3 0 4 
Fabrizio Coricelli 
Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth 
Pact: The Perspective of New Member States 
W a r s a w , JJ u n e 2 0 0 5
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
Materials published here have a working paper character. They can be subject to further publication. The views 
and opinions expressed here reflect the author(s) point of view and not necessarily those of the CASE. 
The paper was prepared for the international conference "Europe after the Enlargement", organized by CASE 
- Center for Social and Economic Research in Warsaw on April 8-9, 2005. 
Keywords: fiscal rules, Stability and Growth Pact, Economic and Monetary Union. 
© CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw 2005 
Graphic Design: Agnieszka Natalia Bury 
DTP: CeDeWu Sp. z o.o. 
ISSN 1506-1701, ISBN: 83-7178-304-380-9 
Publisher: 
CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research 
12 Sienkiewicza, 00-944 Warsaw, Poland 
tel.: (48 22) 622 66 27, 828 61 33, fax: (48 22) 828 60 69 
e-mail: case@case.com.pl 
http://www.case.com.pl/ 
2
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
Contents 
Abstract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 
1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 
2. Fiscal policy and the pace of transition to the Euro . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 
3. Fiscal policy in NMs: an heterogeneous picture . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 
3.1. Size of the government . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 
3.2. Deficits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 
3.3. Debts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 
4. Shortcomings of the existing framework for new members . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 
4.1. GDP volatility and the 3% ceiling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 
4.2. Pro-cyclical bias. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 
4.3. Evaluating policies not only outcomes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 
5. Conclusions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 
3
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
Fabrizio Coricelli holds a Ph.D. in Economics from the University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia. He is currently 
Full Professor of Economics at the University of Siena and Visiting Professor of Economics at the University of 
Ljubljana, Slovenia. He is a Research Fellow at the Centre for Economic Policy Research, London, and at the 
William Davidson Institute, University of Michigan. He is member of the Advisory Council of CASE, Warsaw. 
From 1987 to 1989 he worked at the International Monetary Fund and from 1989 to 1993 at the World Bank. 
In 2002-2002 he was Economic Advisor at the European Commission, DG ECFIN. He has published extensively 
on issues concerning the transition from central planning to a market economy. He has been consultant for the 
World Bank, the OECD, EBRD and UNECE, focusing on formerly planned economies. 
4
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
Abstract 
Current developments in the design and management of fiscal rules in the European Union may have 
negative implications for New Member States. Loosening of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) and a 
growing degree of arbitrariness in its implementation reduce incentives for fiscal adjustment in New 
Member States, adjustment that would be crucial during the transition to the Eurozone. High budget 
deficits may prove a serious obstacle in the process of catching up of New Member States to the income 
levels of EU-15 countries. 
5
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
1. Introduction1 
Following entry in the European Union in May 2004, the larger New Member States (Czech Republic, Poland, 
Hungary and Slovakia) have been subjected to the Excessive Deficit procedure, according to the rules of the 
Stability and Growth Pact (see Box 1). Hungary has even been declared in a state of excessive deficit. This 
pattern contrasts with past experience in the European Union. Entry in the European Monetary Union has been 
in the past a powerful mechanism to induce fiscal adjustment in EU members, such as Italy for instance. In the 
last few years, however, the Stability and Growth Pact has ceased to be an effective constraint on fiscal policy in 
EU countries. The decision of the ECOFIN (European Council of Economic Ministers) to stop the excessive 
deficit procedure for France and Germany weakened the credibility of fiscal rules in the EU. The reform of the 
Pact approved in March 2005 introduced a few innovations with respect to the old Pact, by allowing countries 
to breach under several circumstances the 3% ceiling, which is the maximum budget deficit as a ratio of GDP 
admissible for EU members. First, countries will be excused not only when there are exceptional circumstances, 
such as a decline in output higher than 2%, but also when there is a persistent slowdown of the economy, or 
when countries undertake reforms, for instance pension reform, that have an adverse impact on the budget. 
Furthermore, the horizon for adjustment has been lengthened. It is hardly disputable that the inability to 
effectively pressure large EU countries to adjust their budgets and the reform of the SGP have sharply increased 
the degree of arbitrariness in the evaluation of fiscal policy and in the implementation of the SGP. 
1 The author wish to thank, without implicating, Anders Aslund, Jean Pisani-Ferry and Vito Tanzi for very useful comments on an earlier draft 
of this chapter. 
6 
Box 1: The Stability and Growth Pact (*) 
The Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) is the concrete EU answer to concerns on the continuation of budgetary discipline in Economic and 
Monetary Union (EMU). Adopted in 1997, the SGP strengthened the Treaty provisions on fiscal discipline in EMU foreseen by articles 99 and 
104, and the full provisions took effect when the euro was launched on 1 January 1999. In March 2005 the Ecofin approved modification, 
especially in the implementation of the SGP. 
The principal concern of the SGP was enforcing fiscal discipline as a permanent feature of EMU. Safeguarding sound government finances as a 
means to strengthening the conditions for price stability and for strong and sustainable growth conducive to employment creation. However, 
it was also recognised that the loss of the exchange rate instrument in EMU would imply a greater role for automatic fiscal stabilisers at 
national level to help economies adjust to asymmetric shocks, and would make it "necessary to ensure that national budgetary policies support 
stability oriented monetary policies". This is the rationale behind the core commitment of the SGP, i.e. to set the "… medium-term objective of 
budgetary positions close to balance or in surplus…" which "… will allow all Member States to deal with normal cyclical fluctuations while keeping 
the government deficit within the reference value of 3% of GDP". 
Formally, the SGP consists of three elements as follows: 
• a political commitment by all parties involved in the SGP (Commission, Member States, Council) to the full and timely 
implementation of the budget surveillance process. These are contained in a Resolution agreed by the Amsterdam European 
Council of 17 June 1997. This political commitment ensures that effective peer pressure is exerted on a Member State failing to 
live up to its commitments. 
• preventive elements which through regular surveillance aim at preventing budget deficits going above the 3% reference value. To 
this end, Council Regulation 1466/97 reinforces the multilateral surveillance of budget positions and the co-ordination of economic 
policies. It foresees the submission by all Member States of stability and convergence programmes, which are examined by the 
Council. The Regulation foresees also the possibility to trigger the early warning mechanism in the event a significance slippage in 
the budgetary position of a Member State is identified. 
• dissuasive elements which in the event of the 3% reference value being breached, require Member States to take immediate 
corrective action and, if necessary, allow for the imposition of sanctions. These elements are contained in Council Regulation 
1467/97 on speeding up and clarifying the implementation of the excessive deficit procedure. 
Besides these legal basis, the Code of Conduct on the content and format of the stability and convergence programmes, endorsed by the 
ECOFIN Council on 10 July 2001, incorporates the essential elements of Council Regulation 1466/97 into guidelines to assist the Member 
States in drawing up their programmes. It also aims at facilitating the examination of the programmes by the Commission, the Economic and 
Financial Committee and the Council. 
(*) Source: European Commission website.
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
In such a context, rather than clear reference points and clear constraints, access to the Eurozone and the 
SGP become for NMs moving or elusive targets and “flexible” constraints. 
In this paper we argue that an effective implementation of the SGP is crucial for NMs, perhaps even more 
than for “old” EU members. Indeed, NMs are still emerging markets, characterized by dependence on foreign 
finance, large current account deficit, weak financial markets, higher potential output growth, but also higher 
volatility of main macroeconomic variables. 
Interestingly, one of the official justifications for the reform of the SGP has been enlargement of the EU: “The 
Stability and Growth Pact needs to be strengthened and its implementation to be clarified, with the aim of 
improving the coordination and monitoring of economic policies. In doing so, due account should be taken of 
changing circumstances, in particular the increased economic heterogeneity in the Community of 25 Members 
and the prospects of demographic changes” (European Commission, Proposal for a Council Regulation, Brussels 
20.4.2005). Although some new features of the SGP, such as consideration of different growth of potential 
output, different initial conditions in debt levels and the fiscal impact of growth-enhancing reforms, represent 
improvements, one cannot neglect the risks that a less clear set of rules may produce an increased arbitrariness 
in the implementation of the SGP. This is the most worrying aspect of recent developments. We also emphasize 
that giving more relevance to debt sustainability rather than budget deficits, while generally correct, risks to give 
the wrong incentives to NMs, most of them characterized by low levels of debt. The peculiar features of NMs, 
such as the low development of financial sectors and high volatility output and fiscal revenues, call for a careful 
definition of safe debt-to-GDP ratios. We argue that there is little room for increasing debt ratios in NMs and 
we suggest to complement the SGP framework with national expenditure rules. These rules should also serve 
as a more effective reference for evaluating policies, avoiding confusion between policies and noisy outcomes. 
The paper is structured as follows. In section 2 we argue that during the transition to the Euro, especially 
during the ERMII period NMs have to rely on tight fiscal policies in order to avoid sizable output costs and the 
risk of failing the transition to the Euro. In section 3 we discuss the main trends of fiscal policy in NMs, highlighting 
the presence of two distinct patterns, one of low deficits in small countries and the other of high deficits in larger 
countries. In section 4 we discuss some features of the SGP, and its revisions, from the perspective of NMs. 
Section 5 contains some concluding remarks. 
2. Fiscal policy and the pace of transition to the Euro 
The target of entry in the European Monetary Union has been effective in fostering fiscal adjustment in 
several EU countries during the 1990s (see Gali and Perotti (2004) among others). Similarly, the same effect 
could be at work for new EU members, that eventually have to join the Eurozone. However, one can identify 
two distinct patterns of behavior in new EU members. One group of countries, the smaller ones, have embarked 
in a process of prudent fiscal policy that is accompanying their fast entry into the Euro. Another group, formed 
by the larger countries, entered the EU with high and growing budget deficits. At the same time, they have opted 
for a much slower path towards the Euro. Of course, the two aspects are closely linked, as fulfilling the 
Maastricht criterion on the budget ceiling of 3% of GDP is a pre-requisite for joining the Eurozone. The 
procedures leading to accession to the EU did not involve any conditionality on macroeconomic indicators for 
Candidate countries. In several NMs there was a marked deterioration of the fiscal accounts during the run-up 
to entry in the EU. Apparently, NMs did not perceive they would be subject to tight fiscal constraints upon entry, 
although the ceiling of 3% on budget deficit and the Stability and Growth Pact apply to every member of the EU. 
There was a strange, perhaps accidental, convergence between the positions of “populist” forces within the new 
members pushing for higher deficits and EU institutions, EU Commission and ECB, that explicitly favored a slow 
process of entry in the Eurozone. In a nutshell, the idea was that there was a trade-off between “real” and 
7
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
“nominal” convergence and not a complementarity between the two. Budget deficits could be tolerated as they 
were considered instruments for stimulating growth. 
3. Fiscal policy in NMs: an heterogeneous picture 
The first feature of public finances in NMs is that the “size of government” (revenue, or expenditure-to-GP 
ratios) in these countries seems to be high for their level of development, proxied by incomes per capita. 
3.1. Size of the government 
Figure 1 shows that the size of government in NMs is not far from the EU average, in spite of the fact that 
the average GDP per capita in NMs is below 50% of the EU average. This is true for Central European countries, 
while the Baltics are characterized by a much smaller size of government. One could thus conclude that the size 
of the government is too large for the level of development of NMs. In other words, one could argue that NMs 
have adopted prematurely the “European model”. It should be noted, however, that GDP per capita is only one 
of the variables affecting the “natural” size of the government. The demographic structure is certainly another 
factor, and in this respect NMs have a population structure and population growth similar to old EU members. 
Another factor recently emphasized by Rodrik (1998), is the degree of openness to foreign trade of an economy. 
According to Rodrik, trade openness increases the risk of output fluctuations of an economy, resulting from 
fluctuations in terms of trade. Indeed, the income effect of terms of trade changes is given by the variation in 
terms of trade multiplied by the share of trade-to-GDP. If the latter increases, the income effect of terms of trade 
fluctuations increases as well. An increase in the size of the government would compensate such effects, 
stabilizing output changes. 
Although this view might have some relevance for the evaluation of the size of governments in NMs, it should 
be taken into account that for NMs increase in openness goes hand-in-hand with integration in the EU, which 
implies an integration both in trade flows but also in terms of factor movements and financial sectors. Free capital 
Figure 1. Size of governments in NMS. Total expenditure of general government/GDP in 2003 
8 
60.0 
50.0 
40.0 
30.0 
20.0 
10.0 
0.0 
Baltics CE-4 Eu-15 
Source: Eurostat
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
mobility induces pressure for reductions in the size of governments through tax competition. Moreover, capital 
mobility and financial integration allows more diversification of risk in all EU member states. As a result, the 
Rodrik channel is less relevant as the financial sector permits to insure against risk of income fluctuations. 
Finally, the large size of governments of NMs results from an explicit strategy followed during their transition 
process. Such strategy was largely affected by the so-called “attraction of Europe” (Boeri 2000). In contrast with 
the strategy followed in most countries of the former Soviet Union, NMs implemented far-reaching market 
oriented reforms and the same time maintained a system of safety nets, in some cases extremely generous. Such 
strategy was perhaps one of the key elements for the success of the transition in NMs. Looking forward, however, 
the issue is whether maintaining such a large government may interfere with the growth process of NMs. 
Most NMs have indeed problems similar to old EU members. High tax burden on labor have likely affected 
incentive to work and thus labor supply. Employment rates are low in NMs, unemployment rates are generally 
high and the underground economy is estimated to be very large2. 
The experience of NMs has been highly heterogeneous: one can identify two distinct groups of countries 
that are following different fiscal strategies with sharp differences in the behavior of budget deficits and debts. 
3.2. Deficits 
Budget deficits have been on average well above 3% of GDP, except for Slovenia and the Baltics. Interestingly, 
it appears that country size matters for fiscal policy. However, low-deficit countries, especially the Baltics, are 
also the countries with a currency board, or a fixed exchange rate regime. 
The comparison between the Baltics and Slovenia on one side, and the other NMs on the other side suggests 
that high budget deficits cannot be attributed to special factors associated with transition and EU accession. 
Without denying that these factors have exerted some pressure on budget deficits, it is nevertheless clear that 
they cannot account for such a sharp different pattern of behavior within countries characterized by the same 
transition and EU-accession process. The difference in size of the countries perhaps suggests the importance of 
8.0 
7.0 
6.0 
5.0 
4.0 
3.0 
2.0 
1.0 
2 For these reasons, several NMs have opted for a policy of low income and corporate taxes. This strategy has brought Estonia, Lithuania and 
Slovakia to adopt a flat tax system, that is currently under attack from several government officials in old EU members. 
9 
Figure 2: Growth in New EU members, CE-4 vs. Baltics 
0.0 
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 
Annual GDP growth rate (in %) 
CE-04 
Baltic 3 
Source: Eurostat
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
political economy factors. In small and more homogeneous countries there is less scope for using the budgetary 
process to buy consensus for election and re-election. However, it is not easy to distinguish such political factors 
from economic factors, such as the stronger constraints for small and highly open economies. 
Nevertheless, it is interesting to contrast also the much better growth performance of the Baltic countries 
with that of the CE-4 countries (Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia) (Figure 2), which suggests that 
prudent fiscal policy and growth were complements in the Baltic states. 
In addition, there is no clear correlation between size of budget deficits and public investments, contrary to 
what it is often heard as justification of high deficits in NMs (Figure 3). 
0.0 
-1.0 
-2.0 
-3.0 
-4.0 
-5.0 
-6.0 
Thus, it can be argued that large NMs perceived they had no binding constraint in their fiscal accounts during 
the process of entry in the EU. 
3.3. Debts 
On average NMs display debt-to-GDp ratios well below those of old EU members. However, EU countries 
may not be a good comparator for judging debt ratios of NMs, that are emerging markets rather than established 
advanced economies. 
Financial sectors are still underdeveloped in CEECs and their public debts have a large component of foreign 
debt. If compared with Latin America, for instance, debt ratios of NMs, are of the same order of magnitude. 
Even after entry in the EU, as long as they remain outside the Euro-zone, NMs debt should be considered as 
emerging market debt, subject to the same volatility and risks of other emerging economies. Indeed, in the 
recent revisions of the SGP, countries with debt-to-GDP ratios below 60 percent should have more room for 
expansionary fiscal policy. While one could support such proposal when applied to current EU members, its 
rationale for new members is highly questionable. 
The stock of public debt in NMs should be evaluated from two perspectives, different from the simple debt-to- 
GDP ratio and from long-term solvency issues. The first is the size of public debt relative to the size of 
domestic financial markets. Indeed, in countries with still underdeveloped financial sectors, the crowding out 
effect of public debt can be very serious. Figure 5 displays debt-to-M2 ratios for NMs and compares them with 
10 
Figure 3. Budget deficits in NMs 
-7.0 
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 
Budget deficit (as a percentage of GDP) 
CE-4 
Baltic 3 
Source: Eurostat
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
70 
60 
50 
40 
30 
20 
10 
old EU countries. The striking result is that this measure gives a picture in which debt ratios in NMs are much 
closer to those of old EU member states and in some cases even higher. 
The second relevant perspective for countries that are still emerging economies is related to the notion of 
“natural debt limit” recently proposed by Mendoza and Oviedo (2004), that takes into account the uncertainty 
associated to high volatility of revenues, combined with rigidity in expenditure, for countries that might face 
severe constraints on availability of foreign borrowing. Emerging economies do not have the same ability to use 
international financial markets to smooth the effects of large shocks. In cases of severe difficulties emerging 
economies find it very hard to borrow abroad at reasonable rates. This phenomenon has been defined as one of 
“sudden stop” in the recent literature (see Calvo et al (2003)). Such sudden stop can be seen as a “worst case” 
scenario for a country. In such an event, the country has to adjust its imbalances, including budget deficits. Given 
that emerging markets have accumulated public debts, largely owed to foreigners, the question is whether in the 
event of a sudden stop these countries are able to service their debt, taking into account their ability to raise 
revenues and compress expenditure. 
11 
Figure 4. Debt-to-GDP ratios in 2003 
0 
Estonia Latvia Lithuania Slovenia Czech 
Republic 
Slovakia Poland Hungary EU-15 
Maastricht criterion 
Source: Eurostat 
Figure 5. Debt-to-M2 ratios 
140% 
120% 
100% 
80% 
60% 
40% 
20% 
0% 
Czech 
Rep. 
Euro-area 
Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovakia Slovenia 
Source: Eurostat and EBRD
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
This perspective gives a much more relevant evaluation of debt sustainability than measures of long run 
solvency. 
The key elements that make this approach relevant are the fact that emerging economies display a much 
higher volatility of fiscal revenues than advanced market economies. This means that in an adverse situation 
revenue-to-GDP ratio may decline sharply in emerging economies. At the same time public expenditure cannot 
be compressed to zero, as there are items that are rigid. Of course, the notion of rigidity of expenditures depend 
on the structure of expenditure and the political process associated to it. Nevertheless, we can usefully identify 
the rigidity of expenditure looking at the minimum ratio observed in recent years for a country or, as for 
revenues at the difference between the mean and the standard deviation of revenue-to-GDP realizations. 
Figure 6 indicates that NMs, like other emerging economies, display a much higher volatility of revenue-to- 
GDP ratios. We select the case of Estonia to compute the “natural debt limit”. The reason is that Estonia is the 
country with the lowest debt-to-GDP ratio and with fast real GDP growth. In such a case, computation of debt 
solvency will indicate a very high equilibrium debt-to-GDP ratio. As a result, one would be tempted to advise 
Estonia to rapidly increase its public debt, to exploit the room between its current levels and the 60% 
compatible with fulfilling the Maastricht criterion on debt. In fact, computing the natural debt limit for Estonia is 
instructive as it shows that current levels are not very far from the levels consistent with such “natural limit”. 
− 
= 
T G 
NDL m m 
The definition of NDL is , with 
−γ 
R 
Tm = “worst case” realization of revenue-to-GDP ratio 
Gm = minimum level of expenditure 
R = real interest rate 
γ = rate of growth of real GDP. 
It is useful to compare such definition with the level consistent with long run solvency 
, 
= − 
R 
T G 
−γ 
D 
where the value of the numerator indicates the current level of primary surplus. 
We compute the worst case level of revenue-to-GDP ratio for Estonia as the difference between the average 
ratio and twice its standard deviation. We use the same formula for minimum expenditure. We use a real interest 
rate differential with respect to real growth of 1.6. Interestingly, the NDL is equal to 20 percent of GDP. Of 
course, such calculation is only illustrative. However, it is useful to compare it with the traditional level computed 
looking at long run solvency. Using the same numbers for the real interest rate and the real rate of growth, such 
a level is 66% . The huge difference between the two measures of equilibrium debt levels indicates the 
important feature of revenue volatility typical of an emerging economy. This example suggests that for NMs one 
should use some sort of different scale of evaluation for the debt-to-GDOP ratio. An implication is that for NMs 
it is advisable to give large weight to deficit indicators, rather than the Maastricht debt ratio. Of course, this 
implies that NMs approaching 60% are a fortiori in a risky zone. 
The emphasis on deficits rather than debts would seem highly questionable (see Buiter (2004)) for countries 
that are characterized by much higher rates of growth of output. As shown in next section, our approach and 
that of Buiter can be reconciled by taking seriously the close-to-balance budget over the cycle, that is the 
cornerstone of the Stability and Growth Pact. Our view might seem overly restrictive for NMs, but in fact it only 
12
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
suggests that during the period of transition to the Euro, debt of NMs has a much higher risk than that of old EU 
members. Such risk is unlikely to be incorporated in risk premia by the market, as it is a risk associated with a 
low probability event (the worst case scenario). 
Figure 6. Volatility of revenues Standard deviation of Revenues/GDP, average 1995-2004 
6.00 
5.00 
4.00 
3.00 
2.00 
1.00 
NMs should be advised to adopt medium term fiscal frameworks that imply close-to-balance budget over the 
cycle, and thus stable debt-to-GDP ratio over the same horizon. Unfortunately, the current approach to 
implementation of the SGP has several drawbacks, especially if viewed from the perspective of NMs. 
4. Shortcomings of the existing framework for new members 
The EU fiscal framework is based on three main assumptions. 
(i) On the basis of the volatility of GDP for EU member states, it appears that 3% provides a sufficient 
margin to absorb “normal” cyclical fluctuations. During “exceptional times” the 3% ceiling can be breached 
without penalties. This implies that in “normal” times there is no pro-cyclical bias in the rule during “bad times”. 
It remains open the issue of the incentives to avoid pro-cyclicality during “good times”. The SGP is indeed a way 
to tackle this issue by indicating that countries should ensure convergence over the medium term to a balanced 
structural position. Accordingly, in periods of favorable cycles governments should run budget surpluses, 
matched by deficits during downturns. As, on average, the budget is balanced, the 3% ceiling will be passed only 
during exceptional times. This is connected to the idea of safety margins. 
(ii) The EC estimates that in most EU countries the budget elasticity to the output gap is between 0.5 to 
0.6. This means that one should observe a cyclical deficit of roughly half the output gap. In order to pass the 
3 percent ceiling one should experience a negative output gap of roughly 6 percentage points of potential 
output, it the budget is initially balanced. This event is rather unusual. For instance, in France during the period 
1980-2002 the largest negative output gap was 2.6 percent in 1985, while in Germany it never exceeded 1.6 
percent. 
13 
0.00 
Czech 
Rep. 
Estonia Hungary* Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak 
Rep. 
Eu-15 
* For Hungary data are for the period 2001-2004 
Source: Author's calculation on data from Eurostat.
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
(iii) The cyclically adjusted balance provides a good measure of the discretionary policy of national 
governments. 
Summing up, a country that behaves well should have counter-cyclical deficits due to the functioning of 
automatic stabilizers. This functioning of automatic stabilizers is fully consistent with the 3 percent limit for well-behaved 
countries. We will in turn discuss the three elements of the EU fiscal framework and highlight their 
limitations. First, we show that the foundations for the 3% ceiling and the cyclical safety margin are rather weak, 
especially for NMs. Finally, we emphasize the drawbacks of the evaluation and monitoring procedures of the EC, 
that are not solved by looking at the cyclically adjusted budget. 
4.1. GDP volatility and the 3% ceiling 
The 3% deficit ceiling had been thought for countries with potential output growth of about 2%. With an 
elasticity of the budget balance to the output gap estimated by the EC at about 0.5, a country shifting from the 
potential growth path to a decline of 2% in GDP would suffer a worsening of the budget of 2% of GDP. Thus, 
if countries followed the objective of close-to-balance budget over the cycle, they would risk to hit the 3% 
ceiling only in exceptional cases. However, countries characterized by much higher rates of growth of potential 
output are also exposed to much wider band of oscillation of GDP. A negative GDP change of 2% from a 
potential growth path of 5% would imply a 7 percentage points change. With similar elasticity of the budget to 
GDP, which is indeed the case for NMs, that have revenue-to-GDP ratios of the same magnitude of EU-15 
countries, NMs can easily hit the 3% ceiling even in a normal cycle3. 
Incomes per capita in NMs are on average 40 percent of those of the average EU country. Convergence to 
EU levels of GDP per capita is going to be a long term phenomenon. Thus, for a few decades NMs should display 
higher rates of growth than those of EU countries. Assuming the Barro well-known rule of thumb on 
convergence, NMs should grow at a rate that is 2 percent higher than the average EU. Studies on the European 
Union and in general on monetary unions, suggest higher rates of convergence, close to 3 percent. As the 
average rate of growth of potential output is around 2 percent in the EU, potential output in acceding countries 
can be expected to grow between 4 and 5 percent per annum. The volatility of GDP growth is also likely to be 
much higher than that of EU countries. This implies that with neutral fiscal policy stance, fluctuations in cyclical 
budget balances should display a much larger amplitude, following the higher amplitude of fluctuations in output. 
This can indeed be observed in the data. Looking at the period 1996-mid 2002, a recent paper by the ECB finds 
that NMs posted an average rate of growth of GDP of about 4% against a 2.2% of Euro area countries. Volatility 
was much higher in NMs, with a standard deviation of output growth almost three times higher than that of the 
Euro area (Süppel (2003)). The study concludes that since higher growth and higher volatility of growth reflect 
a catching up process, they are going to persist in the medium run. Given these structural features, the 3% ceiling 
on the budget deficit does not represent a sufficient margin to absorb cyclical swings in budget deficits. For 
current EU members, with an estimated elasticity of the budget to the output gap of around 0.5, the 3% budget 
deficit limit represents a wide enough margin to absorb regular cyclical fluctuations in the budget. While this is 
disputable even for current EU members, it is hardly applicable to acceding countries. 
4.2. Pro-cyclical bias 
A second possible drawback of existing rules is the pro-cyclical bias, associated to the fact that the budget 
deficit deteriorates during recessions and if it approaches the 3% ceiling, governments have to undertake 
3 As shown by the EC(2003), the GDP elasticity of the budget is dominated by the revenue effects. Coricelli and Ercolani (2004) find indeed 
output-gap budget elasticities for NMs only slightly lower, at around 0.45, than those of EU-15 countries. 
14
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
adjustments during “bad times”. According to Gali and Perotti (2003), the Maastricht criterion on the budget 
deficit has not been a constraint on counter-cyclical policies by countries in EMU. This effect is derived through 
an estimate of the impact of the output gap on the behavior of the cyclically adjusted deficit, contrasting the pre 
with post-Maastricht phase. They find no effect of a pro-cyclical bias after the introduction of fiscal constraints. 
A recent report by CEPR (2004) broadly confirms this result. It finds that only in the case of Portugal and Italy 
there has been a tightening of fiscal policy during a downturn. However, it could be argued that a similar effect 
would has been detected for Germany and France, had the Excessive Deficit procedure been approved by the 
ECOFIN. This would have implied a pro-cyclical stance in four members of the EMU during the most important 
episode of downturn of the post-Maastricht period. Thus, although there is no strong evidence of pro-cyclical 
bias in the existing fiscal rules, it clearly emerges that a sizable slowdown in the rate of growth of output sharply 
increases the probability of hitting the 3% ceiling, a problem that is bound to be much more serious for NMs, 
as the magnitude of the changes in growth rates is likely to be much higher than that of current EU members. 
Furthermore, looking at correlations between cyclical variations of government consumption and GDP, we 
found that NMs, as other emerging markets display a pro-cyclical fiscal policy (see Fiorito (1997) and Talvi and 
Vegh (2000) for a discussion of such methodology). Considering that government consumption does not vary 
automatically with the cycle, it can be used as a proxy for the discretionary component of fiscal policy. A positive 
correlation between the cyclical components of government consumption and of GDP is a measure of the pro-cyclicality 
of fiscal policy. Indeed, for several NMs such correlation was positive or close to zero during the period 
1995-2003 (Table 1, Coricelli and Eianchovina (2004)). This indicates that, so far, there has been little counter-cyclical 
role for fiscal policy in NMs. The fact that EU fiscal rules do not provide effective disincentives for pro-cyclical 
policies, either during good or bad times, might be a serious drawback for NMs that tend to have 
pro-cyclical fiscal policies. 
Table 1. Correlation between cyclical variations of government consumption and GDP, 1995-2003(*) 
Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovakia Slovenia 
0.80 0.03 -0.06 0.30 0.63 0.84 0.34 -0.58 
(*)Quarterly data. Cyclical variations are computed as percentage deviations from trend, computed with Hodrik-Prescott filter. 
Source: Author's calculation on data from Eurostat. 
4.3. Evaluating policies not only outcomes 
Rules are important because they can strengthen the credibility of policies. The current crisis of the SGP 
illustrates however the distinction between the credibility of policies and that of policy-makers. There is indeed 
an inconsistency in the current framework. Besides the motivations for the specific numbers chosen, there has 
been several papers by the EC to provide economic foundations to the whole apparatus of the deficit/debt 
ceilings and the SGP. The cornerstones are: 
The task of the EC is to monitor fiscal accounts and to evaluate the Stability and Convergence Programmes 
of national governments. When the structural (or cyclically adjusted) balance is seen increasing to an area that 
will put the country at risk of breaching the 3% ceiling, governments are invited to adopt an adjustment plan that 
would put the country in a safe area. On this basis national governments and EC discuss the budgetary plans. If 
the government follows those plans it should be defined as a “dependable” government, and thus a credible 
policy-maker. However, if a government behaves accordingly to the stated plans and ex post the EC identifies 
the government as behaving against the rules, there is an obvious problem. Of course, in the interpretation of 
the outcomes there is always scope for opportunistic behavior of policy-makers. Nevertheless, it is fair to admit 
that there are fundamental flaws in the rules. Unexpected outcomes, unrelated to policy actions cannot be used 
to evaluate policy-makers. The conceptual underpinning of the 3% ceiling is flawed. 
15
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
Consider the following example. Country A in year t has a balanced budget. In the following three years it 
plans to increase expenditure in line with the expected rate of growth of output. Assuming no change in tax rates 
and in tax collection, and assuming that a unitary elasticity of revenue with respect to GDP, the budget is 
expected to remain balanced in the period of planning. Furthermore, the country was growing at 3 percent in 
the year t-1. GDP is expected to remain at 3 percent for the three years considered. In fact, the economy slows 
down and the rate of growth declines to 1% per annum. The output gap may remain positive (actual output 
greater than potential). Nevertheless, the deficit deteriorates, approaching the 3 percent ceiling. From an ex ante 
point of view the government has maintained its promises. The cause of the deficit is a forecast error. The 
increase in the budget deficit would be measured as totally due to an increase in the structural deficit. However, 
the government has not switched to a looser policy through discretionary measures. It is just the ex post 
evaluation of policy that depicts a behavior of the policy-maker that does not reflect the reality. The first 
conclusion to draw is that the current framework for evaluating fiscal policy in the EU is misleading. This 
interpretation has surfaced also in the revised SGP. A proper definition of discretionary policy should take into 
account the fact that the actual budgetary process is based on expected output (see also Buti and Van den Noord 
(2003) and Larch and Salto (2003)). 
If governments were welfare maximizers, they would generally follow a fiscal rule consistent with tax 
smoothing. This amounts to set expenditure accordingly to the expected growth of potential output4. 
Abstracting from measurement errors of potential output, this rule would imply a structural balanced budget and 
cyclical budget balances proportional to the deviation of the rate of growth from potential growth. Actual 
developments of GDP will determine the movements in the budget balance and not the level of the output gap. 
Expenditure will be by construction counter-cyclical, with a unitary elasticity of expenditure-to-GDP ratio with 
respect to the deviation of growth from potential. Although this cyclical movements of expenditure is different 
from what are commonly defined as automatic stabilizers, in fact they work in a similar fashion as potentially 
stabilizing forces. 
Of course, if there is a persistent over-estimation of potential growth, there will be a persistent deficit. For 
this reason, a confidence interval on the calculation of potential growth should be applied and the lower end of 
the expected band should be chosen, ensuring a prudent management of expenditure. This error is likely to be 
much smaller than the forecast error on actual GDP. Neutral fiscal policy can be defined as the one consistent 
with the above rule (see also Buti and Van den Noord (2003) and CEPR, MEI 13, 2004). The difference between 
actual and neutral policy can be defined as discretionary policy. Moreover, from this discretionary policy one 
should subtract the effect of forecast error of actual GDP to obtain what Buti and van den Noord define as 
“genuine” discretionary policy, as expenditure is planned ex ante on the basis of expected output. 
Thus, even with the amendments introduced in the SGP, the current framework is affected by ambiguity of 
interpretation of fiscal stance, leaving room to political influence on such interpretations. 
The Stability and Growth Pact and the numerical limit of 3% on the deficit are an example of how rules can 
be simple but at the same time highly ambiguous, especially within the new SGP . The 3% limit is very simple 
and within the SGP the procedures that the EC has to follow are roughly automatic. However, the fact that 
ECOFIN has the final word on whether the ED procedure should be adopted, combined with controversial 
measures, such as the cyclically adjusted balance, used to evaluate fiscal stance, reduce the credibility of EU fiscal 
rules and make its implementation subject to decisive political interference. 
The first conclusion is that the existing indicators used by the EC to evaluate the fiscal policy of EU 
governments are misleading5. However, forecasts are likely to be biased, reflecting an opportunistic behavior by 
governments that for political reasons tend to overestimate growth (Larch and Salto (2003)). Interestingly, in the 
4 See Coricelli and Ercolani (2004) on this type of rule. 
5 This is recognized in the two papers by economists at the EC indicated above (Buti and Van den Noord (2003), Larch and Salto (2003)). 
16
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
main episode of crisis of the SGP, associated to the early warning to Germany and France, the forecast error was 
as large in the EC data as in the national data. Without denying the relevance of political or political economy 
considerations, it clearly emerges that the current framework of evaluation of fiscal policy in the EU leaves ample 
room for arbitrary interpretations and endless debate between national authorities and the EC. To summarize, 
the simplicity of the existing rule is only apparent. The whole mechanism is extremely complex and ambiguous 
in its implementation. The result is a loss of credibility for the entire fiscal framework in the EU. On one side, 
the behavior of ECOFIN damages the credibility of the EC; on the other side, the application of the procedure 
of the SGP damages the credibility of national fiscal authorities, providing an improper assessment of their 
discretionary policy. 
Therefore, there is a need to move to a monitoring of policies and not exclusively the results (a point also 
stressed by Annett et al. (2005)). It is well known that one can reduce the problem of time inconsistency in 
policies acting on the predictable part of policy, not on unforeseen events (Drazen (2004)). All these issues are 
more relevant in an enlarged EU as forecast errors for NMs are bound to be larger given the higher standard 
deviation of GDP growth in the new member countries. 
The debate on the reform of the SGP that is taking place is unlikely to produce a fundamental reform of EU 
fiscal rules. In the summer of 2003 the EC has put forward a proposal for some modifications of the SGP. The 
modifications put forward in 2003 by the EC, however, do not tackle the main issues we discussed above. 
These objectives can be achieved by complementing the SGP with an expenditure rule, that is easy to 
monitor and allows governments to own their own policy and the EU Commission to act as an outside 
monitoring body, even better if complemented by an independent national technical body providing a view on 
the computation of potential growth and assessing policy measures of the government. 
In Coricelli and Ercolani (2004) we argue that a more suitable rule for an enlarged and more heterogeneous 
EU would be a simple expenditure rule, according to which expenditures would grow at the same rate as that 
of potential output (see Box 2). Interestingly, the Czech Republic has introduced a medium-term fiscal program 
with an expenditure rule. 
From the rule described in Box 1 it is apparent that when real GDP growth will be equal to potential GDP 
growth, and inflation equals its target level (that could be the ECB target rate when the country is a member of 
the Eurozone), actual deficit equals its target value. When output growth falls short of potential growth, there 
will be a budget deficit, while a surplus will emerge when output growth is above its potential growth. The rule 
embodies an automatic "growth dividend": in good times the country accumulate surpluses that can be spent in 
bad times, ensuring a stable average level of debt-to-GDP ratio. Whether the rule is consistent with the 3% 
Maastricht ceiling on budget deficit depends on the magnitude of the deviations of output growth from its 
potential rate. What is more important is that if the country follows the above rule it cannot be blamed for lax 
fiscal policy. The worsening of budget deficits will entirely results from a downturn in the economy and not from 
a discretionary loosening of fiscal policy. Monitoring of fiscal policy would be very simple because the rule implies 
specific nominal values for expenditure. In summary, the framework proposed allows for an evaluation of fiscal 
stance that is superior to alternative indicators such as the cyclically-adjusted budget deficit. The proposed 
measure of discretionary fiscal policy better reflects discretionary policy decisions by the government. 
5. Conclusions 
In this paper we wanted to add the dimension of the enlargement to the already heated debate on EU fiscal 
rules. From the analysis it emerged that the main drawbacks of current rules from the perspective of NMs 
countries reveal fundamental shortcomings of the EU fiscal framework, and especially its implementation. 
17
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
Enlargement makes even more visible these shortcomings. However, even more important is the fact that fiscal 
discipline is a key element for a successful and fast convergence of NMs to income levels of the EU-15 countries. 
Such discipline ultimately rests on credible commitment by national authorities. Indeed, the heterogeneous 
experience of NMs, with two distinct groups of countries is telling. The Baltic states have followed prudent fiscal 
policy and a program of reduction of the size of the government. This process has been accompanied by high 
rates of growth of the economy and macroeconomic stability, that has allowed them to enter the fast track of 
Box 2: A medium term framework with an expenditure rule 
Primary expenditure grows in line with the growth rate of potential output, while target revenue, at unchanged tax rates, grows in line with 
actual output. Denoting with a (*) target variables, with y real GDP growth and p the inflation rate, we can write the rule as follows: 
τ τ π π 
− + − + − 
( ) ( * * ) 
− + − 
( ) 1 1 
g y y 
π π 
 
 
( ) 
= − − − − 
true 
t y 
18 
Target expenditure: 
 
  
 
+ + 
1 * * 
  
+ + 
= − 
π 
t 
g g t 
t t 
y 
t y 
π 
1 
1 
* 
Target revenues: 
 
  
 
+ + 
1 * * 
  
+ + 
= − 
t 
t 
π 
t t 
y 
t y 
π 
τ τ 
1 
1 
* 
where we have assumed that the output elasticity of revenues is equal to one. 
Target budget deficit: 
d * = g* −τ * 
With an estimation of potential output that implies that deviations of actual output from potential have zero mean (such as for instance the 
Hodrick-Prescott filter used until recently by the EU Commission), on average actual output will be equal to its potential level. As a result, on 
average, actual deficit will be equal to the target. Actual expenditures is a function of expected output and inflation and of a discretionary 
component, while revenues follow the actual behavior of output and inflation and the discretionary changes in tax rates. Thus, actual 
expenditures and revenues are as follows: 
 
  
 
  
π τ 
+ y 
+ + 
t 
+ + 
= − 
t t 
d 
t t 
t y 
π 
τ τ 
1 
1 
1 
* 
 
  
 
  
+ + + 
y g 
g g t 
+ + 
= − 
t t 
d 
t 
e 
t 
e 
t y 
π 
π 
1 
1 
1 
while the budget deficit, in terms of actual GDP 
d = g – Tt 
where e stands for expected values and d for discretional. 
One can identify a measure of discretionary fiscal policy as the difference between the actual and the target budget deficit. 
 
  
 
g g g y y 
= − − − 
  
1 1 1 
+ + 
t t 
e 
t 
e 
t t 
d 
t t 
d 
t t 
DP 
t y 
π 
1 
The “true” discretionary policy is obtained by subtracting to DP the effects of forecast errors 
τ τ 
− 
t t 
d 
t t 
d 
t t 
e 
t 
t t 
e 
t t 
t 
g g 
y 
DP DP 
π 
π 
+ + 
=  
 
+ + 
1 
1 
* * 
1
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
accession to the Eurozone. Slovenian has followed a similar path, although it is still in the middle of an internal 
debate on tax reform and on the role of the state in the economy. By contrast, Central European countries have 
shown growing budget deficits and raising debt levels. Starting from an oversized government, these countries 
face a challenge to adjust their fiscal accounts in the near future, not only as a precondition for entry in the 
Eurozone, but also as a policy to support a faster rate of growth of their economy. 
19
Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 
References 
Annett, A., J. Decressin and M. Deppler (2005), “Reforming the Stability and Growth Pact”, IMF Policy Discussion Paper, 
PDP 05/02. 
Buiter, W.H. and C. Grafe (2003), “Patching the Pact: Some Suggestions for Enhancing Fiscal Sustainability and 
Macroeconomic Stability in an Enlarged European Union”, forthcoming in The Economics of Transition. 
Buiter, W. (2004): To Purgatory and Beyond: When and How Should the Accession Countries from Central and Eastern 
Europe Become Full Members of EMU?, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 4342. 
Buti, M. and P. Van den Noord (2003), “Discretionary fiscal policy and elections: The experience of the early years of EMU”, 
OECD Working Paper n. 351. 
Calvo, G., A. Izquierdo, and E. Talvi (2003) “Sudden stops, the real exchange rate and fiscal sustainability: Argentina's 
lessons“, NBER Working Paper 9828.. 
Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) (2003), Monitoring European Integration, n. 13, London. 
Centre for European Policy Studies (2002): The Euro at 25: Special Report of the CEPS Macroeconomic Policy Group, 
Brussels. 
Coricelli, F. and E. Eianchovina (2004), “Shocks and volatility in Accession countries of Central-Eastern Europe”, The World 
Bank, mimeo. 
Coricelli, F. and V. Ercolani (2004), “Fiscal Rules on the road to an Enlarged European Union”, in G. Kopits (ed.), Rules-Based 
fiscal policy in Emerging Markets, Palgrave-Macmillan. 
Coricelli, F. (2002): Exchange Rate Policy During the Transition to the European Monetary Union: the Option of Euroization, 
The Economics of Transition, Vol. 10, No. 2. 
Creel, J. (2003), “Ranking Fiscal Policy Rules: the Golden Rule of Public Finance vs. the Stability and Growth Pact”, OFCE, 
n. 2003/4 
Drazen, A. (2004), “Fiscal rules from a Political Economy perspective”, in G. Kopits, Rules-Based fiscal policy in Emerging 
Markets, Palgrave-Macmillan. 
Fiorito, R. (1997), “Stylized facts of government finance in the G-7”, IMF Working Papers, 97/142. 
Gali, J. and R. Perotti (2003), “Fiscal Policy”, Economic Policy, 533-572, CEPR, October. 
Kopits, G. and S. Symansky (1998), “Fiscal Policy Rules”, IMF Occasional Paper, n. 162 
Kopits, G. and I. P. Székely (2002), “Fiscal Policy Challenges of EU Accession fro Central European Economies”, 
International Monetary Fund, mimeo. 
Larch, M. and M. Salto (2003), “Fiscal rules, inertia and discretionary fiscal policy”, European Economy Economic Papers 
n.194, European Commission, October. 
Mendoza, E. and M. Oviedo (2004), “Fiscal solvency and macroeconomic uncertainty in Emerging markets: The tale of the 
tormented insurer”, April, manuscript, University of Maryland. 
Rodrik, D. (1998) “Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?” Journal of Political Economy, 106(5), 
October. 
Talvi, E. and C. Vegh (2000), “Tax base variability and procyclical fiscal policy”, NBER Working Paper n. 7499. 
Calvo, G., A. Izquierdo, and E. Talvi (2003) “Sudden stops, the real exchange rate and fiscal sustainability: Argentina's 
lessons“, NBER Working Paper 9828. 
20

More Related Content

PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 295 - Fiscal Challenges Facing the EU New M...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 291 - The economics of the 'European Neighb...
PDF
Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits
PDF
Monetary Policies in the US and the Eurozone
PDF
Hungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, download
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 294 - Monetary Policy Adjustments on the Fi...
PDF
IEU budget and policy reforms to promote economic growth
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 412 - The Sustainability of Public Finances...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 295 - Fiscal Challenges Facing the EU New M...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 291 - The economics of the 'European Neighb...
Lueber Swiss Debt Brake,, pol econ of fiscal deficits
Monetary Policies in the US and the Eurozone
Hungary's National Reform Programme, pdf, download
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 294 - Monetary Policy Adjustments on the Fi...
IEU budget and policy reforms to promote economic growth
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 412 - The Sustainability of Public Finances...

What's hot (20)

PDF
The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 262
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 443 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy Determinan...
PDF
Interaction between monetary policy and bank regulation: lessons for the ECB
PDF
Programa de estabilidad
PDF
Intellectual capital paradox
PDF
Evolving of PFM for economic policy - game of tools and rules (focus on Slove...
PDF
Gerard-Daphne-6077589-Economics-Thesis
PPTX
Lekcija: Pasaules tautsaimniecības izaicinājumi un perspektīvas
PDF
Brexit watch
PDF
Democracy and Legitimacy in an Economic Union
PDF
Uncommon truths.....
PDF
Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 253 - When Should the Central Europeans Joi...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 301 -
PDF
Euro: problems and solutions
DOC
MorganDunn_HIS3150_draft3
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 270 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Alter...
PDF
Ecb history rolefunctions(2006)
The Economic and Monetary Union: Past, Present and Future
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 262
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 443 - Fiscal and Monetary Policy Determinan...
Interaction between monetary policy and bank regulation: lessons for the ECB
Programa de estabilidad
Intellectual capital paradox
Evolving of PFM for economic policy - game of tools and rules (focus on Slove...
Gerard-Daphne-6077589-Economics-Thesis
Lekcija: Pasaules tautsaimniecības izaicinājumi un perspektīvas
Brexit watch
Democracy and Legitimacy in an Economic Union
Uncommon truths.....
Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 253 - When Should the Central Europeans Joi...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 301 -
Euro: problems and solutions
MorganDunn_HIS3150_draft3
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 270 - Nominal and Real Convergence in Alter...
Ecb history rolefunctions(2006)
Ad

Similar to CASE Network Studies and Analyses 304 - Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact: The Perspective of New Member States (20)

DOC
Master kenmare
PDF
Codice di Condotta del Psc
PDF
The Stability And Growth Pact The Architecture Of Fiscal Policy In Emu Anne B...
PDF
Agenda Eurogrupo/ECOFIN
PDF
Future of the Stability and Growth Pact
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 459 - Economic Policy Coordination in the E...
PDF
The Italian Budget Cycle
PPT
Lecture eu economy in the context of the world crisis
PDF
Six pack
PDF
The Aftermath Of The Global Crisis In The European Union 1st Edition Beta Far...
PDF
The Economic Potential Of A Larger Europe Klaus Liebscher
PDF
Hacia una UME genuina
PPT
Evolution of the stability and growth pact
PDF
final final SGP
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 293 - Has Europe Lost its Heart?
PDF
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution o...
DOC
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)
PPTX
Eurozone crisis
PDF
Stability and Growth Pact
Master kenmare
Codice di Condotta del Psc
The Stability And Growth Pact The Architecture Of Fiscal Policy In Emu Anne B...
Agenda Eurogrupo/ECOFIN
Future of the Stability and Growth Pact
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 459 - Economic Policy Coordination in the E...
The Italian Budget Cycle
Lecture eu economy in the context of the world crisis
Six pack
The Aftermath Of The Global Crisis In The European Union 1st Edition Beta Far...
The Economic Potential Of A Larger Europe Klaus Liebscher
Hacia una UME genuina
Evolution of the stability and growth pact
final final SGP
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 293 - Has Europe Lost its Heart?
The fiscal institution in the Economic and Monetary Union: the contribution o...
EMU and the Growth and Stability Pact (GSP)
Eurozone crisis
Stability and Growth Pact
Ad

More from CASE Center for Social and Economic Research (20)

PDF
In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...
PDF
Praca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencje
PDF
The retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economy
PDF
Problems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economy
PDF
Informal employment and wages in Poland
PDF
The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...
PDF
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final Report
PDF
Increasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to Go
PDF
Is the economy doomed to a long recession?
PDF
mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...
PDF
Nasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii Europejskiej
PDF
Our Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European Union
PDF
The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....
PDF
The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...
PDF
30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus
PDF
Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?
PDF
Estonian corporate tax: Lessons for Poland
PDF
Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...
PDF
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final Report
PDF
The Impact of the State on the Quality of an Economic System: A Cross-Country...
In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...
Praca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencje
The retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economy
Problems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economy
Informal employment and wages in Poland
The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final Report
Increasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to Go
Is the economy doomed to a long recession?
mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...
Nasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii Europejskiej
Our Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European Union
The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....
The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...
30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus
Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?
Estonian corporate tax: Lessons for Poland
Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final Report
The Impact of the State on the Quality of an Economic System: A Cross-Country...

Recently uploaded (20)

PDF
2012_The dark side of valuation a jedi guide to valuing difficult to value co...
PDF
Buy Verified Payoneer Accounts for Sale - Secure and.pdf
PPTX
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
PPTX
ML Credit Scoring of Thin-File Borrowers
PPTX
Module5_Session1 (mlzrkfbbbbbbbbbbbz1).pptx
PPTX
Grp C.ppt presentation.pptx for Economics
PPTX
PROFITS AND GAINS OF BUSINESS OR PROFESSION 2024.pptx
PPTX
OAT_ORI_Fed Independence_August 2025.pptx
PDF
01 KEY PROVISIONS on NGPA and PROFESSIONALIZATION.pdf
PDF
DTC TRADIND CLUB MAKE YOUR TRADING BETTER
PPTX
lesson in englishhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhh
PDF
Principal of magaement is good fundamentals in economics
PDF
Lundin Gold Corporate Presentation August 2025
PDF
Pension Trustee Training (1).pdf From Salih Shah
PPTX
Very useful ppt for your banking assignments Banking.pptx
PDF
5-principles-of-PD-design.pdfvvvhvjvvcjcxhhcjb ggfvjhvjjhbvbbbvccxhgcxzzghjbv...
PDF
HCWM AND HAI FOR BHCM STUDENTS(1).Pdf and ptts
PPTX
General-Characteristics-of-Microorganisms.pptx
PDF
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
PDF
Fintech Regulatory Sandbox: Lessons Learned and Future Prospects
2012_The dark side of valuation a jedi guide to valuing difficult to value co...
Buy Verified Payoneer Accounts for Sale - Secure and.pdf
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
ML Credit Scoring of Thin-File Borrowers
Module5_Session1 (mlzrkfbbbbbbbbbbbz1).pptx
Grp C.ppt presentation.pptx for Economics
PROFITS AND GAINS OF BUSINESS OR PROFESSION 2024.pptx
OAT_ORI_Fed Independence_August 2025.pptx
01 KEY PROVISIONS on NGPA and PROFESSIONALIZATION.pdf
DTC TRADIND CLUB MAKE YOUR TRADING BETTER
lesson in englishhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhh
Principal of magaement is good fundamentals in economics
Lundin Gold Corporate Presentation August 2025
Pension Trustee Training (1).pdf From Salih Shah
Very useful ppt for your banking assignments Banking.pptx
5-principles-of-PD-design.pdfvvvhvjvvcjcxhhcjb ggfvjhvjjhbvbbbvccxhgcxzzghjbv...
HCWM AND HAI FOR BHCM STUDENTS(1).Pdf and ptts
General-Characteristics-of-Microorganisms.pptx
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
Fintech Regulatory Sandbox: Lessons Learned and Future Prospects

CASE Network Studies and Analyses 304 - Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact: The Perspective of New Member States

  • 1. 3 0 4 Fabrizio Coricelli Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact: The Perspective of New Member States W a r s a w , JJ u n e 2 0 0 5
  • 2. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... Materials published here have a working paper character. They can be subject to further publication. The views and opinions expressed here reflect the author(s) point of view and not necessarily those of the CASE. The paper was prepared for the international conference "Europe after the Enlargement", organized by CASE - Center for Social and Economic Research in Warsaw on April 8-9, 2005. Keywords: fiscal rules, Stability and Growth Pact, Economic and Monetary Union. © CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw 2005 Graphic Design: Agnieszka Natalia Bury DTP: CeDeWu Sp. z o.o. ISSN 1506-1701, ISBN: 83-7178-304-380-9 Publisher: CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research 12 Sienkiewicza, 00-944 Warsaw, Poland tel.: (48 22) 622 66 27, 828 61 33, fax: (48 22) 828 60 69 e-mail: case@case.com.pl http://www.case.com.pl/ 2
  • 3. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... Contents Abstract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 2. Fiscal policy and the pace of transition to the Euro . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 3. Fiscal policy in NMs: an heterogeneous picture . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 3.1. Size of the government . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 3.2. Deficits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 3.3. Debts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 4. Shortcomings of the existing framework for new members . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 4.1. GDP volatility and the 3% ceiling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 4.2. Pro-cyclical bias. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 4.3. Evaluating policies not only outcomes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 5. Conclusions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 3
  • 4. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... Fabrizio Coricelli holds a Ph.D. in Economics from the University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia. He is currently Full Professor of Economics at the University of Siena and Visiting Professor of Economics at the University of Ljubljana, Slovenia. He is a Research Fellow at the Centre for Economic Policy Research, London, and at the William Davidson Institute, University of Michigan. He is member of the Advisory Council of CASE, Warsaw. From 1987 to 1989 he worked at the International Monetary Fund and from 1989 to 1993 at the World Bank. In 2002-2002 he was Economic Advisor at the European Commission, DG ECFIN. He has published extensively on issues concerning the transition from central planning to a market economy. He has been consultant for the World Bank, the OECD, EBRD and UNECE, focusing on formerly planned economies. 4
  • 5. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... Abstract Current developments in the design and management of fiscal rules in the European Union may have negative implications for New Member States. Loosening of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) and a growing degree of arbitrariness in its implementation reduce incentives for fiscal adjustment in New Member States, adjustment that would be crucial during the transition to the Eurozone. High budget deficits may prove a serious obstacle in the process of catching up of New Member States to the income levels of EU-15 countries. 5
  • 6. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 1. Introduction1 Following entry in the European Union in May 2004, the larger New Member States (Czech Republic, Poland, Hungary and Slovakia) have been subjected to the Excessive Deficit procedure, according to the rules of the Stability and Growth Pact (see Box 1). Hungary has even been declared in a state of excessive deficit. This pattern contrasts with past experience in the European Union. Entry in the European Monetary Union has been in the past a powerful mechanism to induce fiscal adjustment in EU members, such as Italy for instance. In the last few years, however, the Stability and Growth Pact has ceased to be an effective constraint on fiscal policy in EU countries. The decision of the ECOFIN (European Council of Economic Ministers) to stop the excessive deficit procedure for France and Germany weakened the credibility of fiscal rules in the EU. The reform of the Pact approved in March 2005 introduced a few innovations with respect to the old Pact, by allowing countries to breach under several circumstances the 3% ceiling, which is the maximum budget deficit as a ratio of GDP admissible for EU members. First, countries will be excused not only when there are exceptional circumstances, such as a decline in output higher than 2%, but also when there is a persistent slowdown of the economy, or when countries undertake reforms, for instance pension reform, that have an adverse impact on the budget. Furthermore, the horizon for adjustment has been lengthened. It is hardly disputable that the inability to effectively pressure large EU countries to adjust their budgets and the reform of the SGP have sharply increased the degree of arbitrariness in the evaluation of fiscal policy and in the implementation of the SGP. 1 The author wish to thank, without implicating, Anders Aslund, Jean Pisani-Ferry and Vito Tanzi for very useful comments on an earlier draft of this chapter. 6 Box 1: The Stability and Growth Pact (*) The Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) is the concrete EU answer to concerns on the continuation of budgetary discipline in Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). Adopted in 1997, the SGP strengthened the Treaty provisions on fiscal discipline in EMU foreseen by articles 99 and 104, and the full provisions took effect when the euro was launched on 1 January 1999. In March 2005 the Ecofin approved modification, especially in the implementation of the SGP. The principal concern of the SGP was enforcing fiscal discipline as a permanent feature of EMU. Safeguarding sound government finances as a means to strengthening the conditions for price stability and for strong and sustainable growth conducive to employment creation. However, it was also recognised that the loss of the exchange rate instrument in EMU would imply a greater role for automatic fiscal stabilisers at national level to help economies adjust to asymmetric shocks, and would make it "necessary to ensure that national budgetary policies support stability oriented monetary policies". This is the rationale behind the core commitment of the SGP, i.e. to set the "… medium-term objective of budgetary positions close to balance or in surplus…" which "… will allow all Member States to deal with normal cyclical fluctuations while keeping the government deficit within the reference value of 3% of GDP". Formally, the SGP consists of three elements as follows: • a political commitment by all parties involved in the SGP (Commission, Member States, Council) to the full and timely implementation of the budget surveillance process. These are contained in a Resolution agreed by the Amsterdam European Council of 17 June 1997. This political commitment ensures that effective peer pressure is exerted on a Member State failing to live up to its commitments. • preventive elements which through regular surveillance aim at preventing budget deficits going above the 3% reference value. To this end, Council Regulation 1466/97 reinforces the multilateral surveillance of budget positions and the co-ordination of economic policies. It foresees the submission by all Member States of stability and convergence programmes, which are examined by the Council. The Regulation foresees also the possibility to trigger the early warning mechanism in the event a significance slippage in the budgetary position of a Member State is identified. • dissuasive elements which in the event of the 3% reference value being breached, require Member States to take immediate corrective action and, if necessary, allow for the imposition of sanctions. These elements are contained in Council Regulation 1467/97 on speeding up and clarifying the implementation of the excessive deficit procedure. Besides these legal basis, the Code of Conduct on the content and format of the stability and convergence programmes, endorsed by the ECOFIN Council on 10 July 2001, incorporates the essential elements of Council Regulation 1466/97 into guidelines to assist the Member States in drawing up their programmes. It also aims at facilitating the examination of the programmes by the Commission, the Economic and Financial Committee and the Council. (*) Source: European Commission website.
  • 7. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... In such a context, rather than clear reference points and clear constraints, access to the Eurozone and the SGP become for NMs moving or elusive targets and “flexible” constraints. In this paper we argue that an effective implementation of the SGP is crucial for NMs, perhaps even more than for “old” EU members. Indeed, NMs are still emerging markets, characterized by dependence on foreign finance, large current account deficit, weak financial markets, higher potential output growth, but also higher volatility of main macroeconomic variables. Interestingly, one of the official justifications for the reform of the SGP has been enlargement of the EU: “The Stability and Growth Pact needs to be strengthened and its implementation to be clarified, with the aim of improving the coordination and monitoring of economic policies. In doing so, due account should be taken of changing circumstances, in particular the increased economic heterogeneity in the Community of 25 Members and the prospects of demographic changes” (European Commission, Proposal for a Council Regulation, Brussels 20.4.2005). Although some new features of the SGP, such as consideration of different growth of potential output, different initial conditions in debt levels and the fiscal impact of growth-enhancing reforms, represent improvements, one cannot neglect the risks that a less clear set of rules may produce an increased arbitrariness in the implementation of the SGP. This is the most worrying aspect of recent developments. We also emphasize that giving more relevance to debt sustainability rather than budget deficits, while generally correct, risks to give the wrong incentives to NMs, most of them characterized by low levels of debt. The peculiar features of NMs, such as the low development of financial sectors and high volatility output and fiscal revenues, call for a careful definition of safe debt-to-GDP ratios. We argue that there is little room for increasing debt ratios in NMs and we suggest to complement the SGP framework with national expenditure rules. These rules should also serve as a more effective reference for evaluating policies, avoiding confusion between policies and noisy outcomes. The paper is structured as follows. In section 2 we argue that during the transition to the Euro, especially during the ERMII period NMs have to rely on tight fiscal policies in order to avoid sizable output costs and the risk of failing the transition to the Euro. In section 3 we discuss the main trends of fiscal policy in NMs, highlighting the presence of two distinct patterns, one of low deficits in small countries and the other of high deficits in larger countries. In section 4 we discuss some features of the SGP, and its revisions, from the perspective of NMs. Section 5 contains some concluding remarks. 2. Fiscal policy and the pace of transition to the Euro The target of entry in the European Monetary Union has been effective in fostering fiscal adjustment in several EU countries during the 1990s (see Gali and Perotti (2004) among others). Similarly, the same effect could be at work for new EU members, that eventually have to join the Eurozone. However, one can identify two distinct patterns of behavior in new EU members. One group of countries, the smaller ones, have embarked in a process of prudent fiscal policy that is accompanying their fast entry into the Euro. Another group, formed by the larger countries, entered the EU with high and growing budget deficits. At the same time, they have opted for a much slower path towards the Euro. Of course, the two aspects are closely linked, as fulfilling the Maastricht criterion on the budget ceiling of 3% of GDP is a pre-requisite for joining the Eurozone. The procedures leading to accession to the EU did not involve any conditionality on macroeconomic indicators for Candidate countries. In several NMs there was a marked deterioration of the fiscal accounts during the run-up to entry in the EU. Apparently, NMs did not perceive they would be subject to tight fiscal constraints upon entry, although the ceiling of 3% on budget deficit and the Stability and Growth Pact apply to every member of the EU. There was a strange, perhaps accidental, convergence between the positions of “populist” forces within the new members pushing for higher deficits and EU institutions, EU Commission and ECB, that explicitly favored a slow process of entry in the Eurozone. In a nutshell, the idea was that there was a trade-off between “real” and 7
  • 8. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... “nominal” convergence and not a complementarity between the two. Budget deficits could be tolerated as they were considered instruments for stimulating growth. 3. Fiscal policy in NMs: an heterogeneous picture The first feature of public finances in NMs is that the “size of government” (revenue, or expenditure-to-GP ratios) in these countries seems to be high for their level of development, proxied by incomes per capita. 3.1. Size of the government Figure 1 shows that the size of government in NMs is not far from the EU average, in spite of the fact that the average GDP per capita in NMs is below 50% of the EU average. This is true for Central European countries, while the Baltics are characterized by a much smaller size of government. One could thus conclude that the size of the government is too large for the level of development of NMs. In other words, one could argue that NMs have adopted prematurely the “European model”. It should be noted, however, that GDP per capita is only one of the variables affecting the “natural” size of the government. The demographic structure is certainly another factor, and in this respect NMs have a population structure and population growth similar to old EU members. Another factor recently emphasized by Rodrik (1998), is the degree of openness to foreign trade of an economy. According to Rodrik, trade openness increases the risk of output fluctuations of an economy, resulting from fluctuations in terms of trade. Indeed, the income effect of terms of trade changes is given by the variation in terms of trade multiplied by the share of trade-to-GDP. If the latter increases, the income effect of terms of trade fluctuations increases as well. An increase in the size of the government would compensate such effects, stabilizing output changes. Although this view might have some relevance for the evaluation of the size of governments in NMs, it should be taken into account that for NMs increase in openness goes hand-in-hand with integration in the EU, which implies an integration both in trade flows but also in terms of factor movements and financial sectors. Free capital Figure 1. Size of governments in NMS. Total expenditure of general government/GDP in 2003 8 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0 Baltics CE-4 Eu-15 Source: Eurostat
  • 9. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... mobility induces pressure for reductions in the size of governments through tax competition. Moreover, capital mobility and financial integration allows more diversification of risk in all EU member states. As a result, the Rodrik channel is less relevant as the financial sector permits to insure against risk of income fluctuations. Finally, the large size of governments of NMs results from an explicit strategy followed during their transition process. Such strategy was largely affected by the so-called “attraction of Europe” (Boeri 2000). In contrast with the strategy followed in most countries of the former Soviet Union, NMs implemented far-reaching market oriented reforms and the same time maintained a system of safety nets, in some cases extremely generous. Such strategy was perhaps one of the key elements for the success of the transition in NMs. Looking forward, however, the issue is whether maintaining such a large government may interfere with the growth process of NMs. Most NMs have indeed problems similar to old EU members. High tax burden on labor have likely affected incentive to work and thus labor supply. Employment rates are low in NMs, unemployment rates are generally high and the underground economy is estimated to be very large2. The experience of NMs has been highly heterogeneous: one can identify two distinct groups of countries that are following different fiscal strategies with sharp differences in the behavior of budget deficits and debts. 3.2. Deficits Budget deficits have been on average well above 3% of GDP, except for Slovenia and the Baltics. Interestingly, it appears that country size matters for fiscal policy. However, low-deficit countries, especially the Baltics, are also the countries with a currency board, or a fixed exchange rate regime. The comparison between the Baltics and Slovenia on one side, and the other NMs on the other side suggests that high budget deficits cannot be attributed to special factors associated with transition and EU accession. Without denying that these factors have exerted some pressure on budget deficits, it is nevertheless clear that they cannot account for such a sharp different pattern of behavior within countries characterized by the same transition and EU-accession process. The difference in size of the countries perhaps suggests the importance of 8.0 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 2 For these reasons, several NMs have opted for a policy of low income and corporate taxes. This strategy has brought Estonia, Lithuania and Slovakia to adopt a flat tax system, that is currently under attack from several government officials in old EU members. 9 Figure 2: Growth in New EU members, CE-4 vs. Baltics 0.0 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Annual GDP growth rate (in %) CE-04 Baltic 3 Source: Eurostat
  • 10. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... political economy factors. In small and more homogeneous countries there is less scope for using the budgetary process to buy consensus for election and re-election. However, it is not easy to distinguish such political factors from economic factors, such as the stronger constraints for small and highly open economies. Nevertheless, it is interesting to contrast also the much better growth performance of the Baltic countries with that of the CE-4 countries (Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia) (Figure 2), which suggests that prudent fiscal policy and growth were complements in the Baltic states. In addition, there is no clear correlation between size of budget deficits and public investments, contrary to what it is often heard as justification of high deficits in NMs (Figure 3). 0.0 -1.0 -2.0 -3.0 -4.0 -5.0 -6.0 Thus, it can be argued that large NMs perceived they had no binding constraint in their fiscal accounts during the process of entry in the EU. 3.3. Debts On average NMs display debt-to-GDp ratios well below those of old EU members. However, EU countries may not be a good comparator for judging debt ratios of NMs, that are emerging markets rather than established advanced economies. Financial sectors are still underdeveloped in CEECs and their public debts have a large component of foreign debt. If compared with Latin America, for instance, debt ratios of NMs, are of the same order of magnitude. Even after entry in the EU, as long as they remain outside the Euro-zone, NMs debt should be considered as emerging market debt, subject to the same volatility and risks of other emerging economies. Indeed, in the recent revisions of the SGP, countries with debt-to-GDP ratios below 60 percent should have more room for expansionary fiscal policy. While one could support such proposal when applied to current EU members, its rationale for new members is highly questionable. The stock of public debt in NMs should be evaluated from two perspectives, different from the simple debt-to- GDP ratio and from long-term solvency issues. The first is the size of public debt relative to the size of domestic financial markets. Indeed, in countries with still underdeveloped financial sectors, the crowding out effect of public debt can be very serious. Figure 5 displays debt-to-M2 ratios for NMs and compares them with 10 Figure 3. Budget deficits in NMs -7.0 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Budget deficit (as a percentage of GDP) CE-4 Baltic 3 Source: Eurostat
  • 11. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 old EU countries. The striking result is that this measure gives a picture in which debt ratios in NMs are much closer to those of old EU member states and in some cases even higher. The second relevant perspective for countries that are still emerging economies is related to the notion of “natural debt limit” recently proposed by Mendoza and Oviedo (2004), that takes into account the uncertainty associated to high volatility of revenues, combined with rigidity in expenditure, for countries that might face severe constraints on availability of foreign borrowing. Emerging economies do not have the same ability to use international financial markets to smooth the effects of large shocks. In cases of severe difficulties emerging economies find it very hard to borrow abroad at reasonable rates. This phenomenon has been defined as one of “sudden stop” in the recent literature (see Calvo et al (2003)). Such sudden stop can be seen as a “worst case” scenario for a country. In such an event, the country has to adjust its imbalances, including budget deficits. Given that emerging markets have accumulated public debts, largely owed to foreigners, the question is whether in the event of a sudden stop these countries are able to service their debt, taking into account their ability to raise revenues and compress expenditure. 11 Figure 4. Debt-to-GDP ratios in 2003 0 Estonia Latvia Lithuania Slovenia Czech Republic Slovakia Poland Hungary EU-15 Maastricht criterion Source: Eurostat Figure 5. Debt-to-M2 ratios 140% 120% 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% Czech Rep. Euro-area Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovakia Slovenia Source: Eurostat and EBRD
  • 12. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... This perspective gives a much more relevant evaluation of debt sustainability than measures of long run solvency. The key elements that make this approach relevant are the fact that emerging economies display a much higher volatility of fiscal revenues than advanced market economies. This means that in an adverse situation revenue-to-GDP ratio may decline sharply in emerging economies. At the same time public expenditure cannot be compressed to zero, as there are items that are rigid. Of course, the notion of rigidity of expenditures depend on the structure of expenditure and the political process associated to it. Nevertheless, we can usefully identify the rigidity of expenditure looking at the minimum ratio observed in recent years for a country or, as for revenues at the difference between the mean and the standard deviation of revenue-to-GDP realizations. Figure 6 indicates that NMs, like other emerging economies, display a much higher volatility of revenue-to- GDP ratios. We select the case of Estonia to compute the “natural debt limit”. The reason is that Estonia is the country with the lowest debt-to-GDP ratio and with fast real GDP growth. In such a case, computation of debt solvency will indicate a very high equilibrium debt-to-GDP ratio. As a result, one would be tempted to advise Estonia to rapidly increase its public debt, to exploit the room between its current levels and the 60% compatible with fulfilling the Maastricht criterion on debt. In fact, computing the natural debt limit for Estonia is instructive as it shows that current levels are not very far from the levels consistent with such “natural limit”. − = T G NDL m m The definition of NDL is , with −γ R Tm = “worst case” realization of revenue-to-GDP ratio Gm = minimum level of expenditure R = real interest rate γ = rate of growth of real GDP. It is useful to compare such definition with the level consistent with long run solvency , = − R T G −γ D where the value of the numerator indicates the current level of primary surplus. We compute the worst case level of revenue-to-GDP ratio for Estonia as the difference between the average ratio and twice its standard deviation. We use the same formula for minimum expenditure. We use a real interest rate differential with respect to real growth of 1.6. Interestingly, the NDL is equal to 20 percent of GDP. Of course, such calculation is only illustrative. However, it is useful to compare it with the traditional level computed looking at long run solvency. Using the same numbers for the real interest rate and the real rate of growth, such a level is 66% . The huge difference between the two measures of equilibrium debt levels indicates the important feature of revenue volatility typical of an emerging economy. This example suggests that for NMs one should use some sort of different scale of evaluation for the debt-to-GDOP ratio. An implication is that for NMs it is advisable to give large weight to deficit indicators, rather than the Maastricht debt ratio. Of course, this implies that NMs approaching 60% are a fortiori in a risky zone. The emphasis on deficits rather than debts would seem highly questionable (see Buiter (2004)) for countries that are characterized by much higher rates of growth of output. As shown in next section, our approach and that of Buiter can be reconciled by taking seriously the close-to-balance budget over the cycle, that is the cornerstone of the Stability and Growth Pact. Our view might seem overly restrictive for NMs, but in fact it only 12
  • 13. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... suggests that during the period of transition to the Euro, debt of NMs has a much higher risk than that of old EU members. Such risk is unlikely to be incorporated in risk premia by the market, as it is a risk associated with a low probability event (the worst case scenario). Figure 6. Volatility of revenues Standard deviation of Revenues/GDP, average 1995-2004 6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 NMs should be advised to adopt medium term fiscal frameworks that imply close-to-balance budget over the cycle, and thus stable debt-to-GDP ratio over the same horizon. Unfortunately, the current approach to implementation of the SGP has several drawbacks, especially if viewed from the perspective of NMs. 4. Shortcomings of the existing framework for new members The EU fiscal framework is based on three main assumptions. (i) On the basis of the volatility of GDP for EU member states, it appears that 3% provides a sufficient margin to absorb “normal” cyclical fluctuations. During “exceptional times” the 3% ceiling can be breached without penalties. This implies that in “normal” times there is no pro-cyclical bias in the rule during “bad times”. It remains open the issue of the incentives to avoid pro-cyclicality during “good times”. The SGP is indeed a way to tackle this issue by indicating that countries should ensure convergence over the medium term to a balanced structural position. Accordingly, in periods of favorable cycles governments should run budget surpluses, matched by deficits during downturns. As, on average, the budget is balanced, the 3% ceiling will be passed only during exceptional times. This is connected to the idea of safety margins. (ii) The EC estimates that in most EU countries the budget elasticity to the output gap is between 0.5 to 0.6. This means that one should observe a cyclical deficit of roughly half the output gap. In order to pass the 3 percent ceiling one should experience a negative output gap of roughly 6 percentage points of potential output, it the budget is initially balanced. This event is rather unusual. For instance, in France during the period 1980-2002 the largest negative output gap was 2.6 percent in 1985, while in Germany it never exceeded 1.6 percent. 13 0.00 Czech Rep. Estonia Hungary* Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovak Rep. Eu-15 * For Hungary data are for the period 2001-2004 Source: Author's calculation on data from Eurostat.
  • 14. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... (iii) The cyclically adjusted balance provides a good measure of the discretionary policy of national governments. Summing up, a country that behaves well should have counter-cyclical deficits due to the functioning of automatic stabilizers. This functioning of automatic stabilizers is fully consistent with the 3 percent limit for well-behaved countries. We will in turn discuss the three elements of the EU fiscal framework and highlight their limitations. First, we show that the foundations for the 3% ceiling and the cyclical safety margin are rather weak, especially for NMs. Finally, we emphasize the drawbacks of the evaluation and monitoring procedures of the EC, that are not solved by looking at the cyclically adjusted budget. 4.1. GDP volatility and the 3% ceiling The 3% deficit ceiling had been thought for countries with potential output growth of about 2%. With an elasticity of the budget balance to the output gap estimated by the EC at about 0.5, a country shifting from the potential growth path to a decline of 2% in GDP would suffer a worsening of the budget of 2% of GDP. Thus, if countries followed the objective of close-to-balance budget over the cycle, they would risk to hit the 3% ceiling only in exceptional cases. However, countries characterized by much higher rates of growth of potential output are also exposed to much wider band of oscillation of GDP. A negative GDP change of 2% from a potential growth path of 5% would imply a 7 percentage points change. With similar elasticity of the budget to GDP, which is indeed the case for NMs, that have revenue-to-GDP ratios of the same magnitude of EU-15 countries, NMs can easily hit the 3% ceiling even in a normal cycle3. Incomes per capita in NMs are on average 40 percent of those of the average EU country. Convergence to EU levels of GDP per capita is going to be a long term phenomenon. Thus, for a few decades NMs should display higher rates of growth than those of EU countries. Assuming the Barro well-known rule of thumb on convergence, NMs should grow at a rate that is 2 percent higher than the average EU. Studies on the European Union and in general on monetary unions, suggest higher rates of convergence, close to 3 percent. As the average rate of growth of potential output is around 2 percent in the EU, potential output in acceding countries can be expected to grow between 4 and 5 percent per annum. The volatility of GDP growth is also likely to be much higher than that of EU countries. This implies that with neutral fiscal policy stance, fluctuations in cyclical budget balances should display a much larger amplitude, following the higher amplitude of fluctuations in output. This can indeed be observed in the data. Looking at the period 1996-mid 2002, a recent paper by the ECB finds that NMs posted an average rate of growth of GDP of about 4% against a 2.2% of Euro area countries. Volatility was much higher in NMs, with a standard deviation of output growth almost three times higher than that of the Euro area (Süppel (2003)). The study concludes that since higher growth and higher volatility of growth reflect a catching up process, they are going to persist in the medium run. Given these structural features, the 3% ceiling on the budget deficit does not represent a sufficient margin to absorb cyclical swings in budget deficits. For current EU members, with an estimated elasticity of the budget to the output gap of around 0.5, the 3% budget deficit limit represents a wide enough margin to absorb regular cyclical fluctuations in the budget. While this is disputable even for current EU members, it is hardly applicable to acceding countries. 4.2. Pro-cyclical bias A second possible drawback of existing rules is the pro-cyclical bias, associated to the fact that the budget deficit deteriorates during recessions and if it approaches the 3% ceiling, governments have to undertake 3 As shown by the EC(2003), the GDP elasticity of the budget is dominated by the revenue effects. Coricelli and Ercolani (2004) find indeed output-gap budget elasticities for NMs only slightly lower, at around 0.45, than those of EU-15 countries. 14
  • 15. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... adjustments during “bad times”. According to Gali and Perotti (2003), the Maastricht criterion on the budget deficit has not been a constraint on counter-cyclical policies by countries in EMU. This effect is derived through an estimate of the impact of the output gap on the behavior of the cyclically adjusted deficit, contrasting the pre with post-Maastricht phase. They find no effect of a pro-cyclical bias after the introduction of fiscal constraints. A recent report by CEPR (2004) broadly confirms this result. It finds that only in the case of Portugal and Italy there has been a tightening of fiscal policy during a downturn. However, it could be argued that a similar effect would has been detected for Germany and France, had the Excessive Deficit procedure been approved by the ECOFIN. This would have implied a pro-cyclical stance in four members of the EMU during the most important episode of downturn of the post-Maastricht period. Thus, although there is no strong evidence of pro-cyclical bias in the existing fiscal rules, it clearly emerges that a sizable slowdown in the rate of growth of output sharply increases the probability of hitting the 3% ceiling, a problem that is bound to be much more serious for NMs, as the magnitude of the changes in growth rates is likely to be much higher than that of current EU members. Furthermore, looking at correlations between cyclical variations of government consumption and GDP, we found that NMs, as other emerging markets display a pro-cyclical fiscal policy (see Fiorito (1997) and Talvi and Vegh (2000) for a discussion of such methodology). Considering that government consumption does not vary automatically with the cycle, it can be used as a proxy for the discretionary component of fiscal policy. A positive correlation between the cyclical components of government consumption and of GDP is a measure of the pro-cyclicality of fiscal policy. Indeed, for several NMs such correlation was positive or close to zero during the period 1995-2003 (Table 1, Coricelli and Eianchovina (2004)). This indicates that, so far, there has been little counter-cyclical role for fiscal policy in NMs. The fact that EU fiscal rules do not provide effective disincentives for pro-cyclical policies, either during good or bad times, might be a serious drawback for NMs that tend to have pro-cyclical fiscal policies. Table 1. Correlation between cyclical variations of government consumption and GDP, 1995-2003(*) Czech Republic Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Poland Slovakia Slovenia 0.80 0.03 -0.06 0.30 0.63 0.84 0.34 -0.58 (*)Quarterly data. Cyclical variations are computed as percentage deviations from trend, computed with Hodrik-Prescott filter. Source: Author's calculation on data from Eurostat. 4.3. Evaluating policies not only outcomes Rules are important because they can strengthen the credibility of policies. The current crisis of the SGP illustrates however the distinction between the credibility of policies and that of policy-makers. There is indeed an inconsistency in the current framework. Besides the motivations for the specific numbers chosen, there has been several papers by the EC to provide economic foundations to the whole apparatus of the deficit/debt ceilings and the SGP. The cornerstones are: The task of the EC is to monitor fiscal accounts and to evaluate the Stability and Convergence Programmes of national governments. When the structural (or cyclically adjusted) balance is seen increasing to an area that will put the country at risk of breaching the 3% ceiling, governments are invited to adopt an adjustment plan that would put the country in a safe area. On this basis national governments and EC discuss the budgetary plans. If the government follows those plans it should be defined as a “dependable” government, and thus a credible policy-maker. However, if a government behaves accordingly to the stated plans and ex post the EC identifies the government as behaving against the rules, there is an obvious problem. Of course, in the interpretation of the outcomes there is always scope for opportunistic behavior of policy-makers. Nevertheless, it is fair to admit that there are fundamental flaws in the rules. Unexpected outcomes, unrelated to policy actions cannot be used to evaluate policy-makers. The conceptual underpinning of the 3% ceiling is flawed. 15
  • 16. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... Consider the following example. Country A in year t has a balanced budget. In the following three years it plans to increase expenditure in line with the expected rate of growth of output. Assuming no change in tax rates and in tax collection, and assuming that a unitary elasticity of revenue with respect to GDP, the budget is expected to remain balanced in the period of planning. Furthermore, the country was growing at 3 percent in the year t-1. GDP is expected to remain at 3 percent for the three years considered. In fact, the economy slows down and the rate of growth declines to 1% per annum. The output gap may remain positive (actual output greater than potential). Nevertheless, the deficit deteriorates, approaching the 3 percent ceiling. From an ex ante point of view the government has maintained its promises. The cause of the deficit is a forecast error. The increase in the budget deficit would be measured as totally due to an increase in the structural deficit. However, the government has not switched to a looser policy through discretionary measures. It is just the ex post evaluation of policy that depicts a behavior of the policy-maker that does not reflect the reality. The first conclusion to draw is that the current framework for evaluating fiscal policy in the EU is misleading. This interpretation has surfaced also in the revised SGP. A proper definition of discretionary policy should take into account the fact that the actual budgetary process is based on expected output (see also Buti and Van den Noord (2003) and Larch and Salto (2003)). If governments were welfare maximizers, they would generally follow a fiscal rule consistent with tax smoothing. This amounts to set expenditure accordingly to the expected growth of potential output4. Abstracting from measurement errors of potential output, this rule would imply a structural balanced budget and cyclical budget balances proportional to the deviation of the rate of growth from potential growth. Actual developments of GDP will determine the movements in the budget balance and not the level of the output gap. Expenditure will be by construction counter-cyclical, with a unitary elasticity of expenditure-to-GDP ratio with respect to the deviation of growth from potential. Although this cyclical movements of expenditure is different from what are commonly defined as automatic stabilizers, in fact they work in a similar fashion as potentially stabilizing forces. Of course, if there is a persistent over-estimation of potential growth, there will be a persistent deficit. For this reason, a confidence interval on the calculation of potential growth should be applied and the lower end of the expected band should be chosen, ensuring a prudent management of expenditure. This error is likely to be much smaller than the forecast error on actual GDP. Neutral fiscal policy can be defined as the one consistent with the above rule (see also Buti and Van den Noord (2003) and CEPR, MEI 13, 2004). The difference between actual and neutral policy can be defined as discretionary policy. Moreover, from this discretionary policy one should subtract the effect of forecast error of actual GDP to obtain what Buti and van den Noord define as “genuine” discretionary policy, as expenditure is planned ex ante on the basis of expected output. Thus, even with the amendments introduced in the SGP, the current framework is affected by ambiguity of interpretation of fiscal stance, leaving room to political influence on such interpretations. The Stability and Growth Pact and the numerical limit of 3% on the deficit are an example of how rules can be simple but at the same time highly ambiguous, especially within the new SGP . The 3% limit is very simple and within the SGP the procedures that the EC has to follow are roughly automatic. However, the fact that ECOFIN has the final word on whether the ED procedure should be adopted, combined with controversial measures, such as the cyclically adjusted balance, used to evaluate fiscal stance, reduce the credibility of EU fiscal rules and make its implementation subject to decisive political interference. The first conclusion is that the existing indicators used by the EC to evaluate the fiscal policy of EU governments are misleading5. However, forecasts are likely to be biased, reflecting an opportunistic behavior by governments that for political reasons tend to overestimate growth (Larch and Salto (2003)). Interestingly, in the 4 See Coricelli and Ercolani (2004) on this type of rule. 5 This is recognized in the two papers by economists at the EC indicated above (Buti and Van den Noord (2003), Larch and Salto (2003)). 16
  • 17. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... main episode of crisis of the SGP, associated to the early warning to Germany and France, the forecast error was as large in the EC data as in the national data. Without denying the relevance of political or political economy considerations, it clearly emerges that the current framework of evaluation of fiscal policy in the EU leaves ample room for arbitrary interpretations and endless debate between national authorities and the EC. To summarize, the simplicity of the existing rule is only apparent. The whole mechanism is extremely complex and ambiguous in its implementation. The result is a loss of credibility for the entire fiscal framework in the EU. On one side, the behavior of ECOFIN damages the credibility of the EC; on the other side, the application of the procedure of the SGP damages the credibility of national fiscal authorities, providing an improper assessment of their discretionary policy. Therefore, there is a need to move to a monitoring of policies and not exclusively the results (a point also stressed by Annett et al. (2005)). It is well known that one can reduce the problem of time inconsistency in policies acting on the predictable part of policy, not on unforeseen events (Drazen (2004)). All these issues are more relevant in an enlarged EU as forecast errors for NMs are bound to be larger given the higher standard deviation of GDP growth in the new member countries. The debate on the reform of the SGP that is taking place is unlikely to produce a fundamental reform of EU fiscal rules. In the summer of 2003 the EC has put forward a proposal for some modifications of the SGP. The modifications put forward in 2003 by the EC, however, do not tackle the main issues we discussed above. These objectives can be achieved by complementing the SGP with an expenditure rule, that is easy to monitor and allows governments to own their own policy and the EU Commission to act as an outside monitoring body, even better if complemented by an independent national technical body providing a view on the computation of potential growth and assessing policy measures of the government. In Coricelli and Ercolani (2004) we argue that a more suitable rule for an enlarged and more heterogeneous EU would be a simple expenditure rule, according to which expenditures would grow at the same rate as that of potential output (see Box 2). Interestingly, the Czech Republic has introduced a medium-term fiscal program with an expenditure rule. From the rule described in Box 1 it is apparent that when real GDP growth will be equal to potential GDP growth, and inflation equals its target level (that could be the ECB target rate when the country is a member of the Eurozone), actual deficit equals its target value. When output growth falls short of potential growth, there will be a budget deficit, while a surplus will emerge when output growth is above its potential growth. The rule embodies an automatic "growth dividend": in good times the country accumulate surpluses that can be spent in bad times, ensuring a stable average level of debt-to-GDP ratio. Whether the rule is consistent with the 3% Maastricht ceiling on budget deficit depends on the magnitude of the deviations of output growth from its potential rate. What is more important is that if the country follows the above rule it cannot be blamed for lax fiscal policy. The worsening of budget deficits will entirely results from a downturn in the economy and not from a discretionary loosening of fiscal policy. Monitoring of fiscal policy would be very simple because the rule implies specific nominal values for expenditure. In summary, the framework proposed allows for an evaluation of fiscal stance that is superior to alternative indicators such as the cyclically-adjusted budget deficit. The proposed measure of discretionary fiscal policy better reflects discretionary policy decisions by the government. 5. Conclusions In this paper we wanted to add the dimension of the enlargement to the already heated debate on EU fiscal rules. From the analysis it emerged that the main drawbacks of current rules from the perspective of NMs countries reveal fundamental shortcomings of the EU fiscal framework, and especially its implementation. 17
  • 18. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... Enlargement makes even more visible these shortcomings. However, even more important is the fact that fiscal discipline is a key element for a successful and fast convergence of NMs to income levels of the EU-15 countries. Such discipline ultimately rests on credible commitment by national authorities. Indeed, the heterogeneous experience of NMs, with two distinct groups of countries is telling. The Baltic states have followed prudent fiscal policy and a program of reduction of the size of the government. This process has been accompanied by high rates of growth of the economy and macroeconomic stability, that has allowed them to enter the fast track of Box 2: A medium term framework with an expenditure rule Primary expenditure grows in line with the growth rate of potential output, while target revenue, at unchanged tax rates, grows in line with actual output. Denoting with a (*) target variables, with y real GDP growth and p the inflation rate, we can write the rule as follows: τ τ π π − + − + − ( ) ( * * ) − + − ( ) 1 1 g y y π π   ( ) = − − − − true t y 18 Target expenditure:     + + 1 * *   + + = − π t g g t t t y t y π 1 1 * Target revenues:     + + 1 * *   + + = − t t π t t y t y π τ τ 1 1 * where we have assumed that the output elasticity of revenues is equal to one. Target budget deficit: d * = g* −τ * With an estimation of potential output that implies that deviations of actual output from potential have zero mean (such as for instance the Hodrick-Prescott filter used until recently by the EU Commission), on average actual output will be equal to its potential level. As a result, on average, actual deficit will be equal to the target. Actual expenditures is a function of expected output and inflation and of a discretionary component, while revenues follow the actual behavior of output and inflation and the discretionary changes in tax rates. Thus, actual expenditures and revenues are as follows:       π τ + y + + t + + = − t t d t t t y π τ τ 1 1 1 *       + + + y g g g t + + = − t t d t e t e t y π π 1 1 1 while the budget deficit, in terms of actual GDP d = g – Tt where e stands for expected values and d for discretional. One can identify a measure of discretionary fiscal policy as the difference between the actual and the target budget deficit.     g g g y y = − − −   1 1 1 + + t t e t e t t d t t d t t DP t y π 1 The “true” discretionary policy is obtained by subtracting to DP the effects of forecast errors τ τ − t t d t t d t t e t t t e t t t g g y DP DP π π + + =   + + 1 1 * * 1
  • 19. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... accession to the Eurozone. Slovenian has followed a similar path, although it is still in the middle of an internal debate on tax reform and on the role of the state in the economy. By contrast, Central European countries have shown growing budget deficits and raising debt levels. Starting from an oversized government, these countries face a challenge to adjust their fiscal accounts in the near future, not only as a precondition for entry in the Eurozone, but also as a policy to support a faster rate of growth of their economy. 19
  • 20. Studies & Analyses No. 304 – Fabrizio Coricelli – Design and Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact... References Annett, A., J. Decressin and M. Deppler (2005), “Reforming the Stability and Growth Pact”, IMF Policy Discussion Paper, PDP 05/02. Buiter, W.H. and C. Grafe (2003), “Patching the Pact: Some Suggestions for Enhancing Fiscal Sustainability and Macroeconomic Stability in an Enlarged European Union”, forthcoming in The Economics of Transition. Buiter, W. (2004): To Purgatory and Beyond: When and How Should the Accession Countries from Central and Eastern Europe Become Full Members of EMU?, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 4342. Buti, M. and P. Van den Noord (2003), “Discretionary fiscal policy and elections: The experience of the early years of EMU”, OECD Working Paper n. 351. Calvo, G., A. Izquierdo, and E. Talvi (2003) “Sudden stops, the real exchange rate and fiscal sustainability: Argentina's lessons“, NBER Working Paper 9828.. Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) (2003), Monitoring European Integration, n. 13, London. Centre for European Policy Studies (2002): The Euro at 25: Special Report of the CEPS Macroeconomic Policy Group, Brussels. Coricelli, F. and E. Eianchovina (2004), “Shocks and volatility in Accession countries of Central-Eastern Europe”, The World Bank, mimeo. Coricelli, F. and V. Ercolani (2004), “Fiscal Rules on the road to an Enlarged European Union”, in G. Kopits (ed.), Rules-Based fiscal policy in Emerging Markets, Palgrave-Macmillan. Coricelli, F. (2002): Exchange Rate Policy During the Transition to the European Monetary Union: the Option of Euroization, The Economics of Transition, Vol. 10, No. 2. Creel, J. (2003), “Ranking Fiscal Policy Rules: the Golden Rule of Public Finance vs. the Stability and Growth Pact”, OFCE, n. 2003/4 Drazen, A. (2004), “Fiscal rules from a Political Economy perspective”, in G. Kopits, Rules-Based fiscal policy in Emerging Markets, Palgrave-Macmillan. Fiorito, R. (1997), “Stylized facts of government finance in the G-7”, IMF Working Papers, 97/142. Gali, J. and R. Perotti (2003), “Fiscal Policy”, Economic Policy, 533-572, CEPR, October. Kopits, G. and S. Symansky (1998), “Fiscal Policy Rules”, IMF Occasional Paper, n. 162 Kopits, G. and I. P. Székely (2002), “Fiscal Policy Challenges of EU Accession fro Central European Economies”, International Monetary Fund, mimeo. Larch, M. and M. Salto (2003), “Fiscal rules, inertia and discretionary fiscal policy”, European Economy Economic Papers n.194, European Commission, October. Mendoza, E. and M. Oviedo (2004), “Fiscal solvency and macroeconomic uncertainty in Emerging markets: The tale of the tormented insurer”, April, manuscript, University of Maryland. Rodrik, D. (1998) “Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?” Journal of Political Economy, 106(5), October. Talvi, E. and C. Vegh (2000), “Tax base variability and procyclical fiscal policy”, NBER Working Paper n. 7499. Calvo, G., A. Izquierdo, and E. Talvi (2003) “Sudden stops, the real exchange rate and fiscal sustainability: Argentina's lessons“, NBER Working Paper 9828. 20