Daniel Beland And Alex Waddan https://ebookbell.com/product/the-politics-of-policy-change-welfare- medicare-and-social-security-reform-in-the-united-states-daniel- beland-and-alex-waddan-5102374 How Social Security Works An Introduction To Benefits In Britain Paul Spicker https://ebookbell.com/product/how-social-security-works-an- introduction-to-benefits-in-britain-paul-spicker-51810050 What Future For Social Security Debates And Reforms In National And Crossnational Perspective Jochen Clasen https://ebookbell.com/product/what-future-for-social-security-debates- and-reforms-in-national-and-crossnational-perspective-jochen- clasen-51808666
  • 6. Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment
  • 7. A National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Report National Bureau of Economic Research Conference on Research in Income and Wealth
  • 8. Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment Edited by Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise The University of Chicago Press Chicago and London
  • 9. Jeffrey R. Brown is the William G. Karnes Professor of Finance at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Jeffrey Liebman is the Malcolm Wiener Professor of Public Policy at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. David A. Wise is the John F. Stambaugh Professor of Political Economy at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and director of the program on the economics of aging at the National Bureau of Economic Research. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago 60637 The University of Chicago Press, Ltd., London © 2009 by the National Bureau of Economic Research All rights reserved. Published 2009 Printed in the United States of America 18 17 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 09 1 2 3 4 5 ISBN-13: 978-0-226-07648-5 (cloth) ISBN-10: 0-226-07648-2 (cloth) Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Social security policy in a changing environment / edited by Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise. p. cm. — (A National Bureau of Economic Research conference report) “This volume consists of papers presented at a conference held in Woodstock, Vermont in October 2006”—Acknowledgments. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN-13: 978-0-226-07648-5 (cloth : alk. paper) ISBN-10: 0-226-07648-2 (cloth : alk. paper) 1. Social security— Government policy—United States I. Brown, Jeffrey R. II. Liebman, Jeffrey B. III. Wise, David A. HD7125.S599286 2008 368.4′300973—dc22 2008031051 o The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of the American National Standard for Information Sciences— Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials, ANSI Z39.48-1992.
  • 10. National Bureau of Economic Research Officers Directors at Large Directors by University Appointment Directors by Appointment of Other Organizations Directors Emeriti Andrew Brimmer Carl F. Christ George Hatsopoulos Lawrence R. Klein Franklin A. Lindsay Paul W. McCracken Peter G. Peterson Richard N. Rosett Eli Shapiro Arnold Zellner Jean-Paul Chavas, American Agricultural Economics Association Gail D. Fosler, The Conference Board Martin Gruber, American Finance Association Timothy W. Guinnane, Economic History Association Arthur B. Kennickell, American Statistical Association Thea Lee, American Federation of Labor and Congress of Industrial Organizations William W. Lewis, Committee for Economic Development Robert Mednick, American Institute of Certified Public Accountants Angelo Melino, Canadian Economics Association Harvey Rosenblum, National Association for Business Economics John J. Siegfried, American Economic Association George Akerlof, California, Berkeley Jagdish Bhagwati, Columbia Glen G. Cain, Wisconsin Ray C. Fair, Yale Franklin Fisher, Massachusetts Institute of Technology Mark Grinblatt, California, Los Angeles Saul H. Hymans, Michigan Marjorie B. McElroy, Duke Joel Mokyr, Northwestern Andrew Postlewaite, Pennsylvania Uwe E. Reinhardt, Princeton Nathan Rosenberg, Stanford Craig Swan, Minnesota David B. Yoffie, Harvard Arnold Zellner (Director Emeritus), Chicago Peter C. Aldrich Elizabeth E. Bailey Richard B. Berner John H. Biggs John S. Clarkeson Don R. Conlan Kathleen B. Cooper Charles H. Dallara George C. Eads Jessica P. Einhorn Mohamed El-Erian Jacob A. Frenkel Judith M. Gueron Robert S. Hamada Karen N. Horn John Lipsky Laurence H. Meyer Michael H. Moskow Alicia H. Munnell Rudolph A. Oswald Robert T. Parry James M. Poterba John S. Reed Marina v. N. Whitman Martin B. Zimmerman John S. Clarkeson, chairman Kathleen B. Cooper, vice-chairman James M. Poterba, president and chief executive officer Robert Mednick, treasurer Kelly Horak, controller and assistant corporate secretary Alterra Milone, corporate secretary Gerardine Johnson, assistant corporate secretary
  • 11. Relation of the Directors to the Work and Publications of the National Bureau of Economic Research 1. The object of the NBER is to ascertain and present to the economics profession, and to the public more generally, important economic facts and their interpretation in a scientific manner without policy recommendations. The Board of Directors is charged with the respon- sibility of ensuring that the work of the NBER is carried on in strict conformity with this ob- ject. 2. The President shall establish an internal review process to ensure that book manuscripts proposed for publication DO NOT contain policy recommendations. This shall apply both to the proceedings of conferences and to manuscripts by a single author or by one or more co- authors but shall not apply to authors of comments at NBER conferences who are not NBER affiliates. 3. No book manuscript reporting research shall be published by the NBER until the Presi- dent has sent to each member of the Board a notice that a manuscript is recommended for pub- lication and that in the President’s opinion it is suitable for publication in accordance with the above principles of the NBER. Such notification will include a table of contents and an ab- stract or summary of the manuscript’s content, a list of contributors if applicable, and a re- sponse form for use by Directors who desire a copy of the manuscript for review. Each manu- script shall contain a summary drawing attention to the nature and treatment of the problem studied and the main conclusions reached. 4. No volume shall be published until forty-five days have elapsed from the above notifica- tion of intention to publish it. During this period a copy shall be sent to any Director request- ing it, and if any Director objects to publication on the grounds that the manuscript contains policy recommendations, the objection will be presented to the author(s) or editor(s). In case of dispute, all members of the Board shall be notified, and the President shall appoint an ad hoc committee of the Board to decide the matter; thirty days additional shall be granted for this purpose. 5. The President shall present annually to the Board a report describing the internal manu- script review process, any objections made by Directors before publication or by anyone after publication, any disputes about such matters, and how they were handled. 6. Publications of the NBER issued for informational purposes concerning the work of the Bureau, or issued to inform the public of the activities at the Bureau, including but not limited to the NBER Digest and Reporter, shall be consistent with the object stated in paragraph 1. They shall contain a specific disclaimer noting that they have not passed through the review procedures required in this resolution. The Executive Committee of the Board is charged with the review of all such publications from time to time. 7. NBER working papers and manuscripts distributed on the Bureau’s web site are not deemed to be publications for the purpose of this resolution, but they shall be consistent with the object stated in paragraph 1. Working papers shall contain a specific disclaimer noting that they have not passed through the review procedures required in this resolution. The NBER’s web site shall contain a similar disclaimer. The President shall establish an internal review pro- cess to ensure that the working papers and the web site do not contain policy recommenda- tions, and shall report annually to the Board on this process and any concerns raised in con- nection with it. 8. Unless otherwise determined by the Board or exempted by the terms of paragraphs 6 and 7, a copy of this resolution shall be printed in each NBER publication as described in para- graph 2 above.
  • 12. Contents vii Acknowledgments xi Introduction 1 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise I. Innovative Approaches to Social Security Reform 1. Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 21 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov Comment: Erzo F. P. Luttmer 2. Notional Defined Contribution Pension Systems in a Stochastic Context: Design and Stability 43 Alan J. Auerbach and Ronald Lee Comment: Jeffrey Liebman 3. Reforming Social Security with Progressive Personal Accounts 73 John Geanakoplos and Stephen P. Zeldes Comment: Jason Furman II. Retirement Plan Choice 4. Who Chooses Defined Contribution Plans? 131 Jeffrey R. Brown and Scott J. Weisbenner Comment: Brigitte C. Madrian
  • 13. 5. The Importance of Default Options for Retirement Saving Outcomes: Evidence from the United States 167 John Beshears, James J. Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian Comment: Jeffrey R. Brown III. Reducing Financial Market Risk in Personal Retirement Accounts 6. Reducing the Risk of Investment-Based Social Security Reform 201 Martin Feldstein Comment: David W. Wilcox 7. Pricing Personal Account Benefit Guarantees: A Simplified Approach 229 Andrew Biggs, Clark Burdick, and Kent Smetters Comment: George G. Pennacchi 8. Reducing Social Security PRA Risk at the Individual Level: Life-Cycle Funds and No-Loss Strategies 255 James M. Poterba, Joshua Rauh, Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise Comment: Douglas W. Elmendorf 9. Changing Progressivity as a Means of Risk Protection in Investment-Based Social Security 299 Andrew A. Samwick Comment: Michael Hurd IV. Demographics, Asset Flows, and Macroeconomic Markets 10. The Decline of Defined Benefit Retirement Plans and Asset Flows 333 James M. Poterba, Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise Comment: Jonathan Skinner viii Contents
  • 14. 11. Demographic Change, Relative Factor Prices, International Capital Flows, and Their Differential Effects on the Welfare of Generations 385 Alexander Ludwig, Dirk Krüger, and Axel Börsch-Supan Comment: James M. Poterba V. Mortality Projections 12. Is the U.S. Population Behaving Healthier? 423 David M. Cutler, Edward L. Glaeser, and Allison B. Rosen Comment: James P. Smith Contributors 447 Author Index 451 Subject Index 455 Contents ix
  • 16. Acknowledgments xi This volume consists of papers presented at a conference held in Wood- stock, VT in October 2006. Most of the research was conducted as part of the NBER Retirement Research Center with financial support from the U.S. Social Security Administration (SSA) through grant #10-P-98363-1 to the National Bureau of Economic Research as part of the SSA Retirement Research Consortium. Additional funding sources are noted in individual papers. The findings and conclusions expressed in this volume are those of the re- spective authors and do not represent the views of SSA, any agency of the federal government, or the National Bureau of Economic Research.
  • 18. Introduction Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise 1 This volume compiles selected studies conducted through the National Bu- reau of Economic Research (NBER) Center for Retirement Research. The center was created in 2003 with funding from the U.S. Social Security Ad- ministration and is structured to provide analysis that can inform Social Security policy. In setting our research agenda, we have been guided by three principles. First, reform must recognize the changing and uncertain environment in which the Social Security system will operate. Second, sev- eral alternative routes to sustainable solvency should be explored. Third, the potential routes to solvency should be evaluated for “resiliency” to fu- ture uncertain demographic, economic, and social trends. While some of the center’s research focuses directly on Social Security reform, other research aims to inform Social Security policy by analyzing the changing economic environment in which future Social Security ben- eficiaries will live. For example, several of our center’s projects have stud- ied trends in private-sector retirement saving—particularly the shift from defined benefit (DB) to defined contribution (DC) pension plans—be- cause the “optimal” Social Security replacement rate may evolve as the structure of private retirement savings changes over time. We have also studied trends in health care costs because decisions about Social Secu- rity benefits, and indeed how much of society’s resources to devote to So- Jeffrey R. Brown is the William G. Karnes Professor of Finance at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Re- search. Jeffrey Liebman is the Malcolm Wiener Professor of Public Policy at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and a research associate of the Na- tional Bureau of Economic Research. David A. Wise is the John F. Stambaugh Professor of Political Economy at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and director of the program on the economics of aging at the National Bureau of Economic Re- search.
  • 19. cial Security, may depend in part on health care costs. And we have stud- ied the uncertain nature of future demographic, economic, and social trends—such as the age structure of the population, marriage and divorce rates, women’s labor force participation, productivity, market rates of re- turn, and the like. The volume is organized into five parts. Part I introduces several inno- vative approaches to Social Security reform. Part II examines individual behavior in making retirement saving decisions, such as how much to save or how to allocate savings among alternative investment options. Part III analyzes different approaches to reducing the financial market risk faced by individuals who invest in personal retirement accounts. Part IV looks at aggregate trends in retirement asset flows and their effect on macro- economic markets. Part V considers health trends and their projected effects on future mortality. This introduction summarizes each of the chap- ters, drawing heavily on the authors’ own summaries. Innovative Approaches to Social Security Reform In recent years, the debate about Social Security reform in the United States has focused on a limited range of proposals, a fact which may have contributed to the partisan nature of reform discussions. An important aim of our center is to expand the range of approaches considered and to assess the resiliency of alternative proposals to uncertain future demo- graphic, financial, and other trends. The first three chapters in this volume analyze new ideas for Social Security reform. The first considers reforms that would remove the disincentive in Social Security for long careers. The second analyzes notional defined contribution social security systems and evaluates their ability to self-adjust to uncertain future circumstances, and thus to retain their financial stability over the long term. The third devel- ops a reform proposal based on progressive personal accounts, which blend characteristics of funded personal accounts with some of the core objectives of traditional social security policy. In chapter 1, “Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers,” Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov ex- plore the relationship between Social Security policy and labor market be- havior at older ages. Since Social Security was instituted in 1935, life ex- pectancy at age twenty has increased from sixty-six to seventy-six for men and from sixty-nine to eighty for women. Health at older ages has also im- proved. Such dramatic advances in health and longevity mean that people have the physical and mental capability to work until older ages. Yet people are retiring younger, even as they live longer and healthier lives. Indeed, the duration of retirement has grown by even more than the increase in life ex- pectancy at retirement. Godi, Shoven, and Slavov consider the role of Social Security policy in 2 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
  • 20. influencing—or, more precisely, distorting—the work and retirement de- cisions of older workers. They highlight the features of Social Security that discourage long careers, discourage work at older ages, and increase the number of years in retirement. The main finding of the chapter is that So- cial Security imposes high implicit tax rates on workers late in their careers. As a result of this distortion, the duration of retirement is suboptimally long, compounding the financial stress on public and private retirement support systems. One example of the distortion in Social Security is how benefits are cal- culated based on the highest thirty-five years of earnings. This means that the thirty-third, thirty-fourth, and thirty-fifth years of work noticeably im- prove retirement benefits by replacing a “zero” in the benefit calculation formula. The thirty-sixth year of work, on the other hand, may or may not count, and if it does, it will replace a lower year of earnings and not a zero in the calculation. Thus, the benefit formula discourages careers of more than thirty-five years. Another aspect of the benefit formula offers dispro- portionately higher benefits to workers with short careers, treating them with the same redistributive advantages as if they were lower earners. Both characteristics of the benefit formula lead to high implicit tax rates at older ages and for longer careers. The authors suggest three reforms that would reduce the distortionary impact of Social Security at older ages. First, they propose using forty years, rather than thirty-five, in benefit computation. Second, they propose disentangling career length and progressivity in the benefit formula. And third, they propose to establish a “paid-up” category of workers who have more than forty years of contributions, who would no longer be subject to the payroll tax. The study finds that these proposed changes would elimi- nate most of the large positive tax rates for older workers. They would also reduce the association between age and tax rate and move tax rates closer to zero for most workers in most years of their lives. With these changes, the implicit tax rates associated with Social Security remain roughly con- stant over a worker’s life, resulting in less distortion of career length choices. The authors find, in addition, that the proposed reforms need not affect the overall progressivity of the Social Security system. However, by reallocating benefits from those with shorter careers to those with longer careers, the reforms would result in less insurance against adverse shocks that cause people to work for fewer years. The study concludes that by eliminating the disincentives against work- ing longer careers, we can capitalize on the good fortunes of increasing life expectancy and favorable health status by paving the way for those in good health to stay in the labor force longer. In chapter 2, “Notional Defined Contribution Pension Systems in a Sto- chastic Context: Design and Stability,” Alan J. Auerbach and Ronald Lee explore a new approach to Social Security reform that is known as “No- Introduction 3
  • 21. tional Defined Contribution” or “Nonfinancial Defined Contribution” (NDC). Sweden was the first country to introduce an NDC system. A num- ber of other countries have introduced NDC plans, including Italy, Poland, Latvia, Mongolia, and the Kyrgyz Republic, and proposed plans for France and Germany have NDC aspects. The NDC programs differ in detail, but the basic principle is that they mimic defined contribution plans without actually setting aside financial assets. Thus, some of the benefits of fully funded defined contribution plans can be achieved—particularly the improved labor supply incentives from a more transparent link between current taxes and future retirement benefits—while avoiding the transitional difficulties of converting from an unfunded pay-as-you-go (PAYGO) system. Under an NDC program, a “notional” capital account is maintained for each participant. Balances in this account earn a rate of return that is declared by the pension plan each year, and notional payments into this account are made over the entire life history to mirror actual taxes or contributions by plan participants. After a designated age such as sixty-two, a participant can begin to draw bene- fits, which is done by using the account to purchase an annuity from the pension plan. The terms of the annuity will depend on mortality risk at that time and on a rate of return stipulated by the pension plan. While NDC plans are seen as having various potential advantages over traditional PAYGO systems, the focus of this chapter is on their financial stability over the long term. The stability results from three factors. First, the rate of return in the notional accounts reflects the underlying PAYGO nature of the program and is based on what is expected to be affordable over time. Second, the annuity structure should buffer the system from the uncertain costs of rising longevity. And third, in the event that the pro- gram’s finances move toward imbalance, a braking mechanism can be in- corporated that automatically modifies the rate of return to help restore the plan to financial health. Given the political difficulties of making fre- quent changes in PAYGO pension programs, the attractiveness of an in- herently stable and self-adjusting system is clear. In this chapter, Auerbach and Lee use a stochastic macroeconomic model for forecasting and simulating the long-term finances of NDC-type public pension programs in the context of demographic and economic trends in the United States. Because future patterns of demographic and economic change are uncertain, the model generates a probability distri- bution of outcomes (benefit flows and rates of return) for generations of plan participants for the NDC program, as well as for the overall financial stability of the NDC system. The study finds that an NDC system similar to that currently in use in Sweden, which bases rates of return on the growth rate of average wages and utilizes a brake to adjust the rate of return during periods of financial stress, effectively eliminates the accumulation of debt in the Social Security 4 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
  • 22. system, even under the most adverse demographic and economic circum- stances. Thus, the system is effective in preventing inadequate funding of Social Security obligations over the long term. What this version of an NDC system does not do is adjust automatically to situations when there is excess money accumulating in the system. Put differently, the braking mechanism is asymmetric, automatically making corrections when the financial balances of the system move toward in- creased debt, but without correction when the financial balances move to- ward asset accumulation. Only a symmetric brake, which raises rates of re- turn during periods of financial strength, avoids large accumulations of financial assets. Other findings from the simulations are first, that the brake can be more gradual than under the Swedish system and still provide a stable distribu- tion of outcomes; second, that an NDC system in which rates of return are based on total rather than per capita economic growth is inherently more stable; and third, that a considerable share of the volatility in the financial performance of NDC systems is attributable to economic uncertainty, rather than demographic uncertainty. In chapter 3, “Reforming Social Security with Progressive Personal Ac- counts,” John Geanakoplos and Stephen P. Zeldes develop yet another ap- proach to Social Security reform. Their reform plan is designed to preserve the core objectives of the current Social Security system and, at the same time, gain the benefits of personal accounts. Advocates for retaining the current system argue that Social Security should redistribute wealth from those who have earned more over their whole working lives to those who have earned less. They also suggest that different generations should share in the risks and benefits of macroeco- nomic growth. So if real wages go up over time, retirees should get some benefit from those macroeconomic gains, even though they are no longer working. Advocates for personal accounts, on the other hand, support ownership by individuals of tangible assets that cannot be revoked by a fu- ture government. They also like the idea that people know the current mar- ket valuation of their retirement resources, as they are accrued over time, so that rational planning for retirement can take place outside of Social Se- curity. Geanakoplos and Zeldes seek to find a common ground between these two approaches and to develop a plan that preserves the core goals of each one. They demonstrate that it is possible to convert Social Security into a system of personal accounts with irrevocable ownership of market priced assets, while at the same time redistributing benefits based on lifetime in- come and sharing macroeconomic gains across generations. They refer to the plan as progressive personal accounts. The proposed system uses the payroll tax to buy assets in a personal re- tirement account for each Social Security recipient. Income-based redis- Introduction 5
  • 23. tribution is accomplished through a variable government match (or tax) on these Social Security contributions. High lifetime earners receive lower matches (or a tax) on contributions to their personal account, while low lifetime earners receive a higher government match. Risk sharing across generations is accomplished through the creation of a new kind of deriva- tive security whose payoffs depend on the average earnings of those work- ing at a specific point in time. So if younger workers are doing well and re- ceiving high wages, the old will get higher payoffs from their investment in the derivative security. Every year a worker would pay the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) payroll tax and receive a certain number of these securities in the worker’s account. According to the authors, it is possible to create a system of progressive personal accounts that exactly mimics the promised taxes and payouts of the current Social Security system. The resulting system would preserve some of the core goals of Social Security, as it is structured today, but would also improve upon it due to the increased transparency, enhanced property rights, and lower political risk (of legislation removing benefits) that naturally come with individual accounts. Chapter 3 lays out the me- chanics of such a system in detail. Retirement Plan Choice With the growth of 401(k)-type plans, retirement saving is becoming an increasingly important complement to Social Security as a component of financial support in retirement. In addition, some Social Security reform proposals would supplement the defined benefits provided by the current U.S. Social Security system with either voluntary or mandatory personal retirement accounts (PRAs). The increasing importance of individually- owned retirement savings accounts, whether integrated within the Social Security system or outside the system, will make decision making by indi- viduals a more important aspect of retirement planning in the future. The next two chapters in the volume look at how people make decisions about retirement plans when individual decisions need to be made. In chapter 4, “Who Chooses Defined Contribution Plans?,” Jeffrey R. Brown and Scott J. Weisbenner analyze the decisions made by a group of 50,000 workers who currently have a choice between a defined benefit (DB) and a defined contribution (DC) pension system. Their study is based on the experience of employees in the State Universities Retirement System (SURS) of Illinois, where workers make a one-time, lifetime, irrevocable choice among three retirement plans: (1) a traditional formula-based DB plan; (2) a “portable DB plan,” which is slightly less generous than the tra- ditional DB program if one retires from the system, but more generous if the worker takes an early lump-sum distribution; and (3) a completely self- managed DC plan. Individuals who fail to make an active choice within the 6 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
  • 24. first six months of employment are automatically defaulted into the tradi- tional DB plan. Other aspects of the SURS experience are also relevant to the study. First, the wages of individuals earned from SURS-covered employment are not also covered by Social Security. So for most, the decision made is a decision about people’s primary source of income in retirement. Second, the combined employer/employee retirement contributions to the SURS system are at least 14.6 percent of annual salary, which is larger than the payroll tax paid by those in the Social Security system. Therefore, the SURS system looms large as part of a participant’s lifetime financial plan. And third, the choice of retirement programs is available to employees with diverse job characteristics and earnings, including campus administrators, faculty members, clerical staff, university police and fire protection work- ers, and others. There are two major findings from the study. First, despite initial pro- jections that a majority of new employees would actively select the self- managed DC plan or portable DB plan, the evidence is that a majority of new employees never makes an active pension choice and, thus, are de- faulted into the traditional DB plan. The proportion of new employees not making a choice among plans, and hence defaulting into the traditional DB plan, has been roughly three-fifths over the period 2001 to 2004. Second, approximately 15 percent of new employees choose the self- managed DC plan, despite the fact that the DC plan is likely inferior to the portable DB plan, given the financial features of the various plans and rea- sonable assumptions about future financial market returns. Interestingly, individuals are more likely than average to choose the self-managed DC plan if they are more highly educated, have higher earnings, are married, and work in a location where a higher fraction of other employees also chose the self-managed plan. The findings suggest that these “educated, high earning, young professionals” have a strong preference for DC plans, even when the financial terms are unfavorable. For example, among the 650 individuals in the sample who are full-time, aged thirty to thirty-nine, aca- demics at a university, married, have earnings in excess of $50,000, and are still active employees as of spring 2006, 52 percent of them chose the self- managed DC plan, compared with 15 percent in the sample as a whole. The analysis raises the question of why some individuals appear to make suboptimal choices. The authors speculate that there are at least five rea- sons why they may do so. First, participants may simply have difficulty pro- cessing the complex information that they are provided when making this choice, due either to time constraints or some form of bounded rationality. Second, the information provided by SURS may not be optimally designed to facilitate meaningful comparisons between the self-managed DC plan and the portable benefits package. Third, individuals may understand the rules, but may overestimate their investment abilities, or the expected mar- Introduction 7
  • 25. ket return of the DC plan. Fourth, individuals may believe there is politi- cal risk in the traditional or portable benefit plans, arising from the chronic underfunding of the SURS system. Fifth, individuals may place a high value on choice for its own sake. In continuing research, the authors are ex- ploring these alternative hypotheses using a survey of current SURS par- ticipants. In chapter 5, “The Importance of Default Options for Retirement Sav- ing Outcomes: Evidence from the United States,” John Beshears, James J. Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte C. Madrian look at a very similar issue in the context of 401(k) plans. In this case, the worker’s decision is about whether to enroll in the 401(k) plan, what portion of their income to allo- cate to the plan, and how to invest it among the various investment options offered in the plan. Much like the previous chapter, a core finding is that de- faults matter a lot. Many people avoid making an active decision about their retirement saving, and so the default provisions of their 401(k) plan are what people end up doing “by default.” The chapter summarizes a breadth of empirical evidence on how the de- fault provisions of retirement saving plans impact savings behavior along multiple dimensions, such as savings plan participation, savings rates, as- set allocation, and postretirement savings distributions. The findings are that defaults impact savings outcomes at every step along the way. For ex- ample, some 401(k) plans have automatic enrollment, requiring employees to explicitly “opt-out” of the plan. Others require eligible employees to ac- tively enroll in the plan, or “opt-in.” Automatic enrollment is found to dra- matically raise participation rates. When the 401(k) plan has a default savings rate and a default investment allocation, employees are much more likely to choose those defaults, rather than to specify an alternative. As a result, the higher the default contribu- tion rate, the higher the savings rate among those participating. Defaults even matter when employees leave their jobs, and their 401(k) balances may be left in the account, or they may be distributed to employees with the option to roll over the funds to another retirement plan. When the funds are distributed (which happens automatically in most smaller accounts), they are much more likely to be removed permanently from retirement sav- ing, while undistributed funds tend to be left in the plans. The findings of this study are relevant not only to the design of a com- pany’s 401(k) plan, but also to how one would structure a personal account system within Social Security. For example, a voluntary PRA system within Social Security would lead to higher participation and higher sav- ing if it has automatic enrollment (rather than requiring active enrollment) and if the default savings rate is higher. The findings on asset allocation are also relevant and suggest careful attention to the investment options made available to participants as well as to the default allocations among them. A clear conclusion of this research is that defaults are not neutral—they 8 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
  • 26. can either facilitate or hinder better savings outcomes. The authors em- phasize that current public policies toward saving include examples of both. Reducing Financial Market Risk in Personal Retirement Accounts The next section of the volume also relates to the increasing importance of individual retirement saving and, particularly, to the potential implica- tions of a PRA component in Social Security. A significant concern, par- ticularly if PRAs were to become part of Social Security, is with the impo- sition of investment risk on plan participants. The concern is that the economic well-being of some retirees could be undermined by poor invest- ment returns. There is, therefore, great interest in strategies that could re- duce the riskiness of PRAs while preserving the other features of PRAs. While the chapters in this section are focused on reducing the risk of PRAs, the results are also relevant to retirement saving taking place in 401(k) plans and other financial accounts that are separate from Social Security. The first chapter in this section considers financial market products that cap downside market risk. The second analyzes an approach in which the government would guarantee a minimum investment return. The third studies the extent to which life-cycle investment strategies could reduce the variance in retirement income levels. The fourth investigates the extent to which increased progressivity in the traditional Social Security system could be used to buffer lower-income retirees against PRA market risk. In chapter 6, “Reducing the Risk of Investment-Based Social Security Reform,” Martin Feldstein presents a market-based approach to reducing the risk of investment-based Social Security that could be tailored to indi- vidual risk preferences. With this new form of risk reduction, substituting an investment-based PRA for the traditional pure PAYGO plan could achieve both a significantly higher expected retirement income and a very high probability that the investment-based annuity would be at least as large as the PAYGO benefit. A key feature of the approach developed in the chapter is a guarantee that the individual would not lose any of the real value of each year’s PRA savings and might be guaranteed to earn at least some minimum real rate of return. In one example of such a plan, the current 12.4 percent PAYGO tax is compared with a mixed plan that has a 6.2 percent PAYGO tax and 6.2 per- cent annual PRA savings. This new mixed plan, when fully phased in, would have the following desirable characteristics: (1) The median value of the combined retirement income (i.e., the sum of the PAYGO benefit and the PRA annuity) would be 147 percent of the traditional PAYGO benefit. (2) There would be a 95 percent probability that the combined retirement income (the PAYGO benefit and the PRA annuity) exceeds the traditional PAYGO benefit. (3) There would be less than one chance in 100 that the Introduction 9
  • 27. combined retirement income would be less than 96 percent of the tradi- tional PAYGO benefit. (4) Each year’s PRA saving would be guaranteed to earn at least a 1 percent real rate of return between the time that it is saved and its value at age sixty-six. It is, therefore, referred to in the chapter as a “No Lose” plan. (5) The variable annuity purchased at age sixty-six would have a similar “No Lose” feature, that is, a guaranteed real rate of return of at least 1 percent. The “No Lose” concepts developed in the chapter rely on financial in- struments already available in the marketplace. The idea is that the amount saved in a PRA each year would be guaranteed to retain at least its real value by age sixty-six. The simplest way to achieve such a No Lose PRA ac- count would be to combine Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities (TIPS, which have a guaranteed real return) with equities. The fraction of the an- nual PRA saving that would have to be invested in TIPS to guarantee that the annual PRA saving would retain its real value by age sixty-six depends on the age of the saver and the rate of return on the TIPS of the relevant maturity. For example, if the saver is twenty-one years old and the real re- turn on TIPS is 2 percent, a $1,000 PRA saving would be divided between $410 in TIPS and the remaining $590 in equities. The 2 percent real return and the forty-five-year investment period imply that the $410 would accu- mulate to $1,000 at the initial price level by age sixty-six. Even if the equity portion became completely worthless, the PRA account would be worth the initial $1,000 real dollars. At older working ages, there are fewer years for the TIPS to accumulate and, therefore, a larger fraction of the initial saving must be invested in TIPS. For example, a forty-year-old would have to invest $598 out of each $1,000 of new saving in TIPS to guarantee the $1,000 value of the account at age sixty-six with the remaining $402 invested in equities. In practice, of course, the value at age sixty-six of the annual PRA saving would be worth substantially more than the guaranteed amount because the equity portion of the account would add additional value. Indeed, the likelihood (based on past market returns) is that the equity portion would add very substan- tial additional value. The chapter considers a range of “No Lose” options with varying trade- offs between the guaranteed minimum return and the distribution of pos- sible higher returns. For example, the approach can be easily modified to increase the guarantee from a zero real return (No Lose) to a 1 percent real rate of return. Indeed, different trade-offs might be more or less desirable to different individuals, based on their particular risk preferences. These options are then evaluated relative to the baseline values that would be pro- vided through a traditional PAYGO Social Security system. Simulations are used to derive the probability distributions of retirement incomes rela- tive to the “benchmark” benefits specified in current law. Calculations of expected utility show that the risk reduction techniques developed in the 10 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
  • 28. chapter can raise expected utility relative to investment-based plans with no guarantees. Finally, the chapter shows how these approaches might be applied to deal with the aging of the population without the large rise in the payroll tax that would otherwise be required. In closely related work reported in chapter 7, “Pricing Personal Account Benefit Guarantees: A Simplified Approach,” Andrew Biggs, Clark Bur- dick, and Kent Smetters develop a methodology for estimating the market cost of return guarantees. Given the size of Social Security benefit en- titlements and the market risks inherent in personal account investing, guarantees constitute a significant contingent liability to the guarantee provider. Most of the existing research on guarantees has estimated their cost, based on a probability distribution of possible investment outcomes, and then used the distribution to calculate an “expected” cost of the minimum guarantee. According to the authors, however, this approach does not re- flect fully how guarantees would be priced in the financial marketplace. In particular, it ignores the greater valuation placed by the market on losses relative to the expected value of the losses. Indeed, the total “market cost” of a benefit guarantee, including the associated cost of market risk, could be several times larger than its “expected cost.” This chapter demonstrates how a model for calculating the expected cost of a benefit guarantee can be modified to present the market price of personal account guarantees as a supplement to expected cost valuations. The simplified method for esti- mating the market price of a guarantee is shown to produce results equiv- alent to the Black-Scholes model. The approach is illustrated using a Social Security reform proposal from Senator John Sununu (R-NH) and Representative Paul Ryan (R-WI). This proposal would introduce personal accounts investing from 5 to 10 percent of wages, depending upon the worker’s earnings level. At retirement, indi- viduals would receive either the proceeds of their personal account or their currently scheduled benefit, whichever is greater. Thus, this plan effectively guarantees that accounts would produce benefits no lower than those scheduled for the current program. In the illustrative policy, the “expected cost” valuation of the proposed guarantee is calculated to be 11.3 percent of total benefits to new retirees in 2050, while the “market value” cost is calculated to be 28.2 percent of benefits. In chapter 8, “Reducing Social Security PRA Risk at the Individual Level: Life-Cycle Funds and No-Loss Strategies,” James M. Poterba, Joshua Rauh, Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise explore the implications for asset accumulation of different investment strategies. In a Social Secu- rity system with a personal retirement account (PRA) component, retire- ment savers would have to decide how to allocate their PRA portfolios across a broad range of asset classes and financial products. Asset alloca- tion decisions have important consequences for retirement wealth accu- Introduction 11
  • 29. mulation because they affect the expenses of investing as well as the risk of low returns. The goal of this study is to assess the relative risk associated with alternative asset allocation strategies in PRAs, though it also offers in- sight on the consequences of different asset allocation rules in 401(k)-type plans. The approach used in the study is to simulate the distribution of balances in PRA retirement saving accounts under various assumptions about the asset allocation strategies that investors may choose. In addition to a range of age-invariant strategies, such as an all-bond and an all-stock strategy, the chapter considers several different “life-cycle funds” that automatically alter the investor’s mix of assets as he or she ages. These funds allocate a higher fraction of an investor’s portfolio to stocks at the beginning of a working career and then gradually decrease the equity fraction as the worker approaches retirement. The authors also consider a “no lose” allo- cation strategy for retirement saving, in which households purchase enough riskless bonds at each age to ensure that they will have no less than their nominal contribution when they reach retirement age and then invest the balance in corporate stock. This strategy combines a riskless floor for retirement income with some upside investment potential, along the lines of what is described in chapter 6. The best asset allocation strategy—the one with the highest expected utility to the investor—is found to depend on the relative importance of four issues: the expected return on stocks, the risk aversion of the investing household, the amount of financial wealth held outside the PRA, and the expenses associated with different investment options. At modest levels of risk aversion, or when the household has access to substantial non-PRA wealth at retirement, the historical pattern of stock and bond returns im- plies that an all-stock investment strategy brings higher expected utility than any of the more conservative strategies. When the expected return on stocks is reduced, however, other strategies may dominate the all-equity allocation for investors with high levels of relative risk aversion. In these circumstances, the value of a mix of stocks and inflation-indexed bonds (TIPS) or an inexpensive life-cycle product may be higher than an all-stocks strategy. The findings also underscore the importance of avoiding high expense ratios. Many of the available life-cycle products have higher expense ratios than could be achieved by the household simply holding a stock index fund and some TIPS (or bonds) and either holding them in fixed proportions throughout their lifetime or rebalancing toward TIPS (or bonds) as they get older. Households who are unable to do this on their own will not do terribly in life-cycle funds, but they will lose money relative to what they could get if they executed very simple investing strategies on their own. A very different approach to reducing PRA risk is explored in chapter 9, “Changing Progressivity as a Means of Risk Protection in Investment- 12 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
  • 30. Based Social Security,” by Andrew A. Samwick. This chapter analyzes changes in the progressivity of the Social Security benefit formula as an al- ternative means of lessening the overall risk for lower-income Social Secu- rity beneficiaries. Because Social Security benefits provide a larger share of retirement income for lower-income households, Samwick argues, the most direct way to make sure that they do not fall into poverty in old age is to increase the progressivity of the benefit formula. Doing so would lessen the need to provide insurance against the possibility of low returns in the PRAs because low-income retirees would depend less on their PRAs to stay out of poverty. In the illustrative reform plans studied by Samwick, individual PRA ac- counts are created with contributions of 2 percent of covered earnings per year. At the same time, traditional Social Security benefits are reduced by 40 percent. Samwick evalues four different approaches to the 40 percent aggregate benefit cut, each with a different degree of progressivity in the benefit formula. The least progressive version would maintain the progres- sivity of Social Security benefits at its current level, but reduced all benefits by 40 percent. The most progressive version would provide an equal re- tirement benefit to everyone, regardless of past earnings. The other two scenarios are in between, offering moderate increases in benefit progres- sivity. A series of simulations are conducted to analyze the implications of these policy alternatives on the economic well-being of lower income households, as well as to evaluate the optimal allocation of PRA assets among different asset classes. The key finding is that under baseline parameters, a flat Social Security benefit independent of earnings (the most progressive option) al- lows the bottom 30 percent of the earnings distribution to achieve a higher expected utility than under the proportional reductions to the current ben- efit formula even with no investments in equity. An additional 30 percent of earners can lessen their equity investments without loss of welfare relative to those available under the scaled-back current formula. Under more real- istic and less extreme changes to the traditional benefit, about half of the eq- uity risk can be eliminated for the lowest earnings decile, and some equity risk can be eliminated for the bottom six deciles. The optimal allocation to equities in the PRA is not particularly sensi- tive to the progressivity of the reductions in the traditional benefits—in most simulations, the optimal share in equities increases slightly for low earners and decreases slightly for higher earners with more progressive re- ductions in the traditional benefits. Demographics, Asset Flows, and Macroeconomic Markets Many analysts have suggested that population aging will adversely affect the assets of baby boomers when they retire. These analysts argue that Introduction 13
  • 31. when a large population cohort is working and accumulating resources for retirement, their demand for investments is high, thereby increasing asset prices. Conversely, when a large cohort retires, they are more likely to sell their assets to finance consumption and thereby drive down asset prices. This argument suggests that the rapidly increasing population of older people in the United States and around the world might lead to lower re- turns in financial markets in the decades ahead. The extent to which these predictions will be realized is difficult to pre- dict. It is particularly difficult in an international context, where macro- economic markets are interrelated, and where financial capital flows freely across countries. The next two chapters in the volume consider the effects of population aging on asset markets, one focused on retirement saving in the United States and one on global financial markets. Chapter 10 is part of a series of investigations by James M. Poterba, Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise aimed at forecasting the flow of funds into and out of retirement-related asset holdings in the United States. In “The Decline of Defined Benefit Retirement Plans and Asset Flows,” these investigators focus on the flow of funds into and out of “traditional” de- fined benefit (DB) pension plans. A companion study, also referenced in the chapter, focuses on the flow of funds into and out of 401(k)-type sav- ings plans. Together, these studies project the direction and magnitude of asset flows for a very significant portion of retirement-related investments. These analyses provide quantitative documentation, as well as future forecasting, of a fundamental transition in saving for retirement in the United States. What we have experienced over the last twenty-five years is a massive shift from saving through employer-managed defined benefit (DB) pensions to saving in individually managed defined contribution (DC) retirement plans, particularly 401(k) plans. Thus, to understand the effect of demographic trends on the demand for retirement assets in the coming decades, it is important to evaluate the likely flows into and out of both 401(k)-type plans and DB plans. The projections in the chapter suggest that the average (over all people) of the present value of real DB benefits at age sixty-five attained an histor- ical maximum in 2003, when the value was about $73,000. The present value declines after 2003, as the proportion of new retirees covered by DB plans declines. The projections also suggest that the average value of 401(k) assets at age sixty-five surpasses the average present value of DB benefits at age sixty-five in about 2010. Thereafter, the value of 401(k) assets grows rapidly, attaining levels much greater than the maximum present value of DB benefits. If equity returns between 2006 and 2040 are comparable to those observed historically, by 2040 average projected 401(k) assets will be over six times larger than the historical maximum level of DB benefits at age sixty-five, attained in 2003. Even if equity returns average 300 basis points below their historical value, the authors project that average 401(k) 14 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
  • 32. assets in 2040 would be 3.7 times as large as the value of DB benefits in 2003. The offsetting and dominating influence of 401(k)-type saving, com- pared with flows in DB assets, is the central conclusion of the analysis. Fo- cusing on DB assets alone suggests that an aging population, in conjunc- tion with a shift away from DB plans, will lead to a decline in the real value of pension assets averaged across all retirees in future cohorts. When com- bining projected 401(k) assets with projected DB assets, however, the study finds that real pension assets not only increase, but increase substantially, in future decades. These results underscore the need for further analysis of the factors that determine the diffusion of 401(k) plans across corporations, especially small companies with low-wage workers, as well as the contribution behavior and withdrawal behavior of 401(k) participants. The growing role of 401(k)-type plans in the retirement landscape suggests that understand- ing asset accumulation and drawdown in these plans is a critical com- ponent of any analysis of the effect of demographic change on financial markets. Chapter 11 extends the analysis of demographic change and asset mar- kets from the United States to international financial markets. In “Demo- graphic Change, Relative Factor Prices, International Capital Flows, and Their Differential Effects on the Welfare of Generations,” Alexander Lud- wig, Dirk Krüger, and Axel Börsch-Supan develop a simulation model to analyze the impact of demographic change on macroeconomic markets around the world. While the size, rate of growth, and age distribution of the population is changing worldwide, the magnitude of demographic changes and the tim- ing and character of those changes differ significantly across countries and across regions of the world. There is variation in aggregate population growth rates and trends, variation in the ratio of the working-age popula- tion to the total adult population, and variation in the portion of the pop- ulation at older ages. These demographic variations, and the varying paths of demographic change over time, affect international flows of capital and other resources. And these flows, in conjunction with the demographic changes themselves, affect the macroeconomic characteristics of different countries and the welfare of different generations within them. The authors present the following intuitive explanation, which plays out in their more rigorous macroeconomic modeling. First, changes in the population structure will alter aggregate labor supply and aggregate sav- ings that, in turn, alter the prices for labor and capital. As the working age population declines, for example, labor will become scarcer, relative to cap- ital; real wages will increase; and real rates of return to capital will de- crease. Second, as countries reform their PAYGO pension systems to par- tially funded systems, the additional supply of capital from those reforms Introduction 15
  • 33. reinforces the downward pressure on the rate of return to capital. The wel- fare implications of changing factor prices differ across generations, as younger generations gain from wage increases and older generations lose from lower capital returns. The goal of this study is to quantify these effects in an international con- text, accounting for international flows of resources across countries. Much of the work leading up to this study has been in developing an eco- nomic model to make these calculations. The study finds that the rate of return to capital decreases by roughly 80 to 90 basis points if capital is allowed to flow freely across regions. The sim- ulations indicate that capital flows from rapidly aging regions to the rest of the world will initially be substantial, but that trends are reversed subse- quently. However, because long-term demographic trends are highly cor- related across Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries, the capital flows across countries do not affect much the long-run decrease in the rate of return on capital. In other words, the impact of open markets in moderating the macroeconomic impact of de- mographic change within countries is less important because of the simi- larities in demographic change across countries in the long term. In terms of the generational welfare effects, the simulations suggest that for younger households with few capital assets, increases in wages will dominate the decline in rates of return on capital. For example, abstracting from Social Security and its reform, the cohort born in 2005 will gain about 0.6 to 0.9 percent in terms of lifetime consumption. Older, asset-rich indi- viduals, on the other hand, tend to lose because of the decline in interest rates on capital. However, if demographic changes necessitate reforms in Social Security, then reduced benefits or increased taxes will moderate the welfare gains to the younger generation. Mortality Projections The financial footing of the Social Security system depends importantly on the longevity of program participants. In the past several decades, longevity in the United States has increased substantially, adding to the fi- nancial burden on the Social Security program. What the future holds is less clear and requires the consideration of multiple factors. In chapter 12, “Is the U.S. Population Behaving Healthier?,” David M. Cutler, Edward L. Glaeser, and Allison B. Rosen compare the risk factor profile of the popu- lation in the early 1970s with that of the population in the early 2000s and consider the implications of recent trends for future reductions in mor- tality. The first part of the chapter estimates the impact of demographics, smoking, drinking, obesity, blood pressure, and cholesterol on ten-year mortality rates, comparing the predicted ten-year mortality in the two time 16 Jeffrey R. Brown, Jeffrey Liebman, and David A. Wise
  • 34. periods. For the population aged twenty- to seventy-four, the ten-year probability of death fell from 9.8 percent in 1971 to 1975 to 8.4 percent in 1999 to 2002. For the population aged fifty-five to seventy-four, the ten- year risk of death falls from 25.7 percent to 21.7 percent. The largest con- tributors to these changes are reductions in smoking and better control of blood pressure. While overall health has improved, not all risk factor trends have been in a positive direction. Smoking rates have fallen by more than a third since 1960, and alcohol consumption has declined by 20 percent since 1980, both leading to better health. Demographically, the population is bet- ter educated, and better-educated people live longer than less-educated people. On the other hand, obesity rates have doubled in the past two decades, and diabetes has increased as a result. The second part of the analysis considers the impact on mortality if cur- rent trends continue. The mortality forecast integrates together several of the most important risk factors associated with mortality. Smoking and obesity are found to be the most important and offsetting components of the forecast. Based on reduced smoking, the mortality risk for the entire population aged twenty-five and older would be expected to decline by 8 percent. Increasing obesity, however, with current treatment rates—leads to increased hypertension and high cholesterol—and a 13 percent increase in mortality risk. While suggestive, the authors emphasize that there is considerable un- certainty in making health projections for the future. For example, two- thirds of the U.S. population is overweight or obese. As a result, continued increases in weight from current levels have a bigger impact on health than did increases in weight from lower levels of body mass index (BMI). At the same time, however, the detrimental impact of BMI on health can be mod- erated dramatically by controlling hypertension and high cholesterol. So the question is not just whether weight will continue to increase. Also crit- ical is the extent to which those who are overweight or obese take medica- tions to control the health risks associated with high BMI. That, too, is highly uncertain. Understanding how to improve utilization of and adher- ence to recommended medications are key issues. Introduction 17
  • 36. 21 1.1 Introduction When Social Security was instituted in 1935, the period life expectancy at age twenty for males was sixty-six and for females sixty-nine. Today, twenty-year-old males have a period life expectancy of seventy-six and fe- males eighty. This increase in life expectancy has been accompanied by a corresponding improvement in health at all ages. Cutler, Liebman, and Smyth (2007) find that, in terms of mortality, men at age sixty-eight in 2000 have roughly the same mortality risk as men at age sixty-two in 1960. Thus, at a same age, men in the year 2000 are roughly six years younger. In terms of self-assessed health status, they find that the difference is even larger, ap- proximately ten years. Their bottom line is, “Our best guess is that people aged 62 in the 1960s are in equivalent health to people aged 70 or more to- day” (p. 14). In related work, Shoven (2004) suggests that the age of elderly people is more appropriately measured by remaining life expectancy than by years since birth. These improvements in life expectancy and health status enable individ- uals to prolong their careers and delay retirement. However, the length of retirement has actually grown by more than the increase in life expectancy 1 Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov Gopi Shah Goda is a Robert Wood Johnson Scholar in Health Policy Research at Harvard University. John B. Shoven is the Charles R. Schwab Professor of Economics at Stanford Uni- versity, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. Sita Nataraj Slavov is an assistant professor of economics at Occidental College. This research was supported by the U.S. Social Security Administration (SSA) through grant #10-P-98363-1-01 to the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) as part of the SSA Retirement Research Consortium. The opinions and conclusions expressed are solely those of the authors and do not represent the opinions or policy of SSA or any agency of the Federal Government.
  • 37. at retirement. Figure 1.1 shows labor force participation rates by age in 1965 and 2003. Both early retirees and median retirees are retiring earlier in 2003 than they were in 1965. Figure 1.2 displays labor force participa- tion rates by remaining life expectancy rather than age and shows that the average length of retirement for men has increased almost 50 percent since 1965. In 1965, the average length of retirement for the median male retiree was thirteen years. By 2003, it was nineteen years. Roughly half of the ad- ditional years were due to improvements in life expectancy, and half were due to earlier retirement. Individuals may choose to use increases in their life expectancy for ad- ditional leisure or additional consumption, and it is possible that the shift toward longer retirements is optimal. However, there are a number of fea- tures of Social Security that distort incentives toward increased retirement length by imposing high implicit tax rates on longer careers and working at older ages. For example, Social Security benefits are computed based on the average of an individual’s highest thirty-five years of earnings. An in- dividual with fewer than thirty-five years of earnings has a relatively strong incentive to work for an additional year as the additional earnings clearly raise the average upon which the benefit is based. On the other hand, an individual who has already worked for thirty-five years has a diminished incentive to work an additional year—the earnings from that year will, at best, replace one of the previous highest thirty-five in the benefit computa- 22 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov Fig. 1.1 Labor force participation of men by age, 1965 and 2003
  • 38. tion. Thus, the benefit formula encourages careers of thirty-five years or less. Several other features of the benefit computation—which we will dis- cuss in detail in the following—contribute to the disincentives for long ca- reers. In this chapter, we examine the disincentives for long careers created by Social Security. Our main finding is that the structure of these programs imposes high implicit tax rates on workers late in their careers. As a result of this distortion, we believe retirements are suboptimally long. The con- sequences of this distortion are significant: a lot of the stress on public and private pension systems is caused by the increased length of retirement. We also outline ways to reduce or eliminate the implicit taxes on long careers and working at older ages. The potential benefits of a larger work force for Social Security and Medicare (and gross domestic product [GDP]) are large. 1.2 Work Incentives in U.S. Social Security In this section, we investigate the impact of Old Age and Survivors In- surance (OASI) on the career-length incentives of both stylized and actual workers. In each year of their working life, we compute the workers’ pres- ent value of Social Security taxes minus benefits under the assumption that Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 23 Fig. 1.2 Labor force participation of men by remaining life expectancy, 1965 and 2003
  • 39. they stop working after the current year (i.e., they accumulate no further earnings). The implicit Social Security tax rate is defined as the increase in the net tax burden from working an additional year as a percentage of the current year’s earnings. In other words, this is the additional net tax the worker incurs by prolonging his or her career by one year. This variable captures the worker’s incentive to continue working for an additional year as opposed to retiring. Throughout our analysis, OASI benefits are com- puted under 2005 law. That is, we sum each worker’s highest thirty-five years of wage-indexed earnings that fall below the earnings cap and divide this amount by 420 months to get the worker’s average indexed monthly earnings (AIME). We then compute the worker’s primary insurance amount (PIA): the PIA is equal to 90 percent of the first $x of AIME, plus 32 percent of the amount between $x and $y, plus 15 percent of the re- mainder of AIME, where x and y are the constructed bend points for the appropriate retirement year.1 The worker receives the PIA—indexed for in- flation—every month from retirement until death. A minimum of ten years of work is required to qualify for any benefits. In computing taxes and ben- efits, we assume an aggregate wage growth rate of 3.5 percent, an inflation rate of 2.5 percent, and a discount rate of 4.5 percent. The OASI tax rate is assumed to be 10.6 percent applied to capped earnings using the historical earnings caps. Benefit streams are discounted for mortality using the So- cial Security Administration’s intermediate scenario mortality rates. Our analysis is similar to that of Feldstein and Samwick (1992). Feld- stein and Samwick compute marginal net tax rates for stylized workers who vary by gender, income, and marital status. They show that the addi- tional tax paid on an additional dollar of income varies significantly across workers and over a worker’s lifetime—in particular, marginal tax rates are significantly higher for single workers and for younger workers. Their find- ing that marginal tax rates decline with age comes from the fact that as a worker approaches retirement, the present value of the additional benefit received increases. However, they only compute marginal tax rates for workers between ages twenty-five and sixty, and each year of earnings over this thirty-five-year period is assumed to count in the benefit computation. This assumption overlooks a major disincentive for long careers: after a worker has accumulated thirty-five years of earnings, additional years are likely to have little, if any, impact on benefits. As we will show in the fol- lowing, taking account of this fact implies that older workers face signifi- cantly higher implicit tax rates than younger workers. 1.2.1 A Stylized Computation To illustrate our argument, we compute implicit tax rates for a set of four male stylized workers under current law. Three of our stylized workers re- 24 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov 1. The 2005 bendpoints ($627 and $3,779) were multiplied by the appropriate wage adjust- ment factor to be in line with the year in which the worker retires.
  • 40. ceive simulated earnings profiles equal to either the average, 10th per- centile, or 90th percentile earnings for their age group. In order to simulate wage histories, we use Outgoing Rotation Groups from the 2001 and 2002 Current Population Survey to compute the wage for each of the three earn- ings levels within each age group. We then divide this by the aggregate av- erage wage across all age groups. This ratio is multiplied by the historical average wage in each year of the worker’s life to arrive at a wage for the worker. For example, consider an average male thirty-year-old worker in 1950. The national average annual wage in 1950 was $2,763. According to our computations, a thirty-year-old male earns 1.13 times the national av- erage; therefore, his simulated wage would be $2,763 1.13 $3,122. A fourth stylized worker earns the historical earnings cap in each year. We assume that all stylized workers start work at age twenty and retire at the normal retirement age. The implicit Social Security tax rate for a given career length is calculated as described previously. The results of this exercise are shown in figure 1.3. Note that for less than ten years of work, the worker is not yet vested in the system and, therefore, faces an implicit tax rate of the full 10.6 percent. (These years are not shown in figure 1.3.) Two points should be clear from the graph. First, all workers experience a sharp increase in their implicit tax rate at thirty-five years of work. The reason for this increase is that Social Security benefits are calculated based Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 25 Fig. 1.3 Implicit tax rates by career length
  • 41. on the highest thirty-five years of indexed annual earnings. This means that the thirty-third, thirty-fourth, and thirty-fifth year of work noticeably im- prove retirement benefits because the earnings of that year replace a zero in the calculation of average indexed monthly earnings (AIME). On the other hand, the thirty-sixth year of work may or may not enter the calcu- lation, and if it does, it will replace a lower year of earnings and not a zero in the calculation. The marginal incentive to work for the thirty-sixth year and beyond is much lower than for the first thirty-five years. Part-time work after a career of thirty-five years or more will, in particular, usually have no impact on subsequent benefits, and, therefore, the 10.6 percent OASI payroll tax is simply a tax and has no component of deferred bene- fits. For people who enter the workforce immediately after high school and who do not leave the labor force for an extended period, thirty-five years of earnings will be accumulated by the age of fifty-three. Second, the median and low earners each experience a sharp increase in their implicit tax rate earlier in their careers—for the middle-income earner, after twelve years of work, and for the low-income earner, after twenty-two years of work. This increase results from the fact that the PIA formula is sharply progressive, combined with the fact that the AIME cal- culation does not distinguish between workers with lower earnings and those with higher earnings but shorter covered careers. At the beginning of their careers, workers tend to have a low AIME because they have signifi- cantly fewer than thirty-five years of positive earnings. The benefit com- putation replaces the missing years of earnings with zeros, and these work- ers appear to be in a lower income group than their true lifetime earnings would imply. The progressivity of the PIA formula translates this low AIME into a disproportionately high monthly benefit. As workers accu- mulate positive earnings years, the benefit computation begins to treat them as if they have higher lifetime incomes. A sharp increase in the im- plicit tax rate occurs when a worker accumulates enough positive earnings years to cross a PIA bend point. Thus, the current formula favors workers with short careers by treating them as if they were low earners. In some cases, for instance, where the short career was necessitated by poor health, that may be appropriate. In most cases, however, the current treatment seems inappropriate and blunts the incentive to work long careers. This effect is most pronounced for low-income workers, who face the sharpest increase in their implicit tax rate. These distortions lead us to evaluate the following three reforms: 1. Use forty years, rather than thirty-five, in the AIME computation. If forty years were used instead of thirty-five, this would remove some of the discouragement currently built into the system for staying in the work- force. An extra five years of work would count toward the calculation of re- tirement benefits. 26 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov
  • 42. 2. Disentangle career length and progressivity. Average indexed monthly earnings could be calculated only for the months with covered earnings (eliminating the zeros from the computation and dividing by the number of months of nonzero earnings rather than 420). The PIA would be calculated using this modified AIME formula. However, a single person would only get the full PIA at the Normal Re- tirement Age (NRA) if they worked a full career (currently thirty-five years, proposed to be forty years under the first reform). If they worked fewer years, their benefits would be reduced proportionately. For example, consider how we currently treat someone with a ten-year high-income ca- reer. Their benefits are determined as if they were a relative low earner with the twenty-five years of zeros in the earnings calculation. The alternative would be to give them 10/35ths of the PIA of a high earner. This would re- sult in a reduction of benefits for short career workers. This reform is illus- trated in figure 1.4. 3. Establish a “paid-up” category of workers who have more than forty years of contributions. Under the first proposed reform, the number of years in the benefit cal- culation is forty. A complementary policy is to only collect forty years of payroll taxes from workers. After forty years of covered employment, the worker would be declared “paid-up” for Social Security. This should be rel- atively easy to administer—conceivably an indicator would be added to the individual’s Social Security number reflecting the fact that paid-up Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 27 Fig. 1.4 PIA under current and proposed law
  • 43. status had been achieved. A related idea was mentioned in Burtless and Quinn (2002), namely allowing workers who reach the NRA to opt out of additional Social Security contributions. There is a theoretical justification for these policies. The intuition of op- timal tax theory would be to place heavier taxes on more inelastic supply (and demand) and lighter taxes or no taxes on highly elastic behavior. Our hypothesis is that the forty-first and forty-second years of work, for in- stance, are far more sensitive to incentives than the twenty-first and twenty-second years of work. The practical significance of these three re- forms is to make employment of veteran workers more attractive for both the employee and the employer. Taken together, these three proposals result in a benefit cut. In order to compensate for this and keep the reforms benefit-neutral in aggregate, we increase retirement benefits proportionately in order to keep aggregate benefits constant before and after the reforms.2 Assuming no behavioral changes, the adjustment needed is a 19.4 percent increase in benefits. The proposals also result in redistribution from those with shorter careers to those with longer ones. Figure 1.5 illustrates this by depicting our stylized average earner’s PIA, as a function of career length, under both the current and the proposed law. Under the proposed law, a worker’s PIA would rise more sharply as he or she accumulated years of work—that is, benefits are more responsive to a decision to delay retirement. Workers with fewer than thirty-one years of covered earnings would receive a smaller PIA than un- der the current system; however, as their career length extends beyond thirty-one years, their PIA rises above the current level. A similar result holds for the low and high earners. On the revenue side, introducing the “paid-up” category of workers who have worked forty years constitutes a reduction in the amount of tax rev- enues the system receives. We estimate that at most 4.35 percent of OASI revenue comes from income that was earned after an individual worked forty years.3 Thus, instituting the “paid-up” reform would require a payroll tax increase of 0.5 percent, changing the current OASI tax from 10.6 per- cent to 11.1 percent. All future calculations of the impact of the three pro- posed reforms account for the tax and benefit adjustments to ensure bene- fit- and revenue-neutrality. 28 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov 2. The revenue effects are estimated using the Social Security Benefits and Earnings Public- Use File described in the following section. 3. The estimate of the fraction of OASI revenue earned in years 41 comes from the Social Security Benefits and Earnings Public-Use File, 2004, described in more detail in the follow- ing section. The beneficiaries’ earnings were indexed to 2003 using the historical Social Secu- rity average wage index. This estimate is biased upward because the data set only includes earnings below the taxable maximum, which has increased significantly over the period 1951 to 2003. This implies the program has expanded over this time period, and earnings in the ear- lier part of this period are underrepresented.
  • 44. We repeat our implicit tax rate computations for the four stylized work- ers under the proposed reforms. The results are shown in figure 1.6 and la- beled “Proposed Law.” Current Law results are also shown for comparison purposes. Note that implicit tax rates remain roughly constant over each worker’s life, resulting in less distortion of career length choices. Moreover, implicit tax rates for all income groups are closer to zero. The decreasing trend arises from the present value of future benefits increasing as a worker gets closer to the NRA. At forty years of work, all workers enter the “paid- up” category and no longer participate in the system. The proposed reforms do not affect the overall progressivity of the So- cial Security system as is shown in table 1.1. At the thirty-five-year career length, the average income earner’s internal rates of return (IRRs) are con- stant before and after the reforms at 1.17 percent. The three policies do not change the relative position of the low- and high-income earners. After an individual has worked thirty-five years, he or she is always better off under the proposed reforms. 1.2.2 Data and Results The drawback of using stylized workers is, of course, that they do not re- flect the diversity of actual workers’ labor market experiences. In particu- lar, the stylized workers’ ages and career lengths are perfectly correlated. This makes it difficult to capture the experience of, for example, a woman who takes time out of the labor force to raise children. Thus, we repeat our computations using the Social Security Benefits and Earnings Public-Use Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 29 Fig. 1.5 Monthly primary insurance amount under current and proposed law: Av- erage income earner
  • 45. Fig. 1.6 Implicit tax rates by career length under current and proposed laws Table 1.1 Internal rates of return for workers with 35-year career (%) Current law Proposed law Low-income earner 2.47 2.46 Average-income earner 1.17 1.17 High-income earner 0.66 0.66
  • 46. File, 2004, which contains benefit and earnings data on a 1 percent ran- dom, representative sample entitled to receive a Social Security benefit in December 2004. The full sample contains data on 473,366 beneficiaries. Unfortunately, this data set provides no way to link couples; therefore, we include only workers who are receiving benefits based on their own earn- ings records. We limit our attention to beneficiaries receiving retirement benefits who started working in 1951 or later, which leaves 123,552 indi- viduals born between 1910 and 1942.4 We continue to use Social Security intermediate scenario assumptions for mortality. For the actual worker computations under the proposed law, we intro- duce an earnings threshold: years in which earnings are less than 5 percent of the earnings cap are not counted toward the years of work calculation, but are subject to payroll taxes.5 The rationale for the earnings threshold is that many individuals—particularly as they get older—have years in which they work a small number of hours. Without an earnings threshold, these individuals’ benefits would increase disproportionately (given the modified AIME computation and the progressivity of the PIA formula), and they would accumulate years of credit toward the paid-up status. The result is that many older individuals in the sample would face large nega- tive implicit tax rates. The earnings threshold reduces this distortion. Of course, this means that years where earnings were under the threshold face the full tax, unless the individual had attained paid-up status by working more than forty years. On balance, however, we find that distortions are significantly less with the earnings threshold. (This issue did not arise with the stylized workers as our simulated earnings profiles never fell below the 5 percent threshold.) In order to illustrate the complexity of patterns that actual individuals face, we plot histograms of the ages at which individuals attain ten years of covered earnings (vesting age at which individuals become eligible for ben- efits), thirty-five years of covered earnings (the current number used in the benefit computation), and forty years of covered earnings (the proposed number to be used in the benefit computation). The results are broken down by gender and appear as figures 1.7 to 1.9. While workers tend to reach ten years of work at age thirty, thirty-five years at age fifty-five, and forty years at age sixty (like our stylized work- ers), there is considerable individual variation, particularly for females. A sizeable number of females reach these experience levels considerably later than assumed in our stylized example. These figures illustrate the impor- Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 31 4. Only aggregate earnings are recorded for years 1937 to 1950. 5. This is not unlike the earnings needed to obtain a quarter of coverage in the current sys- tem, $920 in 2005. To receive four quarters of coverage, an individual would need $3,680 in earnings, approximately 4 percent of the 2005 earnings cap of $90,000. Earnings below this level are subject to the payroll tax even though benefits are not increased.
  • 47. tance of using actual workers to study the career length incentives created by the system, particularly if we are interested in the impact on women. Figures 1.10 and 1.11 show our calculations of the average implicit tax rate broken down by career length (figure 1.10), age (figure 1.11), and gen- der. The current law computations exhibit the same features as did those for stylized workers. Workers face increases in their implicit tax rates un- der current law as they age and increase their career length. This is a result of moving from one PIA bend point to the next and from accumulating thirty-five years of earnings. This result occurs for both male and female 32 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov Fig. 1.7 Distribution of vesting age: Graphs by gender Fig. 1.8 Distribution of thirty-five-year career age: Graphs by gender
  • 48. workers, and it is present whether we look at means or medians (not shown). Under the proposed law, male workers’ implicit tax rates move closer to zero for all age and experience groups. There is also a much smaller asso- ciation between implicit tax rate and age. Most of the large, positive im- plicit tax rates—which occur late in their careers—are eliminated. Those that remain are faced by individuals who earn less than the earnings threshold and, therefore, are being subject to the full OASI tax rate of 10.6 percent. Individuals with earnings below the threshold drive up the aver- Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 33 Fig. 1.9 Distribution of forty-year career age: Graphs by gender Fig. 1.10 Average implicit Social Security tax rates, by career length: Graphs by gender
  • 49. age implicit tax rates faced under the proposed reforms at older ages; how- ever, the average annual income earned by people who face the full OASI tax rate is only $1,115. One of the main differences between the treatment under the current law and the proposed law is the sharp decrease in the number of people and the amount of income facing the full tax rate under the three reforms. The changes redistribute from short-careered workers to long-careered workers as shown in figure 1.12. Individuals who work more than forty years and are thus subject to the paid-up policy reform no longer see ear- lier earnings years being replaced by later, potentially higher earning years. While this could lead to a decrease in their calculated PIA, the IRR would be higher under the proposed reforms because the added benefit from re- placing a year of earnings in the current calculation is small relative to the amount of taxes paid. Females tend to experience a larger subsidy under both current law and the proposed policies due to the fact that the system is progressive and fe- males in the sample have lower earnings, and also because their mortality probabilities are more favorable, making the expected future additional benefits larger. We define the Gender Gap to be the difference between av- erage male and female implicit Social Security tax rates. Table 1.2 summa- rizes calculations of the Gender Gap under different mortality assump- tions and shows that approximately 40 percent of the difference between male and female implicit tax rates is due to more favorable female mortal- ity; the remaining is attributed to differences in underlying earnings levels. The reforms may disproportionately penalize women, who are more likely to take time out of the labor force for child or elderly care and expe- 34 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov Fig. 1.11 Average implicit Social Security tax rates, by age: Graphs by gender
  • 50. rience shorter careers. Benefit levels are 0.89 percent higher for males but 1.45 percent lower for females under the three reforms. One possible pol- icy to alleviate this effect would be to give women an across-the-board credit for working of one, two, or three years. This policy is similar to the treatment of individuals who take time out of the labor force to raise chil- dren in countries such as Germany. In the German system, a child-raising parent is treated as though he or she earned the average wage until the child’s third birthday. The differences between the PIA in the current sys- Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 35 Fig. 1.12 Percentage change in PIA by career length Table 1.2 Average implicit Social Security tax (ISST) rates under different mortality assumptions (%) Average ISST Gender gap Current law Males 0.90 Females using female mortality 3.99 4.89 Females using male mortality 2.18 3.08 Portion of gender gap explained by mortality differences 37 Proposed law Males 0.93 Females using female mortality 5.33 4.40 Females using male mortality 3.34 2.41 Portion of gender gap explained by mortality differences 45
  • 51. tem and the PIA under the proposed reforms along with a credit for women are given in table 1.3. Note that offering a credit to women of even one year has a substantial effect on the level of benefits. Our calculations of mean implicit tax rates mask a considerable amount of variation across workers. To illustrate this variation, we plot individual implicit tax rates as a function of age for a small subsample of individuals under both current law and the proposed reforms. These are shown in fig- ures 1.13 (current law) and 1.14 (proposed law). Most individuals experi- ence features similar to the stylized workers: under current law, there are sharp increases in implicit tax rate as they cross PIA bend points and an- other sharp increase when they accumulate thirty-five years of work. There is considerable variation across workers in the timing of these increases. The proposed law eliminates most of the large positive tax rates for older workers. It also reduces the association between age and tax rate and moves tax rates closer to zero for most workers in most years of their lives. However, many of the workers experience single years with large negative implicit tax rates. These are years in which earnings are low—these years 36 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov Table 1.3 Percentage change in primary insurance amount by gender and years of credit given for women (%) No credit 1-year credit 2-year credit 3-year credit Male benefits 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.89 Female benefits 1.45 1.69 4.73 7.67 Total 0.02 1.20 2.39 3.53 Fig. 1.13 Current law: Graphs by gender
  • 52. disproportionately increase PIA (due to the progressivity of the formula) and contribute toward paid up status. 1.3 Conclusion The U.S. labor market has proved to be very flexible in absorbing new workers as evidenced by its ability to accommodate large numbers of work- ers as women entered the labor force in the past several decades, and the economy has benefited greatly as a result of the larger workforce. By elim- inating the disincentives against working longer careers, we can capitalize on the good fortunes of increasing life expectancy and favorable health sta- tus by paving the way for more capable individuals to stay in the labor force. References Burtless, Gary, and Joseph Quinn. 2002. Is working longer the answer for an aging workforce? Center for Retirement Research. Issue in Brief no. 11. Center for Re- tirement Research at Boston College. Butrica, Barbara A., Richard W. Johnson, Karen E. Smith, and Eugene Steuerle. 2006. The implicit tax on work at older ages. National Tax Journal 59:211–34. Cutler, David M., Jeffrey B. Liebman, and Seamus Smyth. 2007. How fast should the Social Security eligibility age rise? NBER Retirement Research Center Working Paper no. NB04-05. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 37 Fig. 1.14 Proposed law: Graphs by gender
  • 53. Feldstein, Martin, and Andrew Samwick. 1992. Social Security rules and marginal tax rates. National Tax Journal 45 (1): 1–22. Fenge, Robert, Silke Uebelmesser, and Martin Werding. 2002. Second-best prop- erties of implicit Social Security taxes: Theory and evidence. CESifo Working Paper no. 743. Gruber, Jonathan, and David A. Wise. 1997. Social Security and retirement around the world. NBER Working Paper no. 6134. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, August. Shoven, John B. 2004. The impact of major improvement in life expectancy on the financing of Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid. In Coping with Methuse- lah: The impact of molecular biology on medicine and society, ed. Henry J. Aaron and William B. Schwartz, 166–97. Washington DC: Brookings Institution. Comment Erzo F. P. Luttmer This chapter tackles the important question of how the Social Security benefit formula can be adjusted so that it generates fewer incentives for in- dividuals to retire early. Social Security provides retirement incentives when the additional Social Security taxes paid by postponing retirement for a year exceed the increase in the present value of future Social Security benefits from working this additional year. Goda, Shoven, and Slavov re- fer to this difference, when expressed as a fraction of earnings, as the im- plicit Social Security tax. Two features in the current Social Security law cause this implicit Social Security tax to be high for individuals with long careers. First, the current Social Security law bases benefits on the average of the thirty-five highest years of indexed earnings. Thus, current earnings will increase this average less for individuals who already have worked for thirty-five years than for individuals who have not yet worked thirty-five years because for the former group the current year’s earnings crowd out a prior year’s earnings in the benefit formula. Second, the progressivity of Social Security benefits depends on the average indexed earnings of the highest thirty-five years of earnings (including years with zero earnings) rather than basing this average only on those years with positive earnings. As a result, Social Security redistributes from workers with long careers to those with short careers even if these two groups have the same earnings per year worked. This redistribution further raises the implicit Social Se- curity tax on those with longer careers. Goda, Shoven, and Slavov analyze a reform proposal that would reduce the implicit early retirement incentives in the Social Security benefit rules. This reform would base benefits on the average of the forty highest years of 38 Gopi Shah Goda, John B. Shoven, and Sita Nataraj Slavov Erzo F. P. Luttmer is an associate professor at the John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and a faculty research fellow of the National Bureau of Economic Re- search.
  • 54. positive indexed earnings (i.e., excluding years with zero earnings) and re- duce benefits pro rata based on the number of years with positive earnings for people who have fewer than forty years of positive earnings. For ex- ample, a person with twenty years of positive earnings would receive half the benefits of someone who has the same average earnings based on forty years of positive earnings. Finally, after forty years of positive earnings, one would become “paid-up,” that is, exempt from paying any further So- cial Security taxes. Under this proposal, Social Security benefits and the Social Security tax rate are adjusted such that average benefits and average Social Security tax revenue are the same as under the current law. Using data on a 1 percent random sample of Social Security beneficiar- ies in 2004 who started working after or during 1951 and claim benefits based on their own earnings record, Goda, Shoven, and Slavov carefully evaluate the reform proposal’s impact on the Social Security incentive to retire as well as its distributional impact. They find that this reform would lead to a sharp reduction in retirement incentives: the implicit Social Se- curity tax rate would fall substantially, typically by 4 to 7 percentage points, for men and women between the ages of fifty and seventy. As a re- sult, Social Security would no longer provide this group of workers with an incentive to retire early. By design, this proposal would increase benefits for those with longer careers at the expense of those with shorter careers. However, the reform does not substantially affect the overall progressivity of the Social Security system. The proposed reform would reduce the av- erage benefits of women relative to those of men, but this can be fixed with a minor adjustment. Goda, Shoven, and Slavov analyze one of three implicit marginal Social Security taxes, namely the implicit Social Security tax “on postponing re- tirement by one year.” In other words, it is the implicit tax on working this year when the counterfactual is retiring in the following year. This is prob- ably the most plausible counterfactual for older workers. The second im- plicit Social Security tax is the tax on the extensive margin of working this year holding labor supply constant in the future years. In other words, it is the incentive to take one year off from working, for example, for child care or schooling reasons. This margin is probably the more relevant one for younger workers. Finally, there is the implicit Social Security tax on the in- tensive margin: the effect of earning one extra dollar on expected Social Se- curity benefits net of taxes holding earnings in all other years constant. Feldstein and Samwick (1992) also calculate implicit Social Security taxes and find, in apparent contradiction to Goda, Shoven, and Slavov’s findings, that these tax rates fall with age. Goda, Shoven, and Slavov attri- bute this difference to the fact that Feldstein and Samwick only calculate implicit marginal Social Security tax rates for workers with at most thirty- five years of earnings. This, however, is not the reason why Feldstein and Samwick obtain different results. The difference in findings arises because Removing the Disincentives in Social Security for Long Careers 39
  • 55. Random documents with unrelated content Scribd suggests to you:
  • 56. the hierophants came and led him away to be of their company till his death: the ceremony was ended. My attendants, arrayed as the goddesses Hathor and Nut, conducted me from the shrine. I was unrobed of my sacred panoplies and once more from a goddess became a woman, and as a woman I sought my couch and wept and wept. For had I not at the first temptation in my heart broken the law and betrayed the trust of her who, as then I believed, is and was and shall be; her whose veil no mortal man had lifted, the Mother of the sun and all its stars?
  • 57. CHAPTER V The Summons None knew my fault. Yet I knew, and what is known to one soul is known to all souls, since one is all and all are one. Moreover, it was known to That which begets souls, That from which they come and to which they return again, again to come, as Plato, the great philosopher, who died before my day, has taught us in his writings. Also it was known to that accursed priest who was the cause and partner of my crime. I was overcome; I was eaten up with shame, I who thought myself purer than the mountain snows, as indeed I was and, in the flesh, to this hour have remained. Soon I could no longer bear my torment. To Noot I went, Noot the high-priest, my counsellor and master, and in a secret place kneeling on my knees, there I told him all. He hearkened with a little smile upon his withered face, then answered, “Daughter, in your honesty you do but reveal that which I knew —how I knew it matters not. And now take comfort, since the blame is not altogether yours, or even that of this new-made priest, whose foot was caught in the same snare. You worship Isis, as I do, but what is Isis whom we portray on earth as a woman glorious above all women? Is she not Nature’s self, the universal Mother, the Supreme in whom all gods and goddesses have a part? She wars on Aphrodite, it is true, yet does not that mean that in verity she wars upon herself? And are we not as Isis is, not one but many poured into a single mould, for do we not all war upon ourselves? Believe me, Daughter, the human heart is a great battleground where the higher and the lower parts of us fight with spiritual spears and arrows, till one side or the other wins victory and hoists the banner of good or evil, of Isis or of Set. Only out of struggle comes perfectness; that which has never struggled is a dead creature from whom little may be hoped. The ore must be melted in the fire and
  • 58. lo! the most of it is dross, refuse to be thrown away. Had it never known the fire, there could be no pure gold to adorn the brows of Heaven, nor even copper and iron to shape the swords of men. Rejoice, then, that you have felt the hurt of fire.” “Master,” I answered, “Lord of Wisdom to whom alone Ayesha bows the knee, your words are true and comfortable, yet bethink you, and if it is permitted, interpret me this riddle. I dreamed a dream of the time before my earthly days—you know it well for I have told it to you. I dreamed of a place in Heaven and of two goddesses matched against each other and of a command that was laid upon me to bring woe upon those who had deserted the one and turned to the other. Now if they were parts of a single whole, why should this command be laid upon me?” “Daughter, in your dream you were ordained to be a Sword of Vengeance, not because the Egyptians turned from one part of the holy Unity to another part of that Unity, but because they have become corrupt and faithless, worshipping no gods save themselves and following after that which is low, not that which is high. Such is my answer, yet of the truth or the falsehood of that dream I say nothing. Perchance it was but a dream.” “Perchance, Master. Yet in that dream, true or false, I saw a face, and lo! a few nights gone I, draped as Isis in the shrine, I saw that face again and knew it; knew also that with it my fate is intertwined. What of this?” “Daughter, who are we that we should read the mysteries of Fate, we who know not whence we come nor whither we go, nor what we have been, nor why we are? It may be that you have some mission toward the spirit that is clothed in the flesh of yonder man. It may be that you are destined to uplift that spirit, and in so doing yourself to be trodden down. If so, I say that in the end you shall rise again and bear him upward with you.” He paused, and I knelt silent, pondering the prophecy, for such I knew it well to be. Then again he spoke, “You heard a laughter in the shrine, yet there was no laughter save that of the evil in your own heart, mocking and triumphant. Such laughter mayhap you will often hear, but while you can hear it
  • 59. and repent, be not dismayed. When the ears of the soul grow deaf then utter loss is near; while they are open, hope remains. Those who still strive can never wholly fall. Fate rules us every one, yet within the circle of that Fate power is given to us to work out our redemption. I have finished. Ask me no more.” “What punishment, Master?” I asked. “Daughter, this. For a while look no more upon that man. I say for a while, since with you I hold that his destiny and yours are intertwined. I have a command for you: that presently you accompany me hence to lands beyond the seas. Now, go rest, and in rest find forgetfulness.” So I went, wondering yet comforted, though I knew well that Noot the Holy had not told me all, no, nor yet the half of what he knew. For often those to whom the gods give vision are forbid to speak it, lest, as in the old Hebrew parable, men should eat of the tree of knowledge and grow like to them. Or perchance they cannot speak it, since it comes to them in a tongue which may not be rendered in the words that the passer-by would understand. So indeed it is with me to-day. Thus it came about that soon I and my master, Noot, left Philæ and as before travelled the Nile disguised. Never since then have my eyes looked upon that island and its holy fane which Holly, who has visited it, tells me is now a ruin with stark, Hathor-headed columns standing here and there amongst the tumbled stones. He says, moreover, that his people who rule the land to-day purpose to sink it beneath the Nile that the lands below may be enriched and multiplied. Herein I see an allegory; the temples of Isis are drowned and the learning they held is lost in order that more food may grow to feed the common and the ignorant. Yet to what end, seeing that if there is more food, more men will come to eat it, all of them common and ignorant, while Isis and her wisdom are swallowed in the slime. Thus has it ever been in Egypt, and doubtless elsewhere, for such is Nature’s law. Food breeds multitudes and where carrion is, there are flies, while in the deserts both are lacking. Yet I think
  • 60. that the deserts and the few that wander on them beneath the sun and stars are nearer far to God. Once more disguised as merchants, I and Noot, my master, took ship and visited far lands to see their state and gather wisdom. We visited Rome, then breaking her shackles and rising to her greatness. They were a great people, those Romans that Noot out of his foresight told me would one day rule the world. Or perhaps it was I who told Noot, judging them by their qualities; I am not sure. At least I loved them not, because of their rude natures, their lack of arts and their love of power and gain. Therefore when I had studied their language and their politics I passed on. We came to Greece and tarried there awhile, studying philosophies and other things. The Greeks I did love, because they were beautiful and called forth beauty from all they touched. Also they were brave who defied the Persian might and had they but stood together, might have queened it on the earth. But they would not, for ever State tore out the throat of State, so that in the end all were undone and overwhelmed by a multitude of commoner folk who held Greece before them, for such was their destiny. Moreover, they worshipped gods made like themselves, with all the faults of men grown greater and more vile, and told fables concerning them fit to please children, which I thought strange in a people that could produce such philosophers and poets. Yet those gods had come down to them from their fathers, and it is hard to shake off the yoke of gods until some greater god appears and breaks it with the hammer of war. Here in Greece it was that I posed to its most famous sculptor for a statue of Aphrodite, or rather it was as a mould of perfect Womanhood that I posed, desiring that this sculptor, who pleased me, should have one flawless model to copy in his future work, for which he blessed me, naming that statue “Beauty’s Self.” Yet when I visited him a while afterward I found that he had changed this name to Aphrodite. I was angered who did not desire that my loveliness should be accredited to mine enemy and that of Isis whom I served, and asked him why this had been done.
  • 61. He answered, humbly enough, because of a dream in which the Paphian had appeared to him and threatened him with blindness unless he gave her own name to so divine a face and form. Moreover, being in the thrall of superstition he prayed me, even with tears, that thus it might remain, since otherwise he must break that statue and as he thought, be blinded as well. So out of pity I let him have his way and even gave him my hand to kiss in token of forgiveness. Thus it comes about that Aphrodite unashamed throughout the ages has taken the tribute of a million eyes, clothed in a borrowed loveliness. So be it, since what she has stolen is but a fraction of the truth. No sculptor, however great, can mould the perfect out of frozen stone. From Greece, still disguised as a merchant and his daughter, we wandered to Jerusalem, feigning to trade in pearls and gems, since there I would study the religion of the Jews whereof I had heard so much. The “City of Peace” it was called among the Egyptians of old times, or so they interpreted its name, but never found I one in which there was less of peace. Fierce-faced were those Jews and quarrelsome; revengeful too and ever waging war, public and private, upon one another. A peculiar people, as they name themselves, full of hate, particularly of the stranger within their gates. To trade with them was scarcely possible, because he who sold them wares was always left the loser, though for this I who sought their philosophy, not their gold, cared nothing. So I turned myself to the study of their faith, and found that God, as they interpreted Him, was well-nigh as fierce as were his worshippers. Yet this I will say, that He was one God, not many, and a true God also, since otherwise how could his prophets have written so gloriously concerning Him? Moreover, it was their belief that He would come to earth and lead them to the conquest of the world. This, Holly tells me, has chanced though not in the shape they hoped, since the King who came would have led them but to the conquest of the evil that is in the hearts of men and to the knowledge of a life to be, in which they had small faith. Therefore they persecuted and slew Him as a malefactor after their cruel
  • 62. fashion, and what is now accepted by millions, so says Holly, they still reject. I preached to them, for my heart burned in me at the sight of their sacrifices. Yes, I preached to them against the shedding of blood, telling them of a higher philosophy of gentleness and mercy. For a while they listened, then took up stones and stoned me, so that had I and Noot not been protected by Heaven, we should have been slain. After this affront I turned my back upon Jerusalem and its hook-nosed, fierce-eyed people, and went to Cyprus where I debated with the lewd priests of Aphrodite at Paphos. Thence I got me back to Egypt whence I had been absent many years. At Naukratis priests of Isis who knew of our coming, how I cannot tell, perchance Noot had told them by messenger, or in a dream as he could do, met us and conducted us up the Nile to the temple of Isis at Memphis. Here we were received in state in the great hall of the temple and lo! at the head of those who welcomed us was the Greek Kallikrates, now by his holiness and zeal risen high in the service of the goddess. When I saw him, beauteous as of old, my heart stood still and the blood rushed to my brow. Yet I gave no sign, treating him as a stranger on whom my eyes had never fallen until that hour. He for his part stared at me with a puzzled air, then shook his head as one does who sees a face that he believes he has met in dream and yet is doubtful. For be it remembered, this man had looked on me but once, when robed as Isis I received him into the company of her priests at Philæ, and then but for a moment in the light of the moon. Perchance he still thought that it was the goddess herself whom he saw thus and not a mortal. At the least he did not know that I, the beauteous prophetess who came to Memphis after wandering through the world, was the same as she who had sat upon the throne of Isis at Philæ and whom by chance he had kissed upon the lips. Mayhap even he did not remember the kiss, or if he remembered, set it down as part of the ceremonial. Thus, if I knew him but too well, to him I was a stranger.
  • 63. I bethought me of flight, knowing in my heart that to me this man was as the fabled sword that hung above the head of Damocles, though what harm I had to fear from him, I did not know. Again I sought the counsel of Noot who smiled and answered, “Have I not told you, Daughter, that perils must be faced since those from which we flee will be swift to overtake us? If Destiny has brought you and this man together, be certain that it is for its own purposes. Surely you have learned your lesson and steeled your soul against all fleshly vanities.” “Yes, my Father,” I answered proudly, “I have learned my lesson and steeled my soul. Moreover, your thought is my thought, nor will I turn my back on any man. Here I bide, defying woman’s weakness and all the wiles of evil gods.” “Well spoken,” answered Noot, and blessed me in the ancient words. Yet as he did so I noted that he sighed and shook his head. For many a moon, I know not how many who, having all time at my command, seem to have lost its petty count, I remained there in the temple at Memphis of which soon I became the prophetess and the head of the priestesses. Ere long the fame of my divinations spread far and wide, so that from all the land those who sought wisdom or knowledge of the future would come to consult me, bringing great gifts to the goddess, though not one gem or piece of gold did Noot or I keep for ourselves, who indeed had no need of such common dross. So I sat in a carven chair in the sanctuary, my diviner’s bowl at my side, and uttered dark sayings like to those of the famous oracles of the Greeks at Delphi, many of which fulfilled themselves. For in truth, I think that there was a spirit in me—whether it came from the Heavens or elsewhere I do not know—which enabled me to read much that was passing upon the earth and even sometimes that which had not yet happened upon the earth. So the renown of the Lady Isis spread till I became a power in the land. Moreover, thus I learned many things, for those who consult an oracle, like those who seek the help of a physician, lay bare their souls, keeping no secret back.
  • 64. Now at this time Egypt and all the countries round seethed with war like a pot boiling on the flames. For years Egypt had beaten off the attacks of the Persians, but now the Pharaoh Nectanebes, the second of that name who then sat upon the throne, the last native king who reigned upon the Nile, was threatened by Artaxerxes, that one of this accursed race who was named Ochus. This Persian Ochus had gathered a mighty force to subdue Egypt, hundreds of thousands of men, tens of thousands of horsemen, hundreds of triremes and of transport ships. The last act of the tragedy had begun of which the end was to be the crushing of Egypt who never more should know a Pharaoh of her own blood and choosing. Of all these things I learned through those who came to consult the oracle of Isis, and much did I talk of them with Noot. Now of myself during these long years of quiet and preparation for great events, I will say that ever my spirit grew in purity and strength. I put the things of earth behind me, I grew nearer to the Divine, and in the night time I communed with my soul which seemed to have become a part of that which is above the world. The Greek, Kallikrates, I saw continually, but no word passed between us save such as had to do with matters of our faith and of the worship of Isis in whose service he now stood high. Never did we interchange a touch or a look of love. He was apart from me and I from him. And yet always in my heart I feared this man, this beautiful man, the warrior who had become a priest, for some prescience told me that he would bring disaster on my head, or I should bring it upon his, I knew not which. So there we sat in the sanctuary, Noot the wise and aged, who yet never seemed to change, Kallikrates the priest, and I, and alone or together gave counsel to kings and captains, or uttered oracles. Clear seemed our sky and free from trouble, yet on the far horizon in my spirit I discerned the tempest clouds arising, the terrible clouds in which the lightnings played like the swords of Destiny that in a day to come were doomed to overwhelm and pierce us through. Nectanebes the second, the Pharaoh, came to his palace at Memphis to gather troops from Upper Egypt and made great
  • 65. offerings to the gods, seeking their favour in the coming war. Now I saw him for the first time, a gray-haired, fat, heavy-jowled man, bald-headed, large-nosed, with great eyes like to those of an ox. Such was Nectanebes, the magician, the consorter with familiar spirits, named the Destroyer, a title which the gods who hated him must have given him in irony since himself he was doomed to be destroyed. But one good thing can I say of this Nectanebes, that he was a lover of the arts and raised glorious buildings to the gods. Learning that I, the high-priestess, had dwelt at Philæ, he came to consult me as to the beautiful temple with the Hathor-headed columns which he built there and through my counsel it was made perfect, for I drew its plans, or at least those of its adornments. Holly tells me that even as a ruin, although so small, there is no lovelier building in all Egypt. Now this Pharaoh thought me a Greek and did not know that I was Arab and the daughter of him of Ozal in Yaman, whom his father, the first Nectanebes, had brought to his death because once long ago I had been refused as a wife to himself or to this son of his who now had succeeded him. Of these things doubtless he remembered little or nothing, since that was one of the smallest of Egypt’s wars. But I, I remembered and swore that in payment for my father’s blood I would bring his accursed House to ruin. Always also I received him veiled since I did not desire that he should look upon my beauty and inquire concerning my history; therefore, as a prophetess had a right to do, I received the Pharaoh veiled. Often he came to visit me because he had learned that I was a mistress of Magic and he who practised magic much hoped that I would teach him secrets he did not know, and show him how to lay spells upon his enemies. This indeed I did, but the secrets that I taught him were evil and the spells were spears that when he threw them would fall back upon his head. So the scene was set, and at length came the summons to begin the play with the watching world for audience. A writing sealed with Pharaoh’s seal was brought to the temple of Isis, commanding Noot the high-priest, and me, Ayesha, who now was named Oracle-of-Isis, and the Greek Kallikrates, Chief of the
  • 66. Ceremonies, whose office it was to assist me in my divinations, to attend the court of Pharaoh and there declare to him the future of the war as it should be revealed to us by the great goddess whom we served. At first we refused to go, whereon there came another message which said that if we continued to refuse, we should be brought. The Pharaoh wished to offer no affront to Isis, the messenger declared, but the matter was urgent, as great things hung upon the revelations which we alone could make, and some of the kings and generals who were gathered in the temple as allies of Nectanebes, being the worshippers of other gods, could not set foot in the holy shrine of Isis. Then, there being no help for it, we answered that we would come that very night at the rising of the moon. Hastily consulting together we planned the words of an oracle, double-edged words that yet prophesied good to Nectanebes and encouraged him to war; for thus we believed we should most quickly bring about his downfall. Yet as those words were never spoken I will not write them down.
  • 67. CHAPTER VI The Divination Accompanied by the priests and priestesses of Isis clad in their robes and chanting the holy songs, I was borne veiled to the palace of the Pharaoh in a litter, with its curtains drawn. On my right hand walked Noot the high-priest, white-bearded, venerable; and on my left the Greek Kallikrates, Master of the Rites. Thus we came to the palace of which the outer courts were filled with Grecian soldiers of the guard, some of whom in past years Kallikrates had once commanded, although as a shaven priest of Isis, disguised in his white robes, they knew him no more. These men stared at us, ready to mock and yet afraid, as did Phœnicians, Sidonians, men of Cyprus, and others who were gathered in the courts as though awaiting some great event. In an outer hall a captain of the guard bade our escort of priests and priestesses to await our return, but we three, that is I, Ayesha, Noot, and Kallikrates, were summoned to the small banqueting chamber where Nectanebes with a few of the most highly placed of his guests sat at their feast. Among these were the King of Sidon, two more kings from Cyprus, three Grecian generals, some great nobles of Egypt, and others. Also certain royal ladies were present, and among them one who instantly drew my eyes to her. She was younger than I—perchance there may have been ten years between us, tall, slender, and lovely in her dark fashion, with a strong, quiet face and large brooding eyes, soft as a deer’s and rather blue than black in colour. Suddenly as we entered I, who note all, saw these eyes grow frightened like to those of one who sees some spirit returned from the halls of Death; saw also the rich-hued face turn pale, then grow red again as the blood flowed back; saw the breast heave beneath the jewelled robes, so sharply that a flower fell from them, and the lips of coral part as though to utter some remembered name.
  • 68. Wondering what had thus disturbed this beauteous royalty since I, being veiled, it could not have been the vision of myself, I glanced round and perceived that Kallikrates, who was on my left, but a little behind me, had become pale as a dead man and stood like one frozen into stone. “Who is that royal woman?” I whispered to Noot through my veil, for royal I knew her to be by the Uræus circlet she wore upon her raven hair. “Pharaoh’s daughter, Amenartas,” he whispered back, “whom the Greeks call The Maiden because she will take no man in marriage.” Then I remembered a certain confession that once I had heard sitting on the throne of the goddess Isis at Philæ, of how the penitent had loved a girl of the royal House of Egypt, and for her sake killed his own dear brother; remembered also that this penitent was none other than the priest Kallikrates. Now I understood all, and though Kallikrates was naught to me save a fellow servant of the goddess, I hated that Amenartas and became aware that between her and me there was war unending, though how and why I knew not. Next I looked at a man clad in kingly robes who sat on Pharaoh’s right. He was a large man of about five and forty years of age with dark, handsome face and shifting eyes; one with a jovial aspect which yet I felt to be but a mask covering a heart full of evil schemes. From his purple robe sewn with pearls and the style of his attire and headdress I guessed that this must be Tenes the Phœnician, King of the city of Sidon that was reported the wealthiest in the world, which city, having revolted, had joined Egypt in its war against the Persians. Instantly I weighed that man in the balance of my mind and wrote him down as an ambitious rogue who was also a coward and, as I judged from the many charms he wore, full of superstition. The others I had no time to study for at once the Pharaoh began to speak. “Greeting, Prophetess,” he said, rising from his chair and bowing to us, or rather to me, “Greeting, High-priest of Isis, Queen of
  • 69. Heaven, Mistress of the World; greeting also, Priest, Master of the Rites of Isis. Pharaoh thanks you all for thus promptly answering to his summons, since this night Egypt needs your wisdom more perchance than ever before in all the ages of its history.” “Be pleased, O Pharaoh, to set out what you desire of us, the servants of the eternal goddess,” said Noot. “This, High-priest: that you should declare the future to us. Hearken! As you know, the great war has begun. The mighty Tenes here, King of Sidon, my ally, by the help of the Greeks I sent him, has defeated the Persians and against these Cyprus also is in revolt. But now Artaxerxes Ochus has seized the throne of Persia, having murdered all who stood between it and him, with the help of Bagoas the eunuch, his counsellor and general. He has raised a countless host and is pouring down upon Sidon and upon Egypt. Therefore we would learn how the war shall go and to what gods we must sacrifice to secure the victory.” “O Pharaoh,” answered Noot, “in bygone years when your father sat upon the throne and I was the Kherheb, yes, the first magician of Egypt, he asked me such questions as these, and having prayed to my goddess, I answered him in the words that she commanded. None heard those words save your father himself, for he and I were alone together. Yet there was that in them which made him wroth so that he sought to kill me, and to save my life I fled out of Egypt, going whither the goddess led me. Afterward I was called back to Egypt where once more I am high-priest of Isis though the office of Kherheb is filled by another. How know I, Pharaoh, if I obey you as I obeyed your father, and again the goddess should utter prophecies which are not pleasing to the ears of kings, that once more my life may not be sought in payment?” “I swear, High-priest,” answered Nectanebes eagerly, “that whatever may be revealed by the goddess, you shall take no harm. I swear it by the name and throne of the holy Isis, to whom I will make great gifts, and all this company are witnesses of the oath. If it be broken, may the curse of Isis and of all the gods of Egypt fall upon the head of me and mine. Draw nigh now that I may touch you with my sceptre, thereby forgiving all that you have said or shall say
  • 70. against me or my House, and restoring to you your office of Kherheb of Egypt, whereof my father, who to-day is gathered in Osiris, robbed you.” So Noot drew near and Pharaoh touched him with his sceptre, a cedar wand surmounted with a little golden image of Horus, which he always carried because of his throne-name which signified “Horus-of-Gold.” Moreover, he re-created him Kherheb and in token of it set upon his shoulders the gold chain from his own neck, and swore to him his place and power for life and the gift of an alabaster coffin wherein to lie after life was done. This sarcophagus, however, Noot refused, saying darkly that it was fated that he should sleep his last sleep far away from Egypt. Then he, Noot, drew back and as he went I saw Pharaoh’s daughter rise and whisper awhile in her father’s ear. He listened and nodded. Then he said, “Come hither, priest who is named ‘Lover-of-Isis’ and Master of her rites, the royal Lady of Egypt says to me that in bygone days when she was scarce a woman, she thinks that before you were a priest, you held some command amongst the Greeks of my guard, as from your stature and bearing I can well believe. She says also that if her memory serves her, you slew some man in a quarrel and for this reason fled away and sought refuge with Isis. If such things happened I have forgotten them, nor do I ask concerning them. Let them lie. Yet, lest you should be afraid that old tales may be told against you or vengeance wrought upon you, come hither also and receive pardon for the past, and protection and advancement for the future and with these a gift from Pharaoh.” Now I marvelled at this lady’s foresight and cunning which showed her how to take advantage of Pharaoh’s mood and safeguard one who once had loved her, all of which told me that she must be a wise woman as well as beauteous. Also it told me that the worship of this man had been pleasing to her. Then Kallikrates drew near and was touched with the sceptre. Moreover, Pharaoh spoke to him in like words that he had spoken to Noot, pardoning him all and promising him much. Moreover, in token of his favour he gave him a gold cup of Grecian workmanship having two handles, that was chased about with the story of the loves of Aphrodite and Adonis,
  • 71. and bordered with a wreath of those anemones which were fabled to have sprung from his blood. This glorious, flower-like cup from which the guests, when we entered, were pledging themselves in wine of Cyprus, Pharaoh lifted from the board and sent to Kallikrates, a great gift which made it clear to me how deeply he desired to propitiate the goddess in the persons of her servants. Lastly the private scribe was commanded to write down these decrees that he had spoken, which he did forthwith, sealing them with Pharaoh’s seal and giving one copy to Noot whilst keeping the other to be filed among the records. Thus Noot and Kallikrates were protected from all things, but to me, the Prophetess, nothing was said, as I thought for two reasons, first because I was known to Pharaoh, who as I have told, had often consulted me upon matters of magic, and secondly because as the “voice of the goddess” I was holy and above reward or punishment at the hands of man. Thus I thought, with how much truth shall be seen. The gifts were received, the papyrus had been hidden away in the robe of Noot, and there was silence in the chamber. To me, Ayesha, this heavy silence was full of omen. My soul, made keen and fine with ceaseless contemplation of things that are above the earth, in that silence seemed to hear the breath of the watching gods of Egypt. To me it was as though they had gathered there to listen to the fate of this their ancient home on earth. Yes, I felt them about me; or at the least I felt a spirit stirring. The company at the table drank no more wine and ceased from speech. They sat still staring in front of them and notwithstanding the glitter of the ornaments that proclaimed their royalty or rule, to me they were as dead men in a tomb. Only the Princess of Egypt, Amenartas, seemed to be alive and outside the circle of this doom, for I noted that her splendid eyes sought the face, the perfect, carven face of the priest Kallikrates and that though he stood with folded arms and gaze fixed upon the ground, he knew it, for now and again covertly he glanced back at her. At length one of those guests could bear no more, and spoke. He was a close-lipped, war-worn Grecian general who afterward I
  • 72. learned was named Kleinios of Cos, the commander of Pharaoh’s mercenary forces. “By Zeus!” he cried, “are we men or are we stones, or are we shades in Hades? Let these diviners divine and have done, for I would get me to my wine again.” “Aye,” broke in Tenes, King of Sidon. “Bid them divine, Pharaoh, since we have much to agree upon ere I sail at dawn.” Then all the company cried, “Divine! Divine!” save Amenartas only, who searched the face of Kallikrates with her eyes, as though she would learn what lay behind its cold and priestly mask. “So be it,” said Noot, “but first I pray Pharaoh to bid all mean men depart.” Pharaoh waved his sceptre and the butlers and attendants bowed and went. Then Noot motioned to Kallikrates, who thereon shook the sistrum that he bore and, in his rich, low voice, uttered a chant to the goddess, that which was used to summon her presence. He ended his chant and Noot began to pray. “Hear me, thy prophet, O thou who wast and art and shalt be, thou in whose bosom is locked all the wisdom of heaven and earth,” he prayed. “These kings and great ones desire knowledge, declare it unto them according to thy will. They desire truth—let them learn the truth in such fashion as thou shalt decree.” Then he was silent. None spoke, yet it seemed that a command came to the three of us, for suddenly Noot looked at the priest Kallikrates, a very strange look. Next the priest Kallikrates, rising from his knees, laid down the sistrum and taking the beautiful cup that Pharaoh had given him, went to the table and washed it with pure water from a silver ewer, then filled it to the brim from the ewer and brought it to me, Ayesha. Now I knew that I was commanded to gaze into that cup and to say what things I saw. So I set it on the ground in front of me and kneeling, threw my veil over it and gazed into the water in the shallow golden cup. For a little while I saw nothing, till presently a face formed in the water, the face of the royal lady, Amenartas, which stared up at me out of the cup. Yes, it stared hard and seemed to threaten me,
  • 73. for in its eyes were hate and vengeance. Then another face came and covered it, the face of Kallikrates the priest, and in its eyes were trouble and desire. Now I knew that the goddess Isis, or perchance another, she of the Greeks, spoke to me of matters that had to do with myself and not with the fate of Egypt. In my heart I prayed to the Queen of Heaven to rid me of these visions, though to give me others I did not pray her, since it was my design to speak certain politic words which we had prepared. Yet other visions came unsought, for some spirit possessed me, a spirit of truth and destiny. They were many and all of them terrible. I saw battlefields; I saw men fall in thousands, I saw cities in flames. I saw that false-eyed king, Tenes, dead. I saw the General, Kleinios of Cos, also dead, lying on a heap of Grecian slain. I saw the Pharaoh Nectanebes flying up Nile upon a boat—I knew it was up Nile because the current rippled against the prow of his ship, I saw him seized by black savages and throttled with a rope till his tongue hung out and the great round eyes started from his head. I saw the temples of Egypt burning and a fierce-faced, drunken king hacking at the statues of the gods with a Persian sword and butchering the priests upon the altar. Then I saw no more but a voice called in my ears, “Death to Egypt! Death and desolation! Death to her king, death to her priests, death to her gods! Finished, finished, all is finished!” I cast the bowl from me. It overset but lo! there flowed from it not water but blood, or dark-hued wine, staining the white marble of the pavement. I stared at it! All stared at this god-sent horror! “A trick!” cried the Princess Amenartas. “She has coloured the water behind the shelter of her veil.” The others too, especially the Greeks, took up the cry, echoing, “A trick, a brazen trick!” Only I noted that Pharaoh was silent, Pharaoh who knew that Ayesha, named Isis-come-to-Earth, did not deal in tricks; Pharaoh who himself practised magic and had seen such omens sent by Set. Lo! Pharaoh looked afraid and spoke no word, only glared with his great eyes at the stain upon the marble.
  • 74. “What answer did the goddess give to your prayer, Prophetess,” asked Amenartas, sneering at me. “This answer, royal Lady of Egypt,” and I pointed to the marble, “the answer of blood.” “Blood! Whose blood? That of the Persians?” “Nay, Lady, that of many who sit at this feast and who ere long shall sit at the table of Osiris, and of thousands who cling to them. Yet be comforted, Lady, not your blood. I think that you have much mischief to work ere you sit also at the table of Osiris, or mayhap at that of Set,” I added, giving thrust for thrust. “Declare then their names, Seeress.” “Nay, I declare them not. Go, seek them for yourself, Lady, or let Pharaoh your father seek, for is he not a magician? though what god gives him vision I do not know. You name me cheat, or rather you name the goddess cheat. Therefore the goddess is dumb and her prophetess is dumb.” “Aye, I name you cheat,” she cried, who in her heart was mad with fear, “and cheat you are. Now let this temple hag who hides her hideousness behind a silken screen unveil that we may see her as she is, and let her be searched and the vase of dye be taken from her bosom or her robes.” “Aye, let her be searched,” shouted the guests who were also afraid. “No need to search, high lords,” I said in a quavering voice, as though I too were overcome with fear. “I will obey the Princess. I will unveil, yet I beseech you all, make not a mock of me when you see me as I am. Once I was perchance as fair as that royal Lady who commands, but years of abstinence and the sleepless search for wisdom mar the features and wither the frame. Moreover, time touches the locks, such of them as remain to me, since these too grow thin with age. Yet I will unveil and the vase of precious dye shall be the prize of him who first can snatch it from my bosom or my robe.” “Aye,” said one of them, it was the king Tenes, “and in payment for her trick we will make her drink what remains of it to give colour to her poor old carcase.”
  • 75. “Aye,” I answered, “and I will drink what remains of it for I think the stuff is harmless. Oh! be not angry because a poor conjurer plays her tricks.” Now Noot stared at me as though he were about to speak. Then his face changed like to that of a man who of a sudden receives a command that others cannot hear. He let fall his eyes, remaining silent, and I, watching, knew that it was the will of the goddess, or at least Noot’s will, that I should unveil. I glanced at the priest Kallikrates but he stood still, looking like Apollo’s self frozen into stone. During this play I had loosened the fastenings of my veil and hood and now of a sudden I cast them from me, revealing myself clad as Isis, that is in little save a transparent, clinging robe fastened about my middle. On my breast, hanging from a chain of pearls, were her holy symbols carved in gems and gold, and on my head her vulture cap beneath which my tresses hung almost to my feet, having the golden feathers of the cap adorned with sapphires and with rubies and the uræus rising from it fashioned of glittering diamonds. Aye, I unveiled and stood before them, my arms folded upon the jewelled girdle beneath my breast. “Behold! Kings and Lords,” I said, “the temple hag stands before you in such poor shape as it has pleased the gods to fashion her. Now let him who can see it, come, take the vase that hides this unveiled trickster’s dye.” For a moment there was silence while those brutal men devoured my white loveliness with their eyes, taking count of every beauty of my perfect face and form. Amenartas stared at me and her ruddy cheeks went pale; yes, even the coral faded from her rich lips. Then from between those lips there burst these words: “This is not a woman! This is the very goddess. Beware of her, ye men, for she is terrible.” “Nay, nay,” I answered humbly, “I am but a poor mortal, not even royal like to yourself, Lady—but a poor mortal with some wits and wisdom, though perchance Isis for a while to your sight has
  • 76. touched me with her splendour. Come, take the vase ere I veil myself again.” Then those men went mad, all save Pharaoh, who sat brooding. “Goddess or woman,” they cried, “give her to us who henceforward can never look upon the beauty of another.” King Tenes rose, his coarse face afire and his shifting eyes fixed upon me greedily. “By Baal and by Ashtoreth!” he cried, “goddess or woman, never have I seen such an one as this prophetess of Isis. Hearken, Pharaoh, before the feast we disputed together concerning a great sum of gold and in the end it was confessed by you that it was due to me in aid of my costs of war although, so you said, it could not be found in Egypt save by raiding the rich treasury of Isis. Perchance the goddess learned of this design of yours and by way of answer sent us an evil oracle. I know not, but this I do know, that she sent you also a means to pay the debt without cost to yourself or the robbing of her sacred treasury. Give me this fair priestess to comfort me with her wisdom and otherwise”—here the company laughed coarsely—“and I will talk no more of the matter of that gold.” Pharaoh listened without raising his head, then looked on me with rolling eyes and answered: “Which would anger the goddess most, King Tenes—to lose her gold or her prophetess?” “The former as I think, Pharaoh, seeing that gold is scarce, and prophetesses—true or false—are many. Give her to me, I say.” “I cannot for my oath’s sake, King Tenes.” “You swore an oath to yonder high-priest and to yonder man, who looks like a Grecian god clad in a priest’s robe and is called Master-of-the-Rites, but to this lady you swore none.” “I swore the oath to Isis, King Tenes, and if I break it doubtless she will be avenged upon me. Go your way; the gold shall follow you to the last ounce, but the prophetess is not mine to give.” Now Tenes stared at me again and I, who hated him with all my soul, gave him back his stare with interest, though this did but seem to inflame him the more. Then he turned on Pharaoh furiously and answered in a cold voice,
  • 77. “Hear me, Pharaoh. It is but a small matter, yet my mind is set upon this woman who knows the heart of the gods and can pour their wisdom into my ears. Therefore make your choice: “In Sidon there are two factions of almost equal strength. One of them says ‘Make an alliance with Egypt and fight the Persian Ochus whom already you have defeated once.’ The other says ‘Make an alliance with Ochus and as reward in a day to come sit on Pharaoh’s throne!’ I have taken the first counsel as you know. Yet it is not too late to change that counsel for a second which perchance would prove the wiser, if there be aught in yonder divination,” and he pointed to the blood-stain upon the marble floor. Then he went on: “Moreover, I have my captains about me at this board and those that serve me wait without with all my fleet, and therefore should it be changed I need not fear to tell you so and to your face. So I say to you that if you will not please me in this small matter, presently my ambassadors go forth to Susa with a message for the ear of Ochus to which it would rejoice you to listen, seeing that without the strong aid of Sidon and her fleets Egypt cannot conquer in this war.” Thus Tenes spoke and laid his hand upon the pommel of his short Phœnician sword. Now the face of Pharaoh, bearded thus in his own city and at his own board, grew red with rage and I saw that he was about to answer this outland king, defying him as many of the great monarchs who filled his throne before him would have done. But ere he could speak his royal daughter Amenartas whispered in his ear and although I could not hear her words, I read their purport in her face. They were—“Tenes speaks truth. Without Sidon you cannot stand against the Persians and Egypt is lost. Let the woman go. Isis, understanding, will forgive, who otherwise must see the Persian Holy Fire burning on her altars.” Pharaoh heard and the anger written in his eyes was changed to trouble. Rolling them in his fashion he looked on Noot and said to him as one who asks a question, “I swore an oath to you, Kherheb, and to yonder priest, but to the prophetess I swore no oath and perchance Egypt’s fate hangs
  • 78. upon this business.” The old high-priest paused awhile like a man who awaits a message. If so, it seemed to come, for presently he answered in a quiet voice, “Pharaoh is right; Egypt’s fate hangs upon this business; also Pharaoh’s fate; also that of King Tenes and many others. The only fate which is not touched, whether it be finished in this way or in that, is the fate of yonder seeress who is named Isis-come-to-Earth, since the goddess will protect her own. Settle the matter as you will, Pharaoh. Only settle it swiftly, because under our rule it is time that I and my company who wait without should return to the temple to make our nightly prayer and offerings to the goddess, the Queen of all the earth, the Queen of Pharaoh and of Egypt; the Queen of the King of Sidon, and in the end the Queen also of Artaxerxes Ochus, the Persian, as one day surely he shall learn.” Thus spoke Noot unconcernedly and hearing him, I laughed, for now I was sure that I had nothing to fear from Tenes or from any other man upon the earth. Therefore I laughed, which that company thought strange in one who was about to be borne away a slave, and bade Kallikrates give me my veil and hood, also the cloak that I had thrown off when I entered the banqueting hall. He obeyed, and while he was assisting me to cover up my beauty in the folds of that veil, I noted that alone among all the men here present, this beauty did not seem to stir him at all. Had he been clothing a marble or an ivory image of the goddess, as every day it was his duty to do at sunrise, anointing it with perfumes and garlanding it with flowers, he could not have been less moved. Or perhaps so truly had the priest in him overcome the man that he had learned to cloak all the feelings of a man. Or perhaps it was because that royal Amenartas watched his every movement with her eyes. I know not, but this I do know, that his calm angered me and it came into my mind that were I not the head-priestess of Isis and sworn to her, there should be a different tale to tell. Yes, even in that moment of destiny this came into my mind, which shows that in my soul I had not forgotten the meeting of our lips in yonder shrine
  • 79. at Philæ. At least I have often thought so since, I, who have had much time for thought. “Priestess, you are mine,” cried King Tenes in triumph. “Make ready to sail with me for Sidon within an hour.” “Do you think that I am yours, King Tenes?” I asked in a musing voice as I fastened the folds of my veil and arranged the hood. “If so, I hold otherwise. I hold that I, Ayesha, a free-born lady of the ancient Arab blood, am not the slave of any Phœnician who for a little while chances to be a king, but of her who is the Queen of kings, Isis the Mother. Nay, Tenes, I am more, I am Isis herself, Isis- come-to-Earth. It seems that go with you I must, since such is the will of the goddess, but, Phœnician, take heed. Should you dare to befoul me even with a touch, I tell you that I have strength at my command and that ere long Sidon shall lack a king and Set shall gain a subject. For your own sake therefore and for that of Sidon, think again and let me be!” Now the great jaws of Tenes fell and he stared at me open- mouthed. “Yet you shall go with me,” he muttered thickly, “and for the rest Ashtoreth rules in Sidon, not Isis, for know that there are two Queens of Heaven.” “Aye, Tenes, a false queen and a true, and let the false beware of the true.” Then I turned to Nectanebes and said, “Is it still your command, O Pharaoh, that I accompany this ally of yours to Sidon? Bethink you ere you answer, since much hangs upon your words.” “Yea, Priestess, it must be so. I have spoken and my decree is recorded. The fate of Egypt is more than that of any priestess and doubtless King Tenes will treat you well. If not, you say that you have strength to defend yourself against him.” Now as I answered, I laughed lightly and the sound of my laughter was like the tinkle of falling silver. “So be it, Pharaoh. To me it is nothing; indeed I would see Sidon, the glorious city, while she still is Sidon, home of merchants, mistress of the seas. Still ere I go, shall I tell you something,
  • 80. Pharaoh, of what was shewn to me in yonder bowl before its water was turned to blood—by dye from that vase which none of you has found? If I remember right, for as you who practise magic, know, Pharaoh, such visions fade quickly like dreams at dawn—I say that if I remember right, it had to do with the fate of a great king. Have you ever seen a king, O Pharaoh, when in place of the chain of royalty a collar of rope is set about his throat and drawn hard till the tongue is thrust from the royal mouth and the royal eyes start from their sockets? Nay? Then shall I draw his picture? Perchance in days to come you would know it again?” “Witch, accursed witch!” shouted Pharaoh. “Take her, Tenes, and begone, though sooner would I nurture a viper in my bosom,” and rising from the board, he turned and fled away. Again I laughed as I answered, “I must go, but it seems that Pharaoh has gone first. Royal Amenartas, watch the good god, your father, for I think that he is too superstitious and that which men believe fulfils itself upon them.” Then I went to Noot and spoke with him—few words for already the guards were advancing upon me. “Fear nothing, Daughter,” he said, “you are safe.” “I know that I am safe, Master, yet be ready to come to my aid when I call, as my spirit tells me that call I shall.” He bent his head and the guards came up. As I went I glanced at the priest Kallikrates, who taking no note of me or of my fate, still stood staring at the royal Amenartas like a statue cut in stone, while she stared back at him.
  • 81. CHAPTER VII The Quelling of the Storm They set me on board a great ship, on the prow of which were images of certain gods of the Phœnicians, called by the Greeks Pataeci, not unlike to that which the Egyptians worshipped by the name of Bes, before which images burned fire. There was a royal cabin in that ship which was given to me, and with it splendid robes and furnishings of gold for my table. At dawn we cast off from the quay of the white-walled city while thousands of the worshippers of Isis who learned that I was being taken from them, stood upon the quay and wailed, crying that the Mouth-of-Isis was sent away to slavery and that where her “Mouth” went, there the goddess would follow, leaving vengeance to fall upon their heads. For that the head-priestess of Isis should be given into the hands of barbarians and their foreign gods was such a crime as had not been known in Egypt. Therefore they wailed, prophesying evil, and I stood upon the stern alone in my white robes, veiled, and hearkened to them, for none dared to come near to me. Yes, I hearkened and blessed them with my hands, whereat they knelt and wailed the more. When at last we had passed down the Nile and were out upon the great sea, sailing swiftly for Sidon over quiet waters, I, Ayesha, having taken counsel of the goddess and of my woman’s craft, sent for King Tenes, who was also on board the ship, and received him in his own cabin that had been given up to me. For my heart was black with rage against him, and against Nectanebes, Pharaoh of Egypt, who had betrayed me, and in my heart I swore that I would destroy them both. Yes, there I, the captive, sat and received the captor king in his own cabin, purposing his doom, though how this was to be accomplished as yet I did not know.
  • 82. “O King,” I said, “I, your slave who, when not a slave, was high- priestess of Isis in Egypt and her seeress, into whose breast the goddess poured her wisdom and her secrets, as indeed still she does, would speak with you, and since I could not come to you among so many men, have prayed your Majesty to come to me. What would you do with me, King Tenes, since it has pleased you to force Pharaoh to give me into your keeping? Is it an oracle that you desire concerning your fate or that of your country in the war? If so, I will——” “Nay, Priestess,” he broke in hurriedly, “of your oracles I and others have had enough. They are bitter bread for daily food. Keep them, I pray you, to nurture your own soul.” “What would you of me then, King Tenes, that you have been at such pains to steal me away from Egypt, even threatening Pharaoh to break your solemn pact with him if he did not give me into your hands, me, the snared bird, who by chance was left out of his oath to the high-priest and Isis’s officer, the Greek.” “Lady Ayesha,” blurted out Tenes, “that I have learned to be by birth, daughter of Yarab, once ruler of Ozal, upon whom, with the Egyptians, I made war in the past and brought to his death, because of you, Lady, tell me, you who are wise, what would any man of you who had beheld your beauty as I saw it some nights gone?” “Man, being man, that is, a ravening beast fashioned like a god in shape but not in soul, would make me his prey, Tenes. Such at least was the desire of the first Nectanebes whom you aided with the ships of Sidon to destroy my father, and of many since his time.” “Good. Well, I who am a man and something more, being not a god indeed, but a great king, would make you my prey, as you say, for to tell truth, having once looked on you I seek no other woman in the whole world.” Now I threw back my veil and studied him with my eyes. “So you would take me for your queen, Tenes? Indeed I guessed as much. But what would your other queen, for doubtless you have one, say to this, O King?” “My queen!” he said in an astonished voice, “my queen?”
  • 83. “Surely, Tenes, you would scarcely dare to proffer less than queenship to such a one as I?” “May be not. Well, let us say that I would make you my queen, since in Sidon it is not difficult to be rid of others of whom one may be weary; that is, it is not difficult to a king who also is high-priest of Baal and of Ashtoreth. Yes, yes, I am sure that I would make you my queen. I will offer it to you in writing if you desire.” “Aye, I do desire it, King, and that there may be no faults or traps in it, I myself will draw up the writing for you to sign. Only I doubt much whether I shall accept the offer if it is made.” “Why not, Lady? Is it a small thing to be Queen of Sidon?” “For Ayesha, daughter of Yarab, high-priestess and prophetess of Isis, the wisest and most beauteous woman in the world, one who has never turned to look on man, it is a very small thing indeed, King Tenes. It is so small a thing that I will not deign to accept that proffered crown of yours, unless——” “Unless what, Lady?” “Unless it is made larger, King, so large and wide that she who wears it holds rule over all the earth.” “By Baal, Ashtoreth, and Moloch, all three of them, what mean you, Woman?” “What I say, Man. I mean that when you are monarch, not of Sidon only, but of Egypt, Cyprus, Persia, and all the East, then perchance I will marry you, unless my fancy changes, as it may do, but certainly not before.” “Surely you are mad,” he gasped. “How can I gather all these diadems upon a single brow? It is impossible.” “Aye, for you it is impossible, King Tenes, but for me it is possible. I can gather them and set them on your brow and on my own, I who have within me all the wisdom of the earth and much of the strength of Heaven. Understand that if I desire it and you follow my counsel, I can crown you emperor of the world, no less, but the question is, do I desire it and will you follow my counsel?” “Lady, I swear that you are mad, unless in truth you are a goddess as they say in Egypt.”
  • 84. “Perchance I am somewhat of a goddess, and being so, marvel whether for any reward that can be given I shall debase myself by taking such a one as you to husband, King Tenes. Now, first, look on me well and answer whether you do indeed desire me and are ready to win me through toil and danger, or whether you will let me be. For know, Tenes, that though I seem to be your captive, you cannot snare me or do me violence. Lay but a finger on me against my will, and it shall be your death, since I have those to aid me whom you cannot see. Now look—and answer.” He looked, devouring me with his greedy eyes, then said, “Of a truth I desire you more than anything on the earth, and since I may not do so otherwise, for I perceive that you are too strong for me, will take you at your own price. Yea, even if I must wait for years, still I will take you. Now tell me, most beauteous and most wise, what I must do, and swear to me that when I am king of all things you will wed me.” “Aye, Tenes, I swear that when you are king of all things I will wed you,” I answered gently, laughing in my heart as I remembered that the first and last of all things, the greatest of all things, is— Death. “Hearken. You shall bring me to Sidon, not as a captive but as a strange goddess who has come to aid you and your people, and with honour shall you receive me in Sidon, causing your priests and priestesses to offer me worship and incense.” “And if so, what then?” “Then, when I have studied your people and your preparations for war, we will take counsel together and I will show you how you may prevail. Tell me, Tenes, do you love Pharaoh Nectanebes?” “Nay, Lady, I hate him who asks too much and gives too little, as I hated his father before him. Still we sleep in the same bed and prop up the same wall, and if one of us ceases to support the wall, the Persians will push it down on both.” “I understand. Yet even so it comes into my mind that perchance you would have been safer had you been pushing at the wall with the Persian Ochus and not holding it up with the Egyptian Nectanebes.” He glanced at me with his shifting eyes and answered,
  • 85. “I have had that thought, as you know well, but having rebelled against Ochus, defeated his satraps, and slain thousands of his soldiers, or rather those of his father, if I climb the wall I might find spears waiting for me on the farther side. Lady, it is too late.” “Yes, King Tenes, perhaps it is too late; I will consider of the matter in your interest and my own. But first send me papyrus and writing tools that I may set down our pact. When you have approved and signed it, then I will consider of this and other matters and not before. For the while, farewell.” He rose and went unwillingly enough and when I was alone in the cabin I laughed in my heart. This fish had been easy to hook, but he was a large fish and strong, and I must beware lest he pull me into the deep sea where both might drown together. Moreover, the man was hateful to me, more so even than that ox-eyed, heavy- jowled Pharaoh, and his presence seemed to poison the air I breathed. Yet if I entered into this pact with him doubtless I must breathe it often, which vexed me who shrank from men and their desires, and above all from this man. Yet he had done me wrong and insult; he had helped the Egyptians to make war upon my people and he had taken me as a slave, me, Ayesha, thinking to make of me his woman, and cost what it might, I would pay him back as I would pay back Nectanebes who sold me. The papyrus was brought to me by a slave and on it I wrote such a contract as I think was never signed by a king before. It was brief and ran thus:— “Ayesha, daughter of Yarab, high-priestess of Isis, prophetess of Isis, known in Heaven and among her servants as Isis-come-to- Earth, and Child of Wisdom, to Tenes, King of Sidon. “When you, Tenes, are king not only of Sidon but of Egypt, Cyprus, Persia, and the East, as I can make you, if you obey me in all things, then I, Ayesha, vow myself to you as your sole wife and queen. But if, ere this dignity is mine and yours, you dare even to touch my robe, then in the name of Isis and speaking with the voice of Isis, I, Ayesha, vow to you shame and death in the world and after it all the torments of hell and the jaws of the Devourer that await the judgment of Thoth on perjured souls beyond the Sun.
  • 86. “Accepted and sealed by Ayesha, daughter of Yarab and by Tenes, King of Sidon.” Having copied this writing, I sent it to Tenes by the slave that he might study it. Awhile later he asked audience of me, and entering, said in a thick voice that only a madman would set his seal to such words. I looked at him and answered that it was nothing to me whether he sealed or did not seal them; indeed that considering all, I should be better pleased if he let the bargain be. He stared at me and rage took hold of him who was inflamed with wine. “Who are you,” he said, “that dare to talk thus to Tenes the King? You are but a woman clad in the robes of a priestess who pretend to powers you have not. Why should I not take you and have done?” Now I mocked him, answering, “Because I think you love to sit upon a throne better than to lie in a grave, Tenes, even in a king’s coffin. Still, as you desire to know more particularly, I will put your question to the goddess, who is not far from me even on this ship, and to-morrow when the sun is up I will pass on her words to you—that is, if you live to look upon to- morrow’s sun, King Tenes,” I added, staring him in the eyes. These words seemed to sober him, for he turned pale and left the cabin, making a sign to avert the evil eye, but as I noted, taking the writing with him. Yet me he left perplexed and afraid, for my heart was not so bold as my mouth! Now that night, whether by chance or by the will of Heaven, a great tempest sprang up suddenly. The captain of the trireme, a Greek or a half-Greek of Naukratis, Philo by name, whom now upon this ship I met for the first time, came himself to warn me, and to make sure that all was fast in my cabin. He was a quick-brained man, very active in his body and pleasant-faced, with a brown, pointed beard, who had seen some five and thirty years upon the earth. I had made inquiries concerning him from a certain slave who attended me, and was told that although he pretended to timidity,
  • 87. this Philo was in truth a great warrior and one of the best handlers of a bow upon the mouths of Nile, since that which he aimed at he always hit, even if it were a fowl in flight. Moreover, he was a very good seaman and, it was said, faithful to those he served and a worshipper of the gods. “If so,” I answered to that old slave, “how comes it that this Philo, instead of a humble captain, is not the first general or admiral among the Greeks, as a man of such quality should be?” “Because, divine Lady, of certain faults,” answered the slave, “such faults as have made of me what I am instead of the Count of a Nome upon the Nile as I should have been. This Philo has always thought more of the welfare of others than of his own, which is a very evil weakness; also he has loved women too much, which is a worse.” “Vile sins indeed,” I said, “more particularly the second. The wise always think of themselves first, and the holy never love more than one woman, and her not too much, which perhaps is why the wise and the holy are so hateful and so dull. Bring this Philo to me; he is one whom I should wish to know.” In the end Philo came, though whether because my message had reached him, or because of the advancing storm, I am not certain. At least he came, and as he bowed before me, made a certain secret sign whereby I knew that he was a worshipper of Isis and one of high degree, though not of the highest, since when I tried him with that sign he could not answer. Still his rank in our great company was enough, and thenceforward we spoke to each other under the seal of the goddess, or as our phrase went in those days “within the shadow of her wings,” as brother and sister might, or rather as mother and son. That is, we did this after I had proved him further and brought to his mind the fate of those who betray the goddess and her ministers upon earth. This Philo told me in few words, that although the trireme was Egyptian and named Hapi after the god of Nile, for this voyage she was under charter to Tenes and for the most part manned with Sidonians, also with low fellows from Cyprus and the coast-ports.
  • 88. Welcome to our website – the perfect destination for book lovers and knowledge seekers. We believe that every book holds a new world, offering opportunities for learning, discovery, and personal growth. That’s why we are dedicated to bringing you a diverse collection of books, ranging from classic literature and specialized publications to self-development guides and children's books. More than just a book-buying platform, we strive to be a bridge connecting you with timeless cultural and intellectual values. With an elegant, user-friendly interface and a smart search system, you can quickly find the books that best suit your interests. Additionally, our special promotions and home delivery services help you save time and fully enjoy the joy of reading. Join us on a journey of knowledge exploration, passion nurturing, and personal growth every day! ebookbell.com