SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Chapter Seventeen 1
Chapter:
Theories of
Consumption
Chapter Seventeen 2
The consumption function was central to Keynes’ theory of economic
fluctuations presented in The General Theory in 1936.
• Keynes conjectured that the marginal propensity to consume— the
amount consumed out of an additional dollar of income is between
zero and one. He claimed that the fundamental law is that out of
every dollar of earned income, people will consume part of it and save
the rest.
• Keynes also proposed the average propensity to consume, the ratio of
consumption to income falls as income rises.
• Keynes also held that income is the primary determinant of
consumption and that the interest rate does not have an important role.
Chapter Seventeen 3
Consumption
spending by
households
depends
on
autonomous
consumption
marginal
propensity to
consume (MPC)
disposable
income
C = C + c Y, C > 0, 0 < c <1
C
Y
C
C determines the intercept on the
vertical axis. The slope of the
consumption function is lower case c,
the MPC.
C
=
C
+
c
C
=
C
+
c Y
Y
Chapter Seventeen 4
C
Y
C
APC = C/Y = C/Y + c
1
1
APC1
APC2
This consumption function
exhibits three properties that
Keynes conjectured. First,
the marginal propensity to
consume c is between zero
and one. Second, the average
propensity to consume falls
as income rises. Third,
consumption is determined by
current income Y.
As Y rises, C/Y falls, and so the average propensity to consume C/Y
falls. Notice that the interest rate is not included in this equation as a
determinant of consumption.
Chapter Seventeen 5
To understand the marginal propensity to consume (MPC),
consider a shopping scenario. A person who loves to shop
probably has a large MPC, let’s say (.99). This means that for
every extra dollar he or she earns after tax deductions, he or
she spends $.99 of it. The MPC measures the sensitivity of
the change in one variable, consumption, with respect to a
change in the other variable, income.
Chapter Seventeen 6
During World War II, on the basis of Keynes’s consumption function,
economists predicted that the economy would experience what they
called secular stagnation—a long depression of infinite duration—
unless the government used fiscal policy to stimulate aggregate demand.
It turned out that the end of the war did not throw the United States into an
depression, but it did suggest that Keynes’s conjecture that the average
propensity to consume would fall as income rose appeared not to hold.
Simon Kuznets constructed new aggregate data on consumption and
investment dating back to 1869. His work would later earn him a
Nobel Prize. Kuznets discovered that the ratio of consumption to income w
stable over time, despite large increases in income; again, Keynes’s
conjecture was called into question.
This brings us to the puzzle…
Chapter Seventeen 7
The failure of the secular-stagnation hypothesis and the findings of
Kuznets both indicated that the average propensity to consume is fairly
constant over time. This presented a puzzle: Why did Keynes’s
conjectures hold up well in the studies of household data and in the
studies of short time-series, but fail when long-time series were
examined?
C
Y
Short-run
consumption
function
(falling APC)
Long-run
consumption
function
(constant APC)
Studies of household data and short
time-series found a relationship
between consumption and income
similar to the one Keynes conjectured
— this is called the short-run
consumption function. But, studies
using long time-series found that the
APC did not vary systematically with
income—this relationship is called the
long-run consumption function.
Chapter Seventeen 8
The economist Irving Fisher developed the model
with which economists analyze how rational,
forward-looking consumers make intertemporal
choices—that is, choices involving different periods
of time. The model illuminates the constraints
consumers face, the preferences they have, and how
these constraints and preferences together determine
their choices about consumption and saving.
When consumers are deciding how much to
consume today versus how much to consume
in the future, they face an intertemporal
budget constraint, which measures the total
resources available for consumption today and in the
future.
Chapter Seventeen 9
Here is an interpretation of the consumer’s budget constraint:
The consumer’s budget constraint implies that if the interest
rate is zero, the budget constraint shows that total
consumption in the two periods equals total income
in the two periods. In the usual case in which the
interest rate is greater than zero, future consumption and future income
are discounted by a factor of 1 + r. This discounting arises from the
interest earned on savings. Because the consumer earns interest on
current income that is saved, future income is worth less than current
income. Also, because future consumption is paid for out of savings
that have earned interest, future consumption costs less than current
consumption. The factor 1/(1+r) is the price of second-period
consumption measured in terms of first-period consumption; it is the
amount of first-period consumption that the consumer must forgo to
obtain 1 unit of second-period consumption.
Chapter Seventeen 10
Here are the combinations of first-period and second-period consumption
the consumer can choose. If he chooses a point between A and B, he
consumes less than his income in the first period and saves the rest for
the second period. If he chooses between A and C, he consumes more that
his income in the first period and borrows to make up the difference.
First-period consumption
Second-pe
riod
consumpti
on
Consumer’s budget constraint
Saving
Borrowing
A
C
B
Horizontal intercept is
Y1 + Y2/(1+r)
Vertical intercept is
(1+r)Y1 + Y2
Y1
Y2
Chapter Seventeen 11
The consumer’s preferences regarding consumption in the
two periods can be represented by indifference curves. An
indifference curve shows the combination of first-period and
second-period consumption that makes the consumer equally
happy. The slope at any point on the indifference curve
shows how much second-period consumption the consumer
requires in order to be compensated for a 1-unit reduction in
first-period consumption. This slope is the marginal rate of
substitution between first-period consumption and second-
period consumption. It tells us the rate at which the
consumer is willing to substitute second-period consumption
for first-period consumption.
Chapter Seventeen 12
First-period consumption
Second-
period
consumpti
on
W
Z
X
Y
IC1
IC2
Indifference curves represent the consumer’s preferences over first-
period and second-period consumption. An indifference curve gives the
combinations of consumption in the two periods that make the consumer
equally happy. Higher indifferences curves such as IC2 are preferred to
lower ones such as IC1. The consumer is equally happy at points W, X,
and Y, but prefers point Z to all the others. Point Z is on a higher
indifference curve and is therefore not equally preferred to W, X, and Y.
Chapter Seventeen 13
First-period consumption
Second-
period
consumpti
on
O
IC1
IC2
The consumer achieves his highest (or optimal) level of satisfaction
by choosing the point on the budget constraint that is on the highest
indifference curve. Here the slope of the indifference curve
equals the slope of the budget line. At the optimum, the indifference
curve is tangent to the budget constraint. The slope of the indifference
curve is the marginal rate of substitution MRS, and the slope of the
budget line is 1 + the real interest rate. At point O, MRS = 1 + r.
IC3
Chapter Seventeen 14
First-period consumption
Second-
period
consumpti
on
O
IC1
IC2
An increase in either first-period income or second-period income
shifts the budget constraint outward. If consumption in period one and
consumption in period two are both normal goods—those that are
demanded more as income rises, this increase in income raises
consumption in both periods.
Chapter Seventeen 15
Economists decompose the impact of an increase in the real interest
rate on consumption into two effects: an income effect and a
substitution effect. The income effect is the change in consumption
that results from the movement to a higher indifference curve. The
substitution effect is the change in consumption that results from the
change in the relative price of consumption in the two periods.
First-period consumption
Second-pe
riod
consumpti
on
B
IC1
IC2
A
C
An increase in the interest rate
rotates the budget constraint
around the point C, where C is
(Y1, Y2). The higher interest rate
reduces first period consumption
(move to point A) and raises
second-period consumption
(move to point B).
New budget
constraint
Old budget
constraint
Y1
Y2
Chapter Seventeen 16
The inability to borrow prevents current consumption from exceeding
current income. A constraint on borrowing can therefore be expressed
as C1 < Y1.
This inequality states that consumption in period one must be less than
or equal to income in period one. This additional constraint on the
consumer is called a borrowing constraint, or sometimes, a liquidity
constraint.
The analysis of borrowing leads us to conclude that there are two
consumption functions. For some consumers, the borrowing
constraint is not binding, and consumption in both periods depends
on the present value of lifetime income. For other consumers, the
borrowing constraint binds. Hence, for those consumers who would
like to borrow but cannot, consumption depends only on current income.
Chapter Seventeen 17
In the 1950s, Franco Modigliani, Ando, and Brumberg used Fisher’s
model of consumer behavior to study the consumption function. One of
their goals was to study the consumption puzzle. According to Fisher’s
model, consumption depends on a person’s lifetime income.
Modigliani emphasized that income varies systematically over people’s
lives and that saving allows consumers to move income from those
times in life when income is high to those times when income is low.
This interpretation of consumer behavior formed the basis of his
life-cycle hypothesis.
Chapter Seventeen 18
In 1957, Milton Friedman proposed the permanent-income hypothesis
to explain consumer behavior. Its essence is that current consumption is
proportional to permanent income. Friedman’s permanent-income
hypothesis complements Modigliani’s life-cycle hypothesis: both use
Fisher’s theory of the consumer to argue that consumption should not
depend on current income alone. But unlike the life-cycle hypothesis,
which emphasizes that income follows a regular pattern over a person’s
lifetime, the permanent-income hypothesis emphasizes that people
experience random and temporary changes in their incomes from year
to year.
Friedman suggested that we view current income Y as the sum of two
components, permanent income YP
and transitory income YT
.
Chapter Seventeen 19
Robert Hall was first to derive the implications of rational expectations
for consumption. He showed that if the permanent-income hypothesis
is correct, and if consumers have rational expectations, then changes
in consumption over time should be unpredictable. When changes in a
variable are unpredictable, the variable is said to follow a random walk.
According to Hall, the combination of the permanent-income
hypothesis and rational expectations implies that consumption follows
a random walk.
Chapter Seventeen 20
Recently, economists have turned to psychology for further explanations
of consumer behavior. They have suggested that consumption decisions
are not made completely rationally. This new subfield infusing
psychology into economics is called behavior economics. Harvard’s
David Laibson notes that many consumers judge themselves to be
Imperfect decisionmakers. Consumers’ preferences may be time-
inconsistent: they may alter their decisions simply because time passes.
Pull of Instant
Gratification

More Related Content

PPT
Macroeconomics chapter 16
PPT
Mankiw_7e_Chapter17 (1).ppt
PPT
23 consumption
PPTX
Consumption
PPTX
Ma II.pptx
PDF
Mankiw8e sm macro-chap16_170-183
PPT
Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter (16)
PPT
consumption 2.ppt
Macroeconomics chapter 16
Mankiw_7e_Chapter17 (1).ppt
23 consumption
Consumption
Ma II.pptx
Mankiw8e sm macro-chap16_170-183
Gregory mankiw macroeconomic 7th edition chapter (16)
consumption 2.ppt

Similar to Theories of Consumption in macroecnomics.ppt (20)

PPT
Consumption.ppt
PPT
MACROECONOMICS-CH16
PDF
consumption and investment
PDF
AN ENQUIRY INTO CONSUMPTION THEORIES.pdf
PPTX
Consumption Theory - advanced Macroeconomics
PPTX
Consumption Function Assignment of Macroeconomic
PDF
chapter9.pdf economics chapter 9 uct notes
PPT
Principal of Macroeconomic for 2nd year for those who who did not do their fo...
PPTX
Consumption, Investment and Stabilization(1).pptx
PPT
Chapter 3 -consumption and investment for BBA
PPTX
Macro II Chapter 2.pptx For economics stude.
PDF
Consumption hypotheses
PDF
Complete Macro Economics: Consumption Function
PPTX
mukul ppt.pptx Consumption FunctioN By Mukul
PPT
Consumer prefrence and choice
PDF
Consumption Function: Keynes Psychological Law of Consumption Function
PDF
Consumption theories.pdf
PPSX
Consumption function and investment function chapter 2
PDF
slides_endowment.pdf
PPTX
Consumption
Consumption.ppt
MACROECONOMICS-CH16
consumption and investment
AN ENQUIRY INTO CONSUMPTION THEORIES.pdf
Consumption Theory - advanced Macroeconomics
Consumption Function Assignment of Macroeconomic
chapter9.pdf economics chapter 9 uct notes
Principal of Macroeconomic for 2nd year for those who who did not do their fo...
Consumption, Investment and Stabilization(1).pptx
Chapter 3 -consumption and investment for BBA
Macro II Chapter 2.pptx For economics stude.
Consumption hypotheses
Complete Macro Economics: Consumption Function
mukul ppt.pptx Consumption FunctioN By Mukul
Consumer prefrence and choice
Consumption Function: Keynes Psychological Law of Consumption Function
Consumption theories.pdf
Consumption function and investment function chapter 2
slides_endowment.pdf
Consumption
Ad

Recently uploaded (20)

PDF
NISM Series V-A MFD Workbook v December 2024.khhhjtgvwevoypdnew one must use ...
PDF
How to Get Business Funding for Small Business Fast
PDF
THE COMPLETE GUIDE TO BUILDING PASSIVE INCOME ONLINE
PPTX
Sales & Distribution Management , LOGISTICS, Distribution, Sales Managers
PDF
Charisse Litchman: A Maverick Making Neurological Care More Accessible
PDF
TyAnn Osborn: A Visionary Leader Shaping Corporate Workforce Dynamics
PDF
Module 2 - Modern Supervison Challenges - Student Resource.pdf
PDF
NewBase 12 August 2025 Energy News issue - 1812 by Khaled Al Awadi_compresse...
PDF
Cours de Système d'information about ERP.pdf
PDF
Susan Semmelmann: Enriching the Lives of others through her Talents and Bless...
PPTX
Principles of Marketing, Industrial, Consumers,
PPTX
operations management : demand supply ch
PDF
Blood Collected straight from the donor into a blood bag and mixed with an an...
PPTX
TRAINNING, DEVELOPMENT AND APPRAISAL.pptx
PDF
Keppel_Proposed Divestment of M1 Limited
PPTX
CTG - Business Update 2Q2025 & 6M2025.pptx
PDF
Family Law: The Role of Communication in Mediation (www.kiu.ac.ug)
PDF
Satish NS: Fostering Innovation and Sustainability: Haier India’s Customer-Ce...
PPTX
2025 Product Deck V1.0.pptxCATALOGTCLCIA
PPTX
BUSINESS CYCLE_INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT.pptx
NISM Series V-A MFD Workbook v December 2024.khhhjtgvwevoypdnew one must use ...
How to Get Business Funding for Small Business Fast
THE COMPLETE GUIDE TO BUILDING PASSIVE INCOME ONLINE
Sales & Distribution Management , LOGISTICS, Distribution, Sales Managers
Charisse Litchman: A Maverick Making Neurological Care More Accessible
TyAnn Osborn: A Visionary Leader Shaping Corporate Workforce Dynamics
Module 2 - Modern Supervison Challenges - Student Resource.pdf
NewBase 12 August 2025 Energy News issue - 1812 by Khaled Al Awadi_compresse...
Cours de Système d'information about ERP.pdf
Susan Semmelmann: Enriching the Lives of others through her Talents and Bless...
Principles of Marketing, Industrial, Consumers,
operations management : demand supply ch
Blood Collected straight from the donor into a blood bag and mixed with an an...
TRAINNING, DEVELOPMENT AND APPRAISAL.pptx
Keppel_Proposed Divestment of M1 Limited
CTG - Business Update 2Q2025 & 6M2025.pptx
Family Law: The Role of Communication in Mediation (www.kiu.ac.ug)
Satish NS: Fostering Innovation and Sustainability: Haier India’s Customer-Ce...
2025 Product Deck V1.0.pptxCATALOGTCLCIA
BUSINESS CYCLE_INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT.pptx
Ad

Theories of Consumption in macroecnomics.ppt

  • 2. Chapter Seventeen 2 The consumption function was central to Keynes’ theory of economic fluctuations presented in The General Theory in 1936. • Keynes conjectured that the marginal propensity to consume— the amount consumed out of an additional dollar of income is between zero and one. He claimed that the fundamental law is that out of every dollar of earned income, people will consume part of it and save the rest. • Keynes also proposed the average propensity to consume, the ratio of consumption to income falls as income rises. • Keynes also held that income is the primary determinant of consumption and that the interest rate does not have an important role.
  • 3. Chapter Seventeen 3 Consumption spending by households depends on autonomous consumption marginal propensity to consume (MPC) disposable income C = C + c Y, C > 0, 0 < c <1 C Y C C determines the intercept on the vertical axis. The slope of the consumption function is lower case c, the MPC. C = C + c C = C + c Y Y
  • 4. Chapter Seventeen 4 C Y C APC = C/Y = C/Y + c 1 1 APC1 APC2 This consumption function exhibits three properties that Keynes conjectured. First, the marginal propensity to consume c is between zero and one. Second, the average propensity to consume falls as income rises. Third, consumption is determined by current income Y. As Y rises, C/Y falls, and so the average propensity to consume C/Y falls. Notice that the interest rate is not included in this equation as a determinant of consumption.
  • 5. Chapter Seventeen 5 To understand the marginal propensity to consume (MPC), consider a shopping scenario. A person who loves to shop probably has a large MPC, let’s say (.99). This means that for every extra dollar he or she earns after tax deductions, he or she spends $.99 of it. The MPC measures the sensitivity of the change in one variable, consumption, with respect to a change in the other variable, income.
  • 6. Chapter Seventeen 6 During World War II, on the basis of Keynes’s consumption function, economists predicted that the economy would experience what they called secular stagnation—a long depression of infinite duration— unless the government used fiscal policy to stimulate aggregate demand. It turned out that the end of the war did not throw the United States into an depression, but it did suggest that Keynes’s conjecture that the average propensity to consume would fall as income rose appeared not to hold. Simon Kuznets constructed new aggregate data on consumption and investment dating back to 1869. His work would later earn him a Nobel Prize. Kuznets discovered that the ratio of consumption to income w stable over time, despite large increases in income; again, Keynes’s conjecture was called into question. This brings us to the puzzle…
  • 7. Chapter Seventeen 7 The failure of the secular-stagnation hypothesis and the findings of Kuznets both indicated that the average propensity to consume is fairly constant over time. This presented a puzzle: Why did Keynes’s conjectures hold up well in the studies of household data and in the studies of short time-series, but fail when long-time series were examined? C Y Short-run consumption function (falling APC) Long-run consumption function (constant APC) Studies of household data and short time-series found a relationship between consumption and income similar to the one Keynes conjectured — this is called the short-run consumption function. But, studies using long time-series found that the APC did not vary systematically with income—this relationship is called the long-run consumption function.
  • 8. Chapter Seventeen 8 The economist Irving Fisher developed the model with which economists analyze how rational, forward-looking consumers make intertemporal choices—that is, choices involving different periods of time. The model illuminates the constraints consumers face, the preferences they have, and how these constraints and preferences together determine their choices about consumption and saving. When consumers are deciding how much to consume today versus how much to consume in the future, they face an intertemporal budget constraint, which measures the total resources available for consumption today and in the future.
  • 9. Chapter Seventeen 9 Here is an interpretation of the consumer’s budget constraint: The consumer’s budget constraint implies that if the interest rate is zero, the budget constraint shows that total consumption in the two periods equals total income in the two periods. In the usual case in which the interest rate is greater than zero, future consumption and future income are discounted by a factor of 1 + r. This discounting arises from the interest earned on savings. Because the consumer earns interest on current income that is saved, future income is worth less than current income. Also, because future consumption is paid for out of savings that have earned interest, future consumption costs less than current consumption. The factor 1/(1+r) is the price of second-period consumption measured in terms of first-period consumption; it is the amount of first-period consumption that the consumer must forgo to obtain 1 unit of second-period consumption.
  • 10. Chapter Seventeen 10 Here are the combinations of first-period and second-period consumption the consumer can choose. If he chooses a point between A and B, he consumes less than his income in the first period and saves the rest for the second period. If he chooses between A and C, he consumes more that his income in the first period and borrows to make up the difference. First-period consumption Second-pe riod consumpti on Consumer’s budget constraint Saving Borrowing A C B Horizontal intercept is Y1 + Y2/(1+r) Vertical intercept is (1+r)Y1 + Y2 Y1 Y2
  • 11. Chapter Seventeen 11 The consumer’s preferences regarding consumption in the two periods can be represented by indifference curves. An indifference curve shows the combination of first-period and second-period consumption that makes the consumer equally happy. The slope at any point on the indifference curve shows how much second-period consumption the consumer requires in order to be compensated for a 1-unit reduction in first-period consumption. This slope is the marginal rate of substitution between first-period consumption and second- period consumption. It tells us the rate at which the consumer is willing to substitute second-period consumption for first-period consumption.
  • 12. Chapter Seventeen 12 First-period consumption Second- period consumpti on W Z X Y IC1 IC2 Indifference curves represent the consumer’s preferences over first- period and second-period consumption. An indifference curve gives the combinations of consumption in the two periods that make the consumer equally happy. Higher indifferences curves such as IC2 are preferred to lower ones such as IC1. The consumer is equally happy at points W, X, and Y, but prefers point Z to all the others. Point Z is on a higher indifference curve and is therefore not equally preferred to W, X, and Y.
  • 13. Chapter Seventeen 13 First-period consumption Second- period consumpti on O IC1 IC2 The consumer achieves his highest (or optimal) level of satisfaction by choosing the point on the budget constraint that is on the highest indifference curve. Here the slope of the indifference curve equals the slope of the budget line. At the optimum, the indifference curve is tangent to the budget constraint. The slope of the indifference curve is the marginal rate of substitution MRS, and the slope of the budget line is 1 + the real interest rate. At point O, MRS = 1 + r. IC3
  • 14. Chapter Seventeen 14 First-period consumption Second- period consumpti on O IC1 IC2 An increase in either first-period income or second-period income shifts the budget constraint outward. If consumption in period one and consumption in period two are both normal goods—those that are demanded more as income rises, this increase in income raises consumption in both periods.
  • 15. Chapter Seventeen 15 Economists decompose the impact of an increase in the real interest rate on consumption into two effects: an income effect and a substitution effect. The income effect is the change in consumption that results from the movement to a higher indifference curve. The substitution effect is the change in consumption that results from the change in the relative price of consumption in the two periods. First-period consumption Second-pe riod consumpti on B IC1 IC2 A C An increase in the interest rate rotates the budget constraint around the point C, where C is (Y1, Y2). The higher interest rate reduces first period consumption (move to point A) and raises second-period consumption (move to point B). New budget constraint Old budget constraint Y1 Y2
  • 16. Chapter Seventeen 16 The inability to borrow prevents current consumption from exceeding current income. A constraint on borrowing can therefore be expressed as C1 < Y1. This inequality states that consumption in period one must be less than or equal to income in period one. This additional constraint on the consumer is called a borrowing constraint, or sometimes, a liquidity constraint. The analysis of borrowing leads us to conclude that there are two consumption functions. For some consumers, the borrowing constraint is not binding, and consumption in both periods depends on the present value of lifetime income. For other consumers, the borrowing constraint binds. Hence, for those consumers who would like to borrow but cannot, consumption depends only on current income.
  • 17. Chapter Seventeen 17 In the 1950s, Franco Modigliani, Ando, and Brumberg used Fisher’s model of consumer behavior to study the consumption function. One of their goals was to study the consumption puzzle. According to Fisher’s model, consumption depends on a person’s lifetime income. Modigliani emphasized that income varies systematically over people’s lives and that saving allows consumers to move income from those times in life when income is high to those times when income is low. This interpretation of consumer behavior formed the basis of his life-cycle hypothesis.
  • 18. Chapter Seventeen 18 In 1957, Milton Friedman proposed the permanent-income hypothesis to explain consumer behavior. Its essence is that current consumption is proportional to permanent income. Friedman’s permanent-income hypothesis complements Modigliani’s life-cycle hypothesis: both use Fisher’s theory of the consumer to argue that consumption should not depend on current income alone. But unlike the life-cycle hypothesis, which emphasizes that income follows a regular pattern over a person’s lifetime, the permanent-income hypothesis emphasizes that people experience random and temporary changes in their incomes from year to year. Friedman suggested that we view current income Y as the sum of two components, permanent income YP and transitory income YT .
  • 19. Chapter Seventeen 19 Robert Hall was first to derive the implications of rational expectations for consumption. He showed that if the permanent-income hypothesis is correct, and if consumers have rational expectations, then changes in consumption over time should be unpredictable. When changes in a variable are unpredictable, the variable is said to follow a random walk. According to Hall, the combination of the permanent-income hypothesis and rational expectations implies that consumption follows a random walk.
  • 20. Chapter Seventeen 20 Recently, economists have turned to psychology for further explanations of consumer behavior. They have suggested that consumption decisions are not made completely rationally. This new subfield infusing psychology into economics is called behavior economics. Harvard’s David Laibson notes that many consumers judge themselves to be Imperfect decisionmakers. Consumers’ preferences may be time- inconsistent: they may alter their decisions simply because time passes. Pull of Instant Gratification