Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
LOCALIZING
DEVELOPMENT


    A World Bank Policy Research Report
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
LOCALIZING
DEVELOPMENT
DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                  Ghazala Mansuri and Vijayendra Rao
© 2013 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank
1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433
Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org

Some rights reserved
1 2 3 4 15 14 13 12

This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. Note that The World
Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content included in the work. The World Bank
therefore does not warrant that the use of the content contained in the work will not infringe on the
rights of third parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you.
    The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the
views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The
World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors,
denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on
the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance
of such boundaries.
    Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges
and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved.

Rights and Permissions



This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Unported license (CC BY 3.0)
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are
free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the
following conditions:
Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: Mansuri, Ghazala, and Vijayendra Rao. 2013. Localizing
    Development: Does Participation Work? Washington, DC: World Bank. DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-
    8256-1. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0.
Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the
   attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official
   World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation.
All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, The World Bank,
1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625; e-mail: pubrights@worldbank
.org.

ISBN (paper): 978-0-8213-8256-1
ISBN (electronic): 978-0-8213-8990-4
DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-8256-1

Cover image: Zwelethu Mthethwa, South Africa, born 1960
Waiting, 1996
hand-colored digital print on paper
World Bank Art Collection PN 466513
Cover design: Bill Pragluski, Critical Stages, LLC

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Mansuri, Ghazala.
   Localizing development : does participation work? / by Ghazala Mansuri and Vijayendra Rao.
      p. cm.
   Includes bibliographical references and index.
   ISBN 978-0-8213-8256-1 — ISBN 978-0-8213-8990-4 (electronic)
   1. Economic development—Citizen participation. 2. Economic development projects—Citizen
participation. 3. Community development. 4. Decentralization in government. I. Rao, Vijayendra.
II. World Bank. III. Title.
   HD82.M36 2012
   338.9—dc23
                                                                                       2012034769
Contents


Foreword        ix

Acknowledgments             xi

About the Authors           xv

Abbreviations        xvii

Overview        1
     The History of Participatory Development and Decentralization   2
     A Conceptual Framework for Participation     4
     Empirical Findings      5
     Moving Beyond the Evidence        11
     Conclusion      13

1.   Why Does Participation Matter?          15
     The History of Participatory Development     20
     Organic versus Induced Participation    31
     Scope of the Report and Roadmap      41
     Notes      44
     References     45

2.   A Conceptual Framework for Participatory
     Development     49
     Market Failure       50
     Government Failure       52
     Civil Society Failure    54
     Conclusions           80
     Notes      80
     References      82



                                                                         v
CONTENTS



           3.   The Challenge of Inducing Participation            87
                Participation and the Capacity to Engage     91
                Diagnosing Failure Triangles      94
                Deriving Hypotheses       112
                Notes       117
                References      118

           4.   How Important Is Capture?           121
                Corruption and Local Accountability       122
                Participation and Resource Allocation in Induced
                 Community-Driven Development Programs           128
                Participation and Resource Allocation under Decentralization     136
                Can Electoral Incentives Reduce Rent-Seeking?     141
                Conclusions      146
                Notes       148
                References      152

           5.   Does Participation Improve Development Outcomes?                 161
                Identification of Beneficiaries     162
                Sustainable Management of Common-Pool Resources           172
                Participation and the Quality of Local Infrastructure    182
                Community Engagement in Public Service Delivery         188
                The Poverty Impact of Participatory Projects      213
                Conclusions      221
                Notes       224
                References      234

           6.   Does Participation Strengthen Civil Society?            247
                Participatory Decision Making and Social Cohesion in
                 Induced Development Projects        247
                Representation Quotas and Inclusion Mandates      253
                Community-Driven Reconstruction          262
                Participatory Councils and Deliberative Spaces   266
                Conclusions      275
                Notes      277
                References     279

           7.   Conclusion:
                How Can Participatory Interventions Be Improved?                283
                The Importance of Context      288
                Donors, Governments, and Trajectories of Change    290
                Open Research Questions       291
                Monitoring, Evaluation, and Attention to Context:
                 Results of a Survey of World Bank Projects    295



vi
CONTENTS



      The Need for Better Monitoring and Evaluation and
       Different Project Structures    304
      Notes      306
      References     308

Figures
1.1   A typology of induced participation          37
3.1   Possible trajectories of local participation     110
7.1   World Bank project managers’ years of experience
      working on community-driven development and
      local governance projects        300
7.2   Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe
      monitoring and evaluation is a priority for
      senior management          301
7.3   Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe
      government counterparts would engage in monitoring and
      evaluation if the Bank did not require it       301
7.4   Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe
      the Bank creates the right incentives for them to engage in
      monitoring and evaluation          302
7.5   Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe
      that project supervision budgets are tailored to project size,
      project complexity, and country context         302
7.6   Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe
      that participatory development projects are supported
      long enough to achieve sustainability in community processes     303




                                                                                   vii
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Foreword


Promoting participation through community development projects
and local decentralization has become a central tenet of development
policy. The World Bank alone has invested about $85 billion over the
last decade on development assistance for participation.
   However, some observers feel that policy making in the area is con-
ceptually weak, that project design is informed more by slogans than
careful analysis. There have also been questions about whether partici-
patory development is effective in reducing poverty, improving service
delivery, and building the capacity for collective action. Some observ-
ers also find that participatory projects are complex to implement and
deeply affected by context, and are thus unsuited for large development
institutions such as the World Bank.
   This groundbreaking report carefully examines each of these con-
cerns. It outlines a conceptual framework for participation that is cen-
tered on the concept of civil society failure and how it interacts with
market and government failures. The authors use this framework to
understand the key policy debates surrounding participatory develop-
ment and to frame the key policy questions. The report conducts the
most comprehensive review of the evidence on the impact of participa-
tory projects to date, looking at more than 400 papers and books.
   For me, an important lesson from this report is its recognition of the
difference between “organic” and “induced” participation. Organic par-
ticipation is organized by civic groups outside government, sometimes
in opposition to it; induced participation attempts to promote civic
action through bureaucratically managed development interventions.
Inducing participation requires a fundamentally different approach
to development, one that is long term, context sensitive, committed to

                                                                            ix
FOREWORD



           developing a culture of learning by doing through honest monitoring
           and evaluation systems, and that has the capacity to learn from failure.
           The report argues that participatory development is most effective when
           it works within a “sandwich” formed by support from an effective cen-
           tral state and bottom-up civic action.
              This report represents an important contribution. It has significant
           implications for how to improve participation in development interven-
           tions and for development policy more broadly.

           Martin Ravallion
           Acting Chief Economist and Senior Vice President
           The World Bank
           Washington, DC
           September 20, 2012




x
Acknowledgments


WE ARE GRATEFUL TO MARTIN RAVALLION, THE DIRECTOR OF THE
World Bank’s Development Economics Research Group (DECRG),
and our managers, Peter Lanjouw and Will Martin, for giving us the
time and the freedom to write this report in the best way we knew how.
It has been more than three years in preparation, and we know that their
patience was often tested. We hope the effort was worth it. We would
also like to thank them for their prodding and constructive comments
and suggestions at every stage of the process. We are also grateful to
Gershon Feder, who started us off on this journey 10 years ago, when
he convinced us that writing a big-picture piece on participatory devel-
opment could be valuable. We acknowledge financial support from the
DEC-managed Knowledge for Change Program (KCP-TF090806).
    Radu Ban and Catherine Gamper helped research the report. Radu
assisted with gathering and summarizing some of the literature and,
along with Monica Yanez-Pagans, helped maintain the bibliographic
database. Catherine’s primary contribution was the analysis of data
from World Bank reports and the management of the survey of project
managers that forms an important part of chapter 7. Maribel Flewitt
and Pauline Kokila provided excellent and uncomplaining administra-
tive support.
    Several other people worked on various aspects of the report, either
as summer interns or on a part-time basis. They include Shahana
Chattaraj, Deborah Davis, Indrajit Roy, and Bhrigupati Singh. Kent
Eaton; Jesse Ribot, J. F. Lund, and T. True; Rachel Riedl and Tyler
Dickovick; and Catherine Benson and Arun Agrawal provided back-
ground papers that contributed to our understanding of the


                                                                           xi
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS



                   management of common property resources, and decentralization in
                   Africa and Latin America.
                      The World Bank’s Office of the Publisher has been immensely
                   supportive in bringing this report to timely completion. We would
                   particularly like to thank Barbara Karni, who copyedited the manu-
                   script and worked on the margin callouts; Janice Tuten, the publication
                   production manager; and Stephen McGroarty, the acquisitions editor.
                   We are also grateful to Marina Galvani, the World Bank’s art curator,
                   who helped us locate a wonderful piece of artwork for our cover, by the
                   South African artist Zwelethu Mthethwa, from the Bank’s collection.
                      Helpful and critical comments from Shanta Devarajan and Brian
                   Levy when this report was still a concept note led to a major recon-
                   ceptualization. We believe the report is much better for it. We are
                   deeply grateful for the thoughtful, constructive, and detailed written
                   comments from our colleagues in DECRG: Varun Gauri, Karla Hoff,
                   Phil Keefer, Stuti Khemani, and Berk Özler. Karla Hoff also helped us
                   sharpen and clarify many points of theory. We benefited greatly from
                   discussions with other DECRG colleagues during various stages of writ-
                   ing this report. In particular, we would like to thank Francisco Ferreira,
                   Deon Filmer, Emanuella Galasso, and Michael Woolcock.
                      The first draft of this report was widely circulated within the Bank.
                   We received useful written comments from people from various depart-
                   ments, including the Social Development Anchor, the Community
                   Driven Development (CDD) Community of Practice, the Chief
                   Economist’s offices in Africa and South Asia, the Human Development
                   Anchor, and the Africa Decentralization team. We also benefited
                   greatly from discussions with and comments from Robert Chase, Scott
                   Guggenheim, Janmejay Singh, and Susan Wong. Robert Zoellick’s
                   comments on a summary of the report helped us sharpen some of the
                   points in the conclusion.
                      We received extremely insightful and detailed written comments
                   on an early draft of the report from a distinguished roster of external
                   academic reviewers, to whom we are deeply indebted: Pranab Bardhan,
                   Patrick Heller, Macartan Humphries, Dilip Mookherjee, and Jean-
                   Philippe Platteau.
                      Over the years, our work on this report has been influenced by dis-
                   cussions with, and support from, a variety of colleagues and friends.
                   We would particularly like to thank Kamran Akbar, Kripa Ananthpur,
                   Arjun Appadurai, Granville and Nancy Austin, Rachid Bajwa, Tim

xii
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS



Besley, Mary Breeding, Monica Das Gupta, Peter Evans, Ariel Fiszbein,
Archon Fung, John Gaventa, Qazi Azmat Isa, Ahmad Jamal, Agha
Jawad, Shahnaz Kapadia, Michael Lipton, Deepa Narayan, Rohini
Pande, Drew Permut, Menno Pradhan, Jesse Ribot, Paromita Sanyal,
Amartya Sen, Parmesh Shah, Shubha Shankaran, Brian Silver, J. P.
Singh, Ann Swidler, Mike Walton, Susan Watkins, and members of the
Successful Societies Program at the Canadian Institute for Advanced
Research (CIFAR).
   Finally, Ghazala Mansuri would like to thank her son, Omar
Sheheryar Agha, whose enthusiasm and intellectual curiosity has been a
constant source of nourishment and whose patience with the seemingly
endless weekends and nights spent on this report has been extraordi-
nary for one so young. Vijayendra Rao would like to thank his father,
Surendra Rao, for his many stimulating discussions and for his unstint-
ing encouragement throughout the process of writing this report. He
also thanks his mother, Vasanthi Rao Lokkur, and his partner, Monica
Biradavolu, for their steadfast support.

Ghazala Mansuri and Vijayendra Rao
Washington, DC
September 20, 2012




                                                                                      xiii
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
About the Authors


Ghazala Mansuri is a lead economist in the Poverty Reduction and
Equity Group of the World Bank. Her research spans four broad
areas: rural land, labor and credit markets, the economics of household
behavior, and the political economy of participatory development and
institutional and governance reforms for development. Her research
on the political economy of local development includes a number of
evaluations of participatory development programs. Dr. Mansuri has
published extensively in leading journals in economics and develop-
ment. She holds a Ph.D. in economics from Boston University.

Vijayendra Rao is lead economist in the Development Research
Group of the World Bank. He integrates his training in economics
with theories and methods from anthropology, sociology, and political
science to study the social and political context of extreme poverty in
developing countries. Dr. Rao has published widely in leading journals
in economics and development studies on subjects that include the rise
in dowries in India, domestic violence, the economics of public celebra-
tions, sex work in Calcutta, deliberative democracy, and village democ-
racy. He co-edited Culture and Public Action and History, Historians,
and Development Policy. He serves on the editorial boards of Economic
Development and Cultural Change, the Journal of Development Studies,
and the World Bank Economic Review and is a member of the Advisory
Committee of the Successful Societies Program at the Canadian
Institute for Advanced Research (CIFAR). He holds a Ph.D. in econom-
ics from the University of Pennsylvania.




                                                                           xv
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Abbreviations


AKRSP                Agha Khan Rural Support Program
BPL                  Below Poverty Line
DFID                 Department for International Development
DPIP                 District Poverty Initiative Program
EDUCO                Educación con Participación de la Comunidad
                     (Education with Community Participation)
GDP                  gross domestic product
HIV/AIDS             human immunodeficiency virus/
                     acquired immune deficiency syndrome
IAT                  Implicit Association Test
KALAHI–CIDSS         Kapit Bisig Laban Sa Kahirapan–Comprehensive
                     and Integrated Delivery of Social Services
KDP                  Kecamatan Development Program
M&E                  monitoring and evaluation
MIS                  management information system
NGO                  nongovernmental organization
NRSP                 National Rural Support Program
PSF                  Programa Saude da Famılia
                     (Family Health Program)
PT                   Partido dos Trabalhadores (Workers’ Party)
SC                   Scheduled Caste
ST                   Scheduled Tribe
TASAF                Tanzanian Social Action Fund
USAID                U.S. Agency for International Development
VP                   van panchayat (local forest council)
ZAMSIF               Zambia Social Fund
 All amounts are presented in U.S. dollars unless otherwise indicated.
                                                                         xvii
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Overview


OV ER THE PAST DECA DE, THE WOR LD BA NK H AS A LLOCATED
almost $85 billion to local participatory development. Driving this
massive injection of funding has been the underlying belief that involv-
ing communities in at least some aspects of project design and imple-
mentation creates a closer connection between development aid and
its intended beneficiaries. Indeed, local participation is proposed as a
method to achieve a variety of goals, including sharpening poverty tar-
geting, improving service delivery, expanding livelihood opportunities,
and strengthening demand for good governance.
    In principle, a more engaged citizenry should be able to achieve a
higher level of cooperation and make government more accountable.
In practice, little is known about how best to foster such engagement.
Can participation be induced through the type of large-scale govern-
ment and donor-funded participatory programs that have become a
leitmotif of development policy? It is this question that is at the heart of
this Policy Research Report.
    The two major modalities for inducing local participation are com-
munity development and decentralization of resources and authority to
local governments. Community development supports efforts to bring
villages, urban neighborhoods, or other household groupings into the
process of managing development resources without relying on formally
constituted local governments. Community development projects—
variously labeled community-driven development, community-based
development, community livelihood projects, and social funds—
include efforts to expand community engagement in service delivery.
Designs for this type of aid can range from community-based targeting,


                                                                               1
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          in which only the selection of beneficiaries is decentralized, to projects
                          in which communities are also involved to varying degrees in the design
                          and management of resources.
                             Decentralization refers to efforts to strengthen village and municipal
                          governments on both the demand and supply sides. On the demand
                          side, decentralization strengthens citizens’ participation in local govern-
                          ment by, for example, instituting regular elections, improving access to
                          information, and fostering mechanisms for deliberative decision mak-
                          ing. On the supply side, it enhances the ability of local governments to
                          provide services by increasing their financial resources, strengthening
                          the capacity of local officials, and streamlining and rationalizing their
                          administrative functions.
                             This report focuses on assessing the impact of large-scale, policy-
                          driven efforts to induce participation. It does not, as such, examine
                          the literature on organic participation—participation spurred by
                          civic groups, whether organized or not, acting independently of and
                          sometimes even in opposition to government. Organic participation
                          is important, but it has not been the focus of donor funding. The
                          report does draw on lessons from efforts to scale up organic movements
                          through induced policy interventions. In this context, it views nongov-
                          ernment organizations (NGOs) that are largely dependent on donor or
                          government funding through participatory interventions as part of the
                          effort to induce participation.
                             The report focuses on the “demand-side” aspects of participatory
                          development. Important “supply-side” aspects of governance (fi scal
                          decentralization, taxation policy, local government procedures, and
                          bureaucratic inefficiency) have been dealt with extensively elsewhere
                          and were beyond the scope of this work.
                             Most of the fi ndings reviewed derive from econometric analysis.
                          However, the report draws on case studies to develop specific ideas and
                          to illustrate the conceptual framework. It also draws on observational
                          studies from large samples to illustrate key points.


                          The History of Participatory Development and
                          Decentralization
                          Participatory development and decentralization have common intel-
                          lectual origins. Deliberative decision making has been a central feature


2
OVERVIEW



of most religious and cultural traditions. In Athenian democracy, for
example, important decisions were made in public deliberative settings
in which all citizens (a group that excluded all women, slaves, and chil-
dren) were expected to participate. Modern notions of participation
arguably derive from the 18th and 19th centuries, notably from the
work of Rousseau and John Stuart Mill.
   In the early postcolonial period, the 1950s and 1960s, the U.S.
Agency for International Development (USAID) and other donors
helped drive the first wave of interest in participatory development by
funding and promoting cooperative institutions, community-based
development, and decentralization. By the 1970s, however, interest in
participatory development had waned with the realization that coopera-
tives had largely failed and government reform was difficult to imple-
ment or sustain. The focus of policy shifted to large-scale investments
in agricultural and industrial growth. By the mid-1980s, however, activ-
ists and scholars attacked this approach, seeing it as “top-down” and
inherently disempowering and biased against the interests of the poor.
Economists such as Sen and Ostrom made a vigorous case for a more
bottom-up and deliberative vision of development that allows the “com-
mon sense” and “social capital” of communities to play a central part in
decisions that affect them. Their scholarship led to renewed interest in
community-based development, decentralization, and participation by
donors and governments. As the social costs of structural adjustment
programs became evident by the early 1990s, donors began to actively
fund such participatory approaches, with the aim of ensuring minimal
levels of investment in public services and infrastructure and in social
programs to protect the most vulnerable.
   This renewed policy interest in participatory initiatives, along with
the expansion in funding, has proceeded, in large part, with little
systematic effort to understand the particular challenges entailed in
inducing participation or to learn from the failures of past programs.
As a result, the process is, arguably, still driven more by ideology and
optimism than by systematic analysis, either theoretical or empirical.
   The aim of this report is to fill some of these lacunae. It does so by
first outlining a conceptual framework within which local participatory
development interventions can be analyzed and then using the evidence
to draw some broad lessons with this framework as a guide.


                                                                                   3
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?




                          A Conceptual Framework for Participation
                          Market and government failures are now reasonably well understood.
                          Policy makers are less likely than they once were to assume that markets
                          work perfectly or that governments can always provide effective solu-
                          tions to market failures. In contrast, the policy literature is rife with
                          solutions to market and government failures that assume that groups
                          of people—village communities, urban neighborhood associations,
                          school councils, water user groups—will always work toward the com-
                          mon interest. Rarely is much thought given to the possibility of “civil
                          society failure.” In fact, organizing groups of people to solve market and
                          government failures is itself subject to problems of coordination, asym-
                          metric information, and pervasive inequality.
                             Civil society failure at the local level can be broadly thought of as a
                          situation in which groups that live in geographic proximity are unable
                          to act collectively to reach a feasible and preferable outcome. It includes
                          coordinated actions that are inefficient—or efficient but welfare reduc-
                          ing on average—as well as the inability to undertake any coordinated
                          action at all. Development policy that uses participatory processes needs
                          to be informed by a thoughtful diagnosis of potential civil society fail-
                          ures, so that policy makers can clearly understand the tradeoffs involved
                          in devolving decisions to local communities and can identify potential
                          ways of repairing such failures.
                             Thinking of local development policy as occurring at the intersection
                          of market, government, and civil society failures invariably increases
                          appreciation of context. Such interactions are deeply conditioned by
                          culture, politics, and social structure, and they vary from place to
                          place. A policy that works in one country, or even one municipality,
                          may fail miserably in another. Moreover, effective collective action is
                          usually conditioned by a “cooperative infrastructure” that presupposes
                          functional state institutions—and is likely to be far more challenging
                          in its absence.
                             Empowering civic groups may lead to good outcomes. But it is not
                          clear that inducing civic empowerment is always superior to a pure
                          market-based strategy or a strategy that strengthens the role of central
                          bureaucrats. Policy makers need to keep all of these considerations in
                          mind as they consider how best to harness the power of communities.




4
OVERVIEW




Empirical Findings
This report reviews almost 500 studies on participatory development
and decentralization. The findings shed light on three key issues.


How Important Is Capture?
The purpose of participatory programs is to enhance the involvement
of the poor and the marginalized in community-level decision-making
bodies in order to give citizens greater say in decisions that affect their
lives. Do these programs result in choices that are better aligned with
their preferences? Does fostering participation increase social cohesion?
Does it produce more resilient and inclusive local institutions? Does it
reduce capture and corruption?
    On balance, the review of the literature finds that participants in
civic activities tend to be wealthier, more educated, of higher social sta-
tus (by caste and ethnicity), male, and more politically connected than
nonparticipants. This picture may partly reflect the higher opportunity
cost of participation for the poor. It also appears, however, that the poor
often benefit less from participatory processes than do the better off,
because resource allocation processes typically reflect the preferences of
elite groups. Studies from a variety of countries show that communi-
ties in which inequality is high have worse outcomes, especially where
political, economic, and social power are concentrated in the hands of a
few. “Capture” also tends to be greater in communities that are remote
from centers of power; have low literacy; are poor; or have significant
caste, race, or gender disparities.
    Policy design may also have unintended consequences. A large
injection of resources for a participatory development project can,
for example, attract the attention of the better off, making exclusion
more likely. Participatory projects also often fail to build cohesive and
resilient organizations. During the course of a project, cash or other
material payoffs induce people to participate and build networks—but
these mechanisms tend to dissolve when the incentives are withdrawn.
Only when projects explicitly link community-based organizations
with markets, or provide skills training, do they tend to improve group
cohesiveness and collective action beyond the life of the project.




                                                                                     5
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                             Spending decisions do seem to be better aligned with local needs
                          under democratic decentralization, and resources are reallocated in
                          favor of the less advantaged. But much depends on the nature of
                          electoral incentives and the capacity of higher levels of government to
                          provide oversight and ensure downward accountability.
                             Capacity also matters. The benefits of decentralization seem to be
                          weaker in more remote, more isolated, and less literate localities. Such
                          localities also tend to be more poorly served by mass media and other
                          sources of information, and they are less likely to have adequate central
                          oversight.


                          Does Participation Improve Development Outcomes?
                          On balance, greater community involvement seems to modestly
                          improve resource sustainability and infrastructure quality. But the evi-
                          dence suggests that people who benefit tend to be the most literate, the
                          least geographically isolated, and the most connected to wealthy and
                          powerful people. Participation thus appears to affect the distribution
                          of benefits in ways that suggest that capture is often not “benevolent”
                          or altruistic.
                             Project design and implementation rules play a critical role in deter-
                          mining whether participatory programs are captured. Demand-driven,
                          competitive application processes can exclude the weakest communities
                          and exacerbate horizontal inequities.
                             For many years, willingness to contribute to programs and projects
                          has been seen as evidence of commitment and of the sustainability of
                          programs or of infrastructure. But this belief has little basis in evidence.
                          What little is known suggests that co-fi nancing—the sine qua non
                          of participatory projects—tends to exclude the poorest, particularly
                          when individuals or communities self-select into a program. Evidence
                          also suggests that co-fi nancing requirements for local governments
                          can widen horizontal inequities in targeted transfer programs, because
                          poorer municipalities or counties have an incentive to reduce the pov-
                          erty threshold for transfer eligibility in order to reduce their own co-
                          payment burden.
                             The review of the evidence on community management of common-
                          pool resources and community engagement in the creation and main-
                          tenance of small-scale infrastructure focuses on five main questions:

                             •   What evidence is there for greater resource sustainability under
                                 decentralized or community management?
6
OVERVIEW




  •   What evidence is there of more inclusive management and
      greater equity in the distribution of benefits?
  •   To what extent do community characteristics such as wealth
      inequality, ethnic heterogeneity, and management experience
      affect the sustainability of resources or infrastructure?
  •   How much can local management systems help overcome
      adverse local characteristics—that is, can good design induce
      the right type and level of participation?
  •   How dependent is success on the role played by the central state?
Four main findings emerge from the literature:

  •   Inequality tends to worsen both efficiency and equity, and there
      can be important tradeoffs between resource sustainability and
      equity.
  •   Transferring management responsibilities to a resource or an
      infrastructure scheme does not usually involve handing over
      control to a cohesive organic entity with the requisite capac-
      ity; often it requires creating local management capacity. In the
      absence of deliberate efforts to create such capacity and provide
      resources for ongoing maintenance and management, invest-
      ments in infrastructure are largely wasted and natural resources
      poorly managed.
  •   Clear mechanisms for downward accountability are critical.
      The literature is rife with cases in which decentralization is used
      to tighten central control and increase incentives for upward
      accountability rather than to increase local discretion. The
      absence of robust mechanisms for downward accountability
      tends to go hand in hand with complex reporting and plan-
      ning requirements, which are usually beyond the capacity of
      local actors and become a tool for retaining control and assign-
      ing patronage. Most of these requirements are holdovers from
      past rules designed to extract resources from rather than benefit
      communities.
  •   Communities need to benefit from the resources they manage.
      For natural resources that create substantial externalities, the
      benefit should be commensurate with the size of the externality
      created by the resource and should at least compensate com-
      munities for the alternative uses to which they could put the
      resource for immediate gain.

                                                                                   7
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                              Only a few studies compare community-managed infrastructure
                          projects with similar projects delivered by governmental line depart-
                          ments using a more “top-down” delivery mechanism. These studies
                          find that community engagement seems to improve both the quality of
                          construction and the management of local infrastructure—implying
                          lower levels of corruption relative to government provision.
                              This suggests that carefully designed projects have the potential to
                          limit capture. Indeed, a key feature of the projects studied is that the
                          implementing agencies provided significant oversight during construc-
                          tion, the maintenance and recurrent costs were explicitly budgeted for,
                          and the implementing agency was available to provide training and sup-
                          port for maintenance. These concerns imply considerable engagement
                          of higher-tier governments or implementing agencies in building local
                          capacity, monitoring outcomes, and setting the broad parameters under
                          which management is devolved—with a view to enhancing downward
                          rather than upward accountability while leaving sufficient discretion at
                          the local level.
                              Studies of community participation in health service and educa-
                          tion fi nd modestly positive results overall, although the causal link
                          between participation and service delivery outcomes is often vague.
                          Studies that are able to assess the impact of participation typically find
                          that although inducing community engagement alone has little impact
                          on outcomes, community engagement can substantially amplify the
                          impact of investments in other health or education inputs. In the case
                          of health service delivery, for example, the formation of community
                          health groups appears to have virtually no effect on any health-related
                          outcome when done in isolation but is effective when combined with
                          inputs such as trained health personnel or the upgrading of health facili-
                          ties. Community engagement leads to significantly larger reductions in
                          maternal and infant mortality, larger improvements in health-related
                          behaviors, and greater use of health facilities than investments in health
                          inputs alone can deliver. Interestingly, successful programs are often
                          located within larger government health delivery systems. This finding
                          is encouraging, because government participation is usually central for
                          scaling up health initiatives. The evidence also suggests that the most
                          successful programs tend to be implemented by local governments
                          that have some discretion and are downwardly accountable. Devolving
                          the management of public programs to NGOs appears to work less
                          well, although the evidence remains thin. Community engagement

8
OVERVIEW



in education has somewhat similar but more muted effects, primarily
because impacts on learning tend to be weak, at least over the time
spans covered by evaluations, which may be too short to measure results.
Overall, studies report an increase in school access, an improvement
in retention rates and attendance, and a reduction in grade repetition.
   Interventions that provide information to households and communi-
ties about the quality of services in their community as well as govern-
ment standards of service tend to improve outcomes. Moreover, they do
so even when no additional resources are expended.
   Funding also matters. Increasing the fiscal burden on poor commu-
nities can reduce the quality of public service delivery. When projects
do not cover maintenance and recurrent costs, communities are left
with crumbling schools without teachers and clinics without medicines.
   As with other interventions, however, poorer, more remote areas
are less able to realize gains from decentralized service delivery. The
benefits of decentralization are smaller when communities are less well
administered and more embedded in an extractive equilibrium charac-
terized by weak democratic practices and a politicized administration.
Literacy is also an important constraint—an effect that is consistent
across several studies.
   The evidence suggests that community-based development efforts
have had a limited impact on income poverty. Projects with significant
microfi nance components do show positive impacts on savings and
assets, but these effects appear to be confined largely to the life cycle of
the project. There is also some evidence that community-based devel-
opment projects improve nutrition and diet quality, especially among
children, although some of these studies find that larger benefits accrue
to better-off households.


Does Participation Strengthen Civil Society?
There is little evidence that induced participation builds long-lasting
cohesion, even at the community level. Group formation tends to be
both parochial and unequal. Absent some kind of affirmative action
program, groups that form under the aegis of interventions tend to
systematically exclude disadvantaged and minority groups and women.
Moreover, because similar types of people tend to form groups with
one another, projects rarely promote cross-group cohesion—and may
actually reinforce existing divisions.

                                                                                     9
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                             An important question in this context is the role of facilitators who
                          work with communities. The evidence on this issue is scant, but the
                          few studies that have tried to measure their effects find that facilitators
                          strongly influence the stated preferences of community members, who
                          often tell facilitators what they think they want to hear.
                             Participation often tends to be driven by project-related incentives;
                          people get together to derive benefits from project funds. It is very difficult
                          to know whether these effects will last beyond the tenure of the project
                          and the limited evidence indicates that it usually does not. There is some
                          heartening evidence, though, that participation may have intrinsic value.
                          Communities tend to express greater satisfaction with decisions in which
                          they participate, even when participation does not change the outcome
                          or when outcomes are not consistent with their expressed preferences.
                             The ballot box, though far from perfect, appears to provide a clearer
                          mechanism for sanctioning unpopular policy choices or excessive rent-
                          seeking by traditional or political elites than more informal forums for
                          deliberation. In decentralized settings, credible and open elections help
                          align the decisions of politicians with the demands of their constituents.
                          When participatory and deliberative councils exist in such settings, they
                          can foster a significant degree of civic engagement. It is less clear how
                          citizens can collectively sanction negligent or corrupt officials or local
                          leaders where such venues for the exercise of voice are not available.
                             Repairing civic failures requires that social inequalities be addressed.
                          One way of trying to do so is to mandate the inclusion of disadvantaged
                          groups in the participatory process. There is virtually no evidence from
                          evaluations of community-driven development projects on whether
                          such mandates work. However, a growing body of evidence from vil-
                          lage democracies in India indicates broadly positive impacts. Quotas in
                          village councils and presidencies for disadvantaged groups and women
                          tend to change political incentives in favor of the interests of the group
                          that is favored by the quota.
                             Mandated inclusion also appears to provide an incubator for new
                          political leadership. Evidence indicates that women and other excluded
                          groups are more likely to run for nonmandated seats once they have had
                          some experience on a mandated seat. Quotas can also weaken prevailing
                          stereotypes that assign low ability and poor performance to traditionally
                          excluded groups. However, lasting change requires that the inclusion
                          mandates remain in place for long enough to change perceptions and
                          social norms.

10
OVERVIEW



    Democratic decentralization works because village and municipal
democracies incentivize local politicians to nurture their constituencies.
Because decentralized programs usually come with a constitutional
mandate or other legal sanction from the center, they are relatively
permanent and can therefore change social and political dynamics over
the long term. In contrast, community-based projects are usually ad
hoc interventions that are unable to open political opportunities for
real social change.
    Participatory interventions have been used in postconflict settings as
a quick way of getting funds to the ground. The limited evidence on
their effectiveness suggests that such projects have made little headway
in building social cohesion or rebuilding the state. However, evidence
from Africa seems to suggest that people emerging from civic conflict
have a strong desire to participate in their communities and that well-
designed and implemented projects could draw on this need.
    In sum, the evidence suggests that, although local actors may have an
informational and locational advantage, they use it to the benefit of the
disadvantaged only where institutions and mechanisms to ensure local
accountability are robust. Local oversight is most effective when other,
higher-level institutions of accountability function well and communi-
ties have the capacity to effectively monitor service providers and others
in charge of public resources. Local participation appears to increase,
rather than diminish, the need for functional and strong institutions at
the center. It also implies that implementing agencies for donor-funded
projects need to have the capacity to exercise adequate oversight. There
is little evidence that they can substitute for a nonfunctional state as
a higher-level accountability agent, however. Reforms that enhance
judicial oversight, allow for independent audit agencies, and protect
and promote the right to information and a free media appear to be
necessary for effective local oversight.



Moving Beyond the Evidence
Three main lessons emerge from distilling the evidence and thinking
about the broader challenges in inducing participation.

1. Induced participatory interventions work best when they are sup-
ported by a responsive state. The state does not necessarily have to

                                                                                   11
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          be democratic—though being democratic helps a great deal. But in the
                          sphere in which the intervention is being conducted—at the level of
                          the community or the neighborhood—the state has to be responsive to
                          community demands.
                             Parachuting funds into communities without any monitoring by a
                          supportive state can result in the capture of decision making by elites
                          who control the local cooperative infrastructure, leading to a high risk
                          of corruption. In the absence of a supportive state, participatory engage-
                          ment may still be able to make a difference, but projects implemented
                          in such environments face much greater challenges.

                          2. Context, both local and national, is extremely important. Outcomes
                          from interventions are highly variable across communities; local
                          inequality, history, geography, the nature of social interactions, net-
                          works, and political systems all have a strong influence. The variability
                          of these contexts is sometimes so large, and their effect so unpredictable,
                          that projects that function well usually do so because they have strong
                          built-in systems of learning and great sensitivity and adaptability to
                          variations in context.

                          3. Effective civic engagement does not develop within a predictable
                          trajectory. Instead, it is likely to proceed along a “punctuated equi-
                          librium,” in which long periods of seeming quietude are followed
                          by intense, and often turbulent, change. Donor-driven participatory
                          projects often assume a far less contentious trajectory. Conditioned by
                          bureaucratic imperatives, they often declare that clear, measurable, and
                          usually wildly optimistic outcomes will be delivered within a specified
                          timeframe. There is a danger that such projects set themselves up for
                          failure that derives not from what they achieve on the ground but from
                          their unrealistic expectations.
                             One important reason for this overly ambitious approach, espe-
                          cially at the World Bank, is that many donors’ institutional structure
                          continues to derive from a focus on capital-intensive development and
                          reconstruction. Building dams, bridges, and roads, or even schools and
                          clinics, is a much more predictable activity than changing social and
                          political systems. Repairing civil society and political failure requires a
                          shift in the social equilibrium that derives from a change in the nature
                          of social interactions and from modifying norms and local cultures.
                          These much more difficult tasks require a fundamentally different

12
OVERVIEW



approach to development—one that is flexible, long term, self-critical,
and strongly infused with the spirit of learning by doing.
   The variability of local context and the unpredictable nature of
change trajectories in participatory interventions underscore the need
for effective systems of monitoring and assessing impact. Such projects
require constant adjustment, learning in the field, and experimentation
in order to be effective—none of which can be done without tailoring
project design to the local context, carefully monitoring implementa-
tion, and designing robust evaluation systems.
   As demonstrated in chapter 7 of this report, the World Bank falls far
short on these measures—and other donors probably perform no better.
The results are sobering—and instructive. Despite wide differences in
contexts, the Project Assessment Documents of World Bank–funded
projects (which lay out a project’s design) are striking in their similarity,
with language often simply cut and pasted from one project to another.
A review of the monitoring and evaluation (M&E) systems in World
Bank projects in which at least a third of the budget was allocated to
local participation, as well as a survey of project managers, also reveals
pervasive inattention to monitoring and evaluation systems. Only 40
percent of Project Assessment Documents included a monitoring system
as an essential part of the project design, and a third failed to mention
basic monitoring requirements such as a management information
system (MIS). When monitoring was mentioned, it usually involved
collecting extremely imprecise indicators, and even this data collection
was done irregularly. Even less attention was paid to evaluating project
effectiveness through a credible evaluation. The majority of project
managers indicated that the Bank’s operational policies do not provide
adequate incentives for M&E and that M&E is not perceived to be a
priority of senior management. M&E seems to be treated as a box to
be checked to obtain a loan rather than as an instrument for improving
project effectiveness.



Conclusion
Evaluations of participatory development efforts improved somewhat
between 2007 and 2012, generating some new evidence. However, the
evidence base for most questions relevant to policy remains thin, and
far too little attention is still paid to monitoring and evaluation. Project

                                                                                      13
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          design continues to show little appreciation of context, and inflexible
                          institutional rules fail to internalize the complexity inherent in engag-
                          ing with civic-led development. Unless these problems are addressed,
                          participatory development projects will continue to struggle to make a
                          difference.
                             Local participation tends to work well when it has teeth and when
                          projects are based on well-thought-out and tested designs, facilitated by
                          a responsive center, adequately and sustainably funded, and conditioned
                          by a culture of learning by doing. To ensure that it supports projects
                          with these characteristics, the World Bank and other donor agencies
                          need to take several steps:

                            •   Project structures need to change to allow for flexible, long-term
                                engagement. Patience is a virtue.
                            •   Project designs and impact evaluations need to be informed by
                                political and social analyses, in addition to economic analysis.
                            •   Monitoring needs to be taken far more seriously. The use of
                                new, more cost-effective tools, such as short message service
                                (SMS)–based reporting, could help enormously.
                            •   Clear systems of facilitator feedback as well as participatory
                                monitoring and redress systems need to be created.
                            •   Most important, there needs to room for honest feedback to
                                facilitate learning, instead of a tendency to rush to judgment
                                coupled with a pervasive fear of failure. The complexity of
                                participatory development requires a high tolerance for failure
                                and clear incentives for project managers to report evidence of
                                it. Failure is sometimes the best way to learn about what works.
                                Only in an environment in which failure is tolerated can innova-
                                tion take place and evidence-based policy decisions be made.




14
CHAPTER ONE




Why Does Participation
Matter?

OV ER THE PAST DECA DE, THE WOR LD BA NK H AS A LLOCATED
almost $85 billion to local participatory development.1 Other develop-
ment agencies—bilateral donors and regional development banks—
have probably spent at least as much, as have the governments of most
developing countries.2
   The current wave of interest in participation began as a reaction to
the highly centralized development strategies of the 1970s and 1980s,
which created the widespread perception among activists and nongov-
ernmental organization (NGOs) that “top-down” development aid was
deeply disconnected from the needs of the poor, the marginalized, and
the excluded. Underlying this shift was the belief that giving the poor
a greater say in decisions that affected their lives by involving them
in at least some aspects of project design and implementation would
result in a closer connection between development aid and its intended
beneficiaries.
   Local participation has acquired a life of its own over the past decade.   Local participation has been
It is now proposed as a way to achieve a variety of goals, including          proposed as a way to improve
improving poverty targeting, building community-level social capital,         poverty targeting, build social
and increasing the demand for good governance.                                capital, and increase demand
   One of the key objectives of participation is to incorporate local         for good governance.
knowledge and preferences into the decision-making processes of
governments, private providers, and donor agencies. When potential
beneficiaries are able to make key decisions, participation becomes self-
initiated action—what is known as the “exercise of voice and choice,”
or “empowerment.” Participation is expected to lead to better-designed
development projects, more effective service delivery, and improvements
in the targeting of benefits. Ultimately, it is expected to lead to a more

                                                                                                           15
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                      equitable allocation of public resources and to reductions in corruption
                                      and rent-seeking.
     The two major modalities for        The two major modalities for fostering local participation are com-
      fostering local participation   munity development and decentralization of resources and authority
     are community development        to local governments. Community development supports efforts to
       and local decentralization.    bring villages, urban neighborhoods, and other household groupings
                                      into the process of managing development resources, without relying
                                      on formally constituted local governments. Community development
                                      projects are labeled as community-driven development, community-
                                      based development, community livelihood projects, and social funds.
                                      In recent years, the effort to expand community engagement in service
                                      delivery has also introduced participatory education and health proj-
                                      ects, which have some of the same features as community-driven and
                                      community-based development projects. Designs for this type of aid
                                      can range from community-based targeting, in which only the selection
                                      of beneficiaries is decentralized, to projects in which communities are
                                      also involved to varying degrees in project design, project management,
                                      and the management of resources.
                                         Decentralization refers to efforts to strengthen village and municipal
                                      governments on both the demand and supply sides. On the demand
                                      side, it strengthens citizens’ participation in local government—by, for
                                      example, instituting regular elections, improving access to informa-
                                      tion, and fostering mechanisms for deliberative decision making. On
                                      the supply side, it enhances the ability of local governments to provide
                                      services by increasing their financial resources, strengthening the capac-
                                      ity of local officials, and streamlining and rationalizing administrative
                                      functions.
                                         Community development and decentralization share a common
                                      intellectual pedigree, firmly rooted in historical notions of participa-
                                      tory government. Proponents of participation hold that it has intrinsic
                                      value because it enhances pro-social thinking, strengthens citizenship,
                                      and enables more inclusive civic engagement. Insofar as taking part in
                                      community decision making also builds capacity for self-reliance and
                                      collective action (what is sometimes called “social capital”), participa-
                                      tion also has instrumental value. When successful, participation can
                                      transform passive residents into effective public citizens, who use it as
                                      a tool to hold states and markets accountable and influence decisions
                                      that affect their lives.



16
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



   Advocates of community development view it as a mechanism                 Community development
for enhancing sustainability, improving efficiency and effectiveness,         and decentralization share a
scaling up poverty reduction programs, making development more               common intellectual pedigree,
inclusive, empowering poor people, building social capital, strength-        firmly rooted in historical
ening governance, and complementing market and public sector                 notions of participatory
activities (see, for example, Dongier and others 2001). They argue           government.
that community-driven development in particular is able to achieve
these results by aligning development priorities with community goals;
enhancing communication between aid agencies and beneficiaries;
expanding the resources available to the poor (through microcredit,
social funds, and occupational training); and strengthening the capac-
ity of community-based organizations to represent and advocate for
their communities. Community-driven development has the explicit
objective of reversing power relations in a manner that creates agency
and voice for poor people and gives them more control over develop-
ment assistance. It also strengthens their capacity to undertake and
manage self-initiated development activities.
   Advocates for local decentralization are motivated by a closely
related logic that argues that reducing the distance between govern-
ment and citizens allows governments to be closely observed. Citizens
can communicate their preferences and needs to elected officials and
closely monitor their performance, which improves both transparency
and accountability; they are more likely to notice when local govern-
ment officials steal money from a construction project, engage in
nepotism, or spend their budgets without taking the views of citizens
into account. Enhanced visibility is coupled with a greater capacity
for citizens to mobilize and demand better services and hold local
governments “socially accountable” by activating the local capacity for
collective action. Decentralization, it is argued, also improves electoral
accountability, because better-informed citizens are more capable of
making more informed electoral choices. Furthermore, local govern-
ments “hear” citizens better through direct interactions or deliberative
forums, which increase the voice of citizens. Thus, according to advo-
cates, decentralization improves voice, accountability, and transparency,
making governments more responsive to the needs of citizens.
   Advocates of both community development and decentralization
also argue that these forms of participatory development can be a train-
ing ground for citizenship. Local democracies teach citizens how to



                                                                                                        17
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   engage in democratic politics and to engage, deliberate, and mobilize
                                   in ways that strengthen civil society.
                                      This vision is not universally shared. Some skeptics have misgivings
                                   about the basic precepts of the approach; others are concerned about
                                   the practical challenges of implementing large participatory projects on
                                   tight timelines (Cooke and Kothari 2001; Harriss 2001; Li 2007; Mosse
                                   2002). Particularly when the incentives they face are poorly aligned
                                   with the needs of the project, implementers may gloss over differences
                                   within target groups and local power structures or evade the difficult
                                   task of institution building in favor of more easily deliverable and mea-
                                   surable outcomes. Community development may also be inherently
                                   subject to elite capture because of the entrenched influence of local elites
                                   (Abraham and Platteau 2004).
       The capacity of donor-led      The capacity of donor-led participation to educate and transform
        participation to educate   communities has been challenged on several grounds. First, some
     and transform communities     researchers argue that the exercise of voice and choice can be costly
        has been challenged on     (Mansuri and Rao 2004). It may involve financial losses for benefi-
                several grounds.   ciaries, because of the time required to ensure adequate participation.
                                   Participation may also lead to psychological or physical duress for the
                                   most socially and economically disadvantaged, because it may require
                                   that they take positions that are in conflict with the interests of power-
                                   ful groups. The premise of participatory approaches is that its potential
                                   benefits outweigh such costs, but critics argue that this is by no means
                                   certain.
                                      Second, as participation has become mainstreamed, it has often
                                   been used to promote pragmatic policy interests, such as cost-effective
                                   delivery or low-cost maintenance rather than as a vehicle for radical
                                   social transformation, by shifting some of the costs of service delivery
                                   to potential beneficiaries. Indeed, in both Asia (Bowen 1986) and Africa
                                   (Ribot 1995), participation has been described as a form of forced or
                                   corvée labor, with the poor pressured into making far more substantial
                                   contributions than the rich.
                                      Third, critics argue that the belief that participatory experiences
                                   will transform the attitudes and implementation styles of authoritarian
                                   bureaucracies (governments or donors) may be naive. The routiniza-
                                   tion of participatory planning exercises into the work of public sector
                                   agencies creates additional pressure on resources while leaving imple-
                                   menters unclear about the implications of this new accountability. An
                                   examination of several participatory projects finds that even in projects

18
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



with high levels of participation, “local knowledge” was often a con-
struct of the planning context and concealed the underlying politics of
knowledge production and use (Mosse 2002). Four potential pitfalls
were identified:

  •   Participatory exercises are often public events that are open
      ended regarding target groups and program activities. Thus,
      such events are inherently political, and the resulting project
      design is often shaped by local power and gender relations.
  •   Outside agendas are often expressed as local knowledge. Project
      facilitators shape and direct participatory exercises, and the
      “needs” of beneficiaries are often shaped by perceptions of what
      the project can deliver.
  •   Participants may concur in the process of problem definition
      and planning in order to manipulate the program to serve their
      own interests. Although their concurrence can benefit both proj-
      ect staff and beneficiaries, it places consensus and action above
      detailed planning.
  •   Participatory processes can be used to legitimize a project that
      has previously established priorities and little real support from
      the community.
   Fourth, critics argue that local governments in developing countries      Critics argue that local
are not necessarily more accountable and transparent than central            governments in developing
governments because of the absence of prerequisites for local account-       countries are not necessarily
ability to work (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2006). These prerequisites           more accountable and
include an educated and aware citizenry, relative social and economic        transparent than central
equality, law and order, the ability to run free and fair elections within   governments.
a constitutional setting, reliable and trustworthy information channels,
and oversight by an active and effective civil society.
   This report thus appears in the midst of a raging debate over the
effectiveness of participatory development. Does it work? Does it
increase accountability? Is it captured by elites? Does it increase voice
and choice? Is it “empowering”? Is the money directed toward partici-
patory development well spent? Sparked by concerns that the expan-
sion in funding has not been accompanied by careful evaluations and
independent analysis (Mansuri and Rao 2004), in recent years there
has been a sharp increase in research, particularly impact evaluations,
of community-based development. Scholars from a variety of disciplines
have also substantially increased the understanding of the political

                                                                                                         19
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   economy of decentralization. The goal of this report is to place this
                                   research within an integrated conceptual framework, to summarize its
                                   conclusions, and to draw implications for policy.



                                   The History of Participatory Development
               The idea of civic   The idea of civic participation is as old as the idea of democracy (Elster
         participation is as old   1998); it has existed in many different cultures throughout history. In
     as the idea of democracy.     ancient Athens, policy decisions were made deliberatively, in public set-
                                   tings, with every male citizen given the opportunity to state his point
                                   of view. In Hinduism and Buddhism, public debate and deliberation
                                   have long been seen as a superior form of discourse (Sen 2005). Local
                                   deliberative institutions in South Asia, where these religions predomi-
                                   nate, have been documented dating back to about the fifth century BC
                                   (Altekar 1949). The Quran requires that communal affairs be decided
                                   by mutual consultation (shura) (Ayish 2008). In Islam, the community
                                   (umma) uses shura to not only deliberate but also provide inputs into
                                   public policy, which the ruler (khalifa) must consider.
                                      In pre-European Africa, Zulu chiefs could not make decisions
                                   without first consulting their councils (chila ya njama). Although the
                                   chiefs exercised ritual power, their influence depended on their ability
                                   to persuade and convince, not coerce. Among the Akan people in West
                                   Africa, the authority of the chief was greatly circumscribed. He was
                                   required to act in concurrence with counselors; an attempt to act on his
                                   own was legitimate grounds for dethronement.
         Local decentralization       Local decentralization has an even longer history than participation.
     has an even longer history    Archaeological evidence shows that small city-states in Mesopotamia
            than participation.    and districts in Egypt ruled for many hundreds of years before being
                                   unified (around 3200 BC) into centrally ruled nations. Through con-
                                   quest, these nations formed even greater empires, but cities and districts
                                   within the conquered territories, although obliged to pay tribute and
                                   contribute soldiers to their overlords’ armies, essentially enjoyed home
                                   rule. In addition, as soon as the hold of the conqueror faltered, local
                                   hegemony grew strong (Gardiner 1961; Kramer 1971).
                                      Around 1200 BC, for instance, when the great powers of Egypt
                                   and Mesopotamia faced internal problems and invasion from the
                                   north, Phoenician vassal cities seized the opportunity to declare their



20
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



independence. Although each city continued to rule itself, the cities
agreed to form a loose geopolitical alliance. For the next 600 years,
even during periods of foreign rule, ships from the Phoenician alliance
plied the Mediterranean and traded throughout their vast economic
empire (Mann 1986). When Phoenicia was later conquered—first by
the Greeks, then by the Romans—its cities were forced to levy, collect,
and send back revenues to the central power, but their municipal life
continued to thrive. Rome actually encouraged (nonsubversive) civic
activity, contributing handsomely to public buildings and activities
across the empire (Abbot and Johnson 1968).
   Decentralized but loosely affiliated structures were also the rule in
South Asia during the Mauryan (321–185 BC) and Mughal (1526–
1857) eras. Village governments had considerable authority and power
over practical affairs; the center was seen largely as a place of moral and
symbolic authority that extracted taxes and tribute. In Africa, vassals
used collective decision making to hold chieftains in check, and com-
munity members used consultations and popular assemblies to hold
vassal governments accountable to the public at large.
   The modern theory of participation was first coherently articulated         Rousseau first articulated the
in the 18th century by Jean-Jacques Rousseau, author of The Social            modern theory of
Contract. Rousseau outlined a vision of democracy in which equal citi-        participation in the 18th
zens assemble to make decisions in an interdependent, deliberative man-       century.
ner, to uncover the “general will”—that is, to forge a policy in which
benefits and burdens are equally shared (Pateman 1976). Rousseau was
searching for a vision of human progress in which communities and
connectedness could complement the Enlightenment’s notions of indi-
vidual liberty, and in which the human soul was more important than
science (Damrosch 2007). To Rousseau, participation was more than
a method of decision making. It was a process by which an individual
developed empathy for another’s point of view and learned to take
account of the public interest in order to gain cooperation. Participation
therefore served an important educative function: the individual learned
how to become a public citizen, and community members developed a
sense of belonging. Rousseau intimately linked the notion of participa-
tion with the development of civic life—an idea that has had a profound
influence on subsequent political thought.
   Among the many 19th century philosophers who built on these
ideas, perhaps the most notable was John Stuart Mill (1859, 1879),



                                                                                                         21
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   who also emphasized the educative value of participation. Influenced by
                                   Alexis de Tocqueville’s laudatory descriptions in Democracy in America
                                   (1838) of local political institutions in the United States and the spirit
                                   of participatory democracy they fostered, Mill became deeply skepti-
                                   cal of centralized forms of government. His fears led him to argue that
                                   universal suffrage and participation in national government are of little
                                   use if citizens have not been prepared for participation at the local level.
                                   Mill applied this logic to notions of participation in industry, where, he
                                   argued, collective management would lead to individuals valuing public
                                   over individual interests.
                                      Mill’s vision of a participatory society was taken forward by
                                   G. D. H. Cole, Henry Maine, and other philosophers (known as the
                                   English Pluralists), who rejected the idea of a centralized state and argued
                                   that “individual freedom would best be realized in the groups and associ-
                                   ations that made up the fabric of modern civil society” (Mantena 2009).
                                   Henry Maine is of particular relevance to contemporary development
                                   thought. Sent to India in the 1860s to advise the British government on
                                   legal matters, he came across several accounts by British administrators
                                   of thriving indigenous systems of autonomous village governments that
                                   had many characteristics of participatory democracies. These “data” led
                                   him to articulate a theory of the village community as an alternative to
                                   the centralized state (Maine 1876). In Maine’s view, village communi-
                                   ties, led by a council of elders (panchayat), were not subject to a set of
                                   laws articulated from above but had more fluid legal and governance
                                   structures that adapted to changing conditions while maintaining strict
                                   adherence to traditional customs (Mantena 2009).
      Support for participation       Community development and government decentralization thus
stems from a belief that it has    have a common intellectual history, stemming from a belief that par-
both intrinsic and instrumental    ticipation has both intrinsic and instrumental value. Participation in
                          value.   decision making, Maine believed, makes individuals into public citi-
                                   zens by training them to think in terms of the public good rather than
                                   merely private interests; it builds the capacity for collective action and
                                   what modern social theorists would call “agency.” Participation also
                                   has instrumental value in developing the ability of citizens to hold the
                                   state and markets accountable and to influence decisions that affect
                                   their lives. As the concept evolved, two distinct forms of participa-
                                   tion emerged: participation in Rousseau’s sense of building a collec-
                                   tive identity and participation in the sense of electing a representative
                                   government.

22
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



Participation in Asia, Africa, and Latin America
Rousseau, Mill, and Maine had a deep influence on colonial thought.
In India, which became fertile territory for colonial experiments in gov-
ernance, the liberal British Viceroy Lord Ripon instituted local govern-
ment reforms in 1882 for the primary purpose of providing “political
education” and reviving and extending India’s indigenous system of
government (Tinker 1967).
    Maine’s description of autonomously governed and self-reliant           Autonomously governed and
Indian village communities also influenced Mohandas Gandhi, who              self-reliant Indian village
made it a central tenet of his philosophy of decentralized economic and     communities were a central
political power, as articulated in his writings on village self-reliance,   tenet of Gandhi’s philosophy
collected in his book Village Swaraj (Gandhi 1962). Gandhi saw the          of decentralized economic and
self-reliant village as the cornerstone of a system of government and of    political power.
economic life. The village was to be “a complete republic, independent
of its neighbors for its own vital wants, and yet interdependent for
many others where dependence is a necessity.” Gandhi’s village-republic
would be emblematic of a “perfect democracy,” ensuring equality across
castes and religions and self-sufficiency in all needs; it would be driven
by cooperation and nonviolence. Gandhi remains a central figure in
the participatory and decentralization movements in both India and
the development community at large, particularly among people who
see participation as an antidote to the community-corroding effects of
economic growth and modernization.
    Decentralization in colonial anglophone Africa followed a similar
trajectory, as the colonial powers adopted a policy of “decentralized
despotism” (Mamdani 1996). The principal colonizers established
administrative systems to efficiently govern and extract revenues from
the conquered territories. The British established “indirect rule” that
was, according to Mamdani, based on the lessons they had learned in
India from the innovations in local self-government initiated by Ripon.
The British converted traditional chiefs into “administrative chiefs”
responsible for several functions at the lowest level of the civil admin-
istration, granting them fiscal and functional autonomy as long as they
did not challenge the colonial state. Decentralization in colonial India
and Africa was as much an effort at streamlining colonial power as it
was an effort at good governance.
    In the French colonies, by contrast, decentralization involved
the direct application of French administrative structures, culture,


                                                                                                      23
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  civil law, and education to the colonies. The early colonies, such as
                                  Senegal, were organized according to the French local government
                                  model, based on urban communes represented by municipal councils.
                                  Citizens of the “four communes” of Senegal (Dakar, Gorée, St. Louis,
                                  and Rufisque) even elected representatives to the French parliament in
                                  Paris. Developments in Senegalese communes mirrored political devel-
                                  opments in France: when, in 1831, French communes were given legal
                                  status and the principle of elected municipal councils was established,
                                  these changes applied to the communes in Senegal.
                                     As the French acquired more territory and extended their control over
                                  larger populations, they reversed their policies and began to rule their
                                  new African colonies indirectly, through Africans. They established a
                                  code de l’ indigénat, which outlined the legal system under which indig-
                                  enous populations were to be governed (Levine 2004). This law pro-
                                  vided for the establishment of administrative cercles ruled by appointed
                                  indigenous authorities, religious courts, and the native police. Cercles
                                  comprised cantons, and cantons comprised villages. Villages were gov-
                                  erned by chefs du village, cantons by chefs de canton, and cercles by cercle
                                  commandeurs, each of whom was appointed by and responsible to the
                                  French authorities. The administrators who supervised these chiefs were
                                  recruited, trained, and fielded by the central state. Ribot (2009) points
                                  out that in “all these decentralized systems, the colonial rulers used local
                                  ‘customary’ chiefs to administer the rural world—that is, maintain law
                                  and order, collect taxes, and conscript labor. The systems were created
                                  to manage Africans under local administrative rule.”
                                     In Latin America, Spanish and Portuguese rule left a centralized
                                  legacy (Selee and Tulchin 2004; Grindle 2007; Eaton 2008). Colonial
                                  systems were based on the extraction of wealth and required highly
                                  centralized structures to coordinate the process. In Mexico, for example,
                                  the conquistadores appointed local councils tasked with maintaining
                                  law and order and overseeing food and water supplies (Grindle 2007);
                                  the councils were supervised and held in check by district agents, who
                                  were also responsible for tax collection.
                                     After independence, countries in Latin America modified these
After independence, countries
                                  structures to conform with the more federalist notions from France
    in Latin America modified
                                  and the United States. In Brazil, for instance, the First Republic (which
   their centralized structures
                                  followed the centralized empire established immediately after inde-
     to conform with the more
                                  pendence) had pronounced federal features but provided little or no
federalist notions from France
                                  support for local governments or municipalities. With its collapse, in
        and the United States.

24
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



1930, decentralization gave way to centralized institutions (Melo and
Rezende 2004) and, paradoxically, “municipalism” became a hallmark
of the more centralized developmentalist period.


History of Policy in Participatory Development
By the end of World War II, the disintegration of colonial regimes
made reconstruction and development the central endeavors in Africa
and Asia. Driven by the Bretton Woods institutions, development was
viewed as a “big” undertaking, influenced by structural theories and
planning models. “Small” development also had proponents, particu-
larly among policy makers at the United Nations and the U.S. Agency
for International Development (USAID), who tended toward a com-
munitarian vision of human progress. Their influence led to a first wave
of participatory development in the 1950s that by 1960 had spread to
more than 60 countries in Africa, Asia, and Latin America (White 1999;
Arizpe 2004).3 By 1959, USAID had pumped more than $50 million
into community development projects in about 30 countries. In the con-
text of the Cold War, community development was seen as a means of
protecting newly independent states against the dual threats of external
military aggression and internal subversion. Perhaps the most important
motive was to provide a democratic alternative to Communism (White
1999; Arizpe 2004).
    In the 1950s, the communitarian approach was also promoted in            In the 1950s, the U.S.
India, primarily by the U.S. government and the Ford Foundation,             government and the Ford
where it resonated because of its compatibility with Gandhian ideals.        Foundation promoted the
The Ford Foundation approach drew on ideas from regional planners            communitarian approach to
in the United States who were concerned about the erosion of com-            development in India.
munities with the onset of modernization and urbanization, as well as
on Gandhi’s ideas about sustainable village communities (Immerwahr
2010). In 1952, a Ford Foundation–supported program based on par-
ticipatory models of community development was launched in 16,500
villages; the government of India soon expanded the program to cover
the entire country.
    Funding for community development programs began to dry up in            Funding for community
the early 1960s, because of their perceived failures and because the spec-   development programs began
ter of famine in Asia made the more top-down, technical approaches           to dry up in the early 1960s.
to development seem more urgent. White (1999) argues that com-
munity development programs during this period were undermined

                                                                                                         25
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   by the inability of donors to incorporate the lessons learned about elite
                                   capture or to engage in genuine partnerships with beneficiaries. As a
                                   consequence, community development programs were widely perceived,
                                   whether correctly or not, as having failed to achieve their stated objec-
                                   tives. They were more or less completely abandoned by the end of the
                                   1960s.
                                      As donor interest in local participatory development waned, there
                                   was a revival of interest among radical thinkers. Particularly influential
                                   were Frantz Fanon’s The Wretched of the Earth (1961) and Paulo Freire’s
                                   Pedagogy of the Oppressed (1970). Fanon’s work, which was sometimes
                                   accused of exhorting readers to violence, was born out of frustration
                                   with the racism, torture, and vindictiveness of the colonial administra-
                                   tion in Algeria. In The Wretched of the Earth, he critiques both impe-
                                   rialism and nationalism and calls for the redistribution of wealth and
                                   technology that orient effective power in favor of the poorest people.
                                      Freire was influenced by Fanon and by liberation theologists in
                                   Brazil. His lifelong commitment to adult education helped him explore
                                   the ways in which the oppressed could overcome powerlessness and
                                   “unfreedom.” In Pedagogy of the Oppressed, he stresses the need to
                                   develop an educational system that is more “dialogic,” is rooted in
                                   students’ lived experiences, and values local and diverse kinds of knowl-
                                   edge. This kind of education becomes a tool for “conscientizing” illiter-
                                   ate (and oppressed) populations. In effect, Freire argues for a model of
                                   education that does not consider students’ minds a tabula rasa. Instead,
                                   the role of education is to make students more self-aware and sensitive to
                                   their position and to that of others—a theme very similar to Rousseau’s
                                   notion of the “general will.”
During the 1960s and 1970s,           During the 1960s and 1970s, policy makers began to shift their
 policy makers began to shift      focus to agricultural and industrial growth. This shift was given intel-
their focus to agricultural and    lectual support from the apparent success of industrializing planning
         industrial growth . . .   models of Soviet Russia and from early neoclassical growth models.
                                   The McNamara era at the World Bank focused first on large infra-
                                   structure projects and later on the centralized provision of housing,
                                   education, and health. Politically, centralized polities appeared to be
                                   viable and desirable. Even in the established democracies, mainstream
                                   democratic theories emphasized the representative rather than participa-
                                   tory features of democracy and the desirability of stability rather than
                                   the involvement of the lower classes. Democracy came to be thought
                                   of as merely a method of aggregating preferences by choosing leaders,

26
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



and the deliberation and civic empowerment aspects of the concept
were deemphasized (see Schumpeter 1942 and Dahl 1963 for typical
formulations).
   Also during this period, economists, who had long been skeptical of      . . . and economists, who
community-centered development, began to have a profound influence           had long been skeptical
on development policy. The early literature on development policy was       of community-centered
strongly influenced by the work of Mancur Olson (1965, 2), who argued        development, began to have
that without coercion or some other special device to make individuals      a profound influence on
act in their common interest “rational self-interested individuals will     development policy.
not act to achieve their common or group interests.” Olson was con-
cerned with “exploitation of the great by the small,” because people with
smaller interests in a public good would tend to free-ride on the efforts
of people with greater interests.
   Hardin’s (1968) powerful idea of the “tragedy of the commons” had
even broader implications for a range of economic issues, including
the domain of the public and the private, decentralization of power to
local governments, and the provision and management of common-
pool resources. Like Hardin, property rights theorists such as Demsetz
(1970) and North (1990) argued that common property resources
would be overexploited as demand rose unless the commons were
enclosed or protected by strong state regulation. This view generated a
great deal of pessimism in multilateral development institutions about
the viability of local provision or management of public goods or the
commons. It created a strong impetus for centralized state provision
of public goods, central regulation of common-pool resources, and an
emphasis on private property rights.
   At the same time, there was strong support among economic
theorists for decentralized government with electoral democracy.
Economists approached this problem in several ways. Tiebout’s (1956)
work on the theory of local government expenditures emphasized the
efficiency of decentralized governance. He argued that in a community
context, if mobility were relatively costless, individuals would reveal
their true preferences for levels and combinations of public goods pro-
vision by “voting with their feet”—moving to the locality that offered
their preferred tax-benefit mix. Competition among jurisdictions sup-
plying different combinations of local public goods would thus lead to
an efficient supply of such goods.
   The Tiebout hypothesis later came under heavy attack on the
grounds that its assumptions—full information about community

                                                                                                         27
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  characteristics, costless mobility, no externalities, no economies of scale,
                                  and static preferences—were untenable in developing countries, and
                                  indeed in many developed countries as well. Nevertheless, Tiebout con-
                                  tinues to be widely invoked to support the view that competition among
                                  local jurisdictions in the provision of public goods increases allocative
                                  efficiency—and consequently to justify a push toward decentralization.
     By the mid-1980s, critics        By the mid-1980s, critics of the top-down approach began to com-
    of the top-down approach      plain that many large-scale, centralized, government-initiated devel-
 began to complain that many      opment programs—from schooling to health to credit to irrigation
      large-scale, centralized,   systems—were performing poorly while rapidly degrading common-
          government-initiated    pool resources and having significant negative environmental and
  development programs were       poverty impacts. These complaints reawakened interest in local deci-
            performing poorly.    sion making and the local management of resources. Led by Chambers
                                  (1983) and others, a new participatory development movement applied
                                  these ideas to small-scale projects in ways that allowed the poor to act as
                                  informed participants, with external agents serving mainly as facilitators
                                  and sources of funds. Further support came from the increasingly strong
                                  critique of development from academic social scientists such as Escobar
                                  (1995) and Scott (1999), who argued that top-down perspectives were
                                  both disempowering and ineffective. Meanwhile, highly successful
                                  community-driven development initiatives—such as the Self-Employed
                                  Women’s Association in India, the Orangi Slum Improvement Project in
                                  Pakistan, and the Iringa Nutrition Project in Tanzania—were providing
                                  important lessons for large donors (Krishna, Uphoff, and Esman 1997).
                                      Thinking in mainstream development circles was also significantly
                                  affected by the work of Hirschman (1970, 1984); Cernea (1985); and
                                  Ostrom (1990). Hirschman’s (1970) notions of “voice” and “exit” helped
                                  development practitioners understand how collective agency could
                                  improve well-being. Hirschman’s (1984) own attempts to apply these
                                  ideas to participatory development helped confirm his theories. Cernea
                                  (1985) showed how large organizations such as the World Bank could
                                  “put people first” by working systematically at the local level. Ostrom’s
                                  (1990) work on the management of common-pool resources shifted per-
                                  ceptions about the potential for collective action in poor communities.
                                  She argued that what made Olson’s and Hardin’s work most powerful
                                  also made it dangerous as a foundation for policy making, as their
                                  results depended on a set of constraints imposed for purposes of analy-
                                  sis. The relevance of their theories for policy making, she contended,
                                  was an open question rather than a foregone conclusion. In the real

28
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



world, the capabilities of the people involved can be changed, altering
the constraints. Ostrom and others assembled considerable evidence
from case studies showing that endogenous institutions often man-
aged common-pool resources successfully. Thus, Hardin’s “remorseless
tragedies” were not an inevitable outcome of community management.
    Sen’s (1985, 1999) effort to shift the focus of development from
material well-being to a broad-based “capability” approach also deeply
influenced the development community. Central to this approach were
strategies to “empower” poor people—an agenda taken on by the World
Bank and other donors as part of their response to criticism of top-down
development. Arguments for “participatory development,” as advocated
by Chambers (1983) and others, led to the inclusion of participation as a
crucial means of allowing the poor to have some control over decisions
that affected them.
    These intellectual developments paralleled the rise of pro-democracy
movements, which led to the breakdown of authoritarian regimes in
many parts of the world (Leftwich 1993; O’Donnell 1993). The 1980s
and 1990s witnessed the collapse of totalitarian systems in Eastern
Europe, the former Soviet Union, and Indonesia and the radical redistri-
bution of power and authority in Brazil and the Philippines. The rise of
democratic movements and the conviction that centralized state institu-
tions were corrupt, unaccountable, and unable to deliver public services
led to a growing belief in the value of decentralized government. Mexico
is a typical example. By 1982, international donors had begun to advise
the country’s central government to both initiate structural adjustment
and share administrative and fiscal responsibilities with lower tiers of
government (Mizrahi 2004; Grindle 2007).
    USAID was among the earliest donors to extend explicit support          USAID was among the
to democratic decentralization. In the late 1980s, with the fall of         earliest donors to extend
Communism in Eastern Europe, the agency spelled out its agenda to           explicit support to democratic
support democratic local governance. It viewed decentralization as a        decentralization.
“means to empower citizens locally and to disperse power from the
central government to localities” (USAID 2000, 4 ). By the early 1990s,
the British and French governments, the Development Assistance
Committee, the European Council, the Heads of State and Government
of the Organization of African Unity, and the Commonwealth Heads
of Government had all (re)committed to strengthening democracy, par-
ticipation, and accountability through the mechanism of decentraliza-
tion. The United Nations Development Programme began to explicitly

                                                                                                        29
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    extend assistance to decentralization in 1992; by 1999, it had spent more
                                    than $138 million on decentralization projects.
                 The World Bank        The World Bank was perhaps most instrumental in popularizing the
            was instrumental in     concept of decentralization, by articulating the pressing significance
     popularizing the concept of    of governance issues, especially in Africa. Its focus on governance was
                decentralization.   motivated by the difficult economic climate of the 1980s, coupled
                                    with the realization that investment lending required an appropriate
                                    policy framework to achieve its objectives. Its influential publication,
                                    Governance and Development, summed up the benefits of local decen-
                                    tralization as resulting in significant improvements in efficiency and
                                    effectiveness (World Bank 1992).
                                       Support for decentralization was by no means unqualified: some
                                    observers noted that the “pure decentralization of fi scal federalism
                                    theory” (Prud’homme 1995, 202) could jeopardize macroeconomic
                                    stability and increase regional disparities within countries. Nonetheless,
                                    by 1996, the Bank recognized the role of citizen participation in holding
                                    state structures accountable as key to effective local government.
                                       If the move toward local decentralization was driven largely by a
                                    desire for better governance, community development was driven by the
                                    belief that investing in the “social capital” of communities would lead
                                    to their empowerment and give them a sustainable capacity to fashion
                                    development in their own terms. The inclusion of participatory ele-
                                    ments in large-scale development assistance came quickly at the World
                                    Bank, in social investment funds (Narayan and Ebbe 1997) and other
                                    forms of assistance. Initially focused on targeting poverty, these projects
                                    moved toward a more holistic effort to encourage participation through
                                    institutions that organize the poor and build their capabilities to act
                                    collectively in their own interest (Narayan 2002). The World Bank’s
                                    (2001) World Development Report 2000/2001: Attacking Poverty focused
                                    on empowerment as a key priority of development policy. Its publication
                                    led to a broad-based effort at the Bank to scale up community-based
                                    development. The World Development Report 2004: Making Services
                                    Work for Poor People identified local accountability and local decen-
                                    tralization as important elements of programs that seek to improve the
                                    delivery of public services (World Bank 2004). More recently, donors
                                    have recognized that strengthening governance is key to effective devel-
                                    opment and that improving civic participation, or the “demand side” of
                                    governance, should be an important object of community development
                                    and decentralization. With this second wave of interest in participatory

30
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



approaches to development, participatory notions have, once again, been
absorbed into the mainstream of development thought and practice.4
    Thus, the two types of local participation—community develop-
ment and local decentralization—have common goals and intellectual
origins. They became distinct modalities promoted by distinct ideologi-
cal camps in the second half of the 20th century. In the current (21st
century) wave of interest in local participation, policy does not distin-
guish clearly between the two interpretations. Many decentralization
programs with local electoral democracy place local deliberative forums
at the heart of decision making (examples include participatory budget-
ing and gram sabhas [village assemblies]), and many community-driven
projects build electoral accountability into their leadership selection
process. Thus, lessons from the evidence on village democracy could
have implications for the design of community-driven projects, and
lessons from participatory forums in community-driven projects could
have implications for the design of decentralization programs. For this
reason, both are treated here within the common framework of local
participatory development.



Organic versus Induced Participation
Achieving participatory governance and building civic capacity has            Organic participation is
historically been an organic rather than a state-led process—a process        spurred by civic groups acting
spurred by civic groups acting independently of, and often in opposi-         independently of, and often in
tion to, government. Organic participation is usually driven by social        opposition to, government.
movements aimed at confronting powerful individuals and institu-
tions within industries and government and improving the function-
ing of these spheres through a process of conflict, confrontation, and
accommodation.
   Such processes are often effective because they arise endogenously,
within a country’s trajectory of change, and are directed by highly
motivated, charismatic leaders who mobilize citizens to give voice to
their interests (grievances, rights, and concerns) and exploit political
opportunities. Social movements demand change by confronting situa-
tions they find untenable; they ultimately achieve their goals when they
are able to influence the political process or obtain political power. They
engage in a process of creative destruction. First, they imagine a world in
which social and political relationships are more equitably arranged—or

                                                                                                          31
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    at least restructured in a manner congruent with the interests of the
                                    movement—they articulate their vision of this world to expand their
                                    influence. Then, they mobilize citizens who believe in this vision to
                                    fight for the cause, often at considerable personal cost.
                                        Organic participation is a broad term that covers a variety of civic
                                    activities. It has historically been the norm for civic expression. It
                                    includes social movements that fight for greater democratic expression
                                    and for the rights of the underprivileged, such as the civil rights move-
                                    ment in the United States and the anti-apartheid movement in South
                                    Africa. It also includes attempts to build membership-based organiza-
                                    tions to improve livelihoods and living standards, such as the Grameen
                                    Bank in Bangladesh or the Self-Employed Women’s Association in
                                    India. Organic participation may also include labor movements that
                                    form unions to protect workers and trade associations formed to repre-
                                    sent the interests of a particular industry.
 Induced participation refers to        Induced participation, by contrast, refers to participation promoted
participation promoted through      through policy actions of the state and implemented by bureaucracies
  policy actions of the state and   (the “state” can include external governments working through bilateral
implemented by bureaucracies.       and multilateral agencies, which usually operate with the consent of the
                                    sovereign state). Induced participation comes in two forms: decentral-
                                    ization and community-driven development.
                                        The important difference between induced and organic participation
                                    is that powerful institutions extrinsically promote inducted participa-
                                    tion, usually in a manner that affects a large number of communities
                                    at the same time. In contrast, intrinsically motivated local actors drive
                                    organic participation.
                                        There is often some overlap between organic and induced participa-
                                    tion. Governments may decentralize because of the efforts of social
                                    movements, and the designs of induced participatory programs are
                                    often built on organic models. A government may decide to scale up
                                    the efforts of small-scale organic initiatives and thus turn them into
                                    induced initiatives. An important question is whether efforts initiated
                                    by organic participation can be scaled up by policy interventions in the
                                    form of projects. Rather than wait for the slow process of the endog-
                                    enous development of civic capacity, can policy interventions harness
                                    the capacity of citizens to help themselves and improve the quality of
                                    government and the functioning of markets?
                                        The organic development of civic capacity is a complex process
                                    that is deeply imbedded in a country’s history, its internal conflicts,

32
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



its conception of nationalism, its levels of education and literacy, the
distribution of education and wealth, the nature of the state, the nature
of economic and political markets, and a variety of other conditions.
Organic participation is driven by self-motivated leaders who work
tirelessly, with little compensation, often at a high opportunity cost.
They are constantly innovating, networking, and organizing to get the
movement to succeed. When this complex process of organic change,
driven by intrinsically motivated people, is turned into policy—projects
and interventions to induce participation—it has to be transformed into
manageable, bureaucratically defined entities, with budgets, targets, and
extrinsically motivated salaried staff as agents of change. This transfor-
mation is common to all large-scale, state-led policy initiatives; it has
been famously characterized by Scott (1999) as “seeing like a state.”
But participatory interventions are different from other types of policy
initiatives, because they are based on an inherent irony: the government
is creating institutions structured to resist failures in government. When
government induces participation by means of projects, its agents often
must act against their self-interest by promoting institutions whose pur-
pose is to upset the equilibrium that gives them considerable personal
advantage. Moreover, by devolving power to the local level, higher levels
of government cede power, authority, and finances to communities over
which they may have little control.
    Despite these challenges, in recent years, some countries have           Some countries have induced
successfully induced participation by actively promoting participa-          participation by actively
tory spaces within decentralized systems of governance. One of the           promoting participatory
best-known cases involves participatory budgeting in Porto Alegre,           spaces within decentralized
Brazil. Baiocchi (2005) reviews the history of Brazil’s transition from      systems of governance.
dictatorship to democracy in 1985, placing the Porto Alegre experi-
ment within the context of this shift. By 1988, decentralization to
the local level was codified in the new Brazilian constitution, and
municipal elections were held. Two years later, a candidate from the
Workers Party, which had become a leader in the citizens’ rights move-
ment during the dictatorship, was elected mayor of Porto Alegre.5
The new mayor introduced participatory budgeting. After some years of
experimentation, by the year 2000 participatory budgeting assemblies
were drawing more than 14,000 participants from the city’s poorer
classes and achieving substantial success in improving a range of devel-
opment outcomes. About 9–21 percent of the city’s annual budget was
dedicated to pro-poor investments, leading to almost full sewerage and

                                                                                                      33
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          water coverage, a threefold increase in municipal school enrollment, and
                          a significant increase in housing for poor families.
                             Another important, if less than ideal, example of an entire country
                          trying to introduce empowered participatory governance is the pan-
                          chayat (rural governance) reform in India. Before the enactment of the
                          73rd amendment to the constitution, in 1992, village democracy in
                          India was extremely uneven, despite the fact that most state constitu-
                          tions mandated regular village elections and gave village governments
                          some degree of fiscal authority. The amendment addressed these prob-
                          lems in several ways:

                            •   It set up a three-tiered panchayat system consisting of gram
                                panchayats (village councils), block panchayats (block councils),
                                and zila panchayats (district councils).
                            •   It systematized panchayat elections to all three levels, established
                                independent election commissions, and gave the panchayats
                                more fiscal authority and political power.
                            •   It mandated that gram sabhas (village meetings) be held at
                                regular intervals throughout the year, to allow anyone in the
                                village to discuss budgets, development plans, and the selec-
                                tion of beneficiaries and to interrogate gram panchayat and local
                                administrative officials on any issue.
                            •   It reserved a proportion of seats on gram panchayats, including
                                the position of gram panchayat president, for members of disad-
                                vantaged castes (according to their share of the village popula-
                                tion) and women (who are allocated a third of all seats in the
                                gram panchayat and a third of gram panchayat presidencies on a
                                rotating basis).
                              By making deliberative processes through the gram sabha a corner-
                          stone of village government, the central authorities in India created a
                          civic sphere that was not organically derived but, rather, sponsored by
                          the state—in effect, blurring the boundary between the state and civil
                          society and between organic and induced participation. By reducing
                          its monopoly on power and altering its relationship with citizens, the
                          government changed the terms of citizens’ engagement with the power
                          structure. However, although a constitutional amendment sparked
                          reforms in village democracy, responsibility for implementing those
                          reforms remained with state governments, which has made the quality
                          of the implementation variable, and dependent on local state politics.

34
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



   Village democracy in China is another example of a centrally driven
policy change toward decentralization and participation. Through
much of China’s long history, the central state has ruled the country-
side only indirectly. In fact, during the Ming (1468–1644) and Qing
(1644–1911) dynasties, the imperial bureaucracy extended only to the
xian (county) level, leaving control of the countryside largely in the
hands of the local gentry and elites. It was not until the modern era
(comprising the Republican Period [1911–49] and the People’s Republic
of China [1949–present]) that the central government consolidated its
control of the countryside. Beginning with land reforms in 1949 and
accelerating with the collectivization of agriculture in the mid-1950s,
the state established official bureaucracies at the county, township, and
(through the Communist Party Secretariat and branches) village levels.
Despite tight governmental control for state purposes, however, rural
citizens remained marginalized when it came to social services, and the
vast majority of national resources went to build cities and industry. It
was not until the 1970s that administrative power was decentralized to
rural communes, which were converted into townships and villages. In
these new entities, the more entrepreneurial officials soon began using
their newfound authority and discretion to take advantage of opportu-
nities opened up by market liberalization. Within a few years, China’s
countryside became a dynamic new source of economic growth.
   Politically and administratively, however, decollectivization and the
break-up of the communes left a vacuum in governance below the town-
ship level. To fill this gap, China enacted the Draft Village Organic Law
(1987) and the Village Organic Law (1998), which reaffirmed villagers’
right to self-government, the popular election of local officials, and the
central Communist Party’s role in village rule. These reforms recog-
nized the village as the most important funder and provider of local
public goods and services for the rural population. They vested land
ownership rights in the village or collective and allocated use rights to
households on terms regulated by national law. Electoral democracy at
the local level now coexists with nominated or appointed Communist
Party rule at the apex. Since 1998, China has held direct elections
for village committees, the organizational blocks of rural life that are
responsible for public services at the local level. The electoral process,
enshrined in Article 14 of the Organic Law on Villagers Committees,
combines a process of public nomination with secret ballots. The
design of this process was based on a series of pilots encouraged by the

                                                                                                 35
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  government in as many as 24 provinces (Zhenyao 2007), making China
                                  one of the few countries in the world where popular deliberations have
                                  been organized to determine electoral mechanisms.
  In China, the introduction of       In Brazil and India, participatory innovations were the culmina-
 local democracy was entirely     tion of long periods of engagement by social movements that exploited
   the result of a technocratic   political opportunities at the center to slowly move the case for partici-
        decision by the center.   patory democracy forward. This was not the case in China, where the
                                  introduction of local democracy was entirely the result of a technocratic
                                  decision by the center. As such, local democracy is more an administra-
                                  tive mandate, which could be withdrawn.
                                      Unlike participatory innovations in decentralized local governments,
                                  community-driven development interventions are usually packaged as
                                  “projects” and designed as grants or loans that work within, and are
                                  often implemented by, existing government institutions. They are con-
                                  sequently greatly influenced by the institutional structures and incen-
                                  tives of donors and bound by their time frames (usually three to five
                                  years). At their best, these projects attempt to speed up the rate of insti-
                                  tutional change by nudging reforms in a direction to which national
                                  governments are already committed. More typically, community-driven
                                  development projects work in parallel with local governments, often
                                  bypassing them by setting up competing sources of authority within
                                  communities. Some projects have very ambitious goals (“reduce poverty
                                  by 20 percent,” “rebuild trust,” “enhance civic capacity”). Others have
                                  more circumscribed objectives, such as the introduction of a participa-
                                  tory mechanism into particular arenas (schools with parent-teacher
                                  associations, rural clinics with village health committees). Many proj-
                                  ects that are not classified as community driven also use deliberative and
                                  participatory processes for limited objectives, such as selecting deserving
                                  beneficiaries for targeted programs, forming village committees to man-
                                  age the construction of a village infrastructure project, or establishing
                                  microcredit groups.
                                      Figure 1.1 illustrates the difficult task of characterizing the differ-
                                  ent modalities of induced participation. The nature of participation
                                  is influenced not just by the social and political context in which it is
                                  situated but also by the way in which it is designed. Both the context
                                  and the design have a strong influence on incentives for implementers
                                  and beneficiaries and, consequently, on accountability and the sustain-
                                  ability of the intervention.
                                      A country’s political system matters a great deal. In democracies,
                                  electoral incentives shape participatory interventions. Participatory
36
Figure 1.1 A typology of induced participation


                                           Nondemocratic state
                                                                                  Political                                                        Short term
                                                                               decentralization
                                                                                                                    Single purpose

                                                                              Deconcentration
                             Induced                                                                               Multiple purpose
                                                                              Community-driven
                                                                                                                                                    Long term
                                                                                development
                                            Democratic state
         Type of local
     participatory project
       or intervention
                                                                                                  Implementation




                                                  Central                           Local                        Independent project           Direct implementation
                                                government                       government                    implementation agency                   by NGO




                             Organic




                                                                                                                                                                       WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?
                                                                                                     Funding


                                                                   Central                              Local
                                                                                                                                       Donor
                                                                 government                           revenue
37
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



      In democracies, electoral       projects are often pushed through just before elections as an easy way
  incentives shape participatory      to dole out money to voters. There is a constant tension between central
                  interventions.      and local governments, with central governments attempting to reclaim
                                      powers that have been locally devolved. Stable democracies also allow
                                      for more stable trajectories of decentralization. They have an affinity
                                      for empowered participation functioning in the presence of strong civic
                                      institutions, which can play an important role in local empowerment.
                                          Nondemocratic countries, particularly countries that have a history
                                      of careening between democracy and dictatorship, have more unstable
                                      polities. As a result, citizens cannot always act in ways that are consistent
                                      with the expectation of long-term change. This uncertainty, in turn,
                                      reduces their confidence that the increase in local power brought about
                                      by a project will result in lasting change, making them more fearful of
                                      eventual retaliation by local elites. Even nondemocratic countries that
                                      have stable, technocratically driven administrations can demonstrate a
                                      commitment to local decentralization, motivated by allocative efficiency.
                                      Thus, there can be situations in which democratic participation at the
                                      local level is coupled with a more authoritarian structure at the center.
                                          The next node in figure 1.1 categorizes participation into three
                                      modalities: political decentralization, deconcentration, and community-
                                      driven development. In politically decentralized systems, community
                                      leaders are democratically elected through credible and competitive
                                      elections. At the same time, power and finances are devolved to local
                                      governments. Administrative decentralization occurs when central
                                      authorities allocate some functions of government to lower-level admin-
                                      istrators, who generally report to the central state. Community-based
                                      and community-driven development refer to projects in which com-
                                      munities, functioning outside a formal system of government, are given
                                      funds that they manage to implement subinterventions. In practice,
                                      these modalities often overlap, or exist in parallel, with a variety of sub-
                                      modalities. For instance, some community-driven development projects
                                      are designed to strengthen local democratically elected governments or
                                      create alternative power structures to counter the power of nonelected
                                      local administrators.
         The stability of political       The stability of political decentralization depends on the extent to
    decentralization depends on       which the center is committed to local democracy; decentralization is
the extent to which the center is     most stable when village and municipal democracies have been granted
 committed to local democracy.        constitutional sanction. Political decentralization sharply increases the
                                      incentives for electoral accountability and therefore for the sustained

 38
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



empowerment of citizens, but it can be influenced by clientelistic
politics. In deconcentrated systems, local administrators tend to face
incentives driven by the center; they are therefore usually characterized
by upward rather than downward accountability. Effective deconcen-
tration, which is technocratically driven, can also result in the efficient
allocation of tasks. It is, however, not generally conducive to the devel-
opment of sustained local participation.
   The effectiveness of community-driven interventions at the local             The effectiveness of
level is highly conditioned by local capacity, in particular the capacity       community-driven
for collective action. Local social structures and levels of elite control      interventions at the local level
can play a strong role in its functioning. In such interventions, the           is highly conditioned by local
challenge is for state agencies responsible for projects to internalize the     capacity, in particular the
intrinsic and instrumental values of participation and to ensure that           capacity for collective action.
projects are implemented in a manner that meets their stated inten-
tions. If participation is introduced to solve a principal-agent problem
in a situation in which the central managers of an agency lack the
information and the capacity to monitor the quality of services in local
communities, participation will likely be seen as a complement to their
objectives. In contrast, if central agencies are enmeshed in a nexus of
accommodation and capture with local elites, which would be jeopar-
dized by effective participation, central government officials will more
likely see participation as a threat.
   In its early stages, the process of participation may be more noisy
than useful; changing this dynamic requires sustained engagement
and a strong commitment from the center. The nature of the state thus
affects the quality of participation. A state that is reasonably effective
and seeks to improve its ability to deliver local public goods and services
could provide an enabling environment for participation. A weak state
that is dominated by elites and enmeshed in structures of expropriation
and that introduces participation only in response to external donor
pressure probably would not provide such an environment.
   The next node in figure 1.1 indicates that participatory interventions
that focus on a single objective (such as parental control over schools)
are fundamentally different from interventions with multiple purposes
(such as devolution of a set of powers to village governments or liveli-
hoods projects that provide everything from credit and jobs to nutrition
and sanitation). The structure of incentives in each is different. It affects
the extent and nature of community participation and the involvement
of higher levels of government.

                                                                                                              39
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                An important concern, depicted in the next node in figure 1.1, is
                             whether the intervention has a long or short horizon. Interventions with
                             long-term horizons—say, an effort to introduce local democracy at the
                             local level that has constitutional sanction—fundamentally improve the
                             incentives of citizens to confront local elites and fight for their interests.
                             Interventions with short-term horizons will incentivize individuals to
                             extract all the rents that they can from the project during its tenure.
                                The top half of figure 1.1 maps some of the permutations within
                             which participatory interventions can be designed. Each permutation
                             results in different incentives, which influence the effectiveness and
                             sustainability of the project. It suggests that a community-based effort
                             to manage village schools run within a political decentralized system
                             within a democratic country is more likely to lead to a sustainable and
                             equitable improvement in welfare than a well-funded community-
                             driven development project with a three-year horizon that is run by
                             a deconcentrated administration within an unstable authoritarian
                             country.
                                The bottom half of figure 1.1 shows how project implementation
                             matters. Central governments, local governments, NGOs, and indepen-
                             dent project implementation agencies can all run induced participatory
                             projects. Typically, some combination of these bodies runs projects (for
                             instance, the central government or the project agency may hire an NGO
                             to implement a project at the local level). Who manages project imple-
                             mentation has implications for accountability and the quality of imple-
                             mentation. If democratically elected, local governments can be the most
                             downwardly accountable. NGOs and project implementation agencies
                             are deeply affected by the incentives of their organizations; unless their
                             organizational incentives are set up in a way that encourages them to do
                             so, they may not be accountable to the demands of communities.
          Funding matters.      Funding also matters. Is funding derived entirely from central alloca-
                             tions to local communities? Is it dependent on local revenue generation
                             through taxes and community participation, or is it entirely dependent
                             on donor funds? Each situation is affected by a different political
                             economy and incentives for community participation. If, for example,
                             a community-based effort to manage schools is managed exclusively
                             by NGOs and dependent on donor funds, it might be well funded and
                             well managed in the short term but it would be subject to the risk of
                             failure in the long term. In contrast, if the intervention is managed by
                             local governments and funded by local taxes, implementation may be
                             ineffective in the short term, because of clientelism and the inability of
40
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



local governments to collect taxes. However, the project could become
more effective over the long term as communities become more politi-
cally mature.



Scope of the Report and Roadmap
The scope of this report is broad. The report focuses on the impact of
efforts to induce participation. It therefore does not review the large
body of literature on organic participation, although it draws on several
lessons from efforts to scale-up organic movements through induced
policy interventions.
   The focus is on participatory development; much less attention is
paid to the important “supply-side” aspects of governance (fiscal decen-
tralization, taxation policy, local government procedures, and bureau-
cratic inefficiency). The literature on this issue has been the subject of
other reports and reviews by the World Bank, in particular the series of
books edited by Anwar Shah (2006a, 2006b, 2006c, 2006d).
   “Local” development does not mean decentralization to subnational
bodies, such as state or district governments. Decentralization of this
kind is the subject of a large body of literature related to fiscal federalism
and its variants. The focus here is on local participatory development.
Attention is therefore confined to the lowest level of government, typi-
cally the municipal and village levels, and to community organizations,
village committees, and neighborhood associations.
   The report examines large-scale participatory projects that have
been evaluated based on representative samples of target populations
with adequate counterfactuals (alternate scenarios of what would have
happened to the targeted communities in the absence of the interven-
tion). The ideal counterfactual would be the same community in the
absence of the intervention—a situation that cannot be observed.
Econometricians and statisticians have therefore devised various
methods that attempt to approximate this ideal by finding methods of
selecting “control” groups. These methods include randomized trials,
regression discontinuity designs, well-designed methods of matching,
and natural experiments.
   A limitation of the counterfactuals used by evaluations of partici-
patory projects is that they generally compare communities with the
intervention to control communities in which the status quo is main-
tained. Few compare the participatory intervention to an alternate type
                                                                                                    41
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          of intervention (or “arm”) that could help inform design. For example,
                          very few studies compare outcomes delivered by participatory interven-
                          tions with top-down interventions, limiting the ability to determine
                          whether participatory methods work better or worse than alternate
                          designs. Examining the impact of a participatory intervention with
                          respect to the status quo remains extremely useful, however, because
                          it allows researchers to credibly assess the impact of the intervention.
                          Several useful lessons emerge from the review of a large body of such
                          evidence. Most of the fi ndings, therefore, derive from econometric
                          analysis, although case studies are used to develop ideas and illustrate
                          the conceptual framework. Several observational studies are also sum-
                          marized to illustrate key points throughout the report.
                              Another criterion used to select studies for review is that they were
                          published in a peer-reviewed journal or written by scholars with a track
                          record of peer-reviewed publication. Some studies that do not satisfy
                          these criteria were included because of thinness in the literature on a
                          particular topic or some other compelling reason. In such cases, poten-
                          tial problems with the study are clearly identified before conclusions are
                          drawn from it. (Throughout the report, the strengths and weaknesses in
                          the methodology used by the researchers is assessed and conclusions are
                          drawn only from studies whose methodology can be defended.)
                              The rest of this report is organized as follows. Chapter 2 provides a
                          conceptual framework for participatory development. It develops the
                          notion of civil society failure and explores the interactions among civil
                          society failure, government failure, and market failure as key to diag-
                          nosing problems in local development. The chapter also examines the
                          implications of civil society failure and how such failure relates to the
                          size of groups and elite control and capture.
                              Chapter 3 focuses on the challenge of inducing participation by
                          developing some of the policy implications of this “failure triangle.” It
                          develops a set of criteria for diagnosing civil society failures and under-
                          standing how the intersection of market, government, and civil society
                          failure affects the dynamics of local development. This framework is
                          used to examine the challenges of implementation, including the role of
                          donors and facilitators, and of working within the multiple uncertain-
                          ties of highly variant contexts and unknown trajectories of change. A
                          set of hypotheses is derived from the conceptual framework.




42
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



    Chapters 4, 5, and 6 present the evidence in support of and at odds
with the hypotheses. Chapter 4 focuses on the evidence on elite capture
and its importance within the broader context of leadership and rep-
resentation within communities. It also examines the role of political
and electoral incentives in determining the quality of leadership and the
local prevalence of corruption, investigating whether corruption can be
countered by better accountability mechanisms. The chapter attempts
to answer a series of questions: How does inequality in communities
affect the process of resource allocation? To what extent do elites domi-
nate the process of decision making? To what extent does introducing
local democracy make government more accountable? To what extent
does it change political incentives? Does devolving the allocation of
funds to communities make them more susceptible to corruption and
theft? Under what conditions does participation empower citizens to
act in their own interests?
    Chapter 5 examines the claim that participation improves the deliv-
ery of public goods and services, the management of common property
resources, and living standards. It begins by examining the effectiveness
of community-based approaches in targeting the poor. It tries to deter-
mine whether localized projects outperform centrally driven projects in
targeted private transfers to the poor and whether local projects allocate
public goods in a manner that better matches the needs of the poor.
The chapter then looks at the impact of participation on common-pool
resources, local infrastructure, schooling, and health. Does involving
communities in managing local public facilities improve maintenance?
Are common-property resources more sustainable when communities
manage them? Does involving parents in the management of schools
improve learning outcomes? Does oversight of local public clinics and
hospitals by individuals who come within their scope of operation
improve health outcomes? When citizens participate in decisions on
local public goods and services, are they more satisfied with how the
agents of government provide these services? More generally, are par-
ticipatory projects effective in expanding livelihood options for the poor
and generating wealth?
    Chapter 6 assesses the evidence on whether participatory develop-
ment can build civil society. The evidence is examined to answer some
fundamental questions: How do deliberative processes actually work




                                                                                                 43
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          in developing countries? Is deliberation equitable? Is it sustainable?
                          Under what conditions does it build the capacity to engage? Can local
                          inequalities in power and social structure be remedied by mandating
                          the inclusion of women and discriminated against minorities in leader-
                          ship positions? Does improving, and equalizing, access to information
                          result in better outcomes? Does participation build social capital? Does
                          it improve the community’s capacity to monitor and sanction govern-
                          ment? How well do participatory projects work in postconflict settings
                          in particularly dysfunctional states?
                              Chapter 7 poses some remaining open questions and suggests some
                          directions for future research on participatory development. It then
                          assesses the World Bank’s approach to participatory development,
                          reviewing the extent to which it reflects some of the principles that are
                          essential to effective implementation. The chapter reviews design docu-
                          ments from a large sample of World Bank participatory projects and
                          reports findings from a survey of project managers. It offers some policy
                          recommendations for the World Bank and other agencies engaged in
                          designing and implementing induced participatory projects.



                          Notes
                          1. Lack of data availability and problems with definitions make it difficult
                             to find accurate estimates of total World Bank lending for these sectors.
                             According to the Bank’s Social Development Department, total lending
                             for community-based and community-drive development was $54 billion
                             over the 1999–2011 period, with $7.8 billion allocated in fiscal 2010 alone.
                             Between 1990 and 2007, another $31.6 billion was allocated to lending for
                             projects with decentralization components, raising the total allocation for
                             local participatory development to about $85 billion.
                          2. Reliable figures are hard to come by because of the large numbers of such
                             organizations and the diverse ways in which they report their data.
                          3. Community development programs were also in vogue in francophone
                             Africa as animation rurale, since at least 1945 (White 1999).
                          4. White (1999) identifies a second wave in the 1970s and 1980s, initiated
                             by the UN system. In fact, it seems more a ripple than a wave, as it had
                             little influence on large lending agencies. White calls the current interest
                             in community-driven development a third wave, “with the added impetus
                             given by the conversion of the World Bank to the cause” (109).
                          5. The left-leaning Workers Party was founded in 1980 as a party where “social
                             movements can speak.”



44
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?




References
Abbot, F. F., and C. Johnson. 1968. Municipal Administration in the Roman
     Empire. New York: Russell and Russell.
Abraham, A., and J.-P. Platteau. 2004. “Participatory Development: When
     Culture Creeps.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton,
     210–33. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Altekar, A. S. 1949. State and Government in Ancient India: From Earliest Times
     till 1200 A.D. New Delhi: Motilal Banarsidass.
Arizpe, L. 2004. “The Intellectual History of Culture and Development
     Institutions.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton,
     163–84. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Ayish, M. I. 2008. The New Arab Public Sphere. Berlin: Frank and Timme
     GmbH Verlag.
Baiocchi, G. 2005. Militants and Citizens: The Politics of Participatory
     Democracy in Porto Alegre. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2006. “The Rise of Local Governments: An
     Overview.” In Decentralization and Governance in Developing Countries,
     ed. P. Bardhan and D. Mookherhee, 1–52. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Bowen, J. R. 1986. “On the Political Construction of Tradition: Gotong
     Royong in Indonesia.” Journal of Asian Studies 45(3): 545–61.
Cernea, M. M. 1985. Putting People First: Sociological Variables in Rural
     Development. New York: Oxford University Press.
Chambers, R. 1983. Rural Development: Putting the Last First. Harlow, U.K.:
     Pearson Education.
Cooke, B., and U. Kothari. 2001. Participation: The New Tyranny? London:
     Zed Books.
Dahl, R. 1963. A Preface to Democratic Theory. Chicago: University of Chicago
     Press.
Damrosch, L. 2007. Jean-Jacques Rousseau: Restless Genius. New York: Mariner
     Books.
Demsetz, H. 1970. “The Private Production of Public Goods.” Journal of Law
     and Economics 13(2): 293–306.
de Tocqueville, Alexis. 1838. Democracy in America. New York: George
     Dearborn and Company.
Dongier, P., J. V. Domelen, E. Ostrom, A. Ryan, W. Wakeman, A. Bebbington,
     S. Alkire, T. Esmail, and M. Polski. 2001. “Community Driven
     Development.” In A Sourcebook for Poverty Reduction Strategies, ed. Jeni
     Klugman, 301–31. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Eaton, K. 2008. “Decentralization and Governance: Lessons from Latin
     America.” Background paper for World Bank Policy Research Report,
     Washington, DC.
Elster, J. 1998. “Introduction.” In Deliberative Democracy. ed. J. Elster, 1–18,
     Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Escobar, A. 1995. Encountering Development: The Making and Unmaking of the
     Third World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.



                                                                                                       45
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Fanon, F. 1961. Les damnés de la terre. Paris: François Maspero.
                          Freire, P. 1970. Pedagogy of the Oppressed. New York: Herder and Herder.
                          Gandhi, M. 1962. Village Swaraj. Ahmedabad, India: Navjivan Press.
                          Gardiner, A. 1961. Egypt of the Pharaohs: An Introduction. New York: Oxford
                               University Press.
                          Grindle, M. 2007. Going Local: Decentralization, Democratization, and the
                               Promise of Good Governance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
                          Hardin, G. 1968. “The Tragedy of the Commons.” Science 162(3859):
                               1243–48.
                          Harriss, J. 2001. Depoliticizing Development: The World Bank and Social
                               Capital. New Delhi: LeftWord Books.
                          Hirschman, A. O. 1970. Exit Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms,
                               Organizations and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
                          ———. 1984. Getting Ahead Collectively: Grassroots Experiences in Latin
                               America. New York: Pergamon.
                          Immerwahr, D. 2010. Community Development in India. Working Paper,
                               Department of History, University of California, Berkeley.
                          Kramer, S.N. 1971, The Sumerians: Their History, Culture and Character.
                               Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
                          Krishna, A., N. T. Uphoff, and M. J. Esman. 1997. Reasons for Hope: Instructive
                               Experiences in Rural Development. West Hartford, CT: Kumarian.
                          Leftwich, A. 1993. “Governance, Democracy and Development in the Third
                               World.” Third World Quarterly 14(3): 605–24.
                          Levine, V. T. 2004. Politics in Francophone Africa. Boulder, CO: Lynne
                               Rienner.
                          Li, T. 2007. The Will to Improve. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
                          Maine, H. 1876. Village Communities in the East and West. London: John
                               Murray.
                          Mamdani, M. 1996. Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Legacy
                               of Late Colonialism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
                          Mann, M. 1986. The Sources of Social Power: A History of Power from the
                               Beginning to A.D 1760, vol. I. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University
                               Press.
                          Mansuri, G., and V. Rao. 2004. “Community-Based and -Driven Development:
                               A Critical Review.” World Bank Research Observer 19(1): 1–39.
                          Mantena, K. 2009. Alibis of Empire. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
                          Melo, M., and F. Rezende. 2004. “Decentralism and Governance in Brazil.”
                               In Decentralization and Governance in Latin America, ed. J. S. Tulchin
                               and A. Selee, 37–66. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press.
                          Mill, J. S. 1859. On Liberty. London: John W. Parker and Son.
                          ———. 1879. “Chapters on Socialism.” Fortnightly Review 25(February):
                               217–37; March: 373–82; April: 513–30.
                          Mizrahi, Y. 2004. “Twenty Years of Decentralization in Mexico: A Top-Down
                               Process.” In Decentralization, Democratic Governance, and Civil Society in
                               Comparative Perspective: Africa, Asia and Latin America, ed. P. Oxhorn,
                               J. S. Tulchin, and A. D. Selee, 33–58. Washington, DC: Woodrow
                               Wilson Center Press.


46
WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER?



Mosse, D. 2002. “People’s Knowledge, Participation and Patronage:
     Operations and Representations in Rural Development.” In Empowerment
     and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook, ed. D. Narayan. Washington, DC:
     World Bank.
Narayan, D. 2002. Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook.
     Washington, DC: World Bank.
Narayan, D., and K. Ebbe. 1997. “Design of Social Funds: Participation,
     Demand Orientation, and Local Organizational Capacity.” World Bank
     Discussion Paper 375, World Bank, Washington, DC.
North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance.
     Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
O’Donnell, G. 1993. “On the State, Democratization and Some Conceptual
     Problems (A Latin American View with Glances at Some Post-Communist
     Countries).” World Development 21(8): 1355–70.
Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of
     Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for
     Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Pateman, C. 1976. Participation and Democratic Theory. Cambridge, U.K.:
     Cambridge University Press.
Prud’homme, R. 1995. “The Dangers of Decentralization.” World Bank
     Research Observer 10(2): 201–20.
Ribot, J. C. 1995. “From Exclusion to Participation: Turning Senegal’s
     Forestry Policy Around?” World Development 23(9): 1587–99.
———. 2009. “Forestry and Democratic Decentralization in Sub-Saharan
     Africa: A Review.” In Governing Africa’s Forests in a Globalized World, ed.
     L. A. German, A. Karsenty, and A. Tiani, 29–55. London: Earthscan.
Schumpeter, J. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper
     and Brothers.
Scott, J. 1999. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human
     Condition Have Failed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Selee, A. D., and J. S. Tulchin. 2004. “Decentralization and Democratic
     Governance: Lessons and Challenges.” In Decentralization, Democratic
     Governance, and Civil Society in Comparative Perspective: Africa, Asia and
     Latin America, ed. P. Oxhorn, J. S. Tulchin, and A. D. Selee, 295–319.
     Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press.
Sen, A. 1985. Commodities and Capabilities. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
———. 1999. Development as Freedom. New York: Knopf.
———. 2005. Argumentative Indian. London: Allen Lane.
Shah, A., ed. 2006a. Local Budgeting. Public Sector Governance and
     Accountability Series. Washington, DC: World Bank.
———. 2006b. Local Governance in Developing Countries. Public Sector
     Governance and Accountability Series. Washington, DC: World Bank.
———. 2006c. Local Governance in Industrial Countries. Public Sector
     Governance and Accountability Series. Washington, DC: World Bank.
———. 2006d. Local Public Financial Management. Public Sector Governance
     and Accountability Series. Washington, DC: World Bank.


                                                                                                       47
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Tiebout, C. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political
                              Economy 64(5): 416–24.
                          Tinker, H. 1967. The Foundations of Local Self-Government in India, Pakistan
                              and Burma. Bombay: Lalvani.
                          USAID. 2000. USAID’s Experience in Decentralization and Local Governance.
                              Washington, DC: Center for Democracy and Governance, USAID.
                          White, H. 1999. “Politicising Development? The Role of Participation in
                              the Activities of Aid Agencies.” In Foreign Aid: New Perspectives, ed.
                              K. Gupta, 109–25. Boston: Kluwer Academic Press.
                          World Bank. 1992. Governance and Development. Washington, DC: World
                              Bank.
                          ———. 2001. World Development Report 2000/2001: Attacking Poverty.
                              Washington, DC: World Bank.
                          ———. 2004. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor
                              People. Washington, DC: World Bank.
                          Zhenyao, W. 2007. “The Process of Establishing and Extending Direct
                              Elections in Rural China.” In Narratives of Chinese Economic Reforms:
                              How Does China Cross the River? ed. X. Zhang, S. Fan, and A. de Haan.
                              Singapore: World Scientific.




48
CHAPTER TWO




A Conceptual Framework for
Participatory Development

DESPITE THE RECENT UPSURGE IN INTEREST, PARTICIPATORY DE -
velopment policy is beset with a lack of conceptual clarity. Allocations
of many millions of dollars are justified by little more than slogans,
such as “empowering the poor,” “improving accountability,” “building
social capital,” and “improving the demand side of governance.” Part
of the conceptual challenge lies in understanding what these notions
mean, how they fit within broader conceptions of development policy,
and how they differ across diverse contexts and over time. This chapter
presents a framework within which to think about some of these issues.
The goal is to understand participatory interventions as a response to
a development failure, much as other development interventions are
viewed as responses to market or government failures.
   The chapter begins by briefly reviewing the concept of market fail-         Participatory development
ure, the key construct used to justify development policy. It then reviews    policy is beset with a lack of
the extension of the basic notion of failure to the state before introduc-    conceptual clarity . . .
ing the concept of civil society failure. The section on civil society
failures discusses how a vibrant civil society can help mitigate market
and government failures and illustrates how the interaction of markets,
government, and civil society failures affect local development. The
chapter argues that participatory development interventions should, for
                                                                              . . . with many millions of
the most part, be understood as an attempt to repair civil society failure.
                                                                              dollars justified by little more
This framework leads to an extended discussion of the various elements
                                                                              than buzzwords.
of civil society failure—the roles of coordination and cooperation, cul-
ture, inequality and elite domination, and group heterogeneity—and
discusses some consequent challenges and concerns.




                                                                                                           49
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                 Market Failure
                                 Markets fail when they are unable to allocate resources efficiently.
                                 They fail for a variety of reasons: one party to a transaction may have
                                 more information than the other; a firm may monopolize control over
                                 a market by restricting the entry of competitors; failures in information
                                 or coordination may cause a common need to not be provided by the
                                 market mechanism, resulting in a missing market.
      Although inequality and       Although inequality and poverty can coexist with both efficient and
     poverty can coexist with    inefficient markets, market failures tend to deepen poverty traps and
 both efficient and inefficient    inhibit growth. Therefore, in theory, correcting or repairing market fail-
markets, market failures tend    ures can help economies produce larger pies, and—in situations where
 to deepen poverty traps and     the market failure disproportionately affects the poor—allocate larger
               inhibit growth.   shares of the pie to the poor. Correcting market failures is thought of as
                                 one of the central challenges of development (Hoff and Stiglitz 2001;
                                 Devarajan and Kanbur 2005). The other main challenge is distributing
                                 resources equitably—in particular ensuring that the poor benefit from
                                 development.
                                    Many market failures are caused by externalities—situations in
                                 which an act produces a cost (or benefit) that is borne (enjoyed) by a
                                 party that was not involved in it. Externalities exist in the marketplace
                                 when the exchange of goods and services between two individuals has
                                 consequences, positive or negative, for people who were not involved in
                                 the decision.
                                    A negative externality occurs when an individual or firm does not
                                 bear the full cost of its decisions. In this case, the cost to society is
                                 greater than the cost borne by the individual or firm. Examples include
                                 companies that pollute the environment without having to pay for
                                 cleaning it up. Negative externalities lead to the overproduction of
                                 goods and services, because sellers are not charged the full costs their
                                 goods and services impose.
                                    A positive externality exists when an individual or firm does not
                                 receive the full benefit of its decisions. In this case, the benefit to society
                                 is greater than the benefit reaped by the individual or firm. Examples
                                 of positive externalities are spillovers from research and development or
                                 the pollination of crops by bees. Positive externalities lead to the under-
                                 production of goods and services, because sellers are not compensated
                                 for the full benefits of the goods and services they create.
                                    Coordination failures are a special case of externalities in which
                                 the failure of individuals “to coordinate complementary changes in
50
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



their actions leads to a state of affairs that is worse for everyone than
an alternate state of affairs that is also an equilibrium” (Hoff 2000,
145). When parties to a transaction are unable to reliably connect and
coordinate with one another, they are often forced into situations that
make at least one of them worse off without making the other better
off. The market is not always able to solve this problem, for a variety of
reasons. Formal and informal institutions to enforce contracts may not
exist or may be unreliable, for example, making transactions unpredict-
able and subject to manipulation and rent-seeking.
    Another important cause of market failure is the existence of con-        Important causes of market
straints in the distribution of information. Information is asymmetric        failure include externalities,
when some firms or individuals have more information than others.              of which coordination failures
Poor households typically have very little access to formal credit mar-       are a special case, and
kets, for example, and rely largely on informal lenders partly because it     constraints in the distribution
is difficult for commercial banks to collect reliable information on their     of information.
ability to repay loans.
    Poverty and inequality exist in the absence of market failures, and
market failures exist in the absence of poverty and inequality. But a
highly unequal distribution of resources can amplify the effects of mar-
ket failures such as failures of credit and labor markets. Market failures
can also lead to highly skewed distributions of power or social status
that are resistant to change, leading to poverty traps.
    A poverty trap is a situation in which a group of people and their
descendants remain in a perpetual state of poverty because of mecha-
nisms such as credit market imperfections, corruption, dysfunctional
institutions, or decreasing returns from investments in health, educa-
tion, or physical capital. In an inequality trap, the entire distribution
is stable, because—as noted in the World Development Report 2006:
Equity and Development—the various dimensions of inequality (wealth,
power, social status) interact to protect the rich from downward mobil-
ity and obstruct upward mobility by the poor (World Bank 2006; Rao
2006). The unequal distribution of power between the rich and the
poor—between dominant and subservient groups—helps elites main-
tain control over resources and reduces the potential productivity of the
poor. Credit and capital market failures tend to have a disproportionate
impact on the poor, and asymmetries in information can both be caused
by and perpetuate inequalities in income and power.
    Consider, for instance, agricultural laborers working for a large land-
holder. Illiteracy, malnourishment, and indebtedness are likely to make
it very difficult for such workers to break out of the cycle of poverty.
                                                                                                           51
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                      Even if laws were in place making it possible to challenge the land-
                                      holder’s dictates, illiterate workers would have great difficulty navigating
                                      the political and judicial institutions that might help them assert their
                                      rights. In many parts of the world, entrenched social structures widen
                                      this distance between landholders and laborers: landholders typically
                                      belong to a dominant group defined by race or caste, whereas tenants
                                      belong to a subservient group. Such group-based inequalities are more
                                      likely to be intergenerationally perpetuated when social norms and
                                      networks prevent intermarriage across groups.
        Inequity can combine with         Inequity, which can exist even in perfectly functioning markets
        market failures to magnify    is, thus, a concern in its own right. In addition, it can combine with
     inefficiencies and can result     market failures to magnify inefficiencies and can result in situations in
         in situations in which the   which the aggregate loss in welfare is disproportionately borne by the
         aggregate loss in welfare    poor. These factors provide a rationale for government intervention
       is disproportionately borne    where it can intervene in ways that improve outcomes—by, for example,
                       by the poor.   providing services such as health, education, credit, or insurance to
                                      communities in which markets are unwilling or unable to do so or by
                                      implementing land reform or other equalizing interventions to correct
                                      for poverty and inequality traps.



                                      Government Failure
                                      The concern with looking to government to solve market failures is that
                                      problems of coordination, information asymmetry, and inequality also
                                      characterize the government. Government failure occurs when a policy
                                      or political intervention makes resource allocation less efficient than the
                                      outcome produced by the market (Besley 2006).
                                         It is useful to distinguish government failures, which are common
                                      to all political systems, from political failures, which are government
                                      failures within a democratic framework. Like market failures, govern-
                                      ment and political failures are related to failures in information and
                                      coordination.
        Looking to government to         Information failures. The classic information failure in governance is
          solve market failures is    ignorance—the inability of a government to know the preferences of its
                 problematic . . .    citizens. Ignorance results in the misallocation of resources—providing
                                      schools where clinics are needed, building roads that head off in untrav-
                                      eled directions while septic tanks fester. Decentralization is often seen
                                      as a solution to this problem, because bringing government closer to the

52
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



people increases the public’s access to information and the government’s      . . . because it, too,
knowledge of citizens’ preferences.                                           suffers from problems of
    Another cause of government failure is information asymmetries—           coordination, information
situations in which one set of agents in a transaction has more relevant      asymmetry, and inequality.
information than another. Governments keep vast amounts of infor-
mation that citizens cannot access—details about contracts for public
projects, budgetary allocations, and lists of people under detention.
    Coordination failures. Governments are continually subject to vari-
ous types of coordination failures, which result in some people being
unable to influence decision making while others have undue access to
state favors as a result of lobbying, corruption, or both. Coordination
failures can also arise when incentives in the political system prevent
good candidates from running for office, resulting in societies being
managed by ineffective leaders, or when polarized sets of preferences
result in inaction (a failure of collective action). Coordination failures
can create endemic problems such as absenteeism among public ser-
vants, which disproportionately affects schools and clinics in poor and
isolated communities (World Bank 2004). They can also result in a
“loss of the monopoly over the means of coercion” (Bates 2008), leaving
countries vulnerable to civil war and ethnic strife.
    Inequity. Just as in the case of market failure, the burden of govern-    Just as in the case of
ment failure frequently falls disproportionately on the poor. Poor and        market failure, the burden of
illiterate people tend to suffer from vast gaps in information about          government failure frequently
laws and government procedures. In relatively stable societies with           falls disproportionately on
deep-seated inequalities, the rich are likely to use their influence to        the poor.
control the reins of power; in cases of complete state failure, politicians
can use their power to extract resources from the poor and powerless,
thereby transforming the state into an instrument of predation (Bates
2008).
    One of the challenges of development is to understand where, when,
and how to balance the power of the state against the freedom of mar-
kets. Can governments solve market failures and redress inequities in
a manner that does not weaken market efficiency? Can markets take
over the provision of services such as water supply, health, and educa-
tion when a government is unable to do so? Can governments provide
credit and insurance in underserved areas that the private sector will not
enter? What level of government regulation will optimally solve infor
mation and coordination problems while not impeding the potential
for sustainable growth?

                                                                                                           53
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



       One of the challenges of        As markets and governments are fundamentally interconnected,
policy making is to understand      the challenges of information and coordination influence not just
      where, when, and how to       failures within markets and governments but also the links between
balance the power of the state      them. Institutional economists have demonstrated that development
          against the freedom       occurs when institutions are able to resolve market failures and address
                    of markets.     inequality in a manner that is conducive to long-run inclusive growth
                                    (World Bank 2005; Acemoglu and Robinson 2006).



                                    Civil Society Failure
                                    The fundamental goal of local participatory development is to build an
                                    effective local civic sphere. The philosopher Jurgen Habermas (1991)
                                    argues that civil society is activated by a “public sphere” in which citi-
                                    zens, collectively and publicly, create a “third space” that engages with
                                    states and markets. Thus, civil society is symbiotically linked to the
                                    effective functioning of markets and governments.
                                        An effective civil society is the social arena in which citizens par-
                                    ticipate, voluntarily organizing to work toward their collective benefit.
                                    It is the space in which individuals turn into citizens. The terms civil
                                    society and nongovernmental organization (NGO) are often used inter-
                                    changeably, but civil society is much more than a collection of NGOs.
                                    As defined by the sociologist Jeffrey Alexander (2006, 4), ideally, civil
                                    society is

                                      “a world of values and institutions that generates the capacity for
                                      social criticism and democratic integration at the same time. Such
                                      a sphere relies on solidarity, on feelings for others whom we do not
                                      know but whom we respect out of principle, not experience, because
                                      of our putative commitment to a common secular faith.”

                                    Any collective effort to voluntarily mobilize citizens with shared val-
                                    ues toward a common goal—consumer cooperatives, credit groups,
                                    neighborhood associations, religious organizations, social movements
                                    of various kinds, producer cooperatives, and a variety of formal and
                                    informal associations and advocacy organizations—is arguably a civil
   Historians have increasingly     society activity.1
  recognized how fundamental           Following Habermas, contemporary historians have increasingly
           civic action is to the   recognized how fundamental civic action is to the development process.
         development process.       Bayly (2004, 2008) shows that poorer countries that have had high rates
54
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



of growth in recent years, such as India and China, did not simply bor-
row Western ideas and technologies. Instead, groups of highly educated
elites who served as peer educators and activated the civic sphere indi-
genized those ideas and ideologies. In India, for instance, beginning in
the early 19th century, liberal leaders created an ecumene (public sphere)
that laid the foundation for the vibrant civic and democratic life of the
country today. McCloskey (2006) and Mokyr (2010) argue that the cre-
ation of an entrepreneurial class requires the development of networks
and discourse that foster “bourgeois virtues,” which in turn facilitate the
development of innovation and capitalism. An active and effective civil
society thus allows citizens to engage with governments and markets,
hold them accountable, and generate a culture that facilitates economic
and democratic activity.
    In their ideal state, the three spheres, while complementary in their
functions, have competing ideological bases: civil society involves col-
lective action, with justice, fairness, and other social norms as core goals;
ideally, it is based on the principles of reciprocity, open criticism, and
debate.2 In contrast, markets involve individual actors following indi-
vidual goals of maximizing profits and generating wealth.
    Firms tend to depend on a hierarchically organized division of labor,
rather than equality, to meet their goals. Governments tend to be orga-
nized around politics, the goal of which is the reproduction of power;
they depend on authority and loyalty to function. In contrast, civil
society tends to be mobilized around common interests and the prin-
ciple of equality (Alexander 2006). All three spheres are needed to bal-
ance one another—and create a virtuous cycle. Market and government
failures and inequity thrive in the absence of an active and engaged civil
society, and civil society failures can exacerbate market and govern-
ment failures. When the three spheres are equally healthy, they work
in concert; the unequal tendencies of the market are balanced by the
equalizing valance of the civic sphere, and the tendency of governments
to monopolize power is balanced by pressures for accountability and
openness that come from civil society.


Civil Society Interaction with Markets and Governments
Civic interaction with markets and governments is often conflictual:
being held accountable, answering uncomfortable questions, and
responding to requests from mobilized groups of citizens are often
costly and unpleasant for government officials and private sector actors.
                                                                                        55
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



      To be effective, civic action   Absent appropriate regulation, markets would be motivated solely by
     often has to force agents of     profit maximization. In many cases, the short-term interests of a firm
     government and the market        or industry do not coincide with the best interests of citizens. Similarly,
       to act against their private   in the absence of civic accountability, the interests of political leaders
     interests and in the interest    would be to hold on to power, capture rents, and preserve the existing
                       of citizens.   hierarchy. Civic action is thus almost never smooth; to be effective,
                                      it has to introduce constraints into the decision-making processes of
                                      governments and markets that cannot be ignored and that often force
                                      them to act against their private interests (by reducing profit margins
                                      or limiting power).
In its interaction with markets,         In its interaction with markets, a well-functioning civil society acts
 a well-functioning civil society     first as a watchdog—through consumer groups, for instance, that high-
        acts first as a watchdog.      light firm behaviors that are detrimental to consumers. These behaviors
                                      include practices that endanger people’s lives (such as food and drug
                                      adulteration) as well as practices that are unethical, inefficient, and
                                      inequitable, such as collusion and price fixing. Pressure from civil society
                                      groups has been responsible, in many parts of the world, for the estab-
                                      lishment of agencies to regulate drugs, food, automobiles, and corporate
                                      behavior. When they function well, civil society groups also watch out
                                      for egregious inequities, such as discrimination in hiring practices or
                                      price discrimination against particular groups or communities. The
                                      civil rights movement in the United States, the Arab Spring in Tunisia
                                      and the Arab Republic of Egypt, the Solidarity movement in Poland,
                                      and pro-democracy rallies in the Islamic Republic of Iran are archetypal
                                      examples of civil society activity. Civil society can be a source of counter-
                                      vailing power that acts as a check on government. Such a check is usually
                                      a good thing, but it can sometimes be socially detrimental—as it is, for
                                      example, when vigilante groups attempt to impose unpopular points of
                                      view through a reign of terror or when extremists capture the state.
                                         In addition to their watchdog function, civil society groups play a
                                      direct role in generating economic activity (microfinance organizations
                                      are a prime example). Moreover, an active civic sphere can help create
                                      an enabling environment for the rise of an entrepreneurial class, by
                                      facilitating social networks that transmit information and creating col-
                                      lectives to help with credit and insurance. Trade groups such as farm-
                                      ers cooperatives, industry federations, and ethnic networks that help
                                      migrants with credit and jobs are all examples of civil society activity.
                                         An engaged civil sphere is even more critical to good government. If
                                      government is transparent and accountable, it is transparent to and held
                                      accountable by civil society. Civil society works much more effectively
56
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



when it is cohesive—when it has a high capacity for collective action,       An engaged civil sphere
which is central to the functioning of an effective state—because cohe-      makes a critical contribution
sion gives citizens the capability of engaging effectively with the state.   to good government by
Some scholars follow Putnam (1993) and others in calling this capacity       keeping it transparent and
“social capital.” This term dilutes the idea of an engaged public sphere     accountable.
into something conceptually much weaker, making it overly simplistic
and therefore less effective as a guide for policy (Mansuri and Rao
2004).
   Markets interact with civil society in various ways—by providing
information on products and services, for example, or by funding the
creation of civil society organizations that are consistent with their
interests. Governments engage with civil society in similar ways, pro-
viding it with information and attempting to influence and control it,
including through rules that prohibit rallies and political organizing.
Governments also attempt to nurture, and even create, civil society
activity in order to jump-start a participatory development process.3


Markets, Government, and Civil Society at the Local Level
Civil society, markets, and governments interact at various levels—
global, national, subnational (state/district), and local (city/village/
neighborhood). Each level has a unique set of challenges, modes of
operation, and incentive structures.
   Market failures work differently at each level. Market failures in the
global sphere require global coordination and regulation to correct—a
role that, for instance, the World Trade Organization (WTO) attempts
to perform. Market failures at the national level are the concern of
governments and central banks. Market failures at the local level may
be addressed by local approaches such as microcredit and microinsur-
ance. The appropriate level of action may depend on the type of market
failure. The management of river basin issues that affect multiple coun-
tries requires regional action, for example; the creation of a collective
response to global warming requires global action.
   Government also operates at different levels. Concerns about global
governance are addressed by the United Nations system and by negotia-
tions between and among governments. The functions of government
should be allocated to the levels most competent to handle them. Some
functions, such as national defense, foreign policy, and interstate rela-
tions, cannot be sensibly decentralized. In allocating other functions
to local levels, a few trade-offs need to be considered (Bardhan and
                                                                                                         57
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    Mookherjee 2006). Local governments can be better informed about
                                    citizen preferences, and they are better able to respond to the needs of
                                    citizens because of better information and lower transactions costs. But
                                    they may have difficulty coordinating decision making across commu-
                                    nities (because of intercommunity externalities or spillovers). Moreover,
                                    decentralization leads to a potential loss in scale economies.
              The optimal design        Thus, the optimal design of decentralization requires trading off
     of decentralization requires   the advantages of better-aligned incentives against the disadvantages
      trading off the advantages    of more challenging coordination problems. In general, the provision of
     of better-aligned incentives   local public goods is best decentralized when preferences and needs for
      against the disadvantages     the goods are heterogeneous, vary with time, and require a high degree
             of more challenging    of responsiveness to community needs or local knowledge and when
         coordination problems.     there are few intercommunity spillovers or economies of scale. Public
                                    goods and services that typically fall into these categories include sanita-
                                    tion and drainage, local irrigation canals, and village roads. Often com-
                                    mon-pool resources such as water bodies and forests can also be locally
                                    managed. Conversely, if a public good is homogenous; has significant
                                    economies of scale, perhaps because of technical complexity; or requires
                                    central coordination, it should usually be managed centrally (examples
                                    include national vaccination campaigns and national highways).
                                        The decentralization of government functions could, however,
                                    merely result in the decentralization of government failure. Local gov-
                                    ernments fail for a number of reasons, including the absence of demo-
                                    cratic mechanisms by which voters can communicate preferences, lack
                                    of effective political competition, and lack of civic capacity. When this
                                    is the case, policies tend to reflect the views of the people in power, there
                                    is a general lack of accountability to citizens, and the decentralization
                                    of resource allocation decisions can actually exacerbate rent-seeking and
                                    corruption (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2006; Besley 2006). In mak-
                                    ing decisions about decentralization in developing countries, it is thus
                                    important to understand the nature and degree of potential government
                                    failure at different levels of government, as well as the potential for civil
                                    society failure, and to balance these considerations with policy prescrip-
                                    tions that rely on politics-free economic theory.
                                        Just as markets and governments operate at different levels, so does
                                    civil society. Most political theorists generally think about civil society
                                    as operating at the level of nation-states, in the context of national
                                    politics (Alexander 2006). But in recent years there has been increasing
                                    recognition of a global public sphere and global civil society (examples

58
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



include the movement to combat climate change (or the protests against       Just as markets and
“neoliberal” development institutions that promote “market fundamen-         governments operate at
talism”). A vibrant civil society at the national level is important not     different levels, so does
just for its own sake—to make effective citizens—but also for repairing      civil society.
market and government failures. Social movements have made markets
accountable by exposing systematic failures in particular industries (an
example is Ralph Nader’s highly successful effort to improve automobile
safety). They have equalized the rights and welfare of excluded social
groups (including indigenous people in Latin America and nonwhites
in South Africa) and pushed for greater democracy (in Indonesia) and
openness in government (in India). The larger development challenge
is to build a virtuous cycle of checks and balances among markets,
governments, and civil society that compensates and corrects for the
weaknesses in each sphere.
    The concern here is with the local civil sphere—groups of citizens
who organize themselves into collectives to hold the local state account-
able; assist with the functions of government (school committees, public
village meetings); remedy market failures such as lack of access to credit
or insurance (microcredit and microinsurance groups); and directly
manage common resources (forest management groups, water users
groups). If government functions are decentralized to the local level, it
is important to have citizen groups that watch out and correct for local
government failures through a process of active engagement.
    Local civil society can also have important linkages with a national
civic sphere. Following Rousseau and Mill, local governments, commu-
nity organizations, and local civic groups are thought to be a training
ground for civic activity. If several small local ecumenes develop that
connect with and learn from one another by exchanging ideas and
methods and providing mutual support, they may have the capacity to
shift civic culture at the national level.


Defining Civil Society Failure
Civil society failure can be broadly thought of as a situation in which      Civil society failure can be
civic action is either absent or operates in a way that results in a net     broadly thought of as a
reduction in efficiency.4 It can occur because a group is unable to act       situation in which civic action
collectively. For example, a group of individuals may be unable to coor-     is either absent or operates
dinate their actions and make collective decisions that would leave all      in a way that results in a net
members of the group better off over the long run because individuals        reduction in efficiency.

                                                                                                          59
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          act in their own short-run best interest (the “tragedy of the commons”).
                          It can also occur when one subgroup is able to mobilize collectively to
                          further its interests while other subgroups, with different interests, are
                          unable to do so, with the potential result that the welfare of the average
                          citizen is reduced.
                              How does participation occur? Collective participation occurs in two
                          stages. Individuals first have to decide to participate in civic groups;
                          the groups then have to be able to resolve the challenges of collective
                          action and act with a common purpose. Failure can affect both indi-
                          vidual incentives for participation and the group’s capacity for collective
                          action. There can also be varying degrees of institutional receptivity to
                          participatory activity. For instance, receptivity to participation increases
                          when a country transitions from dictatorship to democracy. It is low in
                          an authoritarian country that functions by suppressing voice and dissent.
                          Even in authoritarian societies, however, there may be some nascent vul-
                          nerabilities in the political structure that change activists can exploit—as
                          they did in the Arab Spring and South Africa; if those vulnerabilities
                          increase (say, because of international pressure), the receptivity for par-
                          ticipation could increase as well. In the literature on social movements,
                          these vulnerabilities are referred to as the “political opportunity struc-
                          ture” (Kriesi 2007). Such structures can be either “open” (allowing easy
                          access to the political system) or “closed” (making such access difficult).
                          Effective civic action requires that groups have enough information to
                          identify and gauge political opportunities and are then able to mobilize
                          citizens in a manner that takes advantage of them.
                              Participation is a broad term that covers a variety of activities, includ-
                          ing the following:
                             •   participation in decision making through consultative processes
                                 or deliberative bodies without the authority to make or veto
                                 resource allocation decisions
                             •   the contribution of cash, material goods, or physical labor to
                                 construct public goods or provide public services
                             •   the monitoring and sanctioning of public and private service
                                 providers
                             •   the provision of information and involvement in awareness-
                                 raising activities
                             •   the formation of neighborhood committees (for instance, to
                                 reduce crime or resolve local conflicts)
                             •   the selection or election of local representatives.

60
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



    Instrumental, ideological, and identity-based motives induce indi-        Instrumental, ideological, and
viduals to participate in civic activities. Instrumental motives have to      identity-based motives induce
do with the economic and political benefits an individual may reap by          individuals to participate in
participating. For instance, if a community development project comes         civic activities.
into a village with funds for building local infrastructure, an individual
may participate in meetings associated with the project in order to gain
access to the funds to repair a road outside her house; he or she may vote
in a local council election in order to help remove a corrupt politician
from office. Ideological motives have to do with adhering to a shared
belief. In some countries, for instance, nationalism is strongly tinged
with the ideology of communitarianism, making participation in com-
munity projects an expression of patriotism. Identity-based motives
have to do with social or religious identity. Examples include helping
build a mosque or church or mobilizing a caste group to fight for greater
dignity within a village.
    Participation entails some costs. The most obvious is the opportunity     Participation entails some
cost of time, which depends on an individual’s economic position, employ-     costs. The most obvious is
ment status, and family obligations, among other factors. Participation       the opportunity cost of time,
also involves a range of social costs, which can be prohibitively high for    which is higher for the poor.
individuals or groups that are otherwise proscribed from free engagement
in communal public life, as is often the case for women and members of
disadvantaged castes, ethnic groups, or tribes. There may also be psychic
costs. Years of oppression may have caused low-caste groups to have
internalized discriminatory ideologies, making it particularly challeng-
ing to mobilize them for development activity. Communities that have
grown accustomed to receiving free benefits from the state may be find
it troubling to be asked to exert physical effort to obtain those benefits.
Individuals, embedded in their particular social groups and networks,
will balance all these costs and benefits before deciding to participate.
    The decision to participate is not merely an individual decision, how-
ever, as civic activity is most effective—perhaps only effective—when
engaged in collectively. Although an individual may want to participate,
the group to which he or she belongs may be unable to come to a collec-
tive decision. Participation by groups—the classic challenge of collective
action—thus needs to be distinguished from participation by individu-
als. Furthermore, an individual’s decision to participate is deeply con-
nected to the group’s ability to cooperate; if individuals believe that the
group will be ineffective or unable to reach consensus, they will be less
inclined to participate.

                                                                                                          61
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     Mancur Olson (1965) theorized almost 50 years ago that without
                                  coercion or some other special device to make individuals act in their
                                  common interest, “rational self-interested individuals will not act to
                                  achieve their common or group interests.” Olson was concerned with
                                  “exploitation of the great by the small,” noting that people with smaller
                                  interests in a public good would tend to free ride on the efforts of people
                                  with greater interests.
                                     Under what conditions will a group of people cooperate? Under what
                                  conditions will they trust one another enough to believe that the prom-
                                  ises they have made are credible? Ostrom (1990) emphasizes the role of
                                  social institutions that generate norms, impose sanctions, and improve
                                  the incentives for collective action, basing her analysis on field observa-
                                  tions that demonstrate the success of collective action in management
                                  of commons. Arguing against a general theory of collective action, she
                                  contends that particularities matter a great deal but postulates a set of
                                  “design principles” that may serve as a guide. These principles include
                                  clearly defined boundaries to the commons, with a defined commu-
                                  nity associated with the resource; rules to manage the commons that
                                  are appropriate to local conditions; arrangements to manage collective
                                  decisions, which are themselves subject to collective negotiations; gra-
                                  dated sanctions, with heavier sanctions for repeated or more egregious
                                  violators of rules; low-cost and widely accepted mechanisms to resolve
                                  conflict; and the absence of excessive government interference. In deriv-
                                  ing these conditions, Ostrom was thinking specifically about common-
                                  pool resource management; her arguments do not necessarily apply to
                                  the wider issue of local participatory development.
  Under what conditions will a       Incorporating these insights and summarizing work by game
   group of people cooperate?     theorists on collective action over the last four decades, Dasgupta
     Under what conditions will   (2009) identifies two necessary conditions for cooperation:
they trust one another enough
                                     1. At every stage in the agreed course of action, it is in the interest
   to believe that the promises
                                        of every party to plan to keep its word if every other party also
 they have made are credible?
                                        does so.
                                     2. At every stage of the agreed course of action, every party
                                        believes that all parties will keep their word.
                                     The first condition self-enforces promises by ensuring that promises
                                  made by one person are expected to be reciprocated by others. This con-
                                  dition is not sufficient, however, because even if it is met, it is still possi-
                                  ble that every agent believes that everyone else will act opportunistically.

62
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



If this is the case, then all parties will think that it is in their best interest
not to cooperate. The second condition is needed to generate trust, by
ensuring that all parties believe that everyone else will keep his or her
word. Together, the two conditions generate a system of self-enforcing
beliefs that facilitate collective action.
    What, then, are the conditions and the social environments that
ensure that both conditions are met? When are promises that people
make to one another credible, hence ensuring cooperation?
    People may belong to “cultures”—relational environments that gen-
erate ideologies and preferences that are conducive to collective action.
People from the same “culture” share the following characteristics:
   1. Mutual affection. Coordination is facilitated when parties care
      about one another sufficiently and recognize that others feel the
      same way.
   2. Pro-social disposition. If people trust one another enough to know
      that any promises made are credible, then even in the absence of
      mutual affection, a group can have strong ties that generate loy-
      alty. Loyalty of this kind can be shaped by group-specific culture
      and upbringing; members of a community internalize norms of
      cooperation to the extent that they feel shame or guilt when not
      cooperating. Loyalty can also arise because of the presence of
      social norms that prescribe punishment for people who do not
      have a pro-social disposition toward the group.
   Incentives can also help ensure cooperation. People are more likely               People are more likely to keep
to keep agreements if a “cooperative infrastructure”—a set of institu-               agreements if a “cooperative
tions that ensures that keeping promises is in the interest of each party            infrastructure”—a set of
if everyone else keeps them—is in place. Three types of cooperative                  institutions that ensures
infrastructure can be identified:                                                     that keeping promises is in
   3. External enforcement. External enforcement of agreements made                  the interest of every party if
      within the group requires an explicit contract enforced by an                  everyone else keeps them—is
      established structure of power and authority, such as the state                in place.
      and its legal institutions or, in the absence of a formal state, a
      traditional leader (such as a chief, warlord, or head of a traditional
      panchayat [village council]). The external enforcer does not have
      to act: the very fact that such enforcement exists will lead people
      to make credible commitments to one another, and promises will
      be reinforced by the belief that they will be kept. Collective action
      can be more successful in the presence of a successful state, and

                                                                                                                 63
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                        state failure can reinforce failures in civic action, just as civil soci-
                                        ety failure can reinforce state failure. When the external enforcer
                                        cannot be trusted to enforce agreements, the parties will not trust
                                        one another enough to enter into collective agreements, which
                                        could result in noncooperation.
                                     4. Reputation as a capital asset. Even in the absence of external
                                        enforcement, people will keep their promises if they value their
                                        reputation enough. Reputation becomes a capital asset because
                                        individuals want to maintain status, uphold an ethical code, or
                                        preserve long-term relationships.
                                     5. Long-term relationships. In a long-term relationship, reputation
                                        becomes a capital asset after a transaction is completed, because
                                        it enables individuals to enter into other credible contracts.
                                        Agreements, therefore, are mutually enforced. To achieve func-
                                        tioning social relationships, the community might impose stiff
                                        sanctions on anyone who breaks an agreement.
                                      In practice, characteristics 3, 4, and 5 could blend with one another,
                                   as all of these solutions impose collective sanctions on people who
                                   intentionally fail to comply with agreements. However, as Dasgupta
                                   (2009) points out, “a credible threat of punishment for misdemeanors
                                   would be an effective deterrent only if future costs and benefits are not
                                   discounted at too high a rate relative to other parameters of the social
                                   environment.” In situations in which individuals are forced to become
                                   myopic—in periods of civil conflict or social disruption, for instance—
                                   such self-reinforcing norms may be rendered ineffective, leading to civic
                                   failure (Coate and Ravallion 1993).
      Capacity for cooperation        Where individuals are bound together in multiple social, eco-
       can be enhanced where       nomic, and political relationships, the capacity for cooperation can be
individuals are bound together     enhanced. If, for instance, the mutual provision of credit and insurance
  in multiple social, economic,    depends on norms of obligation and cooperation, which in turn depend
    and political relationships.   on commitments for marriage or political support, the violation of one
                                   interaction would result in a collapse of all the others. Thus, interlinked
                                   agreements make cooperation robust.
                                      They may, however, also make them deeply inequitable. Highly hier-
                                   archical societies, such as societies in rural India and West Africa, which
                                   depend on elites enforcing norms and “taking care” of others lower in
                                   the social hierarchy, may make such societies both highly cooperative
                                   and deeply ridden with inequality traps.

64
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



   Coordination failures in civic action. What makes civic participation
effective in some contexts and ineffective in others? What are the chal-
lenges local communities face in activating their capacity for collective
action?
   The most important source of civil society failure is probably coor-        The most important source of
dination failure. An important reason to devolve decisions to the local        civil society failure is probably
level is to reduce coordination problems—by allowing the people most           coordination failure.
affected by projects to manage them directly.
   Such devolution by no means implies that coordination failures will
disappear. Coordination failures at the local level have two main causes:
the lack of a cooperative infrastructure (institutions that make individu-
als’ promises to the collective credible) and the absence of a mechanism
to help ensure that individuals in a group have altruistic, or common,
preferences (that is, “pro-social dispositions”).
   Consider the challenges of setting up a project that encourages a com-
munity to sustainably manage a local forest. For the project to work,
individuals in the community have to agree to restrict their harvesting
of trees from the forest. They also have to participate in activities, such
as planting and nurturing trees and policing forest grounds to prevent
outsiders from poaching. If all individuals were left to their own devices
and did not engage in collective action, a tragedy of the commons would
occur, leading rapidly to deforestation and the destruction of local liveli-
hoods. In practice, many forest communities around the world have,
over centuries, evolved strong norms of collective action to manage
common resources, setting up an effective cooperative infrastructure.
   The presence of a cooperative infrastructure affects the outcomes           The presence, or absence, of
of development projects. Say a project wants to improve the collective         a cooperative infrastructure
management of a forest by setting up a community-managed fund that             affects the outcomes of
provides financial incentives for individuals to cooperate by compen-           development projects.
sating them for income lost by limiting their harvest. The fund would
be far more effective if a traditional leader was present who was in
complete agreement with the aims of the project, was considered hon-
est and beyond reproach, and had the authority to enforce agreements
made between individuals and the fund. The fund would also be more
likely to succeed if the community had evolved a method by which
promises were rendered credible because each individual believed the
promises made by every other individual, based on long-term ties and
a strong belief that violating promises would result in ostracism from
the community. Ideally, the fund would introduce enough additional

                                                                                                             65
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          incentives within this favorable cooperative environment to sustain
                          cooperation during periods of change and vulnerability. In the absence
                          of an authority figure or strong long-term ties within the community,
                          the fund would degenerate into a haven for rent-seekers, creating a fail-
                          ure. Thus, an authority figure and the long-term ties that come from
                          repeated interactions among individuals in the community are both
                          examples of effective cooperative infrastructure.
                              Consider another example, a decentralized program in which a vil-
                          lage council is given the authority to select beneficiaries for a centrally
                          managed poverty reduction program. As part of the program, it is man-
                          dated that beneficiary selection should be vetted in open village meet-
                          ings, where anyone in the village can question the choices of the village
                          council. This mandate is an attempt to use local participation and local
                          knowledge to improve poverty targeting, create links between villag-
                          ers and the central government, and hold local governments publically
                          accountable. If the central government were weak and its functionaries
                          corrupt, decisions made in the village meeting would not be enforced.
                          If this were the case, villagers would decide not to waste their time par-
                          ticipating in such meetings, because the benefits would not be worth
                          the cost. The project’s attempt to foster participatory, community-based
                          targeting would fail because of a weak state’s inability to enforce col-
                          lectively made decisions.
                              State enforcement can matter in the management of common-pool
                          goods as well. If communities are required to follow laws and regula-
                          tions passed by the state and these laws and regulations are poorly
                          enforced, there is no incentive for the community to follow the law. If
                          the community had strong norms of collective action, it would revert
                          to traditional forms of resource management. If it did not, the common
                          resources would be privatized and allocated in a way that reflected the
                          interests of the most powerful.
                              An interesting example of how cooperative infrastructure helps
                          facilitate participation in the decentralization process comes from Tsai’s
                          (2007) work on China.5 Tsai asks a simple question: How can variations
                          in the provision of public goods be explained in the absence of formal
                          institutions of accountability? The Chinese state has decentralized to
                          local governments primary responsibility for the provision of basic pub-
                          lic goods and services (road construction, drainage systems, irrigation
                          works, primary school facilities, sanitation). Some village governments
                          provide outstanding public goods and services, whereas others provide

66
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



barely anything at all. According to Tsai, the explanation for this varia-
tion is the presence in some villages of local “solidary” groups, which
provide informal institutions of accountability. A solidary group is a
collection of individuals who share moral obligations and interests.
Of the three types of groups Tsai delineates—village temple groups,
village churches, and lineage groups—only temple groups and some
lineage groups have the two structural characteristics crucial to Tsai’s
argument—namely, the group must be encompassing (open to every-
one under the jurisdiction of the local government), and it must be
embedding (incorporating local officials into the group as members).6
“When the boundaries of a solidary group overlap with the adminis-
trative boundaries of the local government, embedded officials have a
strong social obligation to contribute to the good of the group,” writes
Tsai (2007, 356). In groups with embedded officials, the incentive for
accountability is an amorphous sense of moral standing or prestige for
the provision of public goods.
   This thesis is quite different from the idea of civic “social capital.”
Whatever “social capital” such groups may have, groups that do not
meet the “embedding” criteria (such as church groups) are not able
to hold village officials accountable for the provision of public goods,
as Communist Party members are prohibited from membership.7 In
contrast, village temple groups can be both encompassing and embed-
ded; they are thus able to serve effectively as informal institutions of
accountability. Lineage groups play this role only marginally, because
their segmentation makes them less cohesive.
   A more daring claim made by Tsai is that neither bureaucratic insti-
tutions of top-down control nor democratic institutions seem to have
a significant positive effect on the provision of public goods by village
governments. “Implementation of elections does not guarantee good
governmental performance, especially when other democratic institu-
tions are weak” (Tsai 2007, 370).
   In countries with strong traditions of electoral democracy, externally    In countries with strong
induced improvements in the cooperative infrastructure that come             traditions of electoral
from the state, such as improved enforcement of laws or decentraliza-        democracy, externally
tion programs with strong participatory elements, can substantially          induced improvements in the
improve the quality of participation. Consider the case of the South         cooperative infrastructure
Indian state of Kerala. Kerala has a long history of egalitarian social      that come from the state can
programs emphasizing education, health, and women’s equality, but            substantially improve the
until 1996 these efforts were mainly top-down programs directed from         quality of participation.

                                                                                                        67
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     the state capital. Although Kerala is blessed with a literate and engaged
                                     electorate, participation was restricted to the political sphere and to
                                     membership in unions.
                                        Following passage of a constitutional amendment in 1993, which
                                     mandated that state governments devolve resources and powers to
                                     democratically elected village councils (gram panchayats), Kerala began
                                     to plan and initiate a radical and deeply participatory program of decen-
                                     tralization (Heller and Issac 2003). The program rested on three pil-
                                     lars. It devolved 40 percent of the state’s development budget to village
                                     councils, devolved substantial powers to these councils, and instituted
                                     an extensive people’s campaign—a grassroots training and awareness-
                                     raising effort to inform citizens about and energize them to participate
                                     in the panchayat system.
                                        The campaign instituted a planning process based on a set of nested
                                     piecemeal stages (for example, working committees meetings and devel-
                                     opment seminars held in conjunction with the village meetings, which
                                     are structured to facilitate participation). Instead of open deliberation,
                                     attendees (members of the public) are divided into resource-themed
                                     groups or committees. The discussions within each group yield consen-
                                     sual decisions regarding the designated resource. This structure, which
                                     operates uniformly in all districts in Kerala, is geared toward increas-
                                     ing the efficiency of consensual decision making about public resource
                                     demands and prioritizing individual beneficiaries for the allocation of
                                     government-subsidized private benefits. The process has been facilitated
                                     by various training programs to instruct citizens on deliberative plan-
                                     ning and village functionaries on methods for turning plans into actions
                                     that result in more effective public service delivery.
      In Kerala, India, the state       In Kerala, direct intervention by the democratic state increased
      created mechanisms that        demand for participation not only by creating greater opportunities of
     strengthened its links with     participatory planning but also by providing resources to make that
                    civil society.   planning meaningful while embedding it within a decentralized sys-
                                     tem of government with enforcement authority. The state thus created
                                     mechanisms that strengthened its links with civil society.
                                        Literacy in Kerala was almost 100 percent—much higher than the
                                     Indian average at the time of 66 percent; the state also has a long history
                                     of civic mobilization because of strong labor unions associated with the
                                     communist movement. Local participation in Kerala thus did not start
                                     from scratch; it was fostered by channeling democratically and politi-
                                     cally aware citizens into participatory avenues that resulted in better

68
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



local government. In the absence of Kerala’s well-developed democratic
and participatory traditions, it is unlikely that the people’s campaign
would have worked.
    To fully understand the nature of a failure of collective action, it     To fully understand the nature
is thus important to understand how context, history, and culture            of a failure of collective
shape the nature of cooperative infrastructure. The local history of a       action, it is important to
community shapes the norms that have evolved to facilitate collective        understand how context,
action, the extent to which such norms exclude women or disadvantaged        history, and culture shape
groups, and whether those norms are transferrable. Local collective          the nature of cooperative
action norms may be effective enough to manage water resources, for          infrastructure.
instance, but not school management. Similarly, the history and evolu-
tion of the national government—the extent to which it supports an
active civic culture and has an effective legal system and democratic
systems—has deep implications for the success of efforts to foster local
participation.
    Culture and civic identity. Coordinating civic action at the local
level is also affected by the formation of collective identity—which, in
many societies, has been consciously shaped to facilitate cooperation.
In a small, ethnically homogenous community, intermarriage may have
forged strong ties across families.8 In some instances, such ties could
result in common preferences and strong deference to the views of tra-
ditional authority figures. More generally, a common cultural identity
helps individuals anticipate how others in the group will react to their
actions, greatly facilitating collective action.
    State policy can forge a common cultural identity and common
preferences. For instance, the state can actively create a communitarian
national identity by introducing notions of cooperation into the con-
stitution; symbols of the state, such as the flag or pledges of allegiance;
and school curricula.
    One way of thinking about how culture and civic identity affect
the capacity for collective action is by thinking about the formation of
what Rao (2008) calls “symbolic public goods.” Rao builds on the work
of Chwe (1999, 2001), who demonstrates how collective action needs
to distinguish between structure and strategy. Chwe’s basic argument
goes as follows. Most models of collective action assume, implicitly,
some preexisting “common knowledge.” When a group of individuals
plays a collective action game, whether static or dynamic, it is assumed
that individual A knows the payoffs, information sets, costs, incentives,
possible moves, and so forth faced by individual B. Individual B, in

                                                                                                         69
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    turn, knows all of this about individual A and knows that individual A
                                    knows everything about individual B. Individual A, in turn, knows that
                                    individual B knows that individual A knows, and so on. This common
                                    knowledge assumption permits games of strategy to be played with a
                                    common understanding of the rules of the game: everyone knows how
                                    everyone else is playing.
                                       In contrast, a cricket player persuaded to play baseball will be quickly
                                    confused—enough to be unable to understand or appreciate the skill,
                                    strategy, and actions of the other players. It is this aspect of coordina-
                                    tion and common understanding that common knowledge attempts
                                    to capture. It plays a coordinating function that is a precondition for
                                    collective activity, which cannot occur in its absence. Common knowl-
                                    edge is arguably the core concept behind such amorphous notions as
                                    “trust” and “social capital,” which figure prominently in the discourse
                                    on collective action.9
                                       In order to understand collective action, therefore, it is crucial to
                                    understand its social context through the symbolic public goods that
                                    facilitate it. Yet symbolic public goods are themselves the product of
                                    strategy and contestation. They can take a variety of forms, including
                                    intangible processes of identity formation such as nationalism; physical
                                    entities, such as mosques and temples; and periodic ritual events, such
                                    as festivals. All of these forms share characteristics of public goods, in
                                    the sense that they can be simultaneously “nonrival” (consumption by
                                    one person does not reduce the ability of others to consume the same
                                    good) and sometimes “nonexcludable” (it is not possible to deny anyone
                                    access to the good).
        Symbolic public goods          Indonesia has constructed symbolic public goods to facilitate coop-
     facilitate the social basis    erative behavior. Postcolonial Indonesia was dominated by upper-class
           for collective action.   Muslims from Java. The country’s history in the decades following
                                    independence can be seen primarily as the “Javanization” of the country
                                    (Ricklefs 2002). The ideological basis of Javanese belief is that social
                                    interaction is “collective, consensual and cooperative” (Bowen 1986,
                                    545). Bowen argues that much of this belief is expressed in the term
                                    gotong royong (mutual assistance), which has become the framework for
                                    Indonesian nationalism and the basis for construction of a national tra-
                                    dition. Sukarno, the “father” of Indonesia, attempted to use the notion
                                    to unify the diverse (Islamic, non-Islamic, nationalist, Communist)
                                    groups in the new country by calling for a spirit of ke gotong royong
                                    (gotong royong-ness). Gotong royong provided a form of cultural legiti-
                                    macy for state control.
70
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



   When Sukarno was ousted, in a coup in 1967, his successor, Suharto,
introduced a “New Order” economic policy. Especially in its initial
phases, the new policy adopted the two-pronged strategy of putting
policies in place to enable high rates of growth and passing on the
benefits of that growth to the rural poor. An important element in this
strategy was to dictatorially force the spirit of gotong royong into hamlets
and villages around the country. Gotong royong became a key element
in development strategies in rural areas, particularly in the mobilization
of rural labor. In order to protect the political and cultural unity of the
Indonesian state, Suharto believed that it had to be strongly authoritar-
ian and that development had to proceed in a cooperative and collabora-
tive manner. By the early 1970s, the Sanskrit word svadaya (self-help)
started to be used in combination with gotong royong, and svadaya gotong
royong (mobilizing) became central to the implementation of develop-
ment policy (Bowen 1986).
   In a detailed ethnography of local development in a Javanese com-
munity, Sullivan (1992) demonstrates that the combination of an
autocratic state and the principle of svadaya resulted in a form of forced
labor. To be a good Indonesian, one had to contribute labor and cash
for development projects. Collective action was the norm, not the excep-
tion. Mobilizing communities was straightforward: grants received by
the village headman (kepala desa) were small, because donors assumed
that the gap between the expected cost of the proposed project and the
funds allocated would be provided locally. In fact, ward leaders actively
mobilized contributions from the community. Everyone was expected
to contribute free labor; individuals who failed to do so could be labeled
unpatriotic or uncooperative and face social, political, material, and
even physical sanctions.
   In this manner, Indonesian political leaders constructed the symbolic       Indonesia consciously
public good of nationalism, deploying “imagined” traditional beliefs           built symbolic goods by
that made the individual subservient to the community. As most of              establishing a communitarian
this effort was undertaken in the context of a military dictatorship, the      ethic (gotong royong) as state
approach was successful in coordinating public action.                         policy via school curricula and
   Suharto’s two-pronged strategy yielded good results for more than           public education campaigns.
two decades, with high rates of growth and substantial improvements
in the living standards of the poor. These improvements were achieved
in a cost-effective way by, in effect, taxing the poor in the name of
community participation. Suharto suppressed freedom and imposed an
implicitly regressive tax structure, but he also achieved excellent poverty
reduction and human development outcomes.
                                                                                                           71
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     In the past decade, with the rise of a robust democratic order and a
                                  concerted effort to decentralize the political and fiscal authority of state
                                  and district governments, the authority of village leaders in Indonesia
                                  has been increasingly questioned. But, as recent survey data demon-
                                  strate, the spirit of gotong royong has by no means disappeared. It has
                                  been so deeply institutionalized that not abiding by it is seen as a viola-
                                  tion of a communitarian ethic, which remains part of the foundation
                                  of what it means to be a good Indonesian. A 2004 survey of the Second
                                  Urban Poverty Project evaluation (Pradhan, Rao, and Rosemberg 2010)
                                  shows that levels of participation in public goods construction remain
                                  high, at 47 percent, with 59 percent of those respondents saying they
                                  participate primarily because of “tradition” or “obligation.” This high
                                  level of participation has real consequences: communities in Indonesia
                                  contribute 37 percent of the cost of village public goods. Indonesia has
                                  thus successfully introduced a communitarian ideology that facilitates
                                  the spirit of cooperation at the local level, improving the capacity for
                                  collective action.
  The state can also attempt         Rather than build symbolic public goods, the state can attempt to
       to directly manipulate     manipulate preferences to induce behaviors that are in line with its
       preferences to induce      policy objectives. Agrawal (2005) provides an example of this phenom-
behaviors that are in line with   enon in India, where, he argues, the state explicitly attempted to shift
         its policy objectives.   the preferences of forest communities toward a more collective purpose
                                  in order to facilitate community-based forest management. Based on a
                                  variety of archival and survey data, Agrawal seeks to understand how
                                  villagers in the Kumaon region shifted from violently protesting the
                                  government’s efforts to regulate forests in the 1920s to using active com-
                                  munity-managed forest conservation methods by the 1990s. He finds
                                  that the shift was achieved by the decentralization of decision making
                                  to the local level and by explicit efforts to induce community members
                                  to value forests as a public good and to build trust between government
                                  officials and local forest councils.
                                     Villages with forest councils and active council headmen made
                                  greater attempts at regulation and the desire for forest protection grew
                                  stronger in villages that were most closely involved in actual monitor-
                                  ing (Agrawal 2005). Efforts to change the way villagers thought about
                                  the forests were so successful that council members and headmen often
                                  acted against their own material and family interests in enforcing rules
                                  of forest protection.


72
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



   Inequality and the role of elites. One of the purported advantages of   One of the purported
local participation is its capacity to improve the match between benefi-    advantages of local
ciaries’ preferences and the allocation of public goods and benefits. The   participation is its capacity to
principle of subsidiarity states that when preferences of communities      improve the match between
are heterogeneous or vary with time, decentralizing decision making        beneficiaries’ preferences and
and project management results in more efficient outcomes and a better      the allocation of public goods
preference match.                                                          and benefits.
   Local communities in many developing countries tend to be not
only very heterogeneous but also highly unequal. It is therefore also
important to understand how both inequality and heterogeneity affect
local civic failure.
   The seminal insight on the role of inequality in collective action      Olson’s seminal insight was
comes from Olson (1965), who theorized that if the rich have a strong      that if the rich have a strong
interest in the provision of a public good, inequality could facilitate    interest in the provision of a
collective action because it would be in the interest of the wealthy       public good, inequality can
to provide the good, allowing the poor to free ride. Economists have       facilitate collective action . . .
extended this basic insight in several ways (Baland and Platteau 2006;
Bardhan, Ghatak, and Karaivanov 2006).
   Baland, Bardhan, and Bowles (2006) summarize these extensions.          . . . later theorists have
They note that inequality can have ambiguous and contradictory effects     demonstrated that the link
on collective action, for a variety of reasons:                            between inequality and
                                                                           collective action is more
  •   Higher income may increase rich people’s demand for a public
                                                                           ambiguous.
      good but also increase the opportunity cost of their time, mean-
      ing they may be less able to devote time to its provision. If the
      opportunity cost of the rich is high enough, it may discourage
      collective action. It could also result in situations in which the
      collective objective is achieved by the rich providing money and
      the poor providing labor.
  •   Poor participants’ lower assets may reduce both their demand
      for the resource and their ability to extract large amounts of it.
      Thus, poorer people may choose not to participate in setting up
      a committee to manage a high school—but they would also be
      less likely to send their children to the school.
  •   Inequality may increase the propensity of the rich to contribute
      toward a public good, but it may also discourage poorer people
      from participating at all, as Olson (1965) notes.
  •   Collective provision of public goods may be easier in situations
      of both very high inequality and almost perfectly equality,


                                                                                                           73
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                           where everyone has an equal interest in the good. Inequality
                                           could therefore have a U–shaped effect on collective action.
                                         These results are derived in the context of static collective action
                                     problems, where communities are not engaged in repeated interactions.
                                     Where community members have lived together for a long time and
                                     expect to continue to engage in social and economic relations over the
                                     long term—situations that are very common in developing countries—
                                     the relationship between equity and the cooperative infrastructure
                                     becomes much more salient. Rural communities are often character-
                                     ized by inequality in income and wealth, which is usually highly cor-
                                     related with inequality in power and social status. These communities
                                     are trapped in an “inequality trap,” in which the same families have
                                     been rich, and poor, for generations. The same rich families maintain
                                     a tight hold over power relations in the village and rule with dictatorial
                                     authority. In such situations, high inequality is combined with a strong
                                     cooperative infrastructure; if the local feudal leader believes that collec-
                                     tive action is in his best interest, he will ensure that it occurs.
             Inequality traps can        In such situations, successful collective action comes with high
       create situations in which    inequality, as in the Olson model. But, as Dasgupta (2009) demon-
     successful collective action    strates in models with repeated games, rather than allowing the poor
                exploits the poor.   to free ride on the contributions of the rich, inequality traps can harbor
                                     exploitation. The reason, in intuitive terms, is that the poor who refuse
                                     to cooperate could face sanctions that would push them to accept out-
                                     comes that would make them worse off than they would have been in
                                     the absence of collective action. If they discount their future payoffs at a
                                     low enough rate, they may be forced to enter into cooperative situations
                                     whose outcomes make them better off than they would have been with
                                     sanctions, but worse off than they would have been acting on their own.
                                     Consequently, a cooperative equilibrium could be sustained in which
                                     the poor would be exploited over the long term.
                                         Anthropologists have long noted that in such situations the poor tend
                                     to internalize such unequal norms: a disadvantaged group may view
                                     its status within the hierarchy as correct and appropriate and therefore
                                     be subject to what Rao and Walton (2004) call “constraining prefer-
                                     ences.” For instance, preferences derived from the Hindu caste system
                                     may create an acceptance of hierarchy and constrain the motivation
                                     for mobility. These beliefs are also simultaneously external constraints;
                                     individuals from lower castes who engage in class struggle may face
                                     severe social sanctions. For people at the top of the hierarchy, both types

74
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



of constraints provide the means to maintain their high position; for
people at the bottom, these internal and external constraints can limit
aspirations, create discrimination and exploitation, and block mobility.
Inequality can thus result in the systematic exclusion of disadvantaged
groups and women.
   An important aspect of the relationship between inequality and col-
lective action is the role elites play in local development. An influential
strand of the literature on elites focuses on “capture,” arguing that elite
domination sharply increases the risk that elites gain control over com-
munity development resources provided to benefit local communities
(see, for example, Abraham and Platteau 2004). In contrast, studies
of organic collective action emphasize that the leaders of such social
movements usually emerge from the educated middle and upper classes
(Morris and Staggenborg 2004).
   One problem in understanding the role of elites in development is
that the term refers to a large and heterogeneous set of people. Elites
can be the most educated or the most experienced members of a com-
munity, or they can be the wealthiest and most powerful. Elite can also
refer to men or to people who belong to a dominant ethnic, religious, or
caste group. None of these characteristics is mutually exclusive; an elite
individual may possess many of these attributes simultaneously. The
relevant question is the purpose to which elites direct the dominance
and influence they possess.
    When power is used to facilitate collective action toward the public      Elite control can be an
good—because of an ethic of public service, a communitarian norm,             effective part of the
or another reason that results in altruistic behavior—elite control can       cooperative infrastructure
be an effective part of the cooperative infrastructure: elites can help       when power is used to
mobilize communities, persuade others, and shepherd them toward               facilitate collective action
collectively driven, welfare-enhancing behavior. Local development            toward the public good.
projects demand fairly sophisticated leaders; educated elites are in a
position to negotiate with bureaucrats, read and interpret project docu-
ments, manage accounts, and engage in other important activities that
are part of the everyday business of local projects. This type of control
can be described as a form of “benevolent capture” (Rao and Ibanez
2005; Beard and Dasgupta 2006).
   However, even benevolent elites have social networks and work
within them to facilitate change. Thus, beneficiaries of local projects
are likely to be people who are more closely linked to the leadership. In
developing countries in particular, younger generations tend to be better

                                                                                                             75
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



 Control becomes malevolent       educated than older generations, so any form of participation is likely to
  capture when elites extract     be led by younger people, creating a degree of intergenerational conflict.
    public resources for their        Control becomes malevolent capture when elites extract public
              private benefit.     resources for their private benefit. Capture can manifest itself in vari-
                                  ous ways, including theft, corruption, and the distribution of benefits
                                  to close relatives.
 It is important to distinguish       It is important to distinguish capture from another practice that
      capture from clientelism.   is, generally, inimical to the public good—clientelism. Clientelism
                                  occurs when leaders allocate public resources to feed and nurture their
                                  networks and relationships in an effort to consolidate social status and
                                  power.
                                      In nondemocratic settings, within which many communities in the
                                  developing world function, whether capture is benevolent or malevolent
                                  is a function of the particularities of the community: whether leaders
                                  are hereditary or appointed by higher levels of government; the degree
                                  to which communitarian norms or “symbolic public goods” have
                                  developed in those communities; and, as in Tsai’s example from China,
                                  whether nondemocratic forms of accountability exist. In nondemocratic
                                  settings, clientelism is largely a consequence of social norms and align-
                                  ments. Benefits are doled out to individuals and groups to whom the
                                  leader has a social obligation, or to build alliances, or sustain a potlatch.
                                      The local context also determines the nature of elite capture in the
                                  presence of democratic decentralization. Bardhan and Mookherjee
                                  (1999, 2000) construct a model of elite capture with electoral compe-
                                  tition. They find that the level of capture depends on the nature and
                                  extent of political participation, the political awareness of different
                                  groups in the population, and the evenness of competition between
                                  local political parties representing different interests. Wealthy groups
                                  can make contributions to the finances of politicians, who can then use
                                  the funds to recruit “unaware” voters. Aware voters vote on the basis of
                                  their interests. Levels of political participation and awareness depend
                                  on the distribution of literacy, socioeconomic status, and exposure to
                                  media. Democratic decentralization will result in a greater dispersion
                                  in the quality of governance, increasing the gap between more and less
                                  advanced regions. It will also tend to highlight local inequalities and
                                  the distribution of interests, making the extent of capture much more
                                  specific to the local context.
                                      Clientelism in democratic settings occurs when relationships between
                                  citizens and politicians are predicated on a material transaction, “the

76
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



direct exchange of a citizen’s vote in return for direct payments or          Clientelism in democratic
continuing access to employment, goods and services” (Kitschelt and           settings occurs when
Wilkinson 2007, 2). As Bardhan and Mookherjee (2011) point out,               relationships between citizens
(democratic) clientelism has several important negative consequences          and politicians are predicated
for development. First, resources are directed toward short-term benefits      on a material transaction.
with quick political gains—cash payments and private goods (housing,
subsidized food) rather than goods that contribute to development in
the long term (education, health). Private transfers, moreover, tend to
be directed toward swing voters at the expense of voters who are not
amenable to switching votes. Voters who are more easily monitored by
the political party (to ensure that the transfers result in clear political
gains) benefit at the expense of voters who are more difficult to moni-
tor. The consequence is that allocations are unequally distributed even
among deserving beneficiaries. Clientelism can thus reduce efficiency
and exacerbate inequality even in the absence of explicit capture.
   When initiating a local development project, it is therefore important
to understand the role of elites and to distinguish between elite control,
which often contributes to effective participation at the local level;
clientelism; and outright capture. Understanding local structures of
inequality and local social and political relationships insulates against
the naïve and potentially disempowering belief that participation will
necessarily benefit the poor. Explicitly recognizing structures of power
and dominance could result in designs to address such inequalities with
affirmative action programs, such as the mandated inclusion of women
and minorities in village councils, the adoption of programs that exclu-
sively target certain groups, or the use of monitoring and audit systems
to reduce the prevalence of capture.
   Group composition and collective action. The number of groups in a         The number of groups in
community makes a difference, particularly if each group has a distinct       a community can make a
identity and preferences. Groups tend to care more for their own mem-         difference, particularly if each
bers than for the members of other groups. Consequently, individuals          group has a distinct identity
may balance their individual incentives to participate with the interest      and preferences.
that derives from their group identity.
   The fact that larger communities have more groups within them
would suggest that collective action is more difficult to achieve in more
populous communities. However, as Alesina and La Ferrara (2005)
point out, more heterogeneous societies may be more productive,
because diversity may allow different skills to play complementary roles
in the production process. The presence of groups that are interlinked

                                                                                                            77
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    in production processes may increase incentives to avoid disagreement
                                    and conflict.
                                        The relationship between the size of a community and its capacity
                                    for collective action goes beyond the issue of heterogeneity. As Olson
                                    (1965) argues, larger communities also have more free riders, because
                                    the impact of each individual defector is smaller. Moreover, if the public
                                    good generated is not “pure” (not nonexcludable), an individual’s share
                                    in the public good declines in larger groups, reducing the incentive for
                                    collective action. This phenomenon is known in the literature as the
                                    group-size paradox. However, in the case of pure (nonexcludable) public
                                    goods, Olson’s result is reversed, as larger groups are able to produce
                                    more of them. Moreover, Esteban and Ray (2000) show that when
                                    the marginal cost of participation rises sufficiently, larger groups have
                                    a greater capacity to come to agreement even if the good is excludable
                                    (that is, it has characteristics of a private good).
                                        To understand what this means, consider a situation in which poor
                                    people need to mobilize to counter a powerful and exploitative local
                                    leader. The marginal cost of participation of a poor person in this case
                                    is extremely high, both because, being poor, the opportunity cost of
                                    her time is high and because the more she participates, the more visible
                                    she becomes and the more she risks becoming a target of the leader.
                                    Consequently, mobilization against the leader is unlikely to happen unless
                                    a large enough number of poor people would benefit from doing so.
      Larger, more unequal, or          It is therefore not necessarily true that larger communities, more
           more heterogeneous       unequal communities, or more heterogeneous communities are more
           communities are not      prone to collective action failure. The impact of these factors is complex
     necessarily more prone to      and highly dependent on the purpose underlying the collective action,
       collective action failure.   the extent of interdependence within the community, the nature of the
                                    cooperative infrastructure, the opportunity cost of participation, the
                                    level of poverty, and the extent of literacy and political awareness.
                                        Information failures. A purported advantage of decentralization is
                                    that it solves an important information failure—the inability of dis-
                                    tant central governments to observe the preferences of people who are
                                    socially, administratively, or geographically far away from central deci-
                                    sion makers. This lack of information becomes particularly acute when
                                    preferences are highly variable, either across heterogeneous populations
                                    or over time. Decentralization promises to make governments more
                                    responsive to the needs of citizens by making it more proximate to citi-
                                    zens. Whether decentralization actually solves the information problem

78
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



by improving the match between policy decisions and the preferences
of beneficiaries is an empirical question.
   Information failures in the civic arena are largely failures in the links      Information failures in
between civil society, the state, and markets. Such failures are widely           the civic arena are largely
prevalent and highly correlated with inequality and heterogeneity. They           failures in the links between
include imperfections in the availability of information about such basic         civil society, the state, and
issues as transparency in village budgets, citizens’ knowledge of legal           markets.
and bureaucratic procedures, and opportunities for credit and insur-
ance. Greater inequality contributes greatly to asymmetric information;
richer and more powerful people are likely to have better connected
networks, better access to powerful people in government, more educa-
tion (and therefore greater awareness), and greater capacity to influence
decision making. Lack of information and transparency greatly hampers
efforts at political and social accountability (Khemani 2007). The recti-
fication of information failures (by mass media, information campaigns,
or “report cards” in a credible manner and on a regular basis) has the
potential to improve the ability of citizens to mobilize themselves to
hold states and markets more accountable. With better information,
citizens become more aware and better able to make more informed
electoral decisions, which results in greater electoral accountability.
Even in the absence of electoral accountability, better information may
enable citizens to engage in a more informed version of “rude” account-
ability—that is, confronting public officials directly and forcing them
to be more responsive to their needs (Hossain 2009).
   In confronting the government, lobbying for resources, and making
demands on the state, unequal communities face a problem in that
the interests of the rich differ from the interests of the poor and the
rich have more voice. Even if the poor mobilize, inequality may create
distortions in linking civic groups to the state (Esteban and Ray 2006).
More unequal communities will have more polarized lobbies, which
have distorting effects when governments lack information about the
preferences of different types of citizens. More polarized lobbies may
also be more effective in voicing their interests. Consequently, govern-
ments may be more influenced by the preferences of extreme groups and
end up making inefficient decisions. Thus, in the Esteban-Ray model,
inequality creates a particular type of civil society failure.
   Solving imperfections in the provision of information is relatively
straightforward, in that it is less likely to involve a reversal in local power
relations. However, solving information asymmetries—equalizing

                                                                                                                  79
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



         Equalizing access to      access to information between the rich and the poor—is often not
      information is relatively    enough. Direct confrontation with structures of power may be neces-
          straightforward . . .    sary to create more accountable and responsive policies. Whether the
                                   provision of information improves the functioning of states and markets
                                   and the capacity of citizens to mobilize remains an empirical question.



                                   Conclusions
    . . . but citizens may need       Fads, rather than analysis, tend to drive policy decisions on par-
    to confront the structures     ticipatory development. Passionate advocates spark a wave of interest,
        of power directly to use   followed in a few years by disillusionment, which gives ammunition to
     that information to make      centralizers, who engineer a sharp reversal. In time, excessive centraliza-
governments more responsive        tion generates negative fallout, which reinvigorates the climate for local
                        to them.   participation.
                                      There have been at least two such waves in the post–World War II
                                   period (as shown in chapter 1). If current trends are extrapolated, another
                                   centralizing shift may have begun. Advocates and the vicissitudes of
                                   fashion are perhaps unavoidable in the aid allocation process, but they
                                   need to be supplemented by a thoughtful diagnosis of market, govern-
                                   ment, and civil society failures; inequality; and a contextual understand-
  Participatory development        ing of the best ways to rectify them.
    policy needs to be driven         These spheres do not operate independently; well-being is enhanced
   by a thoughtful diagnosis       by both improving the functioning of each sphere and enhancing the
  of the interaction between       links among them. The problems of information asymmetry and coor-
market, government, and civil      dination that affect markets and governments also affect civil society.
              society failures.    Decisions about whether, when, and how to promote local participation
                                   are therefore never easy. They need to be made with an understanding
                                   of the cooperative infrastructure; the role of elites; and the economic,
                                   political, and social costs and benefits associated with localizing decision
                                   making in a given country at a given time.


                                   Notes
                                    1. Effective civic action can also have harmful consequences for the aver-
                                       age citizen, particularly when multiple groups with competing interests
                                       coexist within the same society—when, for instance, a fringe group is
                                       able to impose its beliefs on society at large by effectively mobilizing its
                                       members and cowering the majority into submission (Kuran 2004). This


80
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



     situation represents a case of civil society failure that is, arguably, not a
     sustainable equilibrium in the long run.
2.   These notions of justice and fairness may vary from society to society and
     group to group. But every social group has norms that determine what is
     fair and just, and civic action is mobilized based on these norms.
3.   See Bardhan (2005) for an elaboration of this point. Another way of look-
     ing at the connection among governments, markets, and civil society is to
     examine them within the frame of accountability relationships (see figure
     3.2 in World Bank 2004). When citizens/clients organize collectively, they
     engage with the state by participating in politics and finding various other
     ways of expressing voice. The state consists of politicians and policy mak-
     ers who engage in a compact with service providers. The compact can be
     managerial, with the state directly managing the service providers through
     a government bureaucracy, or the government can delegate the provision
     of services to the market by having private providers deliver public services
     to citizens. The 2004 World Development Report specifies two routes by
     which a group of citizens can hold service providers accountable. The “long
     route” involves electoral accountability; citizens reward governments that
     are responsible for service provision by reelecting them or removing them
     from office by voting for their opponents. The “short route” decentralizes
     service provisions to communities, so that frontline providers are under the
     direct control and management of citizens, who exercise “client power” to
     hold them directly accountable.
4.   The standard benchmark for market and government failures is “con-
     strained Pareto efficiency”—the failure of self-interested individuals to
     obtain a Pareto optimum subject to constraints of information, given
     fi xed preferences and technology. In the civic sphere, preferences cannot
     be assumed to be fi xed; deliberative processes are intended to change
     preferences. Furthermore, coordinated actions can change information
     and the possibilities for contracting. For these reasons, a tight definition
     of civil society failure is elusive at this stage. The authors are grateful to
     Karla Hoff for alerting them to this point. For discussions of the related
     concept of “community failure,” see Hayami and Kikuchi (1981), Baland
     and Platteau (1996), Aoki (2001), and Bardhan (2005).
5.   In the course of a year of research, Tsai surveyed 316 villages in four
     provinces in northern and southern China.
6.   Village temple groups are organized around a village guardian deity, an
     aspect of Chinese popular religion attacked during the Cultural Revolution
     period but subsequently rehabilitated. Lineage groups are organized around
     village ancestral halls.
7.   Village church groups cannot be embedded, because Party members are
     prohibited from taking part in church activities. By contrast, given the
     centrality of the village temple as a symbolic resource—and the fact that
     the temple council is a fulcrum on which moral standing and prestige
     are regulated—Party members are almost always members of the temple
     council and among the top donors to temple activities.


                                                                                           81
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                           8. The focus here is on the role of culture in building collective identity. For
                              more on how a cultural lens can help with development policy, see Rao
                              and Walton (2004) and Lamont and Small (2008).
                           9. See Bouchard (2009) for an exposition of the related idea of “collective
                              imaginaries.”



                          References
                          Abraham, A., and J.-P. Platteau. 2004. “Participatory Development: When
                              Culture Creeps.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton,
                              210–33. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
                          Acemoglu, D., and J. A. Robinson. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and
                              Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
                          Agrawal, A. 2005. “Environmentality: Community, Intimate Government,
                              and the Making of Environmental Subjects in Kumaon, India.” Current
                              Anthropology 46(2): 161–89.
                          Alesina, A., and E. La Ferrara. 2005. “Ethnic Diversity and Economic
                              Performance.” Journal of Economic Literature 43(3): 762–800.
                          Alexander, J. 2006. The Civil Sphere. New York: Oxford University Press.
                          Aoki, M. 2001. Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis. Cambridge, MA:
                              MIT Press.
                          Baland, J.-M., P. Bardhan, and S. Bowles. 2006. “Introduction.” In Inequality,
                              Cooperation and Environmental Sustainability, ed. J.-M. Baland,
                              P. Bardhan, and S. Bowles, 1–9. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
                              Press.
                          Baland, J.-M., and J.P. Platteau. 1996. Halting Degradation of Natural
                              Resources: Is there a Role for Rural Communities? Oxford, U.K.: Clarendon
                              Press.
                          ———. 2006. “Collective Action and the Commons.” In Inequality,
                              Cooperation and Environmental Sustainability, ed. J.-M. Baland, P.
                              Bardhan, and S. Bowles, 10–35. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
                              Press.
                          Bardhan, P. 2005. Scarcity, Conflict and Cooperation. Cambridge, MA: MIT
                              Press.
                          Bardhan, P., M. Ghatak, and A. Karaivanov. 2006. “Inequality and Collective
                              Action.” In Inequality, Cooperation and Environmental Sustainability,
                              ed. J.-M. Baland, P. Bardhan, and S. Bowles, 36–59. Princeton, NJ:
                              Princeton University Press.
                          Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 1999. “Relative Capture of Local and National
                              Governments: An Essay in the Political Economy of Decentralization.”
                              Working Paper, Institute for Economic Development, Boston University,
                              Boston.
                          ———. 2000. “Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels.”
                              American Economic Review 90(2): 135–39.


82
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



———. 2006. “The R ise of Local Governments: An Overview.” In
    Decentralization and Governance in Developing Countries, ed. P. Bardhan
    and D. Mookherjee, 1–52. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
———. 2011. “Political Clientelism and Capture: Theory and Evidence from
    West Bengal.” Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of
    California, Berkeley.
Bates, R. H. 2008. “State Failure.” Annual Review of Political Science 11(1): 1–12.
Bayly, C. A. 2004. The Birth of the Modern World: 1780–1914. Malden, MA:
    Blackwell.
———. 2008. “Indigenous and Colonia l Origins of Comparative
    Development.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4474, World
    Bank, Washington, DC.
Beard, V. A., and A. Dasgupta. 2006. “Collective Action and Community-
    Driven Development in Rural and Urban Indonesia.” Urban Studies
    43(9): 1451–68.
Besley, T. 2006. Principled Agents? The Political Economy of Good Government.
    Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.
Bouchard, G. 2009. “Collective Imaginaries and Population Health: How
    Health Data Can Highlight Cultural History.” In Successful Societies:
    How Institutions and Culture Affect Health, ed. P. A. Hall and M. Lamont,
    169–200. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Bowen, J. R. 1986. “On the Political Construction of Tradition: Gotong
    Royong in Indonesia.” Journal of Asian Studies 45(3): 545–61.
Chwe, M. S.-Y. 1999. “Structure and Strategy in Collective Action.” American
    Journal of Sociology 105(1): 128–56.
———. 2001. Rational Ritual: Culture, Coordination, and Common Knowledge.
    Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Coate, S., and M. Ravallion. 1993. “Reciprocity without Commitment:
    Characterization and Performance of Informal Insurance Arrangements.”
    Journal of Development Economics 40(1): 1–24.
Dasgupta, P. 2009. “Trust and Cooperation among Economic Agents.”
    Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society 364(1533): 3301–9.
Devarajan, S., and R. Kanbur. 2005. “A Framework for Scaling-Up Poverty
    Reduction with Illustrations from South India.” Working Paper,
    Department of Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.
Esteban, J., and D. Ray. 2000. “Collective Action and the Group-Size
    Paradox.” American Political Science Review 95(3): 663–72.
———. 2006. “Inequality, Lobbying and Resource Allocation.” American
    Economic Review (March): 257–79.
Habermas, J. 1991. Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere. Cambridge,
    MA: MIT Press.
Hayami, Y. and M. Kikuchi. 1981. Asian Village Economy at the Crossroads: An
    Economic Approach to Institutional Change. Tokyo: University of Tokyo
    Press.
Heller, P., and T. M. Thomas Issac. 2003. “Democracy and Development:
    Decentralized Planning in Kerala.” In Deepening Democracy, ed. A. Fung
    and E. O. Wright, 77–110. London: Verso.


                                                                                           83
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Hoff, K. 2000. “Beyond Rosenstein-Rodan: The Modern Theory of
                              Coordination Problems in Development.” In Annual World Bank
                              Conference on Development Economics, ed. B. Pleskovic and N. Stern,
                              145–76. Washington, DC: World Bank.
                          Hoff, K., M. Kshetramade, and E. Fehr. 2011. “Caste and Punishment:
                              The Legacy of Caste Culture in Norm Enforcement.” Economic Journal
                              121(556): F449–F475.
                          Hoff, K., and J. E. Stiglitz. 2001. “Modern Economic Theory and
                              Development.” In Frontiers of Development Economics, ed. G. Meier and
                              J. Stiglitz, 389–459. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.
                          Hossain, N. 2009. Rude Accountability in the Unreformed State: Informal
                              Pressures on Frontline Bureaucrats in Bangladesh. Institute for Development
                              Studies, Sussex, United Kingdom.
                          Khemani, S. 2007. “Can Information Campaigns Overcome Political
                              Obstacles to Serving the Poor?” In The Politics of Service Delivery in
                              Democracies: Better Access for the Poor, ed. S. Devarajan and I. Widlung,
                              56–69. Stockholm: Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Government of Sweden.
                          Kitschelt, H., and S. I. Wilkinson. 2007. “Citizen-Politician Linkages: An
                              Introduction.” In Patrons, Clients and Policies: Patterns of Democratic
                              Accountability and Political Competition, ed. H. Kitschelt and S. I.
                              Wilkinson, 1–49. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
                          Kriesi, H. 2007. “Political Context and Opportunity.” In The Blackwell
                              Companion to Social Movements, ed. D. A. Snow, S. A. Soule, and
                              H. Kriesi, 67–90. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell.
                          Kuran, T. 2004. “Why the Middle East Is Economically Underdeveloped:
                              Historical Mechanisms of Institutional Stagnation.” Journal of Economic
                              Perspectives 18(3): 71–90.
                          Lamont, M., and M. L. Small. 2008. “How Culture Matters: Enriching Our
                              Understanding of Poverty.” In The Colors of Poverty, ed. A. C. Lin and
                              D. R. Harris, 76–102. New York: Russell Sage.
                          Mansuri, G., and V. Rao. 2004. “Community-Based and -Driven Development:
                              A Critical Review.” World Bank Research Observer 19(1): 1–39.
                          McCloskey, D. 2006. The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce.
                              Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
                          Mokyr, J. 2010. The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain
                              1700–1850. London: Penguin Press.
                          Morris, A. D., and S. Staggenborg. 2004. “Leadership in Social Movements.”
                              In The Blackwell Companion to Social Movements, ed. D. A. Snow, S. A.
                              Soule, and H. Kriese, 171–96. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell.
                          Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of
                              Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
                          Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for
                              Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.
                          Pradhan, M, V. Rao, and C. Rosemberg. 2010. “The Impact of Community
                              Level Activities of the Second Urban Poverty Project (UPP).” Department
                              of Economics, University of Amsterdam, Amsterdam.



84
A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT



Putnam, R. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy.
     Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Rao, V. 2006. “On Inequality Traps and Development Policy.” Development
     Outreach 8(1): 10–13.
———. 2008. “Symbolic Public Goods and the Coordination of Collective
     Action: A Comparison of Local Development in India and Indonesia.” In
     Contested Commons: Conversations Between Economists and Anthropologists,
     ed. P. Bardhan and I. Ray, 46–65. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell.
Rao, V., and A. M. Ibanez. 2005. “The Social Impact of Social Funds in
     Jamaica: A ‘Participatory Econometric’ Analysis of Targeting, Collective
     Action, and Participation in Community-Driven Development.” Journal
     of Development Studies 41(5): 788–838.
Rao, V., and M. Walton, eds. 2004. Culture and Public Action. Palo Alto, CA:
     Stanford University Press.
Ricklefs, M . 2002. A History of Modern Indonesia since c. 1200, 3rd. ed. Palo
     Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
Sullivan, J. 1992. Local Government and Community in Java: An Urban Case-
     Study. Singapore: Oxford University Press.
Tsai, L. 2007. Accountability without Democracy: Solidarity Groups and Public
     Goods Provision in Rural China. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University
     Press.
World Bank. 2004. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for
     Poor People. Washington, DC: World Bank.
———. 2005. “The Effectiveness of World Bank Support for Community-
     Based and -Driven Development.” Operations Evaluation Department,
     World Bank, Washington, DC.
———. 2006. World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development.
     Washington, DC: World Bank.




                                                                                        85
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
CHAPTER THREE




The Challenge of
Inducing Participation

THIS CHAPTER APPLIES THE ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK OUTLINED
in chapter 2 in order to better understand the challenges faced in resolv-
ing civil society failures, improving the interaction of civil society with
markets and governments, and implementing participatory projects.
What can participatory development achieve, and under what condi-
tions? What do the structures of failure at the local level say about
options for policy? What are some of the challenges of using policy
interventions to repair civic failures and induce participation? How
do incentives within donor institutions and government bureaucracies
affect the implementation of participatory projects? The chapter uses
the analytical framework to derive a set of hypotheses that guide the
analysis of the evidence in the subsequent chapters.
    Under the right conditions, effective local participation can be a        Under the right conditions,
powerful force for change and the achievement of various develop-             effective local participation
ment objectives. Local development moves from being “participatory”           can be a powerful force for
to “empowered” when decisions made by ordinary people through                 change and the achievement
deliberation are tied to policy decisions and actions—what Fung and           of various development
Wright (2003) call “empowered participatory governance.” This process         objectives.
is characterized by three foundational principles:

  •   Participation must have a practical orientation.
  •   Participation must be “bottom up,” in the sense that all of the
      people most affected by the problem and knowledgeable about
      solutions to it should be involved in decision making.
  •   Participation must be deliberative.
   Fung and Wright define deliberation as a process of collective deci-
sion making in which a group reaches a consensus across diverse points

                                                                                                          87
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  of view. It is an alternate to what economists call “preference aggrega-
                                  tion” through electoral mechanisms. In electoral decision making, pref-
                                  erences are aggregated by counting votes. Deliberative decision making
                                  requires that participants listen to one another’s positions and generate
                                  group choices after due consideration of other points of view, even if
                                  they do not necessarily endorse those choices or find them optimal.
                                     After examining various successful cases of empowered participatory
                                  governance around the world, Fung and Wright conclude that in order
                                  to advance these foundational principles, governance institutions need
                                  to incorporate three design features:

                                    •   Devolution. Local decision-making units should have meaning-
                                        ful power and be downwardly accountable.
                                    •   Centralized supervision and coordination. Local decision-making
                                        units need to share information, learn from one another, and
                                        discover what works by trial and error while being monitored
                                        and held accountable by the center.
                                    •   State-centered, not voluntary. Empowered participation should
                                        remake state institutions to align with their foundational prin-
                                        ciples rather than develop parallel structures.
         Ironically, empowered       Ironically, empowered participation requires a strong, functioning
       participation requires a   state that has not only internalized the broad objective of deepening
     strong, functioning state.   democracy and developed a much more astute view of citizens’ role in
                                  shaping policy but has also actively promoted and supervised the process
                                  by which this process happens.
                                     The premise underlying participatory development is the power of
                                  the group—the notion that individuals are far more effective when they
                                  work together toward a common objective than when they attempt to
                                  achieve the same objective on their own. By mobilizing citizens to work
                                  together for their collective well-being, participatory development has
                                  the potential to redress some failures of the state and some failures of
                                  markets while improving the capacity of individuals to bond and work
                                  together.
                                     One reason participation can do so is that it can have intrinsic value.
                                  People may value the simple courtesy of having their opinions heard, of
                                  being listened to. If public decisions are determined deliberatively rather
                                  than dictatorially, in a manner that gives everyone—poor and rich,
                                  female and male, lower and upper caste—an equal voice, the process by
                                  which decisions are made has, in itself, the potential to enhance agency.

88
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



Political theorists contend that participation has the potential to lead to
a process of positive self-transformation by catalyzing a set of desirable
changes in individuals: enhanced facility for practical reasoning, greater
tolerance of difference, more sensitivity about the need for reciprocity,
enhanced ability to think and act with autonomy on the basis of their
own preferences, and the ability to engage in moral discourse and make
moral judgments (Warren 1995).
    Much of the value of participation can be encapsulated in Hirschman’s      Participation can have
(1970) view that “voice” has both intrinsic and instrumental value. The        intrinsic value: people may
anthropologist Arjun Appadurai (2004) goes farther, describing voice as        value the simple courtesy of
a “cultural capacity.” Voice, he contends, is a matter not just of people      being listened to.
demanding democratic rights but of engaging with social, political, and
economic issues in terms of metaphor, rhetoric, organization, and pub-
lic performance, in order to negotiate and navigate their worlds. This
“capacity to aspire” is not evenly distributed. In situations where the rich
have consistently benefited from better social, political, and economic
connections and have the cultural tools to navigate those worlds, they
are “more likely . . . to be conscious of the links between the more and
less immediate objects of aspiration.” The rich are thus better able to
navigate their way toward actualizing their aspirations. If participation
is to build this navigational capacity, then voice and the capacity to
aspire need to be “reciprocally linked, with each accelerating the nurture
of the other” (Appadurai 2004).
    Participatory interventions are, however, more often justified by their
instrumental value—their potential to make states and markets more
accountable to the needs of citizens, to help communities mobilize to
improve credit and livelihood opportunities and manage common prop-
erty resources. The accountability function of participation requires
groups to mobilize in a manner that changes the incentives of the agents
of the state so that they act in the interests of citizens. State failure
often occurs because the incentives of the individuals who comprise
the state, and function as its agents, are not aligned with the needs of
citizens; instead, these agents seek to maximize their own interests. In
the absence of adequate oversight, this tendency could result in a range
of adverse outcomes, from absenteeism to corruption and theft of public
resources. Furthermore, if oversight of officials is largely managerial
(that is, from the top rather than the bottom), local officials are account-
able only upward, motivating officials to fulfi ll the dictates of their
bosses rather than meeting local needs. The consequences—phantom

                                                                                                              89
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                      schools with crumbling buildings and absent teachers, nonfunctioning
                                      toilets that are used to store fodder, roads that crumble at the first sign
                                      of rain—are ubiquitous in the developing world.
         Participation has the           Participation has the potential to force agents of the state to act
  potential to force agents of        against their private interests and for the public good. It makes
 the state to act against their       accountability—whether it be electoral, social, or “rude”—inherently
  private interests and for the       conflictual. How this conflict is managed and channeled depends on
                  public good.        the nature of the state, the institutional incentives of its agents, the
                                      division of power and responsibility between political leadership and
                                      bureaucrats, the nature and extent of the decentralization of authority,
                                      and the receptivity of the state to the demands of citizens.
                                         Participation is also used to enhance livelihood opportunities and
                                      credit for the poor. Microcredit programs mobilize groups of individu-
                                      als to collectively enforce the repayment schedule of every member, in
                                      an attempt to resolve coordination problems and asymmetries in infor-
                                      mation on the creditworthiness of individuals, which prevent banks
                                      and other large credit suppliers from servicing such communities.
                                      Self-help groups have also been mobilized to help expand livelihood
                                      opportunities more generally—by providing training in handicrafts
                                      and agricultural techniques, for example, and assisting in small-scale
                                      entrepreneurial and other activities. The group provides peer education
                                      and technical and moral support, using the power of networks to diffuse
                                      information and knowledge.
               Participation has         Participation has been used to try to redress the underprovision of
      been used to try to redress     public goods and services such as roads, water tanks, schools, and health
     the underprovision of public     clinics, which local governments typically provide. In community-
          goods and services . . .    driven development interventions, such public goods and services may
                                      be handed over entirely to communities to manage. In times of unex-
                                      pected crisis—when a typhoon or earthquake strikes and governments
                                      and markets are unable to respond quickly, for example—communi-
                                      ties are mobilized to rebuild homes, roads, and bridges and manage
                                      emergency aid. When a country is emerging from a long war or civil
                                      strife, community-based aid is often used to lead postconflict efforts at
                                      reconstruction.
        . . . and to reduce social,      Participation has also been used to try to reduce social, political, and
          political, and economic     economic inequality. By reserving leadership positions in civic bodies
                        inequality.   for women or other disadvantaged groups, participatory interventions
                                      have explicitly attempted to redress discrimination by promoting more
                                      egalitarian notions of leadership and breaking the power of traditional

90
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



elites. These interventions are inherently conflictual, in that they chal-
lenge the prerogatives of the people in authority.
    Using civic groups to help reduce poverty usually involves far less
confl ict with elites, because it does not challenge the basis of their
authority. In many countries, for instance, community-based participa-
tory bodies select the beneficiaries of poverty reduction programs, an
alternative method of targeting that even local elites may perceive as fair.



Participation and the Capacity to Engage
An important way in which participatory interventions can work is by           Participatory interventions
changing the character of everyday interactions—a process that, over           have the potential to change
time, reshapes social relationships. In highly unequal environments,           the character of everyday
social status structures the way people talk to one another. Moving            interactions—a process that,
toward accountable government both requires and brings about a                 over time, reshapes social
change in the tone and content of discourse. The conversation shifts           relationships.
from being embedded within existing power relationships and con-
ditioned by social norms to one in which people confront authority,
demand change, debate points of policy, and speak as citizens rather
than as subjects. Such shifts in “recognition” can have important eco-
nomic implications (Basu 2011).
   To bring about this change, citizens must have access to a new tool-        To bring about this change,
kit of discursive strategies—conciliatory, confrontational, pleading,          citizens must have access to
demanding, threatening—that they are able to strategically deploy.             a new toolkit of discursive
Even if these approaches do not have an immediate impact on the                strategies that they are able
allocation of public resources, changes in the nature of speech can, over      to deploy strategically.
time, build what Gibson and Woolcock (2008) call the “capacity to
engage.” Having the tools for “deliberative contestation” gives marginal-
ized groups a more equitable shot at negotiating, asserting, and making
demands that are in line with their interests and life experience. With
repeated interaction, more equality in the ability to articulate demands
can help move communities toward a trajectory of better and more equi-
table governance. This expansion in their strategic toolkits can change
not only how people are perceived within their communities but also
how they perceive themselves.
   Rao and Sanyal (2010) analyzed the transcripts of 300 gram sab-
has (village meetings) from India. This excerpt—from an interaction
between the upper-caste president of the panchayat (village council),

                                                                                                           91
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          a poor upper-caste villager (Jayaraman), and a poor villager (Muniraj)
                          from an untouchable (Dalit) caste—provides an example of deliberative
                          contestation in which the Dalit villager asserts his rights as a citizen.

                            Jayaraman: There are 45 families in our village. None of us has any
                            land. We work for meager daily wages. Whatever little we get we
                            spend on our children’s education. But it’s impossible to educate our
                            children up to high school because we don’t have the money. . . .
                            So we request that the government do something. . . . Our whole area
                            is dirty. Even the water is muddy, and that’s what we drink. . . . How
                            many times we have requested a road near the cremation ground and
                            for the supply for clean water?! We can only request and apply. The
                            rest is up to you.

                            Panchayat president: If there are 20–25 houses in an area, a ward
                            member should be appointed to represent the area. That ward member
                            should listen to your problems and must do something to help you.

                            Muniraj: That way [if we have a ward member], we will have the
                            guts to enter this room [where the gram sabha meeting is taking
                            place]. If the required ward members are not with us, to whom can
                            we voice our woes? Who will represent us? . . . If the ward member
                            belongs to another community, he won’t even listen to our problems.
                            Earlier, there was a time when a backward caste person was not even
                            allowed to sit in the same area with others! The officers and leaders
                            who come here [to the gram sabha meeting] already have a preset plan
                            about what to do and say. You come, sit on the chair, say something,
                            decide among yourselves, and go away. What’s there for us to do?!
                            You’ve enjoyed power for all these years. Why don’t you let us have a
                            turn? . . . We don’t want any problem at the communal level. For us,
                            whether X comes or Y comes, it is the same. We vote, but what hap-
                            pens later? Whereas other people get water even before they ask for
                            it, we have to ask endlessly, and even so, our demand is not fulfilled.
                            . . . We don’t want to fight with anyone. But at least there should be
                            someone to listen to our problems. We’ve been without water sup-
                            ply for the past one month. Even the village president knows it. He
                            has promised to send water. But the ward member is not allowing
                            us to take water. The water is sent to all his relatives. We cannot do
                            anything to stop it.

92
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



  Panchayat president: In any competition, it’s a rule that one should
  win and the other should lose. There’s no community-based dis-
  crimination or problem. If all of you in booth number 1 join and
  vote for me, I become the president. On the other hand, if everyone
  in the other booths votes for another person, then he’ll become the
  president. And then what will matter is what he can do for those
  booths that voted for him. Today, among youngsters, the level of
  public awareness is very high. Anyone can become a leader. . . . Even
  though there are problems between your two groups, I try to medi-
  ate. I don’t encourage communal riots.

  Muniraj: Everyone should be treated equally. No one should be
  treated as inferior to others. We should also be given a chance to sit
  on the dais [where the leaders sit]. Why should we be denied that
  right? Just because I talk like this, it doesn’t mean that I fight with
  you or disrespect you. I am simply voicing my feeling.

   Caste-based divisions have deep historical roots in India. They mani-
fest themselves in practices such as physical distancing and symbolic
deference. It is noteworthy that these traditional patterns of interaction
are now being openly challenged in gram sabha meetings, as Muniraj’s
angry complaints indicate. Lower-caste challenges are not completely
new; what makes the exchange excerpted above different is that it comes
not from a member of the educated elite but from an ordinary villager
embedded in everyday, local structures of inequality. Ordinary people
from disadvantaged castes now have a stake in political participation,
because the gram sabha allows them to momentarily discard the stigma
of their ascriptive identity and low economic status and slip into their
identity as citizens with equal rights in the eyes of the state. These
public interactions have the potential to challenge entrenched social
relations because they make overt the heretofore unseen “weapons of
the weak”—the expression of dissatisfaction in private while present-
ing compliant demeanors in public, foot dragging in respond to the
demands of elites. Such interactions expose “hidden transcripts” (Scott
1990) such as the feelings of oppression and domination felt by lower
castes and provide a means to challenge them.
   Minor as it may seem, the fact that poor people and people from
lower castes are able to make demands and voice complaints gives
them a sense of possessing equal recognition as citizens. When—and

                                                                                             93
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     whether—such small-scale changes cascade into effective civic capacity
                                     depends on the community’s level of literacy and numeracy, the level
                                     of inequality, and the extent to which inequality is embedded within
                                     durable social and power relationships.



                                     Diagnosing Failure Triangles
      Each type of participatory     Each type of participatory intervention can be associated with a dif-
        intervention needs to be     ferent diagnosis of the failures it will confront—whether it is trying
     associated with a different     to generate an intrinsic or instrumental outcome, address a long-term
      diagnosis of the failures it   development objective, or respond to a short-term crisis. Each type of
                    will confront.   intervention may employ a different definition of community (a micro-
                                     credit group is very different from a group of households mobilized to
                                     reconstruct homes after a hurricane). Not only can these groups differ
                                     in their composition, they may also have different geographic and social
                                     boundaries and incentives for collective action. Consequently, they may
                                     be subject to different types of failures.
                                        Potential spillovers from one civic objective to another also need to
                                     be thought through. Will building microcredit groups also result in
                                     the formation of groups that can fight village council corruption? Will
                                     starting a social fund to deal with postearthquake reconstruction result
                                     in a community-based institution that can act as a substitute for a failed
                                     local state?
                                        Government intervention may be justified when markets fail or
                                     economic and social inequalities need to be narrowed (see chapter 2).
                                     Theory also indicates that “each public service should be provided by
                                     the jurisdiction having control over the minimum geographic area that
                                     would internalize [its] benefits and costs” (Oates 1972, 55). Local needs
                                     are difficult for central governments to ascertain, because of the huge
                                     information costs of doing so and because of heterogeneities in prefer-
                                     ences and variations in the condition and composition of communities.
                                     For this reason, theory suggests that decisions on such issues as the
                                     provision of local public goods need to be decentralized.1
                                        Justifications for government interventions are complicated by the
                                     fact that governments themselves are prone to failure, because of prob-
                                     lems of coordination, commitment, and information asymmetries—
                                     locally as well as at the center. The power exercised by government can
                                     reflect and reproduce inequality. The degree to which community-based

94
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



bodies and local governments are embedded within structures of local             Local civic action is believed
inequality can be extremely heterogeneous, making central monitoring             to be the most effective way
of local bodies very difficult. Consequently, local civic action (local par-      of redressing local government
ticipation) is seen as the most effective and sustainable way of redressing      failure . . .
local government failure—dealing with corruption, giving the poor a
greater say in policy decisions, and holding local governments more
accountable.
    There are, however, some omissions in this logic, which often tend to        . . . but civil society and
be ignored. First, civil society is subject to the same sorts of failures and    government, which are subject
inequalities as markets and states. Incorporating failures and inequali-         to failure themselves, shape
ties in civil society makes the policy logic far more complicated and less       and condition each other, in
prescriptive. Participation is usually not a substitute but a complement         a manner determined by the
to the state. Civil society exists in a symbiotic relationship with the state:   nature of the failure.
it both shapes and conditions the state and is shaped and conditioned
by it.
    Second, the development of civic capacity is not just a local challenge;     Developing civil society
civil society matters in checking the tendency of all levels of govern-          is not just a local
ment—central and local—toward authoritarianism. In addition, civic               challenge . . . doing so
groups play an important role in the development of markets, by creat-           helps check the tendency
ing an enabling environment for entrepreneurship; protecting the inter-          of all levels of government—
ests of workers; providing credit, and other functions that are important        central and local—toward
for inclusive economic growth. Thus, one challenge of development is             authoritarianism.
to develop civic activity at both the micro and macro levels.
    Third, civil society is not an abstract concept that exists outside local    Civil society is not an abstract
forms of knowledge, social structures, meaning and belief systems, and           concept that exists outside
power relations. It is shaped by people, who are products as much of             local forms of knowledge,
their social and cultural milieus as of economic and political systems.          social structures, meaning
The manner in which people organize, the interests around which they             and belief systems, and power
mobilize, the styles and narratives of their discourse and resistance, and       relations . . .
the objects of their resistance are hybrid products of local dynamics and
national and global influences. Policy makers should therefore be care-
ful not to impose conceptions of civil society that come from outside            . . . it is shaped by people,
the local environment (for example, Western political theory). Instead,          who are products as much
they should try to understand the meaning of terms such as “civil,”              of their social and cultural
“society,” and “participation” from within indigenous frames. Indeed,            milieus as of economic and
policy makers should try to understand how history and the history               political systems.
of interventions—whether colonial or developmental—have shaped
those frames (Comaroff and Comaroff 1999). Doing so calls for a less
prescriptive and more adaptive approach to policy.

                                                                                                                 95
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                        Finally, when all three spheres—markets, governments, and civil
                                     society—are beset by failures and inequalities, which is typically the
                                     case almost everywhere, policy becomes murky, leading back to a vari-
                                     ant of the old balanced and unbalanced growth debates of the 1950s
                                     (Levy and Fukuyama 2010). Should development policy be sequen-
                                     tial—focusing first, for example, on building markets and spurring
                                     industrial growth—in the expectation that better government and civic
                                     capacity will follow, or should it focus on first developing an effective
                                     government or effective civic sphere? Should the strategy attempt to be
                                     more balanced by simultaneously improving the functioning of all three
                                     spheres? How do market, government, and civil society capacities at the
                                     macro level affect policy options at the local level? At the local level—
                                     where every village and neighborhood faces a different set of problems
                                     and is conditioned by different social structures, geographies, climates,
                                     and levels of connectivity—answers to these questions are perhaps best
                                     drawn deductively by examining the evidence, as chapters 4–6 do.


                                     Local Government Failure and the Nexus of Accommodation
                                     In most communities in the developing world, both the state and the
                                     market have failed. Local market failures—in the provision of public
                                     goods, such as schooling, health, and local infrastructure; in access to
                                     credit, markets, and so forth—are easy to identify. Local government
                                     failure can, however, be dispersed across a variety of local institutions
                                     and individuals. A local government typically consists of leaders and
                                     bureaucrats. Leaders can be members of village councils, neighbor-
                                     hood committees, mayors and municipal councils, city administrators,
                                     or chiefs and their advisers. They function within various systems of
                                     accountability. They may be elected in regular, independently super-
                                     vised elections or in “endogenous” elections that are organized and
                                     supervised locally; they may be appointed by upper-level political lead-
                                     ers and thus free of local accountability; or they may be hereditary.
       Local government failure         Even in formally constituted democracies, the theoretical logic of
           is dispersed across a     democratic accountability does not necessarily map into the real world
     variety of local institutions   logic of interactions between government and citizens. Locally orga-
                 and individuals.    nized elections can be manipulated by local leaders to their advantage;
                                     independent elections, although much more effective and important
                                     as accountability mechanisms, can be subject to clientelism and the
                                     appropriation of public funds to pay for electoral campaigns. Even if

96
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



leaders appointed by upper levels of government are accountable only             The theoretical logic of
upward, the central government can be effective in requiring good                democratic accountability
local government. Hereditary leaders selected in democratic settings,            does not necessarily map
although often authoritarian, can be subject to various long-term com-           into the real world logic
mitments, contracts, and symbolic functions that obligate them to act            of interactions between
in the interests of their subjects.                                              government and citizens.
    All local leaders are placed in the difficult position of negotiating
power with the central government, within the context of central regu-
lations and political incentives. The degree of autonomy enjoyed by
local leaders depends on their bargaining power with the center. At the
lowest tier of government, leaders may have limited room to maneuver
and be constantly in the position of having to beg for resources from
higher levels. They may, however, have established fiefdoms that are
politically important to the center, giving them a measure of power and
autonomy. The authority of local leaders and bureaucrats depends on
the extent to which they control the funds and functions of government
and on their local capacity to raise revenues. The less they depend on
the center for funds, the greater their autonomy. But local governments
often function within the domain of local strongmen, such as large
landowners or warlords, who wield considerable influence and whose
own demands and interests need to be satisfied.
    Local leaders also have to share power with local bureaucrats, who
are also subject to the institutional structures of government. Local
bureaucrats often come from the lowest rung of government service;
their professional incentives are geared toward pleasing their central
bosses and moving up in the hierarchy. They often perform important
functions at the local level and control an array of public resources,
which gives them considerable power within the village or municipal-
ity. These local bureaucrats can range from district administrators to
“street-level” officials, such as extension officers and junior engineers,
to employees of local governments, such as janitors and bill collectors.
    In participatory projects, it is the street-level bureaucrats (usually       In participatory projects,
known as “project facilitators”) who have the most proximate impact              project facilitators have the
on outcomes, because they are the people who deal with communities               most proximate impact on
on a day-to-day basis. They are expected to mobilize communities;                outcomes, because they
build the capacity for collective action; ensure adequate representation         are the people who deal
and participation; and, where necessary, break elite domination. These           with communities on a
trainers, anthropologists, engineers, economists, and accountants must           day-to-day basis.
be culturally and politically sensitive charismatic leaders. It is ironic that

                                                                                                                 97
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     this difficult role, on which participation can succeed or fail, is usually
                                     entrusted to the least experienced, worst-paid, and most junior staff.
Local politicians, bureaucrats,          All of these weaknesses of local government can lead to situations in
   strongmen, and other elites       which resources would have been allocated more efficiently had the gov-
  often function in a “nexus of      ernment not intervened. Weaknesses are caused by accommodations made
 accommodation” that is hard         to the center, by the manipulation of accountability mechanisms, and by
                      to break.      accommodations to local strongmen and between local bureaucrats and
                                     politicians (Migdal 1988). The concentration of power in any of these
                                     actors—a local strongman who also heads the village council, for exam-
                                     ple—can lead to a strong local state but one that tends to be dictatorial in
                                     its decisions. When all actors are equally powerful, power and authority
                                     can be diffused in a way that makes actions unpredictable, dilutes respon-
                                     sibility for action, and weakens the cooperative infrastructure.
       It is difficult for central        It is difficult for central governments to monitor the work of local
   governments to monitor the        governments because of the very imperfections in information and coor-
    work of local governments        dination that caused power to be devolved in the first place. The nexus
            because of the very      of social structures, power relations, the management of accommoda-
  imperfections in information       tions, the needs of citizens, and the quality of personnel vary greatly
 and coordination that caused        from jurisdiction to jurisdiction, causing communities to have a high
   power to be devolved in the       degree of heterogeneity. These variations place an untenable burden
                     first place.     of monitoring and supervision on the central government; if power is
                                     decentralized, they can produce an entirely new set of government fail-
                                     ures. The constant process of accommodation among the center, local
                                     strongmen, local government leaders, and bureaucrats, often makes the
                                     interests of citizens the last priority—the residual element in a hierarchy
                                     of interests that must be accommodated.
Participation has the potential          Participation has the potential to change this dynamic. It can move
  to move the actions of local       the actions of local governments toward the interests of citizens by
       governments toward the        adding their voice to the mix of necessary accommodations. If civic
        interests of citizens by     groups are sophisticated enough to understand the procedures of local
       adding their voice to the     governments and nimble enough to know how to exploit the politi-
              mix of necessary       cal economy of accommodation, they can become a potent political
          accommodations . . .       force. If the cooperative infrastructure is strong and elite interests not
                                     dominant, citizens can be united, lobby effectively, and persuade local
. . . but realizing this potential   governments to listen to their points of view, furthering their interests
        requires radical change,     by changing incentives within local governments.
   including confrontation with          Although participatory projects are packaged and promoted on
                           elites.   the promise of “empowerment” or enhancing the “demand side of



98
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



governance,” they often downplay the fact that both outcomes require            Lasting change is unlikely
radical change—a confrontation with local elites and a shift, to use            if the radical process of
Migdal’s language, in the “nexus of accommodation.” If external donors          breaking the local nexus
and central and state governments have not completely internalized              of accommodation is not
these radical goals and participation is instead nothing more than a            internalized and supported by
donor-driven mandate, it is unlikely that interventions will be imple-          donors and the central state.
mented in a manner that is truly empowering. Instead, the goals will
be processed within the existing nexus of accommodation, and lasting
change in outcomes will be unlikely—and may actually lead to elite
capture. Participatory interventions then become archetypes of what
Hoff and Stiglitz (2001) call “shallow interventions”—interventions
that result in no sustainable and irreversible changes in political dynam-
ics and therefore have a negligible impact on outcomes. To achieve a
“deep intervention,” the state has to commit to a long-term process of
engineering; a more downwardly accountable cooperative infrastructure
that is equity enhancing and empowering. Doing so requires strong
monitoring to avoid elite backlash, subversion, or capture, and the abil-
ity to distinguish between benevolent and malevolent elite engagement
with communities.


Participation and Political Opportunity
Effective participation requires the skillful exploitation of local political   Effective participation requires
opportunities (Kreisi 2007). An individual’s political opportunity set          the skillful exploitation of
is determined by his or her interests (material, ideological, or identity       local political opportunities.
based), as well as by the economic, social, political, or psychic con-
straints he or she faces. The decision to participate, however, depends
largely on the actions of the other members of the group to which an
individual belongs. A group’s willingness to mobilize and act collec-
tively depends on its shared opportunity set, the gains that accrue from
acting collectively, and the costs and other constraints associated with
coordinating collective activity. It is not just individual and collective
interests that influence the set of opportunities—it is also the beliefs
about those opportunities (Elster 1989). These beliefs are important
because they may cause actors to underestimate or overestimate their
capacity to effect change. Sociologists call this mix of individual and
group political opportunities and beliefs the “political opportunity
structure” (Kriesi 2007).



                                                                                                             99
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                      Indonesia provides an interesting example of how a village group
                                   was able to exploit political opportunities for change by developing its
                                   capacity to engage (Gibson and Woolcock 2008). An extended conflict
                                   over a leaky dam served as a flashpoint for organizing farmers and other
                                   villagers who depended on its shrinking reservoir supply for irrigation
                                   and drinking water. Initially, villagers used bureaucratic channels to
                                   request repairs to the dam. When their demands fell on deaf ears,
                                   they began expressing their anger through arguments and small-scale
                                   violence among themselves, including a hoe fight between two family
                                   members that resulted in head injuries.
                                      As unrest peaked in 2001, the villagers changed their tactics and
                                   began to mobilize hundreds of teachers, police, civil servants, and rice
                                   paddy owners and workers through a broad array of social networks.
                                   This mass mobilization caught the attention of a candidate for the local
                                   council, who used it as an opportunity to confront the incumbent. As
                                   hundreds of villagers blockaded a key road to the dam, the candidates
                                   sat in chairs facing the dilapidated structure until the deputy head of
                                   the council arrived and promised to make the repairs—which were
                                   completed within a year.
                                      This victory gave rise to a flurry of peaceful and fruitful engage-
                                   ment aimed at forcing the government to compensate farmers for lands
                                   inundated by the dam. In using the original conflict to develop their
                                   capacity to engage with local officials—and exploit the competition
                                   between them—the villagers developed new open political opportunity
                                   structures and beliefs about themselves that will have a lasting impact
                                   on local power relations.
   Localizing development can         An open political opportunity structure is one in which civic action
open up political opportunities    can exploit changes in the political system—in the structure of the
       by bringing the locus of    state, in leadership, or in dominance by a particular elite—to further
        decision making closer     the interests of a particular group. Localizing development—through
     to citizens, increasing the   decentralization or a community-driven development project, for
 benefits to participation while    example—can open up political opportunities by bringing the locus
             reducing its costs.   of decision making closer to citizens, which increases the benefits to
                                   participation while reducing its costs. Because of the nexus of accom-
                                   modation between local and central politicians and between local and
                                   central bureaucrats, however, the effectiveness of local civic mobiliza-
                                   tion can be modest. Although civic mobilization can potentially change
                                   the incentives of the agents of the local state so that they act more in
                                   the interests of citizens, these agents will have to balance the demands
                                   of local citizens against the demands of central authorities and the
100
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



competing demands of other local actors. In the absence of a sharp and
sustainable shift in the nexus of accommodation, therefore, expansion
of civic opportunities at the local level may have limited impact.
   Acemoglu and Robinson offer some important insights into the
process of participatory democratic change in Economic Origins of
Dictatorship and Democracy. They find that the conditions under which
political opportunities for citizens are maximized and the manner in
which citizens can effect change in a manner that progressively empow-
ers them depends on whether a particular group believes it has the capac-
ity “to obtain its favored policies against the resistance” of the people in
power and can convince other groups that it can do so (Acemoglu and
Robinson 2006, 21). Before they can act, citizens have to be persuaded
that any move toward an open political opportunity structure will be
durable and that old political institutions enmeshed with old economic
and social arrangements will give way to more accountable structures. If
change is seen as temporary, individuals will tend to use the opportunity
to maximize their immediate personal gains. Citizens will participate in
a manner that challenges powerful elites only if they feel they can “lock
in” political power in a way that is not easily reversed.
   Citizens’ willingness to act is further complicated by uncertainty          Before they can act, citizens
about decentralization, which could be recentralized during the next           have to be persuaded that any
political cycle, as has happened in almost every developing country.           move toward an open political
Similarly, in the absence of durable shifts toward a more accountable          opportunity structure will be
state, participation in community-driven development projects may              durable.
not lead to greater citizen mobilization on other issues, as the costs
will exceed the benefits. In contrast, a genuine change in the political
opportunity structure, accompanied by collective mobilization, can
permanently increase the cost to elites of maintaining their domination.
   Citizens thus make decisions about participation based on the likely
success of a specific reform, their beliefs about how sustainable it is, and
the potential for repression and backlash. Even with active participa-
tion, a small number of protagonists will lead the charge—spurred on
by lower opportunity costs or greater altruism. Some people will prefer
to have a free ride whereas others will play it safe, waiting to see how
quickly the winds change before deciding to act. There will also be
antagonists—people who actively oppose civic agents because those
agents challenge their interests.
   Elites who stand to lose under the new regime will include many
local and central bureaucrats, local strongmen, and local and central
politicians. Some elites may become protagonists, however, if they see a
                                                                                                        101
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    way that a change in policy could serve their own interests; there is, in
                                    fact, a risk of elite capture if gains from an intervention accrue mainly to
                                    these pro-reform elites and their supporters. A third category of elites—
                                    often better-educated citizens with high moral but low political author-
                                    ity, such as teachers, pastors, and imams—may help lead the process,
                                    either because they are altruistic and see doing so as a way of effecting
                                    positive change or because leadership gives them an opportunity to
                                    gain power and status. In this case, elite domination can facilitate an
                                    intervention and may even be essential to its success.
    In some societies, there is         Part of the challenge of introducing decentralized and participatory
  no recognizable conception        government into societies with “traditional” authority structures is that
 of citizenship in the textbook     traditional systems function with a different theory of governance,
          sense of the term . . .   which the community generally accepts as just and legitimate. In some
                                    societies, there is no recognizable conception of citizenship in the text-
                                    book sense of the term; there are, instead, only leaders and subjects.
                                    The legitimacy of local leaders is based on a gift economy, a system of
     . . . instead, leaders and
                                    mutual obligation between leaders and subjects in which civic activity
subjects relate to one another
                                    consists largely of subjects making requests to leaders. Leaders grant
   through systems of mutual
                                    these requests if they are able to do so, expecting obedience in return.
                     obligation.
                                    The resulting equilibrium creates elite dominance, authoritarian rule,
                                    and sharp inequalities in wealth, power, and social status.
                                        Development projects come with “modern” notions of governance
                                    and citizenship, which are predicated on the assumptions that govern-
                                    ment and citizens represent separate and equal spheres and separate loci
                                    of power and that “good governance” requires leaders to be accountable
                                    to citizens. This notion of governance is based on competition and
                                    negotiation for power rather than on mutual obligation.
Shifting from a gift-based to a         Shifting from a gift-based to a competition- and negotiation-based
competition- and negotiation-       model of governance and citizenship is a highly contentious process.
  based model of governance         During periods of what can be called “traditional equilibrium”—when
     and citizenship is a highly    social and political roles are well defined and everyone’s actions and
          contentious process.      interactions are highly predictable—levels of conflict are low. Within
                                    this system, however, there may be few opportunities to break inequality
                                    traps or empower the poor. At best, the poor can employ Scott’s (1990)
                                    “weapons of the weak” to express resentment without explicit confron-
                                    tation. Participatory interventions—along with other efforts to reduce
                                    inequalities, such as land reform—seek to disrupt this equilibrium
                                    by changing the local cooperative infrastructure, replacing leadership
                                    legitimized by mutual obligation with a relationship between leaders

102
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



and citizens based on democratic accountability. Unless traditional
inequalities resting on inherited wealth, status, and identity are concur-
rently replaced by a system in which power and status reward ability and
effort, however, the traditional order and existing power structures will
subsume and subvert any nascent participatory institutions.
   If, however, participatory interventions break down durable inequali-
ties, collective well-being could well diminish in the short run, as elites
resist, object to, and attempt to disrupt this challenge to their status.
Some of their subjects will be left anchorless, not knowing how to
navigate the new environment. Others will compete for power by using
violence. The major challenge during this transition period is to channel
conflicts into venues for deliberation and debate, in order to achieve a
negotiated transition to a new regime. If the process is effective, it will
lead to a new equilibrium in which leadership is legitimated by its ability
to meet the needs of citizens and social status is based on achievement.


Implementation Challenges: The Role of Donors
Challenges in inducing participation lie not only in the power dynam-         Challenges in inducing
ics within communities; they are also deeply influenced by incentives          participation lie not only in
within agencies tasked with funding and implementing participatory            the power dynamics within
projects. In particular, donors—both multilateral and bilateral—have          communities . . .
been key players in the spread of participatory innovations. They have
been responsible for transferring ideas and techniques from one region
of the world to another and actively scaling up interventions developed
in a few communities to an entire country. Donors have tended to
ignore the fact that context (historical trajectories, social and economic
inequality, ethnic heterogeneity, and symbolic public goods) affects
political and social institutions, especially at the community level, rely-
ing instead on “best practice” templates.
   This tendency results in what Evans (2004) calls “institutional            . . . they are also deeply
monocropping”—the “imposition of blueprints based on idealized                influenced by incentives
versions of Anglo-American institutions, the applicability of which is        within agencies tasked with
presumed to transcend national circumstances and cultures.” Other             funding and implementing
critics, including Harriss (2001) and Cooke and Kothari (2001), argue         participatory projects.
that in participatory projects, complex and contextual concepts such
as community, empowerment, and capacity for collective action are
applied to large development projects on tight timelines. Consequently,
project implementers, whose incentives are often poorly aligned with

                                                                                                              103
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          the needs of the project, may gloss over differences within target groups
                          that underscore local power structures and sidestep the difficult task of
                          institution building in favor of more easily deliverable and measurable
                          outcomes.
                              Mosse’s (2005) ethnography of the Indo-British Rain-Fed Farming
                          Project (IBRFP), funded by the United Kingdom’s Overseas Development
                          Administration (ODA) and Department for International Development
                          (DFID), illustrates how the process of induced participation works in
                          a large, scaled-up, donor-driven project. Mosse studied the project over
                          several years and was involved in it in various capacities—as a planner,
                          social expert, soil and water conservation consultant, and adviser—as
                          it evolved through different planning and implementation phases. He
                          studied all of its phases, from inception, in 1992, as a participatory
                          project geared toward bringing agricultural technologies and innova-
                          tions to the tribal Bhil population in central India; to its assessment by
                          the development community, in 1995, as an “exemplary success”; to its
                          culmination, in 1998–99, by which time it was declared a failure. ODA–
                          DFID’s Indian partner organization was a fertilizer company, which
                          Mosse found to be unusually committed to the participatory ethic. The
                          company hired a large field staff of community organizers and trained a
                          large number of village-level volunteers, called jankars (“knowledgeable
                          people”), who gradually emerged as crucial local mediators and brokers.
                              The project began with a “village entry” participatory rural appraisal.
                          The very nature of a participatory rural appraisal—which is typically
                          held in the courtyard of a village headman or other notable—subjects it
                          to a high degree of bias and reflects the effects of local power. The type
                          of knowledge that was communicated, the tone of the discourse, and the
                          words used all reflected the biases of the more active, articulate members
                          of the village, who defined the community’s needs and then became
                          crucial links for the community organizations in the initial trust-
                          building phase of the project. The poorer members of the community
                          were usually unwilling, inarticulate participants in such processes. In
                          response, the community organizations gradually changed their tactics.
                          They approached women and nonelites for more discreet, informal rural
                          appraisal–type exercises, which had repercussions for their position in
                          relation to village elites.
                              Matters were hardly as simple as ensuring that all points of view
                          were represented, however: villagers quickly learned to anticipate the
                          outsider’s point of view, sense project staff ’s capacities for providing

104
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



assistance, and structure their demands accordingly. The project soon
came to be seen as a patron of particular activities and constituencies.
The participatory rural appraisal and planning stage became, in effect,
a process of mutual collusion in which “local knowledge” and desires
were effectively domesticated by the project’s vocabulary, as community
perspectives seamlessly melded with the project’s interests. Although
planners continued to use the language of participation and empower-
ment, villagers viewed the project as just another kind of patronage.
Better-off villagers hoped for various forms of assistance in terms of
capital investment (seeds, inputs, loans for pump sets); worse-off villag-
ers came to view the project as a source of wage labor and credit.
   Was there anything wrong with the way this participatory project
progressed? The answer depends on what hopes one harbors for “par-
ticipation.” Rather than evaluating the project from an abstract ideal,
Mosse studied various dynamics. The community organizations and
other field staff had to undergo a tricky process of earning the trust of
community members. Doing so required them to become familiar with
local notables, institutional figures, and bureaucrats. As they did so,
they gradually became implicated in various village hierarchies and fac-
tions and in local networks of exchange, favors, and mutual assistance.
The village-level jankars became more or less “empowered” over time
(although their fortunes could wax and wane with the fortunes of the
project), although this empowerment arose mainly through relations
with outsiders. This process, Mosse argues, is one of the generic dilem-
mas of participatory approaches: such projects often demand not less
but more intensive agency presence, they may be less cost-efficient, and
they may foster dependency and patronage (Mosse 2005).
   So when did things begin to go “wrong” with this project? Two inter-
pretations must be separated: Mosse’s evaluation of the implementation
stage of the project and the organizational judgments that first declared
the project a success and then a failure.
   In Mosse’s view, the implementation stage brought with it entirely
new organizational dynamics: prioritizing quantifiable targets, setting
numerical goals, moving away from learning and experimentation. This
transition created a “regime of implementation” (2005, 109). Staff mem-
bers faced growing pressure to meet implementation targets, set from
above and demanded from below. The jankars, working closely with but
junior to the community organization project staff, began to “regard
themselves primarily as project employees (if not private contractors),

                                                                                            105
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          with the power to assess work and sanction payment” (Mosse 2005,
                          114). As one senior project employee reported, “we rather skewed the
                          potential of jankars as real agents of a more indigenous type of develop-
                          ment. They became the delivery mechanisms, which [was a departure]
                          from the original thinking” (114). As for the villagers, “although they
                          were now familiar with the official rhetoric of ‘people’s participa-
                          tion’ (janasabhagita), in common parlance ‘participation’ (bhagidari)
                          implied simply that a contribution (of money or labor) had to be
                          made . . . the extent and nature of villager’s bhagidari (contribution) was
                          a matter for negotiation and agreement with outsider patrons” (114). By
                          this phase, participatory rural appraisal “became largely symbolic. Staff
                          now knew how to write them [participatory appraisals] up; how to move
                          swiftly to expenditure. . . . As the logic of implementation pushed prac-
                          tice toward standardization, it was virtually impossible to ensure that
                          ‘participatory planning’ involved local problem solving or even choosing
                          between alternatives. In fact, the ‘quality’ of the “participatory process’
                          mattered less and less” (116).
                              Mosse’s analysis describes the phase shift typically experienced by
                          most participatory projects, from a somewhat open-ended planning
                          phase to a more structured implementation phase. It is possible to con-
                          ceive of it as a kind of rhythm of participatory projects, which could,
                          therefore, have been anticipated.
                              More damaging, according to Mosse, was the effect of this shift on
                          the service delivery aspect of the project and the kind of demands that
                          should have been but were not factored in. “Villagers themselves had
                          little control over project processes and budgets. Rather than imple-
                          menting their own ‘village development plan,’ they found that compo-
                          nents of the plan (individual schemes and subsidies) would be delivered
                          on an item-by-item basis—instead of in logically related bundles—by
                          an administrative system that was unknown and unpredictable. One
                          example of a logical bundle was a request by a group of women in a
                          village for support for a project consisting of an interlinked package
                          of activities—ducks, goats, rabi seeds, and a pump set” (Mosse 2005,
                          263). Mosse argues that one of the key problems in the shift from the
                          planning to the implementation phase is that once a set of practices is
                          in place, the system generates its own priorities, activities, and goals,
                          which may be quite different from the formal goals regarding commu-
                          nity participation and empowerment expressed in policy papers or even
                          project design documents. The relationship between policy and practice
                          in participatory interventions therefore needs careful consideration.
106
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



   Another problem is that there are stratified, relatively autonomous
levels of project actors with narrow points of overlap (Mosse describes
this relationship as an “hourglass”), as illustrated in Mosse’s multisited
ethnography of head offices, consultants, budget specialists, project
staff, village-level community organizations, volunteers, and villagers.
This hourglass relationship is crucial to the question of how to scale
up projects. Mosse describes a wrong turn, a transition point in the
project, as “DFID–imposed disorder” caused by a “grossly simplified
view of ‘up-scaling,’ ‘mainstreaming,’ ‘fast-tracking,’ and ‘replication.’ ”
As a result, “a huge burden was placed on a complex and shaky system:
the project had to create a new organizational structure, to quadruple
the size of its operations . . . fast-track its process (reduce village entry
time) . . . create further linkages [to both the local government and the
rural commercial sectors], while retaining its intense focus on participa-
tion . . .” (Mosse 2005, 185).
   Most strikingly, throughout the period in which the project was
first declared a success and then a failure, field activities, levels of work,
and modes of engagement remained more or less the same, and project
actors maintained relative autonomy. This meant, according to Mosse,
that the project’s “fall from grace” was not a result of a shift in design or
implementation but a result of changing policy fashions. The late 1990s
saw an increased emphasis on partnerships with state structures; para-
statal projects lost favor, as they were not seen to be “replicable models”
(Mosse 2005, 199). What Mosse finds worrisome is that with policy
fashion cycles becoming shorter, the ability to gain the trust of local
populations may be increasingly compromised, as projects abruptly
dispense with groups that no longer serve their policy objectives.
   Several lessons emerge from Mosse’s account:

   •   The expectation of abrupt shifts in policy has adverse effects
       at every level of the project—and crucially contributes to the
       shallowness of the intervention. If the project is seen as end-
       ing within a very proximate period rather than contributing to
       sustainable change, higher-level project officials will spend their
       time trying to frame the intervention as a success rather than
       working to lay the foundation for lasting change.
   •   The expectation of abrupt shifts in policy influences the qual-
       ity and character of mobilization. Because the intervention is
       seen as time bound, people participate largely in order to reap
       material gain. They take what they can from the resources the
                                                                                               107
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                          project brings and say what they have to say to gain access to
                                          those material benefits. Although such behavior may create
                                          some short-term improvements in material well-being, it does
                                          not result in a lasting shift in power relationships and stronger
                                          mechanisms for voice and mobility.
                                      •   Even if the intervention is long lasting, participatory change
                                          takes time. A short project cycle that initiates but then termi-
                                          nates a trajectory of change can leave communities hanging
                                          off a cliff.
                                      •   Participatory projects work well when they are given the free-
                                          dom to learn by doing, to constantly experiment and innovate
                                          based on feedback from the ground. As the project expands,
                                          however, experimentation becomes more difficult, and efforts
                                          are directed more toward meeting the letter rather than the
                                          spirit of project goals.
                                      •   Facilitators play a crucial role in participatory projects.


                                    Implementation Challenges: The Role of Facilitators
Facilitators are at the frontline   Facilitators are at the frontline of induced participation. They identify
  of induced participation . . .    the failures of local civil society, markets, and government; design inter-
                                    ventions to repair them; and look for ways to repair the associated civic
                                    failures, seek political opportunities, and mobilize the community to
                                    exploit them. Facilitators are paid to play the role that the social activ-
                                    ist would play in an organic participatory movement. Their incentives
                                    are rarely aligned in a manner that results in truly empowered change,
                                    however. For example, although their job requires flexibility, time,
                                    and constant engagement with experimentation, facilitators are given
                                    targets (mobilize X communities in Y days). Because they are poorly
                                    compensated and know the project will end in two or three years, they
                                    are constantly looking for other work. They are often poorly monitored,
                                    allowing them to submit false reports on the achievement of project
                                    targets.
                                        Perhaps of greatest concern, facilitators working under these condi-
                                    tions may take shortcuts to persuade or force people to participate, using
                                    messages for recruitment that are quite different from stated project
                                    goals. For example, they may try to meet their participation targets by
                                    using messages with a strong emotional impact or by luring people with
                                    the implicit promise of monetary benefit. Instead of being seen as agents

108
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



of change, facilitators may be perceived as part of the existing nexus of      . . . but their incentives are
accommodation. The question, then, is whether they can legitimately            often not set up to truly
affect radical change when they are perceived as part of the state appa-       empower communities.
ratus? When change requires radical advocacy, do these facilitators, who
report upward to people who may not permit them to advocate radical
change, face the right incentives? More fundamentally, what can facili-
tators accomplish? Within which spaces can they work for change? Can
induced participatory development really generate political and social
empowerment? Many factors affect the answers to these questions, but
it is clear that interventions will not succeed without higher levels of
government being actively committed to the development of active civic
engagement at the local level.


Implementation Challenges: Trajectories of Change
A major problem with donor-induced participation is that it works              Donors’ institutional
within an “infrastructure template.” Donors’ institutional structures          structures and incentives are
and incentives are optimally suited to projects with short timelines           optimally suited to projects
and linear trajectories of change with clear, unambiguous projected            with short timelines and linear
outcomes. When a bridge is built, for instance, the outcome is easily          trajectories of change with
verified, the trajectory of change is predictable, and the impact is almost     clear, unambiguous projected
immediate. Participatory interventions, which engage in the much more          outcomes . . .
complex task of shifting political and social equilibriums, have very
different trajectories.
   Unfortunately, most participatory projects that emerge from donor           . . . but civic change is a highly
agencies are designed within the same assumed trajectory and three- to         unpredictable process.
five-year cycles as infrastructure projects. At the end of the project cycle,
these projects are expected to have met various civic objectives (better
social capital, community empowerment, improved accountability).
Almost all community-driven projects go farther, projecting gains in
outcomes such as a poverty reduction, school enrollment, sanitation
and health, and so forth. The assumption is that within the period
of the project cycle, the intervention will activate civic capacity to the
extent that it will repair political and market failures enough to have an
observable impact on “hard” outcomes.
   Three assumptions are inherent in this thinking:

   •   Civic engagement will be activated in the initial period of the
       project.

                                                                                                                109
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?




                             •   Civic capacity will be deepened enough to repair government
                                 and market failures.
                             •   This improvement in the quality of governments and markets
                                 will result in a measurable change in outcomes.
                             Figure 3.1 illustrates the problems with these assumptions. The
                          project-based assumption (illustrated by the dotted lines) shows a path
                          in which civil society and governance outcomes improve in a predict-
                          able linear manner that is congruent with changes in measurable out-
                          comes. The problem with this reasoning is that civic change is a highly
                          unpredictable process; many things have to take place to make it hap-
                          pen. Individuals have to believe that collective mobilization is worth
                          the effort and be willing to participate; civic groups have to solve the
                          collective action problem and exploit political opportunities to effect
                          change; the nexus of accommodation in government has to be disrupted
                          by the rising cost of ignoring citizens’ interests, so that politicians and
                          bureaucrats change their actions; and their new actions have to result
                          in changes in outcomes. A change in outcomes has to be preceded by
                          an improvement in civic capacity, which possibly unleashes a series of
                          changes that will change outcomes (Woolcock 2009). The reality is
                          depicted by the solid lines in figure 3.1.
                             Predicting when meaningful change will occur in each node
                          is extremely difficult because a number of factors come into play,



                          Figure 3.1 Possible trajectories of local participation

                          Household welfare, public          Projected development
                          goods, quality of public           path for welfare outcomes
                          services                                                                Realized
                                                                                                  development
                                                                                                  path for welfare
                                                                                                  outcomes




                                                                                                  Time




                          Civil society and governance      Projected development        Realized development
                          outcomes                          path for civil society and   path for civil society and
                                                            governance outcomes          governance outcomes


110
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



including the nature of the cooperative infrastructure; the history of
civic engagement and politics; the level of development; the extent to
which the state has committed to the process of change and is therefore
effectively incentivizing, enforcing, and monitoring the actions of its
agents; the level of literacy; information flows—in other words, all of
the factors that affect civic failure. Social equilibrium is hard to change
because it has evolved after years of repeated interactions within par-
ticular economic, political, and social environments.
   Therefore, whether at the micro or the macro level, civic engage-
ment often tends to be absorbed, in its early stages, within the nexus
of accommodation, with the leaders co-opted by elites. Furthermore,
as discussed earlier in this chapter, until citizens are convinced that the
high cost of fighting for their interests and resisting elite domination
is worth the effort, they are unlikely to engage in an effective manner.
Widespread participation occurs when a tipping point is reached—
when enough people are convinced of the value of participation, when
they sense a fundamental change in the nature of politics and power,
and when enough people convince enough others to engage, resulting
in a participatory cascade. Borrowing from evolutionary biologists,
sociologists describe this process as one of “punctuated equilibrium”
(Koopmans 2007)—a process in which long periods of stability are
punctuated by brief periods of extremely rapid change. At the local
level, the wide diversity in the nature of communities reinforces this
unpredictability in the timing of change. Each community is likely to
have a different change trajectory.
   Thus, particularly when it is packaged within a project, induced            Particularly when it is
participation is almost set up for failure because of unrealistic predic-      packaged within a project,
tions that emerge from bureaucratic imperatives. The challenge of              induced participation is
policy interventions is to figure out where each community is within            almost set up for failure
this complex trajectory of change and to create an enabling environment        because of unrealistic
in which that change can occur in a manner that improves develop-              predictions that emerge from
ment objectives. For induced participatory projects to have a chance           bureaucratic imperatives.
of meeting their objectives, they have to attempt to adopt the spirit of
experimentation, learning, and persistent engagement that character-
izes organic participatory change. Unfortunately, donors are bound by
strict timelines; imperatives to disperse money quickly and effectively;
and internal incentives that make honest and effective monitoring and
evaluation a low priority at the project level, despite the rhetoric in sup-
port of it.

                                                                                                         111
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?




                          Deriving Hypotheses
                          Public spending to improve living conditions for the most disadvan-
                          taged is widely accepted as the cornerstone of any credible development
                          strategy. There is also a sense that any serious policy shift in this direc-
                          tion needs to include a larger role for civil society. In line with this,
                          many developing countries have devolved the management of key public
                          services, have decentralized the implementation of targeted poverty
                          reduction programs, and are increasingly providing local public goods
                          through mechanisms that induce some type of community participa-
                          tion. At the core of these efforts is the idea that greater civic engagement
                          can make resource allocation both more responsive and more account-
                          able, with the greatest benefits realized by people with the least influence
                          and the least capacity to opt for private alternatives.
                             The traditional economic justification for local provision of pub-
                          lic goods and services is that it allows subjurisdictions to tailor the
                          level, quality, and cost of services to the preferences of local residents.
                          Governments are assumed to be largely benign and citizens mobile, able
                          to “vote with their feet” by moving to areas where regulations, taxes,
                          and services best match their preferences and needs.
                             Most public goods and services (schools, drinking water, sanitation,
                          roads) are inherently local; they serve a reasonably well-defined group
                          from which nonresidents can be effectively excluded. In such cases,
                          devolution should increase both efficiency and equity, because it frees
                          up a distant center from having to acquire costly information on local
                          preferences and the supply of local public goods. Local agents may also
                          have access to emerging information, such as recent adverse shocks, that
                          may be only poorly reflected in the types of data available to distant cen-
                          tral administrators. To the extent that some of the salient characteristics
                          of poverty are also location specific, decentralizing the identification
                          of beneficiaries may also increase the efficiency of resource allocation.
                          Citizen mobility also creates external performance pressure on sub-
                          jurisdictions to compete for the best talent and the most productive
                          and profitable businesses, which curbs excessive rent-seeking by public
                          officials and increases service quality. Menes (2003) argues that this
                          process accounts for the decline in municipal corruption in the United
                          States at the turn of the 20th century. As railroads were developed and
                          the frontier became accessible, the capacity of local government officials
                          to extract rents declined (see also Rondinelli, Mccullough, and Johnson
                          1989; Khan 2002).
112
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



    If citizens are mobile and governments benign, there seem to be few
efficiency arguments for centralized resource allocation, except when
significant intercommunity coordination problems arise from spillovers,
externalities, or economies of scale that require centralized manage-
ment. (Rules and regulations regarding environmental pollution, vac-
cination programs, and defense are good examples.)
    The situation is quite different in most developing countries, where
the main arguments for decentralization center on accountability.
In this view, the fundamental problem with the central provision of
public goods and services is bureaucratic inefficiency and rampant
rent-seeking. Localizing resource allocation decisions brings ordinary
citizens, who have the greatest stake in the quality of services provided
as well as the greatest incentive to restrict rent-seeking, into closer prox-
imity with relevant decision makers. Decentralization allows citizens to
observe the actions of officials and providers, to use this information
to induce higher levels of transparency, and to generate social pressure
for policy reform.
    Concerns about corruption have amplified the accountability argu-            The main argument for
ment for decentralization.2 Over the past decade, the view that corrup-         decentralization in most
tion poses a major threat to development has acquired considerable cur-         developing countries is that
rency. Corruption is seen as adding substantially to the cost of providing      it increases accountability,
basic public goods and services; dampening the redistributive objectives        thereby reducing corruption.
of poverty reduction programs; and, perhaps worst of all, changing the
incentives facing both citizens and public officials.3 As reform efforts
directed at legal and financial institutions at the center have produced
little success, the push for more local solutions has grown, with the
greatest emphasis on civil society oversight and monitoring of public
officials and providers.4
    This emphasis on local accountability has effectively created a new
justification for the decentralization of resource allocation decisions
that remains relevant even when there is no significant variation in
preferences for public goods. Arguments for state and donor support to
local participatory institutions are couched in terms of giving voice to
the most disadvantaged members of society in order to create demand
for better governance.
    Influential voices on the other side of the debate over participation
point out that shifting the locus of decision making downward need
not have salutary effects if social structures reflect long histories and
deeply entrenched power hierarchies. In such contexts, they argue, local
inequalities of wealth and power can acquire much greater significance,
                                                                                                          113
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                      as important resource allocation decisions shift downward; in the
                                      extreme, they can exacerbate local inequality and perpetuate or even
                                      reinvigorate local power relations.
                                         Where localities are also heterogeneous in other respects, such as in
                                      their ethnic, racial, or tribal composition, there may be additional coor-
                                      dination challenges and greater potential for redistributive projects to
                                      generate or exacerbate local conflicts. Some researchers, such as Henkel
                                      and Stirrat (2001), even argue that although the language used by par-
                                      ticipatory programs is designed precisely to manage such underlying
                                      dissent, the search for “consensus” often simply results in the subordina-
                                      tion of minority voices or the proliferation of formal governance rules
                                      that make participation costly, particularly for the people with the least
                                      capacity. In the presence of significant group heterogeneity, electoral
                                      incentives can also induce political agents to allocate resources to satisfy
                                      more parochial interests, at the cost of broader investments in public
                                      goods and services.
   Whether local governments             Whether or not local governments or participatory programs can
or participatory programs can         be responsive to local needs may depend to a significant degree on the
 be responsive to local needs         resources they can access relative to their mandate and the discretion
  may depend to a significant          they have over the allocation of resources across diverse needs. For many
 degree on the resources they         reasons, including the political context in which central governments
   can access relative to their       undertake decentralization, in most developing countries, devolution
                  mandate . . .       of responsibility for taxation has been far more contentious than the
                                      devolution of responsibilities for expenditure, particularly when local
                                      governments are elected. With few exceptions, however, and regardless
      . . . and the discretion they   of the type of decentralization undertaken, local governments obtain
       have over the allocation of    the bulk of their resources as transfers, whether formula based or dis-
         resources across diverse     cretionary and ad hoc, from central or intermediate-level governments;
                            needs.    taxation authority is rarely devolved to any substantial degree. As a
                                      result, there is an unavoidable tension between central and lower levels
                                      of governments regarding accountability and fiscal discipline at the local
                                      level. Local officials blame the center for their failures in service provi-
                                      sion by claiming that the center has assigned unfunded mandates to
                                      them, limiting their ability to meet their responsibilities. Discretionary
                                      transfers from the center are considered particularly detrimental for
                                      local provision of public goods and services, because they not only limit
                                      the local government’s ability to plan investments and expenditures,
                                      they also leave local governments vulnerable to various types of manipu-
                                      lation from the center. For their part, central governments bemoan

114
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



local governments’ “soft budget constraints,” a situation in which local
governments that are unconstrained by their revenue-raising capacity
are tempted to overspend and then ask the center for a bailout in the
form of supplemental transfers from tax revenues generated elsewhere.
Of course, such overspending may itself be a response to an unfunded
expenditure mandate.
   In principle, local governments could raise some or all of their           In practice, devolving revenue
resources directly from their constituents, through taxes and fees, and       raising to the local level is
there are important arguments in favor of devolving revenue-raising           difficult.
responsibilities. Some researchers have even gone as far as to argue that
central transfers should be contingent on such revenue-raising efforts, as
such a move would force local governments to accept responsibility for
poor service provision and incentivize citizens to monitor local officials’
performance more closely. In practice, however, devolving revenue rais-
ing to the local level is difficult.
   Central governments also have a mandate to mitigate interregional
disparities through appropriately targeted fiscal transfers, which can
include considerations of need intensity and demographic size. As Cai
and Treisman (2004) argue, when regional differences in the productiv-
ity of specific factors are significant (because of location, agglomeration
externalities, or the endowment of resource), local taxation authority
can unleash a race to the bottom. As local governments compete to
attract the wealthy, less well-endowed localities become weaker and
more dependent on central transfers. This situation can exacerbate
regional disparities in government services and increase horizontal
wealth inequality. The worst-off areas may also have the least incentive
to give up rent-seeking activities.
   Some observers suggest that the timelines and objectives of donor-         Donors’ evaluation criteria
funded projects can exacerbate these challenges. Donor-funded projects,       create incentives to select
they argue, value the rapid disbursement of inputs, the creation of           areas that are easily reached
community organizations, the achievement of predetermined rates of            and organized . . .
return on investments, and improvements in the income and assets of
beneficiaries. These evaluation criteria create an incentive to select areas
that are easily reached and organized and to target project benefits to        . . . . and to target project
households that are able to quickly absorb project funds in productive        benefits to households that
activities.5                                                                  are able to quickly absorb
   A key concern is the possibility of civil society failure (defined in       project funds in productive
chapter 2). A group might be unable to act collectively, or collective        activities.
action could occur in a well-coordinated but dysfunctional manner that

                                                                                                          115
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     reduces the welfare of the average citizen (as in the case, for example,
                                     of an organized fringe group that uses terror and violence to further its
                                     extremist ends at high social cost).
     When civic participation is        When is civic participation likely to be the best answer to government
  likely to be the best solution     and market failures, and when is it not? The answers are deeply con-
     to government and market        textual, fundamentally conditioned by social structures and historical
 failures, and when it is not, is    trajectories, and different for every community. A policy that works in
          highly contextual. . . .   one village may fail miserably in another. Moreover, as effective collective
                                     action depends on the cooperative infrastructure provided by a strong
                                     state, it is not at all clear that strong civil society creates strong govern-
. . . and thus best determined       ments; the reality is more complex and nuanced. Similarly, although
     by turning to the evidence.     empowering civic groups may often lead to good outcomes, doing so is
                                     not always superior to a pure market-based strategy for raising incomes
                                     or to a strategy that strengthens the role of central bureaucrats to,
                                     say, improve social services. Keeping this in mind, the decision about
                                     whether, when, and how to promote local participation should be made
                                     with an understanding of the tradeoffs involved in moving decisions to
                                     local communities—in a particular country, within a particular region
                                     in a country, and at a particular time.
                                        Theorizing and thinking through the conceptual foundations of
                                     these questions can yield important insights, but several open questions
                                     are best answered by examining the evidence. When does participation
                                     work, and when does it fail to achieve specific objectives? How impor-
                                     tant is capture? Does handing over large sums of money to community
                                     groups empower the poor, or do elites use it to enrich themselves? What
                                     mechanisms are most effective in improving the capacity for collective
                                     action and building social capital? What methods reduce civic inequal-
                                     ity and elite capture and truly empower the poor? Do participatory
                                     projects result in choices that are better aligned with people’s prefer-
                                     ences? Does fostering participation enhance social cohesion? Does it
                                     strengthen civil society? Does it produce more resilient and inclusive
                                     local institutions? To what extent does group heterogeneity and illit-
                                     eracy affect the quality of participation? Does participation improve
                                     development outcomes at the local level? Does it help the sustainable
                                     management of local resources? Chapters 4–6 provide a broad and com-
                                     prehensive review of the evidence on these and many related questions.
                                        For the reasons outlined in chapter 1, the focus of the review of
                                     the evidence is on large-scale participatory projects that have been



116
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



evaluated based on representative samples of target populations with
good counterfactuals—studies that have a valid control group for the
communities targeted (or “treated”) by the intervention. Generally
speaking, this means that the findings come from econometric analysis,
although some well-designed qualitative research is examined to inform
the results.



Notes
1. Needs can be unlimited, however. Normative theories of fiscal federal-
   ism and decentralization consequently pay equal attention to the budget
   constraints associated with financing expenditure and the tax assignments
   of federal and local jurisdictions. Although these fundamental issues on
   the supply side of decentralization are not the focus of this report, they are
   important to keep in mind.
2. The World Bank and the U.S. Agency for International Development
   (USAID) have been leading champions of this new emphasis on fighting
   corruption. See the World Development Report 2004 (World Bank 2004)
   on the effect of corruption on service delivery
3. Tanzi and Davoodi (1997) show that corruption can reduce public revenue
   and increase income inequality by allowing well-positioned individuals to
   benefit unduly from government programs intended for the poor.
4. Myerson (1993) and Persson, Roland, and Tabellini (1997) provide the-
   retical arguments for the relationship between political institutions and
   corruption. Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006) provide a good overview of
   the conceptual literature on the relationship between decentralization and
   corruption and review much of the empirical evidence.
5. Bernard and others (2008) find evidence on the proliferation of community
   organizations in Burkina Faso and Senegal that appears to be consistent
   with this hypothesis. They report a dramatic growth in both market- and
   community-oriented village organizations over the two-decade period
   between the early 1980s, when participatory approaches first became popu-
   lar popularity, to about 2002. In Burkina Faso, where 22 percent of sample
   villages had village organizations in 1982, 91 percent had at least one vil-
   lage organization by 2002; in Senegal, where 10 percent of sample villages
   had at least one village organization in 1982, the figure rose to 65 percent.
   Household participation in village organizations also rose dramatically,
   with 57 percent of households in Burkina Faso and 69 percent in Senegal
   participating in at least one village organization. However, one-fifth of all
   registered organizations had not undertaken any activity by the time of the
   survey, and among those that had, most members reported that the proj-
   ects undertaken were either incomplete or had not yielded any significant
   benefits.



                                                                                                  117
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?




                          References
                          Acemoglu, D., and J. A. Robinson. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and
                              Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.
                          Appadurai, A. 2004. “The Capacity to Aspire: Culture and the Terms of
                              Recognition.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton,
                              59–84. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
                          Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2006. Decentralization and Governance in
                              Developing Countries. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
                          Basu, K. 2011. Beyond the Invisible Hand: Groundwork for a New Economics.
                              Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
                          Bernard, T., M.-H. Collion, A. De Janvry, P. Rondot, and E. Sadoulet.
                              2008. “Do Village Organizations Make a Difference in African Rural
                              Development? A Study for Senegal and Burkina Faso.” World Development
                              36(11): 2188–204.
                          Cai, H., and D. Treisman. 2004. “State Corroding Federalism.” Journal of
                              Public Economics 88(3–4): 819–43.
                          Comaroff, J., and J. Comaroff. 1999. Civil Society and Political Imagination in
                              Africa. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
                          Cooke, B., and U. Kothari. 2001. Participation: The New Tyranny? London:
                              Zed Books.
                          Elster, J. 1989. Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences. Cambridge, U.K.:
                              Cambridge University Press.
                          Evans, P. 2004. “Development as Institutional Change: The Pitfalls of
                              Monocropping and the Potentials of Deliberation.” Studies in Comparative
                              International Development 38(4): 30–52.
                          Fung, A., and E. O. Wright. 2003. “Thinking about Empowered Participatory
                              Governance.” In Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in
                              Empowered Participatory Governance, ed. A. Fung and E. O. Wright,
                              3–42. New York: Verso.
                          Gibson, C., and M. Woolcock. 2008. “Empowerment, Deliberative Development
                              and Local Level Politics in Indonesia: Participatory Projects as a Source of
                              Countervailing Power.” Studies in Comparative International Development
                              2(43): 151–80.
                          Harriss, J. 2001. Depoliticizing Development: The World Bank and Social
                              Capital. New Delhi: LeftWord.
                          Henkel, H., and R. Stirrat. 2001. “Participation as Spiritual Duty; Empowerment
                              as Secular Subjection.” In Participation: The New Tyranny? ed. B. Cooke
                              and U. Kothari, 168–84. London: Zed Books.
                          Hirschman, A. O. 1970. Exit Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms,
                              Organizations and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
                          Hoff, K., and J. E. Stiglitz. 2001. “Modern Economic Theory and
                              Development.” In Frontiers of Development Economics, ed. G. Meier and
                              J. Stiglitz, 389–459. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.
                          Khan, M. H. 2002. “Corruption and Governance in Early Capitalism: World
                              Bank Strategies and Their Limitations.” In Reinventing the World Bank,



118
THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION



    ed. J. Pincus and J. Winters, 164–84. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
    Press.
Koopmans, R. 2007. “Protest in Time and Space: The Evolution of Waves of
    Contention.” In The Blackwell Companion to Social Movements, ed. D. A.
    Snow, S. A. Soule, and H. Kriesi, 19–46. New York: Blackwell.
Kriesi, H. 2007. “Political Context and Opportunity.” In The Blackwell
    Companion to Social Movements, ed. D. A. Snow, S. A. Soule, and
    H. Kriesi, 67–90. New York: Blackwell.
Levy, B., and F. Fukuyama. 2010. Development Strategies: Integrating
    Governance and Growth. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Menes, R. 2003. “Corruption in Cities: Graft and Politics in American Cities
    at the Turn of the Twentieth Century.” NBER Working Paper 9990,
    National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Migdal, J. S. 1988. Strong Societies and Weak States: State-Society Relations and
    State Capabilities in the Third World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
    Press.
Mosse, D. 2005. Cultivating Development: An Ethnography of Aid Policy and
    Practice. London: Pluto Press.
Myerson, R. B. 1993. “Effectiveness of Electoral Systems for Reducing
    Government Corruption: A Game-Theoretic Analysis.” Games and
    Economic Behavior 5(1): 118–32.
Oates, W. 1972. Fiscal Federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Persson, T., G. Roland, and G. Tabellini. 1997. “Separation of Powers
    and Political Accountability.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4):
    1163–202.
Rao, V., and P. Sanyal. 2010. “Dignity through Discourse: Poverty and the
    Culture of Deliberation in Indian Village Democracies.” Annals of the
    American Academy of Political and Social Science 629(May): 146–72.
Rondinelli, D. A., J. S. Mccullough, and R. W. Johnson. 1989. “Analyzing
    Decentralization Policies in Developing-Countries: A Political-Economy
    Framework.” Development and Change 20(1): 57–87.
Rose-Ackerman, S. 2008. “Corruption and Government.” International
    Peacekeeping 15(3): 328–43.
Scott, J. 1990. Domination and the Art of Resistance: Hidden Transcripts. New
    Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Tanzi, V., and H. Davoodi. 1997. “Corruption, Public Investment, and
    Growth.” IMF Working Paper 97/139, International Monetary Fund,
    Washington, DC.
Warren, M. E. 1995. “The Self in Discursive Democracy.” In The Cambridge
    Companion to Habermas, ed. S. K. White, 167–200. Cambridge, U.K.:
    Cambridge University Press.
Woolcock, M. 2009. “Towards a Plurality of Methods in Project Evaluation:
    A Contextualized Approach to Understanding Impact Trajectories and
    Efficacy.” Journal of Development Effectiveness 1(1): 1–14.
World Bank. 2004. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for
    Poor People. Washington, DC: World Bank.



                                                                                                  119
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
CHAPTER FOUR




How Important
Is Capture?

A KEY ASSUMPTION UNDERLYING SUPPORT FOR PARTICIPATORY
programs and local decentralization is that they increase the involve-
ment of the poor and the marginalized in local decision making,
thereby enhancing “voice” and reducing capture and corruption. How
empirically grounded are these assumptions?
   This chapter attempts to answer this question. It first examines
whether the real worry should be corruption narrowly defined or more
routine and legal forms of rent-seeking, including clientelism. It then
reviews the evidence for elite capture in participatory programs and
discusses potential implications for the inclusion and empowerment
objectives of such programs. The next two sections look at the impact
of democratic decentralization on the behavior of local political agents.
The last section summarizes the broad lessons that emerge from the
evidence.
   Theorists have written a good deal on local accountability in the
context of political decentralization; the body of empirical literature is
also large. This chapter does not attempt to do justice to either body
of research. Instead, it uses the literature somewhat selectively to frame
the questions that are most relevant to understanding the “demand
side” of local governance and to highlight the empirical studies that
have informed this debate. Attention is confined, for the most part, to
empirical studies of developing countries.




                                                                             121
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?




                                      Corruption and Local Accountability
Corruption adds substantially         Corruption—defined narrowly as theft, graft, and bribes—has come
 to the cost of providing basic       to be viewed as a major threat to development.1 It adds substantially
public goods and services . . .       to the cost of providing basic public goods and services; dampens the
                                      redistributive objectives of poverty-reduction programs; and, perhaps
                                      worst of all, changes the incentives both citizens and public officials
                                      face. Reducing corruption through legal and financial reforms is rarely
           . . . it can also change
                                      an option. Instead, most international donor organizations, notably
      the incentives citizens and
                                      the World Bank and the U.S. Agency for International Development
              public officials face.
                                      (USAID), have come to see decentralization and civic engagement as
                                      an alternative route to increasing accountability in both the public and
                                      private sphere.
      Civic engagement is often           The view that decentralization is needed to combat corruption is
        seen as key to reducing       not unchallenged. Some observers argue that decentralization could
                     corruption.      increase opportunities for theft, bribes, and graft.2 There is also a con-
                                      cern that devolution could simply shift the form of rent-seeking from
                                      outright theft and graft to other, more pernicious and ostensibly legal,
                                      avenues of resource capture. In the extreme, both equity and efficiency
                                      could decline as a result, even as measured levels of corruption fall. Too
                                      sharp a focus on corruption defined narrowly can divert attention from
                                      the true welfare cost of rent-seeking under decentralized resource alloca-
                                      tion, particularly where there are significant opportunities for capture
                                      by local elites. Bardhan (2002) and Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006a)
                                      advocate a broader view that includes all types of political corruption,
                                      in addition to theft, bribes, and graft.3 The literature on corruption is
                                      reviewed here with these concerns in mind.
                                          Only a few studies examine the relationship between decentralized
                                      resource allocation and the level of corruption. This literature includes
                                      a series of papers using cross-country data that by and large argue that
                                      corruption tends to be lower in countries that are more decentralized,
                                      but only when local governments face “hard budget constraints” (that
                                      is, rely less on fiscal transfers from the center and more on their own
                                      revenues).4 For example, Estache and Sinha (1995) report a positive
                                      association between expenditure decentralization and levels of infra-
                                      structure provided by local governments, but only when both revenue
                                      generation and expenditure responsibilities are decentralized.
                                          Fisman and Gatti (2002a, 2002b) find similar results. Using data
                                      from the United States for 1976–87, they report a positive correlation

122
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



between a state’s dependence on fiscal transfers from the center and
convictions for abuse of state public office (Fisman and Gatti 2002a).
In a second study, based on cross-country data for 1980–95, they find
a negative association between expenditure decentralization and per-
ceived corruption (Fisman and Gatti 2002b). However, both studies
are plagued with problems of potential reverse causality and unobserved
heterogeneity across the units of analysis, making the results difficult
to interpret.
   Using roughly the same sample of countries over the same time
period as Fisman and Gatti (2002b), Treisman (2007) shows that the
key result in their study is sensitive to the set of controls used. The
negative association between expenditure decentralization and corrup-
tion (using a range of measures of both) disappears once an additional
control, the proportion of Protestants in the population, is added.
Apparently, countries with more Protestants tend to be both less corrupt
and more decentralized.5
   The metric of corruption used in these studies is also problematic.        The use of perception data
For the most part, country-level corruption measures are either aggre-        to measure corruption
gated from corruption perception surveys or derived from country-risk         may be more warranted in
analyses. Most studies that compare perception data with data on the          low-corruption than high-
actual incidence of corruption find that perception data correlate poorly      corruption settings.
with the actual incidence of corruption, however defined.6 They also
find that perceptions may be sensitive to the absolute level of corrup-
tion, as measured by the number of occurrences, rather than just relative
corruption levels. Thus, perceptions of corruption tend to be greater in
larger countries. The relationship between perceptions of corruption
and absolute and relative corruption levels weakens as levels of corrup-
tion rise. The use of perception data may therefore be more warranted
in low-corruption than high-corruption settings.
   More recent cross-country studies attempt to overcome some of these        Decentralization can increase
problems by using a more objective metric of corruption. Fan, Lin, and        opportunities for corruption.
Treisman (2009) examine how political decentralization affects the
odds of bribe extraction by corrupt officials. They attempt to rectify the
problems with perception data by combining a cross-country data set on
decentralization with a firm-level survey conducted in 80 countries that
provides information on the experiences of firms with graft and bribes.
Their results suggest that decentralization can increase opportunities for
corruption when the number of tiers of public employees increases, par-
ticularly when governments are also strapped for funds and public sector

                                                                                                           123
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   employees are poorly paid and have few resources. Overall, their results
                                   suggest that as the complexity of governance structures and the number
                                   of tiers increases, as it does under decentralization, there is a danger of
                                   more uncoordinated rent-seeking and higher net levels of corruption.7
                                      By and large, however, attention has moved to within-country analy-
                                   ses that use more carefully constructed data and objective measures
                                   of corruption. This newer body of literature also attempts to identify
                                   causal effects by focusing on specific policy shifts, such as audits,
                                   increased monitoring, a change in access to information, or variation
                                   in the political incentives of incumbents, which allow for a clearer
                                   analysis of the relationship between decentralized resource allocation
                                   and corruption.8
                                      This literature has produced some important insights. Studies con-
                                   fi rm substantial levels of graft and theft in decentralized programs
                                   (although few compare levels of corruption with and without decen-
                                   tralization). They also highlight the potential risks of incomplete and
                                   differential access to information. In particular, they find that opportu-
                                   nities for corruption are greater when some individuals or communities
                                   are less well placed to benefit from information. This literature also
                                   underscores the manifold constraints that communities—particularly
                                   those which are poorer, more remote, and more unequal—face in moni-
                                   toring and sanctioning corrupt officials or service providers.
Corruption tends to be higher         Overall, the evidence suggests that corruption tends to be higher in
  in remote communities that       remote communities that have low education levels and low exposure
have low education levels and      to media—qualities that tend to be positively correlated with poverty
   low exposure to media . . .     and inequality—and that within such communities, the costs of cor-
                                   ruption are higher for the poor. Perhaps more surprisingly, interventions
                                   from the center appear to constrain corrupt local practices—particu-
          . . . and within such    larly when they augment citizen “voice” at the local level by increasing
      communities, the costs       information on resource flows through well-publicized audits or media
      of corruption are higher     campaigns. On balance, therefore, there appears to be little reason to be
                   for the poor.   sanguine about community-based monitoring or information provision
                                   in the absence of a strong reform-minded center, an active and indepen-
                                   dent media, and highly able communities.
      The center can constrain        Reinikka and Svensson (2004, 2005, 2007) examine the extent of
     corrupt local practices by    corruption in the allocation of public resources for education in Uganda
    augmenting citizen “voice”     during the 1990s. They study a large government program that pro-
through advertised audits and      vided grants to primary schools to cover their nonwage expenditures.
            media campaigns.       The program was managed by the central government but used district

124
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



offices as distribution channels. Their measure of corruption is the
difference between disbursed flows from the central government to
lower tiers of government and the resources actually received by final
beneficiaries. The data come from a public expenditure tracking survey.
   Reinikka and Svensson (2004) show that primary schools in Uganda          Local officials and politicians
received only 13 percent of the grants allocated to them for nonwage         captured 87 percent of the
expenditures; local officials and politicians captured the rest. The allo-    grants allocated to primary
cation of the amounts that did reach schools was also quite regressive.      schools in Uganda for
Schools in the poorest communities fared worst, obtaining significantly       nonwage expenditures.
smaller shares of their entitlements.9 A benefit incidence analysis of
the program, conducted in 1996 by the World Bank, found that the
poorest quintile received about as much as the richest quintile. This
finding highlights the difficulty of using benefit incidence analysis to
understand the distributional impact of public spending when allocated
expenditure rather than actual spending is used. It also highlights the
potential for local capture to completely undo and even reverse the
redistributive goals of poverty reduction programs.
   Reinikka and Svensson (2007) examine the extent to which infor-
mation on the flow of funds can restrain corruption. In response to
the enormous leakage of funds found in the first public expenditure
tracking survey, the central government initiated a campaign in which
national newspapers, including their local language editions, began pub-
lishing the monthly transfer of capitation grants to districts. Reinikka
and Svensson show that schools that were closer to newspaper outlets
managed to claim a significantly larger part of their entitlement after
the newspaper campaign was initiated and that head teachers in such
schools were also more knowledgeable of the rules governing the grant
program as well as the timing of fund release by the central government.
They also find significant increases in enrollment and student learning
outcomes following the information campaign (Reinikka and Svensson
2005), with much larger effects for schools located near newspaper
outlets.
    Bjorkman (2006) confirms these results. Using district-level data,
she finds that districts that were more exposed to the newspaper cam-
paign obtained a larger share of their allocated budget and had substan-
tially greater increases in student test scores.
   Francken, Minten, and Swinnen (2009) use a measure of corrup-
tion similar to the one Reinikka and Svensson (2005) use to examine
the impact of media on the local capture of public education funds in

                                                                                                        125
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     Madagascar. They find very little evidence of capture in resource flows
                                     from the center, where the education bureaucracy was closely moni-
                                     tored, to the district. In contrast, they observe significant levels of cap-
                                     ture at the district level, with capture increasing with distance from the
                                     center. These results point to the importance of central monitoring for
                                     accountability at the local level. The study also finds a strong negative
                                     effect of media access on corruption, with substantially larger negative
                                     effects in more educated communities, which were presumably better
                                     able to use information on budgets to monitor providers. In line with
                                     earlier findings on capture, the authors note that the misappropriation
                                     of funds was greater in districts in which the program director was a
                                     member of the local elite or had a lower level of education.
 Relative to the better-off, the        Shankar, Gaiha, and Jha (2010) highlight the risk of differential
     poor had less and worse-        information access in their study of India’s National Rural Employment
 quality information on India’s      Guarantee Scheme (NREGS). This targeted workfare program was
   National Rural Employment         launched with a nationwide effort to disseminate information through
 Guarantee Scheme and were           the media and through village-level meetings organized by the local
 less likely to participate in it.   government. The program has been plagued with problems of resource
                                     misappropriation, including the fudging of muster rolls, the manipula-
                                     tion of wages, and outright bribe-taking by local officials. Survey data
                                     reveal that the nonpoor had more and better-quality information on the
                                     program and were also more likely to participate. Better-informed par-
                                     ticipants were also more likely to obtain the full benefits of the program
                                     in terms of wages, the timing of payment, and hours worked. Poorer
                                     participants were more likely to report having paid bribes. This finding
                                     is particularly important given concerns about the level of corruption
                                     in this program.10
          An intensive top-down         Few studies assess the relative effectiveness of bottom-up and
       audit reduced corruption      top-down anticorruption interventions. The best study is by Olken
        as measured by missing       (2007), who reports the results of a field experiment conducted in vil-
               expenditures . . .    lages supported by the Kecamatan Development Program (KDP) in
                                     Indonesia, which builds local infrastructure using a community-driven
                                     development approach. The experiment assessed the relative effective-
      . . . but it appears to have   ness of community-based versus external monitoring of KDP road
             increased nepotism.     construction projects by inducing random variation in the mechanism
                                     by which corruption could be detected. A subset of study villages was
                                     assigned to the bottom-up intervention, in which citizens were encour-
                                     aged to participate in village-level meetings at which project officials
                                     documented their expenses in relation to the use of public funds for the

126
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



construction of local roads; a second subset was assigned to the top-
down intervention, in which villages were informed that road construc-
tion expenses would be closely monitored by local officials. The odds
of an audit in this group were 100 percent. In the control villages, the
usual process of government audit was expected; the odds of an audit
were about 4 percent. The study finds that intensive top-down audits
reduced missing expenditures on materials and wages by about 8 per-
centage points. In contrast, grassroots monitoring reduced only missing
wage expenditures. Given the larger budget share of nonwage expen-
ditures, the overall impact of community monitoring was negligible.
   These results suggest that community monitoring may be con-
strained, for several reasons. There may be freeriding, in the sense that
community members may be unwilling to monitor providers when
benefits are largely nonexcludable (as they are for roads), or they may be
unable to detect corruption when the activity entails technical inputs.
Although the study cannot separate out these channels, the fact that
villagers were able to detect missing wage payments but appear to have
had a harder time knowing how much of any construction input was
actually used in the road suggests that capacity constraints are likely to
be at least part of the story.
   Although the intensive top-down audit reduced corruption as mea-
sured by missing expenditures, it appears to have increased nepotism.
Relatives of members of the implementation committee, including the
village leader, were significantly more likely to be hired, suggesting the
need for a broader view inclusive of all types of political corruption, in
line with Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006a).
   The level of resource capture that should be considered problematic is
somewhat fuzzy. The pursuit of a policy designed primarily to minimize
corruption may make little sense if there are other, possibly conflicting,
policy goals (see Mookherjee 1997; Waller, Verdier, and Gardner 2002).
The key issue, therefore, may not be whether decentralization elimi-
nates capture but rather how large the implied efficiency and equity
losses are and the extent to which they attenuate the poverty reduction
agendas of development projects.
   Olken’s (2006) study of losses in Indonesia’s subsidized rice program
(Operasi Pasar Khusus [OPK]) is instructive in this regard. The pro-
gram allowed eligible households to purchase up to 20 kilograms of rice
a month. Roughly half of rural households were eligible to participate,
and the implied subsidy was significant.11 About 18 percent of the rice

                                                                                                   127
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                 went missing, and ineligible households purchased a large amount of
                                 OPK rice. Much of the corruption was concentrated in a small fraction
                                 of villages, most of which were located in the most corrupt districts.12
                                 One-half to two-thirds of total program benefits were lost to corruption
                                 and mistargeting, making the project welfare reducing in net terms.
                                 What is perhaps most interesting is that losses from mistargeting far
 A narrow focus on corruption    outweighed losses from outright corruption.
           may miss the larger      These results highlight the point that a focus on corruption defined
 problems of resource capture    narrowly as outright theft, bribes, or graft may miss the larger problems
     through rent-seeking and    of resource capture through other, often legal, forms of rent-seeking
    resource losses caused by    or resource losses caused by the poor implementation and monitoring
     poor implementation and     capacity of project staff or community members. This issue is examined
          monitoring capacity.   in the sections that follow.



                                 Participation and Resource Allocation in Induced
                                 Community-Driven Development Programs
                                 A small number of studies have looked carefully at who participates
                                 in organizations formed by community-driven development projects.
                                 Overall, the evidence suggests that participants tend to be dispropor-
                                 tionately from wealthier, more educated, and more politically connected
                                 households. They also tend to belong to ethnic or tribal groups that
                                 enjoy higher status. In Bolivia and Burkina Faso, wealthier households
                                 were not only more likely to be active in local associations; they also had
                                 more memberships per household. In Indonesia, poorer and less edu-
                                 cated households tended to participate less; the wealthiest also spent less
                                 time and money on community organizations, suggesting an inverted
                                 U-shape in participation (Grootaert, Oh, and Swamy 2002).13
   Participants in community        Burkina Faso and Senegal reveal a similar pattern of exclusion
      organizations tend to be   (Arcand and Fafchamps 2012). Arcand and Fafchamps find little evi-
       disproportionately from   dence that community organizations created by donor-sponsored proj-
wealthier, more educated, and    ects are more inclusive than other community groups. On the contrary,
   more politically connected    they find that members of externally funded community organizations
                  households.    were more likely to be older and to have more land wealth.
                                    Elite dominance is also evident in Indonesia’s Second Urban Poverty
                                 Project (UPP2), which provided one-time allocations to support
                                 implementation of community development plans through access to
                                 credit, mobilization of community members, and financing of small

128
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



infrastructure. Pradhan, Rao, and Rosenberg (2009) find that groups
managing fund allocation decisions were more likely to have members
who were educated, affluent, politically connected, and male; while
members of groups implementing funded projects, were more likely to
be less affluent, less educated, and female.
   In rural Pakistan, villagers who belong to community organizations         Participation by poor
supported by the Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund (PPAF) are far             and low-caste residents
more likely to own land than villagers who do not belong (Mansuri             is lower in more unequal
2012b). They are also significantly more likely to have some schooling         communities . . .
and to belong to households that are connected to traditional village
leaders and local politicians. On average, community organization
members have twice as much land as nonmembers and almost one
additional year of schooling. However, village characteristics matter. In     . . . and higher in communities
villages with a larger fraction of household heads with some schooling,       with above-average levels of
landlessness is less of a barrier to community organization membership.       education.
Conversely, in more unequal villages, lower-caste households are less
likely to belong to a community organization, although this discour-
agement effect is dampened as the proportion of low-caste households
in the village rises.14
   One explanation for elite dominance in participatory bodies may be         The mere fact that
that members of a society who are well endowed, whether in wealth or          participants at the community
ability, may be the only ones who possess the requisite resources, capa-      level are from the elite may
bilities, and leisure to represent their community’s interests. Educated      not be sufficient evidence
community members may also be best placed to articulate community             of capture.
demands with external actors and facilitate the application procedures
projects require. Better-educated people may also be more altruistic as
leaders and thus less likely to engage in resource misappropriation of all
types. On the other hand, the most disadvantaged may be least able to
spare the time or resources needed for participatory decision making.
They may also be least equipped to deal with its technical demands. In
sum, the mere fact that participants at the community level are from
the elite may not be sufficient evidence of capture: by virtue of their
education, exposure, networks, and greater leisure time, members of
the elite may have both the ability and the willingness to effectively
represent the community.
   These findings raise several important questions. Does the identity
of participants in community-based organizations affect the allocation
of resources for intended beneficiaries? Can participatory programs
serve their empowerment and inclusion objectives if participation itself

                                                                                                         129
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  is not democratized? These questions are particularly important if not
                                  all spending on public goods and services benefits the poor equally.
                                  Investments in primary schooling, basic health facilities, and safe drink-
                                  ing water are likely to yield larger benefits for poorer households than
                                  investments in higher education and hospitals. Investments in public
                                  irrigation systems may be even more exclusionary, because only people
                                  who own land may be well placed to benefit from higher productivity
                                  and higher land values.
  In Jamaica, better-educated         The first set of studies examined looks at the extent to which com-
 and better-networked people      munity level projects funded by social funds or community-driven
     were more likely to obtain   development programs are well aligned with the stated priorities of the
   projects that matched their    poor or other disadvantaged groups, including women. Rao and Ibanez
                  preferences.    (2005) look at this issue using retrospective data from survey respon-
                                  dents in communities funded by the Jamaica Social Investment Fund.
                                  They find that the match between the projects funded and the prefer-
                                  ences of community members was poor overall. In only two of the five
                                  communities studied did the project match the preferences of a majority
                                  in the community. Overall, better-educated and better-networked peo-
                                  ple were more likely to obtain projects that matched their preferences.
                                  Some 80 percent of respondents nevertheless reported satisfaction with
                                  the project. The authors argue that this high level of satisfaction may
                                  reflect “benevolent” capture, in which the elite are best informed about
                                  true community needs, feasible projects, or both and act altruistically
                                  to obtain benefits for their communities.
                                      Dasgupta and Beard (2007) find similar results in their study of the
                                  performance of community development boards in Indonesia’s Urban
                                  Poverty Project (UPP). Communities were selected for this case study
                                  in part because they had high levels of social cohesion, as measured by
                                  the authors. The authors find that community development boards that
                                  were dominated by elite groups delivered more benefits to the poor, who
                                  fared much worse under apparently more egalitarian community devel-
                                  opment boards. Based on their findings, they argue that elite control
                                  over local decision making must be distinguished from elite capture.
                                      Other researchers argue that even when it induces no change in
                                  selected projects, the deliberative process creates a sense of satisfaction
                                  and legitimacy, because people like to be consulted, even when the
                                  consultative process does not yield a change in resource allocation.15
                                  Olken (2007) examines whether observed project choice in Indonesia
                                  reflects, in part, the underlying participatory mechanism adopted by

130
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



the KDP program. To test this hypothesis, he randomized the final
project selection method across villages. In one group, projects were
selected publicly, at a village meeting; in the other, they were chosen
by secret ballot. The list of proposed projects was subject to an earlier
process of selection about which little is known, except that village elites
were in attendance during their selection. The study finds no impact of
the political mechanism on project choice, despite high turnout in the
election and sparse attendance at the village meeting, which attracted
mainly the village and supra-village elite.
   However, the election mechanism increased satisfaction with the pro-         The deliberative process may
posed project, even though there was no change in the project selected.         create a sense of satisfaction
Olken argues that this finding may indicate a preference for greater             and legitimacy, even when it
participation; specifically more equitable participation may have a nor-         does not yield a change in
mative aspect, creating greater satisfaction as well as greater “buy-in” for    resource allocation.
the policies and choices adopted regardless of the impact on substantive
outcomes. A potential problem with this interpretation is that given the
balloting process, village residents would also have needed more infor-
mation ex ante on the set of projects proposed in order to vote on them.
The study cannot separately identify the potential impact of information
and voting on satisfaction. What it does indicate is that a considerable
level of exclusion is possible in the type of deliberative process that
community-driven development projects typically employ. In this case,
village and supra-village elites dominated the initial process of selecting
the menu of projects on which the rest of the community could vote.
   These limitations notwithstanding, this set of studies suggests that
evidence of elite influence need not indicate malevolent intent. For one
thing, the preferences of nonelite groups could change as a result of
community deliberation over the use of funds, particularly if they are
initially less informed about the feasibility or potential benefits of spe-
cific projects. If this is the case, what appears to be capture could well
reflect a more altruistic or benevolent process, with local elites taking
the lead in advocating for public goods that the community most needs
and acting as intermediaries between the implementing agency and the
beneficiary community. Some observers argue that this is indeed what
often happens. The projects finally selected are often the projects that
best serve the needs of the most disadvantaged in the community, even
though they were not initially proposed by them. White (2002) notes,
for example, that the disproportionate number of schools and health
facilities funded by social funds reflects the preferences of the “prime

                                                                                                           131
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   movers” behind these projects, who are often school teachers or health
                                   workers.
         Community facilitators’       Platteau and Gaspart (2003), among others, take a very different
        preferences may heavily    position. They argue that any assessment that elicits community prefer-
      influence the deliberation    ences ex post may not reveal much about the extent of elite capture or
                       process.    corruption in the use of funds, because poor villagers may be unable or
                                   unwilling to express reservations about the funded project, or the role
                                   of the elite, for fear of repercussions or loss of resources. They suggest
                                   that community facilitators often play an influential role in the process
                                   of project selection, that facilitator preferences are likely to heavily
                                   influence the deliberation process, and that it is these preferences, as
                                   much as the preferences of prime movers within the community, that
                                   are reflected in project proposals (see also Murphy 1990; Mohan and
                                   Stokke 2000).
                                       Separating these issues is difficult in practice. Doing so requires data
                                   on the projects specific groups or individuals prefer before and after any
                                   deliberative process; the facilitation and deliberation process within
                                   communities; the preferences of facilitators; the location of projects,
                                   proposed and selected; and the identity of beneficiaries. In practice, the
                                   data collected on preferences, process, project location, and beneficiaries
                                   tend to be fairly coarse. Most studies ask questions about the top three
                                   needs of the community or its main problems, without reference to a
                                   budget; the expected cost share for beneficiaries; or, most critically, proj-
                                   ect location. Survey respondents may thus state that upgrading roads or
                                   drinking water sources in the community is a priority, but it is unclear
                                   which road or drinking water source they wish to upgrade. It is rarely
                                   the case, however, that a “community” inhabits an area small and cohe-
                                   sive enough to allow everyone to benefit equally from all infrastructure
                                   investments. In most cases, roads, drinking water schemes, and irriga-
                                   tion channels are provided to specific neighborhoods or habitations, and
                                   location determines who benefits. Data on the nature of the facilitation
                                   process or its role in modifying or shaping preferences are even rarer.
                                       In line with the concerns of critics like Platteau and Gaspart (2003),
                                   recent experimental work by Humphreys, Masters, and Sandbu (2006)
                                   finds that facilitator preferences significantly predict the choices of par-
                                   ticipants in consultative meetings. They use data from a national forum
                                   held in São Tomé and Príncipe to discuss policy issues related to the use
                                   of newly discovered oil reserves. About 5 percent of the adult population
                                   attended small group meetings, whose leaders were randomly assigned.

132
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



Groups led by women were more likely than groups led by men to pri-
oritize investments in local health clinics over hospitals. Unlike groups
led by men, they also preferred investments in improving transportation
services rather than investments in improving roads and expanding
road networks. They were also more likely to accept higher taxation of
windfall earnings and to opt for saving rather than spending windfalls.
Furthermore, groups led by older adults were more likely than groups
led by younger people to emphasize health as a national priority and to
favor commercial transport over passenger transport and better roads
over public transportation services. Meetings led by women and older
people also reached much higher levels of consensus than meetings led
by men and younger people.
   The only published study that has collected ex ante preference data         One study finds substantial
for public good projects is Labonne and Chase (2009). They find sub-            evidence of capture by
stantial evidence of capture by local leaders at the project proposal stage    local leaders at the project
but only in more unequal villages with a less politically active popula-       proposal stage . . .
tion. Local leaders in such villages, they find, exercise greater influence
over resource allocation at meetings at the supra-village level, where
proposed projects are approved.
   Gugerty and Kremer (2008) take a different approach. They look              . . . but only in more unequal
at the impact of a participatory agricultural project in rural Kenya on        villages with a less politically
group membership and agricultural productivity. The project provided           active population.
leadership training and agricultural inputs to small self-help organiza-
tions, most of whose members were poor women with little education.
The project spent $674 per group, or an average of $34 per member,
half of which was allocated to agricultural inputs, which were provided
to the group as a whole. As the typical comparison group had $243
in assets before the project started, this spending represented a large
increase in the group’s capital stock.16 The study finds that the groups
selected for the intervention were far more likely to attract new members
and that new members were also likely to be more educated, to have
formal sector income, and to take over group leadership positions.17
Moreover, although exit rates were similar in program and comparison
groups, more members left the program groups because of intragroup
conflicts. Older female members, who were among the most vulnerable,
were also disproportionately more likely to leave.
   In sum, the program appears to have unleashed a process in which
group membership and leadership moved into the hands of younger
and better-educated women. It also induced the entry of more men and

                                                                                                            133
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



 A rapid increase in resources    more efforts on the part of government officials to build links to the
    may serve only to increase    groups. However, despite the large injection of funds, the project yielded
                     exclusion.   unimpressive gains in agricultural productivity. The authors conjecture
                                  that a rapid increase in resources may serve only to increase exclusion.
                                      In a somewhat similar vein, Mansuri (2012a) compares the distribu-
                                  tion of beneficiaries of village level infrastructure projects built by a
                                  participatory program and projects built by government line depart-
                                  ments in the same villages and at comparable size and cost (see chapter
                                  5 for a fuller discussion of this study). She finds that benefits from the
                                  participatory project were no better distributed than benefits from the
                                  relevant government project and that the share of the landless, the poor,
                                  and people from low castes was far below their population share in both
                                  cases. Moreover, investment in the most excludable schemes—irriga-
                                  tion channels—tended to be the least pro-poor. Beneficiaries were also
                                  far more likely to be members of a community organization, and as
                                  discussed above, members of community organizations were far more
                                  likely to be drawn from people with land wealth, education, or political
                                  networks.
  Local inequality may reduce         Another way to assess whether capture is benevolent is to determine
   the odds that a community      whether community characteristics affect the allocation of resources.
   selects a pro-poor project.    Araujo and others (2008) assess the relationship between community
                                  inequality and the odds of selecting a more pro-poor excludable project
                                  in Ecuador’s social fund. They find that local inequality significantly
                                  reduced the odds that a community selected a pro-poor project. They
                                  also find that the impact of inequality on project choice was amplified
                                  in communities that had a larger share of indigenous households, sug-
                                  gesting that ethno-linguistic heterogeneity can exacerbate capture by
                                  local elites.18
                                      Community inequality can also reduce access to private transfers.
      Community inequality can    Galasso and Ravallion (2005) find that greater land inequality signifi-
       reduce access to private   cantly worsened targeting in the program in Bangladesh that they stud-
                     transfers.   ied. They also find that targeting was less effective in remote and isolated
                                  villages. Bardhan, Mookherjee and Torrado (2010) find that villages with
                                  greater land inequality allocate a significantly smaller share of private
                                  benefits to scheduled castes and tribes. Shankar, Gaiha, and Jha (2010)
                                  find that poor and low-caste households are considerably less likely
                                  to participate in the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme
                                  (NREGS) program in Indian villages with greater wealth inequality.



134
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



    Conning and Kevane (2002) identify some of these patterns in a review
of community-based targeting that focuses on the tradeoff between bet-
ter information and local capture. They conclude that communities are
more effective than outside agencies in targeting programs to the poor
only when they are relatively egalitarian, have open and transparent sys-
tems of decision making, and establish clear rules for determining who
is poor. Communities with a low capacity to mobilize information and
monitor disbursements are more vulnerable to corruption and capture
by elites, as are more heterogeneous communities, where multiple and
conflicting identities can create competing incentives.
    In sum, context matters a great deal in the degree to which partici-
patory programs achieve their inclusion objectives, as do the specifics
of program design and implementation. Overall, however, poorer, less
educated, and more marginalized groups tend to participate less, as do
women of all socioeconomic backgrounds. Higher average literacy levels
are almost uniformly beneficial for pro-poor participation, and wealth
inequality and remoteness of location tend to reduce participation by
the poor.
    Participation also affects the allocation of resources. A reasonable
amount of evidence shows that elite domination of the participatory          Elite domination of the
process is not without consequence and should not be routinely viewed        participatory process is not
as benign. What does appear to be the case, however, is that a well-         without consequence and
articulated deliberative process may build legitimacy for the resource       should not be routinely viewed
allocation decisions made by the elite even when they are not apparently     as benign.
well aligned with the initial preferences of the poor. The evidence here
is thin, however; much more is needed in order to draw any sensible
conclusion.
    There is also some evidence that an increase in external funding can
displace the most vulnerable people by inducing greater participation
by the more educated, wealthy, and young. This finding is consistent
with the case several critics make that short-duration donor-funded
projects can create conditions under which program implementers have
strong incentives to rapidly mobilize communities in order to disburse
project funds. As doing so is easier in relatively developed and acces-
sible localities, programs tend to focus on them and on the relatively
well placed and influential within them. This finding resonates with
the worry that co-financing requirements and competition for access to
project funds—common features in many participatory projects—can



                                                                                                       135
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    encourage disproportionate participation by people in a position to con-
                                    tribute or with a greater capacity to propose viable projects (see the dis-
                                    cussion in chapter 5). Program design may therefore matter a good deal.


                                    Participation and Resource Allocation under
                                    Decentralization
 Democratic decentralization        A significant body of theoretical literature suggests that political elites
may limit outright capture . . .    may be just as likely as traditional elite groups to engage in rent-seeking
                                    behavior, including the use of public resources to woo particular con-
                                    stituencies in order to gain electoral advantage (see, for example, Cox
                                    and McCubbins 1986; Persson and Tabellini 2000). It is important in
                                    this context to understand the distinction between outright corrup-
. . . but insofar as it increases   tion and clientelism. Democratic decentralization may limit outright
  opportunities for clientelism,    capture, but insofar as it increases opportunities for clientelism, the
              the consequences      consequences for development can be equally negative, as discussed in
        for development can be      chapter 3. Clientelism can lead to the unequal treatment of the equally
               equally negative.    deserving, exacerbating inequality and causing resources to be used
                                    inefficiently as a result of the prioritization of short-term political gains.
                                        How important clientelism and capture are is, of course, an empiri-
                                    cal question. One way to assess their importance is to check whether
                                    electoral results predict future resource allocations or past allocations
                                    predict future electoral results. Several studies confirm such patterns.
                                    Following the 1994 elections in Brazil, federal deputies allocated more
                                    resources for local public goods to municipalities in which they had
                                    received the greatest number of votes. Looking at the allocation of
                                    public works from 1996 to 1999, Finan (2004) finds that a 10 percent
                                    increase in vote shares for a candidate in the previous election, implied
                                    an expected increase of R$75,174 in public works for a municipality
                                    during the electoral cycle. Miguel and Zaidi (2003) find that adminis-
                                    trative districts in Ghana in which the ruling party won all parliamen-
                                    tary seats in the 1996 election received 27 percent more school funding
                                    in 1998–99. Bratton and van de Walle (1997) cite several cases in Africa
                                    where state resources were used to reward faithful supporters. They note
                                    that by “electively distributing favors and material benefits to loyal fol-
                                    lowers who are not citizens of the polity so much as the ruler’s clients,”
                                    rulers often ensure the political stability of their regime and personal
                                    political survival.

136
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



   De Janvry, Nakagawa, and Sadoulet (2009) test this hypothesis
using electoral data from Zambia. They match local election results
in 1998, 2001, and 2006 with ward-level data on resource allocation
under three social fund programs (CRP I, CRP II, and ZAMSIF). They
examine whether the percentage of votes received by the majority party’s
candidate for the district council influenced the allocation of project
resources in the ward and whether past allocations to a ward affected
the political fortunes of incumbents. On the first question, they find
that in highly decentralized districts, a 10 percent increase in the major-
ity party’s share of the vote was associated with a 32 percent increase
in per capita resources in the ward. Interestingly, the increase occurred
only in wards with high literacy rates. They also find that incumbents
were rewarded for higher per capita budgets: a doubling of the allocated
per capita budget in the three years preceding an election increased an
incumbent’s odds of reelection by 4–5 percent. This effect is large, given
that only 24 percent of the wards in subject districts received a project
and that 39 percent elected a councilor from the incumbent district
majority. The authors find no evidence of a trade-off between pro-poor
program targeting and the political use of public resources, however, as
the poorest wards were both more likely to be funded and more likely
to vote for the district majority party.
   Schady (2000) finds that expenditures on projects funded by the              Expenditures on projects
Peruvian social fund FONCODES increased significantly before                   funded by the Peruvian social
national elections over the period 1991–95. Projects were also more            fund increased significantly
likely to be directed at poorer provinces, which returned smaller shares       before national elections.
of votes for the incumbent president in the previous election. He sug-
gests that funding decisions were made on the basis of both political
and poverty criteria.
   In Mexico, municipal-level expenditures by PROGR ESA–
Oportunidades, a national conditional cash transfer program, increased
the incumbent party’s share of the vote by about 4.3 percent (Rodriguez-
Chamussy 2009). This effect was particularly strong when the Partido de
la Revolución Democrática (PRD) was the incumbent party. Incumbent
opposition party mayors also benefitted, however, presumably by suc-
cessfully claiming some credit for benefits delivered to their constituents.
   Manacorda, Miguel, and Vigorito (2011) study a large government-
initiated poverty reduction program in Uruguay. They find that pro-
gram beneficiaries were 21–28 percent more likely to support the current
government than nonbeneficiaries.

                                                                                                         137
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                        Camacho and Conover (2011) examine the targeting performance of
                                     a poverty score card issued by the Colombian government to determine
                                     eligibility for a wide range of programs, including unemployment ben-
                                     efits, housing improvement grants, food aid for the elderly, educational
                                     subsidies, and a publicly provided health insurance program. The cen-
                                     tral government designed the scoring system but allowed municipalities
                                     discretion over the administration and timing of the door-to-door inter-
                                     views. The authors find sharp discontinuities in the score, precisely at
                                     the eligibility threshold of 47. They find that in municipalities in which
                                     a relatively high proportion of families had identical interview answers,
                                     an overwhelming number with identical answers obtained scores below
                                     47. Scores calculated using the disaggregated data largely agree with
                                     the assigned scores, suggesting that the manipulation occurred mainly
                                     through the recording of fake answers at the local level rather than an
                                     overwriting of the score at a later point. This evidence of local manipu-
                                     lation is strengthened by their finding that the sharp discontinuity in
                                     the score density emerged only after the score algorithm was released
                                     to municipal officials and households became aware that eligibility was
                                     based on the score. In fact, 91 percent of families with suspicious scores
                                     were interviewed after 1997, when the score algorithm became well
                                     known to municipal officials. The authors also find a larger discon-
                                     tinuity at the poverty threshold in more competitive elections, where
                                     additional votes were more valuable.
          In India, villagers who       Several studies from India find a similar pattern. Using data from
belonged to the political party      four Indian states, Markussen (2006) finds that villagers who belong
      of the leader of the gram      to the political party of the leader (pradhan) of the gram panchayat (vil-
   panchayat were more likely        lage council) were 32 percent more likely to receive Below Poverty Line
 to receive Below Poverty Line       (BPL) cards intended for the poor, regardless of their economic and
     (BPL) cards, regardless of      social status. A more nuanced finding concerns the interplay between
     their economic and social       land inequality and electoral accountability. Membership in the prad-
                           status.   han’s party increased the likelihood of receiving benefits only in gram
                                     panchayats in which land inequality was above a certain threshold.
                                        Besley, Pande, and Rao (2005, 2007) show that the households of
                                     pradhans and other gram panchayat leaders are significantly more likely
                                     to be assigned BPL cards. In their study, this tendency was substantially
                                     muted in villages with higher historical literacy rates. In these villages,
                                     the landless and illiterate were also more likely to attend gram sabha
                                     (village assembly) meetings. Gram sabhas are expected to be held at least
                                     once a year; several public programs rely on these meetings to generate

138
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



beneficiary lists. The benefits of higher village literacy did not extend
to women, however.
   Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006b) find that poverty, land inequality,          Poverty, land inequality, and
and the fraction of low-caste households substantially increases capture      the fraction of low-caste
in the allocation of resources by local governments for public goods.         households substantially
Local governments in West Bengal, India, selected projects that gener-        increased capture in the
ated less employment for the poor in villages in which a larger fraction      allocation of resources by
of the population was poor or low caste and land was more unequally           local governments for public
distributed. They find much less evidence of capture in the allocation of      goods in West Bengal.
private transfers—mainly credit and the supply of agricultural inputs—
distributed by the government, although here, too, the share of the poor
was smaller in more unequal villages and villages with larger shares of
low-caste households.
   Research also points to the significance of legislative malapportion-
ment on the allocation of resources at the local level and the perfor-
mance of local governments under decentralization. Malapportionment
occurs when there is a discrepancy between the share of legislative seats
held by a geographical unit and its population share, so that some votes
count more than others in legislative decision making at the center.
Samuels and Snyder (2001) argue that some malapportionment may
be necessary in the transition to democracy at the local level in order
to appease antidemocratic elites, who demand that their privileges be
protected. Malapportionment may therefore be more important in rural
areas with entrenched local elites and significant wealth inequality or
in areas with a history of ethnic or linguistic conflict. The authors find
that the overrepresentation of rural districts and counties seems to be
typical in emerging democracies. In Latin America, for example, malap-
portionment tends to favor conservative rural districts at the expense of
more urban or politically progressive districts.
   Ansolabehere, Gerber, and Snyder (2002) show that counties in the
United States that were overrepresented relative to their populations
received relatively more per capita transfers from the state before the
court order mandating redistricting in the 1960s. Following redistrict-
ing, these inequities were largely eliminated, as almost $7 billion a year
moved from formerly overrepresented to formerly underrepresented
counties.
   One implication of malapportionment is that central governments
that rely on overrepresented, nondemocratic localities to secure national
legislative majorities may also tend to tolerate subnational authoritarian

                                                                                                         139
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



      Central governments that       enclaves and be unresponsive to efforts to reform local politics.19
         rely on nondemocratic       Emerging democracies will then tend to undergo a period in which
   localities to secure national     democracy is simultaneously strengthened at the center and under-
     legislative majorities may      mined at the local level.
      also tolerate subnational         Several political theorists have noted a relationship between political
    authoritarian enclaves and       and economic liberalization at the national level and the maintenance
  be unresponsive to efforts to      of authoritarian regimes at the subnational level (see, for example,
           reform local politics.    O’Donnell 1993; Fox 1994; Snyder 1999). There is very little empirical
                                     evidence from developing countries on whether legislative malappor-
                                     tionment protects authoritarian enclaves at the local level.
      Bolivia’s decentralization        Faguet (2004) provides some evidence on how an effort to reduce
 process doubled the share of        malapportionment in the resource allocation process can help improve
national tax revenues devolved       local accountability in a developing country. In Bolivia, the decen-
           to municipalities . . .   tralization process not only doubled the share of national tax revenues
                                     devolved to municipalities, it also required that resources be allocated
                                     strictly on a per capita basis—which limited ad hoc and clientelistic
                                     resource assignment. At the same time, a redistricting effort created
                                     198 new municipalities (64 percent of the total) and expanded exist-
        . . . and required that      ing municipalities to include suburbs and surrounding rural areas.
resources be allocated strictly      Together, these changes led to a massive shift of resources in favor of
        on a per capita basis.       smaller and poorer districts in which the largest beneficiaries were dis-
                                     tricts with the worst demographic indicators and the poorest infrastruc-
                                     ture endowment. Before decentralization, Bolivia’s three largest cities
                                     received 86 percent of all devolved funds; the remaining 14 percent was
                                     divided among 308 municipalities. After decentralization, these shares
                                     were reversed, with the three largest cities receiving just 27 percent of
                                     devolved funds.
                                        Using data on political, institutional, administrative, and governance
                                     indicators for all 311 Bolivian municipalities over the period 1987–96,
                                     Faguet shows that decentralization shifted public investment toward
                                     significantly higher investments in human capital and social services
                                     and that the reallocation was well aligned with local needs. Education
                                     investments were higher in areas with lower literacy; water and sanita-
                                     tion investments were higher in areas with lower water and sewerage
                                     connection rates; and investments in water management and agriculture
                                     were higher in areas at greater risk of malnutrition. This alignment of
                                     investments with local needs was driven in large part by the 250 small-
                                     est and poorest municipalities. Popular participation in local govern-
                                     ments was formalized through local oversight committees (comités de

140
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



vigilancia), which were empowered to exercise oversight over municipal
allocations of “popular participation funds” and to freeze disbursements
to local governments that misused funds.
   De Janvry, Nakagawa, and Sadoulet (2009) also find a shift in
resource allocation with decentralization. They look at the allocation
of the Zambia social fund (ZAMSIF) across districts that vary in the
discretion they can exercise in the allocation of these resources. They
find greater diversity in funded projects in more decentralized districts,
as well as a shift toward income-generating projects as opposed to broad
public goods, such as education, health, and water supply/sanitation.
However, the increased investments appeared to benefit the poor, and
there was an overall shift of resources in favor of the poorest wards.



Can Electoral Incentives Reduce Rent-Seeking?
Ultimately, of course, the question of interest is whether a shift toward      There is little good evidence
democracy at the local level reduces capture on balance. There is very         on whether a shift toward
little good evidence on this issue. What there is suggests that local          democracy at the local level
democracy has the potential to mitigate capture, albeit not always most        reduces capture.
efficiently, and that electoral rules such as term limits, the political
context in which decentralization occurs, and the ability of the center
to oversee resource allocation at the local level matter a great deal.
    Foster and Rosenzweig (2004) develop a model of two-party democ-
racy in which local governments need to allocate the public budget
across three types of goods: a public good (roads) that disproportion-
ately benefits the poor, by raising wages; a club good (irrigation facili-
ties) that disproportionately benefits landowners; and a neutral public
good (schools). The model establishes that an increase in the share of
landless households should lead to larger investments in road construc-
tion under a democratic regime relative to a regime that specifically
favors the local elite. Using data from 250 villages in rural India, Foster
and Rosenzweig show that an increase in the population weight of the
poor induces resource allocations that favor the poor. Their evidence
suggests that public irrigation investment crowds out private irrigation
investment, so that the shift toward more pro-poor public goods also
implies a net gain in total output.
    Political economy agency models, such as those by Barro (1973) and
Ferejohn (1986), predict that incumbent politicians will refrain from

                                                                                                           141
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  maximizing rent extraction in their first term in order to get reelected
                                  and enjoy future rents. Persuasive empirical evidence that this is indeed
                                  the case has emerged based on term limits of U.S. state governors. Besley
                                  and Case (1995) show that governors eligible for reelection were signifi-
                                  cantly more likely to reduce taxes and expenditures than governors not
                                  facing reelection.
                                     List and Sturm (2006) show that electoral rules affect even secondary
                                  policies, such as environmental protection. They find that environmen-
                                  tal spending is higher when governors are eligible for reelection and that
                                  the spending gap between eligible and final-term governors increases in
                                  states with a large pro-environmental population.
            Results from Brazil      Evidence on the relationship between term limits and political
         suggest that electoral   incentives has also started to emerge for developing countries. Ferraz
   rules that enhance political   and Finan (2011) look at mayoral elections in Brazilian municipalities.
  accountability play a crucial   Using data from the 2003 audits conducted by the Brazilian central
   role in constraining corrupt   government, they examine the allocation of federal resources by local
                      behavior.   governments. Municipalities were selected by lottery for an audit each
                                  month; audit reports were made available on the Internet and sent to
                                  all levels of government about two months after completion. Ferraz
                                  and Finan find that the share of total audited resources that was misap-
                                  propriated was 27 percent larger in municipalities with second-term
                                  mayors, who did not have reelection incentives because of term limits,
                                  and that the effects were more pronounced in municipalities with less
                                  access to information and in municipalities in which the likelihood
                                  of judicial punishment was lower. Overall, their findings suggest that
                                  electoral rules that enhance political accountability play a crucial role
                                  in constraining corrupt behavior. Assuming that in the absence of
                                  reelection incentives, first-term mayors would behave like second-term
                                  mayors, they estimate that reelection incentives reduced the misappro-
                                  priation of resources by about $160 million.
                                     De Janvry, Finan, and Sadoulet (forthcoming) provide additional
                                  evidence of the impact of term limits on the performance of mayors in
                                  Brazilian municipal elections. They focus on the impact of term limits
                                  on the effectiveness of the Bolsa Escola program on student dropout
                                  rates.20 The authors find that municipalities governed by a first-term
                                  mayor eligible for reelection had an additional 2 percentage point
                                  reduction in the dropout rate, which represented a 36 percent improve-
                                  ment in program performance compared with municipalities governed
                                  by a second-term mayor not eligible for reelection. Once the potential

142
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



selection of children into the program is accounted for, the reduction
in dropout rates is about 8 percentage points, representing a decline
of 52 percent relative to the preprogram dropout rate of 15 percent.21
Various robustness checks validate these results. The authors also find
some evidence for heterogeneity in program impact. Wealthier munici-
palities generally do better, but so do municipalities that have more
open and competitive electoral practices, which display less evidence of
nepotism and administrative politicization.
   De Janvry, Finan, and Sadoulet attempt to understand the chan-
nel through which mayoral effort translates into lower dropout rates
by looking at differences in program implementation.22 Their fi nd-
ings indicate that first-term mayors were somewhat more likely to rely
on the registration of children through schools and to involve social
councils in various ways in implementing the program. In contrast,
second-term mayors were somewhat more likely to register children in
the mayor’s office and to send program coordinators to the homes of
children who did not comply with the program’s attendance require-
ments. The authors argue that in-school registration of children is more
transparent and indicates higher levels of effort. One could argue the
opposite—that in-school registration could favor the inclusion of lower-
risk (and potentially better-off) children, whereas registration through
the mayor’s office, along with follow-up through program coordinators,
may induce more noncompliers to openly drop out. If this is the case,
dropout rates could be higher for second-term mayors precisely because
they select poorer and riskier children and enforce the conditionality
stipulated by the program, whereas reelection incentives may make first-
term mayors more likely to engage in clientelistic behavior, as Khemani
and Wane (2008) argue, than to deliver higher-quality public services.
Disentangling these effects requires data on the child’s household char-
acteristics and compliance with the program.
   The reelection incentives of local politicians, including the need to
reward supporters, can also influence resource allocation in participa-
tory development projects. Arcand and Bassole (2008), for example,
show that, on average, the village of the Conseil Rural (rural council)
president was 18.5 percent more likely to receive funding for a subproj-
ect under the Programme National d’Infrastructures Rurales, a large
community-driven development program in Senegal. Baird, McIntosh,
and Özler (2009) find that wards and districts in which elected repre-
sentatives were not from the ruling party generated fewer applications

                                                                                                 143
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   for projects funded by Tanzania’s Social Action Fund (TASAF), sug-
                                   gesting the use of decentralized project resources to build support for
                                   the incumbent party.23 Case (2001) finds that block grants provided by
                                   the Albanian social assistance program were distributed across commu-
                                   nities in a manner consistent with the core-supporter model.
                                      Several recent studies examine the restraining effect of election
                                   incentives on corruption in local governments. Ferraz and Finan (2008)
                                   examine whether access to information on the corrupt practices of local
                                   politicians affects voter behavior by comparing municipalities in Brazil
                                   that were randomly audited before the elections with municipalities
                                   that were audited after the elections. They find that the disclosure of
                                   audit reports had a significant impact on the reelection rates of corrupt
                                   mayors and that exposure to media was important, with larger effects
                                   in municipalities with radio stations.
                                      Henderson and Kuncoro (2011) find that Indonesia’s move toward
                                   decentralized local governance in 2001 decreased the level of corruption
                                   as measured by the reported bribes paid by firms to government line
                                   departments for activities under local control. The extent of the reduc-
                                   tion was greater in districts where Islamic (rather than secular) parties,
                                   whose local platforms emphasized anticorruption policies, were elected
                                   in 2001. The authors see this evidence as pointing to the importance
                                   of corruption as a political issue in the selection of local leaders and
                                   indicative of the potential for democracy at the local level to constrain
                                   corruption.
    When localities are largely       Brollo (2009) focuses on the political opportunity that the audits of
 dependent on fiscal transfers      local government can provide to the central government. This study
   from the center, the central    reveals that much of the observed impact on the reelection odds of
  government can use devices       incumbent mayors in Brazil occurs because the central government
such as audits to control local    uses audit reports to strategically reward and punish allies and competi-
            political selection.   tors. Brollo finds that municipalities in which two or more instances of
                                   corruption were found received smaller transfers from the center, but
                                   corrupt mayors who were affiliated with the president’s political party
                                   were actually compensated with larger transfers in order to avoid future
                                   political losses caused by any reputational effects. In contrast, pure
                                   reputation effects dominated only when information was released close
                                   to the election. This finding suggests that when localities are largely
                                   dependent on fiscal transfers from the center, as Brazilian municipalities
                                   are, the central government can use devices such as audits to control
                                   local political selection. It also suggests that voters may care far more

144
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



about the delivery of public goods and transfers than about the extent
to which politicians, who are able to deliver these services, are corrupt.
   Bobonis, Camara-Fuertes, and Schwabe (2011) examine whether
the public disclosure of information about political corruption affects
the re-election odds and future behavior of politicians. They find that
audits do little to reduce corruption but can be instrumental in improv-
ing the odds of re-election. Using data on publicly released audits of
municipal governments in Puerto Rico, they find that audited levels
of corruption in municipalities that were audited before the previous
election and municipalities that were not are similar. However, mayors
were able to translate the reputational gain provided by a good audit
into higher odds of reelection and higher levels of rent-seeking in future
periods.
   Litschig and Zamboni (2007) and Di Tella and Schargrodsky (2003)             Mechanisms other than
focus on the impact of judicial institutions and “corruption crack-             electoral and social
downs” on resource misappropriation and fiscal mismanagement. These              accountability, such as judicial
studies point to the importance of mechanisms other than electoral and          reforms, are important for
social accountability for improving governance.                                 improving governance.
   Litschig and Zamboni (2007) exploit exogenous variation in the
location of state judiciary branches to assess the impact of judicial insti-
tutions on corruption by civil servants in local governments in Brazil.24
Using audit data to construct an estimate of offenses per civil servant
in counties, with and without state judiciary branches, they find that
offenses per civil servant were about 35 percent lower in counties with
a branch of the judiciary.25
   Di Tella and Schargrodsky (2003) study the price paid for basic              In Buenos Aires, the prices
inputs during a crackdown on corruption in public hospitals in Buenos           public hospitals paid for basic
Aires in 1996–97. The crackdown was conducted by a newly elected                inputs fell about 18 percent
city government, which collected and compared prices paid by all                during the first six months of a
public hospitals for a set of homogenous basic inputs for which quality         crackdown on corruption.
differences should not have been a concern. The authors find that the
prices paid by hospitals for basic inputs fell about 18 percent during the
first six months of the crackdown. Although there was some increase
afterward, prices remained significantly below the pre-crackdown phase
nine months later. The longer-term effects were larger when procure-
ment officers were better paid.
   These studies suggest that institutions at the local level cannot substi-
tute for weak and corrupt formal institutions of accountability. Instead,
local oversight over the use and management of public resources is likely

                                                                                                            145
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    to be effective only when other institutions of accountability, including
                                    institutions at the center, function well and communities have the rel-
                                    evant information and the capacity to sanction lax or corrupt providers
                                    and others in charge of public resources.26 In addition, broader reforms
                                    that enhance judicial oversight, allow for independent audit agencies,
                                    and protect and promote the right to information and a free media
                                    appear to be necessary for effective local oversight.



                                    Conclusions
                                    The literature on decentralization identifies a central trade-off between
                                    the advantages of local information and the hazards of local capture.
                                    The evidence reviewed in this chapter indicates that in many cases, the
                                    hazards of local capture can outweigh the benefits of local information.
                                       In the majority of cases, participants in community-driven develop-
                                    ment projects belong to the elite, whose preferences are often reflected
                                    in the resource allocation process. The extent to which their dominance
                                    distorts the poverty reduction intent of decentralized public programs
                                    depends on the extent to which elite dominance can be construed as
                                    capture. Community characteristics—including inequalities of wealth
                                    and political power, geographic isolation, and ethnic heterogeneity—
                                    appear to play a decisive role in this regard. Malevolent forms of capture
                                    are more likely in communities with greater wealth inequality, commu-
                                    nities that are isolated or poor and communities in which caste, race,
                                    and gender disparities are important and are embedded in a hierarchical
                                    structure which valorizes particular groups.
     Local actors may have an          Participatory programs attempt to deal with these concerns by using
  informational and locational      local facilitators to build community capacity. However, little is known
                advantage . . .     about the facilitation process, the training received by facilitators, or
                                    the incentive structures they face. There is also little evidence of any
                                    self-correcting mechanism through which community engagement
         . . . but they appear to
                                    counteracts the potential capture of public resources. Instead, the bulk
     use it to the benefit of the
                                    of the evidence suggests that the more unequal the initial distribution
     disadvantaged only where
                                    of assets, the better positioned the nonpoor are to capture the benefits of
  institutions and mechanisms
                                    external efforts to help the poor. Local actors may have an informational
 to ensure local accountability
                                    and locational advantage, but they appear to use it to the benefit of the
                      are robust.
                                    disadvantaged only where institutions and mechanisms to ensure local
                                    accountability are robust.

146
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



   Other dimensions of community capacity also matter a great deal.                Participatory programs face
Participatory programs face far greater challenges in remote or isolated           far greater challenges in
localities and in areas with lower literacy levels and higher levels of            remote or isolated localities
poverty. Such localities also tend to be less well served by mass media            and in areas with lower
and other sources of information and are less likely to have adequate              literacy levels and higher
central oversight.                                                                 levels of poverty.
   Local democracy can have both favorable and unfavorable effects on
the level and distribution of public resources. The outcome is context             Local democracy can
dependent. It varies with the nature of political institutions, at both            have both favorable and
the national and the local level; the level of voter awareness; and the            unfavorable effects on the
accountability mechanisms in place. The potential for resource capture             level and distribution of public
by political elites appears to be considerable.                                    resources. The outcome is
   The literature also indicates that democratic decentralization can              context dependent.
lead to a greater use of public budgets to reward particular constituents
for their loyalty and to improve the fortunes of political allies.
   The important question is whether democratic decentralization                   On balance, the ballot box
narrows the overall scope for capture. The answer appears to warrant               provides a clearer mechanism
cautious optimism, provided political institutions and rules are designed          for sanctioning unpopular
to address perverse incentives. On balance the ballot box, though far              policy choices or excessive
from perfect, provides a clearer mechanism than less formal deliberation           rent-seeking by traditional
for sanctioning unpopular policy choices or excessive rent-seeking by              or political elites than less
traditional or political elites. It is less clear how citizens can collectively    formal deliberation.
sanction negligent or corrupt officials or local leaders where such ven-
ues for the exercise of citizen voice are not available. This suggests that        Institutions at the local
community-driven development projects may be able to induce greater                level cannot substitute for
accountability by mandating inclusion and using electoral processes to             weak and corrupt formal
select community representatives.                                                  institutions of accountability.
   In sum, far from being a substitute for weak and corrupt formal
institutions of accountability, local oversight over the use and manage-
ment of public resources is effective only when institutions of account-
ability at the center function well and communities have the capacity              Effective local oversight
to effectively monitor service providers and others in charge or public            requires well-functioning
resources. This finding appears to increase, rather than diminish, the              institutions at the center . . .
need for a functional and strong center and vigilant and able imple-               and reforms that enhance
menting agencies. There is little evidence that donors can substitute              judicial oversight, allow for
for a nonfunctional central government as a higher-level accountability            independent audit agencies,
agent. Effective local oversight appears to require reforms that enhance           and protect and promote
judicial oversight, allow for independent audit agencies, and protect and          the right to information and a
promote the right to information and a free media.                                 free media.

                                                                                                                147
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?




                          Notes
                           1. See in particular Mauro (1995). The causal relationship between corrup-
                              tion and economic development has been argued both ways. Glaeser and
                              others (2004) argue that corruption tends to decline as economic progress
                              occurs.
                           2. See, for example, Shleifer and Vishny (1993); Manor (1999); and Bardhan
                              and Mookherjee (2006b). Recent theoretical work on incentives in
                              principal-agent models also shows that decentralization can raise the pro-
                              pensity of individuals to accept bribes (see, for example, Carbonara 2000).
                           3. Several writers argue that it may not always be sensible to pursue a policy
                              designed to minimize corruption, narrowly defined as bribes, graft, and
                              theft, particularly when there are other, possibly conflicting policy goals
                              (see, for example, Waller, Verdier, and Gardner 2002). The implications of
                              corruption for efficiency have been a somewhat contested issue. Some writ-
                              ers, like Huntington (1968) argue that bribes, graft, and theft are necessary
                              for greasing the “squeaking wheels” of a rigid bureaucracy or that they are
                              an unpleasant but unavoidable side effect of needed government interven-
                              tion to prevent market failure (Acemoglu and Verdier 2000). Others point
                              out that corruption can skew the incentives of the most economically effi-
                              cient people away from socially productive activities toward rent-seeking
                              activities and that the people who “grease the wheels” may simply be the
                              most successful at rent-seeking rather than production (Treisman 2000).
                              Rose-Ackerman (2008) argues that the use of public office to influence
                              resource allocation or move legislation in favor of particular groups or
                              causes should not be viewed as corruption, as constituency-based politics
                              can motivate voters to monitor the actions of their representatives, thereby
                              reducing incentives for outright corruption.
                           4. An important strand in the cross-country literature on corruption focuses
                              on the relationship between corruption and a country’s level of economic
                              development, its political institutions, and aspects of its culture. Much of
                              this literature tests hypotheses that have emerged from theoretical studies
                              that seek to explain the relative prevalence of corruption across countries
                              (see, for example, Olson 1993; Shleifer and Vishny 1993; and Campante,
                              Chor, and Do 2009). Studies that look at the relationship between eco-
                              nomic development and corruption find evidence for a strong negative
                              relationship. Higher levels of economic development are associated with
                              lower levels of corruption, although the direction of causality is not clear.
                              Some writers argue that development reduces corruption (see Treisman
                              2000); others argue that countries with lower corruption levels experience
                              more economic development (see Kaufmann and Kraay 2002). Studies
                              also find that other features of the economy, including the level of eco-
                              nomic inequality, natural resource endowments, and exposure to foreign
                              competition, influence the extent of corruption. You and Khagram (2005)
                              argue that in more unequal societies, the wealthy have greater incentives
                              and opportunities to skew resources and power in their favor through cor-
                              ruption, while the poor are more vulnerable to extortion and less able to


148
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



     hold the rich and powerful to account. Ades and Di Tella (1999) find that
     corruption tends to be higher in countries with greater income inequality.
     Leite and Weidmann (1999) find that larger natural resource endowments
     are associated with more corruption. Myerson (1993) and Persson, Roland,
     and Tabellini (1997) provide theoretical arguments for the relationship
     between political institutions and corruption.
5.   Corruption also appears to be higher in countries that have fewer political
     rights, in ex-communist regimes (Triesman 2000), and in countries that
     have less press freedom (Brunetti and Weder 2003). Corruption levels
     are lower in countries that have a history of common law and procedural
     fairness, such as former British colonies; in countries that pay higher
     wages to their civil bureaucrats; and countries with larger numbers of
     ethno-linguistic groups (Treisman 2000; on wages see Evans and Rauch
     2000). Some researchers argue that corruption levels are also lower where
     women play a greater role in the government and the economy (see, for
     example, Dollar, Fisman, and Gatti 2001; Swamy and others 2000).
6.   Donchev and Ujhelyi (2009) show that factors commonly found to “cause”
     corruption—religion, the level of development, democratic institutions—
     are better at explaining perceptions of corruption than actual levels of it.
     Controlling for such variables, they find at best a very weak relationship
     between corruption and indexes of corruption perception, for all the
     measures of corruption experience the use. Olken (2007) and Donchev
     and Ujhelyi (2009) show that corruption perceptions vary systematically
     by individual and household characteristics such as education, age, gen-
     der, and income. A number of studies find a positive correlation between
     perceptions of corruption and a range of societal characteristics. Several
     studies find that reported perceptions of corruption are positively correlated
     with levels of local inequality and ethnic heterogeneity (see, for example,
     Mauro 1995; La Porta and others 1999; and Olken 2007). Others find a
     negative relationship between social capital, measured by levels of trust
     and civic activism, and corruption (on the relationship between social
     capital and corruption, see Putnam 1993; Paldam and Svendsen 2002;
     Bjornskov 2003). These studies cannot rule out reverse causality (high
     levels of corruption reducing trust and civic activism).
7.   This finding is consistent with the theoretical model developed by Shleifer
     and Vishny (1993).
8.   Moving from perception data to data on actual corruption experience is
     not always straightforward. In general, different measures of corruption
     do not produce the same conclusions. Moreover, the impact of a policy
     shift can vary across measures of corruption and possibly with the level
     of social tolerance for corruption in a society, as Mendez and Sepulveda
     (2010) show. Ades and Di Tella (1999) argue that hard data on corrup-
     tion, such as the number of reported fraud cases, are likely to reflect the
     classification system used in each country as well as both the incidence of
     corruption and the corruption deterrence system in place.
9.   Public expenditure tracking data collected in other African countries yields
     a similar pattern of missing expenditures.


                                                                                                           149
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          10. A number of other studies show that governments tend to be more
                              responsive when the electorate is better informed. The mass media have
                              an important role to play in this regard. Drèze and Sen (1990) make this
                              argument forcefully in noting the relative success that India, which has a
                              free media, has had avoiding famines compared with China. Besley and
                              Burgess (2002) show that Indian states with higher newspaper circulation
                              (which also had higher literacy rates and greater election turnout) were
                              more likely to be responsive to food shortages. Stromberg (2004a, 2004b)
                              shows how access to media can affect the allocation of resources to specific
                              groups and thus influence the incidence of redistributive programs. A
                              number of cross-country studies find a negative correlation between press
                              freedom and corruption (Stapenhurst 2000; Brunetti and Weder 2003;
                              Ahrend 2002). Djankov and others (2003) find a negative relationship
                              between state ownership of the media and measures of good governance,
                              including political rights, service delivery, and social outcomes. However,
                              the independence of the media (and the degree of state ownership) may
                              itself depend on the size of political rents and thus the scale of opportu-
                              nities for resource misappropriation. Besley and Prat (2006) argue that
                              the press is more likely to be free where political rents are small and there
                              is scope for a multiplicity of media outlets and sources for advertising
                              revenue. Mullainathan and Shleifer (2002) point out that greater media
                              concentration need not imply less media autonomy if competition generates
                              a struggle for market share that leads to the publication of more stories
                              that tend to confirm the prior beliefs of readers.
                          11. OPK rice was available at 60 percent below market price, implying a subsidy
                              of about 9 percent of preprogram monthly household expenditures for a
                              median household purchasing its full allotment of subsidized rice.
                          12. The measure of corruption is obtained by comparing administrative data
                              on the amount of rice distributed with survey data on the amount house-
                              holds actually received. A potential issue is that the survey data provide
                              information only on whether a household obtained any subsidized rice,
                              without naming the program or the number of times it did so. Olken
                              (2006) therefore assumes that each household that received rice received
                              its full monthly allotment and that the rice was obtained from the OPK.
                          13. The study incorporates data from various sources, including focus group
                              interviews with households and community leaders on service quality and
                              on local institutions, data on service coverage and administration, and
                              a household survey that included information on participation in local
                              associations and the use of specific services.
                          14. The study uses census data from 155 villages. The villages are a random
                              subset of all the villages in which an NGO, the National Rural Support
                              Program, was active. The National Rural Support Program is funded
                              through the Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund, a World Bank–supported
                              community-driven development program.
                          15. See chapter 6 for more on deliberative councils and their role in resource
                              allocation.
                          16. The inputs provided were sufficient to cultivate at least 3.5 acres of land.


150
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



17. The control group was generated by randomizing the order in which groups
    entered the program.
18. To obtain representative measures of community poverty and inequality,
    Araujo and others (2008) use poverty mapping techniques to combine
    household and census data. They then combine these with administrative
    data on project type and cost at the community level.
19. Redistricting could also create new constituencies of swing voters, allowing
    politicians to better target communities whose electoral choices could be
    influenced by the provision of public goods (Lindbeck and Weibull 1987;
    Dixit and Londregan 1996; Persson and Tabellini 2001). The swing voter
    is theorized to be closest to the center of the political spectrum. There
    is empirical support for the swing voter model in both developed and
    developing countries. Levitt and Snyder (1997) show that in the United
    States, government spending increases the incumbent’s vote share in
    congressional elections. Sorribas-Navarro and Sole-Olle (2008) confirm
    this result in national elections in Spain. Dahlberg and Johansson (2002)
    find that incumbent governments in Sweden distributed temporary grants
    for ecologically sustainable development programs to regions with more
    swing voters.
20. Bolsa Escola gives conditional cash transfers to poor mothers of school-age
    children if the children attend school on a regular basis. Municipalities were
    allocated a fi xed number of stipends and were responsible for identifying
    beneficiary children. By design, households with a monthly per capita
    income of less than R$90 (about $40) were eligible. They were offered a
    transfer of R$15 per child, up to a maximum of R$45 per household.
21. Selection is likely to be important, as almost half of eligible children were
    left out of the program because of limits on stipends at the municipality
    level. Beneficiary children had an initial dropout rate that was less than
    a third the dropout rate of nonbeneficiaries. The authors deal with this
    problem by estimating the treatment effect after controlling for child
    fi xed-effects and by allowing children with a different pretreatment drop-
    out status to have different year effects. Identification is then based on a
    comparison of the change in dropout levels between treated children and
    their comparable untreated counterparts.
22. Program implementation varied greatly across municipalities, despite clear
    eligibility rules at the federal level. Implementation processes varied, for
    example, in the location at which children were registered, the manner in
    which the school attendance conditionality was monitored, and the extent
    to which program coordinators were involved in verifying compliance.
    Much of this variation appears to be tied to whether the municipality was
    led by a first-term or second-term mayor.
23. In his study of Indonesia’s Urban Poverty Project, Fritzen (2007) finds that
    electoral incentives induced more pro-poor actions by elected members of
    community development boards, which are responsible for selecting and
    managing all activities funded by the project. A concern with this study
    is that the key variables used to determine elite capture are perceptions
    of the board members whose behavior was being assessed, making any


                                                                                                           151
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                              inference difficult. The data on perceptions are also aggregated into scores
                              in a somewhat obscure manner.
                          24. State judiciary branches are assigned only to the most populous county
                              among contiguous counties forming a judiciary district. Counties with
                              nearly similar populations but without a local judicial presence serve as
                              the counterfactual case.
                          25. Ferraz and Finan (2011) also find that the presence of a judge reduces
                              corruption among second-term mayors. Litschig and Zamboni (2007)
                              are unable to find evidence of any impact of mayoral incumbency on
                              corruption levels. However, their strategy makes their results not directly
                              comparable to the studies by Ferraz and Finan (2008, 2011).
                          26. A comprehensive review of the case study evidence on civil society engage-
                              ment in reducing corruption (Grimes 2008) finds that community efforts
                              at monitoring and sanctioning corrupt practices have bite only when
                              there is a strong and engaged advocate at the center. In the absence of
                              such conditions, civil society efforts are able to succeed in only a limited
                              way, largely by inducing resignations through naming and shaming and
                              through protests to raise awareness.



                          References
                          Acemoglu, D., and T. Verdier. 2000. “The Choice between Market Failures
                              and Corruption.” American Economic Review 90(1): 194–211.
                          Ades, A., and R. Di Tella. 1999. “Rents, Competition, and Corruption.”
                              American Economic Review 89(4): 982–93.
                          Ahrend, R. 2002. “Press Freedom, Human Capital, and Corruption.” DELTA
                              Working Paper Series 36, Ecole Normale Supérieure, Paris.
                          Ansolabehere, S., A. Gerber, and J. M. Snyder Jr. 2002. “Equal Votes, Equal
                              Money: Court-Ordered Redistricting and Public Expenditures in the
                              American States.” American Political Science Review 96(4): 767–77.
                          Araujo, M. C., F. H. G. Ferreira, P. Lanjouw, and B. Özler. 2008. “Local
                              Inequality and Project Choice: Theory and Evidence from Ecuador.”
                              Journal of Public Economics 92(5–6): 1022–46.
                          Arcand, J.-L., and L. Bassole. 2008. “Does Community Driven Development
                              Work? Evidence from Senegal.” CERDI-CNRS, Université d’Auvergne,
                              France.
                          Arcand, J.-L., and M. Fafchamps. 2012. “Matching in Community-Based
                              Organizations.” Journal of Development Economics 98(2): 203–19.
                          Baird, S., C. McIntosh, and B. Özler. 2009. The Squeaky Wheels Get the Grease:
                              Applications and Targeting in Tanzania’s Social Action Fund. World Bank,
                              Washington, DC.
                          Bardhan, P. 2002. “Decentralization of Governance and Development.”
                              Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(4): 185–205.
                          Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2006a. “Decentralization, Corruption, and
                              Government Accountability.” In International Handbook on the Economics


152
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



    of Corruption, ed. S. Rose-Ackerman. Cheltenham, United Kingdom:
    Edward Elgar.
———. 2006b. “Pro-poor Targeting and Accountability of Local Govern-
    ments in West Bengal.” Journal of Development Economics 79(2): 303–327
———. Forthcoming. “Land Reform and Farm Productivity in West Bengal.”
    American Economic Journal, Applied Economics.
Bardhan, P., D. Mookherjee, and M. P. Torrado. 2010. “Impact of Political
    Reservations in West Bengal Local Governments on Anti-Poverty
    Targeting.” Journal of Globalization and Development 1(1): 1–34.
Barro, R. 1973. “The Control of Politicians: An Economic Model.” Public
    Choice 14: 19–42.
Besley, T., and R. Burgess. 2002. “The Political Economy of Government
    Responsiveness: Theory and Evidence from India.” Quarterly Journal of
    Economics 117(4): 1415–51.
Besley, T., and A. Case. 1995. “Does Electoral Accountability Affect
    Economic Policy Choices? Evidence from Gubernatorial Term Limits.”
    Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3): 769–98.
Besley, T., R. Pande, and V. Rao. 2005. “Participatory Democracy in Action:
    Survey Evidence from South Rural India.” Journal of the European
    Economic Association 3(2–3): 648–57.
———. 2007. “Just Rewards? Local Politics and Public Resource Allocation
    in South India.” LSE, STICERD Research Paper DEDPS49, Suntory
    and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines,
    Lond School of Economies, London.
Besley, T., and A. Prat. 2006. “Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media
    Capture and Government Accountability.” American Economic Review
    96(3): 720–36.
Bjorkman, M. 2006, “Does Money Matter for Student Performance? Evidence
    from a Grant Program in Uganda.” Working Paper 326, Innocenzo
    Gasparini Institute for Economic Research (IGIER), Universitá Bocconi,
    Milan.
Bjornskov, C. 2003. “Corruption and Social Capital.” Working Paper 03-13,
    Aarhus School of Business, Aarhus, Germany.
Bobonis, G. J., L. Camara-Fuertes, and R. Schwabe. 2011. “The Dynamic
    Effects of Information on Political Corruption: Theory and Evidence
    from Puerto Rico.” Working Paper 428, Department of Economics,
    University of Toronto, Toronto, ON.
Bratton, M., and N. Van de Walle. 1997. Democratic Experiments in Africa.
    Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Brollo, F. 2009. “Who Is Punishing Corrupt Politicians—Voters or the
    Central Government? Evidence from the Brazilian Anti-Corruption
    Program.” Institute for Economic Development Working Paper dp-168,
    Department of Economics, Boston University, Boston.
Brunetti, A., and B. Weder. 2003. “A Free Press Is Bad News for Corruption.”
    Journal of Public Economics 87(7–8): 1801–24.
Camacho, A., and E. Conover. 2011. “Manipulation of Social Program
    Eligibility.” American Economic Journal-Economic Policy 3(2): 41–65.


                                                                                                     153
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Campante, F. R., D. Chor, and Q. Do. 2009. “Instability and the Incentives
                              for Corruption.” Economics and Politics 21(1): 42–92.
                          Carbonara, E. 2000. “Corruption and Decentralisation.” Dipartimento di
                              Scienze Economiche, Working Paper 342/83, University of Bologna,
                              Italy.
                          Case, A. 2001. “Election Goals and Income Redistribution: Recent Evidence
                              from Albania.” European Economic Review 45(3): 405–23.
                          Conning, J., and M. Kevane. 2002. “Community-Based Targeting Mechanisms
                              for Social Safety Nets: A Critical Review.” World Development 30(3):
                              375–94.
                          Cox, G. W., and M. D. McCubbins. 1986. “Electoral-Politics as a Redistributive
                              Game.” Journal of Politics 48(2): 370–89.
                          Dahlberg, M., and E. Johansson. 2002. “On the Vote-Purchasing Behavior
                              of Incumbent Governments.” American Political Science Review 96(1):
                              27–40.
                          Dasgupta, A., and V. A. Beard. 2007. “Community Driven Development,
                              Collective Action and Elite Capture in Indonesia.” Development and
                              Change 38(2): 229–49.
                          De Janvry, A., F. Finan, and E. Sadoulet. Forthcoming. “Local Electoral
                              Incentives and Decentralized Program Performance.” Review of Economics
                              and Statistics.
                          De Janvry, A., H. Nakagawa, and E. Sadoulet. 2009. “Pro-Poor Targeting and
                              Electoral Rewards in Decentralizing to Communities the Provision of
                              Local Public Goods in Rural Zambia.” University of California, Berkeley.
                          Di Tella, R., and E. Schargrodsky. 2003. “The Role of Wages and Auditing
                              During a Crackdown on Corruption in the City of Buenos Aires.” Journal
                              of Law and Economics 46(1): 269–92.
                          Dixit, A., and J. Londregan. 1996. “The Determinants of Success of Special
                              Interests in Redistributive Politics.” Journal of Politics 58(4): 1132–55.
                          Djankov, S., C. McLeish, T. Nenova, and A. Shleifer. 2003. “Who Owns the
                              Media?” Journal of Law and Economics 46(2): 341–81.
                          Dollar, D., R. Fisman, and R. Gatti. 2001. “Are Women Really the ‘Fairer’
                              Sex? Corruption and Women in Government.” Journal of Economic
                              Behavior and Organization 46(4): 423–29.
                          Donchev, D., and G. Ujhelyi. 2009. “What Do Corruption Indices Measure?”
                              Department of Economics, University of Houston, Houston, TX.
                          Drèze, J., and A. Sen, eds. 1990. The Political Economy of Hunger: Entitlement
                              and Well-Being, World Institute for Development Economics Research Studies
                              in Development Economics vol. 1. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
                          Estache, A., and S. Sinha. 1995. “Does Decentralization Increase Spending
                              on Public Infrastructure?” Policy Research Working Paper 1457, World
                              Bank, Washington, DC.
                          Evans, P. B., and J. E. Rauch. 2000. “Bureaucratic Structure and Bureaucratic
                              Performance in Less Developed Countries.” Journal of Public Economics
                              75(1): 49–71.
                          Faguet, J. P. 2004. “Does Decentra lization Increase Government
                              Responsiveness to Local Needs? Evidence from Bolivia.” Journal of Public
                              Economics 88(3–4): 867–93.

154
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



Fan, C. S., C. Lin, and D. Treisman. 2009. “Political Decentralization
     and Corruption: Evidence from around the World.” Journal of Public
     Economics 93(1–2): 14–34.
Ferejohn, J. 1986. “Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control.” Public
     Choice 50: 5–25.
Ferraz C. and F. Finan. 2008. “Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects
     of Brazil’s Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes.” Quarterly
     Journal of Economics 123(2): 703–45.
———. 2011. “Electoral Accountability and Corruption: Evidence from
     the Audits of Local Governments.” American Economic Review 101(4):
     1274–311.
Finan, F. 2004. “Political Patronage and Local Development: A Brazilian
     Case Study.” Working Paper, Department of Agricultural and Resource
     Economics, University of California, Berkeley.
Fisman, R., and R. Gatti. 2002a. “Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence
     across Countries.” Journal of Public Economics 83(3): 325–45.
———. 2002b. “Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence from U.S.
     Federal Transfer Programs.” Public Choice 113(1–2): 25–35.
Foster, A., and M. Rosenzweig. 2004. “Democratization and the Distribution
     of Local Public Goods in a Poor Rural Economy.” Working Paper 01-056,
     Penn Institute for Economic Research, University of Pennsylvania,
     Philadelphia.
Fox, J. 1994. “The Difficult Transition from Clientelism to Citizenship:
     Lessons from Mexico.” World Politics 46(2): 151–84.
Francken, N., B. Minten, and J. F. M. Swinnen. 2009. “Media, Monitoring,
     and Capture of Public Funds: Evidence from Madagascar.” World
     Development 37(1): 242–55.
Fritzen, S. A. 2007. “Can the Design of Community-Driven Development
     Reduce the Risk of Elite Capture? Evidence from Indonesia.” World
     Development 35(8): 1359–75.
Galasso, E., and M. Ravallion. 2005. “Decentralized Targeting of an
     Antipoverty Program.” Journal of Public Economics 89(4): 705–27
Glaeser, E. L., R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Schleifer. 2004. “Do
     Institutions Cause Growth?” Journal of Economic Growth 9(3): 271–303.
Grimes, M. 2008. “The Conditions of Successful Civil Society Involvement
     in Combating Corruption: A Survey of Case Study Evidence.” QoG
     Working Paper 22: 21, Department of Political Science, University of
     Gothenburg, Sweden.
Grootaert, C., G. T. Oh, and A. Swamy. 2002. “Social Capital, Household
     Welfare and Poverty in Burkina Faso.” Journal of African Economies 11(1):
     4–38.
Gugerty, M. K., and M. Kremer. 2008. “Outside Funding and the Dynamics
     of Participation in Community Associations.” American Journal of
     Political Science 52(3): 585–602
Henderson, V. J., a nd A . Kuncoro. 2011. “Corruption a nd L oca l
     Democratization in Indonesia: The Role of Islamic Parties.” Journal of
     Development Economics 24(2): 164–80.

                                                                                                       155
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Humphreys, M., W. A. Masters, and M. E. Sandbu. 2006. “The Role of
                               Leaders in Democratic Deliberations: Results from a Field Experiment
                               in São Tomé and Principe.” World Politics 58(4): 583–622.
                          Huntington, S. P. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, CT:
                               Yale University Press.
                          Kaufmann, D., and A. Kraay. 2002. “Growth without Governance.”
                               Economia: Journal of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic
                               Association 3(1): 169–215.
                          Khemani, S., and W. Wane. 2008. “Populist Fiscal Policy.” Policy Research
                               Working Paper 4762, World Bank, Washington, DC.
                          La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny. 1999. “The
                               Quality of Government.” Journal of Law Economics & Organization 15(1):
                               222–79.
                          Labonne, J., and R. S. Chase. 2009. “Who Is at the Wheel When Communities
                               Drive Development? Evidence from the Philippines.” World Development
                               37(1): 219–31.
                          Leite, C., and J. Weidmann. 1999. “Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural
                               Resources, Corruption, and Economic Growth.” IMF Working Paper
                               99/85, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
                          Levitt, S. D., and J. M. Snyder. 1997. “The Impact of Federal Spending on
                               House Election Outcomes.” Journal of Political Economy 105(1): 30–53.
                          Lindbeck, A., and J. Weibull. 1987. “Balanced Budget Redistribution as the
                               Outcome of Political Competition.” Public Choice 52: 273–97.
                          List, J. A., and D. M. Sturm. 2006. “How Elections Matter: Theory and
                               Evidence from Environmental Policy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
                               121(4): 1249–81.
                          Litschig, S., and Y. Zamboni. 2007. “The Effect of Judicial Institutions
                               on Local Governance and Corruption.” Discussion Paper 0607-15,
                               Department of Economics, Columbia University, New York.
                          Manacorda, M., E. Miguel, and A. Vigorito. 2011. “Government Transfers
                               and Political Support.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics
                               3(3): 1–28.
                          Manor, J. 1999. The Political Economy of Democratic Decentralization.
                               Washington, DC: World Bank.
                          Mansuri, G. 2012a. “Bottom Up or Top Down; Participation and the
                               Provision of Local Public Goods.” World Bank, Poverty Reduction and
                               Economic Management, Washington, DC.
                          ———. 2012b. “Harnessing Community: Assortative Matching in Participa-
                               tory Community Organizations.” World Bank, Poverty Reduction and
                               Economic Management, Washington, DC.
                          Markussen, T. 2006. “Inequality and Party Capture: Theory and Evidence
                               from South India.” Discussion Paper 10-26, Department of Economics,
                               University of Copenhagen, Copenhagen, Denmark.
                          Mauro, P. 1995. “Corruption and Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
                               110(3): 681–712.
                          Mendez, F., and F. Sepulveda. 2010. “What Do We Talk about When We
                               Talk about Corruption?” Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 26(3):
                               493–514.

156
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



Miguel, E., and F. Zaidi. 2003. “Do Politicians Reward Their Supporters?
     Public Spending and Incumbency Advantage in Ghana.” University of
     California, Berkeley.
Mohan, G., and K. Stokke. 2000. “Participatory Development and
     Empowerment: The Dangers of Localism.” Third World Quarterly 21(2):
     247–68.
Mookherjee, D. 1997. “Incentive Reforms in Developing Country Bureau-
     cracies Lessons from Tax Administration.” Paper prepared for the
     Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics, World Bank,
     Washington, DC.
Mullainathan, S., and A. Shleifer. 2002. “Media Bias.” NBER Working Paper
     9295, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Murphy, W. 1990. “Creating the Appearance of Consensus in Mende Political
     Discourse.” American Anthropologist 92(1): 24–41.
Myerson, R. B. 1993. “Effectiveness of Electoral Systems for Reducing
     Government Corruption: A Game-Theoretic Analysis.” Games and
     Economic Behavior 5(1): 118–32.
O’Donnell, G. 1993. “On the State, Democratization and Some Conceptual
     Problems (A Latin American View with Glances at Some Post-Communist
     Countries).” World Development 21(8): 1355–69.
Olken, B. 2006. “Corruption and the Costs of Redistribution: Micro Evidence
     from Indonesia.” Journal of Public Economics 90(4–5): 853–70.
———. 2007. “Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment in
     Indonesia.” Journal of Political Economy 115(2): 200–49.
Olson, M. 1993. “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development.” American
     Political Science Review 87(3):567–76.
Paldam, M., and T. Svendsen. 2002. “Missing Social Capital and the
     Transition in Eastern Europe.” Journal for Institutional Innovation,
     Development and Transition 5: 21–34.
Persson, T., G. Roland, and G. Tabellini. 1997. “Separation of Powers
     and Political Accountability.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4):
     1163–202.
Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 2000. Political Economics: Explaining Economic
     Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
———. 2001. “Political Institutions and Policy Outcomes: What Are the
     Stylized Facts?” CESifo Working Paper 459, CESifo Group, Munich.
Platteau, J.-P., and F. Gaspart. 2003. “The Risk of Resource Misappropriation
     in Community-Driven Development.” World Development 31(10):
     1687–703.
Pradhan, M., V. Rao, and C. Rosenberg. 2009. The Impact of the Community
     Level Activities of the Second Urban Poverty Project. World Bank,
     Washington, DC.
Putnam, R. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy.
     Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Rao, V., and A. M. Ibanez. 2005. “The Social Impact of Social Funds in
     Jamaica: A ‘Participatory Econometric’ Analysis of Targeting, Collective
     Action, and Participation in Community-Driven Development.” Journal
     of Development Studies 41(5): 788–838.

                                                                                                      157
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Reinikka, R., and J. Svensson. 2004. “Local Capture: Evidence from a
                              Central Government Transfer Program in Uganda.” Quarterly Journal of
                              Economics 119(2): 679–705.
                          ———. 2005. “Fighting Corruption to Improve Schooling: Evidence from
                              a Newspaper Campaign in Uganda.” Journal of the European Economic
                              Association 3(2–3): 259–67.
                          ———. 2007. “The Returns from Reducing Corruption: Evidence from
                              Education in Uganda.” CEPR Discussion Paper 6363, Center for
                              Economic Policy and Research, London.
                          Rodriguez-Chamussy, L. 2009. “Local Electoral Rewards from Centralized
                              Social Programs: Are Mayors Getting the Credit?” Department of
                              Agricultural and Resources Economics, University of California,
                              Berkeley.
                          Rose-Ackerman, S. 2008. “Corruption and Government.” International
                              Peacekeeping 15(3): 328–43.
                          Samuels, D., and R. Snyder. 2001. “The Value of a Vote: Malapportionment
                              in Comparative Perspective.” British Journal of Political Science 31(4):
                              651–71.
                          Schady, N. R. 2000. “The Political Economy of Expenditures by the Peruvian
                              Social Fund (FONCODES), 1991–95.” American Political Science Review
                              94(2): 289–304.
                          Shankar, S., R. Gaiha, and R. Jha. 2010. “Information and Corruption:
                              The National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme in India.” ASARC
                              Working Paper 32-32, Australia South Asia Research Centre, Australian
                              National University, Canberra.
                          Shleifer, A., and R. W. Vishny. 1993. “Corruption.” Quarterly Journal of
                              Economics 108(3): 599–617.
                          Snyder, R. 1999. “After Neoliberalism: The Politics of Reregulation in
                              Mexico.” World Politics 51(2): 173–204.
                          Sorribas-Navarro, P., and A. Sole-Olle. 2008. “The Effects of Partisan
                              Alignment on the Allocation of Intergovernmental Transfers. Differences-
                              in-Differences Estimates for Spain.” Journal of Public Economics 92(12):
                              2302–19.
                          Stapenhurst, R. 2000. The Media’s Role in Curbing Corruption. Washington,
                              DC: World Bank Institute.
                          Stromberg, D. 2004a. “Mass Media Competition, Political Competition, and
                              Public Policy.” Review of Economic Studies 71(1): 265–84.
                          ———. 2004b. “Radio’s Impact on Public Spending.” Quarterly Journal of
                              Economics 119(1): 189–221.
                          Swamy, A., S. Knack, Y. Lee, and O. Azfar, 2000. “Gender and Cor-
                             ruption.” CDE Working Paper Series, Center for Development
                             Economics, Williams College, Williamstown, MA.
                          Treisman, D. 2000. “The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National Study.”
                               Journal of Public Economics 76(3): 399–457.
                          ———. 2007. “What Have We Learned about the Causes of Corruption
                               from Ten Years of Cross-National Empirical Research?” Annual Review
                               of Political Science 10(June): 211–44.

158
HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE?



Waller, C. J., T. Verdier, and R. Gardner. 2002. “Corruption: Top Down or
    Bottom Up?” Economic Inquiry 40(4): 688–703.
White, H. 2002. “Social Funds: A Review of the Issues.” Journal of
    International Development 14(5): 605–10.
World Bank. 2004. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for
    Poor People. Washington, DC: World Bank.
You, J. S., and S. Khagram. 2005. “A Comparative Study of Inequality and
    Corruption.” American Sociological Review 70(1): 136–57.




                                                                                                  159
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
CHAPTER FIVE




Does Participation Improve
Development Outcomes?

MUCH OF THE IMPETUS FOR INV ESTMENT IN PA RTICIPATORY
poverty reduction projects and decentralization efforts has come from
the hope that greater civic engagement will lead to faster and more
equitable development. In line with this notion, many countries have
shifted the provision of basic public services to the local level, and there
has been much greater emphasis on citizen engagement in service deliv-
ery through community health groups, school management commit-
tees, and similar groups. Common-pool resources are also increasingly
managed more locally, and small-scale infrastructure is often provided
through decentralized poverty reduction programs, social funds, and
community-driven development projects. Community-based livelihood
programs, which focus more directly on increasing income and employ-
ment, have also become an important component of large-scale poverty
reduction programs.
   This chapter assesses the extent to which this shift toward the local
has enhanced the pace of development, increased equity in access to
public programs, and improved the sustainability of development
efforts. The first section reviews efforts to decentralize the identifica-
tion of beneficiary households and communities for poverty reduction
and social insurance programs. The second section reviews efforts to
devolve the management of common-pool resources and summarizes
the evidence for greater resource sustainability and equity. The third
section examines local infrastructure delivered through participatory
mechanisms. The fourth section reviews efforts to induce greater com-
munity oversight in the delivery of health and education services. The
fifth section assesses the evidence on the poverty impacts of participa-
tory projects. The last section sums up the broad lessons learned.

                                                                               161
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?




                                   Identification of Beneficiaries
                                   A common approach to evaluating the relative efficiency of alternative
                                   targeting mechanisms has been to compare leakage and undercover-
                                   age rates. Much of the literature focuses almost exclusively on leakage
                                   and the extent to which it reflects resource capture by elites.1 Although
                                   this aspect of targeting is important, an exclusive focus on the identity
                                   of beneficiaries can draw attention away from what is ultimately of
                                   greatest interest: whether the poverty reduction objectives of targeted
                                   programs are achievable given the size and distribution of the budget
                                   (see Ravallion 2009b).
                                      Participatory poverty reduction programs typically use a combina-
                                   tion of targeting methods to identify beneficiary households and com-
                                   munities. When the government manages and implements programs,
                                   the center may allocate resources to subnational jurisdictions, using
                                   administrative criteria to satisfy broad political economy concerns,
                                   such as support to the poorest areas or the need to ensure horizontal
                                   equity. Local governments may then be required to identify the poor,
                                   or the most poorly served by public services, within their jurisdiction.
                                   Geographic and poverty targeting at higher levels is often combined
                                   with a demand-driven process at the community level to generate bene-
                                   ficiary lists for infrastructure projects. Community-driven development
                                   and social fund programs often do this by working with local nongov-
                                   ernmental organizations (NGOs) and community activists. Elected or
                                   selected local leaders are usually responsible for identifying beneficiaries
                                   when programs are implemented through local governments.
    The process of beneficiary         The process of beneficiary identification at the local level also varies
      identification at the local   substantially, both within and across projects, and is often left fuzzy.
level varies substantially, both   Critics worry that this leaves the process open to rent-seeking. One
   within and across projects,     response to the problem has been to use poverty monitoring tools to select
  possibly leaving the process     beneficiaries at the very local level.2 The use of such tools is not without
          open to rent-seeking.    costs, however, as it devalues the relevance of information at the local
                                   level—precisely the level at which such information is likely to be most
                                   valuable. The evidence reviewed below sheds some light on this issue.
                                      Participatory programs that invest in local public goods also rely on
                                   community and household self-selection. All social funds, for example,
                                   require community co-financing, with or without competition for
                                   funds. Communities as a whole, or specific community groups, must
                                   decide whether or not to submit a proposal for a project based on the

162
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



implied level of benefits and the cost of participation. The assumption
for targeted social funds is that the level of benefits is too low to make
participation advantageous for the better-off.
   Co-financing has long been seen as a cornerstone of participatory
development. It can be in the form of free or low-wage labor, cash, or
materials. It is believed that community co-financing ensures commu-
nity engagement in all aspects of the project, at construction and after,
thereby ensuring that investments are sustainable. As the community,
along with the government or donor agency, decides on the level of
provision of the good or service, co-financing is sometimes seen as a
lump-sum tax on public good provision.
   However, many observers view co-financing as an egregious aspect of         Many observers view
participatory projects, one that forces people with the least to either pay   co-financing—a cornerstone
more for their development needs than the better-off do or to opt out         of participatory development
and be excluded altogether from project benefits. Free labor provision         projects—as an egregious tax
by community members has even been compared with forced or corvée             on the poor.
labor (see chapter 1).3
   When communities compete for funds, with or without co-financ-
ing requirements, the overall targeting performance of projects also
depends on the capacity of eligible communities to submit adequate
proposals. Communities that have low capacity or cannot meet co-
financing requirements are often unable to submit projects for con-
sideration. Even the best-intentioned implementing agencies cannot
prevent this type of initial exclusion: although the use of administrative
criteria, such as the number of poor households served, can improve
targeting among applicants, it cannot reverse exclusion in the pool of
submitted projects.
   Program conditions such as the resources allocated to building com-        There is a pervasive concern
munity capacity or the information available to potential beneficiaries        in the literature about the
can therefore determine who applies for benefits as well as who gets           extent to which better-off
approved. Many community-based projects have remedial mechanisms              communities are more likely to
that are intended to ensure that all eligible communities can submit          propose and win subprojects.
feasible projects. Nonetheless, there is a pervasive concern in the litera-
ture about the extent to which better-off communities—communities
with greater capacity, political networks, or wealth—are more likely to
propose and win subprojects. This issue is addressed in the review that
follows, as far as is possible, by examining the targeting strategy and its
outcomes at different stages of the targeting process—that is, by look-
ing at factors such as program reliance on administrative targeting, a

                                                                                                        163
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   competitive fund allocation process, self-selection to determine eligibil-
                                   ity, and the extent to which program participation entails costs such as
                                   co-financing or a challenging application process.


                                   Central versus Local Targeting of Private Transfers
        Some studies suggest       Most studies that have examined the relative targeting performance of
        that local co-financing     the center versus local areas in assigning private benefits find support
 requirements can exacerbate       for more pro-poor targeting at the local level. However, the increase in
          horizontal inequities,   targeting performance is small, with programs only mildly pro-poor
   particularly when eligibility   on balance. Moreover, some evidence suggests that the local targeting
           thresholds are also     of poor areas or households is substantially improved when the center
                 decentralized.    provides stronger incentives for pro-poor targeting by local govern-
                                   ments or implementing agencies, often by retaining control over key
                                   design features of the program, such as eligibility thresholds. Some
                                   studies suggest that local co-fi nancing requirements can exacerbate
                                   horizontal inequities, particularly when eligibility thresholds are also
                                   decentralized.
                                      Evidence from an Albanian economic support program (the Ndihme
                                   Ekonomika) indicates that local officials were able to target recipients
                                   better than the center could have done using proxy entitlement indica-
                                   tors (Alderman 2002). The program provided social assistance to some
                                   20 percent of the population through a block grant to communes.
                                   Local officials determined eligibility and the amount of the transfer to
                                   beneficiary households.
                                      Galasso and Ravallion (2005) find similar evidence for a decentral-
                                   ized poverty program in Bangladesh. The Food-for-Education program
                                   distributed fixed food rations to selected poor households conditional
                                   on their school-age children attending at least 85 percent of classes.
                                   The center was responsible for identifying eligible union parishads, the
                                   lowest level of local government. Villages in eligible union parishads
                                   were then made responsible for identifying program beneficiaries.
                                   The program was mildly pro-poor (slightly more poor than nonpoor
                                   households received rations). Although the targeting differential was
  The center is often better at    small—the program achieved about one-fifth the maximum targeting
  targeting poor communities       differential—almost all of it occurred because beneficiaries were well
         than identifying poor     targeted within villages.4
      households within such          A series of other studies broadly supports these fi ndings. Coady
                 communities.      (2001) examines a large Mexican cash transfer program (Progresa),

164
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



which selected poor households on the basis of census data without any
community involvement. He finds some support for the center’s ability
to target eligible communities but, in line with other studies, finds that
the center is far less able to identify poor households within targeted
poor communities.
   In their study of the Trabajar 2 program in Argentina, Ravallion
(2000) and Jalan and Ravallion (2003) demonstrate the center’s role
in providing incentives for more pro-poor targeting by local govern-
ments. This World Bank–supported program, introduced in 1997,
expanded an earlier workfare program, Trabajar 1, in order to provide
an additional period of short-term work to poor households and to
locate socially useful projects in poor areas. Under Trabajar 2, the
central government allocated funds to the provinces, making an effort
to provide more program funding to poorer provinces. Provincial gov-
ernments then allocated funds to projects within the provinces. Local
governments and NGOs proposed subprojects and bore their nonwage
costs. The results show that self-targeting in the program worked well,
with participants overwhelmingly drawn from among the poorest
households. The studies also find some improvement in reaching poorer
areas within provinces. About a third of the overall improvement came
from better targeting of provinces; the rest came from better targeting
of poor areas within provinces.5
   However, a more recent assessment of the targeting performance of
this program (Ronconi 2009) finds greater leakage and smaller income
effects. It also finds some evidence that nontargeted beneficiaries were
more politically connected.
   A number of studies use data from rural India to examine whether
participation in mandatory village assemblies (gram sabhas) called by
elected village councils (gram panchayats) to discuss resource allocation
decisions in the village improved the allocation of central transfer pro-
grams. These programs provide an array of government schemes, ranging
from subsidized food through the public distribution system to housing
schemes and free hospitalization to poor households. In collaboration
with state government officials, through a census, the gram panchayat
identifies households eligible to receive Below Poverty Line (BPL)
cards. The list of BPL households, as well as the subsequent selection
of beneficiaries for specific schemes, needs to be ratified at public gram
sabha meetings. The Indian Planning Commission reports that there is
a perception of significant mistargeting in the allocation of BPL cards.

                                                                                       165
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



 Some evidence suggests that         Besley, Pande, and Rao (2005, 2007) find that villages that hold a
    villages in India that hold   gram sabha do a better job of targeting BPL cards to the most disad-
    a gram sabha do a better      vantaged villagers. People without any formal schooling, for example,
     job of targeting the most    fare substantially better in villages that hold gram sabhas. However, not
               disadvantaged.     all villages hold such meetings, and among those that do, only about
                                  a fifth discuss beneficiary selection for public programs. Consequently,
                                  most local politicians in their sample (87 percent of the 540 surveyed)
                                  believed that they, rather than the gram sabha, were responsible for
                                  benefit allocation decisions.
                                     Bardhan and others (2008) also find that villages that had greater
                                  gram sabha participation rates were more pro-poor in their allocation of
                                  benefits. Although they are careful to point out that this finding does
                                  not provide evidence of a causal impact of gram sabha meetings on tar-
                                  geting, they argue that it is consistent with the hypothesis that village
                                  meetings “formed a channel of accountability of gram panchayats to
                                  poor and low caste groups” (p. 7). Besley, Pande, and Rao (2007) also
                                  find support for the disciplinary effect of the gram sabha on capture.
                                  They show that the odds of a politician’s household receiving a BPL card
                                  were lower in villages in which a gram sabha was held.
                                     These results are only suggestive, as the design of these studies does
                                  not allow the authors to determine why some villages hold meetings
                                  and others do not. Several studies using data from India have tried to
                                  identify village characteristics that predict the holding of gram sabhas as
                                  well as household characteristics associated with participation. Bardhan
                                  and others (2008) find that participation rates were higher in villages in
                                  which the proportion of landless and scheduled caste households was
                                  lower. Besley, Pande, and Rao (2007) find higher participation rates
                                  for the landless and low caste in villages with higher average levels of
                                  education.
                                     Kumar (2007) looks at the effect of community participation on
                                  the targeting of BPL cards in India. Her data come from the state
                                  of Madhya Pradesh, where a participatory development project, the
                                  District Poverty Initiatives Project (DPIP), was initiated in 2001. She
                                  assesses the extent to which DPIP, which aims to build political aware-
                                  ness and confidence among the disadvantaged, affects the allocation of
                                  BPL cards to eligible households. Her results indicate that the targeting
                                  of BPL cards is indeed more pro-poor in DPIP villages, where a greater
                                  fraction of BPL cardholders are landless and belong to lower castes. (See
                                  also the discussion in chapter 6.)

166
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



   Ravallion (2009a) examines the relationship between central and
local targeting, using data from the implementation of Di Bao, a decen-
tralized urban poverty reduction program in China. The program aims
to provide all urban households with a transfer payment sufficient to
bring their incomes up to a predetermined poverty line. The center set
the guidelines and provided about 60 percent of the program’s costs on
average, making some effort to bear a larger share of the cost in poorer
provinces.6 Municipalities were allowed to set the eligibility threshold
for benefits and identify beneficiaries.
   The question of interest is whether poorer municipalities had incen-
tives under these conditions to understate their poverty problems by set-
ting lower thresholds. The analysis shows that poorer cities did indeed
set lower poverty lines and thus had lower participation rates. As a
result, equally poor families ended up with very different levels of access
to the program, with the poor in the poorest cities typically faring worst.
This problem greatly diminished the program’s ability to reach the poor.
   An important dimension of inducing greater civic engagement in the           Local determination of
identification of beneficiaries is that local perceptions of need may not         need may take into account
coincide with the ways the center determines program eligibility. This          variables not observed by
divergence in perceptions may account for some of the perceived leakage         the center.
in transfer programs when such programs are assessed using means tests
or other information that external agents can observe. The literature in
this area is sparse, but the evidence suggests that local determination of
need may take into account variables not observed by the center, pos-
sibly creating a divergence in notions of eligibility between the center
and localities.
   In a case study of famine relief efforts in Southern Sudan, Harragin         The mechanisms used to
(2004) finds that local ideas of how food should be distributed differed         identify beneficiaries are
from the ideas of aid workers, resulting in a poorly designed project.          crucial in determining how
Ethnographic and case study evidence supports the view that the mech-           pro-poor decentralized
anisms used to identify beneficiaries are crucial in determining how             targeting will be, especially
pro-poor decentralized targeting will be, especially when community             when community members
members have unequal access to project implementers.                            have unequal access to
   Alatas and others (2012) report on a field experiment designed to             project implementers.
understand how community methods fare relative to a proxy means
test in targeting resources to the poor.7 They collected proxy means
test information for all households in all sample villages, randomly
varying its use in assigning eligibility. In a third of sample villages, only
the proxy means test was used to assign eligibility; in another third,

                                                                                                            167
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                 beneficiaries were selected through a community ranking exercise; in
                                 another third, the proxy means test was used to determine eligibility of
                                 people identified by the community. The authors find very little support
                                 for the benefits of community targeting over the proxy means test when
                                 poverty status is measured based on per capita expenditures. This find-
                                 ing is somewhat surprising given the substantial leakage and exclusion
                                 that can occur under even the best-designed proxy means test. One
                                 would expect that in very small communities like the ones the authors
                                 worked with, access to relevant information on recent shocks might at
                                 least improve coverage of the eligible based on per capita consumption.
      Meetings confined to the       The authors also fi nd no evidence that meetings confi ned to the
 village elite may not produce   village elite produced worse targeting outcomes than meetings that
     worse targeting outcomes    included a more representative group. Furthermore, households more
 than meetings that include a    closely connected to elites were not more likely to benefit when meetings
   more representative group.    were confined to elites. Despite poorer targeting outcomes, community
                                 targeting resulted in higher satisfaction levels.
                                    Alatas and others (2012) use data on poverty perceptions to make
                                 sense of these results. They check the correlation of a household’s sub-
                                 jective ranking of itself and other households against rankings from the
                                 community targeting exercise and the proxy means test. They find a
                                 higher correlation of self-perception with the rankings obtained under
                                 community targeting. Taken together, they argue, their results suggest
                                 that communities employ a concept of poverty that is different from per
                                 capita expenditure and that this difference explains the ostensibly worse
                                 performance of community targeting. As communities use different cri-
                                 teria to ascribe poverty status, they contend, it is understandable that a
                                 strategy that valorizes their preferences yields greater satisfaction levels.
                                    Gugerty and Kremer (2006) also find that the women’s groups
                                 they study in Kenya reported more satisfaction with group leadership.
                                 There was little improvement in objective measures of group activity,
                                 however, and the women did not have better attendance rates than the
                                 comparison groups.
                                    Although these results are interesting, it is difficult to know how
                                 to assess their validity. In the study by Alatas and others (2012), for
                                 example, the treatment provided a one-time transfer that was a little
                                 less than a third of the monthly transfer received by eligible households
                                 under the Indonesian government’s main transfer program, the Bantuan
                                 Langsung Tunai (BLT), potentially limiting the gains from capture.
                                 Equally important, aware that this was a small study and distinct from

168
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



the BLT, village elites and government administrators may have found       Much of the evidence from
it opportune to demonstrate transparency. The careful design of the        studies of large-scale transfer
community-based targeting meeting, along with the very small and           programs points to substantial
relatively homogeneous subvillages or neighborhoods that were selected     heterogeneity in the manner
for the study, may also have affected the results. Much of the evidence    in which community input is
from studies of large-scale transfer programs, including programs in       solicited and to significant
Indonesia, points to substantial heterogeneity in the manner in which      capture of funds.
community input is solicited and to significant capture of funds (see
chapter 4).


Central versus Local Targeting of Public Goods
Several studies of social funds find pro-poor geographic targeting by
the center in allocating local public goods. Some, however, find weaker
central capacity to target the poor within eligible areas. Chase and
Sherburne-Benz (2001) and Pradhan and Rawlings (2002), for example,
find that investments made under the Zambia social fund (ZAMSIF)
and the Nicaragua social fund were generally well targeted to both poor
communities and poor households. In Zambia, however, targeting was
effective only in rural communities; in urban areas, better-off com-
munities and households were selected. A review of social fund projects
by the World Bank’s Independent Evaluation Group (2002) also finds
this bias. Araujo and others (2008) find that geographic targeting at
the level of the community appears to have worked well in Ecuador’s
social fund, with poorer communities more likely to be selected for
subproject funding.
   Paxson and Schady (2002) assess the poverty targeting of the            Several studies of social funds
Peruvian social fund using district-level data on expenditures and pov-    find pro-poor geographic
erty. They find that the fund, which emphasized geographic targeting,       targeting by the center . . .
reached the poorest districts but not the poorest households in those
districts: better-off households were slightly more likely than poor
households to benefit. Using propensity score matching techniques,
Chase (2002) fi nds similar results in Armenia. Although the social
fund was successful in targeting communities with the poorest infra-
structure, these communities were not always among the poorest, and
the fund was slightly regressive in targeting households in rural areas.
   De Janvry, Nakagawa, and Sadoulet (2009) explore the relationship       . . . but some find weaker
between decentralization and pro-poor targeting within districts under     central capacity to target the
the third phase of ZAMSIF. Districts were grouped into three categories    poor within eligible areas.

                                                                                                      169
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                 based on administrative capacity. In districts with the lowest capacity,
                                 targeting remained fully centralized. Districts with greater capacity
                                 were given progressively more control over resources, culminating in
                                 full decentralization of decision making for some.
                                     Decentralization did not affect the allocation of funds across dis-
                                 tricts, but it did affect a district’s capacity to allocate resources across
                                 its wards. Using two measures of welfare (school enrollment and an
                                 index of housing conditions), the authors find that the center’s target-
                                 ing of districts was not progressive—and was even somewhat regres-
                                 sive in some phases. In contrast, the within-district targeting of wards
                                 became more progressive over time in all districts, especially districts
                                 given greater discretion. A caveat regarding these results is that the
                                 districts that had greater discretion over resource allocation decisions
                                 also had greater managerial capacity. It is unclear, therefore, whether
                                 more progressive targeting in these districts reflected greater decen-
                                 tralization or greater capacity. Interestingly, within-district effects in
                                 the higher-capacity districts were driven almost entirely by wards with
                                 high literacy levels.
 A study in Tanzania finds that       Baird, McIntosh, and Özler (2009) focus on the process by which
   demand-driven application     Tanzania’s Social Action Fund (TASAF) allocated subprojects within
      processes were strongly    districts. Using administrative data on project submission and approval,
                   regressive.   they find that the demand-driven application process was strongly
                                 regressive, with many more applications originating from wealthier
                                 and more literate districts. The political affiliation of ward and district
                                 representatives also influenced the allocation of TASAF money. Wards
                                 that were aligned with the party in power were significantly more likely
                                 to apply; wards in which both the ward and the district representatives
                                 were from the opposition party were significantly less likely to apply.
                                 Ironically, a strongly pro-poor allocation of district-level budgets from
                                 the center managed to undo much of this regressivity in applications,
                                 leaving a mildly pro-poor program overall, although the poverty reduc-
                                 tion objectives of the center were considerably attenuated.
                                     Labonne and Chase’s (2009) work on the KALAHI-CIDSS project
                                 in the Philippines also provides a good example of the tension between
                                 pro-poor targeting and a competitive demand-driven process of sub-
                                 project elicitation. As in other community-driven development and
                                 social fund projects, facilitators in KALAHI-CIDSS help communities
                                 identify priorities and prepare and submit proposals. After review at a
                                 municipal-level meeting, a subset of proposed projects is funded.

170
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



   In the study, respondents were asked to name the three most press-
ing issues in the village before any project activities got under way.
Combining these data with administrative data on projects proposed
and accepted, the authors assessed whether the preferences of spe-
cific groups mattered at the project proposal and acceptance stage.
Consistent with other studies, they find that the competitive subproject
proposal and approval process led to fewer applications from poorer and
less politically connected villages. In addition, while the village leader’s
preferences on both project type and location appeared to be influential
in determining which projects were put forward, these preferences were
much less likely to sway the outcome at the municipal level. In fact, as
in Tanzania, municipal allocation rules undid some of the regressivity in
proposed projects. Given the initial bias in proposed projects, however,
municipal allocation rules had limited success, and funded proposals
remained well aligned with the village leader’s preferences. The influ-
ence of the village leader was much greater in villages with greater
wealth inequality. Controlling for poverty, more unequal villages were
also more likely to have their projects approved, indicating that local
leaders in more unequal villages may also exercise greater influence over
the inter-village approval process.
   As discussed above, China’s Di Bao program (Ravallion 2009a) sug-           The poorest communities may
gests that the poorest communities may underparticipate or self-select         underparticipate or self-select
out of programs that require them to foot part of the bill for private         out of programs that require
benefits or local public goods. This tendency may partly account for            them to foot part of the bill
the lack of applications from poorer districts and wards in the TASAF          for private benefits or local
program. A key similarity between the two programs is that eligibility         public goods.
criteria are decentralized and a portion of the funds come from the
center, which progressively targets poorer localities (districts in TASAF
and municipalities in Di Bao). Under TASAF, participation by poorer
districts is depressed at the application stage, whereas under Di Bao,
municipalities have an incentive to depress their participation rates in
the program in the face of budget constraints. In both cases, the net
effect is that despite progressive targeting from the center, the overall
poverty impact of the program is attenuated. Chase (2002) also argues
that mandatory community contributions in the Armenia Social Fund
may have led to a selection bias against the poorest communities, which
are often unwilling or unable to contribute.
   In the TASAF and ZAMSIF studies, weak community capacity also
appears to be a deterrent to participation. Unlike the Di Bao program,

                                                                                                          171
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    wealthier districts in TASAF or KALAHI-CIDSS were also not able
                                    to target their own poor better than poorer districts, suggesting greater
                                    capture of program benefits by the relatively well off.



                                    Sustainable Management of Common-Pool Resources
 Institutions for local resource    Local institutions for resource governance have increased substantially
   governance have increased        over the past two decades, at least in numbers, as national governments
substantially over the past two     have created new institutional arrangements to engage local popula-
                    decades . . .   tions in the governance of natural resources (Stern, Dietz, and Ostrom
                                    2003). Estimates place the share of the world’s natural forests officially
                                    managed with some form of popular participation at about 12 percent
                                    (Sunderlin, Hatcher, and Liddle 2008)—and this figure probably sig-
                                    nificantly underestimates the actual figure, as it excludes forests that are
                                    officially managed by the state but actually managed by local communi-
                                    ties and private individuals.
        . . . accompanied by a          This expansion has been accompanied by a more enfranchising
      more enfranchising view       view of decentralized natural resource management, which represents
      of decentralized natural      a major shift from the past. Historically, popular participation in the
 resource management, which         management of natural resources was closely associated with colonial
      represents a major shift      efforts to extend control over local resources. In the case of forests, an
                 from the past.     expansion in local participation under colonial rule was precipitated by
                                    industrialization and higher prices for timber and other forest products.
                                    In the case of water for irrigation, local participation increased when
                                    colonial governments made large investments in irrigation infrastruc-
                                    ture, which also created greater management needs.8 Many newly inde-
                                    pendent nations chose to reverse this process, initially, by recentralizing
                                    and consolidating power at the center.
                                        Decentralization efforts around natural resource management gained
                                    momentum in development policy circles only in the 1970s, largely
                                    under outside pressure from international aid organizations and donors,
                                    motivated by both concerns about the accountability of central govern-
                                    ments and recognition of resource depletion and climate change.9 By
                                    the 1980s, decentralized natural resource management had come to be
                                    associated with the broader project of poverty reduction10 and the build-
                                    ing of democratic local institutions (Ribot, Lund, and Treue 2010).11
                                        The push for localizing natural resource management has thus paral-
                                    leled the broader move toward participatory development over the past

172
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



two decades. A large body of literature, based largely on case studies,       Community management of
has been extremely influential in this process. It has established the         common-pool resources has
pervasive presence of local institutions in the management of natural         come to be seen as a viable
resources, with or without state support, and demonstrated the viability      alternative to privatization or
of community management as an alternative to either privatization or          management by a centralized
management by a centralized state bureaucracy.12                              state bureaucracy.
   In practice, the local management of common-pool resources takes
many institutional forms, and there is often substantial divergence
between formal and de facto community control as well as the types of
decision making transferred to local governments or user communities.
The extent and type of central government involvement also varies a
great deal with the value placed on the resource. The scale of national
and international interest in a common-pool resource also depends on
the size of the externality it creates. With forests, the interests of the
global community can also be relevant; they can determine the form
of management as well as the allocation of benefits. In contrast, in the
case of irrigation water or pastures, the main concerns are likely to be
capture by insiders and local incentives and capacity to maintain the
resource base.
   It is important to distinguish community-based natural resource
management (CBNRM) and decentralization. Like community-driven
development, CBNRM refers to the direct or indirect involvement of
local communities at a relatively small scale to shape the use, distribu-
tion, and management of resources. Democratic decentralization—
under which local representative authorities receive powers in the name
of local citizens—can be considered a manifestation of CBNRM,
but the devolution of powers to user groups, chiefs, NGOs, private
corporations, or private individuals is not decentralization. Likewise,
transfers to local line ministries (that is, deconcentration) is not a form
of CBNRM.13
   These distinctions are borne in mind in the literature review pre-
sented in this chapter. The review is selective, with a focus on the fol-
lowing questions: When does community engagement in resource man-
agement enhance resource sustainability (regenerated forests, increased
forest cover, more sustainable fish and livestock harvesting, better water
storage and use systems)? Is local management more inclusive and more
equitable than central management or an unmanaged commons? In
each case, to what extent is success shaped or constrained by preexisting
community characteristics? Can local management systems be designed

                                                                                                          173
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   to overcome adverse local characteristics—that is, can design induce the
                                   right type and level of participation? How dependent is success on the
                                   role played by the central state?
                                      The literature on community involvement in the management of
                                   natural resources is large and multidisciplinary, but most of it is based
                                   on case studies. Well-done case studies can add greatly to the under-
                                   standing of processes; they are often less helpful, however, in establish-
                                   ing causal relationships between the structural features of communities,
                                   the institutions of governance established within them, and their impact
                                   on measures of system performance. The few research studies that use
                                   large datasets and attempt to deal with problems of selection into com-
                                   munity management, are therefore highlighted in the discussion below.


                                   Local Management and Resource Sustainability
                                   Much of the literature on CBNRM and decentralized resource man-
                                   agement focuses on the conditions under which the commons can
                                   be better governed—that is, the conditions under which community
                                   participation leads to greater resource sustainability (see, for example,
                                   Wade 1985; Ostrom 1990; Baland and Platteau 1997). This focus is
                                   in large part driven by Hardin’s concerns about the fate of an unregu-
                                   lated commons. Many case studies suggest the viability of community
                                   management of natural resources with or without state assistance (see
                                   Agrawal and Benson 2010 for a review). The verdict on government-
                                   initiated institutions for community resource management has been
                                   bleaker.14
Several studies based on large         However, several studies that use large data sets to examine the impact of
  data sets suggest that it may    government-initiated institutions of community forest management
   be possible for governments     show that it may be possible for governments to successfully induce
 to successfully induce natural    natural resource management on a large scale. A key point made by
    resource management on a       all of these studies is that there is considerable selection in community
                    large scale.   management of natural resources, because community takeover is usu-
                                   ally voluntary. Case studies cannot deal with such selection or with
                                   spillover effects, which can also bias results considerably.
                                       Edmonds (2002) uses data from Nepal to determine the impact
                                   on the level of extraction of wood for fuel of a government-initiated
                                   program that transferred management of forests to local user groups.
                                   The evidence suggests that there was a significant reduction in wood
                                   extraction in areas with forest user groups.15

174
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



    Somanathan, Prabhakar, and Singh (2005) assess the impact of
local forest councils (van panchayats [VPs]) on forest degradation in the
Indian state of Uttaranchal. Unlike Edmonds, they use satellite-based
measures of forest quality (principally predictors of canopy cover) over
a large geographical region that included VP and non VP forests in
Uttaranchal. This methodology circumvents the problem of using com-
munity reported measures of local forest quality. The authors assess the
long-run impact of decentralized management by village councils on
forest stocks. Their study is also the only one that compares the cost of
state and community management.16
    The results indicate that broadleaved forests, which are of much greater   A study of India suggests that
relevance for local use, improved significantly under VP management but         community management of
that there was no improvement in pine forests (VP–managed pine forests         state forests would generate
did no worse than comparable state-managed forests). At the same time,         annual savings equal to
community management was far more cost effective than state manage-            the value of total annual
ment. The authors’ calculations suggest that transferring state forests to     production of firewood from
community management would generate annual savings equal to the                state forests.
value of the total annual production of firewood from state forests.
    Baland and others (2010) also assess the impact of VPs on forest
degradation in Uttaranchal, using a wider set of measures of forest qual-
ity. They find that VP management improved the extraction of wood
for fuel and fodder but did not lead to broader improvements in forest
quality, such as canopy cover or forest regeneration. Their results indicate
that VPs had little impact on tree-cutting or timber extraction, which
may be a much greater source of forest degradation than the extraction
of wood for fuel and fodder. However, the improvement that did occur
was not at the cost of neighboring non VP forest parcels.17 Their findings
suggest that community management is often a response to the degrada-
tion of local forests. If this is the case, then any simple comparison of
community-managed forests with forests managed by the state, or not
managed at all, will tend to show no or even negative impact, as Agrawal
and Chhatre find in their study of the Indian Himalayas (2006).
    The impact of inequality on collective action has been at the center
of a number of theoretical and empirical studies of management by
communities or users, particularly in the fisheries sector and in the
management of irrigation. It has also been an important focus in the
case study literature on common-pool resource management. Ostrom,
Lam, and Lee (1994) and Ostrom (1990) show that farmer-managed
irrigation schemes have more equitable water distribution, for example,

                                                                                                          175
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  but they do not compare the functioning of farmer-managed systems
                                  in more and less equal communities.
      Maintenance of irrigation      Studies that look explicitly at the impact of local inequality on the
          systems tends to be     maintenance of irrigation systems find by and large that maintenance
       worse in more unequal      is worse in more unequal communities. Dayton-Johnson (2000) devel-
           and heterogeneous      ops a model of cooperation in small irrigation systems, which he tests
             communities . . .    with data from a survey of Mexican irrigation societies. He finds that
                                  social heterogeneity and landholding inequality are consistently and sig-
                                  nificantly associated with lower levels of maintenance. Bardhan (2000)
                                  finds similar results in South India.
                                     Dayton-Johnson and Bardhan (2002) attempt to reconcile views
                                  from the field study literature with Olson’s (1965) view that inequality
                                  should be good for collective action. Their study pulls together data
                                  from a number of irrigation systems, including three large-scale studies
                                  from Nepal, southern India, and central Mexico. Overall, the findings
                                  suggest that however it is defined, heterogeneity weakens a group’s abil-
                                  ity to use social norms to enforce collective agreements and generally
                                  has a negative impact on cooperation. Moreover, even after controlling
                                  for social heterogeneity, inequality in the distribution of wealth con-
                                  tinues to exercise a significant and largely negative effect. The authors
                                  conclude that although “Olson effects” are theoretically plausible under
                                  certain conditions, they do not seem to be operative in the irrigation
                                  systems they examine. They do fi nd some evidence for a U-shaped
                                  relationship between inequality and collective action, with conservation
                                  possible only when inequality is very low or very high, not in between.
                                  In a similar vein, Bardhan, Ghatak, and Karaivanov (2007) show that
                                  when private inputs, such as land, are complementary in production
                                  with collective inputs, such as irrigation water, inequality in the owner-
                                  ship of private inputs tends to worsen maintenance.
       . . . but adequate local
                                     A number of studies note, however, that adequate local discretion
       discretion may be able
                                  can overcome problems created by inequalities among resource users.
        to overcome problems
                                  Adhikari and Lovett (2006) use data from forest user groups in Nepal
  created by inequality among
                                  to argue that successful collective action can be achieved even when
                resource users.
                                  inequalities among resource users exist, provided that communities can
        A great deal of forest    exercise discretion in creating institutions for resource management.
conservation and regeneration        A number of other case studies of forestry management highlight the
     has been achieved under      same point. Hobley (1996) finds that in some states in India, as well as
   community management in        in Nepal, a great deal of forest conservation and regeneration has been
Nepal and some Indian states.     achieved under community management. Adhikari and Lovett (2006)

176
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



and Hobley (1996) report on cases in which user communities were able
to exercise substantial discretion and had clear incentives to manage and
preserve the resource.
   In Africa, accounts of failure far outnumber accounts of success,         Donor-supported projects
except in Cameroon, Malawi, and Tanzania. Ribot, Lund, and Treue             often fail to empower local
(2010), who review a large number of case studies, blame this failure on     bodies, relying instead on
weak local governments and poorly thought-out donor programs. They           disenfranchising colonial
note that donor-supported projects often fail to empower representative      practices oriented toward
and downwardly accountable local bodies, relying instead on disenfran-       extraction and control.
chising colonial practices oriented toward extraction and control (see
also Ribot 2007; Ribot, Chhatre, and Lankina 2008).
   These results suggest that successful collective action requires the      Successful collective action
establishment of clear and credible systems of accountability and that       requires the establishment
such rules may not be forthcoming in unequal communities, creat-             of clear and credible systems
ing a space for central effort in setting the rules of the game. Dayton-     of accountability, which may
Johnson and Bardhan’s (2002) analysis provides an important                  not be forthcoming in unequal
insight. They note that heterogeneity affects not just the extent            communities.
of cooperation, given a set of rules, but the type of rules chosen.
Furthermore, not all rules are equally conducive to good performance
or equity, and unequal communities are less likely to pick effective and
equitable rules.                                                             When externalities are
   Ribot (2004) notes that when externalities are significant, it is par-     significant, it is particularly
ticularly important that standards and rules be set at a higher level. If,   important that standards and
for example, conversion is forbidden as a precondition for local control     rules be set at a higher level.
of the forests, incentives may need to be put in place that link conser-
vation with livelihoods. In the absence of such incentives, there is no
inherent reason to believe that local people will not sell off or convert
forests if doing so is the most lucrative option.                            In much of Africa, the
                                                                             devolution of responsibilities
Is Local Management More Equitable?                                          to communities has been
                                                                             mainly about maintaining
Community management is expected to satisfy the twin goals of attain-        opportunities for rent-
ing resource sustainability and increasing equity in the distribution of     seeking or ensuring resource
benefits. But these objectives are not necessarily complementary. Ribot,      sustainability for the benefit
Lund, and Treue (2010) argue that in much of Africa, the devolution          of higher-level groups or
of responsibilities to communities has been mainly about maintaining         international interests . . .
opportunities for rent-seeking or ensuring resource sustainability for the
benefit of higher-level national groups or international interests, with      . . . with the costs borne
the costs borne mainly by local inhabitants.                                 mainly by local inhabitants.

                                                                                                           177
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



 When local structures are not      Several other studies also suggest that decentralization can create
 accountable to communities,     perverse outcomes for the poorest and most vulnerable groups when
          decentralization can   local structures are not accountable to communities. In India, Kumar
    create perverse outcomes     (2002) reports that the joint management of Sal (Shorea robusta) forests
     for the poorest and most    has, if anything, deepened poverty because, despite community partici-
            vulnerable groups.   pation in the management of these forests, the emphasis has remained
                                 on high forests and timber production, which originated under colonial
                                 rule as an aspect of “scientific forestry.” As the forest canopy closes,
                                 however, nonwood forest products, which are of particular importance
                                 for the poor, decline, deepening poverty.
                                    In Tanzania, Lund and Treue (2008) fi nd that the taxation and
                                 licensing system for the production of timber and charcoal that was
                                 introduced under decentralized forest management has created new
                                 entry barriers for the poorest producers, making them more dependent
                                 on town-based traders and village leaders. Wood (1999) argues that
                                 larger farmers in the more backward state of Bihar in India routinely
                                 negotiate preferential access to irrigation systems by paying bribes to
                                 local officials.
   The poor may have greater        The poor are often more dependent than the nonpoor on access to
       motivation to maintain    natural resources. Jodha (1986, 2001) estimates that 15–25 percent of
    resources such as forests    the incomes of the rural poor in India comes from natural resources. In
    or pastures, because they    their survey of a large number of studies of India and West Africa, Beck
  depend on them for a larger    and Nesmith (2001) also find higher levels of reliance on common-pool
        share of their income.   resources among the landless poor. Gregerson and Contreras (1989)
                                 estimate that more than a third of the world’s population relies on local
                                 forests to meet basic household needs. Studies also indicate that the
                                 relatively better-off tend to benefit more from common-pool resources,
                                 although the poor are far more dependent on such resources (that is,
                                 the share of forest income in their total income is higher), perhaps
                                 indicating some scope for redistribution (Cavendish 2000; Campbell
                                 2003; Fisher 2004; Narain, Gupta, and Van’t Veld 2005; Lund and
                                 Treue 2008). The products the poor derive from the forest—fuel,
                                 water, fodder, and food—also have few affordable market alternatives
                                 and thus also constitute an important safety net (Pattanayak and Sills
                                 2001; McSweeney 2005). As a result, some researchers argue that poorer
                                 members of a community may have a greater motivation to maintain
                                 resources such as forests or pastures, given the right set of incentives, as
                                 the risk-adjusted return to doing so may be higher for them.
                                    In practice, however, rules regarding access and fees are rarely
                                 changed when management becomes more local. One reason is that
178
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



the poor, who rely the most on the forest, are often also a minority           In practice, however, local
group whose interests do not coincide with those of village leaders or         management seems to
the village majority. The choice of local institutions and the rules regu-     disproportionately benefit
lating such institutions are set by higher-level institutions that reflect a    the rich, powerful, and well
multitude of values and interests, ranging from concerns with resource         connected.
sustainability, biodiversity, and carbon storage to the desire for a strate-
gic political advantage or enhanced opportunities for rent-seeking. The
choices these institutions make are influenced by national elites as well
as a host of international interests, including bilateral and multilateral
donors (Ferguson 1996; Blaikie 2006; Ribot, Lund, and Treue 2010).
As a result, policies originally designed to favor elites under colonial
structures are often maintained, even when countries officially promote
popular participation in natural resource management. Mustalahti and
Lund (2010), for example, find that despite official policies supporting
community participation in forestry in the Lao People’s Democratic
Republic, Mozambique, and Tanzania, local communities were sys-
tematically prevented from sharing in the returns from commercially
valuable forest resources. A number of other studies raise similar con-
cerns regarding the disproportionate advantages obtained by the rich,
powerful, and well connected (see, for example, Ribot 1995; Larson and
Ribot 2007; Lund and Treue 2008).
   Beck and Nesmith’s (2001) review suggests that a process of pro-            Unless management regimes
gressive exclusion of the poor from natural resource–based livelihood          are specifically designed
sources may be underway even where conservation has been success-              to include poor people,
ful, as in India and Tanzania. They caution that unless management             community-based natural
regimes are specifically designed to include poor people, CBNRM may             resource management may
end up as little more than donor- supported control by elites. Dasgupta        end up as little more than
and Mäler (1995) illustrates how this cycle can lead to an environmental       donor-supported control by
poverty trap. Nerlove (1991) shows that increasing rates of deforesta-         elites.
tion may lead to greater population growth and even faster rates of
deforestation.
   Several studies caution against assuming that the introduction of
simple participatory mechanisms can ensure downward accountability
in the absence of clear mechanisms for ensuring compliance. Two case
studies from Tanzania and Senegal are illustrative. Lund (2007) reports
that a new requirement in Tanzania that elected forest committee mem-
bers provide oral accounts of all forest-related incomes and expenditures
at quarterly village assemblies led to greater equity in the distribution
of forest-related incomes. However, as Ribot, Lund, and Treue (2010)
note, such simple changes in rules, though powerful, may work only
                                                                                                              179
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



   Without credible sanctions,      when there is clear support from higher tiers of government and com-
    community members have          mensurate mechanisms to sanction local leaders are in place. They note
       no ability or capacity to    that in the Tanzanian case, a watchful donor and an involved district
      monitor corrupt officials,     council and forest office provided this support. In contrast, they note
    who know that allegations       that in Senegal, which lacked such support, community members had
      of misappropriation can       no ability or capacity to monitor corrupt officials, who knew that alle-
     be denied or ignored with      gations of misappropriation could be denied or ignored with impunity.
                       impunity.       Common-pool resources also vary widely in their potential impact
                                    on livelihoods and in the number of actors at various levels who have a
                                    stake in their use, conservation, and regeneration. Forests, for example,
                                    can generate tremendous value at the local and national level, but forest
                                    preservation and regeneration often yield large positive externalities at
                                    the global level. In contrast, the returns to small irrigation schemes are
                                    plausibly confined to a limited number of local actors. Communities
                                    that live in or near specific natural resources can therefore face very
                                    different incentives to engage, individually or collectively, in efforts to
                                    preserve or restore the resource base.
          Local governments or         The question of who benefits from forest land is an important case
   community user groups are        in point. A common issue highlighted in the literature is that local gov-
     often given management         ernments or community user groups are often given management rights
  rights over forests that have     over forests that have few livelihood improvement opportunities. In
   few livelihood improvement       contrast, private interests or the central state control productive forests.
              opportunities . . .   Even in countries like Tanzania, where there is significant decentralized
                                    forest management, most joint forest management agreements have
    . . . leaving them with the     been made in relation to the montane rainforests, where laws prohibit
    largely unfunded costs of       use in order to maintain national and international biodiversity. Where
management and with little by       productive forests are under joint management, by village councils or
                 way of returns.    community-based groups, they either yield low-value nontimber forest
                                    products for subsistence use (Topp-Jorgensen and others 2005; Meshack
                                    and others 2006) or are degraded or of low value with little by way of
                                    immediate livelihood opportunities, at least in the short run (Lund
                                    2007; Mustalahti and Lund 2010). The result is that local communities
                                    are often required to bear the largely unfunded costs of management
                                    and with little by way of returns.
                                       There are also issues about what constitutes the “community,” as the
                                    case of people who live on the borders of forests demonstrates. On the
                                    one hand, living near a forest can leave them more vulnerable to crop
                                    damage and livestock losses from protected forest wildlife. On the other
                                    hand, they can be restricted in expanding their farmland if the forest

180
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



border becomes “hard” (Lund and Treue 2008). Similar issues arise for
pastoralist and agro-pastoralist groups, who are often not represented
in community user groups or local councils.
   Several studies question the assumption underlying the move toward         The existence of viable
CBNRM—namely, that viable and well-functioning local institutions             local institutions cannot be
exist to which decision-making power simply needs to be transferred.          assumed. Such institutions
They argue that CBNRM is in the main a process of creating the                need to be created through
necessary institutional structures at the local level, to which specific       deliberate effort.
responsibilities can then be devolved. Although these new institutions
may be based on historical forms, the creation of accountable institu-
tions at the local level implies a much greater involvement of the state in
resource governance arrangements. Thus, even where communities and
local groups have long-standing rights to manage local resources, such
rights require at least the implicit if not explicit sanction of the state.
For resources that are deemed valuable—such as timber and fish—local
rights typically exist as a result of explicit actions by government and
state agencies (Ribot, Lund, and Treue 2010; Agrawal 2010). Agrawal
(2010) notes that of the 400 million hectares of tropical forests currently
under formal community control, more than half was transferred to
community management in the past quarter century. Fujiie, Hayami,
and Kikuchi (2005) look at the creation of irrigation association groups
in the Philippines, which were formed as part of the broader decentral-
ization process. They find that only 20 percent of the irrigation associa-
tion groups included in their study had communal irrigation systems
in existence before the National Irrigation Authority got involved (see
also Mosse 2005 on India and Wilder and Lankao 2006 on Mexico).
   State intervention thus seems to determine the impact of participa-        State intervention seems
tion on natural resource management, equity, and local livelihoods,           to determine the impact
much as it does for other programs or reform processes that induce            of participation on natural
greater local participation. The distribution of responsibilities and         resource management, equity,
resources between the center and the locality as well as the mandate          and local livelihoods.
local citizens have to protect, improve, monitor, and benefit from the
natural resource are critical.
   Baird (2006) highlights another significant issue: the impact of donor
and government reporting requirements and incentive structures on the
quality of local management. The central government in Lao PDR pro-
vided incentives to provinces to expand aquaculture ponds but not fish
sanctuaries. In response, provinces met the central government’s quota
by reporting fish sanctuaries as aquaculture ponds. Similarly, irrigation

                                                                                                         181
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                 reports in India provided by local officials to higher levels often inflate
                                 the areas covered by irrigation in order to “meet” targets (Wood 1999).
       Communities and local        Communities and local governments can obtain significant indirect
      governments can obtain     benefits if more effective management of the common-pool resource
   significant benefits if more    increases public revenues for local investment. Ribot, Lund, and
     effective management of     Treue (2010) argue that such benefits can provide the right incentives
   the common-pool resource      for conservation when management of the forest itself is unlikely to
 increases public revenues for   be a lucrative venture. They argue that revenue raising is one of the
             local investment.   most prominent outcomes of decentralized forest management in
                                 Africa. In Uganda, for example, local governments are entitled to keep
                                 40 percent of the revenues from the management of national forest
                                 reserves (Muhereza 2006; Turyahabwe and others 2007), even though
                                 they are effectively sidelined as far as management of these reserves
                                 goes. Revenues have also increased substantially for rural communities
                                 in Cameroon and Tanzania in community forestry areas (Oyono and
                                 Efoua 2006; Oyono and Nzuzi 2006; Lund 2007). These funds are
                                 used to cover the direct costs of forest management as well as to fund
                                 public infrastructure and services such as roads, schools, and health
                                 clinics (Ribot, Lund, and Treue 2010), or to provide micro loans, as in
                                 Nepal (Pokharel 2009).



                                 Participation and the Quality of Local Infrastructure
                                 Participatory development programs usually invest a good deal in build-
                                 ing community infrastructure. The argument for doing so is twofold.
                                 First, lack of adequate infrastructure—connector roads, wholesale mar-
                                 kets, irrigation channels, electricity, school buildings, sanitation, and
                                 the like—significantly constrains prospects for development, and this
                                 lack is far more acute in the poorest communities. Second, it is expected
                                 that devolving responsibility to the local level will produce projects that
                                 are not only better aligned with the preferences and needs of final users,
                                 but are also of higher quality, and more likely to be well maintained.
                                    Ideally, participatory programs are expected to work with commu-
                                 nities to ensure need, feasibility, and adequacy of scale; to monitor the
                                 project over the construction cycle; and to create systems for project
                                 maintenance. Most programs require some form of community co-
                                 financing as a mechanism for inducing greater community engagement
                                 and “ownership” of the project. Some also require upfront community
                                 commitment of resources for project maintenance. Many participatory
182
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



projects also restrict the menu of feasible subprojects, either overtly or de   Competition in the project
facto, to a small set of public goods (typically roads, culverts, and drain-    selection process is intended
age systems; drinking water and sanitation facilities; and schools, and         to weed out bad projects and
clinics). Although this appears to be contradictory to a demand-driven          encourage communities to
process of project selection, in practice, it may serve to restrict choice to   align projects with program
a small set of public goods that communities are better able to maintain        objectives.
or where the opportunities for capture are limited.18 Competition in
the project selection process is also intended to weed out bad projects
and to encourage communities to put in the requisite effort to align the
proposed project with program objectives.
   How successful are these efforts? Does local provision create infra-
structure that is better designed, better constructed, and better main-
tained? Does this imply less capture? Are projects of better quality than
similar types of infrastructure created by central line departments? How
important are community characteristics such as wealth inequality, eth-
nic heterogeneity, remoteness, and low levels of education or poverty?
Can the right incentives (such as interjurisdictional competition for
funds) or the right investments (such as community capacity building)
mitigate the impact of potentially negative community characteristics?
Specifically, can local provision create “good” projects in “bad” com-
munities, and do the poor gain as a result? The following subsections
present the evidence on these questions.


Bottom-up versus Top-down
Given the resources allocated to social funds of various types, surpris-
ingly few studies compare the relative performance of subprojects built
by local governments or community groups and subprojects built by
central line departments. Even fewer simultaneously address the ques-
tion of infrastructure quality and the distribution of benefits. Yet it is
far from clear that benefits, even from well-designed and constructed
projects, are more equitably distributed.
   The first study to carefully assess this question used data from
132 infrastructure projects in 99 randomly selected rural communi-
ties across northern Pakistan, where the Agha Khan Rural Support
Program (AKRSP) has promoted participatory rural development for
more than 30 years. Khwaja (2004, 2009) compares infrastructure
projects provided by the community, with AKRSP support, with similar
projects provided by government line departments. His research yields
three interesting findings. First, community engagement, with AKRSP
                                                                                                          183
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                   Community       facilitation, substantially improved project maintenance (the main
      engagement in Pakistan       outcome of interest) but only when participation was confined to the
substantially improved project     nontechnical aspects of the project. When communities got involved in
              maintenance . . .    technical project decisions, participation was detrimental. The intuition
                                   behind this claim is that decisions requiring local information are more
             . . . but only when   likely to be sensitive to the community’s investment, whereas decisions
   participation was confined       that require technical information should be more responsive to the
  to the nontechnical aspects      external agency’s investment. Second, communities were less able to
    of the project. Community      maintain projects that were technically complex or new.19 They did
      involvement in technical     better when preexisting projects were refurbished or the project selected
   decisions was detrimental.      was one in which they had previous experience. Third, inequality in the
                                   incidence of project benefits (across both participatory and government
                                   provided projects) has a U-shaped effect on maintenance. As inequlity
                                   in the distribution of project benefits increases, maintenance levels first
                                   fall then rise.20 As Khwaja notes, under perfect inequality in the distri-
                                   bution of benefits, the project is effectively privatized, and maintenance
                                   no longer requires any coordination. 21 This U-shaped relationship
                                   between inequality and project maintenance is similar to the tradeoff
                                   between resource sustainability and wealth inequality in the literature
                                   on common pool resources.
                                      Mansuri (2012a) uses data from the three largest provinces of
                                   Pakistan to provide further insights on the relationship between partici-
                                   pation and project quality. Her study combines administrative, census,
                                   and survey data from 230 infrastructure projects in 80 villages.22 About
                                   half of the projects were constructed by government line departments;
                                   while the rest were built by the community with support from the
                                   National Rural Support Program (NRSP).23 The study assesses two
                                   aspects of project quality: design and construction, and current condi-
                                   tion and maintenance. The first aspect, provides evidence of capture,
                                   in the narrow sense of theft and corruption, in construction, while the
                                   second reflects a communities’ capacity for coordination and is therefore
                                   more comparable with Khwaja’s (2004, 2009) work.
                                      Compared with the northern areas, the rest of Pakistan has far
                                   greater levels of local inequality and ethnic heterogeneity. Land owner-
                                   ship, which is almost entirely hereditary, is extremely skewed, with the
                                   top 5 percent of landowners owning more than 40 percent of all land
                                   while more than half of rural households are landless. The caste (zaat)
                                   structure is also extremely hierarchical. Given these features, Mansuri’s
                                   findings are encouraging.

184
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



   Mansuri finds that participatory projects in the study villages appear        The scope for outright
to be better designed and constructed than comparable projects deliv-           rent-seeking through the
ered by government line departments and the effects are economically            diversion of project funds was
large. This finding suggests that the scope for outright rent-seeking            considerably muted when
through the diversion of project funds can be considerably muted                infrastructure in Pakistan
when infrastructure is provided with community engagement. NRSP-                was provided with community
supported projects are also better maintained, in line with the evidence        engagement. . . .
provided by Khwaja (2009). This may be due, at least in part, to NRSP’s
(and AKRSP’s) approach to project maintenance. Maintenance costs                . . . but benefits were no
are built into project costs at the proposal stage and although the com-        better distributed than in
munity is entirely responsible for project maintenance postconstruc-            projects directed from the
tion, NRSP (and AKRSP) continue to provide technical assistance as              center.
needed. This is very much in line with the following discussion on the
importance of building community capacity to undertake resource
management.
   That said, project quality alone can reveal only so much about cap-
ture. If project benefits are effectively privatized at the local level, there
may be little incentive to engage in the type of rent-seeking that could
reduce the quality of project construction. The results here are far less
encouraging. As discussed in chapter 4, Mansuri (2012b) finds that
benefits from the participatory project are no better distributed than
benefits from the relevant government project. In both types of projects,
the share of the landless, the poor, and people from low castes was far
below their share in the population.


Can “Good” Programs Compensate for “Bad” Communities?
An important premise in the literature on participatory programs is that        Well-designed participatory
well designed and implemented projects can overcome adverse commu-              efforts can overcome the
nity characteristics. Specifically, that the challenge to collective action      negative effects of wealth
posed by local inequality, ethnic divides, and exclusionary practices           inequality and community
of various types, can be overcome by inducing participation through             heterogeneity to a large
a well-implemented program. Khwaja’s (2009) analysis provides an                degree.
encouraging assessment. Project characteristics, which include the
participatory delivery mechanism facilitated by AKRSP, significantly
outweigh community characteristics, suggesting that well-designed
participatory efforts can, to a large degree, overcome the negative effects
of wealth inequality and community heterogeneity. The study also finds
that the quality of local leadership matters: projects in communities

                                                                                                             185
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   in the northern areas of Pakistan that had more educated leaders, and
                                   leaders who were actively engaged in community affairs, were better
                                   maintained.24
                                       Mansuri (2012a) finds that after controlling for participation (that
                                   is, facilitation by the NRSP), inequality does not affect project mainte-
                                   nance much. However, projects were far better maintained in commu-
                                   nities with above average levels of schooling. The impact of inequality
                                   on construction quality is different, however. The quality of construc-
                                   tion of NRSP-supported projects worsens significantly in villages that
                                   are more unequal, and this effect is amplified when projects are also
                                   more technically complex or are built on older preexisting (usually
                                   government-provided) projects. The study thus shows that although
                                   participation appears to dampen opportunities for rent-seeking, greater
                                   effort is required to ensure the quality of projects in more unequal
                                   communities.
                                       A number of large participatory development programs use some
                                   form of interjurisdictional competition to improve community incen-
                                   tives to allocate funds in a more transparent and equitable manner.
                                   Grant funds from the central government can also induce competition
                                   across localities if they are tied to the achievement of specific outcomes,
                                   reform processes, and so forth.
           In more competitive         Chavis (2009) is perhaps the only study that has looked at the impact
  subdistricts in Indonesia, the   of competition on the quality of infrastructure subprojects. The study
 set of projects submitted and     used administrative data from the Indonesian Kecamatan Development
 funded had larger community       Program (KDP), funded by the World Bank. Like other community-
contributions, a more pro-poor     driven development programs, KDP involves communities in the allo-
 allocation of project benefits,    cation of funds for the construction of local public goods. In the KDP,
          and lower unit costs.    each funded kecamatan (subdistrict) receives a block grant, based on
                                   population. The grants are allocated at the village level by a competitive
                                   process of project selection that is managed by an intervillage council
                                   with representation from each village. As a result, subdistricts with more
                                   villages face a greater competition for funds. Chavis proposes that this
                                   competitive pressure is plausibly exogenous and that it changes the pro-
                                   cess by which the block grant is allocated, inducing greater compliance
                                   with KDP rules and thus higher-quality projects in more competitive
                                   subdistricts.25 He tests this hypothesis using administrative data on
                                   more than 3,000 road project proposals received in a single year (road
                                   projects typically account for almost half of all KDP subproject funds).
                                   The results indicate that in more competitive subdistricts, the set of

186
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



projects submitted and funded had larger community contributions, a
more pro-poor allocation of project benefits, and lower unit costs.
   A potential limitation of using reported unit costs and distribution
of beneficiaries at the time of proposal submission and approval is
that there are no independent data against which these claims can be
checked. Chavis attempts to overcome this problem by using corrobo-
rative evidence from an earlier study by Olken (2007), which shows
a considerable amount of overinvoicing of labor and materials in the
stated costs of KDP road projects (see discussion in chapter 3). Using
data from this study, Chavis confirms that there is also less theft in
road projects in more competitive subdistricts, bolstering the finding
on lower reported unit road costs in project proposals.
   Recall, however, that demand-driven application processes can be
strongly regressive (see the first section of this chapter). Taken together,
these results suggest that high project construction quality and main-
tenance do not imply an equitable distribution of resources. There can
be a significant trade-off between equity and sustainability.


Community Capacity and Project Quality
Several of the studies reviewed in the previous sections point to the rel-    Lack of community capacity
evance of building community capacity for project quality and mainte-         is often the key constraint on
nance. This section reviews studies that suggest that lack of community       project quality.
capacity is often the key constraint on project quality.
   Katz and Sara (1997) cite inadequate technical support from project
implementers as one of the key reasons for the failure of water projects
in their global review. They note that in the absence of community
supervision or management, projects were often left in the hands of
private contractors, whose incentives can be suspect. Community mem-
bers were unable to make informed choices about the type of project to
build, monitor the work of contractors, or maintain projects after they
were constructed without adequate training.
   Isham and Kahkonen (2002) make similar points in their analysis            Communities often require
of water projects in India, Indonesia, and Sri Lanka. They find that           considerable support in
communities often require considerable support in understanding the           understanding the technical
technical aspects of projects.                                                aspects of projects.
   Newman and others (2002) raise similar concerns in their evalua-
tion of the Bolivian social fund. They find that water projects improved
water quality only when community-level training was also provided.

                                                                                                         187
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



      Water projects in Bolivia      They attribute the significant reduction in under-five mortality associ-
   improved water quality and        ated with the provision of health clinics to the fact that investments in
    access to water only when        health went beyond providing infrastructure to providing other neces-
 community-level training was        sary technical inputs as well. In contrast, education projects led to little
                also provided.       change in education outcomes, because no resources were provided
                                     beyond the building of schools.
   Results of an experiment in           In a more recent study, Leino (2007) provides further support for
      Kenya suggest that water       this hypothesis from a field experiment in Kenya. The study, which allo-
projects are better maintained       cated funds for maintenance to a random subset of water management
      when water management          committees, fi nds that water projects were better maintained when
committees are given funds to        water management committees were given funds to carry out regular
carry out regular maintenance.       maintenance activities.
                                         Very few studies attempt to assess the long-term sustainability of
                                     participatory infrastructure projects. Kleemeier (2000) is an exception.
                                     She looks at a rural piped water program in Malawi. Only half of the
                                     schemes, which were 3–26 years old, were performing well; the rest were
                                     performing poorly or had failed entirely. Moreover, the schemes that
                                     were in good working condition were either small or new. Kleemeier
                                     notes that her findings are an indictment not of the participatory pro-
                                     cess itself but of the lack of attention implementers paid to the weak link
                                     between communities and external agencies with the requisite technical
                                     capacity. Community groups were capable of making small repairs nec-
                                     essary to keep water flowing, but they were unable to undertake more
                                     substantive preventative maintenance and repairs. In the end, the water
                                     department had to send in government-employed monitoring assistants
                                     and supervisors to ensure that preventive maintenance was performed.
   Large donors often support            Kleemeier notes that CARE, a large international NGO, was con-
           communities in the        fronted with much the same situation in Indonesia (see also Hodgkin
   construction of projects . . .    and Kusumahadi 1993). Although it supported communities in the
                                     construction of projects, it provided little support for postconstruction
  . . . but provide little support   activities. Although small and simple schemes can survive this neglect,
for postconstruction activities.     larger schemes that require external technical inputs cannot. In a related
                                     study, Uphoff (1986) notes that local organizations can be effective only
                                     if they have adequate links with political and administrative centers.



                                     Community Engagement in Public Service Delivery
                                     Much of the effort to improve accountability in the allocation of
                                     resources for public services focuses on expanding citizen oversight
188
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



and engagement. These efforts have taken a number of forms, ranging            If local governments or
from the decentralization of service delivery to local governments and         participatory programs are
the signing of contracts with private providers and NGOs to programs           beholden to elites, they may
that induce greater community participation in service provision and           underprovide some services
quality by transferring resources directly to community organizations.         and overcharge for the
   The review of the evidence focuses on outcomes related to improve-          services they do provide . . .
ments in service quality, as measured by learning, school retention,
infant and maternal mortality, and access to services. As Bardhan              . . . leaving the poor to bear
and Mookherjee (2005) caution, the distributional and welfare con-             a disproportionate cost of
sequences of decentralized delivery are likely to be as important as the       service provision.
impact on service quality. In essence, if local governments or participa-
tory programs are beholden to local elites, they may overprovide some
services and undercharge for the services they do provide, leaving the
poor to bear a disproportionate cost of service provision.


School-Based Management and the Decentralization of Education
The decentralization of education takes many forms. The review here
divides the literature broadly into decentralization efforts directed at
schools (generally referred to as “school-based management”) and the
decentralization of education services to local governments.
   School-based management is a form of decentralization in which deci-
sion making is devolved, either from a central line ministry or a lower-tier
government, whether provincial or municipal, to the school or com-
munity. As with the devolution of authority in other domains, increased
school and community discretion is expected to improve school quality
(as measured by student performance and use of the school budget) and
enhance satisfaction with the quality of service provision.
   School-based management typically involves setting up a school
management committee or council that includes the school principal,
teachers, and members of the school community, in particular parents
but also local leaders and other community members. School commit-
tees are usually tasked with monitoring school performance and provid-
ing oversight on the use of resources. Less frequently, such committees
are granted authority over teacher hiring and firing and decisions about
the curriculum and the allocation of school budgets.
   Many developing countries have adopted school-based management
programs over the past two decades, often as part of a larger effort to
decentralize resource allocation and service delivery. The extent to
which resources and decision-making authority are transferred, as well
                                                                                                            189
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          as the agents to whom authority is transferred, varies widely. There is
                          also a great deal of variation in the extent to which community and par-
                          ent engagement is mandated, the form it takes, and the type of oversight
                          local and higher-level governments provide.
                              Barrera-Osorio and Linden (2009) categorize school-based manage-
                          ment approaches along two dimensions: who has the power to make
                          decisions and the degree of decision making devolved to the school
                          level. They note that “with so many possible combinations of these two
                          dimensions, almost every school-based management reform is unique”
                          (p. 4).
                              Bruns, Filmer, and Patrinos (2011) divide school-based management
                          programs into three broad groups: strong versions, in which school
                          councils have significant authority over both staffing and school bud-
                          gets; intermediate versions, in which school councils have some say in
                          curriculum but very limited authority over resources or staffing deci-
                          sions; and weak versions, in which school councils are largely advisory
                          in nature. They also provide a useful framework for understanding
                          the channels through which school-based management can enhance
                          accountability, highlighting four facets: increasing choice and participa-
                          tion, giving citizens a stronger voice, making information about school
                          performance widely available, and strengthening school level incen-
                          tives for effective service delivery for the poor (see Bruns, Filmer, and
                          Patrinos 2011 for a comprehensive review of school-based management).
                          The review here focuses on evidence for the second channel, insofar as
                          studies can unpack multifaceted interventions to identify the impact of
                          a specific component.
                              In all cases, the decentralization of education is expected to induce
                          greater efficiency in the use of education budgets and create better per-
                          formance incentives for local officials and school staff. The expectation
                          is that decentralization can deliver improvements in a range of schooling
                          outcomes, from enrollment and retention to better student performance
                          on standardized tests, and that it can do so cost-effectively.
                              As with all decentralization efforts, there is the usual set of risks.
                          Programs can be captured, with resources flowing to better-off loca-
                          tions or schools or siphoned off for private use. Local government agents
                          may also lack the capacity to manage funds or make effective decisions
                          regarding resource allocation, staffing, or curriculum. Theory would
                          predict that both types of problems would tend to be worse in com-
                          munities that are poorer, more unequal, or in which citizens are more
                          alienated from the political process.
190
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



   Caldwell (2005) notes that as with broader decentralization efforts,
governments have supported school-based management for a variety
of reasons. Governments on the left have initiated school management
reforms as part of larger efforts to increase community empowerment.
Governments on the right have often justified school-based manage-
ment on the basis of greater freedom or more choice, which has also
been interpreted as an effort to create a market among schools in public
education systems.
   These divergent motives have made school-based management politi-         A consensus has been forged
cally contentious, with little agreement on what the expected outcomes       that the primary purpose of
should be. In recent years, however, a consensus has been forged that        school-based management
the primary purpose of school-based management is the improvement            is the improvement of
of educational outcomes. With this, evidence on the effects of school-       educational outcomes.
based management on educational outcomes has also started to emerge.
According to Caldwell (2005), early studies were marred by the lack
of a clear objective for school-based management as well as by the lack
of data. In contrast, what he calls third-generation studies, starting in
the late 1990s, look at programs in which improvement in learning
outcomes is a central objective and adequate data are available to assess
impact.
   Before examining the evidence, it is useful to point out that few,
if any, studies are able to measure the extent or quality of commu-
nity engagement or identify its influence on school management.
Studies that do attempt to separate out community participation from
other aspects of decentralization, such as school autonomy, tend to
assume that the level of community or parent participation, usually
self-reported, is independent of unobserved community or student
characteristics that could influence outcomes. Similar assumptions
are made about reported levels of school autonomy. Gunnarsson and
others (2009) make an important point in this regard. They find that
levels of reported school autonomy and parental participation are not
only poorly correlated with each other but that both vary more within
countries than between them.26
   A smaller body of literature looks at the impact of decentralizing edu-   The scope, timing, and
cation to local governments. A general concern with studies that look        extent of decentralization
at the impact of decentralization is that the scope, timing, and extent      usually depend on a number
of decentralization usually depend on a number of political economy          of political economy
considerations that are neither evident ex post nor malleable ex ante. As    considerations that are neither
such, strong assumptions about the plausible exogeneity of the timing        evident ex post nor malleable
or extent of decentralization are often required. The extent to which        ex ante.
                                                                                                         191
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     the results of such studies are credible depends in part on the extent to
                                     which panel data, along with some feature of the decentralization, can
                                     be used to construct a credible counterfactual against which outcomes
                                     under decentralization can be compared.
  Decentralization in any form           Overall, the evidence suggests that decentralization in any form
     seems to improve school         improves school access. There is also some evidence that student reten-
                    access . . .     tion rates and attendance improve and grade repetition is reduced. There
                                     is little evidence, however, of any improvement in learning outcomes.
. . . but there is little evidence
                                         Most evaluations do not cover the time periods typically associ-
          of any improvement in
                                     ated with improvements in learning outcomes. As Bruns, Filmer, and
     learning outcomes over the
                                     Patrinos (2011) point out, much of the evidence from developed coun-
                periods studied.
                                     tries indicates that it can take up to eight years to see an impact on
        Reform processes that        student learning. This lack of impact on student learning is consistent
 attempt to change structures        with a basic concern highlighted in chapter 2. Reform processes that
   of authority and power may        attempt to change structures of authority and power may require longer
  require longer time spans to       time spans to realize gains than the timeline of impact studies allows.
realize gains than the timeline      It may also be easier to observe gains in some dimensions than others.
  of impact studies allows . . .     Outcomes may also worsen before they improve. Some studies, for
                                     example, show a decline in student quality at school entry, as children
       . . . and outcomes may
                                     from less privileged backgrounds enter school for the first time. Their
   actually worsen before they
                                     entry may partly account for the negligible improvement in learning
                      improve.
                                     despite improvement in attendance and school retention. Even in stud-
                                     ies with longer time frames, however, results for learning outcomes are
                                     mixed, as shown below.

                                     Social fund–supported school infrastructure investments. Although
                                     social funds have invested substantial resources in upgrading school
                                     infrastructure, only a few studies look at the impacts of such invest-
                                     ments on schooling outcomes. The few that have find an improvement
                                     in school access. No study looks at learning outcomes.
     Several studies find that           Paxson and Schady (2002) find that the Peruvian social fund
social funds increased school        increased school attendance, particularly among younger children.
      attendance, particularly       Other researchers find similar results for social funds in Armenia
     among younger children.         (Chase 2002) and Zambia (Chase and Sherburne-Benz 2001); Chase
                                     and Sherburne-Benz also find that children were in more appropriate
                                     grades. Household expenditure on schooling in Zambia was also higher
                                     in communities that used social funds to rehabilitate schools, probably
                                     because of the higher fees charged by parent-teacher associations in such



192
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



schools. Although increased spending need not be welfare enhancing for
poor households, the authors argue that taken together with improved
attendance rates and grade-appropriate placement of children, it is
indicative of unmet demand for schooling in these communities.

School-based management.           Several countries have implemented
strong versions of school-based management. An early program is
the Educación con Participación de la Comunidad (Education with
Community Participation [EDUCO]) program in El Salvador. Under
this program, the state bore all schooling costs (tuition, uniforms,
textbooks). Parents were expected to contribute time and labor to the
school. Each school had an Association for Community Education
(ACE), with elected parent members. The ACEs managed the school
budget; they could hire and fire teachers and monitor teacher perfor-
mance (Sawada and Ragatz 2005). Half of all rural students in grades
1–9 were enrolled in an EDUCO school by 2001 (Di Gropello 2006).
   Jimenez and Sawada (1999, 2003) find that students in EDUCO
schools had higher attendance and lower dropout rates than students
in traditional schools. Attending an EDUCO school raised the odds
of school retention by about 64 percent. As the decision to enroll in
an EDUCO school is endogenous, the authors use the availability of
EDUCO at the municipality level as an instrument for a school being
in the EDUCO program. They attempt to isolate the channel through
which the EDUCO effect is realized by adding a community partici-
pation variable to the estimation. This estimation yields a positive and
significant effect, leading the authors to conclude that EDUCO worked
mainly through community participation.
   These results are interesting, but the empirical strategy is not con-
vincing. In practice, any number of municipal characteristics could
influence a municipalities’ eligibility for the EDUCO program and
thus the odds of a school entering the program. Similarly, any number
of community characteristics could affect the odds of a school selecting
into the program as well as the observed dropout effects.
   Jimenez and Sawada (1999) and Sawada (1999) also find positive
changes in teacher attitudes and behavior, particularly teacher absen-
teeism. Sawada and Ragatz (2005) uses propensity score matching to
identify the impact of EDUCO on a range of outcomes. Their results
also indicate lower teacher absenteeism. Community associations and



                                                                                      193
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  parents also report much greater influence over administrative pro-
                                  cesses, including teacher hiring and firing. There is also some, albeit
                                  limited, evidence of an improvement in student test scores. The authors
                                  note that EDUCO schools tend to be located in poorer, more remote,
                                  and more rural communities which could explain the lower compara-
                                  tive test scores.
 A school autonomy reform in          A similar school autonomy reform in Nicaragua allowed school
  Nicaragua that gave school      councils to hire and fire the school principal and make decisions about
    councils decision-making      school maintenance and student learning. King and Özler (1998) look
  authority had no impact on      at the impact of the program on student test scores. They use matching
    average student learning.     methods to find comparable nonautonomous public and private schools.
                                  The study finds no impact of the reform on student learning on average.
                                  However, students performed better in schools that reported exercising
                                  greater de facto autonomy. The results, though interesting, are difficult
                                  to interpret, because the study cannot identify why some schools exer-
                                  cised greater autonomy. A subsequent study (King, Özler, and Rawlings
                                  1999) that tried to determine which aspects of community decision
                                  making were responsible for the improved learning finds that the school
                                  council’s autonomy over staffing decisions had the greatest impact.
                                      In contrast Eskeland and Filmer (2002), who assess the decen-
                                  tralization of education in Argentina, find positive impacts of school
                                  autonomy but not of parental participation. They theorize that while
                                  greater school autonomy increases the ability of school officials to
                                  extract rents, greater participation by parents in schools can channel
                                  this discretionary power toward improved learning. The expectation
                                  is that community and parental engagement in schools can constrain
                                  rent-seeking by local officials or school administrators. The question is
                                  whether communities have the capacity, ability, or incentive to play this
                                  monitoring role, particularly in poorer and less developed areas, which
                                  may be most in need of education reform. Interestingly, they find that,
                                  consistent with their model, school autonomy has a larger impact on
                                  learning in communities that have higher levels of participation.
  In contrast, giving oversight       These results are broadly corroborated by a randomized experiment
power to community members        in Kenya that, among other things, increased community monitoring of
      in Kenya improved both      teachers through local school committees. Duflo, Dupas, and Kremer
      teacher attendance and      (2008) find that giving oversight power to community members—in
        student performance.      this case through local school committees—improved teacher atten-
                                  dance and student performance.27



194
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



    Gunnarsson and others (2009) cast light on why the learning impacts
of school autonomy and community participation are so mixed. They
use data from eight Latin American countries to argue that local
managerial effort, at the level of the school as well as the community,
is likely to be endogenous. Their results demonstrate that correcting
for the endogeneity of school autonomy and parental participation
can completely reverse the positive and significant effects of school
autonomy. Encouragingly, in their sample countries, the positive effect
of community participation remains positive and is strengthened when
the endogeneity of participation is addressed.
    Chaudhury and Parajuli (2010) study a school-based management           A school-based management
program in Nepal that transferred school management to the com-             program in Nepal was
munity. School management committees, composed of parents as                associated with an increase
well as “influential local citizens,” were given the authority to repost     in school access but not
government teachers, hire and fire community-recruited teachers, and         learning.
index teacher salaries to school performance. The committees were also
given untied block grants to invest in school improvement. Exogenous
variation in program participation, which was voluntary, was ran-
domly induced in some communities through an advocacy group that
persuaded treatment communities to participate in the program. Two
years into the program, results show an increase in school access but no
effect on learning.
    In some school-based management programs, community groups
play a more consultative role, with very limited discretion over bud-
gets or teacher hiring and firing decisions. One such program is the
Programa Escuelas de Calidad (Quality Schools Program [PEC]) in
Mexico, which provides five-year grants of up to $15,000 to schools
that commit to invest in education quality. In exchange for PEC grants,
schools need to prepare an education improvement plan in collaboration
with parent associations. During the first years of the grant period, all
investments must be made in upgrading school facilities and providing
learning materials. The last installment of the grant can be used in part
for teacher training and development. Participation in PEC is voluntary,
but the program targets disadvantaged urban schools.
    Using two years of nationally representative panel data, Skoufias and
Shapiro (2006) find significant declines in dropout, grade repetition,
and failure rates. Dropout rates decreased by 0.24 points, failure rates
by 0.24 points, and repetition rates by 0.31 points.



                                                                                                     195
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                       Murnane, Willet, and Cardenas (2006) use longitudinal data from
                                   all seven years of PEC, which allows them to control for pre-PEC trends
                                   in relevant outcomes in both PEC and non-PEC schools. Using only
                                   schools that entered PEC in the program’s second year of operation and
                                   had similar historical trends as non-PEC schools, they find that PEC
                                   decreased dropout rates by about 6 percent over three years of participa-
                                   tion. The largest effects occurred in states that were more developed.
A school-based program in the          A similar school-based program in the Philippines funded infrastruc-
   Philippines appears to have     ture along with teacher training, curriculum development, and the pro-
    had a positive but modest      vision of textbooks. This program required schools to develop a five-year
             effect on learning.   school improvement plan in partnership with the community. Khattri,
                                   Ling, and Jha (2010) evaluate the program using retrospective admin-
                                   istrative data along with propensity score matching to identify coun-
                                   terfactual schools. They find positive but modest effects on learning.
       Grade failure and grade         The Apoyo a la Gestión Escolar (School Management Support
 repetition in Mexico declined     [AGE]) program in Mexico provided parent associations with resources
    following introduction of a    that could be used to rehabilitate and upgrade school infrastructure.
   school-based management         The funds were subject to being audited annually on a random basis.
                      program.     Gertler, Patrinos, and Rubio-Codina (2007) find substantial positive
                                   effects of giving parent associations more management responsibili-
                                   ties.28 Their results indicate a reduction in both grade failure and grade
                                   repetition of about 0.4 percentage points in AGE beneficiary schools.
                                   Given a mean failure rate of 10 percent and a mean repetition rate of
                                   9.6 percent at baseline, these values imply about a 4 percent decrease in
                                   the proportion of students failing and the proportion of students repeat-
                                   ing a grade. The effects are larger for schools that received benefits for
                                   more than one year.29
                                       A couple of recent studies have examined interventions in India
                                   designed to induce greater community monitoring of school-based com-
                                   mittees. Banerjee and others (2010) report on a randomized evaluation
                                   that had three intervention arms. The first arm provided information to
                                   villagers about the role of an existing institution, the village education
                                   committee. Baseline data indicated very little awareness of its existence,
                                   even among its own members. The second arm added to the first by
                                   also providing information on student test scores and how to evaluate
                                   a child’s learning level. The third arm supplemented the first two arms
                                   by teaching volunteers in the village a simple technique for teaching
                                   children how to read in an after-school reading program. Each interven-
                                   tion arm was implemented in 65 villages; a fourth group of 85 villages
                                   formed the control group.
196
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



   The authors find virtually no impact of the first and second arms of       In India, inducing better
this intervention. Even village education committee members them-           monitoring of schools by
selves were not significantly more likely to be aware that they were         providing more information
on the village education committee following the intervention. What         and training to communities
effects the authors do observe appear to reflect a decline in awareness      about school management has
in the control group. The first two interventions also had no effect         had mixed effects.
on children’s learning. In villages that received the third intervention
arm, however, children were 1.7 percent more likely to read letters and
1.8 percent more likely to read words or paragraphs. The authors note
that this small increase should be viewed with some optimism, given
the small number of children who attended the after-school reading
program.
   Pandey, Goyal, and Sundararaman (2011) present fi ndings from
another study that provided information to communities about their
roles and responsibilities in school management in the Indian states of
Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, and Uttar Pradesh. At baseline, there were
significant differences across states in test scores, teacher absence, and
parental awareness of the village education committees. In line with
Banerjee and others (2010), they find that only 8 percent of parents in
Uttar Pradesh knew about the village education committee and only
2 percent could name its chair. In contrast, in Karnataka, 63 percent of
parents were aware of the village education committee and 44 percent
knew the name of its chair. The information campaign was also more
intense and prolonged than the one studied by Banerjee and others
(2010).30 The findings also differ in important ways. Pandey, Goyal,
and Sundararaman find significant gains in teacher attendance, teach-
ing time, and the functioning of school committees. They also find
higher levels of parental and community engagement and higher stu-
dent math scores, with much larger impacts in the two lagging states,
Uttar Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh. The emergence of some learning
gains is encouraging. The percentage of children receiving benefits
from government entitlement programs (cash stipends, uniforms, mid-
day meals) also rose, although in the more backward states of Madhya
Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh, these benefits were provided mainly to
high-caste students.

Decentralization of schooling to local governments. Decentralization
of schooling to municipal governments appears to have had little
impact on average student learning, although there is some evidence of
improvement in learning outcomes in wealthier and administratively
                                                                                                   197
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



 Decentralization of schooling        more capable localities. Madeira (2007) finds that school decentraliza-
   to municipal governments           tion in the Brazilian state of São Paolo increased dropout and failure
 appears to have little impact        rates across all primary school grades, widening the gap between “good”
 on average student learning.         and “bad” schools ranked by their initial dropout rates. These negative
                                      effects occurred despite an increase in school resources and a reduction
                                      in class size and student teacher ratios. Worse yet, the negative effects
                                      were significantly larger for schools in poorer, more rural, and more
                                      unequal communities, and the effects intensified with the number of
                                      years the school was decentralized.31
          Average test scores in          Similar results emerge from a study by Galiani, Gertler, and
        Argentina rose following      Schargrodsky (2008), who find an increase in average test scores in
            decentralization . . .    Argentina in schools that were decentralized. However, all of the
                                      increase was concentrated in wealthier schools located in munici-
                                      palities and provinces that had greater administrative capacity.
                                      Decentralization actually decreased scores for schools in poorer areas
                                      and in municipalities that were in provinces that had run fiscal deficits
      . . . but all of the increase   before decentralization.
              was concentrated in         Kosec (2011) shows how preferences over public spending can differ
       wealthier schools located      systematically across localities that vary in initial wealth. The study
             in municipalities and    focuses on investment in public preprimary education across municipal-
      provinces that had greater      ities in Brazil following legal changes that increased resources for educa-
         administrative capacity.     tion.32 Kosec shows that poorer municipalities used significantly more
                                      resources to enhance the availability of public preprimary education,
                                      which then had a substantial payoff in student learning. In contrast,
                                      wealthier municipalities used the funds largely to enhance the qual-
                                      ity of primary education. Investments in public preprimary education
                                      were lower in municipalities that were more unequal, suggesting that
                                      polarization can undermine the influence of the poor on public policy.
                                          Madeira (2007) attributes some of the perverse learning effects in
                                      Brazil to the democratization of schooling, which expanded school
                                      access for less well-prepared students, especially in grades 1 and 2.
                                      Rodriguez (2006) assesses the impact of school decentralization in
                                      Colombia, using a strategy that compares the performance of students
                                      in public and private schools on standardized tests. She finds that once
                                      the change in the composition of children in public schools as a result
                                      of decentralization is accounted for, the average standardized test scores
                                      of public school students improved significantly more than the scores of
                                      students in private schools.33



198
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



   Pradhan and others (2011) study an intervention aimed at strength-
ening school committees in Indonesia. They find that measures that
increased linkages between schools and local government officials were
the most effective in improving schooling outcomes and the legitimacy
of the participatory process, particularly when combined with better
accountability of the school committees themselves through open elec-
tions. In contrast, interventions that provided funds and training to
incumbent school committee members had no effect. Moreover, even
the most effective intervention (election with linkage) did not alter
parental willingness to invest time or resources in the school committee
though it did increase the amount of time parents devoted to home-
work, by about 80 minutes a week.34
   A number of intermediate outcomes also improved. Specifically,
the election intervention improved perceptions of school committee
effectiveness by teachers, suggesting that elections may improve legiti-
macy. Elections also improved teacher motivation and effort. Elections
alone increased teaching time by 0.63 hours a day, mostly in lesson
preparation time. Elections plus linkage increased daily teaching time
by 1.1 hours, mostly in time spent grading. The proportion of teachers
observed in the classroom at the time of the survey decreased with the
election intervention, however, which is puzzling. The authors also find
no impact on student dropout or repetition rates in any arm, although
they find some improvement in student learning in the linkage and
election plus linkage arms.
   The results from a companion qualitative study suggest an inter-
esting tension. On the one hand, school committees appreciated
receiving grants that were directly under their control and reported
this control as the impetus for more face-to-face dialogue with the
community. On the other hand, the grants seem to have resulted in
greater conflict between the school committee and the principal (as
might be expected). There were also some challenges in implementing        In Indonesia, partnership
elections, with school committees resisting changes in membership.         between school committees
When elections were conducted as designed, however, they enhanced          and village councils resulted
community awareness and participation in school committee activi-          in concrete actions by the
ties and legitimized the committee. Simply providing training to           village council and significant
incumbent committee members had little effect, either qualitatively or     impacts that school
quantitatively. The key finding in this study is that the linkage process   committees could not have
created a partnership between the school committee and the village         achieved alone.


                                                                                                      199
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     council that resulted in concrete actions by the village council and led
                                     to significant schooling impacts that school committees alone could
                                     not have achieved.


                                     Community Engagement in Delivering Primary Health Care Services
                                     Many developing countries have experimented with community-based
                                     health care models. Often cited examples of success include Costa Rica
                                     and Jamaica, where community-level health education programs and
                                     community-based service provision are believed to have led to major
                                     reductions in mortality, despite fairly stagnant economic conditions
                                     (Riley 2005).
                                         Community-based health service provision encompasses a wide
                                     range of programs. Most programs supply trained health care providers,
                                     who work at the community level and are often charged with activating
                                     communities in some fashion, usually through women’s groups. The
                                     main focus of community-based health provision is on maternal and
                                     child care and household health behaviors. Most programs also rely
                                     on community volunteers or facilitators to build trust, mobilize local
                                     resources, coordinate group activities, or complement services provided
                                     by trained staff.
                                         A number of randomized control trials yield evidence on the health
                                     impacts of such interventions. Most are small-scale interventions but
                                     some work directly with existing government health delivery systems or
                                     test mechanisms that can be scaled up through existing health delivery
                                     systems.
       A small but growing body          This small but growing body of literature by and large confirms the
        of literature by and large   potentially beneficial impact of community-based health programs,
         confirms the potentially     particularly for maternal and child health. A potential caveat is that
              beneficial impact of    the role of community engagement per se is often difficult to isolate,
       community-based health        because most programs undertake a bundle of activities.
       programs, particularly for        Only a few evaluations separate the role of community engagement
      maternal and child health.     from other bundled interventions. These studies find that community
                                     volunteers and health groups can positively affect both health behaviors
                                     and health outcomes—but only when they complement other inputs,
                                     such as trained health professionals and improved health services. There
                                     is also some evidence on the efficacy of transferring the management of
                                     community-based health programs to local governments and the role
                                     of public-private partnerships in the delivery of health services. The

200
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



findings suggest positive, significant, and economically large effects of     Decentralizing health service
decentralizing health service delivery to local governments. In contrast,   delivery to local governments
the findings on public-private partnerships in the delivery of health        appears to produce positive,
services are more mixed.                                                    significant, and economically
    The literature on community-based health delivery can be grouped        large effects.
into four categories: community engagement in the allocation of
resources for health-related investments, community engagement in
providing health-related services and information, community moni-
toring of health care providers, and decentralization of basic health
services to local governments or NGOs. The literature on each category
is reviewed below.

Community engagement in resource allocation.             Communities
often choose to allocate resources from social funds or community-
driven development projects to upgrading or building primary health
care facilities. Few evaluations have anything to say about the impact
of such investments on health behaviors or outcomes. Among the few
that do is an early study of social funds by Chase and Sherburne-Benz
(2001), which finds an increase in the use of primary care services in
communities that invested in a health facility constructed by ZAMSIF,
the Zambia social fund. Under ZAMSIF, communities received social
investment funds for investment in small infrastructure projects such
as the rehabilitation of community health posts. Chase and Sherburne-
Benz find that social fund beneficiaries were more likely to go first to
a health post rather than a hospital when they sought treatment. They
were also significantly more likely to report an illness, although they
were no more likely than controls to seek treatment. The study also
finds more limited evidence that the vaccination prevalence rate rose in
areas with rehabilitated health posts.35
   Arcand and Bassole (2008) find an increase in the use of basic health
services and access to clean drinking water in communities that partici-
pated in the Programme National d’Infrastructures Rurales in Senegal.
Access to basic health services rose 24 percentage points and access
to clean drinking water 22 percentage points. The program was also
associated with positive nutritional impacts (as measured by height for
age, weight for age, and weight for height) for children, which were
substantially larger for children from poorer households. The chan-
nel through which improvements occurred is not clear, however, as
discussed next.

                                                                                                      201
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   Community engagement in the provision of health care services.
                                   A number of randomized control trials have attempted to assess the
                                   effectiveness of demand-side interventions in primary health care. A
                                   randomized pilot study of Ghana’s Community Health and Family
                                   Planning Project (Navrongo) casts some light on the added benefits
                                   of engaging community volunteers in the provision of health services
                                   (Binka and others 2007). One arm of the intervention tested the impact
                                   of adding community-based, volunteer-provided health services to the
                                   basic set of clinical services, along with revolving funds and user fees to
                                   ensure organizational sustainability. Trained supervisors from the com-
                                   munity recruited community health volunteers, organized community
                                   supervision of their work, and managed essential health resources. User
                                   fees and revolving accounts sustained this work. A second arm deployed
                                   trained nurses to villages as “community health officers.” A third arm
                                   engaged the community in ensuring that the trained nurses would
                                   be available. A fourth arm was held as the control. In the third arm,
                                   community members helped construct housing for nurses using volun-
                                   teer labor, ensuring that nurses could reside in the village. They also
                                   provided other types of community assistance and supported services
                                   provided by resident nurses.
   Working with chiefs, village       The findings suggest that over an eight-year period, posting nurses
        elders, and community      to community locations reduced childhood mortality rates substantially
 volunteers, community-based       relative to control areas. In contrast, volunteer services had no impact
       nurses in Ghana helped      on child survival. However, where volunteers worked alongside trained
      develop social insurance     nurses, outcomes were superior to the first two interventions. Working
     mechanisms that allowed       in concert with chiefs, village elders, and community volunteers, com-
  formal care to substitute for    munity-based nurses helped develop various types of social insurance
               traditional care.   mechanisms, such as deferred payment. These mechanisms allowed for-
                                   mal care to substitute for traditional care, reducing the delay in health
                                   seeking that tends to precipitate childhood mortality (see Nyonator
                                   and others 2005 for a detailed discussion). The authors interpret these
                                   results as reflecting the limited ability of volunteers alone to change
                                   entrenched behaviors like seeking traditional healers.
                                      Linnemayr and Alderman (2011) evaluate an intervention in Senegal
                                   that focused on the provision of nutrition-related information to moth-
                                   ers of young children through a community-based mechanism. The
                                   nutrition intervention was undertaken as a pilot program within the
                                   Programme de Renforcement de la Nutrition, which included cook-
                                   ing workshops and a monthly community-level meeting on nutritional

202
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



practices, targeted at mothers. The program also provided vitamin and
iron supplements, bednets, and deworming.
    The pilot was randomized across 212 villages in three poor rural
regions.36 The results indicate significant improvements in health care
practices in program villages but no effect on child growth measures, at
least in the full sample of children. The one exception is children who
were born or of breastfeeding age during the intervention. The nutri-
tional status of these children rose significantly. Because of the bundled
nature of the intervention, however, the role of each of its components
remains unclear.
    A number of studies assess the role of community facilitators in
motivating better health practices. Manandhar and others (2004) report
on one such study, in a district in Nepal. The sample consisted of 12
pairs of village development committees, one of which was randomly
assigned to treatment.37 The study collected baseline data on almost
29,000 eligible women from some 28,000 households. Follow-up data
were collected two years after the intervention. In each intervention
cluster, a local facilitator was recruited (nominated by the local com-
munity or identified by word of mouth or through an advertisement).
The facilitator conducted a monthly women’s group meeting in every
ward (the level below the village development committee). Each facilita-
tor held 10 group meetings. A number of issues were discussed in the
meetings, including the identification and prioritization of health issues
related to pregnancy and childbirth and potential solutions, including
community-generated funds, stretcher schemes, and home visits by
group members. The role of the facilitator was to activate and support
the women’s groups, not to provide health support. Health services were
strengthened in both the control and intervention clusters, through the
provision of supplies at local health facilities, the provision of newborn
care kits, and the training of community health workers.
    Over the two-year trial period, the neonatal mortality rate in inter-
vention clusters fell 30 percent, though there was no difference in
stillbirth rates. Maternal mortality also declined 80 percent (2 maternal
deaths versus 11 in control clusters). There were significant improve-
ments in health behaviors, such as antenatal care, the use of supple-
ments, the share of births in health facilities with trained attendants,
and use of clean kits. Birth attendants were more likely to wash their
hands, and maternal and child illness was more likely to be treated at
a health facility. Moreover, 95 percent of the groups remained active

                                                                                        203
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    after the trial period. These results were achieved with only 37 percent
                                    of newly pregnant women (8 percent of married women) ever attending
                                    the women’s meetings.
                                       Tripathy and others (2010) conducted a similar trial in Jharkhand
                                    and Orissa, two of India’s poorest states, where neonatal and maternal
                                    mortality rates are higher than the national average. In treatment vil-
                                    lages, local facilitators were trained to support women’s groups, which
                                    met about 20 times in all over three years. Health committees were
                                    formed in both intervention and control clusters to discuss health
                                    entitlements from service providers, particularly for mothers and
                                    newborns.38
                                       This intervention witnessed a 45 percent reduction in early neonatal
                                    deaths (0–6 days). By the third year of the trial, there was also a 57 per-
                                    cent reduction in moderate depression among mothers. There were no
                                    significant differences in health care–seeking behavior, but there were
                                    significant improvements in home care practices (use of safe kits, hand
                                    washing by birth attendants, boiling of threads used to tie the cord, and
                                    so forth). More infants were also exclusively breastfed at six weeks. The
                                    cost per life-year saved was about $33 ($48 with health-service strength-
                                    ening activities). Although the availability of delivery kits increased in
                                    both control and intervention clusters, women’s groups generated more
                                    uptake of the kits in intervention areas.
                                       Olken, Onishi, and Wong (2011) evaluate a pilot program in
                                    Indonesia (PNPM Generasi) that provided block grants to villages to
                                    encourage investments intended to improve specific health and educa-
                                    tion indicators.39 In some communities, the grant was incentivized, in
                                    that the amount of the grant the following year was based partially on
                                    the village’s performance on each of the 12 targeted health and educa-
                                    tion indicators. The performance bonus was competitively allocated
                                    among villages within the same subdistrict. For the evaluation, program
                                    villages were randomly assigned to receive either the incentivized or
                                    the nonincentivized grant. The data come from three survey waves,
                                    conducted between 2007 and 2010.
   A program in Indonesia that         The study finds that the program reached beneficiaries and had very
  gave block grants to villages     significant effects on a range of intermediate behaviors, at both midline
to encourage them to improve        and endline. For health, the strongest intermediate impacts were on
 specific health and education       growth monitoring and the distribution of iron sachets to pregnant
   indicators achieved positive     women. The intervention was also associated with a 9.6 percent reduc-
            midline results . . .   tion in malnutrition and a significant increase in prenatal visits and
                                    immunizations. Health impacts were also larger in incentivized areas.
204
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



Incentives did not affect education indicators, however, and some health       . . . but many results were not
impacts also disappeared by endline. For example, the project had large        sustained.
impacts on reducing neonatal and infant mortality at midline, but these
impacts disappeared by the endline. The endline results also show no
impact on learning.
    Importantly, nontargeted indicators also improved across the board,
with an average improvement of 0.0362 standard deviation, with sta-
tistically significant improvements in indicators such as facility-based
deliveries. The grant also appears to have been most effective in more
disadvantaged areas.
    In looking at the mechanisms through which the project worked, the
authors suggest that Generasi appears to have had the greatest impact on
community effort. It mobilized cadres working at village health posts
and ratcheted up participation in meetings about health education and
related topics. Households in Generasi areas also felt that both health
and education services had improved.
    In terms of overall service provision, however, there were no sta-
tistically significant impacts. If anything, there was a slight decrease
in health provider inputs and effort and some increase in the prices
charged by providers. There is also some evidence of deterioration in
the quality of care. Combined with the fact that the main effects come
from greater community effort in direct service provision, these results
are disturbing from the point of view of sustainability, as is the finding
that there was no impact of the program on any indicator of community
outreach or monitoring and no spillover to other community activities.

Community monitoring of health care providers.            Perhaps the best-
known assessment of the efficacy of community monitoring in improv-
ing health service delivery is of a randomized citizen’s report card project
in Uganda (Bjorkman and Svensson 2007). The main objective of the
project was to improve the quality of basic health services by improv-
ing community capacity to monitor service providers. The report card
intervention was randomly assigned to half of 50 rural communities
across 9 districts. Meetings of users and providers were held at which
the information collected in the report cards was disseminated together        Following the introduction of
with practical information on how best to use this information.40              citizen report cards in Uganda,
   The authors find large and significant improvements in a number               the under-five mortality
of treatment practices, from staff absenteeism to waiting time and the         rate fell 33 percent and
quality of preventive care. They find a 16 percent increase in the use          vaccination rates and infant
of health facilities, along with greater community satisfaction with           weight rose.
                                                                                                          205
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          service providers. Some health outcomes also improved substantially.
                          In particular, the under-five mortality rate fell 33 percent and vaccina-
                          tion prevalence rates and infant weight increased. During this period,
                          there was no increase in government funding or investment in health
                          facilities or services.
                             Given the size of the effect on under-five mortality, understanding
                          the precise channel through which change occurred, as well as the
                          role of community monitoring, is clearly of great value. The interven-
                          tion suggests three competing channels through which service quality
                          changes could have come about: greater community monitoring (a
                          demand-side channel), provision of information to providers regarding
                          their performance relative to expectations (a supply-side channel), and
                          the bringing together of the community and providers (which could
                          increase both the efficacy of information and community willingness
                          to monitor). The authors test for the relevance of the demand- versus
                          supply-side channels by replacing treatment indicators with measures
                          of staff and community engagement as explanatory variables. They find
                          that the coefficients on community engagement are positive, statistically
                          significant, and larger than the coefficients on treatment indicators. In
                          contrast, the coefficients on staff engagement are not significant or have
                          the wrong sign. The authors posit that these results are more supportive
                          of the demand-driven explanation. Although this finding is encourag-
                          ing, the results are at best suggestive, as it is unclear precisely what the
                          community or staff engagement variables are capturing.
                             An interesting descriptive study by Uzochukwu, Akpala, and
                          Onwujekwe (2004) casts valuable light on potential hurdles in scaling
                          up community engagement in service delivery. The authors report on
                          the Bamako Initiative program in Nigeria, which aimed to strengthen
                          primary health care by increasing community engagement. The pro-
                          gram created village- and district-level health committees and gave
                          them substantial authority. The committees’ mandate was to supervise
                          the activities of traditional birth attendants; select, supervise, and pay
                          village health workers; manage revenues and profits from drug sales;
                          set the remuneration of health workers; and make decisions about the
                          level of user fees and rules for exemption. Despite very broad-based
                          participation and awareness of its functions, the committee focused
                          largely on ancillary functions, such as the provision of health education
                          and a waste disposal system. It remained entirely outside all important
                          decision-making processes, such as hiring and payment of staff, setting

206
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



user fees, or providing oversight over budgets. There was also some
disconnect between reports from health facility heads and community
members about the extent of community involvement, with health facil-
ity heads claiming far greater community engagement in planning and
management decisions than community members did.
   Few if any empirical studies collect this type of qualitative data that
could help elucidate the channels through which participation works
to improve outcomes and the potential constraints that could limit
effective community engagement. Moreover, no careful empirical study
has been conducted of the Bamako program that could bring these
participation results together with results on service quality and health
outcomes.

Decentralization of basic health services to local governments or            Decentralization of basic
NGOs. Decentralization of basic health care services to local govern-        health care services to local
ments appears to have been successful overall. The evidence suggests         governments appears to have
substantial gains on a number of child health outcomes as well as on a       been successful overall.
wider range of health behaviors. Some studies also find improvements
in labor market outcomes and decreased fertility.
   The devolution of health service provision to NGOs appears to have        Devolution of health service
been less successful, although there is evidence of some positive out-       provision to NGOs appears
comes. In particular, when programs are devolved to NGOs, improve-           to have been less successful,
ments in health tend to be confined to outcomes specifically targeted          although there is evidence of
by the program. There are also some perverse effects of the imposition       some positive outcomes.
of user fees.
   Much of the evidence on the benefits of decentralized delivery of
basic health services comes from a set of studies on Brazil’s family
health program, the Programa Saude da Famılia (PSF). The PSF was
first rolled out in 1994, as a small pilot initiative covering a few areas.
By 2006, it had expanded into a nationwide program; by 2009, the
program covered more than 90 percent of Brazilian municipalities.
   Municipal governments manage the PSF, under the supervision of            Assessments of Brazil’s
the Brazilian Ministry of Health. PSF teams—which usually consist of         decentralized family health
a doctor, a nurse, an assistant nurse, and six community health workers,     program find positive and
as well as a dental and a social work professional in some cases—are         economically large effects
responsible for monitoring the health status of about 3,000–4,500            on health outcomes and
people (about 1,000 households). Teams make home visits and perform          behaviors.
community-based health promotion activities. All services are delivered
free of charge to ensure access by the most disadvantaged. Assessments

                                                                                                       207
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          of the program find positive and economically large effects on health
                          outcomes, particularly for neonates, and health behaviors. They also
                          find substantial gains in child school attendance, adult labor supply,
                          and employment and a decline in fertility.
                             Macinko and others (2007) uses the differential adoption and expan-
                          sion rates of the PSF as a quasi-experiment to assess the relationship
                          between changes in PSF coverage over time and changes in health
                          outcomes that are most likely to be sensitive to primary care. Their data
                          cover six years (1999–2004) and include 557 Brazilian micro-regions in
                          27 states. Each micro-region includes several municipalities.
                             This study finds a significant reduction in postneonatal mortality
                          (deaths of children from 30 days to 1 year) and mortality from diarrheal
                          diseases. In exploring the mechanisms through which PSF might work,
                          the authors note that areas with greater PSF coverage also have higher
                          prevalence rates of behaviors stressed by community health workers,
                          such as breastfeeding, use of oral rehydration therapy, and child immu-
                          nizations. The authors provide a back of the envelope estimation of
                          program costs of about $30 per capita.41
                             A related study (Macinko, Guanais, and DeSouza 2006) finds high
                          levels of satisfaction with PSF among users, with more than 75 percent
                          reporting that child health services were of good quality. The presence
                          of the program in a given municipality was also associated with better
                          perceived health.
                             A potential limitation of the study by Macinko, Guanais, and
                          DeSouza (2006) is that variation in the timing or rate of PSF adoption
                          could be endogenous. Well-governed municipalities could decentralize
                          health services early, for example, or municipalities with the worst out-
                          comes could decentralize first. In either case, estimated impacts would
                          be biased, with the direction of the bias not clear.42
                             Rocha and Soares (2009) also use the differential adoption and
                          expansion rates of the PSF as a quasi-experiment. They use municipal
                          panel data from 1995 to 2003. These data include information on a
                          range of demographic and socioeconomic characteristics in addition
                          to program coverage and mortality. Difference-in-difference estimates
                          suggest a substantial decline in mortality, especially during the first year
                          of life.43 Municipalities that had been in the program for three years,
                          for example, reduced infant mortality by 1.5 more infants per 1,000 live
                          births than comparable municipalities that did not adopt PSF. Based



208
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



on the 1993 average infant mortality rate in Brazil of 27 per 1,000 live
births, this difference corresponds to a 5.6 percent reduction in the
infant mortality rate. For a municipality eight years into the program,
infant mortality declined by 5.4 deaths per 1,000 live births, a 20 per-
cent decline relative to the 1993 national average.44 Gains were largest
in the two poorest regions (the North and the Northeast), which also
provided fewer public goods.45 Gains were also larger in less urbanized
municipalities and municipalities with less access to treated water and
poorer sanitation systems. The largest impacts of the program on infant
mortality were associated with complications during pregnancy; infec-
tious diseases (diarrhea and other intestinal diseases, influenza); and
respiratory diseases (asthma, bronchitis)—precisely the sorts of condi-
tions for which the presence of a community-based health program
would be most effective.
   The authors also look at the effects of PSF on household behavior,      The program was also
using several rounds of census data. They find no effects on child labor    associated with increases in
supply. In contrast, they find that school enrollment was 4.5 percent       school enrollment, adult labor
higher eight years after PSF exposure. In addition, adult labor supply     supply, and employment and
was 6.8 percentage points higher and employment 11 percentage points       a decline in fertility.
higher.
   The other case on which there is robust evidence of improve-
ments in infant mortality is Pakistan’s Lady Health Worker Program
(formally known as the National Program for Family Planning and
Primary Health Care), introduced by the government in 1994. Lady
health workers are typically young women who have at least eight years
of schooling and live in the community they serve. They are given
15 months of training to deliver care in community settings.
   Lady health workers make home visits and are expected to be avail-
able at their own home, which is known as a “health home.” They
provide antenatal care, contraceptive advice, growth monitoring,
and immunization services, with each worker responsible for about
1,000–1,500 people (about 175 households). Although the program
is a federal program, lady health workers report to basic health units
and rural health centers, which are managed by provincial and district
governments.
   Bhutta and others (2011) present the results of a randomized clus-
ter trial in which lady health workers in treatment villages were given
additional training in group counseling; the promotion of specific



                                                                                                     209
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    health behaviors; the establishment of linkages with traditional birth
                                    attendants; and the recognition of urgent care cases and the need to refer
                                    them to basic health units, rural health centers, or hospitals. In addition,
                                    the trial created volunteer community health committees in treatment
                                    villages, with the aim of promoting maternal and newborn care in the
                                    village. Community health committees were expected to conduct advo-
                                    cacy work with community elders and local political leaders, organize
                                    an emergency fund for transporting the sick to an appropriate facility,
                                    and help lady health workers conduct group education sessions.46
                                       The study finds a 15–20 percent reduction in perinatal and newborn
                                    mortality in the intervention area. It also fi nds improvement in 16
                                    household behaviors related to maternal and early newborn care, with
                                    gains rising over time. The largest improvements were in antenatal care
                                    and facility (instead of at-home) births.
         Lady health workers in        The authors point out that these gains occurred despite implemen-
          Pakistan successfully     tation through the government health system rather than by workers
        delivered a package of      employed directly by the research team, in a difficult to reach and
      preventive and promotive      underdeveloped area. Although lady health workers were unable to
       health care services . . .   complete the full set of activities they were expected to engage in,
                                    they still managed to successfully deliver a package of preventive and
  . . . but to be effective, they   promotive health care services. However, the authors stress, in order
          need close oversight.     to be effective, community health workers and programs need close
                                    oversight.
                                       This study points to the importance of carefully assessing the addi-
                                    tional gain from organizing volunteer-based community health com-
                                    mittees. Given that the largest gains were in facility births, the role of
                                    the community health committees in organizing transport may have
                                    been key, but the importance of transport is not clear from the study.
                                    The study also cannot separate the effect of the additional training pro-
                                    vided to lady health workers from the effect of setting up community
                                    health committees.
                                       Jokhio, Winter, and Cheng (2005) report on an earlier cluster-
                                    randomized trial in rural Pakistan that trained traditional birth atten-
                                    dants in antenatal and newborn care. Traditional birth attendants were
                                    also provided with clean delivery kits from primary health care centers
                                    and linked to lady health workers. Concurrently, outreach clinics were
                                    established in intervention clusters (two clinics in each of three clus-
                                    ters), where obstetricians conducted eight outreach sessions during the
                                    six-month trial.

210
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



   The study finds a reduction in neonatal mortality of 30 percent,
identical to the outcome in Nepal’s experiment with women’s groups
and larger than the results from the lady health worker trial. However,
the sample consists of only seven clusters, including both treatment and
control areas. It also fails to distinguish the impact of training birth
attendants, and hence using existing structures, from the impact of
outreach clinics. In practice, however, 91 percent of the women in the
intervention group received care from traditional birth attendants, with
only 16 percent visiting outreach clinics.
   The Projahnmo project in Bangladesh tested a model similar to the
lady health worker program, with one difference (Baqui and others
2008). Two treatment arms were established, in order to test the efficacy
of a home-based care model against a community-based care model. In
both intervention arms, male and female community mobilizers held
group meetings on birth and newborn care preparedness. Community
resource people were enlisted to encourage women to attend these meet-
ings and seek antenatal care.
   In the home care intervention, one community health worker was
recruited (by an NGO) per four villages with a total population of
about 4,000 people. The community health worker was trained for six
weeks in behavior change communication and the clinical assessment
and management of illnesses in neonates. He or she was responsible
for tracking pregnancies during routine surveillance activities, making
scheduled antenatal and postnatal home visits, diagnosing illnesses
for referral, and administering penicillin to neonates who could not
be taken to health facilities for treatment. In the community care arm
of the intervention, only group meetings with mobilizers and resource
people were held; no home visits were made. However, female volunteers
(including traditional birth attendants) were recruited to identify preg-   An intervention in Bangladesh
nant women, encourage them to attend meetings held by mobilizers,           that created community health
and receive routine antenatal and early postnatal care. These volunteers    groups had no impact on any
were responsible for about 18,000 people.                                   outcomes.
   This study finds very significant improvements in neonatal mortality
but only in the home care arm, which saw a 30 percent decline in neona-     In contrast, a home care
tal mortality during the last 6 months of the 30-month trial (relative to   intervention was associated
the control arm). In the home care clusters, there was also a sizable and   with a 30 percent decline
statistically significant improvement in the use of supplements during       in neonatal mortality as well
pregnancy, the use of clean equipment, and newborn care practices. In       as improvements in other
contrast, there was no significant improvement in health behaviors in        health outcomes.

                                                                                                       211
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          the community care arm. Furthermore, each community health worker
                          in this trial was responsible for 4,000 people, a ratio similar to the
                          primary health care worker-to-population ratio in Bangladesh’s health
                          care system, suggesting an easy route for scaling up existing health
                          infrastructure.
                             Two studies look at the impact of devolving primary health care pro-
                          vision to NGOs. Kremer and others (2006) evaluate the effects of a pilot
                          program under which the Cambodian Ministry of Health contracted
                          with NGOs to run public health facilities in 12 districts. The project,
                          which ran from 1999 to 2003, covered 1.26 million people, about
                          11 percent of Cambodia’s population. In some districts (“contracting in”
                          districts), contracted NGOs were expected to work within the existing
                          government system to procure drugs, equipment, and supplies and to
                          use Ministry of Health personnel. They could request transfers of per-
                          sonnel but not hire or fire staff; their operating expenses were financed
                          through the government budget. In others districts (“contracting out”
                          districts), NGOs had full management authority. They could hire
                          and fire staff; bring in health workers from other parts of the country;
                          and procure drugs, supplies, and equipment from any source. 47 Staff
                          members from the Ministry of Health were allowed to join the NGO
                          by taking a leave of absence from the civil service. If fired by the NGO,
                          they were allowed to return to government service in another district.48
                             The study finds that both contracting out and contracting in had
                          significant positive effects on most measures of health center manage-
                          ment, including the health center’s hours of service, staff presence dur-
                          ing unannounced visits, and availability of equipment, supplies, and
                          vaccines.49 The authors also look at the impact on the specific health
                          outcomes targeted by the program. They find that both contracting
                          in and contracting out had positive and significant effects on the use
                          of public health facilities for curative care consultations, as well as on
                          antenatal care, vitamin A distribution to children, and child immuniza-
                          tion. In contrast, there was less systematic improvement in nontargeted
                          outcomes, such as the treatment of diarrhea and knowledge about HIV
                          risk factors.
                             Yoong (2007) studies the Rogi Kalyan Samiti (Patient Welfare
                          Committee [RKS]) program, in the Indian state of Madhya Pradesh,
                          which transferred control over some aspects of hospital management
                          to a local NGO.50 The study used the phased implementation of this
                          transfer of authority to identify its impact on child immunization rates.

212
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



   Using difference-in-difference estimates, the study finds that chil-
dren ages 0–3 received significantly fewer appropriate vaccines per year
of exposure after a hospital was transferred to the NGO. Interestingly,
the reduction in immunization rates was confi ned to the relatively
better-off, with no negative effect on the poor, who were exempt from
the user fees charged by the NGO. It is useful to note that vaccination
is not generally a candidate for decentralization, because of significant
interpersonal and interjurisdictional externalities.51



The Poverty Impact of Participatory Projects
Evidence on the poverty impacts of participatory development projects        Evidence on the poverty
and decentralization reforms is scarce. This section draws some lessons      impacts of participatory
from the little evidence there is, with some important qualifiers: the        development projects and
number of studies is small; the studies examine fairly disparate interven-   decentralization reforms is
tions; and, with a few exceptions, outcomes are typically assessed within    scarce.
a relatively short time span, even though, as discussed in chapter 3, some
outcomes, such as changes in income or assets, are likely to be realized
only over much longer time periods. It is also unclear whether most
projects operate at a scale that could plausibly affect average poverty
levels in program communities or even effect a permanent change in
the income or assets of participating households.
   Participatory projects provide a bundle of interventions, of which the    Participatory projects provide
encouragement or facilitation of participation is but one. Most provide      a bundle of interventions.
resources for local public goods, productivity-enhancing investments,
or private transfers, and many provide all three, often bundled with
some form of microcredit. All of these interventions inject resources into
communities and could thus have an independent effect on income.
   Many community-driven development programs are also moving
decisively toward greater support for livelihood activities. Such projects
tend to encompass a broad array of productive activities, including crop
production and nontraditional agricultural activities, such as aquacul-
ture and medicinal plants, livestock, agro-forestry, fishing, and fish
farming. Most programs also support postproduction activities, which
can include agro-processing enterprises as well as rural marketing ser-
vices. Projects usually provide some type of grant to eligible members
or groups for productive investments, which can be either individual
or collective and often include a training component, which may cover

                                                                                                           213
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   project formulation, skill enhancement, or the basics of business man-
                                   agement and marketing. Many projects include innovative multisectoral
                                   programs, including linkages with government line ministries at many
                                   levels. Careful evaluations of these efforts would add much to the
                                   knowledge base on the effectiveness of participatory poverty reduction
                                   programs.
  The evidence on the impact           The literature reviewed below provides a mixed picture. Some studies
  of participatory projects on     find improvements in assets or income, other do not. Studies that pres-
          poverty is mixed . . .   ent longer-term results tend to find that income gains either disappear
                                   or survive only for specific subgroups, not always the poorest or most
    . . . and most studies find     disadvantaged. There are also concerns about evaluation strategies. The
 that income gains disappear       review excludes studies that use extremely poor data or an evaluation
  over time or survive only for    strategy that is flawed in a fundamental way.
     subgroups, which are not          An evaluation of the long-running KALAHI-CIDSS program in
   always the poorest or most      the Philippines finds a 5 percent increase in consumption, concentrated
               disadvantaged.      among poor households (Labonne 2011).52 The program was also
                                   associated with higher labor force participation rates for both men and
                                   women and greater income diversification, as evident in reported par-
                                   ticipation rates at midline (2006), particularly for women. Interestingly,
                                   during the financial downturn, the participation rate for both men and
                                   women fell significantly, but mainly in control areas. The program thus
                                   appears to have had a protective effect on employment and participation
                                   rates, particularly for women.
                                       Reported impacts are likely to be significantly biased, however—
                                   and the bias is likely to be in the direction of finding positive income
                                   impacts, since the results do not correct appropriately for sample size or
                                   initial differences between program and control groups.53
    A careful evaluation of the        A careful evaluation of the KDP program in Indonesia (Voss 2008)
    KDP program in Indonesia       finds no impact on average household consumption. However, there
       concludes that it led to    are significant gains among households in the bottom quintile of the
significant consumption gains       consumption distribution and similar losses for households in the top
       by the bottom quintile.     quintile.54 In the matched household sample, per capita consumption
                                   by the bottom quintile rose about 5 percent. The author carefully dem-
                                   onstrates that the estimated impact is likely to be robust to problems
                                   in the data.
                                       A potential problem with this study is that the 2002 survey
                                   (SUSENAS) appears to have mismeasured household consumption. As
                                   a result, households whose consumption was erroneously understated
                                   in 2002 registered an increase in consumption in 2007, and households

214
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



whose consumption was erroneously overstated in 2002 registered con-
sumption losses. This concern is not significant when looking at aver-
age changes, because program placement and mismeasurement are not
likely to be correlated. It is a concern when disaggregating the data into
quintiles using 2002 poverty status or per capita consumption, because
the quintile level estimates may be biased. The authors use two alter-
native strategies to demonstrate that this bias is unlikely to be large.55
Interestingly, the study finds no impact on the consumption of other
disadvantaged groups, such as households with low levels of education
or households headed by women, which suffer from more severe pov-
erty, suggesting that consumption growth in the bottom quintile was
concentrated among poor households near the poverty line.
   A randomized evaluation of GoBifo, another World Bank–funded
project, in Sierra Leone also finds no impact on household income four
years after project inception (Casey, Glennerster, and Miguel 2011).56
The evaluation sample included 238 villages, half of which were ran-
domly held as controls. The baseline evaluation was conducted in 2005
and the follow-up in 2009.
   GoBifo provided block grants of $4,667 (roughly $100 per house-
hold) to rural communities for construction of local public goods
and for skills training and small business start-up capital. The project
required village development committees to submit development plans
for grant use to district councils through ward development commit-
tees for review and approval. The government implemented the project.
Community facilitators supported GoBifo communities by encouraging
inclusive decision making; greater participation of marginalized groups,
such as women and youth; and transparent budgeting practices.
   The results indicate some gains in household assets, such as housing
quality and durables, as well as impacts on intermediate outcomes, such
as the number of petty traders in the village and the range of goods
available for sale. However, the authors do not discuss whether these
gains accrued to poor or otherwise disadvantaged households. It is not
clear whether this study collected detailed consumption data.
   The Programme National d’Infrastructures Rurales (PNIR) was
implemented in 90 of the poorest communautés rurales in Senegal.57 Its
main objective was to support the decentralization and fiscal reform
process by providing resources for rural infrastructure investments which
were allocated using a participatory mechanism. At the village level,
the program set up a community development committee (Comité de

                                                                                        215
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     Concertation et de Gestion), with mandated inclusion of women and other
                                     marginalized groups.
                                        Evaluation of the program used a quasi-experimental approach
                                     (Arcand and Bassole 2008). Eligibility for PNIR was based on an index
                                     of access to basic services at the communauté rurale level, allowing the
                                     authors to choose control communities using the same set of indicators
                                     and regional controls.58
                                        The evaluation finds no reduction in household poverty, as measured
                                     by consumption expenditures, when villages that received the program
                                     are compared with controls, regardless of whether the program village
                                     received any PNIR funding. This comparison comes closest perhaps to
                                     a test of the impact of participation per se on income, as PNIR villages
                                     should differ from controls only in the community mobilization effort
                                     of PNIR rather than because of project funds. This comparison does
                                     find significant improvements in the nutritional status of children (as
                                     measured by weight for age, height for age, and weight for height), how-
                                     ever, with larger gains for poorer households. It also finds improvements
                                     in access to clean drinking water, which rose 22 percentage points, and
                                     basic health services, which rose 24 percentage points. It is unclear what
                                     drove these improvements, however.
                                        When the study confines attention to program villages and compares
                                     outcomes for households in villages with completed projects with out-
                                     comes in villages without completed projects, it finds large and signifi-
                                     cant impacts on consumption, particularly for the poor, but no impact
                                     on child nutrition. This finding suggests that nutritional gains do not
                                     vary because of investments in local public goods, whereas income and
                                     consumption do. These results are less robust than results that compare
                                     PNIR communities to control communities since it is unclear what
                                     determines the odds of a PNIR village actually getting a project.59 The
                                     study also finds that poverty is reduced only in villages that invested in
                                     income-generating agricultural projects and, curiously, in schools rather
                                     than in drinking water or public health facilities.
      Analysis of India’s District      An evaluation of the District Poverty Initiative Program (DPIP) in
      Poverty Initiative Program     Andhra Pradesh (Deininger and Liu 2009) also yields mixed results.
             finds no change in       The authors use two rounds of data, from 2004 and 2006, collected
      consumption or nutrition.      from three districts in the state (Anantapur, Adilabad, and Srikakulam)
                                     to evaluate program impacts. As all the municipalities (mandals) in their
                                     sample benefitted from DPIP, they construct a counterfactual using
                                     years in the program. Specifically, control mandals are mandals that

216
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



entered the program two and half years after treatment mandals and so
have fewer years of exposure to the program. The sample includes 41
programs and 10 controls mandals, selected through propensity score
matching to eliminate bias because of initial selection.60 The authors
assess program impact on household consumption, nutritional intake,
and nonfinancial assets. Using the full sample of matched households,
they find no change in consumption or nutrition, though there was a
significant (16 percent) improvement in nonfinancial assets.
   DPIP began in 2001, with the objective of using women’s self-help
groups, which had been organized in Andhra Pradesh under earlier
development projects, to promote economic and social empowerment.61
The bulk of DPIP support was directed at building the capacity of
self-help groups and providing them with a one-time grant to promote
microcredit and savings through a “community investment fund.”62
The presence of women’s self-help groups was an important factor in
the selection of the first DPIP districts.
   Confining attention to self-help group participants, the authors find
an 11 percentage point increase in consumption, a 10–12 percentage
point increase in nutrition, and a 23 percentage point increase in non-
financial assets. This comparison is valid only insofar as self-help group
membership was driven by the same factors in the old and new DPIP
districts. The widespread prevalence of self-help groups in the old DPIP
districts much before the program was initiated, casts some doubt on
this. That said, the results suggest that benefits were confined largely to
members, which seems sensible given that benefits were mainly in the
form of transfers to organized self-help groups (the project created no
public goods). Disaggregating by poverty status, the authors find that
benefits were entirely concentrated among the poor, with the greatest
benefits going to the poorest.
   Four other studies find little or no impact on poverty. Park and         China’s flagship community-
Wang (2009) evaluate China’s Poor Village Investment Program—a              based poverty alleviation
community-based poverty alleviation program initiated in 2001 that          program had no impact on
financed investments in infrastructure projects in “poor” villages.63        mean income or consumption
Projects were to be selected through a participatory mechanism. The         growth . . .
study finds no impact of the project on mean income or consumption
growth—although income and consumption among the better-off                 . . . although there were
rose significantly.64 For the nonpoor, per capita household income rose      substantial positive effects
6.6 percent and per capita consumption expenditure rose 8.8 percent.65      on income and consumption
The program also reduced the odds of migration by nonpoor households        among the better-off.

                                                                                                      217
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    by 5.2 percent. In contrast, there was no effect on the migration odds
                                    of the poor.
                                       The study uses panel data on some 666 eligible villages and 5,500
                                    households surveyed in 2001 and 2004. The identification strategy
                                    relies on the gradual phasing in of planned investments within desig-
                                    nated poor villages. Hence, the main concern for identification is not
                                    the potential bias because of village selection but the bias induced by
                                    the timing of program investments. The authors use propensity score
                                    matching with time-invariant variables, or variables measured before
                                    the start of the program, to deal with this problem.66
                                       The implied transfer of wealth to the relatively better off is consider-
                                    able, given the authors’ estimates that in 2004 the central government
                                    allocated some Y 32.7 billion (about $4 billion)—more than 5 percent
                                    of the central government budget—to poverty investment programs.
                                       An evaluation of the Southwest China Poverty Reduction Project
                                    (SWP) provides a rare longer-run perspective on program impact
                                    (Chen, Mu, and Ravallion 2009). The SWP was introduced in 1995 in
                                    the counties of Guangxi, Guizhou, and Yunnan with the explicit goal
                                    of achieving a large and sustainable reduction in poverty in the poor-
                                    est villages in these counties.67 Like other participatory programs, the
                                    SWP included a bundle of interventions along with community-based
                                    participation in the selection of beneficiaries and activities. Within
                                    selected villages, it was expected that virtually all households would
                                    benefit from infrastructure investments such as improved rural roads,
                                    power lines, and piped water supply. Broad-based benefits were also
                                    expected from improved social services, including upgrading village
                                    schools and health clinics and training teachers and village health care
                                    workers. People with school-age children also received tuition subsidies,
                                    as a conditional cash transfer. Individual loans were available for invest-
                                    ments in a wide range of productive activities, ranging from investments
                                    in yield improvement and animal husbandry to nonfarm enterprises.
                                    Microloans accounted for more than 60 percent of all disbursements.
 The Southwest China Poverty           The project yielded sizable and statistically significant improvements
    Reduction Project yielded       in mean household income in participating villages during the project
     sizable improvements in        cycle. But four years after the project had ended, these gains had largely
   mean household income in         disappeared.68 The only group that was able to sustain income gains
  participating villages during     were initially poor but relatively well-educated households, which may
          the project cycle . . .   have been genuinely credit constrained because of poverty. Given the
                                    numerous interventions bundled in this program, the authors do not

218
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



attempt to isolate the effects of community participation. Given the         . . . but four years after the
observed heterogeneity in long-term gains, they do attempt to infer the      project had ended, these
potential impact of using participatory practices to identify beneficia-      gains had largely disappeared.
ries for loans. They conclude that the weak overall performance of the
project may have been caused by a participatory beneficiary selection
process that apparently favored the better-educated overall but, perhaps
because of program capture, failed to provide enough opportunities for
the educated poor.
   The authors also point to a broader concern with the assessment of        Additional funding from
the longer-term impacts of programs that are geographically placed,          participatory programs
even when program assignment is random. Additional funding from              could simply displace local
participatory programs could simply displace local government spend-         government spending in
ing in project areas, or governments could increase funding in non-          project areas, or governments
project areas. There is some evidence for such displacement in their         could increase funding in
study areas. Comparison villages appear to catch up with project vil-        nonproject areas.
lages. Early gains in project villages disappeared as enrollment in con-
trol villages rose, for example. The authors note that this process may
account, in part, for the smaller long-term impacts they observe, but the
size of the bias introduced does not indicate that it could fully account
for the absence of an average income impact over the longer term.
   Fearon, Humphreys, and Weinstein (2009) study a community-                A participatory project in
driven reconstruction project implemented by the International Rescue        postconflict northern Liberia
Committee in post conflict northern Liberia. This careful study finds          had no apparent impact on
no impact of the project on livelihoods or access to public goods or         livelihoods or access to public
services. The authors also find no evidence that the community-driven         goods or services.
reconstruction program reduced the need for households in treatment
communities to walk to key services. However, they do find that school-
age children and young adults in treatment communities had higher
school attendance rates, and there was a significant increase in female
employment (see also the discussion of this study in chapter 6).
   Two recent studies use randomized designs to study World Bank–
funded community-driven development programs that provide support
to individuals to obtain skills and business training and to establish or
expand microenterprises. Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez (2011) assess
the Youth Opportunities Program, implemented under the Northern
Uganda Social Action Fund (NUSAF). This program provided sub-
stantial grants (worth almost 1.5 years of salary) to young adults chosen
by lottery. About 60 percent of the grant was invested in vocational
training or productive assets, with a substantial portion of the rest used

                                                                                                        219
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  for working capital, savings, and consumption. The results at midline
                                  suggest a significant increase in the number of hours worked as well
                                  as a 50 percent increase in net income. Given the interest rates facing
                                  young adults, these investments would likely not have been made in
                                  the absence of grant funding, underscoring the need to expand access
                                  to capital markets for the poor and for young people, who lack assets as
                                  well as employment experience.
                                     Gine and Mansuri (2012) assess a program to provide business
                                  training and microloans to members of rural community organiza-
                                  tions established by the National Rural Support Program (NRSP)
                                  and funded by the Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund (PPAF). Many
                                  community organization members already had some experience with
                                  microcredit loans from NRSP.
                                     Community organizations were randomized into two groups, one
                                  of which was offered the opportunity to obtain eight days of business
                                  training at no cost. About two-thirds of people offered training took it.
                                  Both groups were also offered the opportunity to apply for a loan that
                                  was about five times the size of the standard loan (the base loan was
                                  about Rs. 20,000, about six to seven months of daily wage labor earn-
                                  ings for one household member). Access to the loan was randomized
                                  through a lottery in which about half of applicants were chosen.
                                     Gine and Mansuri find that business training reduced business fail-
                                  ure and that the best businesses survived. Training also raised consump-
                                  tion, increased income (by about 12 percent), and improved business
                                  practices. However, the gains were confined largely to men.69 Uptake of
                                  the loan was modest, with less than a third of eligible members apply-
                                  ing, and the authors find no additional income gain for lottery winners.
 Business training in Pakistan       Alwang, Gacitua-Mario, and Centurion (2008) report on PRODECO,
    reduced business failure,     a project that supports group-based income-generating activities in
     raised consumption and       the southern departments of Itapua, Misiones, and Neembucu in
       income, and improved       Paraguay. Its main objectives are to empower marginalized groups and
       business practices . . .   to strengthen local government capacity to identify, design, implement,
                                  and monitor community development projects. PRODECO provides
       . . . but the gains were   grants to eligible groups for productive investments. Groups are formed
      confined largely to men.     in targeted communities by “development agents,” which can be NGOs
                                  or public sector employees. Once the income-generating activity is
                                  identified, groups are trained in project formulation, technical skills
                                  related to the project, and business management and marketing basics.
                                  Approved projects can receive up to $30,000.70

220
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



   The evaluation finds significant poverty impacts, but the design of
the evaluation is unclear. Survey data were collected on participant and
nonparticipant households. However, the authors do not specify how
this sample was created. The authors then use a matching technique as
well as an instrumental variables strategy to deal with selection. They
do not discuss the matching variables or indicate when they were mea-
sured. The district-level instrument is a measure of political participa-
tion through voting; it is unclear how it can deal with selection at the
household level. The second instrument is ownership of a refrigerator.
Use of this measure ostensibly exploits the targeting criteria of the proj-
ect, but as the data come years after the project is implemented, it is
unclear why household assets years after the program was implemented
should satisfy the exclusion restriction. Moreover, the data suggest that
program participants are more likely than nonparticipants to own a
refrigerator. Finally, the evaluation says nothing about the participa-
tory process through which projects were identified, approved, and
ultimately run.
   A qualitative study by Marcus (2002) underscores the lack of longer-       Participatory project
term sustainability of participatory efforts. Marcus’s study includes a       investments in Mali, Mongolia,
desk review of three social funds and an analysis of qualitative data from    and Tajikistan were not
beneficiary communities. The projects reviewed were implemented by             sustainable, particularly
Save the Children in Mali, Mongolia, and Tajikistan. The review finds          for the poorest.
that, on balance, project investments were not sustainable, particularly
for the poorest, once targeted assistance in the form of school fees and
food subsidies was phased out.



Conclusions
The literature on decentralized targeting identifies a trade-off between       On balance, the evidence
the advantages of local information and the hazards of local capture.         appears to indicate that local
On balance, the evidence appears to indicate that local capture can           capture can overwhelm the
overwhelm the benefits of local information.                                   benefits of local information.
   Project design and implementation rules also play a critical role in
determining whether participatory programs are captured. Demand-              Demand-driven, competitive
driven, competitive application processes can exclude the weakest com-        application processes
munities and exacerbate horizontal inequities. Under some conditions,         can exclude the weakest
co-financing requirements—which have become the sine qua non of                communities and exacerbate
participatory projects—can exacerbate the exclusion of the poorest            horizontal inequities.

                                                                                                         221
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   households and communities and attenuate the impacts of poverty
                                   reduction programs.
  Co-financing requirements—           Community contributions and a demand-driven competitive proj-
  which have become the sine       ect approval process are expected to generate higher-quality projects
      qua non of participatory     that are better aligned with community needs. They are also expected
     projects—can exacerbate       to enhance the sustainability of community infrastructure by giving
  the exclusion of the poorest     beneficiaries a real stake in maintaining local public goods. At the
 households and communities        same time, if the most disadvantaged among the eligible have the least
 and attenuate the impacts of      capacity to propose viable projects and are thus more likely to opt out
  poverty reduction programs.      of the process altogether, the intended poverty reduction impacts of the
                                   program are attenuated and cross-community inequities in capacity and
                                   resources can increase.
                                      The political relationship between the center and localities also mat-
                                   ters, as do the incentives of local politicians under democratic decentral-
                                   ization. The objectives of the center and localities can diverge widely.


                                   Involving Communities
     On balance, the evidence      On balance, the evidence suggests that greater community involvement
         suggests that greater     tends to improve resource sustainability and the quality of infrastruc-
       community involvement       ture. However, four concerns permeate the literature:
    tends to improve resource
 sustainability and the quality      •   Inequality tends to reduce both efficiency and equity, and there
                                         can be important tradeoffs between resource sustainability and
              of infrastructure.
                                         equity.
                                     •   Transferring management responsibilities for a resource or an
                                         infrastructure scheme does not usually involve handing over
                                         control to a cohesive organic entity with the requisite capac-
                                         ity; often it requires creating local management capacity. In the
                                         absence of deliberate efforts to create such capacity and provide
                                         resources for ongoing maintenance and management, invest-
                                         ments in infrastructure are largely wasted and natural resources
                                         poorly managed.
                                     •   Clear mechanisms for downward accountability are critical.
                                         The literature is rife with cases in which decentralization is used
                                         to tighten central control and increase incentives for upward
                                         accountability rather than to increase local discretion. The
                                         absence of robust mechanisms for downward accountability
                                         tends to go hand in hand with complex reporting and planning

222
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



      requirements, which are usually beyond the capacity of local
      actors and become a tool for retaining control and assigning
      patronage. Most of these requirements are holdovers from past
      rules designed to extract resources from local rather than benefit
      communities.
  •   Communities need to benefit from the resources they manage.
      For natural resources that create substantial externalities, the
      benefit should be commensurate with the size of the externality
      created by the resource and should at least compensate com-
      munities for the alternative uses to which they could put the
      resource for immediate gain. These concerns imply consider-
      able engagement of higher-tier governments or implement-
      ing agencies in building local capacity, monitoring outcomes,
      and setting the broad parameters under which management
      is devolved—with a view to enhancing downward rather than
      upward accountability while leaving sufficient discretion at the
      local level.


Decentralizing Delivery of Education and Health
The evidence on the extent to which decentralizing the delivery of edu-
cation and health has improved service access for the poor and other dis-
advantaged groups and led to improvements in service quality is mixed.
Because efforts to engage communities in improving basic health ser-
vices or primary schools usually also involve a substantial injection of
funds for other activities (trained health personnel, upgraded facilities,
stipends, uniforms, school meals), unpacking the impact of community
engagement is d ifficult. The few studies that try to do so suggest that
encouraging community participation can be beneficial when projects
also provide technical support, such as community-based trained
health personnel, or make investments in upgrading health and school
facilities.
   The evidence also suggests that the most successful programs are          The most successful programs
implemented by local governments that have some discretion and are           are implemented by local
downwardly accountable. Devolving programs to NGOs works less                governments that have some
well, on average. Interventions that provide information to households       discretion and are downwardly
and communities about the quality of services in their community as          accountable.
well as government standards of service tend to improve outcomes even
when no additional resources are expended.

                                                                                                      223
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   Improving Livelihoods
        A few studies find that     Few studies of participatory poverty reduction programs fi nd clear
  projects with large livelihood   poverty impacts. Some positive income effects emerge for subgroups,
   components perform better       although in most cases the methodology used to generate these results
       than other participatory    is questionable. There is some evidence, however, that projects with
projects, but more evaluations     larger livelihood components (credit, skills) perform better than other
                    are needed.    participatory projects, at least in the short run. Given this potential,
                                   such projects should be carefully evaluated.



                                   Notes
                                    1. Leakage occurs when benefits accrue to people other than the intended
                                       beneficiaries. Undercoverage occurs when some intended beneficiaries
                                       cannot be covered, because of budget constraints.
                                    2. A poverty monitoring tool allows eligibility to be enforced though an
                                       administrative process, using indicators of household or community wel-
                                       fare that are intended to proxy for income, which is costly and often dif-
                                       ficult to observe. The process usually involves some type of means test based
                                       on easily observed and verified aspects of a household’s or community’s
                                       poverty status, such as demographic and socioeconomic characteristics
                                       that are expected to be strongly correlated with relative deprivation.
                                    3. Although private transfers can also include some stipulations to contribute
                                       labor (as in the case of workfare programs) or undertake specific behaviors
                                       (such as vaccinating one’s children or enrolling them in school), the benefits
                                       are largely internalized by the household in the form of income or gains
                                       from improved health and schooling. This is not the case for the provision
                                       of free labor for a nonexcludable local public good, as the labor-providing
                                       household can internalize only a fraction of the benefits.
                                    4. As Galasso and Ravallion (2005) note, the requirement that all thanas
                                       (municipalities or county subdivisions) participate in the program is likely
                                       to have constrained the scope for pro-poor geographic targeting at the
                                       center. Such political economy constraints tend to be a common feature
                                       of social programs.
                                    5. Despite their higher allocations, the provinces were initially less able to
                                       target their poor areas, possibly because wealthier areas were better able to
                                       propose and co-finance feasible projects. In response, a project monitor-
                                       ing tool was developed to continuously update targeting performance at
                                       the district level. Ravallion (2000) shows that this simple but powerful
                                       tool—which can be adapted for regular project monitoring and evalua-
                                       tion—was able to substantially improve the intraprovincial targeting of
                                       the poor.
                                    6. Because data on the shares obtained by provinces are not available, it is
                                       unclear how successful this effort was.


224
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



 7. Proxy means tests are increasingly being used to target beneficiaries pre-
    cisely because of concerns about program capture. They tend to impose
    uniform eligibility requirements, with some regional variation, leaving
    little room for discretion in the identification of beneficiaries at the local
    level.
 8. Mustafa (2007), for example, views British colonial water development
    projects in India and Pakistan as an effort to increase the power of the state
    and ensure security. British authorities sought to “increase government
    control of the local populations by encouraging them to take up settled
    agriculture and thereby minimize the security threat they might pose to
    the power of the state.” Mosse (2001) emphasizes that political control has
    always been a component of decentralized task management in India; it
    was part of a political process that allowed chiefs to maintain and extend
    their control
 9. These developments were reflected in the title of the Eighth World Forestry
    Congress—“Forests for People”—held in 1978. The same year, both the
    Food and Agriculture Organization and the World Bank presented policy
    papers indicating the change in focus (Hobley 1996; Arnold 1998; Wardell
    and Lund 2006; see also Dasgupta 2009).
10. In 1992, the Rio Declaration and Agenda 21 called for participatory natu-
    ral resource management strategies as means of increasing efficiency and
    equity in natural resource use and management. The emphasis on poverty
    reduction was strengthened even more in the United Nations Millennium
    Declaration (United Nations 2000).
11. Forestry, for example, historically focused on establishing plantations and
    woodlots. The handing over of rights to existing natural forests to rural
    communities emerged only in the 1980s (Arnold 1998).
12. Scholarship on common property regimes spans many disciplines.
    Anthropologists, resource economists, environmentalists, historians, politi-
    cal scientists, rural sociologists, and others have contributed to the growing
    body of literature, which also comprises political ecological, ethnographic,
    and historical approaches. Although Ostrom’s work has clearly been the
    most influential in this regard, Dasgupta, Agarwal, Ribot, Bardhan, and
    others have also made important contributions. Recent empirical work
    on the commons draws significantly on theories of property rights and
    institutions. For a review of some of this literature, see; Bates (1989);
    Libecap (1989); Eggertsson (1990); North (1990); and the introduction
    in Ensminger (1992), which discusses the early foundations of this litera-
    ture in the work of Coase (1960), Cheung (1970), Commons (1970), and
    Alchian and Demsetz (1972).
13. As Ribot, Lund, and Treue (2010) note, democratic decentralization is
    specifically about including whole populations—all citizens—in decision
    making based on representative authority, whereas CBNRM defines a
    community for each intervention (the user group, “stakeholders,” fish-
    ers). Under CBNRM, the mode of representation of the “community”
    is variously defined through appointed committees, elected committees,
    stakeholder forums, participatory processes, customary chiefs, project


                                                                                            225
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                personnel, and so forth. In contrast, democratic decentralization involves
                                transfers to elected local government authorities, and the community is
                                defined simply as the citizens who live in the jurisdiction.
                          14.   See also Morrow and Hull’s (1996) study of the Yanesha Forestry
                                Cooperative in Peru.
                          15.   As the paper relies on a single cross-section and forest user groups were not
                                placed randomly, the author uses a number of creative econometric strate-
                                gies, including the use of administrative data to control for heterogeneity
                                in the placement of forest groups. The results remain robust. The main
                                outcome measure is self-reported collections of firewood and fodder.
                          16.   Their empirical strategy involves comparing adjacent VP and non–VP for-
                                est parcels in order to control for unobservable community characteristics.
                                They also control for a number of geographical attributes (such as slope,
                                aspect, altitude, and distance from the village) that affect forest quality.
                          17.   The study uses a large sample of randomly selected forest parcels and
                                objective measures of forest quality, including canopy cover, height, girth,
                                species of trees, and lopping and regeneration rates. The authors deal with
                                unobserved heterogeneity in the existence of a VP by comparing conditions
                                in VP and non–VP forest patches that are adjacent to a particular village.
                                This methodology allows them to control for time-invariant characteristics
                                of local geography, climate, and communities. They address the potential
                                for negative externalities to neighboring non–VP forests by including
                                controls for distance to the nearest VP forest.
                          18.   Khwaja (2009), for example, notes that communities often report choosing
                                a particular type of project simply because they believed that it was one
                                the external agency could or would approve; asking for a different type of
                                project, they believed, would lead to not getting any project at all.
                          19.   Project complexity was measured by whether the project required cash
                                or skilled labor and the community’s experience in maintaining such a
                                project.
                          20.   Controlling for inequality in wealth (land ownership), an increase in the
                                heterogeneity index from the first to the third quartile (0.25–0.43) is
                                associated with a 7 percent drop in maintenance.
                          21.   The argument is that as a member’s share of project returns increases, her
                                share of maintenance costs may not increase commensurately if free riding
                                is possible and maintenance costs are increasing. However, as inequality
                                in returns increases further, people with substantial shares may become
                                willing to bear the necessary maintenance costs, perhaps by contracting
                                out the work.
                          22.   Survey data included engineers’ assessments of the quality of project con-
                                struction, the physical condition of the project on the survey date, and
                                beneficiary assessments of project performance. Information on household
                                landholdings, assets, caste, education, and other characteristics for all
                                households in study villages came from the census.
                          23.   The NRSP operates much like the Agha Khan Rural Support Program.
                                Both are now substantially funded by an apex institution, the Pakistan
                                Poverty Alleviation Fund, which is financed by the World Bank.


226
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



24. An increase in the quality of the leader from the first to the third quartile
    increased the quality of maintenance by almost 8 percentage points.
25. The exogeneity argument relies on the fact that both the subdistrict and
    the village are administrative units based on population and geography and
    are thus not likely to be influenced by the presence of the KDP. However, it
    is not clear that the number of villages per subdistrict is uncorrelated with
    other unobserved subdistrict characteristics, such as ethnic heterogeneity
    or geography, which could exert an independent effect on project quality.
    For example, location and geography could influence local labor market
    conditions, the cost of materials and transportation, construction methods,
    and pre–KDP stocks of village infrastructure. Similarly, if ethnic/religious
    identity is part of the calculation in setting administrative boundaries,
    subdistricts with greater ethnic diversity could have a larger number of
    more homogeneous villages. If such villages are also more cohesive, with
    higher levels of village monitoring, average project quality could be higher
    in subdistricts that comprise more villages. Given the limitations this study
    faces in relying exclusively on administrative data from the KDP, it deals
    with these issues well.
26. Gunnarsson and others (2009) use data from eight Latin American coun-
    tries. They find that differences across countries explain just 9 percent
    of the variation in school autonomy and 6 percent of the variation in
    community participation, although cross-country differences in man-
    dated levels of autonomy and participation are substantial. Educational
    systems are highly nationalized in Bolivia and the Dominican Republic;
    more locally managed in Brazil, Chile, and Colombia; and somewhere in
    between in Argentina and Peru. Interestingly, the two countries with the
    greatest parental participation, Colombia and the Dominican Republic,
    are at opposite ends of the range of legal centralization. Cuba has both
    extremely low levels of autonomy and participation and extremely high
    educational achievement.
27. The program they evaluate sought to address the challenges created by
    the introduction of free primary education in Kenya and the associated
    influx of new students with varying levels of academic preparation.
28. A second component of this program was a training program for parent
    associations, which provided training in the management of school funds
    and in the participatory management process. The authors do not evaluate
    this component, which was introduced at a later stage.
29. The authors use the gradual phasing in of the intervention to identify
    average treatment effects using a pipeline approach. An index of school
    quality (which included student density; teacher student ratio; and failure,
    repetition, and dropout rates) was used to target schools for AGE. The
    authors use this index to check whether schools that received AGE during
    the study period were similar at baseline to schools that received AGE later.
    They also use school fi xed effects and a school-specific linear time trend.
    Although this strategy cannot deal with unobserved time-variant school
    characteristics that are correlated with both the timing of AGE treatment
    and the quality outcomes of interest, the authors argue correctly that such


                                                                                            227
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                unobserved time-variant school characteristics are unlikely to be driving
                                the results. The authors also find little evidence that changes in unobserved
                                student ability drove the results. Not only did they find no effect on the
                                dropout rate in treatment schools but, compared with preintervention
                                trends, enrollment levels actually improved.
                          30.   The film, poster, and calendar conveyed information on the detailed roles
                                and responsibilities of the three state-specific school oversight committees.
                                The intervention was conducted in three rounds in each gram panchayat
                                (village council), separated by a period of two to three weeks. Each round
                                consisted of two to three meetings in different neighborhoods of the gram
                                panchayat. The campaign also included the distribution of posters and
                                take-home calendars and the convening of neighborhood meetings to
                                ensure participation by members of disadvantaged castes. The tools were
                                the same in all three states (the information communicated was state spe-
                                cific, pertaining to the School Development and Monitoring Committee
                                (SDMC) in Karnataka, the parent-teacher association in Madhya Pradesh,
                                and the village education committee in Uttar Pradesh). In addition to
                                the information campaign treatment in each of the three states, a second
                                treatment was tested only in Karnataka. The only dimension in which
                                the second treatment was different from the first was that the film had an
                                additional one- to two-minute component at the end. To increase aware-
                                ness about the economic benefits of schooling, this component showed
                                average wages in the state for different levels of schooling and encouraged
                                the audience to become involved in monitoring outcomes at the school.
                          31.   The school reform in the state of São Paolo allowed municipalities to
                                take over any primary or secondary school. During the period of the
                                study, municipal governments took over more than half of all state-run
                                schools. The author uses this gradual takeover to identify the impact of
                                school decentralization on intermediate outcomes. As municipal govern-
                                ments could decide which schools to decentralize, the impact of school
                                decentralization cannot be assessed without accounting for this selection
                                effect. The direction of the bias is unclear, as municipalities could choose
                                to decentralize either the best- or the worst-performing schools in order
                                to show the greatest impact from decentralization. The author deals with
                                this problem by using an eight-year school panel. The data include a large
                                number of time-variant characteristics for each school and its community
                                and span the period before and after decentralization, allowing the author
                                to conduct robustness checks, including a check for parallel trends, to deal
                                with the potential bias caused by initial selection.
                          32.   Municipal governments in Brazil are required to provide primary educa-
                                tion; preprimary education is offered on an optional basis, with substantial
                                variation in provision levels. Kosec uses changes in the law that occurred
                                in 1998 (FUNDEF) and 2007 (FUNDEB) and panel data on municipal
                                education policy over a 13-year period (1995–2008).
                          33.   Both Galiani, Gertler, and Schargrodsky (2008) and Rodriguez (2006) rely
                                on variation in the timing of decentralization across provinces to identify
                                the impact of decentralization.


228
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



34. School committees were randomly assigned to receive or not receive a
    grant. All funded school committees then received one of three interven-
    tions: training, democratic election of school committee members, or a
    facilitated collaboration between the school committee and the village
    council (linkage), yielding eight study arms in all. The sample included
    520 schools in 9 districts and 44 subdistricts in the provinces of Java and
    Yogyakarta; 100 schools were left as controls. The data come from three
    surveys: a baseline (administered in 2007), a midterm (administered in
    early 2008), and an endline (administered in late 2008).
35. The study uses a combination of pipeline and matching methods to esti-
    mate the impact of social fund investments.
36. There was considerable deviation from assigned status. To deal with this
    problem, the authors report estimates of impact using assigned treatment
    status (that is, “intent to treat”) as well as actual treatment status, using
    assigned status as an instrument as well as an input into the propensity
    score in a matching approach.
37. A village development committee has a population of about 7,000. Forty-
    two village development committees were matched into 21 pairs on the
    basis of ethnic composition and population density; 12 random pairs were
    selected for the study (1 intervention and 1 control cluster in each pair).
38. The sample comes from 36 rural clusters in 3 districts (12 per district), with
    a total population of 228,000. Eighteen clusters were randomly allocated
    to the treatment group, the other 18 were held as controls. All women
    15–49 who had given birth during the study period (July 2005–July 2008)
    could participate; women could enter anytime if they gave birth. Baseline
    mortality rates were established over a nine-month period.
39. The grants—whose average size ranged from $8,500 in 2007 to $18,200
    in 2009—could be used for a range of health-related activities, including
    hiring extra midwives or teachers for the village, subsidizing the costs of
    prenatal and postnatal care to women, providing supplementary meals to
    children, offering scholarships, improving health or school facilities, and
    rehabilitating roads to improve access to health and education facilities
    during the rainy season. Activities had to be used to support one of the
    12 indicators of health and education service delivery identified by the
    program, which included antenatal and postnatal care, childbirth assisted
    by trained birth attendant, immunization, school enrollment, and school
    attendance, among others.
40. Facilitators from local NGOs led three meetings: a meeting with commu-
    nity members, a meeting with the staff of the relevant health facility, and
    a meeting that brought the community and health facility staff together.
    At the community meeting, facilitators provided community members
    with an assessment of the performance of the relevant primary health
    care facility, both in absolute terms and relative to other local providers
    and the government standard for health service delivery at the dispensary
    level. Communities were then encouraged to identify the key problems
    and the best way to monitor the provider. The health facility staff meeting
    was held at the health facility. At this meeting, the facilitators contrasted


                                                                                            229
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                information on the quality of service provision they had obtained from the
                                baseline survey with the information provided by the facility. At the third
                                meeting, community representatives and health facility staff developed a
                                shared action plan, or a contract, outlining what needed to be done and
                                how and when it would be done, as well as who would be responsible.
                                After the initial meetings, the community was expected to monitor the
                                provider. However, facilitators supported this process through follow-up
                                meetings. These meetings took place during the facilitator’s day-to-day
                                interaction with the community-based organizations in the village.
                          41.   In 2005, federal government transfers to municipalities totaled R$5.7 bil-
                                lion (about $2.6 billion), which represents about $14 per person covered.
                                This figure does not include the municipal contributions, which varied
                                from zero to almost 100 percent.
                          42.   The authors add micro-region fi xed effects as well as a number of other
                                time-variant regional variables to reduce potential selection problems; they
                                do not test for parallel trends before the study period, however, without
                                which the conditional exogeneity of program expansion rates cannot be
                                assumed.
                          43.   The authors do a careful job of dealing with selection issues. To deal
                                with time-invariant differences across municipalities, such as differences
                                in initial mortality rates or health service quality, they add municipal
                                fi xed effects to the difference-in-difference specification. Time-variant
                                differences, such as the occurrence of health shocks, are more problem-
                                atic. The authors include state-specific time dummies to deal with this
                                issue. Because the number of municipalities was large, they could not use
                                municipality-specific time trends. Instead, they add a wide range of munici-
                                pality variables, including immunization coverage, health and education
                                infrastructure, and municipality population. They cluster standard errors
                                at the municipality level.
                          44.   For mortality of children ages 1–4, the coefficients correspond to reduc-
                                tions of 6.4 percent (0.07 in absolute terms) for municipalities three years
                                into the program and 25 percent (0.28 in absolute terms) for municipalities
                                eight years into the program.
                          45.   In the North, a municipality eight years into the program is estimated
                                to experience a reduction of 15.0 infant deaths per 1,000 live births. The
                                reduction in the Northeast is 13.8 per 1,000 live births.
                          46.   Sessions were to be held quarterly, in a local household, with adolescent
                                girls, women of reproductive age, and older women. Lady health workers
                                and traditional birth attendants were expected to facilitate these sessions
                                using materials specifically developed for this purpose, including a docu-
                                drama on pregnancy and newborn care.
                          47.   The 12 districts selected for the study were randomly assigned to three
                                groups: four were eligible to receive “contracting-in” bids, four were eligible
                                to receive “contracting-out” bids, and four served as a comparison group.
                                The authors collected data on individual health care outcomes and care-
                                seeking behavior from a random sample of 30 villages in each of the 12
                                districts involved in the contracting project. About 20,000 people in 3,700


230
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



      households were included in the samples. A baseline survey was conducted
      in 1997; a full follow-up was conducted in 2003. Although the same vil-
      lages were sampled in both survey years, within villages a new random
      sample of households was taken each time. The data are thus a panel at the
      village level and a repeated cross-section at the household level. In treated
      districts, the management of government health care services was put out
      to competitive bid by qualified organizations, such as NGOs and private
      firms. For each district, the organization with the highest combined score
      on the technical quality of the proposal and price was awarded a contract
      to manage the district’s government health care service. In the end, only
      international NGOs, firms, and universities submitted bids. All the win-
      ners were international NGOs. The comparison districts continued to be
      managed by local employees.
48.   In the end, only a few staff members were fired. Salaries in the “contracting
      in” districts were based on the civil service pay structure, plus additional
      amounts decided by the contractors that could be raised from user fees. In
      “contracting-out” districts, NGOs were free to implement the pay structure
      of their choosing.
49.   Not all districts in the initial treatment groups were actually treated. The
      authors report “treatment on treated” effects using assignment to treatment
      as an instrument.
50.   Each hospital continued to receive the same line-item grants from the state
      government to ensure prereform levels of funding. The RKS also raised
      its own money through user fees, the leasing of hospital property, loans,
      and donations. It had full autonomy over the use of hospital assets but no
      authority over government-appointed doctors.
51.   It identified transfer of control as the date at which the RKS became active,
      as reflected in the date at which it started to collect revenue. It aggregated
      RKS activity at the district level and grouped districts into high- and
      low-exposure, within which it measured exposure as the number of years
      in a high-exposure district. The estimation includes district and cohort
      fi xed effects as well as controls for maternal demographics and child
      characteristics.
      The poor are identified as holders of Below Poverty Line (BPL) cards,
      issued by the government for a range of poverty-related benefits.
52.   Participating municipalities receive an annual grant, equivalent to
      =300,000 for each barangay (the smallest administrative unit, often a vil-
      P
      lage). The grant is then allocated competitively among barangays in the
      municipality. The annual per capita allocation is about =300. The project
                                                                 P
      was implemented in the poorest quartile of municipalities. The study uses
      propensity score matching to create comparison municipalities. As the
      program was provided at the municipal level, matching was done at the
      municipal level. The final sample included 16 municipalities, half of which
      received the program and half of which served as controls. Comparison
      municipalities were clearly better off at baseline, but a check for parallel
      trends finds no significant differences between treatment and control
      municipalities once standard errors are corrected for intramunicipality


                                                                                             231
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                correlation. Data were collected at three points in time: baseline (2003),
                                midline (2006), and endline (2010).
                          53.   Since treatment assignment was at the municipal level while analysis was
                                at the household level, a correction needs to be done to account for the
                                intracluster correlation of standard errors at the municipal level. Given
                                the small number of municipalities included in the study, this correction
                                is likely to substantially increase standard errors. Although this correc-
                                tion is made for the parallel trends estimation—wiping out all differences
                                between treatment and control municipalities, as one might expect—no
                                standard error correction is reported for the impact results.
                          54.   The author uses propensity score matching methods to create a matched
                                sample of 300 treatment and control subdistricts. The treated subdistricts
                                were drawn from treated subdistricts in the 2002 SUSENAS survey, which
                                also serves as the baseline, in conjunction with the 2003 PODES village
                                census. Control subdistricts were drawn from non–KDP subdistricts in
                                the same survey that did not benefit from similar government programs. A
                                matched sample of about 6,000 households was also created using available
                                household characteristics. The follow-up data were collected in 2007.
                          55.   The baseline and midline surveys were also conducted at different times,
                                with the follow-up overlapping Ramadan, the Muslim month of fasting,
                                followed by the Eid festival, when consumption is higher, particularly
                                among the poor.
                          56.   Chapter 6 discusses the study’s findings on social cohesion and collective
                                action.
                          57.   A communauté rurale is an administrative unit with 42 villages on average
                                and a population of about 13,000,
                          58.   The study uses data from 36 communautés rurales, half of which were
                                controls. The sample includes 71 villages, 750 households, and 1,000
                                children. Analysis is done at the village, household, and child level, using
                                baseline and follow-up data. Village, household, and child fi xed effects
                                are included, depending on the level of analysis. The authors check for
                                parallel trends across treatment and control communities in the key
                                outcome variables before PNIR and cannot reject the null hypothesis of
                                similar trends. However, this check for parallel trends is run at the level
                                of the communauté rurale, whereas the analysis is conducted at the child,
                                household, and village level.
                          59.   Political influence variables at the village level are used as instruments to
                                deal with potential selection in project awards. A concern with this strategy
                                is that it is not clear whether political influence affects village outcomes
                                only through its effects on accessing PNIR funds. If political influence can
                                also be used to attract other public or private resources to the village, the
                                exclusion conditions necessary for the use of political influence variables
                                as instruments would be violated.
                          60.   The authors do not check for parallel trends in outcome variables before
                                program inception. It is therefore unclear whether the propensity score
                                matching exercise and difference-in-difference technique can take care of
                                selection bias from time-invariant or time-variant sources.


232
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



61. A typical program self-help group consists of 10–15 members who meet
    regularly to discuss social issues and activities, make a small deposit into
    a joint account, and make decisions on loans.
62. In later years, the program also tried to increase the availability of rice to
    low-income households through bulk purchases from the public distribu-
    tion system and resale to poor village households at a discounted price.
    Rice was provided as an in-kind loan for self-help group members. The
    provision of grain as in-kind credit when needed was also expected to
    boost meeting attendance, saving, and repayment.
63. The program covered 148,000 villages officially designated as poor, which
    represent about 21 percent of all villages in rural China. Some 140 million
    people (about 15 percent of China’s rural population) live in these villages.
64. The authors find a substantial increase in overall spending on public
    infrastructure in program villages with completed projects. This increased
    spending occurred because of larger investments by both the government
    and the village community, suggesting that community financing was
    used to leverage government funds, as is the practice in community-driven
    development projects. Interestingly, however, the program had no effect on
    what the authors describe as village corvée labor. It is not clear whether the
    supply of such labor failed to increase because villages were not required to
    contribute labor to the projects or because villagers responded by reducing
    labor on other communal activities. There is also some heterogeneity in
    the financing of infrastructure investments in western versus nonwestern
    regions. The increase in investment was twice as large in nonwestern
    villages, entirely because of larger contributions from the community,
    including village labor. In contrast, communal labor inputs were reduced
    in western villages that began investments under the project.
65. Of the 588 villages in the matched sample, 552 had at least one poor
    household, 484 had at least one nonpoor household, and 448 villages had
    both nonpoor and poor households. The restricted sample included the
    448 villages with both types of households. A comparison of results for
    nonpoor and poor households using the restricted sample is analogous to
    controlling for village fi xed effects, as the authors compare the average
    change in income for the village poor (nonpoor) with the average change
    for the village poor (nonpoor) in the matched village. As villages with
    both nonpoor and poor households are more heterogeneous with respect
    to poverty, a comparison of estimates for the restricted and full samples
    also suggests how program impacts may vary along this dimension.
66. By the end of 2004, 55 percent of poor villages (366 sample villages)
    had completed plans and 37 percent (244 sample villages) had begun
    investments based on the plans. According to the authors, a main reason
    why most villages had yet to begin planned investments three years after
    the program began was that county governments generally concentrated
    annual program allocations in a subset of villages. The decision to fund
    village plans sequentially rather than simultaneously reflected practical
    concerns, such as economies of scale in investments and the fi xed costs
    associated with supervising the design and implementation of plans in


                                                                                            233
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                each village. The village data confirm that the increase in treated villages
                                over time reflected the gradual expansion of investments in new villages
                                within rather than across counties.
                          67.   Some 1,800 of a total of 7,600 villages were selected in the three counties,
                                using specific and objective criteria.
                          68.   As program placement was targeted based on geography and poverty, the
                                authors obtain a counterfactual set of villages by selecting randomly from
                                non–SWP villages in the same counties and then using propensity score
                                matching methods to arrive at a plausible counterfactual.
                          69.   Neither study includes data on the longer-term sustainability of impact
                                from the grant or skills and business training.
                          70.   Targeting of the poorest was ensured through a two-step process. In the
                                first stage, the poorest districts in the three departments were identified
                                using a poverty map. In the second stage, households were screened based
                                on eligibility criteria (in rural areas, households could not own more than
                                two cows or farm more than 10 hectares; in all areas, households could not
                                own an air conditioner, a refrigerator, or a four-wheel vehicle). Participatory
                                targeting was not used to identify beneficiaries, despite the participatory
                                intent of the program.



                          References
                          Adhikari, B., and J. C. Lovett. 2006. “Institutions and Collective Action: Does
                              Heterogeneity Matter in Community-Based Resource Management?”
                              Journal of Development Studies 42(3): 426–45.
                          Agrawal, A. 2010. “Environment, Community, Government.” In In the Name
                              of Humanity, ed. I. Feldman and M. Ticktin, 190–217. Durham, NC:
                              Duke University Press.
                          Agrawal, A., and C. Benson. 2010. “Local Resource Governance Institutions:
                              Outcomes and Explanations.” Background paper for Policy Research
                              Report, World Bank, Washington, DC.
                          Agrawal, A., and A. Chhatre. 2006. “Explaining Success on the Commons:
                              Community Forest Governance in the Indian Himalaya.” World
                              Development 35: 149–66.
                          Agrawal, A., A. Chhatre, and R. Hardin. 2008. “Changing Governance of the
                              World’s Forests.” Science 320: 1460–62.
                          Alatas, V., A. Banerjee, R. Hanna, B. A. Olken, and J. Tobias. 2012. “How
                              to Target the Poor: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia.”
                              American Economic Review 102(4): 1206–40.
                          Alchian, A., and H. Demsetz. 1972. “Production, Information Costs, and
                              Economic Organization.” American Economic Review 62: 777–95.
                          Alderman, H. 2002. “Do Local Officials Know Something We Don’t?
                              Decentralization of Targeted Transfers in Albania.” Journal of Public
                              Economics 83(3): 375–404.


234
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



Alwang, J., E. Gacitua-Mario, and V. Centurion. 2008. “Economic and Social
    Impacts on Participating Households of a Community-Driven Development
    Project in Southern Paraguay.” World Bank, Washington, DC.
Araujo, M. C., F. H. G. Ferreira, P. Lanjouw, and B. Özler. 2008. “Local
    Inequality and Project Choice: Theory and Evidence from Ecuador.”
    Journal of Public Economics 92(5–6): 1022–46.
Arcand, J.-L., and L. Bassole. 2008. “Does Community Driven Development
    Work? Evidence from Senegal.” CERDI–CNRS, Université d’Auvergne,
    France.
Arnold, M. 1998. “Managing Forests as a Common Property.” Working Paper
    136, Food and Agricultural Organization, Rome.
Baird, I. G. 2006. “Strength in Diversity: Fish Sanctuaries and Deep-Water
    Pools in Laos.” Fisheries Management and Ecology 13(1): 1–8.
Baird, S., C. McIntosh, and B. Özler. 2009. The Squeaky Wheels Get the Grease:
    Applications and Targeting in Tanzania’s Social Action Fund. Development
    Economics Research Group, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Baland, J. M., P. Bardhan, S. Das, and D. Mookherjee. 2010. “Forests to
    the People: Decentralization and Forest Degradation in the Indian
    Himalayas.” World Development 38(11): 1642–56.
Baland, J. M., and J. P. Platteau. 1997. “Coordination Problems in Local-Level
    Resource Management.” Journal of Development Economics 53 (1): 197–210.
Banerjee, A. V., R. Banerji, E. Duf lo, R. Glennerster, and S. Khemani.
    2010. “Pitfalls of Participatory Programs: Evidence from Randomized
    Experiments in Education in India.” American Economic Journal:
    Economic Policy 2(1): 1–30.
Baqui, A. H., S. El-Arifeen, G. L. Darmstadt, S. Ahmed, E. K. Williams,
    H. R. Seraji, and I. Mannan. 2008. “Effect of Community-Based
    Newborn-Care Intervention Package Implemented Through Two
    Service-Delivery Strategies in Sylhet District, Bangladesh: A Cluster-
    Randomised Controlled Trial.” Lancet 371: 1936–44.
Bardhan, P. 2000. “Irrigation and Cooperation: An Empirical Analysis of
    48 Irrigation Communities in South India.” Economic Development and
    Cultural Change 48(4): 847–65.
Bardhan, P., M. Ghatak, and A. Karaivanov. 2007. “Wealth Inequality and
    Collective Action.” Journal of Public Economics 91(9): 1843–74.
Bardhan, P, S. Mitra, D. Mookherjee, and A. Sarkar. 2008. “Political
    Participation, Clientelism, and Targeting of Local Government
    Programs.” Discussion Paper, Economic Research Unit/2008-03, Indian
    Statistical Institute, Calcutta.
Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2005. “Decentralization, Corruption, and
    Government Accountability: An Overview.” In International Handbook
    of Economic Corruption, ed. S. Rose-Ackerman. Northhampton, MA:
    Edward Elgar Publishing.
Barrera-Osorio, F., and L. L. Linden. 2009. “The Use and Misuse of
    Computers in Education: Evidence from a Randomized Experiment
    in Colombia.” Policy Research Working Paper 4836, World Bank,
    Washington, DC.


                                                                                          235
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Bates, R. 1989. Toward a Political Economy of Agrarian Development in Kenya.
                               Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
                          Beck, T., and C. Nesmith. 2001. “Building on Poor People’s Capacities: The
                               Case of Common Property Resources in India and West Africa.” World
                               Development 29(1): 119–33.
                          Besley, T., and R. Kanbur. 1993. “The Principles of Targeting.” In Including
                               the Poor, ed. M. Lipton and J. Van der Gaag, 67–90. Washington, DC:
                               World Bank.
                          Besley, T., R. Pande, and V. Rao. 2005. “Participatory Democracy in Action:
                               Survey Evidence from Rural India.” Journal of the European Economic
                               Association 3(2–3): 648–57.
                          ———. 2007. “Just Rewards? Local Politics and Public Resource Allocation
                               in South India.” Development Economics Paper, London School of
                               Economics and the Suntory and Toyota International Centres for
                               Economics and Related Disciplines, London.
                          Bhutta, Z. Q. A., S. Soofi, S. Cousens, S. Mohammad, Z. A. Memon, I. Ali,
                               and A. Feroze. 2011. “Improvement of Perinatal and Newborn Care
                               in Rural Pakistan Through Community-Based Strategies: A Cluster-
                               Randomised Effectiveness Trial.” Lancet 377: 403–12.
                          Binka, F. N., A. A. Bawah, J. F. Phillips, A. Hodgson, M. Adjuik, and
                               B. Macleod. 2007. “Rapid Achievement of the Child Survival Millennium
                               Development Goal: Evidence from the Navrongo Experiment in Northern
                               Ghana.” Tropical Medicine and International Health 12: 578–83.
                          Bjorkman, M., and J. Svensson. 2007. “Power to the People: Evidence from
                               a Randomized Field Experiment of a Community-Based Monitoring
                               Project in Uganda.” Policy Research Working Paper 4268, World Bank,
                               Washington, DC.
                          Blaikie, P. 2006. “Is Small Really Beautiful? Community-Based Natural
                               Resource Management in Malawi and Botswana.” World Development
                               34(11): 1942–57.
                          Blattman, C., N. Fiala, and S. Martinez. 2011. “Can Employment Programs
                               Reduce Poverty and Social Instability? Experimental Evidence from
                               a Ugandan Aid Program (Mid-Term Results).” Yale University, New
                               Haven, CT.
                          Bruns, B., D. Filmer, and H. A. Patrinos. 2011. Making Schools Work New
                               Evidence on Accountability Reforms. Washington, DC: World Bank.
                          Caldwell, B. J. 2005. School-Based Management. Education Policy Series. Paris:
                               International Institute for Educational Planning (IIEP) and International
                               Academy of Education (IAE).
                          Campbell, T. 2003. Quiet Revolution: Decentralization and the Rise of Political
                               Participation in Latin American Cities. Pittsburg, PA: University of
                               Pittsburg Press.
                          Casey, K., R. Glennerster, and E. Miguel. 2011. “Reshaping Institutions:
                               Evidence on External Aid and Local Collective Action.” NBER Working
                               Paper 17012, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
                          Cavendish, W. 2000. “Empirical Regularities in the Poverty-Environment
                               Relationship of Rural Households: Evidence from Zimbabwe.” World
                               Development 28(11): 1979–2003.

236
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



Chase, R. S. 2002. “Supporting Communities in Transition: The Impact of
    the Armenian Social Investment Fund.” World Bank Economic Review
    16(2): 219–40.
Chase, R. S., and L. Sherburne-Benz. 2001. “Household Effects of Community
    Education and Health Initiatives: Evaluating the Impact of the Zambia
    Social Fund.” World Bank, Social Development Unit, Washington, DC.
Chaudhury, N., and D. Parajuli. 2010. “Giving It Back: Evaluating the Impact
    of Devolution of School Management to Communities in Nepal.” World
    Bank, Washington, DC.
Chavis, L. 2009. “Decentralizing Development: Allocating Public Goods
    via Competition.” Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North
    Carolina, Chapel Hill.
Chen, S., R. Mu, and M. Ravallion. 2009. “Are There Lasting Impacts of Aid
    to Poor Areas?” Journal of Public Economics 93(3–4): 512–28.
Cheung, S. 1970. “The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of Non-
    Exclusive Resources.” Journal of Law and Economics 13(1): 49–70.
Coady, D. 2001. “An Evaluation of the Distributional Power of Progresa’s Cash
    Transfers in Mexico.” FCND Discussion Paper, International Food Policy
    Research Institute, Washington, DC.
Coase, R. H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and
    Economics 3(1): 1–44.
Commons, J. R. 1970. The Economics of Collective Action. Madison, WI:
    University of Wisconsin Press.
Dasgupta, P. 2009. “Trust and Cooperation among Economic Agents.”
    Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society 364: 3301–09.
Dasgupta, P. and K. G. Mäler. 1995. “Poverty, Institutions, and the
    Environmental Resource-Base.” In Handbook of Development Economics,
    vol. III(A), ed. J. Behrman and T. N. Srinivasan, 2371–63. Amsterdam:
    North-Holland.
Dayton-Johnson, J. 2000. “Choosing Rules to Govern the Commons: A
    Model with Evidence from Mexico.” Journal of Economic Behavior &
    Organization 42(1): 19–41.
Dayton-Johnson, J., and P. Bardhan. 2002. “Inequality and Conservation on
    the Local Commons: A Theoretical Exercise.” Economic Journal 112(481):
    577–602.
Deininger, K., and Y. Liu. 2009. “Longer-Term Economic Impacts of Self-
    Help Groups in India.” Policy Research Working Paper 4886, World
    Bank, Washington, DC.
De Janvry, A., H. Nakagawa, and E. Sadoulet. 2009. “Pro-Poor Targeting and
    Electoral Rewards in Decentralizing to Communities the Provision of
    Local Public Goods in Rural Zambia.” University of California, Berkeley.
Di Gropello, E. 2006. “A Comparative Analysis of School-Based Management
    in Central America.” Working Paper 72, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Duflo, E., P. Dupas, and M. Kremer. 2008. “Peer Effects, Pupil-Teacher
    Ratios, and Teacher Incentives: Evidence from a Randomized Evaluation
    in Kenya.” Online Working Paper CCPR 055-08, California Center for
    Population Research, University of California, Los Angeles.

                                                                                         237
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Edmonds, E. V. 2002. “Government-Initiated Community Resource
                               Management and Local Resource Extraction from Nepal’s Forests.”
                               Journal of Development Economics 68(1): 89–115.
                          Eggertsson, T. 1990. Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge, U.K.:
                               Cambridge University Press.
                          Ensminger, J. 1992. Making a Market: The Institutional Transformation of an
                               African Society. New York: Cambridge University Press.
                          Eskeland, G. S., and D. Filmer. 2002. “Autonomy, Participation, and
                               Learning in Argentine Schools: Findings and Their Implications for
                               Decentralization.” Policy Research Working Paper 276, World Bank,
                               Washington, DC.
                          Fearon, J. D., M. Humphreys, and J. M. Weinstein. 2009. “Can Development
                               Aid Contribute to Social Cohesion after Civil War? Evidence from a Field
                               Experiment in Post-Conflict Liberia.” American Economic Review 99(2):
                               287–91.
                          Ferguson, J. 1996. The Anti-Politics Machine. Development, Depolitization, and
                               Bureaucratic Power in Lesotho. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University
                               Press.
                          Fisher, M. 2004. “Household Welfare and Forest Dependence in Southern
                               Malawi.” Environment and Development Economics 9(2): 135–54.
                          Fujiie, M., Y. Hayami, and M. Kikuchi. 2005. “The Conditions of Collective
                               Action for Local Commons Management: The Case of Irrigation in the
                               Philippines.” Agricultural Economics 33(2): 179–89.
                          Galasso, E., and M. Ravallion. 2005. “Decentralized Targeting of an
                               Antipoverty Program.” Journal of Public Economics 89(4): 705–27.
                          Galiani, S., P. Gertler, and E. Schargrodsky. 2008. “School Decentralization:
                               Helping the Good Get Better, but Leaving the Poor Behind.” Journal of
                               Public Economics 92: 2106–20.
                          Gertler, P., H. Patrinos, and M. Rubio-Codina. 2007. “Empowering Parents
                               to Improve Education: Evidence from Rural Mexico.” Policy Research
                               Working Paper 3935, World Bank, Washington, DC.
                          Gine, X., and G. Mansuri. 2012. “Money or Ideas? A Field Experiment
                               on Constraints to Entrepreneurship in Rural Pakistan.” World Bank,
                               Washington, DC.
                          Gregerson, H. M., and A. H. Contreras. 1989. Economic Analysis of Forestry
                               Projects. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization.
                          Gugerty, M. K., and M. Kremer. 2006. Outside Funding and the Dynamics
                               of Participation in Community Associations. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
                               University Press.
                          Gunnarsson, V., P. F. Orazem, M. A. Sanchez, and A. Verdisco. 2009. “Does
                               Local School Control Raise Student Outcomes? Evidence on the Roles
                               of School Autonomy and Parental Participation.” Economic Development
                               and Cultural Change 58: 25–52.
                          Harragin, S. 2004. “Relief and an Understanding of Local Knowledge: The
                               Case of Southern Sudan.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and
                               M. Walton, 307–27. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.


238
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



Hobley, M. 1996. “Institutional Change within the Forestry Sector:
     Centralized Decentralization.” Working Paper 92, Overseas Development
     Institute, London.
Hodgkin, J., and M. Kusumahadi. 1993. “A Study of the Sustainability
     of Care-Assisted Water Supply and Sanitation Projects, 1979–1991.”
     Associates in Rural Development, Burlington, VT.
Isham, J., and S. Kahkonen. 2002. “Institutional Determinants of the Impact
     of Community-Based Water Services: Evidence from Sri Lanka and
     India.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 50(3): 667–91.
Jalan, J., and M. Ravallion. 2003. “Estimating the Benefit Incidence of an
     Antipoverty Program by Propensity-Score Matching.” Journal of Business
     and Economic Statistics 21(1): 19–30.
Jimenez, E., and Y. Sawada. 1999. “Do Community-Managed Schools Work?
     An Evaluation of El Salvador’s Educo Program.” World Bank Economic
     Review 13(3): 415–41.
———. 2003. “Does Community Management Help Kids in Schools?
     Evidence Using Panel Data from El Salvador’s Educo Program.” Faculty
     of Economics, University of Tokyo.
Jodha, N. S. 1986. “Common Property Resources and Rural Poor in Dry
     Regions of India.” Economic and Political Weekly 21(27): 1169–81.
———. 2001. Common Property Resources in Crisis. New Delhi: Oxford
     University Press.
Jokhio, A. H., H. R. Winter, and K. K. Cheng. 2005. “An Intervention
     Involving Traditional Birth Attendants and Perinatal and Maternal
     Mortality in Pakistan.” New England Journal of Medicine 325: 2091–99.
Katz, T., and J. Sara. 1997. “Making Rural Water Supply Sustainable:
     Recommendations from a Global Study.” World Bank, Washington, DC.
Khattri, N., C. Ling, and S. Jha. 2010. “The Effects of School-Based
     Management in the Philippines: A n Initia l A ssessment Using
     Administrative Data.” Policy Research Working Paper 5248, World
     Bank, Washington, DC.
Khwaja, A. I. 2004. “Is Increasing Community Participation Always a Good
     Thing?” Journal of the European Economic Association 2(2–3): 427–36.
———. 2009. “Can Good Projects Succeed in Bad Communities?” Journal of
     Public Economics 93(7–8): 899–916.
King, E. M., and B. Özler. 1998. “What’s Decentralization Got to Do with
     Learning? The Case of Nicaragua’s School Autonomy Reform.” World
     Bank, Development Economics Research Group, Washington, DC.
King, E. M., B. Özler, and L. B. Rawlings. 1999. “Nicaragua’s School
     Autonomy Reform: Fact or Fiction?” Working Paper 19, Impact
     Evaluation of Education Reforms Series, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Kleemeier, E. 2000. “The Impact of Participation on Sustainability:
     An Analysis of the Malawi Rural Piped Scheme Program.” World
     Development 28(5): 929–44.
Kosec, K. 2011. “Politics and Preschool: The Political Economy of Investment
     in Pre-Primary Education.” Policy Research Working Paper Series 5647,
     World Bank, Washington, DC.


                                                                                         239
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Kremer, M., E. Bloom, E. King, I. Bhushan, D. Clingingsmith, B. Loevinsohn,
                              R. Hong, and J. B. Schwartz. 2006. Contracting for Health: Evidence from
                              Cambodia. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
                          Kumar, N. R. 2007. “Pro-Poor Targeting and Participatory Governance:
                              Evidence from Central India.” Working Paper dp-176, Institute for
                              Economic Development, Department of Economics, Boston University,
                              Boston, MA.
                          Kumar, S. 2002. “Does ‘Participation’ in Common Pool Resource Management
                              Help the Poor? A Social Cost-Benefit Analysis of Joint Forest Management
                              in Jharkhand, India.” World Development 30: 763–82.
                          Labonne, J. 2011. “The KALAHI–CIDSS Impact Evaluation: A Synthesis
                              Report.” World Bank, Washington, DC.
                          Larson, A., and J. C. Ribot. 2007. “The Poverty of Forestry Policy: Double
                              Standards on and Uneven Playing Field.” Journal of Sustainability Science
                              2(2): 189–204.
                          Leino, J. 2007. “Ladies First? Gender and the Community Management
                              of Water Infrastructure in Kenya.” Graduate Student and Research
                              Fellow Working Paper 30, Harvard University, Center for International
                              Development, Cambridge, MA.
                          Libecap, G. 1989. Contracting for Property Rights. New York: Cambridge
                              University Press.
                          Linnemayr, S., and H. Alderman. 2011. “Almost Random: Evaluating a Large-
                              Scale Randomized Nutrition Program in the Presence of Crossover.”
                              Journal of Development Economics 96: 106–14.
                          Lund, J. F. 2007. “Is Small Beautiful? Village Level Taxation of Natural
                              Resources in Tanzania.” Public Administration and Development 27(4):
                              307–18.
                          Lund, J. F., and T. Treue. 2008. “Are We Getting There? Evidence of
                              Decentralized Forest Management from the Tanzanian Miombo
                              Woodlands.” World Development 36(12): 2780–800.
                          Macinko, J., M. F. M. De Souza, F. C. Guanais, and C. C. D. S. Simoes. 2007.
                              “Going to Scale with Community-Based Primary Care: An Analysis of
                              the Family Health Program and Infant Mortality in Brazil, 1999–2004.”
                              Social Science & Medicine 65: 2070–80.
                          Macinko, J., F. C. Guanais, and M. D. M. De Souza. 2006. “Evaluation of
                              the Impact of the Family Health Program on Infant Mortality in Brazil,
                              1990–2002.” Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 60: 13–19.
                          Madeira, R. 2007. “The Effects of Decentralization on Schooling: Evidence
                              from the São Paulo State Education Reform.” Department of Economics,
                              Boston University, Boston, MA.
                          Manandhar, D. S., D. Osrin, B. P. Shrestha, N. Mesko, J. Morrison,
                              K. M. Tumbahangphe, and S. Tamang. 2004. “Effect of a Participatory
                              Intervention with Women’s Groups on Birth Outcomes in Nepal: Cluster-
                              Randomised Controlled Trial.” Lancet 364: 970–79.
                          Mansuri, G. 2012a. “Bottom up or Top Down: Participation and the Provision
                              of Local Public Goods.” World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Equity
                              Unit, Washington, DC.


240
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



———. 2012b. “Harnessing Community: A ssortative Matching in
    Participatory Community Organizations.” World Bank, Poverty
    Reduction and Equity Unit, Washington DC.
Marcus, R. 2002. “Social Funds as Instruments for Reducing Childhood
    Poverty: Lessons from Save the Children’s Experience.” Journal of
    International Development 14(8): 653–66.
McSweeney, K. 2005. “Natural Insurance, Forest Access, and Compounded
    Misfortune: Forest Resources in Smallholder Coping Strategies before
    and after Hurricane Mitch, Northeastern Honduras.” World Development
    33(9): 1453–71.
Meshack, C. K., B. Ahdikari, N. Doggart, and J. C. Lovett. 2006. “Transaction
    Costs of Community-Based Forest Management: Empirical Evidence
    from Tanzania.” African Journal of Ecology 44(4): 468–77.
Morrow, C. E., and R. W. Hull. 1996. “Donor-Initiated Common Pool
    Resource Institutions: The Case of the Yanesha Forestry Cooperative.”
    World Development 24(10): 1641–57.
Mosse, D. 2001. “People’s Knowledge, Participation, and Patronage:
    Operations and Representations in Rural Development.” In Participation:
    The New Tyranny, ed. B. Cooke and U. Kothari. London: Zed Books.
———. 2005. Cultivating Development: An Ethnography of Aid Policy and
    Practice. London: Pluto Press.
Muhereza, F. 2006. “Decentralizing Natural Resource Management and the
    Politics of Institutional Resource Management in Uganda’s Forest Sub-
    Sector.” Africa Development 31: 67–101.
Murnane, R. J., J. B. Willet, and S. Cardenas. 2006. “Did the Participation
    of Schools in Programa Escuelas De Calidad (PEC) Influence Student
    Outcomes?” Working Paper, Harvard University Graduate School of
    Education, Cambridge, MA.
Mustafa, D. 2007. “Social Construction of Hydro-Politics: The Geographical
    Scales of Water and Security in the Indus Basin.” Geographical Review
    97(4): 484–501.
Mustalahti, I., and J. F. Lund. 2010. “Where and How Can Participatory
    Forest Management Succeed? Learning from Tanzania, Mozambique,
    and Laos.” Society & Natural Resources 23(1): 31–44.
Narain, U., S. Gupta, and K. Van’t Veld. 2005. “Poverty and Environment:
    Exploring the Relationship Between Household Incomes, Private Assets,
    and Natural Assets.” Discussion Paper 05-18, Resources for the Future,
    Washington, DC.
———. 2008. “Poverty and Resource Dependence in Rural India.” Ecological
    Economics 66(1): 161–76.
Nerlove, M. 1991. “Population and the Environment: A Parable of Firewood
    and Other Tales.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73(4):
    1334–47.
Newman, J., M. Pradhan, L. B. Rawlings, G. Ridder, R. C. And, and J. L.
    Evia. 2002. “An Impact Evaluation of Education, Health, and Water
    Supply Investments by the Bolivian Social Investment Fund.” World Bank
    Economic Review 16(2): 241–74.


                                                                                         241
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Nkonya, E., D. Phillip, T. Mogues, J. Pender, M. K. Yahaya, G. Adebowale,
                              T. Arokoyo, and E. Kato. 2008. “From the Ground Up Impacts of a Pro-
                              Poor Community-Driven Development Project in Nigeria.” Discussion
                              Paper 00756, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington,
                              DC.
                          North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance.
                              Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
                          Nyonator, F. K., J. K. Awoonor-Williams, J. F. Phillips, T. C. Jones, and
                              R. A. Miller. 2005. “The Ghana Community-Based Health Planning and
                              Services Initiative for Scaling Up Service Delivery Innovation.” Health
                              Policy and Planning 20(1): 25–34.
                          Olken, B. 2007. “Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment
                              in Indonesia.” Journal of Political Economy 115(2): 200–49.
                          Olken, B. A., J. Onishi, and S. Wong. 2011. “Indonesia’s PNPM Generasi
                              Program: Final Impact Evaluation Report.” World Bank, Social
                              Development Department, Washington, DC.
                          Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of
                              Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
                          Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for
                              Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.
                          Ostrom, E., W. F. Lam, and M. Lee. 1994. “The Performance of Self-
                              Governing Irrigation Systems in Nepal.” Human Systems Management
                              13(3): 197–207.
                          Oyono, P. R., and S. Efoua. 2006. “Qui représente qui? Choix organisation-
                              nels, identités sociales et formation d’une élite forestière au Cameron.”
                              Africa Development 31(2): 147–82.
                          Oyono, P., and F. Nzuzi. 2006. “Au sortir d’une longue ‘nuit’ institutionnelle,
                              nouvelles transactions entre les politiques forestières et les sociétés rurales
                              en RD Congo post-conflit.” Afrique et Développement 31(2): 183–214.
                          Pandey, P., S. Goyal, and V. Sundararaman. 2011. “Does Information Improve
                              School Accountability? Results of a Large Randomized Trial.” Discussion
                              Paper 49, World Bank, Washington, DC.
                          Pandey, S. K., and E. C. Stazyk. 2008. “Antecedents and Correlates of Public
                              Service Motivation.” In Motivation in Public Management: The Call of
                              Public Service, ed. J. L. Perry and A. Hondeghem, 101–17. Oxford, U.K.:
                              Oxford University Press.
                          Pandey, S., B. Wright, and D. Moynihan. 2008. “Public Service Motivation
                              and Interpersonal Citizenship Behavior in Public Organizations: Testing
                              a Preliminary Model.” International Public Management Journal 11(1):
                              89–108.
                          Park, A., and S. Wang. 2009. “Community-Based Development and Poverty
                              Alleviation: An Evaluation of China’s Poor Village Investment Program.”
                              Draft background paper for the 2006 China Poverty Assessment, World
                              Bank, Washington, DC.
                          Pattanayak, S. K., and E. O. Sills. 2001. “Do Tropical Forests Provide
                              Natural Insurance? The Microeconomics of Non-Timber Forest Product
                              Collection in the Brazilian Amazon.” Land Economics 77(4): 595–
                              613.

242
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



Paxson, C., and N. R. Schady. 2002. “The Allocation and Impact of Social
    Funds: Spending on School Infrastructure in Peru.” World Bank Economic
    Review 16(2): 297–319.
Pokharel, R. P. 2009. “Pro-Poor Programs Financed through Nepal’s
    Community Forestry Funds: Does Income Matter?” Mountain Research
    and Development 29: 67–74.
Pradhan, D. S. M., A. Beatty, M. Wong, A. Alishjabana, A. Gaduh, and
    R. P. Artha. 2011. “Improving Educational Quality through Enhancing
    Community Participation: Results from a Randomized Field Experiment
    in Indonesia.” Faculty of Economics and Business Administration,
    University of Amsterdam.
Pradhan, M., and L. B. Rawlings. 2002. “The Impact and Targeting of Social
    Infrastructure Investments: Lessons from the Nicaraguan Social Fund.”
    World Bank Economic Review 16(2): 275–95.
Ravallion, M. 2000. “Monitoring Targeting Performance When Decentralized
    Allocations to the Poor Are Unobserved.” World Bank Economic Review
    14(2): 331–45.
———. 2009a. “Decentralizing Eligibility for a Federal Antipoverty Program:
    A Case Study for China.” World Bank Economic Review 23(1): 1–30.
———. 2009b. “How Relevant Is Targeting to the Success of an Antipoverty
    Program?” World Bank Research Observer 24(1): 205–31.
Ribot, J. C. 1995. “From Exclusion to Participation: Turning Senegal’s
    Forestry Policy Around?” World Development 23(9): 1587–99.
———. 2004. Waiting for Democracy: The Politics of Choice in Natural Resource
    Decentralizations. Washington, DC: World Resources Institute.
———. 2007. “Institutional Choice and Recognition in the Consolidation of
    Local Democracy.” Democracy 50: 43–49.
Ribot, J. C., A. Chhatre, and T. Lankina. 2008. “Institutional Choice and
    Recognition in the Formation and Consolidation of Local Democracy.”
    Conservation and Society 6(1): 1–11.
Ribot, J. C., J. Lund, and T. Treue. 2010. “Forestry and Democratic
    Decentralization in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Review.” Background paper
    prepared for Policy Research Report, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Riley, J. C. 2005. Poverty and Life Expectancy: The Jamaica Paradox.
    Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.
Rocha, R., and R. R. Soares. 2009. “Evaluating the Impact of Community-
    Based Health Interventions: Evidence from Brazil’s Family Health
    Program.” Global Development Network, New Delhi.
Rodriguez, C. 2006. “Households’ Schooling Behavior and Political Economy
    Trade-Offs After Decentralization.” Working Paper, Universidad de los
    Andes, Colombia.
Ronconi, L. 2009. “Estimates of the Benefit Incidence of Workfare.” Journal
    of LACEA Economia (Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association)
    8587.
Sawada, Y. 1999. “Community Participation, Teacher Effort, and Educational
    Outcome: The Case of El Salvador’s Educo Program.” Working Paper
    307, William Davidson Institute, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor,
    MI.

                                                                                         243
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Sawada, Y., and A. Ragatz. 2005. “Decentralization of Education, Teacher
                              Behavior, and Outcomes.” In Incentives to Improve Teaching, ed. E. Vegas.
                              Washington, DC: World Bank.
                          Skoufias, E., and J. Shapiro. 2006. “The Pitfalls of Evaluating a School Grants
                              Program Using Non-Experimental Data.” Policy Research Working Paper
                              4036, World Bank, Washington, DC.
                          Somanathan, E., R. Prabhakar, and B. Singh. 2005. “Does Decentralization
                              Work? Forest Conservation in the Himalayas.” Indian Statistical
                              Institute, New Delhi.
                          Stern, P. C., T. Dietz, and E. Ostrom. 2003. “The Struggle to Govern the
                              Commons.” Science 302: 1907–12.
                          Sunderlin, W. D., J. Hatcher, and M. Liddle. 2008. “From Exclusion to
                              Ownership? Challenges and Opportunities in Advancing Forest Tenure
                              Reform.” Rights and Resources Initiatives, Washington DC.
                          Topp-Jorgensen, E., M. K. Poulsen, J. F. Lund, and J. F. Massao. 2005.
                              “Community-Based Monitoring of Natural Resource Use and Forest
                              Quality in Montane Forests and Miombo Woodlands of Tanzania.”
                              Biodiversity and Conservation 14(11): 2653–77.
                          Tripathy, P., N. Nair, S. Barnett, R. Mahapatra, J. Borghi, S. Rath, and
                              S. Rath. 2010. “Effect of a Participatory Intervention with Women’s
                              Groups on Birth Outcomes and Maternal Depression in Jharkhand and
                              Orissa, India: A Cluster-Randomised Controlled Trial.” Lancet 375:
                              1182–92.
                          Turyahabwe, N., C. J. Geldenhuys, S.Watts, and J.Obua. 2007. “Local
                              Organizations and Decentralised Forest Management in Uganda: Roles,
                              Challenges, and Policy Implications. International Forestry Review.
                              9(2):581–96.
                          United Nations. 2000. “Millennium Declaration.” United Nations, New York.
                          Uphoff, N. 1986. Local Institutional Development: An Analytical Sourcebook
                              with Cases. Sterling, VA: Kumarian Press.
                          Uzochukwu, B. S. C., C. O. Akpala, and O. E. Onwujekwe. 2004. “How
                              Do Health Workers and Community Members Perceive and Practice
                              Community Participation in the Bamako Initiative Programme in
                              Nigeria? A Case Study of Oji River Local Government Area.” Social
                              Science and Medicine 59: 157–62.
                          Voss, J. 2008. “Impact Evaluation of the Second Phase of the Kecamatan
                              Development Program in Indonesia.” World Bank, Jakarta.
                          Wade, R. 1985. “The Market for Public Office: Why the Indian State Is
                              Not Better at Development.” In The Economics of Corruption and Illegal
                              Markets, ed. G. Fiorentini and S. Zamagni. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward
                              Elgar Publishing.
                          Wardell, D. A., and C. Lund. 2006. “Governing Access to Forests in Northern
                              Ghana: Micro-Politics and the Rents of Non-Enforcement.” World
                              Development 34(11): 1887–906.




244
DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES?



Wilder, M., and P. R. Lankao. 2006. “Paradoxes of Decentralization: Water
    Reform and Social Implications in Mexico.” World Development 34:
    1977–95.
Wood, G. 1999. “Private Provision after Public Neglect: Bending Irrigation
    Markets in North Bihar.” Development and Change 30(4): 775–94.
World Bank. 2002. “Social Funds: Assessing Effectiveness.” Operations
    Evaluations Department, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Yoong, J. 2007. “Does Decentralization Hurt Childhood Immunization?”
    Department of Economics, Stanford University, Stanford, CA.




                                                                                        245
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
CHAPTER SIX




Does Participation
Strengthen Civil Society?

PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT PROJECTS OFTEN INCLUDE BUILD-
ing “social capital” and hearing the “voices of the poor” as key objec-
tives. This chapter reviews the literature on how effective participatory
development projects have been in achieving these goals. It presents
evidence on several important questions. How do deliberative processes
actually work in developing countries? Is deliberation equitable? Is it
sustainable? Under what conditions does it build the capacity to engage?
Can local inequalities in power and social structure be remedied by
mandating the inclusion of women and discriminated minorities in
leadership positions? Does participation build “social capital”? Can
inducing participation improve a community’s capacity to address dis-
putes and improve cohesion in postconflict settings? Is there evidence
that induced participation enhances social cohesion and the “voice” of
marginalized groups in local decision-making bodies?



Participatory Decision Making and Social Cohesion in
Induced Development Projects
Participatory development projects expend considerable resources and
effort building community-level organizations with the expectation that
doing so not only allows disadvantaged groups to participate directly
in decision-making processes but that it can also encourage dialogue
between groups otherwise separated by wealth, gender, or social status,
thereby creating the basis for greater social cohesion. If this is the case,
induced participation may help build social cohesion and strengthen
democratic values and practices even in communities where there are

                                                                               247
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  important social cleavages caused by inequality, ethnic heterogeneity,
                                  or conflict.
  The hypothesis that induced        The hypothesis that induced participation may help build social
  participation may help build    cohesion turns out to be a particularly difficult one to evaluate. The
  social cohesion turns out to    measurement of social outcomes is itself challenging, because projects
 be a particularly difficult one   usually provide resources for local public goods, private transfers, micro-
                   to evaluate.   credit, and skills training, in addition to community mobilization. The
                                  provision of resources makes it difficult to isolate the impact of partici-
                                  pation on social outcomes. Exposure to participatory messaging may
                                  also make members of program communities more likely to indicate
                                  more willingness to cooperate or to report higher levels of trust and
                                  support for democracy regardless of any substantive change in attitudes
                                  or practices. Local facilitators spend considerable time with community
                                  members elucidating the benefits of program participation, community
                                  collective action, self-help groups, contributions to development proj-
                                  ects, and so forth. Isolating the impact of participation on preferences,
                                  trust, networks, or cooperation is therefore likely to be difficult even
                                  in the best-designed evaluation. Self-reported retrospective accounts of
                                  change are perhaps the least reliable source of information.
                                     To make matters worse, very few evaluations of community-driven
                                  development or social fund projects have been able to deal effectively
                                  with the problem of identifying comparison communities for assessing
                                  project impact. In the majority of cases, comparison groups are created
                                  by identifying communities that did not get the program but look oth-
                                  erwise similar to program communities. Because matching communi-
                                  ties on the relevant social variables (trust, cooperation, density of social
                                  networks, political participation, and so forth) is rarely an option, most
                                  studies match on the usual set of sociodemographic variables available
                                  in national income statistics and expenditure surveys. Matching in this
                                  way is particularly problematic if, as is often the case, participatory
                                  programs rely on community “willingness” or “readiness” to participate
                                  rather than on clear eligibility criteria. Although matching in this way
                                  may be sensible from a programmatic perspective, it makes causal infer-
                                  ence challenging, because outcomes of interest (such as greater political
                                  awareness) may be precisely why a community was selected in the first
                                  place, rather than an outcome of the program.
                                     These challenges affect both the quantity and quality of the literature
                                  on participation and social cohesion. Three recent studies, all of which
                                  focus on community-driven reconstruction projects, are exceptions.

248
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



The first evaluates a community reconstruction project implemented              A project in Liberia shows
by the International Rescue Committee in northern Liberia (Fearon,             an increase in trust and
Humphreys, and Weinstein 2009).1 Survey results indicate a reduction           participation by marginalized
in social tension and an increase in trust in local leadership, as well        groups and a reduction in
as an increase in participation by marginalized groups in community            social tension. But there is
decision-making activities. The authors use a behavioral public goods          no evidence of an increase
game to augment and validate these survey-based findings on the                in broader collective action
impact of participation on social cohesion and cooperation.2 They find          capacity.
that a larger percentage of households in the program communities
(71 percent versus 62 percent in the comparison communities) contrib-
uted the maximum amount. However, the difference was driven mainly
by contributions from internally displaced persons who had returned
to their villages after the war and benefited from this project as well as
other programs directed at resettling them. Moreover, the evidence does
not support any increase in broader collective action or in democratic
values or practices in program villages. There was also no change in the
attitudes of traditional leaders toward community decision making.
   The second study is an ongoing evaluation of a community-driven             An ongoing evaluation
reconstruction program in Afghanistan. It also finds some positive,             of a community-driven
albeit preliminary, evidence on the impact of a national community-            reconstruction project in
driven reconstruction project (the National Support Program) on                Afghanistan finds preliminary
political attitudes and social cohesion (Beath, Christia, and Enikolopev       positive evidence on political
2011).3 The results from an initial follow-up suggest significant shifts in     attitudes and social cohesion.
political attitudes (regarding trust in government and local leaders, in
women’s role in the community, and in women as leaders, for example)
and in social cohesion. A caveat is that self-reports of political attitudes
such as trust in government or greater community cooperation can
be difficult to interpret in the absence of corroborating evidence on
outcomes. There is little evidence that village elites in program villages
were less likely to exercise influence in village development councils
or that there was any change in the types of households that benefited
from government programs. As discussed in earlier chapters, communi-
ties that have community-driven development projects routinely report
greater social cohesion and levels of satisfaction, and self-reports are
generally more positive when questions are posed in language that more
closely evokes the language used by facilitators.4
   The third study, by Casey, Glennerster, and Miguel (2011), finds
less positive results. The GoBifo (Move Forward) project in Sierra
Leone, funded primarily by the World Bank, provided block grants

                                                                                                         249
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



    A study from Sierra Leone     worth about $5,000 per community (roughly $100 per household) for
      finds no evidence that a     local public goods, skills training, and microentrepreneurship. The
   community-driven program       project staff also provided training in democratic decision making and
     had any impact on social     encouraged the participation of socially marginalized groups (mainly
 cohesion or collective action.   women and youth) in local decision-making bodies.5 Like the first two
                                  studies, this study randomly assigned eligible communities to program
                                  and comparison status and combined survey methods with what they
                                  refer to as “structured community activities.” These activities assessed
                                  how communities responded to a matching grant opportunity to invest
                                  in a small public good (building materials), made communal decisions
                                  between two alternatives, and allocated a small endowment among
                                  community members. Despite the careful design and the long evalua-
                                  tion period (four years between baseline in 2005 and endline in 2009),
                                  the study finds no evidence that the program had an impact on any
                                  measure of social cohesion or collective action used (local fundraising
                                  capacity, decision-making processes, and so forth). There was also no
                                  evidence of a shift in social attitudes or norms with respect to women’s
                                  participation in public activities.
                                     Another approach to measuring social cohesion is to assess the extent
                                  to which community-level organizations bring together diverse groups
                                  of people who may otherwise not have an opportunity to interact with
                                  one another, thereby creating a new deliberative space. A growing body
                                  of literature on participatory councils is starting to generate interesting
                                  evidence on this issue in the context of local decentralization, but only
                                  three studies look at the extent to which community organizations are
                                  cohesive in their membership patterns. Doing so is important, because
                                  community-driven projects often work through self-help groups, which
                                  are endogenously formed. A community or village may therefore have
                                  several such groups, which may or may not be brought together into
                                  higher-level organizations.
                                     Arcand and Fafchamps (2012) look at community organizations in
                                  Burkina Faso and Senegal. They find that community organizations
                                  tend to sort sharply by wealth and status. Survey research in São Paulo
                                  and Mexico City also finds that citizens who participate in associations
                                  are likely to be highly stratified by education, gender, labor market
                                  status, and other factors (Houtzager, Acharya, and Lavalle 2007).
                                  Mansuri (2012) finds that community organizations supported by the
                                  National Rural Support Program in Pakistan were highly segregated
                                  along wealth, ethnicity, education, and political power within villages,

250
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



in addition to almost complete sorting by gender. However, she finds
that some communities do much better than others. Sorting on status
(education, land, and caste) is significantly dampened in villages with
above-average levels of schooling but similar levels of land inequality
and caste composition. In contrast, sorting by land intensifies in vil-
lages that are more unequal in land wealth, and sorting by caste status
intensifies in villages that have more low-caste households.
   Four other studies provide some interesting insights, though their
evaluation designs are flawed. Chase, Christensen, and Thongyou
(2006) use data from an evaluation of the Thailand Social Fund to
assess whether the fund selected villages with specific characteristics
and whether implementation of the program had an impact on the
level of social capital in the selected villages. Using a combination of
household survey and qualitative data, they find that the social fund
provided funding to villages with particular preexisting social capital
characteristics (greater norms of self-sacrifice, higher levels of trust
among neighbors, and a history of collective action). They also find
some evidence that exposure to the program enhanced social cohesion.6
These results are suggestive at best, as the social capital variables were
generated after program implementation, making any causal inference
difficult. Moreover, program effects were weak, with social fund villages
performing significantly better than control villages on only 19 percent
of the social capital measures listed in the study.
   Labonne and Chase (2008) study K ALAHI–CIDSS, a large
community-driven development program in the Philippines. Using
data from 135 villages in 16 municipalities, the authors assess the
program’s impact on social capital indicators such as participation in
local governance activities, village group membership, and relationships
between local officials and citizens. They find that trust in local officials
increased in villages that received funding—even though the propor-
tion of households that requested services decreased.
   Two studies use data from the District Poverty Initiatives Project
(DPIP) in India to measure changes in social capital and political
empowerment. The DPIP supported the formation of women’s self-help
groups to promote economic and social empowerment.
   Deininger and Liu (2008) use recall data to measure changes in
social capital and political participation in treatment and control groups
in Andhra Pradesh between 2000 and 2004.7 They find a significant
increase in the level of social capital and political participation in DPIP

                                                                                             251
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          areas, with identical effects across participants and nonparticipants.8
                          They interpret this finding as evidence that the program had large posi-
                          tive social externalities. However, the design of the evaluation does not
                          allow for a clean test of this effect, because it is unclear whether control
                          communities are comparable on the relevant measures of social cohesion
                          or social capital at baseline. The measures of social cohesion used are
                          also closely linked to the rhetoric of participatory projects.
                             Kumar (2007) examines whether participation in DPIP, which runs
                          parallel to and outside the local government structure, helped poor
                          and lower-caste households engage effectively with the participatory
                          processes organized by local governments in Madhya Pradesh. She finds
                          a significant impact on political participation by poor rural women in
                          program areas. Households in program villages not only had greater
                          political awareness and better knowledge of other government pro-
                          grams, but they were also more likely to participate in village affairs, to
                          know about gram sabha (village assembly) meetings, and to participate
                          in them. They also reported being more active participants, and speak-
                          ing, voting, or objecting to decisions more often than other participants.
                          As in the study by Deininger and Liu, however, this paper’s evaluation
                          strategy is problematic, because it cannot identify why some villages
                          were selected into DPIP and others were not.9
                             There is also fair bit of suggestive evidence that localities in which
                          civic institutions are more vibrant have better outcomes. Few, if any,
                          of these studies are able to identify a causal link from decentralization
                          or participation in a community-drive development program to the
                          quality of civic institutions, however. Olken (2006) finds that villages
                          with more social organizations (community self-help groups, religious
                          study groups, women’s organizations) were less likely to experience
                          both outright corruption in the form of missing rice and less leakage
                          to village elites. Camacho and Conover (2011) find that municipalities
                          in Colombia that had better monitoring by community organizations
                          experienced less leakage from targeted programs. Galasso and Ravallion
                          (2005) find that Bangladeshi villages in which the Grameen Bank
                          was present received more program resources from the center and that
                          these resources were better targeted to the poor. Arcand, Bassole, and
                          Tranchant (2008) examine the extent to which participatory gover-
                          nance bodies, such as the Conseil de Concertation et de Gestion (CCG)
                          in Senegal, are able to compete with local elected leaders from the
                          Conseil Rural in attracting project funds to their communities. The

252
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



community-driven development project designed the CCG as a parallel          Some evidence suggests
participatory institution to ensure the representation of vulnerable and     that localities in which civic
marginalized groups that were less likely to be represented in the Conseil   institutions are more vibrant
Rural through the electoral process. The authors find that villages with      have better outcomes . . .
more CCG members who were not in the Conseil Rural were more likely
to receive a project, suggesting that although political elites may direct   . . . but whether
projects to their own villages, villagers who engage in participatory        decentralization, or
governance structures can enhance resource flows to their communities.        participation in a community-
                                                                             driven development program,
                                                                             improved the quality of civic
Representation Quotas and Inclusion Mandates                                 institutions remains unclear.

This section focuses on how reservations and quotas in local councils
and inclusion mandates have been used to address specific types of
social exclusion and make democratic institutions (and political incen-
tives) more responsive to people who would otherwise have little voice.
Many of the results come from the literature on mandated representa-
tion in Indian village councils (gram panchayats). These studies look
at whether leaders from disadvantaged groups have incentives to align
their actions with the interests of their particular group or the general
public.


Effects on Women
Women are systematically excluded from collective bodies, and from
positions of power, in many parts of the world. Looking at what she
calls “participatory exclusions” in community forestry groups in India
and Nepal, Agarwal (2001) fi nds that fewer than 10 percent of the
members of groups with decision-making authority are women, even
though women are required to do much of the work involved in for-
est management. Women’s underrepresentation affects the decisions
made by these groups and thus has distributional consequences. It also
reduces the effectiveness of the organizations, by failing to make use of
the information and skills women may have. Such exclusion can have a
reinforcing impact on discrimination against women.
   On the basis of fieldwork conducted over two years, Agarwal finds
that participatory exclusions occur for a variety of reasons. Social
norms exclude women from participating in public spaces, and gen-
dered norms of “acceptable” behaviors restrict women’s attendance

                                                                                                         253
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          at public gatherings. Women f ind men’s behavior “aggressive.”
                          Restrictions on women’s visibility and mobility affect their ability to
                          participate, they face negative stereotypes about their ability to con-
                          tribute effectively to proceedings that have public implications, and
                          they face norms that relegate them to work on women-specific tasks.
                          Many groups also have exclusionary rules, such as allowing only one
                          person per household to belong to a forestry group, which effectively
                          excludes women.
                             To get around social restrictions of this kind, in 1992 India adopted
                          a constitutional amendment mandating that one-third of all seats on
                          village councils and a third of all presidencies of these councils be
                          reserved for women. Many states randomly rotate the council seats and
                          presidencies reserved for women. A series of studies has exploited this
                          random allocation to study the impact of mandating seats for women
                          on a variety of outcomes.
                             Chattopadhyay and Duflo (2004b) analyze survey data from 265
                          village councils in the states of West Bengal and Rajasthan. In the
                          Birbhum district of West Bengal, the share of women among partici-
                          pants in the village council was significantly higher when the president
                          was a woman (rising from 6.9 percent to 9.8 percent), and female presi-
                          dents in reserved villages were twice as likely as male presidents to have
                          addressed a request or complaint to the gram panchayat in the previous
                          six months. In contrast, in Rajasthan the fact that the president was a
                          woman had no effect on women’s participation in the village council or
                          on the incidence of women’s complaints.
                             The authors also look at the effect of the policy of reserving seats for
                          women on the provision of public goods. They find that the gender of
                          the president affected the provision of public goods in both West Bengal
                          and Rajasthan, with significantly more investments in drinking water in
                          gram panchayats in which the president was a woman. In West Bengal,
                          gram panchayats were less likely to have set up informal schools when the
                          presidency was reserved for a woman. The evidence on roads was mixed,
                          with roads receiving significantly more funding in gram panchayats
                          reserved for women in West Bengal and less in gram panchayats reserved
                          for women in Rajasthan. In both states, the provision of public goods
                          in reserved constituencies was more closely aligned with the preferences
                          of women than with the preferences of men. Women invested less in
                          public goods that were more closely linked to men’s concerns (education
                          in West Bengal and roads in Rajasthan).

254
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



   Duflo and Topalova (2004) look at the effects of political reserva-          Reservation of gram panchayat
tion for women with data from a larger geographical area (11 states in         seats for women led to more
India). They present evidence on three aspects of women’s performance          investment in drinking water
in office (as measured by the quality and quantity of various public            infrastructure . . .
goods provided and the likelihood of taking bribes) as well as evidence
on perceptions of their performance by voters in India’s village councils.
Consistent with the results in Chattopadhyay and Duflo (2004b), they            . . . and to less spending on
find that reservation for women led to more investment in drinking              public goods preferred by men.
water infrastructure, with significantly more public drinking water
taps and hand pumps when the leadership of the gram panchayat was
reserved for a woman and weak evidence that the drinking water facili-
ties were in better repair. Overall, the average effect of reservation on
the availability of public goods in a village was positive and statistically
significant. The average effect of the reservation on the quality of public
goods was positive as well but not significant. The authors conclude that
women leaders did a better job than men at delivering drinking water
infrastructure and at least as good a job delivering other public goods.
   Duflo and Topalova also find that both men and women reported
being less likely to pay a bribe to obtain a service when the gram pan-
chayat presidency was held by a woman. However, respondents in vil-
lages with female presidents were also 2 percent less likely to declare that
they were satisfied with the public goods they received. Interestingly,
respondents also reported being significantly less satisfied with the
quality of the public health services in villages with women presidents,
despite the fact that health services were centrally administered and not
under the jurisdiction of panchayats in any of the 11 states during the
study period.
   Beaman and others (2009) compare villagers’ attitudes toward hypo-
thetical and actual women leaders in councils that have been reserved
for women once, twice, or never in West Bengal. Random allocation of
reservation implies that a difference in voter attitudes in reserved and
unreserved villages captures the causal effect of mandated reservations.
An important innovation of this study is the collection and use of
detailed survey and experimental data on voters’ taste for female lead-
ers, their perceptions of gender roles, and of the effectiveness of female
leaders. The authors examine explicit and implicit measures of voters’
tastes. Explicit tastes are captured through voters’ stated feelings toward
the general idea of male and female leaders; implicit tastes are captured
through Implicit Association Tests (IATs).10

                                                                                                         255
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



      Both men and women in           To examine voter perceptions of leader effectiveness, the authors
 India perceive women as less      asked villagers to evaluate the effectiveness of hypothetical female and
   effective leaders than men.     male leaders described through vignettes and recorded speeches in
                                   which the leader’s gender is experimentally manipulated. The results
                                   show that in villages that never experienced political reservation, villag-
                                   ers, particularly men, disliked the idea of female leaders. On a scale of
                                   1–10, the average man rated his feeling toward female leaders one point
                                   below his feelings toward male leaders. Men perceived female leaders
                                   as less effective than male leaders. The average male villager rated the
                                   same speech and vignette describing a leader’s decision 0.05 standard
                                   deviations lower when the leader’s gender was experimentally manipu-
                                   lated to be female. Female villagers’ evaluation of hypothetical female
                                   leaders, although less negative, was not statistically different from that
                                   of male villagers’.
                                      Mandated exposure to a female leader did not affect villagers’ stated
                                   taste for male leaders. Neither the “feeling” rating of leaders nor the taste
                                   IAT showed increased approval of female leaders in villages reserved for
                                   a female leader. However, among male villagers, it weakened the ste-
                                   reotype (as measured by the occupation IAT) that men are associated
                                   with leadership activities and women with domestic activities. It also
                                   radically altered perceptions of the effectiveness of female leaders among
                                   male villagers. In the speech and vignette experiments, male villagers
                                   who were required to have a female leader considered hypothetical
                                   female and male leaders equally effective. This reduction in bias was
                                   absent among female villagers. The authors provide evidence suggest-
                                   ing that a likely reason for this difference is the lower levels of political
                                   knowledge and exposure to local politics among women. Consistent
                                   with the experimental data, they find that prior exposure improved
                                   villagers’ evaluation of their actual leader along multiple dimensions.
   Reserving gram panchayat           Analyzing data from the same sample, Beaman and others (2012)
 seats for women may elevate       find that the reservation of seats for women has effects outside the politi-
       the aspirations parents     cal sphere. According to their study, reservations positively affected
      have for their daughters     both the aspirations parents had for their daughters and the aspirations
   and the aspirations of girls    of girls themselves. They examine the impact of women’s reservations
               themselves . . .    on parents’ preferences for their children not to become housewives, to
                                   hold a job requiring a good education, not to marry before 18, to receive
   . . . but reserving seats for   higher education, and to be the president of a village. The gap between
 women has not always led to       mothers and fathers in gram panchayats in which positions for women
               positive effects.   were never reserved was large, ranging from 24 percent for their child

256
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



not marrying before 18, to 75 percent for their daughter not becoming
a housewife. This gap was, on average, 20 percentage points smaller
in gram panchayats with a randomly assigned woman president. The
authors also surveyed adolescents ages 11–15. They find that the gender
gap in their career and education aspirations was 32 percentage points
smaller in villages that reserved seats for women.
   Bhavnani (2009) assesses the long-term impact of the reservation of
seats for women on municipal councils in Mumbai by examining the
relative change in political power in councils that had previously been
reserved for women. He tests for the continuing effects of the 1997
reservations on various aspects of the 2002 elections. His main find-
ing is that women won 21.6 percent of wards that had been reserved
for women in 1997 but were open to both genders in 2002 (treatment
wards) and only 3.7 percent of wards that were open to both men and
women in 1997 and 2002 (control wards). Women’s chances of winning
ward elections in 2002 were thus more than quintupled by the reserva-
tion of seats five years earlier. Bhavnani also examines the mechanisms
through which the electoral chances for women may have increased
in the previously reserved constituencies. He finds that the increase is
explained by both an incumbency effect and an increase in the number
of woman candidates running in the previously reserved constituency.
   Some studies show that reserving seats for women has not always led
to positive effects. Bardhan, Mookherjee, and Torrado (2010) examine
all 16 rural districts in West Bengal (89 villages in 57 gram panchay-
ats), drawing on the results of a household survey conducted between
2003 and 2004. Using a stratified random sample of 20 households per
village, they examine the determinants of access to a variety of local
government programs, including provision of toilets, participation in
public works, receipt of Below Poverty Line (BPL) cards, and access to
agricultural minikits. They find that the reservation of seats for women
led to no improvement in intravillage household targeting to female-
headed households and a worsening of targeting to households from
schedule castes and tribes. These effects were mitigated in villages that
had high land inequality. The authors interpret these findings to suggest
that female leaders are inexperienced and weak and that their leadership
exacerbates clientelistic allocations. In high inequality areas, female
leaders are also from elite families, which makes them more effective.
   Ban and Rao (2009) draw on community-level and household survey
data and surveys of village presidents in four southern Indian states.

                                                                                            257
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                 They find no significant effect of women’s leadership on participation
                                 in public village meetings or the existence of women’s organizations
                                 in the community. They also find that women presidents in reserved
                                 gram panchayats were significantly less likely than male presidents
                                 to meet with higher-level officials. Relative to unreserved gram pan-
                                 chayats, panchayats reserved for women invested significantly more in
                                 education-related activities. But on the vast majority of activities, female
                                 presidents behaved no differently from male presidents. In contrast to
                                 Chattopadhyay and Duflo (2004a), Ban and Rao find no evidence that
                                 female presidents acted in accordance with women’s preferences.
    More experienced female         Ban and Rao fi nd considerable heterogeneity in their results. In
        presidents in reserved   particular, female presidents in reserved gram panchayats were unam-
       gram panchayats were      biguously more effective when they were more experienced. Women in
unambiguously more effective     reserved gram panchayats performed worse when most of the land in the
  than less experienced ones.    village was owned by upper castes, suggesting that caste structures may
                                 be correlated with structures of patriarchy in ways that make condi-
                                 tions particularly difficult for women. The authors also find that female
                                 presidents in reserved gram panchayats performed best in states where
                                 reservations had been in place longest, indicating the importance of
                                 the maturity of the reservation system. This effect, in conjunction with
                                 the positive effect of the president’s political experience, points toward
                                 a hopeful future, as it suggests that as women acquire more experience
                                 and the system continues to mature, women will become more effec-
                                 tive leaders.
                                    Leino (2007) examines whether incentives for female participation
                                 improved the maintenance of infrastructure in Kenya. The interven-
                                 tion aimed to increase women’s participation in the maintenance of
                                 water sources by encouraging them to attend community meetings at
                                 which water management committees were elected. Once elected, the
                                 water management committees were trained by a facilitating NGO to
                                 manage maintenance tasks for water schemes. The meetings were held
                                 at times convenient for women, and NGO facilitators emphasized the
                                 importance of women’s participation at each meeting.
                                    The intervention was successful in increasing the number of women
                                 on water management committees. It also increased the number of
                                 women holding leadership positions in the committee, more than
                                 doubling the odds that a woman was a committee chair. This effect
                                 appears to have persisted through the three-year period of the study.
                                 The increase in female leadership on the water management committees

258
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



had no impact on the quality of infrastructure maintenance, however.          In Kenya, incentives for
There is thus little evidence of any efficiency gain because of greater        inclusion increased female
female participation—although, as the author notes, the more inter-           leadership on water
esting result may be that increased inclusion can be achieved with no         management committees, but
apparent efficiency cost.                                                      the increase had no impact
                                                                              on the quality of infrastructure
                                                                              maintenance.
Effect on Disadvantaged Castes
Chattopadhyay and Duflo (2004a) examine how the type and loca-
tion of public goods differs in unreserved gram panchayats and gram
panchayats in which presidencies were reserved for historically disad-
vantaged Scheduled Castes (SC) in West Bengal.11 Identification of
the caste reservation effect was based on the random assignment of
gram panchayats reserved for scheduled castes. The authors studied
investments in drinking water facilities, irrigation facilities, roads, and
education centers, measured using a participatory survey in which a
representative group of villagers was shown a village map that depicted
the location of all infrastructure schemes and then was asked which
investments had been built or repaired since the last election.
   The authors find that SC presidents did not significantly change the
types of investments in public goods relative to presidents from unre-
served gram panchayats. SC hamlets in SC–reserved gram panchayats
received 14 percent more investment in public goods than SC hamlets
in unreserved gram panchayats.
   Chin and Prakash (2010) assess the extent to which reservation
for disadvantaged castes and tribes improves living conditions for
the poorest. Using panel data from 16 Indian states over the period
1960–92, they examine the effect of state-level reservations for SCs
and Scheduled Tribes (STs) on state-level measures of overall poverty.
The main question of interest is whether on balance, minority political
representation is welfare enhancing for all of the poor. The authors find
that reservations for SCs reduced overall poverty—that is, benefits to
minority groups did not appear to have come at a cost to poor or near-
poor nonminorities. Reservation policies for STs were more effective in
reducing poverty in rural than in urban areas, suggesting some caution
in generalizing findings in the absence of more empirical work.
   Using data from four southern Indian states, Besley and others
(2004) examine the effect of reservations for SCs and STs on the
distribution of low-spillover and high-spillover goods within and

                                                                                                          259
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          between villages at the gram panchayat level. They measure access
                          to low-spillover (household-level) public goods through a household
                          survey that defines access as having had a house or toilet built under
                          a government scheme or having received a private water or electricity
                          connection through a government scheme since the last gram panchayat
                          election. They measure access to high-spillover public goods (public
                          goods that are easily accessed across groups and neighborhoods) using
                          data on gram panchayat activity from an independent audit of village
                          facilities. An index constructed from these data measures whether the
                          gram panchayat undertook any construction or improvement activity on
                          village roads, drains, streetlights, or water sources since the last gram
                          panchayat election.
                             Using a household-level regression with village fi xed effects, the
                          authors find that low-spillover public goods (access to which is more
                          easily restricted to particular groups and neighborhoods) were targeted
                          more toward SC/ST households. On average, a household from an
                          SC/ST was 6 percent more likely to receive such a public good than a
                          non–SC/ST household. The extent of such targeting was enhanced by
                          living in a reserved gram panchayat. Relative to living in a nonreserved
                          gram panchayat, living in a reserved gram panchayat increased a SC/ST
                          household’s likelihood of getting such a low-spillover public good by
                          7 percent.
                             Besley and others (2004) consider the village-level incidence of
                          high-spillover public goods, as measured by the gram panchayat activity
                          index. They find that on average, this index was 0.04 points higher in
                          the president’s village. Thus, for high-spillover public goods, proximity
                          to the elected representative matters. In contrast, for low-spillover public
                          goods, sharing the politician’s group identity matters most.
                             Besley, Pande, and Rao (2005) show that reservation makes it more
                          likely that SC/ST households will receive a Below Poverty Line card,
                          which provides access to targeted benefits. This finding suggests that
                          SC/ST leaders favor members of their own group.
                             Bardhan, Mookherjee, and Torrado (2010) find that SC/ST reserva-
                          tion has a positive effect on per capita benefits allocated to the village
                          as a whole. It also improves intrahousehold targeting to both female-
                          headed and SC/ST households—a sharp contrast to their results on
                          women’s reservations. In a related paper combining theory with an
                          analysis of the same data set, Bardhan and Mookherjee (2012) find that
                          the effects of SC/ST reservation are entirely consistent with a model of

260
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



clientelism. This result is also consistent with the results of Besley and
others (2004).
   This literature details the largely positive impacts of inclusion man-        The majority of studies find
dates. Other studies find that reservation mandates have had a mixed              that India’s constitutionally
impact in terms of giving groups more voice or aligning the interests of         mandated rules on inclusion
caste leaders with the preferences of their groups.                              have given disadvantaged
   Palaniswamy and Krishnan (2008) identify the effects of SC/ST                 groups more benefits. . . .
political reservation in the Indian state of Karnataka by exploiting the
random allocation of reservations, conditional on village population
size and the proportion of the SC/ST population in the village. In look-
ing at the distribution of grants within village councils, they find that
villages represented in the village council by SC/ST members attract
fewer resources. They also find that reservations for other backward
classes (OBCs) allow some politically dominant castes (Vokkaligas and
Lingayats) to run in these reserved constituencies. Such villages are
likely to receive more resources, suggesting that elite capture may persist
despite the presence of reservations.
   Dunning and Nilekani (2010) use a regression discontinuity design
to compare the impact of caste reservations on otherwise similar village
councils in Karnataka. They find very weak policy and redistributive
effects.
   Munshi and Rosenzweig (2009) analyze survey data on Indian local              . . . but some studies find that
governments at the ward level over multiple terms. They show that                reservation mandates have
reservations for disadvantaged castes can have adverse village-level out-        had adverse effects.
comes, by increasing the odds of electing lower-quality politicians who
are able to attract fewer public resources. The caste system, the authors
contend, serves as a commitment-enforcing device. Fearing social
sanctions, a leader elected with the support of his or her caste is more
likely to make decisions that reflect the preferences of the caste. When
a caste group is large, it is able to elect its most able leader and to ensure
that the leader implements a policy that does not deviate from the
policy preferred by the median member of the caste. However, political
reservations for disadvantaged castes make it less likely that a leader
will be elected from a numerically dominant caste. Setting the main
explanatory variable as the existence of a numerically dominant caste,
the authors run a ward-level regression (the dependent variables are the
characteristics of the elected ward leader and the ward-level provision
of public goods). As they observe the same ward over multiple electoral
terms, they are able to isolate within-ward variations in the identity

                                                                                                            261
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          of leaders from a numerically dominant caste. The results show that,
                          without a caste reservation, the existence of a dominant caste results in
                          the election of a wealthier leader, as well as a leader who is more likely
                          to be in an occupation involving independent decision making (farm
                          operator, business person, or professional), and this appears to increase
                          the overall level of local public resources the ward receives by about
                          16 percent.
                             In sum, while mandates thus seem to increase the representation
                          of women and excluded groups in leadership positions and can be an
                          effective mechanism for promoting greater inclusion in local councils.
                          Their effects on resource allocation and the effectiveness of local gov-
                          ernments seem to depend on the context. In particular, while women
                          leaders are more effective in more mature reservation systems, their
                          political effectiveness continues to be hampered by land inequality, the
                          strength of existing structures of patriarchy, and the power of dominant
                          caste groups.
                             In contrast, caste reservation seems to affect the local political
                          economy by changing the incentives for clientelistic allocations. For
                          the most part, clientelism seems to narrowly benefit SC/ST households
                          with potentially detrimental effects for the majority of village residents.
                             The evidence also hints at the possibility that reservation rules
                          are sometimes not properly enforced but instead captured by male-
                          dominated structures of power. The vast majority of the evidence
                          derives from Indian village democracies, however. The effects in non-
                          democratic settings may be different.



                          Community-Driven Reconstruction
                          The active involvement of citizens in public life has come to be viewed
                          as an important mechanism for managing or mitigating confl ict at
                          all levels; participatory development projects are seen as an important
                          mechanism for reengaging citizens in public life. In the aftermath of
                          widespread conflict, participation usually takes the form of reconstruc-
                          tion projects. The basic argument is that broad-based involvement
                          in reconstruction planning can play an important role in rebuilding
                          citizenship and trust in government institutions in a context in which
                          state-society relations are frayed (Cliffe, Guggenheim, and Kostner
                          2003; World Bank 2011).

262
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



   The conflict-reducing role of participatory development goes beyond
postconflict conditions, however. Community-driven development
projects are usually implemented in contexts where formal governance
institutions are weak and access to judicial institutions, courts, or the
local police is limited largely to people with wealth or political power.
In such settings, ordinary confl icts over property rights, the use of
natural resources, and violence (domestic or communal) must often be
arbitrated within the community itself, often through informal justice
institutions. The impartiality of such informal mechanisms may be
limited for marginalized groups within a community.
   In such environments, participatory projects could change the condi-
tions under which disputes emerge and are resolved. On the one hand,
the new informal institutional structures created by such projects could
empower marginalized groups to demand more even and effective judi-
cial services, from both formal and informal providers. On the other,
they could create new struggles over the allocation of project resources
and the distribution of power within localities, which could exacerbate      Overall, the evidence on the
local conflicts.                                                              effectiveness of community-
   There is as yet little reliable evidence on the relative effectiveness    driven reconstruction projects
of community-driven reconstruction projects as a means of deliver-           as a means of delivering
ing development aid or (re)building civil society under conditions of        development aid or rebuilding
conflict. What evidence there is, is not altogether encouraging, though       civil society is weak.
there are some positive findings.
   Strand and others (2003) review 14 World Bank–funded community-
driven reconstruction projects. They find that although community-
driven reconstruction projects may provide a fast-track disbursement
tool, the poor and marginalized have only limited access to such projects.
Governments often have an incentive to provide community-driven
reconstruction resources selectively, in order to increase their political
support and may be reluctant to extend such programs to areas that are
less important politically, making it difficult to scale programs up.         Community-level trust and
   The authors also find that community-level trust and reconciliation        reconciliation building is
building is effective only if it is linked to a comparable process at the    effective only if it is linked to
national level. They conclude that community-driven reconstruction           a comparable process at the
projects should be viewed not just as humanitarian efforts but also as       national level.
potential political tools. An understanding of existing political and
social relations and reconciliation structures on the ground, as well as
the establishment of community capacity, are thus necessary precondi-
tions for the equitable distribution of resources in such projects.

                                                                                                           263
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     Pearce (2007), who studied civil society participation in Colombia
                                 and Guatemala, argues that civil society organizations can play a
                                 prominent role in building citizenship by confronting violent actors in
                                 all spaces and levels of socialization. By restoring plurality and open-
                                 ing “invisibly sealed boundaries,” civil society organizations can curb
                                 violence by encouraging victims to understand violence.
                                     A key metric of the success of community-driven reconstruction
                                 projects is the extent to which they improve state-society relations and
                                 build social cohesion and citizenship. This set of objectives can be dif-
                                 ficult to evaluate, as the studies reviewed below illustrate. A second and
                                 perhaps equally important measure of success is the extent to which
                                 resources flow to activities and groups most targeted by such programs,
                                 usually the people most likely to be victimized by violence.
                                     Barron, Woolcock, and Diprose (2011) examine a community-
                                 driven reconstruction project in Aceh, Indonesia (BRA–KDP) that
                                 built on the national Kecamatan Development Program by targeting
                                 resources to victims of the conflict.12 Program targeting by the center
                                 worked well, as confl ict-affected communities were included in the
                                 program. Targeting within communities was weak, however, with
                                 conflict victims generally faring no better than nonvictims, despite the
                                 explicit intended targeting of conflict victims. Conflict victims were
                                 also more likely to report that their preferred projects were not selected
                                 for implementation.
                                     Project funds were also used to provide private transfers to beneficia-
  A postconflict reconstruction   ries rather than investments in public goods. Not surprisingly, survey
 project in Indonesia may have   responses revealed income gains in program communities (the survey
reduced rather than increased    was conducted while the program was still disbursing funds). The
conflict victims’ acceptance of   study finds little evidence for any improvement in social cohesion or
                 excombatants.   trust in governmental institutions, however. In fact, there is evidence
                                 that BRA–KDP was associated with less acceptance of excombatants
                                 by conflict victims in project areas, though there is no evidence of a
                                 greater tendency for tensions to escalate into violence (possibly because
                                 excombatants received some of the funds that were meant for civilian
                                 conflict victims).
                                     A potential solution to the problem of measuring social cohesion
                                 is to complement survey data with behavioral games, which provide
                                 clearer measures of political practice and cooperation. The Fearon,
                                 Humphreys, and Weinstein (2009) study cited earlier suggests that there
                                 is a greater propensity to contribute cash and labor in program villages,

264
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



with much of the effect coming from contributions by excombatants.
Survey evidence also suggests that individuals in communities with
community-driven reconstruction projects report less social tension
and exhibit greater acceptance of previously marginalized groups. There
is no evidence, however, of any improvement in material well-being,
though there is some evidence of improvement in local public goods.
Fearon, Humphreys, and Weinstein do not see this improvement in
public goods as unmixed evidence of the benefits of community-driven
reconstruction in a conflict environment. In fact, they make the point
that confl ict usually occurs at levels that are higher than the “com-
munity” that such programs target. It is possible that strengthening
cohesion at the local level could exacerbate conflict across communities.
Their study finds no discernible effect on participants’ beliefs in broader
democratic principles or other measures of citizenship. Furthermore,
there was little impact on measures of social inclusion of refugees or new
migrants into the community, although respondents in treated commu-
nities report greater trust in their leaders (see also Beath, Christia, and
Enikolopev 2011 on Afghanistan).
   Bellows and Miguel (2006) estimate the effects of the civil war
in Sierra Leone (1991–2002), using unique nationally representative
household data on conflict experiences, postwar economic outcomes,
and local politics and collective action. They fi nd strong evidence
that individuals whose households had been subjected to intense
violence were much more likely to attend community meetings, vote,
and contribute to local public goods; they were also more likely to be
cognizant of local political dynamics. Several tests indicate that selec-
tion into victimization is not driving the results.13 The relationship
between confl ict intensity and postwar outcomes is weaker at more
aggregate levels, however, suggesting that the war’s primary impact
was on individual preferences rather than on institutions or local
social norms.
   The use of community-driven reconstruction in postconflict settings
is deeply affected by the context. The limited evidence is mixed. In
some settings (Afghanistan, Liberia), such projects may have a positive       There is no evidence that
effect on social cohesion. In some settings, people with a more direct        postconflict community-
experience of war (excombatants in Liberia, people affected by violence       based interventions increase
in Sierra Leone) were more likely to contribute to their communities          trust or cohesion beyond the
and to participate in community meetings; in other settings, this was         community level, or improve
not the case. There is also no evidence to suggest that community-based       material outcomes.

                                                                                                        265
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   interventions in postconflict settings increased trust and cohesion, had
                                   an affect beyond the community level, or improved material outcomes.



                                   Participatory Councils and Deliberative Spaces
Public deliberation envisions a    Public deliberation envisions a world in which citizens engage in rea-
 world in which citizens engage    soned, thoughtful debate to come to a consensual decision. It is the ideal
in reasoned, thoughtful debate     form of participation. Its goal is to aggregate preferences through con-
       to come to a consensual     versation, to allow the diverse views of a community to be consolidated
                       decision.   and presented as one representative view.
                                       Public deliberation is expected to have a number of beneficial
                                   effects—mirroring but intensifying the effects of participation. At the
                                   intrinsic level, public deliberation is expected to give voice and create a
                                   sense of agency and community; at the instrumental level, it is expected
                                   to enhance the capacity for collective action and repair civic failures by
                                   bringing the interests of citizens to the attention of the state. Important
                                   are not only formal deliberative forums but also what Mansbridge
                                   (1999) calls “deliberative systems,” where discussion and debate con-
                                   tinue outside formal spaces as informal conversations between citizens
                                   and representatives, political activists, media, and other citizens. This
                                   everyday deliberation changes the nature of participation, making it
                                   more discursive and consensual than merely ritualistic. Mansbridge
                                   claims that “when a deliberative system works well, it filters out and
                                   discards the worst ideas available on public matters while it picks up,
                                   adopts, and applies the best ideas.” If, however, “the deliberative system
                                   works badly, it distorts facts, portrays ideas in forms the originators
                                   would disown, and encourages citizens to adopt ways of thinking
                                   and acting that are good neither for them nor for the larger polity”
                                   (Mansbridge 1999, 211). Deliberation is also at the heart of what Fung
                                   and Wright (2003) call “empowered participatory governance,” a system
                                   of governance that translates deliberative decision making into policy
                                   decisions and actions (see chapter 4).
                                       Two sets of questions arise in considering the effectiveness of such
                                   a system. The first has to do with whether deliberation that empowers
                                   all participants is possible in highly unequal societies. The second has
                                   to do with whether deliberative capacity can be built and nurtured.
                                   Can policy interventions induce a system of empowered participatory
                                   governance? In what contexts does deliberation work well?

266
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



Africa
Deliberative democracy is not widespread in Africa, although indig-            Deliberative decision-making
enous traditions of deliberative decision making, particularly in rural        groups led by women and
communities, have carried over to public decision making to varying            older men tend to have
degrees (see chapter 1). In the island nation of São Tomé and Príncipe,        different priorities and
all adults were invited to a national forum in 2004 to gather in facilitated   emphasize different processes
groups to discuss policy issues related to the use of the newly discovered     than other groups.
oil reserves. Local facilitators were randomly assigned throughout the
country. Humphreys, Masters, and Sandbu (2006) find that leaders
significantly influenced the outcomes of deliberation, with one-fifth to
one-third of the variance in outcomes explained by leader fixed effects.
They also find that groups led by women and older men tended to have
different priorities and emphasize different processes than other groups.
    A similar situation appears to prevail in Malawi, where evidence from
more than a thousand ethnographic journals, in which field researchers
capture the conversations of rural Malawians, shows a marked differ-
ence between the quality of deliberation in informal and formal settings
(Swidler and Watkins 2011). The data, collected in conjunction with a
study on the role of social networks in the HIV/AIDS epidemic, show
that people in rural areas engage in deliberation “frequently, energeti-
cally, sometimes vociferously” in everyday settings—markets, village
meetings, and chiefs’ courts—and freely “assert a variety of claims
and moral principles” (p. 4) In induced settings such as donor-funded
projects with deliberative modalities, however, they behave more like
students in a rote-learning environment. Such settings “invoke the hier-
archical template of school, with its colonial remnants and its deference
to the prestige of modern learning” (Swidler and Watkins 2011, 4). Both
facilitators and participants treat such forums like classrooms, where
deliberation must be taught, giving citizens neither voice nor agency, as
they are not engaging in a debate over their interests but simply acting
out the scripts written by facilitators who are, in turn, following the
dictates of donors.
    Can deliberative skills be transferred from the private sphere to for-
mal democratic settings? Can deliberation be cultivated without active
instruction? In many contexts, communications media promise to be
a useful tool. Paluck and Green (2009) examine the effects of a radio
program that attempted to promote independent thought and collective
action while discouraging blind obedience and deference to authority in

                                                                                                        267
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                      postgenocide Rwanda. The program was randomly assigned to pairs of
                                      communities matched on a vector of observable characteristics, with the
                                      control community receiving a comparable structured program about
                                      HIV/AIDS. The program encouraging independent thought improved
                                      people’s willingness to express dissent and seek collective solutions to
                                      common problems, but it had little effect on their beliefs and attitudes.
                                         Paluck (2010) tests the impact of a year-long radio talk show that
                                      was broadcast in tandem with a soap opera on randomly assigned com-
                                      munities in the Democratic Republic of Congo. Control communities
                                      heard only the soap opera. The talk show was designed to encourage
                                      tolerance and sharing of different perspectives; the soap opera pro-
                                      moted intergroup contact. Compared with individuals exposed only
                                      to the soap opera, talk show listeners were more likely to engage in
                                      discussion. However, they were also more intolerant, more focused on
                                      grievances, and less likely to aid members of the community whom
                                      they disliked.
                                         These two media experiments demonstrate the potential and pitfalls
              Deliberative skills     of media-based strategies to promote deliberation in different post-
      are ubiquitous in informal      conflict African contexts. Although deliberative skills are ubiquitous
            forums in Africa . . .    in informal forums, it is difficult to translate those skills to formal
                                      settings, which tend to be driven by leaders and follow predetermined
                                      scripts. The challenge for citizens is to develop appropriate political and
                                      cultural skills—what Swidler (1986) has called a cultural toolkit—to
                                      navigate the public sphere. The radio experiments in Rwanda and the
                                      Democratic Republic of Congo were structured precisely to develop this
                                      toolkit. They had mixed effects, helping build the capacity for delibera-
        . . . but it is difficult to   tion and collective action in Rwanda while generating more noise than
translate those skills to formal      signal in collective discussions in the Democratic Republic of Congo.
     settings, which tend to be       The radio experiments also raise the question of how long-lasting these
   driven by leaders and follow       effects are in the absence of active participation by a state that is com-
        predetermined scripts.        mitted to the idea of deliberation. Whether the effects will be sustained
                                      after the programs stop airing remains an open question.


                                      Asia
                                      Gram sabhas (village assemblies) constitute the largest formal delibera-
                                      tive institution in human history, affecting more than 700 million rural
                                      Indian residents living in more than a million villages. Besley, Pande,
                                      and Rao (2005) analyze data on gram sabhas from 5,180 randomly

268
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



selected households in 527 villages in South India to determine whether
they yield instrumental (policy) benefits. They focus on a specific policy
administered at the village level—access to a BPL card, which provides
an array of public benefits. The authors estimate a regression that
exploits within-village variation in individual characteristics to examine
whether the targeting of BPL cards differs depending on whether the
village held a gram sabha the previous year. They find that the targeting
of landless and illiterate individuals was more intensive in villages that
had held a gram sabha. Moreover, these effects were economically sig-
nificant, raising the probability of receiving a BPL card from 8 percent
to 10 percent. Some caution about these results is warranted, however,
as it is possible that holding a gram sabha is correlated with other village
characteristics that are important in shaping the way public resources
are targeted.
    Rao and Sanyal’s (2010) qualitative analysis of 290 gram sabha
transcripts from the same villages finds that the forums allow disad-           Gram sabhas are more
vantaged castes to gain voice and seek dignity and agency (see chapter         than mere opportunities for
4). Ban, Jha, and Rao’s (2012) quantitative analysis of coded versions of      cheap talk . . .
these transcripts emphasizes that these forums have characteristics that
are consistent with an efficient democracy. Deriving hypotheses from
models of group decision making under uncertainty, they analyze the
transcript data to test two competing hypotheses of the types of equi-
librium that could characterize gram sabha interactions: “cheap talk”
(discussions are not substantive even though they may appear equitable)
and “efficient democracy” (meetings follow patterns of good democratic
practice). They find that in villages with high caste heterogeneity and
less village-wide agreement on policy priorities, the priorities of the
median “voter” (a reference individual whose expressed preferences
track those of 50 percent of the population) are more likely to dominate
the discourse, and landed elites have a negligible effect. Ban, Jha, and
Rao conclude that gram sabhas are more than mere opportunities for             . . . discourse within them
cheap talk, that they more closely follow patterns observed in a well-         follows patterns observed in a
functioning democracy.                                                         well-functioning democracy.
    Heller, Harilal, and Chaudhuri (2007) analyze qualitative and
quantitative data from a survey of 72 gram sabhas in Kerala, where a
“people’s campaign” systematized and empowered deliberative systems
in gram sabhas, which are considered exemplars of Fung and Wright’s
(2003) “empowered participatory governance.” The authors find that
civil society inputs strongly influenced the decisions of local and state

                                                                                                         269
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   governments and that the campaign had positive effects on social inclu-
                                   sion, giving both lower-caste groups and women a more active role in
                                   decision making.
                                       The evidence from India highlights three main principles of effec-
   Gram sabhas work because        tive participatory governance. First, gram sabhas work because they are
       they are constitutionally   constitutionally mandated, which gives them legitimacy and clout and
  mandated, which gives them       ensures that they are seen as ongoing rituals that will not disappear.
      legitimacy and clout and     Regularity ensures that public interactions have to accommodate all cit-
 ensures that they are seen as     izens, regardless of class, caste, or gender and that all citizens can voice
   ongoing rituals that will not   their opinions publicly in a way that holds local government account-
                    disappear.     able. If deliberative forums are temporary or ad hoc events, they can
                                   be much more easily ignored, manipulated, and rendered ineffective.
                                       Second, the evidence suggests that in order to provide the right
                                   incentive for participation, deliberative forums must have clout. Third,
                                   embedding such forums within the context of electoral democracy is
                                   helpful, but providing voice and agency to all citizens in settings with
                                   low literacy is a challenge.
                                       Indonesia has a long tradition of consensual decision making at
                                   the local level. The World Bank–supported Kecamatan Development
                                   Program (KDP) attempted to move these traditions into more formal,
                                   modern settings. Over its 10-year life (1998–2008), KDP provided
                                   block grants directly to rural communities to fund projects prepared
                                   and selected through a deliberative process. The aim was to create par-
                                   ticipatory structures that would be a permanent alternative to decision
                                   making led by elites. KDP has been the subject of much scholarship and
                                   has generated a large number of important research findings highlighted
                                   throughout this report. The focus here is on the findings on the efficacy
                                   of deliberative forums.
                                       Olken (2010) presents the results of an experiment in which 49
            One study finds that    KDP villages were randomly assigned to choose development projects
       deliberation may be less    through the standard KDP deliberative process or by plebiscite (direct
effective in equalizing decision   vote). Two types of projects were chosen by these processes for each
   making than plebiscites . . .   village—a general project and a women’s project chosen exclusively by
                                   women. Olken finds that plebiscites resulted in dramatically higher
                                   satisfaction among villagers and increased their knowledge about the
                                   project, their perception of benefits, and their willingness to contribute.
                                   He finds that the type of projects selected did not change as a result of
                                   the plebiscite. For the women’s project, the plebiscite resulted in projects
                                   being located in poorer areas of the village, suggesting that it shifted

270
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



power toward poorer women, who may have been disenfranchised in               . . . and that plebiscites may
more elite-dominated deliberative meetings. These results demonstrate         increase the legitimacy of and
that deliberation may be less effective in equalizing decision making         satisfaction with development
than a direct election and that plebiscites may increase the legitimacy       interventions.
of and satisfaction with development interventions.
   Olken’s results are contradicted, to some degree, by an in-depth,
large-sample qualitative study by Barron, Woolcock, and Diprose
(2011), who take the unusual approach of combining a counterfactual
design with qualitative analysis to study the mediating impact of KDP’s
deliberative spaces on local confl ict. Their analysis investigates two
central questions: how KDP interacted with prevailing social tensions
and management of local conflict and, more generally, whether delib-
erative interventions such as KDP support progressive, nonviolent social
change in a dynamic environment or make things worse.
   The authors selected two districts in Indonesia considered to have
high capacity in their ability to manage conflict and two considered to
have low capacity. Within each district, three subdistricts (kecamatans)
were chosen—three that had KDP matched with one that was a con-
trol. The treatment and control subdistricts were matched through
propensity score analysis, with the scores reflecting various economic
indicators, including poverty rates and the availability of infrastructure.
Qualitative observations supplemented the propensity score matching
method in order to eliminate poor matches. Data were collected from
41 villages in these matched kecamatans where conflicts were observed,
and cases of confl ict in the treatment and control kecamatans were
matched to be similar in type. Data collection was conducted over a
seven-month period by a team of researchers who conducted case studies
of conflict, interviewed key informants, observed deliberative processes,
and conducted focus group discussions. The researchers also culled data
on other local conflicts from local newspapers.
   The study finds that although KDP and other development projects
frequently trigger conflict because of competition over resources, the         In Indonesia, deliberative
deliberative spaces within KDP make those confl icts far less likely           spaces made conflicts far
to escalate and turn violent, largely because decisions emerge from a         less likely to escalate and
consultative process that communities perceive as legitimate and equi-        turn violent, because
table. The likelihood of violence is also mitigated by the fact that KDP      decisions emerged from a
has facilitators and other procedures to manage conflict as it arises.         consultative process.
However, there is little evidence that KDP has a positive impact on con-
flict at an aggregate level or even a direct positive impact on nonproject-

                                                                                                            271
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   related conflict at the local level. The project’s main impacts, in fact, are
                                   on conflicts that emerge from the project itself. There are three main
                                   reasons for this finding: villages have other mechanisms to deal with
                                   nonproject-related conflicts, KDP facilitators are not perceived to have
                                   the legitimacy to mediate disputes outside KDP, and project facilitators
                                   do not have the capacity to deal with nonproject disputes.
                                      KDP impacts are highly variable, though in both low- and high-
                                   capacity districts, program functionality matters more than the inherent
                                   capacity to manage conflict. There is also considerable variance over
                                   time, because KDP was not a standard project but had a considerable
                                   learning-by-doing component. This learning took place at differ-
                                   ent rates in different contexts, depending on the support the project
                                   received from government officials, the resistance of people whose inter-
                                   ests were most threatened by KDP’s transparency and accountability,
                                   and the quality of implementation. KDP is an assemblage of principles
                                   and procedures over which frontline facilitators have some modest dis-
                                   cretion while interacting with villagers over many months. The quality
                                   of facilitators also varies, with some working tirelessly, beyond the call
                                   of duty; some merely doing what the job description requires; and some
                                   (though not many) capitulating to corruption.


                                   Latin America
                                   Latin America has witnessed several significant innovations, notably
                                   participatory budgeting. As described in chapter 1, participatory bud-
                                   geting began as an organic innovation in the city of Porto Alegre, Brazil,
                                   where over time civic activists made the case for greater public delib-
                                   eration in determining municipal budgets. When the party supported
                                   by activists (the Partido dos Trabalhadores [PT]) came into power, it
                                   implemented a deliberative process for budgetary decision making that
                                   came to be called “participatory budgeting” (Baiocchi 2011).
                                      A series of studies tracking outcomes before and after the introduc-
 Participatory budgeting made      tion of participatory budgeting (albeit without a counterfactual) finds
   the budgeting process more      substantial improvements. The budgeting process became substan-
 transparent and responsive to     tially more transparent and responsive to citizens’ needs (Souza 2001;
    citizens’ needs, empowered     Schneider and Baquero 2006; Zamboni 2007), it also empowered
    marginalized groups, made      marginalized groups and made the budget more pro-poor (Souza
the budget more pro-poor, and      2001; Schneider and Goldfrank 2002; Serageldin and others 2003;
             reduced corruption.   Evans 2004). And the level of corruption decreased (Ackerman 2004;

272
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



Cabannes 2004). However, while accountability improved as a result
of a more transparent and deliberative process, the forums’ lack of legal
authority resulted in power remaining with the mayor’s office (Wampler
2004).
   These studies are descriptive or tracking analyses of largely organic
innovations. They say little about how participatory budgeting would
work if induced by an intervention or how any changes that resulted
would compare to a counterfactual in which participatory budgeting
was not introduced.
   One of the few counterfactual analyses of participatory budgeting is
by Baiocchi, Heller, and Silva (2011), who use a discontinuity design.
They match five municipalities in which the PT came to power with
a small margin of victory in 1996 and subsequently implemented par-
ticipatory budgeting with five municipalities in the same region and
of similar size in which the PT lost by a small margin, resulting in
the nonadoption of participatory budgeting. As the PT is very much a
party born of civil society and Brazil’s social movements of the 1980s,
Baiocchi, Heller, and Silva (2011) assume that two municipalities in
which the PT garnered similar vote shares will be similar in terms
of their local tradition of political activism and the composition and
strength of civil society. In matching municipalities in this manner, they
also try to control for scale and geography.
   The researchers selected five pairs of the best-matched municipalities
(one pair in the South, two in the Southeast, one in the Northeast, and      Participatory budgeting
one in the North). Analyzing a mix of data from quantitative surveys         facilitated much more
and carefully collected in-depth interviews and group discussions, they      effective forms of
find that, in general, participatory budgeting municipalities facilitated     engagement . . .
much more effective forms of engagement than their non–participatory
budgeting counterparts. In all municipalities with participatory budget-
ing, the effect was to increase the flow of information about municipal
governance, create a space for citizens to voice their demands and to
scrutinize what were once highly insulated and discretionary decision-
making processes. This allowed citizens to bargain from a position of
greater strength with municipal authorities.
   There was considerable variation across the municipalities in how
these outcomes were achieved, however. One municipality, João
Monlevade, combined direct participation with a range of planning and
coordination functions. Another, Gravataí, fashioned a set of processes
that were very direct and required little mediation but that also made it

                                                                                                       273
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                     much more difficult to coordinate at higher levels. A third, Camaragibe,
                                     built a system that went beyond the budget to encompass administra-
                                     tion. Its participatory administration resulted in a highly complex
                                     institutional design that combined forums with a range of coordinating
                                     institutions. The Camaragibe model required a high degree of media-
                                     tion, in the form of powerful delegates who were often closer to the
                                     state than to their communities. These differences reflected pragmatic
                                     adaptations of participatory budgeting to local realities, in particular to
                                     local civic capacity.
                                        Participatory budgeting improved governance outcomes, but did it
                                     repair civil society failures? In three of the five cases studied, Baiocchi,
                                     Heller, and Silva find that changes in civil society–state relations
                                     brought about by participatory budgeting were in the direction of
                                     democratic deepening, with municipalities graduating from the status
                                     of simple representative democracies in which civil society had little
                                     power to communities with more deliberative systems. However, the
                                     introduction of participatory budgeting does not inevitably deepen
                                     democracy, as illustrated by one case (Mauá), in which an improve-
                                     ment in the mode of engagement came at the expense of civil society’s
                                     autonomy, and the political party actually exercised more control over
                                     civic actors. Overall, institutional reform mattered mostly for chang-
                                     ing the institutional setting—for creating more meaningful points of
       . . . it did not inevitably   interface between the local state and civil society. Institutional reform
  deepen democracy, however.         did not have much of an impact on the self-organization of civil society.


                                     Summary
                                     What the evidence from all these regions shows is that context—the
                                     degree of capacity of civic groups, their relationship with the state, the
                                     responsiveness of the state, and the quality of facilitation and implemen-
                                     tation—affects the impact of deliberative processes. Geography matters,
                                     as does history, the literacy levels of the population, culture (especially
                                     the culture of deliberation), and the level of social and economic equal-
                                     ity. It is possible to build deliberative capacity and to use that capacity
  Context—the capacity of civic      to repair civil society failures in some contexts—but it does not happen
 groups, the responsiveness of       quickly; doing so requires long-term and sustained engagement. There
   the state, and the quality of     may be some role for interventions that focus on communications
facilitation—affects the impact      media, but questions remain as to how long-lasting such effects will
      of deliberative processes.     be. The quality of facilitation matters, but facilitators may also lead

274
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



discussions that reflect their own preferences rather than the preferences
of citizens. Most important, the degree to which the state is responsive
to deliberative innovations makes a great deal of difference.



Conclusions
Collective civic action has two broad aspects. The first is cohesion—the
ability of a community to coordinate and to manage its own affairs
on matters that are relatively independent of states and markets. The
second is the ability of a community to represent its collective interests
to the agents of the state and persuade the state to be more responsive
to its needs.
   Can projects that attempt to induce participation and build “social        Whether projects that attempt
capital” help repair civil society failures? The evidence on this important   to induce participation and
question is weak, for several reasons.                                        build “social capital” can help
   First, there is a problem of attribution. Because much of what             repair civil society failures
induced participation does is get facilitators to work with communities,      remains unclear.
an important question is whether it is the facilitators who are causing
the impact or the community’s experience with managing collective             Facilitators strongly influence
activity. The few studies that have tried to measure facilitator effects      the preferences community
find that facilitators strongly influence stated preferences. Participation     members state.
also tends to be driven by project-related incentives—people get
together to derive benefits from project funds. It is very difficult
to know whether these effects will last beyond the tenure of the proj-
ect, although the limited evidence on this issue indicates that it
may not.
   Respondents also tend to repeat project slogans in their responses,        Community members repeat
in the belief that this is what outsiders want to hear. As a result, simple   project slogans in their
survey questions on complex concepts like “trust” and “ability to coop-       responses, in the belief that
erate” often tend to elicit answers that are more reflective of rhetoric       outsiders want to hear them.
than reality.
   Keeping these important caveats in mind, there is some evidence,
mainly from self-reports of participants, indicating a higher incidence of    Absent affirmative action,
trust and cooperative activity in treatment than in control areas. Group      groups that form under the
formation, however, tends to be both parochial and unequal. Absent            aegis of interventions tend to
some kind of affirmative action program, groups that form under the            exclude disadvantaged groups
aegis of interventions tend to systematically exclude disadvantaged and       and women, sometimes
minority groups and women. Moreover, similar types of people tend to          reinforcing existing divisions.

                                                                                                         275
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                  form groups with one another. As a result, projects rarely promote cross-
                                  group cohesion and may even reinforce existing divisions.
Evidence from Africa seems to        Participatory interventions are often also seen as a valuable tool in
suggest that people emerging      postconflict settings, where the need to get funds on the ground quickly
     from civic conflict have a    is great. The limited evidence on the effectiveness of such projects in
  strong desire to participate.   postconflict areas suggests that context matters a great deal, as does the
          A well-designed and     quality of the intervention. Projects tend to have very limited impact on
   implemented project could      building social cohesion or rebuilding the state. They tend to exclude
   draw on this inherent need.    the poor and be dominated by elites. However, evidence from Africa
                                  seems to suggest that people emerging from civic conflict have a strong
                                  desire to participate. A well-designed and implemented project could
                                  effectively draw on this inherent need.
  Quotas for women and other         Repairing civic failures requires reducing social inequalities. One
      disadvantaged groups in     way of doing so is to mandate the inclusion of disadvantaged groups in
 decision-making bodies must      the participatory process. Evaluations of community-driven develop-
  remain in place long enough     ment projects provide virtually no evidence on this important question.
    to change perceptions and     However, a growing body of evidence from village democracies in India
                 social norms.    indicates broadly positive impacts. Quotas in village councils and presi-
                                  dencies for disadvantaged groups and women tend to change political
                                  incentives in favor of the interests of the group favored by the quota.
                                  Mandated inclusion also appears to provide an incubator for new politi-
                                  cal leadership while changing the incentives for clientelism. Evidence
                                  indicates that women and other excluded groups are more likely to stand
                                  for office for nonmandated seats once they have had some experience
                                  in a mandated seat. Quotas can also weaken prevailing stereotypes that
                                  attribute low ability and poor performance to traditionally excluded
                                  groups. However, lasting change requires that the inclusion mandates
                                  remain in place long enough to change perceptions and social norms.
                                     Do deliberative forums help improve voice? Forums in which citizens
                                  gather to make direct representations to civic authorities or are empow-
                                  ered to make decisions that have a direct bearing on their lives seem to
                                  work when they have teeth. In particular, when the central and local
                                  governments recognize the legitimacy of deliberative forums and are
                                  responsive to them, they can transform the nature of civil society and
                                  state interactions. The ability of citizens to engage in public discus-
                                  sions on policy questions is strongly related to literacy: deliberation is
                                  far more effective in literate settings. However, even in poor, unequal
  Deliberative forums seem to     settings, there is evidence that deliberation may have intrinsic value by
   work when they have teeth.     promoting dignity and giving voice to the disadvantaged. Perhaps the

276
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



most consistent finding is that deliberative forums are more effective               Deliberative forums are more
where they are an integral part of the policy-making process and where              effective where they are an
higher-tier governments are committed to ensuring greater citizen                   integral part of the policy-
participation.                                                                      making process and where
                                                                                    higher-tier governments are
                                                                                    committed to ensuring greater
Notes                                                                               citizen participation.

 1. The community reconstruction project was randomly implemented in 42
    of 83 eligible communities (program villages were selected through a public
    lottery). The project aimed to improve the material well-being of resident
    households, reinforce democratic political attitudes, and increase social
    cohesion. To assess the impact of the program, the authors used survey
    data collected at baseline and follow-up as well as a study on behavioral
    outcomes. The survey data included the usual range of socioeconomic
    welfare measures as well as measures of social cohesion and trust.
 2. The public goods game assessed the amount of funding a community
    could raise for a collective project. Each player started out with an “endow-
    ment” provided by the game implementer. Players were then offered an
    opportunity to invest their endowment in a common pool. Money added
    to the common pool was multiplied—typically doubled or tripled—by the
    game implementer and divided equally among all players, irrespective of
    individual contributions, which remained anonymous. If all players coop-
    erate fully (that is, contribute the entire endowment), the common pool
    is maximized and each player gets a multiple of his or her initial endow-
    ment. With anonymous contributions, each player faces the temptation
    to free-ride on the contributions of others.
 3. Village pairs were randomly allocated to treatment and control groups.
 4. Because project resources were spent largely on local public goods that
    were under construction at the time of the survey, the welfare effects were
    not assessed.
 5. The village development committees (VDCs) set up by the project were
    required to channel their village development plans through ward develop-
    ment committees (WDCs), which forwarded them to the district council
    for final approval.
 6. The authors use matching techniques and national survey data collected
    before program implementation to select comparison communities. The
    social capital measures were obtained through qualitative work in the
    sample villages, following program implementation.
 7. The comparison group is obtained by exploiting a pipeline setting. The
    program was introduced in phases. The second phase (Rural Poverty
    Reduction project [RPRP]) started three years after the first phrase (DPIP)
    and was introduced in different districts. At the time of the survey, DPIP
    had been available to survey villages for about three years and RPRP was
    just starting. A potential concern with the pipeline strategy is geographical
    variation across treatment and control areas. The study does not test for

                                                                                                             277
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                parallel trends. Instead, it uses propensity score matching on observables
                                over an area of common support at the village and household level.
                           8.   The authors identify three subgroups of interest: people who joined new
                                groups under the program (new participants), people who already partici-
                                pated in a self-help group before the program started but converted into
                                a program group subsequently (converted participants), and people who
                                did not join the program (nonparticipants). To control for household self-
                                selection into a program’s self-help group, they form control groups using
                                households that were potentially new, converted, and nonparticipants in
                                the control districts based on their participation status three years after
                                the program became available.
                           9.   The author attempts to deal with selection into DPIP by using a quasi-
                                experimental evaluation design that exploits state borders as an exogenous
                                source of variation in treatment assignment. The strategy involves select-
                                ing only treatment villages in Madhya Pradesh that are close to its border
                                with Uttar Pradesh and then “pairing” each village with its neighbor in
                                Uttar Pradesh, which did not have the option of being a DPIP village
                                but is assumed to be similar to the treated village in all other respects.
                                She uses a similar strategy for control villages, selected from villages in
                                Madhya Pradesh that were also on the border but did not get DPIP,
                                yielding “control pairs.” This identification strategy rests on two crucial
                                untested assumptions, namely, that (a) the treatment and control villages
                                in Madhya Pradesh had the same baseline levels for the relevant response
                                variables as the ”paired” village in Uttar Pradesh and (b) any difference
                                in the relevant baseline outcomes in Madhya Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh
                                was the same in the control and treatment pairs. Only under these condi-
                                tions could this approach reveal the treatment effect of DPIP. There is
                                no prima facie reason to expect this set of assumptions to hold, and the
                                author provides no evidence in support of them, other than a comparison
                                based on village population, caste composition, and gender ratio before
                                the program. It is unclear why these variables are the relevant ones for the
                                outcomes of interest.
                          10.   The IAT is an experimental method used in social psychology. It relies
                                on the idea that respondents who more easily pair two concepts in a rapid
                                categorization task associate those concepts more strongly. The taste IAT
                                is a computer-based double-categorization task that examines the strength
                                of respondents’ association between images of (anonymous) male and
                                female leaders and normative categories of good and bad. To measure
                                gender occupation stereotypes, the authors use an IAT that examines the
                                strength of association between male and female names on the one hand
                                and leadership and domestic tasks on the other.
                          11.   Scheduled Castes and Scheduled Tribes (SCs and STs) are groups mandated
                                by Indian federal constitutional guarantees for affirmative action because
                                of their former status as “untouchables.” OBCs (Other Backward Classes)
                                are castes listed by state governments in India as deserving of affirmative
                                action because of a history of poverty or discrimination.
                          12.   The study used propensity score matching to identify control villages that
                                did not receive project funds. It used an instrumental variable approach
                                to evaluate the effects of the program in treatment villages.
278
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



13. The authors acknowledge that they cannot rule out the possibility that
    omitted variable bias is playing some role—that is, that the types of people
    victimized tended to be the people who would have become postwar local
    leaders anyway. However, there is no strong evidence that more educated
    people or community leaders were targeted. Additional tests—demon-
    strating robustness in the youth subsample and in chiefdoms without
    permanent bases, where conflict-related violence victimization is likely to
    be more indiscriminate or random—argue against the hypothesis that the
    systematic targeting of community leaders is driving the results.



References
Ackerman, J. 2004. “Co-Governance for Accountability: Beyond ‘Exit’ and
    ‘Voice’.” World Development 32(3): 447–63.
Agarwal, B. 2001. “Participatory Exclusions, Community Forestry, and
    Gender: An Analysis for South Asia and a Conceptual Framework.” World
    Development 29(10): 1623–48.
Arcand, J.-L., L. Bassole, G. Rota-Graziosi, and J. P. Tranchant. 2008. “The
    Making of a (Vice) President: Party Politics, Ethnicity, Village Loyalty
    and Community-Driven Development.” CERDI Working Paper 200633,
    Centre d’Etudes et de Recherches sur le Développement International,
    Clermont-Ferrand, France.
Arcand, J.-L., and M. Fafchamps. 2012. “Matching in Community-Based
    Organizations.” Journal of Development Economics 98(2): 203–19.
Baiocchi, G., P. Heller, and M. Silva. 2011. Bootstrapping Democracy:
    Transforming Local Governance and Civil Society in Brazil. Stanford, CA:
    Stanford University Press.
Ban, R., S. Jha, and V. Rao. 2012. “Who Has Voice in a Deliberative
    Democracy: Evidence from Transcripts of Village Parliaments in South
    Asia.” Journal of Development Economics 99(2): 428–38.
Ban, R., and V. Rao. 2009. “Is Deliberation Equitable: Evidence from
    Transcripts of Village Meetings in India.” Policy Research Working Paper
    4928, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2012. Political Clientelism and Capture:
    Theory and Evidence from West Bengal. Working Paper, Department of
    Economics, University of California, Berkeley.
Bardhan, P. K., D. Mookherjee, and M. P. Torrado. 2010. “Impact of Political
    Reservations in West Bengal Local Governments on Anti-Poverty
    Targeting.” Journal of Globalization and Development 1(1): 1–34.
Barron, P., M. Woolcock, and R. Diprose. 2011. Contesting Development:
    Participatory Projects and Local Conflict Dynamics in Indonesia. New
    Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Beaman, L., R. Chattopadhyay, E. Duflo, R. Pande, and P. Topalova. 2009.
    “Powerful Women: Does Exposure Reduce Bias?” Quarterly Journal of
    Economics 124(4): 1497–540.
Beaman, L., E. Duflo, R. Pande, and P. Topalova. 2012. “Female Leadership
    Raises Aspirations and Educational Attainment for Girls: A Policy
    Experiment in India.” Science 335(6068): 582–86.                                             279
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Beath, A., F. Christia, and R. Enikolopev. 2011. Elite Capture of Local
                               Institutions: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Afghanistan. Working
                               Paper, Department of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge,
                               MA.
                          Bellows, J., and E. Miguel. 2006. “War and Institutions: New Evidence from
                               Sierra Leone.” American Economic Review 96(2): 394–99.
                          Besley, T., R. Pande, L. Rahman, and V. Rao. 2004. “The Politics of Public
                               Good Provision: Evidence from Indian Local Governments.” Journal of
                               the European Economics Association 2(2–3): 416–26.
                          Besley, T., R. Pande, and V. Rao. 2005. “Participatory Democracy in Action:
                               Survey Evidence from Rural India.” Journal of the European Economic
                               Association 3(2–3): 648–57.
                          Bhavnani, R. R. 2009. “Do Electoral Quotas Work after They Are Withdrawn?
                               Evidence from a Natural Experiment in India.” American Political Science
                               Review 103(1): 23–35.
                          Cabannes, Y. 2004. “Participatory Budgeting: A Significant Contribution to
                               Participatory Democracy.” Environment and Urbanization 16(1): 27–46.
                          Casey, K., R. Glennerster, and E. Miguel. 2011. “Reshaping Institutions:
                               “Evidence on Aid Impacts Using a Pre-Analysis Plan.” Abdul Latif Jameel
                               Poverty Action Lab Working Paper, MIT, Cambridge, MA.
                          Camacho, A., and E. Conover. 2011. “Manipulation of Social Program
                               Eligibility.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 3(2): 41–65.
                          Chase, R. S., R. N. Christensen, and M. Thongyou. 2006. Picking Winners or
                               Making Them? Evaluating the Social Capital Impact of CDD in Thailand.
                               World Bank, Social Development Department, Washington, DC.
                          Chattopadhyay, R., and E. Duflo. 2004a. “The Impact of Reservation in the
                               Panchayati Raj: Evidence from a Nationwide Randomized Experiment.”
                               Economic and Political Weekly 39(9): 979–86.
                          ———. 2004b. “Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized
                               Policy Experiment in India.” Econometrica 72(5): 1409–33.
                          Chin, A., and N. Prakash. 2010. “The Redistributive Effects of Political
                               Reservation for Minorities: Evidence from India.” NBER Working Paper
                               16509, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
                          Cliffe, S., S. Guggenheim, and M. Kostner. 2003. “Community-Driven
                               Reconstruction as an Instrument in War-to-Peace Transitions.”
                               Conflict Prevention and Reconstruction Working Paper 7, World Bank,
                               Washington, DC.
                          Deininger, K., and Y. Liu. 2008. “Economic and Social Impacts of Self-Help
                               Groups in India.” World Bank, Development Economics Research
                               Group, Washington, DC.
                          Duflo, E., and P. Topalova. 2004. “Unappreciated Service: Performance,
                               Perceptions, and Women Leaders in India.” Working Paper, Department
                               of Economics, MIT, Cambridge, MA.
                          Dunning, T., and J. Nilekani. 2010. “When Formal Institutions Are Not
                               Enough: Caste, Party Politics, and Distribution in Indian Village
                               Councils.” Working Paper, Department of Political Science, Yale
                               University, New Haven, CT.


280
DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY?



Evans, P. 2004. “Development as Institutional Change: The Pitfalls of
    Monocropping and the Potentials of Deliberation.” Studies in Comparative
    International Development 38(4): 30–52.
Fearon, J. D., M. Humphreys, and J. M. Weinstein. 2009. “Can Development
    Aid Contribute to Social Cohesion after Civil War? Evidence from a Field
    Experiment in Post-Conflict Liberia.” American Economic Review 99(2):
    287–91.
Fung, A., and E. O. Wright. 2003. “Thinking about Empowered Participatory
    Governance.” In Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in
    Empowered Participatory Governance, ed. A. Fung, and E. O. Wright,
    3–42. New York: Verso.
Galasso, E., and M. Ravallion. 2005. “Decentralized Targeting of an
    Antipoverty Program.” Journal of Public Economics 89(4): 705–27.
Heller, P., K. N. Harilal, and S. Chaudhuri. 2007. “Building Local Democracy:
    Evaluating the Impact of Decentralization in Kerala, India.” World
    Development 35(4): 626–48.
Houtzager, P., A. Acharya, and A. J. Lavalle. 2007. “Associations and the
    Exercise of Citizenship in New Democracies: Evidence from São Paulo
    and Mexico City.” IDS Working Paper 285, Institute of Development
    Studies, Brighton, United Kingdom.
Humphreys, M., W. A. Masters, and M. E. Sandbu. 2006. “The Role of
    Leaders in Democratic Deliberations: Results from a Field Experiment
    in São Tomé and Príncipe.” World Politics 58(4): 583–622.
Kumar, N. R. 2007. Pro-Poor Targeting and Participatory Governance: Evidence
    from Central India. Institute for Economic Development Working Paper,
    Department of Economics, Boston University, Boston, MA.
Labonne, J., and R. S. Chase. 2008. Do Community-Driven Development
    Projects Enhance Social Capital? Evidence from the Philippines. Policy
    Research Working Paper, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Leino, J. 2007. “Ladies First? Gender and the Community Management
    of Water Infrastructure in Kenya.” Working Paper, Department of
    Economics, University of California, Berkeley.
Mansbridge, J. 1999. “Everyday Talk in the Deliberative System.” In Essays in
    Democracy and Disagreement, ed. S. Macedo, 211–42. New York: Oxford
    University Press.
Mansuri, G. 2012. “Harnessing Community: Assortative Matching in
    Participatory Community Organizations.” Poverty Reduction and Equity
    Group, World Bank, Washington DC.
Munshi, K., and M. Rosenzweig. 2009. “The Efficacy of Parochial Politics:
    Caste, Commitment, and Competence in Indian Local Governments.”
    NBER Working Paper 14335, National Bureau of Economic Research,
    Cambridge, MA.
Olken, B. 2006. “Corruption and the Costs of Redistribution: Micro Evidence
    from Indonesia.” Journal of Public Economics 90(4–5): 853–70.
———. 2010. “Direct Democracy and Local Public Goods: Evidence from a
    Field Experiment in Indonesia.” American Political Science Review 104(2):
    243–67.


                                                                                               281
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          Palaniswamy, N., and N. Krishnan. 2008. “Local Politics, Political Institutions
                              and Public Resource Allocation.” IFPRI Discussion Paper, International
                              Food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC.
                          Paluck, E. L. 2010. “Is It Better Not to Talk? Group Polarization, Extended
                              Contact, and Perspective Taking in Eastern Democratic Republic of
                              Congo.” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 36(9): 1170–85.
                          Paluck, E. L., and D. P. Green. 2009. “Deference, Dissent, and Dispute
                              Resolution: An Experimental Intervention Using Mass Media to Change
                              Norms and Behavior in Rwanda.” American Political Science Review
                              103(4): 622–44.
                          Pearce, J. 2007. “Violence, Power and Participation: Building Citizenship
                              in Contexts of Chronic Violence.” IDS Working Paper 274, Institute of
                              Development Studies, Brighton, United Kingdom.
                          Rao, V., and P. Sanyal. 2010. “Dignity Through Discourse: Poverty and the
                              Culture of Deliberation in Indian Village Democracies.” Annals of the
                              American Academy of Political and Social Science 629(May): 146–72.
                          Schneider, A., and M. Baquero. 2006. “Get What You Want, Give What You
                              Can: Embedded Public Finance in Porto Alegre.” IDS Working Paper 22,
                              Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, United Kingdom.
                          Schneider, A., and B. Goldfrank. 2002. “Budgets and Ballots in Brazil:
                              Participatory Budgeting from the City to the State.” IDS Working Paper
                              149, Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, United Kingdom.
                          Serageldin, M., J. Driscoll, L. M. S. Miguel, L. Valenzuela, C. Bravo,
                              E. Solloso, C. Sola-Morales, and T. Watkin. 2003. “Assessment of
                              Participatory Budgeting in Brazil.” Paper prepared for the Inter-American
                              Development Bank, Washington, DC.
                          Souza, C. 2001. “Participatory Budgeting in Brazilian Cities: Limits and
                              Possibilities in Building Democratic Institutions.” Environment and
                              Urbanization 13(1): 159–84.
                          Strand, A., H. Toje, A. M. Jerve, and I. Samset. 2003. “Community-Driven
                              Development in Contexts of Conflict.” Case Study, Chr. Michelsen
                              Institute, Bergen, Norway.
                          Swidler, A. 1986. “Culture in Action: Symbols and Strategies.” American
                              Sociological Review 51(2): 273–86.
                          Swidler, A., and S. Watkins. 2011. “Practices of Deliberation in Rural Malawi.”
                              Paper presented at the conference “Deliberation and Development: New
                              Directions,” World Bank, Washington, DC, November.
                          Wampler, B. 2004. “Expanding Accountability through Participatory
                              Institutions: Mayors, Citizens, and Budgeting in Three Brazilian
                              Municipalities.” Latin American Politics and Society 46(2): 73–99.
                          World Bank. 2011. World Development Report 2011: Conflict, Security, and
                              Development. Washington, DC: World Bank.
                          Zamboni, Y. 2007. “Participatory Budgeting and Local Governance: An
                              Evidence-Based Evaluation of Participatory Budgeting Experiences in
                              Brazil.” University of Bristol, United Kingdom.




282
CHAPTER SEVEN




Conclusion:
How Can Participatory
Interventions Be Improved?
DEVELOPMENT IS MORE THAN A TECHNICAL UNDERTAKING THAT
can be handled by experts. It is a complex and often contentious process
that works better when citizens participate in decisions that shape their
lives and allows them to monitor the people whose task it is to govern
their destinies. Consequently, it may make sense to engage citizens
in the process of development and to induce communities to act col-
lectively to make governments more accountable. Involving citizens in
decision making may also have intrinsic value, because training them
in the everyday business of democratic governance may enhance their
dignity and promote their quest for freedom. As recent popular move-
ments have demonstrated, these values have wide resonance.
    The value of participation is clear. What is far less clear is whether   The value of participation is
participation can be induced through the type of large-scale govern-         clear . . .
ment and donor-funded participatory programs that have become a
                                                                             . . . less clear is whether it can
leitmotif of development policy. This question is at the heart of this
                                                                             be induced through the kind
report.
                                                                             of programs that have become
    This report does not emphasize more organic forms of participa-
                                                                             a leitmotif of development
tion, in the form of trade unions, civic watchdog groups, producer and
                                                                             policy.
consumer cooperatives, or activist groups of various types. Such engage-
ment has tremendous capacity to initiate positive change. Indeed, it
has been a driving force in many societal transformations throughout
history, including the anticolonial and civil rights movements of the last
century, the growing environmental movements, and the many ongoing
movements for political and human rights, including recent popular
democracy movements in the Middle East.1
    In practice, organic and induced forms of participation are often
linked. Large-scale induced projects may scale up organic initia-
tives or develop in conjunction with organic activism. An initial
                                                                                                          283
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          outside stimulus may spur the growth of more organic institutions or
                          movements.
                              From the perspective of development policy, however, it is induced
                          participation that is being fostered, and it is on this that much hope has
                          been pinned and tremendous resources expended. Moreover, there is
                          a particular challenge at the heart of attempts to induce participation.
                          It is to harness the spirit of organic participation—which is driven by
                          motivated agents, is contextually sensitive and long-term, and is con-
                          stantly innovating in response to local realities—and to turn it into a
                          large, state-driven, bureaucratically led enterprise. It is this challenge
                          that is the focus of our report.
                              This report examines two major modalities for inducing local partici-
                          pation: community development and the decentralization of resources
                          and authority to local governments. Community development supports
                          efforts to bring villages, urban neighborhoods, or other groupings of
                          people into the process of managing development resources through a
                          project-based approach. Advocates for community development believe
                          that it enhances the capacity for collective action, builds community
                          cohesion or “social capital,” and strengthens the ability of the poor and
                          disenfranchised to obtain better public services from providers and
                          greater responsiveness from governments. The most common justifica-
                          tion for community-based development is that it empowers the power-
                          less by increasing “voice.”
                              Community development projects are sometimes implemented
                          through formally constituted local governments, but often they oper-
                          ate quite independently, and in some cases, such as in postconfl ict
                          environments, they effectively substitute for formal decentralization.
                          Community development projects have been variously labeled as
                          “social funds,” “community-based development,” and “community-
                          driven development”—all terms coined within the World Bank over
                          the past two decades. Within each of these categories, project designs
                          can range from community-based targeting, in which only the selec-
                          tion of beneficiaries is decentralized, to projects in which communities
                          are involved in all aspects, from design to implementation and resource
                          management.
                              In recent years, as the effort to expand community engagement
                          in service delivery has increased, participatory education and health
                          projects have become more common. These projects have many of
                          the same features as more traditional community-based development
                          or community-driven development projects, which usually focus on
284
CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED?



infrastructure, skills training, private transfers, and credit, in addition
to “community mobilization.” Most recently, such projects have also
morphed into community livelihood projects, which, as their name
suggests, focus greater attention on expanding opportunities for sustain-
able livelihoods for the poor through the promotion of participatory
mechanisms for expanding access to markets, investing in communal
assets, and building market linkages.
    Decentralization refers to efforts to strengthen village and municipal
governments on both the demand and supply sides. On the demand
side, decentralization strengthens citizens’ participation in local govern-
ment by, for example, instituting regular elections, improving access to
information, and fostering mechanisms for deliberative decision mak-
ing. On the supply side, decentralization aims to enhance the ability
of local governments to provide services by increasing their financial
resources, strengthening the capacity of local officials and streamlining
and rationalizing their administrative functions. As this report is about
participatory development, the decentralization evidence focuses on the
demand side.2
    This report builds a conceptual framework for thinking about when         Markets and governments
and how to induce participation that is structured around the idea of         are now widely recognized as
“civil society failure.” Markets and governments are now widely recog-        subject to failure . . .
nized as subject to failure. Yet the policy literature, particularly at the
local level, is rife with solutions to market and government failures that    . . . but civic groups are often
assume that groups of people (village communities, urban neighbor-            (erroneously) assumed to
hood associations, school councils, water user groups) will always work       always work toward a common
toward a common interest. Rarely is much thought explicitly given to          interest.
the possibility of civil society failure—the possibility that communities,
however constituted, may also face significant problems of coordination,
asymmetric information, and inequality, which may limit their ability
to respond to and resolve market and government failures.3
    Development policy related to participatory processes needs to be
informed by a thoughtful diagnosis of potential civil society failure and
its interaction with market and government failures. Such an analysis
is necessary for developing a clearer understanding of the tradeoffs
involved in moving decisions to local communities, in each context. It
is also necessary for identifying the avenues that any given project or
policy provides to rectify or repair specific civil society failures.
    The report reviews more than 500 empirical studies of participatory
development interventions to address issues of central interest to policy
makers. These issues include the following:
                                                                                                          285
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?




                                   •   The viability of using participatory poverty reduction projects
                                       as a vehicle for improving important development outcomes,
                                       such as service delivery, livelihoods, infrastructure quality, or the
                                       management of common pool resources
                                   •   The potential for induced participatory projects to increase gov-
                                       ernment accountability and reduce capture and corruption
                                   •   The efficacy of participatory projects versus programs imple-
                                       mented in parallel by local governments
                                   •   The feasibility of sustaining positive outcomes when projects go
                                       to scale
                                   •   Whether induced participation can create durable improvements
                                       in social cohesion, citizenship, “voice,” or the capacity for collec-
                                       tive action.
                                     A growing body of literature allows for a better understanding of
                                 some of these questions. This newer literature, as well as a large body
                                 of case studies, was used to build an evidence base for these questions.
                                 In doing so, the report cast a relatively wide net, using well-executed
                                 studies by economists, sociologists, political scientists, and anthropolo-
                                 gists. The report, does not, however, make any attempt to be exhaustive,
                                 particularly for the case study evidence.
                                     On several important issues, the literature is thin. For these issues,
                                 the report relied on the few (often one or two) carefully executed stud-
                                 ies that were available. Greater weight was placed on studies that had
                                 a valid comparison group. Without an adequate comparison group, it
                                 is difficult to attribute observed changes in beneficiary communities to
                                 the specific program or intervention being assessed. The wider process
                                 of development can alter outcomes over time through processes that
                                 operate independently of the intervention.
                                     Generally speaking, the report’s findings derive from econometric
                                 analysis. Ideally, this econometric work should be complemented by
                                 good qualitative work, which can help to illuminate the processes that
                                 resulted in the observed impact. There is an unfortunate dearth of such
                                 work.
                                     Three lessons, drawn from the evidence, appear to be abundantly clear:

                                   •   Context, both local and national, is extremely important. Out-
      Context, both local and          comes from interventions are highly variable across communi-
        national, is extremely         ties. History; geography; and the nature of social interactions,
                    important.         networks, and political systems all have a strong influence. As a

286
CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED?



      result, a successful project designed for one context may fail mis-
      erably in another. Strong built-in systems of learning and moni-
      toring, sensitivity to context, and the willingness and ability to
      adapt are therefore critical in implementing projects. As some of
      the evidence shows, carefully designed projects, whether they are
      implemented by governments or by donor-funded implementing
      agencies, are able to limit the negative impact of “bad” commu-
      nity characteristics, at least to a degree.
  •   The idea that all communities have a stock of “social capital”        The idea that all communities
      that can be readily harnessed is naive in the extreme. Building       have a stock of “social
      citizenship, engaging communities in monitoring service provid-       capital” that can be readily
      ers and governments, and supporting community-based man-              harnessed is naive in the
      agement of natural resources or management of infrastructure          extreme.
      requires a serious and sustained engagement in building local
      capacity.
  •   Both theory and evidence indicate that induced participatory          Induced participatory
      interventions work best when they are supported by a responsive       development appears to
      state. Although local actors may have an informational and loca-      increase, rather than diminish,
      tional advantage, they appear to use it to benefit the disadvan-       the need for functional
      taged only where institutions and mechanisms to ensure local          and strong institutions at
      accountability are robust. In fact, local oversight is most effec-    the center.
      tive when higher-level institutions of accountability function
      well and communities have the capacity to effectively monitor
      service providers and others in charge or public resources. Thus,
      induced participatory development appears to increase, rather
      than diminish, the need for functional and strong institutions
      at the center. It also implies that project implementing agencies
      for donor-funded projects need to have the capacity to exercise
      adequate oversight. However, there is little evidence that donors
      alone can substitute for a nonfunctional state as a higher-level
      accountability agent. When funds are parachuted into com-
      munities without any monitoring by a supportive state, decision
      making is captured by elites who control the local cooperative
      infrastructure, leading to a high risk of corruption. Reforms that
      enhance judicial oversight, allow for independent audit agencies,
      and protect and promote the right to information and a free
      media appear to be necessary for effective local participation.
   These findings are consistent with the large body of case study
evidence that Fox (1993) describes as a “sandwich movement” of

                                                                                                       287
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



            To effectively induce   enlightened state action from above interacting with social mobiliza-
      participation, enlightened    tion from below.4 The state does not necessarily have to be democratic
        state action from above     (although democratic states are more likely to support development).
      has to interact with social   However, in the sphere in which the intervention is conducted—at
       mobilization from below.     the level of the community or the neighborhood—the state has to be
                                    responsive to community demands. For example, schools that incorpo-
    In the local sphere, within     rate parents into decision making will be more responsive to parental
      which the intervention is     demands if parents have a measure of control over school budgets.
 conducted, the center has to       Village governments will become more responsive to the needs of citi-
   ensure that local agents of      zens when both function within an electoral democracy supplemented
   the state are responsive to      by deliberative interactions.
         community demands.

                                    The Importance of Context
  Inducing local participation      Inducing local participation is a difficult, often unpredictable, and
           is a difficult, often     potentially contentious undertaking. The empirical evidence presented
unpredictable, and potentially      in this report must be viewed with this fact in mind. The heterogene-
    contentious undertaking.        ity in outcomes should not be surprising once the role played by local
                                    conditions and the precise contours of project design are understood.
                                    Given the increased (and sensible) emphasis on civic engagement for
                                    effective and equitable development, it is important to build a body of
                                    solid evidence on the effectiveness of specific modalities for inducing
                                    participation and to assess the cost-effectiveness of such efforts.
                                       In view of the substantial reliance on evidence from quantitative
                                    evaluations of community-driven development projects and decentral-
                                    ization efforts, it is also important to reiterate that an effective evalu-
                                    ation must proceed with some understanding of a project’s trajectory
                                    and the timeline over which an impact on specific project outcomes is
                                    likely to be observed. Predicting a trajectory of change is hard to do in
                                    participatory projects. Very few evaluations take this issue seriously or
                                    verify assumptions about long-term impacts by returning to the site of
                                    the project after a few years have passed. Moreover, some outcomes may
                                    be inherently difficult to measure. Most evaluations, for example, are
                                    likely to miss subtle shifts in perceptions or beliefs that could mature
                                    years later into effective civic activism or a more inclusive society.
                                       Local development policy occurs at the intersection of market, gov-
                                    ernment, and civil society failures; interactions are deeply conditioned
                                    by culture, politics, and social structure, and they vary from place to

288
CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED?



place. Context matters, at both the national and the local level (for more
on context, see Goodin and Tilly 2006). At the national level, nation-
alist ideologies—the manner in which the (colonial and postcolonial)
state has created and propagated identity—can create symbolic public
goods that facilitate collective action by building a participatory ethic.
   History matters. The way policies and institutions—land reforms,           History matters.
education systems, the judiciary, the media, and efforts at social inclu-
sion—have evolved can influence the responsiveness of governments to
civic mobilization, affecting the incentives for collective action. A his-
tory of organic participation matters greatly, for several reasons. Some
countries have a long history of civic participation, developed in the
process of struggles for independence from colonial rule or against the
rule of entrenched elites. Such social movements help give legitimacy to
civic activists and create a culture that facilitates civic mobilization. A
history of organic participation creates a community of peer educators,
who can train others on how to reach a consensus, engage in partici-
patory planning, and hold governments accountable for their actions.
In time, organic participation can make it easier to institute a cadre
of trained facilitators who can spearhead scaled-up community-based
interventions. A history of organic participation also creates an enabling
environment within which social entrepreneurs can spark participatory
innovations, the most effective of which can have important lessons for
scaled-up induced interventions.
   The social, economic, demographic, and cultural contexts mat-              The social, economic,
ter. The nature and extent of social and economic inequality and the          demographic, and cultural
composition and diversity of groups affect both induced and organic           contexts matter.
participation. Inequality and heterogeneity strongly affect the cultures
and norms of cooperation that evolve within a community. These
norms have a bearing not only on the nature of collective action but
also on the role of local leaders. Do local leaders act in ways that sup-
port or undermine the larger interests of the community they claim to
represent? Do they maximize rents, or do they lead with the collective
welfare of the community in mind?
   Geography matters. Remoteness from more developed areas, difficult          Geography matters.
terrain, and harsh weather conditions can increase vulnerability, lead-
ing to weaker development outcomes. Both social heterogeneity and
geography have a bearing on the local cooperative infrastructure—the
community’s capacity for collective action. If a village has a long history
of successfully managing common property resources, that capacity

                                                                                                          289
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                   could potentially translate into a collaboration to manage a school, for
                                   example. Urban migrant communities can consist of people from the
                                   same region (who therefore retain rural norms and customs) or differ-
                                   ent places (which could make cooperative behavior more challenging).
              Politics matters.       Politics matters.5 The nature of the local state and its relationship
                                   with local communities deeply affects the extent to which the “nexus of
                                   accommodation” hampers development. As described in chapter 3, in
                                   contexts with compound market, government, and civil society failures,
                                   local and national political leaders, bureaucrats, and strongmen are
                                   often embedded within an extractive equilibrium in which the interests
                                   of citizens are given the lowest priority. Breaking this nexus—changing
                                   the equilibrium in a manner that makes the state more responsive to the
                                   needs of citizens—is at the heart of effective participatory development.



                                   Donors, Governments, and Trajectories of Change
                                   Effective civic engagement does not develop along a predictable trajec-
                                   tory. It is likely to proceed along a “punctuated equilibrium,” character-
                                   ized by long periods of seeming quietude followed by intense and often
                                   turbulent change. The “quiet” periods are not inactive. They are full
                                   of nascent, covert action, during which civic activists slowly begin to
                                   influence their neighbors to think differently, act collectively, deliber-
                                   ate effectively, and develop the courage to take on powerful interests.
                                   Without such risk-taking, the nexus of accommodation is hard to break.
    Donor-driven participatory        When donor-driven induced participatory projects attempt to build
     projects often ignore the     civic capacity, they assume a far less contentious trajectory. Conditioned
       fact that effective civic   by bureaucratic imperatives, they often declare that clear, measurable,
engagement does not develop        and usually wildly optimistic outcomes—including greater civic capac-
along a predictable trajectory.    ity—will be delivered within a specified timeframe. As most projects
                                   are sold as poverty reduction or local infrastructure projects, declared
                                   outcomes include declines in poverty and vulnerability, without much
                                   attention to the effort, resources, or time frame required to achieve a
                                   sustained increase in the incomes of the poor. Unrealistic expectations
                                   often set such projects up for failure.
 Changing social and political        One important reason behind this overly ambitious approach,
systems is far less predictable    especially at the World Bank, is that it maintains a path-dependent
  than building dams, bridges,     institutional structure that continues to derive from a focus on capital-
     roads, schools, or clinics.   intensive development and reconstruction. Building dams, bridges,

290
CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED?



roads, or even schools and clinics is a much more predictable activity
than changing social and political systems. Repairing civil society and
addressing political failures requires a shift in the social equilibrium
that derives from a change in the nature of social interactions and from
modifying norms and local cultures.
   These tasks are much harder to achieve than building infrastructure.       A fundamentally different
They require a fundamentally different approach to development—one           approach to development—one
that is flexible, long term, self-critical, and strongly infused with the     that is flexible, long term, self-
spirit of learning by doing. As demonstrated later in this chapter, the      critical, and strongly infused
World Bank falls far short of adopting this kind of approach in its          with the spirit of learning by
participatory projects. Other donors are probably not much different.        doing—is needed.


Open Research Questions
The evidence on many participation-related issues is thin. More
research is needed on several open questions.


What Is the Link between Local Civic Capacity
and a National Civic Sphere?
Under what conditions will attempts to build local civic capacity help
build a national civic sphere? This question goes at least as far back as
John Stuart Mill, who believed that good citizenship is built at the local
level. Many participatory interventions—particularly interventions
that attempt to transform the nature of citizenship by improving the
“demand side” of governance and “building trust” in postconflict situ-
ations—are premised on the belief that such interventions will lead to
a more accountable and cohesive civic culture at the national level. Very
little is known about whether these local interventions are effective,
however, or whether they can coalesce into national civic movements.
In fact, the evidence suggests that under some conditions, greater local
cohesiveness can actually exacerbate communal tensions.


How Important Is the State?
A related set of questions refers to the incentives faced by central
governments in devolving power to local communities. Under what
conditions can devolution be sustained over the long term instead of

                                                                                                          291
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                          being rolled back by central authorities? How does this possibility of
                          policy reversal affect the design and implementation of such programs?
                          If participatory projects require an effective central state, is participa-
                          tory development inappropriate in countries with weak states? How can
                          local development be promoted in communities in which the central
                          state is not effective?
                              The evidence overwhelmingly suggests that effective community-
                          based interventions have to be implemented in conjunction with a
                          responsive state. Yet almost all econometric studies of participatory
                          interventions focus on the communities themselves rather than the
                          context within which they operate.
                              More generally, research is needed on how to make the state, and its
                          agents, more responsive to communities. What is most important—
                          incentives, better monitoring, or training?
                              There is also a debate over whether donors can substitute for a non-
                          functional central government as a higher-level accountability agent.
                          It is possible that they may help in the short term (by improving the
                          performance of interventions) but be harmful in the long term (by
                          hampering the evolution of an effective state). This largely theoretical
                          debate should be complemented by better evidence.


                          How Important Is Democracy?
                          Credible elections within decentralized settings appear to provide a
                          clearer mechanism than informal deliberation for punishing unpopular
                          policy choices or excessive rent-seeking by incumbents. More research
                          should be conducted on the conditions under which elections work,
                          and—in particular—whether community-driven development projects
                          that induce greater accountability with elections and mandated inclu-
                          sion improve their effectiveness. Another important open question is
                          the extent to which a shift toward democracy at the local level affects
                          the allocation of resources, particularly if it shifts resources away from
                          traditional elites and toward the less powerful in society.


                          How Do Top-down and Bottom-up Approaches Compare?
                          The evidence is very limited on how top-down approaches compare with
                          bottom-up approaches in delivering goods and services to communities.
                          Most evaluations of participatory approaches typically compare the

292
CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED?



intervention with the status quo—a counterfactual in which nothing is
done. Such an approach says nothing about whether participatory inter-
ventions are better or worse than centrally administered interventions.


How Effective Are Local Interventions with “Soft Outcomes”?
Questions remain even about the efficacy of local interventions that seek
to achieve “soft outcomes.” Does participation build the capacity for
collective action? Is it empowering? Do citizenship training programs
work? Very few studies examine these questions, most of which do not
lend themselves to easy generalization. Moreover, the literature tends to
measure soft outcomes with responses to survey questions, which can be
unreliable in measuring impact. Greater use of framed field experiments
and behavioral games in conjunction with survey data could be beneficial.


What Is the Appropriate Role for Nongovernmental Organizations and
Facilitators?
Very little is known about the efficacy of the widespread practice of
hiring nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) to plan and implement
projects and provide services at the local level. Is doing so more efficient
than giving such authority directly to local governments or community
bodies?
   Facilitators are the lynchpins of induced participation, yet almost
nothing is known about their incentives, their training, or the social
and political constraints they face. Much more could be learned about
how to improve their performance and even the extent to which basic
factors such as experience, age, and gender affect performance.


How Should the Poor Be Targeted?
Too little evidence is available on whether targeting the poor with proxy
means testing or other centralized “objective” metrics of household
status is better or worse than community-based targeting.


How Important Is Corruption?
A few important studies of corruption have been conducted, and there
is an increasing, and healthy, trend toward relying more on direct

                                                                                    293
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                 measures of corruption (for example, engineering assessments of road
                                 quality) rather than perception-based measures. This kind of research
                                 should become the norm, as improving the demand side of governance
                                 is often claimed as a cure for corruption and perception-based measures
                                 tend to map poorly to measured levels of corruption and capture.


                                 How Well Have Livelihood Projects Worked?
                                 Livelihood projects and other attempts to use community-based inter-
                                 ventions to repair market failures, including community management
                                 of microcredit funds, remain largely unstudied. Very little is known
                                 about attempts to use community groups (artisans cooperatives, farm-
                                 ers cooperatives, and so forth) for income-generating activities. Some
                                 case study evidence exist on these issues, but little rigorous quantitative
                                 analysis has been conducted.


                                 What Makes Deliberation Effective?
                                 Another set of questions goes to the heart of the decision-making
                                 process within communities. What makes deliberation effective? Do
                                 facilitators contribute to the deliberative process? To what extent does
                                 deliberation influence the process of preference aggregation, building
                                 consensus among people with heterogeneous interests? How can the
                                 quality of deliberation be improved? Can deliberative spaces be made
                                 more effective and deliberative systems built?


                                 What Kind of Research Should Be Conducted?
                                 Most studies of large-scale participatory interventions ignore the pro-
                                 cesses that lead to an outcome (or the lack of one). Process is much bet-
                                 ter understood with the use of qualitative tools. Thus, more than most
                                 other development interventions, evaluations of participatory projects
                                 call for a mix of qualitative and quantitative methods—something that
                                 is almost never done well. A promising mode of enquiry is the use of
                                 qualitative data with research designs that are typically associated with
                                 quantitative studies—large samples, experimental designs, or the use of
  Very few well-done, in-depth   methods to generate credible counterfactuals such as matching.
ethnographies of participatory      Very few well-done, in-depth ethnographies of participatory projects
projects have been conducted.    have been conducted. Although some development anthropologists are

294
CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED?



beginning to do serious work in this area, much of the literature on the
anthropology of participatory development seems to rely on thin data (a
perfunctory reading of project literature, “touch the water buffalo” field
visits that last a week or two). Some of these studies have received wide
attention in the anthropological literature, but their appeal likely derives
from their ability to tap into preexisting prejudices about “neoliberal”
institutions rather than from the carefully grounded ethnographic
insights that characterize the best anthropological work.



Monitoring, Evaluation, and Attention to Context:
Results of a Survey of World Bank Projects
The variability in the local context and the uncertainty surrounding           To be effective, participatory
the trajectories of participatory development projects highlight the           development projects
importance of developing effective monitoring and evaluation (M&E)             require constant adjustment,
systems. To be effective, participatory development projects require           learning in the field, and
constant adjustment, learning in the field, and experimentation.                experimentation.
    A notable example of an effectively monitored induced commu-
nity development project is the $1.3 billion Kecamatan Development
Program (KDP) in Indonesia, which was active between 1998 and
2008. KDP provided block grants directly to rural community-based
organizations to fund development plans prepared through a participa-
tory process. In this regard, it was very similar to a large number of other
community-based projects. Where it differed was in the extent to which
it relied on context-specific design and attention to monitoring systems
(Guggenheim 2006).
    KDP’s design was based on two key elements: a careful analysis of
existing state and community capacity and cooperative infrastructure,
drawn from a set of studies of local institutions, and a deep under-
standing of the history of community development in Indonesia.
Implementation involved creating a tiered network of motivated and
trained facilitators, who created a feedback loop to facilitate learn-
ing and worked with engineers to supervise construction. Villagers
took control of expenditures and procured goods and services on a
competitive basis. They formed monitoring teams that checked the
delivery of material and the quality of construction, reporting their
findings to the village forum. In addition to participatory monitoring,
the project conducted audits at the subdistrict (kecamatan) level. In

                                                                                                          295
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                addition, independent NGOs and journalists were contracted to moni-
                                tor and report on the quality of the project on a random basis. These
                                innovations in monitoring were supplemented with more conventional
                                quantitative tools, such as a carefully designed management informa-
                                tion system (MIS), several qualitative and quantitative evaluations, and
                                case studies (Wong 2003). Most important, the project emphasized an
                                honest system of communication, which allowed observations, both
                                critical and complimentary, to constantly inform innovations in design
                                and implementation. KDP is among a small group of World Bank–
                                funded participatory projects that have made an effort to build effective
                                monitoring systems.
    Most World Bank–funded         As part of the background work for this report, the authors con-
  participatory projects have   ducted a review of M&E systems in World Bank–supported participa-
  not made an effort to build   tory projects, with a view to understanding the extent to which induced
    effective monitoring and    projects take learning by doing seriously.6 The data come from the
          evaluation systems.   analysis of documents from 345 projects in operation between 1999
                                and 2007, all of which allocated more than a third of their budgets to
                                participation. For a randomly selected subsample of 20 percent of these
                                projects, the design of the M&E system was assessed by analyzing the
                                project appraisal documents for each project. These documents—one
                                of the main documents the Bank’s Executive Board examines before
                                approving a loan—should ideally include a detailed account of the mon-
                                itoring system and of the manner in which the project will be evaluated.
                                   The analysis also examined implementation status reports and imple-
                                mentation completion reports for the sampled projects, in order to assess
                                the effectiveness of the M&E systems proposed in the project appraisal
                                documents. Implementation status reports are typically prepared by
                                the project manager after every supervision mission. Implementation
                                completion reports are self-evaluations of projects screened by the
                                Independent Evaluation Group.7 The analysis also assessed informa-
                                tion from project supervision documents, which synthesize the results
                                of regular project visits by Bank operational task teams.
                                   An important limitation of these data is that they exclude any kind
                                of M&E activity that is not reported in project documents. A survey of
                                managers of current and recently completed community development
                                projects was conducted to fill this gap. The survey, conducted in 2010,
                                was sent to all 165 managers of the 245 projects that were either active
                                in 2009 or had closed the previous year.8 Forty-one managers (25 per-
                                cent) completed most of the survey questions (all figures reported in
                                this chapter come from project managers who completed a significant
296
CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED?



portion of the survey). The responses suggest that the survey was more
likely to be completed by project managers whose projects had some
type of M&E system in place. The results therefore likely provide an
upper bound on the presence and quality of monitoring and evaluation
systems in place across all participatory projects at the World Bank.


Findings from Project Documents
One of the striking things about the project appraisal documents is how      The design and even the
similar they are. It is almost as if there is a template for participatory   language of World Bank
projects. Not only the design but also the language often seems to be cut    project documents often seem
and pasted from one project to the next, suggesting a lack of attention      to be cut and pasted from one
to context in designing participatory projects.                              project to the next.
   Although all of the project appraisal documents surveyed mentioned
M&E, only about 40 percent described it as an essential part of the
project design. And although 80 percent of the implementing agen-
cies engaged an M&E specialist, the quality of the specialist—like the
quality of the implementation—was highly variable. Furthermore, only
about 40 percent of the sample documents detailed the kind of monitor-
ing information that was collected. One-third of the documents did not
even state that an MIS—a key project monitoring tool—was part of the
information collection system.
   To improve the quality of project M&E, the Bank introduced a new
results-based management framework in 2004. All project appraisal
documents are now required to show how the project’s monitoring
indicators will make it possible to attribute outcomes to changes intro-
duced by the project. In the past, indicators were so broadly defined—
“reduction in the gap between rural and urban income inequalities,”
“improvement of GDP per capita”—that they may or may not have
been an outcome of the project. The new results framework requires
that relevant and easily measured indicators be included in the final
matrix of outcomes, so that project impacts can be more easily tracked.
Furthermore, the results framework must include data collection
methods and measurable objectives, as well as implementation status
reports based on monitoring data, to improve learning by doing.9 The         Introduction of the results-
results-based framework was also expected to make M&E more useful            based framework in 2004
as a planning and management tool.                                           does not appear to have
   Sampled projects from before and after 2004 were analyzed to              improved the quality of
determine whether the introduction of these new standards improved           monitoring and evaluation of
the quality of M&E systems. The results show that although the               World Bank projects.
                                                                                                       297
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                 number of M&E indicators was reduced by nearly half, 40 percent of
                                 the indicators remained imprecisely formulated (“improved allocation
                                 of expenditures,” “careful monitoring of effectiveness”). And although
                                 the number of indicators reported in implementation status reports
                                 rose (from a quarter to about two-thirds), only 22 percent of projects
                                 appeared to have collected data on the indicators that were supposed to
                                 measure intermediate progress. Most projects thus did not have access
                                 to timely monitoring data and could therefore not have been engaged in
                                 learning by doing based on real-time project performance data.
                                    The monitoring systems used in these projects were also assessed
                                 based on aide-memoires, midterm reviews, and implementation com-
                                 pletion reports, which provide a running picture of the Bank team’s
                                 most important observations and recommendations over the life of the
                                 project.10 Seventy-five percent of the assessments of monitoring systems
                                 tended to be negative. The most frequently observed deficiencies were
                                 the lack of a well-designed M&E system and poor implementation.
                                 These deficiencies were most often attributed to poor human and tech-
                                 nical capacity and lack of sufficient funding. Other reasons included the
                                 lack of institutional capacity, the absence of a baseline (which made it
                                 impossible to track progress), and the formulation of outcome indicators
                                 that could not realistically be attributed to the impacts of the project.
                                    Projects performed more or less similarly on evaluations. Although
                                 half the project documents explicitly mentioned that impacts were
                                 being evaluated and 70 percent of those mentioned some kind of
                                 impact evaluation with a comparison group, only 14 percent described
                                 the methods employed. Among the more credible methods mentioned
                                 were propensity score matching and randomized trials. But the major-
                                 ity used beneficiary assessments, participatory appraisals, and percep-
                                 tion surveys, which are not well suited to making causal claims. In the
                                 remaining 30 percent of projects, it was not clear what was meant by an
                                 evaluation or how it was to be performed.
        Having more than one        The degree to which M&E can help the project adapt through
    manager over the life of a   learning mechanisms depends on the attention it receives from project
 project—as half of the World    managers (that is, whether M&E is a management priority). The experi-
 Bank’s participatory projects   ence of project managers with participatory projects may also matter.
    did—can be disruptive for    Among all 374 managers of participatory projects, 44 percent were
   effective management and      managing more than one project, and about a third of these manag-
             learning systems.   ers were managing three or more projects. Project managers tended to
                                 be fairly inexperienced with participatory projects, with an average of

298
CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED?



1.85 years of experience in managing projects of this type and 4.3 years
of experience managing projects of any kind. Half of all projects had
two or more managers over their life, which can be disruptive for man-
agement and for effective learning systems.
    An important aspect of learning by doing—and the satisfaction of
beneficiaries—is the existence of an effective grievance and complaint
mechanism. A third of all project appraisal documents from 1999 to
2007 mention some kind of grievance mechanism, and the average rose
from a fifth of all projects before 2004 to half of all projects after 2004.
Most project documents from both periods, however, provided very
little information about the grievance mechanism. Only a quarter of
documents that mentioned such a process explained how it worked, and
only a third made provisions for documenting complaints. Complaints
received through these mechanisms were sorted into three categories:
poor quality of construction works, lack of transparent project selection
criteria, and lack of community involvement in the selection process.
This rather generalized complaint system raises questions about how
well these processes are established in practice.                             Half of all projects since
    Complaints and grievance systems can be powerful tools for ensuring       2004 have included grievance
that difficulties experienced by various project partners are considered       mechanisms . . .
and addressed in a timely manner. If used correctly, these systems can
not only enhance project effectiveness but also promote community             . . . but few explained how
ownership of the project. In contrast, using these mechanisms as decora-      the mechanism worked or
tive planning instruments may undermine the engagement of different           indicated how complaints
stakeholders if their complaints are not acted on.                            were to be documented.


Findings from a Survey of Project Managers
The group of managers who completed the survey had far more experi-
ence with participatory projects than the average project manager: only
5 percent had fewer than 2 years of experience, and almost 60 percent
had more than 10 years of experience managing participatory projects
(figure 7.1).
   More than 60 percent of survey respondents reported that the project
had an MIS system that collected and maintained data on both devel-
opment objectives and intermediate outcomes. More than 60 percent
reported that monitoring data were publically available in some form,
and half of these managers indicated that this information was avail-
able on a website. Almost two-thirds reported that the project collected

                                                                                                            299
LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK?



                                    Figure 7.1 World Bank project managers’ years of experience working on
                                    community-driven development and local governance projects
                                                                     70

                                                                     60     58.5




                                    Percentage of project managers
                                                                     50

                                                                     40

                                                                     30

                                                                     20
                                                                                      14.6
                                                                                             12.2
                                                                                                            9.8
                                                                     10
                                                                                                                   2.4   2.4
                                                                      0
                                                                          More than   5–7    7–10            2–5   0–2   Do not
                                                                             10                                           know
                                                                                             Years of experience



                                    tracking data and that an impact evaluation was either underway or
                                    had been completed. A large share also listed other types of monitor-
                                    ing activities, including field missions, participatory assessments, and
                                    facilitator feedback.
                                       In the survey, 88 percent of project managers stated that their project
                                    had a grievance mechanism in place, and 64 percent of these manag-
                                    ers (54 percent overall) reported that a record of grievances was being
                                    maintained. The results presented below should therefore be viewed as
                                    the opinions of seasoned project managers who were engaged to some
       Eighty percent of project    degree in building effective M&E systems into their projects.
    managers surveyed believe          Strikingly, the vast majority of project managers do not perceive
that if the Bank did not require    M&E as a priority for Bank Senior Management (figure 7.2). They also
    monitoring and evaluation,      believe that if the Bank did not require M&E, government counterparts
       government counterparts      would not engage in it (figure 7.3). A large majority (75 percent) also
     would not engage in it . . .   believe that the Bank’s operational policies do not provide any incen-
    . . . and 75 percent believe    tives to engage in systematic M&E (figure 7.4).
    that the Bank’s operational        Two-thirds of project managers believe that the Bank’s M&E
     policies do not provide the    requirements and supervision budgets are not tailored to project size,
  right incentives to engage in     project complexity, or country context (figure 7.5). Only a third believe
     systematic monitoring and      that the standard timeframe for projects (an average of 5.5 years) is suf-
                     evaluation.    ficient for realizing participatory objectives (figure 7.6).

300
CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED?



Figure 7.2 Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe
monitoring and evaluation is a priority for senior management
                                 50
                                                                                                         48.6

                                 40
Percentage of pro
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?
Localizing development. Does Participation work?

More Related Content

PPTX
Participatory development
DOCX
Presentation by ashish sadekar
DOCX
Presentation by ashutosh mutsaddi
PDF
Informe Final al CNA - LA AU
PDF
World bank on cities
PPTX
Sussex Development Lecture presentation by Ghazala Mansuri and Vijayendra Rao...
PDF
COMMUNITY PARTICIPATION AND THE PERFORMANCE OF PROJECT IMPLEMENTATION IN BUMB...
PPTX
Notes on participation
Participatory development
Presentation by ashish sadekar
Presentation by ashutosh mutsaddi
Informe Final al CNA - LA AU
World bank on cities
Sussex Development Lecture presentation by Ghazala Mansuri and Vijayendra Rao...
COMMUNITY PARTICIPATION AND THE PERFORMANCE OF PROJECT IMPLEMENTATION IN BUMB...
Notes on participation

Similar to Localizing development. Does Participation work? (20)

PDF
Research Inventy : International Journal of Engineering and Science
PDF
participatorydevelopment-140914180657-phpapp01 (1).pdf
PPTX
participatorydevelopment-140914180657-phpapp01.pptx
PPTX
Peoples participation UCD.pptx
PPTX
Participatorydevelopment 140914180657-phpapp01
DOCX
16.particepatory rural development projects
DOCX
16.particepatory rural development projects
PPTX
An Analysis of the Concept of Public Participation Using the third World Bank...
PPTX
KULIAH-PARTICIPATION_SEM4_2022.pptx
PPT
Participatory approaches to rural development
PPTX
Construction Management in Developing Countries, Lecture 7
PDF
Participationfrom Tyranny To Transformation Exploring New Approaches To Parti...
PDF
Participation in Urban Development and Governance
PDF
Impact of People's Participation in the Decentralized Participatory Planning...
PPT
Participation in Development. 1.ppt
PPTX
Analysis of Cost and Schedule Performance of International Development Projects
PDF
Participation, Power and Democracy: A Comparative Study of Community Engageme...
PDF
Participatory Rural Development in Nigeria An Assessment of the 3’I’s Initiat...
PPTX
CSC 12 Q3 0406_PS_Participatory Development in Community Action Initiatives (...
PPTX
REPORT People-Centered.pptxdjdjddbdhsbsbsb
Research Inventy : International Journal of Engineering and Science
participatorydevelopment-140914180657-phpapp01 (1).pdf
participatorydevelopment-140914180657-phpapp01.pptx
Peoples participation UCD.pptx
Participatorydevelopment 140914180657-phpapp01
16.particepatory rural development projects
16.particepatory rural development projects
An Analysis of the Concept of Public Participation Using the third World Bank...
KULIAH-PARTICIPATION_SEM4_2022.pptx
Participatory approaches to rural development
Construction Management in Developing Countries, Lecture 7
Participationfrom Tyranny To Transformation Exploring New Approaches To Parti...
Participation in Urban Development and Governance
Impact of People's Participation in the Decentralized Participatory Planning...
Participation in Development. 1.ppt
Analysis of Cost and Schedule Performance of International Development Projects
Participation, Power and Democracy: A Comparative Study of Community Engageme...
Participatory Rural Development in Nigeria An Assessment of the 3’I’s Initiat...
CSC 12 Q3 0406_PS_Participatory Development in Community Action Initiatives (...
REPORT People-Centered.pptxdjdjddbdhsbsbsb
Ad

More from Oswar Mungkasa (20)

PPTX
Urun Rembuk. Permukiman dan Ketahanan Pangan
PDF
Merengkuh kota ramah pejalan kaki dan Pesepeda. Pembelajaran Mancanegara dan ...
PPTX
Tata Kelola Kolaboratif dalam Pengembangan Wilayah Berkelanjutan. Konsep, Pra...
DOCX
Sudah saatnya mempopulerkan upcycling
PDF
Green infrastructure in jakarta basic understanding and implementation effort...
DOCX
Tata Kelola Kolaboratif dalam Desain Kebijakan Publik. Studi Kasus Pelaksanaa...
PPTX
Fakta, Isu dan SAran Penyempurnaan BP TAPERA
PDF
Tata kelola kolaboratif. Menata Kolaborasi Pemangku Kepentingan
DOCX
Pedoman kepemimpinan bersama
PDF
Memudahkan upaya kolaborasi beragam pemangku kepentingan
PDF
MAKALAH. Bekerja dari Rumah (working from home). Menuju Tatanan Baru Era Covi...
DOCX
Bekerja jarak jauh (telecommuting/Working from home/WFH). Konsep-Penerapan-Pe...
PPTX
PRESENTATION. Public Lecture "Jakarta's Response to COVID 19: Strategy-Lesson...
DOCX
Bekerja jarak jauh (telecommuting). Konsep, penerapan dan pembelajaran
PDF
LAPORAN. Memori Akhir Jabatan Koordinator Pelaksanaan Program Strategi Ketaha...
PDF
Laporan. Pelaksanaan Kegiatan Pelaksana Tugas Deputi Gubernur DKI Jakarta bid...
PDF
Laporan. Pelaksanaan Kegiatan Kedeputian Gubernur DKI Jakarta bidang Tata Rua...
PDF
Presentation. Collaboration Towards A Resilient Jakarta
PDF
Pengenalan konsep saleh sosial dalam pembangunan sanitasi
PDF
Suplemen HUD Magz Edisi 5 /2015. Kota BATAM Menyongsong MEA 2015
Urun Rembuk. Permukiman dan Ketahanan Pangan
Merengkuh kota ramah pejalan kaki dan Pesepeda. Pembelajaran Mancanegara dan ...
Tata Kelola Kolaboratif dalam Pengembangan Wilayah Berkelanjutan. Konsep, Pra...
Sudah saatnya mempopulerkan upcycling
Green infrastructure in jakarta basic understanding and implementation effort...
Tata Kelola Kolaboratif dalam Desain Kebijakan Publik. Studi Kasus Pelaksanaa...
Fakta, Isu dan SAran Penyempurnaan BP TAPERA
Tata kelola kolaboratif. Menata Kolaborasi Pemangku Kepentingan
Pedoman kepemimpinan bersama
Memudahkan upaya kolaborasi beragam pemangku kepentingan
MAKALAH. Bekerja dari Rumah (working from home). Menuju Tatanan Baru Era Covi...
Bekerja jarak jauh (telecommuting/Working from home/WFH). Konsep-Penerapan-Pe...
PRESENTATION. Public Lecture "Jakarta's Response to COVID 19: Strategy-Lesson...
Bekerja jarak jauh (telecommuting). Konsep, penerapan dan pembelajaran
LAPORAN. Memori Akhir Jabatan Koordinator Pelaksanaan Program Strategi Ketaha...
Laporan. Pelaksanaan Kegiatan Pelaksana Tugas Deputi Gubernur DKI Jakarta bid...
Laporan. Pelaksanaan Kegiatan Kedeputian Gubernur DKI Jakarta bidang Tata Rua...
Presentation. Collaboration Towards A Resilient Jakarta
Pengenalan konsep saleh sosial dalam pembangunan sanitasi
Suplemen HUD Magz Edisi 5 /2015. Kota BATAM Menyongsong MEA 2015
Ad

Recently uploaded (20)

PDF
FOISHS ANNUAL IMPLEMENTATION PLAN 2025.pdf
PDF
Uderstanding digital marketing and marketing stratergie for engaging the digi...
PDF
advance database management system book.pdf
DOC
Soft-furnishing-By-Architect-A.F.M.Mohiuddin-Akhand.doc
PPTX
202450812 BayCHI UCSC-SV 20250812 v17.pptx
PDF
LDMMIA Reiki Yoga Finals Review Spring Summer
PDF
BP 704 T. NOVEL DRUG DELIVERY SYSTEMS (UNIT 2).pdf
PDF
Chinmaya Tiranga quiz Grand Finale.pdf
PPTX
Chinmaya Tiranga Azadi Quiz (Class 7-8 )
PDF
FORM 1 BIOLOGY MIND MAPS and their schemes
PPTX
Computer Architecture Input Output Memory.pptx
PPTX
Unit 4 Computer Architecture Multicore Processor.pptx
PDF
medical_surgical_nursing_10th_edition_ignatavicius_TEST_BANK_pdf.pdf
PDF
ChatGPT for Dummies - Pam Baker Ccesa007.pdf
PDF
Τίμαιος είναι φιλοσοφικός διάλογος του Πλάτωνα
PDF
A GUIDE TO GENETICS FOR UNDERGRADUATE MEDICAL STUDENTS
PPTX
B.Sc. DS Unit 2 Software Engineering.pptx
PPTX
A powerpoint presentation on the Revised K-10 Science Shaping Paper
PPTX
Introduction to pro and eukaryotes and differences.pptx
PPTX
TNA_Presentation-1-Final(SAVE)) (1).pptx
FOISHS ANNUAL IMPLEMENTATION PLAN 2025.pdf
Uderstanding digital marketing and marketing stratergie for engaging the digi...
advance database management system book.pdf
Soft-furnishing-By-Architect-A.F.M.Mohiuddin-Akhand.doc
202450812 BayCHI UCSC-SV 20250812 v17.pptx
LDMMIA Reiki Yoga Finals Review Spring Summer
BP 704 T. NOVEL DRUG DELIVERY SYSTEMS (UNIT 2).pdf
Chinmaya Tiranga quiz Grand Finale.pdf
Chinmaya Tiranga Azadi Quiz (Class 7-8 )
FORM 1 BIOLOGY MIND MAPS and their schemes
Computer Architecture Input Output Memory.pptx
Unit 4 Computer Architecture Multicore Processor.pptx
medical_surgical_nursing_10th_edition_ignatavicius_TEST_BANK_pdf.pdf
ChatGPT for Dummies - Pam Baker Ccesa007.pdf
Τίμαιος είναι φιλοσοφικός διάλογος του Πλάτωνα
A GUIDE TO GENETICS FOR UNDERGRADUATE MEDICAL STUDENTS
B.Sc. DS Unit 2 Software Engineering.pptx
A powerpoint presentation on the Revised K-10 Science Shaping Paper
Introduction to pro and eukaryotes and differences.pptx
TNA_Presentation-1-Final(SAVE)) (1).pptx

Localizing development. Does Participation work?

  • 3. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT A World Bank Policy Research Report
  • 5. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Ghazala Mansuri and Vijayendra Rao
  • 6. © 2013 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433 Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org Some rights reserved 1 2 3 4 15 14 13 12 This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. Note that The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content included in the work. The World Bank therefore does not warrant that the use of the content contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of third parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries. Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved. Rights and Permissions This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Unported license (CC BY 3.0) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following conditions: Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: Mansuri, Ghazala, and Vijayendra Rao. 2013. Localizing Development: Does Participation Work? Washington, DC: World Bank. DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213- 8256-1. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0. Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation. All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625; e-mail: pubrights@worldbank .org. ISBN (paper): 978-0-8213-8256-1 ISBN (electronic): 978-0-8213-8990-4 DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-8256-1 Cover image: Zwelethu Mthethwa, South Africa, born 1960 Waiting, 1996 hand-colored digital print on paper World Bank Art Collection PN 466513 Cover design: Bill Pragluski, Critical Stages, LLC Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Mansuri, Ghazala. Localizing development : does participation work? / by Ghazala Mansuri and Vijayendra Rao. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-0-8213-8256-1 — ISBN 978-0-8213-8990-4 (electronic) 1. Economic development—Citizen participation. 2. Economic development projects—Citizen participation. 3. Community development. 4. Decentralization in government. I. Rao, Vijayendra. II. World Bank. III. Title. HD82.M36 2012 338.9—dc23 2012034769
  • 7. Contents Foreword ix Acknowledgments xi About the Authors xv Abbreviations xvii Overview 1 The History of Participatory Development and Decentralization 2 A Conceptual Framework for Participation 4 Empirical Findings 5 Moving Beyond the Evidence 11 Conclusion 13 1. Why Does Participation Matter? 15 The History of Participatory Development 20 Organic versus Induced Participation 31 Scope of the Report and Roadmap 41 Notes 44 References 45 2. A Conceptual Framework for Participatory Development 49 Market Failure 50 Government Failure 52 Civil Society Failure 54 Conclusions 80 Notes 80 References 82 v
  • 8. CONTENTS 3. The Challenge of Inducing Participation 87 Participation and the Capacity to Engage 91 Diagnosing Failure Triangles 94 Deriving Hypotheses 112 Notes 117 References 118 4. How Important Is Capture? 121 Corruption and Local Accountability 122 Participation and Resource Allocation in Induced Community-Driven Development Programs 128 Participation and Resource Allocation under Decentralization 136 Can Electoral Incentives Reduce Rent-Seeking? 141 Conclusions 146 Notes 148 References 152 5. Does Participation Improve Development Outcomes? 161 Identification of Beneficiaries 162 Sustainable Management of Common-Pool Resources 172 Participation and the Quality of Local Infrastructure 182 Community Engagement in Public Service Delivery 188 The Poverty Impact of Participatory Projects 213 Conclusions 221 Notes 224 References 234 6. Does Participation Strengthen Civil Society? 247 Participatory Decision Making and Social Cohesion in Induced Development Projects 247 Representation Quotas and Inclusion Mandates 253 Community-Driven Reconstruction 262 Participatory Councils and Deliberative Spaces 266 Conclusions 275 Notes 277 References 279 7. Conclusion: How Can Participatory Interventions Be Improved? 283 The Importance of Context 288 Donors, Governments, and Trajectories of Change 290 Open Research Questions 291 Monitoring, Evaluation, and Attention to Context: Results of a Survey of World Bank Projects 295 vi
  • 9. CONTENTS The Need for Better Monitoring and Evaluation and Different Project Structures 304 Notes 306 References 308 Figures 1.1 A typology of induced participation 37 3.1 Possible trajectories of local participation 110 7.1 World Bank project managers’ years of experience working on community-driven development and local governance projects 300 7.2 Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe monitoring and evaluation is a priority for senior management 301 7.3 Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe government counterparts would engage in monitoring and evaluation if the Bank did not require it 301 7.4 Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe the Bank creates the right incentives for them to engage in monitoring and evaluation 302 7.5 Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe that project supervision budgets are tailored to project size, project complexity, and country context 302 7.6 Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe that participatory development projects are supported long enough to achieve sustainability in community processes 303 vii
  • 11. Foreword Promoting participation through community development projects and local decentralization has become a central tenet of development policy. The World Bank alone has invested about $85 billion over the last decade on development assistance for participation. However, some observers feel that policy making in the area is con- ceptually weak, that project design is informed more by slogans than careful analysis. There have also been questions about whether partici- patory development is effective in reducing poverty, improving service delivery, and building the capacity for collective action. Some observ- ers also find that participatory projects are complex to implement and deeply affected by context, and are thus unsuited for large development institutions such as the World Bank. This groundbreaking report carefully examines each of these con- cerns. It outlines a conceptual framework for participation that is cen- tered on the concept of civil society failure and how it interacts with market and government failures. The authors use this framework to understand the key policy debates surrounding participatory develop- ment and to frame the key policy questions. The report conducts the most comprehensive review of the evidence on the impact of participa- tory projects to date, looking at more than 400 papers and books. For me, an important lesson from this report is its recognition of the difference between “organic” and “induced” participation. Organic par- ticipation is organized by civic groups outside government, sometimes in opposition to it; induced participation attempts to promote civic action through bureaucratically managed development interventions. Inducing participation requires a fundamentally different approach to development, one that is long term, context sensitive, committed to ix
  • 12. FOREWORD developing a culture of learning by doing through honest monitoring and evaluation systems, and that has the capacity to learn from failure. The report argues that participatory development is most effective when it works within a “sandwich” formed by support from an effective cen- tral state and bottom-up civic action. This report represents an important contribution. It has significant implications for how to improve participation in development interven- tions and for development policy more broadly. Martin Ravallion Acting Chief Economist and Senior Vice President The World Bank Washington, DC September 20, 2012 x
  • 13. Acknowledgments WE ARE GRATEFUL TO MARTIN RAVALLION, THE DIRECTOR OF THE World Bank’s Development Economics Research Group (DECRG), and our managers, Peter Lanjouw and Will Martin, for giving us the time and the freedom to write this report in the best way we knew how. It has been more than three years in preparation, and we know that their patience was often tested. We hope the effort was worth it. We would also like to thank them for their prodding and constructive comments and suggestions at every stage of the process. We are also grateful to Gershon Feder, who started us off on this journey 10 years ago, when he convinced us that writing a big-picture piece on participatory devel- opment could be valuable. We acknowledge financial support from the DEC-managed Knowledge for Change Program (KCP-TF090806). Radu Ban and Catherine Gamper helped research the report. Radu assisted with gathering and summarizing some of the literature and, along with Monica Yanez-Pagans, helped maintain the bibliographic database. Catherine’s primary contribution was the analysis of data from World Bank reports and the management of the survey of project managers that forms an important part of chapter 7. Maribel Flewitt and Pauline Kokila provided excellent and uncomplaining administra- tive support. Several other people worked on various aspects of the report, either as summer interns or on a part-time basis. They include Shahana Chattaraj, Deborah Davis, Indrajit Roy, and Bhrigupati Singh. Kent Eaton; Jesse Ribot, J. F. Lund, and T. True; Rachel Riedl and Tyler Dickovick; and Catherine Benson and Arun Agrawal provided back- ground papers that contributed to our understanding of the xi
  • 14. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS management of common property resources, and decentralization in Africa and Latin America. The World Bank’s Office of the Publisher has been immensely supportive in bringing this report to timely completion. We would particularly like to thank Barbara Karni, who copyedited the manu- script and worked on the margin callouts; Janice Tuten, the publication production manager; and Stephen McGroarty, the acquisitions editor. We are also grateful to Marina Galvani, the World Bank’s art curator, who helped us locate a wonderful piece of artwork for our cover, by the South African artist Zwelethu Mthethwa, from the Bank’s collection. Helpful and critical comments from Shanta Devarajan and Brian Levy when this report was still a concept note led to a major recon- ceptualization. We believe the report is much better for it. We are deeply grateful for the thoughtful, constructive, and detailed written comments from our colleagues in DECRG: Varun Gauri, Karla Hoff, Phil Keefer, Stuti Khemani, and Berk Özler. Karla Hoff also helped us sharpen and clarify many points of theory. We benefited greatly from discussions with other DECRG colleagues during various stages of writ- ing this report. In particular, we would like to thank Francisco Ferreira, Deon Filmer, Emanuella Galasso, and Michael Woolcock. The first draft of this report was widely circulated within the Bank. We received useful written comments from people from various depart- ments, including the Social Development Anchor, the Community Driven Development (CDD) Community of Practice, the Chief Economist’s offices in Africa and South Asia, the Human Development Anchor, and the Africa Decentralization team. We also benefited greatly from discussions with and comments from Robert Chase, Scott Guggenheim, Janmejay Singh, and Susan Wong. Robert Zoellick’s comments on a summary of the report helped us sharpen some of the points in the conclusion. We received extremely insightful and detailed written comments on an early draft of the report from a distinguished roster of external academic reviewers, to whom we are deeply indebted: Pranab Bardhan, Patrick Heller, Macartan Humphries, Dilip Mookherjee, and Jean- Philippe Platteau. Over the years, our work on this report has been influenced by dis- cussions with, and support from, a variety of colleagues and friends. We would particularly like to thank Kamran Akbar, Kripa Ananthpur, Arjun Appadurai, Granville and Nancy Austin, Rachid Bajwa, Tim xii
  • 15. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Besley, Mary Breeding, Monica Das Gupta, Peter Evans, Ariel Fiszbein, Archon Fung, John Gaventa, Qazi Azmat Isa, Ahmad Jamal, Agha Jawad, Shahnaz Kapadia, Michael Lipton, Deepa Narayan, Rohini Pande, Drew Permut, Menno Pradhan, Jesse Ribot, Paromita Sanyal, Amartya Sen, Parmesh Shah, Shubha Shankaran, Brian Silver, J. P. Singh, Ann Swidler, Mike Walton, Susan Watkins, and members of the Successful Societies Program at the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research (CIFAR). Finally, Ghazala Mansuri would like to thank her son, Omar Sheheryar Agha, whose enthusiasm and intellectual curiosity has been a constant source of nourishment and whose patience with the seemingly endless weekends and nights spent on this report has been extraordi- nary for one so young. Vijayendra Rao would like to thank his father, Surendra Rao, for his many stimulating discussions and for his unstint- ing encouragement throughout the process of writing this report. He also thanks his mother, Vasanthi Rao Lokkur, and his partner, Monica Biradavolu, for their steadfast support. Ghazala Mansuri and Vijayendra Rao Washington, DC September 20, 2012 xiii
  • 17. About the Authors Ghazala Mansuri is a lead economist in the Poverty Reduction and Equity Group of the World Bank. Her research spans four broad areas: rural land, labor and credit markets, the economics of household behavior, and the political economy of participatory development and institutional and governance reforms for development. Her research on the political economy of local development includes a number of evaluations of participatory development programs. Dr. Mansuri has published extensively in leading journals in economics and develop- ment. She holds a Ph.D. in economics from Boston University. Vijayendra Rao is lead economist in the Development Research Group of the World Bank. He integrates his training in economics with theories and methods from anthropology, sociology, and political science to study the social and political context of extreme poverty in developing countries. Dr. Rao has published widely in leading journals in economics and development studies on subjects that include the rise in dowries in India, domestic violence, the economics of public celebra- tions, sex work in Calcutta, deliberative democracy, and village democ- racy. He co-edited Culture and Public Action and History, Historians, and Development Policy. He serves on the editorial boards of Economic Development and Cultural Change, the Journal of Development Studies, and the World Bank Economic Review and is a member of the Advisory Committee of the Successful Societies Program at the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research (CIFAR). He holds a Ph.D. in econom- ics from the University of Pennsylvania. xv
  • 19. Abbreviations AKRSP Agha Khan Rural Support Program BPL Below Poverty Line DFID Department for International Development DPIP District Poverty Initiative Program EDUCO Educación con Participación de la Comunidad (Education with Community Participation) GDP gross domestic product HIV/AIDS human immunodeficiency virus/ acquired immune deficiency syndrome IAT Implicit Association Test KALAHI–CIDSS Kapit Bisig Laban Sa Kahirapan–Comprehensive and Integrated Delivery of Social Services KDP Kecamatan Development Program M&E monitoring and evaluation MIS management information system NGO nongovernmental organization NRSP National Rural Support Program PSF Programa Saude da Famılia (Family Health Program) PT Partido dos Trabalhadores (Workers’ Party) SC Scheduled Caste ST Scheduled Tribe TASAF Tanzanian Social Action Fund USAID U.S. Agency for International Development VP van panchayat (local forest council) ZAMSIF Zambia Social Fund All amounts are presented in U.S. dollars unless otherwise indicated. xvii
  • 21. Overview OV ER THE PAST DECA DE, THE WOR LD BA NK H AS A LLOCATED almost $85 billion to local participatory development. Driving this massive injection of funding has been the underlying belief that involv- ing communities in at least some aspects of project design and imple- mentation creates a closer connection between development aid and its intended beneficiaries. Indeed, local participation is proposed as a method to achieve a variety of goals, including sharpening poverty tar- geting, improving service delivery, expanding livelihood opportunities, and strengthening demand for good governance. In principle, a more engaged citizenry should be able to achieve a higher level of cooperation and make government more accountable. In practice, little is known about how best to foster such engagement. Can participation be induced through the type of large-scale govern- ment and donor-funded participatory programs that have become a leitmotif of development policy? It is this question that is at the heart of this Policy Research Report. The two major modalities for inducing local participation are com- munity development and decentralization of resources and authority to local governments. Community development supports efforts to bring villages, urban neighborhoods, or other household groupings into the process of managing development resources without relying on formally constituted local governments. Community development projects— variously labeled community-driven development, community-based development, community livelihood projects, and social funds— include efforts to expand community engagement in service delivery. Designs for this type of aid can range from community-based targeting, 1
  • 22. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? in which only the selection of beneficiaries is decentralized, to projects in which communities are also involved to varying degrees in the design and management of resources. Decentralization refers to efforts to strengthen village and municipal governments on both the demand and supply sides. On the demand side, decentralization strengthens citizens’ participation in local govern- ment by, for example, instituting regular elections, improving access to information, and fostering mechanisms for deliberative decision mak- ing. On the supply side, it enhances the ability of local governments to provide services by increasing their financial resources, strengthening the capacity of local officials, and streamlining and rationalizing their administrative functions. This report focuses on assessing the impact of large-scale, policy- driven efforts to induce participation. It does not, as such, examine the literature on organic participation—participation spurred by civic groups, whether organized or not, acting independently of and sometimes even in opposition to government. Organic participation is important, but it has not been the focus of donor funding. The report does draw on lessons from efforts to scale up organic movements through induced policy interventions. In this context, it views nongov- ernment organizations (NGOs) that are largely dependent on donor or government funding through participatory interventions as part of the effort to induce participation. The report focuses on the “demand-side” aspects of participatory development. Important “supply-side” aspects of governance (fi scal decentralization, taxation policy, local government procedures, and bureaucratic inefficiency) have been dealt with extensively elsewhere and were beyond the scope of this work. Most of the fi ndings reviewed derive from econometric analysis. However, the report draws on case studies to develop specific ideas and to illustrate the conceptual framework. It also draws on observational studies from large samples to illustrate key points. The History of Participatory Development and Decentralization Participatory development and decentralization have common intel- lectual origins. Deliberative decision making has been a central feature 2
  • 23. OVERVIEW of most religious and cultural traditions. In Athenian democracy, for example, important decisions were made in public deliberative settings in which all citizens (a group that excluded all women, slaves, and chil- dren) were expected to participate. Modern notions of participation arguably derive from the 18th and 19th centuries, notably from the work of Rousseau and John Stuart Mill. In the early postcolonial period, the 1950s and 1960s, the U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID) and other donors helped drive the first wave of interest in participatory development by funding and promoting cooperative institutions, community-based development, and decentralization. By the 1970s, however, interest in participatory development had waned with the realization that coopera- tives had largely failed and government reform was difficult to imple- ment or sustain. The focus of policy shifted to large-scale investments in agricultural and industrial growth. By the mid-1980s, however, activ- ists and scholars attacked this approach, seeing it as “top-down” and inherently disempowering and biased against the interests of the poor. Economists such as Sen and Ostrom made a vigorous case for a more bottom-up and deliberative vision of development that allows the “com- mon sense” and “social capital” of communities to play a central part in decisions that affect them. Their scholarship led to renewed interest in community-based development, decentralization, and participation by donors and governments. As the social costs of structural adjustment programs became evident by the early 1990s, donors began to actively fund such participatory approaches, with the aim of ensuring minimal levels of investment in public services and infrastructure and in social programs to protect the most vulnerable. This renewed policy interest in participatory initiatives, along with the expansion in funding, has proceeded, in large part, with little systematic effort to understand the particular challenges entailed in inducing participation or to learn from the failures of past programs. As a result, the process is, arguably, still driven more by ideology and optimism than by systematic analysis, either theoretical or empirical. The aim of this report is to fill some of these lacunae. It does so by first outlining a conceptual framework within which local participatory development interventions can be analyzed and then using the evidence to draw some broad lessons with this framework as a guide. 3
  • 24. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? A Conceptual Framework for Participation Market and government failures are now reasonably well understood. Policy makers are less likely than they once were to assume that markets work perfectly or that governments can always provide effective solu- tions to market failures. In contrast, the policy literature is rife with solutions to market and government failures that assume that groups of people—village communities, urban neighborhood associations, school councils, water user groups—will always work toward the com- mon interest. Rarely is much thought given to the possibility of “civil society failure.” In fact, organizing groups of people to solve market and government failures is itself subject to problems of coordination, asym- metric information, and pervasive inequality. Civil society failure at the local level can be broadly thought of as a situation in which groups that live in geographic proximity are unable to act collectively to reach a feasible and preferable outcome. It includes coordinated actions that are inefficient—or efficient but welfare reduc- ing on average—as well as the inability to undertake any coordinated action at all. Development policy that uses participatory processes needs to be informed by a thoughtful diagnosis of potential civil society fail- ures, so that policy makers can clearly understand the tradeoffs involved in devolving decisions to local communities and can identify potential ways of repairing such failures. Thinking of local development policy as occurring at the intersection of market, government, and civil society failures invariably increases appreciation of context. Such interactions are deeply conditioned by culture, politics, and social structure, and they vary from place to place. A policy that works in one country, or even one municipality, may fail miserably in another. Moreover, effective collective action is usually conditioned by a “cooperative infrastructure” that presupposes functional state institutions—and is likely to be far more challenging in its absence. Empowering civic groups may lead to good outcomes. But it is not clear that inducing civic empowerment is always superior to a pure market-based strategy or a strategy that strengthens the role of central bureaucrats. Policy makers need to keep all of these considerations in mind as they consider how best to harness the power of communities. 4
  • 25. OVERVIEW Empirical Findings This report reviews almost 500 studies on participatory development and decentralization. The findings shed light on three key issues. How Important Is Capture? The purpose of participatory programs is to enhance the involvement of the poor and the marginalized in community-level decision-making bodies in order to give citizens greater say in decisions that affect their lives. Do these programs result in choices that are better aligned with their preferences? Does fostering participation increase social cohesion? Does it produce more resilient and inclusive local institutions? Does it reduce capture and corruption? On balance, the review of the literature finds that participants in civic activities tend to be wealthier, more educated, of higher social sta- tus (by caste and ethnicity), male, and more politically connected than nonparticipants. This picture may partly reflect the higher opportunity cost of participation for the poor. It also appears, however, that the poor often benefit less from participatory processes than do the better off, because resource allocation processes typically reflect the preferences of elite groups. Studies from a variety of countries show that communi- ties in which inequality is high have worse outcomes, especially where political, economic, and social power are concentrated in the hands of a few. “Capture” also tends to be greater in communities that are remote from centers of power; have low literacy; are poor; or have significant caste, race, or gender disparities. Policy design may also have unintended consequences. A large injection of resources for a participatory development project can, for example, attract the attention of the better off, making exclusion more likely. Participatory projects also often fail to build cohesive and resilient organizations. During the course of a project, cash or other material payoffs induce people to participate and build networks—but these mechanisms tend to dissolve when the incentives are withdrawn. Only when projects explicitly link community-based organizations with markets, or provide skills training, do they tend to improve group cohesiveness and collective action beyond the life of the project. 5
  • 26. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Spending decisions do seem to be better aligned with local needs under democratic decentralization, and resources are reallocated in favor of the less advantaged. But much depends on the nature of electoral incentives and the capacity of higher levels of government to provide oversight and ensure downward accountability. Capacity also matters. The benefits of decentralization seem to be weaker in more remote, more isolated, and less literate localities. Such localities also tend to be more poorly served by mass media and other sources of information, and they are less likely to have adequate central oversight. Does Participation Improve Development Outcomes? On balance, greater community involvement seems to modestly improve resource sustainability and infrastructure quality. But the evi- dence suggests that people who benefit tend to be the most literate, the least geographically isolated, and the most connected to wealthy and powerful people. Participation thus appears to affect the distribution of benefits in ways that suggest that capture is often not “benevolent” or altruistic. Project design and implementation rules play a critical role in deter- mining whether participatory programs are captured. Demand-driven, competitive application processes can exclude the weakest communities and exacerbate horizontal inequities. For many years, willingness to contribute to programs and projects has been seen as evidence of commitment and of the sustainability of programs or of infrastructure. But this belief has little basis in evidence. What little is known suggests that co-fi nancing—the sine qua non of participatory projects—tends to exclude the poorest, particularly when individuals or communities self-select into a program. Evidence also suggests that co-fi nancing requirements for local governments can widen horizontal inequities in targeted transfer programs, because poorer municipalities or counties have an incentive to reduce the pov- erty threshold for transfer eligibility in order to reduce their own co- payment burden. The review of the evidence on community management of common- pool resources and community engagement in the creation and main- tenance of small-scale infrastructure focuses on five main questions: • What evidence is there for greater resource sustainability under decentralized or community management? 6
  • 27. OVERVIEW • What evidence is there of more inclusive management and greater equity in the distribution of benefits? • To what extent do community characteristics such as wealth inequality, ethnic heterogeneity, and management experience affect the sustainability of resources or infrastructure? • How much can local management systems help overcome adverse local characteristics—that is, can good design induce the right type and level of participation? • How dependent is success on the role played by the central state? Four main findings emerge from the literature: • Inequality tends to worsen both efficiency and equity, and there can be important tradeoffs between resource sustainability and equity. • Transferring management responsibilities to a resource or an infrastructure scheme does not usually involve handing over control to a cohesive organic entity with the requisite capac- ity; often it requires creating local management capacity. In the absence of deliberate efforts to create such capacity and provide resources for ongoing maintenance and management, invest- ments in infrastructure are largely wasted and natural resources poorly managed. • Clear mechanisms for downward accountability are critical. The literature is rife with cases in which decentralization is used to tighten central control and increase incentives for upward accountability rather than to increase local discretion. The absence of robust mechanisms for downward accountability tends to go hand in hand with complex reporting and plan- ning requirements, which are usually beyond the capacity of local actors and become a tool for retaining control and assign- ing patronage. Most of these requirements are holdovers from past rules designed to extract resources from rather than benefit communities. • Communities need to benefit from the resources they manage. For natural resources that create substantial externalities, the benefit should be commensurate with the size of the externality created by the resource and should at least compensate com- munities for the alternative uses to which they could put the resource for immediate gain. 7
  • 28. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Only a few studies compare community-managed infrastructure projects with similar projects delivered by governmental line depart- ments using a more “top-down” delivery mechanism. These studies find that community engagement seems to improve both the quality of construction and the management of local infrastructure—implying lower levels of corruption relative to government provision. This suggests that carefully designed projects have the potential to limit capture. Indeed, a key feature of the projects studied is that the implementing agencies provided significant oversight during construc- tion, the maintenance and recurrent costs were explicitly budgeted for, and the implementing agency was available to provide training and sup- port for maintenance. These concerns imply considerable engagement of higher-tier governments or implementing agencies in building local capacity, monitoring outcomes, and setting the broad parameters under which management is devolved—with a view to enhancing downward rather than upward accountability while leaving sufficient discretion at the local level. Studies of community participation in health service and educa- tion fi nd modestly positive results overall, although the causal link between participation and service delivery outcomes is often vague. Studies that are able to assess the impact of participation typically find that although inducing community engagement alone has little impact on outcomes, community engagement can substantially amplify the impact of investments in other health or education inputs. In the case of health service delivery, for example, the formation of community health groups appears to have virtually no effect on any health-related outcome when done in isolation but is effective when combined with inputs such as trained health personnel or the upgrading of health facili- ties. Community engagement leads to significantly larger reductions in maternal and infant mortality, larger improvements in health-related behaviors, and greater use of health facilities than investments in health inputs alone can deliver. Interestingly, successful programs are often located within larger government health delivery systems. This finding is encouraging, because government participation is usually central for scaling up health initiatives. The evidence also suggests that the most successful programs tend to be implemented by local governments that have some discretion and are downwardly accountable. Devolving the management of public programs to NGOs appears to work less well, although the evidence remains thin. Community engagement 8
  • 29. OVERVIEW in education has somewhat similar but more muted effects, primarily because impacts on learning tend to be weak, at least over the time spans covered by evaluations, which may be too short to measure results. Overall, studies report an increase in school access, an improvement in retention rates and attendance, and a reduction in grade repetition. Interventions that provide information to households and communi- ties about the quality of services in their community as well as govern- ment standards of service tend to improve outcomes. Moreover, they do so even when no additional resources are expended. Funding also matters. Increasing the fiscal burden on poor commu- nities can reduce the quality of public service delivery. When projects do not cover maintenance and recurrent costs, communities are left with crumbling schools without teachers and clinics without medicines. As with other interventions, however, poorer, more remote areas are less able to realize gains from decentralized service delivery. The benefits of decentralization are smaller when communities are less well administered and more embedded in an extractive equilibrium charac- terized by weak democratic practices and a politicized administration. Literacy is also an important constraint—an effect that is consistent across several studies. The evidence suggests that community-based development efforts have had a limited impact on income poverty. Projects with significant microfi nance components do show positive impacts on savings and assets, but these effects appear to be confined largely to the life cycle of the project. There is also some evidence that community-based devel- opment projects improve nutrition and diet quality, especially among children, although some of these studies find that larger benefits accrue to better-off households. Does Participation Strengthen Civil Society? There is little evidence that induced participation builds long-lasting cohesion, even at the community level. Group formation tends to be both parochial and unequal. Absent some kind of affirmative action program, groups that form under the aegis of interventions tend to systematically exclude disadvantaged and minority groups and women. Moreover, because similar types of people tend to form groups with one another, projects rarely promote cross-group cohesion—and may actually reinforce existing divisions. 9
  • 30. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? An important question in this context is the role of facilitators who work with communities. The evidence on this issue is scant, but the few studies that have tried to measure their effects find that facilitators strongly influence the stated preferences of community members, who often tell facilitators what they think they want to hear. Participation often tends to be driven by project-related incentives; people get together to derive benefits from project funds. It is very difficult to know whether these effects will last beyond the tenure of the project and the limited evidence indicates that it usually does not. There is some heartening evidence, though, that participation may have intrinsic value. Communities tend to express greater satisfaction with decisions in which they participate, even when participation does not change the outcome or when outcomes are not consistent with their expressed preferences. The ballot box, though far from perfect, appears to provide a clearer mechanism for sanctioning unpopular policy choices or excessive rent- seeking by traditional or political elites than more informal forums for deliberation. In decentralized settings, credible and open elections help align the decisions of politicians with the demands of their constituents. When participatory and deliberative councils exist in such settings, they can foster a significant degree of civic engagement. It is less clear how citizens can collectively sanction negligent or corrupt officials or local leaders where such venues for the exercise of voice are not available. Repairing civic failures requires that social inequalities be addressed. One way of trying to do so is to mandate the inclusion of disadvantaged groups in the participatory process. There is virtually no evidence from evaluations of community-driven development projects on whether such mandates work. However, a growing body of evidence from vil- lage democracies in India indicates broadly positive impacts. Quotas in village councils and presidencies for disadvantaged groups and women tend to change political incentives in favor of the interests of the group that is favored by the quota. Mandated inclusion also appears to provide an incubator for new political leadership. Evidence indicates that women and other excluded groups are more likely to run for nonmandated seats once they have had some experience on a mandated seat. Quotas can also weaken prevailing stereotypes that assign low ability and poor performance to traditionally excluded groups. However, lasting change requires that the inclusion mandates remain in place for long enough to change perceptions and social norms. 10
  • 31. OVERVIEW Democratic decentralization works because village and municipal democracies incentivize local politicians to nurture their constituencies. Because decentralized programs usually come with a constitutional mandate or other legal sanction from the center, they are relatively permanent and can therefore change social and political dynamics over the long term. In contrast, community-based projects are usually ad hoc interventions that are unable to open political opportunities for real social change. Participatory interventions have been used in postconflict settings as a quick way of getting funds to the ground. The limited evidence on their effectiveness suggests that such projects have made little headway in building social cohesion or rebuilding the state. However, evidence from Africa seems to suggest that people emerging from civic conflict have a strong desire to participate in their communities and that well- designed and implemented projects could draw on this need. In sum, the evidence suggests that, although local actors may have an informational and locational advantage, they use it to the benefit of the disadvantaged only where institutions and mechanisms to ensure local accountability are robust. Local oversight is most effective when other, higher-level institutions of accountability function well and communi- ties have the capacity to effectively monitor service providers and others in charge of public resources. Local participation appears to increase, rather than diminish, the need for functional and strong institutions at the center. It also implies that implementing agencies for donor-funded projects need to have the capacity to exercise adequate oversight. There is little evidence that they can substitute for a nonfunctional state as a higher-level accountability agent, however. Reforms that enhance judicial oversight, allow for independent audit agencies, and protect and promote the right to information and a free media appear to be necessary for effective local oversight. Moving Beyond the Evidence Three main lessons emerge from distilling the evidence and thinking about the broader challenges in inducing participation. 1. Induced participatory interventions work best when they are sup- ported by a responsive state. The state does not necessarily have to 11
  • 32. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? be democratic—though being democratic helps a great deal. But in the sphere in which the intervention is being conducted—at the level of the community or the neighborhood—the state has to be responsive to community demands. Parachuting funds into communities without any monitoring by a supportive state can result in the capture of decision making by elites who control the local cooperative infrastructure, leading to a high risk of corruption. In the absence of a supportive state, participatory engage- ment may still be able to make a difference, but projects implemented in such environments face much greater challenges. 2. Context, both local and national, is extremely important. Outcomes from interventions are highly variable across communities; local inequality, history, geography, the nature of social interactions, net- works, and political systems all have a strong influence. The variability of these contexts is sometimes so large, and their effect so unpredictable, that projects that function well usually do so because they have strong built-in systems of learning and great sensitivity and adaptability to variations in context. 3. Effective civic engagement does not develop within a predictable trajectory. Instead, it is likely to proceed along a “punctuated equi- librium,” in which long periods of seeming quietude are followed by intense, and often turbulent, change. Donor-driven participatory projects often assume a far less contentious trajectory. Conditioned by bureaucratic imperatives, they often declare that clear, measurable, and usually wildly optimistic outcomes will be delivered within a specified timeframe. There is a danger that such projects set themselves up for failure that derives not from what they achieve on the ground but from their unrealistic expectations. One important reason for this overly ambitious approach, espe- cially at the World Bank, is that many donors’ institutional structure continues to derive from a focus on capital-intensive development and reconstruction. Building dams, bridges, and roads, or even schools and clinics, is a much more predictable activity than changing social and political systems. Repairing civil society and political failure requires a shift in the social equilibrium that derives from a change in the nature of social interactions and from modifying norms and local cultures. These much more difficult tasks require a fundamentally different 12
  • 33. OVERVIEW approach to development—one that is flexible, long term, self-critical, and strongly infused with the spirit of learning by doing. The variability of local context and the unpredictable nature of change trajectories in participatory interventions underscore the need for effective systems of monitoring and assessing impact. Such projects require constant adjustment, learning in the field, and experimentation in order to be effective—none of which can be done without tailoring project design to the local context, carefully monitoring implementa- tion, and designing robust evaluation systems. As demonstrated in chapter 7 of this report, the World Bank falls far short on these measures—and other donors probably perform no better. The results are sobering—and instructive. Despite wide differences in contexts, the Project Assessment Documents of World Bank–funded projects (which lay out a project’s design) are striking in their similarity, with language often simply cut and pasted from one project to another. A review of the monitoring and evaluation (M&E) systems in World Bank projects in which at least a third of the budget was allocated to local participation, as well as a survey of project managers, also reveals pervasive inattention to monitoring and evaluation systems. Only 40 percent of Project Assessment Documents included a monitoring system as an essential part of the project design, and a third failed to mention basic monitoring requirements such as a management information system (MIS). When monitoring was mentioned, it usually involved collecting extremely imprecise indicators, and even this data collection was done irregularly. Even less attention was paid to evaluating project effectiveness through a credible evaluation. The majority of project managers indicated that the Bank’s operational policies do not provide adequate incentives for M&E and that M&E is not perceived to be a priority of senior management. M&E seems to be treated as a box to be checked to obtain a loan rather than as an instrument for improving project effectiveness. Conclusion Evaluations of participatory development efforts improved somewhat between 2007 and 2012, generating some new evidence. However, the evidence base for most questions relevant to policy remains thin, and far too little attention is still paid to monitoring and evaluation. Project 13
  • 34. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? design continues to show little appreciation of context, and inflexible institutional rules fail to internalize the complexity inherent in engag- ing with civic-led development. Unless these problems are addressed, participatory development projects will continue to struggle to make a difference. Local participation tends to work well when it has teeth and when projects are based on well-thought-out and tested designs, facilitated by a responsive center, adequately and sustainably funded, and conditioned by a culture of learning by doing. To ensure that it supports projects with these characteristics, the World Bank and other donor agencies need to take several steps: • Project structures need to change to allow for flexible, long-term engagement. Patience is a virtue. • Project designs and impact evaluations need to be informed by political and social analyses, in addition to economic analysis. • Monitoring needs to be taken far more seriously. The use of new, more cost-effective tools, such as short message service (SMS)–based reporting, could help enormously. • Clear systems of facilitator feedback as well as participatory monitoring and redress systems need to be created. • Most important, there needs to room for honest feedback to facilitate learning, instead of a tendency to rush to judgment coupled with a pervasive fear of failure. The complexity of participatory development requires a high tolerance for failure and clear incentives for project managers to report evidence of it. Failure is sometimes the best way to learn about what works. Only in an environment in which failure is tolerated can innova- tion take place and evidence-based policy decisions be made. 14
  • 35. CHAPTER ONE Why Does Participation Matter? OV ER THE PAST DECA DE, THE WOR LD BA NK H AS A LLOCATED almost $85 billion to local participatory development.1 Other develop- ment agencies—bilateral donors and regional development banks— have probably spent at least as much, as have the governments of most developing countries.2 The current wave of interest in participation began as a reaction to the highly centralized development strategies of the 1970s and 1980s, which created the widespread perception among activists and nongov- ernmental organization (NGOs) that “top-down” development aid was deeply disconnected from the needs of the poor, the marginalized, and the excluded. Underlying this shift was the belief that giving the poor a greater say in decisions that affected their lives by involving them in at least some aspects of project design and implementation would result in a closer connection between development aid and its intended beneficiaries. Local participation has acquired a life of its own over the past decade. Local participation has been It is now proposed as a way to achieve a variety of goals, including proposed as a way to improve improving poverty targeting, building community-level social capital, poverty targeting, build social and increasing the demand for good governance. capital, and increase demand One of the key objectives of participation is to incorporate local for good governance. knowledge and preferences into the decision-making processes of governments, private providers, and donor agencies. When potential beneficiaries are able to make key decisions, participation becomes self- initiated action—what is known as the “exercise of voice and choice,” or “empowerment.” Participation is expected to lead to better-designed development projects, more effective service delivery, and improvements in the targeting of benefits. Ultimately, it is expected to lead to a more 15
  • 36. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? equitable allocation of public resources and to reductions in corruption and rent-seeking. The two major modalities for The two major modalities for fostering local participation are com- fostering local participation munity development and decentralization of resources and authority are community development to local governments. Community development supports efforts to and local decentralization. bring villages, urban neighborhoods, and other household groupings into the process of managing development resources, without relying on formally constituted local governments. Community development projects are labeled as community-driven development, community- based development, community livelihood projects, and social funds. In recent years, the effort to expand community engagement in service delivery has also introduced participatory education and health proj- ects, which have some of the same features as community-driven and community-based development projects. Designs for this type of aid can range from community-based targeting, in which only the selection of beneficiaries is decentralized, to projects in which communities are also involved to varying degrees in project design, project management, and the management of resources. Decentralization refers to efforts to strengthen village and municipal governments on both the demand and supply sides. On the demand side, it strengthens citizens’ participation in local government—by, for example, instituting regular elections, improving access to informa- tion, and fostering mechanisms for deliberative decision making. On the supply side, it enhances the ability of local governments to provide services by increasing their financial resources, strengthening the capac- ity of local officials, and streamlining and rationalizing administrative functions. Community development and decentralization share a common intellectual pedigree, firmly rooted in historical notions of participa- tory government. Proponents of participation hold that it has intrinsic value because it enhances pro-social thinking, strengthens citizenship, and enables more inclusive civic engagement. Insofar as taking part in community decision making also builds capacity for self-reliance and collective action (what is sometimes called “social capital”), participa- tion also has instrumental value. When successful, participation can transform passive residents into effective public citizens, who use it as a tool to hold states and markets accountable and influence decisions that affect their lives. 16
  • 37. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? Advocates of community development view it as a mechanism Community development for enhancing sustainability, improving efficiency and effectiveness, and decentralization share a scaling up poverty reduction programs, making development more common intellectual pedigree, inclusive, empowering poor people, building social capital, strength- firmly rooted in historical ening governance, and complementing market and public sector notions of participatory activities (see, for example, Dongier and others 2001). They argue government. that community-driven development in particular is able to achieve these results by aligning development priorities with community goals; enhancing communication between aid agencies and beneficiaries; expanding the resources available to the poor (through microcredit, social funds, and occupational training); and strengthening the capac- ity of community-based organizations to represent and advocate for their communities. Community-driven development has the explicit objective of reversing power relations in a manner that creates agency and voice for poor people and gives them more control over develop- ment assistance. It also strengthens their capacity to undertake and manage self-initiated development activities. Advocates for local decentralization are motivated by a closely related logic that argues that reducing the distance between govern- ment and citizens allows governments to be closely observed. Citizens can communicate their preferences and needs to elected officials and closely monitor their performance, which improves both transparency and accountability; they are more likely to notice when local govern- ment officials steal money from a construction project, engage in nepotism, or spend their budgets without taking the views of citizens into account. Enhanced visibility is coupled with a greater capacity for citizens to mobilize and demand better services and hold local governments “socially accountable” by activating the local capacity for collective action. Decentralization, it is argued, also improves electoral accountability, because better-informed citizens are more capable of making more informed electoral choices. Furthermore, local govern- ments “hear” citizens better through direct interactions or deliberative forums, which increase the voice of citizens. Thus, according to advo- cates, decentralization improves voice, accountability, and transparency, making governments more responsive to the needs of citizens. Advocates of both community development and decentralization also argue that these forms of participatory development can be a train- ing ground for citizenship. Local democracies teach citizens how to 17
  • 38. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? engage in democratic politics and to engage, deliberate, and mobilize in ways that strengthen civil society. This vision is not universally shared. Some skeptics have misgivings about the basic precepts of the approach; others are concerned about the practical challenges of implementing large participatory projects on tight timelines (Cooke and Kothari 2001; Harriss 2001; Li 2007; Mosse 2002). Particularly when the incentives they face are poorly aligned with the needs of the project, implementers may gloss over differences within target groups and local power structures or evade the difficult task of institution building in favor of more easily deliverable and mea- surable outcomes. Community development may also be inherently subject to elite capture because of the entrenched influence of local elites (Abraham and Platteau 2004). The capacity of donor-led The capacity of donor-led participation to educate and transform participation to educate communities has been challenged on several grounds. First, some and transform communities researchers argue that the exercise of voice and choice can be costly has been challenged on (Mansuri and Rao 2004). It may involve financial losses for benefi- several grounds. ciaries, because of the time required to ensure adequate participation. Participation may also lead to psychological or physical duress for the most socially and economically disadvantaged, because it may require that they take positions that are in conflict with the interests of power- ful groups. The premise of participatory approaches is that its potential benefits outweigh such costs, but critics argue that this is by no means certain. Second, as participation has become mainstreamed, it has often been used to promote pragmatic policy interests, such as cost-effective delivery or low-cost maintenance rather than as a vehicle for radical social transformation, by shifting some of the costs of service delivery to potential beneficiaries. Indeed, in both Asia (Bowen 1986) and Africa (Ribot 1995), participation has been described as a form of forced or corvée labor, with the poor pressured into making far more substantial contributions than the rich. Third, critics argue that the belief that participatory experiences will transform the attitudes and implementation styles of authoritarian bureaucracies (governments or donors) may be naive. The routiniza- tion of participatory planning exercises into the work of public sector agencies creates additional pressure on resources while leaving imple- menters unclear about the implications of this new accountability. An examination of several participatory projects finds that even in projects 18
  • 39. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? with high levels of participation, “local knowledge” was often a con- struct of the planning context and concealed the underlying politics of knowledge production and use (Mosse 2002). Four potential pitfalls were identified: • Participatory exercises are often public events that are open ended regarding target groups and program activities. Thus, such events are inherently political, and the resulting project design is often shaped by local power and gender relations. • Outside agendas are often expressed as local knowledge. Project facilitators shape and direct participatory exercises, and the “needs” of beneficiaries are often shaped by perceptions of what the project can deliver. • Participants may concur in the process of problem definition and planning in order to manipulate the program to serve their own interests. Although their concurrence can benefit both proj- ect staff and beneficiaries, it places consensus and action above detailed planning. • Participatory processes can be used to legitimize a project that has previously established priorities and little real support from the community. Fourth, critics argue that local governments in developing countries Critics argue that local are not necessarily more accountable and transparent than central governments in developing governments because of the absence of prerequisites for local account- countries are not necessarily ability to work (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2006). These prerequisites more accountable and include an educated and aware citizenry, relative social and economic transparent than central equality, law and order, the ability to run free and fair elections within governments. a constitutional setting, reliable and trustworthy information channels, and oversight by an active and effective civil society. This report thus appears in the midst of a raging debate over the effectiveness of participatory development. Does it work? Does it increase accountability? Is it captured by elites? Does it increase voice and choice? Is it “empowering”? Is the money directed toward partici- patory development well spent? Sparked by concerns that the expan- sion in funding has not been accompanied by careful evaluations and independent analysis (Mansuri and Rao 2004), in recent years there has been a sharp increase in research, particularly impact evaluations, of community-based development. Scholars from a variety of disciplines have also substantially increased the understanding of the political 19
  • 40. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? economy of decentralization. The goal of this report is to place this research within an integrated conceptual framework, to summarize its conclusions, and to draw implications for policy. The History of Participatory Development The idea of civic The idea of civic participation is as old as the idea of democracy (Elster participation is as old 1998); it has existed in many different cultures throughout history. In as the idea of democracy. ancient Athens, policy decisions were made deliberatively, in public set- tings, with every male citizen given the opportunity to state his point of view. In Hinduism and Buddhism, public debate and deliberation have long been seen as a superior form of discourse (Sen 2005). Local deliberative institutions in South Asia, where these religions predomi- nate, have been documented dating back to about the fifth century BC (Altekar 1949). The Quran requires that communal affairs be decided by mutual consultation (shura) (Ayish 2008). In Islam, the community (umma) uses shura to not only deliberate but also provide inputs into public policy, which the ruler (khalifa) must consider. In pre-European Africa, Zulu chiefs could not make decisions without first consulting their councils (chila ya njama). Although the chiefs exercised ritual power, their influence depended on their ability to persuade and convince, not coerce. Among the Akan people in West Africa, the authority of the chief was greatly circumscribed. He was required to act in concurrence with counselors; an attempt to act on his own was legitimate grounds for dethronement. Local decentralization Local decentralization has an even longer history than participation. has an even longer history Archaeological evidence shows that small city-states in Mesopotamia than participation. and districts in Egypt ruled for many hundreds of years before being unified (around 3200 BC) into centrally ruled nations. Through con- quest, these nations formed even greater empires, but cities and districts within the conquered territories, although obliged to pay tribute and contribute soldiers to their overlords’ armies, essentially enjoyed home rule. In addition, as soon as the hold of the conqueror faltered, local hegemony grew strong (Gardiner 1961; Kramer 1971). Around 1200 BC, for instance, when the great powers of Egypt and Mesopotamia faced internal problems and invasion from the north, Phoenician vassal cities seized the opportunity to declare their 20
  • 41. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? independence. Although each city continued to rule itself, the cities agreed to form a loose geopolitical alliance. For the next 600 years, even during periods of foreign rule, ships from the Phoenician alliance plied the Mediterranean and traded throughout their vast economic empire (Mann 1986). When Phoenicia was later conquered—first by the Greeks, then by the Romans—its cities were forced to levy, collect, and send back revenues to the central power, but their municipal life continued to thrive. Rome actually encouraged (nonsubversive) civic activity, contributing handsomely to public buildings and activities across the empire (Abbot and Johnson 1968). Decentralized but loosely affiliated structures were also the rule in South Asia during the Mauryan (321–185 BC) and Mughal (1526– 1857) eras. Village governments had considerable authority and power over practical affairs; the center was seen largely as a place of moral and symbolic authority that extracted taxes and tribute. In Africa, vassals used collective decision making to hold chieftains in check, and com- munity members used consultations and popular assemblies to hold vassal governments accountable to the public at large. The modern theory of participation was first coherently articulated Rousseau first articulated the in the 18th century by Jean-Jacques Rousseau, author of The Social modern theory of Contract. Rousseau outlined a vision of democracy in which equal citi- participation in the 18th zens assemble to make decisions in an interdependent, deliberative man- century. ner, to uncover the “general will”—that is, to forge a policy in which benefits and burdens are equally shared (Pateman 1976). Rousseau was searching for a vision of human progress in which communities and connectedness could complement the Enlightenment’s notions of indi- vidual liberty, and in which the human soul was more important than science (Damrosch 2007). To Rousseau, participation was more than a method of decision making. It was a process by which an individual developed empathy for another’s point of view and learned to take account of the public interest in order to gain cooperation. Participation therefore served an important educative function: the individual learned how to become a public citizen, and community members developed a sense of belonging. Rousseau intimately linked the notion of participa- tion with the development of civic life—an idea that has had a profound influence on subsequent political thought. Among the many 19th century philosophers who built on these ideas, perhaps the most notable was John Stuart Mill (1859, 1879), 21
  • 42. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? who also emphasized the educative value of participation. Influenced by Alexis de Tocqueville’s laudatory descriptions in Democracy in America (1838) of local political institutions in the United States and the spirit of participatory democracy they fostered, Mill became deeply skepti- cal of centralized forms of government. His fears led him to argue that universal suffrage and participation in national government are of little use if citizens have not been prepared for participation at the local level. Mill applied this logic to notions of participation in industry, where, he argued, collective management would lead to individuals valuing public over individual interests. Mill’s vision of a participatory society was taken forward by G. D. H. Cole, Henry Maine, and other philosophers (known as the English Pluralists), who rejected the idea of a centralized state and argued that “individual freedom would best be realized in the groups and associ- ations that made up the fabric of modern civil society” (Mantena 2009). Henry Maine is of particular relevance to contemporary development thought. Sent to India in the 1860s to advise the British government on legal matters, he came across several accounts by British administrators of thriving indigenous systems of autonomous village governments that had many characteristics of participatory democracies. These “data” led him to articulate a theory of the village community as an alternative to the centralized state (Maine 1876). In Maine’s view, village communi- ties, led by a council of elders (panchayat), were not subject to a set of laws articulated from above but had more fluid legal and governance structures that adapted to changing conditions while maintaining strict adherence to traditional customs (Mantena 2009). Support for participation Community development and government decentralization thus stems from a belief that it has have a common intellectual history, stemming from a belief that par- both intrinsic and instrumental ticipation has both intrinsic and instrumental value. Participation in value. decision making, Maine believed, makes individuals into public citi- zens by training them to think in terms of the public good rather than merely private interests; it builds the capacity for collective action and what modern social theorists would call “agency.” Participation also has instrumental value in developing the ability of citizens to hold the state and markets accountable and to influence decisions that affect their lives. As the concept evolved, two distinct forms of participa- tion emerged: participation in Rousseau’s sense of building a collec- tive identity and participation in the sense of electing a representative government. 22
  • 43. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? Participation in Asia, Africa, and Latin America Rousseau, Mill, and Maine had a deep influence on colonial thought. In India, which became fertile territory for colonial experiments in gov- ernance, the liberal British Viceroy Lord Ripon instituted local govern- ment reforms in 1882 for the primary purpose of providing “political education” and reviving and extending India’s indigenous system of government (Tinker 1967). Maine’s description of autonomously governed and self-reliant Autonomously governed and Indian village communities also influenced Mohandas Gandhi, who self-reliant Indian village made it a central tenet of his philosophy of decentralized economic and communities were a central political power, as articulated in his writings on village self-reliance, tenet of Gandhi’s philosophy collected in his book Village Swaraj (Gandhi 1962). Gandhi saw the of decentralized economic and self-reliant village as the cornerstone of a system of government and of political power. economic life. The village was to be “a complete republic, independent of its neighbors for its own vital wants, and yet interdependent for many others where dependence is a necessity.” Gandhi’s village-republic would be emblematic of a “perfect democracy,” ensuring equality across castes and religions and self-sufficiency in all needs; it would be driven by cooperation and nonviolence. Gandhi remains a central figure in the participatory and decentralization movements in both India and the development community at large, particularly among people who see participation as an antidote to the community-corroding effects of economic growth and modernization. Decentralization in colonial anglophone Africa followed a similar trajectory, as the colonial powers adopted a policy of “decentralized despotism” (Mamdani 1996). The principal colonizers established administrative systems to efficiently govern and extract revenues from the conquered territories. The British established “indirect rule” that was, according to Mamdani, based on the lessons they had learned in India from the innovations in local self-government initiated by Ripon. The British converted traditional chiefs into “administrative chiefs” responsible for several functions at the lowest level of the civil admin- istration, granting them fiscal and functional autonomy as long as they did not challenge the colonial state. Decentralization in colonial India and Africa was as much an effort at streamlining colonial power as it was an effort at good governance. In the French colonies, by contrast, decentralization involved the direct application of French administrative structures, culture, 23
  • 44. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? civil law, and education to the colonies. The early colonies, such as Senegal, were organized according to the French local government model, based on urban communes represented by municipal councils. Citizens of the “four communes” of Senegal (Dakar, Gorée, St. Louis, and Rufisque) even elected representatives to the French parliament in Paris. Developments in Senegalese communes mirrored political devel- opments in France: when, in 1831, French communes were given legal status and the principle of elected municipal councils was established, these changes applied to the communes in Senegal. As the French acquired more territory and extended their control over larger populations, they reversed their policies and began to rule their new African colonies indirectly, through Africans. They established a code de l’ indigénat, which outlined the legal system under which indig- enous populations were to be governed (Levine 2004). This law pro- vided for the establishment of administrative cercles ruled by appointed indigenous authorities, religious courts, and the native police. Cercles comprised cantons, and cantons comprised villages. Villages were gov- erned by chefs du village, cantons by chefs de canton, and cercles by cercle commandeurs, each of whom was appointed by and responsible to the French authorities. The administrators who supervised these chiefs were recruited, trained, and fielded by the central state. Ribot (2009) points out that in “all these decentralized systems, the colonial rulers used local ‘customary’ chiefs to administer the rural world—that is, maintain law and order, collect taxes, and conscript labor. The systems were created to manage Africans under local administrative rule.” In Latin America, Spanish and Portuguese rule left a centralized legacy (Selee and Tulchin 2004; Grindle 2007; Eaton 2008). Colonial systems were based on the extraction of wealth and required highly centralized structures to coordinate the process. In Mexico, for example, the conquistadores appointed local councils tasked with maintaining law and order and overseeing food and water supplies (Grindle 2007); the councils were supervised and held in check by district agents, who were also responsible for tax collection. After independence, countries in Latin America modified these After independence, countries structures to conform with the more federalist notions from France in Latin America modified and the United States. In Brazil, for instance, the First Republic (which their centralized structures followed the centralized empire established immediately after inde- to conform with the more pendence) had pronounced federal features but provided little or no federalist notions from France support for local governments or municipalities. With its collapse, in and the United States. 24
  • 45. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? 1930, decentralization gave way to centralized institutions (Melo and Rezende 2004) and, paradoxically, “municipalism” became a hallmark of the more centralized developmentalist period. History of Policy in Participatory Development By the end of World War II, the disintegration of colonial regimes made reconstruction and development the central endeavors in Africa and Asia. Driven by the Bretton Woods institutions, development was viewed as a “big” undertaking, influenced by structural theories and planning models. “Small” development also had proponents, particu- larly among policy makers at the United Nations and the U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID), who tended toward a com- munitarian vision of human progress. Their influence led to a first wave of participatory development in the 1950s that by 1960 had spread to more than 60 countries in Africa, Asia, and Latin America (White 1999; Arizpe 2004).3 By 1959, USAID had pumped more than $50 million into community development projects in about 30 countries. In the con- text of the Cold War, community development was seen as a means of protecting newly independent states against the dual threats of external military aggression and internal subversion. Perhaps the most important motive was to provide a democratic alternative to Communism (White 1999; Arizpe 2004). In the 1950s, the communitarian approach was also promoted in In the 1950s, the U.S. India, primarily by the U.S. government and the Ford Foundation, government and the Ford where it resonated because of its compatibility with Gandhian ideals. Foundation promoted the The Ford Foundation approach drew on ideas from regional planners communitarian approach to in the United States who were concerned about the erosion of com- development in India. munities with the onset of modernization and urbanization, as well as on Gandhi’s ideas about sustainable village communities (Immerwahr 2010). In 1952, a Ford Foundation–supported program based on par- ticipatory models of community development was launched in 16,500 villages; the government of India soon expanded the program to cover the entire country. Funding for community development programs began to dry up in Funding for community the early 1960s, because of their perceived failures and because the spec- development programs began ter of famine in Asia made the more top-down, technical approaches to dry up in the early 1960s. to development seem more urgent. White (1999) argues that com- munity development programs during this period were undermined 25
  • 46. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? by the inability of donors to incorporate the lessons learned about elite capture or to engage in genuine partnerships with beneficiaries. As a consequence, community development programs were widely perceived, whether correctly or not, as having failed to achieve their stated objec- tives. They were more or less completely abandoned by the end of the 1960s. As donor interest in local participatory development waned, there was a revival of interest among radical thinkers. Particularly influential were Frantz Fanon’s The Wretched of the Earth (1961) and Paulo Freire’s Pedagogy of the Oppressed (1970). Fanon’s work, which was sometimes accused of exhorting readers to violence, was born out of frustration with the racism, torture, and vindictiveness of the colonial administra- tion in Algeria. In The Wretched of the Earth, he critiques both impe- rialism and nationalism and calls for the redistribution of wealth and technology that orient effective power in favor of the poorest people. Freire was influenced by Fanon and by liberation theologists in Brazil. His lifelong commitment to adult education helped him explore the ways in which the oppressed could overcome powerlessness and “unfreedom.” In Pedagogy of the Oppressed, he stresses the need to develop an educational system that is more “dialogic,” is rooted in students’ lived experiences, and values local and diverse kinds of knowl- edge. This kind of education becomes a tool for “conscientizing” illiter- ate (and oppressed) populations. In effect, Freire argues for a model of education that does not consider students’ minds a tabula rasa. Instead, the role of education is to make students more self-aware and sensitive to their position and to that of others—a theme very similar to Rousseau’s notion of the “general will.” During the 1960s and 1970s, During the 1960s and 1970s, policy makers began to shift their policy makers began to shift focus to agricultural and industrial growth. This shift was given intel- their focus to agricultural and lectual support from the apparent success of industrializing planning industrial growth . . . models of Soviet Russia and from early neoclassical growth models. The McNamara era at the World Bank focused first on large infra- structure projects and later on the centralized provision of housing, education, and health. Politically, centralized polities appeared to be viable and desirable. Even in the established democracies, mainstream democratic theories emphasized the representative rather than participa- tory features of democracy and the desirability of stability rather than the involvement of the lower classes. Democracy came to be thought of as merely a method of aggregating preferences by choosing leaders, 26
  • 47. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? and the deliberation and civic empowerment aspects of the concept were deemphasized (see Schumpeter 1942 and Dahl 1963 for typical formulations). Also during this period, economists, who had long been skeptical of . . . and economists, who community-centered development, began to have a profound influence had long been skeptical on development policy. The early literature on development policy was of community-centered strongly influenced by the work of Mancur Olson (1965, 2), who argued development, began to have that without coercion or some other special device to make individuals a profound influence on act in their common interest “rational self-interested individuals will development policy. not act to achieve their common or group interests.” Olson was con- cerned with “exploitation of the great by the small,” because people with smaller interests in a public good would tend to free-ride on the efforts of people with greater interests. Hardin’s (1968) powerful idea of the “tragedy of the commons” had even broader implications for a range of economic issues, including the domain of the public and the private, decentralization of power to local governments, and the provision and management of common- pool resources. Like Hardin, property rights theorists such as Demsetz (1970) and North (1990) argued that common property resources would be overexploited as demand rose unless the commons were enclosed or protected by strong state regulation. This view generated a great deal of pessimism in multilateral development institutions about the viability of local provision or management of public goods or the commons. It created a strong impetus for centralized state provision of public goods, central regulation of common-pool resources, and an emphasis on private property rights. At the same time, there was strong support among economic theorists for decentralized government with electoral democracy. Economists approached this problem in several ways. Tiebout’s (1956) work on the theory of local government expenditures emphasized the efficiency of decentralized governance. He argued that in a community context, if mobility were relatively costless, individuals would reveal their true preferences for levels and combinations of public goods pro- vision by “voting with their feet”—moving to the locality that offered their preferred tax-benefit mix. Competition among jurisdictions sup- plying different combinations of local public goods would thus lead to an efficient supply of such goods. The Tiebout hypothesis later came under heavy attack on the grounds that its assumptions—full information about community 27
  • 48. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? characteristics, costless mobility, no externalities, no economies of scale, and static preferences—were untenable in developing countries, and indeed in many developed countries as well. Nevertheless, Tiebout con- tinues to be widely invoked to support the view that competition among local jurisdictions in the provision of public goods increases allocative efficiency—and consequently to justify a push toward decentralization. By the mid-1980s, critics By the mid-1980s, critics of the top-down approach began to com- of the top-down approach plain that many large-scale, centralized, government-initiated devel- began to complain that many opment programs—from schooling to health to credit to irrigation large-scale, centralized, systems—were performing poorly while rapidly degrading common- government-initiated pool resources and having significant negative environmental and development programs were poverty impacts. These complaints reawakened interest in local deci- performing poorly. sion making and the local management of resources. Led by Chambers (1983) and others, a new participatory development movement applied these ideas to small-scale projects in ways that allowed the poor to act as informed participants, with external agents serving mainly as facilitators and sources of funds. Further support came from the increasingly strong critique of development from academic social scientists such as Escobar (1995) and Scott (1999), who argued that top-down perspectives were both disempowering and ineffective. Meanwhile, highly successful community-driven development initiatives—such as the Self-Employed Women’s Association in India, the Orangi Slum Improvement Project in Pakistan, and the Iringa Nutrition Project in Tanzania—were providing important lessons for large donors (Krishna, Uphoff, and Esman 1997). Thinking in mainstream development circles was also significantly affected by the work of Hirschman (1970, 1984); Cernea (1985); and Ostrom (1990). Hirschman’s (1970) notions of “voice” and “exit” helped development practitioners understand how collective agency could improve well-being. Hirschman’s (1984) own attempts to apply these ideas to participatory development helped confirm his theories. Cernea (1985) showed how large organizations such as the World Bank could “put people first” by working systematically at the local level. Ostrom’s (1990) work on the management of common-pool resources shifted per- ceptions about the potential for collective action in poor communities. She argued that what made Olson’s and Hardin’s work most powerful also made it dangerous as a foundation for policy making, as their results depended on a set of constraints imposed for purposes of analy- sis. The relevance of their theories for policy making, she contended, was an open question rather than a foregone conclusion. In the real 28
  • 49. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? world, the capabilities of the people involved can be changed, altering the constraints. Ostrom and others assembled considerable evidence from case studies showing that endogenous institutions often man- aged common-pool resources successfully. Thus, Hardin’s “remorseless tragedies” were not an inevitable outcome of community management. Sen’s (1985, 1999) effort to shift the focus of development from material well-being to a broad-based “capability” approach also deeply influenced the development community. Central to this approach were strategies to “empower” poor people—an agenda taken on by the World Bank and other donors as part of their response to criticism of top-down development. Arguments for “participatory development,” as advocated by Chambers (1983) and others, led to the inclusion of participation as a crucial means of allowing the poor to have some control over decisions that affected them. These intellectual developments paralleled the rise of pro-democracy movements, which led to the breakdown of authoritarian regimes in many parts of the world (Leftwich 1993; O’Donnell 1993). The 1980s and 1990s witnessed the collapse of totalitarian systems in Eastern Europe, the former Soviet Union, and Indonesia and the radical redistri- bution of power and authority in Brazil and the Philippines. The rise of democratic movements and the conviction that centralized state institu- tions were corrupt, unaccountable, and unable to deliver public services led to a growing belief in the value of decentralized government. Mexico is a typical example. By 1982, international donors had begun to advise the country’s central government to both initiate structural adjustment and share administrative and fiscal responsibilities with lower tiers of government (Mizrahi 2004; Grindle 2007). USAID was among the earliest donors to extend explicit support USAID was among the to democratic decentralization. In the late 1980s, with the fall of earliest donors to extend Communism in Eastern Europe, the agency spelled out its agenda to explicit support to democratic support democratic local governance. It viewed decentralization as a decentralization. “means to empower citizens locally and to disperse power from the central government to localities” (USAID 2000, 4 ). By the early 1990s, the British and French governments, the Development Assistance Committee, the European Council, the Heads of State and Government of the Organization of African Unity, and the Commonwealth Heads of Government had all (re)committed to strengthening democracy, par- ticipation, and accountability through the mechanism of decentraliza- tion. The United Nations Development Programme began to explicitly 29
  • 50. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? extend assistance to decentralization in 1992; by 1999, it had spent more than $138 million on decentralization projects. The World Bank The World Bank was perhaps most instrumental in popularizing the was instrumental in concept of decentralization, by articulating the pressing significance popularizing the concept of of governance issues, especially in Africa. Its focus on governance was decentralization. motivated by the difficult economic climate of the 1980s, coupled with the realization that investment lending required an appropriate policy framework to achieve its objectives. Its influential publication, Governance and Development, summed up the benefits of local decen- tralization as resulting in significant improvements in efficiency and effectiveness (World Bank 1992). Support for decentralization was by no means unqualified: some observers noted that the “pure decentralization of fi scal federalism theory” (Prud’homme 1995, 202) could jeopardize macroeconomic stability and increase regional disparities within countries. Nonetheless, by 1996, the Bank recognized the role of citizen participation in holding state structures accountable as key to effective local government. If the move toward local decentralization was driven largely by a desire for better governance, community development was driven by the belief that investing in the “social capital” of communities would lead to their empowerment and give them a sustainable capacity to fashion development in their own terms. The inclusion of participatory ele- ments in large-scale development assistance came quickly at the World Bank, in social investment funds (Narayan and Ebbe 1997) and other forms of assistance. Initially focused on targeting poverty, these projects moved toward a more holistic effort to encourage participation through institutions that organize the poor and build their capabilities to act collectively in their own interest (Narayan 2002). The World Bank’s (2001) World Development Report 2000/2001: Attacking Poverty focused on empowerment as a key priority of development policy. Its publication led to a broad-based effort at the Bank to scale up community-based development. The World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People identified local accountability and local decen- tralization as important elements of programs that seek to improve the delivery of public services (World Bank 2004). More recently, donors have recognized that strengthening governance is key to effective devel- opment and that improving civic participation, or the “demand side” of governance, should be an important object of community development and decentralization. With this second wave of interest in participatory 30
  • 51. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? approaches to development, participatory notions have, once again, been absorbed into the mainstream of development thought and practice.4 Thus, the two types of local participation—community develop- ment and local decentralization—have common goals and intellectual origins. They became distinct modalities promoted by distinct ideologi- cal camps in the second half of the 20th century. In the current (21st century) wave of interest in local participation, policy does not distin- guish clearly between the two interpretations. Many decentralization programs with local electoral democracy place local deliberative forums at the heart of decision making (examples include participatory budget- ing and gram sabhas [village assemblies]), and many community-driven projects build electoral accountability into their leadership selection process. Thus, lessons from the evidence on village democracy could have implications for the design of community-driven projects, and lessons from participatory forums in community-driven projects could have implications for the design of decentralization programs. For this reason, both are treated here within the common framework of local participatory development. Organic versus Induced Participation Achieving participatory governance and building civic capacity has Organic participation is historically been an organic rather than a state-led process—a process spurred by civic groups acting spurred by civic groups acting independently of, and often in opposi- independently of, and often in tion to, government. Organic participation is usually driven by social opposition to, government. movements aimed at confronting powerful individuals and institu- tions within industries and government and improving the function- ing of these spheres through a process of conflict, confrontation, and accommodation. Such processes are often effective because they arise endogenously, within a country’s trajectory of change, and are directed by highly motivated, charismatic leaders who mobilize citizens to give voice to their interests (grievances, rights, and concerns) and exploit political opportunities. Social movements demand change by confronting situa- tions they find untenable; they ultimately achieve their goals when they are able to influence the political process or obtain political power. They engage in a process of creative destruction. First, they imagine a world in which social and political relationships are more equitably arranged—or 31
  • 52. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? at least restructured in a manner congruent with the interests of the movement—they articulate their vision of this world to expand their influence. Then, they mobilize citizens who believe in this vision to fight for the cause, often at considerable personal cost. Organic participation is a broad term that covers a variety of civic activities. It has historically been the norm for civic expression. It includes social movements that fight for greater democratic expression and for the rights of the underprivileged, such as the civil rights move- ment in the United States and the anti-apartheid movement in South Africa. It also includes attempts to build membership-based organiza- tions to improve livelihoods and living standards, such as the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh or the Self-Employed Women’s Association in India. Organic participation may also include labor movements that form unions to protect workers and trade associations formed to repre- sent the interests of a particular industry. Induced participation refers to Induced participation, by contrast, refers to participation promoted participation promoted through through policy actions of the state and implemented by bureaucracies policy actions of the state and (the “state” can include external governments working through bilateral implemented by bureaucracies. and multilateral agencies, which usually operate with the consent of the sovereign state). Induced participation comes in two forms: decentral- ization and community-driven development. The important difference between induced and organic participation is that powerful institutions extrinsically promote inducted participa- tion, usually in a manner that affects a large number of communities at the same time. In contrast, intrinsically motivated local actors drive organic participation. There is often some overlap between organic and induced participa- tion. Governments may decentralize because of the efforts of social movements, and the designs of induced participatory programs are often built on organic models. A government may decide to scale up the efforts of small-scale organic initiatives and thus turn them into induced initiatives. An important question is whether efforts initiated by organic participation can be scaled up by policy interventions in the form of projects. Rather than wait for the slow process of the endog- enous development of civic capacity, can policy interventions harness the capacity of citizens to help themselves and improve the quality of government and the functioning of markets? The organic development of civic capacity is a complex process that is deeply imbedded in a country’s history, its internal conflicts, 32
  • 53. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? its conception of nationalism, its levels of education and literacy, the distribution of education and wealth, the nature of the state, the nature of economic and political markets, and a variety of other conditions. Organic participation is driven by self-motivated leaders who work tirelessly, with little compensation, often at a high opportunity cost. They are constantly innovating, networking, and organizing to get the movement to succeed. When this complex process of organic change, driven by intrinsically motivated people, is turned into policy—projects and interventions to induce participation—it has to be transformed into manageable, bureaucratically defined entities, with budgets, targets, and extrinsically motivated salaried staff as agents of change. This transfor- mation is common to all large-scale, state-led policy initiatives; it has been famously characterized by Scott (1999) as “seeing like a state.” But participatory interventions are different from other types of policy initiatives, because they are based on an inherent irony: the government is creating institutions structured to resist failures in government. When government induces participation by means of projects, its agents often must act against their self-interest by promoting institutions whose pur- pose is to upset the equilibrium that gives them considerable personal advantage. Moreover, by devolving power to the local level, higher levels of government cede power, authority, and finances to communities over which they may have little control. Despite these challenges, in recent years, some countries have Some countries have induced successfully induced participation by actively promoting participa- participation by actively tory spaces within decentralized systems of governance. One of the promoting participatory best-known cases involves participatory budgeting in Porto Alegre, spaces within decentralized Brazil. Baiocchi (2005) reviews the history of Brazil’s transition from systems of governance. dictatorship to democracy in 1985, placing the Porto Alegre experi- ment within the context of this shift. By 1988, decentralization to the local level was codified in the new Brazilian constitution, and municipal elections were held. Two years later, a candidate from the Workers Party, which had become a leader in the citizens’ rights move- ment during the dictatorship, was elected mayor of Porto Alegre.5 The new mayor introduced participatory budgeting. After some years of experimentation, by the year 2000 participatory budgeting assemblies were drawing more than 14,000 participants from the city’s poorer classes and achieving substantial success in improving a range of devel- opment outcomes. About 9–21 percent of the city’s annual budget was dedicated to pro-poor investments, leading to almost full sewerage and 33
  • 54. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? water coverage, a threefold increase in municipal school enrollment, and a significant increase in housing for poor families. Another important, if less than ideal, example of an entire country trying to introduce empowered participatory governance is the pan- chayat (rural governance) reform in India. Before the enactment of the 73rd amendment to the constitution, in 1992, village democracy in India was extremely uneven, despite the fact that most state constitu- tions mandated regular village elections and gave village governments some degree of fiscal authority. The amendment addressed these prob- lems in several ways: • It set up a three-tiered panchayat system consisting of gram panchayats (village councils), block panchayats (block councils), and zila panchayats (district councils). • It systematized panchayat elections to all three levels, established independent election commissions, and gave the panchayats more fiscal authority and political power. • It mandated that gram sabhas (village meetings) be held at regular intervals throughout the year, to allow anyone in the village to discuss budgets, development plans, and the selec- tion of beneficiaries and to interrogate gram panchayat and local administrative officials on any issue. • It reserved a proportion of seats on gram panchayats, including the position of gram panchayat president, for members of disad- vantaged castes (according to their share of the village popula- tion) and women (who are allocated a third of all seats in the gram panchayat and a third of gram panchayat presidencies on a rotating basis). By making deliberative processes through the gram sabha a corner- stone of village government, the central authorities in India created a civic sphere that was not organically derived but, rather, sponsored by the state—in effect, blurring the boundary between the state and civil society and between organic and induced participation. By reducing its monopoly on power and altering its relationship with citizens, the government changed the terms of citizens’ engagement with the power structure. However, although a constitutional amendment sparked reforms in village democracy, responsibility for implementing those reforms remained with state governments, which has made the quality of the implementation variable, and dependent on local state politics. 34
  • 55. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? Village democracy in China is another example of a centrally driven policy change toward decentralization and participation. Through much of China’s long history, the central state has ruled the country- side only indirectly. In fact, during the Ming (1468–1644) and Qing (1644–1911) dynasties, the imperial bureaucracy extended only to the xian (county) level, leaving control of the countryside largely in the hands of the local gentry and elites. It was not until the modern era (comprising the Republican Period [1911–49] and the People’s Republic of China [1949–present]) that the central government consolidated its control of the countryside. Beginning with land reforms in 1949 and accelerating with the collectivization of agriculture in the mid-1950s, the state established official bureaucracies at the county, township, and (through the Communist Party Secretariat and branches) village levels. Despite tight governmental control for state purposes, however, rural citizens remained marginalized when it came to social services, and the vast majority of national resources went to build cities and industry. It was not until the 1970s that administrative power was decentralized to rural communes, which were converted into townships and villages. In these new entities, the more entrepreneurial officials soon began using their newfound authority and discretion to take advantage of opportu- nities opened up by market liberalization. Within a few years, China’s countryside became a dynamic new source of economic growth. Politically and administratively, however, decollectivization and the break-up of the communes left a vacuum in governance below the town- ship level. To fill this gap, China enacted the Draft Village Organic Law (1987) and the Village Organic Law (1998), which reaffirmed villagers’ right to self-government, the popular election of local officials, and the central Communist Party’s role in village rule. These reforms recog- nized the village as the most important funder and provider of local public goods and services for the rural population. They vested land ownership rights in the village or collective and allocated use rights to households on terms regulated by national law. Electoral democracy at the local level now coexists with nominated or appointed Communist Party rule at the apex. Since 1998, China has held direct elections for village committees, the organizational blocks of rural life that are responsible for public services at the local level. The electoral process, enshrined in Article 14 of the Organic Law on Villagers Committees, combines a process of public nomination with secret ballots. The design of this process was based on a series of pilots encouraged by the 35
  • 56. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? government in as many as 24 provinces (Zhenyao 2007), making China one of the few countries in the world where popular deliberations have been organized to determine electoral mechanisms. In China, the introduction of In Brazil and India, participatory innovations were the culmina- local democracy was entirely tion of long periods of engagement by social movements that exploited the result of a technocratic political opportunities at the center to slowly move the case for partici- decision by the center. patory democracy forward. This was not the case in China, where the introduction of local democracy was entirely the result of a technocratic decision by the center. As such, local democracy is more an administra- tive mandate, which could be withdrawn. Unlike participatory innovations in decentralized local governments, community-driven development interventions are usually packaged as “projects” and designed as grants or loans that work within, and are often implemented by, existing government institutions. They are con- sequently greatly influenced by the institutional structures and incen- tives of donors and bound by their time frames (usually three to five years). At their best, these projects attempt to speed up the rate of insti- tutional change by nudging reforms in a direction to which national governments are already committed. More typically, community-driven development projects work in parallel with local governments, often bypassing them by setting up competing sources of authority within communities. Some projects have very ambitious goals (“reduce poverty by 20 percent,” “rebuild trust,” “enhance civic capacity”). Others have more circumscribed objectives, such as the introduction of a participa- tory mechanism into particular arenas (schools with parent-teacher associations, rural clinics with village health committees). Many proj- ects that are not classified as community driven also use deliberative and participatory processes for limited objectives, such as selecting deserving beneficiaries for targeted programs, forming village committees to man- age the construction of a village infrastructure project, or establishing microcredit groups. Figure 1.1 illustrates the difficult task of characterizing the differ- ent modalities of induced participation. The nature of participation is influenced not just by the social and political context in which it is situated but also by the way in which it is designed. Both the context and the design have a strong influence on incentives for implementers and beneficiaries and, consequently, on accountability and the sustain- ability of the intervention. A country’s political system matters a great deal. In democracies, electoral incentives shape participatory interventions. Participatory 36
  • 57. Figure 1.1 A typology of induced participation Nondemocratic state Political Short term decentralization Single purpose Deconcentration Induced Multiple purpose Community-driven Long term development Democratic state Type of local participatory project or intervention Implementation Central Local Independent project Direct implementation government government implementation agency by NGO Organic WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? Funding Central Local Donor government revenue 37
  • 58. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? In democracies, electoral projects are often pushed through just before elections as an easy way incentives shape participatory to dole out money to voters. There is a constant tension between central interventions. and local governments, with central governments attempting to reclaim powers that have been locally devolved. Stable democracies also allow for more stable trajectories of decentralization. They have an affinity for empowered participation functioning in the presence of strong civic institutions, which can play an important role in local empowerment. Nondemocratic countries, particularly countries that have a history of careening between democracy and dictatorship, have more unstable polities. As a result, citizens cannot always act in ways that are consistent with the expectation of long-term change. This uncertainty, in turn, reduces their confidence that the increase in local power brought about by a project will result in lasting change, making them more fearful of eventual retaliation by local elites. Even nondemocratic countries that have stable, technocratically driven administrations can demonstrate a commitment to local decentralization, motivated by allocative efficiency. Thus, there can be situations in which democratic participation at the local level is coupled with a more authoritarian structure at the center. The next node in figure 1.1 categorizes participation into three modalities: political decentralization, deconcentration, and community- driven development. In politically decentralized systems, community leaders are democratically elected through credible and competitive elections. At the same time, power and finances are devolved to local governments. Administrative decentralization occurs when central authorities allocate some functions of government to lower-level admin- istrators, who generally report to the central state. Community-based and community-driven development refer to projects in which com- munities, functioning outside a formal system of government, are given funds that they manage to implement subinterventions. In practice, these modalities often overlap, or exist in parallel, with a variety of sub- modalities. For instance, some community-driven development projects are designed to strengthen local democratically elected governments or create alternative power structures to counter the power of nonelected local administrators. The stability of political The stability of political decentralization depends on the extent to decentralization depends on which the center is committed to local democracy; decentralization is the extent to which the center is most stable when village and municipal democracies have been granted committed to local democracy. constitutional sanction. Political decentralization sharply increases the incentives for electoral accountability and therefore for the sustained 38
  • 59. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? empowerment of citizens, but it can be influenced by clientelistic politics. In deconcentrated systems, local administrators tend to face incentives driven by the center; they are therefore usually characterized by upward rather than downward accountability. Effective deconcen- tration, which is technocratically driven, can also result in the efficient allocation of tasks. It is, however, not generally conducive to the devel- opment of sustained local participation. The effectiveness of community-driven interventions at the local The effectiveness of level is highly conditioned by local capacity, in particular the capacity community-driven for collective action. Local social structures and levels of elite control interventions at the local level can play a strong role in its functioning. In such interventions, the is highly conditioned by local challenge is for state agencies responsible for projects to internalize the capacity, in particular the intrinsic and instrumental values of participation and to ensure that capacity for collective action. projects are implemented in a manner that meets their stated inten- tions. If participation is introduced to solve a principal-agent problem in a situation in which the central managers of an agency lack the information and the capacity to monitor the quality of services in local communities, participation will likely be seen as a complement to their objectives. In contrast, if central agencies are enmeshed in a nexus of accommodation and capture with local elites, which would be jeopar- dized by effective participation, central government officials will more likely see participation as a threat. In its early stages, the process of participation may be more noisy than useful; changing this dynamic requires sustained engagement and a strong commitment from the center. The nature of the state thus affects the quality of participation. A state that is reasonably effective and seeks to improve its ability to deliver local public goods and services could provide an enabling environment for participation. A weak state that is dominated by elites and enmeshed in structures of expropriation and that introduces participation only in response to external donor pressure probably would not provide such an environment. The next node in figure 1.1 indicates that participatory interventions that focus on a single objective (such as parental control over schools) are fundamentally different from interventions with multiple purposes (such as devolution of a set of powers to village governments or liveli- hoods projects that provide everything from credit and jobs to nutrition and sanitation). The structure of incentives in each is different. It affects the extent and nature of community participation and the involvement of higher levels of government. 39
  • 60. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? An important concern, depicted in the next node in figure 1.1, is whether the intervention has a long or short horizon. Interventions with long-term horizons—say, an effort to introduce local democracy at the local level that has constitutional sanction—fundamentally improve the incentives of citizens to confront local elites and fight for their interests. Interventions with short-term horizons will incentivize individuals to extract all the rents that they can from the project during its tenure. The top half of figure 1.1 maps some of the permutations within which participatory interventions can be designed. Each permutation results in different incentives, which influence the effectiveness and sustainability of the project. It suggests that a community-based effort to manage village schools run within a political decentralized system within a democratic country is more likely to lead to a sustainable and equitable improvement in welfare than a well-funded community- driven development project with a three-year horizon that is run by a deconcentrated administration within an unstable authoritarian country. The bottom half of figure 1.1 shows how project implementation matters. Central governments, local governments, NGOs, and indepen- dent project implementation agencies can all run induced participatory projects. Typically, some combination of these bodies runs projects (for instance, the central government or the project agency may hire an NGO to implement a project at the local level). Who manages project imple- mentation has implications for accountability and the quality of imple- mentation. If democratically elected, local governments can be the most downwardly accountable. NGOs and project implementation agencies are deeply affected by the incentives of their organizations; unless their organizational incentives are set up in a way that encourages them to do so, they may not be accountable to the demands of communities. Funding matters. Funding also matters. Is funding derived entirely from central alloca- tions to local communities? Is it dependent on local revenue generation through taxes and community participation, or is it entirely dependent on donor funds? Each situation is affected by a different political economy and incentives for community participation. If, for example, a community-based effort to manage schools is managed exclusively by NGOs and dependent on donor funds, it might be well funded and well managed in the short term but it would be subject to the risk of failure in the long term. In contrast, if the intervention is managed by local governments and funded by local taxes, implementation may be ineffective in the short term, because of clientelism and the inability of 40
  • 61. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? local governments to collect taxes. However, the project could become more effective over the long term as communities become more politi- cally mature. Scope of the Report and Roadmap The scope of this report is broad. The report focuses on the impact of efforts to induce participation. It therefore does not review the large body of literature on organic participation, although it draws on several lessons from efforts to scale-up organic movements through induced policy interventions. The focus is on participatory development; much less attention is paid to the important “supply-side” aspects of governance (fiscal decen- tralization, taxation policy, local government procedures, and bureau- cratic inefficiency). The literature on this issue has been the subject of other reports and reviews by the World Bank, in particular the series of books edited by Anwar Shah (2006a, 2006b, 2006c, 2006d). “Local” development does not mean decentralization to subnational bodies, such as state or district governments. Decentralization of this kind is the subject of a large body of literature related to fiscal federalism and its variants. The focus here is on local participatory development. Attention is therefore confined to the lowest level of government, typi- cally the municipal and village levels, and to community organizations, village committees, and neighborhood associations. The report examines large-scale participatory projects that have been evaluated based on representative samples of target populations with adequate counterfactuals (alternate scenarios of what would have happened to the targeted communities in the absence of the interven- tion). The ideal counterfactual would be the same community in the absence of the intervention—a situation that cannot be observed. Econometricians and statisticians have therefore devised various methods that attempt to approximate this ideal by finding methods of selecting “control” groups. These methods include randomized trials, regression discontinuity designs, well-designed methods of matching, and natural experiments. A limitation of the counterfactuals used by evaluations of partici- patory projects is that they generally compare communities with the intervention to control communities in which the status quo is main- tained. Few compare the participatory intervention to an alternate type 41
  • 62. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? of intervention (or “arm”) that could help inform design. For example, very few studies compare outcomes delivered by participatory interven- tions with top-down interventions, limiting the ability to determine whether participatory methods work better or worse than alternate designs. Examining the impact of a participatory intervention with respect to the status quo remains extremely useful, however, because it allows researchers to credibly assess the impact of the intervention. Several useful lessons emerge from the review of a large body of such evidence. Most of the fi ndings, therefore, derive from econometric analysis, although case studies are used to develop ideas and illustrate the conceptual framework. Several observational studies are also sum- marized to illustrate key points throughout the report. Another criterion used to select studies for review is that they were published in a peer-reviewed journal or written by scholars with a track record of peer-reviewed publication. Some studies that do not satisfy these criteria were included because of thinness in the literature on a particular topic or some other compelling reason. In such cases, poten- tial problems with the study are clearly identified before conclusions are drawn from it. (Throughout the report, the strengths and weaknesses in the methodology used by the researchers is assessed and conclusions are drawn only from studies whose methodology can be defended.) The rest of this report is organized as follows. Chapter 2 provides a conceptual framework for participatory development. It develops the notion of civil society failure and explores the interactions among civil society failure, government failure, and market failure as key to diag- nosing problems in local development. The chapter also examines the implications of civil society failure and how such failure relates to the size of groups and elite control and capture. Chapter 3 focuses on the challenge of inducing participation by developing some of the policy implications of this “failure triangle.” It develops a set of criteria for diagnosing civil society failures and under- standing how the intersection of market, government, and civil society failure affects the dynamics of local development. This framework is used to examine the challenges of implementation, including the role of donors and facilitators, and of working within the multiple uncertain- ties of highly variant contexts and unknown trajectories of change. A set of hypotheses is derived from the conceptual framework. 42
  • 63. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? Chapters 4, 5, and 6 present the evidence in support of and at odds with the hypotheses. Chapter 4 focuses on the evidence on elite capture and its importance within the broader context of leadership and rep- resentation within communities. It also examines the role of political and electoral incentives in determining the quality of leadership and the local prevalence of corruption, investigating whether corruption can be countered by better accountability mechanisms. The chapter attempts to answer a series of questions: How does inequality in communities affect the process of resource allocation? To what extent do elites domi- nate the process of decision making? To what extent does introducing local democracy make government more accountable? To what extent does it change political incentives? Does devolving the allocation of funds to communities make them more susceptible to corruption and theft? Under what conditions does participation empower citizens to act in their own interests? Chapter 5 examines the claim that participation improves the deliv- ery of public goods and services, the management of common property resources, and living standards. It begins by examining the effectiveness of community-based approaches in targeting the poor. It tries to deter- mine whether localized projects outperform centrally driven projects in targeted private transfers to the poor and whether local projects allocate public goods in a manner that better matches the needs of the poor. The chapter then looks at the impact of participation on common-pool resources, local infrastructure, schooling, and health. Does involving communities in managing local public facilities improve maintenance? Are common-property resources more sustainable when communities manage them? Does involving parents in the management of schools improve learning outcomes? Does oversight of local public clinics and hospitals by individuals who come within their scope of operation improve health outcomes? When citizens participate in decisions on local public goods and services, are they more satisfied with how the agents of government provide these services? More generally, are par- ticipatory projects effective in expanding livelihood options for the poor and generating wealth? Chapter 6 assesses the evidence on whether participatory develop- ment can build civil society. The evidence is examined to answer some fundamental questions: How do deliberative processes actually work 43
  • 64. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? in developing countries? Is deliberation equitable? Is it sustainable? Under what conditions does it build the capacity to engage? Can local inequalities in power and social structure be remedied by mandating the inclusion of women and discriminated against minorities in leader- ship positions? Does improving, and equalizing, access to information result in better outcomes? Does participation build social capital? Does it improve the community’s capacity to monitor and sanction govern- ment? How well do participatory projects work in postconflict settings in particularly dysfunctional states? Chapter 7 poses some remaining open questions and suggests some directions for future research on participatory development. It then assesses the World Bank’s approach to participatory development, reviewing the extent to which it reflects some of the principles that are essential to effective implementation. The chapter reviews design docu- ments from a large sample of World Bank participatory projects and reports findings from a survey of project managers. It offers some policy recommendations for the World Bank and other agencies engaged in designing and implementing induced participatory projects. Notes 1. Lack of data availability and problems with definitions make it difficult to find accurate estimates of total World Bank lending for these sectors. According to the Bank’s Social Development Department, total lending for community-based and community-drive development was $54 billion over the 1999–2011 period, with $7.8 billion allocated in fiscal 2010 alone. Between 1990 and 2007, another $31.6 billion was allocated to lending for projects with decentralization components, raising the total allocation for local participatory development to about $85 billion. 2. Reliable figures are hard to come by because of the large numbers of such organizations and the diverse ways in which they report their data. 3. Community development programs were also in vogue in francophone Africa as animation rurale, since at least 1945 (White 1999). 4. White (1999) identifies a second wave in the 1970s and 1980s, initiated by the UN system. In fact, it seems more a ripple than a wave, as it had little influence on large lending agencies. White calls the current interest in community-driven development a third wave, “with the added impetus given by the conversion of the World Bank to the cause” (109). 5. The left-leaning Workers Party was founded in 1980 as a party where “social movements can speak.” 44
  • 65. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? References Abbot, F. F., and C. Johnson. 1968. Municipal Administration in the Roman Empire. New York: Russell and Russell. Abraham, A., and J.-P. Platteau. 2004. “Participatory Development: When Culture Creeps.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton, 210–33. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Altekar, A. S. 1949. State and Government in Ancient India: From Earliest Times till 1200 A.D. New Delhi: Motilal Banarsidass. Arizpe, L. 2004. “The Intellectual History of Culture and Development Institutions.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton, 163–84. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Ayish, M. I. 2008. The New Arab Public Sphere. Berlin: Frank and Timme GmbH Verlag. Baiocchi, G. 2005. Militants and Citizens: The Politics of Participatory Democracy in Porto Alegre. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2006. “The Rise of Local Governments: An Overview.” In Decentralization and Governance in Developing Countries, ed. P. Bardhan and D. Mookherhee, 1–52. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Bowen, J. R. 1986. “On the Political Construction of Tradition: Gotong Royong in Indonesia.” Journal of Asian Studies 45(3): 545–61. Cernea, M. M. 1985. Putting People First: Sociological Variables in Rural Development. New York: Oxford University Press. Chambers, R. 1983. Rural Development: Putting the Last First. Harlow, U.K.: Pearson Education. Cooke, B., and U. Kothari. 2001. Participation: The New Tyranny? London: Zed Books. Dahl, R. 1963. A Preface to Democratic Theory. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Damrosch, L. 2007. Jean-Jacques Rousseau: Restless Genius. New York: Mariner Books. Demsetz, H. 1970. “The Private Production of Public Goods.” Journal of Law and Economics 13(2): 293–306. de Tocqueville, Alexis. 1838. Democracy in America. New York: George Dearborn and Company. Dongier, P., J. V. Domelen, E. Ostrom, A. Ryan, W. Wakeman, A. Bebbington, S. Alkire, T. Esmail, and M. Polski. 2001. “Community Driven Development.” In A Sourcebook for Poverty Reduction Strategies, ed. Jeni Klugman, 301–31. Washington, DC: World Bank. Eaton, K. 2008. “Decentralization and Governance: Lessons from Latin America.” Background paper for World Bank Policy Research Report, Washington, DC. Elster, J. 1998. “Introduction.” In Deliberative Democracy. ed. J. Elster, 1–18, Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Escobar, A. 1995. Encountering Development: The Making and Unmaking of the Third World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 45
  • 66. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Fanon, F. 1961. Les damnés de la terre. Paris: François Maspero. Freire, P. 1970. Pedagogy of the Oppressed. New York: Herder and Herder. Gandhi, M. 1962. Village Swaraj. Ahmedabad, India: Navjivan Press. Gardiner, A. 1961. Egypt of the Pharaohs: An Introduction. New York: Oxford University Press. Grindle, M. 2007. Going Local: Decentralization, Democratization, and the Promise of Good Governance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Hardin, G. 1968. “The Tragedy of the Commons.” Science 162(3859): 1243–48. Harriss, J. 2001. Depoliticizing Development: The World Bank and Social Capital. New Delhi: LeftWord Books. Hirschman, A. O. 1970. Exit Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. ———. 1984. Getting Ahead Collectively: Grassroots Experiences in Latin America. New York: Pergamon. Immerwahr, D. 2010. Community Development in India. Working Paper, Department of History, University of California, Berkeley. Kramer, S.N. 1971, The Sumerians: Their History, Culture and Character. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Krishna, A., N. T. Uphoff, and M. J. Esman. 1997. Reasons for Hope: Instructive Experiences in Rural Development. West Hartford, CT: Kumarian. Leftwich, A. 1993. “Governance, Democracy and Development in the Third World.” Third World Quarterly 14(3): 605–24. Levine, V. T. 2004. Politics in Francophone Africa. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. Li, T. 2007. The Will to Improve. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Maine, H. 1876. Village Communities in the East and West. London: John Murray. Mamdani, M. 1996. Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Legacy of Late Colonialism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Mann, M. 1986. The Sources of Social Power: A History of Power from the Beginning to A.D 1760, vol. I. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Mansuri, G., and V. Rao. 2004. “Community-Based and -Driven Development: A Critical Review.” World Bank Research Observer 19(1): 1–39. Mantena, K. 2009. Alibis of Empire. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Melo, M., and F. Rezende. 2004. “Decentralism and Governance in Brazil.” In Decentralization and Governance in Latin America, ed. J. S. Tulchin and A. Selee, 37–66. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press. Mill, J. S. 1859. On Liberty. London: John W. Parker and Son. ———. 1879. “Chapters on Socialism.” Fortnightly Review 25(February): 217–37; March: 373–82; April: 513–30. Mizrahi, Y. 2004. “Twenty Years of Decentralization in Mexico: A Top-Down Process.” In Decentralization, Democratic Governance, and Civil Society in Comparative Perspective: Africa, Asia and Latin America, ed. P. Oxhorn, J. S. Tulchin, and A. D. Selee, 33–58. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press. 46
  • 67. WHY DOES PARTICIPATION MATTER? Mosse, D. 2002. “People’s Knowledge, Participation and Patronage: Operations and Representations in Rural Development.” In Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook, ed. D. Narayan. Washington, DC: World Bank. Narayan, D. 2002. Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook. Washington, DC: World Bank. Narayan, D., and K. Ebbe. 1997. “Design of Social Funds: Participation, Demand Orientation, and Local Organizational Capacity.” World Bank Discussion Paper 375, World Bank, Washington, DC. North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. O’Donnell, G. 1993. “On the State, Democratization and Some Conceptual Problems (A Latin American View with Glances at Some Post-Communist Countries).” World Development 21(8): 1355–70. Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press. Pateman, C. 1976. Participation and Democratic Theory. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Prud’homme, R. 1995. “The Dangers of Decentralization.” World Bank Research Observer 10(2): 201–20. Ribot, J. C. 1995. “From Exclusion to Participation: Turning Senegal’s Forestry Policy Around?” World Development 23(9): 1587–99. ———. 2009. “Forestry and Democratic Decentralization in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Review.” In Governing Africa’s Forests in a Globalized World, ed. L. A. German, A. Karsenty, and A. Tiani, 29–55. London: Earthscan. Schumpeter, J. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper and Brothers. Scott, J. 1999. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Selee, A. D., and J. S. Tulchin. 2004. “Decentralization and Democratic Governance: Lessons and Challenges.” In Decentralization, Democratic Governance, and Civil Society in Comparative Perspective: Africa, Asia and Latin America, ed. P. Oxhorn, J. S. Tulchin, and A. D. Selee, 295–319. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press. Sen, A. 1985. Commodities and Capabilities. Amsterdam: Elsevier. ———. 1999. Development as Freedom. New York: Knopf. ———. 2005. Argumentative Indian. London: Allen Lane. Shah, A., ed. 2006a. Local Budgeting. Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series. Washington, DC: World Bank. ———. 2006b. Local Governance in Developing Countries. Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series. Washington, DC: World Bank. ———. 2006c. Local Governance in Industrial Countries. Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series. Washington, DC: World Bank. ———. 2006d. Local Public Financial Management. Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series. Washington, DC: World Bank. 47
  • 68. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Tiebout, C. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political Economy 64(5): 416–24. Tinker, H. 1967. The Foundations of Local Self-Government in India, Pakistan and Burma. Bombay: Lalvani. USAID. 2000. USAID’s Experience in Decentralization and Local Governance. Washington, DC: Center for Democracy and Governance, USAID. White, H. 1999. “Politicising Development? The Role of Participation in the Activities of Aid Agencies.” In Foreign Aid: New Perspectives, ed. K. Gupta, 109–25. Boston: Kluwer Academic Press. World Bank. 1992. Governance and Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. ———. 2001. World Development Report 2000/2001: Attacking Poverty. Washington, DC: World Bank. ———. 2004. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People. Washington, DC: World Bank. Zhenyao, W. 2007. “The Process of Establishing and Extending Direct Elections in Rural China.” In Narratives of Chinese Economic Reforms: How Does China Cross the River? ed. X. Zhang, S. Fan, and A. de Haan. Singapore: World Scientific. 48
  • 69. CHAPTER TWO A Conceptual Framework for Participatory Development DESPITE THE RECENT UPSURGE IN INTEREST, PARTICIPATORY DE - velopment policy is beset with a lack of conceptual clarity. Allocations of many millions of dollars are justified by little more than slogans, such as “empowering the poor,” “improving accountability,” “building social capital,” and “improving the demand side of governance.” Part of the conceptual challenge lies in understanding what these notions mean, how they fit within broader conceptions of development policy, and how they differ across diverse contexts and over time. This chapter presents a framework within which to think about some of these issues. The goal is to understand participatory interventions as a response to a development failure, much as other development interventions are viewed as responses to market or government failures. The chapter begins by briefly reviewing the concept of market fail- Participatory development ure, the key construct used to justify development policy. It then reviews policy is beset with a lack of the extension of the basic notion of failure to the state before introduc- conceptual clarity . . . ing the concept of civil society failure. The section on civil society failures discusses how a vibrant civil society can help mitigate market and government failures and illustrates how the interaction of markets, government, and civil society failures affect local development. The chapter argues that participatory development interventions should, for . . . with many millions of the most part, be understood as an attempt to repair civil society failure. dollars justified by little more This framework leads to an extended discussion of the various elements than buzzwords. of civil society failure—the roles of coordination and cooperation, cul- ture, inequality and elite domination, and group heterogeneity—and discusses some consequent challenges and concerns. 49
  • 70. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Market Failure Markets fail when they are unable to allocate resources efficiently. They fail for a variety of reasons: one party to a transaction may have more information than the other; a firm may monopolize control over a market by restricting the entry of competitors; failures in information or coordination may cause a common need to not be provided by the market mechanism, resulting in a missing market. Although inequality and Although inequality and poverty can coexist with both efficient and poverty can coexist with inefficient markets, market failures tend to deepen poverty traps and both efficient and inefficient inhibit growth. Therefore, in theory, correcting or repairing market fail- markets, market failures tend ures can help economies produce larger pies, and—in situations where to deepen poverty traps and the market failure disproportionately affects the poor—allocate larger inhibit growth. shares of the pie to the poor. Correcting market failures is thought of as one of the central challenges of development (Hoff and Stiglitz 2001; Devarajan and Kanbur 2005). The other main challenge is distributing resources equitably—in particular ensuring that the poor benefit from development. Many market failures are caused by externalities—situations in which an act produces a cost (or benefit) that is borne (enjoyed) by a party that was not involved in it. Externalities exist in the marketplace when the exchange of goods and services between two individuals has consequences, positive or negative, for people who were not involved in the decision. A negative externality occurs when an individual or firm does not bear the full cost of its decisions. In this case, the cost to society is greater than the cost borne by the individual or firm. Examples include companies that pollute the environment without having to pay for cleaning it up. Negative externalities lead to the overproduction of goods and services, because sellers are not charged the full costs their goods and services impose. A positive externality exists when an individual or firm does not receive the full benefit of its decisions. In this case, the benefit to society is greater than the benefit reaped by the individual or firm. Examples of positive externalities are spillovers from research and development or the pollination of crops by bees. Positive externalities lead to the under- production of goods and services, because sellers are not compensated for the full benefits of the goods and services they create. Coordination failures are a special case of externalities in which the failure of individuals “to coordinate complementary changes in 50
  • 71. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT their actions leads to a state of affairs that is worse for everyone than an alternate state of affairs that is also an equilibrium” (Hoff 2000, 145). When parties to a transaction are unable to reliably connect and coordinate with one another, they are often forced into situations that make at least one of them worse off without making the other better off. The market is not always able to solve this problem, for a variety of reasons. Formal and informal institutions to enforce contracts may not exist or may be unreliable, for example, making transactions unpredict- able and subject to manipulation and rent-seeking. Another important cause of market failure is the existence of con- Important causes of market straints in the distribution of information. Information is asymmetric failure include externalities, when some firms or individuals have more information than others. of which coordination failures Poor households typically have very little access to formal credit mar- are a special case, and kets, for example, and rely largely on informal lenders partly because it constraints in the distribution is difficult for commercial banks to collect reliable information on their of information. ability to repay loans. Poverty and inequality exist in the absence of market failures, and market failures exist in the absence of poverty and inequality. But a highly unequal distribution of resources can amplify the effects of mar- ket failures such as failures of credit and labor markets. Market failures can also lead to highly skewed distributions of power or social status that are resistant to change, leading to poverty traps. A poverty trap is a situation in which a group of people and their descendants remain in a perpetual state of poverty because of mecha- nisms such as credit market imperfections, corruption, dysfunctional institutions, or decreasing returns from investments in health, educa- tion, or physical capital. In an inequality trap, the entire distribution is stable, because—as noted in the World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development—the various dimensions of inequality (wealth, power, social status) interact to protect the rich from downward mobil- ity and obstruct upward mobility by the poor (World Bank 2006; Rao 2006). The unequal distribution of power between the rich and the poor—between dominant and subservient groups—helps elites main- tain control over resources and reduces the potential productivity of the poor. Credit and capital market failures tend to have a disproportionate impact on the poor, and asymmetries in information can both be caused by and perpetuate inequalities in income and power. Consider, for instance, agricultural laborers working for a large land- holder. Illiteracy, malnourishment, and indebtedness are likely to make it very difficult for such workers to break out of the cycle of poverty. 51
  • 72. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Even if laws were in place making it possible to challenge the land- holder’s dictates, illiterate workers would have great difficulty navigating the political and judicial institutions that might help them assert their rights. In many parts of the world, entrenched social structures widen this distance between landholders and laborers: landholders typically belong to a dominant group defined by race or caste, whereas tenants belong to a subservient group. Such group-based inequalities are more likely to be intergenerationally perpetuated when social norms and networks prevent intermarriage across groups. Inequity can combine with Inequity, which can exist even in perfectly functioning markets market failures to magnify is, thus, a concern in its own right. In addition, it can combine with inefficiencies and can result market failures to magnify inefficiencies and can result in situations in in situations in which the which the aggregate loss in welfare is disproportionately borne by the aggregate loss in welfare poor. These factors provide a rationale for government intervention is disproportionately borne where it can intervene in ways that improve outcomes—by, for example, by the poor. providing services such as health, education, credit, or insurance to communities in which markets are unwilling or unable to do so or by implementing land reform or other equalizing interventions to correct for poverty and inequality traps. Government Failure The concern with looking to government to solve market failures is that problems of coordination, information asymmetry, and inequality also characterize the government. Government failure occurs when a policy or political intervention makes resource allocation less efficient than the outcome produced by the market (Besley 2006). It is useful to distinguish government failures, which are common to all political systems, from political failures, which are government failures within a democratic framework. Like market failures, govern- ment and political failures are related to failures in information and coordination. Looking to government to Information failures. The classic information failure in governance is solve market failures is ignorance—the inability of a government to know the preferences of its problematic . . . citizens. Ignorance results in the misallocation of resources—providing schools where clinics are needed, building roads that head off in untrav- eled directions while septic tanks fester. Decentralization is often seen as a solution to this problem, because bringing government closer to the 52
  • 73. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT people increases the public’s access to information and the government’s . . . because it, too, knowledge of citizens’ preferences. suffers from problems of Another cause of government failure is information asymmetries— coordination, information situations in which one set of agents in a transaction has more relevant asymmetry, and inequality. information than another. Governments keep vast amounts of infor- mation that citizens cannot access—details about contracts for public projects, budgetary allocations, and lists of people under detention. Coordination failures. Governments are continually subject to vari- ous types of coordination failures, which result in some people being unable to influence decision making while others have undue access to state favors as a result of lobbying, corruption, or both. Coordination failures can also arise when incentives in the political system prevent good candidates from running for office, resulting in societies being managed by ineffective leaders, or when polarized sets of preferences result in inaction (a failure of collective action). Coordination failures can create endemic problems such as absenteeism among public ser- vants, which disproportionately affects schools and clinics in poor and isolated communities (World Bank 2004). They can also result in a “loss of the monopoly over the means of coercion” (Bates 2008), leaving countries vulnerable to civil war and ethnic strife. Inequity. Just as in the case of market failure, the burden of govern- Just as in the case of ment failure frequently falls disproportionately on the poor. Poor and market failure, the burden of illiterate people tend to suffer from vast gaps in information about government failure frequently laws and government procedures. In relatively stable societies with falls disproportionately on deep-seated inequalities, the rich are likely to use their influence to the poor. control the reins of power; in cases of complete state failure, politicians can use their power to extract resources from the poor and powerless, thereby transforming the state into an instrument of predation (Bates 2008). One of the challenges of development is to understand where, when, and how to balance the power of the state against the freedom of mar- kets. Can governments solve market failures and redress inequities in a manner that does not weaken market efficiency? Can markets take over the provision of services such as water supply, health, and educa- tion when a government is unable to do so? Can governments provide credit and insurance in underserved areas that the private sector will not enter? What level of government regulation will optimally solve infor mation and coordination problems while not impeding the potential for sustainable growth? 53
  • 74. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? One of the challenges of As markets and governments are fundamentally interconnected, policy making is to understand the challenges of information and coordination influence not just where, when, and how to failures within markets and governments but also the links between balance the power of the state them. Institutional economists have demonstrated that development against the freedom occurs when institutions are able to resolve market failures and address of markets. inequality in a manner that is conducive to long-run inclusive growth (World Bank 2005; Acemoglu and Robinson 2006). Civil Society Failure The fundamental goal of local participatory development is to build an effective local civic sphere. The philosopher Jurgen Habermas (1991) argues that civil society is activated by a “public sphere” in which citi- zens, collectively and publicly, create a “third space” that engages with states and markets. Thus, civil society is symbiotically linked to the effective functioning of markets and governments. An effective civil society is the social arena in which citizens par- ticipate, voluntarily organizing to work toward their collective benefit. It is the space in which individuals turn into citizens. The terms civil society and nongovernmental organization (NGO) are often used inter- changeably, but civil society is much more than a collection of NGOs. As defined by the sociologist Jeffrey Alexander (2006, 4), ideally, civil society is “a world of values and institutions that generates the capacity for social criticism and democratic integration at the same time. Such a sphere relies on solidarity, on feelings for others whom we do not know but whom we respect out of principle, not experience, because of our putative commitment to a common secular faith.” Any collective effort to voluntarily mobilize citizens with shared val- ues toward a common goal—consumer cooperatives, credit groups, neighborhood associations, religious organizations, social movements of various kinds, producer cooperatives, and a variety of formal and informal associations and advocacy organizations—is arguably a civil Historians have increasingly society activity.1 recognized how fundamental Following Habermas, contemporary historians have increasingly civic action is to the recognized how fundamental civic action is to the development process. development process. Bayly (2004, 2008) shows that poorer countries that have had high rates 54
  • 75. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT of growth in recent years, such as India and China, did not simply bor- row Western ideas and technologies. Instead, groups of highly educated elites who served as peer educators and activated the civic sphere indi- genized those ideas and ideologies. In India, for instance, beginning in the early 19th century, liberal leaders created an ecumene (public sphere) that laid the foundation for the vibrant civic and democratic life of the country today. McCloskey (2006) and Mokyr (2010) argue that the cre- ation of an entrepreneurial class requires the development of networks and discourse that foster “bourgeois virtues,” which in turn facilitate the development of innovation and capitalism. An active and effective civil society thus allows citizens to engage with governments and markets, hold them accountable, and generate a culture that facilitates economic and democratic activity. In their ideal state, the three spheres, while complementary in their functions, have competing ideological bases: civil society involves col- lective action, with justice, fairness, and other social norms as core goals; ideally, it is based on the principles of reciprocity, open criticism, and debate.2 In contrast, markets involve individual actors following indi- vidual goals of maximizing profits and generating wealth. Firms tend to depend on a hierarchically organized division of labor, rather than equality, to meet their goals. Governments tend to be orga- nized around politics, the goal of which is the reproduction of power; they depend on authority and loyalty to function. In contrast, civil society tends to be mobilized around common interests and the prin- ciple of equality (Alexander 2006). All three spheres are needed to bal- ance one another—and create a virtuous cycle. Market and government failures and inequity thrive in the absence of an active and engaged civil society, and civil society failures can exacerbate market and govern- ment failures. When the three spheres are equally healthy, they work in concert; the unequal tendencies of the market are balanced by the equalizing valance of the civic sphere, and the tendency of governments to monopolize power is balanced by pressures for accountability and openness that come from civil society. Civil Society Interaction with Markets and Governments Civic interaction with markets and governments is often conflictual: being held accountable, answering uncomfortable questions, and responding to requests from mobilized groups of citizens are often costly and unpleasant for government officials and private sector actors. 55
  • 76. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? To be effective, civic action Absent appropriate regulation, markets would be motivated solely by often has to force agents of profit maximization. In many cases, the short-term interests of a firm government and the market or industry do not coincide with the best interests of citizens. Similarly, to act against their private in the absence of civic accountability, the interests of political leaders interests and in the interest would be to hold on to power, capture rents, and preserve the existing of citizens. hierarchy. Civic action is thus almost never smooth; to be effective, it has to introduce constraints into the decision-making processes of governments and markets that cannot be ignored and that often force them to act against their private interests (by reducing profit margins or limiting power). In its interaction with markets, In its interaction with markets, a well-functioning civil society acts a well-functioning civil society first as a watchdog—through consumer groups, for instance, that high- acts first as a watchdog. light firm behaviors that are detrimental to consumers. These behaviors include practices that endanger people’s lives (such as food and drug adulteration) as well as practices that are unethical, inefficient, and inequitable, such as collusion and price fixing. Pressure from civil society groups has been responsible, in many parts of the world, for the estab- lishment of agencies to regulate drugs, food, automobiles, and corporate behavior. When they function well, civil society groups also watch out for egregious inequities, such as discrimination in hiring practices or price discrimination against particular groups or communities. The civil rights movement in the United States, the Arab Spring in Tunisia and the Arab Republic of Egypt, the Solidarity movement in Poland, and pro-democracy rallies in the Islamic Republic of Iran are archetypal examples of civil society activity. Civil society can be a source of counter- vailing power that acts as a check on government. Such a check is usually a good thing, but it can sometimes be socially detrimental—as it is, for example, when vigilante groups attempt to impose unpopular points of view through a reign of terror or when extremists capture the state. In addition to their watchdog function, civil society groups play a direct role in generating economic activity (microfinance organizations are a prime example). Moreover, an active civic sphere can help create an enabling environment for the rise of an entrepreneurial class, by facilitating social networks that transmit information and creating col- lectives to help with credit and insurance. Trade groups such as farm- ers cooperatives, industry federations, and ethnic networks that help migrants with credit and jobs are all examples of civil society activity. An engaged civil sphere is even more critical to good government. If government is transparent and accountable, it is transparent to and held accountable by civil society. Civil society works much more effectively 56
  • 77. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT when it is cohesive—when it has a high capacity for collective action, An engaged civil sphere which is central to the functioning of an effective state—because cohe- makes a critical contribution sion gives citizens the capability of engaging effectively with the state. to good government by Some scholars follow Putnam (1993) and others in calling this capacity keeping it transparent and “social capital.” This term dilutes the idea of an engaged public sphere accountable. into something conceptually much weaker, making it overly simplistic and therefore less effective as a guide for policy (Mansuri and Rao 2004). Markets interact with civil society in various ways—by providing information on products and services, for example, or by funding the creation of civil society organizations that are consistent with their interests. Governments engage with civil society in similar ways, pro- viding it with information and attempting to influence and control it, including through rules that prohibit rallies and political organizing. Governments also attempt to nurture, and even create, civil society activity in order to jump-start a participatory development process.3 Markets, Government, and Civil Society at the Local Level Civil society, markets, and governments interact at various levels— global, national, subnational (state/district), and local (city/village/ neighborhood). Each level has a unique set of challenges, modes of operation, and incentive structures. Market failures work differently at each level. Market failures in the global sphere require global coordination and regulation to correct—a role that, for instance, the World Trade Organization (WTO) attempts to perform. Market failures at the national level are the concern of governments and central banks. Market failures at the local level may be addressed by local approaches such as microcredit and microinsur- ance. The appropriate level of action may depend on the type of market failure. The management of river basin issues that affect multiple coun- tries requires regional action, for example; the creation of a collective response to global warming requires global action. Government also operates at different levels. Concerns about global governance are addressed by the United Nations system and by negotia- tions between and among governments. The functions of government should be allocated to the levels most competent to handle them. Some functions, such as national defense, foreign policy, and interstate rela- tions, cannot be sensibly decentralized. In allocating other functions to local levels, a few trade-offs need to be considered (Bardhan and 57
  • 78. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Mookherjee 2006). Local governments can be better informed about citizen preferences, and they are better able to respond to the needs of citizens because of better information and lower transactions costs. But they may have difficulty coordinating decision making across commu- nities (because of intercommunity externalities or spillovers). Moreover, decentralization leads to a potential loss in scale economies. The optimal design Thus, the optimal design of decentralization requires trading off of decentralization requires the advantages of better-aligned incentives against the disadvantages trading off the advantages of more challenging coordination problems. In general, the provision of of better-aligned incentives local public goods is best decentralized when preferences and needs for against the disadvantages the goods are heterogeneous, vary with time, and require a high degree of more challenging of responsiveness to community needs or local knowledge and when coordination problems. there are few intercommunity spillovers or economies of scale. Public goods and services that typically fall into these categories include sanita- tion and drainage, local irrigation canals, and village roads. Often com- mon-pool resources such as water bodies and forests can also be locally managed. Conversely, if a public good is homogenous; has significant economies of scale, perhaps because of technical complexity; or requires central coordination, it should usually be managed centrally (examples include national vaccination campaigns and national highways). The decentralization of government functions could, however, merely result in the decentralization of government failure. Local gov- ernments fail for a number of reasons, including the absence of demo- cratic mechanisms by which voters can communicate preferences, lack of effective political competition, and lack of civic capacity. When this is the case, policies tend to reflect the views of the people in power, there is a general lack of accountability to citizens, and the decentralization of resource allocation decisions can actually exacerbate rent-seeking and corruption (Bardhan and Mookherjee 2006; Besley 2006). In mak- ing decisions about decentralization in developing countries, it is thus important to understand the nature and degree of potential government failure at different levels of government, as well as the potential for civil society failure, and to balance these considerations with policy prescrip- tions that rely on politics-free economic theory. Just as markets and governments operate at different levels, so does civil society. Most political theorists generally think about civil society as operating at the level of nation-states, in the context of national politics (Alexander 2006). But in recent years there has been increasing recognition of a global public sphere and global civil society (examples 58
  • 79. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT include the movement to combat climate change (or the protests against Just as markets and “neoliberal” development institutions that promote “market fundamen- governments operate at talism”). A vibrant civil society at the national level is important not different levels, so does just for its own sake—to make effective citizens—but also for repairing civil society. market and government failures. Social movements have made markets accountable by exposing systematic failures in particular industries (an example is Ralph Nader’s highly successful effort to improve automobile safety). They have equalized the rights and welfare of excluded social groups (including indigenous people in Latin America and nonwhites in South Africa) and pushed for greater democracy (in Indonesia) and openness in government (in India). The larger development challenge is to build a virtuous cycle of checks and balances among markets, governments, and civil society that compensates and corrects for the weaknesses in each sphere. The concern here is with the local civil sphere—groups of citizens who organize themselves into collectives to hold the local state account- able; assist with the functions of government (school committees, public village meetings); remedy market failures such as lack of access to credit or insurance (microcredit and microinsurance groups); and directly manage common resources (forest management groups, water users groups). If government functions are decentralized to the local level, it is important to have citizen groups that watch out and correct for local government failures through a process of active engagement. Local civil society can also have important linkages with a national civic sphere. Following Rousseau and Mill, local governments, commu- nity organizations, and local civic groups are thought to be a training ground for civic activity. If several small local ecumenes develop that connect with and learn from one another by exchanging ideas and methods and providing mutual support, they may have the capacity to shift civic culture at the national level. Defining Civil Society Failure Civil society failure can be broadly thought of as a situation in which Civil society failure can be civic action is either absent or operates in a way that results in a net broadly thought of as a reduction in efficiency.4 It can occur because a group is unable to act situation in which civic action collectively. For example, a group of individuals may be unable to coor- is either absent or operates dinate their actions and make collective decisions that would leave all in a way that results in a net members of the group better off over the long run because individuals reduction in efficiency. 59
  • 80. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? act in their own short-run best interest (the “tragedy of the commons”). It can also occur when one subgroup is able to mobilize collectively to further its interests while other subgroups, with different interests, are unable to do so, with the potential result that the welfare of the average citizen is reduced. How does participation occur? Collective participation occurs in two stages. Individuals first have to decide to participate in civic groups; the groups then have to be able to resolve the challenges of collective action and act with a common purpose. Failure can affect both indi- vidual incentives for participation and the group’s capacity for collective action. There can also be varying degrees of institutional receptivity to participatory activity. For instance, receptivity to participation increases when a country transitions from dictatorship to democracy. It is low in an authoritarian country that functions by suppressing voice and dissent. Even in authoritarian societies, however, there may be some nascent vul- nerabilities in the political structure that change activists can exploit—as they did in the Arab Spring and South Africa; if those vulnerabilities increase (say, because of international pressure), the receptivity for par- ticipation could increase as well. In the literature on social movements, these vulnerabilities are referred to as the “political opportunity struc- ture” (Kriesi 2007). Such structures can be either “open” (allowing easy access to the political system) or “closed” (making such access difficult). Effective civic action requires that groups have enough information to identify and gauge political opportunities and are then able to mobilize citizens in a manner that takes advantage of them. Participation is a broad term that covers a variety of activities, includ- ing the following: • participation in decision making through consultative processes or deliberative bodies without the authority to make or veto resource allocation decisions • the contribution of cash, material goods, or physical labor to construct public goods or provide public services • the monitoring and sanctioning of public and private service providers • the provision of information and involvement in awareness- raising activities • the formation of neighborhood committees (for instance, to reduce crime or resolve local conflicts) • the selection or election of local representatives. 60
  • 81. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT Instrumental, ideological, and identity-based motives induce indi- Instrumental, ideological, and viduals to participate in civic activities. Instrumental motives have to identity-based motives induce do with the economic and political benefits an individual may reap by individuals to participate in participating. For instance, if a community development project comes civic activities. into a village with funds for building local infrastructure, an individual may participate in meetings associated with the project in order to gain access to the funds to repair a road outside her house; he or she may vote in a local council election in order to help remove a corrupt politician from office. Ideological motives have to do with adhering to a shared belief. In some countries, for instance, nationalism is strongly tinged with the ideology of communitarianism, making participation in com- munity projects an expression of patriotism. Identity-based motives have to do with social or religious identity. Examples include helping build a mosque or church or mobilizing a caste group to fight for greater dignity within a village. Participation entails some costs. The most obvious is the opportunity Participation entails some cost of time, which depends on an individual’s economic position, employ- costs. The most obvious is ment status, and family obligations, among other factors. Participation the opportunity cost of time, also involves a range of social costs, which can be prohibitively high for which is higher for the poor. individuals or groups that are otherwise proscribed from free engagement in communal public life, as is often the case for women and members of disadvantaged castes, ethnic groups, or tribes. There may also be psychic costs. Years of oppression may have caused low-caste groups to have internalized discriminatory ideologies, making it particularly challeng- ing to mobilize them for development activity. Communities that have grown accustomed to receiving free benefits from the state may be find it troubling to be asked to exert physical effort to obtain those benefits. Individuals, embedded in their particular social groups and networks, will balance all these costs and benefits before deciding to participate. The decision to participate is not merely an individual decision, how- ever, as civic activity is most effective—perhaps only effective—when engaged in collectively. Although an individual may want to participate, the group to which he or she belongs may be unable to come to a collec- tive decision. Participation by groups—the classic challenge of collective action—thus needs to be distinguished from participation by individu- als. Furthermore, an individual’s decision to participate is deeply con- nected to the group’s ability to cooperate; if individuals believe that the group will be ineffective or unable to reach consensus, they will be less inclined to participate. 61
  • 82. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Mancur Olson (1965) theorized almost 50 years ago that without coercion or some other special device to make individuals act in their common interest, “rational self-interested individuals will not act to achieve their common or group interests.” Olson was concerned with “exploitation of the great by the small,” noting that people with smaller interests in a public good would tend to free ride on the efforts of people with greater interests. Under what conditions will a group of people cooperate? Under what conditions will they trust one another enough to believe that the prom- ises they have made are credible? Ostrom (1990) emphasizes the role of social institutions that generate norms, impose sanctions, and improve the incentives for collective action, basing her analysis on field observa- tions that demonstrate the success of collective action in management of commons. Arguing against a general theory of collective action, she contends that particularities matter a great deal but postulates a set of “design principles” that may serve as a guide. These principles include clearly defined boundaries to the commons, with a defined commu- nity associated with the resource; rules to manage the commons that are appropriate to local conditions; arrangements to manage collective decisions, which are themselves subject to collective negotiations; gra- dated sanctions, with heavier sanctions for repeated or more egregious violators of rules; low-cost and widely accepted mechanisms to resolve conflict; and the absence of excessive government interference. In deriv- ing these conditions, Ostrom was thinking specifically about common- pool resource management; her arguments do not necessarily apply to the wider issue of local participatory development. Under what conditions will a Incorporating these insights and summarizing work by game group of people cooperate? theorists on collective action over the last four decades, Dasgupta Under what conditions will (2009) identifies two necessary conditions for cooperation: they trust one another enough 1. At every stage in the agreed course of action, it is in the interest to believe that the promises of every party to plan to keep its word if every other party also they have made are credible? does so. 2. At every stage of the agreed course of action, every party believes that all parties will keep their word. The first condition self-enforces promises by ensuring that promises made by one person are expected to be reciprocated by others. This con- dition is not sufficient, however, because even if it is met, it is still possi- ble that every agent believes that everyone else will act opportunistically. 62
  • 83. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT If this is the case, then all parties will think that it is in their best interest not to cooperate. The second condition is needed to generate trust, by ensuring that all parties believe that everyone else will keep his or her word. Together, the two conditions generate a system of self-enforcing beliefs that facilitate collective action. What, then, are the conditions and the social environments that ensure that both conditions are met? When are promises that people make to one another credible, hence ensuring cooperation? People may belong to “cultures”—relational environments that gen- erate ideologies and preferences that are conducive to collective action. People from the same “culture” share the following characteristics: 1. Mutual affection. Coordination is facilitated when parties care about one another sufficiently and recognize that others feel the same way. 2. Pro-social disposition. If people trust one another enough to know that any promises made are credible, then even in the absence of mutual affection, a group can have strong ties that generate loy- alty. Loyalty of this kind can be shaped by group-specific culture and upbringing; members of a community internalize norms of cooperation to the extent that they feel shame or guilt when not cooperating. Loyalty can also arise because of the presence of social norms that prescribe punishment for people who do not have a pro-social disposition toward the group. Incentives can also help ensure cooperation. People are more likely People are more likely to keep to keep agreements if a “cooperative infrastructure”—a set of institu- agreements if a “cooperative tions that ensures that keeping promises is in the interest of each party infrastructure”—a set of if everyone else keeps them—is in place. Three types of cooperative institutions that ensures infrastructure can be identified: that keeping promises is in 3. External enforcement. External enforcement of agreements made the interest of every party if within the group requires an explicit contract enforced by an everyone else keeps them—is established structure of power and authority, such as the state in place. and its legal institutions or, in the absence of a formal state, a traditional leader (such as a chief, warlord, or head of a traditional panchayat [village council]). The external enforcer does not have to act: the very fact that such enforcement exists will lead people to make credible commitments to one another, and promises will be reinforced by the belief that they will be kept. Collective action can be more successful in the presence of a successful state, and 63
  • 84. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? state failure can reinforce failures in civic action, just as civil soci- ety failure can reinforce state failure. When the external enforcer cannot be trusted to enforce agreements, the parties will not trust one another enough to enter into collective agreements, which could result in noncooperation. 4. Reputation as a capital asset. Even in the absence of external enforcement, people will keep their promises if they value their reputation enough. Reputation becomes a capital asset because individuals want to maintain status, uphold an ethical code, or preserve long-term relationships. 5. Long-term relationships. In a long-term relationship, reputation becomes a capital asset after a transaction is completed, because it enables individuals to enter into other credible contracts. Agreements, therefore, are mutually enforced. To achieve func- tioning social relationships, the community might impose stiff sanctions on anyone who breaks an agreement. In practice, characteristics 3, 4, and 5 could blend with one another, as all of these solutions impose collective sanctions on people who intentionally fail to comply with agreements. However, as Dasgupta (2009) points out, “a credible threat of punishment for misdemeanors would be an effective deterrent only if future costs and benefits are not discounted at too high a rate relative to other parameters of the social environment.” In situations in which individuals are forced to become myopic—in periods of civil conflict or social disruption, for instance— such self-reinforcing norms may be rendered ineffective, leading to civic failure (Coate and Ravallion 1993). Capacity for cooperation Where individuals are bound together in multiple social, eco- can be enhanced where nomic, and political relationships, the capacity for cooperation can be individuals are bound together enhanced. If, for instance, the mutual provision of credit and insurance in multiple social, economic, depends on norms of obligation and cooperation, which in turn depend and political relationships. on commitments for marriage or political support, the violation of one interaction would result in a collapse of all the others. Thus, interlinked agreements make cooperation robust. They may, however, also make them deeply inequitable. Highly hier- archical societies, such as societies in rural India and West Africa, which depend on elites enforcing norms and “taking care” of others lower in the social hierarchy, may make such societies both highly cooperative and deeply ridden with inequality traps. 64
  • 85. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT Coordination failures in civic action. What makes civic participation effective in some contexts and ineffective in others? What are the chal- lenges local communities face in activating their capacity for collective action? The most important source of civil society failure is probably coor- The most important source of dination failure. An important reason to devolve decisions to the local civil society failure is probably level is to reduce coordination problems—by allowing the people most coordination failure. affected by projects to manage them directly. Such devolution by no means implies that coordination failures will disappear. Coordination failures at the local level have two main causes: the lack of a cooperative infrastructure (institutions that make individu- als’ promises to the collective credible) and the absence of a mechanism to help ensure that individuals in a group have altruistic, or common, preferences (that is, “pro-social dispositions”). Consider the challenges of setting up a project that encourages a com- munity to sustainably manage a local forest. For the project to work, individuals in the community have to agree to restrict their harvesting of trees from the forest. They also have to participate in activities, such as planting and nurturing trees and policing forest grounds to prevent outsiders from poaching. If all individuals were left to their own devices and did not engage in collective action, a tragedy of the commons would occur, leading rapidly to deforestation and the destruction of local liveli- hoods. In practice, many forest communities around the world have, over centuries, evolved strong norms of collective action to manage common resources, setting up an effective cooperative infrastructure. The presence of a cooperative infrastructure affects the outcomes The presence, or absence, of of development projects. Say a project wants to improve the collective a cooperative infrastructure management of a forest by setting up a community-managed fund that affects the outcomes of provides financial incentives for individuals to cooperate by compen- development projects. sating them for income lost by limiting their harvest. The fund would be far more effective if a traditional leader was present who was in complete agreement with the aims of the project, was considered hon- est and beyond reproach, and had the authority to enforce agreements made between individuals and the fund. The fund would also be more likely to succeed if the community had evolved a method by which promises were rendered credible because each individual believed the promises made by every other individual, based on long-term ties and a strong belief that violating promises would result in ostracism from the community. Ideally, the fund would introduce enough additional 65
  • 86. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? incentives within this favorable cooperative environment to sustain cooperation during periods of change and vulnerability. In the absence of an authority figure or strong long-term ties within the community, the fund would degenerate into a haven for rent-seekers, creating a fail- ure. Thus, an authority figure and the long-term ties that come from repeated interactions among individuals in the community are both examples of effective cooperative infrastructure. Consider another example, a decentralized program in which a vil- lage council is given the authority to select beneficiaries for a centrally managed poverty reduction program. As part of the program, it is man- dated that beneficiary selection should be vetted in open village meet- ings, where anyone in the village can question the choices of the village council. This mandate is an attempt to use local participation and local knowledge to improve poverty targeting, create links between villag- ers and the central government, and hold local governments publically accountable. If the central government were weak and its functionaries corrupt, decisions made in the village meeting would not be enforced. If this were the case, villagers would decide not to waste their time par- ticipating in such meetings, because the benefits would not be worth the cost. The project’s attempt to foster participatory, community-based targeting would fail because of a weak state’s inability to enforce col- lectively made decisions. State enforcement can matter in the management of common-pool goods as well. If communities are required to follow laws and regula- tions passed by the state and these laws and regulations are poorly enforced, there is no incentive for the community to follow the law. If the community had strong norms of collective action, it would revert to traditional forms of resource management. If it did not, the common resources would be privatized and allocated in a way that reflected the interests of the most powerful. An interesting example of how cooperative infrastructure helps facilitate participation in the decentralization process comes from Tsai’s (2007) work on China.5 Tsai asks a simple question: How can variations in the provision of public goods be explained in the absence of formal institutions of accountability? The Chinese state has decentralized to local governments primary responsibility for the provision of basic pub- lic goods and services (road construction, drainage systems, irrigation works, primary school facilities, sanitation). Some village governments provide outstanding public goods and services, whereas others provide 66
  • 87. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT barely anything at all. According to Tsai, the explanation for this varia- tion is the presence in some villages of local “solidary” groups, which provide informal institutions of accountability. A solidary group is a collection of individuals who share moral obligations and interests. Of the three types of groups Tsai delineates—village temple groups, village churches, and lineage groups—only temple groups and some lineage groups have the two structural characteristics crucial to Tsai’s argument—namely, the group must be encompassing (open to every- one under the jurisdiction of the local government), and it must be embedding (incorporating local officials into the group as members).6 “When the boundaries of a solidary group overlap with the adminis- trative boundaries of the local government, embedded officials have a strong social obligation to contribute to the good of the group,” writes Tsai (2007, 356). In groups with embedded officials, the incentive for accountability is an amorphous sense of moral standing or prestige for the provision of public goods. This thesis is quite different from the idea of civic “social capital.” Whatever “social capital” such groups may have, groups that do not meet the “embedding” criteria (such as church groups) are not able to hold village officials accountable for the provision of public goods, as Communist Party members are prohibited from membership.7 In contrast, village temple groups can be both encompassing and embed- ded; they are thus able to serve effectively as informal institutions of accountability. Lineage groups play this role only marginally, because their segmentation makes them less cohesive. A more daring claim made by Tsai is that neither bureaucratic insti- tutions of top-down control nor democratic institutions seem to have a significant positive effect on the provision of public goods by village governments. “Implementation of elections does not guarantee good governmental performance, especially when other democratic institu- tions are weak” (Tsai 2007, 370). In countries with strong traditions of electoral democracy, externally In countries with strong induced improvements in the cooperative infrastructure that come traditions of electoral from the state, such as improved enforcement of laws or decentraliza- democracy, externally tion programs with strong participatory elements, can substantially induced improvements in the improve the quality of participation. Consider the case of the South cooperative infrastructure Indian state of Kerala. Kerala has a long history of egalitarian social that come from the state can programs emphasizing education, health, and women’s equality, but substantially improve the until 1996 these efforts were mainly top-down programs directed from quality of participation. 67
  • 88. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? the state capital. Although Kerala is blessed with a literate and engaged electorate, participation was restricted to the political sphere and to membership in unions. Following passage of a constitutional amendment in 1993, which mandated that state governments devolve resources and powers to democratically elected village councils (gram panchayats), Kerala began to plan and initiate a radical and deeply participatory program of decen- tralization (Heller and Issac 2003). The program rested on three pil- lars. It devolved 40 percent of the state’s development budget to village councils, devolved substantial powers to these councils, and instituted an extensive people’s campaign—a grassroots training and awareness- raising effort to inform citizens about and energize them to participate in the panchayat system. The campaign instituted a planning process based on a set of nested piecemeal stages (for example, working committees meetings and devel- opment seminars held in conjunction with the village meetings, which are structured to facilitate participation). Instead of open deliberation, attendees (members of the public) are divided into resource-themed groups or committees. The discussions within each group yield consen- sual decisions regarding the designated resource. This structure, which operates uniformly in all districts in Kerala, is geared toward increas- ing the efficiency of consensual decision making about public resource demands and prioritizing individual beneficiaries for the allocation of government-subsidized private benefits. The process has been facilitated by various training programs to instruct citizens on deliberative plan- ning and village functionaries on methods for turning plans into actions that result in more effective public service delivery. In Kerala, India, the state In Kerala, direct intervention by the democratic state increased created mechanisms that demand for participation not only by creating greater opportunities of strengthened its links with participatory planning but also by providing resources to make that civil society. planning meaningful while embedding it within a decentralized sys- tem of government with enforcement authority. The state thus created mechanisms that strengthened its links with civil society. Literacy in Kerala was almost 100 percent—much higher than the Indian average at the time of 66 percent; the state also has a long history of civic mobilization because of strong labor unions associated with the communist movement. Local participation in Kerala thus did not start from scratch; it was fostered by channeling democratically and politi- cally aware citizens into participatory avenues that resulted in better 68
  • 89. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT local government. In the absence of Kerala’s well-developed democratic and participatory traditions, it is unlikely that the people’s campaign would have worked. To fully understand the nature of a failure of collective action, it To fully understand the nature is thus important to understand how context, history, and culture of a failure of collective shape the nature of cooperative infrastructure. The local history of a action, it is important to community shapes the norms that have evolved to facilitate collective understand how context, action, the extent to which such norms exclude women or disadvantaged history, and culture shape groups, and whether those norms are transferrable. Local collective the nature of cooperative action norms may be effective enough to manage water resources, for infrastructure. instance, but not school management. Similarly, the history and evolu- tion of the national government—the extent to which it supports an active civic culture and has an effective legal system and democratic systems—has deep implications for the success of efforts to foster local participation. Culture and civic identity. Coordinating civic action at the local level is also affected by the formation of collective identity—which, in many societies, has been consciously shaped to facilitate cooperation. In a small, ethnically homogenous community, intermarriage may have forged strong ties across families.8 In some instances, such ties could result in common preferences and strong deference to the views of tra- ditional authority figures. More generally, a common cultural identity helps individuals anticipate how others in the group will react to their actions, greatly facilitating collective action. State policy can forge a common cultural identity and common preferences. For instance, the state can actively create a communitarian national identity by introducing notions of cooperation into the con- stitution; symbols of the state, such as the flag or pledges of allegiance; and school curricula. One way of thinking about how culture and civic identity affect the capacity for collective action is by thinking about the formation of what Rao (2008) calls “symbolic public goods.” Rao builds on the work of Chwe (1999, 2001), who demonstrates how collective action needs to distinguish between structure and strategy. Chwe’s basic argument goes as follows. Most models of collective action assume, implicitly, some preexisting “common knowledge.” When a group of individuals plays a collective action game, whether static or dynamic, it is assumed that individual A knows the payoffs, information sets, costs, incentives, possible moves, and so forth faced by individual B. Individual B, in 69
  • 90. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? turn, knows all of this about individual A and knows that individual A knows everything about individual B. Individual A, in turn, knows that individual B knows that individual A knows, and so on. This common knowledge assumption permits games of strategy to be played with a common understanding of the rules of the game: everyone knows how everyone else is playing. In contrast, a cricket player persuaded to play baseball will be quickly confused—enough to be unable to understand or appreciate the skill, strategy, and actions of the other players. It is this aspect of coordina- tion and common understanding that common knowledge attempts to capture. It plays a coordinating function that is a precondition for collective activity, which cannot occur in its absence. Common knowl- edge is arguably the core concept behind such amorphous notions as “trust” and “social capital,” which figure prominently in the discourse on collective action.9 In order to understand collective action, therefore, it is crucial to understand its social context through the symbolic public goods that facilitate it. Yet symbolic public goods are themselves the product of strategy and contestation. They can take a variety of forms, including intangible processes of identity formation such as nationalism; physical entities, such as mosques and temples; and periodic ritual events, such as festivals. All of these forms share characteristics of public goods, in the sense that they can be simultaneously “nonrival” (consumption by one person does not reduce the ability of others to consume the same good) and sometimes “nonexcludable” (it is not possible to deny anyone access to the good). Symbolic public goods Indonesia has constructed symbolic public goods to facilitate coop- facilitate the social basis erative behavior. Postcolonial Indonesia was dominated by upper-class for collective action. Muslims from Java. The country’s history in the decades following independence can be seen primarily as the “Javanization” of the country (Ricklefs 2002). The ideological basis of Javanese belief is that social interaction is “collective, consensual and cooperative” (Bowen 1986, 545). Bowen argues that much of this belief is expressed in the term gotong royong (mutual assistance), which has become the framework for Indonesian nationalism and the basis for construction of a national tra- dition. Sukarno, the “father” of Indonesia, attempted to use the notion to unify the diverse (Islamic, non-Islamic, nationalist, Communist) groups in the new country by calling for a spirit of ke gotong royong (gotong royong-ness). Gotong royong provided a form of cultural legiti- macy for state control. 70
  • 91. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT When Sukarno was ousted, in a coup in 1967, his successor, Suharto, introduced a “New Order” economic policy. Especially in its initial phases, the new policy adopted the two-pronged strategy of putting policies in place to enable high rates of growth and passing on the benefits of that growth to the rural poor. An important element in this strategy was to dictatorially force the spirit of gotong royong into hamlets and villages around the country. Gotong royong became a key element in development strategies in rural areas, particularly in the mobilization of rural labor. In order to protect the political and cultural unity of the Indonesian state, Suharto believed that it had to be strongly authoritar- ian and that development had to proceed in a cooperative and collabora- tive manner. By the early 1970s, the Sanskrit word svadaya (self-help) started to be used in combination with gotong royong, and svadaya gotong royong (mobilizing) became central to the implementation of develop- ment policy (Bowen 1986). In a detailed ethnography of local development in a Javanese com- munity, Sullivan (1992) demonstrates that the combination of an autocratic state and the principle of svadaya resulted in a form of forced labor. To be a good Indonesian, one had to contribute labor and cash for development projects. Collective action was the norm, not the excep- tion. Mobilizing communities was straightforward: grants received by the village headman (kepala desa) were small, because donors assumed that the gap between the expected cost of the proposed project and the funds allocated would be provided locally. In fact, ward leaders actively mobilized contributions from the community. Everyone was expected to contribute free labor; individuals who failed to do so could be labeled unpatriotic or uncooperative and face social, political, material, and even physical sanctions. In this manner, Indonesian political leaders constructed the symbolic Indonesia consciously public good of nationalism, deploying “imagined” traditional beliefs built symbolic goods by that made the individual subservient to the community. As most of establishing a communitarian this effort was undertaken in the context of a military dictatorship, the ethic (gotong royong) as state approach was successful in coordinating public action. policy via school curricula and Suharto’s two-pronged strategy yielded good results for more than public education campaigns. two decades, with high rates of growth and substantial improvements in the living standards of the poor. These improvements were achieved in a cost-effective way by, in effect, taxing the poor in the name of community participation. Suharto suppressed freedom and imposed an implicitly regressive tax structure, but he also achieved excellent poverty reduction and human development outcomes. 71
  • 92. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? In the past decade, with the rise of a robust democratic order and a concerted effort to decentralize the political and fiscal authority of state and district governments, the authority of village leaders in Indonesia has been increasingly questioned. But, as recent survey data demon- strate, the spirit of gotong royong has by no means disappeared. It has been so deeply institutionalized that not abiding by it is seen as a viola- tion of a communitarian ethic, which remains part of the foundation of what it means to be a good Indonesian. A 2004 survey of the Second Urban Poverty Project evaluation (Pradhan, Rao, and Rosemberg 2010) shows that levels of participation in public goods construction remain high, at 47 percent, with 59 percent of those respondents saying they participate primarily because of “tradition” or “obligation.” This high level of participation has real consequences: communities in Indonesia contribute 37 percent of the cost of village public goods. Indonesia has thus successfully introduced a communitarian ideology that facilitates the spirit of cooperation at the local level, improving the capacity for collective action. The state can also attempt Rather than build symbolic public goods, the state can attempt to to directly manipulate manipulate preferences to induce behaviors that are in line with its preferences to induce policy objectives. Agrawal (2005) provides an example of this phenom- behaviors that are in line with enon in India, where, he argues, the state explicitly attempted to shift its policy objectives. the preferences of forest communities toward a more collective purpose in order to facilitate community-based forest management. Based on a variety of archival and survey data, Agrawal seeks to understand how villagers in the Kumaon region shifted from violently protesting the government’s efforts to regulate forests in the 1920s to using active com- munity-managed forest conservation methods by the 1990s. He finds that the shift was achieved by the decentralization of decision making to the local level and by explicit efforts to induce community members to value forests as a public good and to build trust between government officials and local forest councils. Villages with forest councils and active council headmen made greater attempts at regulation and the desire for forest protection grew stronger in villages that were most closely involved in actual monitor- ing (Agrawal 2005). Efforts to change the way villagers thought about the forests were so successful that council members and headmen often acted against their own material and family interests in enforcing rules of forest protection. 72
  • 93. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT Inequality and the role of elites. One of the purported advantages of One of the purported local participation is its capacity to improve the match between benefi- advantages of local ciaries’ preferences and the allocation of public goods and benefits. The participation is its capacity to principle of subsidiarity states that when preferences of communities improve the match between are heterogeneous or vary with time, decentralizing decision making beneficiaries’ preferences and and project management results in more efficient outcomes and a better the allocation of public goods preference match. and benefits. Local communities in many developing countries tend to be not only very heterogeneous but also highly unequal. It is therefore also important to understand how both inequality and heterogeneity affect local civic failure. The seminal insight on the role of inequality in collective action Olson’s seminal insight was comes from Olson (1965), who theorized that if the rich have a strong that if the rich have a strong interest in the provision of a public good, inequality could facilitate interest in the provision of a collective action because it would be in the interest of the wealthy public good, inequality can to provide the good, allowing the poor to free ride. Economists have facilitate collective action . . . extended this basic insight in several ways (Baland and Platteau 2006; Bardhan, Ghatak, and Karaivanov 2006). Baland, Bardhan, and Bowles (2006) summarize these extensions. . . . later theorists have They note that inequality can have ambiguous and contradictory effects demonstrated that the link on collective action, for a variety of reasons: between inequality and collective action is more • Higher income may increase rich people’s demand for a public ambiguous. good but also increase the opportunity cost of their time, mean- ing they may be less able to devote time to its provision. If the opportunity cost of the rich is high enough, it may discourage collective action. It could also result in situations in which the collective objective is achieved by the rich providing money and the poor providing labor. • Poor participants’ lower assets may reduce both their demand for the resource and their ability to extract large amounts of it. Thus, poorer people may choose not to participate in setting up a committee to manage a high school—but they would also be less likely to send their children to the school. • Inequality may increase the propensity of the rich to contribute toward a public good, but it may also discourage poorer people from participating at all, as Olson (1965) notes. • Collective provision of public goods may be easier in situations of both very high inequality and almost perfectly equality, 73
  • 94. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? where everyone has an equal interest in the good. Inequality could therefore have a U–shaped effect on collective action. These results are derived in the context of static collective action problems, where communities are not engaged in repeated interactions. Where community members have lived together for a long time and expect to continue to engage in social and economic relations over the long term—situations that are very common in developing countries— the relationship between equity and the cooperative infrastructure becomes much more salient. Rural communities are often character- ized by inequality in income and wealth, which is usually highly cor- related with inequality in power and social status. These communities are trapped in an “inequality trap,” in which the same families have been rich, and poor, for generations. The same rich families maintain a tight hold over power relations in the village and rule with dictatorial authority. In such situations, high inequality is combined with a strong cooperative infrastructure; if the local feudal leader believes that collec- tive action is in his best interest, he will ensure that it occurs. Inequality traps can In such situations, successful collective action comes with high create situations in which inequality, as in the Olson model. But, as Dasgupta (2009) demon- successful collective action strates in models with repeated games, rather than allowing the poor exploits the poor. to free ride on the contributions of the rich, inequality traps can harbor exploitation. The reason, in intuitive terms, is that the poor who refuse to cooperate could face sanctions that would push them to accept out- comes that would make them worse off than they would have been in the absence of collective action. If they discount their future payoffs at a low enough rate, they may be forced to enter into cooperative situations whose outcomes make them better off than they would have been with sanctions, but worse off than they would have been acting on their own. Consequently, a cooperative equilibrium could be sustained in which the poor would be exploited over the long term. Anthropologists have long noted that in such situations the poor tend to internalize such unequal norms: a disadvantaged group may view its status within the hierarchy as correct and appropriate and therefore be subject to what Rao and Walton (2004) call “constraining prefer- ences.” For instance, preferences derived from the Hindu caste system may create an acceptance of hierarchy and constrain the motivation for mobility. These beliefs are also simultaneously external constraints; individuals from lower castes who engage in class struggle may face severe social sanctions. For people at the top of the hierarchy, both types 74
  • 95. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT of constraints provide the means to maintain their high position; for people at the bottom, these internal and external constraints can limit aspirations, create discrimination and exploitation, and block mobility. Inequality can thus result in the systematic exclusion of disadvantaged groups and women. An important aspect of the relationship between inequality and col- lective action is the role elites play in local development. An influential strand of the literature on elites focuses on “capture,” arguing that elite domination sharply increases the risk that elites gain control over com- munity development resources provided to benefit local communities (see, for example, Abraham and Platteau 2004). In contrast, studies of organic collective action emphasize that the leaders of such social movements usually emerge from the educated middle and upper classes (Morris and Staggenborg 2004). One problem in understanding the role of elites in development is that the term refers to a large and heterogeneous set of people. Elites can be the most educated or the most experienced members of a com- munity, or they can be the wealthiest and most powerful. Elite can also refer to men or to people who belong to a dominant ethnic, religious, or caste group. None of these characteristics is mutually exclusive; an elite individual may possess many of these attributes simultaneously. The relevant question is the purpose to which elites direct the dominance and influence they possess. When power is used to facilitate collective action toward the public Elite control can be an good—because of an ethic of public service, a communitarian norm, effective part of the or another reason that results in altruistic behavior—elite control can cooperative infrastructure be an effective part of the cooperative infrastructure: elites can help when power is used to mobilize communities, persuade others, and shepherd them toward facilitate collective action collectively driven, welfare-enhancing behavior. Local development toward the public good. projects demand fairly sophisticated leaders; educated elites are in a position to negotiate with bureaucrats, read and interpret project docu- ments, manage accounts, and engage in other important activities that are part of the everyday business of local projects. This type of control can be described as a form of “benevolent capture” (Rao and Ibanez 2005; Beard and Dasgupta 2006). However, even benevolent elites have social networks and work within them to facilitate change. Thus, beneficiaries of local projects are likely to be people who are more closely linked to the leadership. In developing countries in particular, younger generations tend to be better 75
  • 96. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Control becomes malevolent educated than older generations, so any form of participation is likely to capture when elites extract be led by younger people, creating a degree of intergenerational conflict. public resources for their Control becomes malevolent capture when elites extract public private benefit. resources for their private benefit. Capture can manifest itself in vari- ous ways, including theft, corruption, and the distribution of benefits to close relatives. It is important to distinguish It is important to distinguish capture from another practice that capture from clientelism. is, generally, inimical to the public good—clientelism. Clientelism occurs when leaders allocate public resources to feed and nurture their networks and relationships in an effort to consolidate social status and power. In nondemocratic settings, within which many communities in the developing world function, whether capture is benevolent or malevolent is a function of the particularities of the community: whether leaders are hereditary or appointed by higher levels of government; the degree to which communitarian norms or “symbolic public goods” have developed in those communities; and, as in Tsai’s example from China, whether nondemocratic forms of accountability exist. In nondemocratic settings, clientelism is largely a consequence of social norms and align- ments. Benefits are doled out to individuals and groups to whom the leader has a social obligation, or to build alliances, or sustain a potlatch. The local context also determines the nature of elite capture in the presence of democratic decentralization. Bardhan and Mookherjee (1999, 2000) construct a model of elite capture with electoral compe- tition. They find that the level of capture depends on the nature and extent of political participation, the political awareness of different groups in the population, and the evenness of competition between local political parties representing different interests. Wealthy groups can make contributions to the finances of politicians, who can then use the funds to recruit “unaware” voters. Aware voters vote on the basis of their interests. Levels of political participation and awareness depend on the distribution of literacy, socioeconomic status, and exposure to media. Democratic decentralization will result in a greater dispersion in the quality of governance, increasing the gap between more and less advanced regions. It will also tend to highlight local inequalities and the distribution of interests, making the extent of capture much more specific to the local context. Clientelism in democratic settings occurs when relationships between citizens and politicians are predicated on a material transaction, “the 76
  • 97. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT direct exchange of a citizen’s vote in return for direct payments or Clientelism in democratic continuing access to employment, goods and services” (Kitschelt and settings occurs when Wilkinson 2007, 2). As Bardhan and Mookherjee (2011) point out, relationships between citizens (democratic) clientelism has several important negative consequences and politicians are predicated for development. First, resources are directed toward short-term benefits on a material transaction. with quick political gains—cash payments and private goods (housing, subsidized food) rather than goods that contribute to development in the long term (education, health). Private transfers, moreover, tend to be directed toward swing voters at the expense of voters who are not amenable to switching votes. Voters who are more easily monitored by the political party (to ensure that the transfers result in clear political gains) benefit at the expense of voters who are more difficult to moni- tor. The consequence is that allocations are unequally distributed even among deserving beneficiaries. Clientelism can thus reduce efficiency and exacerbate inequality even in the absence of explicit capture. When initiating a local development project, it is therefore important to understand the role of elites and to distinguish between elite control, which often contributes to effective participation at the local level; clientelism; and outright capture. Understanding local structures of inequality and local social and political relationships insulates against the naïve and potentially disempowering belief that participation will necessarily benefit the poor. Explicitly recognizing structures of power and dominance could result in designs to address such inequalities with affirmative action programs, such as the mandated inclusion of women and minorities in village councils, the adoption of programs that exclu- sively target certain groups, or the use of monitoring and audit systems to reduce the prevalence of capture. Group composition and collective action. The number of groups in a The number of groups in community makes a difference, particularly if each group has a distinct a community can make a identity and preferences. Groups tend to care more for their own mem- difference, particularly if each bers than for the members of other groups. Consequently, individuals group has a distinct identity may balance their individual incentives to participate with the interest and preferences. that derives from their group identity. The fact that larger communities have more groups within them would suggest that collective action is more difficult to achieve in more populous communities. However, as Alesina and La Ferrara (2005) point out, more heterogeneous societies may be more productive, because diversity may allow different skills to play complementary roles in the production process. The presence of groups that are interlinked 77
  • 98. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? in production processes may increase incentives to avoid disagreement and conflict. The relationship between the size of a community and its capacity for collective action goes beyond the issue of heterogeneity. As Olson (1965) argues, larger communities also have more free riders, because the impact of each individual defector is smaller. Moreover, if the public good generated is not “pure” (not nonexcludable), an individual’s share in the public good declines in larger groups, reducing the incentive for collective action. This phenomenon is known in the literature as the group-size paradox. However, in the case of pure (nonexcludable) public goods, Olson’s result is reversed, as larger groups are able to produce more of them. Moreover, Esteban and Ray (2000) show that when the marginal cost of participation rises sufficiently, larger groups have a greater capacity to come to agreement even if the good is excludable (that is, it has characteristics of a private good). To understand what this means, consider a situation in which poor people need to mobilize to counter a powerful and exploitative local leader. The marginal cost of participation of a poor person in this case is extremely high, both because, being poor, the opportunity cost of her time is high and because the more she participates, the more visible she becomes and the more she risks becoming a target of the leader. Consequently, mobilization against the leader is unlikely to happen unless a large enough number of poor people would benefit from doing so. Larger, more unequal, or It is therefore not necessarily true that larger communities, more more heterogeneous unequal communities, or more heterogeneous communities are more communities are not prone to collective action failure. The impact of these factors is complex necessarily more prone to and highly dependent on the purpose underlying the collective action, collective action failure. the extent of interdependence within the community, the nature of the cooperative infrastructure, the opportunity cost of participation, the level of poverty, and the extent of literacy and political awareness. Information failures. A purported advantage of decentralization is that it solves an important information failure—the inability of dis- tant central governments to observe the preferences of people who are socially, administratively, or geographically far away from central deci- sion makers. This lack of information becomes particularly acute when preferences are highly variable, either across heterogeneous populations or over time. Decentralization promises to make governments more responsive to the needs of citizens by making it more proximate to citi- zens. Whether decentralization actually solves the information problem 78
  • 99. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT by improving the match between policy decisions and the preferences of beneficiaries is an empirical question. Information failures in the civic arena are largely failures in the links Information failures in between civil society, the state, and markets. Such failures are widely the civic arena are largely prevalent and highly correlated with inequality and heterogeneity. They failures in the links between include imperfections in the availability of information about such basic civil society, the state, and issues as transparency in village budgets, citizens’ knowledge of legal markets. and bureaucratic procedures, and opportunities for credit and insur- ance. Greater inequality contributes greatly to asymmetric information; richer and more powerful people are likely to have better connected networks, better access to powerful people in government, more educa- tion (and therefore greater awareness), and greater capacity to influence decision making. Lack of information and transparency greatly hampers efforts at political and social accountability (Khemani 2007). The recti- fication of information failures (by mass media, information campaigns, or “report cards” in a credible manner and on a regular basis) has the potential to improve the ability of citizens to mobilize themselves to hold states and markets more accountable. With better information, citizens become more aware and better able to make more informed electoral decisions, which results in greater electoral accountability. Even in the absence of electoral accountability, better information may enable citizens to engage in a more informed version of “rude” account- ability—that is, confronting public officials directly and forcing them to be more responsive to their needs (Hossain 2009). In confronting the government, lobbying for resources, and making demands on the state, unequal communities face a problem in that the interests of the rich differ from the interests of the poor and the rich have more voice. Even if the poor mobilize, inequality may create distortions in linking civic groups to the state (Esteban and Ray 2006). More unequal communities will have more polarized lobbies, which have distorting effects when governments lack information about the preferences of different types of citizens. More polarized lobbies may also be more effective in voicing their interests. Consequently, govern- ments may be more influenced by the preferences of extreme groups and end up making inefficient decisions. Thus, in the Esteban-Ray model, inequality creates a particular type of civil society failure. Solving imperfections in the provision of information is relatively straightforward, in that it is less likely to involve a reversal in local power relations. However, solving information asymmetries—equalizing 79
  • 100. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Equalizing access to access to information between the rich and the poor—is often not information is relatively enough. Direct confrontation with structures of power may be neces- straightforward . . . sary to create more accountable and responsive policies. Whether the provision of information improves the functioning of states and markets and the capacity of citizens to mobilize remains an empirical question. Conclusions . . . but citizens may need Fads, rather than analysis, tend to drive policy decisions on par- to confront the structures ticipatory development. Passionate advocates spark a wave of interest, of power directly to use followed in a few years by disillusionment, which gives ammunition to that information to make centralizers, who engineer a sharp reversal. In time, excessive centraliza- governments more responsive tion generates negative fallout, which reinvigorates the climate for local to them. participation. There have been at least two such waves in the post–World War II period (as shown in chapter 1). If current trends are extrapolated, another centralizing shift may have begun. Advocates and the vicissitudes of fashion are perhaps unavoidable in the aid allocation process, but they need to be supplemented by a thoughtful diagnosis of market, govern- ment, and civil society failures; inequality; and a contextual understand- Participatory development ing of the best ways to rectify them. policy needs to be driven These spheres do not operate independently; well-being is enhanced by a thoughtful diagnosis by both improving the functioning of each sphere and enhancing the of the interaction between links among them. The problems of information asymmetry and coor- market, government, and civil dination that affect markets and governments also affect civil society. society failures. Decisions about whether, when, and how to promote local participation are therefore never easy. They need to be made with an understanding of the cooperative infrastructure; the role of elites; and the economic, political, and social costs and benefits associated with localizing decision making in a given country at a given time. Notes 1. Effective civic action can also have harmful consequences for the aver- age citizen, particularly when multiple groups with competing interests coexist within the same society—when, for instance, a fringe group is able to impose its beliefs on society at large by effectively mobilizing its members and cowering the majority into submission (Kuran 2004). This 80
  • 101. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT situation represents a case of civil society failure that is, arguably, not a sustainable equilibrium in the long run. 2. These notions of justice and fairness may vary from society to society and group to group. But every social group has norms that determine what is fair and just, and civic action is mobilized based on these norms. 3. See Bardhan (2005) for an elaboration of this point. Another way of look- ing at the connection among governments, markets, and civil society is to examine them within the frame of accountability relationships (see figure 3.2 in World Bank 2004). When citizens/clients organize collectively, they engage with the state by participating in politics and finding various other ways of expressing voice. The state consists of politicians and policy mak- ers who engage in a compact with service providers. The compact can be managerial, with the state directly managing the service providers through a government bureaucracy, or the government can delegate the provision of services to the market by having private providers deliver public services to citizens. The 2004 World Development Report specifies two routes by which a group of citizens can hold service providers accountable. The “long route” involves electoral accountability; citizens reward governments that are responsible for service provision by reelecting them or removing them from office by voting for their opponents. The “short route” decentralizes service provisions to communities, so that frontline providers are under the direct control and management of citizens, who exercise “client power” to hold them directly accountable. 4. The standard benchmark for market and government failures is “con- strained Pareto efficiency”—the failure of self-interested individuals to obtain a Pareto optimum subject to constraints of information, given fi xed preferences and technology. In the civic sphere, preferences cannot be assumed to be fi xed; deliberative processes are intended to change preferences. Furthermore, coordinated actions can change information and the possibilities for contracting. For these reasons, a tight definition of civil society failure is elusive at this stage. The authors are grateful to Karla Hoff for alerting them to this point. For discussions of the related concept of “community failure,” see Hayami and Kikuchi (1981), Baland and Platteau (1996), Aoki (2001), and Bardhan (2005). 5. In the course of a year of research, Tsai surveyed 316 villages in four provinces in northern and southern China. 6. Village temple groups are organized around a village guardian deity, an aspect of Chinese popular religion attacked during the Cultural Revolution period but subsequently rehabilitated. Lineage groups are organized around village ancestral halls. 7. Village church groups cannot be embedded, because Party members are prohibited from taking part in church activities. By contrast, given the centrality of the village temple as a symbolic resource—and the fact that the temple council is a fulcrum on which moral standing and prestige are regulated—Party members are almost always members of the temple council and among the top donors to temple activities. 81
  • 102. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? 8. The focus here is on the role of culture in building collective identity. For more on how a cultural lens can help with development policy, see Rao and Walton (2004) and Lamont and Small (2008). 9. See Bouchard (2009) for an exposition of the related idea of “collective imaginaries.” References Abraham, A., and J.-P. Platteau. 2004. “Participatory Development: When Culture Creeps.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton, 210–33. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Acemoglu, D., and J. A. Robinson. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Agrawal, A. 2005. “Environmentality: Community, Intimate Government, and the Making of Environmental Subjects in Kumaon, India.” Current Anthropology 46(2): 161–89. Alesina, A., and E. La Ferrara. 2005. “Ethnic Diversity and Economic Performance.” Journal of Economic Literature 43(3): 762–800. Alexander, J. 2006. The Civil Sphere. New York: Oxford University Press. Aoki, M. 2001. Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Baland, J.-M., P. Bardhan, and S. Bowles. 2006. “Introduction.” In Inequality, Cooperation and Environmental Sustainability, ed. J.-M. Baland, P. Bardhan, and S. Bowles, 1–9. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Baland, J.-M., and J.P. Platteau. 1996. Halting Degradation of Natural Resources: Is there a Role for Rural Communities? Oxford, U.K.: Clarendon Press. ———. 2006. “Collective Action and the Commons.” In Inequality, Cooperation and Environmental Sustainability, ed. J.-M. Baland, P. Bardhan, and S. Bowles, 10–35. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Bardhan, P. 2005. Scarcity, Conflict and Cooperation. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Bardhan, P., M. Ghatak, and A. Karaivanov. 2006. “Inequality and Collective Action.” In Inequality, Cooperation and Environmental Sustainability, ed. J.-M. Baland, P. Bardhan, and S. Bowles, 36–59. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 1999. “Relative Capture of Local and National Governments: An Essay in the Political Economy of Decentralization.” Working Paper, Institute for Economic Development, Boston University, Boston. ———. 2000. “Capture and Governance at Local and National Levels.” American Economic Review 90(2): 135–39. 82
  • 103. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT ———. 2006. “The R ise of Local Governments: An Overview.” In Decentralization and Governance in Developing Countries, ed. P. Bardhan and D. Mookherjee, 1–52. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. ———. 2011. “Political Clientelism and Capture: Theory and Evidence from West Bengal.” Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley. Bates, R. H. 2008. “State Failure.” Annual Review of Political Science 11(1): 1–12. Bayly, C. A. 2004. The Birth of the Modern World: 1780–1914. Malden, MA: Blackwell. ———. 2008. “Indigenous and Colonia l Origins of Comparative Development.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4474, World Bank, Washington, DC. Beard, V. A., and A. Dasgupta. 2006. “Collective Action and Community- Driven Development in Rural and Urban Indonesia.” Urban Studies 43(9): 1451–68. Besley, T. 2006. Principled Agents? The Political Economy of Good Government. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Bouchard, G. 2009. “Collective Imaginaries and Population Health: How Health Data Can Highlight Cultural History.” In Successful Societies: How Institutions and Culture Affect Health, ed. P. A. Hall and M. Lamont, 169–200. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Bowen, J. R. 1986. “On the Political Construction of Tradition: Gotong Royong in Indonesia.” Journal of Asian Studies 45(3): 545–61. Chwe, M. S.-Y. 1999. “Structure and Strategy in Collective Action.” American Journal of Sociology 105(1): 128–56. ———. 2001. Rational Ritual: Culture, Coordination, and Common Knowledge. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Coate, S., and M. Ravallion. 1993. “Reciprocity without Commitment: Characterization and Performance of Informal Insurance Arrangements.” Journal of Development Economics 40(1): 1–24. Dasgupta, P. 2009. “Trust and Cooperation among Economic Agents.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society 364(1533): 3301–9. Devarajan, S., and R. Kanbur. 2005. “A Framework for Scaling-Up Poverty Reduction with Illustrations from South India.” Working Paper, Department of Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY. Esteban, J., and D. Ray. 2000. “Collective Action and the Group-Size Paradox.” American Political Science Review 95(3): 663–72. ———. 2006. “Inequality, Lobbying and Resource Allocation.” American Economic Review (March): 257–79. Habermas, J. 1991. Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Hayami, Y. and M. Kikuchi. 1981. Asian Village Economy at the Crossroads: An Economic Approach to Institutional Change. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press. Heller, P., and T. M. Thomas Issac. 2003. “Democracy and Development: Decentralized Planning in Kerala.” In Deepening Democracy, ed. A. Fung and E. O. Wright, 77–110. London: Verso. 83
  • 104. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Hoff, K. 2000. “Beyond Rosenstein-Rodan: The Modern Theory of Coordination Problems in Development.” In Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, ed. B. Pleskovic and N. Stern, 145–76. Washington, DC: World Bank. Hoff, K., M. Kshetramade, and E. Fehr. 2011. “Caste and Punishment: The Legacy of Caste Culture in Norm Enforcement.” Economic Journal 121(556): F449–F475. Hoff, K., and J. E. Stiglitz. 2001. “Modern Economic Theory and Development.” In Frontiers of Development Economics, ed. G. Meier and J. Stiglitz, 389–459. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Hossain, N. 2009. Rude Accountability in the Unreformed State: Informal Pressures on Frontline Bureaucrats in Bangladesh. Institute for Development Studies, Sussex, United Kingdom. Khemani, S. 2007. “Can Information Campaigns Overcome Political Obstacles to Serving the Poor?” In The Politics of Service Delivery in Democracies: Better Access for the Poor, ed. S. Devarajan and I. Widlung, 56–69. Stockholm: Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Government of Sweden. Kitschelt, H., and S. I. Wilkinson. 2007. “Citizen-Politician Linkages: An Introduction.” In Patrons, Clients and Policies: Patterns of Democratic Accountability and Political Competition, ed. H. Kitschelt and S. I. Wilkinson, 1–49. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Kriesi, H. 2007. “Political Context and Opportunity.” In The Blackwell Companion to Social Movements, ed. D. A. Snow, S. A. Soule, and H. Kriesi, 67–90. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell. Kuran, T. 2004. “Why the Middle East Is Economically Underdeveloped: Historical Mechanisms of Institutional Stagnation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(3): 71–90. Lamont, M., and M. L. Small. 2008. “How Culture Matters: Enriching Our Understanding of Poverty.” In The Colors of Poverty, ed. A. C. Lin and D. R. Harris, 76–102. New York: Russell Sage. Mansuri, G., and V. Rao. 2004. “Community-Based and -Driven Development: A Critical Review.” World Bank Research Observer 19(1): 1–39. McCloskey, D. 2006. The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Mokyr, J. 2010. The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain 1700–1850. London: Penguin Press. Morris, A. D., and S. Staggenborg. 2004. “Leadership in Social Movements.” In The Blackwell Companion to Social Movements, ed. D. A. Snow, S. A. Soule, and H. Kriese, 171–96. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell. Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press. Pradhan, M, V. Rao, and C. Rosemberg. 2010. “The Impact of Community Level Activities of the Second Urban Poverty Project (UPP).” Department of Economics, University of Amsterdam, Amsterdam. 84
  • 105. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT Putnam, R. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Rao, V. 2006. “On Inequality Traps and Development Policy.” Development Outreach 8(1): 10–13. ———. 2008. “Symbolic Public Goods and the Coordination of Collective Action: A Comparison of Local Development in India and Indonesia.” In Contested Commons: Conversations Between Economists and Anthropologists, ed. P. Bardhan and I. Ray, 46–65. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell. Rao, V., and A. M. Ibanez. 2005. “The Social Impact of Social Funds in Jamaica: A ‘Participatory Econometric’ Analysis of Targeting, Collective Action, and Participation in Community-Driven Development.” Journal of Development Studies 41(5): 788–838. Rao, V., and M. Walton, eds. 2004. Culture and Public Action. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Ricklefs, M . 2002. A History of Modern Indonesia since c. 1200, 3rd. ed. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. Sullivan, J. 1992. Local Government and Community in Java: An Urban Case- Study. Singapore: Oxford University Press. Tsai, L. 2007. Accountability without Democracy: Solidarity Groups and Public Goods Provision in Rural China. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. World Bank. 2004. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People. Washington, DC: World Bank. ———. 2005. “The Effectiveness of World Bank Support for Community- Based and -Driven Development.” Operations Evaluation Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. ———. 2006. World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. 85
  • 107. CHAPTER THREE The Challenge of Inducing Participation THIS CHAPTER APPLIES THE ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK OUTLINED in chapter 2 in order to better understand the challenges faced in resolv- ing civil society failures, improving the interaction of civil society with markets and governments, and implementing participatory projects. What can participatory development achieve, and under what condi- tions? What do the structures of failure at the local level say about options for policy? What are some of the challenges of using policy interventions to repair civic failures and induce participation? How do incentives within donor institutions and government bureaucracies affect the implementation of participatory projects? The chapter uses the analytical framework to derive a set of hypotheses that guide the analysis of the evidence in the subsequent chapters. Under the right conditions, effective local participation can be a Under the right conditions, powerful force for change and the achievement of various develop- effective local participation ment objectives. Local development moves from being “participatory” can be a powerful force for to “empowered” when decisions made by ordinary people through change and the achievement deliberation are tied to policy decisions and actions—what Fung and of various development Wright (2003) call “empowered participatory governance.” This process objectives. is characterized by three foundational principles: • Participation must have a practical orientation. • Participation must be “bottom up,” in the sense that all of the people most affected by the problem and knowledgeable about solutions to it should be involved in decision making. • Participation must be deliberative. Fung and Wright define deliberation as a process of collective deci- sion making in which a group reaches a consensus across diverse points 87
  • 108. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? of view. It is an alternate to what economists call “preference aggrega- tion” through electoral mechanisms. In electoral decision making, pref- erences are aggregated by counting votes. Deliberative decision making requires that participants listen to one another’s positions and generate group choices after due consideration of other points of view, even if they do not necessarily endorse those choices or find them optimal. After examining various successful cases of empowered participatory governance around the world, Fung and Wright conclude that in order to advance these foundational principles, governance institutions need to incorporate three design features: • Devolution. Local decision-making units should have meaning- ful power and be downwardly accountable. • Centralized supervision and coordination. Local decision-making units need to share information, learn from one another, and discover what works by trial and error while being monitored and held accountable by the center. • State-centered, not voluntary. Empowered participation should remake state institutions to align with their foundational prin- ciples rather than develop parallel structures. Ironically, empowered Ironically, empowered participation requires a strong, functioning participation requires a state that has not only internalized the broad objective of deepening strong, functioning state. democracy and developed a much more astute view of citizens’ role in shaping policy but has also actively promoted and supervised the process by which this process happens. The premise underlying participatory development is the power of the group—the notion that individuals are far more effective when they work together toward a common objective than when they attempt to achieve the same objective on their own. By mobilizing citizens to work together for their collective well-being, participatory development has the potential to redress some failures of the state and some failures of markets while improving the capacity of individuals to bond and work together. One reason participation can do so is that it can have intrinsic value. People may value the simple courtesy of having their opinions heard, of being listened to. If public decisions are determined deliberatively rather than dictatorially, in a manner that gives everyone—poor and rich, female and male, lower and upper caste—an equal voice, the process by which decisions are made has, in itself, the potential to enhance agency. 88
  • 109. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION Political theorists contend that participation has the potential to lead to a process of positive self-transformation by catalyzing a set of desirable changes in individuals: enhanced facility for practical reasoning, greater tolerance of difference, more sensitivity about the need for reciprocity, enhanced ability to think and act with autonomy on the basis of their own preferences, and the ability to engage in moral discourse and make moral judgments (Warren 1995). Much of the value of participation can be encapsulated in Hirschman’s Participation can have (1970) view that “voice” has both intrinsic and instrumental value. The intrinsic value: people may anthropologist Arjun Appadurai (2004) goes farther, describing voice as value the simple courtesy of a “cultural capacity.” Voice, he contends, is a matter not just of people being listened to. demanding democratic rights but of engaging with social, political, and economic issues in terms of metaphor, rhetoric, organization, and pub- lic performance, in order to negotiate and navigate their worlds. This “capacity to aspire” is not evenly distributed. In situations where the rich have consistently benefited from better social, political, and economic connections and have the cultural tools to navigate those worlds, they are “more likely . . . to be conscious of the links between the more and less immediate objects of aspiration.” The rich are thus better able to navigate their way toward actualizing their aspirations. If participation is to build this navigational capacity, then voice and the capacity to aspire need to be “reciprocally linked, with each accelerating the nurture of the other” (Appadurai 2004). Participatory interventions are, however, more often justified by their instrumental value—their potential to make states and markets more accountable to the needs of citizens, to help communities mobilize to improve credit and livelihood opportunities and manage common prop- erty resources. The accountability function of participation requires groups to mobilize in a manner that changes the incentives of the agents of the state so that they act in the interests of citizens. State failure often occurs because the incentives of the individuals who comprise the state, and function as its agents, are not aligned with the needs of citizens; instead, these agents seek to maximize their own interests. In the absence of adequate oversight, this tendency could result in a range of adverse outcomes, from absenteeism to corruption and theft of public resources. Furthermore, if oversight of officials is largely managerial (that is, from the top rather than the bottom), local officials are account- able only upward, motivating officials to fulfi ll the dictates of their bosses rather than meeting local needs. The consequences—phantom 89
  • 110. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? schools with crumbling buildings and absent teachers, nonfunctioning toilets that are used to store fodder, roads that crumble at the first sign of rain—are ubiquitous in the developing world. Participation has the Participation has the potential to force agents of the state to act potential to force agents of against their private interests and for the public good. It makes the state to act against their accountability—whether it be electoral, social, or “rude”—inherently private interests and for the conflictual. How this conflict is managed and channeled depends on public good. the nature of the state, the institutional incentives of its agents, the division of power and responsibility between political leadership and bureaucrats, the nature and extent of the decentralization of authority, and the receptivity of the state to the demands of citizens. Participation is also used to enhance livelihood opportunities and credit for the poor. Microcredit programs mobilize groups of individu- als to collectively enforce the repayment schedule of every member, in an attempt to resolve coordination problems and asymmetries in infor- mation on the creditworthiness of individuals, which prevent banks and other large credit suppliers from servicing such communities. Self-help groups have also been mobilized to help expand livelihood opportunities more generally—by providing training in handicrafts and agricultural techniques, for example, and assisting in small-scale entrepreneurial and other activities. The group provides peer education and technical and moral support, using the power of networks to diffuse information and knowledge. Participation has Participation has been used to try to redress the underprovision of been used to try to redress public goods and services such as roads, water tanks, schools, and health the underprovision of public clinics, which local governments typically provide. In community- goods and services . . . driven development interventions, such public goods and services may be handed over entirely to communities to manage. In times of unex- pected crisis—when a typhoon or earthquake strikes and governments and markets are unable to respond quickly, for example—communi- ties are mobilized to rebuild homes, roads, and bridges and manage emergency aid. When a country is emerging from a long war or civil strife, community-based aid is often used to lead postconflict efforts at reconstruction. . . . and to reduce social, Participation has also been used to try to reduce social, political, and political, and economic economic inequality. By reserving leadership positions in civic bodies inequality. for women or other disadvantaged groups, participatory interventions have explicitly attempted to redress discrimination by promoting more egalitarian notions of leadership and breaking the power of traditional 90
  • 111. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION elites. These interventions are inherently conflictual, in that they chal- lenge the prerogatives of the people in authority. Using civic groups to help reduce poverty usually involves far less confl ict with elites, because it does not challenge the basis of their authority. In many countries, for instance, community-based participa- tory bodies select the beneficiaries of poverty reduction programs, an alternative method of targeting that even local elites may perceive as fair. Participation and the Capacity to Engage An important way in which participatory interventions can work is by Participatory interventions changing the character of everyday interactions—a process that, over have the potential to change time, reshapes social relationships. In highly unequal environments, the character of everyday social status structures the way people talk to one another. Moving interactions—a process that, toward accountable government both requires and brings about a over time, reshapes social change in the tone and content of discourse. The conversation shifts relationships. from being embedded within existing power relationships and con- ditioned by social norms to one in which people confront authority, demand change, debate points of policy, and speak as citizens rather than as subjects. Such shifts in “recognition” can have important eco- nomic implications (Basu 2011). To bring about this change, citizens must have access to a new tool- To bring about this change, kit of discursive strategies—conciliatory, confrontational, pleading, citizens must have access to demanding, threatening—that they are able to strategically deploy. a new toolkit of discursive Even if these approaches do not have an immediate impact on the strategies that they are able allocation of public resources, changes in the nature of speech can, over to deploy strategically. time, build what Gibson and Woolcock (2008) call the “capacity to engage.” Having the tools for “deliberative contestation” gives marginal- ized groups a more equitable shot at negotiating, asserting, and making demands that are in line with their interests and life experience. With repeated interaction, more equality in the ability to articulate demands can help move communities toward a trajectory of better and more equi- table governance. This expansion in their strategic toolkits can change not only how people are perceived within their communities but also how they perceive themselves. Rao and Sanyal (2010) analyzed the transcripts of 300 gram sab- has (village meetings) from India. This excerpt—from an interaction between the upper-caste president of the panchayat (village council), 91
  • 112. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? a poor upper-caste villager (Jayaraman), and a poor villager (Muniraj) from an untouchable (Dalit) caste—provides an example of deliberative contestation in which the Dalit villager asserts his rights as a citizen. Jayaraman: There are 45 families in our village. None of us has any land. We work for meager daily wages. Whatever little we get we spend on our children’s education. But it’s impossible to educate our children up to high school because we don’t have the money. . . . So we request that the government do something. . . . Our whole area is dirty. Even the water is muddy, and that’s what we drink. . . . How many times we have requested a road near the cremation ground and for the supply for clean water?! We can only request and apply. The rest is up to you. Panchayat president: If there are 20–25 houses in an area, a ward member should be appointed to represent the area. That ward member should listen to your problems and must do something to help you. Muniraj: That way [if we have a ward member], we will have the guts to enter this room [where the gram sabha meeting is taking place]. If the required ward members are not with us, to whom can we voice our woes? Who will represent us? . . . If the ward member belongs to another community, he won’t even listen to our problems. Earlier, there was a time when a backward caste person was not even allowed to sit in the same area with others! The officers and leaders who come here [to the gram sabha meeting] already have a preset plan about what to do and say. You come, sit on the chair, say something, decide among yourselves, and go away. What’s there for us to do?! You’ve enjoyed power for all these years. Why don’t you let us have a turn? . . . We don’t want any problem at the communal level. For us, whether X comes or Y comes, it is the same. We vote, but what hap- pens later? Whereas other people get water even before they ask for it, we have to ask endlessly, and even so, our demand is not fulfilled. . . . We don’t want to fight with anyone. But at least there should be someone to listen to our problems. We’ve been without water sup- ply for the past one month. Even the village president knows it. He has promised to send water. But the ward member is not allowing us to take water. The water is sent to all his relatives. We cannot do anything to stop it. 92
  • 113. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION Panchayat president: In any competition, it’s a rule that one should win and the other should lose. There’s no community-based dis- crimination or problem. If all of you in booth number 1 join and vote for me, I become the president. On the other hand, if everyone in the other booths votes for another person, then he’ll become the president. And then what will matter is what he can do for those booths that voted for him. Today, among youngsters, the level of public awareness is very high. Anyone can become a leader. . . . Even though there are problems between your two groups, I try to medi- ate. I don’t encourage communal riots. Muniraj: Everyone should be treated equally. No one should be treated as inferior to others. We should also be given a chance to sit on the dais [where the leaders sit]. Why should we be denied that right? Just because I talk like this, it doesn’t mean that I fight with you or disrespect you. I am simply voicing my feeling. Caste-based divisions have deep historical roots in India. They mani- fest themselves in practices such as physical distancing and symbolic deference. It is noteworthy that these traditional patterns of interaction are now being openly challenged in gram sabha meetings, as Muniraj’s angry complaints indicate. Lower-caste challenges are not completely new; what makes the exchange excerpted above different is that it comes not from a member of the educated elite but from an ordinary villager embedded in everyday, local structures of inequality. Ordinary people from disadvantaged castes now have a stake in political participation, because the gram sabha allows them to momentarily discard the stigma of their ascriptive identity and low economic status and slip into their identity as citizens with equal rights in the eyes of the state. These public interactions have the potential to challenge entrenched social relations because they make overt the heretofore unseen “weapons of the weak”—the expression of dissatisfaction in private while present- ing compliant demeanors in public, foot dragging in respond to the demands of elites. Such interactions expose “hidden transcripts” (Scott 1990) such as the feelings of oppression and domination felt by lower castes and provide a means to challenge them. Minor as it may seem, the fact that poor people and people from lower castes are able to make demands and voice complaints gives them a sense of possessing equal recognition as citizens. When—and 93
  • 114. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? whether—such small-scale changes cascade into effective civic capacity depends on the community’s level of literacy and numeracy, the level of inequality, and the extent to which inequality is embedded within durable social and power relationships. Diagnosing Failure Triangles Each type of participatory Each type of participatory intervention can be associated with a dif- intervention needs to be ferent diagnosis of the failures it will confront—whether it is trying associated with a different to generate an intrinsic or instrumental outcome, address a long-term diagnosis of the failures it development objective, or respond to a short-term crisis. Each type of will confront. intervention may employ a different definition of community (a micro- credit group is very different from a group of households mobilized to reconstruct homes after a hurricane). Not only can these groups differ in their composition, they may also have different geographic and social boundaries and incentives for collective action. Consequently, they may be subject to different types of failures. Potential spillovers from one civic objective to another also need to be thought through. Will building microcredit groups also result in the formation of groups that can fight village council corruption? Will starting a social fund to deal with postearthquake reconstruction result in a community-based institution that can act as a substitute for a failed local state? Government intervention may be justified when markets fail or economic and social inequalities need to be narrowed (see chapter 2). Theory also indicates that “each public service should be provided by the jurisdiction having control over the minimum geographic area that would internalize [its] benefits and costs” (Oates 1972, 55). Local needs are difficult for central governments to ascertain, because of the huge information costs of doing so and because of heterogeneities in prefer- ences and variations in the condition and composition of communities. For this reason, theory suggests that decisions on such issues as the provision of local public goods need to be decentralized.1 Justifications for government interventions are complicated by the fact that governments themselves are prone to failure, because of prob- lems of coordination, commitment, and information asymmetries— locally as well as at the center. The power exercised by government can reflect and reproduce inequality. The degree to which community-based 94
  • 115. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION bodies and local governments are embedded within structures of local Local civic action is believed inequality can be extremely heterogeneous, making central monitoring to be the most effective way of local bodies very difficult. Consequently, local civic action (local par- of redressing local government ticipation) is seen as the most effective and sustainable way of redressing failure . . . local government failure—dealing with corruption, giving the poor a greater say in policy decisions, and holding local governments more accountable. There are, however, some omissions in this logic, which often tend to . . . but civil society and be ignored. First, civil society is subject to the same sorts of failures and government, which are subject inequalities as markets and states. Incorporating failures and inequali- to failure themselves, shape ties in civil society makes the policy logic far more complicated and less and condition each other, in prescriptive. Participation is usually not a substitute but a complement a manner determined by the to the state. Civil society exists in a symbiotic relationship with the state: nature of the failure. it both shapes and conditions the state and is shaped and conditioned by it. Second, the development of civic capacity is not just a local challenge; Developing civil society civil society matters in checking the tendency of all levels of govern- is not just a local ment—central and local—toward authoritarianism. In addition, civic challenge . . . doing so groups play an important role in the development of markets, by creat- helps check the tendency ing an enabling environment for entrepreneurship; protecting the inter- of all levels of government— ests of workers; providing credit, and other functions that are important central and local—toward for inclusive economic growth. Thus, one challenge of development is authoritarianism. to develop civic activity at both the micro and macro levels. Third, civil society is not an abstract concept that exists outside local Civil society is not an abstract forms of knowledge, social structures, meaning and belief systems, and concept that exists outside power relations. It is shaped by people, who are products as much of local forms of knowledge, their social and cultural milieus as of economic and political systems. social structures, meaning The manner in which people organize, the interests around which they and belief systems, and power mobilize, the styles and narratives of their discourse and resistance, and relations . . . the objects of their resistance are hybrid products of local dynamics and national and global influences. Policy makers should therefore be care- ful not to impose conceptions of civil society that come from outside . . . it is shaped by people, the local environment (for example, Western political theory). Instead, who are products as much they should try to understand the meaning of terms such as “civil,” of their social and cultural “society,” and “participation” from within indigenous frames. Indeed, milieus as of economic and policy makers should try to understand how history and the history political systems. of interventions—whether colonial or developmental—have shaped those frames (Comaroff and Comaroff 1999). Doing so calls for a less prescriptive and more adaptive approach to policy. 95
  • 116. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Finally, when all three spheres—markets, governments, and civil society—are beset by failures and inequalities, which is typically the case almost everywhere, policy becomes murky, leading back to a vari- ant of the old balanced and unbalanced growth debates of the 1950s (Levy and Fukuyama 2010). Should development policy be sequen- tial—focusing first, for example, on building markets and spurring industrial growth—in the expectation that better government and civic capacity will follow, or should it focus on first developing an effective government or effective civic sphere? Should the strategy attempt to be more balanced by simultaneously improving the functioning of all three spheres? How do market, government, and civil society capacities at the macro level affect policy options at the local level? At the local level— where every village and neighborhood faces a different set of problems and is conditioned by different social structures, geographies, climates, and levels of connectivity—answers to these questions are perhaps best drawn deductively by examining the evidence, as chapters 4–6 do. Local Government Failure and the Nexus of Accommodation In most communities in the developing world, both the state and the market have failed. Local market failures—in the provision of public goods, such as schooling, health, and local infrastructure; in access to credit, markets, and so forth—are easy to identify. Local government failure can, however, be dispersed across a variety of local institutions and individuals. A local government typically consists of leaders and bureaucrats. Leaders can be members of village councils, neighbor- hood committees, mayors and municipal councils, city administrators, or chiefs and their advisers. They function within various systems of accountability. They may be elected in regular, independently super- vised elections or in “endogenous” elections that are organized and supervised locally; they may be appointed by upper-level political lead- ers and thus free of local accountability; or they may be hereditary. Local government failure Even in formally constituted democracies, the theoretical logic of is dispersed across a democratic accountability does not necessarily map into the real world variety of local institutions logic of interactions between government and citizens. Locally orga- and individuals. nized elections can be manipulated by local leaders to their advantage; independent elections, although much more effective and important as accountability mechanisms, can be subject to clientelism and the appropriation of public funds to pay for electoral campaigns. Even if 96
  • 117. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION leaders appointed by upper levels of government are accountable only The theoretical logic of upward, the central government can be effective in requiring good democratic accountability local government. Hereditary leaders selected in democratic settings, does not necessarily map although often authoritarian, can be subject to various long-term com- into the real world logic mitments, contracts, and symbolic functions that obligate them to act of interactions between in the interests of their subjects. government and citizens. All local leaders are placed in the difficult position of negotiating power with the central government, within the context of central regu- lations and political incentives. The degree of autonomy enjoyed by local leaders depends on their bargaining power with the center. At the lowest tier of government, leaders may have limited room to maneuver and be constantly in the position of having to beg for resources from higher levels. They may, however, have established fiefdoms that are politically important to the center, giving them a measure of power and autonomy. The authority of local leaders and bureaucrats depends on the extent to which they control the funds and functions of government and on their local capacity to raise revenues. The less they depend on the center for funds, the greater their autonomy. But local governments often function within the domain of local strongmen, such as large landowners or warlords, who wield considerable influence and whose own demands and interests need to be satisfied. Local leaders also have to share power with local bureaucrats, who are also subject to the institutional structures of government. Local bureaucrats often come from the lowest rung of government service; their professional incentives are geared toward pleasing their central bosses and moving up in the hierarchy. They often perform important functions at the local level and control an array of public resources, which gives them considerable power within the village or municipal- ity. These local bureaucrats can range from district administrators to “street-level” officials, such as extension officers and junior engineers, to employees of local governments, such as janitors and bill collectors. In participatory projects, it is the street-level bureaucrats (usually In participatory projects, known as “project facilitators”) who have the most proximate impact project facilitators have the on outcomes, because they are the people who deal with communities most proximate impact on on a day-to-day basis. They are expected to mobilize communities; outcomes, because they build the capacity for collective action; ensure adequate representation are the people who deal and participation; and, where necessary, break elite domination. These with communities on a trainers, anthropologists, engineers, economists, and accountants must day-to-day basis. be culturally and politically sensitive charismatic leaders. It is ironic that 97
  • 118. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? this difficult role, on which participation can succeed or fail, is usually entrusted to the least experienced, worst-paid, and most junior staff. Local politicians, bureaucrats, All of these weaknesses of local government can lead to situations in strongmen, and other elites which resources would have been allocated more efficiently had the gov- often function in a “nexus of ernment not intervened. Weaknesses are caused by accommodations made accommodation” that is hard to the center, by the manipulation of accountability mechanisms, and by to break. accommodations to local strongmen and between local bureaucrats and politicians (Migdal 1988). The concentration of power in any of these actors—a local strongman who also heads the village council, for exam- ple—can lead to a strong local state but one that tends to be dictatorial in its decisions. When all actors are equally powerful, power and authority can be diffused in a way that makes actions unpredictable, dilutes respon- sibility for action, and weakens the cooperative infrastructure. It is difficult for central It is difficult for central governments to monitor the work of local governments to monitor the governments because of the very imperfections in information and coor- work of local governments dination that caused power to be devolved in the first place. The nexus because of the very of social structures, power relations, the management of accommoda- imperfections in information tions, the needs of citizens, and the quality of personnel vary greatly and coordination that caused from jurisdiction to jurisdiction, causing communities to have a high power to be devolved in the degree of heterogeneity. These variations place an untenable burden first place. of monitoring and supervision on the central government; if power is decentralized, they can produce an entirely new set of government fail- ures. The constant process of accommodation among the center, local strongmen, local government leaders, and bureaucrats, often makes the interests of citizens the last priority—the residual element in a hierarchy of interests that must be accommodated. Participation has the potential Participation has the potential to change this dynamic. It can move to move the actions of local the actions of local governments toward the interests of citizens by governments toward the adding their voice to the mix of necessary accommodations. If civic interests of citizens by groups are sophisticated enough to understand the procedures of local adding their voice to the governments and nimble enough to know how to exploit the politi- mix of necessary cal economy of accommodation, they can become a potent political accommodations . . . force. If the cooperative infrastructure is strong and elite interests not dominant, citizens can be united, lobby effectively, and persuade local . . . but realizing this potential governments to listen to their points of view, furthering their interests requires radical change, by changing incentives within local governments. including confrontation with Although participatory projects are packaged and promoted on elites. the promise of “empowerment” or enhancing the “demand side of 98
  • 119. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION governance,” they often downplay the fact that both outcomes require Lasting change is unlikely radical change—a confrontation with local elites and a shift, to use if the radical process of Migdal’s language, in the “nexus of accommodation.” If external donors breaking the local nexus and central and state governments have not completely internalized of accommodation is not these radical goals and participation is instead nothing more than a internalized and supported by donor-driven mandate, it is unlikely that interventions will be imple- donors and the central state. mented in a manner that is truly empowering. Instead, the goals will be processed within the existing nexus of accommodation, and lasting change in outcomes will be unlikely—and may actually lead to elite capture. Participatory interventions then become archetypes of what Hoff and Stiglitz (2001) call “shallow interventions”—interventions that result in no sustainable and irreversible changes in political dynam- ics and therefore have a negligible impact on outcomes. To achieve a “deep intervention,” the state has to commit to a long-term process of engineering; a more downwardly accountable cooperative infrastructure that is equity enhancing and empowering. Doing so requires strong monitoring to avoid elite backlash, subversion, or capture, and the abil- ity to distinguish between benevolent and malevolent elite engagement with communities. Participation and Political Opportunity Effective participation requires the skillful exploitation of local political Effective participation requires opportunities (Kreisi 2007). An individual’s political opportunity set the skillful exploitation of is determined by his or her interests (material, ideological, or identity local political opportunities. based), as well as by the economic, social, political, or psychic con- straints he or she faces. The decision to participate, however, depends largely on the actions of the other members of the group to which an individual belongs. A group’s willingness to mobilize and act collec- tively depends on its shared opportunity set, the gains that accrue from acting collectively, and the costs and other constraints associated with coordinating collective activity. It is not just individual and collective interests that influence the set of opportunities—it is also the beliefs about those opportunities (Elster 1989). These beliefs are important because they may cause actors to underestimate or overestimate their capacity to effect change. Sociologists call this mix of individual and group political opportunities and beliefs the “political opportunity structure” (Kriesi 2007). 99
  • 120. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Indonesia provides an interesting example of how a village group was able to exploit political opportunities for change by developing its capacity to engage (Gibson and Woolcock 2008). An extended conflict over a leaky dam served as a flashpoint for organizing farmers and other villagers who depended on its shrinking reservoir supply for irrigation and drinking water. Initially, villagers used bureaucratic channels to request repairs to the dam. When their demands fell on deaf ears, they began expressing their anger through arguments and small-scale violence among themselves, including a hoe fight between two family members that resulted in head injuries. As unrest peaked in 2001, the villagers changed their tactics and began to mobilize hundreds of teachers, police, civil servants, and rice paddy owners and workers through a broad array of social networks. This mass mobilization caught the attention of a candidate for the local council, who used it as an opportunity to confront the incumbent. As hundreds of villagers blockaded a key road to the dam, the candidates sat in chairs facing the dilapidated structure until the deputy head of the council arrived and promised to make the repairs—which were completed within a year. This victory gave rise to a flurry of peaceful and fruitful engage- ment aimed at forcing the government to compensate farmers for lands inundated by the dam. In using the original conflict to develop their capacity to engage with local officials—and exploit the competition between them—the villagers developed new open political opportunity structures and beliefs about themselves that will have a lasting impact on local power relations. Localizing development can An open political opportunity structure is one in which civic action open up political opportunities can exploit changes in the political system—in the structure of the by bringing the locus of state, in leadership, or in dominance by a particular elite—to further decision making closer the interests of a particular group. Localizing development—through to citizens, increasing the decentralization or a community-driven development project, for benefits to participation while example—can open up political opportunities by bringing the locus reducing its costs. of decision making closer to citizens, which increases the benefits to participation while reducing its costs. Because of the nexus of accom- modation between local and central politicians and between local and central bureaucrats, however, the effectiveness of local civic mobiliza- tion can be modest. Although civic mobilization can potentially change the incentives of the agents of the local state so that they act more in the interests of citizens, these agents will have to balance the demands of local citizens against the demands of central authorities and the 100
  • 121. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION competing demands of other local actors. In the absence of a sharp and sustainable shift in the nexus of accommodation, therefore, expansion of civic opportunities at the local level may have limited impact. Acemoglu and Robinson offer some important insights into the process of participatory democratic change in Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. They find that the conditions under which political opportunities for citizens are maximized and the manner in which citizens can effect change in a manner that progressively empow- ers them depends on whether a particular group believes it has the capac- ity “to obtain its favored policies against the resistance” of the people in power and can convince other groups that it can do so (Acemoglu and Robinson 2006, 21). Before they can act, citizens have to be persuaded that any move toward an open political opportunity structure will be durable and that old political institutions enmeshed with old economic and social arrangements will give way to more accountable structures. If change is seen as temporary, individuals will tend to use the opportunity to maximize their immediate personal gains. Citizens will participate in a manner that challenges powerful elites only if they feel they can “lock in” political power in a way that is not easily reversed. Citizens’ willingness to act is further complicated by uncertainty Before they can act, citizens about decentralization, which could be recentralized during the next have to be persuaded that any political cycle, as has happened in almost every developing country. move toward an open political Similarly, in the absence of durable shifts toward a more accountable opportunity structure will be state, participation in community-driven development projects may durable. not lead to greater citizen mobilization on other issues, as the costs will exceed the benefits. In contrast, a genuine change in the political opportunity structure, accompanied by collective mobilization, can permanently increase the cost to elites of maintaining their domination. Citizens thus make decisions about participation based on the likely success of a specific reform, their beliefs about how sustainable it is, and the potential for repression and backlash. Even with active participa- tion, a small number of protagonists will lead the charge—spurred on by lower opportunity costs or greater altruism. Some people will prefer to have a free ride whereas others will play it safe, waiting to see how quickly the winds change before deciding to act. There will also be antagonists—people who actively oppose civic agents because those agents challenge their interests. Elites who stand to lose under the new regime will include many local and central bureaucrats, local strongmen, and local and central politicians. Some elites may become protagonists, however, if they see a 101
  • 122. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? way that a change in policy could serve their own interests; there is, in fact, a risk of elite capture if gains from an intervention accrue mainly to these pro-reform elites and their supporters. A third category of elites— often better-educated citizens with high moral but low political author- ity, such as teachers, pastors, and imams—may help lead the process, either because they are altruistic and see doing so as a way of effecting positive change or because leadership gives them an opportunity to gain power and status. In this case, elite domination can facilitate an intervention and may even be essential to its success. In some societies, there is Part of the challenge of introducing decentralized and participatory no recognizable conception government into societies with “traditional” authority structures is that of citizenship in the textbook traditional systems function with a different theory of governance, sense of the term . . . which the community generally accepts as just and legitimate. In some societies, there is no recognizable conception of citizenship in the text- book sense of the term; there are, instead, only leaders and subjects. The legitimacy of local leaders is based on a gift economy, a system of . . . instead, leaders and mutual obligation between leaders and subjects in which civic activity subjects relate to one another consists largely of subjects making requests to leaders. Leaders grant through systems of mutual these requests if they are able to do so, expecting obedience in return. obligation. The resulting equilibrium creates elite dominance, authoritarian rule, and sharp inequalities in wealth, power, and social status. Development projects come with “modern” notions of governance and citizenship, which are predicated on the assumptions that govern- ment and citizens represent separate and equal spheres and separate loci of power and that “good governance” requires leaders to be accountable to citizens. This notion of governance is based on competition and negotiation for power rather than on mutual obligation. Shifting from a gift-based to a Shifting from a gift-based to a competition- and negotiation-based competition- and negotiation- model of governance and citizenship is a highly contentious process. based model of governance During periods of what can be called “traditional equilibrium”—when and citizenship is a highly social and political roles are well defined and everyone’s actions and contentious process. interactions are highly predictable—levels of conflict are low. Within this system, however, there may be few opportunities to break inequality traps or empower the poor. At best, the poor can employ Scott’s (1990) “weapons of the weak” to express resentment without explicit confron- tation. Participatory interventions—along with other efforts to reduce inequalities, such as land reform—seek to disrupt this equilibrium by changing the local cooperative infrastructure, replacing leadership legitimized by mutual obligation with a relationship between leaders 102
  • 123. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION and citizens based on democratic accountability. Unless traditional inequalities resting on inherited wealth, status, and identity are concur- rently replaced by a system in which power and status reward ability and effort, however, the traditional order and existing power structures will subsume and subvert any nascent participatory institutions. If, however, participatory interventions break down durable inequali- ties, collective well-being could well diminish in the short run, as elites resist, object to, and attempt to disrupt this challenge to their status. Some of their subjects will be left anchorless, not knowing how to navigate the new environment. Others will compete for power by using violence. The major challenge during this transition period is to channel conflicts into venues for deliberation and debate, in order to achieve a negotiated transition to a new regime. If the process is effective, it will lead to a new equilibrium in which leadership is legitimated by its ability to meet the needs of citizens and social status is based on achievement. Implementation Challenges: The Role of Donors Challenges in inducing participation lie not only in the power dynam- Challenges in inducing ics within communities; they are also deeply influenced by incentives participation lie not only in within agencies tasked with funding and implementing participatory the power dynamics within projects. In particular, donors—both multilateral and bilateral—have communities . . . been key players in the spread of participatory innovations. They have been responsible for transferring ideas and techniques from one region of the world to another and actively scaling up interventions developed in a few communities to an entire country. Donors have tended to ignore the fact that context (historical trajectories, social and economic inequality, ethnic heterogeneity, and symbolic public goods) affects political and social institutions, especially at the community level, rely- ing instead on “best practice” templates. This tendency results in what Evans (2004) calls “institutional . . . they are also deeply monocropping”—the “imposition of blueprints based on idealized influenced by incentives versions of Anglo-American institutions, the applicability of which is within agencies tasked with presumed to transcend national circumstances and cultures.” Other funding and implementing critics, including Harriss (2001) and Cooke and Kothari (2001), argue participatory projects. that in participatory projects, complex and contextual concepts such as community, empowerment, and capacity for collective action are applied to large development projects on tight timelines. Consequently, project implementers, whose incentives are often poorly aligned with 103
  • 124. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? the needs of the project, may gloss over differences within target groups that underscore local power structures and sidestep the difficult task of institution building in favor of more easily deliverable and measurable outcomes. Mosse’s (2005) ethnography of the Indo-British Rain-Fed Farming Project (IBRFP), funded by the United Kingdom’s Overseas Development Administration (ODA) and Department for International Development (DFID), illustrates how the process of induced participation works in a large, scaled-up, donor-driven project. Mosse studied the project over several years and was involved in it in various capacities—as a planner, social expert, soil and water conservation consultant, and adviser—as it evolved through different planning and implementation phases. He studied all of its phases, from inception, in 1992, as a participatory project geared toward bringing agricultural technologies and innova- tions to the tribal Bhil population in central India; to its assessment by the development community, in 1995, as an “exemplary success”; to its culmination, in 1998–99, by which time it was declared a failure. ODA– DFID’s Indian partner organization was a fertilizer company, which Mosse found to be unusually committed to the participatory ethic. The company hired a large field staff of community organizers and trained a large number of village-level volunteers, called jankars (“knowledgeable people”), who gradually emerged as crucial local mediators and brokers. The project began with a “village entry” participatory rural appraisal. The very nature of a participatory rural appraisal—which is typically held in the courtyard of a village headman or other notable—subjects it to a high degree of bias and reflects the effects of local power. The type of knowledge that was communicated, the tone of the discourse, and the words used all reflected the biases of the more active, articulate members of the village, who defined the community’s needs and then became crucial links for the community organizations in the initial trust- building phase of the project. The poorer members of the community were usually unwilling, inarticulate participants in such processes. In response, the community organizations gradually changed their tactics. They approached women and nonelites for more discreet, informal rural appraisal–type exercises, which had repercussions for their position in relation to village elites. Matters were hardly as simple as ensuring that all points of view were represented, however: villagers quickly learned to anticipate the outsider’s point of view, sense project staff ’s capacities for providing 104
  • 125. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION assistance, and structure their demands accordingly. The project soon came to be seen as a patron of particular activities and constituencies. The participatory rural appraisal and planning stage became, in effect, a process of mutual collusion in which “local knowledge” and desires were effectively domesticated by the project’s vocabulary, as community perspectives seamlessly melded with the project’s interests. Although planners continued to use the language of participation and empower- ment, villagers viewed the project as just another kind of patronage. Better-off villagers hoped for various forms of assistance in terms of capital investment (seeds, inputs, loans for pump sets); worse-off villag- ers came to view the project as a source of wage labor and credit. Was there anything wrong with the way this participatory project progressed? The answer depends on what hopes one harbors for “par- ticipation.” Rather than evaluating the project from an abstract ideal, Mosse studied various dynamics. The community organizations and other field staff had to undergo a tricky process of earning the trust of community members. Doing so required them to become familiar with local notables, institutional figures, and bureaucrats. As they did so, they gradually became implicated in various village hierarchies and fac- tions and in local networks of exchange, favors, and mutual assistance. The village-level jankars became more or less “empowered” over time (although their fortunes could wax and wane with the fortunes of the project), although this empowerment arose mainly through relations with outsiders. This process, Mosse argues, is one of the generic dilem- mas of participatory approaches: such projects often demand not less but more intensive agency presence, they may be less cost-efficient, and they may foster dependency and patronage (Mosse 2005). So when did things begin to go “wrong” with this project? Two inter- pretations must be separated: Mosse’s evaluation of the implementation stage of the project and the organizational judgments that first declared the project a success and then a failure. In Mosse’s view, the implementation stage brought with it entirely new organizational dynamics: prioritizing quantifiable targets, setting numerical goals, moving away from learning and experimentation. This transition created a “regime of implementation” (2005, 109). Staff mem- bers faced growing pressure to meet implementation targets, set from above and demanded from below. The jankars, working closely with but junior to the community organization project staff, began to “regard themselves primarily as project employees (if not private contractors), 105
  • 126. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? with the power to assess work and sanction payment” (Mosse 2005, 114). As one senior project employee reported, “we rather skewed the potential of jankars as real agents of a more indigenous type of develop- ment. They became the delivery mechanisms, which [was a departure] from the original thinking” (114). As for the villagers, “although they were now familiar with the official rhetoric of ‘people’s participa- tion’ (janasabhagita), in common parlance ‘participation’ (bhagidari) implied simply that a contribution (of money or labor) had to be made . . . the extent and nature of villager’s bhagidari (contribution) was a matter for negotiation and agreement with outsider patrons” (114). By this phase, participatory rural appraisal “became largely symbolic. Staff now knew how to write them [participatory appraisals] up; how to move swiftly to expenditure. . . . As the logic of implementation pushed prac- tice toward standardization, it was virtually impossible to ensure that ‘participatory planning’ involved local problem solving or even choosing between alternatives. In fact, the ‘quality’ of the “participatory process’ mattered less and less” (116). Mosse’s analysis describes the phase shift typically experienced by most participatory projects, from a somewhat open-ended planning phase to a more structured implementation phase. It is possible to con- ceive of it as a kind of rhythm of participatory projects, which could, therefore, have been anticipated. More damaging, according to Mosse, was the effect of this shift on the service delivery aspect of the project and the kind of demands that should have been but were not factored in. “Villagers themselves had little control over project processes and budgets. Rather than imple- menting their own ‘village development plan,’ they found that compo- nents of the plan (individual schemes and subsidies) would be delivered on an item-by-item basis—instead of in logically related bundles—by an administrative system that was unknown and unpredictable. One example of a logical bundle was a request by a group of women in a village for support for a project consisting of an interlinked package of activities—ducks, goats, rabi seeds, and a pump set” (Mosse 2005, 263). Mosse argues that one of the key problems in the shift from the planning to the implementation phase is that once a set of practices is in place, the system generates its own priorities, activities, and goals, which may be quite different from the formal goals regarding commu- nity participation and empowerment expressed in policy papers or even project design documents. The relationship between policy and practice in participatory interventions therefore needs careful consideration. 106
  • 127. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION Another problem is that there are stratified, relatively autonomous levels of project actors with narrow points of overlap (Mosse describes this relationship as an “hourglass”), as illustrated in Mosse’s multisited ethnography of head offices, consultants, budget specialists, project staff, village-level community organizations, volunteers, and villagers. This hourglass relationship is crucial to the question of how to scale up projects. Mosse describes a wrong turn, a transition point in the project, as “DFID–imposed disorder” caused by a “grossly simplified view of ‘up-scaling,’ ‘mainstreaming,’ ‘fast-tracking,’ and ‘replication.’ ” As a result, “a huge burden was placed on a complex and shaky system: the project had to create a new organizational structure, to quadruple the size of its operations . . . fast-track its process (reduce village entry time) . . . create further linkages [to both the local government and the rural commercial sectors], while retaining its intense focus on participa- tion . . .” (Mosse 2005, 185). Most strikingly, throughout the period in which the project was first declared a success and then a failure, field activities, levels of work, and modes of engagement remained more or less the same, and project actors maintained relative autonomy. This meant, according to Mosse, that the project’s “fall from grace” was not a result of a shift in design or implementation but a result of changing policy fashions. The late 1990s saw an increased emphasis on partnerships with state structures; para- statal projects lost favor, as they were not seen to be “replicable models” (Mosse 2005, 199). What Mosse finds worrisome is that with policy fashion cycles becoming shorter, the ability to gain the trust of local populations may be increasingly compromised, as projects abruptly dispense with groups that no longer serve their policy objectives. Several lessons emerge from Mosse’s account: • The expectation of abrupt shifts in policy has adverse effects at every level of the project—and crucially contributes to the shallowness of the intervention. If the project is seen as end- ing within a very proximate period rather than contributing to sustainable change, higher-level project officials will spend their time trying to frame the intervention as a success rather than working to lay the foundation for lasting change. • The expectation of abrupt shifts in policy influences the qual- ity and character of mobilization. Because the intervention is seen as time bound, people participate largely in order to reap material gain. They take what they can from the resources the 107
  • 128. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? project brings and say what they have to say to gain access to those material benefits. Although such behavior may create some short-term improvements in material well-being, it does not result in a lasting shift in power relationships and stronger mechanisms for voice and mobility. • Even if the intervention is long lasting, participatory change takes time. A short project cycle that initiates but then termi- nates a trajectory of change can leave communities hanging off a cliff. • Participatory projects work well when they are given the free- dom to learn by doing, to constantly experiment and innovate based on feedback from the ground. As the project expands, however, experimentation becomes more difficult, and efforts are directed more toward meeting the letter rather than the spirit of project goals. • Facilitators play a crucial role in participatory projects. Implementation Challenges: The Role of Facilitators Facilitators are at the frontline Facilitators are at the frontline of induced participation. They identify of induced participation . . . the failures of local civil society, markets, and government; design inter- ventions to repair them; and look for ways to repair the associated civic failures, seek political opportunities, and mobilize the community to exploit them. Facilitators are paid to play the role that the social activ- ist would play in an organic participatory movement. Their incentives are rarely aligned in a manner that results in truly empowered change, however. For example, although their job requires flexibility, time, and constant engagement with experimentation, facilitators are given targets (mobilize X communities in Y days). Because they are poorly compensated and know the project will end in two or three years, they are constantly looking for other work. They are often poorly monitored, allowing them to submit false reports on the achievement of project targets. Perhaps of greatest concern, facilitators working under these condi- tions may take shortcuts to persuade or force people to participate, using messages for recruitment that are quite different from stated project goals. For example, they may try to meet their participation targets by using messages with a strong emotional impact or by luring people with the implicit promise of monetary benefit. Instead of being seen as agents 108
  • 129. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION of change, facilitators may be perceived as part of the existing nexus of . . . but their incentives are accommodation. The question, then, is whether they can legitimately often not set up to truly affect radical change when they are perceived as part of the state appa- empower communities. ratus? When change requires radical advocacy, do these facilitators, who report upward to people who may not permit them to advocate radical change, face the right incentives? More fundamentally, what can facili- tators accomplish? Within which spaces can they work for change? Can induced participatory development really generate political and social empowerment? Many factors affect the answers to these questions, but it is clear that interventions will not succeed without higher levels of government being actively committed to the development of active civic engagement at the local level. Implementation Challenges: Trajectories of Change A major problem with donor-induced participation is that it works Donors’ institutional within an “infrastructure template.” Donors’ institutional structures structures and incentives are and incentives are optimally suited to projects with short timelines optimally suited to projects and linear trajectories of change with clear, unambiguous projected with short timelines and linear outcomes. When a bridge is built, for instance, the outcome is easily trajectories of change with verified, the trajectory of change is predictable, and the impact is almost clear, unambiguous projected immediate. Participatory interventions, which engage in the much more outcomes . . . complex task of shifting political and social equilibriums, have very different trajectories. Unfortunately, most participatory projects that emerge from donor . . . but civic change is a highly agencies are designed within the same assumed trajectory and three- to unpredictable process. five-year cycles as infrastructure projects. At the end of the project cycle, these projects are expected to have met various civic objectives (better social capital, community empowerment, improved accountability). Almost all community-driven projects go farther, projecting gains in outcomes such as a poverty reduction, school enrollment, sanitation and health, and so forth. The assumption is that within the period of the project cycle, the intervention will activate civic capacity to the extent that it will repair political and market failures enough to have an observable impact on “hard” outcomes. Three assumptions are inherent in this thinking: • Civic engagement will be activated in the initial period of the project. 109
  • 130. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? • Civic capacity will be deepened enough to repair government and market failures. • This improvement in the quality of governments and markets will result in a measurable change in outcomes. Figure 3.1 illustrates the problems with these assumptions. The project-based assumption (illustrated by the dotted lines) shows a path in which civil society and governance outcomes improve in a predict- able linear manner that is congruent with changes in measurable out- comes. The problem with this reasoning is that civic change is a highly unpredictable process; many things have to take place to make it hap- pen. Individuals have to believe that collective mobilization is worth the effort and be willing to participate; civic groups have to solve the collective action problem and exploit political opportunities to effect change; the nexus of accommodation in government has to be disrupted by the rising cost of ignoring citizens’ interests, so that politicians and bureaucrats change their actions; and their new actions have to result in changes in outcomes. A change in outcomes has to be preceded by an improvement in civic capacity, which possibly unleashes a series of changes that will change outcomes (Woolcock 2009). The reality is depicted by the solid lines in figure 3.1. Predicting when meaningful change will occur in each node is extremely difficult because a number of factors come into play, Figure 3.1 Possible trajectories of local participation Household welfare, public Projected development goods, quality of public path for welfare outcomes services Realized development path for welfare outcomes Time Civil society and governance Projected development Realized development outcomes path for civil society and path for civil society and governance outcomes governance outcomes 110
  • 131. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION including the nature of the cooperative infrastructure; the history of civic engagement and politics; the level of development; the extent to which the state has committed to the process of change and is therefore effectively incentivizing, enforcing, and monitoring the actions of its agents; the level of literacy; information flows—in other words, all of the factors that affect civic failure. Social equilibrium is hard to change because it has evolved after years of repeated interactions within par- ticular economic, political, and social environments. Therefore, whether at the micro or the macro level, civic engage- ment often tends to be absorbed, in its early stages, within the nexus of accommodation, with the leaders co-opted by elites. Furthermore, as discussed earlier in this chapter, until citizens are convinced that the high cost of fighting for their interests and resisting elite domination is worth the effort, they are unlikely to engage in an effective manner. Widespread participation occurs when a tipping point is reached— when enough people are convinced of the value of participation, when they sense a fundamental change in the nature of politics and power, and when enough people convince enough others to engage, resulting in a participatory cascade. Borrowing from evolutionary biologists, sociologists describe this process as one of “punctuated equilibrium” (Koopmans 2007)—a process in which long periods of stability are punctuated by brief periods of extremely rapid change. At the local level, the wide diversity in the nature of communities reinforces this unpredictability in the timing of change. Each community is likely to have a different change trajectory. Thus, particularly when it is packaged within a project, induced Particularly when it is participation is almost set up for failure because of unrealistic predic- packaged within a project, tions that emerge from bureaucratic imperatives. The challenge of induced participation is policy interventions is to figure out where each community is within almost set up for failure this complex trajectory of change and to create an enabling environment because of unrealistic in which that change can occur in a manner that improves develop- predictions that emerge from ment objectives. For induced participatory projects to have a chance bureaucratic imperatives. of meeting their objectives, they have to attempt to adopt the spirit of experimentation, learning, and persistent engagement that character- izes organic participatory change. Unfortunately, donors are bound by strict timelines; imperatives to disperse money quickly and effectively; and internal incentives that make honest and effective monitoring and evaluation a low priority at the project level, despite the rhetoric in sup- port of it. 111
  • 132. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Deriving Hypotheses Public spending to improve living conditions for the most disadvan- taged is widely accepted as the cornerstone of any credible development strategy. There is also a sense that any serious policy shift in this direc- tion needs to include a larger role for civil society. In line with this, many developing countries have devolved the management of key public services, have decentralized the implementation of targeted poverty reduction programs, and are increasingly providing local public goods through mechanisms that induce some type of community participa- tion. At the core of these efforts is the idea that greater civic engagement can make resource allocation both more responsive and more account- able, with the greatest benefits realized by people with the least influence and the least capacity to opt for private alternatives. The traditional economic justification for local provision of pub- lic goods and services is that it allows subjurisdictions to tailor the level, quality, and cost of services to the preferences of local residents. Governments are assumed to be largely benign and citizens mobile, able to “vote with their feet” by moving to areas where regulations, taxes, and services best match their preferences and needs. Most public goods and services (schools, drinking water, sanitation, roads) are inherently local; they serve a reasonably well-defined group from which nonresidents can be effectively excluded. In such cases, devolution should increase both efficiency and equity, because it frees up a distant center from having to acquire costly information on local preferences and the supply of local public goods. Local agents may also have access to emerging information, such as recent adverse shocks, that may be only poorly reflected in the types of data available to distant cen- tral administrators. To the extent that some of the salient characteristics of poverty are also location specific, decentralizing the identification of beneficiaries may also increase the efficiency of resource allocation. Citizen mobility also creates external performance pressure on sub- jurisdictions to compete for the best talent and the most productive and profitable businesses, which curbs excessive rent-seeking by public officials and increases service quality. Menes (2003) argues that this process accounts for the decline in municipal corruption in the United States at the turn of the 20th century. As railroads were developed and the frontier became accessible, the capacity of local government officials to extract rents declined (see also Rondinelli, Mccullough, and Johnson 1989; Khan 2002). 112
  • 133. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION If citizens are mobile and governments benign, there seem to be few efficiency arguments for centralized resource allocation, except when significant intercommunity coordination problems arise from spillovers, externalities, or economies of scale that require centralized manage- ment. (Rules and regulations regarding environmental pollution, vac- cination programs, and defense are good examples.) The situation is quite different in most developing countries, where the main arguments for decentralization center on accountability. In this view, the fundamental problem with the central provision of public goods and services is bureaucratic inefficiency and rampant rent-seeking. Localizing resource allocation decisions brings ordinary citizens, who have the greatest stake in the quality of services provided as well as the greatest incentive to restrict rent-seeking, into closer prox- imity with relevant decision makers. Decentralization allows citizens to observe the actions of officials and providers, to use this information to induce higher levels of transparency, and to generate social pressure for policy reform. Concerns about corruption have amplified the accountability argu- The main argument for ment for decentralization.2 Over the past decade, the view that corrup- decentralization in most tion poses a major threat to development has acquired considerable cur- developing countries is that rency. Corruption is seen as adding substantially to the cost of providing it increases accountability, basic public goods and services; dampening the redistributive objectives thereby reducing corruption. of poverty reduction programs; and, perhaps worst of all, changing the incentives facing both citizens and public officials.3 As reform efforts directed at legal and financial institutions at the center have produced little success, the push for more local solutions has grown, with the greatest emphasis on civil society oversight and monitoring of public officials and providers.4 This emphasis on local accountability has effectively created a new justification for the decentralization of resource allocation decisions that remains relevant even when there is no significant variation in preferences for public goods. Arguments for state and donor support to local participatory institutions are couched in terms of giving voice to the most disadvantaged members of society in order to create demand for better governance. Influential voices on the other side of the debate over participation point out that shifting the locus of decision making downward need not have salutary effects if social structures reflect long histories and deeply entrenched power hierarchies. In such contexts, they argue, local inequalities of wealth and power can acquire much greater significance, 113
  • 134. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? as important resource allocation decisions shift downward; in the extreme, they can exacerbate local inequality and perpetuate or even reinvigorate local power relations. Where localities are also heterogeneous in other respects, such as in their ethnic, racial, or tribal composition, there may be additional coor- dination challenges and greater potential for redistributive projects to generate or exacerbate local conflicts. Some researchers, such as Henkel and Stirrat (2001), even argue that although the language used by par- ticipatory programs is designed precisely to manage such underlying dissent, the search for “consensus” often simply results in the subordina- tion of minority voices or the proliferation of formal governance rules that make participation costly, particularly for the people with the least capacity. In the presence of significant group heterogeneity, electoral incentives can also induce political agents to allocate resources to satisfy more parochial interests, at the cost of broader investments in public goods and services. Whether local governments Whether or not local governments or participatory programs can or participatory programs can be responsive to local needs may depend to a significant degree on the be responsive to local needs resources they can access relative to their mandate and the discretion may depend to a significant they have over the allocation of resources across diverse needs. For many degree on the resources they reasons, including the political context in which central governments can access relative to their undertake decentralization, in most developing countries, devolution mandate . . . of responsibility for taxation has been far more contentious than the devolution of responsibilities for expenditure, particularly when local governments are elected. With few exceptions, however, and regardless . . . and the discretion they of the type of decentralization undertaken, local governments obtain have over the allocation of the bulk of their resources as transfers, whether formula based or dis- resources across diverse cretionary and ad hoc, from central or intermediate-level governments; needs. taxation authority is rarely devolved to any substantial degree. As a result, there is an unavoidable tension between central and lower levels of governments regarding accountability and fiscal discipline at the local level. Local officials blame the center for their failures in service provi- sion by claiming that the center has assigned unfunded mandates to them, limiting their ability to meet their responsibilities. Discretionary transfers from the center are considered particularly detrimental for local provision of public goods and services, because they not only limit the local government’s ability to plan investments and expenditures, they also leave local governments vulnerable to various types of manipu- lation from the center. For their part, central governments bemoan 114
  • 135. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION local governments’ “soft budget constraints,” a situation in which local governments that are unconstrained by their revenue-raising capacity are tempted to overspend and then ask the center for a bailout in the form of supplemental transfers from tax revenues generated elsewhere. Of course, such overspending may itself be a response to an unfunded expenditure mandate. In principle, local governments could raise some or all of their In practice, devolving revenue resources directly from their constituents, through taxes and fees, and raising to the local level is there are important arguments in favor of devolving revenue-raising difficult. responsibilities. Some researchers have even gone as far as to argue that central transfers should be contingent on such revenue-raising efforts, as such a move would force local governments to accept responsibility for poor service provision and incentivize citizens to monitor local officials’ performance more closely. In practice, however, devolving revenue rais- ing to the local level is difficult. Central governments also have a mandate to mitigate interregional disparities through appropriately targeted fiscal transfers, which can include considerations of need intensity and demographic size. As Cai and Treisman (2004) argue, when regional differences in the productiv- ity of specific factors are significant (because of location, agglomeration externalities, or the endowment of resource), local taxation authority can unleash a race to the bottom. As local governments compete to attract the wealthy, less well-endowed localities become weaker and more dependent on central transfers. This situation can exacerbate regional disparities in government services and increase horizontal wealth inequality. The worst-off areas may also have the least incentive to give up rent-seeking activities. Some observers suggest that the timelines and objectives of donor- Donors’ evaluation criteria funded projects can exacerbate these challenges. Donor-funded projects, create incentives to select they argue, value the rapid disbursement of inputs, the creation of areas that are easily reached community organizations, the achievement of predetermined rates of and organized . . . return on investments, and improvements in the income and assets of beneficiaries. These evaluation criteria create an incentive to select areas that are easily reached and organized and to target project benefits to . . . . and to target project households that are able to quickly absorb project funds in productive benefits to households that activities.5 are able to quickly absorb A key concern is the possibility of civil society failure (defined in project funds in productive chapter 2). A group might be unable to act collectively, or collective activities. action could occur in a well-coordinated but dysfunctional manner that 115
  • 136. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? reduces the welfare of the average citizen (as in the case, for example, of an organized fringe group that uses terror and violence to further its extremist ends at high social cost). When civic participation is When is civic participation likely to be the best answer to government likely to be the best solution and market failures, and when is it not? The answers are deeply con- to government and market textual, fundamentally conditioned by social structures and historical failures, and when it is not, is trajectories, and different for every community. A policy that works in highly contextual. . . . one village may fail miserably in another. Moreover, as effective collective action depends on the cooperative infrastructure provided by a strong state, it is not at all clear that strong civil society creates strong govern- . . . and thus best determined ments; the reality is more complex and nuanced. Similarly, although by turning to the evidence. empowering civic groups may often lead to good outcomes, doing so is not always superior to a pure market-based strategy for raising incomes or to a strategy that strengthens the role of central bureaucrats to, say, improve social services. Keeping this in mind, the decision about whether, when, and how to promote local participation should be made with an understanding of the tradeoffs involved in moving decisions to local communities—in a particular country, within a particular region in a country, and at a particular time. Theorizing and thinking through the conceptual foundations of these questions can yield important insights, but several open questions are best answered by examining the evidence. When does participation work, and when does it fail to achieve specific objectives? How impor- tant is capture? Does handing over large sums of money to community groups empower the poor, or do elites use it to enrich themselves? What mechanisms are most effective in improving the capacity for collective action and building social capital? What methods reduce civic inequal- ity and elite capture and truly empower the poor? Do participatory projects result in choices that are better aligned with people’s prefer- ences? Does fostering participation enhance social cohesion? Does it strengthen civil society? Does it produce more resilient and inclusive local institutions? To what extent does group heterogeneity and illit- eracy affect the quality of participation? Does participation improve development outcomes at the local level? Does it help the sustainable management of local resources? Chapters 4–6 provide a broad and com- prehensive review of the evidence on these and many related questions. For the reasons outlined in chapter 1, the focus of the review of the evidence is on large-scale participatory projects that have been 116
  • 137. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION evaluated based on representative samples of target populations with good counterfactuals—studies that have a valid control group for the communities targeted (or “treated”) by the intervention. Generally speaking, this means that the findings come from econometric analysis, although some well-designed qualitative research is examined to inform the results. Notes 1. Needs can be unlimited, however. Normative theories of fiscal federal- ism and decentralization consequently pay equal attention to the budget constraints associated with financing expenditure and the tax assignments of federal and local jurisdictions. Although these fundamental issues on the supply side of decentralization are not the focus of this report, they are important to keep in mind. 2. The World Bank and the U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID) have been leading champions of this new emphasis on fighting corruption. See the World Development Report 2004 (World Bank 2004) on the effect of corruption on service delivery 3. Tanzi and Davoodi (1997) show that corruption can reduce public revenue and increase income inequality by allowing well-positioned individuals to benefit unduly from government programs intended for the poor. 4. Myerson (1993) and Persson, Roland, and Tabellini (1997) provide the- retical arguments for the relationship between political institutions and corruption. Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006) provide a good overview of the conceptual literature on the relationship between decentralization and corruption and review much of the empirical evidence. 5. Bernard and others (2008) find evidence on the proliferation of community organizations in Burkina Faso and Senegal that appears to be consistent with this hypothesis. They report a dramatic growth in both market- and community-oriented village organizations over the two-decade period between the early 1980s, when participatory approaches first became popu- lar popularity, to about 2002. In Burkina Faso, where 22 percent of sample villages had village organizations in 1982, 91 percent had at least one vil- lage organization by 2002; in Senegal, where 10 percent of sample villages had at least one village organization in 1982, the figure rose to 65 percent. Household participation in village organizations also rose dramatically, with 57 percent of households in Burkina Faso and 69 percent in Senegal participating in at least one village organization. However, one-fifth of all registered organizations had not undertaken any activity by the time of the survey, and among those that had, most members reported that the proj- ects undertaken were either incomplete or had not yielded any significant benefits. 117
  • 138. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? References Acemoglu, D., and J. A. Robinson. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Appadurai, A. 2004. “The Capacity to Aspire: Culture and the Terms of Recognition.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton, 59–84. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2006. Decentralization and Governance in Developing Countries. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Basu, K. 2011. Beyond the Invisible Hand: Groundwork for a New Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Bernard, T., M.-H. Collion, A. De Janvry, P. Rondot, and E. Sadoulet. 2008. “Do Village Organizations Make a Difference in African Rural Development? A Study for Senegal and Burkina Faso.” World Development 36(11): 2188–204. Cai, H., and D. Treisman. 2004. “State Corroding Federalism.” Journal of Public Economics 88(3–4): 819–43. Comaroff, J., and J. Comaroff. 1999. Civil Society and Political Imagination in Africa. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Cooke, B., and U. Kothari. 2001. Participation: The New Tyranny? London: Zed Books. Elster, J. 1989. Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Evans, P. 2004. “Development as Institutional Change: The Pitfalls of Monocropping and the Potentials of Deliberation.” Studies in Comparative International Development 38(4): 30–52. Fung, A., and E. O. Wright. 2003. “Thinking about Empowered Participatory Governance.” In Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance, ed. A. Fung and E. O. Wright, 3–42. New York: Verso. Gibson, C., and M. Woolcock. 2008. “Empowerment, Deliberative Development and Local Level Politics in Indonesia: Participatory Projects as a Source of Countervailing Power.” Studies in Comparative International Development 2(43): 151–80. Harriss, J. 2001. Depoliticizing Development: The World Bank and Social Capital. New Delhi: LeftWord. Henkel, H., and R. Stirrat. 2001. “Participation as Spiritual Duty; Empowerment as Secular Subjection.” In Participation: The New Tyranny? ed. B. Cooke and U. Kothari, 168–84. London: Zed Books. Hirschman, A. O. 1970. Exit Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Hoff, K., and J. E. Stiglitz. 2001. “Modern Economic Theory and Development.” In Frontiers of Development Economics, ed. G. Meier and J. Stiglitz, 389–459. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Khan, M. H. 2002. “Corruption and Governance in Early Capitalism: World Bank Strategies and Their Limitations.” In Reinventing the World Bank, 118
  • 139. THE CHALLENGE OF INDUCING PARTICIPATION ed. J. Pincus and J. Winters, 164–84. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Koopmans, R. 2007. “Protest in Time and Space: The Evolution of Waves of Contention.” In The Blackwell Companion to Social Movements, ed. D. A. Snow, S. A. Soule, and H. Kriesi, 19–46. New York: Blackwell. Kriesi, H. 2007. “Political Context and Opportunity.” In The Blackwell Companion to Social Movements, ed. D. A. Snow, S. A. Soule, and H. Kriesi, 67–90. New York: Blackwell. Levy, B., and F. Fukuyama. 2010. Development Strategies: Integrating Governance and Growth. Washington, DC: World Bank. Menes, R. 2003. “Corruption in Cities: Graft and Politics in American Cities at the Turn of the Twentieth Century.” NBER Working Paper 9990, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Migdal, J. S. 1988. Strong Societies and Weak States: State-Society Relations and State Capabilities in the Third World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Mosse, D. 2005. Cultivating Development: An Ethnography of Aid Policy and Practice. London: Pluto Press. Myerson, R. B. 1993. “Effectiveness of Electoral Systems for Reducing Government Corruption: A Game-Theoretic Analysis.” Games and Economic Behavior 5(1): 118–32. Oates, W. 1972. Fiscal Federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Persson, T., G. Roland, and G. Tabellini. 1997. “Separation of Powers and Political Accountability.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): 1163–202. Rao, V., and P. Sanyal. 2010. “Dignity through Discourse: Poverty and the Culture of Deliberation in Indian Village Democracies.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 629(May): 146–72. Rondinelli, D. A., J. S. Mccullough, and R. W. Johnson. 1989. “Analyzing Decentralization Policies in Developing-Countries: A Political-Economy Framework.” Development and Change 20(1): 57–87. Rose-Ackerman, S. 2008. “Corruption and Government.” International Peacekeeping 15(3): 328–43. Scott, J. 1990. Domination and the Art of Resistance: Hidden Transcripts. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Tanzi, V., and H. Davoodi. 1997. “Corruption, Public Investment, and Growth.” IMF Working Paper 97/139, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Warren, M. E. 1995. “The Self in Discursive Democracy.” In The Cambridge Companion to Habermas, ed. S. K. White, 167–200. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Woolcock, M. 2009. “Towards a Plurality of Methods in Project Evaluation: A Contextualized Approach to Understanding Impact Trajectories and Efficacy.” Journal of Development Effectiveness 1(1): 1–14. World Bank. 2004. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People. Washington, DC: World Bank. 119
  • 141. CHAPTER FOUR How Important Is Capture? A KEY ASSUMPTION UNDERLYING SUPPORT FOR PARTICIPATORY programs and local decentralization is that they increase the involve- ment of the poor and the marginalized in local decision making, thereby enhancing “voice” and reducing capture and corruption. How empirically grounded are these assumptions? This chapter attempts to answer this question. It first examines whether the real worry should be corruption narrowly defined or more routine and legal forms of rent-seeking, including clientelism. It then reviews the evidence for elite capture in participatory programs and discusses potential implications for the inclusion and empowerment objectives of such programs. The next two sections look at the impact of democratic decentralization on the behavior of local political agents. The last section summarizes the broad lessons that emerge from the evidence. Theorists have written a good deal on local accountability in the context of political decentralization; the body of empirical literature is also large. This chapter does not attempt to do justice to either body of research. Instead, it uses the literature somewhat selectively to frame the questions that are most relevant to understanding the “demand side” of local governance and to highlight the empirical studies that have informed this debate. Attention is confined, for the most part, to empirical studies of developing countries. 121
  • 142. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Corruption and Local Accountability Corruption adds substantially Corruption—defined narrowly as theft, graft, and bribes—has come to the cost of providing basic to be viewed as a major threat to development.1 It adds substantially public goods and services . . . to the cost of providing basic public goods and services; dampens the redistributive objectives of poverty-reduction programs; and, perhaps worst of all, changes the incentives both citizens and public officials face. Reducing corruption through legal and financial reforms is rarely . . . it can also change an option. Instead, most international donor organizations, notably the incentives citizens and the World Bank and the U.S. Agency for International Development public officials face. (USAID), have come to see decentralization and civic engagement as an alternative route to increasing accountability in both the public and private sphere. Civic engagement is often The view that decentralization is needed to combat corruption is seen as key to reducing not unchallenged. Some observers argue that decentralization could corruption. increase opportunities for theft, bribes, and graft.2 There is also a con- cern that devolution could simply shift the form of rent-seeking from outright theft and graft to other, more pernicious and ostensibly legal, avenues of resource capture. In the extreme, both equity and efficiency could decline as a result, even as measured levels of corruption fall. Too sharp a focus on corruption defined narrowly can divert attention from the true welfare cost of rent-seeking under decentralized resource alloca- tion, particularly where there are significant opportunities for capture by local elites. Bardhan (2002) and Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006a) advocate a broader view that includes all types of political corruption, in addition to theft, bribes, and graft.3 The literature on corruption is reviewed here with these concerns in mind. Only a few studies examine the relationship between decentralized resource allocation and the level of corruption. This literature includes a series of papers using cross-country data that by and large argue that corruption tends to be lower in countries that are more decentralized, but only when local governments face “hard budget constraints” (that is, rely less on fiscal transfers from the center and more on their own revenues).4 For example, Estache and Sinha (1995) report a positive association between expenditure decentralization and levels of infra- structure provided by local governments, but only when both revenue generation and expenditure responsibilities are decentralized. Fisman and Gatti (2002a, 2002b) find similar results. Using data from the United States for 1976–87, they report a positive correlation 122
  • 143. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? between a state’s dependence on fiscal transfers from the center and convictions for abuse of state public office (Fisman and Gatti 2002a). In a second study, based on cross-country data for 1980–95, they find a negative association between expenditure decentralization and per- ceived corruption (Fisman and Gatti 2002b). However, both studies are plagued with problems of potential reverse causality and unobserved heterogeneity across the units of analysis, making the results difficult to interpret. Using roughly the same sample of countries over the same time period as Fisman and Gatti (2002b), Treisman (2007) shows that the key result in their study is sensitive to the set of controls used. The negative association between expenditure decentralization and corrup- tion (using a range of measures of both) disappears once an additional control, the proportion of Protestants in the population, is added. Apparently, countries with more Protestants tend to be both less corrupt and more decentralized.5 The metric of corruption used in these studies is also problematic. The use of perception data For the most part, country-level corruption measures are either aggre- to measure corruption gated from corruption perception surveys or derived from country-risk may be more warranted in analyses. Most studies that compare perception data with data on the low-corruption than high- actual incidence of corruption find that perception data correlate poorly corruption settings. with the actual incidence of corruption, however defined.6 They also find that perceptions may be sensitive to the absolute level of corrup- tion, as measured by the number of occurrences, rather than just relative corruption levels. Thus, perceptions of corruption tend to be greater in larger countries. The relationship between perceptions of corruption and absolute and relative corruption levels weakens as levels of corrup- tion rise. The use of perception data may therefore be more warranted in low-corruption than high-corruption settings. More recent cross-country studies attempt to overcome some of these Decentralization can increase problems by using a more objective metric of corruption. Fan, Lin, and opportunities for corruption. Treisman (2009) examine how political decentralization affects the odds of bribe extraction by corrupt officials. They attempt to rectify the problems with perception data by combining a cross-country data set on decentralization with a firm-level survey conducted in 80 countries that provides information on the experiences of firms with graft and bribes. Their results suggest that decentralization can increase opportunities for corruption when the number of tiers of public employees increases, par- ticularly when governments are also strapped for funds and public sector 123
  • 144. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? employees are poorly paid and have few resources. Overall, their results suggest that as the complexity of governance structures and the number of tiers increases, as it does under decentralization, there is a danger of more uncoordinated rent-seeking and higher net levels of corruption.7 By and large, however, attention has moved to within-country analy- ses that use more carefully constructed data and objective measures of corruption. This newer body of literature also attempts to identify causal effects by focusing on specific policy shifts, such as audits, increased monitoring, a change in access to information, or variation in the political incentives of incumbents, which allow for a clearer analysis of the relationship between decentralized resource allocation and corruption.8 This literature has produced some important insights. Studies con- fi rm substantial levels of graft and theft in decentralized programs (although few compare levels of corruption with and without decen- tralization). They also highlight the potential risks of incomplete and differential access to information. In particular, they find that opportu- nities for corruption are greater when some individuals or communities are less well placed to benefit from information. This literature also underscores the manifold constraints that communities—particularly those which are poorer, more remote, and more unequal—face in moni- toring and sanctioning corrupt officials or service providers. Corruption tends to be higher Overall, the evidence suggests that corruption tends to be higher in in remote communities that remote communities that have low education levels and low exposure have low education levels and to media—qualities that tend to be positively correlated with poverty low exposure to media . . . and inequality—and that within such communities, the costs of cor- ruption are higher for the poor. Perhaps more surprisingly, interventions from the center appear to constrain corrupt local practices—particu- . . . and within such larly when they augment citizen “voice” at the local level by increasing communities, the costs information on resource flows through well-publicized audits or media of corruption are higher campaigns. On balance, therefore, there appears to be little reason to be for the poor. sanguine about community-based monitoring or information provision in the absence of a strong reform-minded center, an active and indepen- dent media, and highly able communities. The center can constrain Reinikka and Svensson (2004, 2005, 2007) examine the extent of corrupt local practices by corruption in the allocation of public resources for education in Uganda augmenting citizen “voice” during the 1990s. They study a large government program that pro- through advertised audits and vided grants to primary schools to cover their nonwage expenditures. media campaigns. The program was managed by the central government but used district 124
  • 145. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? offices as distribution channels. Their measure of corruption is the difference between disbursed flows from the central government to lower tiers of government and the resources actually received by final beneficiaries. The data come from a public expenditure tracking survey. Reinikka and Svensson (2004) show that primary schools in Uganda Local officials and politicians received only 13 percent of the grants allocated to them for nonwage captured 87 percent of the expenditures; local officials and politicians captured the rest. The allo- grants allocated to primary cation of the amounts that did reach schools was also quite regressive. schools in Uganda for Schools in the poorest communities fared worst, obtaining significantly nonwage expenditures. smaller shares of their entitlements.9 A benefit incidence analysis of the program, conducted in 1996 by the World Bank, found that the poorest quintile received about as much as the richest quintile. This finding highlights the difficulty of using benefit incidence analysis to understand the distributional impact of public spending when allocated expenditure rather than actual spending is used. It also highlights the potential for local capture to completely undo and even reverse the redistributive goals of poverty reduction programs. Reinikka and Svensson (2007) examine the extent to which infor- mation on the flow of funds can restrain corruption. In response to the enormous leakage of funds found in the first public expenditure tracking survey, the central government initiated a campaign in which national newspapers, including their local language editions, began pub- lishing the monthly transfer of capitation grants to districts. Reinikka and Svensson show that schools that were closer to newspaper outlets managed to claim a significantly larger part of their entitlement after the newspaper campaign was initiated and that head teachers in such schools were also more knowledgeable of the rules governing the grant program as well as the timing of fund release by the central government. They also find significant increases in enrollment and student learning outcomes following the information campaign (Reinikka and Svensson 2005), with much larger effects for schools located near newspaper outlets. Bjorkman (2006) confirms these results. Using district-level data, she finds that districts that were more exposed to the newspaper cam- paign obtained a larger share of their allocated budget and had substan- tially greater increases in student test scores. Francken, Minten, and Swinnen (2009) use a measure of corrup- tion similar to the one Reinikka and Svensson (2005) use to examine the impact of media on the local capture of public education funds in 125
  • 146. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Madagascar. They find very little evidence of capture in resource flows from the center, where the education bureaucracy was closely moni- tored, to the district. In contrast, they observe significant levels of cap- ture at the district level, with capture increasing with distance from the center. These results point to the importance of central monitoring for accountability at the local level. The study also finds a strong negative effect of media access on corruption, with substantially larger negative effects in more educated communities, which were presumably better able to use information on budgets to monitor providers. In line with earlier findings on capture, the authors note that the misappropriation of funds was greater in districts in which the program director was a member of the local elite or had a lower level of education. Relative to the better-off, the Shankar, Gaiha, and Jha (2010) highlight the risk of differential poor had less and worse- information access in their study of India’s National Rural Employment quality information on India’s Guarantee Scheme (NREGS). This targeted workfare program was National Rural Employment launched with a nationwide effort to disseminate information through Guarantee Scheme and were the media and through village-level meetings organized by the local less likely to participate in it. government. The program has been plagued with problems of resource misappropriation, including the fudging of muster rolls, the manipula- tion of wages, and outright bribe-taking by local officials. Survey data reveal that the nonpoor had more and better-quality information on the program and were also more likely to participate. Better-informed par- ticipants were also more likely to obtain the full benefits of the program in terms of wages, the timing of payment, and hours worked. Poorer participants were more likely to report having paid bribes. This finding is particularly important given concerns about the level of corruption in this program.10 An intensive top-down Few studies assess the relative effectiveness of bottom-up and audit reduced corruption top-down anticorruption interventions. The best study is by Olken as measured by missing (2007), who reports the results of a field experiment conducted in vil- expenditures . . . lages supported by the Kecamatan Development Program (KDP) in Indonesia, which builds local infrastructure using a community-driven development approach. The experiment assessed the relative effective- . . . but it appears to have ness of community-based versus external monitoring of KDP road increased nepotism. construction projects by inducing random variation in the mechanism by which corruption could be detected. A subset of study villages was assigned to the bottom-up intervention, in which citizens were encour- aged to participate in village-level meetings at which project officials documented their expenses in relation to the use of public funds for the 126
  • 147. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? construction of local roads; a second subset was assigned to the top- down intervention, in which villages were informed that road construc- tion expenses would be closely monitored by local officials. The odds of an audit in this group were 100 percent. In the control villages, the usual process of government audit was expected; the odds of an audit were about 4 percent. The study finds that intensive top-down audits reduced missing expenditures on materials and wages by about 8 per- centage points. In contrast, grassroots monitoring reduced only missing wage expenditures. Given the larger budget share of nonwage expen- ditures, the overall impact of community monitoring was negligible. These results suggest that community monitoring may be con- strained, for several reasons. There may be freeriding, in the sense that community members may be unwilling to monitor providers when benefits are largely nonexcludable (as they are for roads), or they may be unable to detect corruption when the activity entails technical inputs. Although the study cannot separate out these channels, the fact that villagers were able to detect missing wage payments but appear to have had a harder time knowing how much of any construction input was actually used in the road suggests that capacity constraints are likely to be at least part of the story. Although the intensive top-down audit reduced corruption as mea- sured by missing expenditures, it appears to have increased nepotism. Relatives of members of the implementation committee, including the village leader, were significantly more likely to be hired, suggesting the need for a broader view inclusive of all types of political corruption, in line with Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006a). The level of resource capture that should be considered problematic is somewhat fuzzy. The pursuit of a policy designed primarily to minimize corruption may make little sense if there are other, possibly conflicting, policy goals (see Mookherjee 1997; Waller, Verdier, and Gardner 2002). The key issue, therefore, may not be whether decentralization elimi- nates capture but rather how large the implied efficiency and equity losses are and the extent to which they attenuate the poverty reduction agendas of development projects. Olken’s (2006) study of losses in Indonesia’s subsidized rice program (Operasi Pasar Khusus [OPK]) is instructive in this regard. The pro- gram allowed eligible households to purchase up to 20 kilograms of rice a month. Roughly half of rural households were eligible to participate, and the implied subsidy was significant.11 About 18 percent of the rice 127
  • 148. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? went missing, and ineligible households purchased a large amount of OPK rice. Much of the corruption was concentrated in a small fraction of villages, most of which were located in the most corrupt districts.12 One-half to two-thirds of total program benefits were lost to corruption and mistargeting, making the project welfare reducing in net terms. What is perhaps most interesting is that losses from mistargeting far A narrow focus on corruption outweighed losses from outright corruption. may miss the larger These results highlight the point that a focus on corruption defined problems of resource capture narrowly as outright theft, bribes, or graft may miss the larger problems through rent-seeking and of resource capture through other, often legal, forms of rent-seeking resource losses caused by or resource losses caused by the poor implementation and monitoring poor implementation and capacity of project staff or community members. This issue is examined monitoring capacity. in the sections that follow. Participation and Resource Allocation in Induced Community-Driven Development Programs A small number of studies have looked carefully at who participates in organizations formed by community-driven development projects. Overall, the evidence suggests that participants tend to be dispropor- tionately from wealthier, more educated, and more politically connected households. They also tend to belong to ethnic or tribal groups that enjoy higher status. In Bolivia and Burkina Faso, wealthier households were not only more likely to be active in local associations; they also had more memberships per household. In Indonesia, poorer and less edu- cated households tended to participate less; the wealthiest also spent less time and money on community organizations, suggesting an inverted U-shape in participation (Grootaert, Oh, and Swamy 2002).13 Participants in community Burkina Faso and Senegal reveal a similar pattern of exclusion organizations tend to be (Arcand and Fafchamps 2012). Arcand and Fafchamps find little evi- disproportionately from dence that community organizations created by donor-sponsored proj- wealthier, more educated, and ects are more inclusive than other community groups. On the contrary, more politically connected they find that members of externally funded community organizations households. were more likely to be older and to have more land wealth. Elite dominance is also evident in Indonesia’s Second Urban Poverty Project (UPP2), which provided one-time allocations to support implementation of community development plans through access to credit, mobilization of community members, and financing of small 128
  • 149. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? infrastructure. Pradhan, Rao, and Rosenberg (2009) find that groups managing fund allocation decisions were more likely to have members who were educated, affluent, politically connected, and male; while members of groups implementing funded projects, were more likely to be less affluent, less educated, and female. In rural Pakistan, villagers who belong to community organizations Participation by poor supported by the Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund (PPAF) are far and low-caste residents more likely to own land than villagers who do not belong (Mansuri is lower in more unequal 2012b). They are also significantly more likely to have some schooling communities . . . and to belong to households that are connected to traditional village leaders and local politicians. On average, community organization members have twice as much land as nonmembers and almost one additional year of schooling. However, village characteristics matter. In . . . and higher in communities villages with a larger fraction of household heads with some schooling, with above-average levels of landlessness is less of a barrier to community organization membership. education. Conversely, in more unequal villages, lower-caste households are less likely to belong to a community organization, although this discour- agement effect is dampened as the proportion of low-caste households in the village rises.14 One explanation for elite dominance in participatory bodies may be The mere fact that that members of a society who are well endowed, whether in wealth or participants at the community ability, may be the only ones who possess the requisite resources, capa- level are from the elite may bilities, and leisure to represent their community’s interests. Educated not be sufficient evidence community members may also be best placed to articulate community of capture. demands with external actors and facilitate the application procedures projects require. Better-educated people may also be more altruistic as leaders and thus less likely to engage in resource misappropriation of all types. On the other hand, the most disadvantaged may be least able to spare the time or resources needed for participatory decision making. They may also be least equipped to deal with its technical demands. In sum, the mere fact that participants at the community level are from the elite may not be sufficient evidence of capture: by virtue of their education, exposure, networks, and greater leisure time, members of the elite may have both the ability and the willingness to effectively represent the community. These findings raise several important questions. Does the identity of participants in community-based organizations affect the allocation of resources for intended beneficiaries? Can participatory programs serve their empowerment and inclusion objectives if participation itself 129
  • 150. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? is not democratized? These questions are particularly important if not all spending on public goods and services benefits the poor equally. Investments in primary schooling, basic health facilities, and safe drink- ing water are likely to yield larger benefits for poorer households than investments in higher education and hospitals. Investments in public irrigation systems may be even more exclusionary, because only people who own land may be well placed to benefit from higher productivity and higher land values. In Jamaica, better-educated The first set of studies examined looks at the extent to which com- and better-networked people munity level projects funded by social funds or community-driven were more likely to obtain development programs are well aligned with the stated priorities of the projects that matched their poor or other disadvantaged groups, including women. Rao and Ibanez preferences. (2005) look at this issue using retrospective data from survey respon- dents in communities funded by the Jamaica Social Investment Fund. They find that the match between the projects funded and the prefer- ences of community members was poor overall. In only two of the five communities studied did the project match the preferences of a majority in the community. Overall, better-educated and better-networked peo- ple were more likely to obtain projects that matched their preferences. Some 80 percent of respondents nevertheless reported satisfaction with the project. The authors argue that this high level of satisfaction may reflect “benevolent” capture, in which the elite are best informed about true community needs, feasible projects, or both and act altruistically to obtain benefits for their communities. Dasgupta and Beard (2007) find similar results in their study of the performance of community development boards in Indonesia’s Urban Poverty Project (UPP). Communities were selected for this case study in part because they had high levels of social cohesion, as measured by the authors. The authors find that community development boards that were dominated by elite groups delivered more benefits to the poor, who fared much worse under apparently more egalitarian community devel- opment boards. Based on their findings, they argue that elite control over local decision making must be distinguished from elite capture. Other researchers argue that even when it induces no change in selected projects, the deliberative process creates a sense of satisfaction and legitimacy, because people like to be consulted, even when the consultative process does not yield a change in resource allocation.15 Olken (2007) examines whether observed project choice in Indonesia reflects, in part, the underlying participatory mechanism adopted by 130
  • 151. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? the KDP program. To test this hypothesis, he randomized the final project selection method across villages. In one group, projects were selected publicly, at a village meeting; in the other, they were chosen by secret ballot. The list of proposed projects was subject to an earlier process of selection about which little is known, except that village elites were in attendance during their selection. The study finds no impact of the political mechanism on project choice, despite high turnout in the election and sparse attendance at the village meeting, which attracted mainly the village and supra-village elite. However, the election mechanism increased satisfaction with the pro- The deliberative process may posed project, even though there was no change in the project selected. create a sense of satisfaction Olken argues that this finding may indicate a preference for greater and legitimacy, even when it participation; specifically more equitable participation may have a nor- does not yield a change in mative aspect, creating greater satisfaction as well as greater “buy-in” for resource allocation. the policies and choices adopted regardless of the impact on substantive outcomes. A potential problem with this interpretation is that given the balloting process, village residents would also have needed more infor- mation ex ante on the set of projects proposed in order to vote on them. The study cannot separately identify the potential impact of information and voting on satisfaction. What it does indicate is that a considerable level of exclusion is possible in the type of deliberative process that community-driven development projects typically employ. In this case, village and supra-village elites dominated the initial process of selecting the menu of projects on which the rest of the community could vote. These limitations notwithstanding, this set of studies suggests that evidence of elite influence need not indicate malevolent intent. For one thing, the preferences of nonelite groups could change as a result of community deliberation over the use of funds, particularly if they are initially less informed about the feasibility or potential benefits of spe- cific projects. If this is the case, what appears to be capture could well reflect a more altruistic or benevolent process, with local elites taking the lead in advocating for public goods that the community most needs and acting as intermediaries between the implementing agency and the beneficiary community. Some observers argue that this is indeed what often happens. The projects finally selected are often the projects that best serve the needs of the most disadvantaged in the community, even though they were not initially proposed by them. White (2002) notes, for example, that the disproportionate number of schools and health facilities funded by social funds reflects the preferences of the “prime 131
  • 152. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? movers” behind these projects, who are often school teachers or health workers. Community facilitators’ Platteau and Gaspart (2003), among others, take a very different preferences may heavily position. They argue that any assessment that elicits community prefer- influence the deliberation ences ex post may not reveal much about the extent of elite capture or process. corruption in the use of funds, because poor villagers may be unable or unwilling to express reservations about the funded project, or the role of the elite, for fear of repercussions or loss of resources. They suggest that community facilitators often play an influential role in the process of project selection, that facilitator preferences are likely to heavily influence the deliberation process, and that it is these preferences, as much as the preferences of prime movers within the community, that are reflected in project proposals (see also Murphy 1990; Mohan and Stokke 2000). Separating these issues is difficult in practice. Doing so requires data on the projects specific groups or individuals prefer before and after any deliberative process; the facilitation and deliberation process within communities; the preferences of facilitators; the location of projects, proposed and selected; and the identity of beneficiaries. In practice, the data collected on preferences, process, project location, and beneficiaries tend to be fairly coarse. Most studies ask questions about the top three needs of the community or its main problems, without reference to a budget; the expected cost share for beneficiaries; or, most critically, proj- ect location. Survey respondents may thus state that upgrading roads or drinking water sources in the community is a priority, but it is unclear which road or drinking water source they wish to upgrade. It is rarely the case, however, that a “community” inhabits an area small and cohe- sive enough to allow everyone to benefit equally from all infrastructure investments. In most cases, roads, drinking water schemes, and irriga- tion channels are provided to specific neighborhoods or habitations, and location determines who benefits. Data on the nature of the facilitation process or its role in modifying or shaping preferences are even rarer. In line with the concerns of critics like Platteau and Gaspart (2003), recent experimental work by Humphreys, Masters, and Sandbu (2006) finds that facilitator preferences significantly predict the choices of par- ticipants in consultative meetings. They use data from a national forum held in São Tomé and Príncipe to discuss policy issues related to the use of newly discovered oil reserves. About 5 percent of the adult population attended small group meetings, whose leaders were randomly assigned. 132
  • 153. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? Groups led by women were more likely than groups led by men to pri- oritize investments in local health clinics over hospitals. Unlike groups led by men, they also preferred investments in improving transportation services rather than investments in improving roads and expanding road networks. They were also more likely to accept higher taxation of windfall earnings and to opt for saving rather than spending windfalls. Furthermore, groups led by older adults were more likely than groups led by younger people to emphasize health as a national priority and to favor commercial transport over passenger transport and better roads over public transportation services. Meetings led by women and older people also reached much higher levels of consensus than meetings led by men and younger people. The only published study that has collected ex ante preference data One study finds substantial for public good projects is Labonne and Chase (2009). They find sub- evidence of capture by stantial evidence of capture by local leaders at the project proposal stage local leaders at the project but only in more unequal villages with a less politically active popula- proposal stage . . . tion. Local leaders in such villages, they find, exercise greater influence over resource allocation at meetings at the supra-village level, where proposed projects are approved. Gugerty and Kremer (2008) take a different approach. They look . . . but only in more unequal at the impact of a participatory agricultural project in rural Kenya on villages with a less politically group membership and agricultural productivity. The project provided active population. leadership training and agricultural inputs to small self-help organiza- tions, most of whose members were poor women with little education. The project spent $674 per group, or an average of $34 per member, half of which was allocated to agricultural inputs, which were provided to the group as a whole. As the typical comparison group had $243 in assets before the project started, this spending represented a large increase in the group’s capital stock.16 The study finds that the groups selected for the intervention were far more likely to attract new members and that new members were also likely to be more educated, to have formal sector income, and to take over group leadership positions.17 Moreover, although exit rates were similar in program and comparison groups, more members left the program groups because of intragroup conflicts. Older female members, who were among the most vulnerable, were also disproportionately more likely to leave. In sum, the program appears to have unleashed a process in which group membership and leadership moved into the hands of younger and better-educated women. It also induced the entry of more men and 133
  • 154. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? A rapid increase in resources more efforts on the part of government officials to build links to the may serve only to increase groups. However, despite the large injection of funds, the project yielded exclusion. unimpressive gains in agricultural productivity. The authors conjecture that a rapid increase in resources may serve only to increase exclusion. In a somewhat similar vein, Mansuri (2012a) compares the distribu- tion of beneficiaries of village level infrastructure projects built by a participatory program and projects built by government line depart- ments in the same villages and at comparable size and cost (see chapter 5 for a fuller discussion of this study). She finds that benefits from the participatory project were no better distributed than benefits from the relevant government project and that the share of the landless, the poor, and people from low castes was far below their population share in both cases. Moreover, investment in the most excludable schemes—irriga- tion channels—tended to be the least pro-poor. Beneficiaries were also far more likely to be members of a community organization, and as discussed above, members of community organizations were far more likely to be drawn from people with land wealth, education, or political networks. Local inequality may reduce Another way to assess whether capture is benevolent is to determine the odds that a community whether community characteristics affect the allocation of resources. selects a pro-poor project. Araujo and others (2008) assess the relationship between community inequality and the odds of selecting a more pro-poor excludable project in Ecuador’s social fund. They find that local inequality significantly reduced the odds that a community selected a pro-poor project. They also find that the impact of inequality on project choice was amplified in communities that had a larger share of indigenous households, sug- gesting that ethno-linguistic heterogeneity can exacerbate capture by local elites.18 Community inequality can also reduce access to private transfers. Community inequality can Galasso and Ravallion (2005) find that greater land inequality signifi- reduce access to private cantly worsened targeting in the program in Bangladesh that they stud- transfers. ied. They also find that targeting was less effective in remote and isolated villages. Bardhan, Mookherjee and Torrado (2010) find that villages with greater land inequality allocate a significantly smaller share of private benefits to scheduled castes and tribes. Shankar, Gaiha, and Jha (2010) find that poor and low-caste households are considerably less likely to participate in the National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (NREGS) program in Indian villages with greater wealth inequality. 134
  • 155. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? Conning and Kevane (2002) identify some of these patterns in a review of community-based targeting that focuses on the tradeoff between bet- ter information and local capture. They conclude that communities are more effective than outside agencies in targeting programs to the poor only when they are relatively egalitarian, have open and transparent sys- tems of decision making, and establish clear rules for determining who is poor. Communities with a low capacity to mobilize information and monitor disbursements are more vulnerable to corruption and capture by elites, as are more heterogeneous communities, where multiple and conflicting identities can create competing incentives. In sum, context matters a great deal in the degree to which partici- patory programs achieve their inclusion objectives, as do the specifics of program design and implementation. Overall, however, poorer, less educated, and more marginalized groups tend to participate less, as do women of all socioeconomic backgrounds. Higher average literacy levels are almost uniformly beneficial for pro-poor participation, and wealth inequality and remoteness of location tend to reduce participation by the poor. Participation also affects the allocation of resources. A reasonable amount of evidence shows that elite domination of the participatory Elite domination of the process is not without consequence and should not be routinely viewed participatory process is not as benign. What does appear to be the case, however, is that a well- without consequence and articulated deliberative process may build legitimacy for the resource should not be routinely viewed allocation decisions made by the elite even when they are not apparently as benign. well aligned with the initial preferences of the poor. The evidence here is thin, however; much more is needed in order to draw any sensible conclusion. There is also some evidence that an increase in external funding can displace the most vulnerable people by inducing greater participation by the more educated, wealthy, and young. This finding is consistent with the case several critics make that short-duration donor-funded projects can create conditions under which program implementers have strong incentives to rapidly mobilize communities in order to disburse project funds. As doing so is easier in relatively developed and acces- sible localities, programs tend to focus on them and on the relatively well placed and influential within them. This finding resonates with the worry that co-financing requirements and competition for access to project funds—common features in many participatory projects—can 135
  • 156. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? encourage disproportionate participation by people in a position to con- tribute or with a greater capacity to propose viable projects (see the dis- cussion in chapter 5). Program design may therefore matter a good deal. Participation and Resource Allocation under Decentralization Democratic decentralization A significant body of theoretical literature suggests that political elites may limit outright capture . . . may be just as likely as traditional elite groups to engage in rent-seeking behavior, including the use of public resources to woo particular con- stituencies in order to gain electoral advantage (see, for example, Cox and McCubbins 1986; Persson and Tabellini 2000). It is important in this context to understand the distinction between outright corrup- . . . but insofar as it increases tion and clientelism. Democratic decentralization may limit outright opportunities for clientelism, capture, but insofar as it increases opportunities for clientelism, the the consequences consequences for development can be equally negative, as discussed in for development can be chapter 3. Clientelism can lead to the unequal treatment of the equally equally negative. deserving, exacerbating inequality and causing resources to be used inefficiently as a result of the prioritization of short-term political gains. How important clientelism and capture are is, of course, an empiri- cal question. One way to assess their importance is to check whether electoral results predict future resource allocations or past allocations predict future electoral results. Several studies confirm such patterns. Following the 1994 elections in Brazil, federal deputies allocated more resources for local public goods to municipalities in which they had received the greatest number of votes. Looking at the allocation of public works from 1996 to 1999, Finan (2004) finds that a 10 percent increase in vote shares for a candidate in the previous election, implied an expected increase of R$75,174 in public works for a municipality during the electoral cycle. Miguel and Zaidi (2003) find that adminis- trative districts in Ghana in which the ruling party won all parliamen- tary seats in the 1996 election received 27 percent more school funding in 1998–99. Bratton and van de Walle (1997) cite several cases in Africa where state resources were used to reward faithful supporters. They note that by “electively distributing favors and material benefits to loyal fol- lowers who are not citizens of the polity so much as the ruler’s clients,” rulers often ensure the political stability of their regime and personal political survival. 136
  • 157. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? De Janvry, Nakagawa, and Sadoulet (2009) test this hypothesis using electoral data from Zambia. They match local election results in 1998, 2001, and 2006 with ward-level data on resource allocation under three social fund programs (CRP I, CRP II, and ZAMSIF). They examine whether the percentage of votes received by the majority party’s candidate for the district council influenced the allocation of project resources in the ward and whether past allocations to a ward affected the political fortunes of incumbents. On the first question, they find that in highly decentralized districts, a 10 percent increase in the major- ity party’s share of the vote was associated with a 32 percent increase in per capita resources in the ward. Interestingly, the increase occurred only in wards with high literacy rates. They also find that incumbents were rewarded for higher per capita budgets: a doubling of the allocated per capita budget in the three years preceding an election increased an incumbent’s odds of reelection by 4–5 percent. This effect is large, given that only 24 percent of the wards in subject districts received a project and that 39 percent elected a councilor from the incumbent district majority. The authors find no evidence of a trade-off between pro-poor program targeting and the political use of public resources, however, as the poorest wards were both more likely to be funded and more likely to vote for the district majority party. Schady (2000) finds that expenditures on projects funded by the Expenditures on projects Peruvian social fund FONCODES increased significantly before funded by the Peruvian social national elections over the period 1991–95. Projects were also more fund increased significantly likely to be directed at poorer provinces, which returned smaller shares before national elections. of votes for the incumbent president in the previous election. He sug- gests that funding decisions were made on the basis of both political and poverty criteria. In Mexico, municipal-level expenditures by PROGR ESA– Oportunidades, a national conditional cash transfer program, increased the incumbent party’s share of the vote by about 4.3 percent (Rodriguez- Chamussy 2009). This effect was particularly strong when the Partido de la Revolución Democrática (PRD) was the incumbent party. Incumbent opposition party mayors also benefitted, however, presumably by suc- cessfully claiming some credit for benefits delivered to their constituents. Manacorda, Miguel, and Vigorito (2011) study a large government- initiated poverty reduction program in Uruguay. They find that pro- gram beneficiaries were 21–28 percent more likely to support the current government than nonbeneficiaries. 137
  • 158. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Camacho and Conover (2011) examine the targeting performance of a poverty score card issued by the Colombian government to determine eligibility for a wide range of programs, including unemployment ben- efits, housing improvement grants, food aid for the elderly, educational subsidies, and a publicly provided health insurance program. The cen- tral government designed the scoring system but allowed municipalities discretion over the administration and timing of the door-to-door inter- views. The authors find sharp discontinuities in the score, precisely at the eligibility threshold of 47. They find that in municipalities in which a relatively high proportion of families had identical interview answers, an overwhelming number with identical answers obtained scores below 47. Scores calculated using the disaggregated data largely agree with the assigned scores, suggesting that the manipulation occurred mainly through the recording of fake answers at the local level rather than an overwriting of the score at a later point. This evidence of local manipu- lation is strengthened by their finding that the sharp discontinuity in the score density emerged only after the score algorithm was released to municipal officials and households became aware that eligibility was based on the score. In fact, 91 percent of families with suspicious scores were interviewed after 1997, when the score algorithm became well known to municipal officials. The authors also find a larger discon- tinuity at the poverty threshold in more competitive elections, where additional votes were more valuable. In India, villagers who Several studies from India find a similar pattern. Using data from belonged to the political party four Indian states, Markussen (2006) finds that villagers who belong of the leader of the gram to the political party of the leader (pradhan) of the gram panchayat (vil- panchayat were more likely lage council) were 32 percent more likely to receive Below Poverty Line to receive Below Poverty Line (BPL) cards intended for the poor, regardless of their economic and (BPL) cards, regardless of social status. A more nuanced finding concerns the interplay between their economic and social land inequality and electoral accountability. Membership in the prad- status. han’s party increased the likelihood of receiving benefits only in gram panchayats in which land inequality was above a certain threshold. Besley, Pande, and Rao (2005, 2007) show that the households of pradhans and other gram panchayat leaders are significantly more likely to be assigned BPL cards. In their study, this tendency was substantially muted in villages with higher historical literacy rates. In these villages, the landless and illiterate were also more likely to attend gram sabha (village assembly) meetings. Gram sabhas are expected to be held at least once a year; several public programs rely on these meetings to generate 138
  • 159. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? beneficiary lists. The benefits of higher village literacy did not extend to women, however. Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006b) find that poverty, land inequality, Poverty, land inequality, and and the fraction of low-caste households substantially increases capture the fraction of low-caste in the allocation of resources by local governments for public goods. households substantially Local governments in West Bengal, India, selected projects that gener- increased capture in the ated less employment for the poor in villages in which a larger fraction allocation of resources by of the population was poor or low caste and land was more unequally local governments for public distributed. They find much less evidence of capture in the allocation of goods in West Bengal. private transfers—mainly credit and the supply of agricultural inputs— distributed by the government, although here, too, the share of the poor was smaller in more unequal villages and villages with larger shares of low-caste households. Research also points to the significance of legislative malapportion- ment on the allocation of resources at the local level and the perfor- mance of local governments under decentralization. Malapportionment occurs when there is a discrepancy between the share of legislative seats held by a geographical unit and its population share, so that some votes count more than others in legislative decision making at the center. Samuels and Snyder (2001) argue that some malapportionment may be necessary in the transition to democracy at the local level in order to appease antidemocratic elites, who demand that their privileges be protected. Malapportionment may therefore be more important in rural areas with entrenched local elites and significant wealth inequality or in areas with a history of ethnic or linguistic conflict. The authors find that the overrepresentation of rural districts and counties seems to be typical in emerging democracies. In Latin America, for example, malap- portionment tends to favor conservative rural districts at the expense of more urban or politically progressive districts. Ansolabehere, Gerber, and Snyder (2002) show that counties in the United States that were overrepresented relative to their populations received relatively more per capita transfers from the state before the court order mandating redistricting in the 1960s. Following redistrict- ing, these inequities were largely eliminated, as almost $7 billion a year moved from formerly overrepresented to formerly underrepresented counties. One implication of malapportionment is that central governments that rely on overrepresented, nondemocratic localities to secure national legislative majorities may also tend to tolerate subnational authoritarian 139
  • 160. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Central governments that enclaves and be unresponsive to efforts to reform local politics.19 rely on nondemocratic Emerging democracies will then tend to undergo a period in which localities to secure national democracy is simultaneously strengthened at the center and under- legislative majorities may mined at the local level. also tolerate subnational Several political theorists have noted a relationship between political authoritarian enclaves and and economic liberalization at the national level and the maintenance be unresponsive to efforts to of authoritarian regimes at the subnational level (see, for example, reform local politics. O’Donnell 1993; Fox 1994; Snyder 1999). There is very little empirical evidence from developing countries on whether legislative malappor- tionment protects authoritarian enclaves at the local level. Bolivia’s decentralization Faguet (2004) provides some evidence on how an effort to reduce process doubled the share of malapportionment in the resource allocation process can help improve national tax revenues devolved local accountability in a developing country. In Bolivia, the decen- to municipalities . . . tralization process not only doubled the share of national tax revenues devolved to municipalities, it also required that resources be allocated strictly on a per capita basis—which limited ad hoc and clientelistic resource assignment. At the same time, a redistricting effort created 198 new municipalities (64 percent of the total) and expanded exist- . . . and required that ing municipalities to include suburbs and surrounding rural areas. resources be allocated strictly Together, these changes led to a massive shift of resources in favor of on a per capita basis. smaller and poorer districts in which the largest beneficiaries were dis- tricts with the worst demographic indicators and the poorest infrastruc- ture endowment. Before decentralization, Bolivia’s three largest cities received 86 percent of all devolved funds; the remaining 14 percent was divided among 308 municipalities. After decentralization, these shares were reversed, with the three largest cities receiving just 27 percent of devolved funds. Using data on political, institutional, administrative, and governance indicators for all 311 Bolivian municipalities over the period 1987–96, Faguet shows that decentralization shifted public investment toward significantly higher investments in human capital and social services and that the reallocation was well aligned with local needs. Education investments were higher in areas with lower literacy; water and sanita- tion investments were higher in areas with lower water and sewerage connection rates; and investments in water management and agriculture were higher in areas at greater risk of malnutrition. This alignment of investments with local needs was driven in large part by the 250 small- est and poorest municipalities. Popular participation in local govern- ments was formalized through local oversight committees (comités de 140
  • 161. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? vigilancia), which were empowered to exercise oversight over municipal allocations of “popular participation funds” and to freeze disbursements to local governments that misused funds. De Janvry, Nakagawa, and Sadoulet (2009) also find a shift in resource allocation with decentralization. They look at the allocation of the Zambia social fund (ZAMSIF) across districts that vary in the discretion they can exercise in the allocation of these resources. They find greater diversity in funded projects in more decentralized districts, as well as a shift toward income-generating projects as opposed to broad public goods, such as education, health, and water supply/sanitation. However, the increased investments appeared to benefit the poor, and there was an overall shift of resources in favor of the poorest wards. Can Electoral Incentives Reduce Rent-Seeking? Ultimately, of course, the question of interest is whether a shift toward There is little good evidence democracy at the local level reduces capture on balance. There is very on whether a shift toward little good evidence on this issue. What there is suggests that local democracy at the local level democracy has the potential to mitigate capture, albeit not always most reduces capture. efficiently, and that electoral rules such as term limits, the political context in which decentralization occurs, and the ability of the center to oversee resource allocation at the local level matter a great deal. Foster and Rosenzweig (2004) develop a model of two-party democ- racy in which local governments need to allocate the public budget across three types of goods: a public good (roads) that disproportion- ately benefits the poor, by raising wages; a club good (irrigation facili- ties) that disproportionately benefits landowners; and a neutral public good (schools). The model establishes that an increase in the share of landless households should lead to larger investments in road construc- tion under a democratic regime relative to a regime that specifically favors the local elite. Using data from 250 villages in rural India, Foster and Rosenzweig show that an increase in the population weight of the poor induces resource allocations that favor the poor. Their evidence suggests that public irrigation investment crowds out private irrigation investment, so that the shift toward more pro-poor public goods also implies a net gain in total output. Political economy agency models, such as those by Barro (1973) and Ferejohn (1986), predict that incumbent politicians will refrain from 141
  • 162. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? maximizing rent extraction in their first term in order to get reelected and enjoy future rents. Persuasive empirical evidence that this is indeed the case has emerged based on term limits of U.S. state governors. Besley and Case (1995) show that governors eligible for reelection were signifi- cantly more likely to reduce taxes and expenditures than governors not facing reelection. List and Sturm (2006) show that electoral rules affect even secondary policies, such as environmental protection. They find that environmen- tal spending is higher when governors are eligible for reelection and that the spending gap between eligible and final-term governors increases in states with a large pro-environmental population. Results from Brazil Evidence on the relationship between term limits and political suggest that electoral incentives has also started to emerge for developing countries. Ferraz rules that enhance political and Finan (2011) look at mayoral elections in Brazilian municipalities. accountability play a crucial Using data from the 2003 audits conducted by the Brazilian central role in constraining corrupt government, they examine the allocation of federal resources by local behavior. governments. Municipalities were selected by lottery for an audit each month; audit reports were made available on the Internet and sent to all levels of government about two months after completion. Ferraz and Finan find that the share of total audited resources that was misap- propriated was 27 percent larger in municipalities with second-term mayors, who did not have reelection incentives because of term limits, and that the effects were more pronounced in municipalities with less access to information and in municipalities in which the likelihood of judicial punishment was lower. Overall, their findings suggest that electoral rules that enhance political accountability play a crucial role in constraining corrupt behavior. Assuming that in the absence of reelection incentives, first-term mayors would behave like second-term mayors, they estimate that reelection incentives reduced the misappro- priation of resources by about $160 million. De Janvry, Finan, and Sadoulet (forthcoming) provide additional evidence of the impact of term limits on the performance of mayors in Brazilian municipal elections. They focus on the impact of term limits on the effectiveness of the Bolsa Escola program on student dropout rates.20 The authors find that municipalities governed by a first-term mayor eligible for reelection had an additional 2 percentage point reduction in the dropout rate, which represented a 36 percent improve- ment in program performance compared with municipalities governed by a second-term mayor not eligible for reelection. Once the potential 142
  • 163. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? selection of children into the program is accounted for, the reduction in dropout rates is about 8 percentage points, representing a decline of 52 percent relative to the preprogram dropout rate of 15 percent.21 Various robustness checks validate these results. The authors also find some evidence for heterogeneity in program impact. Wealthier munici- palities generally do better, but so do municipalities that have more open and competitive electoral practices, which display less evidence of nepotism and administrative politicization. De Janvry, Finan, and Sadoulet attempt to understand the chan- nel through which mayoral effort translates into lower dropout rates by looking at differences in program implementation.22 Their fi nd- ings indicate that first-term mayors were somewhat more likely to rely on the registration of children through schools and to involve social councils in various ways in implementing the program. In contrast, second-term mayors were somewhat more likely to register children in the mayor’s office and to send program coordinators to the homes of children who did not comply with the program’s attendance require- ments. The authors argue that in-school registration of children is more transparent and indicates higher levels of effort. One could argue the opposite—that in-school registration could favor the inclusion of lower- risk (and potentially better-off) children, whereas registration through the mayor’s office, along with follow-up through program coordinators, may induce more noncompliers to openly drop out. If this is the case, dropout rates could be higher for second-term mayors precisely because they select poorer and riskier children and enforce the conditionality stipulated by the program, whereas reelection incentives may make first- term mayors more likely to engage in clientelistic behavior, as Khemani and Wane (2008) argue, than to deliver higher-quality public services. Disentangling these effects requires data on the child’s household char- acteristics and compliance with the program. The reelection incentives of local politicians, including the need to reward supporters, can also influence resource allocation in participa- tory development projects. Arcand and Bassole (2008), for example, show that, on average, the village of the Conseil Rural (rural council) president was 18.5 percent more likely to receive funding for a subproj- ect under the Programme National d’Infrastructures Rurales, a large community-driven development program in Senegal. Baird, McIntosh, and Özler (2009) find that wards and districts in which elected repre- sentatives were not from the ruling party generated fewer applications 143
  • 164. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? for projects funded by Tanzania’s Social Action Fund (TASAF), sug- gesting the use of decentralized project resources to build support for the incumbent party.23 Case (2001) finds that block grants provided by the Albanian social assistance program were distributed across commu- nities in a manner consistent with the core-supporter model. Several recent studies examine the restraining effect of election incentives on corruption in local governments. Ferraz and Finan (2008) examine whether access to information on the corrupt practices of local politicians affects voter behavior by comparing municipalities in Brazil that were randomly audited before the elections with municipalities that were audited after the elections. They find that the disclosure of audit reports had a significant impact on the reelection rates of corrupt mayors and that exposure to media was important, with larger effects in municipalities with radio stations. Henderson and Kuncoro (2011) find that Indonesia’s move toward decentralized local governance in 2001 decreased the level of corruption as measured by the reported bribes paid by firms to government line departments for activities under local control. The extent of the reduc- tion was greater in districts where Islamic (rather than secular) parties, whose local platforms emphasized anticorruption policies, were elected in 2001. The authors see this evidence as pointing to the importance of corruption as a political issue in the selection of local leaders and indicative of the potential for democracy at the local level to constrain corruption. When localities are largely Brollo (2009) focuses on the political opportunity that the audits of dependent on fiscal transfers local government can provide to the central government. This study from the center, the central reveals that much of the observed impact on the reelection odds of government can use devices incumbent mayors in Brazil occurs because the central government such as audits to control local uses audit reports to strategically reward and punish allies and competi- political selection. tors. Brollo finds that municipalities in which two or more instances of corruption were found received smaller transfers from the center, but corrupt mayors who were affiliated with the president’s political party were actually compensated with larger transfers in order to avoid future political losses caused by any reputational effects. In contrast, pure reputation effects dominated only when information was released close to the election. This finding suggests that when localities are largely dependent on fiscal transfers from the center, as Brazilian municipalities are, the central government can use devices such as audits to control local political selection. It also suggests that voters may care far more 144
  • 165. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? about the delivery of public goods and transfers than about the extent to which politicians, who are able to deliver these services, are corrupt. Bobonis, Camara-Fuertes, and Schwabe (2011) examine whether the public disclosure of information about political corruption affects the re-election odds and future behavior of politicians. They find that audits do little to reduce corruption but can be instrumental in improv- ing the odds of re-election. Using data on publicly released audits of municipal governments in Puerto Rico, they find that audited levels of corruption in municipalities that were audited before the previous election and municipalities that were not are similar. However, mayors were able to translate the reputational gain provided by a good audit into higher odds of reelection and higher levels of rent-seeking in future periods. Litschig and Zamboni (2007) and Di Tella and Schargrodsky (2003) Mechanisms other than focus on the impact of judicial institutions and “corruption crack- electoral and social downs” on resource misappropriation and fiscal mismanagement. These accountability, such as judicial studies point to the importance of mechanisms other than electoral and reforms, are important for social accountability for improving governance. improving governance. Litschig and Zamboni (2007) exploit exogenous variation in the location of state judiciary branches to assess the impact of judicial insti- tutions on corruption by civil servants in local governments in Brazil.24 Using audit data to construct an estimate of offenses per civil servant in counties, with and without state judiciary branches, they find that offenses per civil servant were about 35 percent lower in counties with a branch of the judiciary.25 Di Tella and Schargrodsky (2003) study the price paid for basic In Buenos Aires, the prices inputs during a crackdown on corruption in public hospitals in Buenos public hospitals paid for basic Aires in 1996–97. The crackdown was conducted by a newly elected inputs fell about 18 percent city government, which collected and compared prices paid by all during the first six months of a public hospitals for a set of homogenous basic inputs for which quality crackdown on corruption. differences should not have been a concern. The authors find that the prices paid by hospitals for basic inputs fell about 18 percent during the first six months of the crackdown. Although there was some increase afterward, prices remained significantly below the pre-crackdown phase nine months later. The longer-term effects were larger when procure- ment officers were better paid. These studies suggest that institutions at the local level cannot substi- tute for weak and corrupt formal institutions of accountability. Instead, local oversight over the use and management of public resources is likely 145
  • 166. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? to be effective only when other institutions of accountability, including institutions at the center, function well and communities have the rel- evant information and the capacity to sanction lax or corrupt providers and others in charge of public resources.26 In addition, broader reforms that enhance judicial oversight, allow for independent audit agencies, and protect and promote the right to information and a free media appear to be necessary for effective local oversight. Conclusions The literature on decentralization identifies a central trade-off between the advantages of local information and the hazards of local capture. The evidence reviewed in this chapter indicates that in many cases, the hazards of local capture can outweigh the benefits of local information. In the majority of cases, participants in community-driven develop- ment projects belong to the elite, whose preferences are often reflected in the resource allocation process. The extent to which their dominance distorts the poverty reduction intent of decentralized public programs depends on the extent to which elite dominance can be construed as capture. Community characteristics—including inequalities of wealth and political power, geographic isolation, and ethnic heterogeneity— appear to play a decisive role in this regard. Malevolent forms of capture are more likely in communities with greater wealth inequality, commu- nities that are isolated or poor and communities in which caste, race, and gender disparities are important and are embedded in a hierarchical structure which valorizes particular groups. Local actors may have an Participatory programs attempt to deal with these concerns by using informational and locational local facilitators to build community capacity. However, little is known advantage . . . about the facilitation process, the training received by facilitators, or the incentive structures they face. There is also little evidence of any self-correcting mechanism through which community engagement . . . but they appear to counteracts the potential capture of public resources. Instead, the bulk use it to the benefit of the of the evidence suggests that the more unequal the initial distribution disadvantaged only where of assets, the better positioned the nonpoor are to capture the benefits of institutions and mechanisms external efforts to help the poor. Local actors may have an informational to ensure local accountability and locational advantage, but they appear to use it to the benefit of the are robust. disadvantaged only where institutions and mechanisms to ensure local accountability are robust. 146
  • 167. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? Other dimensions of community capacity also matter a great deal. Participatory programs face Participatory programs face far greater challenges in remote or isolated far greater challenges in localities and in areas with lower literacy levels and higher levels of remote or isolated localities poverty. Such localities also tend to be less well served by mass media and in areas with lower and other sources of information and are less likely to have adequate literacy levels and higher central oversight. levels of poverty. Local democracy can have both favorable and unfavorable effects on the level and distribution of public resources. The outcome is context Local democracy can dependent. It varies with the nature of political institutions, at both have both favorable and the national and the local level; the level of voter awareness; and the unfavorable effects on the accountability mechanisms in place. The potential for resource capture level and distribution of public by political elites appears to be considerable. resources. The outcome is The literature also indicates that democratic decentralization can context dependent. lead to a greater use of public budgets to reward particular constituents for their loyalty and to improve the fortunes of political allies. The important question is whether democratic decentralization On balance, the ballot box narrows the overall scope for capture. The answer appears to warrant provides a clearer mechanism cautious optimism, provided political institutions and rules are designed for sanctioning unpopular to address perverse incentives. On balance the ballot box, though far policy choices or excessive from perfect, provides a clearer mechanism than less formal deliberation rent-seeking by traditional for sanctioning unpopular policy choices or excessive rent-seeking by or political elites than less traditional or political elites. It is less clear how citizens can collectively formal deliberation. sanction negligent or corrupt officials or local leaders where such ven- ues for the exercise of citizen voice are not available. This suggests that Institutions at the local community-driven development projects may be able to induce greater level cannot substitute for accountability by mandating inclusion and using electoral processes to weak and corrupt formal select community representatives. institutions of accountability. In sum, far from being a substitute for weak and corrupt formal institutions of accountability, local oversight over the use and manage- ment of public resources is effective only when institutions of account- ability at the center function well and communities have the capacity Effective local oversight to effectively monitor service providers and others in charge or public requires well-functioning resources. This finding appears to increase, rather than diminish, the institutions at the center . . . need for a functional and strong center and vigilant and able imple- and reforms that enhance menting agencies. There is little evidence that donors can substitute judicial oversight, allow for for a nonfunctional central government as a higher-level accountability independent audit agencies, agent. Effective local oversight appears to require reforms that enhance and protect and promote judicial oversight, allow for independent audit agencies, and protect and the right to information and a promote the right to information and a free media. free media. 147
  • 168. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Notes 1. See in particular Mauro (1995). The causal relationship between corrup- tion and economic development has been argued both ways. Glaeser and others (2004) argue that corruption tends to decline as economic progress occurs. 2. See, for example, Shleifer and Vishny (1993); Manor (1999); and Bardhan and Mookherjee (2006b). Recent theoretical work on incentives in principal-agent models also shows that decentralization can raise the pro- pensity of individuals to accept bribes (see, for example, Carbonara 2000). 3. Several writers argue that it may not always be sensible to pursue a policy designed to minimize corruption, narrowly defined as bribes, graft, and theft, particularly when there are other, possibly conflicting policy goals (see, for example, Waller, Verdier, and Gardner 2002). The implications of corruption for efficiency have been a somewhat contested issue. Some writ- ers, like Huntington (1968) argue that bribes, graft, and theft are necessary for greasing the “squeaking wheels” of a rigid bureaucracy or that they are an unpleasant but unavoidable side effect of needed government interven- tion to prevent market failure (Acemoglu and Verdier 2000). Others point out that corruption can skew the incentives of the most economically effi- cient people away from socially productive activities toward rent-seeking activities and that the people who “grease the wheels” may simply be the most successful at rent-seeking rather than production (Treisman 2000). Rose-Ackerman (2008) argues that the use of public office to influence resource allocation or move legislation in favor of particular groups or causes should not be viewed as corruption, as constituency-based politics can motivate voters to monitor the actions of their representatives, thereby reducing incentives for outright corruption. 4. An important strand in the cross-country literature on corruption focuses on the relationship between corruption and a country’s level of economic development, its political institutions, and aspects of its culture. Much of this literature tests hypotheses that have emerged from theoretical studies that seek to explain the relative prevalence of corruption across countries (see, for example, Olson 1993; Shleifer and Vishny 1993; and Campante, Chor, and Do 2009). Studies that look at the relationship between eco- nomic development and corruption find evidence for a strong negative relationship. Higher levels of economic development are associated with lower levels of corruption, although the direction of causality is not clear. Some writers argue that development reduces corruption (see Treisman 2000); others argue that countries with lower corruption levels experience more economic development (see Kaufmann and Kraay 2002). Studies also find that other features of the economy, including the level of eco- nomic inequality, natural resource endowments, and exposure to foreign competition, influence the extent of corruption. You and Khagram (2005) argue that in more unequal societies, the wealthy have greater incentives and opportunities to skew resources and power in their favor through cor- ruption, while the poor are more vulnerable to extortion and less able to 148
  • 169. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? hold the rich and powerful to account. Ades and Di Tella (1999) find that corruption tends to be higher in countries with greater income inequality. Leite and Weidmann (1999) find that larger natural resource endowments are associated with more corruption. Myerson (1993) and Persson, Roland, and Tabellini (1997) provide theoretical arguments for the relationship between political institutions and corruption. 5. Corruption also appears to be higher in countries that have fewer political rights, in ex-communist regimes (Triesman 2000), and in countries that have less press freedom (Brunetti and Weder 2003). Corruption levels are lower in countries that have a history of common law and procedural fairness, such as former British colonies; in countries that pay higher wages to their civil bureaucrats; and countries with larger numbers of ethno-linguistic groups (Treisman 2000; on wages see Evans and Rauch 2000). Some researchers argue that corruption levels are also lower where women play a greater role in the government and the economy (see, for example, Dollar, Fisman, and Gatti 2001; Swamy and others 2000). 6. Donchev and Ujhelyi (2009) show that factors commonly found to “cause” corruption—religion, the level of development, democratic institutions— are better at explaining perceptions of corruption than actual levels of it. Controlling for such variables, they find at best a very weak relationship between corruption and indexes of corruption perception, for all the measures of corruption experience the use. Olken (2007) and Donchev and Ujhelyi (2009) show that corruption perceptions vary systematically by individual and household characteristics such as education, age, gen- der, and income. A number of studies find a positive correlation between perceptions of corruption and a range of societal characteristics. Several studies find that reported perceptions of corruption are positively correlated with levels of local inequality and ethnic heterogeneity (see, for example, Mauro 1995; La Porta and others 1999; and Olken 2007). Others find a negative relationship between social capital, measured by levels of trust and civic activism, and corruption (on the relationship between social capital and corruption, see Putnam 1993; Paldam and Svendsen 2002; Bjornskov 2003). These studies cannot rule out reverse causality (high levels of corruption reducing trust and civic activism). 7. This finding is consistent with the theoretical model developed by Shleifer and Vishny (1993). 8. Moving from perception data to data on actual corruption experience is not always straightforward. In general, different measures of corruption do not produce the same conclusions. Moreover, the impact of a policy shift can vary across measures of corruption and possibly with the level of social tolerance for corruption in a society, as Mendez and Sepulveda (2010) show. Ades and Di Tella (1999) argue that hard data on corrup- tion, such as the number of reported fraud cases, are likely to reflect the classification system used in each country as well as both the incidence of corruption and the corruption deterrence system in place. 9. Public expenditure tracking data collected in other African countries yields a similar pattern of missing expenditures. 149
  • 170. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? 10. A number of other studies show that governments tend to be more responsive when the electorate is better informed. The mass media have an important role to play in this regard. Drèze and Sen (1990) make this argument forcefully in noting the relative success that India, which has a free media, has had avoiding famines compared with China. Besley and Burgess (2002) show that Indian states with higher newspaper circulation (which also had higher literacy rates and greater election turnout) were more likely to be responsive to food shortages. Stromberg (2004a, 2004b) shows how access to media can affect the allocation of resources to specific groups and thus influence the incidence of redistributive programs. A number of cross-country studies find a negative correlation between press freedom and corruption (Stapenhurst 2000; Brunetti and Weder 2003; Ahrend 2002). Djankov and others (2003) find a negative relationship between state ownership of the media and measures of good governance, including political rights, service delivery, and social outcomes. However, the independence of the media (and the degree of state ownership) may itself depend on the size of political rents and thus the scale of opportu- nities for resource misappropriation. Besley and Prat (2006) argue that the press is more likely to be free where political rents are small and there is scope for a multiplicity of media outlets and sources for advertising revenue. Mullainathan and Shleifer (2002) point out that greater media concentration need not imply less media autonomy if competition generates a struggle for market share that leads to the publication of more stories that tend to confirm the prior beliefs of readers. 11. OPK rice was available at 60 percent below market price, implying a subsidy of about 9 percent of preprogram monthly household expenditures for a median household purchasing its full allotment of subsidized rice. 12. The measure of corruption is obtained by comparing administrative data on the amount of rice distributed with survey data on the amount house- holds actually received. A potential issue is that the survey data provide information only on whether a household obtained any subsidized rice, without naming the program or the number of times it did so. Olken (2006) therefore assumes that each household that received rice received its full monthly allotment and that the rice was obtained from the OPK. 13. The study incorporates data from various sources, including focus group interviews with households and community leaders on service quality and on local institutions, data on service coverage and administration, and a household survey that included information on participation in local associations and the use of specific services. 14. The study uses census data from 155 villages. The villages are a random subset of all the villages in which an NGO, the National Rural Support Program, was active. The National Rural Support Program is funded through the Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund, a World Bank–supported community-driven development program. 15. See chapter 6 for more on deliberative councils and their role in resource allocation. 16. The inputs provided were sufficient to cultivate at least 3.5 acres of land. 150
  • 171. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? 17. The control group was generated by randomizing the order in which groups entered the program. 18. To obtain representative measures of community poverty and inequality, Araujo and others (2008) use poverty mapping techniques to combine household and census data. They then combine these with administrative data on project type and cost at the community level. 19. Redistricting could also create new constituencies of swing voters, allowing politicians to better target communities whose electoral choices could be influenced by the provision of public goods (Lindbeck and Weibull 1987; Dixit and Londregan 1996; Persson and Tabellini 2001). The swing voter is theorized to be closest to the center of the political spectrum. There is empirical support for the swing voter model in both developed and developing countries. Levitt and Snyder (1997) show that in the United States, government spending increases the incumbent’s vote share in congressional elections. Sorribas-Navarro and Sole-Olle (2008) confirm this result in national elections in Spain. Dahlberg and Johansson (2002) find that incumbent governments in Sweden distributed temporary grants for ecologically sustainable development programs to regions with more swing voters. 20. Bolsa Escola gives conditional cash transfers to poor mothers of school-age children if the children attend school on a regular basis. Municipalities were allocated a fi xed number of stipends and were responsible for identifying beneficiary children. By design, households with a monthly per capita income of less than R$90 (about $40) were eligible. They were offered a transfer of R$15 per child, up to a maximum of R$45 per household. 21. Selection is likely to be important, as almost half of eligible children were left out of the program because of limits on stipends at the municipality level. Beneficiary children had an initial dropout rate that was less than a third the dropout rate of nonbeneficiaries. The authors deal with this problem by estimating the treatment effect after controlling for child fi xed-effects and by allowing children with a different pretreatment drop- out status to have different year effects. Identification is then based on a comparison of the change in dropout levels between treated children and their comparable untreated counterparts. 22. Program implementation varied greatly across municipalities, despite clear eligibility rules at the federal level. Implementation processes varied, for example, in the location at which children were registered, the manner in which the school attendance conditionality was monitored, and the extent to which program coordinators were involved in verifying compliance. Much of this variation appears to be tied to whether the municipality was led by a first-term or second-term mayor. 23. In his study of Indonesia’s Urban Poverty Project, Fritzen (2007) finds that electoral incentives induced more pro-poor actions by elected members of community development boards, which are responsible for selecting and managing all activities funded by the project. A concern with this study is that the key variables used to determine elite capture are perceptions of the board members whose behavior was being assessed, making any 151
  • 172. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? inference difficult. The data on perceptions are also aggregated into scores in a somewhat obscure manner. 24. State judiciary branches are assigned only to the most populous county among contiguous counties forming a judiciary district. Counties with nearly similar populations but without a local judicial presence serve as the counterfactual case. 25. Ferraz and Finan (2011) also find that the presence of a judge reduces corruption among second-term mayors. Litschig and Zamboni (2007) are unable to find evidence of any impact of mayoral incumbency on corruption levels. However, their strategy makes their results not directly comparable to the studies by Ferraz and Finan (2008, 2011). 26. A comprehensive review of the case study evidence on civil society engage- ment in reducing corruption (Grimes 2008) finds that community efforts at monitoring and sanctioning corrupt practices have bite only when there is a strong and engaged advocate at the center. In the absence of such conditions, civil society efforts are able to succeed in only a limited way, largely by inducing resignations through naming and shaming and through protests to raise awareness. References Acemoglu, D., and T. Verdier. 2000. “The Choice between Market Failures and Corruption.” American Economic Review 90(1): 194–211. Ades, A., and R. Di Tella. 1999. “Rents, Competition, and Corruption.” American Economic Review 89(4): 982–93. Ahrend, R. 2002. “Press Freedom, Human Capital, and Corruption.” DELTA Working Paper Series 36, Ecole Normale Supérieure, Paris. Ansolabehere, S., A. Gerber, and J. M. Snyder Jr. 2002. “Equal Votes, Equal Money: Court-Ordered Redistricting and Public Expenditures in the American States.” American Political Science Review 96(4): 767–77. Araujo, M. C., F. H. G. Ferreira, P. Lanjouw, and B. Özler. 2008. “Local Inequality and Project Choice: Theory and Evidence from Ecuador.” Journal of Public Economics 92(5–6): 1022–46. Arcand, J.-L., and L. Bassole. 2008. “Does Community Driven Development Work? Evidence from Senegal.” CERDI-CNRS, Université d’Auvergne, France. Arcand, J.-L., and M. Fafchamps. 2012. “Matching in Community-Based Organizations.” Journal of Development Economics 98(2): 203–19. Baird, S., C. McIntosh, and B. Özler. 2009. The Squeaky Wheels Get the Grease: Applications and Targeting in Tanzania’s Social Action Fund. World Bank, Washington, DC. Bardhan, P. 2002. “Decentralization of Governance and Development.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(4): 185–205. Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2006a. “Decentralization, Corruption, and Government Accountability.” In International Handbook on the Economics 152
  • 173. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? of Corruption, ed. S. Rose-Ackerman. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar. ———. 2006b. “Pro-poor Targeting and Accountability of Local Govern- ments in West Bengal.” Journal of Development Economics 79(2): 303–327 ———. Forthcoming. “Land Reform and Farm Productivity in West Bengal.” American Economic Journal, Applied Economics. Bardhan, P., D. Mookherjee, and M. P. Torrado. 2010. “Impact of Political Reservations in West Bengal Local Governments on Anti-Poverty Targeting.” Journal of Globalization and Development 1(1): 1–34. Barro, R. 1973. “The Control of Politicians: An Economic Model.” Public Choice 14: 19–42. Besley, T., and R. Burgess. 2002. “The Political Economy of Government Responsiveness: Theory and Evidence from India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4): 1415–51. Besley, T., and A. Case. 1995. “Does Electoral Accountability Affect Economic Policy Choices? Evidence from Gubernatorial Term Limits.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3): 769–98. Besley, T., R. Pande, and V. Rao. 2005. “Participatory Democracy in Action: Survey Evidence from South Rural India.” Journal of the European Economic Association 3(2–3): 648–57. ———. 2007. “Just Rewards? Local Politics and Public Resource Allocation in South India.” LSE, STICERD Research Paper DEDPS49, Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines, Lond School of Economies, London. Besley, T., and A. Prat. 2006. “Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability.” American Economic Review 96(3): 720–36. Bjorkman, M. 2006, “Does Money Matter for Student Performance? Evidence from a Grant Program in Uganda.” Working Paper 326, Innocenzo Gasparini Institute for Economic Research (IGIER), Universitá Bocconi, Milan. Bjornskov, C. 2003. “Corruption and Social Capital.” Working Paper 03-13, Aarhus School of Business, Aarhus, Germany. Bobonis, G. J., L. Camara-Fuertes, and R. Schwabe. 2011. “The Dynamic Effects of Information on Political Corruption: Theory and Evidence from Puerto Rico.” Working Paper 428, Department of Economics, University of Toronto, Toronto, ON. Bratton, M., and N. Van de Walle. 1997. Democratic Experiments in Africa. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Brollo, F. 2009. “Who Is Punishing Corrupt Politicians—Voters or the Central Government? Evidence from the Brazilian Anti-Corruption Program.” Institute for Economic Development Working Paper dp-168, Department of Economics, Boston University, Boston. Brunetti, A., and B. Weder. 2003. “A Free Press Is Bad News for Corruption.” Journal of Public Economics 87(7–8): 1801–24. Camacho, A., and E. Conover. 2011. “Manipulation of Social Program Eligibility.” American Economic Journal-Economic Policy 3(2): 41–65. 153
  • 174. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Campante, F. R., D. Chor, and Q. Do. 2009. “Instability and the Incentives for Corruption.” Economics and Politics 21(1): 42–92. Carbonara, E. 2000. “Corruption and Decentralisation.” Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Working Paper 342/83, University of Bologna, Italy. Case, A. 2001. “Election Goals and Income Redistribution: Recent Evidence from Albania.” European Economic Review 45(3): 405–23. Conning, J., and M. Kevane. 2002. “Community-Based Targeting Mechanisms for Social Safety Nets: A Critical Review.” World Development 30(3): 375–94. Cox, G. W., and M. D. McCubbins. 1986. “Electoral-Politics as a Redistributive Game.” Journal of Politics 48(2): 370–89. Dahlberg, M., and E. Johansson. 2002. “On the Vote-Purchasing Behavior of Incumbent Governments.” American Political Science Review 96(1): 27–40. Dasgupta, A., and V. A. Beard. 2007. “Community Driven Development, Collective Action and Elite Capture in Indonesia.” Development and Change 38(2): 229–49. De Janvry, A., F. Finan, and E. Sadoulet. Forthcoming. “Local Electoral Incentives and Decentralized Program Performance.” Review of Economics and Statistics. De Janvry, A., H. Nakagawa, and E. Sadoulet. 2009. “Pro-Poor Targeting and Electoral Rewards in Decentralizing to Communities the Provision of Local Public Goods in Rural Zambia.” University of California, Berkeley. Di Tella, R., and E. Schargrodsky. 2003. “The Role of Wages and Auditing During a Crackdown on Corruption in the City of Buenos Aires.” Journal of Law and Economics 46(1): 269–92. Dixit, A., and J. Londregan. 1996. “The Determinants of Success of Special Interests in Redistributive Politics.” Journal of Politics 58(4): 1132–55. Djankov, S., C. McLeish, T. Nenova, and A. Shleifer. 2003. “Who Owns the Media?” Journal of Law and Economics 46(2): 341–81. Dollar, D., R. Fisman, and R. Gatti. 2001. “Are Women Really the ‘Fairer’ Sex? Corruption and Women in Government.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 46(4): 423–29. Donchev, D., and G. Ujhelyi. 2009. “What Do Corruption Indices Measure?” Department of Economics, University of Houston, Houston, TX. Drèze, J., and A. Sen, eds. 1990. The Political Economy of Hunger: Entitlement and Well-Being, World Institute for Development Economics Research Studies in Development Economics vol. 1. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Estache, A., and S. Sinha. 1995. “Does Decentralization Increase Spending on Public Infrastructure?” Policy Research Working Paper 1457, World Bank, Washington, DC. Evans, P. B., and J. E. Rauch. 2000. “Bureaucratic Structure and Bureaucratic Performance in Less Developed Countries.” Journal of Public Economics 75(1): 49–71. Faguet, J. P. 2004. “Does Decentra lization Increase Government Responsiveness to Local Needs? Evidence from Bolivia.” Journal of Public Economics 88(3–4): 867–93. 154
  • 175. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? Fan, C. S., C. Lin, and D. Treisman. 2009. “Political Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence from around the World.” Journal of Public Economics 93(1–2): 14–34. Ferejohn, J. 1986. “Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control.” Public Choice 50: 5–25. Ferraz C. and F. Finan. 2008. “Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects of Brazil’s Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 123(2): 703–45. ———. 2011. “Electoral Accountability and Corruption: Evidence from the Audits of Local Governments.” American Economic Review 101(4): 1274–311. Finan, F. 2004. “Political Patronage and Local Development: A Brazilian Case Study.” Working Paper, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Berkeley. Fisman, R., and R. Gatti. 2002a. “Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence across Countries.” Journal of Public Economics 83(3): 325–45. ———. 2002b. “Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence from U.S. Federal Transfer Programs.” Public Choice 113(1–2): 25–35. Foster, A., and M. Rosenzweig. 2004. “Democratization and the Distribution of Local Public Goods in a Poor Rural Economy.” Working Paper 01-056, Penn Institute for Economic Research, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia. Fox, J. 1994. “The Difficult Transition from Clientelism to Citizenship: Lessons from Mexico.” World Politics 46(2): 151–84. Francken, N., B. Minten, and J. F. M. Swinnen. 2009. “Media, Monitoring, and Capture of Public Funds: Evidence from Madagascar.” World Development 37(1): 242–55. Fritzen, S. A. 2007. “Can the Design of Community-Driven Development Reduce the Risk of Elite Capture? Evidence from Indonesia.” World Development 35(8): 1359–75. Galasso, E., and M. Ravallion. 2005. “Decentralized Targeting of an Antipoverty Program.” Journal of Public Economics 89(4): 705–27 Glaeser, E. L., R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes, and A. Schleifer. 2004. “Do Institutions Cause Growth?” Journal of Economic Growth 9(3): 271–303. Grimes, M. 2008. “The Conditions of Successful Civil Society Involvement in Combating Corruption: A Survey of Case Study Evidence.” QoG Working Paper 22: 21, Department of Political Science, University of Gothenburg, Sweden. Grootaert, C., G. T. Oh, and A. Swamy. 2002. “Social Capital, Household Welfare and Poverty in Burkina Faso.” Journal of African Economies 11(1): 4–38. Gugerty, M. K., and M. Kremer. 2008. “Outside Funding and the Dynamics of Participation in Community Associations.” American Journal of Political Science 52(3): 585–602 Henderson, V. J., a nd A . Kuncoro. 2011. “Corruption a nd L oca l Democratization in Indonesia: The Role of Islamic Parties.” Journal of Development Economics 24(2): 164–80. 155
  • 176. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Humphreys, M., W. A. Masters, and M. E. Sandbu. 2006. “The Role of Leaders in Democratic Deliberations: Results from a Field Experiment in São Tomé and Principe.” World Politics 58(4): 583–622. Huntington, S. P. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Kaufmann, D., and A. Kraay. 2002. “Growth without Governance.” Economia: Journal of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association 3(1): 169–215. Khemani, S., and W. Wane. 2008. “Populist Fiscal Policy.” Policy Research Working Paper 4762, World Bank, Washington, DC. La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny. 1999. “The Quality of Government.” Journal of Law Economics & Organization 15(1): 222–79. Labonne, J., and R. S. Chase. 2009. “Who Is at the Wheel When Communities Drive Development? Evidence from the Philippines.” World Development 37(1): 219–31. Leite, C., and J. Weidmann. 1999. “Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption, and Economic Growth.” IMF Working Paper 99/85, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Levitt, S. D., and J. M. Snyder. 1997. “The Impact of Federal Spending on House Election Outcomes.” Journal of Political Economy 105(1): 30–53. Lindbeck, A., and J. Weibull. 1987. “Balanced Budget Redistribution as the Outcome of Political Competition.” Public Choice 52: 273–97. List, J. A., and D. M. Sturm. 2006. “How Elections Matter: Theory and Evidence from Environmental Policy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(4): 1249–81. Litschig, S., and Y. Zamboni. 2007. “The Effect of Judicial Institutions on Local Governance and Corruption.” Discussion Paper 0607-15, Department of Economics, Columbia University, New York. Manacorda, M., E. Miguel, and A. Vigorito. 2011. “Government Transfers and Political Support.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 3(3): 1–28. Manor, J. 1999. The Political Economy of Democratic Decentralization. Washington, DC: World Bank. Mansuri, G. 2012a. “Bottom Up or Top Down; Participation and the Provision of Local Public Goods.” World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management, Washington, DC. ———. 2012b. “Harnessing Community: Assortative Matching in Participa- tory Community Organizations.” World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management, Washington, DC. Markussen, T. 2006. “Inequality and Party Capture: Theory and Evidence from South India.” Discussion Paper 10-26, Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Copenhagen, Denmark. Mauro, P. 1995. “Corruption and Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3): 681–712. Mendez, F., and F. Sepulveda. 2010. “What Do We Talk about When We Talk about Corruption?” Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 26(3): 493–514. 156
  • 177. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? Miguel, E., and F. Zaidi. 2003. “Do Politicians Reward Their Supporters? Public Spending and Incumbency Advantage in Ghana.” University of California, Berkeley. Mohan, G., and K. Stokke. 2000. “Participatory Development and Empowerment: The Dangers of Localism.” Third World Quarterly 21(2): 247–68. Mookherjee, D. 1997. “Incentive Reforms in Developing Country Bureau- cracies Lessons from Tax Administration.” Paper prepared for the Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics, World Bank, Washington, DC. Mullainathan, S., and A. Shleifer. 2002. “Media Bias.” NBER Working Paper 9295, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Murphy, W. 1990. “Creating the Appearance of Consensus in Mende Political Discourse.” American Anthropologist 92(1): 24–41. Myerson, R. B. 1993. “Effectiveness of Electoral Systems for Reducing Government Corruption: A Game-Theoretic Analysis.” Games and Economic Behavior 5(1): 118–32. O’Donnell, G. 1993. “On the State, Democratization and Some Conceptual Problems (A Latin American View with Glances at Some Post-Communist Countries).” World Development 21(8): 1355–69. Olken, B. 2006. “Corruption and the Costs of Redistribution: Micro Evidence from Indonesia.” Journal of Public Economics 90(4–5): 853–70. ———. 2007. “Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia.” Journal of Political Economy 115(2): 200–49. Olson, M. 1993. “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development.” American Political Science Review 87(3):567–76. Paldam, M., and T. Svendsen. 2002. “Missing Social Capital and the Transition in Eastern Europe.” Journal for Institutional Innovation, Development and Transition 5: 21–34. Persson, T., G. Roland, and G. Tabellini. 1997. “Separation of Powers and Political Accountability.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): 1163–202. Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 2000. Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. ———. 2001. “Political Institutions and Policy Outcomes: What Are the Stylized Facts?” CESifo Working Paper 459, CESifo Group, Munich. Platteau, J.-P., and F. Gaspart. 2003. “The Risk of Resource Misappropriation in Community-Driven Development.” World Development 31(10): 1687–703. Pradhan, M., V. Rao, and C. Rosenberg. 2009. The Impact of the Community Level Activities of the Second Urban Poverty Project. World Bank, Washington, DC. Putnam, R. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Rao, V., and A. M. Ibanez. 2005. “The Social Impact of Social Funds in Jamaica: A ‘Participatory Econometric’ Analysis of Targeting, Collective Action, and Participation in Community-Driven Development.” Journal of Development Studies 41(5): 788–838. 157
  • 178. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Reinikka, R., and J. Svensson. 2004. “Local Capture: Evidence from a Central Government Transfer Program in Uganda.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(2): 679–705. ———. 2005. “Fighting Corruption to Improve Schooling: Evidence from a Newspaper Campaign in Uganda.” Journal of the European Economic Association 3(2–3): 259–67. ———. 2007. “The Returns from Reducing Corruption: Evidence from Education in Uganda.” CEPR Discussion Paper 6363, Center for Economic Policy and Research, London. Rodriguez-Chamussy, L. 2009. “Local Electoral Rewards from Centralized Social Programs: Are Mayors Getting the Credit?” Department of Agricultural and Resources Economics, University of California, Berkeley. Rose-Ackerman, S. 2008. “Corruption and Government.” International Peacekeeping 15(3): 328–43. Samuels, D., and R. Snyder. 2001. “The Value of a Vote: Malapportionment in Comparative Perspective.” British Journal of Political Science 31(4): 651–71. Schady, N. R. 2000. “The Political Economy of Expenditures by the Peruvian Social Fund (FONCODES), 1991–95.” American Political Science Review 94(2): 289–304. Shankar, S., R. Gaiha, and R. Jha. 2010. “Information and Corruption: The National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme in India.” ASARC Working Paper 32-32, Australia South Asia Research Centre, Australian National University, Canberra. Shleifer, A., and R. W. Vishny. 1993. “Corruption.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(3): 599–617. Snyder, R. 1999. “After Neoliberalism: The Politics of Reregulation in Mexico.” World Politics 51(2): 173–204. Sorribas-Navarro, P., and A. Sole-Olle. 2008. “The Effects of Partisan Alignment on the Allocation of Intergovernmental Transfers. Differences- in-Differences Estimates for Spain.” Journal of Public Economics 92(12): 2302–19. Stapenhurst, R. 2000. The Media’s Role in Curbing Corruption. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute. Stromberg, D. 2004a. “Mass Media Competition, Political Competition, and Public Policy.” Review of Economic Studies 71(1): 265–84. ———. 2004b. “Radio’s Impact on Public Spending.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(1): 189–221. Swamy, A., S. Knack, Y. Lee, and O. Azfar, 2000. “Gender and Cor- ruption.” CDE Working Paper Series, Center for Development Economics, Williams College, Williamstown, MA. Treisman, D. 2000. “The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National Study.” Journal of Public Economics 76(3): 399–457. ———. 2007. “What Have We Learned about the Causes of Corruption from Ten Years of Cross-National Empirical Research?” Annual Review of Political Science 10(June): 211–44. 158
  • 179. HOW IMPORTANT IS CAPTURE? Waller, C. J., T. Verdier, and R. Gardner. 2002. “Corruption: Top Down or Bottom Up?” Economic Inquiry 40(4): 688–703. White, H. 2002. “Social Funds: A Review of the Issues.” Journal of International Development 14(5): 605–10. World Bank. 2004. World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People. Washington, DC: World Bank. You, J. S., and S. Khagram. 2005. “A Comparative Study of Inequality and Corruption.” American Sociological Review 70(1): 136–57. 159
  • 181. CHAPTER FIVE Does Participation Improve Development Outcomes? MUCH OF THE IMPETUS FOR INV ESTMENT IN PA RTICIPATORY poverty reduction projects and decentralization efforts has come from the hope that greater civic engagement will lead to faster and more equitable development. In line with this notion, many countries have shifted the provision of basic public services to the local level, and there has been much greater emphasis on citizen engagement in service deliv- ery through community health groups, school management commit- tees, and similar groups. Common-pool resources are also increasingly managed more locally, and small-scale infrastructure is often provided through decentralized poverty reduction programs, social funds, and community-driven development projects. Community-based livelihood programs, which focus more directly on increasing income and employ- ment, have also become an important component of large-scale poverty reduction programs. This chapter assesses the extent to which this shift toward the local has enhanced the pace of development, increased equity in access to public programs, and improved the sustainability of development efforts. The first section reviews efforts to decentralize the identifica- tion of beneficiary households and communities for poverty reduction and social insurance programs. The second section reviews efforts to devolve the management of common-pool resources and summarizes the evidence for greater resource sustainability and equity. The third section examines local infrastructure delivered through participatory mechanisms. The fourth section reviews efforts to induce greater com- munity oversight in the delivery of health and education services. The fifth section assesses the evidence on the poverty impacts of participa- tory projects. The last section sums up the broad lessons learned. 161
  • 182. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Identification of Beneficiaries A common approach to evaluating the relative efficiency of alternative targeting mechanisms has been to compare leakage and undercover- age rates. Much of the literature focuses almost exclusively on leakage and the extent to which it reflects resource capture by elites.1 Although this aspect of targeting is important, an exclusive focus on the identity of beneficiaries can draw attention away from what is ultimately of greatest interest: whether the poverty reduction objectives of targeted programs are achievable given the size and distribution of the budget (see Ravallion 2009b). Participatory poverty reduction programs typically use a combina- tion of targeting methods to identify beneficiary households and com- munities. When the government manages and implements programs, the center may allocate resources to subnational jurisdictions, using administrative criteria to satisfy broad political economy concerns, such as support to the poorest areas or the need to ensure horizontal equity. Local governments may then be required to identify the poor, or the most poorly served by public services, within their jurisdiction. Geographic and poverty targeting at higher levels is often combined with a demand-driven process at the community level to generate bene- ficiary lists for infrastructure projects. Community-driven development and social fund programs often do this by working with local nongov- ernmental organizations (NGOs) and community activists. Elected or selected local leaders are usually responsible for identifying beneficiaries when programs are implemented through local governments. The process of beneficiary The process of beneficiary identification at the local level also varies identification at the local substantially, both within and across projects, and is often left fuzzy. level varies substantially, both Critics worry that this leaves the process open to rent-seeking. One within and across projects, response to the problem has been to use poverty monitoring tools to select possibly leaving the process beneficiaries at the very local level.2 The use of such tools is not without open to rent-seeking. costs, however, as it devalues the relevance of information at the local level—precisely the level at which such information is likely to be most valuable. The evidence reviewed below sheds some light on this issue. Participatory programs that invest in local public goods also rely on community and household self-selection. All social funds, for example, require community co-financing, with or without competition for funds. Communities as a whole, or specific community groups, must decide whether or not to submit a proposal for a project based on the 162
  • 183. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? implied level of benefits and the cost of participation. The assumption for targeted social funds is that the level of benefits is too low to make participation advantageous for the better-off. Co-financing has long been seen as a cornerstone of participatory development. It can be in the form of free or low-wage labor, cash, or materials. It is believed that community co-financing ensures commu- nity engagement in all aspects of the project, at construction and after, thereby ensuring that investments are sustainable. As the community, along with the government or donor agency, decides on the level of provision of the good or service, co-financing is sometimes seen as a lump-sum tax on public good provision. However, many observers view co-financing as an egregious aspect of Many observers view participatory projects, one that forces people with the least to either pay co-financing—a cornerstone more for their development needs than the better-off do or to opt out of participatory development and be excluded altogether from project benefits. Free labor provision projects—as an egregious tax by community members has even been compared with forced or corvée on the poor. labor (see chapter 1).3 When communities compete for funds, with or without co-financ- ing requirements, the overall targeting performance of projects also depends on the capacity of eligible communities to submit adequate proposals. Communities that have low capacity or cannot meet co- financing requirements are often unable to submit projects for con- sideration. Even the best-intentioned implementing agencies cannot prevent this type of initial exclusion: although the use of administrative criteria, such as the number of poor households served, can improve targeting among applicants, it cannot reverse exclusion in the pool of submitted projects. Program conditions such as the resources allocated to building com- There is a pervasive concern munity capacity or the information available to potential beneficiaries in the literature about the can therefore determine who applies for benefits as well as who gets extent to which better-off approved. Many community-based projects have remedial mechanisms communities are more likely to that are intended to ensure that all eligible communities can submit propose and win subprojects. feasible projects. Nonetheless, there is a pervasive concern in the litera- ture about the extent to which better-off communities—communities with greater capacity, political networks, or wealth—are more likely to propose and win subprojects. This issue is addressed in the review that follows, as far as is possible, by examining the targeting strategy and its outcomes at different stages of the targeting process—that is, by look- ing at factors such as program reliance on administrative targeting, a 163
  • 184. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? competitive fund allocation process, self-selection to determine eligibil- ity, and the extent to which program participation entails costs such as co-financing or a challenging application process. Central versus Local Targeting of Private Transfers Some studies suggest Most studies that have examined the relative targeting performance of that local co-financing the center versus local areas in assigning private benefits find support requirements can exacerbate for more pro-poor targeting at the local level. However, the increase in horizontal inequities, targeting performance is small, with programs only mildly pro-poor particularly when eligibility on balance. Moreover, some evidence suggests that the local targeting thresholds are also of poor areas or households is substantially improved when the center decentralized. provides stronger incentives for pro-poor targeting by local govern- ments or implementing agencies, often by retaining control over key design features of the program, such as eligibility thresholds. Some studies suggest that local co-fi nancing requirements can exacerbate horizontal inequities, particularly when eligibility thresholds are also decentralized. Evidence from an Albanian economic support program (the Ndihme Ekonomika) indicates that local officials were able to target recipients better than the center could have done using proxy entitlement indica- tors (Alderman 2002). The program provided social assistance to some 20 percent of the population through a block grant to communes. Local officials determined eligibility and the amount of the transfer to beneficiary households. Galasso and Ravallion (2005) find similar evidence for a decentral- ized poverty program in Bangladesh. The Food-for-Education program distributed fixed food rations to selected poor households conditional on their school-age children attending at least 85 percent of classes. The center was responsible for identifying eligible union parishads, the lowest level of local government. Villages in eligible union parishads were then made responsible for identifying program beneficiaries. The program was mildly pro-poor (slightly more poor than nonpoor households received rations). Although the targeting differential was The center is often better at small—the program achieved about one-fifth the maximum targeting targeting poor communities differential—almost all of it occurred because beneficiaries were well than identifying poor targeted within villages.4 households within such A series of other studies broadly supports these fi ndings. Coady communities. (2001) examines a large Mexican cash transfer program (Progresa), 164
  • 185. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? which selected poor households on the basis of census data without any community involvement. He finds some support for the center’s ability to target eligible communities but, in line with other studies, finds that the center is far less able to identify poor households within targeted poor communities. In their study of the Trabajar 2 program in Argentina, Ravallion (2000) and Jalan and Ravallion (2003) demonstrate the center’s role in providing incentives for more pro-poor targeting by local govern- ments. This World Bank–supported program, introduced in 1997, expanded an earlier workfare program, Trabajar 1, in order to provide an additional period of short-term work to poor households and to locate socially useful projects in poor areas. Under Trabajar 2, the central government allocated funds to the provinces, making an effort to provide more program funding to poorer provinces. Provincial gov- ernments then allocated funds to projects within the provinces. Local governments and NGOs proposed subprojects and bore their nonwage costs. The results show that self-targeting in the program worked well, with participants overwhelmingly drawn from among the poorest households. The studies also find some improvement in reaching poorer areas within provinces. About a third of the overall improvement came from better targeting of provinces; the rest came from better targeting of poor areas within provinces.5 However, a more recent assessment of the targeting performance of this program (Ronconi 2009) finds greater leakage and smaller income effects. It also finds some evidence that nontargeted beneficiaries were more politically connected. A number of studies use data from rural India to examine whether participation in mandatory village assemblies (gram sabhas) called by elected village councils (gram panchayats) to discuss resource allocation decisions in the village improved the allocation of central transfer pro- grams. These programs provide an array of government schemes, ranging from subsidized food through the public distribution system to housing schemes and free hospitalization to poor households. In collaboration with state government officials, through a census, the gram panchayat identifies households eligible to receive Below Poverty Line (BPL) cards. The list of BPL households, as well as the subsequent selection of beneficiaries for specific schemes, needs to be ratified at public gram sabha meetings. The Indian Planning Commission reports that there is a perception of significant mistargeting in the allocation of BPL cards. 165
  • 186. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Some evidence suggests that Besley, Pande, and Rao (2005, 2007) find that villages that hold a villages in India that hold gram sabha do a better job of targeting BPL cards to the most disad- a gram sabha do a better vantaged villagers. People without any formal schooling, for example, job of targeting the most fare substantially better in villages that hold gram sabhas. However, not disadvantaged. all villages hold such meetings, and among those that do, only about a fifth discuss beneficiary selection for public programs. Consequently, most local politicians in their sample (87 percent of the 540 surveyed) believed that they, rather than the gram sabha, were responsible for benefit allocation decisions. Bardhan and others (2008) also find that villages that had greater gram sabha participation rates were more pro-poor in their allocation of benefits. Although they are careful to point out that this finding does not provide evidence of a causal impact of gram sabha meetings on tar- geting, they argue that it is consistent with the hypothesis that village meetings “formed a channel of accountability of gram panchayats to poor and low caste groups” (p. 7). Besley, Pande, and Rao (2007) also find support for the disciplinary effect of the gram sabha on capture. They show that the odds of a politician’s household receiving a BPL card were lower in villages in which a gram sabha was held. These results are only suggestive, as the design of these studies does not allow the authors to determine why some villages hold meetings and others do not. Several studies using data from India have tried to identify village characteristics that predict the holding of gram sabhas as well as household characteristics associated with participation. Bardhan and others (2008) find that participation rates were higher in villages in which the proportion of landless and scheduled caste households was lower. Besley, Pande, and Rao (2007) find higher participation rates for the landless and low caste in villages with higher average levels of education. Kumar (2007) looks at the effect of community participation on the targeting of BPL cards in India. Her data come from the state of Madhya Pradesh, where a participatory development project, the District Poverty Initiatives Project (DPIP), was initiated in 2001. She assesses the extent to which DPIP, which aims to build political aware- ness and confidence among the disadvantaged, affects the allocation of BPL cards to eligible households. Her results indicate that the targeting of BPL cards is indeed more pro-poor in DPIP villages, where a greater fraction of BPL cardholders are landless and belong to lower castes. (See also the discussion in chapter 6.) 166
  • 187. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Ravallion (2009a) examines the relationship between central and local targeting, using data from the implementation of Di Bao, a decen- tralized urban poverty reduction program in China. The program aims to provide all urban households with a transfer payment sufficient to bring their incomes up to a predetermined poverty line. The center set the guidelines and provided about 60 percent of the program’s costs on average, making some effort to bear a larger share of the cost in poorer provinces.6 Municipalities were allowed to set the eligibility threshold for benefits and identify beneficiaries. The question of interest is whether poorer municipalities had incen- tives under these conditions to understate their poverty problems by set- ting lower thresholds. The analysis shows that poorer cities did indeed set lower poverty lines and thus had lower participation rates. As a result, equally poor families ended up with very different levels of access to the program, with the poor in the poorest cities typically faring worst. This problem greatly diminished the program’s ability to reach the poor. An important dimension of inducing greater civic engagement in the Local determination of identification of beneficiaries is that local perceptions of need may not need may take into account coincide with the ways the center determines program eligibility. This variables not observed by divergence in perceptions may account for some of the perceived leakage the center. in transfer programs when such programs are assessed using means tests or other information that external agents can observe. The literature in this area is sparse, but the evidence suggests that local determination of need may take into account variables not observed by the center, pos- sibly creating a divergence in notions of eligibility between the center and localities. In a case study of famine relief efforts in Southern Sudan, Harragin The mechanisms used to (2004) finds that local ideas of how food should be distributed differed identify beneficiaries are from the ideas of aid workers, resulting in a poorly designed project. crucial in determining how Ethnographic and case study evidence supports the view that the mech- pro-poor decentralized anisms used to identify beneficiaries are crucial in determining how targeting will be, especially pro-poor decentralized targeting will be, especially when community when community members members have unequal access to project implementers. have unequal access to Alatas and others (2012) report on a field experiment designed to project implementers. understand how community methods fare relative to a proxy means test in targeting resources to the poor.7 They collected proxy means test information for all households in all sample villages, randomly varying its use in assigning eligibility. In a third of sample villages, only the proxy means test was used to assign eligibility; in another third, 167
  • 188. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? beneficiaries were selected through a community ranking exercise; in another third, the proxy means test was used to determine eligibility of people identified by the community. The authors find very little support for the benefits of community targeting over the proxy means test when poverty status is measured based on per capita expenditures. This find- ing is somewhat surprising given the substantial leakage and exclusion that can occur under even the best-designed proxy means test. One would expect that in very small communities like the ones the authors worked with, access to relevant information on recent shocks might at least improve coverage of the eligible based on per capita consumption. Meetings confined to the The authors also fi nd no evidence that meetings confi ned to the village elite may not produce village elite produced worse targeting outcomes than meetings that worse targeting outcomes included a more representative group. Furthermore, households more than meetings that include a closely connected to elites were not more likely to benefit when meetings more representative group. were confined to elites. Despite poorer targeting outcomes, community targeting resulted in higher satisfaction levels. Alatas and others (2012) use data on poverty perceptions to make sense of these results. They check the correlation of a household’s sub- jective ranking of itself and other households against rankings from the community targeting exercise and the proxy means test. They find a higher correlation of self-perception with the rankings obtained under community targeting. Taken together, they argue, their results suggest that communities employ a concept of poverty that is different from per capita expenditure and that this difference explains the ostensibly worse performance of community targeting. As communities use different cri- teria to ascribe poverty status, they contend, it is understandable that a strategy that valorizes their preferences yields greater satisfaction levels. Gugerty and Kremer (2006) also find that the women’s groups they study in Kenya reported more satisfaction with group leadership. There was little improvement in objective measures of group activity, however, and the women did not have better attendance rates than the comparison groups. Although these results are interesting, it is difficult to know how to assess their validity. In the study by Alatas and others (2012), for example, the treatment provided a one-time transfer that was a little less than a third of the monthly transfer received by eligible households under the Indonesian government’s main transfer program, the Bantuan Langsung Tunai (BLT), potentially limiting the gains from capture. Equally important, aware that this was a small study and distinct from 168
  • 189. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? the BLT, village elites and government administrators may have found Much of the evidence from it opportune to demonstrate transparency. The careful design of the studies of large-scale transfer community-based targeting meeting, along with the very small and programs points to substantial relatively homogeneous subvillages or neighborhoods that were selected heterogeneity in the manner for the study, may also have affected the results. Much of the evidence in which community input is from studies of large-scale transfer programs, including programs in solicited and to significant Indonesia, points to substantial heterogeneity in the manner in which capture of funds. community input is solicited and to significant capture of funds (see chapter 4). Central versus Local Targeting of Public Goods Several studies of social funds find pro-poor geographic targeting by the center in allocating local public goods. Some, however, find weaker central capacity to target the poor within eligible areas. Chase and Sherburne-Benz (2001) and Pradhan and Rawlings (2002), for example, find that investments made under the Zambia social fund (ZAMSIF) and the Nicaragua social fund were generally well targeted to both poor communities and poor households. In Zambia, however, targeting was effective only in rural communities; in urban areas, better-off com- munities and households were selected. A review of social fund projects by the World Bank’s Independent Evaluation Group (2002) also finds this bias. Araujo and others (2008) find that geographic targeting at the level of the community appears to have worked well in Ecuador’s social fund, with poorer communities more likely to be selected for subproject funding. Paxson and Schady (2002) assess the poverty targeting of the Several studies of social funds Peruvian social fund using district-level data on expenditures and pov- find pro-poor geographic erty. They find that the fund, which emphasized geographic targeting, targeting by the center . . . reached the poorest districts but not the poorest households in those districts: better-off households were slightly more likely than poor households to benefit. Using propensity score matching techniques, Chase (2002) fi nds similar results in Armenia. Although the social fund was successful in targeting communities with the poorest infra- structure, these communities were not always among the poorest, and the fund was slightly regressive in targeting households in rural areas. De Janvry, Nakagawa, and Sadoulet (2009) explore the relationship . . . but some find weaker between decentralization and pro-poor targeting within districts under central capacity to target the the third phase of ZAMSIF. Districts were grouped into three categories poor within eligible areas. 169
  • 190. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? based on administrative capacity. In districts with the lowest capacity, targeting remained fully centralized. Districts with greater capacity were given progressively more control over resources, culminating in full decentralization of decision making for some. Decentralization did not affect the allocation of funds across dis- tricts, but it did affect a district’s capacity to allocate resources across its wards. Using two measures of welfare (school enrollment and an index of housing conditions), the authors find that the center’s target- ing of districts was not progressive—and was even somewhat regres- sive in some phases. In contrast, the within-district targeting of wards became more progressive over time in all districts, especially districts given greater discretion. A caveat regarding these results is that the districts that had greater discretion over resource allocation decisions also had greater managerial capacity. It is unclear, therefore, whether more progressive targeting in these districts reflected greater decen- tralization or greater capacity. Interestingly, within-district effects in the higher-capacity districts were driven almost entirely by wards with high literacy levels. A study in Tanzania finds that Baird, McIntosh, and Özler (2009) focus on the process by which demand-driven application Tanzania’s Social Action Fund (TASAF) allocated subprojects within processes were strongly districts. Using administrative data on project submission and approval, regressive. they find that the demand-driven application process was strongly regressive, with many more applications originating from wealthier and more literate districts. The political affiliation of ward and district representatives also influenced the allocation of TASAF money. Wards that were aligned with the party in power were significantly more likely to apply; wards in which both the ward and the district representatives were from the opposition party were significantly less likely to apply. Ironically, a strongly pro-poor allocation of district-level budgets from the center managed to undo much of this regressivity in applications, leaving a mildly pro-poor program overall, although the poverty reduc- tion objectives of the center were considerably attenuated. Labonne and Chase’s (2009) work on the KALAHI-CIDSS project in the Philippines also provides a good example of the tension between pro-poor targeting and a competitive demand-driven process of sub- project elicitation. As in other community-driven development and social fund projects, facilitators in KALAHI-CIDSS help communities identify priorities and prepare and submit proposals. After review at a municipal-level meeting, a subset of proposed projects is funded. 170
  • 191. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? In the study, respondents were asked to name the three most press- ing issues in the village before any project activities got under way. Combining these data with administrative data on projects proposed and accepted, the authors assessed whether the preferences of spe- cific groups mattered at the project proposal and acceptance stage. Consistent with other studies, they find that the competitive subproject proposal and approval process led to fewer applications from poorer and less politically connected villages. In addition, while the village leader’s preferences on both project type and location appeared to be influential in determining which projects were put forward, these preferences were much less likely to sway the outcome at the municipal level. In fact, as in Tanzania, municipal allocation rules undid some of the regressivity in proposed projects. Given the initial bias in proposed projects, however, municipal allocation rules had limited success, and funded proposals remained well aligned with the village leader’s preferences. The influ- ence of the village leader was much greater in villages with greater wealth inequality. Controlling for poverty, more unequal villages were also more likely to have their projects approved, indicating that local leaders in more unequal villages may also exercise greater influence over the inter-village approval process. As discussed above, China’s Di Bao program (Ravallion 2009a) sug- The poorest communities may gests that the poorest communities may underparticipate or self-select underparticipate or self-select out of programs that require them to foot part of the bill for private out of programs that require benefits or local public goods. This tendency may partly account for them to foot part of the bill the lack of applications from poorer districts and wards in the TASAF for private benefits or local program. A key similarity between the two programs is that eligibility public goods. criteria are decentralized and a portion of the funds come from the center, which progressively targets poorer localities (districts in TASAF and municipalities in Di Bao). Under TASAF, participation by poorer districts is depressed at the application stage, whereas under Di Bao, municipalities have an incentive to depress their participation rates in the program in the face of budget constraints. In both cases, the net effect is that despite progressive targeting from the center, the overall poverty impact of the program is attenuated. Chase (2002) also argues that mandatory community contributions in the Armenia Social Fund may have led to a selection bias against the poorest communities, which are often unwilling or unable to contribute. In the TASAF and ZAMSIF studies, weak community capacity also appears to be a deterrent to participation. Unlike the Di Bao program, 171
  • 192. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? wealthier districts in TASAF or KALAHI-CIDSS were also not able to target their own poor better than poorer districts, suggesting greater capture of program benefits by the relatively well off. Sustainable Management of Common-Pool Resources Institutions for local resource Local institutions for resource governance have increased substantially governance have increased over the past two decades, at least in numbers, as national governments substantially over the past two have created new institutional arrangements to engage local popula- decades . . . tions in the governance of natural resources (Stern, Dietz, and Ostrom 2003). Estimates place the share of the world’s natural forests officially managed with some form of popular participation at about 12 percent (Sunderlin, Hatcher, and Liddle 2008)—and this figure probably sig- nificantly underestimates the actual figure, as it excludes forests that are officially managed by the state but actually managed by local communi- ties and private individuals. . . . accompanied by a This expansion has been accompanied by a more enfranchising more enfranchising view view of decentralized natural resource management, which represents of decentralized natural a major shift from the past. Historically, popular participation in the resource management, which management of natural resources was closely associated with colonial represents a major shift efforts to extend control over local resources. In the case of forests, an from the past. expansion in local participation under colonial rule was precipitated by industrialization and higher prices for timber and other forest products. In the case of water for irrigation, local participation increased when colonial governments made large investments in irrigation infrastruc- ture, which also created greater management needs.8 Many newly inde- pendent nations chose to reverse this process, initially, by recentralizing and consolidating power at the center. Decentralization efforts around natural resource management gained momentum in development policy circles only in the 1970s, largely under outside pressure from international aid organizations and donors, motivated by both concerns about the accountability of central govern- ments and recognition of resource depletion and climate change.9 By the 1980s, decentralized natural resource management had come to be associated with the broader project of poverty reduction10 and the build- ing of democratic local institutions (Ribot, Lund, and Treue 2010).11 The push for localizing natural resource management has thus paral- leled the broader move toward participatory development over the past 172
  • 193. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? two decades. A large body of literature, based largely on case studies, Community management of has been extremely influential in this process. It has established the common-pool resources has pervasive presence of local institutions in the management of natural come to be seen as a viable resources, with or without state support, and demonstrated the viability alternative to privatization or of community management as an alternative to either privatization or management by a centralized management by a centralized state bureaucracy.12 state bureaucracy. In practice, the local management of common-pool resources takes many institutional forms, and there is often substantial divergence between formal and de facto community control as well as the types of decision making transferred to local governments or user communities. The extent and type of central government involvement also varies a great deal with the value placed on the resource. The scale of national and international interest in a common-pool resource also depends on the size of the externality it creates. With forests, the interests of the global community can also be relevant; they can determine the form of management as well as the allocation of benefits. In contrast, in the case of irrigation water or pastures, the main concerns are likely to be capture by insiders and local incentives and capacity to maintain the resource base. It is important to distinguish community-based natural resource management (CBNRM) and decentralization. Like community-driven development, CBNRM refers to the direct or indirect involvement of local communities at a relatively small scale to shape the use, distribu- tion, and management of resources. Democratic decentralization— under which local representative authorities receive powers in the name of local citizens—can be considered a manifestation of CBNRM, but the devolution of powers to user groups, chiefs, NGOs, private corporations, or private individuals is not decentralization. Likewise, transfers to local line ministries (that is, deconcentration) is not a form of CBNRM.13 These distinctions are borne in mind in the literature review pre- sented in this chapter. The review is selective, with a focus on the fol- lowing questions: When does community engagement in resource man- agement enhance resource sustainability (regenerated forests, increased forest cover, more sustainable fish and livestock harvesting, better water storage and use systems)? Is local management more inclusive and more equitable than central management or an unmanaged commons? In each case, to what extent is success shaped or constrained by preexisting community characteristics? Can local management systems be designed 173
  • 194. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? to overcome adverse local characteristics—that is, can design induce the right type and level of participation? How dependent is success on the role played by the central state? The literature on community involvement in the management of natural resources is large and multidisciplinary, but most of it is based on case studies. Well-done case studies can add greatly to the under- standing of processes; they are often less helpful, however, in establish- ing causal relationships between the structural features of communities, the institutions of governance established within them, and their impact on measures of system performance. The few research studies that use large datasets and attempt to deal with problems of selection into com- munity management, are therefore highlighted in the discussion below. Local Management and Resource Sustainability Much of the literature on CBNRM and decentralized resource man- agement focuses on the conditions under which the commons can be better governed—that is, the conditions under which community participation leads to greater resource sustainability (see, for example, Wade 1985; Ostrom 1990; Baland and Platteau 1997). This focus is in large part driven by Hardin’s concerns about the fate of an unregu- lated commons. Many case studies suggest the viability of community management of natural resources with or without state assistance (see Agrawal and Benson 2010 for a review). The verdict on government- initiated institutions for community resource management has been bleaker.14 Several studies based on large However, several studies that use large data sets to examine the impact of data sets suggest that it may government-initiated institutions of community forest management be possible for governments show that it may be possible for governments to successfully induce to successfully induce natural natural resource management on a large scale. A key point made by resource management on a all of these studies is that there is considerable selection in community large scale. management of natural resources, because community takeover is usu- ally voluntary. Case studies cannot deal with such selection or with spillover effects, which can also bias results considerably. Edmonds (2002) uses data from Nepal to determine the impact on the level of extraction of wood for fuel of a government-initiated program that transferred management of forests to local user groups. The evidence suggests that there was a significant reduction in wood extraction in areas with forest user groups.15 174
  • 195. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Somanathan, Prabhakar, and Singh (2005) assess the impact of local forest councils (van panchayats [VPs]) on forest degradation in the Indian state of Uttaranchal. Unlike Edmonds, they use satellite-based measures of forest quality (principally predictors of canopy cover) over a large geographical region that included VP and non VP forests in Uttaranchal. This methodology circumvents the problem of using com- munity reported measures of local forest quality. The authors assess the long-run impact of decentralized management by village councils on forest stocks. Their study is also the only one that compares the cost of state and community management.16 The results indicate that broadleaved forests, which are of much greater A study of India suggests that relevance for local use, improved significantly under VP management but community management of that there was no improvement in pine forests (VP–managed pine forests state forests would generate did no worse than comparable state-managed forests). At the same time, annual savings equal to community management was far more cost effective than state manage- the value of total annual ment. The authors’ calculations suggest that transferring state forests to production of firewood from community management would generate annual savings equal to the state forests. value of the total annual production of firewood from state forests. Baland and others (2010) also assess the impact of VPs on forest degradation in Uttaranchal, using a wider set of measures of forest qual- ity. They find that VP management improved the extraction of wood for fuel and fodder but did not lead to broader improvements in forest quality, such as canopy cover or forest regeneration. Their results indicate that VPs had little impact on tree-cutting or timber extraction, which may be a much greater source of forest degradation than the extraction of wood for fuel and fodder. However, the improvement that did occur was not at the cost of neighboring non VP forest parcels.17 Their findings suggest that community management is often a response to the degrada- tion of local forests. If this is the case, then any simple comparison of community-managed forests with forests managed by the state, or not managed at all, will tend to show no or even negative impact, as Agrawal and Chhatre find in their study of the Indian Himalayas (2006). The impact of inequality on collective action has been at the center of a number of theoretical and empirical studies of management by communities or users, particularly in the fisheries sector and in the management of irrigation. It has also been an important focus in the case study literature on common-pool resource management. Ostrom, Lam, and Lee (1994) and Ostrom (1990) show that farmer-managed irrigation schemes have more equitable water distribution, for example, 175
  • 196. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? but they do not compare the functioning of farmer-managed systems in more and less equal communities. Maintenance of irrigation Studies that look explicitly at the impact of local inequality on the systems tends to be maintenance of irrigation systems find by and large that maintenance worse in more unequal is worse in more unequal communities. Dayton-Johnson (2000) devel- and heterogeneous ops a model of cooperation in small irrigation systems, which he tests communities . . . with data from a survey of Mexican irrigation societies. He finds that social heterogeneity and landholding inequality are consistently and sig- nificantly associated with lower levels of maintenance. Bardhan (2000) finds similar results in South India. Dayton-Johnson and Bardhan (2002) attempt to reconcile views from the field study literature with Olson’s (1965) view that inequality should be good for collective action. Their study pulls together data from a number of irrigation systems, including three large-scale studies from Nepal, southern India, and central Mexico. Overall, the findings suggest that however it is defined, heterogeneity weakens a group’s abil- ity to use social norms to enforce collective agreements and generally has a negative impact on cooperation. Moreover, even after controlling for social heterogeneity, inequality in the distribution of wealth con- tinues to exercise a significant and largely negative effect. The authors conclude that although “Olson effects” are theoretically plausible under certain conditions, they do not seem to be operative in the irrigation systems they examine. They do fi nd some evidence for a U-shaped relationship between inequality and collective action, with conservation possible only when inequality is very low or very high, not in between. In a similar vein, Bardhan, Ghatak, and Karaivanov (2007) show that when private inputs, such as land, are complementary in production with collective inputs, such as irrigation water, inequality in the owner- ship of private inputs tends to worsen maintenance. . . . but adequate local A number of studies note, however, that adequate local discretion discretion may be able can overcome problems created by inequalities among resource users. to overcome problems Adhikari and Lovett (2006) use data from forest user groups in Nepal created by inequality among to argue that successful collective action can be achieved even when resource users. inequalities among resource users exist, provided that communities can A great deal of forest exercise discretion in creating institutions for resource management. conservation and regeneration A number of other case studies of forestry management highlight the has been achieved under same point. Hobley (1996) finds that in some states in India, as well as community management in in Nepal, a great deal of forest conservation and regeneration has been Nepal and some Indian states. achieved under community management. Adhikari and Lovett (2006) 176
  • 197. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? and Hobley (1996) report on cases in which user communities were able to exercise substantial discretion and had clear incentives to manage and preserve the resource. In Africa, accounts of failure far outnumber accounts of success, Donor-supported projects except in Cameroon, Malawi, and Tanzania. Ribot, Lund, and Treue often fail to empower local (2010), who review a large number of case studies, blame this failure on bodies, relying instead on weak local governments and poorly thought-out donor programs. They disenfranchising colonial note that donor-supported projects often fail to empower representative practices oriented toward and downwardly accountable local bodies, relying instead on disenfran- extraction and control. chising colonial practices oriented toward extraction and control (see also Ribot 2007; Ribot, Chhatre, and Lankina 2008). These results suggest that successful collective action requires the Successful collective action establishment of clear and credible systems of accountability and that requires the establishment such rules may not be forthcoming in unequal communities, creat- of clear and credible systems ing a space for central effort in setting the rules of the game. Dayton- of accountability, which may Johnson and Bardhan’s (2002) analysis provides an important not be forthcoming in unequal insight. They note that heterogeneity affects not just the extent communities. of cooperation, given a set of rules, but the type of rules chosen. Furthermore, not all rules are equally conducive to good performance or equity, and unequal communities are less likely to pick effective and equitable rules. When externalities are Ribot (2004) notes that when externalities are significant, it is par- significant, it is particularly ticularly important that standards and rules be set at a higher level. If, important that standards and for example, conversion is forbidden as a precondition for local control rules be set at a higher level. of the forests, incentives may need to be put in place that link conser- vation with livelihoods. In the absence of such incentives, there is no inherent reason to believe that local people will not sell off or convert forests if doing so is the most lucrative option. In much of Africa, the devolution of responsibilities Is Local Management More Equitable? to communities has been mainly about maintaining Community management is expected to satisfy the twin goals of attain- opportunities for rent- ing resource sustainability and increasing equity in the distribution of seeking or ensuring resource benefits. But these objectives are not necessarily complementary. Ribot, sustainability for the benefit Lund, and Treue (2010) argue that in much of Africa, the devolution of higher-level groups or of responsibilities to communities has been mainly about maintaining international interests . . . opportunities for rent-seeking or ensuring resource sustainability for the benefit of higher-level national groups or international interests, with . . . with the costs borne the costs borne mainly by local inhabitants. mainly by local inhabitants. 177
  • 198. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? When local structures are not Several other studies also suggest that decentralization can create accountable to communities, perverse outcomes for the poorest and most vulnerable groups when decentralization can local structures are not accountable to communities. In India, Kumar create perverse outcomes (2002) reports that the joint management of Sal (Shorea robusta) forests for the poorest and most has, if anything, deepened poverty because, despite community partici- vulnerable groups. pation in the management of these forests, the emphasis has remained on high forests and timber production, which originated under colonial rule as an aspect of “scientific forestry.” As the forest canopy closes, however, nonwood forest products, which are of particular importance for the poor, decline, deepening poverty. In Tanzania, Lund and Treue (2008) fi nd that the taxation and licensing system for the production of timber and charcoal that was introduced under decentralized forest management has created new entry barriers for the poorest producers, making them more dependent on town-based traders and village leaders. Wood (1999) argues that larger farmers in the more backward state of Bihar in India routinely negotiate preferential access to irrigation systems by paying bribes to local officials. The poor may have greater The poor are often more dependent than the nonpoor on access to motivation to maintain natural resources. Jodha (1986, 2001) estimates that 15–25 percent of resources such as forests the incomes of the rural poor in India comes from natural resources. In or pastures, because they their survey of a large number of studies of India and West Africa, Beck depend on them for a larger and Nesmith (2001) also find higher levels of reliance on common-pool share of their income. resources among the landless poor. Gregerson and Contreras (1989) estimate that more than a third of the world’s population relies on local forests to meet basic household needs. Studies also indicate that the relatively better-off tend to benefit more from common-pool resources, although the poor are far more dependent on such resources (that is, the share of forest income in their total income is higher), perhaps indicating some scope for redistribution (Cavendish 2000; Campbell 2003; Fisher 2004; Narain, Gupta, and Van’t Veld 2005; Lund and Treue 2008). The products the poor derive from the forest—fuel, water, fodder, and food—also have few affordable market alternatives and thus also constitute an important safety net (Pattanayak and Sills 2001; McSweeney 2005). As a result, some researchers argue that poorer members of a community may have a greater motivation to maintain resources such as forests or pastures, given the right set of incentives, as the risk-adjusted return to doing so may be higher for them. In practice, however, rules regarding access and fees are rarely changed when management becomes more local. One reason is that 178
  • 199. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? the poor, who rely the most on the forest, are often also a minority In practice, however, local group whose interests do not coincide with those of village leaders or management seems to the village majority. The choice of local institutions and the rules regu- disproportionately benefit lating such institutions are set by higher-level institutions that reflect a the rich, powerful, and well multitude of values and interests, ranging from concerns with resource connected. sustainability, biodiversity, and carbon storage to the desire for a strate- gic political advantage or enhanced opportunities for rent-seeking. The choices these institutions make are influenced by national elites as well as a host of international interests, including bilateral and multilateral donors (Ferguson 1996; Blaikie 2006; Ribot, Lund, and Treue 2010). As a result, policies originally designed to favor elites under colonial structures are often maintained, even when countries officially promote popular participation in natural resource management. Mustalahti and Lund (2010), for example, find that despite official policies supporting community participation in forestry in the Lao People’s Democratic Republic, Mozambique, and Tanzania, local communities were sys- tematically prevented from sharing in the returns from commercially valuable forest resources. A number of other studies raise similar con- cerns regarding the disproportionate advantages obtained by the rich, powerful, and well connected (see, for example, Ribot 1995; Larson and Ribot 2007; Lund and Treue 2008). Beck and Nesmith’s (2001) review suggests that a process of pro- Unless management regimes gressive exclusion of the poor from natural resource–based livelihood are specifically designed sources may be underway even where conservation has been success- to include poor people, ful, as in India and Tanzania. They caution that unless management community-based natural regimes are specifically designed to include poor people, CBNRM may resource management may end up as little more than donor- supported control by elites. Dasgupta end up as little more than and Mäler (1995) illustrates how this cycle can lead to an environmental donor-supported control by poverty trap. Nerlove (1991) shows that increasing rates of deforesta- elites. tion may lead to greater population growth and even faster rates of deforestation. Several studies caution against assuming that the introduction of simple participatory mechanisms can ensure downward accountability in the absence of clear mechanisms for ensuring compliance. Two case studies from Tanzania and Senegal are illustrative. Lund (2007) reports that a new requirement in Tanzania that elected forest committee mem- bers provide oral accounts of all forest-related incomes and expenditures at quarterly village assemblies led to greater equity in the distribution of forest-related incomes. However, as Ribot, Lund, and Treue (2010) note, such simple changes in rules, though powerful, may work only 179
  • 200. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Without credible sanctions, when there is clear support from higher tiers of government and com- community members have mensurate mechanisms to sanction local leaders are in place. They note no ability or capacity to that in the Tanzanian case, a watchful donor and an involved district monitor corrupt officials, council and forest office provided this support. In contrast, they note who know that allegations that in Senegal, which lacked such support, community members had of misappropriation can no ability or capacity to monitor corrupt officials, who knew that alle- be denied or ignored with gations of misappropriation could be denied or ignored with impunity. impunity. Common-pool resources also vary widely in their potential impact on livelihoods and in the number of actors at various levels who have a stake in their use, conservation, and regeneration. Forests, for example, can generate tremendous value at the local and national level, but forest preservation and regeneration often yield large positive externalities at the global level. In contrast, the returns to small irrigation schemes are plausibly confined to a limited number of local actors. Communities that live in or near specific natural resources can therefore face very different incentives to engage, individually or collectively, in efforts to preserve or restore the resource base. Local governments or The question of who benefits from forest land is an important case community user groups are in point. A common issue highlighted in the literature is that local gov- often given management ernments or community user groups are often given management rights rights over forests that have over forests that have few livelihood improvement opportunities. In few livelihood improvement contrast, private interests or the central state control productive forests. opportunities . . . Even in countries like Tanzania, where there is significant decentralized forest management, most joint forest management agreements have . . . leaving them with the been made in relation to the montane rainforests, where laws prohibit largely unfunded costs of use in order to maintain national and international biodiversity. Where management and with little by productive forests are under joint management, by village councils or way of returns. community-based groups, they either yield low-value nontimber forest products for subsistence use (Topp-Jorgensen and others 2005; Meshack and others 2006) or are degraded or of low value with little by way of immediate livelihood opportunities, at least in the short run (Lund 2007; Mustalahti and Lund 2010). The result is that local communities are often required to bear the largely unfunded costs of management and with little by way of returns. There are also issues about what constitutes the “community,” as the case of people who live on the borders of forests demonstrates. On the one hand, living near a forest can leave them more vulnerable to crop damage and livestock losses from protected forest wildlife. On the other hand, they can be restricted in expanding their farmland if the forest 180
  • 201. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? border becomes “hard” (Lund and Treue 2008). Similar issues arise for pastoralist and agro-pastoralist groups, who are often not represented in community user groups or local councils. Several studies question the assumption underlying the move toward The existence of viable CBNRM—namely, that viable and well-functioning local institutions local institutions cannot be exist to which decision-making power simply needs to be transferred. assumed. Such institutions They argue that CBNRM is in the main a process of creating the need to be created through necessary institutional structures at the local level, to which specific deliberate effort. responsibilities can then be devolved. Although these new institutions may be based on historical forms, the creation of accountable institu- tions at the local level implies a much greater involvement of the state in resource governance arrangements. Thus, even where communities and local groups have long-standing rights to manage local resources, such rights require at least the implicit if not explicit sanction of the state. For resources that are deemed valuable—such as timber and fish—local rights typically exist as a result of explicit actions by government and state agencies (Ribot, Lund, and Treue 2010; Agrawal 2010). Agrawal (2010) notes that of the 400 million hectares of tropical forests currently under formal community control, more than half was transferred to community management in the past quarter century. Fujiie, Hayami, and Kikuchi (2005) look at the creation of irrigation association groups in the Philippines, which were formed as part of the broader decentral- ization process. They find that only 20 percent of the irrigation associa- tion groups included in their study had communal irrigation systems in existence before the National Irrigation Authority got involved (see also Mosse 2005 on India and Wilder and Lankao 2006 on Mexico). State intervention thus seems to determine the impact of participa- State intervention seems tion on natural resource management, equity, and local livelihoods, to determine the impact much as it does for other programs or reform processes that induce of participation on natural greater local participation. The distribution of responsibilities and resource management, equity, resources between the center and the locality as well as the mandate and local livelihoods. local citizens have to protect, improve, monitor, and benefit from the natural resource are critical. Baird (2006) highlights another significant issue: the impact of donor and government reporting requirements and incentive structures on the quality of local management. The central government in Lao PDR pro- vided incentives to provinces to expand aquaculture ponds but not fish sanctuaries. In response, provinces met the central government’s quota by reporting fish sanctuaries as aquaculture ponds. Similarly, irrigation 181
  • 202. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? reports in India provided by local officials to higher levels often inflate the areas covered by irrigation in order to “meet” targets (Wood 1999). Communities and local Communities and local governments can obtain significant indirect governments can obtain benefits if more effective management of the common-pool resource significant benefits if more increases public revenues for local investment. Ribot, Lund, and effective management of Treue (2010) argue that such benefits can provide the right incentives the common-pool resource for conservation when management of the forest itself is unlikely to increases public revenues for be a lucrative venture. They argue that revenue raising is one of the local investment. most prominent outcomes of decentralized forest management in Africa. In Uganda, for example, local governments are entitled to keep 40 percent of the revenues from the management of national forest reserves (Muhereza 2006; Turyahabwe and others 2007), even though they are effectively sidelined as far as management of these reserves goes. Revenues have also increased substantially for rural communities in Cameroon and Tanzania in community forestry areas (Oyono and Efoua 2006; Oyono and Nzuzi 2006; Lund 2007). These funds are used to cover the direct costs of forest management as well as to fund public infrastructure and services such as roads, schools, and health clinics (Ribot, Lund, and Treue 2010), or to provide micro loans, as in Nepal (Pokharel 2009). Participation and the Quality of Local Infrastructure Participatory development programs usually invest a good deal in build- ing community infrastructure. The argument for doing so is twofold. First, lack of adequate infrastructure—connector roads, wholesale mar- kets, irrigation channels, electricity, school buildings, sanitation, and the like—significantly constrains prospects for development, and this lack is far more acute in the poorest communities. Second, it is expected that devolving responsibility to the local level will produce projects that are not only better aligned with the preferences and needs of final users, but are also of higher quality, and more likely to be well maintained. Ideally, participatory programs are expected to work with commu- nities to ensure need, feasibility, and adequacy of scale; to monitor the project over the construction cycle; and to create systems for project maintenance. Most programs require some form of community co- financing as a mechanism for inducing greater community engagement and “ownership” of the project. Some also require upfront community commitment of resources for project maintenance. Many participatory 182
  • 203. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? projects also restrict the menu of feasible subprojects, either overtly or de Competition in the project facto, to a small set of public goods (typically roads, culverts, and drain- selection process is intended age systems; drinking water and sanitation facilities; and schools, and to weed out bad projects and clinics). Although this appears to be contradictory to a demand-driven encourage communities to process of project selection, in practice, it may serve to restrict choice to align projects with program a small set of public goods that communities are better able to maintain objectives. or where the opportunities for capture are limited.18 Competition in the project selection process is also intended to weed out bad projects and to encourage communities to put in the requisite effort to align the proposed project with program objectives. How successful are these efforts? Does local provision create infra- structure that is better designed, better constructed, and better main- tained? Does this imply less capture? Are projects of better quality than similar types of infrastructure created by central line departments? How important are community characteristics such as wealth inequality, eth- nic heterogeneity, remoteness, and low levels of education or poverty? Can the right incentives (such as interjurisdictional competition for funds) or the right investments (such as community capacity building) mitigate the impact of potentially negative community characteristics? Specifically, can local provision create “good” projects in “bad” com- munities, and do the poor gain as a result? The following subsections present the evidence on these questions. Bottom-up versus Top-down Given the resources allocated to social funds of various types, surpris- ingly few studies compare the relative performance of subprojects built by local governments or community groups and subprojects built by central line departments. Even fewer simultaneously address the ques- tion of infrastructure quality and the distribution of benefits. Yet it is far from clear that benefits, even from well-designed and constructed projects, are more equitably distributed. The first study to carefully assess this question used data from 132 infrastructure projects in 99 randomly selected rural communi- ties across northern Pakistan, where the Agha Khan Rural Support Program (AKRSP) has promoted participatory rural development for more than 30 years. Khwaja (2004, 2009) compares infrastructure projects provided by the community, with AKRSP support, with similar projects provided by government line departments. His research yields three interesting findings. First, community engagement, with AKRSP 183
  • 204. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Community facilitation, substantially improved project maintenance (the main engagement in Pakistan outcome of interest) but only when participation was confined to the substantially improved project nontechnical aspects of the project. When communities got involved in maintenance . . . technical project decisions, participation was detrimental. The intuition behind this claim is that decisions requiring local information are more . . . but only when likely to be sensitive to the community’s investment, whereas decisions participation was confined that require technical information should be more responsive to the to the nontechnical aspects external agency’s investment. Second, communities were less able to of the project. Community maintain projects that were technically complex or new.19 They did involvement in technical better when preexisting projects were refurbished or the project selected decisions was detrimental. was one in which they had previous experience. Third, inequality in the incidence of project benefits (across both participatory and government provided projects) has a U-shaped effect on maintenance. As inequlity in the distribution of project benefits increases, maintenance levels first fall then rise.20 As Khwaja notes, under perfect inequality in the distri- bution of benefits, the project is effectively privatized, and maintenance no longer requires any coordination. 21 This U-shaped relationship between inequality and project maintenance is similar to the tradeoff between resource sustainability and wealth inequality in the literature on common pool resources. Mansuri (2012a) uses data from the three largest provinces of Pakistan to provide further insights on the relationship between partici- pation and project quality. Her study combines administrative, census, and survey data from 230 infrastructure projects in 80 villages.22 About half of the projects were constructed by government line departments; while the rest were built by the community with support from the National Rural Support Program (NRSP).23 The study assesses two aspects of project quality: design and construction, and current condi- tion and maintenance. The first aspect, provides evidence of capture, in the narrow sense of theft and corruption, in construction, while the second reflects a communities’ capacity for coordination and is therefore more comparable with Khwaja’s (2004, 2009) work. Compared with the northern areas, the rest of Pakistan has far greater levels of local inequality and ethnic heterogeneity. Land owner- ship, which is almost entirely hereditary, is extremely skewed, with the top 5 percent of landowners owning more than 40 percent of all land while more than half of rural households are landless. The caste (zaat) structure is also extremely hierarchical. Given these features, Mansuri’s findings are encouraging. 184
  • 205. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Mansuri finds that participatory projects in the study villages appear The scope for outright to be better designed and constructed than comparable projects deliv- rent-seeking through the ered by government line departments and the effects are economically diversion of project funds was large. This finding suggests that the scope for outright rent-seeking considerably muted when through the diversion of project funds can be considerably muted infrastructure in Pakistan when infrastructure is provided with community engagement. NRSP- was provided with community supported projects are also better maintained, in line with the evidence engagement. . . . provided by Khwaja (2009). This may be due, at least in part, to NRSP’s (and AKRSP’s) approach to project maintenance. Maintenance costs . . . but benefits were no are built into project costs at the proposal stage and although the com- better distributed than in munity is entirely responsible for project maintenance postconstruc- projects directed from the tion, NRSP (and AKRSP) continue to provide technical assistance as center. needed. This is very much in line with the following discussion on the importance of building community capacity to undertake resource management. That said, project quality alone can reveal only so much about cap- ture. If project benefits are effectively privatized at the local level, there may be little incentive to engage in the type of rent-seeking that could reduce the quality of project construction. The results here are far less encouraging. As discussed in chapter 4, Mansuri (2012b) finds that benefits from the participatory project are no better distributed than benefits from the relevant government project. In both types of projects, the share of the landless, the poor, and people from low castes was far below their share in the population. Can “Good” Programs Compensate for “Bad” Communities? An important premise in the literature on participatory programs is that Well-designed participatory well designed and implemented projects can overcome adverse commu- efforts can overcome the nity characteristics. Specifically, that the challenge to collective action negative effects of wealth posed by local inequality, ethnic divides, and exclusionary practices inequality and community of various types, can be overcome by inducing participation through heterogeneity to a large a well-implemented program. Khwaja’s (2009) analysis provides an degree. encouraging assessment. Project characteristics, which include the participatory delivery mechanism facilitated by AKRSP, significantly outweigh community characteristics, suggesting that well-designed participatory efforts can, to a large degree, overcome the negative effects of wealth inequality and community heterogeneity. The study also finds that the quality of local leadership matters: projects in communities 185
  • 206. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? in the northern areas of Pakistan that had more educated leaders, and leaders who were actively engaged in community affairs, were better maintained.24 Mansuri (2012a) finds that after controlling for participation (that is, facilitation by the NRSP), inequality does not affect project mainte- nance much. However, projects were far better maintained in commu- nities with above average levels of schooling. The impact of inequality on construction quality is different, however. The quality of construc- tion of NRSP-supported projects worsens significantly in villages that are more unequal, and this effect is amplified when projects are also more technically complex or are built on older preexisting (usually government-provided) projects. The study thus shows that although participation appears to dampen opportunities for rent-seeking, greater effort is required to ensure the quality of projects in more unequal communities. A number of large participatory development programs use some form of interjurisdictional competition to improve community incen- tives to allocate funds in a more transparent and equitable manner. Grant funds from the central government can also induce competition across localities if they are tied to the achievement of specific outcomes, reform processes, and so forth. In more competitive Chavis (2009) is perhaps the only study that has looked at the impact subdistricts in Indonesia, the of competition on the quality of infrastructure subprojects. The study set of projects submitted and used administrative data from the Indonesian Kecamatan Development funded had larger community Program (KDP), funded by the World Bank. Like other community- contributions, a more pro-poor driven development programs, KDP involves communities in the allo- allocation of project benefits, cation of funds for the construction of local public goods. In the KDP, and lower unit costs. each funded kecamatan (subdistrict) receives a block grant, based on population. The grants are allocated at the village level by a competitive process of project selection that is managed by an intervillage council with representation from each village. As a result, subdistricts with more villages face a greater competition for funds. Chavis proposes that this competitive pressure is plausibly exogenous and that it changes the pro- cess by which the block grant is allocated, inducing greater compliance with KDP rules and thus higher-quality projects in more competitive subdistricts.25 He tests this hypothesis using administrative data on more than 3,000 road project proposals received in a single year (road projects typically account for almost half of all KDP subproject funds). The results indicate that in more competitive subdistricts, the set of 186
  • 207. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? projects submitted and funded had larger community contributions, a more pro-poor allocation of project benefits, and lower unit costs. A potential limitation of using reported unit costs and distribution of beneficiaries at the time of proposal submission and approval is that there are no independent data against which these claims can be checked. Chavis attempts to overcome this problem by using corrobo- rative evidence from an earlier study by Olken (2007), which shows a considerable amount of overinvoicing of labor and materials in the stated costs of KDP road projects (see discussion in chapter 3). Using data from this study, Chavis confirms that there is also less theft in road projects in more competitive subdistricts, bolstering the finding on lower reported unit road costs in project proposals. Recall, however, that demand-driven application processes can be strongly regressive (see the first section of this chapter). Taken together, these results suggest that high project construction quality and main- tenance do not imply an equitable distribution of resources. There can be a significant trade-off between equity and sustainability. Community Capacity and Project Quality Several of the studies reviewed in the previous sections point to the rel- Lack of community capacity evance of building community capacity for project quality and mainte- is often the key constraint on nance. This section reviews studies that suggest that lack of community project quality. capacity is often the key constraint on project quality. Katz and Sara (1997) cite inadequate technical support from project implementers as one of the key reasons for the failure of water projects in their global review. They note that in the absence of community supervision or management, projects were often left in the hands of private contractors, whose incentives can be suspect. Community mem- bers were unable to make informed choices about the type of project to build, monitor the work of contractors, or maintain projects after they were constructed without adequate training. Isham and Kahkonen (2002) make similar points in their analysis Communities often require of water projects in India, Indonesia, and Sri Lanka. They find that considerable support in communities often require considerable support in understanding the understanding the technical technical aspects of projects. aspects of projects. Newman and others (2002) raise similar concerns in their evalua- tion of the Bolivian social fund. They find that water projects improved water quality only when community-level training was also provided. 187
  • 208. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Water projects in Bolivia They attribute the significant reduction in under-five mortality associ- improved water quality and ated with the provision of health clinics to the fact that investments in access to water only when health went beyond providing infrastructure to providing other neces- community-level training was sary technical inputs as well. In contrast, education projects led to little also provided. change in education outcomes, because no resources were provided beyond the building of schools. Results of an experiment in In a more recent study, Leino (2007) provides further support for Kenya suggest that water this hypothesis from a field experiment in Kenya. The study, which allo- projects are better maintained cated funds for maintenance to a random subset of water management when water management committees, fi nds that water projects were better maintained when committees are given funds to water management committees were given funds to carry out regular carry out regular maintenance. maintenance activities. Very few studies attempt to assess the long-term sustainability of participatory infrastructure projects. Kleemeier (2000) is an exception. She looks at a rural piped water program in Malawi. Only half of the schemes, which were 3–26 years old, were performing well; the rest were performing poorly or had failed entirely. Moreover, the schemes that were in good working condition were either small or new. Kleemeier notes that her findings are an indictment not of the participatory pro- cess itself but of the lack of attention implementers paid to the weak link between communities and external agencies with the requisite technical capacity. Community groups were capable of making small repairs nec- essary to keep water flowing, but they were unable to undertake more substantive preventative maintenance and repairs. In the end, the water department had to send in government-employed monitoring assistants and supervisors to ensure that preventive maintenance was performed. Large donors often support Kleemeier notes that CARE, a large international NGO, was con- communities in the fronted with much the same situation in Indonesia (see also Hodgkin construction of projects . . . and Kusumahadi 1993). Although it supported communities in the construction of projects, it provided little support for postconstruction . . . but provide little support activities. Although small and simple schemes can survive this neglect, for postconstruction activities. larger schemes that require external technical inputs cannot. In a related study, Uphoff (1986) notes that local organizations can be effective only if they have adequate links with political and administrative centers. Community Engagement in Public Service Delivery Much of the effort to improve accountability in the allocation of resources for public services focuses on expanding citizen oversight 188
  • 209. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? and engagement. These efforts have taken a number of forms, ranging If local governments or from the decentralization of service delivery to local governments and participatory programs are the signing of contracts with private providers and NGOs to programs beholden to elites, they may that induce greater community participation in service provision and underprovide some services quality by transferring resources directly to community organizations. and overcharge for the The review of the evidence focuses on outcomes related to improve- services they do provide . . . ments in service quality, as measured by learning, school retention, infant and maternal mortality, and access to services. As Bardhan . . . leaving the poor to bear and Mookherjee (2005) caution, the distributional and welfare con- a disproportionate cost of sequences of decentralized delivery are likely to be as important as the service provision. impact on service quality. In essence, if local governments or participa- tory programs are beholden to local elites, they may overprovide some services and undercharge for the services they do provide, leaving the poor to bear a disproportionate cost of service provision. School-Based Management and the Decentralization of Education The decentralization of education takes many forms. The review here divides the literature broadly into decentralization efforts directed at schools (generally referred to as “school-based management”) and the decentralization of education services to local governments. School-based management is a form of decentralization in which deci- sion making is devolved, either from a central line ministry or a lower-tier government, whether provincial or municipal, to the school or com- munity. As with the devolution of authority in other domains, increased school and community discretion is expected to improve school quality (as measured by student performance and use of the school budget) and enhance satisfaction with the quality of service provision. School-based management typically involves setting up a school management committee or council that includes the school principal, teachers, and members of the school community, in particular parents but also local leaders and other community members. School commit- tees are usually tasked with monitoring school performance and provid- ing oversight on the use of resources. Less frequently, such committees are granted authority over teacher hiring and firing and decisions about the curriculum and the allocation of school budgets. Many developing countries have adopted school-based management programs over the past two decades, often as part of a larger effort to decentralize resource allocation and service delivery. The extent to which resources and decision-making authority are transferred, as well 189
  • 210. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? as the agents to whom authority is transferred, varies widely. There is also a great deal of variation in the extent to which community and par- ent engagement is mandated, the form it takes, and the type of oversight local and higher-level governments provide. Barrera-Osorio and Linden (2009) categorize school-based manage- ment approaches along two dimensions: who has the power to make decisions and the degree of decision making devolved to the school level. They note that “with so many possible combinations of these two dimensions, almost every school-based management reform is unique” (p. 4). Bruns, Filmer, and Patrinos (2011) divide school-based management programs into three broad groups: strong versions, in which school councils have significant authority over both staffing and school bud- gets; intermediate versions, in which school councils have some say in curriculum but very limited authority over resources or staffing deci- sions; and weak versions, in which school councils are largely advisory in nature. They also provide a useful framework for understanding the channels through which school-based management can enhance accountability, highlighting four facets: increasing choice and participa- tion, giving citizens a stronger voice, making information about school performance widely available, and strengthening school level incen- tives for effective service delivery for the poor (see Bruns, Filmer, and Patrinos 2011 for a comprehensive review of school-based management). The review here focuses on evidence for the second channel, insofar as studies can unpack multifaceted interventions to identify the impact of a specific component. In all cases, the decentralization of education is expected to induce greater efficiency in the use of education budgets and create better per- formance incentives for local officials and school staff. The expectation is that decentralization can deliver improvements in a range of schooling outcomes, from enrollment and retention to better student performance on standardized tests, and that it can do so cost-effectively. As with all decentralization efforts, there is the usual set of risks. Programs can be captured, with resources flowing to better-off loca- tions or schools or siphoned off for private use. Local government agents may also lack the capacity to manage funds or make effective decisions regarding resource allocation, staffing, or curriculum. Theory would predict that both types of problems would tend to be worse in com- munities that are poorer, more unequal, or in which citizens are more alienated from the political process. 190
  • 211. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Caldwell (2005) notes that as with broader decentralization efforts, governments have supported school-based management for a variety of reasons. Governments on the left have initiated school management reforms as part of larger efforts to increase community empowerment. Governments on the right have often justified school-based manage- ment on the basis of greater freedom or more choice, which has also been interpreted as an effort to create a market among schools in public education systems. These divergent motives have made school-based management politi- A consensus has been forged cally contentious, with little agreement on what the expected outcomes that the primary purpose of should be. In recent years, however, a consensus has been forged that school-based management the primary purpose of school-based management is the improvement is the improvement of of educational outcomes. With this, evidence on the effects of school- educational outcomes. based management on educational outcomes has also started to emerge. According to Caldwell (2005), early studies were marred by the lack of a clear objective for school-based management as well as by the lack of data. In contrast, what he calls third-generation studies, starting in the late 1990s, look at programs in which improvement in learning outcomes is a central objective and adequate data are available to assess impact. Before examining the evidence, it is useful to point out that few, if any, studies are able to measure the extent or quality of commu- nity engagement or identify its influence on school management. Studies that do attempt to separate out community participation from other aspects of decentralization, such as school autonomy, tend to assume that the level of community or parent participation, usually self-reported, is independent of unobserved community or student characteristics that could influence outcomes. Similar assumptions are made about reported levels of school autonomy. Gunnarsson and others (2009) make an important point in this regard. They find that levels of reported school autonomy and parental participation are not only poorly correlated with each other but that both vary more within countries than between them.26 A smaller body of literature looks at the impact of decentralizing edu- The scope, timing, and cation to local governments. A general concern with studies that look extent of decentralization at the impact of decentralization is that the scope, timing, and extent usually depend on a number of decentralization usually depend on a number of political economy of political economy considerations that are neither evident ex post nor malleable ex ante. As considerations that are neither such, strong assumptions about the plausible exogeneity of the timing evident ex post nor malleable or extent of decentralization are often required. The extent to which ex ante. 191
  • 212. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? the results of such studies are credible depends in part on the extent to which panel data, along with some feature of the decentralization, can be used to construct a credible counterfactual against which outcomes under decentralization can be compared. Decentralization in any form Overall, the evidence suggests that decentralization in any form seems to improve school improves school access. There is also some evidence that student reten- access . . . tion rates and attendance improve and grade repetition is reduced. There is little evidence, however, of any improvement in learning outcomes. . . . but there is little evidence Most evaluations do not cover the time periods typically associ- of any improvement in ated with improvements in learning outcomes. As Bruns, Filmer, and learning outcomes over the Patrinos (2011) point out, much of the evidence from developed coun- periods studied. tries indicates that it can take up to eight years to see an impact on Reform processes that student learning. This lack of impact on student learning is consistent attempt to change structures with a basic concern highlighted in chapter 2. Reform processes that of authority and power may attempt to change structures of authority and power may require longer require longer time spans to time spans to realize gains than the timeline of impact studies allows. realize gains than the timeline It may also be easier to observe gains in some dimensions than others. of impact studies allows . . . Outcomes may also worsen before they improve. Some studies, for example, show a decline in student quality at school entry, as children . . . and outcomes may from less privileged backgrounds enter school for the first time. Their actually worsen before they entry may partly account for the negligible improvement in learning improve. despite improvement in attendance and school retention. Even in stud- ies with longer time frames, however, results for learning outcomes are mixed, as shown below. Social fund–supported school infrastructure investments. Although social funds have invested substantial resources in upgrading school infrastructure, only a few studies look at the impacts of such invest- ments on schooling outcomes. The few that have find an improvement in school access. No study looks at learning outcomes. Several studies find that Paxson and Schady (2002) find that the Peruvian social fund social funds increased school increased school attendance, particularly among younger children. attendance, particularly Other researchers find similar results for social funds in Armenia among younger children. (Chase 2002) and Zambia (Chase and Sherburne-Benz 2001); Chase and Sherburne-Benz also find that children were in more appropriate grades. Household expenditure on schooling in Zambia was also higher in communities that used social funds to rehabilitate schools, probably because of the higher fees charged by parent-teacher associations in such 192
  • 213. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? schools. Although increased spending need not be welfare enhancing for poor households, the authors argue that taken together with improved attendance rates and grade-appropriate placement of children, it is indicative of unmet demand for schooling in these communities. School-based management. Several countries have implemented strong versions of school-based management. An early program is the Educación con Participación de la Comunidad (Education with Community Participation [EDUCO]) program in El Salvador. Under this program, the state bore all schooling costs (tuition, uniforms, textbooks). Parents were expected to contribute time and labor to the school. Each school had an Association for Community Education (ACE), with elected parent members. The ACEs managed the school budget; they could hire and fire teachers and monitor teacher perfor- mance (Sawada and Ragatz 2005). Half of all rural students in grades 1–9 were enrolled in an EDUCO school by 2001 (Di Gropello 2006). Jimenez and Sawada (1999, 2003) find that students in EDUCO schools had higher attendance and lower dropout rates than students in traditional schools. Attending an EDUCO school raised the odds of school retention by about 64 percent. As the decision to enroll in an EDUCO school is endogenous, the authors use the availability of EDUCO at the municipality level as an instrument for a school being in the EDUCO program. They attempt to isolate the channel through which the EDUCO effect is realized by adding a community partici- pation variable to the estimation. This estimation yields a positive and significant effect, leading the authors to conclude that EDUCO worked mainly through community participation. These results are interesting, but the empirical strategy is not con- vincing. In practice, any number of municipal characteristics could influence a municipalities’ eligibility for the EDUCO program and thus the odds of a school entering the program. Similarly, any number of community characteristics could affect the odds of a school selecting into the program as well as the observed dropout effects. Jimenez and Sawada (1999) and Sawada (1999) also find positive changes in teacher attitudes and behavior, particularly teacher absen- teeism. Sawada and Ragatz (2005) uses propensity score matching to identify the impact of EDUCO on a range of outcomes. Their results also indicate lower teacher absenteeism. Community associations and 193
  • 214. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? parents also report much greater influence over administrative pro- cesses, including teacher hiring and firing. There is also some, albeit limited, evidence of an improvement in student test scores. The authors note that EDUCO schools tend to be located in poorer, more remote, and more rural communities which could explain the lower compara- tive test scores. A school autonomy reform in A similar school autonomy reform in Nicaragua allowed school Nicaragua that gave school councils to hire and fire the school principal and make decisions about councils decision-making school maintenance and student learning. King and Özler (1998) look authority had no impact on at the impact of the program on student test scores. They use matching average student learning. methods to find comparable nonautonomous public and private schools. The study finds no impact of the reform on student learning on average. However, students performed better in schools that reported exercising greater de facto autonomy. The results, though interesting, are difficult to interpret, because the study cannot identify why some schools exer- cised greater autonomy. A subsequent study (King, Özler, and Rawlings 1999) that tried to determine which aspects of community decision making were responsible for the improved learning finds that the school council’s autonomy over staffing decisions had the greatest impact. In contrast Eskeland and Filmer (2002), who assess the decen- tralization of education in Argentina, find positive impacts of school autonomy but not of parental participation. They theorize that while greater school autonomy increases the ability of school officials to extract rents, greater participation by parents in schools can channel this discretionary power toward improved learning. The expectation is that community and parental engagement in schools can constrain rent-seeking by local officials or school administrators. The question is whether communities have the capacity, ability, or incentive to play this monitoring role, particularly in poorer and less developed areas, which may be most in need of education reform. Interestingly, they find that, consistent with their model, school autonomy has a larger impact on learning in communities that have higher levels of participation. In contrast, giving oversight These results are broadly corroborated by a randomized experiment power to community members in Kenya that, among other things, increased community monitoring of in Kenya improved both teachers through local school committees. Duflo, Dupas, and Kremer teacher attendance and (2008) find that giving oversight power to community members—in student performance. this case through local school committees—improved teacher atten- dance and student performance.27 194
  • 215. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Gunnarsson and others (2009) cast light on why the learning impacts of school autonomy and community participation are so mixed. They use data from eight Latin American countries to argue that local managerial effort, at the level of the school as well as the community, is likely to be endogenous. Their results demonstrate that correcting for the endogeneity of school autonomy and parental participation can completely reverse the positive and significant effects of school autonomy. Encouragingly, in their sample countries, the positive effect of community participation remains positive and is strengthened when the endogeneity of participation is addressed. Chaudhury and Parajuli (2010) study a school-based management A school-based management program in Nepal that transferred school management to the com- program in Nepal was munity. School management committees, composed of parents as associated with an increase well as “influential local citizens,” were given the authority to repost in school access but not government teachers, hire and fire community-recruited teachers, and learning. index teacher salaries to school performance. The committees were also given untied block grants to invest in school improvement. Exogenous variation in program participation, which was voluntary, was ran- domly induced in some communities through an advocacy group that persuaded treatment communities to participate in the program. Two years into the program, results show an increase in school access but no effect on learning. In some school-based management programs, community groups play a more consultative role, with very limited discretion over bud- gets or teacher hiring and firing decisions. One such program is the Programa Escuelas de Calidad (Quality Schools Program [PEC]) in Mexico, which provides five-year grants of up to $15,000 to schools that commit to invest in education quality. In exchange for PEC grants, schools need to prepare an education improvement plan in collaboration with parent associations. During the first years of the grant period, all investments must be made in upgrading school facilities and providing learning materials. The last installment of the grant can be used in part for teacher training and development. Participation in PEC is voluntary, but the program targets disadvantaged urban schools. Using two years of nationally representative panel data, Skoufias and Shapiro (2006) find significant declines in dropout, grade repetition, and failure rates. Dropout rates decreased by 0.24 points, failure rates by 0.24 points, and repetition rates by 0.31 points. 195
  • 216. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Murnane, Willet, and Cardenas (2006) use longitudinal data from all seven years of PEC, which allows them to control for pre-PEC trends in relevant outcomes in both PEC and non-PEC schools. Using only schools that entered PEC in the program’s second year of operation and had similar historical trends as non-PEC schools, they find that PEC decreased dropout rates by about 6 percent over three years of participa- tion. The largest effects occurred in states that were more developed. A school-based program in the A similar school-based program in the Philippines funded infrastruc- Philippines appears to have ture along with teacher training, curriculum development, and the pro- had a positive but modest vision of textbooks. This program required schools to develop a five-year effect on learning. school improvement plan in partnership with the community. Khattri, Ling, and Jha (2010) evaluate the program using retrospective admin- istrative data along with propensity score matching to identify coun- terfactual schools. They find positive but modest effects on learning. Grade failure and grade The Apoyo a la Gestión Escolar (School Management Support repetition in Mexico declined [AGE]) program in Mexico provided parent associations with resources following introduction of a that could be used to rehabilitate and upgrade school infrastructure. school-based management The funds were subject to being audited annually on a random basis. program. Gertler, Patrinos, and Rubio-Codina (2007) find substantial positive effects of giving parent associations more management responsibili- ties.28 Their results indicate a reduction in both grade failure and grade repetition of about 0.4 percentage points in AGE beneficiary schools. Given a mean failure rate of 10 percent and a mean repetition rate of 9.6 percent at baseline, these values imply about a 4 percent decrease in the proportion of students failing and the proportion of students repeat- ing a grade. The effects are larger for schools that received benefits for more than one year.29 A couple of recent studies have examined interventions in India designed to induce greater community monitoring of school-based com- mittees. Banerjee and others (2010) report on a randomized evaluation that had three intervention arms. The first arm provided information to villagers about the role of an existing institution, the village education committee. Baseline data indicated very little awareness of its existence, even among its own members. The second arm added to the first by also providing information on student test scores and how to evaluate a child’s learning level. The third arm supplemented the first two arms by teaching volunteers in the village a simple technique for teaching children how to read in an after-school reading program. Each interven- tion arm was implemented in 65 villages; a fourth group of 85 villages formed the control group. 196
  • 217. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? The authors find virtually no impact of the first and second arms of In India, inducing better this intervention. Even village education committee members them- monitoring of schools by selves were not significantly more likely to be aware that they were providing more information on the village education committee following the intervention. What and training to communities effects the authors do observe appear to reflect a decline in awareness about school management has in the control group. The first two interventions also had no effect had mixed effects. on children’s learning. In villages that received the third intervention arm, however, children were 1.7 percent more likely to read letters and 1.8 percent more likely to read words or paragraphs. The authors note that this small increase should be viewed with some optimism, given the small number of children who attended the after-school reading program. Pandey, Goyal, and Sundararaman (2011) present fi ndings from another study that provided information to communities about their roles and responsibilities in school management in the Indian states of Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, and Uttar Pradesh. At baseline, there were significant differences across states in test scores, teacher absence, and parental awareness of the village education committees. In line with Banerjee and others (2010), they find that only 8 percent of parents in Uttar Pradesh knew about the village education committee and only 2 percent could name its chair. In contrast, in Karnataka, 63 percent of parents were aware of the village education committee and 44 percent knew the name of its chair. The information campaign was also more intense and prolonged than the one studied by Banerjee and others (2010).30 The findings also differ in important ways. Pandey, Goyal, and Sundararaman find significant gains in teacher attendance, teach- ing time, and the functioning of school committees. They also find higher levels of parental and community engagement and higher stu- dent math scores, with much larger impacts in the two lagging states, Uttar Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh. The emergence of some learning gains is encouraging. The percentage of children receiving benefits from government entitlement programs (cash stipends, uniforms, mid- day meals) also rose, although in the more backward states of Madhya Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh, these benefits were provided mainly to high-caste students. Decentralization of schooling to local governments. Decentralization of schooling to municipal governments appears to have had little impact on average student learning, although there is some evidence of improvement in learning outcomes in wealthier and administratively 197
  • 218. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Decentralization of schooling more capable localities. Madeira (2007) finds that school decentraliza- to municipal governments tion in the Brazilian state of São Paolo increased dropout and failure appears to have little impact rates across all primary school grades, widening the gap between “good” on average student learning. and “bad” schools ranked by their initial dropout rates. These negative effects occurred despite an increase in school resources and a reduction in class size and student teacher ratios. Worse yet, the negative effects were significantly larger for schools in poorer, more rural, and more unequal communities, and the effects intensified with the number of years the school was decentralized.31 Average test scores in Similar results emerge from a study by Galiani, Gertler, and Argentina rose following Schargrodsky (2008), who find an increase in average test scores in decentralization . . . Argentina in schools that were decentralized. However, all of the increase was concentrated in wealthier schools located in munici- palities and provinces that had greater administrative capacity. Decentralization actually decreased scores for schools in poorer areas and in municipalities that were in provinces that had run fiscal deficits . . . but all of the increase before decentralization. was concentrated in Kosec (2011) shows how preferences over public spending can differ wealthier schools located systematically across localities that vary in initial wealth. The study in municipalities and focuses on investment in public preprimary education across municipal- provinces that had greater ities in Brazil following legal changes that increased resources for educa- administrative capacity. tion.32 Kosec shows that poorer municipalities used significantly more resources to enhance the availability of public preprimary education, which then had a substantial payoff in student learning. In contrast, wealthier municipalities used the funds largely to enhance the qual- ity of primary education. Investments in public preprimary education were lower in municipalities that were more unequal, suggesting that polarization can undermine the influence of the poor on public policy. Madeira (2007) attributes some of the perverse learning effects in Brazil to the democratization of schooling, which expanded school access for less well-prepared students, especially in grades 1 and 2. Rodriguez (2006) assesses the impact of school decentralization in Colombia, using a strategy that compares the performance of students in public and private schools on standardized tests. She finds that once the change in the composition of children in public schools as a result of decentralization is accounted for, the average standardized test scores of public school students improved significantly more than the scores of students in private schools.33 198
  • 219. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Pradhan and others (2011) study an intervention aimed at strength- ening school committees in Indonesia. They find that measures that increased linkages between schools and local government officials were the most effective in improving schooling outcomes and the legitimacy of the participatory process, particularly when combined with better accountability of the school committees themselves through open elec- tions. In contrast, interventions that provided funds and training to incumbent school committee members had no effect. Moreover, even the most effective intervention (election with linkage) did not alter parental willingness to invest time or resources in the school committee though it did increase the amount of time parents devoted to home- work, by about 80 minutes a week.34 A number of intermediate outcomes also improved. Specifically, the election intervention improved perceptions of school committee effectiveness by teachers, suggesting that elections may improve legiti- macy. Elections also improved teacher motivation and effort. Elections alone increased teaching time by 0.63 hours a day, mostly in lesson preparation time. Elections plus linkage increased daily teaching time by 1.1 hours, mostly in time spent grading. The proportion of teachers observed in the classroom at the time of the survey decreased with the election intervention, however, which is puzzling. The authors also find no impact on student dropout or repetition rates in any arm, although they find some improvement in student learning in the linkage and election plus linkage arms. The results from a companion qualitative study suggest an inter- esting tension. On the one hand, school committees appreciated receiving grants that were directly under their control and reported this control as the impetus for more face-to-face dialogue with the community. On the other hand, the grants seem to have resulted in greater conflict between the school committee and the principal (as might be expected). There were also some challenges in implementing In Indonesia, partnership elections, with school committees resisting changes in membership. between school committees When elections were conducted as designed, however, they enhanced and village councils resulted community awareness and participation in school committee activi- in concrete actions by the ties and legitimized the committee. Simply providing training to village council and significant incumbent committee members had little effect, either qualitatively or impacts that school quantitatively. The key finding in this study is that the linkage process committees could not have created a partnership between the school committee and the village achieved alone. 199
  • 220. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? council that resulted in concrete actions by the village council and led to significant schooling impacts that school committees alone could not have achieved. Community Engagement in Delivering Primary Health Care Services Many developing countries have experimented with community-based health care models. Often cited examples of success include Costa Rica and Jamaica, where community-level health education programs and community-based service provision are believed to have led to major reductions in mortality, despite fairly stagnant economic conditions (Riley 2005). Community-based health service provision encompasses a wide range of programs. Most programs supply trained health care providers, who work at the community level and are often charged with activating communities in some fashion, usually through women’s groups. The main focus of community-based health provision is on maternal and child care and household health behaviors. Most programs also rely on community volunteers or facilitators to build trust, mobilize local resources, coordinate group activities, or complement services provided by trained staff. A number of randomized control trials yield evidence on the health impacts of such interventions. Most are small-scale interventions but some work directly with existing government health delivery systems or test mechanisms that can be scaled up through existing health delivery systems. A small but growing body This small but growing body of literature by and large confirms the of literature by and large potentially beneficial impact of community-based health programs, confirms the potentially particularly for maternal and child health. A potential caveat is that beneficial impact of the role of community engagement per se is often difficult to isolate, community-based health because most programs undertake a bundle of activities. programs, particularly for Only a few evaluations separate the role of community engagement maternal and child health. from other bundled interventions. These studies find that community volunteers and health groups can positively affect both health behaviors and health outcomes—but only when they complement other inputs, such as trained health professionals and improved health services. There is also some evidence on the efficacy of transferring the management of community-based health programs to local governments and the role of public-private partnerships in the delivery of health services. The 200
  • 221. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? findings suggest positive, significant, and economically large effects of Decentralizing health service decentralizing health service delivery to local governments. In contrast, delivery to local governments the findings on public-private partnerships in the delivery of health appears to produce positive, services are more mixed. significant, and economically The literature on community-based health delivery can be grouped large effects. into four categories: community engagement in the allocation of resources for health-related investments, community engagement in providing health-related services and information, community moni- toring of health care providers, and decentralization of basic health services to local governments or NGOs. The literature on each category is reviewed below. Community engagement in resource allocation. Communities often choose to allocate resources from social funds or community- driven development projects to upgrading or building primary health care facilities. Few evaluations have anything to say about the impact of such investments on health behaviors or outcomes. Among the few that do is an early study of social funds by Chase and Sherburne-Benz (2001), which finds an increase in the use of primary care services in communities that invested in a health facility constructed by ZAMSIF, the Zambia social fund. Under ZAMSIF, communities received social investment funds for investment in small infrastructure projects such as the rehabilitation of community health posts. Chase and Sherburne- Benz find that social fund beneficiaries were more likely to go first to a health post rather than a hospital when they sought treatment. They were also significantly more likely to report an illness, although they were no more likely than controls to seek treatment. The study also finds more limited evidence that the vaccination prevalence rate rose in areas with rehabilitated health posts.35 Arcand and Bassole (2008) find an increase in the use of basic health services and access to clean drinking water in communities that partici- pated in the Programme National d’Infrastructures Rurales in Senegal. Access to basic health services rose 24 percentage points and access to clean drinking water 22 percentage points. The program was also associated with positive nutritional impacts (as measured by height for age, weight for age, and weight for height) for children, which were substantially larger for children from poorer households. The chan- nel through which improvements occurred is not clear, however, as discussed next. 201
  • 222. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Community engagement in the provision of health care services. A number of randomized control trials have attempted to assess the effectiveness of demand-side interventions in primary health care. A randomized pilot study of Ghana’s Community Health and Family Planning Project (Navrongo) casts some light on the added benefits of engaging community volunteers in the provision of health services (Binka and others 2007). One arm of the intervention tested the impact of adding community-based, volunteer-provided health services to the basic set of clinical services, along with revolving funds and user fees to ensure organizational sustainability. Trained supervisors from the com- munity recruited community health volunteers, organized community supervision of their work, and managed essential health resources. User fees and revolving accounts sustained this work. A second arm deployed trained nurses to villages as “community health officers.” A third arm engaged the community in ensuring that the trained nurses would be available. A fourth arm was held as the control. In the third arm, community members helped construct housing for nurses using volun- teer labor, ensuring that nurses could reside in the village. They also provided other types of community assistance and supported services provided by resident nurses. Working with chiefs, village The findings suggest that over an eight-year period, posting nurses elders, and community to community locations reduced childhood mortality rates substantially volunteers, community-based relative to control areas. In contrast, volunteer services had no impact nurses in Ghana helped on child survival. However, where volunteers worked alongside trained develop social insurance nurses, outcomes were superior to the first two interventions. Working mechanisms that allowed in concert with chiefs, village elders, and community volunteers, com- formal care to substitute for munity-based nurses helped develop various types of social insurance traditional care. mechanisms, such as deferred payment. These mechanisms allowed for- mal care to substitute for traditional care, reducing the delay in health seeking that tends to precipitate childhood mortality (see Nyonator and others 2005 for a detailed discussion). The authors interpret these results as reflecting the limited ability of volunteers alone to change entrenched behaviors like seeking traditional healers. Linnemayr and Alderman (2011) evaluate an intervention in Senegal that focused on the provision of nutrition-related information to moth- ers of young children through a community-based mechanism. The nutrition intervention was undertaken as a pilot program within the Programme de Renforcement de la Nutrition, which included cook- ing workshops and a monthly community-level meeting on nutritional 202
  • 223. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? practices, targeted at mothers. The program also provided vitamin and iron supplements, bednets, and deworming. The pilot was randomized across 212 villages in three poor rural regions.36 The results indicate significant improvements in health care practices in program villages but no effect on child growth measures, at least in the full sample of children. The one exception is children who were born or of breastfeeding age during the intervention. The nutri- tional status of these children rose significantly. Because of the bundled nature of the intervention, however, the role of each of its components remains unclear. A number of studies assess the role of community facilitators in motivating better health practices. Manandhar and others (2004) report on one such study, in a district in Nepal. The sample consisted of 12 pairs of village development committees, one of which was randomly assigned to treatment.37 The study collected baseline data on almost 29,000 eligible women from some 28,000 households. Follow-up data were collected two years after the intervention. In each intervention cluster, a local facilitator was recruited (nominated by the local com- munity or identified by word of mouth or through an advertisement). The facilitator conducted a monthly women’s group meeting in every ward (the level below the village development committee). Each facilita- tor held 10 group meetings. A number of issues were discussed in the meetings, including the identification and prioritization of health issues related to pregnancy and childbirth and potential solutions, including community-generated funds, stretcher schemes, and home visits by group members. The role of the facilitator was to activate and support the women’s groups, not to provide health support. Health services were strengthened in both the control and intervention clusters, through the provision of supplies at local health facilities, the provision of newborn care kits, and the training of community health workers. Over the two-year trial period, the neonatal mortality rate in inter- vention clusters fell 30 percent, though there was no difference in stillbirth rates. Maternal mortality also declined 80 percent (2 maternal deaths versus 11 in control clusters). There were significant improve- ments in health behaviors, such as antenatal care, the use of supple- ments, the share of births in health facilities with trained attendants, and use of clean kits. Birth attendants were more likely to wash their hands, and maternal and child illness was more likely to be treated at a health facility. Moreover, 95 percent of the groups remained active 203
  • 224. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? after the trial period. These results were achieved with only 37 percent of newly pregnant women (8 percent of married women) ever attending the women’s meetings. Tripathy and others (2010) conducted a similar trial in Jharkhand and Orissa, two of India’s poorest states, where neonatal and maternal mortality rates are higher than the national average. In treatment vil- lages, local facilitators were trained to support women’s groups, which met about 20 times in all over three years. Health committees were formed in both intervention and control clusters to discuss health entitlements from service providers, particularly for mothers and newborns.38 This intervention witnessed a 45 percent reduction in early neonatal deaths (0–6 days). By the third year of the trial, there was also a 57 per- cent reduction in moderate depression among mothers. There were no significant differences in health care–seeking behavior, but there were significant improvements in home care practices (use of safe kits, hand washing by birth attendants, boiling of threads used to tie the cord, and so forth). More infants were also exclusively breastfed at six weeks. The cost per life-year saved was about $33 ($48 with health-service strength- ening activities). Although the availability of delivery kits increased in both control and intervention clusters, women’s groups generated more uptake of the kits in intervention areas. Olken, Onishi, and Wong (2011) evaluate a pilot program in Indonesia (PNPM Generasi) that provided block grants to villages to encourage investments intended to improve specific health and educa- tion indicators.39 In some communities, the grant was incentivized, in that the amount of the grant the following year was based partially on the village’s performance on each of the 12 targeted health and educa- tion indicators. The performance bonus was competitively allocated among villages within the same subdistrict. For the evaluation, program villages were randomly assigned to receive either the incentivized or the nonincentivized grant. The data come from three survey waves, conducted between 2007 and 2010. A program in Indonesia that The study finds that the program reached beneficiaries and had very gave block grants to villages significant effects on a range of intermediate behaviors, at both midline to encourage them to improve and endline. For health, the strongest intermediate impacts were on specific health and education growth monitoring and the distribution of iron sachets to pregnant indicators achieved positive women. The intervention was also associated with a 9.6 percent reduc- midline results . . . tion in malnutrition and a significant increase in prenatal visits and immunizations. Health impacts were also larger in incentivized areas. 204
  • 225. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Incentives did not affect education indicators, however, and some health . . . but many results were not impacts also disappeared by endline. For example, the project had large sustained. impacts on reducing neonatal and infant mortality at midline, but these impacts disappeared by the endline. The endline results also show no impact on learning. Importantly, nontargeted indicators also improved across the board, with an average improvement of 0.0362 standard deviation, with sta- tistically significant improvements in indicators such as facility-based deliveries. The grant also appears to have been most effective in more disadvantaged areas. In looking at the mechanisms through which the project worked, the authors suggest that Generasi appears to have had the greatest impact on community effort. It mobilized cadres working at village health posts and ratcheted up participation in meetings about health education and related topics. Households in Generasi areas also felt that both health and education services had improved. In terms of overall service provision, however, there were no sta- tistically significant impacts. If anything, there was a slight decrease in health provider inputs and effort and some increase in the prices charged by providers. There is also some evidence of deterioration in the quality of care. Combined with the fact that the main effects come from greater community effort in direct service provision, these results are disturbing from the point of view of sustainability, as is the finding that there was no impact of the program on any indicator of community outreach or monitoring and no spillover to other community activities. Community monitoring of health care providers. Perhaps the best- known assessment of the efficacy of community monitoring in improv- ing health service delivery is of a randomized citizen’s report card project in Uganda (Bjorkman and Svensson 2007). The main objective of the project was to improve the quality of basic health services by improv- ing community capacity to monitor service providers. The report card intervention was randomly assigned to half of 50 rural communities across 9 districts. Meetings of users and providers were held at which the information collected in the report cards was disseminated together Following the introduction of with practical information on how best to use this information.40 citizen report cards in Uganda, The authors find large and significant improvements in a number the under-five mortality of treatment practices, from staff absenteeism to waiting time and the rate fell 33 percent and quality of preventive care. They find a 16 percent increase in the use vaccination rates and infant of health facilities, along with greater community satisfaction with weight rose. 205
  • 226. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? service providers. Some health outcomes also improved substantially. In particular, the under-five mortality rate fell 33 percent and vaccina- tion prevalence rates and infant weight increased. During this period, there was no increase in government funding or investment in health facilities or services. Given the size of the effect on under-five mortality, understanding the precise channel through which change occurred, as well as the role of community monitoring, is clearly of great value. The interven- tion suggests three competing channels through which service quality changes could have come about: greater community monitoring (a demand-side channel), provision of information to providers regarding their performance relative to expectations (a supply-side channel), and the bringing together of the community and providers (which could increase both the efficacy of information and community willingness to monitor). The authors test for the relevance of the demand- versus supply-side channels by replacing treatment indicators with measures of staff and community engagement as explanatory variables. They find that the coefficients on community engagement are positive, statistically significant, and larger than the coefficients on treatment indicators. In contrast, the coefficients on staff engagement are not significant or have the wrong sign. The authors posit that these results are more supportive of the demand-driven explanation. Although this finding is encourag- ing, the results are at best suggestive, as it is unclear precisely what the community or staff engagement variables are capturing. An interesting descriptive study by Uzochukwu, Akpala, and Onwujekwe (2004) casts valuable light on potential hurdles in scaling up community engagement in service delivery. The authors report on the Bamako Initiative program in Nigeria, which aimed to strengthen primary health care by increasing community engagement. The pro- gram created village- and district-level health committees and gave them substantial authority. The committees’ mandate was to supervise the activities of traditional birth attendants; select, supervise, and pay village health workers; manage revenues and profits from drug sales; set the remuneration of health workers; and make decisions about the level of user fees and rules for exemption. Despite very broad-based participation and awareness of its functions, the committee focused largely on ancillary functions, such as the provision of health education and a waste disposal system. It remained entirely outside all important decision-making processes, such as hiring and payment of staff, setting 206
  • 227. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? user fees, or providing oversight over budgets. There was also some disconnect between reports from health facility heads and community members about the extent of community involvement, with health facil- ity heads claiming far greater community engagement in planning and management decisions than community members did. Few if any empirical studies collect this type of qualitative data that could help elucidate the channels through which participation works to improve outcomes and the potential constraints that could limit effective community engagement. Moreover, no careful empirical study has been conducted of the Bamako program that could bring these participation results together with results on service quality and health outcomes. Decentralization of basic health services to local governments or Decentralization of basic NGOs. Decentralization of basic health care services to local govern- health care services to local ments appears to have been successful overall. The evidence suggests governments appears to have substantial gains on a number of child health outcomes as well as on a been successful overall. wider range of health behaviors. Some studies also find improvements in labor market outcomes and decreased fertility. The devolution of health service provision to NGOs appears to have Devolution of health service been less successful, although there is evidence of some positive out- provision to NGOs appears comes. In particular, when programs are devolved to NGOs, improve- to have been less successful, ments in health tend to be confined to outcomes specifically targeted although there is evidence of by the program. There are also some perverse effects of the imposition some positive outcomes. of user fees. Much of the evidence on the benefits of decentralized delivery of basic health services comes from a set of studies on Brazil’s family health program, the Programa Saude da Famılia (PSF). The PSF was first rolled out in 1994, as a small pilot initiative covering a few areas. By 2006, it had expanded into a nationwide program; by 2009, the program covered more than 90 percent of Brazilian municipalities. Municipal governments manage the PSF, under the supervision of Assessments of Brazil’s the Brazilian Ministry of Health. PSF teams—which usually consist of decentralized family health a doctor, a nurse, an assistant nurse, and six community health workers, program find positive and as well as a dental and a social work professional in some cases—are economically large effects responsible for monitoring the health status of about 3,000–4,500 on health outcomes and people (about 1,000 households). Teams make home visits and perform behaviors. community-based health promotion activities. All services are delivered free of charge to ensure access by the most disadvantaged. Assessments 207
  • 228. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? of the program find positive and economically large effects on health outcomes, particularly for neonates, and health behaviors. They also find substantial gains in child school attendance, adult labor supply, and employment and a decline in fertility. Macinko and others (2007) uses the differential adoption and expan- sion rates of the PSF as a quasi-experiment to assess the relationship between changes in PSF coverage over time and changes in health outcomes that are most likely to be sensitive to primary care. Their data cover six years (1999–2004) and include 557 Brazilian micro-regions in 27 states. Each micro-region includes several municipalities. This study finds a significant reduction in postneonatal mortality (deaths of children from 30 days to 1 year) and mortality from diarrheal diseases. In exploring the mechanisms through which PSF might work, the authors note that areas with greater PSF coverage also have higher prevalence rates of behaviors stressed by community health workers, such as breastfeeding, use of oral rehydration therapy, and child immu- nizations. The authors provide a back of the envelope estimation of program costs of about $30 per capita.41 A related study (Macinko, Guanais, and DeSouza 2006) finds high levels of satisfaction with PSF among users, with more than 75 percent reporting that child health services were of good quality. The presence of the program in a given municipality was also associated with better perceived health. A potential limitation of the study by Macinko, Guanais, and DeSouza (2006) is that variation in the timing or rate of PSF adoption could be endogenous. Well-governed municipalities could decentralize health services early, for example, or municipalities with the worst out- comes could decentralize first. In either case, estimated impacts would be biased, with the direction of the bias not clear.42 Rocha and Soares (2009) also use the differential adoption and expansion rates of the PSF as a quasi-experiment. They use municipal panel data from 1995 to 2003. These data include information on a range of demographic and socioeconomic characteristics in addition to program coverage and mortality. Difference-in-difference estimates suggest a substantial decline in mortality, especially during the first year of life.43 Municipalities that had been in the program for three years, for example, reduced infant mortality by 1.5 more infants per 1,000 live births than comparable municipalities that did not adopt PSF. Based 208
  • 229. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? on the 1993 average infant mortality rate in Brazil of 27 per 1,000 live births, this difference corresponds to a 5.6 percent reduction in the infant mortality rate. For a municipality eight years into the program, infant mortality declined by 5.4 deaths per 1,000 live births, a 20 per- cent decline relative to the 1993 national average.44 Gains were largest in the two poorest regions (the North and the Northeast), which also provided fewer public goods.45 Gains were also larger in less urbanized municipalities and municipalities with less access to treated water and poorer sanitation systems. The largest impacts of the program on infant mortality were associated with complications during pregnancy; infec- tious diseases (diarrhea and other intestinal diseases, influenza); and respiratory diseases (asthma, bronchitis)—precisely the sorts of condi- tions for which the presence of a community-based health program would be most effective. The authors also look at the effects of PSF on household behavior, The program was also using several rounds of census data. They find no effects on child labor associated with increases in supply. In contrast, they find that school enrollment was 4.5 percent school enrollment, adult labor higher eight years after PSF exposure. In addition, adult labor supply supply, and employment and was 6.8 percentage points higher and employment 11 percentage points a decline in fertility. higher. The other case on which there is robust evidence of improve- ments in infant mortality is Pakistan’s Lady Health Worker Program (formally known as the National Program for Family Planning and Primary Health Care), introduced by the government in 1994. Lady health workers are typically young women who have at least eight years of schooling and live in the community they serve. They are given 15 months of training to deliver care in community settings. Lady health workers make home visits and are expected to be avail- able at their own home, which is known as a “health home.” They provide antenatal care, contraceptive advice, growth monitoring, and immunization services, with each worker responsible for about 1,000–1,500 people (about 175 households). Although the program is a federal program, lady health workers report to basic health units and rural health centers, which are managed by provincial and district governments. Bhutta and others (2011) present the results of a randomized clus- ter trial in which lady health workers in treatment villages were given additional training in group counseling; the promotion of specific 209
  • 230. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? health behaviors; the establishment of linkages with traditional birth attendants; and the recognition of urgent care cases and the need to refer them to basic health units, rural health centers, or hospitals. In addition, the trial created volunteer community health committees in treatment villages, with the aim of promoting maternal and newborn care in the village. Community health committees were expected to conduct advo- cacy work with community elders and local political leaders, organize an emergency fund for transporting the sick to an appropriate facility, and help lady health workers conduct group education sessions.46 The study finds a 15–20 percent reduction in perinatal and newborn mortality in the intervention area. It also fi nds improvement in 16 household behaviors related to maternal and early newborn care, with gains rising over time. The largest improvements were in antenatal care and facility (instead of at-home) births. Lady health workers in The authors point out that these gains occurred despite implemen- Pakistan successfully tation through the government health system rather than by workers delivered a package of employed directly by the research team, in a difficult to reach and preventive and promotive underdeveloped area. Although lady health workers were unable to health care services . . . complete the full set of activities they were expected to engage in, they still managed to successfully deliver a package of preventive and . . . but to be effective, they promotive health care services. However, the authors stress, in order need close oversight. to be effective, community health workers and programs need close oversight. This study points to the importance of carefully assessing the addi- tional gain from organizing volunteer-based community health com- mittees. Given that the largest gains were in facility births, the role of the community health committees in organizing transport may have been key, but the importance of transport is not clear from the study. The study also cannot separate the effect of the additional training pro- vided to lady health workers from the effect of setting up community health committees. Jokhio, Winter, and Cheng (2005) report on an earlier cluster- randomized trial in rural Pakistan that trained traditional birth atten- dants in antenatal and newborn care. Traditional birth attendants were also provided with clean delivery kits from primary health care centers and linked to lady health workers. Concurrently, outreach clinics were established in intervention clusters (two clinics in each of three clus- ters), where obstetricians conducted eight outreach sessions during the six-month trial. 210
  • 231. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? The study finds a reduction in neonatal mortality of 30 percent, identical to the outcome in Nepal’s experiment with women’s groups and larger than the results from the lady health worker trial. However, the sample consists of only seven clusters, including both treatment and control areas. It also fails to distinguish the impact of training birth attendants, and hence using existing structures, from the impact of outreach clinics. In practice, however, 91 percent of the women in the intervention group received care from traditional birth attendants, with only 16 percent visiting outreach clinics. The Projahnmo project in Bangladesh tested a model similar to the lady health worker program, with one difference (Baqui and others 2008). Two treatment arms were established, in order to test the efficacy of a home-based care model against a community-based care model. In both intervention arms, male and female community mobilizers held group meetings on birth and newborn care preparedness. Community resource people were enlisted to encourage women to attend these meet- ings and seek antenatal care. In the home care intervention, one community health worker was recruited (by an NGO) per four villages with a total population of about 4,000 people. The community health worker was trained for six weeks in behavior change communication and the clinical assessment and management of illnesses in neonates. He or she was responsible for tracking pregnancies during routine surveillance activities, making scheduled antenatal and postnatal home visits, diagnosing illnesses for referral, and administering penicillin to neonates who could not be taken to health facilities for treatment. In the community care arm of the intervention, only group meetings with mobilizers and resource people were held; no home visits were made. However, female volunteers (including traditional birth attendants) were recruited to identify preg- An intervention in Bangladesh nant women, encourage them to attend meetings held by mobilizers, that created community health and receive routine antenatal and early postnatal care. These volunteers groups had no impact on any were responsible for about 18,000 people. outcomes. This study finds very significant improvements in neonatal mortality but only in the home care arm, which saw a 30 percent decline in neona- In contrast, a home care tal mortality during the last 6 months of the 30-month trial (relative to intervention was associated the control arm). In the home care clusters, there was also a sizable and with a 30 percent decline statistically significant improvement in the use of supplements during in neonatal mortality as well pregnancy, the use of clean equipment, and newborn care practices. In as improvements in other contrast, there was no significant improvement in health behaviors in health outcomes. 211
  • 232. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? the community care arm. Furthermore, each community health worker in this trial was responsible for 4,000 people, a ratio similar to the primary health care worker-to-population ratio in Bangladesh’s health care system, suggesting an easy route for scaling up existing health infrastructure. Two studies look at the impact of devolving primary health care pro- vision to NGOs. Kremer and others (2006) evaluate the effects of a pilot program under which the Cambodian Ministry of Health contracted with NGOs to run public health facilities in 12 districts. The project, which ran from 1999 to 2003, covered 1.26 million people, about 11 percent of Cambodia’s population. In some districts (“contracting in” districts), contracted NGOs were expected to work within the existing government system to procure drugs, equipment, and supplies and to use Ministry of Health personnel. They could request transfers of per- sonnel but not hire or fire staff; their operating expenses were financed through the government budget. In others districts (“contracting out” districts), NGOs had full management authority. They could hire and fire staff; bring in health workers from other parts of the country; and procure drugs, supplies, and equipment from any source. 47 Staff members from the Ministry of Health were allowed to join the NGO by taking a leave of absence from the civil service. If fired by the NGO, they were allowed to return to government service in another district.48 The study finds that both contracting out and contracting in had significant positive effects on most measures of health center manage- ment, including the health center’s hours of service, staff presence dur- ing unannounced visits, and availability of equipment, supplies, and vaccines.49 The authors also look at the impact on the specific health outcomes targeted by the program. They find that both contracting in and contracting out had positive and significant effects on the use of public health facilities for curative care consultations, as well as on antenatal care, vitamin A distribution to children, and child immuniza- tion. In contrast, there was less systematic improvement in nontargeted outcomes, such as the treatment of diarrhea and knowledge about HIV risk factors. Yoong (2007) studies the Rogi Kalyan Samiti (Patient Welfare Committee [RKS]) program, in the Indian state of Madhya Pradesh, which transferred control over some aspects of hospital management to a local NGO.50 The study used the phased implementation of this transfer of authority to identify its impact on child immunization rates. 212
  • 233. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Using difference-in-difference estimates, the study finds that chil- dren ages 0–3 received significantly fewer appropriate vaccines per year of exposure after a hospital was transferred to the NGO. Interestingly, the reduction in immunization rates was confi ned to the relatively better-off, with no negative effect on the poor, who were exempt from the user fees charged by the NGO. It is useful to note that vaccination is not generally a candidate for decentralization, because of significant interpersonal and interjurisdictional externalities.51 The Poverty Impact of Participatory Projects Evidence on the poverty impacts of participatory development projects Evidence on the poverty and decentralization reforms is scarce. This section draws some lessons impacts of participatory from the little evidence there is, with some important qualifiers: the development projects and number of studies is small; the studies examine fairly disparate interven- decentralization reforms is tions; and, with a few exceptions, outcomes are typically assessed within scarce. a relatively short time span, even though, as discussed in chapter 3, some outcomes, such as changes in income or assets, are likely to be realized only over much longer time periods. It is also unclear whether most projects operate at a scale that could plausibly affect average poverty levels in program communities or even effect a permanent change in the income or assets of participating households. Participatory projects provide a bundle of interventions, of which the Participatory projects provide encouragement or facilitation of participation is but one. Most provide a bundle of interventions. resources for local public goods, productivity-enhancing investments, or private transfers, and many provide all three, often bundled with some form of microcredit. All of these interventions inject resources into communities and could thus have an independent effect on income. Many community-driven development programs are also moving decisively toward greater support for livelihood activities. Such projects tend to encompass a broad array of productive activities, including crop production and nontraditional agricultural activities, such as aquacul- ture and medicinal plants, livestock, agro-forestry, fishing, and fish farming. Most programs also support postproduction activities, which can include agro-processing enterprises as well as rural marketing ser- vices. Projects usually provide some type of grant to eligible members or groups for productive investments, which can be either individual or collective and often include a training component, which may cover 213
  • 234. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? project formulation, skill enhancement, or the basics of business man- agement and marketing. Many projects include innovative multisectoral programs, including linkages with government line ministries at many levels. Careful evaluations of these efforts would add much to the knowledge base on the effectiveness of participatory poverty reduction programs. The evidence on the impact The literature reviewed below provides a mixed picture. Some studies of participatory projects on find improvements in assets or income, other do not. Studies that pres- poverty is mixed . . . ent longer-term results tend to find that income gains either disappear or survive only for specific subgroups, not always the poorest or most . . . and most studies find disadvantaged. There are also concerns about evaluation strategies. The that income gains disappear review excludes studies that use extremely poor data or an evaluation over time or survive only for strategy that is flawed in a fundamental way. subgroups, which are not An evaluation of the long-running KALAHI-CIDSS program in always the poorest or most the Philippines finds a 5 percent increase in consumption, concentrated disadvantaged. among poor households (Labonne 2011).52 The program was also associated with higher labor force participation rates for both men and women and greater income diversification, as evident in reported par- ticipation rates at midline (2006), particularly for women. Interestingly, during the financial downturn, the participation rate for both men and women fell significantly, but mainly in control areas. The program thus appears to have had a protective effect on employment and participation rates, particularly for women. Reported impacts are likely to be significantly biased, however— and the bias is likely to be in the direction of finding positive income impacts, since the results do not correct appropriately for sample size or initial differences between program and control groups.53 A careful evaluation of the A careful evaluation of the KDP program in Indonesia (Voss 2008) KDP program in Indonesia finds no impact on average household consumption. However, there concludes that it led to are significant gains among households in the bottom quintile of the significant consumption gains consumption distribution and similar losses for households in the top by the bottom quintile. quintile.54 In the matched household sample, per capita consumption by the bottom quintile rose about 5 percent. The author carefully dem- onstrates that the estimated impact is likely to be robust to problems in the data. A potential problem with this study is that the 2002 survey (SUSENAS) appears to have mismeasured household consumption. As a result, households whose consumption was erroneously understated in 2002 registered an increase in consumption in 2007, and households 214
  • 235. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? whose consumption was erroneously overstated in 2002 registered con- sumption losses. This concern is not significant when looking at aver- age changes, because program placement and mismeasurement are not likely to be correlated. It is a concern when disaggregating the data into quintiles using 2002 poverty status or per capita consumption, because the quintile level estimates may be biased. The authors use two alter- native strategies to demonstrate that this bias is unlikely to be large.55 Interestingly, the study finds no impact on the consumption of other disadvantaged groups, such as households with low levels of education or households headed by women, which suffer from more severe pov- erty, suggesting that consumption growth in the bottom quintile was concentrated among poor households near the poverty line. A randomized evaluation of GoBifo, another World Bank–funded project, in Sierra Leone also finds no impact on household income four years after project inception (Casey, Glennerster, and Miguel 2011).56 The evaluation sample included 238 villages, half of which were ran- domly held as controls. The baseline evaluation was conducted in 2005 and the follow-up in 2009. GoBifo provided block grants of $4,667 (roughly $100 per house- hold) to rural communities for construction of local public goods and for skills training and small business start-up capital. The project required village development committees to submit development plans for grant use to district councils through ward development commit- tees for review and approval. The government implemented the project. Community facilitators supported GoBifo communities by encouraging inclusive decision making; greater participation of marginalized groups, such as women and youth; and transparent budgeting practices. The results indicate some gains in household assets, such as housing quality and durables, as well as impacts on intermediate outcomes, such as the number of petty traders in the village and the range of goods available for sale. However, the authors do not discuss whether these gains accrued to poor or otherwise disadvantaged households. It is not clear whether this study collected detailed consumption data. The Programme National d’Infrastructures Rurales (PNIR) was implemented in 90 of the poorest communautés rurales in Senegal.57 Its main objective was to support the decentralization and fiscal reform process by providing resources for rural infrastructure investments which were allocated using a participatory mechanism. At the village level, the program set up a community development committee (Comité de 215
  • 236. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Concertation et de Gestion), with mandated inclusion of women and other marginalized groups. Evaluation of the program used a quasi-experimental approach (Arcand and Bassole 2008). Eligibility for PNIR was based on an index of access to basic services at the communauté rurale level, allowing the authors to choose control communities using the same set of indicators and regional controls.58 The evaluation finds no reduction in household poverty, as measured by consumption expenditures, when villages that received the program are compared with controls, regardless of whether the program village received any PNIR funding. This comparison comes closest perhaps to a test of the impact of participation per se on income, as PNIR villages should differ from controls only in the community mobilization effort of PNIR rather than because of project funds. This comparison does find significant improvements in the nutritional status of children (as measured by weight for age, height for age, and weight for height), how- ever, with larger gains for poorer households. It also finds improvements in access to clean drinking water, which rose 22 percentage points, and basic health services, which rose 24 percentage points. It is unclear what drove these improvements, however. When the study confines attention to program villages and compares outcomes for households in villages with completed projects with out- comes in villages without completed projects, it finds large and signifi- cant impacts on consumption, particularly for the poor, but no impact on child nutrition. This finding suggests that nutritional gains do not vary because of investments in local public goods, whereas income and consumption do. These results are less robust than results that compare PNIR communities to control communities since it is unclear what determines the odds of a PNIR village actually getting a project.59 The study also finds that poverty is reduced only in villages that invested in income-generating agricultural projects and, curiously, in schools rather than in drinking water or public health facilities. Analysis of India’s District An evaluation of the District Poverty Initiative Program (DPIP) in Poverty Initiative Program Andhra Pradesh (Deininger and Liu 2009) also yields mixed results. finds no change in The authors use two rounds of data, from 2004 and 2006, collected consumption or nutrition. from three districts in the state (Anantapur, Adilabad, and Srikakulam) to evaluate program impacts. As all the municipalities (mandals) in their sample benefitted from DPIP, they construct a counterfactual using years in the program. Specifically, control mandals are mandals that 216
  • 237. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? entered the program two and half years after treatment mandals and so have fewer years of exposure to the program. The sample includes 41 programs and 10 controls mandals, selected through propensity score matching to eliminate bias because of initial selection.60 The authors assess program impact on household consumption, nutritional intake, and nonfinancial assets. Using the full sample of matched households, they find no change in consumption or nutrition, though there was a significant (16 percent) improvement in nonfinancial assets. DPIP began in 2001, with the objective of using women’s self-help groups, which had been organized in Andhra Pradesh under earlier development projects, to promote economic and social empowerment.61 The bulk of DPIP support was directed at building the capacity of self-help groups and providing them with a one-time grant to promote microcredit and savings through a “community investment fund.”62 The presence of women’s self-help groups was an important factor in the selection of the first DPIP districts. Confining attention to self-help group participants, the authors find an 11 percentage point increase in consumption, a 10–12 percentage point increase in nutrition, and a 23 percentage point increase in non- financial assets. This comparison is valid only insofar as self-help group membership was driven by the same factors in the old and new DPIP districts. The widespread prevalence of self-help groups in the old DPIP districts much before the program was initiated, casts some doubt on this. That said, the results suggest that benefits were confined largely to members, which seems sensible given that benefits were mainly in the form of transfers to organized self-help groups (the project created no public goods). Disaggregating by poverty status, the authors find that benefits were entirely concentrated among the poor, with the greatest benefits going to the poorest. Four other studies find little or no impact on poverty. Park and China’s flagship community- Wang (2009) evaluate China’s Poor Village Investment Program—a based poverty alleviation community-based poverty alleviation program initiated in 2001 that program had no impact on financed investments in infrastructure projects in “poor” villages.63 mean income or consumption Projects were to be selected through a participatory mechanism. The growth . . . study finds no impact of the project on mean income or consumption growth—although income and consumption among the better-off . . . although there were rose significantly.64 For the nonpoor, per capita household income rose substantial positive effects 6.6 percent and per capita consumption expenditure rose 8.8 percent.65 on income and consumption The program also reduced the odds of migration by nonpoor households among the better-off. 217
  • 238. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? by 5.2 percent. In contrast, there was no effect on the migration odds of the poor. The study uses panel data on some 666 eligible villages and 5,500 households surveyed in 2001 and 2004. The identification strategy relies on the gradual phasing in of planned investments within desig- nated poor villages. Hence, the main concern for identification is not the potential bias because of village selection but the bias induced by the timing of program investments. The authors use propensity score matching with time-invariant variables, or variables measured before the start of the program, to deal with this problem.66 The implied transfer of wealth to the relatively better off is consider- able, given the authors’ estimates that in 2004 the central government allocated some Y 32.7 billion (about $4 billion)—more than 5 percent of the central government budget—to poverty investment programs. An evaluation of the Southwest China Poverty Reduction Project (SWP) provides a rare longer-run perspective on program impact (Chen, Mu, and Ravallion 2009). The SWP was introduced in 1995 in the counties of Guangxi, Guizhou, and Yunnan with the explicit goal of achieving a large and sustainable reduction in poverty in the poor- est villages in these counties.67 Like other participatory programs, the SWP included a bundle of interventions along with community-based participation in the selection of beneficiaries and activities. Within selected villages, it was expected that virtually all households would benefit from infrastructure investments such as improved rural roads, power lines, and piped water supply. Broad-based benefits were also expected from improved social services, including upgrading village schools and health clinics and training teachers and village health care workers. People with school-age children also received tuition subsidies, as a conditional cash transfer. Individual loans were available for invest- ments in a wide range of productive activities, ranging from investments in yield improvement and animal husbandry to nonfarm enterprises. Microloans accounted for more than 60 percent of all disbursements. The Southwest China Poverty The project yielded sizable and statistically significant improvements Reduction Project yielded in mean household income in participating villages during the project sizable improvements in cycle. But four years after the project had ended, these gains had largely mean household income in disappeared.68 The only group that was able to sustain income gains participating villages during were initially poor but relatively well-educated households, which may the project cycle . . . have been genuinely credit constrained because of poverty. Given the numerous interventions bundled in this program, the authors do not 218
  • 239. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? attempt to isolate the effects of community participation. Given the . . . but four years after the observed heterogeneity in long-term gains, they do attempt to infer the project had ended, these potential impact of using participatory practices to identify beneficia- gains had largely disappeared. ries for loans. They conclude that the weak overall performance of the project may have been caused by a participatory beneficiary selection process that apparently favored the better-educated overall but, perhaps because of program capture, failed to provide enough opportunities for the educated poor. The authors also point to a broader concern with the assessment of Additional funding from the longer-term impacts of programs that are geographically placed, participatory programs even when program assignment is random. Additional funding from could simply displace local participatory programs could simply displace local government spend- government spending in ing in project areas, or governments could increase funding in non- project areas, or governments project areas. There is some evidence for such displacement in their could increase funding in study areas. Comparison villages appear to catch up with project vil- nonproject areas. lages. Early gains in project villages disappeared as enrollment in con- trol villages rose, for example. The authors note that this process may account, in part, for the smaller long-term impacts they observe, but the size of the bias introduced does not indicate that it could fully account for the absence of an average income impact over the longer term. Fearon, Humphreys, and Weinstein (2009) study a community- A participatory project in driven reconstruction project implemented by the International Rescue postconflict northern Liberia Committee in post conflict northern Liberia. This careful study finds had no apparent impact on no impact of the project on livelihoods or access to public goods or livelihoods or access to public services. The authors also find no evidence that the community-driven goods or services. reconstruction program reduced the need for households in treatment communities to walk to key services. However, they do find that school- age children and young adults in treatment communities had higher school attendance rates, and there was a significant increase in female employment (see also the discussion of this study in chapter 6). Two recent studies use randomized designs to study World Bank– funded community-driven development programs that provide support to individuals to obtain skills and business training and to establish or expand microenterprises. Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez (2011) assess the Youth Opportunities Program, implemented under the Northern Uganda Social Action Fund (NUSAF). This program provided sub- stantial grants (worth almost 1.5 years of salary) to young adults chosen by lottery. About 60 percent of the grant was invested in vocational training or productive assets, with a substantial portion of the rest used 219
  • 240. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? for working capital, savings, and consumption. The results at midline suggest a significant increase in the number of hours worked as well as a 50 percent increase in net income. Given the interest rates facing young adults, these investments would likely not have been made in the absence of grant funding, underscoring the need to expand access to capital markets for the poor and for young people, who lack assets as well as employment experience. Gine and Mansuri (2012) assess a program to provide business training and microloans to members of rural community organiza- tions established by the National Rural Support Program (NRSP) and funded by the Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund (PPAF). Many community organization members already had some experience with microcredit loans from NRSP. Community organizations were randomized into two groups, one of which was offered the opportunity to obtain eight days of business training at no cost. About two-thirds of people offered training took it. Both groups were also offered the opportunity to apply for a loan that was about five times the size of the standard loan (the base loan was about Rs. 20,000, about six to seven months of daily wage labor earn- ings for one household member). Access to the loan was randomized through a lottery in which about half of applicants were chosen. Gine and Mansuri find that business training reduced business fail- ure and that the best businesses survived. Training also raised consump- tion, increased income (by about 12 percent), and improved business practices. However, the gains were confined largely to men.69 Uptake of the loan was modest, with less than a third of eligible members apply- ing, and the authors find no additional income gain for lottery winners. Business training in Pakistan Alwang, Gacitua-Mario, and Centurion (2008) report on PRODECO, reduced business failure, a project that supports group-based income-generating activities in raised consumption and the southern departments of Itapua, Misiones, and Neembucu in income, and improved Paraguay. Its main objectives are to empower marginalized groups and business practices . . . to strengthen local government capacity to identify, design, implement, and monitor community development projects. PRODECO provides . . . but the gains were grants to eligible groups for productive investments. Groups are formed confined largely to men. in targeted communities by “development agents,” which can be NGOs or public sector employees. Once the income-generating activity is identified, groups are trained in project formulation, technical skills related to the project, and business management and marketing basics. Approved projects can receive up to $30,000.70 220
  • 241. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? The evaluation finds significant poverty impacts, but the design of the evaluation is unclear. Survey data were collected on participant and nonparticipant households. However, the authors do not specify how this sample was created. The authors then use a matching technique as well as an instrumental variables strategy to deal with selection. They do not discuss the matching variables or indicate when they were mea- sured. The district-level instrument is a measure of political participa- tion through voting; it is unclear how it can deal with selection at the household level. The second instrument is ownership of a refrigerator. Use of this measure ostensibly exploits the targeting criteria of the proj- ect, but as the data come years after the project is implemented, it is unclear why household assets years after the program was implemented should satisfy the exclusion restriction. Moreover, the data suggest that program participants are more likely than nonparticipants to own a refrigerator. Finally, the evaluation says nothing about the participa- tory process through which projects were identified, approved, and ultimately run. A qualitative study by Marcus (2002) underscores the lack of longer- Participatory project term sustainability of participatory efforts. Marcus’s study includes a investments in Mali, Mongolia, desk review of three social funds and an analysis of qualitative data from and Tajikistan were not beneficiary communities. The projects reviewed were implemented by sustainable, particularly Save the Children in Mali, Mongolia, and Tajikistan. The review finds for the poorest. that, on balance, project investments were not sustainable, particularly for the poorest, once targeted assistance in the form of school fees and food subsidies was phased out. Conclusions The literature on decentralized targeting identifies a trade-off between On balance, the evidence the advantages of local information and the hazards of local capture. appears to indicate that local On balance, the evidence appears to indicate that local capture can capture can overwhelm the overwhelm the benefits of local information. benefits of local information. Project design and implementation rules also play a critical role in determining whether participatory programs are captured. Demand- Demand-driven, competitive driven, competitive application processes can exclude the weakest com- application processes munities and exacerbate horizontal inequities. Under some conditions, can exclude the weakest co-financing requirements—which have become the sine qua non of communities and exacerbate participatory projects—can exacerbate the exclusion of the poorest horizontal inequities. 221
  • 242. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? households and communities and attenuate the impacts of poverty reduction programs. Co-financing requirements— Community contributions and a demand-driven competitive proj- which have become the sine ect approval process are expected to generate higher-quality projects qua non of participatory that are better aligned with community needs. They are also expected projects—can exacerbate to enhance the sustainability of community infrastructure by giving the exclusion of the poorest beneficiaries a real stake in maintaining local public goods. At the households and communities same time, if the most disadvantaged among the eligible have the least and attenuate the impacts of capacity to propose viable projects and are thus more likely to opt out poverty reduction programs. of the process altogether, the intended poverty reduction impacts of the program are attenuated and cross-community inequities in capacity and resources can increase. The political relationship between the center and localities also mat- ters, as do the incentives of local politicians under democratic decentral- ization. The objectives of the center and localities can diverge widely. Involving Communities On balance, the evidence On balance, the evidence suggests that greater community involvement suggests that greater tends to improve resource sustainability and the quality of infrastruc- community involvement ture. However, four concerns permeate the literature: tends to improve resource sustainability and the quality • Inequality tends to reduce both efficiency and equity, and there can be important tradeoffs between resource sustainability and of infrastructure. equity. • Transferring management responsibilities for a resource or an infrastructure scheme does not usually involve handing over control to a cohesive organic entity with the requisite capac- ity; often it requires creating local management capacity. In the absence of deliberate efforts to create such capacity and provide resources for ongoing maintenance and management, invest- ments in infrastructure are largely wasted and natural resources poorly managed. • Clear mechanisms for downward accountability are critical. The literature is rife with cases in which decentralization is used to tighten central control and increase incentives for upward accountability rather than to increase local discretion. The absence of robust mechanisms for downward accountability tends to go hand in hand with complex reporting and planning 222
  • 243. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? requirements, which are usually beyond the capacity of local actors and become a tool for retaining control and assigning patronage. Most of these requirements are holdovers from past rules designed to extract resources from local rather than benefit communities. • Communities need to benefit from the resources they manage. For natural resources that create substantial externalities, the benefit should be commensurate with the size of the externality created by the resource and should at least compensate com- munities for the alternative uses to which they could put the resource for immediate gain. These concerns imply consider- able engagement of higher-tier governments or implement- ing agencies in building local capacity, monitoring outcomes, and setting the broad parameters under which management is devolved—with a view to enhancing downward rather than upward accountability while leaving sufficient discretion at the local level. Decentralizing Delivery of Education and Health The evidence on the extent to which decentralizing the delivery of edu- cation and health has improved service access for the poor and other dis- advantaged groups and led to improvements in service quality is mixed. Because efforts to engage communities in improving basic health ser- vices or primary schools usually also involve a substantial injection of funds for other activities (trained health personnel, upgraded facilities, stipends, uniforms, school meals), unpacking the impact of community engagement is d ifficult. The few studies that try to do so suggest that encouraging community participation can be beneficial when projects also provide technical support, such as community-based trained health personnel, or make investments in upgrading health and school facilities. The evidence also suggests that the most successful programs are The most successful programs implemented by local governments that have some discretion and are are implemented by local downwardly accountable. Devolving programs to NGOs works less governments that have some well, on average. Interventions that provide information to households discretion and are downwardly and communities about the quality of services in their community as accountable. well as government standards of service tend to improve outcomes even when no additional resources are expended. 223
  • 244. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Improving Livelihoods A few studies find that Few studies of participatory poverty reduction programs fi nd clear projects with large livelihood poverty impacts. Some positive income effects emerge for subgroups, components perform better although in most cases the methodology used to generate these results than other participatory is questionable. There is some evidence, however, that projects with projects, but more evaluations larger livelihood components (credit, skills) perform better than other are needed. participatory projects, at least in the short run. Given this potential, such projects should be carefully evaluated. Notes 1. Leakage occurs when benefits accrue to people other than the intended beneficiaries. Undercoverage occurs when some intended beneficiaries cannot be covered, because of budget constraints. 2. A poverty monitoring tool allows eligibility to be enforced though an administrative process, using indicators of household or community wel- fare that are intended to proxy for income, which is costly and often dif- ficult to observe. The process usually involves some type of means test based on easily observed and verified aspects of a household’s or community’s poverty status, such as demographic and socioeconomic characteristics that are expected to be strongly correlated with relative deprivation. 3. Although private transfers can also include some stipulations to contribute labor (as in the case of workfare programs) or undertake specific behaviors (such as vaccinating one’s children or enrolling them in school), the benefits are largely internalized by the household in the form of income or gains from improved health and schooling. This is not the case for the provision of free labor for a nonexcludable local public good, as the labor-providing household can internalize only a fraction of the benefits. 4. As Galasso and Ravallion (2005) note, the requirement that all thanas (municipalities or county subdivisions) participate in the program is likely to have constrained the scope for pro-poor geographic targeting at the center. Such political economy constraints tend to be a common feature of social programs. 5. Despite their higher allocations, the provinces were initially less able to target their poor areas, possibly because wealthier areas were better able to propose and co-finance feasible projects. In response, a project monitor- ing tool was developed to continuously update targeting performance at the district level. Ravallion (2000) shows that this simple but powerful tool—which can be adapted for regular project monitoring and evalua- tion—was able to substantially improve the intraprovincial targeting of the poor. 6. Because data on the shares obtained by provinces are not available, it is unclear how successful this effort was. 224
  • 245. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? 7. Proxy means tests are increasingly being used to target beneficiaries pre- cisely because of concerns about program capture. They tend to impose uniform eligibility requirements, with some regional variation, leaving little room for discretion in the identification of beneficiaries at the local level. 8. Mustafa (2007), for example, views British colonial water development projects in India and Pakistan as an effort to increase the power of the state and ensure security. British authorities sought to “increase government control of the local populations by encouraging them to take up settled agriculture and thereby minimize the security threat they might pose to the power of the state.” Mosse (2001) emphasizes that political control has always been a component of decentralized task management in India; it was part of a political process that allowed chiefs to maintain and extend their control 9. These developments were reflected in the title of the Eighth World Forestry Congress—“Forests for People”—held in 1978. The same year, both the Food and Agriculture Organization and the World Bank presented policy papers indicating the change in focus (Hobley 1996; Arnold 1998; Wardell and Lund 2006; see also Dasgupta 2009). 10. In 1992, the Rio Declaration and Agenda 21 called for participatory natu- ral resource management strategies as means of increasing efficiency and equity in natural resource use and management. The emphasis on poverty reduction was strengthened even more in the United Nations Millennium Declaration (United Nations 2000). 11. Forestry, for example, historically focused on establishing plantations and woodlots. The handing over of rights to existing natural forests to rural communities emerged only in the 1980s (Arnold 1998). 12. Scholarship on common property regimes spans many disciplines. Anthropologists, resource economists, environmentalists, historians, politi- cal scientists, rural sociologists, and others have contributed to the growing body of literature, which also comprises political ecological, ethnographic, and historical approaches. Although Ostrom’s work has clearly been the most influential in this regard, Dasgupta, Agarwal, Ribot, Bardhan, and others have also made important contributions. Recent empirical work on the commons draws significantly on theories of property rights and institutions. For a review of some of this literature, see; Bates (1989); Libecap (1989); Eggertsson (1990); North (1990); and the introduction in Ensminger (1992), which discusses the early foundations of this litera- ture in the work of Coase (1960), Cheung (1970), Commons (1970), and Alchian and Demsetz (1972). 13. As Ribot, Lund, and Treue (2010) note, democratic decentralization is specifically about including whole populations—all citizens—in decision making based on representative authority, whereas CBNRM defines a community for each intervention (the user group, “stakeholders,” fish- ers). Under CBNRM, the mode of representation of the “community” is variously defined through appointed committees, elected committees, stakeholder forums, participatory processes, customary chiefs, project 225
  • 246. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? personnel, and so forth. In contrast, democratic decentralization involves transfers to elected local government authorities, and the community is defined simply as the citizens who live in the jurisdiction. 14. See also Morrow and Hull’s (1996) study of the Yanesha Forestry Cooperative in Peru. 15. As the paper relies on a single cross-section and forest user groups were not placed randomly, the author uses a number of creative econometric strate- gies, including the use of administrative data to control for heterogeneity in the placement of forest groups. The results remain robust. The main outcome measure is self-reported collections of firewood and fodder. 16. Their empirical strategy involves comparing adjacent VP and non–VP for- est parcels in order to control for unobservable community characteristics. They also control for a number of geographical attributes (such as slope, aspect, altitude, and distance from the village) that affect forest quality. 17. The study uses a large sample of randomly selected forest parcels and objective measures of forest quality, including canopy cover, height, girth, species of trees, and lopping and regeneration rates. The authors deal with unobserved heterogeneity in the existence of a VP by comparing conditions in VP and non–VP forest patches that are adjacent to a particular village. This methodology allows them to control for time-invariant characteristics of local geography, climate, and communities. They address the potential for negative externalities to neighboring non–VP forests by including controls for distance to the nearest VP forest. 18. Khwaja (2009), for example, notes that communities often report choosing a particular type of project simply because they believed that it was one the external agency could or would approve; asking for a different type of project, they believed, would lead to not getting any project at all. 19. Project complexity was measured by whether the project required cash or skilled labor and the community’s experience in maintaining such a project. 20. Controlling for inequality in wealth (land ownership), an increase in the heterogeneity index from the first to the third quartile (0.25–0.43) is associated with a 7 percent drop in maintenance. 21. The argument is that as a member’s share of project returns increases, her share of maintenance costs may not increase commensurately if free riding is possible and maintenance costs are increasing. However, as inequality in returns increases further, people with substantial shares may become willing to bear the necessary maintenance costs, perhaps by contracting out the work. 22. Survey data included engineers’ assessments of the quality of project con- struction, the physical condition of the project on the survey date, and beneficiary assessments of project performance. Information on household landholdings, assets, caste, education, and other characteristics for all households in study villages came from the census. 23. The NRSP operates much like the Agha Khan Rural Support Program. Both are now substantially funded by an apex institution, the Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund, which is financed by the World Bank. 226
  • 247. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? 24. An increase in the quality of the leader from the first to the third quartile increased the quality of maintenance by almost 8 percentage points. 25. The exogeneity argument relies on the fact that both the subdistrict and the village are administrative units based on population and geography and are thus not likely to be influenced by the presence of the KDP. However, it is not clear that the number of villages per subdistrict is uncorrelated with other unobserved subdistrict characteristics, such as ethnic heterogeneity or geography, which could exert an independent effect on project quality. For example, location and geography could influence local labor market conditions, the cost of materials and transportation, construction methods, and pre–KDP stocks of village infrastructure. Similarly, if ethnic/religious identity is part of the calculation in setting administrative boundaries, subdistricts with greater ethnic diversity could have a larger number of more homogeneous villages. If such villages are also more cohesive, with higher levels of village monitoring, average project quality could be higher in subdistricts that comprise more villages. Given the limitations this study faces in relying exclusively on administrative data from the KDP, it deals with these issues well. 26. Gunnarsson and others (2009) use data from eight Latin American coun- tries. They find that differences across countries explain just 9 percent of the variation in school autonomy and 6 percent of the variation in community participation, although cross-country differences in man- dated levels of autonomy and participation are substantial. Educational systems are highly nationalized in Bolivia and the Dominican Republic; more locally managed in Brazil, Chile, and Colombia; and somewhere in between in Argentina and Peru. Interestingly, the two countries with the greatest parental participation, Colombia and the Dominican Republic, are at opposite ends of the range of legal centralization. Cuba has both extremely low levels of autonomy and participation and extremely high educational achievement. 27. The program they evaluate sought to address the challenges created by the introduction of free primary education in Kenya and the associated influx of new students with varying levels of academic preparation. 28. A second component of this program was a training program for parent associations, which provided training in the management of school funds and in the participatory management process. The authors do not evaluate this component, which was introduced at a later stage. 29. The authors use the gradual phasing in of the intervention to identify average treatment effects using a pipeline approach. An index of school quality (which included student density; teacher student ratio; and failure, repetition, and dropout rates) was used to target schools for AGE. The authors use this index to check whether schools that received AGE during the study period were similar at baseline to schools that received AGE later. They also use school fi xed effects and a school-specific linear time trend. Although this strategy cannot deal with unobserved time-variant school characteristics that are correlated with both the timing of AGE treatment and the quality outcomes of interest, the authors argue correctly that such 227
  • 248. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? unobserved time-variant school characteristics are unlikely to be driving the results. The authors also find little evidence that changes in unobserved student ability drove the results. Not only did they find no effect on the dropout rate in treatment schools but, compared with preintervention trends, enrollment levels actually improved. 30. The film, poster, and calendar conveyed information on the detailed roles and responsibilities of the three state-specific school oversight committees. The intervention was conducted in three rounds in each gram panchayat (village council), separated by a period of two to three weeks. Each round consisted of two to three meetings in different neighborhoods of the gram panchayat. The campaign also included the distribution of posters and take-home calendars and the convening of neighborhood meetings to ensure participation by members of disadvantaged castes. The tools were the same in all three states (the information communicated was state spe- cific, pertaining to the School Development and Monitoring Committee (SDMC) in Karnataka, the parent-teacher association in Madhya Pradesh, and the village education committee in Uttar Pradesh). In addition to the information campaign treatment in each of the three states, a second treatment was tested only in Karnataka. The only dimension in which the second treatment was different from the first was that the film had an additional one- to two-minute component at the end. To increase aware- ness about the economic benefits of schooling, this component showed average wages in the state for different levels of schooling and encouraged the audience to become involved in monitoring outcomes at the school. 31. The school reform in the state of São Paolo allowed municipalities to take over any primary or secondary school. During the period of the study, municipal governments took over more than half of all state-run schools. The author uses this gradual takeover to identify the impact of school decentralization on intermediate outcomes. As municipal govern- ments could decide which schools to decentralize, the impact of school decentralization cannot be assessed without accounting for this selection effect. The direction of the bias is unclear, as municipalities could choose to decentralize either the best- or the worst-performing schools in order to show the greatest impact from decentralization. The author deals with this problem by using an eight-year school panel. The data include a large number of time-variant characteristics for each school and its community and span the period before and after decentralization, allowing the author to conduct robustness checks, including a check for parallel trends, to deal with the potential bias caused by initial selection. 32. Municipal governments in Brazil are required to provide primary educa- tion; preprimary education is offered on an optional basis, with substantial variation in provision levels. Kosec uses changes in the law that occurred in 1998 (FUNDEF) and 2007 (FUNDEB) and panel data on municipal education policy over a 13-year period (1995–2008). 33. Both Galiani, Gertler, and Schargrodsky (2008) and Rodriguez (2006) rely on variation in the timing of decentralization across provinces to identify the impact of decentralization. 228
  • 249. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? 34. School committees were randomly assigned to receive or not receive a grant. All funded school committees then received one of three interven- tions: training, democratic election of school committee members, or a facilitated collaboration between the school committee and the village council (linkage), yielding eight study arms in all. The sample included 520 schools in 9 districts and 44 subdistricts in the provinces of Java and Yogyakarta; 100 schools were left as controls. The data come from three surveys: a baseline (administered in 2007), a midterm (administered in early 2008), and an endline (administered in late 2008). 35. The study uses a combination of pipeline and matching methods to esti- mate the impact of social fund investments. 36. There was considerable deviation from assigned status. To deal with this problem, the authors report estimates of impact using assigned treatment status (that is, “intent to treat”) as well as actual treatment status, using assigned status as an instrument as well as an input into the propensity score in a matching approach. 37. A village development committee has a population of about 7,000. Forty- two village development committees were matched into 21 pairs on the basis of ethnic composition and population density; 12 random pairs were selected for the study (1 intervention and 1 control cluster in each pair). 38. The sample comes from 36 rural clusters in 3 districts (12 per district), with a total population of 228,000. Eighteen clusters were randomly allocated to the treatment group, the other 18 were held as controls. All women 15–49 who had given birth during the study period (July 2005–July 2008) could participate; women could enter anytime if they gave birth. Baseline mortality rates were established over a nine-month period. 39. The grants—whose average size ranged from $8,500 in 2007 to $18,200 in 2009—could be used for a range of health-related activities, including hiring extra midwives or teachers for the village, subsidizing the costs of prenatal and postnatal care to women, providing supplementary meals to children, offering scholarships, improving health or school facilities, and rehabilitating roads to improve access to health and education facilities during the rainy season. Activities had to be used to support one of the 12 indicators of health and education service delivery identified by the program, which included antenatal and postnatal care, childbirth assisted by trained birth attendant, immunization, school enrollment, and school attendance, among others. 40. Facilitators from local NGOs led three meetings: a meeting with commu- nity members, a meeting with the staff of the relevant health facility, and a meeting that brought the community and health facility staff together. At the community meeting, facilitators provided community members with an assessment of the performance of the relevant primary health care facility, both in absolute terms and relative to other local providers and the government standard for health service delivery at the dispensary level. Communities were then encouraged to identify the key problems and the best way to monitor the provider. The health facility staff meeting was held at the health facility. At this meeting, the facilitators contrasted 229
  • 250. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? information on the quality of service provision they had obtained from the baseline survey with the information provided by the facility. At the third meeting, community representatives and health facility staff developed a shared action plan, or a contract, outlining what needed to be done and how and when it would be done, as well as who would be responsible. After the initial meetings, the community was expected to monitor the provider. However, facilitators supported this process through follow-up meetings. These meetings took place during the facilitator’s day-to-day interaction with the community-based organizations in the village. 41. In 2005, federal government transfers to municipalities totaled R$5.7 bil- lion (about $2.6 billion), which represents about $14 per person covered. This figure does not include the municipal contributions, which varied from zero to almost 100 percent. 42. The authors add micro-region fi xed effects as well as a number of other time-variant regional variables to reduce potential selection problems; they do not test for parallel trends before the study period, however, without which the conditional exogeneity of program expansion rates cannot be assumed. 43. The authors do a careful job of dealing with selection issues. To deal with time-invariant differences across municipalities, such as differences in initial mortality rates or health service quality, they add municipal fi xed effects to the difference-in-difference specification. Time-variant differences, such as the occurrence of health shocks, are more problem- atic. The authors include state-specific time dummies to deal with this issue. Because the number of municipalities was large, they could not use municipality-specific time trends. Instead, they add a wide range of munici- pality variables, including immunization coverage, health and education infrastructure, and municipality population. They cluster standard errors at the municipality level. 44. For mortality of children ages 1–4, the coefficients correspond to reduc- tions of 6.4 percent (0.07 in absolute terms) for municipalities three years into the program and 25 percent (0.28 in absolute terms) for municipalities eight years into the program. 45. In the North, a municipality eight years into the program is estimated to experience a reduction of 15.0 infant deaths per 1,000 live births. The reduction in the Northeast is 13.8 per 1,000 live births. 46. Sessions were to be held quarterly, in a local household, with adolescent girls, women of reproductive age, and older women. Lady health workers and traditional birth attendants were expected to facilitate these sessions using materials specifically developed for this purpose, including a docu- drama on pregnancy and newborn care. 47. The 12 districts selected for the study were randomly assigned to three groups: four were eligible to receive “contracting-in” bids, four were eligible to receive “contracting-out” bids, and four served as a comparison group. The authors collected data on individual health care outcomes and care- seeking behavior from a random sample of 30 villages in each of the 12 districts involved in the contracting project. About 20,000 people in 3,700 230
  • 251. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? households were included in the samples. A baseline survey was conducted in 1997; a full follow-up was conducted in 2003. Although the same vil- lages were sampled in both survey years, within villages a new random sample of households was taken each time. The data are thus a panel at the village level and a repeated cross-section at the household level. In treated districts, the management of government health care services was put out to competitive bid by qualified organizations, such as NGOs and private firms. For each district, the organization with the highest combined score on the technical quality of the proposal and price was awarded a contract to manage the district’s government health care service. In the end, only international NGOs, firms, and universities submitted bids. All the win- ners were international NGOs. The comparison districts continued to be managed by local employees. 48. In the end, only a few staff members were fired. Salaries in the “contracting in” districts were based on the civil service pay structure, plus additional amounts decided by the contractors that could be raised from user fees. In “contracting-out” districts, NGOs were free to implement the pay structure of their choosing. 49. Not all districts in the initial treatment groups were actually treated. The authors report “treatment on treated” effects using assignment to treatment as an instrument. 50. Each hospital continued to receive the same line-item grants from the state government to ensure prereform levels of funding. The RKS also raised its own money through user fees, the leasing of hospital property, loans, and donations. It had full autonomy over the use of hospital assets but no authority over government-appointed doctors. 51. It identified transfer of control as the date at which the RKS became active, as reflected in the date at which it started to collect revenue. It aggregated RKS activity at the district level and grouped districts into high- and low-exposure, within which it measured exposure as the number of years in a high-exposure district. The estimation includes district and cohort fi xed effects as well as controls for maternal demographics and child characteristics. The poor are identified as holders of Below Poverty Line (BPL) cards, issued by the government for a range of poverty-related benefits. 52. Participating municipalities receive an annual grant, equivalent to =300,000 for each barangay (the smallest administrative unit, often a vil- P lage). The grant is then allocated competitively among barangays in the municipality. The annual per capita allocation is about =300. The project P was implemented in the poorest quartile of municipalities. The study uses propensity score matching to create comparison municipalities. As the program was provided at the municipal level, matching was done at the municipal level. The final sample included 16 municipalities, half of which received the program and half of which served as controls. Comparison municipalities were clearly better off at baseline, but a check for parallel trends finds no significant differences between treatment and control municipalities once standard errors are corrected for intramunicipality 231
  • 252. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? correlation. Data were collected at three points in time: baseline (2003), midline (2006), and endline (2010). 53. Since treatment assignment was at the municipal level while analysis was at the household level, a correction needs to be done to account for the intracluster correlation of standard errors at the municipal level. Given the small number of municipalities included in the study, this correction is likely to substantially increase standard errors. Although this correc- tion is made for the parallel trends estimation—wiping out all differences between treatment and control municipalities, as one might expect—no standard error correction is reported for the impact results. 54. The author uses propensity score matching methods to create a matched sample of 300 treatment and control subdistricts. The treated subdistricts were drawn from treated subdistricts in the 2002 SUSENAS survey, which also serves as the baseline, in conjunction with the 2003 PODES village census. Control subdistricts were drawn from non–KDP subdistricts in the same survey that did not benefit from similar government programs. A matched sample of about 6,000 households was also created using available household characteristics. The follow-up data were collected in 2007. 55. The baseline and midline surveys were also conducted at different times, with the follow-up overlapping Ramadan, the Muslim month of fasting, followed by the Eid festival, when consumption is higher, particularly among the poor. 56. Chapter 6 discusses the study’s findings on social cohesion and collective action. 57. A communauté rurale is an administrative unit with 42 villages on average and a population of about 13,000, 58. The study uses data from 36 communautés rurales, half of which were controls. The sample includes 71 villages, 750 households, and 1,000 children. Analysis is done at the village, household, and child level, using baseline and follow-up data. Village, household, and child fi xed effects are included, depending on the level of analysis. The authors check for parallel trends across treatment and control communities in the key outcome variables before PNIR and cannot reject the null hypothesis of similar trends. However, this check for parallel trends is run at the level of the communauté rurale, whereas the analysis is conducted at the child, household, and village level. 59. Political influence variables at the village level are used as instruments to deal with potential selection in project awards. A concern with this strategy is that it is not clear whether political influence affects village outcomes only through its effects on accessing PNIR funds. If political influence can also be used to attract other public or private resources to the village, the exclusion conditions necessary for the use of political influence variables as instruments would be violated. 60. The authors do not check for parallel trends in outcome variables before program inception. It is therefore unclear whether the propensity score matching exercise and difference-in-difference technique can take care of selection bias from time-invariant or time-variant sources. 232
  • 253. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? 61. A typical program self-help group consists of 10–15 members who meet regularly to discuss social issues and activities, make a small deposit into a joint account, and make decisions on loans. 62. In later years, the program also tried to increase the availability of rice to low-income households through bulk purchases from the public distribu- tion system and resale to poor village households at a discounted price. Rice was provided as an in-kind loan for self-help group members. The provision of grain as in-kind credit when needed was also expected to boost meeting attendance, saving, and repayment. 63. The program covered 148,000 villages officially designated as poor, which represent about 21 percent of all villages in rural China. Some 140 million people (about 15 percent of China’s rural population) live in these villages. 64. The authors find a substantial increase in overall spending on public infrastructure in program villages with completed projects. This increased spending occurred because of larger investments by both the government and the village community, suggesting that community financing was used to leverage government funds, as is the practice in community-driven development projects. Interestingly, however, the program had no effect on what the authors describe as village corvée labor. It is not clear whether the supply of such labor failed to increase because villages were not required to contribute labor to the projects or because villagers responded by reducing labor on other communal activities. There is also some heterogeneity in the financing of infrastructure investments in western versus nonwestern regions. The increase in investment was twice as large in nonwestern villages, entirely because of larger contributions from the community, including village labor. In contrast, communal labor inputs were reduced in western villages that began investments under the project. 65. Of the 588 villages in the matched sample, 552 had at least one poor household, 484 had at least one nonpoor household, and 448 villages had both nonpoor and poor households. The restricted sample included the 448 villages with both types of households. A comparison of results for nonpoor and poor households using the restricted sample is analogous to controlling for village fi xed effects, as the authors compare the average change in income for the village poor (nonpoor) with the average change for the village poor (nonpoor) in the matched village. As villages with both nonpoor and poor households are more heterogeneous with respect to poverty, a comparison of estimates for the restricted and full samples also suggests how program impacts may vary along this dimension. 66. By the end of 2004, 55 percent of poor villages (366 sample villages) had completed plans and 37 percent (244 sample villages) had begun investments based on the plans. According to the authors, a main reason why most villages had yet to begin planned investments three years after the program began was that county governments generally concentrated annual program allocations in a subset of villages. The decision to fund village plans sequentially rather than simultaneously reflected practical concerns, such as economies of scale in investments and the fi xed costs associated with supervising the design and implementation of plans in 233
  • 254. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? each village. The village data confirm that the increase in treated villages over time reflected the gradual expansion of investments in new villages within rather than across counties. 67. Some 1,800 of a total of 7,600 villages were selected in the three counties, using specific and objective criteria. 68. As program placement was targeted based on geography and poverty, the authors obtain a counterfactual set of villages by selecting randomly from non–SWP villages in the same counties and then using propensity score matching methods to arrive at a plausible counterfactual. 69. Neither study includes data on the longer-term sustainability of impact from the grant or skills and business training. 70. Targeting of the poorest was ensured through a two-step process. In the first stage, the poorest districts in the three departments were identified using a poverty map. In the second stage, households were screened based on eligibility criteria (in rural areas, households could not own more than two cows or farm more than 10 hectares; in all areas, households could not own an air conditioner, a refrigerator, or a four-wheel vehicle). Participatory targeting was not used to identify beneficiaries, despite the participatory intent of the program. References Adhikari, B., and J. C. Lovett. 2006. “Institutions and Collective Action: Does Heterogeneity Matter in Community-Based Resource Management?” Journal of Development Studies 42(3): 426–45. Agrawal, A. 2010. “Environment, Community, Government.” In In the Name of Humanity, ed. I. Feldman and M. Ticktin, 190–217. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Agrawal, A., and C. Benson. 2010. “Local Resource Governance Institutions: Outcomes and Explanations.” Background paper for Policy Research Report, World Bank, Washington, DC. Agrawal, A., and A. Chhatre. 2006. “Explaining Success on the Commons: Community Forest Governance in the Indian Himalaya.” World Development 35: 149–66. Agrawal, A., A. Chhatre, and R. Hardin. 2008. “Changing Governance of the World’s Forests.” Science 320: 1460–62. Alatas, V., A. Banerjee, R. Hanna, B. A. Olken, and J. Tobias. 2012. “How to Target the Poor: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia.” American Economic Review 102(4): 1206–40. Alchian, A., and H. Demsetz. 1972. “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization.” American Economic Review 62: 777–95. Alderman, H. 2002. “Do Local Officials Know Something We Don’t? Decentralization of Targeted Transfers in Albania.” Journal of Public Economics 83(3): 375–404. 234
  • 255. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Alwang, J., E. Gacitua-Mario, and V. Centurion. 2008. “Economic and Social Impacts on Participating Households of a Community-Driven Development Project in Southern Paraguay.” World Bank, Washington, DC. Araujo, M. C., F. H. G. Ferreira, P. Lanjouw, and B. Özler. 2008. “Local Inequality and Project Choice: Theory and Evidence from Ecuador.” Journal of Public Economics 92(5–6): 1022–46. Arcand, J.-L., and L. Bassole. 2008. “Does Community Driven Development Work? Evidence from Senegal.” CERDI–CNRS, Université d’Auvergne, France. Arnold, M. 1998. “Managing Forests as a Common Property.” Working Paper 136, Food and Agricultural Organization, Rome. Baird, I. G. 2006. “Strength in Diversity: Fish Sanctuaries and Deep-Water Pools in Laos.” Fisheries Management and Ecology 13(1): 1–8. Baird, S., C. McIntosh, and B. Özler. 2009. The Squeaky Wheels Get the Grease: Applications and Targeting in Tanzania’s Social Action Fund. Development Economics Research Group, World Bank, Washington, DC. Baland, J. M., P. Bardhan, S. Das, and D. Mookherjee. 2010. “Forests to the People: Decentralization and Forest Degradation in the Indian Himalayas.” World Development 38(11): 1642–56. Baland, J. M., and J. P. Platteau. 1997. “Coordination Problems in Local-Level Resource Management.” Journal of Development Economics 53 (1): 197–210. Banerjee, A. V., R. Banerji, E. Duf lo, R. Glennerster, and S. Khemani. 2010. “Pitfalls of Participatory Programs: Evidence from Randomized Experiments in Education in India.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 2(1): 1–30. Baqui, A. H., S. El-Arifeen, G. L. Darmstadt, S. Ahmed, E. K. Williams, H. R. Seraji, and I. Mannan. 2008. “Effect of Community-Based Newborn-Care Intervention Package Implemented Through Two Service-Delivery Strategies in Sylhet District, Bangladesh: A Cluster- Randomised Controlled Trial.” Lancet 371: 1936–44. Bardhan, P. 2000. “Irrigation and Cooperation: An Empirical Analysis of 48 Irrigation Communities in South India.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 48(4): 847–65. Bardhan, P., M. Ghatak, and A. Karaivanov. 2007. “Wealth Inequality and Collective Action.” Journal of Public Economics 91(9): 1843–74. Bardhan, P, S. Mitra, D. Mookherjee, and A. Sarkar. 2008. “Political Participation, Clientelism, and Targeting of Local Government Programs.” Discussion Paper, Economic Research Unit/2008-03, Indian Statistical Institute, Calcutta. Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2005. “Decentralization, Corruption, and Government Accountability: An Overview.” In International Handbook of Economic Corruption, ed. S. Rose-Ackerman. Northhampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing. Barrera-Osorio, F., and L. L. Linden. 2009. “The Use and Misuse of Computers in Education: Evidence from a Randomized Experiment in Colombia.” Policy Research Working Paper 4836, World Bank, Washington, DC. 235
  • 256. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Bates, R. 1989. Toward a Political Economy of Agrarian Development in Kenya. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Beck, T., and C. Nesmith. 2001. “Building on Poor People’s Capacities: The Case of Common Property Resources in India and West Africa.” World Development 29(1): 119–33. Besley, T., and R. Kanbur. 1993. “The Principles of Targeting.” In Including the Poor, ed. M. Lipton and J. Van der Gaag, 67–90. Washington, DC: World Bank. Besley, T., R. Pande, and V. Rao. 2005. “Participatory Democracy in Action: Survey Evidence from Rural India.” Journal of the European Economic Association 3(2–3): 648–57. ———. 2007. “Just Rewards? Local Politics and Public Resource Allocation in South India.” Development Economics Paper, London School of Economics and the Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines, London. Bhutta, Z. Q. A., S. Soofi, S. Cousens, S. Mohammad, Z. A. Memon, I. Ali, and A. Feroze. 2011. “Improvement of Perinatal and Newborn Care in Rural Pakistan Through Community-Based Strategies: A Cluster- Randomised Effectiveness Trial.” Lancet 377: 403–12. Binka, F. N., A. A. Bawah, J. F. Phillips, A. Hodgson, M. Adjuik, and B. Macleod. 2007. “Rapid Achievement of the Child Survival Millennium Development Goal: Evidence from the Navrongo Experiment in Northern Ghana.” Tropical Medicine and International Health 12: 578–83. Bjorkman, M., and J. Svensson. 2007. “Power to the People: Evidence from a Randomized Field Experiment of a Community-Based Monitoring Project in Uganda.” Policy Research Working Paper 4268, World Bank, Washington, DC. Blaikie, P. 2006. “Is Small Really Beautiful? Community-Based Natural Resource Management in Malawi and Botswana.” World Development 34(11): 1942–57. Blattman, C., N. Fiala, and S. Martinez. 2011. “Can Employment Programs Reduce Poverty and Social Instability? Experimental Evidence from a Ugandan Aid Program (Mid-Term Results).” Yale University, New Haven, CT. Bruns, B., D. Filmer, and H. A. Patrinos. 2011. Making Schools Work New Evidence on Accountability Reforms. Washington, DC: World Bank. Caldwell, B. J. 2005. School-Based Management. Education Policy Series. Paris: International Institute for Educational Planning (IIEP) and International Academy of Education (IAE). Campbell, T. 2003. Quiet Revolution: Decentralization and the Rise of Political Participation in Latin American Cities. Pittsburg, PA: University of Pittsburg Press. Casey, K., R. Glennerster, and E. Miguel. 2011. “Reshaping Institutions: Evidence on External Aid and Local Collective Action.” NBER Working Paper 17012, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Cavendish, W. 2000. “Empirical Regularities in the Poverty-Environment Relationship of Rural Households: Evidence from Zimbabwe.” World Development 28(11): 1979–2003. 236
  • 257. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Chase, R. S. 2002. “Supporting Communities in Transition: The Impact of the Armenian Social Investment Fund.” World Bank Economic Review 16(2): 219–40. Chase, R. S., and L. Sherburne-Benz. 2001. “Household Effects of Community Education and Health Initiatives: Evaluating the Impact of the Zambia Social Fund.” World Bank, Social Development Unit, Washington, DC. Chaudhury, N., and D. Parajuli. 2010. “Giving It Back: Evaluating the Impact of Devolution of School Management to Communities in Nepal.” World Bank, Washington, DC. Chavis, L. 2009. “Decentralizing Development: Allocating Public Goods via Competition.” Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill. Chen, S., R. Mu, and M. Ravallion. 2009. “Are There Lasting Impacts of Aid to Poor Areas?” Journal of Public Economics 93(3–4): 512–28. Cheung, S. 1970. “The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of Non- Exclusive Resources.” Journal of Law and Economics 13(1): 49–70. Coady, D. 2001. “An Evaluation of the Distributional Power of Progresa’s Cash Transfers in Mexico.” FCND Discussion Paper, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC. Coase, R. H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3(1): 1–44. Commons, J. R. 1970. The Economics of Collective Action. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press. Dasgupta, P. 2009. “Trust and Cooperation among Economic Agents.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society 364: 3301–09. Dasgupta, P. and K. G. Mäler. 1995. “Poverty, Institutions, and the Environmental Resource-Base.” In Handbook of Development Economics, vol. III(A), ed. J. Behrman and T. N. Srinivasan, 2371–63. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Dayton-Johnson, J. 2000. “Choosing Rules to Govern the Commons: A Model with Evidence from Mexico.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 42(1): 19–41. Dayton-Johnson, J., and P. Bardhan. 2002. “Inequality and Conservation on the Local Commons: A Theoretical Exercise.” Economic Journal 112(481): 577–602. Deininger, K., and Y. Liu. 2009. “Longer-Term Economic Impacts of Self- Help Groups in India.” Policy Research Working Paper 4886, World Bank, Washington, DC. De Janvry, A., H. Nakagawa, and E. Sadoulet. 2009. “Pro-Poor Targeting and Electoral Rewards in Decentralizing to Communities the Provision of Local Public Goods in Rural Zambia.” University of California, Berkeley. Di Gropello, E. 2006. “A Comparative Analysis of School-Based Management in Central America.” Working Paper 72, World Bank, Washington, DC. Duflo, E., P. Dupas, and M. Kremer. 2008. “Peer Effects, Pupil-Teacher Ratios, and Teacher Incentives: Evidence from a Randomized Evaluation in Kenya.” Online Working Paper CCPR 055-08, California Center for Population Research, University of California, Los Angeles. 237
  • 258. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Edmonds, E. V. 2002. “Government-Initiated Community Resource Management and Local Resource Extraction from Nepal’s Forests.” Journal of Development Economics 68(1): 89–115. Eggertsson, T. 1990. Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Ensminger, J. 1992. Making a Market: The Institutional Transformation of an African Society. New York: Cambridge University Press. Eskeland, G. S., and D. Filmer. 2002. “Autonomy, Participation, and Learning in Argentine Schools: Findings and Their Implications for Decentralization.” Policy Research Working Paper 276, World Bank, Washington, DC. Fearon, J. D., M. Humphreys, and J. M. Weinstein. 2009. “Can Development Aid Contribute to Social Cohesion after Civil War? Evidence from a Field Experiment in Post-Conflict Liberia.” American Economic Review 99(2): 287–91. Ferguson, J. 1996. The Anti-Politics Machine. Development, Depolitization, and Bureaucratic Power in Lesotho. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Fisher, M. 2004. “Household Welfare and Forest Dependence in Southern Malawi.” Environment and Development Economics 9(2): 135–54. Fujiie, M., Y. Hayami, and M. Kikuchi. 2005. “The Conditions of Collective Action for Local Commons Management: The Case of Irrigation in the Philippines.” Agricultural Economics 33(2): 179–89. Galasso, E., and M. Ravallion. 2005. “Decentralized Targeting of an Antipoverty Program.” Journal of Public Economics 89(4): 705–27. Galiani, S., P. Gertler, and E. Schargrodsky. 2008. “School Decentralization: Helping the Good Get Better, but Leaving the Poor Behind.” Journal of Public Economics 92: 2106–20. Gertler, P., H. Patrinos, and M. Rubio-Codina. 2007. “Empowering Parents to Improve Education: Evidence from Rural Mexico.” Policy Research Working Paper 3935, World Bank, Washington, DC. Gine, X., and G. Mansuri. 2012. “Money or Ideas? A Field Experiment on Constraints to Entrepreneurship in Rural Pakistan.” World Bank, Washington, DC. Gregerson, H. M., and A. H. Contreras. 1989. Economic Analysis of Forestry Projects. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization. Gugerty, M. K., and M. Kremer. 2006. Outside Funding and the Dynamics of Participation in Community Associations. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Gunnarsson, V., P. F. Orazem, M. A. Sanchez, and A. Verdisco. 2009. “Does Local School Control Raise Student Outcomes? Evidence on the Roles of School Autonomy and Parental Participation.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 58: 25–52. Harragin, S. 2004. “Relief and an Understanding of Local Knowledge: The Case of Southern Sudan.” In Culture and Public Action, ed. V. Rao and M. Walton, 307–27. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. 238
  • 259. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Hobley, M. 1996. “Institutional Change within the Forestry Sector: Centralized Decentralization.” Working Paper 92, Overseas Development Institute, London. Hodgkin, J., and M. Kusumahadi. 1993. “A Study of the Sustainability of Care-Assisted Water Supply and Sanitation Projects, 1979–1991.” Associates in Rural Development, Burlington, VT. Isham, J., and S. Kahkonen. 2002. “Institutional Determinants of the Impact of Community-Based Water Services: Evidence from Sri Lanka and India.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 50(3): 667–91. Jalan, J., and M. Ravallion. 2003. “Estimating the Benefit Incidence of an Antipoverty Program by Propensity-Score Matching.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 21(1): 19–30. Jimenez, E., and Y. Sawada. 1999. “Do Community-Managed Schools Work? An Evaluation of El Salvador’s Educo Program.” World Bank Economic Review 13(3): 415–41. ———. 2003. “Does Community Management Help Kids in Schools? Evidence Using Panel Data from El Salvador’s Educo Program.” Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo. Jodha, N. S. 1986. “Common Property Resources and Rural Poor in Dry Regions of India.” Economic and Political Weekly 21(27): 1169–81. ———. 2001. Common Property Resources in Crisis. New Delhi: Oxford University Press. Jokhio, A. H., H. R. Winter, and K. K. Cheng. 2005. “An Intervention Involving Traditional Birth Attendants and Perinatal and Maternal Mortality in Pakistan.” New England Journal of Medicine 325: 2091–99. Katz, T., and J. Sara. 1997. “Making Rural Water Supply Sustainable: Recommendations from a Global Study.” World Bank, Washington, DC. Khattri, N., C. Ling, and S. Jha. 2010. “The Effects of School-Based Management in the Philippines: A n Initia l A ssessment Using Administrative Data.” Policy Research Working Paper 5248, World Bank, Washington, DC. Khwaja, A. I. 2004. “Is Increasing Community Participation Always a Good Thing?” Journal of the European Economic Association 2(2–3): 427–36. ———. 2009. “Can Good Projects Succeed in Bad Communities?” Journal of Public Economics 93(7–8): 899–916. King, E. M., and B. Özler. 1998. “What’s Decentralization Got to Do with Learning? The Case of Nicaragua’s School Autonomy Reform.” World Bank, Development Economics Research Group, Washington, DC. King, E. M., B. Özler, and L. B. Rawlings. 1999. “Nicaragua’s School Autonomy Reform: Fact or Fiction?” Working Paper 19, Impact Evaluation of Education Reforms Series, World Bank, Washington, DC. Kleemeier, E. 2000. “The Impact of Participation on Sustainability: An Analysis of the Malawi Rural Piped Scheme Program.” World Development 28(5): 929–44. Kosec, K. 2011. “Politics and Preschool: The Political Economy of Investment in Pre-Primary Education.” Policy Research Working Paper Series 5647, World Bank, Washington, DC. 239
  • 260. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Kremer, M., E. Bloom, E. King, I. Bhushan, D. Clingingsmith, B. Loevinsohn, R. Hong, and J. B. Schwartz. 2006. Contracting for Health: Evidence from Cambodia. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Kumar, N. R. 2007. “Pro-Poor Targeting and Participatory Governance: Evidence from Central India.” Working Paper dp-176, Institute for Economic Development, Department of Economics, Boston University, Boston, MA. Kumar, S. 2002. “Does ‘Participation’ in Common Pool Resource Management Help the Poor? A Social Cost-Benefit Analysis of Joint Forest Management in Jharkhand, India.” World Development 30: 763–82. Labonne, J. 2011. “The KALAHI–CIDSS Impact Evaluation: A Synthesis Report.” World Bank, Washington, DC. Larson, A., and J. C. Ribot. 2007. “The Poverty of Forestry Policy: Double Standards on and Uneven Playing Field.” Journal of Sustainability Science 2(2): 189–204. Leino, J. 2007. “Ladies First? Gender and the Community Management of Water Infrastructure in Kenya.” Graduate Student and Research Fellow Working Paper 30, Harvard University, Center for International Development, Cambridge, MA. Libecap, G. 1989. Contracting for Property Rights. New York: Cambridge University Press. Linnemayr, S., and H. Alderman. 2011. “Almost Random: Evaluating a Large- Scale Randomized Nutrition Program in the Presence of Crossover.” Journal of Development Economics 96: 106–14. Lund, J. F. 2007. “Is Small Beautiful? Village Level Taxation of Natural Resources in Tanzania.” Public Administration and Development 27(4): 307–18. Lund, J. F., and T. Treue. 2008. “Are We Getting There? Evidence of Decentralized Forest Management from the Tanzanian Miombo Woodlands.” World Development 36(12): 2780–800. Macinko, J., M. F. M. De Souza, F. C. Guanais, and C. C. D. S. Simoes. 2007. “Going to Scale with Community-Based Primary Care: An Analysis of the Family Health Program and Infant Mortality in Brazil, 1999–2004.” Social Science & Medicine 65: 2070–80. Macinko, J., F. C. Guanais, and M. D. M. De Souza. 2006. “Evaluation of the Impact of the Family Health Program on Infant Mortality in Brazil, 1990–2002.” Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 60: 13–19. Madeira, R. 2007. “The Effects of Decentralization on Schooling: Evidence from the São Paulo State Education Reform.” Department of Economics, Boston University, Boston, MA. Manandhar, D. S., D. Osrin, B. P. Shrestha, N. Mesko, J. Morrison, K. M. Tumbahangphe, and S. Tamang. 2004. “Effect of a Participatory Intervention with Women’s Groups on Birth Outcomes in Nepal: Cluster- Randomised Controlled Trial.” Lancet 364: 970–79. Mansuri, G. 2012a. “Bottom up or Top Down: Participation and the Provision of Local Public Goods.” World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Equity Unit, Washington, DC. 240
  • 261. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? ———. 2012b. “Harnessing Community: A ssortative Matching in Participatory Community Organizations.” World Bank, Poverty Reduction and Equity Unit, Washington DC. Marcus, R. 2002. “Social Funds as Instruments for Reducing Childhood Poverty: Lessons from Save the Children’s Experience.” Journal of International Development 14(8): 653–66. McSweeney, K. 2005. “Natural Insurance, Forest Access, and Compounded Misfortune: Forest Resources in Smallholder Coping Strategies before and after Hurricane Mitch, Northeastern Honduras.” World Development 33(9): 1453–71. Meshack, C. K., B. Ahdikari, N. Doggart, and J. C. Lovett. 2006. “Transaction Costs of Community-Based Forest Management: Empirical Evidence from Tanzania.” African Journal of Ecology 44(4): 468–77. Morrow, C. E., and R. W. Hull. 1996. “Donor-Initiated Common Pool Resource Institutions: The Case of the Yanesha Forestry Cooperative.” World Development 24(10): 1641–57. Mosse, D. 2001. “People’s Knowledge, Participation, and Patronage: Operations and Representations in Rural Development.” In Participation: The New Tyranny, ed. B. Cooke and U. Kothari. London: Zed Books. ———. 2005. Cultivating Development: An Ethnography of Aid Policy and Practice. London: Pluto Press. Muhereza, F. 2006. “Decentralizing Natural Resource Management and the Politics of Institutional Resource Management in Uganda’s Forest Sub- Sector.” Africa Development 31: 67–101. Murnane, R. J., J. B. Willet, and S. Cardenas. 2006. “Did the Participation of Schools in Programa Escuelas De Calidad (PEC) Influence Student Outcomes?” Working Paper, Harvard University Graduate School of Education, Cambridge, MA. Mustafa, D. 2007. “Social Construction of Hydro-Politics: The Geographical Scales of Water and Security in the Indus Basin.” Geographical Review 97(4): 484–501. Mustalahti, I., and J. F. Lund. 2010. “Where and How Can Participatory Forest Management Succeed? Learning from Tanzania, Mozambique, and Laos.” Society & Natural Resources 23(1): 31–44. Narain, U., S. Gupta, and K. Van’t Veld. 2005. “Poverty and Environment: Exploring the Relationship Between Household Incomes, Private Assets, and Natural Assets.” Discussion Paper 05-18, Resources for the Future, Washington, DC. ———. 2008. “Poverty and Resource Dependence in Rural India.” Ecological Economics 66(1): 161–76. Nerlove, M. 1991. “Population and the Environment: A Parable of Firewood and Other Tales.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73(4): 1334–47. Newman, J., M. Pradhan, L. B. Rawlings, G. Ridder, R. C. And, and J. L. Evia. 2002. “An Impact Evaluation of Education, Health, and Water Supply Investments by the Bolivian Social Investment Fund.” World Bank Economic Review 16(2): 241–74. 241
  • 262. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Nkonya, E., D. Phillip, T. Mogues, J. Pender, M. K. Yahaya, G. Adebowale, T. Arokoyo, and E. Kato. 2008. “From the Ground Up Impacts of a Pro- Poor Community-Driven Development Project in Nigeria.” Discussion Paper 00756, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC. North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press. Nyonator, F. K., J. K. Awoonor-Williams, J. F. Phillips, T. C. Jones, and R. A. Miller. 2005. “The Ghana Community-Based Health Planning and Services Initiative for Scaling Up Service Delivery Innovation.” Health Policy and Planning 20(1): 25–34. Olken, B. 2007. “Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia.” Journal of Political Economy 115(2): 200–49. Olken, B. A., J. Onishi, and S. Wong. 2011. “Indonesia’s PNPM Generasi Program: Final Impact Evaluation Report.” World Bank, Social Development Department, Washington, DC. Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press. Ostrom, E., W. F. Lam, and M. Lee. 1994. “The Performance of Self- Governing Irrigation Systems in Nepal.” Human Systems Management 13(3): 197–207. Oyono, P. R., and S. Efoua. 2006. “Qui représente qui? Choix organisation- nels, identités sociales et formation d’une élite forestière au Cameron.” Africa Development 31(2): 147–82. Oyono, P., and F. Nzuzi. 2006. “Au sortir d’une longue ‘nuit’ institutionnelle, nouvelles transactions entre les politiques forestières et les sociétés rurales en RD Congo post-conflit.” Afrique et Développement 31(2): 183–214. Pandey, P., S. Goyal, and V. Sundararaman. 2011. “Does Information Improve School Accountability? Results of a Large Randomized Trial.” Discussion Paper 49, World Bank, Washington, DC. Pandey, S. K., and E. C. Stazyk. 2008. “Antecedents and Correlates of Public Service Motivation.” In Motivation in Public Management: The Call of Public Service, ed. J. L. Perry and A. Hondeghem, 101–17. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press. Pandey, S., B. Wright, and D. Moynihan. 2008. “Public Service Motivation and Interpersonal Citizenship Behavior in Public Organizations: Testing a Preliminary Model.” International Public Management Journal 11(1): 89–108. Park, A., and S. Wang. 2009. “Community-Based Development and Poverty Alleviation: An Evaluation of China’s Poor Village Investment Program.” Draft background paper for the 2006 China Poverty Assessment, World Bank, Washington, DC. Pattanayak, S. K., and E. O. Sills. 2001. “Do Tropical Forests Provide Natural Insurance? The Microeconomics of Non-Timber Forest Product Collection in the Brazilian Amazon.” Land Economics 77(4): 595– 613. 242
  • 263. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Paxson, C., and N. R. Schady. 2002. “The Allocation and Impact of Social Funds: Spending on School Infrastructure in Peru.” World Bank Economic Review 16(2): 297–319. Pokharel, R. P. 2009. “Pro-Poor Programs Financed through Nepal’s Community Forestry Funds: Does Income Matter?” Mountain Research and Development 29: 67–74. Pradhan, D. S. M., A. Beatty, M. Wong, A. Alishjabana, A. Gaduh, and R. P. Artha. 2011. “Improving Educational Quality through Enhancing Community Participation: Results from a Randomized Field Experiment in Indonesia.” Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, University of Amsterdam. Pradhan, M., and L. B. Rawlings. 2002. “The Impact and Targeting of Social Infrastructure Investments: Lessons from the Nicaraguan Social Fund.” World Bank Economic Review 16(2): 275–95. Ravallion, M. 2000. “Monitoring Targeting Performance When Decentralized Allocations to the Poor Are Unobserved.” World Bank Economic Review 14(2): 331–45. ———. 2009a. “Decentralizing Eligibility for a Federal Antipoverty Program: A Case Study for China.” World Bank Economic Review 23(1): 1–30. ———. 2009b. “How Relevant Is Targeting to the Success of an Antipoverty Program?” World Bank Research Observer 24(1): 205–31. Ribot, J. C. 1995. “From Exclusion to Participation: Turning Senegal’s Forestry Policy Around?” World Development 23(9): 1587–99. ———. 2004. Waiting for Democracy: The Politics of Choice in Natural Resource Decentralizations. Washington, DC: World Resources Institute. ———. 2007. “Institutional Choice and Recognition in the Consolidation of Local Democracy.” Democracy 50: 43–49. Ribot, J. C., A. Chhatre, and T. Lankina. 2008. “Institutional Choice and Recognition in the Formation and Consolidation of Local Democracy.” Conservation and Society 6(1): 1–11. Ribot, J. C., J. Lund, and T. Treue. 2010. “Forestry and Democratic Decentralization in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Review.” Background paper prepared for Policy Research Report, World Bank, Washington, DC. Riley, J. C. 2005. Poverty and Life Expectancy: The Jamaica Paradox. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press. Rocha, R., and R. R. Soares. 2009. “Evaluating the Impact of Community- Based Health Interventions: Evidence from Brazil’s Family Health Program.” Global Development Network, New Delhi. Rodriguez, C. 2006. “Households’ Schooling Behavior and Political Economy Trade-Offs After Decentralization.” Working Paper, Universidad de los Andes, Colombia. Ronconi, L. 2009. “Estimates of the Benefit Incidence of Workfare.” Journal of LACEA Economia (Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association) 8587. Sawada, Y. 1999. “Community Participation, Teacher Effort, and Educational Outcome: The Case of El Salvador’s Educo Program.” Working Paper 307, William Davidson Institute, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI. 243
  • 264. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Sawada, Y., and A. Ragatz. 2005. “Decentralization of Education, Teacher Behavior, and Outcomes.” In Incentives to Improve Teaching, ed. E. Vegas. Washington, DC: World Bank. Skoufias, E., and J. Shapiro. 2006. “The Pitfalls of Evaluating a School Grants Program Using Non-Experimental Data.” Policy Research Working Paper 4036, World Bank, Washington, DC. Somanathan, E., R. Prabhakar, and B. Singh. 2005. “Does Decentralization Work? Forest Conservation in the Himalayas.” Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi. Stern, P. C., T. Dietz, and E. Ostrom. 2003. “The Struggle to Govern the Commons.” Science 302: 1907–12. Sunderlin, W. D., J. Hatcher, and M. Liddle. 2008. “From Exclusion to Ownership? Challenges and Opportunities in Advancing Forest Tenure Reform.” Rights and Resources Initiatives, Washington DC. Topp-Jorgensen, E., M. K. Poulsen, J. F. Lund, and J. F. Massao. 2005. “Community-Based Monitoring of Natural Resource Use and Forest Quality in Montane Forests and Miombo Woodlands of Tanzania.” Biodiversity and Conservation 14(11): 2653–77. Tripathy, P., N. Nair, S. Barnett, R. Mahapatra, J. Borghi, S. Rath, and S. Rath. 2010. “Effect of a Participatory Intervention with Women’s Groups on Birth Outcomes and Maternal Depression in Jharkhand and Orissa, India: A Cluster-Randomised Controlled Trial.” Lancet 375: 1182–92. Turyahabwe, N., C. J. Geldenhuys, S.Watts, and J.Obua. 2007. “Local Organizations and Decentralised Forest Management in Uganda: Roles, Challenges, and Policy Implications. International Forestry Review. 9(2):581–96. United Nations. 2000. “Millennium Declaration.” United Nations, New York. Uphoff, N. 1986. Local Institutional Development: An Analytical Sourcebook with Cases. Sterling, VA: Kumarian Press. Uzochukwu, B. S. C., C. O. Akpala, and O. E. Onwujekwe. 2004. “How Do Health Workers and Community Members Perceive and Practice Community Participation in the Bamako Initiative Programme in Nigeria? A Case Study of Oji River Local Government Area.” Social Science and Medicine 59: 157–62. Voss, J. 2008. “Impact Evaluation of the Second Phase of the Kecamatan Development Program in Indonesia.” World Bank, Jakarta. Wade, R. 1985. “The Market for Public Office: Why the Indian State Is Not Better at Development.” In The Economics of Corruption and Illegal Markets, ed. G. Fiorentini and S. Zamagni. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar Publishing. Wardell, D. A., and C. Lund. 2006. “Governing Access to Forests in Northern Ghana: Micro-Politics and the Rents of Non-Enforcement.” World Development 34(11): 1887–906. 244
  • 265. DOES PARTICIPATION IMPROVE DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES? Wilder, M., and P. R. Lankao. 2006. “Paradoxes of Decentralization: Water Reform and Social Implications in Mexico.” World Development 34: 1977–95. Wood, G. 1999. “Private Provision after Public Neglect: Bending Irrigation Markets in North Bihar.” Development and Change 30(4): 775–94. World Bank. 2002. “Social Funds: Assessing Effectiveness.” Operations Evaluations Department, World Bank, Washington, DC. Yoong, J. 2007. “Does Decentralization Hurt Childhood Immunization?” Department of Economics, Stanford University, Stanford, CA. 245
  • 267. CHAPTER SIX Does Participation Strengthen Civil Society? PARTICIPATORY DEVELOPMENT PROJECTS OFTEN INCLUDE BUILD- ing “social capital” and hearing the “voices of the poor” as key objec- tives. This chapter reviews the literature on how effective participatory development projects have been in achieving these goals. It presents evidence on several important questions. How do deliberative processes actually work in developing countries? Is deliberation equitable? Is it sustainable? Under what conditions does it build the capacity to engage? Can local inequalities in power and social structure be remedied by mandating the inclusion of women and discriminated minorities in leadership positions? Does participation build “social capital”? Can inducing participation improve a community’s capacity to address dis- putes and improve cohesion in postconflict settings? Is there evidence that induced participation enhances social cohesion and the “voice” of marginalized groups in local decision-making bodies? Participatory Decision Making and Social Cohesion in Induced Development Projects Participatory development projects expend considerable resources and effort building community-level organizations with the expectation that doing so not only allows disadvantaged groups to participate directly in decision-making processes but that it can also encourage dialogue between groups otherwise separated by wealth, gender, or social status, thereby creating the basis for greater social cohesion. If this is the case, induced participation may help build social cohesion and strengthen democratic values and practices even in communities where there are 247
  • 268. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? important social cleavages caused by inequality, ethnic heterogeneity, or conflict. The hypothesis that induced The hypothesis that induced participation may help build social participation may help build cohesion turns out to be a particularly difficult one to evaluate. The social cohesion turns out to measurement of social outcomes is itself challenging, because projects be a particularly difficult one usually provide resources for local public goods, private transfers, micro- to evaluate. credit, and skills training, in addition to community mobilization. The provision of resources makes it difficult to isolate the impact of partici- pation on social outcomes. Exposure to participatory messaging may also make members of program communities more likely to indicate more willingness to cooperate or to report higher levels of trust and support for democracy regardless of any substantive change in attitudes or practices. Local facilitators spend considerable time with community members elucidating the benefits of program participation, community collective action, self-help groups, contributions to development proj- ects, and so forth. Isolating the impact of participation on preferences, trust, networks, or cooperation is therefore likely to be difficult even in the best-designed evaluation. Self-reported retrospective accounts of change are perhaps the least reliable source of information. To make matters worse, very few evaluations of community-driven development or social fund projects have been able to deal effectively with the problem of identifying comparison communities for assessing project impact. In the majority of cases, comparison groups are created by identifying communities that did not get the program but look oth- erwise similar to program communities. Because matching communi- ties on the relevant social variables (trust, cooperation, density of social networks, political participation, and so forth) is rarely an option, most studies match on the usual set of sociodemographic variables available in national income statistics and expenditure surveys. Matching in this way is particularly problematic if, as is often the case, participatory programs rely on community “willingness” or “readiness” to participate rather than on clear eligibility criteria. Although matching in this way may be sensible from a programmatic perspective, it makes causal infer- ence challenging, because outcomes of interest (such as greater political awareness) may be precisely why a community was selected in the first place, rather than an outcome of the program. These challenges affect both the quantity and quality of the literature on participation and social cohesion. Three recent studies, all of which focus on community-driven reconstruction projects, are exceptions. 248
  • 269. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? The first evaluates a community reconstruction project implemented A project in Liberia shows by the International Rescue Committee in northern Liberia (Fearon, an increase in trust and Humphreys, and Weinstein 2009).1 Survey results indicate a reduction participation by marginalized in social tension and an increase in trust in local leadership, as well groups and a reduction in as an increase in participation by marginalized groups in community social tension. But there is decision-making activities. The authors use a behavioral public goods no evidence of an increase game to augment and validate these survey-based findings on the in broader collective action impact of participation on social cohesion and cooperation.2 They find capacity. that a larger percentage of households in the program communities (71 percent versus 62 percent in the comparison communities) contrib- uted the maximum amount. However, the difference was driven mainly by contributions from internally displaced persons who had returned to their villages after the war and benefited from this project as well as other programs directed at resettling them. Moreover, the evidence does not support any increase in broader collective action or in democratic values or practices in program villages. There was also no change in the attitudes of traditional leaders toward community decision making. The second study is an ongoing evaluation of a community-driven An ongoing evaluation reconstruction program in Afghanistan. It also finds some positive, of a community-driven albeit preliminary, evidence on the impact of a national community- reconstruction project in driven reconstruction project (the National Support Program) on Afghanistan finds preliminary political attitudes and social cohesion (Beath, Christia, and Enikolopev positive evidence on political 2011).3 The results from an initial follow-up suggest significant shifts in attitudes and social cohesion. political attitudes (regarding trust in government and local leaders, in women’s role in the community, and in women as leaders, for example) and in social cohesion. A caveat is that self-reports of political attitudes such as trust in government or greater community cooperation can be difficult to interpret in the absence of corroborating evidence on outcomes. There is little evidence that village elites in program villages were less likely to exercise influence in village development councils or that there was any change in the types of households that benefited from government programs. As discussed in earlier chapters, communi- ties that have community-driven development projects routinely report greater social cohesion and levels of satisfaction, and self-reports are generally more positive when questions are posed in language that more closely evokes the language used by facilitators.4 The third study, by Casey, Glennerster, and Miguel (2011), finds less positive results. The GoBifo (Move Forward) project in Sierra Leone, funded primarily by the World Bank, provided block grants 249
  • 270. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? A study from Sierra Leone worth about $5,000 per community (roughly $100 per household) for finds no evidence that a local public goods, skills training, and microentrepreneurship. The community-driven program project staff also provided training in democratic decision making and had any impact on social encouraged the participation of socially marginalized groups (mainly cohesion or collective action. women and youth) in local decision-making bodies.5 Like the first two studies, this study randomly assigned eligible communities to program and comparison status and combined survey methods with what they refer to as “structured community activities.” These activities assessed how communities responded to a matching grant opportunity to invest in a small public good (building materials), made communal decisions between two alternatives, and allocated a small endowment among community members. Despite the careful design and the long evalua- tion period (four years between baseline in 2005 and endline in 2009), the study finds no evidence that the program had an impact on any measure of social cohesion or collective action used (local fundraising capacity, decision-making processes, and so forth). There was also no evidence of a shift in social attitudes or norms with respect to women’s participation in public activities. Another approach to measuring social cohesion is to assess the extent to which community-level organizations bring together diverse groups of people who may otherwise not have an opportunity to interact with one another, thereby creating a new deliberative space. A growing body of literature on participatory councils is starting to generate interesting evidence on this issue in the context of local decentralization, but only three studies look at the extent to which community organizations are cohesive in their membership patterns. Doing so is important, because community-driven projects often work through self-help groups, which are endogenously formed. A community or village may therefore have several such groups, which may or may not be brought together into higher-level organizations. Arcand and Fafchamps (2012) look at community organizations in Burkina Faso and Senegal. They find that community organizations tend to sort sharply by wealth and status. Survey research in São Paulo and Mexico City also finds that citizens who participate in associations are likely to be highly stratified by education, gender, labor market status, and other factors (Houtzager, Acharya, and Lavalle 2007). Mansuri (2012) finds that community organizations supported by the National Rural Support Program in Pakistan were highly segregated along wealth, ethnicity, education, and political power within villages, 250
  • 271. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? in addition to almost complete sorting by gender. However, she finds that some communities do much better than others. Sorting on status (education, land, and caste) is significantly dampened in villages with above-average levels of schooling but similar levels of land inequality and caste composition. In contrast, sorting by land intensifies in vil- lages that are more unequal in land wealth, and sorting by caste status intensifies in villages that have more low-caste households. Four other studies provide some interesting insights, though their evaluation designs are flawed. Chase, Christensen, and Thongyou (2006) use data from an evaluation of the Thailand Social Fund to assess whether the fund selected villages with specific characteristics and whether implementation of the program had an impact on the level of social capital in the selected villages. Using a combination of household survey and qualitative data, they find that the social fund provided funding to villages with particular preexisting social capital characteristics (greater norms of self-sacrifice, higher levels of trust among neighbors, and a history of collective action). They also find some evidence that exposure to the program enhanced social cohesion.6 These results are suggestive at best, as the social capital variables were generated after program implementation, making any causal inference difficult. Moreover, program effects were weak, with social fund villages performing significantly better than control villages on only 19 percent of the social capital measures listed in the study. Labonne and Chase (2008) study K ALAHI–CIDSS, a large community-driven development program in the Philippines. Using data from 135 villages in 16 municipalities, the authors assess the program’s impact on social capital indicators such as participation in local governance activities, village group membership, and relationships between local officials and citizens. They find that trust in local officials increased in villages that received funding—even though the propor- tion of households that requested services decreased. Two studies use data from the District Poverty Initiatives Project (DPIP) in India to measure changes in social capital and political empowerment. The DPIP supported the formation of women’s self-help groups to promote economic and social empowerment. Deininger and Liu (2008) use recall data to measure changes in social capital and political participation in treatment and control groups in Andhra Pradesh between 2000 and 2004.7 They find a significant increase in the level of social capital and political participation in DPIP 251
  • 272. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? areas, with identical effects across participants and nonparticipants.8 They interpret this finding as evidence that the program had large posi- tive social externalities. However, the design of the evaluation does not allow for a clean test of this effect, because it is unclear whether control communities are comparable on the relevant measures of social cohesion or social capital at baseline. The measures of social cohesion used are also closely linked to the rhetoric of participatory projects. Kumar (2007) examines whether participation in DPIP, which runs parallel to and outside the local government structure, helped poor and lower-caste households engage effectively with the participatory processes organized by local governments in Madhya Pradesh. She finds a significant impact on political participation by poor rural women in program areas. Households in program villages not only had greater political awareness and better knowledge of other government pro- grams, but they were also more likely to participate in village affairs, to know about gram sabha (village assembly) meetings, and to participate in them. They also reported being more active participants, and speak- ing, voting, or objecting to decisions more often than other participants. As in the study by Deininger and Liu, however, this paper’s evaluation strategy is problematic, because it cannot identify why some villages were selected into DPIP and others were not.9 There is also fair bit of suggestive evidence that localities in which civic institutions are more vibrant have better outcomes. Few, if any, of these studies are able to identify a causal link from decentralization or participation in a community-drive development program to the quality of civic institutions, however. Olken (2006) finds that villages with more social organizations (community self-help groups, religious study groups, women’s organizations) were less likely to experience both outright corruption in the form of missing rice and less leakage to village elites. Camacho and Conover (2011) find that municipalities in Colombia that had better monitoring by community organizations experienced less leakage from targeted programs. Galasso and Ravallion (2005) find that Bangladeshi villages in which the Grameen Bank was present received more program resources from the center and that these resources were better targeted to the poor. Arcand, Bassole, and Tranchant (2008) examine the extent to which participatory gover- nance bodies, such as the Conseil de Concertation et de Gestion (CCG) in Senegal, are able to compete with local elected leaders from the Conseil Rural in attracting project funds to their communities. The 252
  • 273. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? community-driven development project designed the CCG as a parallel Some evidence suggests participatory institution to ensure the representation of vulnerable and that localities in which civic marginalized groups that were less likely to be represented in the Conseil institutions are more vibrant Rural through the electoral process. The authors find that villages with have better outcomes . . . more CCG members who were not in the Conseil Rural were more likely to receive a project, suggesting that although political elites may direct . . . but whether projects to their own villages, villagers who engage in participatory decentralization, or governance structures can enhance resource flows to their communities. participation in a community- driven development program, improved the quality of civic Representation Quotas and Inclusion Mandates institutions remains unclear. This section focuses on how reservations and quotas in local councils and inclusion mandates have been used to address specific types of social exclusion and make democratic institutions (and political incen- tives) more responsive to people who would otherwise have little voice. Many of the results come from the literature on mandated representa- tion in Indian village councils (gram panchayats). These studies look at whether leaders from disadvantaged groups have incentives to align their actions with the interests of their particular group or the general public. Effects on Women Women are systematically excluded from collective bodies, and from positions of power, in many parts of the world. Looking at what she calls “participatory exclusions” in community forestry groups in India and Nepal, Agarwal (2001) fi nds that fewer than 10 percent of the members of groups with decision-making authority are women, even though women are required to do much of the work involved in for- est management. Women’s underrepresentation affects the decisions made by these groups and thus has distributional consequences. It also reduces the effectiveness of the organizations, by failing to make use of the information and skills women may have. Such exclusion can have a reinforcing impact on discrimination against women. On the basis of fieldwork conducted over two years, Agarwal finds that participatory exclusions occur for a variety of reasons. Social norms exclude women from participating in public spaces, and gen- dered norms of “acceptable” behaviors restrict women’s attendance 253
  • 274. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? at public gatherings. Women f ind men’s behavior “aggressive.” Restrictions on women’s visibility and mobility affect their ability to participate, they face negative stereotypes about their ability to con- tribute effectively to proceedings that have public implications, and they face norms that relegate them to work on women-specific tasks. Many groups also have exclusionary rules, such as allowing only one person per household to belong to a forestry group, which effectively excludes women. To get around social restrictions of this kind, in 1992 India adopted a constitutional amendment mandating that one-third of all seats on village councils and a third of all presidencies of these councils be reserved for women. Many states randomly rotate the council seats and presidencies reserved for women. A series of studies has exploited this random allocation to study the impact of mandating seats for women on a variety of outcomes. Chattopadhyay and Duflo (2004b) analyze survey data from 265 village councils in the states of West Bengal and Rajasthan. In the Birbhum district of West Bengal, the share of women among partici- pants in the village council was significantly higher when the president was a woman (rising from 6.9 percent to 9.8 percent), and female presi- dents in reserved villages were twice as likely as male presidents to have addressed a request or complaint to the gram panchayat in the previous six months. In contrast, in Rajasthan the fact that the president was a woman had no effect on women’s participation in the village council or on the incidence of women’s complaints. The authors also look at the effect of the policy of reserving seats for women on the provision of public goods. They find that the gender of the president affected the provision of public goods in both West Bengal and Rajasthan, with significantly more investments in drinking water in gram panchayats in which the president was a woman. In West Bengal, gram panchayats were less likely to have set up informal schools when the presidency was reserved for a woman. The evidence on roads was mixed, with roads receiving significantly more funding in gram panchayats reserved for women in West Bengal and less in gram panchayats reserved for women in Rajasthan. In both states, the provision of public goods in reserved constituencies was more closely aligned with the preferences of women than with the preferences of men. Women invested less in public goods that were more closely linked to men’s concerns (education in West Bengal and roads in Rajasthan). 254
  • 275. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? Duflo and Topalova (2004) look at the effects of political reserva- Reservation of gram panchayat tion for women with data from a larger geographical area (11 states in seats for women led to more India). They present evidence on three aspects of women’s performance investment in drinking water in office (as measured by the quality and quantity of various public infrastructure . . . goods provided and the likelihood of taking bribes) as well as evidence on perceptions of their performance by voters in India’s village councils. Consistent with the results in Chattopadhyay and Duflo (2004b), they . . . and to less spending on find that reservation for women led to more investment in drinking public goods preferred by men. water infrastructure, with significantly more public drinking water taps and hand pumps when the leadership of the gram panchayat was reserved for a woman and weak evidence that the drinking water facili- ties were in better repair. Overall, the average effect of reservation on the availability of public goods in a village was positive and statistically significant. The average effect of the reservation on the quality of public goods was positive as well but not significant. The authors conclude that women leaders did a better job than men at delivering drinking water infrastructure and at least as good a job delivering other public goods. Duflo and Topalova also find that both men and women reported being less likely to pay a bribe to obtain a service when the gram pan- chayat presidency was held by a woman. However, respondents in vil- lages with female presidents were also 2 percent less likely to declare that they were satisfied with the public goods they received. Interestingly, respondents also reported being significantly less satisfied with the quality of the public health services in villages with women presidents, despite the fact that health services were centrally administered and not under the jurisdiction of panchayats in any of the 11 states during the study period. Beaman and others (2009) compare villagers’ attitudes toward hypo- thetical and actual women leaders in councils that have been reserved for women once, twice, or never in West Bengal. Random allocation of reservation implies that a difference in voter attitudes in reserved and unreserved villages captures the causal effect of mandated reservations. An important innovation of this study is the collection and use of detailed survey and experimental data on voters’ taste for female lead- ers, their perceptions of gender roles, and of the effectiveness of female leaders. The authors examine explicit and implicit measures of voters’ tastes. Explicit tastes are captured through voters’ stated feelings toward the general idea of male and female leaders; implicit tastes are captured through Implicit Association Tests (IATs).10 255
  • 276. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Both men and women in To examine voter perceptions of leader effectiveness, the authors India perceive women as less asked villagers to evaluate the effectiveness of hypothetical female and effective leaders than men. male leaders described through vignettes and recorded speeches in which the leader’s gender is experimentally manipulated. The results show that in villages that never experienced political reservation, villag- ers, particularly men, disliked the idea of female leaders. On a scale of 1–10, the average man rated his feeling toward female leaders one point below his feelings toward male leaders. Men perceived female leaders as less effective than male leaders. The average male villager rated the same speech and vignette describing a leader’s decision 0.05 standard deviations lower when the leader’s gender was experimentally manipu- lated to be female. Female villagers’ evaluation of hypothetical female leaders, although less negative, was not statistically different from that of male villagers’. Mandated exposure to a female leader did not affect villagers’ stated taste for male leaders. Neither the “feeling” rating of leaders nor the taste IAT showed increased approval of female leaders in villages reserved for a female leader. However, among male villagers, it weakened the ste- reotype (as measured by the occupation IAT) that men are associated with leadership activities and women with domestic activities. It also radically altered perceptions of the effectiveness of female leaders among male villagers. In the speech and vignette experiments, male villagers who were required to have a female leader considered hypothetical female and male leaders equally effective. This reduction in bias was absent among female villagers. The authors provide evidence suggest- ing that a likely reason for this difference is the lower levels of political knowledge and exposure to local politics among women. Consistent with the experimental data, they find that prior exposure improved villagers’ evaluation of their actual leader along multiple dimensions. Reserving gram panchayat Analyzing data from the same sample, Beaman and others (2012) seats for women may elevate find that the reservation of seats for women has effects outside the politi- the aspirations parents cal sphere. According to their study, reservations positively affected have for their daughters both the aspirations parents had for their daughters and the aspirations and the aspirations of girls of girls themselves. They examine the impact of women’s reservations themselves . . . on parents’ preferences for their children not to become housewives, to hold a job requiring a good education, not to marry before 18, to receive . . . but reserving seats for higher education, and to be the president of a village. The gap between women has not always led to mothers and fathers in gram panchayats in which positions for women positive effects. were never reserved was large, ranging from 24 percent for their child 256
  • 277. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? not marrying before 18, to 75 percent for their daughter not becoming a housewife. This gap was, on average, 20 percentage points smaller in gram panchayats with a randomly assigned woman president. The authors also surveyed adolescents ages 11–15. They find that the gender gap in their career and education aspirations was 32 percentage points smaller in villages that reserved seats for women. Bhavnani (2009) assesses the long-term impact of the reservation of seats for women on municipal councils in Mumbai by examining the relative change in political power in councils that had previously been reserved for women. He tests for the continuing effects of the 1997 reservations on various aspects of the 2002 elections. His main find- ing is that women won 21.6 percent of wards that had been reserved for women in 1997 but were open to both genders in 2002 (treatment wards) and only 3.7 percent of wards that were open to both men and women in 1997 and 2002 (control wards). Women’s chances of winning ward elections in 2002 were thus more than quintupled by the reserva- tion of seats five years earlier. Bhavnani also examines the mechanisms through which the electoral chances for women may have increased in the previously reserved constituencies. He finds that the increase is explained by both an incumbency effect and an increase in the number of woman candidates running in the previously reserved constituency. Some studies show that reserving seats for women has not always led to positive effects. Bardhan, Mookherjee, and Torrado (2010) examine all 16 rural districts in West Bengal (89 villages in 57 gram panchay- ats), drawing on the results of a household survey conducted between 2003 and 2004. Using a stratified random sample of 20 households per village, they examine the determinants of access to a variety of local government programs, including provision of toilets, participation in public works, receipt of Below Poverty Line (BPL) cards, and access to agricultural minikits. They find that the reservation of seats for women led to no improvement in intravillage household targeting to female- headed households and a worsening of targeting to households from schedule castes and tribes. These effects were mitigated in villages that had high land inequality. The authors interpret these findings to suggest that female leaders are inexperienced and weak and that their leadership exacerbates clientelistic allocations. In high inequality areas, female leaders are also from elite families, which makes them more effective. Ban and Rao (2009) draw on community-level and household survey data and surveys of village presidents in four southern Indian states. 257
  • 278. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? They find no significant effect of women’s leadership on participation in public village meetings or the existence of women’s organizations in the community. They also find that women presidents in reserved gram panchayats were significantly less likely than male presidents to meet with higher-level officials. Relative to unreserved gram pan- chayats, panchayats reserved for women invested significantly more in education-related activities. But on the vast majority of activities, female presidents behaved no differently from male presidents. In contrast to Chattopadhyay and Duflo (2004a), Ban and Rao find no evidence that female presidents acted in accordance with women’s preferences. More experienced female Ban and Rao fi nd considerable heterogeneity in their results. In presidents in reserved particular, female presidents in reserved gram panchayats were unam- gram panchayats were biguously more effective when they were more experienced. Women in unambiguously more effective reserved gram panchayats performed worse when most of the land in the than less experienced ones. village was owned by upper castes, suggesting that caste structures may be correlated with structures of patriarchy in ways that make condi- tions particularly difficult for women. The authors also find that female presidents in reserved gram panchayats performed best in states where reservations had been in place longest, indicating the importance of the maturity of the reservation system. This effect, in conjunction with the positive effect of the president’s political experience, points toward a hopeful future, as it suggests that as women acquire more experience and the system continues to mature, women will become more effec- tive leaders. Leino (2007) examines whether incentives for female participation improved the maintenance of infrastructure in Kenya. The interven- tion aimed to increase women’s participation in the maintenance of water sources by encouraging them to attend community meetings at which water management committees were elected. Once elected, the water management committees were trained by a facilitating NGO to manage maintenance tasks for water schemes. The meetings were held at times convenient for women, and NGO facilitators emphasized the importance of women’s participation at each meeting. The intervention was successful in increasing the number of women on water management committees. It also increased the number of women holding leadership positions in the committee, more than doubling the odds that a woman was a committee chair. This effect appears to have persisted through the three-year period of the study. The increase in female leadership on the water management committees 258
  • 279. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? had no impact on the quality of infrastructure maintenance, however. In Kenya, incentives for There is thus little evidence of any efficiency gain because of greater inclusion increased female female participation—although, as the author notes, the more inter- leadership on water esting result may be that increased inclusion can be achieved with no management committees, but apparent efficiency cost. the increase had no impact on the quality of infrastructure maintenance. Effect on Disadvantaged Castes Chattopadhyay and Duflo (2004a) examine how the type and loca- tion of public goods differs in unreserved gram panchayats and gram panchayats in which presidencies were reserved for historically disad- vantaged Scheduled Castes (SC) in West Bengal.11 Identification of the caste reservation effect was based on the random assignment of gram panchayats reserved for scheduled castes. The authors studied investments in drinking water facilities, irrigation facilities, roads, and education centers, measured using a participatory survey in which a representative group of villagers was shown a village map that depicted the location of all infrastructure schemes and then was asked which investments had been built or repaired since the last election. The authors find that SC presidents did not significantly change the types of investments in public goods relative to presidents from unre- served gram panchayats. SC hamlets in SC–reserved gram panchayats received 14 percent more investment in public goods than SC hamlets in unreserved gram panchayats. Chin and Prakash (2010) assess the extent to which reservation for disadvantaged castes and tribes improves living conditions for the poorest. Using panel data from 16 Indian states over the period 1960–92, they examine the effect of state-level reservations for SCs and Scheduled Tribes (STs) on state-level measures of overall poverty. The main question of interest is whether on balance, minority political representation is welfare enhancing for all of the poor. The authors find that reservations for SCs reduced overall poverty—that is, benefits to minority groups did not appear to have come at a cost to poor or near- poor nonminorities. Reservation policies for STs were more effective in reducing poverty in rural than in urban areas, suggesting some caution in generalizing findings in the absence of more empirical work. Using data from four southern Indian states, Besley and others (2004) examine the effect of reservations for SCs and STs on the distribution of low-spillover and high-spillover goods within and 259
  • 280. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? between villages at the gram panchayat level. They measure access to low-spillover (household-level) public goods through a household survey that defines access as having had a house or toilet built under a government scheme or having received a private water or electricity connection through a government scheme since the last gram panchayat election. They measure access to high-spillover public goods (public goods that are easily accessed across groups and neighborhoods) using data on gram panchayat activity from an independent audit of village facilities. An index constructed from these data measures whether the gram panchayat undertook any construction or improvement activity on village roads, drains, streetlights, or water sources since the last gram panchayat election. Using a household-level regression with village fi xed effects, the authors find that low-spillover public goods (access to which is more easily restricted to particular groups and neighborhoods) were targeted more toward SC/ST households. On average, a household from an SC/ST was 6 percent more likely to receive such a public good than a non–SC/ST household. The extent of such targeting was enhanced by living in a reserved gram panchayat. Relative to living in a nonreserved gram panchayat, living in a reserved gram panchayat increased a SC/ST household’s likelihood of getting such a low-spillover public good by 7 percent. Besley and others (2004) consider the village-level incidence of high-spillover public goods, as measured by the gram panchayat activity index. They find that on average, this index was 0.04 points higher in the president’s village. Thus, for high-spillover public goods, proximity to the elected representative matters. In contrast, for low-spillover public goods, sharing the politician’s group identity matters most. Besley, Pande, and Rao (2005) show that reservation makes it more likely that SC/ST households will receive a Below Poverty Line card, which provides access to targeted benefits. This finding suggests that SC/ST leaders favor members of their own group. Bardhan, Mookherjee, and Torrado (2010) find that SC/ST reserva- tion has a positive effect on per capita benefits allocated to the village as a whole. It also improves intrahousehold targeting to both female- headed and SC/ST households—a sharp contrast to their results on women’s reservations. In a related paper combining theory with an analysis of the same data set, Bardhan and Mookherjee (2012) find that the effects of SC/ST reservation are entirely consistent with a model of 260
  • 281. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? clientelism. This result is also consistent with the results of Besley and others (2004). This literature details the largely positive impacts of inclusion man- The majority of studies find dates. Other studies find that reservation mandates have had a mixed that India’s constitutionally impact in terms of giving groups more voice or aligning the interests of mandated rules on inclusion caste leaders with the preferences of their groups. have given disadvantaged Palaniswamy and Krishnan (2008) identify the effects of SC/ST groups more benefits. . . . political reservation in the Indian state of Karnataka by exploiting the random allocation of reservations, conditional on village population size and the proportion of the SC/ST population in the village. In look- ing at the distribution of grants within village councils, they find that villages represented in the village council by SC/ST members attract fewer resources. They also find that reservations for other backward classes (OBCs) allow some politically dominant castes (Vokkaligas and Lingayats) to run in these reserved constituencies. Such villages are likely to receive more resources, suggesting that elite capture may persist despite the presence of reservations. Dunning and Nilekani (2010) use a regression discontinuity design to compare the impact of caste reservations on otherwise similar village councils in Karnataka. They find very weak policy and redistributive effects. Munshi and Rosenzweig (2009) analyze survey data on Indian local . . . but some studies find that governments at the ward level over multiple terms. They show that reservation mandates have reservations for disadvantaged castes can have adverse village-level out- had adverse effects. comes, by increasing the odds of electing lower-quality politicians who are able to attract fewer public resources. The caste system, the authors contend, serves as a commitment-enforcing device. Fearing social sanctions, a leader elected with the support of his or her caste is more likely to make decisions that reflect the preferences of the caste. When a caste group is large, it is able to elect its most able leader and to ensure that the leader implements a policy that does not deviate from the policy preferred by the median member of the caste. However, political reservations for disadvantaged castes make it less likely that a leader will be elected from a numerically dominant caste. Setting the main explanatory variable as the existence of a numerically dominant caste, the authors run a ward-level regression (the dependent variables are the characteristics of the elected ward leader and the ward-level provision of public goods). As they observe the same ward over multiple electoral terms, they are able to isolate within-ward variations in the identity 261
  • 282. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? of leaders from a numerically dominant caste. The results show that, without a caste reservation, the existence of a dominant caste results in the election of a wealthier leader, as well as a leader who is more likely to be in an occupation involving independent decision making (farm operator, business person, or professional), and this appears to increase the overall level of local public resources the ward receives by about 16 percent. In sum, while mandates thus seem to increase the representation of women and excluded groups in leadership positions and can be an effective mechanism for promoting greater inclusion in local councils. Their effects on resource allocation and the effectiveness of local gov- ernments seem to depend on the context. In particular, while women leaders are more effective in more mature reservation systems, their political effectiveness continues to be hampered by land inequality, the strength of existing structures of patriarchy, and the power of dominant caste groups. In contrast, caste reservation seems to affect the local political economy by changing the incentives for clientelistic allocations. For the most part, clientelism seems to narrowly benefit SC/ST households with potentially detrimental effects for the majority of village residents. The evidence also hints at the possibility that reservation rules are sometimes not properly enforced but instead captured by male- dominated structures of power. The vast majority of the evidence derives from Indian village democracies, however. The effects in non- democratic settings may be different. Community-Driven Reconstruction The active involvement of citizens in public life has come to be viewed as an important mechanism for managing or mitigating confl ict at all levels; participatory development projects are seen as an important mechanism for reengaging citizens in public life. In the aftermath of widespread conflict, participation usually takes the form of reconstruc- tion projects. The basic argument is that broad-based involvement in reconstruction planning can play an important role in rebuilding citizenship and trust in government institutions in a context in which state-society relations are frayed (Cliffe, Guggenheim, and Kostner 2003; World Bank 2011). 262
  • 283. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? The conflict-reducing role of participatory development goes beyond postconflict conditions, however. Community-driven development projects are usually implemented in contexts where formal governance institutions are weak and access to judicial institutions, courts, or the local police is limited largely to people with wealth or political power. In such settings, ordinary confl icts over property rights, the use of natural resources, and violence (domestic or communal) must often be arbitrated within the community itself, often through informal justice institutions. The impartiality of such informal mechanisms may be limited for marginalized groups within a community. In such environments, participatory projects could change the condi- tions under which disputes emerge and are resolved. On the one hand, the new informal institutional structures created by such projects could empower marginalized groups to demand more even and effective judi- cial services, from both formal and informal providers. On the other, they could create new struggles over the allocation of project resources and the distribution of power within localities, which could exacerbate Overall, the evidence on the local conflicts. effectiveness of community- There is as yet little reliable evidence on the relative effectiveness driven reconstruction projects of community-driven reconstruction projects as a means of deliver- as a means of delivering ing development aid or (re)building civil society under conditions of development aid or rebuilding conflict. What evidence there is, is not altogether encouraging, though civil society is weak. there are some positive findings. Strand and others (2003) review 14 World Bank–funded community- driven reconstruction projects. They find that although community- driven reconstruction projects may provide a fast-track disbursement tool, the poor and marginalized have only limited access to such projects. Governments often have an incentive to provide community-driven reconstruction resources selectively, in order to increase their political support and may be reluctant to extend such programs to areas that are less important politically, making it difficult to scale programs up. Community-level trust and The authors also find that community-level trust and reconciliation reconciliation building is building is effective only if it is linked to a comparable process at the effective only if it is linked to national level. They conclude that community-driven reconstruction a comparable process at the projects should be viewed not just as humanitarian efforts but also as national level. potential political tools. An understanding of existing political and social relations and reconciliation structures on the ground, as well as the establishment of community capacity, are thus necessary precondi- tions for the equitable distribution of resources in such projects. 263
  • 284. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Pearce (2007), who studied civil society participation in Colombia and Guatemala, argues that civil society organizations can play a prominent role in building citizenship by confronting violent actors in all spaces and levels of socialization. By restoring plurality and open- ing “invisibly sealed boundaries,” civil society organizations can curb violence by encouraging victims to understand violence. A key metric of the success of community-driven reconstruction projects is the extent to which they improve state-society relations and build social cohesion and citizenship. This set of objectives can be dif- ficult to evaluate, as the studies reviewed below illustrate. A second and perhaps equally important measure of success is the extent to which resources flow to activities and groups most targeted by such programs, usually the people most likely to be victimized by violence. Barron, Woolcock, and Diprose (2011) examine a community- driven reconstruction project in Aceh, Indonesia (BRA–KDP) that built on the national Kecamatan Development Program by targeting resources to victims of the conflict.12 Program targeting by the center worked well, as confl ict-affected communities were included in the program. Targeting within communities was weak, however, with conflict victims generally faring no better than nonvictims, despite the explicit intended targeting of conflict victims. Conflict victims were also more likely to report that their preferred projects were not selected for implementation. Project funds were also used to provide private transfers to beneficia- A postconflict reconstruction ries rather than investments in public goods. Not surprisingly, survey project in Indonesia may have responses revealed income gains in program communities (the survey reduced rather than increased was conducted while the program was still disbursing funds). The conflict victims’ acceptance of study finds little evidence for any improvement in social cohesion or excombatants. trust in governmental institutions, however. In fact, there is evidence that BRA–KDP was associated with less acceptance of excombatants by conflict victims in project areas, though there is no evidence of a greater tendency for tensions to escalate into violence (possibly because excombatants received some of the funds that were meant for civilian conflict victims). A potential solution to the problem of measuring social cohesion is to complement survey data with behavioral games, which provide clearer measures of political practice and cooperation. The Fearon, Humphreys, and Weinstein (2009) study cited earlier suggests that there is a greater propensity to contribute cash and labor in program villages, 264
  • 285. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? with much of the effect coming from contributions by excombatants. Survey evidence also suggests that individuals in communities with community-driven reconstruction projects report less social tension and exhibit greater acceptance of previously marginalized groups. There is no evidence, however, of any improvement in material well-being, though there is some evidence of improvement in local public goods. Fearon, Humphreys, and Weinstein do not see this improvement in public goods as unmixed evidence of the benefits of community-driven reconstruction in a conflict environment. In fact, they make the point that confl ict usually occurs at levels that are higher than the “com- munity” that such programs target. It is possible that strengthening cohesion at the local level could exacerbate conflict across communities. Their study finds no discernible effect on participants’ beliefs in broader democratic principles or other measures of citizenship. Furthermore, there was little impact on measures of social inclusion of refugees or new migrants into the community, although respondents in treated commu- nities report greater trust in their leaders (see also Beath, Christia, and Enikolopev 2011 on Afghanistan). Bellows and Miguel (2006) estimate the effects of the civil war in Sierra Leone (1991–2002), using unique nationally representative household data on conflict experiences, postwar economic outcomes, and local politics and collective action. They fi nd strong evidence that individuals whose households had been subjected to intense violence were much more likely to attend community meetings, vote, and contribute to local public goods; they were also more likely to be cognizant of local political dynamics. Several tests indicate that selec- tion into victimization is not driving the results.13 The relationship between confl ict intensity and postwar outcomes is weaker at more aggregate levels, however, suggesting that the war’s primary impact was on individual preferences rather than on institutions or local social norms. The use of community-driven reconstruction in postconflict settings is deeply affected by the context. The limited evidence is mixed. In some settings (Afghanistan, Liberia), such projects may have a positive There is no evidence that effect on social cohesion. In some settings, people with a more direct postconflict community- experience of war (excombatants in Liberia, people affected by violence based interventions increase in Sierra Leone) were more likely to contribute to their communities trust or cohesion beyond the and to participate in community meetings; in other settings, this was community level, or improve not the case. There is also no evidence to suggest that community-based material outcomes. 265
  • 286. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? interventions in postconflict settings increased trust and cohesion, had an affect beyond the community level, or improved material outcomes. Participatory Councils and Deliberative Spaces Public deliberation envisions a Public deliberation envisions a world in which citizens engage in rea- world in which citizens engage soned, thoughtful debate to come to a consensual decision. It is the ideal in reasoned, thoughtful debate form of participation. Its goal is to aggregate preferences through con- to come to a consensual versation, to allow the diverse views of a community to be consolidated decision. and presented as one representative view. Public deliberation is expected to have a number of beneficial effects—mirroring but intensifying the effects of participation. At the intrinsic level, public deliberation is expected to give voice and create a sense of agency and community; at the instrumental level, it is expected to enhance the capacity for collective action and repair civic failures by bringing the interests of citizens to the attention of the state. Important are not only formal deliberative forums but also what Mansbridge (1999) calls “deliberative systems,” where discussion and debate con- tinue outside formal spaces as informal conversations between citizens and representatives, political activists, media, and other citizens. This everyday deliberation changes the nature of participation, making it more discursive and consensual than merely ritualistic. Mansbridge claims that “when a deliberative system works well, it filters out and discards the worst ideas available on public matters while it picks up, adopts, and applies the best ideas.” If, however, “the deliberative system works badly, it distorts facts, portrays ideas in forms the originators would disown, and encourages citizens to adopt ways of thinking and acting that are good neither for them nor for the larger polity” (Mansbridge 1999, 211). Deliberation is also at the heart of what Fung and Wright (2003) call “empowered participatory governance,” a system of governance that translates deliberative decision making into policy decisions and actions (see chapter 4). Two sets of questions arise in considering the effectiveness of such a system. The first has to do with whether deliberation that empowers all participants is possible in highly unequal societies. The second has to do with whether deliberative capacity can be built and nurtured. Can policy interventions induce a system of empowered participatory governance? In what contexts does deliberation work well? 266
  • 287. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? Africa Deliberative democracy is not widespread in Africa, although indig- Deliberative decision-making enous traditions of deliberative decision making, particularly in rural groups led by women and communities, have carried over to public decision making to varying older men tend to have degrees (see chapter 1). In the island nation of São Tomé and Príncipe, different priorities and all adults were invited to a national forum in 2004 to gather in facilitated emphasize different processes groups to discuss policy issues related to the use of the newly discovered than other groups. oil reserves. Local facilitators were randomly assigned throughout the country. Humphreys, Masters, and Sandbu (2006) find that leaders significantly influenced the outcomes of deliberation, with one-fifth to one-third of the variance in outcomes explained by leader fixed effects. They also find that groups led by women and older men tended to have different priorities and emphasize different processes than other groups. A similar situation appears to prevail in Malawi, where evidence from more than a thousand ethnographic journals, in which field researchers capture the conversations of rural Malawians, shows a marked differ- ence between the quality of deliberation in informal and formal settings (Swidler and Watkins 2011). The data, collected in conjunction with a study on the role of social networks in the HIV/AIDS epidemic, show that people in rural areas engage in deliberation “frequently, energeti- cally, sometimes vociferously” in everyday settings—markets, village meetings, and chiefs’ courts—and freely “assert a variety of claims and moral principles” (p. 4) In induced settings such as donor-funded projects with deliberative modalities, however, they behave more like students in a rote-learning environment. Such settings “invoke the hier- archical template of school, with its colonial remnants and its deference to the prestige of modern learning” (Swidler and Watkins 2011, 4). Both facilitators and participants treat such forums like classrooms, where deliberation must be taught, giving citizens neither voice nor agency, as they are not engaging in a debate over their interests but simply acting out the scripts written by facilitators who are, in turn, following the dictates of donors. Can deliberative skills be transferred from the private sphere to for- mal democratic settings? Can deliberation be cultivated without active instruction? In many contexts, communications media promise to be a useful tool. Paluck and Green (2009) examine the effects of a radio program that attempted to promote independent thought and collective action while discouraging blind obedience and deference to authority in 267
  • 288. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? postgenocide Rwanda. The program was randomly assigned to pairs of communities matched on a vector of observable characteristics, with the control community receiving a comparable structured program about HIV/AIDS. The program encouraging independent thought improved people’s willingness to express dissent and seek collective solutions to common problems, but it had little effect on their beliefs and attitudes. Paluck (2010) tests the impact of a year-long radio talk show that was broadcast in tandem with a soap opera on randomly assigned com- munities in the Democratic Republic of Congo. Control communities heard only the soap opera. The talk show was designed to encourage tolerance and sharing of different perspectives; the soap opera pro- moted intergroup contact. Compared with individuals exposed only to the soap opera, talk show listeners were more likely to engage in discussion. However, they were also more intolerant, more focused on grievances, and less likely to aid members of the community whom they disliked. These two media experiments demonstrate the potential and pitfalls Deliberative skills of media-based strategies to promote deliberation in different post- are ubiquitous in informal conflict African contexts. Although deliberative skills are ubiquitous forums in Africa . . . in informal forums, it is difficult to translate those skills to formal settings, which tend to be driven by leaders and follow predetermined scripts. The challenge for citizens is to develop appropriate political and cultural skills—what Swidler (1986) has called a cultural toolkit—to navigate the public sphere. The radio experiments in Rwanda and the Democratic Republic of Congo were structured precisely to develop this toolkit. They had mixed effects, helping build the capacity for delibera- . . . but it is difficult to tion and collective action in Rwanda while generating more noise than translate those skills to formal signal in collective discussions in the Democratic Republic of Congo. settings, which tend to be The radio experiments also raise the question of how long-lasting these driven by leaders and follow effects are in the absence of active participation by a state that is com- predetermined scripts. mitted to the idea of deliberation. Whether the effects will be sustained after the programs stop airing remains an open question. Asia Gram sabhas (village assemblies) constitute the largest formal delibera- tive institution in human history, affecting more than 700 million rural Indian residents living in more than a million villages. Besley, Pande, and Rao (2005) analyze data on gram sabhas from 5,180 randomly 268
  • 289. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? selected households in 527 villages in South India to determine whether they yield instrumental (policy) benefits. They focus on a specific policy administered at the village level—access to a BPL card, which provides an array of public benefits. The authors estimate a regression that exploits within-village variation in individual characteristics to examine whether the targeting of BPL cards differs depending on whether the village held a gram sabha the previous year. They find that the targeting of landless and illiterate individuals was more intensive in villages that had held a gram sabha. Moreover, these effects were economically sig- nificant, raising the probability of receiving a BPL card from 8 percent to 10 percent. Some caution about these results is warranted, however, as it is possible that holding a gram sabha is correlated with other village characteristics that are important in shaping the way public resources are targeted. Rao and Sanyal’s (2010) qualitative analysis of 290 gram sabha transcripts from the same villages finds that the forums allow disad- Gram sabhas are more vantaged castes to gain voice and seek dignity and agency (see chapter than mere opportunities for 4). Ban, Jha, and Rao’s (2012) quantitative analysis of coded versions of cheap talk . . . these transcripts emphasizes that these forums have characteristics that are consistent with an efficient democracy. Deriving hypotheses from models of group decision making under uncertainty, they analyze the transcript data to test two competing hypotheses of the types of equi- librium that could characterize gram sabha interactions: “cheap talk” (discussions are not substantive even though they may appear equitable) and “efficient democracy” (meetings follow patterns of good democratic practice). They find that in villages with high caste heterogeneity and less village-wide agreement on policy priorities, the priorities of the median “voter” (a reference individual whose expressed preferences track those of 50 percent of the population) are more likely to dominate the discourse, and landed elites have a negligible effect. Ban, Jha, and Rao conclude that gram sabhas are more than mere opportunities for . . . discourse within them cheap talk, that they more closely follow patterns observed in a well- follows patterns observed in a functioning democracy. well-functioning democracy. Heller, Harilal, and Chaudhuri (2007) analyze qualitative and quantitative data from a survey of 72 gram sabhas in Kerala, where a “people’s campaign” systematized and empowered deliberative systems in gram sabhas, which are considered exemplars of Fung and Wright’s (2003) “empowered participatory governance.” The authors find that civil society inputs strongly influenced the decisions of local and state 269
  • 290. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? governments and that the campaign had positive effects on social inclu- sion, giving both lower-caste groups and women a more active role in decision making. The evidence from India highlights three main principles of effec- Gram sabhas work because tive participatory governance. First, gram sabhas work because they are they are constitutionally constitutionally mandated, which gives them legitimacy and clout and mandated, which gives them ensures that they are seen as ongoing rituals that will not disappear. legitimacy and clout and Regularity ensures that public interactions have to accommodate all cit- ensures that they are seen as izens, regardless of class, caste, or gender and that all citizens can voice ongoing rituals that will not their opinions publicly in a way that holds local government account- disappear. able. If deliberative forums are temporary or ad hoc events, they can be much more easily ignored, manipulated, and rendered ineffective. Second, the evidence suggests that in order to provide the right incentive for participation, deliberative forums must have clout. Third, embedding such forums within the context of electoral democracy is helpful, but providing voice and agency to all citizens in settings with low literacy is a challenge. Indonesia has a long tradition of consensual decision making at the local level. The World Bank–supported Kecamatan Development Program (KDP) attempted to move these traditions into more formal, modern settings. Over its 10-year life (1998–2008), KDP provided block grants directly to rural communities to fund projects prepared and selected through a deliberative process. The aim was to create par- ticipatory structures that would be a permanent alternative to decision making led by elites. KDP has been the subject of much scholarship and has generated a large number of important research findings highlighted throughout this report. The focus here is on the findings on the efficacy of deliberative forums. Olken (2010) presents the results of an experiment in which 49 One study finds that KDP villages were randomly assigned to choose development projects deliberation may be less through the standard KDP deliberative process or by plebiscite (direct effective in equalizing decision vote). Two types of projects were chosen by these processes for each making than plebiscites . . . village—a general project and a women’s project chosen exclusively by women. Olken finds that plebiscites resulted in dramatically higher satisfaction among villagers and increased their knowledge about the project, their perception of benefits, and their willingness to contribute. He finds that the type of projects selected did not change as a result of the plebiscite. For the women’s project, the plebiscite resulted in projects being located in poorer areas of the village, suggesting that it shifted 270
  • 291. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? power toward poorer women, who may have been disenfranchised in . . . and that plebiscites may more elite-dominated deliberative meetings. These results demonstrate increase the legitimacy of and that deliberation may be less effective in equalizing decision making satisfaction with development than a direct election and that plebiscites may increase the legitimacy interventions. of and satisfaction with development interventions. Olken’s results are contradicted, to some degree, by an in-depth, large-sample qualitative study by Barron, Woolcock, and Diprose (2011), who take the unusual approach of combining a counterfactual design with qualitative analysis to study the mediating impact of KDP’s deliberative spaces on local confl ict. Their analysis investigates two central questions: how KDP interacted with prevailing social tensions and management of local conflict and, more generally, whether delib- erative interventions such as KDP support progressive, nonviolent social change in a dynamic environment or make things worse. The authors selected two districts in Indonesia considered to have high capacity in their ability to manage conflict and two considered to have low capacity. Within each district, three subdistricts (kecamatans) were chosen—three that had KDP matched with one that was a con- trol. The treatment and control subdistricts were matched through propensity score analysis, with the scores reflecting various economic indicators, including poverty rates and the availability of infrastructure. Qualitative observations supplemented the propensity score matching method in order to eliminate poor matches. Data were collected from 41 villages in these matched kecamatans where conflicts were observed, and cases of confl ict in the treatment and control kecamatans were matched to be similar in type. Data collection was conducted over a seven-month period by a team of researchers who conducted case studies of conflict, interviewed key informants, observed deliberative processes, and conducted focus group discussions. The researchers also culled data on other local conflicts from local newspapers. The study finds that although KDP and other development projects frequently trigger conflict because of competition over resources, the In Indonesia, deliberative deliberative spaces within KDP make those confl icts far less likely spaces made conflicts far to escalate and turn violent, largely because decisions emerge from a less likely to escalate and consultative process that communities perceive as legitimate and equi- turn violent, because table. The likelihood of violence is also mitigated by the fact that KDP decisions emerged from a has facilitators and other procedures to manage conflict as it arises. consultative process. However, there is little evidence that KDP has a positive impact on con- flict at an aggregate level or even a direct positive impact on nonproject- 271
  • 292. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? related conflict at the local level. The project’s main impacts, in fact, are on conflicts that emerge from the project itself. There are three main reasons for this finding: villages have other mechanisms to deal with nonproject-related conflicts, KDP facilitators are not perceived to have the legitimacy to mediate disputes outside KDP, and project facilitators do not have the capacity to deal with nonproject disputes. KDP impacts are highly variable, though in both low- and high- capacity districts, program functionality matters more than the inherent capacity to manage conflict. There is also considerable variance over time, because KDP was not a standard project but had a considerable learning-by-doing component. This learning took place at differ- ent rates in different contexts, depending on the support the project received from government officials, the resistance of people whose inter- ests were most threatened by KDP’s transparency and accountability, and the quality of implementation. KDP is an assemblage of principles and procedures over which frontline facilitators have some modest dis- cretion while interacting with villagers over many months. The quality of facilitators also varies, with some working tirelessly, beyond the call of duty; some merely doing what the job description requires; and some (though not many) capitulating to corruption. Latin America Latin America has witnessed several significant innovations, notably participatory budgeting. As described in chapter 1, participatory bud- geting began as an organic innovation in the city of Porto Alegre, Brazil, where over time civic activists made the case for greater public delib- eration in determining municipal budgets. When the party supported by activists (the Partido dos Trabalhadores [PT]) came into power, it implemented a deliberative process for budgetary decision making that came to be called “participatory budgeting” (Baiocchi 2011). A series of studies tracking outcomes before and after the introduc- Participatory budgeting made tion of participatory budgeting (albeit without a counterfactual) finds the budgeting process more substantial improvements. The budgeting process became substan- transparent and responsive to tially more transparent and responsive to citizens’ needs (Souza 2001; citizens’ needs, empowered Schneider and Baquero 2006; Zamboni 2007), it also empowered marginalized groups, made marginalized groups and made the budget more pro-poor (Souza the budget more pro-poor, and 2001; Schneider and Goldfrank 2002; Serageldin and others 2003; reduced corruption. Evans 2004). And the level of corruption decreased (Ackerman 2004; 272
  • 293. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? Cabannes 2004). However, while accountability improved as a result of a more transparent and deliberative process, the forums’ lack of legal authority resulted in power remaining with the mayor’s office (Wampler 2004). These studies are descriptive or tracking analyses of largely organic innovations. They say little about how participatory budgeting would work if induced by an intervention or how any changes that resulted would compare to a counterfactual in which participatory budgeting was not introduced. One of the few counterfactual analyses of participatory budgeting is by Baiocchi, Heller, and Silva (2011), who use a discontinuity design. They match five municipalities in which the PT came to power with a small margin of victory in 1996 and subsequently implemented par- ticipatory budgeting with five municipalities in the same region and of similar size in which the PT lost by a small margin, resulting in the nonadoption of participatory budgeting. As the PT is very much a party born of civil society and Brazil’s social movements of the 1980s, Baiocchi, Heller, and Silva (2011) assume that two municipalities in which the PT garnered similar vote shares will be similar in terms of their local tradition of political activism and the composition and strength of civil society. In matching municipalities in this manner, they also try to control for scale and geography. The researchers selected five pairs of the best-matched municipalities (one pair in the South, two in the Southeast, one in the Northeast, and Participatory budgeting one in the North). Analyzing a mix of data from quantitative surveys facilitated much more and carefully collected in-depth interviews and group discussions, they effective forms of find that, in general, participatory budgeting municipalities facilitated engagement . . . much more effective forms of engagement than their non–participatory budgeting counterparts. In all municipalities with participatory budget- ing, the effect was to increase the flow of information about municipal governance, create a space for citizens to voice their demands and to scrutinize what were once highly insulated and discretionary decision- making processes. This allowed citizens to bargain from a position of greater strength with municipal authorities. There was considerable variation across the municipalities in how these outcomes were achieved, however. One municipality, João Monlevade, combined direct participation with a range of planning and coordination functions. Another, Gravataí, fashioned a set of processes that were very direct and required little mediation but that also made it 273
  • 294. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? much more difficult to coordinate at higher levels. A third, Camaragibe, built a system that went beyond the budget to encompass administra- tion. Its participatory administration resulted in a highly complex institutional design that combined forums with a range of coordinating institutions. The Camaragibe model required a high degree of media- tion, in the form of powerful delegates who were often closer to the state than to their communities. These differences reflected pragmatic adaptations of participatory budgeting to local realities, in particular to local civic capacity. Participatory budgeting improved governance outcomes, but did it repair civil society failures? In three of the five cases studied, Baiocchi, Heller, and Silva find that changes in civil society–state relations brought about by participatory budgeting were in the direction of democratic deepening, with municipalities graduating from the status of simple representative democracies in which civil society had little power to communities with more deliberative systems. However, the introduction of participatory budgeting does not inevitably deepen democracy, as illustrated by one case (Mauá), in which an improve- ment in the mode of engagement came at the expense of civil society’s autonomy, and the political party actually exercised more control over civic actors. Overall, institutional reform mattered mostly for chang- ing the institutional setting—for creating more meaningful points of . . . it did not inevitably interface between the local state and civil society. Institutional reform deepen democracy, however. did not have much of an impact on the self-organization of civil society. Summary What the evidence from all these regions shows is that context—the degree of capacity of civic groups, their relationship with the state, the responsiveness of the state, and the quality of facilitation and implemen- tation—affects the impact of deliberative processes. Geography matters, as does history, the literacy levels of the population, culture (especially the culture of deliberation), and the level of social and economic equal- ity. It is possible to build deliberative capacity and to use that capacity Context—the capacity of civic to repair civil society failures in some contexts—but it does not happen groups, the responsiveness of quickly; doing so requires long-term and sustained engagement. There the state, and the quality of may be some role for interventions that focus on communications facilitation—affects the impact media, but questions remain as to how long-lasting such effects will of deliberative processes. be. The quality of facilitation matters, but facilitators may also lead 274
  • 295. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? discussions that reflect their own preferences rather than the preferences of citizens. Most important, the degree to which the state is responsive to deliberative innovations makes a great deal of difference. Conclusions Collective civic action has two broad aspects. The first is cohesion—the ability of a community to coordinate and to manage its own affairs on matters that are relatively independent of states and markets. The second is the ability of a community to represent its collective interests to the agents of the state and persuade the state to be more responsive to its needs. Can projects that attempt to induce participation and build “social Whether projects that attempt capital” help repair civil society failures? The evidence on this important to induce participation and question is weak, for several reasons. build “social capital” can help First, there is a problem of attribution. Because much of what repair civil society failures induced participation does is get facilitators to work with communities, remains unclear. an important question is whether it is the facilitators who are causing the impact or the community’s experience with managing collective Facilitators strongly influence activity. The few studies that have tried to measure facilitator effects the preferences community find that facilitators strongly influence stated preferences. Participation members state. also tends to be driven by project-related incentives—people get together to derive benefits from project funds. It is very difficult to know whether these effects will last beyond the tenure of the proj- ect, although the limited evidence on this issue indicates that it may not. Respondents also tend to repeat project slogans in their responses, Community members repeat in the belief that this is what outsiders want to hear. As a result, simple project slogans in their survey questions on complex concepts like “trust” and “ability to coop- responses, in the belief that erate” often tend to elicit answers that are more reflective of rhetoric outsiders want to hear them. than reality. Keeping these important caveats in mind, there is some evidence, mainly from self-reports of participants, indicating a higher incidence of Absent affirmative action, trust and cooperative activity in treatment than in control areas. Group groups that form under the formation, however, tends to be both parochial and unequal. Absent aegis of interventions tend to some kind of affirmative action program, groups that form under the exclude disadvantaged groups aegis of interventions tend to systematically exclude disadvantaged and and women, sometimes minority groups and women. Moreover, similar types of people tend to reinforcing existing divisions. 275
  • 296. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? form groups with one another. As a result, projects rarely promote cross- group cohesion and may even reinforce existing divisions. Evidence from Africa seems to Participatory interventions are often also seen as a valuable tool in suggest that people emerging postconflict settings, where the need to get funds on the ground quickly from civic conflict have a is great. The limited evidence on the effectiveness of such projects in strong desire to participate. postconflict areas suggests that context matters a great deal, as does the A well-designed and quality of the intervention. Projects tend to have very limited impact on implemented project could building social cohesion or rebuilding the state. They tend to exclude draw on this inherent need. the poor and be dominated by elites. However, evidence from Africa seems to suggest that people emerging from civic conflict have a strong desire to participate. A well-designed and implemented project could effectively draw on this inherent need. Quotas for women and other Repairing civic failures requires reducing social inequalities. One disadvantaged groups in way of doing so is to mandate the inclusion of disadvantaged groups in decision-making bodies must the participatory process. Evaluations of community-driven develop- remain in place long enough ment projects provide virtually no evidence on this important question. to change perceptions and However, a growing body of evidence from village democracies in India social norms. indicates broadly positive impacts. Quotas in village councils and presi- dencies for disadvantaged groups and women tend to change political incentives in favor of the interests of the group favored by the quota. Mandated inclusion also appears to provide an incubator for new politi- cal leadership while changing the incentives for clientelism. Evidence indicates that women and other excluded groups are more likely to stand for office for nonmandated seats once they have had some experience in a mandated seat. Quotas can also weaken prevailing stereotypes that attribute low ability and poor performance to traditionally excluded groups. However, lasting change requires that the inclusion mandates remain in place long enough to change perceptions and social norms. Do deliberative forums help improve voice? Forums in which citizens gather to make direct representations to civic authorities or are empow- ered to make decisions that have a direct bearing on their lives seem to work when they have teeth. In particular, when the central and local governments recognize the legitimacy of deliberative forums and are responsive to them, they can transform the nature of civil society and state interactions. The ability of citizens to engage in public discus- sions on policy questions is strongly related to literacy: deliberation is far more effective in literate settings. However, even in poor, unequal Deliberative forums seem to settings, there is evidence that deliberation may have intrinsic value by work when they have teeth. promoting dignity and giving voice to the disadvantaged. Perhaps the 276
  • 297. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? most consistent finding is that deliberative forums are more effective Deliberative forums are more where they are an integral part of the policy-making process and where effective where they are an higher-tier governments are committed to ensuring greater citizen integral part of the policy- participation. making process and where higher-tier governments are committed to ensuring greater Notes citizen participation. 1. The community reconstruction project was randomly implemented in 42 of 83 eligible communities (program villages were selected through a public lottery). The project aimed to improve the material well-being of resident households, reinforce democratic political attitudes, and increase social cohesion. To assess the impact of the program, the authors used survey data collected at baseline and follow-up as well as a study on behavioral outcomes. The survey data included the usual range of socioeconomic welfare measures as well as measures of social cohesion and trust. 2. The public goods game assessed the amount of funding a community could raise for a collective project. Each player started out with an “endow- ment” provided by the game implementer. Players were then offered an opportunity to invest their endowment in a common pool. Money added to the common pool was multiplied—typically doubled or tripled—by the game implementer and divided equally among all players, irrespective of individual contributions, which remained anonymous. If all players coop- erate fully (that is, contribute the entire endowment), the common pool is maximized and each player gets a multiple of his or her initial endow- ment. With anonymous contributions, each player faces the temptation to free-ride on the contributions of others. 3. Village pairs were randomly allocated to treatment and control groups. 4. Because project resources were spent largely on local public goods that were under construction at the time of the survey, the welfare effects were not assessed. 5. The village development committees (VDCs) set up by the project were required to channel their village development plans through ward develop- ment committees (WDCs), which forwarded them to the district council for final approval. 6. The authors use matching techniques and national survey data collected before program implementation to select comparison communities. The social capital measures were obtained through qualitative work in the sample villages, following program implementation. 7. The comparison group is obtained by exploiting a pipeline setting. The program was introduced in phases. The second phase (Rural Poverty Reduction project [RPRP]) started three years after the first phrase (DPIP) and was introduced in different districts. At the time of the survey, DPIP had been available to survey villages for about three years and RPRP was just starting. A potential concern with the pipeline strategy is geographical variation across treatment and control areas. The study does not test for 277
  • 298. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? parallel trends. Instead, it uses propensity score matching on observables over an area of common support at the village and household level. 8. The authors identify three subgroups of interest: people who joined new groups under the program (new participants), people who already partici- pated in a self-help group before the program started but converted into a program group subsequently (converted participants), and people who did not join the program (nonparticipants). To control for household self- selection into a program’s self-help group, they form control groups using households that were potentially new, converted, and nonparticipants in the control districts based on their participation status three years after the program became available. 9. The author attempts to deal with selection into DPIP by using a quasi- experimental evaluation design that exploits state borders as an exogenous source of variation in treatment assignment. The strategy involves select- ing only treatment villages in Madhya Pradesh that are close to its border with Uttar Pradesh and then “pairing” each village with its neighbor in Uttar Pradesh, which did not have the option of being a DPIP village but is assumed to be similar to the treated village in all other respects. She uses a similar strategy for control villages, selected from villages in Madhya Pradesh that were also on the border but did not get DPIP, yielding “control pairs.” This identification strategy rests on two crucial untested assumptions, namely, that (a) the treatment and control villages in Madhya Pradesh had the same baseline levels for the relevant response variables as the ”paired” village in Uttar Pradesh and (b) any difference in the relevant baseline outcomes in Madhya Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh was the same in the control and treatment pairs. Only under these condi- tions could this approach reveal the treatment effect of DPIP. There is no prima facie reason to expect this set of assumptions to hold, and the author provides no evidence in support of them, other than a comparison based on village population, caste composition, and gender ratio before the program. It is unclear why these variables are the relevant ones for the outcomes of interest. 10. The IAT is an experimental method used in social psychology. It relies on the idea that respondents who more easily pair two concepts in a rapid categorization task associate those concepts more strongly. The taste IAT is a computer-based double-categorization task that examines the strength of respondents’ association between images of (anonymous) male and female leaders and normative categories of good and bad. To measure gender occupation stereotypes, the authors use an IAT that examines the strength of association between male and female names on the one hand and leadership and domestic tasks on the other. 11. Scheduled Castes and Scheduled Tribes (SCs and STs) are groups mandated by Indian federal constitutional guarantees for affirmative action because of their former status as “untouchables.” OBCs (Other Backward Classes) are castes listed by state governments in India as deserving of affirmative action because of a history of poverty or discrimination. 12. The study used propensity score matching to identify control villages that did not receive project funds. It used an instrumental variable approach to evaluate the effects of the program in treatment villages. 278
  • 299. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? 13. The authors acknowledge that they cannot rule out the possibility that omitted variable bias is playing some role—that is, that the types of people victimized tended to be the people who would have become postwar local leaders anyway. However, there is no strong evidence that more educated people or community leaders were targeted. Additional tests—demon- strating robustness in the youth subsample and in chiefdoms without permanent bases, where conflict-related violence victimization is likely to be more indiscriminate or random—argue against the hypothesis that the systematic targeting of community leaders is driving the results. References Ackerman, J. 2004. “Co-Governance for Accountability: Beyond ‘Exit’ and ‘Voice’.” World Development 32(3): 447–63. Agarwal, B. 2001. “Participatory Exclusions, Community Forestry, and Gender: An Analysis for South Asia and a Conceptual Framework.” World Development 29(10): 1623–48. Arcand, J.-L., L. Bassole, G. Rota-Graziosi, and J. P. Tranchant. 2008. “The Making of a (Vice) President: Party Politics, Ethnicity, Village Loyalty and Community-Driven Development.” CERDI Working Paper 200633, Centre d’Etudes et de Recherches sur le Développement International, Clermont-Ferrand, France. Arcand, J.-L., and M. Fafchamps. 2012. “Matching in Community-Based Organizations.” Journal of Development Economics 98(2): 203–19. Baiocchi, G., P. Heller, and M. Silva. 2011. Bootstrapping Democracy: Transforming Local Governance and Civil Society in Brazil. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Ban, R., S. Jha, and V. Rao. 2012. “Who Has Voice in a Deliberative Democracy: Evidence from Transcripts of Village Parliaments in South Asia.” Journal of Development Economics 99(2): 428–38. Ban, R., and V. Rao. 2009. “Is Deliberation Equitable: Evidence from Transcripts of Village Meetings in India.” Policy Research Working Paper 4928, World Bank, Washington, DC. Bardhan, P., and D. Mookherjee. 2012. Political Clientelism and Capture: Theory and Evidence from West Bengal. Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley. Bardhan, P. K., D. Mookherjee, and M. P. Torrado. 2010. “Impact of Political Reservations in West Bengal Local Governments on Anti-Poverty Targeting.” Journal of Globalization and Development 1(1): 1–34. Barron, P., M. Woolcock, and R. Diprose. 2011. Contesting Development: Participatory Projects and Local Conflict Dynamics in Indonesia. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Beaman, L., R. Chattopadhyay, E. Duflo, R. Pande, and P. Topalova. 2009. “Powerful Women: Does Exposure Reduce Bias?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(4): 1497–540. Beaman, L., E. Duflo, R. Pande, and P. Topalova. 2012. “Female Leadership Raises Aspirations and Educational Attainment for Girls: A Policy Experiment in India.” Science 335(6068): 582–86. 279
  • 300. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Beath, A., F. Christia, and R. Enikolopev. 2011. Elite Capture of Local Institutions: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Afghanistan. Working Paper, Department of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. Bellows, J., and E. Miguel. 2006. “War and Institutions: New Evidence from Sierra Leone.” American Economic Review 96(2): 394–99. Besley, T., R. Pande, L. Rahman, and V. Rao. 2004. “The Politics of Public Good Provision: Evidence from Indian Local Governments.” Journal of the European Economics Association 2(2–3): 416–26. Besley, T., R. Pande, and V. Rao. 2005. “Participatory Democracy in Action: Survey Evidence from Rural India.” Journal of the European Economic Association 3(2–3): 648–57. Bhavnani, R. R. 2009. “Do Electoral Quotas Work after They Are Withdrawn? Evidence from a Natural Experiment in India.” American Political Science Review 103(1): 23–35. Cabannes, Y. 2004. “Participatory Budgeting: A Significant Contribution to Participatory Democracy.” Environment and Urbanization 16(1): 27–46. Casey, K., R. Glennerster, and E. Miguel. 2011. “Reshaping Institutions: “Evidence on Aid Impacts Using a Pre-Analysis Plan.” Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab Working Paper, MIT, Cambridge, MA. Camacho, A., and E. Conover. 2011. “Manipulation of Social Program Eligibility.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 3(2): 41–65. Chase, R. S., R. N. Christensen, and M. Thongyou. 2006. Picking Winners or Making Them? Evaluating the Social Capital Impact of CDD in Thailand. World Bank, Social Development Department, Washington, DC. Chattopadhyay, R., and E. Duflo. 2004a. “The Impact of Reservation in the Panchayati Raj: Evidence from a Nationwide Randomized Experiment.” Economic and Political Weekly 39(9): 979–86. ———. 2004b. “Women as Policy Makers: Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India.” Econometrica 72(5): 1409–33. Chin, A., and N. Prakash. 2010. “The Redistributive Effects of Political Reservation for Minorities: Evidence from India.” NBER Working Paper 16509, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Cliffe, S., S. Guggenheim, and M. Kostner. 2003. “Community-Driven Reconstruction as an Instrument in War-to-Peace Transitions.” Conflict Prevention and Reconstruction Working Paper 7, World Bank, Washington, DC. Deininger, K., and Y. Liu. 2008. “Economic and Social Impacts of Self-Help Groups in India.” World Bank, Development Economics Research Group, Washington, DC. Duflo, E., and P. Topalova. 2004. “Unappreciated Service: Performance, Perceptions, and Women Leaders in India.” Working Paper, Department of Economics, MIT, Cambridge, MA. Dunning, T., and J. Nilekani. 2010. “When Formal Institutions Are Not Enough: Caste, Party Politics, and Distribution in Indian Village Councils.” Working Paper, Department of Political Science, Yale University, New Haven, CT. 280
  • 301. DOES PARTICIPATION STRENGTHEN CIVIL SOCIETY? Evans, P. 2004. “Development as Institutional Change: The Pitfalls of Monocropping and the Potentials of Deliberation.” Studies in Comparative International Development 38(4): 30–52. Fearon, J. D., M. Humphreys, and J. M. Weinstein. 2009. “Can Development Aid Contribute to Social Cohesion after Civil War? Evidence from a Field Experiment in Post-Conflict Liberia.” American Economic Review 99(2): 287–91. Fung, A., and E. O. Wright. 2003. “Thinking about Empowered Participatory Governance.” In Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance, ed. A. Fung, and E. O. Wright, 3–42. New York: Verso. Galasso, E., and M. Ravallion. 2005. “Decentralized Targeting of an Antipoverty Program.” Journal of Public Economics 89(4): 705–27. Heller, P., K. N. Harilal, and S. Chaudhuri. 2007. “Building Local Democracy: Evaluating the Impact of Decentralization in Kerala, India.” World Development 35(4): 626–48. Houtzager, P., A. Acharya, and A. J. Lavalle. 2007. “Associations and the Exercise of Citizenship in New Democracies: Evidence from São Paulo and Mexico City.” IDS Working Paper 285, Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, United Kingdom. Humphreys, M., W. A. Masters, and M. E. Sandbu. 2006. “The Role of Leaders in Democratic Deliberations: Results from a Field Experiment in São Tomé and Príncipe.” World Politics 58(4): 583–622. Kumar, N. R. 2007. Pro-Poor Targeting and Participatory Governance: Evidence from Central India. Institute for Economic Development Working Paper, Department of Economics, Boston University, Boston, MA. Labonne, J., and R. S. Chase. 2008. Do Community-Driven Development Projects Enhance Social Capital? Evidence from the Philippines. Policy Research Working Paper, World Bank, Washington, DC. Leino, J. 2007. “Ladies First? Gender and the Community Management of Water Infrastructure in Kenya.” Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley. Mansbridge, J. 1999. “Everyday Talk in the Deliberative System.” In Essays in Democracy and Disagreement, ed. S. Macedo, 211–42. New York: Oxford University Press. Mansuri, G. 2012. “Harnessing Community: Assortative Matching in Participatory Community Organizations.” Poverty Reduction and Equity Group, World Bank, Washington DC. Munshi, K., and M. Rosenzweig. 2009. “The Efficacy of Parochial Politics: Caste, Commitment, and Competence in Indian Local Governments.” NBER Working Paper 14335, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Olken, B. 2006. “Corruption and the Costs of Redistribution: Micro Evidence from Indonesia.” Journal of Public Economics 90(4–5): 853–70. ———. 2010. “Direct Democracy and Local Public Goods: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia.” American Political Science Review 104(2): 243–67. 281
  • 302. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Palaniswamy, N., and N. Krishnan. 2008. “Local Politics, Political Institutions and Public Resource Allocation.” IFPRI Discussion Paper, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington DC. Paluck, E. L. 2010. “Is It Better Not to Talk? Group Polarization, Extended Contact, and Perspective Taking in Eastern Democratic Republic of Congo.” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 36(9): 1170–85. Paluck, E. L., and D. P. Green. 2009. “Deference, Dissent, and Dispute Resolution: An Experimental Intervention Using Mass Media to Change Norms and Behavior in Rwanda.” American Political Science Review 103(4): 622–44. Pearce, J. 2007. “Violence, Power and Participation: Building Citizenship in Contexts of Chronic Violence.” IDS Working Paper 274, Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, United Kingdom. Rao, V., and P. Sanyal. 2010. “Dignity Through Discourse: Poverty and the Culture of Deliberation in Indian Village Democracies.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 629(May): 146–72. Schneider, A., and M. Baquero. 2006. “Get What You Want, Give What You Can: Embedded Public Finance in Porto Alegre.” IDS Working Paper 22, Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, United Kingdom. Schneider, A., and B. Goldfrank. 2002. “Budgets and Ballots in Brazil: Participatory Budgeting from the City to the State.” IDS Working Paper 149, Institute of Development Studies, Brighton, United Kingdom. Serageldin, M., J. Driscoll, L. M. S. Miguel, L. Valenzuela, C. Bravo, E. Solloso, C. Sola-Morales, and T. Watkin. 2003. “Assessment of Participatory Budgeting in Brazil.” Paper prepared for the Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC. Souza, C. 2001. “Participatory Budgeting in Brazilian Cities: Limits and Possibilities in Building Democratic Institutions.” Environment and Urbanization 13(1): 159–84. Strand, A., H. Toje, A. M. Jerve, and I. Samset. 2003. “Community-Driven Development in Contexts of Conflict.” Case Study, Chr. Michelsen Institute, Bergen, Norway. Swidler, A. 1986. “Culture in Action: Symbols and Strategies.” American Sociological Review 51(2): 273–86. Swidler, A., and S. Watkins. 2011. “Practices of Deliberation in Rural Malawi.” Paper presented at the conference “Deliberation and Development: New Directions,” World Bank, Washington, DC, November. Wampler, B. 2004. “Expanding Accountability through Participatory Institutions: Mayors, Citizens, and Budgeting in Three Brazilian Municipalities.” Latin American Politics and Society 46(2): 73–99. World Bank. 2011. World Development Report 2011: Conflict, Security, and Development. Washington, DC: World Bank. Zamboni, Y. 2007. “Participatory Budgeting and Local Governance: An Evidence-Based Evaluation of Participatory Budgeting Experiences in Brazil.” University of Bristol, United Kingdom. 282
  • 303. CHAPTER SEVEN Conclusion: How Can Participatory Interventions Be Improved? DEVELOPMENT IS MORE THAN A TECHNICAL UNDERTAKING THAT can be handled by experts. It is a complex and often contentious process that works better when citizens participate in decisions that shape their lives and allows them to monitor the people whose task it is to govern their destinies. Consequently, it may make sense to engage citizens in the process of development and to induce communities to act col- lectively to make governments more accountable. Involving citizens in decision making may also have intrinsic value, because training them in the everyday business of democratic governance may enhance their dignity and promote their quest for freedom. As recent popular move- ments have demonstrated, these values have wide resonance. The value of participation is clear. What is far less clear is whether The value of participation is participation can be induced through the type of large-scale govern- clear . . . ment and donor-funded participatory programs that have become a . . . less clear is whether it can leitmotif of development policy. This question is at the heart of this be induced through the kind report. of programs that have become This report does not emphasize more organic forms of participa- a leitmotif of development tion, in the form of trade unions, civic watchdog groups, producer and policy. consumer cooperatives, or activist groups of various types. Such engage- ment has tremendous capacity to initiate positive change. Indeed, it has been a driving force in many societal transformations throughout history, including the anticolonial and civil rights movements of the last century, the growing environmental movements, and the many ongoing movements for political and human rights, including recent popular democracy movements in the Middle East.1 In practice, organic and induced forms of participation are often linked. Large-scale induced projects may scale up organic initia- tives or develop in conjunction with organic activism. An initial 283
  • 304. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? outside stimulus may spur the growth of more organic institutions or movements. From the perspective of development policy, however, it is induced participation that is being fostered, and it is on this that much hope has been pinned and tremendous resources expended. Moreover, there is a particular challenge at the heart of attempts to induce participation. It is to harness the spirit of organic participation—which is driven by motivated agents, is contextually sensitive and long-term, and is con- stantly innovating in response to local realities—and to turn it into a large, state-driven, bureaucratically led enterprise. It is this challenge that is the focus of our report. This report examines two major modalities for inducing local partici- pation: community development and the decentralization of resources and authority to local governments. Community development supports efforts to bring villages, urban neighborhoods, or other groupings of people into the process of managing development resources through a project-based approach. Advocates for community development believe that it enhances the capacity for collective action, builds community cohesion or “social capital,” and strengthens the ability of the poor and disenfranchised to obtain better public services from providers and greater responsiveness from governments. The most common justifica- tion for community-based development is that it empowers the power- less by increasing “voice.” Community development projects are sometimes implemented through formally constituted local governments, but often they oper- ate quite independently, and in some cases, such as in postconfl ict environments, they effectively substitute for formal decentralization. Community development projects have been variously labeled as “social funds,” “community-based development,” and “community- driven development”—all terms coined within the World Bank over the past two decades. Within each of these categories, project designs can range from community-based targeting, in which only the selec- tion of beneficiaries is decentralized, to projects in which communities are involved in all aspects, from design to implementation and resource management. In recent years, as the effort to expand community engagement in service delivery has increased, participatory education and health projects have become more common. These projects have many of the same features as more traditional community-based development or community-driven development projects, which usually focus on 284
  • 305. CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED? infrastructure, skills training, private transfers, and credit, in addition to “community mobilization.” Most recently, such projects have also morphed into community livelihood projects, which, as their name suggests, focus greater attention on expanding opportunities for sustain- able livelihoods for the poor through the promotion of participatory mechanisms for expanding access to markets, investing in communal assets, and building market linkages. Decentralization refers to efforts to strengthen village and municipal governments on both the demand and supply sides. On the demand side, decentralization strengthens citizens’ participation in local govern- ment by, for example, instituting regular elections, improving access to information, and fostering mechanisms for deliberative decision mak- ing. On the supply side, decentralization aims to enhance the ability of local governments to provide services by increasing their financial resources, strengthening the capacity of local officials and streamlining and rationalizing their administrative functions. As this report is about participatory development, the decentralization evidence focuses on the demand side.2 This report builds a conceptual framework for thinking about when Markets and governments and how to induce participation that is structured around the idea of are now widely recognized as “civil society failure.” Markets and governments are now widely recog- subject to failure . . . nized as subject to failure. Yet the policy literature, particularly at the local level, is rife with solutions to market and government failures that . . . but civic groups are often assume that groups of people (village communities, urban neighbor- (erroneously) assumed to hood associations, school councils, water user groups) will always work always work toward a common toward a common interest. Rarely is much thought explicitly given to interest. the possibility of civil society failure—the possibility that communities, however constituted, may also face significant problems of coordination, asymmetric information, and inequality, which may limit their ability to respond to and resolve market and government failures.3 Development policy related to participatory processes needs to be informed by a thoughtful diagnosis of potential civil society failure and its interaction with market and government failures. Such an analysis is necessary for developing a clearer understanding of the tradeoffs involved in moving decisions to local communities, in each context. It is also necessary for identifying the avenues that any given project or policy provides to rectify or repair specific civil society failures. The report reviews more than 500 empirical studies of participatory development interventions to address issues of central interest to policy makers. These issues include the following: 285
  • 306. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? • The viability of using participatory poverty reduction projects as a vehicle for improving important development outcomes, such as service delivery, livelihoods, infrastructure quality, or the management of common pool resources • The potential for induced participatory projects to increase gov- ernment accountability and reduce capture and corruption • The efficacy of participatory projects versus programs imple- mented in parallel by local governments • The feasibility of sustaining positive outcomes when projects go to scale • Whether induced participation can create durable improvements in social cohesion, citizenship, “voice,” or the capacity for collec- tive action. A growing body of literature allows for a better understanding of some of these questions. This newer literature, as well as a large body of case studies, was used to build an evidence base for these questions. In doing so, the report cast a relatively wide net, using well-executed studies by economists, sociologists, political scientists, and anthropolo- gists. The report, does not, however, make any attempt to be exhaustive, particularly for the case study evidence. On several important issues, the literature is thin. For these issues, the report relied on the few (often one or two) carefully executed stud- ies that were available. Greater weight was placed on studies that had a valid comparison group. Without an adequate comparison group, it is difficult to attribute observed changes in beneficiary communities to the specific program or intervention being assessed. The wider process of development can alter outcomes over time through processes that operate independently of the intervention. Generally speaking, the report’s findings derive from econometric analysis. Ideally, this econometric work should be complemented by good qualitative work, which can help to illuminate the processes that resulted in the observed impact. There is an unfortunate dearth of such work. Three lessons, drawn from the evidence, appear to be abundantly clear: • Context, both local and national, is extremely important. Out- Context, both local and comes from interventions are highly variable across communi- national, is extremely ties. History; geography; and the nature of social interactions, important. networks, and political systems all have a strong influence. As a 286
  • 307. CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED? result, a successful project designed for one context may fail mis- erably in another. Strong built-in systems of learning and moni- toring, sensitivity to context, and the willingness and ability to adapt are therefore critical in implementing projects. As some of the evidence shows, carefully designed projects, whether they are implemented by governments or by donor-funded implementing agencies, are able to limit the negative impact of “bad” commu- nity characteristics, at least to a degree. • The idea that all communities have a stock of “social capital” The idea that all communities that can be readily harnessed is naive in the extreme. Building have a stock of “social citizenship, engaging communities in monitoring service provid- capital” that can be readily ers and governments, and supporting community-based man- harnessed is naive in the agement of natural resources or management of infrastructure extreme. requires a serious and sustained engagement in building local capacity. • Both theory and evidence indicate that induced participatory Induced participatory interventions work best when they are supported by a responsive development appears to state. Although local actors may have an informational and loca- increase, rather than diminish, tional advantage, they appear to use it to benefit the disadvan- the need for functional taged only where institutions and mechanisms to ensure local and strong institutions at accountability are robust. In fact, local oversight is most effec- the center. tive when higher-level institutions of accountability function well and communities have the capacity to effectively monitor service providers and others in charge or public resources. Thus, induced participatory development appears to increase, rather than diminish, the need for functional and strong institutions at the center. It also implies that project implementing agencies for donor-funded projects need to have the capacity to exercise adequate oversight. However, there is little evidence that donors alone can substitute for a nonfunctional state as a higher-level accountability agent. When funds are parachuted into com- munities without any monitoring by a supportive state, decision making is captured by elites who control the local cooperative infrastructure, leading to a high risk of corruption. Reforms that enhance judicial oversight, allow for independent audit agencies, and protect and promote the right to information and a free media appear to be necessary for effective local participation. These findings are consistent with the large body of case study evidence that Fox (1993) describes as a “sandwich movement” of 287
  • 308. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? To effectively induce enlightened state action from above interacting with social mobiliza- participation, enlightened tion from below.4 The state does not necessarily have to be democratic state action from above (although democratic states are more likely to support development). has to interact with social However, in the sphere in which the intervention is conducted—at mobilization from below. the level of the community or the neighborhood—the state has to be responsive to community demands. For example, schools that incorpo- In the local sphere, within rate parents into decision making will be more responsive to parental which the intervention is demands if parents have a measure of control over school budgets. conducted, the center has to Village governments will become more responsive to the needs of citi- ensure that local agents of zens when both function within an electoral democracy supplemented the state are responsive to by deliberative interactions. community demands. The Importance of Context Inducing local participation Inducing local participation is a difficult, often unpredictable, and is a difficult, often potentially contentious undertaking. The empirical evidence presented unpredictable, and potentially in this report must be viewed with this fact in mind. The heterogene- contentious undertaking. ity in outcomes should not be surprising once the role played by local conditions and the precise contours of project design are understood. Given the increased (and sensible) emphasis on civic engagement for effective and equitable development, it is important to build a body of solid evidence on the effectiveness of specific modalities for inducing participation and to assess the cost-effectiveness of such efforts. In view of the substantial reliance on evidence from quantitative evaluations of community-driven development projects and decentral- ization efforts, it is also important to reiterate that an effective evalu- ation must proceed with some understanding of a project’s trajectory and the timeline over which an impact on specific project outcomes is likely to be observed. Predicting a trajectory of change is hard to do in participatory projects. Very few evaluations take this issue seriously or verify assumptions about long-term impacts by returning to the site of the project after a few years have passed. Moreover, some outcomes may be inherently difficult to measure. Most evaluations, for example, are likely to miss subtle shifts in perceptions or beliefs that could mature years later into effective civic activism or a more inclusive society. Local development policy occurs at the intersection of market, gov- ernment, and civil society failures; interactions are deeply conditioned by culture, politics, and social structure, and they vary from place to 288
  • 309. CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED? place. Context matters, at both the national and the local level (for more on context, see Goodin and Tilly 2006). At the national level, nation- alist ideologies—the manner in which the (colonial and postcolonial) state has created and propagated identity—can create symbolic public goods that facilitate collective action by building a participatory ethic. History matters. The way policies and institutions—land reforms, History matters. education systems, the judiciary, the media, and efforts at social inclu- sion—have evolved can influence the responsiveness of governments to civic mobilization, affecting the incentives for collective action. A his- tory of organic participation matters greatly, for several reasons. Some countries have a long history of civic participation, developed in the process of struggles for independence from colonial rule or against the rule of entrenched elites. Such social movements help give legitimacy to civic activists and create a culture that facilitates civic mobilization. A history of organic participation creates a community of peer educators, who can train others on how to reach a consensus, engage in partici- patory planning, and hold governments accountable for their actions. In time, organic participation can make it easier to institute a cadre of trained facilitators who can spearhead scaled-up community-based interventions. A history of organic participation also creates an enabling environment within which social entrepreneurs can spark participatory innovations, the most effective of which can have important lessons for scaled-up induced interventions. The social, economic, demographic, and cultural contexts mat- The social, economic, ter. The nature and extent of social and economic inequality and the demographic, and cultural composition and diversity of groups affect both induced and organic contexts matter. participation. Inequality and heterogeneity strongly affect the cultures and norms of cooperation that evolve within a community. These norms have a bearing not only on the nature of collective action but also on the role of local leaders. Do local leaders act in ways that sup- port or undermine the larger interests of the community they claim to represent? Do they maximize rents, or do they lead with the collective welfare of the community in mind? Geography matters. Remoteness from more developed areas, difficult Geography matters. terrain, and harsh weather conditions can increase vulnerability, lead- ing to weaker development outcomes. Both social heterogeneity and geography have a bearing on the local cooperative infrastructure—the community’s capacity for collective action. If a village has a long history of successfully managing common property resources, that capacity 289
  • 310. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? could potentially translate into a collaboration to manage a school, for example. Urban migrant communities can consist of people from the same region (who therefore retain rural norms and customs) or differ- ent places (which could make cooperative behavior more challenging). Politics matters. Politics matters.5 The nature of the local state and its relationship with local communities deeply affects the extent to which the “nexus of accommodation” hampers development. As described in chapter 3, in contexts with compound market, government, and civil society failures, local and national political leaders, bureaucrats, and strongmen are often embedded within an extractive equilibrium in which the interests of citizens are given the lowest priority. Breaking this nexus—changing the equilibrium in a manner that makes the state more responsive to the needs of citizens—is at the heart of effective participatory development. Donors, Governments, and Trajectories of Change Effective civic engagement does not develop along a predictable trajec- tory. It is likely to proceed along a “punctuated equilibrium,” character- ized by long periods of seeming quietude followed by intense and often turbulent change. The “quiet” periods are not inactive. They are full of nascent, covert action, during which civic activists slowly begin to influence their neighbors to think differently, act collectively, deliber- ate effectively, and develop the courage to take on powerful interests. Without such risk-taking, the nexus of accommodation is hard to break. Donor-driven participatory When donor-driven induced participatory projects attempt to build projects often ignore the civic capacity, they assume a far less contentious trajectory. Conditioned fact that effective civic by bureaucratic imperatives, they often declare that clear, measurable, engagement does not develop and usually wildly optimistic outcomes—including greater civic capac- along a predictable trajectory. ity—will be delivered within a specified timeframe. As most projects are sold as poverty reduction or local infrastructure projects, declared outcomes include declines in poverty and vulnerability, without much attention to the effort, resources, or time frame required to achieve a sustained increase in the incomes of the poor. Unrealistic expectations often set such projects up for failure. Changing social and political One important reason behind this overly ambitious approach, systems is far less predictable especially at the World Bank, is that it maintains a path-dependent than building dams, bridges, institutional structure that continues to derive from a focus on capital- roads, schools, or clinics. intensive development and reconstruction. Building dams, bridges, 290
  • 311. CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED? roads, or even schools and clinics is a much more predictable activity than changing social and political systems. Repairing civil society and addressing political failures requires a shift in the social equilibrium that derives from a change in the nature of social interactions and from modifying norms and local cultures. These tasks are much harder to achieve than building infrastructure. A fundamentally different They require a fundamentally different approach to development—one approach to development—one that is flexible, long term, self-critical, and strongly infused with the that is flexible, long term, self- spirit of learning by doing. As demonstrated later in this chapter, the critical, and strongly infused World Bank falls far short of adopting this kind of approach in its with the spirit of learning by participatory projects. Other donors are probably not much different. doing—is needed. Open Research Questions The evidence on many participation-related issues is thin. More research is needed on several open questions. What Is the Link between Local Civic Capacity and a National Civic Sphere? Under what conditions will attempts to build local civic capacity help build a national civic sphere? This question goes at least as far back as John Stuart Mill, who believed that good citizenship is built at the local level. Many participatory interventions—particularly interventions that attempt to transform the nature of citizenship by improving the “demand side” of governance and “building trust” in postconflict situ- ations—are premised on the belief that such interventions will lead to a more accountable and cohesive civic culture at the national level. Very little is known about whether these local interventions are effective, however, or whether they can coalesce into national civic movements. In fact, the evidence suggests that under some conditions, greater local cohesiveness can actually exacerbate communal tensions. How Important Is the State? A related set of questions refers to the incentives faced by central governments in devolving power to local communities. Under what conditions can devolution be sustained over the long term instead of 291
  • 312. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? being rolled back by central authorities? How does this possibility of policy reversal affect the design and implementation of such programs? If participatory projects require an effective central state, is participa- tory development inappropriate in countries with weak states? How can local development be promoted in communities in which the central state is not effective? The evidence overwhelmingly suggests that effective community- based interventions have to be implemented in conjunction with a responsive state. Yet almost all econometric studies of participatory interventions focus on the communities themselves rather than the context within which they operate. More generally, research is needed on how to make the state, and its agents, more responsive to communities. What is most important— incentives, better monitoring, or training? There is also a debate over whether donors can substitute for a non- functional central government as a higher-level accountability agent. It is possible that they may help in the short term (by improving the performance of interventions) but be harmful in the long term (by hampering the evolution of an effective state). This largely theoretical debate should be complemented by better evidence. How Important Is Democracy? Credible elections within decentralized settings appear to provide a clearer mechanism than informal deliberation for punishing unpopular policy choices or excessive rent-seeking by incumbents. More research should be conducted on the conditions under which elections work, and—in particular—whether community-driven development projects that induce greater accountability with elections and mandated inclu- sion improve their effectiveness. Another important open question is the extent to which a shift toward democracy at the local level affects the allocation of resources, particularly if it shifts resources away from traditional elites and toward the less powerful in society. How Do Top-down and Bottom-up Approaches Compare? The evidence is very limited on how top-down approaches compare with bottom-up approaches in delivering goods and services to communities. Most evaluations of participatory approaches typically compare the 292
  • 313. CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED? intervention with the status quo—a counterfactual in which nothing is done. Such an approach says nothing about whether participatory inter- ventions are better or worse than centrally administered interventions. How Effective Are Local Interventions with “Soft Outcomes”? Questions remain even about the efficacy of local interventions that seek to achieve “soft outcomes.” Does participation build the capacity for collective action? Is it empowering? Do citizenship training programs work? Very few studies examine these questions, most of which do not lend themselves to easy generalization. Moreover, the literature tends to measure soft outcomes with responses to survey questions, which can be unreliable in measuring impact. Greater use of framed field experiments and behavioral games in conjunction with survey data could be beneficial. What Is the Appropriate Role for Nongovernmental Organizations and Facilitators? Very little is known about the efficacy of the widespread practice of hiring nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) to plan and implement projects and provide services at the local level. Is doing so more efficient than giving such authority directly to local governments or community bodies? Facilitators are the lynchpins of induced participation, yet almost nothing is known about their incentives, their training, or the social and political constraints they face. Much more could be learned about how to improve their performance and even the extent to which basic factors such as experience, age, and gender affect performance. How Should the Poor Be Targeted? Too little evidence is available on whether targeting the poor with proxy means testing or other centralized “objective” metrics of household status is better or worse than community-based targeting. How Important Is Corruption? A few important studies of corruption have been conducted, and there is an increasing, and healthy, trend toward relying more on direct 293
  • 314. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? measures of corruption (for example, engineering assessments of road quality) rather than perception-based measures. This kind of research should become the norm, as improving the demand side of governance is often claimed as a cure for corruption and perception-based measures tend to map poorly to measured levels of corruption and capture. How Well Have Livelihood Projects Worked? Livelihood projects and other attempts to use community-based inter- ventions to repair market failures, including community management of microcredit funds, remain largely unstudied. Very little is known about attempts to use community groups (artisans cooperatives, farm- ers cooperatives, and so forth) for income-generating activities. Some case study evidence exist on these issues, but little rigorous quantitative analysis has been conducted. What Makes Deliberation Effective? Another set of questions goes to the heart of the decision-making process within communities. What makes deliberation effective? Do facilitators contribute to the deliberative process? To what extent does deliberation influence the process of preference aggregation, building consensus among people with heterogeneous interests? How can the quality of deliberation be improved? Can deliberative spaces be made more effective and deliberative systems built? What Kind of Research Should Be Conducted? Most studies of large-scale participatory interventions ignore the pro- cesses that lead to an outcome (or the lack of one). Process is much bet- ter understood with the use of qualitative tools. Thus, more than most other development interventions, evaluations of participatory projects call for a mix of qualitative and quantitative methods—something that is almost never done well. A promising mode of enquiry is the use of qualitative data with research designs that are typically associated with quantitative studies—large samples, experimental designs, or the use of Very few well-done, in-depth methods to generate credible counterfactuals such as matching. ethnographies of participatory Very few well-done, in-depth ethnographies of participatory projects projects have been conducted. have been conducted. Although some development anthropologists are 294
  • 315. CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED? beginning to do serious work in this area, much of the literature on the anthropology of participatory development seems to rely on thin data (a perfunctory reading of project literature, “touch the water buffalo” field visits that last a week or two). Some of these studies have received wide attention in the anthropological literature, but their appeal likely derives from their ability to tap into preexisting prejudices about “neoliberal” institutions rather than from the carefully grounded ethnographic insights that characterize the best anthropological work. Monitoring, Evaluation, and Attention to Context: Results of a Survey of World Bank Projects The variability in the local context and the uncertainty surrounding To be effective, participatory the trajectories of participatory development projects highlight the development projects importance of developing effective monitoring and evaluation (M&E) require constant adjustment, systems. To be effective, participatory development projects require learning in the field, and constant adjustment, learning in the field, and experimentation. experimentation. A notable example of an effectively monitored induced commu- nity development project is the $1.3 billion Kecamatan Development Program (KDP) in Indonesia, which was active between 1998 and 2008. KDP provided block grants directly to rural community-based organizations to fund development plans prepared through a participa- tory process. In this regard, it was very similar to a large number of other community-based projects. Where it differed was in the extent to which it relied on context-specific design and attention to monitoring systems (Guggenheim 2006). KDP’s design was based on two key elements: a careful analysis of existing state and community capacity and cooperative infrastructure, drawn from a set of studies of local institutions, and a deep under- standing of the history of community development in Indonesia. Implementation involved creating a tiered network of motivated and trained facilitators, who created a feedback loop to facilitate learn- ing and worked with engineers to supervise construction. Villagers took control of expenditures and procured goods and services on a competitive basis. They formed monitoring teams that checked the delivery of material and the quality of construction, reporting their findings to the village forum. In addition to participatory monitoring, the project conducted audits at the subdistrict (kecamatan) level. In 295
  • 316. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? addition, independent NGOs and journalists were contracted to moni- tor and report on the quality of the project on a random basis. These innovations in monitoring were supplemented with more conventional quantitative tools, such as a carefully designed management informa- tion system (MIS), several qualitative and quantitative evaluations, and case studies (Wong 2003). Most important, the project emphasized an honest system of communication, which allowed observations, both critical and complimentary, to constantly inform innovations in design and implementation. KDP is among a small group of World Bank– funded participatory projects that have made an effort to build effective monitoring systems. Most World Bank–funded As part of the background work for this report, the authors con- participatory projects have ducted a review of M&E systems in World Bank–supported participa- not made an effort to build tory projects, with a view to understanding the extent to which induced effective monitoring and projects take learning by doing seriously.6 The data come from the evaluation systems. analysis of documents from 345 projects in operation between 1999 and 2007, all of which allocated more than a third of their budgets to participation. For a randomly selected subsample of 20 percent of these projects, the design of the M&E system was assessed by analyzing the project appraisal documents for each project. These documents—one of the main documents the Bank’s Executive Board examines before approving a loan—should ideally include a detailed account of the mon- itoring system and of the manner in which the project will be evaluated. The analysis also examined implementation status reports and imple- mentation completion reports for the sampled projects, in order to assess the effectiveness of the M&E systems proposed in the project appraisal documents. Implementation status reports are typically prepared by the project manager after every supervision mission. Implementation completion reports are self-evaluations of projects screened by the Independent Evaluation Group.7 The analysis also assessed informa- tion from project supervision documents, which synthesize the results of regular project visits by Bank operational task teams. An important limitation of these data is that they exclude any kind of M&E activity that is not reported in project documents. A survey of managers of current and recently completed community development projects was conducted to fill this gap. The survey, conducted in 2010, was sent to all 165 managers of the 245 projects that were either active in 2009 or had closed the previous year.8 Forty-one managers (25 per- cent) completed most of the survey questions (all figures reported in this chapter come from project managers who completed a significant 296
  • 317. CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED? portion of the survey). The responses suggest that the survey was more likely to be completed by project managers whose projects had some type of M&E system in place. The results therefore likely provide an upper bound on the presence and quality of monitoring and evaluation systems in place across all participatory projects at the World Bank. Findings from Project Documents One of the striking things about the project appraisal documents is how The design and even the similar they are. It is almost as if there is a template for participatory language of World Bank projects. Not only the design but also the language often seems to be cut project documents often seem and pasted from one project to the next, suggesting a lack of attention to be cut and pasted from one to context in designing participatory projects. project to the next. Although all of the project appraisal documents surveyed mentioned M&E, only about 40 percent described it as an essential part of the project design. And although 80 percent of the implementing agen- cies engaged an M&E specialist, the quality of the specialist—like the quality of the implementation—was highly variable. Furthermore, only about 40 percent of the sample documents detailed the kind of monitor- ing information that was collected. One-third of the documents did not even state that an MIS—a key project monitoring tool—was part of the information collection system. To improve the quality of project M&E, the Bank introduced a new results-based management framework in 2004. All project appraisal documents are now required to show how the project’s monitoring indicators will make it possible to attribute outcomes to changes intro- duced by the project. In the past, indicators were so broadly defined— “reduction in the gap between rural and urban income inequalities,” “improvement of GDP per capita”—that they may or may not have been an outcome of the project. The new results framework requires that relevant and easily measured indicators be included in the final matrix of outcomes, so that project impacts can be more easily tracked. Furthermore, the results framework must include data collection methods and measurable objectives, as well as implementation status reports based on monitoring data, to improve learning by doing.9 The Introduction of the results- results-based framework was also expected to make M&E more useful based framework in 2004 as a planning and management tool. does not appear to have Sampled projects from before and after 2004 were analyzed to improved the quality of determine whether the introduction of these new standards improved monitoring and evaluation of the quality of M&E systems. The results show that although the World Bank projects. 297
  • 318. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? number of M&E indicators was reduced by nearly half, 40 percent of the indicators remained imprecisely formulated (“improved allocation of expenditures,” “careful monitoring of effectiveness”). And although the number of indicators reported in implementation status reports rose (from a quarter to about two-thirds), only 22 percent of projects appeared to have collected data on the indicators that were supposed to measure intermediate progress. Most projects thus did not have access to timely monitoring data and could therefore not have been engaged in learning by doing based on real-time project performance data. The monitoring systems used in these projects were also assessed based on aide-memoires, midterm reviews, and implementation com- pletion reports, which provide a running picture of the Bank team’s most important observations and recommendations over the life of the project.10 Seventy-five percent of the assessments of monitoring systems tended to be negative. The most frequently observed deficiencies were the lack of a well-designed M&E system and poor implementation. These deficiencies were most often attributed to poor human and tech- nical capacity and lack of sufficient funding. Other reasons included the lack of institutional capacity, the absence of a baseline (which made it impossible to track progress), and the formulation of outcome indicators that could not realistically be attributed to the impacts of the project. Projects performed more or less similarly on evaluations. Although half the project documents explicitly mentioned that impacts were being evaluated and 70 percent of those mentioned some kind of impact evaluation with a comparison group, only 14 percent described the methods employed. Among the more credible methods mentioned were propensity score matching and randomized trials. But the major- ity used beneficiary assessments, participatory appraisals, and percep- tion surveys, which are not well suited to making causal claims. In the remaining 30 percent of projects, it was not clear what was meant by an evaluation or how it was to be performed. Having more than one The degree to which M&E can help the project adapt through manager over the life of a learning mechanisms depends on the attention it receives from project project—as half of the World managers (that is, whether M&E is a management priority). The experi- Bank’s participatory projects ence of project managers with participatory projects may also matter. did—can be disruptive for Among all 374 managers of participatory projects, 44 percent were effective management and managing more than one project, and about a third of these manag- learning systems. ers were managing three or more projects. Project managers tended to be fairly inexperienced with participatory projects, with an average of 298
  • 319. CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED? 1.85 years of experience in managing projects of this type and 4.3 years of experience managing projects of any kind. Half of all projects had two or more managers over their life, which can be disruptive for man- agement and for effective learning systems. An important aspect of learning by doing—and the satisfaction of beneficiaries—is the existence of an effective grievance and complaint mechanism. A third of all project appraisal documents from 1999 to 2007 mention some kind of grievance mechanism, and the average rose from a fifth of all projects before 2004 to half of all projects after 2004. Most project documents from both periods, however, provided very little information about the grievance mechanism. Only a quarter of documents that mentioned such a process explained how it worked, and only a third made provisions for documenting complaints. Complaints received through these mechanisms were sorted into three categories: poor quality of construction works, lack of transparent project selection criteria, and lack of community involvement in the selection process. This rather generalized complaint system raises questions about how well these processes are established in practice. Half of all projects since Complaints and grievance systems can be powerful tools for ensuring 2004 have included grievance that difficulties experienced by various project partners are considered mechanisms . . . and addressed in a timely manner. If used correctly, these systems can not only enhance project effectiveness but also promote community . . . but few explained how ownership of the project. In contrast, using these mechanisms as decora- the mechanism worked or tive planning instruments may undermine the engagement of different indicated how complaints stakeholders if their complaints are not acted on. were to be documented. Findings from a Survey of Project Managers The group of managers who completed the survey had far more experi- ence with participatory projects than the average project manager: only 5 percent had fewer than 2 years of experience, and almost 60 percent had more than 10 years of experience managing participatory projects (figure 7.1). More than 60 percent of survey respondents reported that the project had an MIS system that collected and maintained data on both devel- opment objectives and intermediate outcomes. More than 60 percent reported that monitoring data were publically available in some form, and half of these managers indicated that this information was avail- able on a website. Almost two-thirds reported that the project collected 299
  • 320. LOCALIZING DEVELOPMENT: DOES PARTICIPATION WORK? Figure 7.1 World Bank project managers’ years of experience working on community-driven development and local governance projects 70 60 58.5 Percentage of project managers 50 40 30 20 14.6 12.2 9.8 10 2.4 2.4 0 More than 5–7 7–10 2–5 0–2 Do not 10 know Years of experience tracking data and that an impact evaluation was either underway or had been completed. A large share also listed other types of monitor- ing activities, including field missions, participatory assessments, and facilitator feedback. In the survey, 88 percent of project managers stated that their project had a grievance mechanism in place, and 64 percent of these manag- ers (54 percent overall) reported that a record of grievances was being maintained. The results presented below should therefore be viewed as the opinions of seasoned project managers who were engaged to some Eighty percent of project degree in building effective M&E systems into their projects. managers surveyed believe Strikingly, the vast majority of project managers do not perceive that if the Bank did not require M&E as a priority for Bank Senior Management (figure 7.2). They also monitoring and evaluation, believe that if the Bank did not require M&E, government counterparts government counterparts would not engage in it (figure 7.3). A large majority (75 percent) also would not engage in it . . . believe that the Bank’s operational policies do not provide any incen- . . . and 75 percent believe tives to engage in systematic M&E (figure 7.4). that the Bank’s operational Two-thirds of project managers believe that the Bank’s M&E policies do not provide the requirements and supervision budgets are not tailored to project size, right incentives to engage in project complexity, or country context (figure 7.5). Only a third believe systematic monitoring and that the standard timeframe for projects (an average of 5.5 years) is suf- evaluation. ficient for realizing participatory objectives (figure 7.6). 300
  • 321. CONCLUSION: HOW CAN PARTICIPATORY INTERVENTIONS BE IMPROVED? Figure 7.2 Percentage of World Bank project managers who believe monitoring and evaluation is a priority for senior management 50 48.6 40 Percentage of pro