[1] Abdellaoui, M. (2000). Parameter-free elicitation of utilities and probability weighting functions. Management Science, 46, 1497–1512.
[10] Deck, C., Lin, S. and Porter, D. (2013). Affecting policy by manipulating prediction markets: experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 85, 48–62.
- [11] Dreber, A., von Essen, E. and Ranehill, E. (2011). Outrunning the gender gap—boys and girls compete equally. Experimental Economics, 14, 567–582.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[12] Ehmke, M. D. T. (2006). Dissertation abstract: The influence of culture on economic behavior with applications to food and the environment. Experimental Economics, 9, 167–168.
[13] Figlewski, S. (1978). Market ‘efficiency’ in a market with heterogeneous information. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 581–597.
[14] Figlewski, S. (1979). Subjective information and market efficiency in a betting market. The Journal of Political Economy, 87, 75–88.
[15] Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.
[16] Forsythe, R., Nelson, F., Neumann, G. and Wright, J. (1992). Anatomy of an experimental political stock market. The American Economic Review, 82, 1142–1161.
[17] Forsythe, R., Rietz, T. and Ross, T. (1999). Wishes, expectations and actions: a survey on price formation in election stock markets. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 39, 83–110 Chie and Yang
- [18] Gjerstad, S. (2005). Risk aversion, beliefs, and prediction market equilibrium. Unpublished Manuscript, Economic Science Laboratory, University of Arizona.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[19] Gresik, T. A. and Satterthwaite, M. A. (1989). The rate at which a simple market converges to efficiency as the number of traders increases: an asymptotic result for optimal trading mechanisms. Journal of Economic Theory, 48, 304–332.
[2] Abdellaoui, M., Vossmann, F. and Weber, M. (2005). Choice-based elicitation and decomposition of decision weights for gains and losses under uncertainty. Management Science, 51, 1384–1399.
- [20] Griffith, R. M. (1949). Odds adjustments by American horse-race bettors. The American Journal of Psychology, 62, 290–294.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[21] Hahn, R. W. and Tetlock, P. C. (2006). Information markets: a new way of making decisions, AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies.
[22] Hanson, R. D. (2006). Designing real terrorism futures. Public Choice, 128, 257–274.
- [24] Hayek, F. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35, 519–530.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- [25] Hazen, T. L. (1987). Volatility and market inefficiency: a commentary on the effects of options, futures, and risk arbitrage on the stock market. Washington and Lee Law Review, 44, 789–805.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
- [26] Isaacs, R. (1953). Optimal horse race bets. American Mathematical Monthly, 60, 310–315.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[27] Knetsch, J., Tang, F. F. and Thaler, R. (2001). The endowment effect and repeated market trials: is the Vickrey auction demand revealing? Experimental Economics, 4, 257–269.
[28] Loomes, G., Starmer, C. and Sugden, R. (2003). Do anomalies disappear in repeated markets? Economic Journal, 113, C153–C166.
[29] Maloney, M. T. and Mulherin, J. H. (2003). The complexity of price discovery in an efficient market: the stock market reaction to the Challenger crash. Journal of Corporate Finance, 9, 453–479.
[3] Ali, M. M. (1977). Probability and utility estimates for racetrack bettors. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 803–15.
- [30] Oechssler, J. (2012). Finitely repeated games with social preferences. Experimental Economics, doi:10.1007/s10683-012-9336-6.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[31] Oliven, K. and Rietz, T. A. (2004). Suckers are born but markets are made: individual rationality, arbitrage, and market efficiency on an electronic futures market. Management Science, 50, 336–351.
[32] Oosterbeek, H., Sloof, R. and Van De Kuilen, G. (2004). Cultural differences in ultimatum game experiments: evidence from a meta-analysis. Experimental Economics, 7, 171–188.
[33] Ottaviani, M. and Sørensen, P. N. (2007). Outcome manipulation in corporate prediction markets. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5, 554– 563. Efficiency of the Experimental Prediction Market: Public Information,… 59
[35] Roll, R. (1984). Orange juice and weather. American Economic Review, 74, 861–880.
- [36] Rosenberg, B., Reid, K. and Lanstein, R. (1985). Persuasive evidence of market inefficiency. Journal of Portfolio Management, 11, 9–16.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[37] Snowberg, E., Wolfers, J. and Zitzewitz, E. (2007). Partisan impacts on the economy: evidence from prediction markets and close elections. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 807–829.
[38] Stott, H. P. (2006). Cumulative prospect theory’s functional menagerie. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 32, 101–130.
[39] Tufano, F. (2010). Are ‘true’ preferences revealed in repeated markets? an experimental demonstration of context-dependent valuations. Experimental Economics, 13, 1–13.
[4] Ballinger, T. P., Hudson, E., Karkoviata, L. and Wilcox, N. T. (2011). Saving behavior and cognitive abilities. Experimental Economics, 14, 349–374.
- [40] Tversky, A. and Fox, C. (1995). Weighing risk and uncertainty. Psychological Review, 102, 269–283.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[41] Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323.
[42] Visser, M. S. and Roelofs, M. R. (2011). Heterogeneous preferences for altruism: gender and personality, social status, giving and taking. Experimental Economics, 14, 490–506.
[43] Weitzman, M. (1965). Utility analysis and group behavior: an empirical study. Journal of Political Economy, 73, 18–26.
- [44] Wolfers, J. and Zitzewitz, E. (2004). Prediction markets. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18, 107–126.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[45] Wu, G. and Gonzalez, R. (1996). Curvature of the probability weighting function. Management Science, 42, 1676–1690.
[5] Berg, J., Nelson, F. and Rietz, T. (2008). Prediction market accuracy in the long run. International Journal of Forecasting, 24, 285–300.
- [6] Camerer, C. F. and Ho, T. H. (1994). Nonlinear weighting of probabilities and violations of the betweenness axiom. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8, 167196.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[7] Christiansen, J. D. (2007). Prediction markets: practical experiments in small markets and behaviours observed. The Journal of Prediction Markets, 1, 17– 41.
- [8] Costa, P. T. and McCrae Jr., R. R. (1985). The NEO personality inventory manual, Odessa, FL: Psychological Assessment Resources.
Paper not yet in RePEc: Add citation now
[9] Croson, R. and Gneezy, U. (2009). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 448–474.