SlideShare a Scribd company logo
The Clean Development Mechanism:

Mexico’s Contribution to the Mitigation of Global Climate Change




                  Diana Piloyan Boudjikanian
                         October, 2009
Table of Contents


Chapter                                                              Page


List of Abbreviations                                                3


Introduction                                                         4


Literature Review                                                    7


1.     Global Climate Change                                         12
       1.1     What Is Global Climate Change?                        12
       1.2     What Causes Global Climate Change?                    12
       1.3     What Are the Consequences of Global Climate Change?   13


2.     Environmental Policy Instruments                              16
       2.1     Voluntary Policy Instruments                          16
               2.1.1    Eco-Audits                                   16
               2.1.2    Environmental Labeling Programs              17
               2.1.3    Voluntary Agreements                         18
       2.2     Mandatory Policy Instruments                          19
               2.2.1    Command-and-Control                          20
               2.2.2    Green Taxes                                  20
               2.2.3    Emissions Trading                            22
               2.2.4    Joint Implementation                         24
               2.2.5    Clean Development Mechanism                  25




                                                                            1
Chapter                                           Page


3.    The Clean Development Mechanism             26
      3.1    Historical Background                26
      3.2    Definition                           28
      3.3    Requirements for CDM Projects        28
      3.4    CDM Project Activity Cycle           32
      3.5    CDM Project Activity Status          34
      3.6    CDM Host Parties                     35
      3.7    Type of CDM Projects                 37
      3.8    Advantages of CDM Projects           37
      3.9    Disadvantages of CDM Projects        39


4.    The Clean Development Mechanism in Mexico   41
      4.1    The Mexican Carbon Fund (FOMECAR)    42
             4.1.1   Objectives                   42
             4.1.2   Potential Participants       43
             4.1.3   Advantages                   43
      4.2    CDM Projects in Mexico               44


Final Comments                                    50


Appendix                                          56


References                                        59




                                                         2
List of Abbreviations
CDM                     Clean Development Mechanism
CER/CERs                Certified Emissions Reduction/Certified Emissions Reductions
CFCs                    Chlorofluorocarbons
CH4                     Methane
CO2                     Carbon dioxide
COP                     Conference of the Parties
DNA                     Designated National Authority
DOE/DOEs                Designated Operational Entity/Designated Operational Entities
ERUs                    Emission Reduction Credits
FOMECAR                 Mexican Carbon Fund (Fondo Mexicano de Carbono)
GEF                     Global Environment Facility
GHG/GHGs                Greenhouse gas/Greenhouse gases
HFCs                    Hydrofluorocarbons
IPCC                    Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
JI                      Joint Implementation
NGOs                    Non-Governmental Organizations
N2O                     Nitrous oxide
NOx                     Nitrogen oxides
O3                      Ozone
OECD                    Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
PFCs                    Perfluorocarbons
PINs                    Project Idea Notes
SF6                     Sulfur hexafluoride
SOx                     Sulfur oxides
SO2                     Sulfur dioxide
UN                      United Nations
UNEP                    United Nations Environment Program
UNFCCC                  United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
U.S.                    United States



                                                                                        3
Introduction
       Global climate change is the most urgent global environmental problem we face today.
This phenomenon is no longer a distant and unknown possibility that might become a reality. On
February 2007 the IPCC released its 4th Assessment Report on Climate Change and recognized,
among other things, that “the scientific uncertainties of global warming are essentially resolved
and that it is very likely man-made” (Borenstein 2007, 1; Maslin 2004, 1). In other words, there
is no question that human activities and consumption patterns have accelerated the natural
process of global warming, up to a point in which human and nonhuman worlds will not have
enough time to adapt to the changes. The question now is which species will have the ability to
adapt and survive; and more importantly, if human beings are among those species that have
what it takes to survive in an altered and unbalanced environment.
       Since global climate change is a very complex problem, its solutions require a wide
variety of policy instruments that combine voluntary, mandatory, legal, political, economic, and
social elements, and the active participation of every country in the world.
       One of the many reasons why the environmental targets, established during the 1997
Kyoto Protocol, have not yet been implemented is the debate between developed and developing
countries regarding their commitments and responsibilities. Developing countries argue that it is
not fair for them to have to lower their GHG emissions by the same percentages as developed
countries, since they emit very low volumes of GHGs and lowering them would halt their efforts
for economic growth. On the other hand, developed countries argue that it is not fair for them to
have to assume the entire burden of lowering their GHG emissions, since it will also be too
costly for their economies. Both sides have valid arguments. However, since we are all part of
the cause of global climate change and we have reached a critical point in time, we need to stop
arguing and work together to implement the needed measures before it is too late.
       Up until a few decades ago, the usual solution for environmental problems had been the
implementation of rules and regulations. However, we can no longer continue relying
exclusively on regulations. We cannot afford to continue resisting the idea that market-based
mechanisms can be useful when dealing with environmental issues, just because we have
traditionally thought of the market as environmentally unfriendly. Neoclassical Economic
Theory tells us that GHG emissions are a negative externality (an activity that affects ‘others’,
without those ‘others’ paying for it). In other words, they escape the control of the market’s

                                                                                               4
normal process, since they do not have a price related to them. However, these externalities can
be internalized by fixing a price for GHG emissions and allowing market forces to reach an
equilibrium between the price and the quantity (emitted volume) of GHGs. Market-based
mechanisms have great potential of being implemented as effective environmental policy
instruments and they should be considered as a viable ally and not an enemy, when dealing with
global environmental problems. One such market-based mechanism is the CDM, which provides
a scheme in which developed and developing countries work together to mitigate climate change.
       After describing the characteristics and effects of global climate change and reviewing
the wide range of environmental policy instruments, focusing on the CDM, I propose that
Mexico should continue using this instrument as part of its global climate change mitigating
environmental policy structure. For this purpose, the paper is divided into the following sections:
       In Chapter 1, I will talk about global climate change and describe its causes and main
consequences, since the purpose of this paper is to find the most effective way in which Mexico
can actively participate in the worldwide efforts to mitigate this environmental crisis.
       In Chapter 2, I will describe the main characteristics and applications of the most
commonly used voluntary and mandatory environmental policy instruments. Voluntary
instruments such as eco-audits, eco-labels, and voluntary agreements, which allow certain
discretion and flexibility; and mandatory instruments such as green taxes, emissions trading,
joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism.
       In Chapter 3, I will describe the elements involved in the design, organization,
monitoring process, and implementation of projects using the clean development mechanism.
       In Chapter 4, I focus my attention on the development of the clean development
mechanism in Mexico. It is important to mention that the partnership between the Mexican
government and the Mexican Carbon Fund (FOMECAR) is crucial for the productive
implementation of this environmental policy instrument, especially in a country in which the
government has not been 100% trustworthy.
       Finally, I provide comments about the global climate crisis, about ways to address this
issue, and about the promise offered by the clean development mechanism, for developing
countries such as Mexico.




                                                                                                  5
I hope that the information found in this paper will be useful for Mexican policymakers
who want to have a better understanding of the clean development mechanism, as an effective
environmental policy instrument, that can be used to address the global climate change issue.
       Before I continue, I would like to explain that this paper’s purpose was to obtain my MA
in Global Environmental Policy, from The American University in Washington, D.C., in
December 2007. That is why the information you are about to read has not been modified or
updated since December 19, 2007.
       It is my hope to write a follow up paper, where I will be able to update the information
about the clean development mechanism and give a current account on the status of the CDM
projects mentioned in this paper.
                                                    With hope for the future and the year 2050…




                                                                                                6
Literature Review
       The following Literature Review has the objective of summarizing the most important
characteristics and schools of thought regarding environmental policy instruments. The initial
level of classification is between voluntary (eco-labels, eco-audits, and voluntary agreements)
and mandatory (market-based taxes, tradable permits, and command-and-control regulation)
policy instruments (Hatch 2005, 5-6). In the case of voluntary approaches, the main
preoccupation is that they may not be enough to achieve the optimal level of environmental
protection (Hatch 2005, 8). On the other hand, it is clear that when dealing with the choice of
what is the best type of environmental policy instrument, the relevant debate lies within the
mandatory policy instruments, specifically, between regulatory and market-based approaches.
       The choice of policy instruments is shaped by a host of criteria, including certainty of
results, cost and economic efficiency, administrative feasibility (enforcement and compatibility
with existing laws), robustness (effectiveness under a variety of circumstances), timeliness
(capacity to provide rapid results), dynamic efficiency (impact on incentives to innovate), public
acceptance, and compatibility with normative values (Eisner 2007, 16).
       In an ideal world, regulators would have exhaustive data on the full universe of
pollutants, and the scientific knowledge necessary to set specific pollution thresholds. However,
in reality, regulators work under conditions of profound information scarcity and uncertainty
(Eisner 2007, 16).
       Environmental policy instruments can be divided into three different schools of thought
(Hansjürgens 2005, 1):
   1) Those in favor of regulatory approaches.
   2) Those in favor of market-based approaches.
   3) Those in favor of a mix between traditional regulatory and market-based approaches, as
       well as, new policy instruments for climate protection (CDM and JI).
       Regulatory instruments such as licensing, standards, and zoning can be described as
institutional measures aimed at directly influencing the environmental performance of polluters,
by regulating processes or products used, by abandoning or limiting the discharge of certain
pollutants, and/or by restricting activities to certain times and areas (OECD 1994, 12).
Command-and-control instruments have the quality of being more conventional, traditional, and
direct approaches when dealing with environmental regulation (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 21).

                                                                                                7
“Their main feature is that there is no other choice left to the polluter: he has to comply or face
penalties in judicial and administrative procedures” (OECD 1994, 12).
       In the case of command-and-control instruments, the government essentially commands
businesses to follow particular forms of behavior by adopting specific standards (technology
and/or performance-based) and then controls their behavior through the imposition of negative
sanctions. Technology-based standards mandate the use of a particular technology and are
usually presented in broad terms that reference the state-of-the-art at the time.
Performance-based standards, such as ambient and emission standards, establish maximum
levels of pollution compatible with regulator goals. Ambient standards define the maximum
levels or concentration of key pollutants that are allowed in a given area. On the other hand,
emission standards establish the maximum amounts of pollution that can be discharged from a
specific source (Eisner 2007, 13).
       This approach is based on specific limitations on the allowable discharges of polluting
substances from each source, coupled with an administrative and legal system to monitor
compliance with the limitations and to impose sanctions or penalties for violations. The pollution
control authority must carry out a series of steps for each source: determine the rules and
regulations that will achieve the given pollution control targets, establish penalties and sanctions
for non-compliance, monitor them, and punish violations (Vig & Kraft 1994, 169).
       As Jody Freeman and Charles Kolstad point out, “command-and-control approaches tend
to force firms to take on similar shares of the pollution control burden, regardless of the cost, by
setting uniform standards for firms” (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 19).
       The advantages of using command-and-control instruments include: direct and visible
response to problems, clear policy goals or standards, uniform treatment of sources, and the
satisfaction of knowing that each discharger is doing its share (or the most that can be expected)
to reduce pollution to desired levels. Its most important weaknesses are: that the technology-
based approach is considered simple; that there is a need to collect large amounts of data in order
to make judgments about costs, control techniques, and production processes; that they are
considered intrusive, inflexible, and inefficient; and that these instruments may discourage
innovation, since there is no reward for doing better than directed (Vig & Kraft 1994, 171-176).




                                                                                                   8
Market-based approaches include instruments based on economic incentives such as:
pollution charges, tradable permits, market friction reductions, and government subsidy
reductions (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 21). These instruments provide, for the purpose of
environmental improvement, monetary incentives for voluntary and non-coerced action by
polluters (OECD 1994, 13).
       Market-based approaches have the objective of solving the defects in the price system
more directly, by putting a charge on the use of resources or on the pollution that imposes costs
(environmental damage) (Vig & Kraft 1994, 177).
       When they are working properly, incentive instruments induce companies to respond in
different ways, depending on the costs of controls, the age of the facility, the nature of the
product, and the degree of economic competitiveness in the regulated industry. The result is a
system that equalizes the marginal costs of control across firms and lowers the overall costs of
environmental protection to society (Vig & Kraft 1994, 185).
       Market-based instruments encourage behavior through market signals, rather than
through explicit directives regarding pollution control levels or methods. They are often
described as ‘harnessing market forces’ because if they are well designed and implemented, they
encourage firms (and/or individuals) to undertake pollution control efforts that are in their best
interest and that collectively meet policy goals (Eisner 2007, 13). Furthermore, while market-
based mechanisms do not offer a panacea, they frequently do offer a practical way to reach
environmental goals, by allowing more flexibility. In other words, instead of relying on the
regulatory authority to identify the best course of action, the individual agent can select the best
way to meet the desired emissions reduction target. As Professor Thomas Tietenberg points out,
“this flexibility achieves environmental goals at lower costs, which makes the goals easier to
achieve and easier to establish” (Tietenberg 1994, 197-211).
       The most common market-based instruments are:
   1) Pollution taxes: tax charged to a firm based on the amount of pollution it generates.
   2) Cap-and-trade programs: regulators determine the acceptable level of pollution (the cap)
       and issue credits allowing for pollution up to the prescribed level. These credits can be
       purchased, sold, or saved (the trade). The most relevant advantages of cap-and-trade
       systems are that regulators can specify a desired level of pollution in advance, and that
       they can promote greater incentives for firms with a comparative advantage in abatement,

                                                                                                  9
to go beyond regulatory standards. “Cap-and-trade programs are the most flexible
        programs for emissions trading to date” (Sterner 2003, 90).
        Market-based instruments provide a continuing incentive to reduce pollutants, they offer
more flexibility for sources, they often complement direct regulation, and they are usually more
cost-effective than direct regulation (Vig & Kraft 1994, 171). In spite of these advantages,
market-based mechanisms are often surrounded by controversy. Critics may shudder at the
thought of purchasing the right to pollute, assuming (incorrectly) that pollution is a completely
avoidable act. They are also worried that trading may not be appropriate in some cases, because
it could result in higher levels of pollution in certain areas, creating ‘hot spots’ (Eisner 2007, 14).
        They should be used when the information needed to set source-specific standards is
lacking; there is value in giving polluters incentives to develop new technologies or control
methods; the marginal costs of complying with uniform standards vary greatly across polluters;
the effects of the emissions do not depend much on the location of the sources; the relationship
between the time of emission and the environmental effects is not very close; there is a fixed
goal to be achieved; and when the number of sources involved is large enough to establish a
well-functioning and competitive market with credits available to trade (Vig & Kraft 1994, 187).
        Unfortunately, “it is common to view regulatory instruments as mutually exclusive – one
must select command-and-control instruments or market-based instruments, for example”
(Eisner 2007, 15). This characterization obscures the importance of various instrument mixes.
        After reviewing the literature related to environmental policy instruments, it is clear that
regulatory and market-based instruments need to be combined for environmental policies to
achieve the desired results. It is not a question of having to choose one or the other. In other
words, the most effective environmental policy will be designed using a mix of instruments
(Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 28).
        Regardless of their differences, both approaches agree on the fact that their goal is to
have cost-effective environmental regulations (Hansjürgens 2005, 3). This performance can be
measured by asking: is the policy meeting its goals in a cost-effective manner
(Harrington, Morgenstern, & Sterner 2004, 1)?
        Most authors agree that until recently, command-and-control instruments have
predominated because risk-averse politicians and legislators prefer instruments that involve more
certain effects.

                                                                                                    10
The flexibility of market-based instruments creates uncertainty about distributional
impacts and local levels of environmental quality. However, they also admit that this trend is
changing (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 30). “Market incentives are suited to a new generation of
problems and are starting to be used more widely” (Vig & Kraft 1994, 170).
       “The past three decades have seen a good deal of speculation and dispute over the
differences between the two types of instruments” (Harrington, Morgenstern, & Sterner 2004,
10). Most authors and policymakers have agreed on the categories of such differences
(Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 20-28; Harrington, Morgenstern, & Sterner 2004, 10-16;
Hatch 2005, 1-9). This recognition can be the first step towards a path of mutual cooperation and
combination of instruments in environmental policy design. That is, if they know what the
differences are between the various policy instruments, they can decide what combination will be
more effective to address diverse environmental issues. These differences are: economic
efficiency, environmental effectiveness, information requirements, administrative burden,
allocation, monitoring and enforcement requirements, adaptability, flexibility, cost revelation,
costs of emissions control, pollution abatement costs, environmental targets, degree of pollutant
mix, stimulation for technological innovation, effect on international competitiveness, source
size and location, performance, and implementation and compliance.
       “Environmental policy could be improved by paying more attention to the evaluation of
the many policy instruments that may be used, their strengths and weaknesses, and the conditions
in which they are likely to be most effective” (Vig & Kraft 1994, 188).
       Now that we have a better understanding of the main characteristics of the available
environmental policy instruments, I will now concentrate on my paper’s objective: to describe
the potential areas in which the CDM can be used, in combination with other policy instruments,
to reduce GHG emissions. And thus, make recommendations for Mexico to continue using the
CDM to contribute to the worldwide efforts against global climate change.




                                                                                              11
1.     Global Climate Change
1.1    What Is Global Climate Change?
       There is no turning back. Global climate change is already happening and it will continue
to have more drastic effects, unless we start cooperating and working together to try to reverse
the damage we have caused. The most sensible approach would be to cut CO2 emissions
immediately. However, if the cost of significantly cutting fossil-fuel emissions is too expensive
and would severely affect the global economy in the short term, maybe the response of the global
economy should be trying to implement CO2 reduction measures, while implementing measures
to adapt to the effects caused by climate change (Maslin 2004, 2 & 136). In other words, we
cannot pin all our hopes on clean energy and technological fixes (Maslin 2004, 2 & 136).
       Climate change challenges the way we organize our society, the concept of nation-state
vs. global responsibility, and our short-term vs. long-term vision, among others
(Maslin 2004, 147).
       There is every reason to worry about the impacts of the changes now underway in the
Earth’s climate system, since the rate of change is unprecedented in the history of human
civilization (Barnett & Adger 2007, 640).
       Climate change is the intensification of the ‘natural’ greenhouse effect from human
activities (See 2001, 3). GHGs control the delicate balance between the amount of radiation that
is trapped and the amount that is reflected, by creating a natural greenhouse (blanket). This
blanket maintains Earth’s average temperature at 35ºC making life on Earth possible
(Maslin 2004, 4). The global average surface temperature is expected to increase between
1.5 and 4.5 ºC by 2100 (Frederick 2001, 61).


1.2    What Causes Global Climate Change?
       There is strong scientific evidence that proves that GHG concentrations have been rising
since the beginning of the Industrial Revolution; and that changes in the atmospheric
concentrations of such gases, especially CO2, are causing average global temperatures to increase
faster than during the past one thousand years (Maslin 2004, 1, 10, & 21). In other words, if
levels of GHGs continue to increase, the temperature in the atmosphere will also increase,
altering the climate around the world (Maslin 2004, 7).



                                                                                              12
The main GHGs are (Maslin 2004, 1 & 11-17; See 2001, 4):
        Water vapor – it is a naturally occurring GHG, expected to increase in the atmosphere, in
response to warmer temperatures. It is entirely produced by natural processes and does not have
an anthropogenic component. In other words, human activity does not directly affect its
concentration.
        CO2 – burning fossil fuels, land use change, coal stoves, landfill sites, and deforestation.
There is evidence that our actions have increased its atmospheric concentration to the highest
level for the last half million years.
        CH4 – burning fossil fuels and agricultural wastes, rice paddies, waste dumps, land use
change, and livestock.
        N2O – burning fossil fuels, use of fertilizers, refinery operations, and emissions from
catalytic converters in transport vehicles.
        HFCs – refrigerants, vehicle air conditioning, electrical switching gear, and halocarbons.
        PFCs – aluminum, magnesium, and halocarbons.
        SF6 – electrical switching gear, aluminum, and magnesium industries.
        CFC-12 – produced by the use of liquid coolants and foams.
        O3 – formed by the reaction of sunlight on air containing hydrocarbons and NOx from car
engines and industrial operations.


1.3     What Are the Consequences of Global Climate Change?
        Global climate change will very likely produce negative and positive effects on human
and nonhuman worlds. In this case, I will focus on the negative impacts, since the purpose of this
paper is to make recommendations to improve Mexico’s climate change mitigation measures. It
is important to mention that all of these effects are estimations and predictions made by using the
most advanced scientific models possible (Maslin 2004, 2). However, there is always the
possibility of “potential surprises that the global climate system might have in store for us”
(Maslin 2004, 2).
        Whatever these economic and human losses might be, the unfortunate reality is that “the
poorest people will suffer the most” (Maslin 2004, 3). In other words, those in the weakest
economic or political positions will have to face the first effects of global warming: “faltering
water supplies, damage to crops, new diseases, and encroaching oceans” (Struck 2007, A03).

                                                                                                 13
Even though we accept the evidence, predicting climate change is complicated, because
the global climate system has different response times and it encompasses many different factors,
which respond differently when the atmosphere warms up (Maslin 2004, 21).
       Some of the potentially devastating effects on human society and on our social,
economic, and ecological systems include the following:
       Global warming - the predicted increase in the global average surface temperature
between 1.5 and 4.5 ºC by 2100 is expected to increase the number of fires and heat waves
(Frederick 2001, 61).
       Weather patterns - will become less predictable, causing an increase of extreme climate
events such as El Niño, changes in precipitation and wind patterns, and an increase in the
number, intensity, frequency, and pathways of storms, monsoons, hurricanes, tornadoes,
cyclones, floods, and droughts (Maslin 2004, 91-94).
       Water stress - it is estimated that approximately five billion people will experience
shrinking water supplies and freshwater scarcity by 2025. The potential increase in water
evaporation from plants and soil, plus the changes in rainfall, will lead to reduced runoff
(Frederick 2001, 67). This will produce desertification of semi-arid lands and droughts, it will
reduce crop productivity, and it may substantially affect hydroelectric power generation
(Campbell & Weitz 2007, 107; Maslin 2004, 1, 2, & 94-96; Max 2007, 1; See 2001, 3).
       Increase in the global average ocean temperature - resulting in thermal expansion,
sea-level rise, and the release of CH4 reserves (Maslin 2004, 2 & 55).
        Alteration of the global deep ocean circulation (Great Ocean Conveyor Belt) -
causing sea-level rise and extremely cold winters in Europe and a succession of weather
repercussions of the same magnitude as the Little Ice Age (Lee 2007, 39; Maslin 2004, 2).
       Rising global average sea-level - it is estimated that sea-level will increase between
20 and 88 cm. by 2100. This will cause small island nations to sink and become uninhabitable,
coastal areas to erode and become unstable, and it will limit tourism (a very important source of
income for island nations) (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106; Maslin 2004, 1 & 84-85).
       Expansion and contraction of ice sheets and glaciers - when polar ice caps melt and are
replaced by vegetation or open water, the albedo effect is altered. In other words, the reflection
of solar radiation will be reduced (since there is less ice) and more heat will be absorbed
(Maslin 2004, 73).

                                                                                               14
Melting permafrost - will alter hydrologic processes, increase the release of CO2 and
CH4, and trigger erosion, subsidence, avalanches, and sea-level rise (Maslin 2004, 57).
       Threatened forests - an increase in the rate of deforestation will add CO2 to the
atmosphere and will reduce the forests’ capacity to absorb existing atmospheric CO2
(Maslin 2004, 2 & 114). The composition of the forests is likely to change and they will become
more vulnerable to disease and insect predation (Sedjo & Sohngen 2001, 75-77). Their weak
composition will prevent them from competing against stronger species and so tree species will
be lost (Sedjo & Sohngen 2001, 77).
       Threatened natural habitats - will result in loss of species and biodiversity, migration of
species to accommodate warmer air and water, crash of global fish stocks, and the destruction of
habitats such as coral reefs, mangroves, wetlands, and marine and mountain ecosystems, among
others (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 104; Maslin 2004, 97-98). As a result, “a quarter of all species
in these regions may become extinct by the middle of this century” (Maslin 2004, 99).
       Changes and possible declines in agricultural productivity - will change planting
seasons, reduce crop yields, and cause food scarcity and famine (Purvis & Busby 2004, 67).
       Environmental refugees - the risk from sea-level rise will increase climate refugees
fleeing their island nations. This will cause large shifts in human internal and cross-border
migration patterns, conflict over resource scarcity in the ‘host’ country, and hostility towards the
refugees (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106; Purvis & Busby 2004, 68; See 2001, 3).
       Human health - the absence of clean water and the extension of the ranges and seasons
for mosquitoes and other tropical disease carriers will increase epidemics, outbreaks of infectious
diseases such as cholera and malaria, and human mortality rates (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106;
Purvis & Busby 2004, 67; See 2001, 3).




                                                                                                 15
2.      Environmental Policy Instruments
        Environmental policy instruments are divided into two groups: voluntary policy
instruments, which include eco-audits, environmental labeling programs, and voluntary
agreements; and mandatory policy instruments, which include command-and-control, emissions
trading, green taxes, joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism, among others
(Hatch 2005, 5-7).
        Basically, the elements that differentiate these instruments from each other are:
environmental effectiveness, economic and political efficiency, implementation and compliance,
administrative efficacy, and their effect on technological innovation (Hatch 2005, 8-9).
        The following tools represent a large mix of environmental policy instruments. Some of
these instruments are already being used to design climate change policies and others are not
currently linked to climate change policies. However, they may be used for this purpose
sometime in the future.
        Let me first describe this mix and in the following chapter, I will focus entirely on the
clean development mechanism.


2.1     Voluntary Policy Instruments
        “Voluntary policy instruments are most often non-binding and allow considerable
flexibility or discretion” (Hatch 2005, 5). Furthermore, depending on the instrument involved, a
different type of political dynamic might develop.
        They include eco-audits, environmental labeling programs (also known as eco-labels),
and voluntary agreements (Hatch 2005, 5).


2.1.1   Eco-Audits
        Eco-audits are voluntary arrangements that provide consumers information about
environmental management practices (Hatch 2005, 6).
        “For firms that choose to adopt specified standards for environmental management,
certified participation in such programs is designed to foster better relations with customers,
suppliers, stakeholders, and employees” (Hatch 2005, 6). In other words, the firm’s
self-evaluation may help it reduce its ecological footprint by doing things more efficiently



                                                                                              16
(Hatch 2005, 6). From the public sector’s perspective, this type of policy instrument offers
environmental benefits without the high administrative costs of direct regulation (Hatch 2005, 6).
        The adoption of ISO 14001 by Japanese corporations is a good example of this
environmental management system. The ISO 14001 certification provides significant process
and structural change that has positive results for long-term environmental performance
(Hatch 2005, 247). “ISO firms are more environmentally active than non-ISO firms”
(Hatch 2005, 247).


2.1.2   Environmental Labeling Programs
        “Environmental labeling programs formulate a set of production or performance criteria
products must meet if they desire to carry the eco-label” (Hatch 2005, 5). Products certified with
eco-labels represent more environmentally benign production and consumption practices in
comparison to non-certified products and offer consumers a choice based on environmental
considerations (Hatch 2005, 5).
        “Eco-labels create incentives for the innovation of more environmentally sound products
or production practices, by providing information upon which the environmentally conscious
consumer can act” (Hatch 2005, 5). Given their voluntary nature, eco-labels are relatively easy to
introduce and implement, since they are “light in terms of the amount of public expenditure,
management, and oversight” (Hatch 2005, 5).
        Their use was recommended during the 1992 Earth Summit and have become very
popular worldwide ever since (Hatch 2005, 17). Agenda 21 “explicitly states that governments
should encourage the expansion of environmental labeling in order to change consumption
patterns” (Hatch 2005, 17). “They seem to fit perfectly into the sustainability strategy, which has
the goal of reconciling economic, social, and ecological objectives, by enabling and fostering
innovation for more sustainable, resource efficient, and ecologically benign production and
consumption patterns” (Hatch 2005, 17).
        Furthermore, environmental labeling is included in several policy papers written by the
Commission on Sustainable Development and the OECD, promoting sustainable consumption
patterns (Hatch 2005, 17). They are also accepted around the world as an environmental
management tool, within the ISO 14000 family, that “can help accelerate diffusion of technical
improvements of products” (Hatch 2005, 18 & 41). The conclusion at the 1998 ‘Berlin

                                                                                                17
Conference Eco-labeling for a Sustainable Future’ underlined their role as a policy tool to
promote environmentally preferable products and services (Hatch 2005, 18).
        Germany launched the Blue Angel program in 1978 to reduce the amount of household
paint solvents (Hatch 2005, 19). This program is “a voluntary instrument managed in public-
private partnership that has proven to be ecologically effective” and is considered the first
environmental labeling program in the world (Hatch 2005, 21 & 246). Through the years it has
improved products and promoted innovation and the diffusion of the best available technology to
reduce product-related environmental problems (Hatch 2005, 40).
        Today, Germany, Canada, the European Union, Scandinavia, Japan, South Africa, and
the United States, among others, have successful eco-labeling programs (World Resources
Institute, 2007). They even founded the Global Eco-labeling Network in 1994 to foster
information exchange and to represent them in international forums (Hatch 2005, 25). For
example: Europe’s ‘flower label’, used by 135 manufacturers, retailers, and flower service
providers; the Rainforest Alliance’s Smart Wood program, which has the Forest Stewardship
Council’s certification, that the wood comes from a sustainable forest; and the Dolphin Safe
label, which certifies that the tuna was caught following U.S. dolphin protection fishing methods
and laws (World Resources Institute, 2007).


2.1.3   Voluntary Agreements
        “Voluntary agreements take a variety of forms ranging from industry covenants that are
legally binding to informal declarations of intent” (Hatch 2005, 6). A voluntary agreement is
defined as “an agreement between government and industry to facilitate voluntary action with a
desirable social outcome, which is encouraged by the government, to be undertaken by the
participant based on the participant’s self interest” (Hatch 2005, 6).
        Since firms voluntarily agree to certain emissions targets, this instrument is more flexible
in terms of method and timing, encourages greater efficiency and innovation, and helps achieve
environmental objectives at lower costs and in less time (Hatch 2005, 6). Moreover, they further
trust and understanding between the government and the industry, which promotes faster
implementation and compliance (Hatch 2005, 99).
        “The voluntary agreements between the German government and the electrical power
generation industry have become a centerpiece of Germany’s climate change policy”

                                                                                                 18
(Hatch 2005, 118). The Netherlands has successfully used voluntary agreements to meet national
environmental goals established in the National Environmental Policy Plan (Resource Renewal
Institute 1995, 1). For example: the chemical industry negotiated a 90% reduction of SO2
emissions by 2010 (Resource Renewal Institute 1995, 1). In the United States, the Environmental
Protection Agency’s (EPA) 33/50 Program uses the Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) data to
identify potential participants to reduce 17 pollutants of the Toxic Release Inventory (TRI)
(Resource Renewal Institute 1995, 1). Companies such as Intel, 3M, Dow Chemical, DuPont,
Xerox, and Patagonia have also shown interest in using this mechanism to comply with
environmental regulations and reach environmental goals (Resource Renewal Institute 1995, 3).
After analyzing the increase in international energy efficiency due to voluntary agreements,
China launched its Shandong Province Enterprise Energy-Efficiency Voluntary Agreement Pilot
program in its industrial sector (Resource Renewal Institute 1995, 9).


2.2    Mandatory Policy Instruments
       The most common mandatory policy instruments are command-and-control regulations,
green taxes, emissions trading, joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism
(Hatch 2005, 6).
       Emissions trading, joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism are
classified as ‘flexible mechanisms’ in the Kyoto Protocol and “offer market-based approaches
for achieving emissions reductions across borders” (Danish 2007, 11). “The rationale for the
flexible mechanisms is straightforward” (Danish 2007, 13). Since all emissions of GHGs have
the same impact, regardless of their location, and the cost of achieving emissions reduction is
quite varied, flexible mechanisms try to ensure that reductions will be implemented wherever
they can be achieved at the lowest cost (Danish 2007, 13). It is important to mention that the
acquisition of ERUs or CERs when using CDM or JI mechanisms respectively should be
supplemental to domestic GHG reduction policies (Albrecht 2002, 17; Hatch 2005, 154).
       Before describing the characteristics of each instrument, it is important to clarify what is
meant by ‘mandatory’ when referring to such environmental policy instruments. For instance,
except for green taxes, these instruments are in a sense both voluntary and mandatory. They are
adopted voluntarily, but once they have been adopted, the firms must abide by the rules
governing each mechanism. For example: developing countries enter clean development

                                                                                                19
mechanism agreements voluntarily, but once they enter them, the agreements have the force of a
contract that must be honored. In the case of emissions trading schemes, polluters have a choice
whether to trade or not, but once they decide to participate in the market, their participation
implies contractual and legal obligations.


2.2.1   Command-and-Control
        Command-and-control policy instruments are divided into two groups: technology-based
regulations, which “prescribe the use of specific equipment, processes, or procedures”
(Hatch 2005, 7); and performance-based standards, which “specify the level of pollutant
emissions allowed” (Hatch 2005, 7).
        Both are effective in achieving their specified environmental objectives with considerable
flexibility (Hatch 2005, 7). Technology-based regulations provide greater flexibility, through the
incorporation of principles such as ‘best available technology’ (Hatch 2005, 7). On the other
hand, performance-based standards are more flexible, since the regulated entities have
considerable discretion to choose the most appropriate method to achieve the prescribed levels of
emissions (Hatch 2005, 7).
        On the other hand, technology-based regulations achieve compliance and oversight much
easier than performance-based standards (Hatch 2005, 7).
        Initially, the efforts to address acid rain pollution in the United States took advantage of
the command-and-control regulatory approach. However, once the quality and reliability of the
monitoring equipment provided more information regarding air pollution and analytical
techniques and capabilities were improved, the use of emissions trading became more feasible
(Hatch 2005, 253).


2.2.2   Green Taxes
        “Green taxes are charges assessed on an amount of pollution that a firm or product
generates” (Hatch 2005, 6). Since firms face the direct costs of their polluting activities, they
have an incentive to control pollution and to choose the most technologically efficient reduction
methods, in order to lower or to avoid the tax (Hatch 2005, 6). “Finding the proper level of
taxation, however, is critical to the effectiveness of this instrument, because it is difficult to
anticipate exactly how much pollution reduction will result from any given tax” (Hatch 2005, 6).

                                                                                                 20
Environmental taxes could help achieve environmental goals, foster technological
innovation, and internalize externalities even if they “cannot be quantified and environmental
targets are set politically” (Hatch 2005, 126).
       Studies in the United States and Europe have shown that taxes on energy use can improve
the overall national economic performance, increase the level of employment, and clean the
environment (Robertson 1996, 1). This type of tax is considered regressive, since it affects the
poor in a higher degree than the rich. In other words, if the tax on household energy increases the
cost of heating and lighting, the poor people would have a hard time finding ways to pay such a
higher cost. However, this can be solved by equally distributing the revenue from energy taxes
(Robertson 1996, 1).
       “In Vermont, 98% of carbon emissions come from housing and transportation and only
2% come from fossil-fueled power plants” (Alex C. Walker Foundation 2002, 1). Since the
Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, which relies on a cap-and-trade system, will not help to
reduce Vermont’s carbon emissions, it needs to use green taxes as a more effective
environmental policy measure. “Carbon or fossil-fuel energy taxes can begin to effect a gradual
reduction of fossil fuel use through increasing prices” (Alex C. Walker Foundation 2002, 1).
       Germany’s tax reform has an ecological component that includes raising existing taxes on
petroleum products (gasoline, diesel fuel, heating oil, and natural gas) and introducing a tax on
electricity, as an effort to reduce energy-related GHG emissions (Hatch 2005, 127-128).
       The Czech Republic has started to design its green tax process in order to drive polluting
businesses to switch to healthier energy sources (Bouc 2007, 1). It is hoped that the system will
be in place and running by January 2008 (Bouc 2007, 1). The green tax “will affect companies
with production or consumption that has a proven negative effect on the environment and health”
(Bouc 2007, 1). A higher tax on coal-powered operations will be among the first green taxes
implemented in the world (Bouc 2007, 1). This initial phase of the green tax will approximately
increase electricity prices by 1%, natural gas prices by 3%, and raw material prices by 10%
(Bouc 2007, 1).




                                                                                                21
2.2.3    Emissions Trading
         This policy instrument “employs the price mechanism to internalize the costs of
pollution, thus encouraging both the static and dynamic efficiencies that lead to ongoing
pollution reduction” (Hatch 2005, 6-7).
         In the case of tradable emissions permits, there is no need to predict the appropriate level
of taxation required to reach emissions reduction goals (Hatch 2005, 7). Under this system,
“policymakers establish an overall target of emissions allowed for an industry, area, or country”
(Hatch 2005, 7). “Permits representing allowable shares of the total emissions are then allocated
to each company” (Hatch 2005, 7). If firms reduce their emissions below the allotted levels, they
can sell their unused permits to firms whose emissions exceed their permits or save (bank) them
for future use (Hatch 2005, 7). Thus, if firms exceed their allotted levels, they must purchase
permits from other firms or face legal sanctions (Hatch 2005, 7).
         There are two main approaches or regimes to emissions trading: cap-and-trade and
baseline-and-credit.
         1- The cap-and-trade (absolute target) approach sets a total cap (absolute quantity of
emissions) measured over a specific period of time, on all emissions from the sources covered by
the regime. This total is allocated between the sources either freely or by auction, in the form of a
right to emit a specific quantity, usually as an allowance. After the initial allocation, sources can
choose to reduce their emissions and sell their allowances, maintain their emissions, or increase
their emissions, through the purchase of additional allowances. The choice to buy and sell
depends on the market price of the allowances and the marginal costs of reducing emissions at
the source. At the end of the trading or compliance period, the actual emissions have to be equal
to the number of allowances for each source. If the emissions are greater than the allowances,
they have to buy more allowances. On the other hand, if emissions are less than the allowances,
they can sell their excess allowances.
         This approach is attractive to both policymakers and environmental groups, since they
provide certainty on the environmental outcome of the trading system. The regime’s cap
determines the total amount of emissions from the sectors covered by the regime, while the
market    determines    where    the   necessary reductions      in   emissions   will   take   place
(Yamin 2005, 87).



                                                                                                  22
2- The baseline-and-credit (relative target) approach does not set a fixed absolute cap on
the emissions from the sectors covered by the regime. The relative target is usually set through
defining a baseline, which is expressed in the efficiency of emissions in relation to the activity of
the source. The same baseline can be set across a wide range of similar installations. When
installations can reduce the emissions more cheaply than the market price of allowances, they
will reduce their emissions and obtain allowances, which they can sell. If, on the other hand, the
reduction of emissions is more expensive than the market price of allowances, they will maintain
or increase their emissions, through the purchase of additional allowances on the market. In this
regime, allowances are not allocated up front. Rather, they are allocated when a source
demonstrates that it performs better than its baseline.
       This regime is usually more attractive for regulated sources, as the absolute effects of
most abatement techniques are usually dependent on the activity of the installation. Any
reduction in emissions caused by the installation of new technology can often easily be outdone
by an increase in activity. Industry usually argues that production growth itself should not be
punished, but that its efficiency should be increased. Relative targets do exactly this
(Yamin 2005, 87).
       The 1990 Amendments to the 1970 Clean Air Act allowed the first formal public
cap-and-trade of acid rain producing SO2 emissions in the United States (May 1992), between
three coal-fired power plants: Wisconsin Power and Light Company (one of the cleanest utilities
at the time), the Tennessee Valley Authority (one of the dirtiest utilities at the time), and
Duquesne Light Co. (utility in Pittsburg) (Hatch 2005, 175). Wisconsin Power and Light
Company reduced its emissions of SO2 by 10,000 pounds and sold its emissions permits to the
other two utilities, who could not afford to reduce their volume of emissions lower than the
legally required level (Allen 1992, A-12). This trade was beneficial because it controlled the
production of acid rain and it allowed the polluting utilities to continue generating electricity,
while giving them the needed time to install non-polluting technology in their production plants
(Allen 1992, A-12).
       Emissions trading examples around the world include: the Regional Clean Air Incentives
Market (RECLAIM) program for trading SOx and NOx emissions from stationary sources in the
Los Angeles area, established by Southern California’s South Coast Air Quality Management
District (Hatch 2005, 12 & 171); the Stratospheric Ozone Protection Program’s marketable

                                                                                                  23
permit system for U.S. producers and importers of CFCs (Hatch 2005, 174); Oregon Energy’s
program to reduce and trade CO2 emissions in energy generating and non-generating facilities
(Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 16); the program in Massachusetts that limits CO2, SO2, and NOx
emissions from its largest fossil-fired power plants (Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 16); Chile’s
emissions trading permits from industrial point sources of particulate matter in Santiago since
1992 (Sterner 2003, 91); Denmark’s CO2 emissions trading from electricity generators
(Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 14); the New South Wales GHG Abatement Scheme
(Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 14); the BP Emissions Trading Scheme and the Royal Dutch Shell
Tradable Emission Permit System, which regulate internal CO2 and CH4 emissions trading
schemes (Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 17); the Chicago Climate Exchange’s voluntary GHG
emissions trading program, targeting emissions and offsets in the United States, Canada, Mexico,
and Brazil from 2003-2006 (Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 17); the United Kingdom’s Emissions
Trading Scheme, considered the world’s first legislative-backed national GHG market, in which
emissions from industrial energy users and electricity generators have been voluntarily traded
since 2002 (Maslin 2004, 131); and the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, the largest
multi-country and multi-sector GHG emissions trading system in the world, in which emissions
from electricity generation and from the production of iron, steel, lime, cement, glass, ceramics,
pulp, and paper have been traded since 2005 (Mufson 2007, A01).


2.2.4   Joint Implementation
        International JI projects received attention since the early 1990s (Kuik, Peters, &
Schrijver 1994, 73 & 161). This attention increased after the signing of the UNFCCC and the
recognition that they can be valuable instruments for cooperation for the reduction of GHG
emissions (Kuik, Peters, & Schrijver 1994, 73 & 161).
        JI is a project-based emissions trading mechanism among countries with Kyoto
commitments (Albrecht 2002, 17). In a JI transaction, an Annex I Party (investing country)
invests in a project in another Annex I Party (host country) to reduce its GHG emissions,
“presumably because the cost of achieving such reduction is lower in the host country than in the
investing country” (Danish 2007, 13). In other words, two or more developed countries
implement certain policies and measures ‘jointly’ and in agreement for the purpose of reducing
GHG emissions with increasing efficiency, cost-effectiveness, and equitability between the

                                                                                               24
participating countries (Kuik, Peters, & Schrijver 1994, 161-162). Furthermore, it is very
important that the criteria for JI take into account economic, social, and environmental concerns
(Kuik, Peters, & Schrijver 1994, 162).
        In both countries, the government and the State or a privately-owned company within the
country is willing to participate in the project (Kuik, Peters, & Schrijver 1994, 73).
        The ‘receiving country’ transfers a corresponding portion of its assigned amount of ERUs
to the ‘investing country’, which adds them to its originally assigned amount. The additionality
requirement must be achieved in order for the transaction to be legally valid. This means that
ERUs should not be credited to reductions that would have occurred even without the
intervention of an investing Annex I Party (Danish 2007, 13).
        Denmark’s JI program will launch three to five pilot projects in the Baltic States
(Hatch 2005, 165). The Swedish Program for an Environmentally Adapted Energy System
finances projects on energy efficiency and use of renewable energy in the Baltic Region and
Eastern Europe (Hatch 2005, 165). Norway’s business sector is interested in establishing a
domestic permit trading system in Eastern Europe (Hatch 2005, 165).
        Even though ERUs have been obtained since 2000, this mechanism’s official starting
date is 2008 (Hatch 2005, 155).


2.2.5   Clean Development Mechanism
        In the following chapter, there is an extensive review of the CDM’s history and a more
detailed explanation of this flexible market-based environmental policy instrument.




                                                                                              25
3.      The Clean Development Mechanism
        Now that we have become familiar with the mix of environmental policy instruments, we
can focus our attention on the CDM, since this is the environmental policy scheme that I am
proposing, as an excellent tool for Mexico to contribute to the mitigation of global climate
change.


3.1     Historical Background
        The UNEP and the World Meteorological Organization set up the UNFCCC, regarded as
the foundation for the international climate change regime (Danish 2007, 10). The UNFCCC,
which was adopted in 1992 and entered into force in 1994, set an overall global framework
(objectives, guiding principles, commitments, and institutional provisions) for intergovernmental
efforts to tackle the challenge posed by climate change; recognized that the climate system is a
shared resource whose stability can be affected by GHG emissions; and established guiding
principles to balance environmental protection, economic development, and the general divisions
of burdens between developed and developing countries (Danish 2007, 10; See 2001, 7).
        Under the Convention, governments gather and share information on national policies
and best practices regarding GHG emissions; launch national strategies for addressing GHG
emissions and for adapting to expected impacts, including the provision of financial and
technical support for developing countries; and cooperate to find ways to cope with the
inevitable effects of climate change (See 2001, 7).
        The countries, which have ratified the UNFCCC, are divided into three groups: Annex I
Parties (developed countries that have been members of the OECD since 1992 and countries with
economies in transition); Annex II Parties (Annex I Parties except countries with economies in
transition); and non-Annex I Parties (developing countries, including the ‘least developed’
countries) (Danish 2007, 10-11; Echegoyen 2007, 5-6; See 2001, 7). See the Appendix for a
detailed list of countries.
        The COP is the Convention’s main policy-making body (Yamin 2005, xxxix). It meets
annually and provides the chief forum for international discussions about climate change
(Yamin 2005, xxxix).




                                                                                              26
The Kyoto Protocol, which was drafted during COP-3 in Kyoto (1997) and entered into
force in 2005, is the most ambitious UNFCCC legally binding international treaty for the
limitation of GHG emissions (Hatch 2005, 153; Maslin 2004, 118).
       The Protocol established differentiated commitments for the Parties (Yamin 2005, xxxix).
Annex I Parties are legally bound to adopt quantitative reduction targets for GHG emissions
(Albrecht 2002, 1). Specifically, they are required to reduce (cap) the emitted volume of six
GHGs (CO2, CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs, and SF6) by an average of 5.2% below 1990 emissions
levels (1995 for the last three gases) during the 2008-2012 budget period (Maslin 2004, 118;
See 2001, 8). Annex I Parties can meet such targets by reducing domestic emissions from the
industrial, energy, services, transportation, household, and agricultural sectors, through
technological innovations; by taking action through domestic forest actions such as afforestation
(planting trees for commercial purposes on land that is not a forest or has not been one for a long
time) and reforestation (reestablishment of existing forests and woodlands which have been
depleted); and by using the newly proposed flexible market-based mechanisms: emissions
trading, joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism (Albrecht 2002, 1-2;
Echegoyen 2007, 7-10).
       It also established that non-Annex I Parties were not obligated to adopt quantitative
commitments for the reduction of GHG emissions (Wiener 2001, 205). However, they must
comply with the general commitments of every Party: registration of the inventory of national
emissions, the adoption of climate change policies, the development of research projects, and the
establishment of global climate change education campaigns (Echegoyen 2007, 7-10).
        “The negotiation of the Kyoto Protocol to the UNFCCC represented a significant
development in international environmental policy” (Toman 2001, 216). Annex I Parties agreed
to numerical GHG emissions targets and participants also agreed that the development and
implementation of flexibility mechanisms provided an excellent opportunity for reducing overall
compliance costs, by investing in cost-effective emissions reduction or sequestration projects in
other countries (Danish 2007, 13; See 2001, 7; Toman 2001, 216).
       Concrete rules and guidelines on the CDM were laid out in 2001 during COP-7 in
Marrakesh (Hatch 2005, 151).




                                                                                                27
3.2    Definition
       The CDM has attracted worldwide interest “since it has become the most globalized
element of the Kyoto Protocol” (Baumert & Petkova 2000, 1) to address the reduction and
mitigation of global climate change. It is known as the ‘Kyoto surprise’ because the consensus
on the final proposal text was reached with unprecedented speed and because it was central for
the final outcome of the Kyoto Protocol (Werksman 2000, 218).
       The CDM, defined in Article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol, is a project-based mechanism that
creates CERs through the reduction of GHGs (CO2, CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs, and SF6) against a
project baseline of a business-as-usual scenario (Hatch 2005, 153). It allows Annex I Parties to
invest in and implement projects that reduce GHG emissions in non-Annex I Parties, creating
CERs that are transferred to Annex I Parties, which use them to comply with emissions limits
established by the Kyoto Protocol (See 2001, 8; Toman 2001, 216-217).
       The CDM allows developed and developing countries to become partners and work
together to reduce GHG emissions (Echegoyen 2007, 11). Developed countries contribute by
investing resources in GHG mitigation projects and developing countries contribute by hosting
such projects.
       CDM projects started in 2000 and are carried out in sectors of great demand and
consumption, such as: energy production (improving its efficiency in use and consumption),
solid waste management (burning of biogas in the landfills), management of animal manure
(capture and burning of methane), and in the destruction of by-product gases from industrial
chemical processes (HFC23), among others (Echegoyen 2007, iii; Toman 2001, 217).


3.3    Requirements for CDM Projects
       The main requirements are the reduction of GHG emissions and the achievement of
sustainable development goals in the host Party.
       The implementation of CDM projects requires the establishment of an appropriate
international legal framework with regulations for operating the mechanism. Article 12 of the
Kyoto Protocol, the Marrakesh Accords, and the CDM Executive Board have established such a
framework, that includes rules for defining, measuring, and certifying CERs; compliance
mechanisms and sanctions for the misuse of CERs; and a clear definition of the benefit
distribution and the authority of the developing countries (Toman 2001, 218; Wilder 2005, 246).

                                                                                             28
In order for CDM projects to be successful, they require public-private partnerships,
active participation of local communities, and cooperation with governments (Baumert &
Petkova 2000, 1). Additionally, they need to embrace emerging global norms, hold decision
makers accountable, include safeguards against corruption, and ensure transparency (Baumert &
Petkova 2000, 1).
       Even before the proper beginning of CDM projects, they must comply with the following
requirements (Hatch 2005, 155-156; Toman 2001, 217-218; Werksman 2000, 218, 224, & 225):
   1. Participation cannot be forced on any country (Michaelowa 2005, 291). In other words,
       the degree of participation is voluntary and approved by each Party involved
       (Danish 2007, 14; Michaelowa 2005, 291).
   2. Project participants are encouraged to use pre-approved, transparent, efficient,
       accountable, and practicable methodologies (Danish 2007, 14). If new methodologies are
       proposed, the Methodology Panel must review and approve them prior to their
       implementation (Danish 2007, 14). Moreover, they are required to provide written
       clarification of their respective roles and of the distribution of CERs arising from the
       project (Yamin 2005, 31).
   3. Host Parties must ratify the Kyoto Protocol, establish an effective institutional and legal
       framework for approving the projects, and must give affirmation that the project activity
       meets its own sustainable development goals (Kenber 2005, 265-266).
   4. Host Parties must also undertake an environmental impact assessment, if project
       participants consider it necessary (Kenber 2005, 266). This assessment is needed to
       guarantee that a basic set of environmental and social serious adverse impacts and major
       threats to sustainable development will be avoided (Kenber 2005, 266). Usually, NGOs
       safeguard    the   environmental   and    social   integrity   of   the   CDM     process
       (Michaelowa 2005, 309).
   5. There must be a mandatory process of public consultation (Kenber 2005, 266). This
       consultation is an opportunity for the public to comment on CDM projects at various
       stages of the project cycle (Kenber 2005, 267). This way, local communities can
       influence project design and ensure that their priorities will be met (Kenber 2005, 267).
       And, at the same time, project developers will be able to recognize community needs and



                                                                                              29
gain public support early in the project cycle, avoiding delays and public opposition in
   the future (Kenber 2005, 267).
6. An equitable geographical spread of projects must be guaranteed (Kenber 2005, 266). In
   other words, CDM projects must not be concentrated in a few developing countries, with
   relatively more developed economies, excluding the smaller ones (Kenber 2005, 266).
7. Operation must be supervised by an intergovernment body that includes representatives
   of the Conference of the Parties (the ultimate authority), an Executive Board, independent
   auditors, and a DNA (Wilder 2005, 247; Yamin 2005, 33). These institutions should be
   credible, internally efficient, and adaptable. They should also ensure that the projects do
   not degenerate into rent-seeking or cater to special interests, without achieving real
   environmental protection and sustainable development.
8. The Executive Board is the main entity responsible for authorizing validated projects and
   project participants (Yamin 2005, 34). It must oversee the effective application of the
   additionality concept, approve new baseline and monitoring methodologies, certify
   independent auditors, provide information about distribution, financing, technical reports,
   and norms, monitor procedure compliance, and maintain an updated registration log and
   project data base (Echegoyen 2007, 17). The Executive Board meets approximately once
   every two months (at least three times a year) and it is integrated by 10 members from
   Parties to the Kyoto Protocol (one member from each of the five UN regional groups, two
   representatives from Annex I and two from non-Annex I Parties, and one member from
   the developing small island nations) (Echegoyen 2007, 17; Yamin 2005, 35-36). The
   members must be impartial during the decision making process (Yamin 2005, 35).
   Decisions are taken by consensus when possible and by a 75% majority in the absence of
   consensus (Yamin 2005, 38).
9. In order to facilitate and expedite the project cycle, the Executive Board has accredited a
   number of DOEs and has built a library of standard emissions baseline methodologies for
   certain types of commonly-implemented projects (Danish 2007, 14).
10. DOEs are private companies that serve as independent project auditors (Echegoyen 2007,
   18). They have the responsibility of validating that a proposed CDM project meets all
   relevant requirements and of verifying that the project has generated reductions on an
   annual basis (Yamin 2005, 39). They maintain a publicly available list of projects, submit

                                                                                           30
annual activity reports to the Executive Board, and provide non-confidential information
   from CDM projects (Yamin 2005, 41). DOEs specialize in the different sectors in which
   CDM projects can be developed, such as: renewable energy, hydroelectric, chemical
   industry, and agriculture, among others (Echegoyen 2007, 18).
11. The DNA is the governmental authority of the Parties participating in the project. It is the
   entity responsible for issuing the written approval that guarantees the voluntary
   participation of the Parties in the proposed project and for evaluating the project’s
   contribution to the host Party’s sustainable development efforts (Yamin 2005, 39).
12. A registry must be established by the Executive Board to ensure the accurate accounting
   of the issuance, holdings, transfer, and acquisition of CERs by the non-Annex I Parties
   (Yamin 2005, 31).
13. Since recipient Parties will not have quantified commitments, CERs will be issued when
   the environmental additionality principle is achieved (Hatch 2005, 155). Additionality is
   crucial, since “it creates the unit of the transaction for the utilization of the CDM”
   (Yamin 2005, 38). Thus, “CDM projects must produce real emissions reductions that
   would not have occurred in the absence of the project”. Moreover, they provide real,
   measurable, and long-term benefits related to the mitigation of climate change.
14. CERs issued between 2000 and 2008 can be used to achieve compliance during the
   Kyoto Protocol’s first commitment period.
15. There is no obligation for the COP or governments to provide any financing for the
   CDM. In other words, any financing is voluntary and may be supplemented by financing
   from the private sector and development banks in the case of large projects (See 2001, 8).
   In OECD countries, such financing is limited, since they have quotas on grants for
   overseas projects (See 2001, 8).
16. Financial and development additionality must be achieved. Financial resources, provided
   by the investor Party, complement and do not replace existing official development aid
   and funding through the GEF (operating financial entity responsible for matching eligible
   projects in developing countries with funds provided by developed countries).
   (Kenber 2005, 266-267). Furthermore, non-Annex I Parties must be encouraged to follow
   long-term GHG emissions reduction paths without unacceptably restricting their
   development path (Kenber 2005, 266-267).

                                                                                             31
17. Parties in non-compliance with these requirements will not be eligible to take advantage
         of the flexibility mechanisms provided by the Kyoto Protocol.


         Additionally, non-Annex I Parties must consider the project’s contributions to their
countries, before deciding to host a specific CDM project. Such contributions include: global
climate change mitigation, sustainability of the local environment, durability of the balance of
payments and the macroeconomic plan, development of national technology and technological
autonomy,      poverty   mitigation,    and   regional,   social,   and   economic     development
(Kenber 2005, 271; Wilder 2005, 255).


3.4      CDM Project Activity Cycle
         Each CDM project must go through the following operational stages, defined by the COP
(Toman 2001, 216):
      1. Identification – identification of a viable project, assessment of its potential net GHG
         emissions reduction and its economic and social effects, and the determination of its
         financing source.
      2. Development of the Project Design Document – there is a specific template which
         contains critical information about the project (Danish 2007, 14). This document includes
         a general description of the project activity; it describes the application of the project’s
         baseline methodology (the estimated allowable CERs); it specifies the duration of the
         project activity and its crediting period; it describes the type of monitoring methodology
         and plan that will be used; it verifies the project’s approval by the receiving Party; it
         estimates the reduction of GHG emissions by sources and the environmental impacts
         associated with such reductions; and finally, it contains comments from the participating
         stakeholders (Echegoyen 2007, Annex F). Project developers are in charge of
         understanding the technical options for reductions of GHGs and their costs
         (Echegoyen 2007, 18; Michaelowa 2005, 308). Moreover, they should be able to apply a
         monitoring methodology once the project starts operating (Echegoyen 2007, 18;
         Michaelowa 2005, 308).
      3. Accreditation and Validation – a DOE independently reviews and evaluates the Project
         Design Document in order to verify its compliance with CDM requirements and start the

                                                                                                  32
validation process (Yamin 2005, 31). The DOE must verify that the host Party has
   ratified the Kyoto Protocol and that the proposed project has the approval of the host
   Party, that it is voluntary, and that it is aimed at sustainable development goals
   (Echegoyen 2007, 18). If the project fulfills all the requirements, the DNA formally
   approves the project by issuing a ‘Host Country Project Approval Letter’, given to the
   Executive Board (Wilder 2005, 247).
4. Registration – once the Executive Board approves the DOE’s recommendations, it
   registers the project as a CDM project activity (Danish 2007, 14). This formal acceptance
   of the validated project ensures that all CDM projects meet the requirements, that they
   are subject to international scrutiny, and that they have been officially approved by the
   government in the host and investor countries (Kenber 2005, 270; Yamin 2005, 31).
5. Monitoring – it consists on the identification, collection, and archiving of information
   necessary to design and implement a monitoring plan (Yamin 2005, 32). The project
   participant must deliver an annual Monitoring Report quantifying the reduction in GHG
   emissions generated by the project (Danish 2007, 14). The implementation of the
   monitoring plan is a condition for the project’s verification and the issuance and
   certification of CERs (Yamin 2005, 32).
6. Verification – a second DOE (independent from the one that validated the project)
   delivers a Verification Report to the Executive Board, verifying that the registered project
   activity has reduced the monitored GHG emissions during the specified time period
   (Yamin 2005, 33).
7. Issuance and Certification of CERs – once the Executive Board accepts the DOE’s
   verification that the project has achieved the reduction in GHG emissions, it instructs the
   CDM Registry Administrator to issue the corresponding CERs into the national registry
   of the Annex I Party within a 15-day period (Yamin 2005, 33). CERs are calculated by
   comparing emissions of the CDM project with emissions of a hypothetical ‘baseline
   scenario’, that reflects the business-as-usual scenario. Baselines can be project specific or
   standardized and are determined by using three different approaches: actual or historical
   emissions, emissions of an ‘economically attractive’ course of action, and/or average
   emissions of similar projects and circumstances undertaken in the previous five years
   (Michaelowa 2005, 290-291).

                                                                                             33
8. Negotiation – once the project has been validated, lawyers draft the CER Purchase
         Agreement, in order to certify the transactions of CERs (Michaelowa 2005, 309). CDM
         projects may obtain CERs for three seven-year periods or for one single ten-year period
         (Michaelowa 2005, 309).


3.5      CDM Project Activity Status
         As of December 9, 2007, there were 864 registered Project Activities, 97,699,935 issued
CERs, with an annual average of 185,473,153 CERs, and it is expected that approximately
1,130,000,000 CERs will be issued by the end of 2012 (UNFCCC).
         According to their status, CDM projects are classified into the following groups:
      1. Registered (864)
      2. Requesting Registration (50)
      3. Requesting Review (57)
      4. Requesting Corrections (39)
      5. Under Review (8)
      6. Rejected (46)
      7. Withdrawn (8)


Table 1         Registered Project Activities by Scale
Scale          Total Number             Percentage
Large          458                      53.01%
Small          406                      46.99%
Total          864                      100%
Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007.


         The Bonn Agreement of 2001 defines the distinction between large-scale and small-scale
CDM projects according to the maximum output capacity of the project (UNFCCC). Industrial
projects are considered large-scale and community projects are considered small-scale
(Department of Sustainable Development 2007, 3).
         Large-scale CDM projects are defined as activities with output capacities greater than 15
megawatts in renewable energy projects; activities with 15 gigawatt hours per year in energy

                                                                                               34
efficiency; or other project activities that both reduce anthropogenic emissions by sources and
directly emit 15 or more kilotons of CO2 equivalent annually (Department of Sustainable
Development 2007, 3).


         Small-scale CDM projects are defined as activities with output capacity equivalent up to
15 megawatts (or an appropriate equivalent); activities which reduce energy consumption on the
supply and/or demand side, by up to the equivalent of 15 gigawatt hours per year; and other
project activities that both reduce anthropogenic emissions by sources and directly emit less than
15 kilotons of CO2 equivalent annually (Thorne 2002, 6).


Table 2         Expected Average Annual CERs from Registered Project Activities
Host Party                        Percentage
China                             48.22%
India                             15.11%
Brazil                             9.39%
Republic of Korea                  7.74%
Mexico                             3.58%
Chile                              2.13%
Others                            13.83%
Total                             100%
Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007.


3.6      CDM Host Parties
         The countries (Parties) that host CDM projects around the world are: Argentina,
Armenia, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Bolivia, Brazil, Cambodia, Chile, China, Colombia, Costa Rica,
Cuba, Cyprus, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Fiji, Georgia, Guatemala,
Honduras, India, Indonesia, Israel, Jamaica, Lao People’s Democratic Republic, Malaysia,
Mexico, Mongolia, Morocco, Nepal, Nicaragua, Nigeria, Pakistan, Panama, Papua New Guinea,
Peru, Philippines, Qatar, Republic of Korea, Republic of Moldova, South Africa, Sri Lanka,
Thailand, Tunisia, Uganda, United Republic of Tanzania, Uruguay, and Vietnam (UNFCCC).


                                                                                               35
Table 3       Registered Project Activities by Host Party
Host Party   Total Number          Percentage
India        296                   34.26%
China        137                   15.86%
Brazil       113                   13.08%
Mexico         98                  11.34%
Chile          21                   2.43%
Others       199                   23.03%
Total        864                   100%
Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007.


Table 4       CERs Issued by Host Party
Host Party                CERs (Percentage)
India                     32.86%
China                     25.77%
Republic of Korea         18.16%
Brazil                    15.55%
Chile                      2.14%
Mexico                     1.97%
Others                     3.55%
Total                     100%
Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007.


Table 5       Registered Project Activities by Region
Region                                                Total Number   Percentage
non-Annex I Asia and the Pacific                      529            61.23%
non-Annex I Latin America and the Caribbean           305            35.30%
non-Annex I Africa                                      23            2.66%
Other                                                    7            0.81%
Total                                                 864            100%
Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007.
                                                                                  36
3.7      Type of CDM Projects
         If we classify the Registered Project Activities according to the type of economic activity
or industry, we observe that about 50% of the projects are related to the energy industry
(renewable and non-renewable); followed by projects aimed at reducing CH4 emissions from
biomass used to generate electricity, animal waste disposal, and landfill chemical reactions with
approximately 24%; 11% of the projects are related to fugitive emissions from fuels and
agriculture; and the remaining 15% are projects related to activities such as energy demand,
manufacturing and chemical industries, transport, and mining and metal production
(Echegoyen 2007, 27).
         We can also classify CDM projects according to the type of GHG that is targeted
(Echegoyen 2007, 24-25):
         CO2 emissions - renewable energy, industrial and household energy efficiency, carbon
capture, and use of biomass to generate electricity.
         CH4 emissions - biogas capture from landfills and animal waste and reduction of natural
gas leaks.
         N2O emissions - modification of chemical processes in textile production.
         HFCs and PFCs emissions - manufacture of coolants, fire extinguishers, and air
conditioning units.
         SF6 emissions - manufacture of heat conductors and coolants.


3.8      Advantages of CDM Projects
         The most important advantages of CDM projects are (Albrecht 2002, 17-19;
Danish 2007, 13; Michaelowa 2005, 305-306; Painuly 2002, 192; See 2001, 8 & 182;
Werksman 2000, 226-227; and Wiener 2001, 212 & 218-219):
      1. Only flexible mechanism that involves developed and developing countries.
      2. Considered as the primary mechanism for involvement of developing countries during
         the Kyoto Protocol’s first commitment period.
      3. Facilitate new market penetration or expansion for the investor company and the
         diversification of domestic risk in overseas markets.




                                                                                                 37
4. Reductions of GHG emissions in the host Party can be traded for money or used by the
   investor Party to meet its own target emissions, at a lower cost, in case its companies are
   not successful in bidding for CDM projects or cannot afford carbon taxes or permits.
5. The investment needed to reduce GHG emissions in non-Annex I Parties may be smaller
   than in Annex I Parties, through the installation of advanced pollution reduction
   technologies.
6. Non-Annex I Parties are beneficiaries of lower fiscal expenditure, inward investments,
   and transfer of technology.
7. Promotion of foreign investments from Annex I to non-Annex I Parties, specifically for
   energy efficiency improvement and use of renewable sources of energy.
8. Effective and efficient transfer of technology, capital, and resources, without
   compromising aid programs to non-energy sectors and sustainability.
9. Annex I Parties can achieve compliance with their quantified emissions limitation and
   reduction of GHGs without actually reducing their own emissions.
10. Non-Annex I Parties will be able to contribute to the ultimate objective of the UNFCCC
   (stabilization of GHG concentrations in the atmosphere) through the assistance received
   from Annex I Parties.
11. In addition to climate change mitigation, these projects assist non-Annex I Parties to
   achieve sustainable development and adapt to the adverse effects of climate change
   (Wilder 2005, 247).
12. Provide a meaningful source for adaptation funding. In this case, adaptation is a positive
   spillover effect from the CDM project.
13. Promote sustainable development in developing countries, while assisting developed
   countries to reduce their compliance costs, by investing in emissions reduction projects in
   developing countries.
14. Provide financial and technological assistance, so developing countries will be able to
   leapfrog dirty technologies.
15. Emerging brokers, accredited monitoring agents, information exchanges, mutual funds,
   and other means of risk diversification are helping to reduce transaction costs.
16. Developed countries can achieve their commitments to limit or reduce their GHG
   emissions through cost-effective and flexible means.

                                                                                           38
17. Its innovative aspects have the potential to transform international environmental laws
         and the climate regime (Danish 2007, 14).
      18. Non-compliance will be punished through the imposition of financial penalties, which
         could provide an additional source of revenue for development assistance for
         non-Annex I Parties (Danish 2007, 15).
      19. Many experts believe that Annex I Parties are likely to rely on CDM projects as a
         significant strategy for compliance with their Kyoto Protocol commitments, since there is
         a perception of abundance of low-cost mitigation project opportunities in developing
         countries.
      20. Since CERs are being generated in countries without a quantitative emissions limit, it
         would seem very possible for such countries to artificially inflate the amount of CERs
         (Michaelowa 2005, 305). However, this perverse incentive was addressed in the COP-7
         where “a stringent body of rules was established and agreed upon to protect the CDM’s
         environmental credibility” (Michaelowa 2005, 305-306).


3.9      Disadvantages of CDM Projects
         The most important disadvantages of CDM projects are (Hatch 2005, 152 & 164;
Wiener 2001, 212):
      1. Potential barriers to participation because of the provisions in agreements under the
         World Trade Organization. Basically, they must decide if projects can be regarded as
         additional, even if they are incompatible with the World Trade Organization.
      2. Complexity of the procedures for receiving approval by the CDM Executive Board
         (Kenber 2005, 264).
      3. Lack of capital for developing projects in poor rural areas.
      4. Lack of management skills among local people.
      5. Lack of guidance on how the sustainable components should be assessed
         (Kenber 2005, 264).




                                                                                               39
6. To preserve environmental integrity, the CDM project cycle inevitably causes transaction
   costs that are higher than with JI or emissions trading (Michaelowa 2005, 306). In other
   words, since partners are hard to identify, each negotiation is novel, each project must be
   approved by both Parties, and each investor needs to monitor its own projects, transaction
   costs will be high.
7. Do not address the needs of areas of poverty in developing countries.
8. Do not necessarily guarantee environmental and economic prosperity at a global scale.
9. Uncertainty in the development and assessment of baselines.
10. Difficulty in formulating an operational definition of additionality.
11. The fact that host countries need to build competence to master all the steps of the project
   cycle, in order to be a competitive provider of CERs and avoid costly outsourcing to
   service providers from developed countries, represents a great challenge for many of
   them (Michaelowa 2005, 306).




                                                                                             40
4.     The Clean Development Mechanism in Mexico
       Mexico, classified as a non-Annex I Party, signed the UNFCCC in 1992 and ratified it
one year later (Echegoyen 2007, 7). Even though Mexico signed the Kyoto Protocol in 1998 and
ratified it two years later, the fulfillment of the objectives of the UNFCCC and the development
of CDM projects gained importance since February 2005, when the Protocol finally came into
force (Echegoyen 2007, iii).
       The CDM offers developing countries, such as Mexico, a great challenge and opportunity
to actively participate in climate change mitigation efforts, while taking advantage of economic,
social, and environmental benefits (Echegoyen 2007, ii). Mexico has a great potential to develop
CDM projects, in lieu of the fact that the environmental impact of its productive sector is still
quite low (compared to developed countries) (Echegoyen 2007, iii).
       It is important to point out that most projects hosted by Mexico are aimed at mitigating or
recovering GHG emissions, CH4 in particular (Echegoyen 2007, 45). Moreover, Mexico has the
potential for developing CDM projects in areas such as: reforestation and afforestation, capture
of biogas from landfills, waste water treatment, energy efficiency in industrial processes,
renewable sources of energy (wind and hydropower), cogeneration of electricity, and conversion
to natural gas, among others (Echegoyen 2007, 46).
       After analyzing the country’s political status, number of developed projects, participation
in the CDM Executive Board, and the amount of generated CERs, among other characteristics,
Point Carbon (a world-leading provider of consulting services for carbon markets) determined
that India, China, Chile, Brazil, and Mexico are the top five non-Annex I Parties with the highest
potential for developing CDM projects (Echegoyen 2007, 28).
       In the words of Miguel Cervantes, the Head of the Climate Change Projects at the
Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources, “Mexico has an important potential,
since it can take advantage of the opportunity provided by CDM projects in the oil sector and in
electricity cogeneration in the private industry” (Sánchez 2007, 1). Mexico’s registered projects
in 2007 have the potential of reducing 6.2 million tons of CO2 (Sánchez 2007, 1). This is 50%
more than last year’s reduction and it is estimated to double during the next couple of years, with
the participation of companies such as PEMEX, Cydsa, Alfa, Minera Antlán, and Mexico’s
Federal Electricity Commission (Sánchez 2007, 1).



                                                                                                41
4.1      The Mexican Carbon Fund (FOMECAR)
         FOMECAR was born from a joint initiative between the Mexican Ministry of
Environment and Natural Resources (SEMARNAT), the Mario Molina Center, and the Mexican
Bank for Foreign Trade (Bancomext, 2007).
         FOMECAR’s main goal is to provide national companies and public entities with
technical and financial support to implement CDM projects and enjoy the additional income
offered by the carbon market (Bancomext, 2007). It also aims at taking advantage of the
opportunity     for   sustainable   development       and   environmental   benefits   to   society
(Bancomext, 2007).
         Considering the eligibility of CDM projects, the Mexican Bank for Foreign Trade and
Nafin (a Mexican development bank that promotes modernization projects) provide financial
resources through lines of credit established with development banks in developed countries, in
order to provide the best possible conditions to support CDM projects (Bancomext, 2007). Such
conditions include: medium and long term financing, floating and fixed interest rates, loan
repayment, according to the project’s specific needs, and maximum financing amount, according
to the project’s structure and particular requirements (Bancomext, 2007).
         In the following sections, I will mention the Mexican Carbon Fund’s objectives, potential
participants, and advantages (Bancomext, 2007).


4.1.1    Objectives
      1. Develop a culture of reduction of GHG emissions among Mexican businesses and local
         and state governments.
      2. Identify, develop, and promote viable projects to operate under the CDM principles.
      3. Encourage the participation of Mexican and foreign financial institutions to support
         competitive and equitable carbon projects.
      4. Organize and carry out seminars, workshops, and training courses to develop PINs.
      5. Provide the needed assistance in document preparation during the registration and
         certification process before the CDM Executive Board.
      6. Provide technical assistance on the feasibility of CDM projects.
      7. Enhance the country’s capacity to take advantage of the carbon market potential in
         Mexico.

                                                                                                42
8. Promote new investments in more efficient and cleaner technologies in Mexico, both
        from domestic and foreign sources.
   9. Provide trade advice on carbon internal markets and identify potential CER buyers, in
        order to maximize the benefits of CDM projects generated in Mexico.
   10. Promote national and international investment in sustainable projects and proper
        environmental management.
   11. Work with the Mexican Bank for Foreign Trade, the World Bank, and other commercial
        banks and international financial institutions, to provide the needed financial resources to
        fund CDM projects and cover all the expenses related to the development and operation
        of such projects.


4.1.2   Potential Participants
        The potential participants in the Mexican Carbon Market can be divided into four groups:
   1. Buyers: foreign public and private funds, commercial and institutional funds, multilateral
        organizations, and companies in Annex I Parties.
   2. Sellers: public sector entities (PEMEX and the Federal Electricity Commission), local and
        state governments, and private companies.
   3. Promoters: project developers, suppliers of technology, legal consultants, insurance
        companies, and DOEs.
   4. Financial support: Mexican and foreign financial institutions, the World Bank, export
        credit agencies, and national and international development banks.


4.1.3   Advantages
   1. Increase in the profitability and economic viability of CDM projects.
   2. CERs will provide a source of additional income.
   3. Direct support for environmental protection policies.
   4. FOMECAR is the first North American initiative to achieve the collaboration of an
        environmental regulatory government entity and a first class financial institution.




                                                                                                 43
4.2      CDM Projects in Mexico
         Even though Mexico currently has 98 registered projects, it needs to better coordinate the
CDM culture and implement well organized mechanisms, in order to promote more projects to
the Mexican public and private sectors (Bancomext, 2007). Fortunately, FOMECAR has the
support of the World Bank’s Carbon Unit to develop methodologies to increase the
establishment of CDM projects (Bancomext, 2007). On a similar note, the Mexican Ministry of
Environment and Natural Resources has international cooperation agreements with Japan, Spain,
Italy, Denmark, France, the Netherlands, Austria, Germany, Portugal, and Canada for the
promotion and establishment of CDM projects in Mexico (Bancomext, 2007).
         For Mexico to obtain the Letter of Approval for CDM projects, the project’s
environmental, economic, and social performance must be reviewed (Echegoyen 2007, 43).
Among other requirements, the project must prove that it will protect biodiversity and reduce the
negative impacts on land use, water use, and of waste management and GHG emissions
(Echegoyen 2007, 43). Additionally, it must improve the country’s economy, its competitive
status, and the population’s quality of life, by promoting profitable investments, generating
wealth and employment opportunities, and transferring technology to improve the local
infrastructure (Echegoyen 2007, 43).
         Mexico’s CDM projects can be classified in the following groups (UNFCCC):


Animal Waste Management System (AWMS) GHG Mitigation Projects
         Objective: mitigate animal effluent related GHG emissions and recover CH4 and N2O
emissions, resulting from aerobic and anaerobic decomposition processes, in an economically
sustainable manner. Benefits: improvements in AWMS practices, improved water quality in and
around the site, and reduction in odor.
      1) Estado de México - registered on December 2005; other Party: United Kingdom of Great
         Britain and Northern Ireland.
      2) Sonora - registered on December 2005, January 2006, February 2006, March 2006 (3),
         May 2006, and September 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and
         Northern Ireland.
      3) Baja California - registered on January 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great
         Britain and Northern Ireland.

                                                                                                44
4) Nuevo León - registered on February 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain
       and Northern Ireland.
   5) Aguascalientes, Guanajuato, and Querétaro - registered on March 2006; other Party:
       United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   6) Jalisco - registered on February 2006 (2), March 2006 (2), and September 2006; other
       Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   7) Sinaloa - registered on July 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and
       Northern Ireland.
   8) Sinaloa and Sonora - registered on September 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of
       Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   9) Aguascalientes and Guanajuato - registered on September 2006; other Party: none.
   10) Nuevo León and Tamaulipas - registered on September 2006; other Party: United
       Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   11) Jalisco and San Luis Potosí - registered on September 2006; other Party: United
       Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   12) Aguascalientes, Michoacán, and Querétaro - registered in 2007; other Party: none.


Animal Waste Management System (AWMS) Methane Recovery Projects
       Objective: mitigate and recover animal effluent related GHGs by improving AWMS
practices. Benefit: reduction of CH4 emissions.
   1) Sinaloa and Sonora - registered on October 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great
       Britain and Northern Ireland.
   2) Oaxaca and Puebla - registered on October 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great
       Britain and Northern Ireland.
   3) Tamaulipas - registered on October 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain
       and Northern Ireland.
   4) Guanajuato - registered on November 2006 (2); other Party: United Kingdom of Great
       Britain and Northern Ireland.
   5) Jalisco and Michoacán - registered on December 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of
       Great Britain and Northern Ireland.



                                                                                           45
6) Guanajuato, Michoacán, and Querétaro - registered on December 2006; other Party:
       United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   7) Coahuila, Durango, and Nuevo León - registered on December 2006; other Party: United
       Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   8) Veracruz - registered on December 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain
       and Northern Ireland.
   9) Coahuila - registered on November 2006 (5) and December 2006; other Party: United
       Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   10) Puebla - registered on October 2006, December 2006, and March 2007; other Party:
       United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   11) Sonora - registered on October 2006, November 2006, March 2007 (2), June 2007, and
       July 2007; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   12) Durango - registered on November 2006 and June 2007 (2); other Party: United
       Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
   13) Chiapas - registered on March 2007; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and
       Northern Ireland.
   14) Estado de México and Puebla - registered on June 2007; other Party: none.
   15) Chihuahua - registered on June 2007; other Party: none.
   16) Coahuila and Durango - registered on June 2007 and July 2007; other Party: none.
   17) Nuevo León - registered on July 2007; other Party: none.
   18) Aguascalientes, Michoacán, and Querétaro - registered on July 2007; other Party: none.
   19) Yucatán - registered on September 2007; other Party: none.


EcoMethane Landfill Gas to Energy Projects
       Objective: capture and destruction of CH4 from sanitary landfills, feed it to a landfill gas
flare and a modular electricity generation plant, and dispose of CH4 safely and control the odor
nuisance, health risks, and adverse environmental impacts. Benefits: reduction of solid municipal
waste and the reduction of CH4 in the atmosphere.
   1) Aguascalientes - registered on May 2006 and July 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of
       Great Britain and Northern Ireland.



                                                                                                46
2) Ecatepec - registered on July 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and
       Northern Ireland.
   3) Tultitlán – registered on May 2007; other Party: none.
   4) Durango - registered on November 2007; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain
       and Northern Ireland.


Methane Recovery and Electricity Generation Project
       Objective: construction of a covered in-ground anaerobic reactor that will use the organic
material produced in the pig farm currently treated in the wastewater ponds, to produce biogas.
Benefits: reduction of CO2 and CH4 emissions.
   1) Altotonga - registered on September 2006, October 2006 (11), November 2006 (10),
       December 2006 (3), and April 2007 (4); other Parties: United Kingdom of Great Britain
       and Northern Ireland and Switzerland.


La Venta II Project
       Objective: construction and use of a wind power plant to generate renewable electricity,
which will be supplied to the Interconnected Mexican National Grid. Benefit: reduction of CO2
emissions.
   1) Oaxaca - registered on April 2007 and June 2007; other Party: Spain.


Eurus Wind Farm
       Objective: take advantage of the available wind resources to provide renewable energy.
Benefits: reduction of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired
power plants.
   1) Oaxaca – registered on October 2006 and January 2007; other Party: none.


Bii Nee Stipa I, II, and III Project
       Objective: generate renewable energy coming from wind resources. Benefits: reduction
of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired power plants. Registered
on December 2005, March 2006, and February 2007; other Party: Spain.



                                                                                                47
La Ventosa Wind Energy Project
       Objective: generate electricity from wind. Benefits: increased percentage of renewable
sourced power in Mexico’s electricity grid and the reduction in GHG emissions.
   1) Oaxaca - registered on June 2007 and October 2007; other Party: Spain.


El Gallo Hydroelectric Project
       Objective: generate renewable electricity using hydroelectric resources. Benefits:
reduction of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired power plants.
Registered on April 2006 and July 2006; other Party: France.


Trojes Hydroelectric Project
       Objective: generate renewable electricity using hydroelectric resources. Benefits:
reduction of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired power plants.
   1) Trojes - registered on April 2006; other Party: none.


Chilatán Hydroelectric Project
       Objective: generate renewable electricity using hydroelectric resources. Benefits:
reduction of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired power plants.
   1) Chilatán - registered on May 2007 and September 2007; other Party: United Kingdom of
       Great Britain and Northern Ireland.


HFC-23 Recovery and Decomposition Project
       Objective: reduction of HFC-23 emissions by recovering and decomposing this gas.
Benefit: reduction of HFC-23 emissions, which is a powerful GHG.
   1) Monterrey - registered on May 2006 and June 2006; other Parties: United Kingdom of
       Great Britain and Northern Ireland, Netherlands, and Japan.




                                                                                                 48
Joint Venture Project of Cogeneration of Electricity and Hot Water
       Objective: utilization of the natural gas and biogas produced from the on-site wastewater
biodigesters to produce clean and renewable energy. Benefits: reduction in the use of natural gas,
conservation of non-renewable resources, and reduction in GHG emissions. Registered on June
2006 and August 2006; other Party: none.


Hasars Landfill Gas Project
       Objective: capture and flare the landfill gas generated through the decomposition of the
organic waste disposed at the landfill site. Benefit: reduction in GHG emissions (CH4 and CO2).
Registered on April 2007, July 2007, and October 2007; other Party: none.


Reduction of the Average Clinker Content in Cement at the CEMEX Operations Project in
Mexico
       Objective: reduction of the average clinker content in cement. Benefits: reduction of
GHG emissions, thermal and electrical energy conservation, and industrial waste utilization.
Registered on June 2007 and November 2007; other Party: none.


       It is estimated that by 2020 municipal solid waste and the CH4 emissions associated with
it will have increased by 86% (Bancomext, 2007). Mexico could take advantage of CDM
projects to reduce CH4 emissions, by attracting investment opportunities and developing new
techniques to use recovered energy for further development (Bancomext, 2007). Moreover, it
could take advantage of projects that reduce negative environmental and health effects and the
amount of sanitary landfills (Bancomext, 2007).
       Fortunately, as we can observe from the prior list of CDM projects in Mexico, its current
CDM projects are mostly related to GHG (CH4, N2O, and CO2) mitigation projects, that are
generated from animal waste and landfills.
       It is also worth mentioning that Mexico’s main partner (investor Party) is the United
Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland.
       Hopefully, Mexico will continue expanding its municipal solid waste management in an
environmentally friendly way and will expand its scope by accepting CDM projects aimed at
other types of objectives and goals.

                                                                                               49
Final Comments
       Scientific research on the relationship between CO2 and the climate began in the
  th
19 century, when J. Tyndall established that CO2 is a GHG (Oreskes 2007, A15). Then, in the
20th century, S. Arrhenius began to suspect that CO2 could alter the Earth’s climate
(Oreskes 2007, A15). This effect was proven by G. Callendar in the 1930s and by C. Keeling and
R. Revelle by the 1960s, when they used the Keeling Curve to demonstrate that atmospheric CO2
was steadily rising (Oreskes 2007, A15). As early as 1965, warnings were being reported to
governments by the scientific community: “we will modify the heat balance of the atmosphere to
such an extent that marked changes in climate … could occur” (Oreskes 2007, A15).
       The IPCC was formed by the UN in 1988 to determine the state and implications of
climate change. It predicted that global warming will trigger enormous physical and social
changes, including scientific, environmental, and socio-economic impacts (Maslin 2004, 13;
Purvis & Busby 2004, 67; Struck 2007, A03).
       The IPCC has issued four Assessment Reports: the first (1990) and second (1995) reports
“laid the groundwork for the Kyoto Protocol” (Borenstein 2007, 1; Smith, Lennon, & Mix 2007,
96). The third report (2001) provided much stronger evidence of a warming Earth, highlighting
the role of GHG emissions, and stating that global warming was “likely caused by human
activity” (Borenstein 2007, 1; Smith, Lennon, & Mix 2007, 96). This report predicted that if
current trends continued, the concentration of GHGs in the atmosphere would double by the end
of the century (Yamin 2005, xxxvi). The fourth report (2007) confirmed that global warming is
“very likely man-made” (Borenstein 2007, 1). There is more than 90% certainty that climate
change is being caused by an anthropogenic enhanced greenhouse effect (Maslin 2004, 15;
Smith, Lennon, & Mix 2007, 96).
       From this brief historic review, we can conclude that we live in a moment in time when
the need to regulate and reduce GHG emissions, especially CO2, has become an urgent task.
Global climate change is real and is happening right now.
       Despite all the scientific evidence collected to support the global warming hypothesis,
there is still a great deal of uncertainty regarding the consequences. The degree of uncertainty is
enhanced even further since it is not just a scientific issue, but an issue that involves Economics,
Sociology, Geopolitics, local Politics, and our choices as consumers and inhabitants of the Earth
(Maslin 2004, 1).

                                                                                                 50
Since global climate change is such a complex issue and it involves the participation of
every country, every industry, and every individual in the world, it also needs a varied set of
environmental policy instruments. Global climate change will not be solved or mitigated by a
single type of policy instrument. We need to use different instruments for different situations and
sometimes what is needed is a combination of instruments. That is why it is so important to have
a broad view and a wide range of instruments from which to choose.
       As we have seen throughout this paper, voluntary and mandatory environmental policy
instruments have positive and negative characteristics. It is impossible to find an environmental
policy instrument that does not have at least one disadvantage. The challenge here is to try to
solve as many obstacles as possible and, at the same time, harness the positive elements and start
working on their application. It is also important to point out that mandatory and voluntary
policy instruments are not exclusive, rather, they complement each other.
       One of the most immediate issues that must be negotiated and resolved involves the
international distribution of responsibility for reducing GHGs and its associated costs
(Shogren & Toman 2001, 40). It is generally accepted that developed and developing countries
have differentiated responsibilities and capabilities.
       Developing countries are relatively more vulnerable to global climate change and will
generally suffer more from its adverse impacts; have less financial and technical capacity
(limited response capacities) for mitigating GHGs; and have more pressing needs (potable water
and   food    supplies)   than    developed     countries   (Campbell   &    Weitz   2007,    106;
Shogren & Toman 2001, 40). In short, “developing countries will be most affected by the
struggle for food, energy, and water as they lack the resources and capacity to quickly adapt to
climate change” (Lee 2007, 39).
       On the other hand, developed countries - which have historically emitted most of the
man-made GHGs causing global climate change - “appear better positioned to cope with at least
the early consequences of modest climate change” (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106; Maslin 2004,
13). Thus, since developed countries bear a greater historical responsibility for the emission of
GHGs and have greater capacity to take action, they are expected to take the lead in combating
global climate change (Danish 2007, 10). That is why if developed countries want developing
countries to share the burden of reducing GHG emissions, they have the moral and ethical
responsibility of assisting them, by providing scientific and technological assistance, so they can

                                                                                                51
manage     the   climate    change    challenge    in    an   effective    and   affordable    way
(Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106).
       Having said that, it is also true that “even if anthropogenic emissions of CO2 are
stabilized or even reduced, the CO2 content in the atmosphere is still expected to increase over
the next 100 years” (Maslin 2004, 75).
       Unfortunately, many countries use this statement as an excuse to avoid taking action,
instead of realizing that it underlines the reality that we do not have the luxury of waiting to see
the full implication of climate change before taking action (Shogren & Toman 2001, 37). We
must put uncertainty aside and act now to do everything possible to reduce GHG emissions and
try to lessen the burden of the consequences and the effects on future generations
(Maslin 2004, 36).
       In the words of British economist Sir Nicholas Stern, “the cost of taking tough measures
to curb pollution will be repaid in the long run” (Struck 2007, A03).
       While it is true that industrialized countries are responsible for the greatest share of past
and current emissions, increased contributions from developing countries are projected to match
the industrialized countries’ current levels somewhere around 2020 (Yamin 2005, xxxvi).
       The CDM is already being implemented in over 50 developing countries under the legal
authority of the COP (Yamin 2005, xxix).
       Despite the fact that the scale of the CDM market is considerably smaller than originally
hoped and expected, it seems likely that the CDM will have an important role in international
climate regimes aimed at reducing GHGs emissions in the future (Kenber 2005, 264).
       Mexico is ranked as the 14th global emitter of GHGs and it has a significant potential for
developing policies and using environmental policy instruments to reduce such emissions
(Bancomext, 2007).
       According to the Kyoto Protocol, non-Annex I Parties are not responsible for reducing
their GHG emissions during the first period of operation (2008-2012) (Bancomext, 2007).
However, it could greatly help the global climate change mitigation efforts if such Parties began
taking steps towards reducing their GHG emissions in a voluntary way or through a partnership
with Annex I and Annex II Parties.




                                                                                                 52
I believe that it is in the best interest of the worldwide efforts to mitigate global climate
change, for Mexico to continue using the CDM as an environmental policy instrument that will
help the country attract foreign investment for development purposes and, at the same time,
contribute to the reduction of GHGs. Even though Mexico is a non-Annex I Party and thus is not
required to comply with quantitative obligations, it has demonstrated an interest in CDM projects
(Echegoyen 2007, 49). Furthermore, it has the political will and the needed financial and
governmental institutions to pursue this task (Bancomext, 2007). For instance, Mexico is the first
non-Annex I Party that will turn in its Third National Report to the UNFCCC; it is responsible
for granting letters of approval for CDM activity projects; the Mexican Bank for Foreign Trade
is the first Mexican financial institution to open a line of credit with Japan for the sole purpose of
financing CDM projects; and it has the ability of using its business strategy component to
identify CDM projects easily and offer solutions for its financing component (Bancomext, 2007).
       Such positive results in management and promotion of CDM projects provide excellent
proof that this mechanism has great potential and promise (Echegoyen 2007, 49). However,
Mexico must work hard to improve its institutional deficiencies. While I have not spent time
describing Mexico’s institutional deficiencies, I should mention that Mexico needs to address
and resolve such deficiencies, for the country to move forward. For instance, it needs to develop
specific sustainability criteria for CDM projects (Echegoyen 2007, 49). Additionally, it must also
continue to work to remove legal obstacles and diversify the type of projects and partners in
CDM projects (Echegoyen 2007, 49).
       The Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources (SEMARNAT) is directing
resources for policies in the Ministries of Energy, Economics, and Social Development in
support of the goals of the Climate Change Commission (Echegoyen 2007, 49). This proves
Mexico’s commitment to increase the establishment of CDM projects (Echegoyen 2007, 49). It
is important to mention that there are many countries that have ratified Kyoto and still have not
been able to enjoy the benefits offered by flexible mechanisms, because they lack the structural
organization needed for CDM projects to begin operations (Echegoyen 2007, 49). Fortunately,
this is not true in Mexico.
       FOMECAR represents a trustworthy and legitimate entity, since it closely monitors
operations to avoid trade offs and special interests to permeate. It coordinates and links the
objectives and goals of the Mexican government, Mexican businesses, and international

                                                                                                   53
businesses, with those of the Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources
(SEMARNAT) and the country’s involvement in CDM projects, ensuring honesty and lack of
corruption. That is precisely why the partnership between the Mexican government and
FOMECAR is crucial for the successful and effective development of CDM projects in Mexico.
This partnership will help Mexico become a regional leader of CDM projects, achieve economic
growth, reduce unemployment, and provide businesses with the structural and financial
investment incentives they need to be willing to participate.
       As I write my final comments, I am cautiously optimistic about the agreements reached
on the final day of COP-13 in Bali. Among other things, representatives from 187 countries have
agreed to launch negotiations towards a crucial and strengthened international climate change
deal by 2009. This new deal will enter into force in 2013, once the first phase of the Kyoto
Protocol expires. However, as a friend of mine pointed out, Bali’s agreements are not that
impressive, since countries agreed to continue ‘talking’ about the possible commitments, instead
of formally accepting them. In other words, the current climate crisis needs more commitments
and fewer conversations!
       Bali produced a road map, an agenda, a deadline, and the realization that there is a huge
task ahead and that time is running out. According to Yvo de Boer, the UNFCCC’s Executive
Secretary, “this is a real breakthrough, parties have recognized the urgency of action on climate
change and have now provided the political response to what scientists have been telling us in
needed” (UNFCCC).
       The recent UN Climate Change Conference in Bali resulted in agreements that reinforce
the importance of the CDM. For example (UNFCCC):
       -   Governments decided that CDM funding for adaptation projects in developing
           countries would begin under the management of the GEF. This ensures that the
           Adaptation Fund will become operational in an early stage of the first commitment
           period of the Kyoto Protocol (2008-2012).
       -   Parties agreed to double the limit in size of small-scale afforestation and reforestation
           project activities. Expanding the number and geographical reach of the CDM to
           countries that have been unable to participate in the CDM for this category of project
           activities.



                                                                                                 54
Our relationship with the planet “has been utterly transformed in a short period of time”
(Gore 2007b, 51). “It is wrong to destroy the habitability of our planet and ruin the prospects of
every generation that follows ours” (Gore 2007a, 1). “What is at stake is our ability to live on
planet Earth and have a future as a civilization. I believe this is a moral issue” (Gore 2006, 298).




                                                                                                  55
Appendix


Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change


   1) Annex I Parties (41).


   2) Annex II Parties (25).


   3) Non-Annex I Parties (150).


    Annex I Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
Australia          Estonia             Italy              Norway       Switzerland
Austria            European            Japan              Poland       Turkey
                   Community
Belarus            Finland             Latvia             Portugal     Ukraine
Belgium            France              Liechtenstein      Romania      United Kingdom
                                                                       of Great Britain
                                                                       and       Northern
                                                                       Ireland
Bulgaria           Germany             Lithuania          Russian      United States
                                                          Federation
Canada             Greece              Luxembourg         Slovakia
Croatia            Hungary             Monaco             Slovenia
Czech Republic     Iceland             Netherlands        Spain
Denmark            Ireland             New Zealand        Sweden
Source: http://unfccc.int/parties_and_observers/items/2704.php




                                                                                       56
Annex II Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
Australia         European          Iceland            Netherlands       Sweden
                  Community
Austria           Finland           Ireland            New Zealand       Switzerland
Belgium           France            Italy              Norway            Turkey
Canada            Germany           Japan              Portugal          United Kingdom
                                                                         of Great Britain
                                                                         and       Northern
                                                                         Ireland
Denmark           Greece            Luxembourg         Spain             United States
Source: Echegoyen López, Mónica Paola. La “Convención Marco de las Naciones Unidas sobre
el Cambio Climático” de 1992 y la participación de México. Mexico: UNAM, 2007.




                                                                                         57
Non-Annex I Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
Afghanistan     Congo                 India            Mozambique              Seychelles
Albania         Cook Islands          Indonesia        Myanmar                 Sierra Leone
Algeria         Costa Rica            Iran             Namibia                 Singapore
Angola          Cuba                  Israel           Nauru                   Solomon Islands
Antigua     and Cyprus                Jamaica          Nepal                   South Africa
Barbuda
Argentina       Cote d’Ivoire         Jordan           Nicaragua               Sri Lanka
Armenia         Democratic People’s   Kazakhstan       Niger                   Sudan
                Republic of Korea
Azerbaijan      Dem. Rep. of Congo    Kenya            Nigeria                 Suriname
Bahamas         Djibouti              Kiribati         Niue                    Swaziland
Bahrain         Dominica              Kuwait           Oman                    Syria
Bangladesh      Dominican Republic    Kyrgyzstan       Pakistan                Tajikistan
Barbados        Ecuador               Lao People’s     Palau                   Thailand
                                      Democratic
                                      Republic
Belize           Egypt                Lebanon          Panama                  Timor-Leste
Benin            El Salvador          Lesotho          Papua New Guinea        Togo
Bhutan           Equatorial Guinea    Liberia          Paraguay                Tonga
Bolivia          Eritrea              Libya            Peru                    Trinidad       and
                                                                               Tobago
Bosnia       and Ethiopia             Madagascar       Philippines             Tunisia
Herzegovina
Botswana         Fiji                 Malawi           Qatar                   Turkmenistan
Brazil           Former    Yugoslav   Malaysia         Republic of Korea       Tuvalu
                 Rep. of Macedonia
Burkina Faso     Gabon                Maldives         Republic of Moldova     Uganda
Burundi          Gambia               Mali             Rwanda                  U. Arab Emirates
Cambodia         Georgia              Malta            Saint Kitts and Nevis   U. Republic of
                                                                               Tanzania
Cameroon         Ghana                Marshall         Saint Lucia             Uruguay
                                      Islands
Cape Verde       Grenada              Mauritania       St.   Vincent       and Uzbekistan
                                                       Grenadines
Central African Guatemala             Mauritius        Samoa                   Vanuatu
Republic
Chad            Guinea                Mexico           San Marino              Venezuela
Chile           Guinea-Bissau         Micronesia       Sao      Tome       and Viet Nam
                                                       Principe
China            Guyana               Mongolia         Saudi Arabia            Yemen
Colombia         Haiti                Montenegro       Senegal                 Zambia
Comoros          Honduras             Morocco          Serbia                  Zimbabwe
Source: http://unfccc.int/parties_and_observers/items/2704.php




                                                                                              58
References


Ahlheim, Michael and Friedrich Schneider. “Allowing for Household Preferences in Emission
Trading: A Contribution to the Climate Policy Debate”. Environmental and Resource
Economics. Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers, Vol. 21 (4), April 2002.

Albrecht, Johan. “Introduction”. In Instruments for Climate Policy: Limited versus Unlimited
Flexibility, edited by Albrecht, Johan. Northampton: Edward Elgar, 2002.

Allen, F. E. “Tennessee Valley Authority is Buying Pollution Rights from Wisconsin Power”.
The Wall Street Journal, Vol. 219 (92), May 1992.

Ardavín Ituarte, José Ramón. “How Can Mexico Take Advantage of the Clean Development
Mechanism: The Mexican Carbon Fund”. Mexico: Fondo Mexicano de Carbono, November
2006.

Barnett, Jon and W. Neil Adger. “Climate Change, Human Security, and Violent Conflict”.
Political Geography. Boston: Elsevier, No. 26, 2007.

Bate, Roger and Julian Morris. Global Warming: Apocalypse or Hot Air?. London: Institute of
Economic Affairs, 1994.

Baumert, Kevin A. and Elena Petkova. “How Will the Clean Development Mechanism Ensure
Transparency, Public Engagement, and Accountability”. Climate Notes. Washington, D.C.:
World Resources Institute, November 2000.

Borenstein, Seth. “Global Warming is ‘Very Likely’ Man-Made”. The Associated Press.
February 2007.

Bouc, Frantisek. “Czech Republic Begins Its Green Tax Process”. The Prague Post.
January 2007.

Campbell, Kurt M. and Richard Weitz. “Summary and Implications of Global Climate Change”.
In The Age of Consequences: The Foreign Policy and National Security Implications of Global
Climate Change, edited by Campbell, Kurt M., Julianne Smith, and Alexander T. J. Lennon,
et-al. Washington, D.C.: Center for Strategic and International Studies, Center for a New
American Security, November 2007.

Coase, Ronald H. “The Problem of Social Cost”. The Journal of Law and Economics.
Chicago: Vol. 3, October 1960.

Dales, J. H. Pollution, Property, and Prices: An Essay in Policy-Making and Economics.
Canada: University of Toronto Press, 1968.



                                                                                         59
Danish, Kyle W. “An Overview of the International Regime Addressing Climate Change”.
Sustainable Development Law and Policy. Washington, D.C.: The American University
Washington College of Law, Vol. VII (2), Winter 2007.

“Driving Business Accountability”. Washington, D.C.: World Resources Institute 2002-2004.

Earth Island Institute. “Strongest Official Climate Statement from IPCC”. Earth Island Journal.
San Francisco: Vol. 22 (1), Spring 2007.

Earth Island Institute. “Viva Sierra Gorda: CO2, Poverty, and Biodiversity”. Earth Island
Journal. San Francisco: Vol. 21 (5), Winter 2007.

Echegoyen López, Mónica Paola. La “Convención Marco de las Naciones Unidas sobre el
Cambio Climático” de 1992 y la participación de México. Mexico: UNAM, 2007.

Eisner, Marc Allen. Governing the Environment: The Transformation of Environmental
Regulation. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2007.

Fiorino, Daniel J. Making Environmental Policy. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995.

FOMECAR. “Mecanismo de Desarrollo Limpio: utilizando la tecnología japonesa para la
eficiencia de energía”. Mexico: Fondo Mexicano de Carbono, 2006.

Frederick, Kenneth D. “Water Resources and Climate Change”. In Climate Change Economics
and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited by Toman, Michael A. Washington, D.C.: Resources for
the Future, 2001.

Freeman, Jody and Charles D. Kolstad. Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation:
Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience. New York: Oxford University Press, 2007.

Fusaro, Peter C. and Marion Yuen. Green Trading Markets: Developing the Second Wave.
Boston: Elsevier, 2005.

Golub, Jonathan. New Instruments for Environmental Policy in EU. United Kingdom:
Routledge, 1998.

Gore, Albert. An Inconvenient Truth: The Planetary Emergency of Global Warming and What
We Can Do About It. New York: Rodale, 2006.

Gore, Albert (a). “Moving Beyond Kyoto”. The New York Times. July 2007.

Gore, Albert (b). “The Power of Truth”. Sierra. San Francisco: Sierra Club, May/June 2007.

Hansjürgens, Bernd. Emissions Trading for Climate Policy: US and European Perspectives.
New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005.


                                                                                             60
Harrington, Winston, Richard D. Morgenstern, and Thomas Sterner. Choosing Environmental
Policy: Comparing Instruments and Outcomes in the United States and Europe.
Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2004.

Hatch, Michael T. Environmental Policymaking: Assessing the Use of Alternative Policy
Instruments. Albany: State University of New York Press, 2005.

Jackson, Tim, Katie Begg, and Stuart Parkinson. Flexibility in Climate Policy: Making the Kyoto
Mechanisms Work. Sterling: Earthscan Publications, 2001.

Kenber, Mark. “The Clean Development Mechanism: A Tool for Promoting Long-Term Climate
Protection and Sustainable Development?”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A
Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom:
Earthscan, 2005.

Klaassen, Ger. Acid Rain and Environmental Degradation: The Economics of Emission Trading.
Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1996.

Kuik, Onno, Paul Peters, and Nico Schrijver. Joint Implementation to Curb Climate Change:
Legal and Economic Aspects. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1994.

Lee, Michael K. “The Day After Tomorrow Scenario: What If Global Warming Causes Rapid
Climate Change?”. Sustainable Development Law and Policy. Washington, D.C.: The American
University Washington College of Law, Vol. VII (2), Winter 2007.

Maslin, Mark. Global Warming: A Very Short Introduction. New York: Oxford University Press,
2004.

Max, Arthur. “Study: Climate Change is One of History’s Greatest Security Challenges”.
The Associated Press. November 2007.

Michaelowa, Axel. “Determination of Baselines and Additionality for the CDM: A Crucial
Element of Credibility of the Climate Regime”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A
Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom:
Earthscan, 2005.

Michaelowa, Axel. “Creating the Foundations for Host Country Participation in the CDM:
Experiences and Challenges in CDM Capacity Building”. In Climate Change and Carbon
Markets: A Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United
Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005.

Michaelowa, Axel and Michael Dutschke. Climate Policy and Development: Flexible
Instruments in Developing Countries. Northampton: Edward Elgar, 2000.

Mol, Arthur, Volkmar Lauber, and Duncan Liefferink. The Voluntary Approach to
Environmental Policy: Joint Environmental Policy-Making in Europe. New York: Oxford
University Press, 2000.
                                                                                 61
Morgenstern, Richard D. and Paul R. Portney. New Approaches on Energy and the Environment:
Policy Advice for the President. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2004.

Mufson, Steven. “Europe’s Problems Color U.S. Plans to Curb Carbon Gases”. The Washington
Post. April 9, 2007.

“New Opportunities for Sustainable Energy in Response to Climate Change”. Department of
Sustainable Development, Policy Series, No. 11, May 2007.

Nordas, Ragnhild and Nils Peter Gleditsch. “Climate Change and Conflict”. Political Geography.
Boston: Elsevier, No. 26, 2007.

OECD. Climate Change: Designing a Tradable Permit System. Paris: Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development, 1994.

OECD. Economic Instruments for Environmental Protection. Paris: Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development, 1989.

Oreskes, Naomi. “The Long Consensus on Climate Change”. The Washington Post.
February 1, 2007.

Orford, Margie, Barry Kantor, and Stefan Raubenheimer. Climate Change and the Kyoto
Protocol’s Clean Development Mechanism. Practical Action Publishing, 2004.

Painuly, Jyoti P. “The Clean Development Mechanism: Potential, Promise, and Limitations”. In
Instruments for Climate Policy: Limited versus Unlimited Flexibility, edited by Albrecht, Johan.
Northampton: Edward Elgar, 2002.

Philibert, Cedric and Julia Reinaud. “Emissions Trading: Taking Stock and Looking Forward”.
Working Paper. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 2004.

Piloyan Boudjikanian, Diana. Derechos de contaminación: opción de política económica en la
lucha por el mejoramiento del medio ambiente. Mexico: Universidad Iberoamericana, 1995.

Purvis, Nigel and Joshua Busby. “The Security Implications of Climate Change for the UN
System”. Policy Brief: The UN and Environmental Security. ECSP Report, Issue 10, 2004.

Ridley, Michael A. Lowering the Cost of Emission Reduction: Joint Implementation in the
Framework Convention on Climate Change. Boston: Kuwer Academic Publishers, 1998.

Robertson, James. “A Radical Green Approach to Taxation Could Both Reduce Bureaucracy and
Help Save the Environment”. The New Internationalist. United Kingdom, No. 278, April 1996.

Sánchez, César and José Manuel López. “Avanza México en bonos verdes”. Reforma.
Mexico: August 10, 2007.


                                                                                             62
Sedjo, Roger A. and Brent Sohngen. “Forests and Climate Change”. In Climate Change
Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited by Toman, Michael A. Washington, D.C.:
Resources for the Future, 2001.

See, Michael. Greenhouse Gas Emissions: Global Business Aspects. Germany: Springer, 2001.

Shogren, Jason F. and Michael A. Toman. “How Much Climate Change is Too Much? An
Economics Perspective”. In Climate Change Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited
by Toman, Michael A. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2001.

Smith, Julianne, Alexander T. J. Lennon, and Derek Mix. “The Race to Replace Kyoto by 2012”.
In The Age of Consequences: The Foreign Policy and National Security Implications of Global
Climate Change, edited by Campbell, Kurt M., Julianne Smith, and Alexander T. J. Lennon,
et-al. Washington, D.C.: Center for Strategic and International Studies, Center for a New
American Security, November 2007.

Sorrell, Steve and Jim Skea. Pollution for Sale: Emissions Trading and Joint Implementation.
Northampton: Edward Elgar, 1999.

Sterner, Thomas. Policy Instruments for Environmental and Natural Resource Management.
Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2003.

Struck, Doug. “UN Global Warming Report Sternly Warns Against Inaction”. The Washington
Post. November 17, 2007.

Thorne, Steve. “Small-Scale CDM Project Activities: What Is In This for Africa?”. Nairobi:
African Negotiators’ Workshop, 2002.

Tietenberg, Thomas H. “Economic Instruments for Environmental Regulation”. Economics and
Environmental Policy. London: Edward Elgar, 1994.

Tietenberg, Thomas H. Environmental Economics and Policy. USA: Pearson, 2004.

Toman, Michael A. “Establishing and Operating the Clean Development Mechanism”. In
Climate Change Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited by Toman, Michael A.
Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2001.

“Vermont Green Tax and Common Assets Project”. Project Report. Georgia: Alex C. Walker
Foundation, 2002.

Vig, Norman J. and Michael E. Kraft. Environmental Policy in the 1990s: Toward a New
Agenda. Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly, 1994.

“Voluntary Agreements: The Dutch Experience”. Green Planning Reports Newsletter.
San Francisco: Resource Renewal Institute, Vol. VII, Spring 1995.


                                                                                         63
Werksman, Jacob. “The Clean Development Mechanism: Unwrapping the Kyoto Surprise”. In
Environmental Markets: Equity and Efficiency, edited by Chichilnisky, Graciela and Geoffrey
Heal. New York: Columbia University Press, 2000.

Wiener, Jonathan Baert. “Policy Design for International Gas Control”. In Climate Change
Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited by Toman, Michael A. Washington, D.C.:
Resources for the Future, 2001.

Wilder, Martijn. “Implementing the Clean Development Mechanism and Emissions Trading
Beyond Europe”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A Handbook of Emission Reduction
Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005.

Yamin, Farhana. “Introduction”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A Handbook of
Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005.

Yamin, Farhana. “The International Rules on the Kyoto Mechanisms”. In Climate Change and
Carbon Markets: A Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana.
United Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005.




                                                                                        64
Internet

Baker and McKenzie. 2007. Baker and McKenzie online. Home page on-line. Available from
http://www.bakernet.com; Internet.

Bancomext. 2007. Mexican Carbon Fund online. Home page on-line. Available from
http://www.bancomext.com/Bancomext/publicasecciones/secciones/11348/Financiamiento.htm;
Internet.

Chicago Climate Exchange. 2007. Chicago Climate Exchange online. Home page on-line.
Available from http://www.chicagoclimatex.com; Internet.

Climate Institute. 2007. Climate Institute online. Home page on-line. Available from
http://www.climate.org; Internet.

Commission of Private Sector Studies for Sustainable Development. 2007. Commission of
Private Sector Studies for Sustainable Development online. Home page on-line. Available from
http://www.cce.org.mx/cespedes; Internet.

Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources. 2007. Mexican Ministry of
Environment and Natural Resources online. Home page on-line. Available from
http://www.semarnat.gob.mx; Internet.

MGM International. 2007. MGM International online. Home page on-line. Available from
http://www.mgminter.com; Internet.

National Institute of Ecology. 2007. National Institute of Ecology online. Home page on-line.
Available from http://www.ine.gob.mx; Internet.

Point Carbon. 2007. Point Carbon          online.   Home   page   on-line.   Available   from
http://www.pointcarbon.com; Internet.

UNFCCC. 2007. United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change online. Home page
on-line. Available from http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; Internet.

UNFCCC. 2007. United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change online. Home page
on-line. Available from http://unfccc.int/parties_and_observers/items/2704.php; Internet.

UNFCCC. 2007. “UN Breakthrough on Climate Change Reached in Bali”. United Nations
Framework Convention on Climate Change online. Home page on-line. Available from
http://unfccc.int; Internet.

World Resources Institute (WRI). 2007. World Resources Institute online. Home page on-line.
Available from http://www.wri.org; Internet.



                                                                                          65

More Related Content

PDF
Summary Durban Climate Change Conference
PDF
Kyoto and Beyond
PPT
Future energy for the present economy
PDF
US-China Joint Glasgow Declaration on Enhancing Climate Action in the 2020s
PDF
Executive Summary- UNEP Emission Gap Report 2021: The Heat is On
PDF
Understanding UNFCCC Conferences of Parties
PDF
2.1b nap sdg i frame overview june 2018 set 2
PPTX
The History of Climate Change Negotiations
Summary Durban Climate Change Conference
Kyoto and Beyond
Future energy for the present economy
US-China Joint Glasgow Declaration on Enhancing Climate Action in the 2020s
Executive Summary- UNEP Emission Gap Report 2021: The Heat is On
Understanding UNFCCC Conferences of Parties
2.1b nap sdg i frame overview june 2018 set 2
The History of Climate Change Negotiations

What's hot (19)

PDF
Recommendations For Nigerias Position
PDF
06 tp6 waste management
DOCX
Adoption of paris agreement cp.21
PDF
APP Email 7.27.05 (e)
PDF
At un climate talks, china and the us pledge to increase cooperation
PPT
responding to the challenge of climate change 101224
PDF
Draftul acordului COP21
PDF
COP26 Glasgow Climate Pact- Outcome Document
DOC
Kyoto protocol
PPTX
COP16 Road to Cancun (ISciences)
DOCX
LATESTREVDR
PPTX
History of Negotiations
PDF
UNFCCC - Position Paper - United States of America
DOCX
Cop summary
PDF
Isdr reprot final09
PDF
UC_LCFS_study_Part_2-FINAL
PDF
Defrosting cop19
DOCX
Recommendations For Nigerias Position
06 tp6 waste management
Adoption of paris agreement cp.21
APP Email 7.27.05 (e)
At un climate talks, china and the us pledge to increase cooperation
responding to the challenge of climate change 101224
Draftul acordului COP21
COP26 Glasgow Climate Pact- Outcome Document
Kyoto protocol
COP16 Road to Cancun (ISciences)
LATESTREVDR
History of Negotiations
UNFCCC - Position Paper - United States of America
Cop summary
Isdr reprot final09
UC_LCFS_study_Part_2-FINAL
Defrosting cop19
Ad

Viewers also liked (12)

PPTX
Rent to own houses and brand new houses rush for sale/affordable houses in ca...
PPTX
Single detached houses rush rush for sale/brand new houses rush for sale in c...
PDF
Pgem q4 2015 earnings slides final
DOCX
Rubrica cotidiafonos
PDF
Producción Nacional Agosto 2016
PPTX
Saneamiento
PPTX
Presentación de la Cadena Productiva de Palta
PDF
08 16 investor presentation
PPTX
Intro to Micro-Pelletizing
PPTX
anyoption - Binary Options eCourse
Rent to own houses and brand new houses rush for sale/affordable houses in ca...
Single detached houses rush rush for sale/brand new houses rush for sale in c...
Pgem q4 2015 earnings slides final
Rubrica cotidiafonos
Producción Nacional Agosto 2016
Saneamiento
Presentación de la Cadena Productiva de Palta
08 16 investor presentation
Intro to Micro-Pelletizing
anyoption - Binary Options eCourse
Ad

Similar to Clean development mechanism (20)

PPT
Cdm Overview
PDF
20081124 unctad fdi-cdm
PPTX
Clean development mechanism
PDF
CDM - A Quick Overview
PPTX
Kyoto protocol and cdm presentation
PPT
Carbon finance for beginners (Kyoto Protocol and its mechanisms; Current stat...
PPT
Understanding Carbon Credits Business
PDF
unepcdmintro.pdf
PDF
9136IIED
PDF
Center for Clean Air Policy- Eligibility Of Land Use
PPTX
kyoto protocol & its impact on india
PDF
State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2010
PPT
Carbon credit
PDF
State and Trend of the Carbon Markets
PPT
Carbon credits
PDF
Climate change mitigation Saadullah Ayaz
PPT
carbon bank
PPT
Introduction to Carbon Markets
PPT
Understanding Carbon Credits Business
DOC
Carbon Credit & Trading Whitepaper
Cdm Overview
20081124 unctad fdi-cdm
Clean development mechanism
CDM - A Quick Overview
Kyoto protocol and cdm presentation
Carbon finance for beginners (Kyoto Protocol and its mechanisms; Current stat...
Understanding Carbon Credits Business
unepcdmintro.pdf
9136IIED
Center for Clean Air Policy- Eligibility Of Land Use
kyoto protocol & its impact on india
State and Trends of the Carbon Market 2010
Carbon credit
State and Trend of the Carbon Markets
Carbon credits
Climate change mitigation Saadullah Ayaz
carbon bank
Introduction to Carbon Markets
Understanding Carbon Credits Business
Carbon Credit & Trading Whitepaper

More from Ibero Posgrados (20)

PDF
Coloquio Internacional "De la Historia del Arte a los Estudios de Arte"
PDF
Maestría en Orientación Psicológica
PDF
Maestría en Ingeniería Calidad
PDF
PROGRAMA CONFERENCIA INTERNACIONAL CONSTRUYENDO CIUDADES MÁS SEGURAS EN AMÉRI...
PDF
XXI Coloquio Internacional de la Maestría en Estudios de Arte
PDF
Especialidad en Derecho Procesal Administrativo
PDF
Maestría en Administración de Servicios de Tecnología de la Información
PDF
Posgrado del Departamento de Salud
PDF
IV Encuentro Centroamericano de Intercambio Académico en Derecho Internacional
PDF
Los signos de los tiempos en la aldea global
PDF
Maestría en Proyectos para el Desarrollo Urbano
PDF
Feria Internacional de Posgrados
PDF
Coloquio México y sus historias: miradas múltiples
PDF
40 aniversario del Departamento de Salud
PDF
Jornada de Seguridad de la Información
PDF
Conmemoración del bicentenario de la restauración de la Compañía de Jesús.
PDF
Programa Coloquio Internacional "Arte popular, artesanía y porvenir"
PDF
5to. Encuentro Nacional e Internacional de Defensoras y Defensores de Derecho...
PDF
Reconocimiento "Tata Vasco" (Foro de los Derechos Humanos)
PDF
Informe Anual 2011 de Reporteros Sin Frontreras
Coloquio Internacional "De la Historia del Arte a los Estudios de Arte"
Maestría en Orientación Psicológica
Maestría en Ingeniería Calidad
PROGRAMA CONFERENCIA INTERNACIONAL CONSTRUYENDO CIUDADES MÁS SEGURAS EN AMÉRI...
XXI Coloquio Internacional de la Maestría en Estudios de Arte
Especialidad en Derecho Procesal Administrativo
Maestría en Administración de Servicios de Tecnología de la Información
Posgrado del Departamento de Salud
IV Encuentro Centroamericano de Intercambio Académico en Derecho Internacional
Los signos de los tiempos en la aldea global
Maestría en Proyectos para el Desarrollo Urbano
Feria Internacional de Posgrados
Coloquio México y sus historias: miradas múltiples
40 aniversario del Departamento de Salud
Jornada de Seguridad de la Información
Conmemoración del bicentenario de la restauración de la Compañía de Jesús.
Programa Coloquio Internacional "Arte popular, artesanía y porvenir"
5to. Encuentro Nacional e Internacional de Defensoras y Defensores de Derecho...
Reconocimiento "Tata Vasco" (Foro de los Derechos Humanos)
Informe Anual 2011 de Reporteros Sin Frontreras

Clean development mechanism

  • 1. The Clean Development Mechanism: Mexico’s Contribution to the Mitigation of Global Climate Change Diana Piloyan Boudjikanian October, 2009
  • 2. Table of Contents Chapter Page List of Abbreviations 3 Introduction 4 Literature Review 7 1. Global Climate Change 12 1.1 What Is Global Climate Change? 12 1.2 What Causes Global Climate Change? 12 1.3 What Are the Consequences of Global Climate Change? 13 2. Environmental Policy Instruments 16 2.1 Voluntary Policy Instruments 16 2.1.1 Eco-Audits 16 2.1.2 Environmental Labeling Programs 17 2.1.3 Voluntary Agreements 18 2.2 Mandatory Policy Instruments 19 2.2.1 Command-and-Control 20 2.2.2 Green Taxes 20 2.2.3 Emissions Trading 22 2.2.4 Joint Implementation 24 2.2.5 Clean Development Mechanism 25 1
  • 3. Chapter Page 3. The Clean Development Mechanism 26 3.1 Historical Background 26 3.2 Definition 28 3.3 Requirements for CDM Projects 28 3.4 CDM Project Activity Cycle 32 3.5 CDM Project Activity Status 34 3.6 CDM Host Parties 35 3.7 Type of CDM Projects 37 3.8 Advantages of CDM Projects 37 3.9 Disadvantages of CDM Projects 39 4. The Clean Development Mechanism in Mexico 41 4.1 The Mexican Carbon Fund (FOMECAR) 42 4.1.1 Objectives 42 4.1.2 Potential Participants 43 4.1.3 Advantages 43 4.2 CDM Projects in Mexico 44 Final Comments 50 Appendix 56 References 59 2
  • 4. List of Abbreviations CDM Clean Development Mechanism CER/CERs Certified Emissions Reduction/Certified Emissions Reductions CFCs Chlorofluorocarbons CH4 Methane CO2 Carbon dioxide COP Conference of the Parties DNA Designated National Authority DOE/DOEs Designated Operational Entity/Designated Operational Entities ERUs Emission Reduction Credits FOMECAR Mexican Carbon Fund (Fondo Mexicano de Carbono) GEF Global Environment Facility GHG/GHGs Greenhouse gas/Greenhouse gases HFCs Hydrofluorocarbons IPCC Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change JI Joint Implementation NGOs Non-Governmental Organizations N2O Nitrous oxide NOx Nitrogen oxides O3 Ozone OECD Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development PFCs Perfluorocarbons PINs Project Idea Notes SF6 Sulfur hexafluoride SOx Sulfur oxides SO2 Sulfur dioxide UN United Nations UNEP United Nations Environment Program UNFCCC United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change U.S. United States 3
  • 5. Introduction Global climate change is the most urgent global environmental problem we face today. This phenomenon is no longer a distant and unknown possibility that might become a reality. On February 2007 the IPCC released its 4th Assessment Report on Climate Change and recognized, among other things, that “the scientific uncertainties of global warming are essentially resolved and that it is very likely man-made” (Borenstein 2007, 1; Maslin 2004, 1). In other words, there is no question that human activities and consumption patterns have accelerated the natural process of global warming, up to a point in which human and nonhuman worlds will not have enough time to adapt to the changes. The question now is which species will have the ability to adapt and survive; and more importantly, if human beings are among those species that have what it takes to survive in an altered and unbalanced environment. Since global climate change is a very complex problem, its solutions require a wide variety of policy instruments that combine voluntary, mandatory, legal, political, economic, and social elements, and the active participation of every country in the world. One of the many reasons why the environmental targets, established during the 1997 Kyoto Protocol, have not yet been implemented is the debate between developed and developing countries regarding their commitments and responsibilities. Developing countries argue that it is not fair for them to have to lower their GHG emissions by the same percentages as developed countries, since they emit very low volumes of GHGs and lowering them would halt their efforts for economic growth. On the other hand, developed countries argue that it is not fair for them to have to assume the entire burden of lowering their GHG emissions, since it will also be too costly for their economies. Both sides have valid arguments. However, since we are all part of the cause of global climate change and we have reached a critical point in time, we need to stop arguing and work together to implement the needed measures before it is too late. Up until a few decades ago, the usual solution for environmental problems had been the implementation of rules and regulations. However, we can no longer continue relying exclusively on regulations. We cannot afford to continue resisting the idea that market-based mechanisms can be useful when dealing with environmental issues, just because we have traditionally thought of the market as environmentally unfriendly. Neoclassical Economic Theory tells us that GHG emissions are a negative externality (an activity that affects ‘others’, without those ‘others’ paying for it). In other words, they escape the control of the market’s 4
  • 6. normal process, since they do not have a price related to them. However, these externalities can be internalized by fixing a price for GHG emissions and allowing market forces to reach an equilibrium between the price and the quantity (emitted volume) of GHGs. Market-based mechanisms have great potential of being implemented as effective environmental policy instruments and they should be considered as a viable ally and not an enemy, when dealing with global environmental problems. One such market-based mechanism is the CDM, which provides a scheme in which developed and developing countries work together to mitigate climate change. After describing the characteristics and effects of global climate change and reviewing the wide range of environmental policy instruments, focusing on the CDM, I propose that Mexico should continue using this instrument as part of its global climate change mitigating environmental policy structure. For this purpose, the paper is divided into the following sections: In Chapter 1, I will talk about global climate change and describe its causes and main consequences, since the purpose of this paper is to find the most effective way in which Mexico can actively participate in the worldwide efforts to mitigate this environmental crisis. In Chapter 2, I will describe the main characteristics and applications of the most commonly used voluntary and mandatory environmental policy instruments. Voluntary instruments such as eco-audits, eco-labels, and voluntary agreements, which allow certain discretion and flexibility; and mandatory instruments such as green taxes, emissions trading, joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism. In Chapter 3, I will describe the elements involved in the design, organization, monitoring process, and implementation of projects using the clean development mechanism. In Chapter 4, I focus my attention on the development of the clean development mechanism in Mexico. It is important to mention that the partnership between the Mexican government and the Mexican Carbon Fund (FOMECAR) is crucial for the productive implementation of this environmental policy instrument, especially in a country in which the government has not been 100% trustworthy. Finally, I provide comments about the global climate crisis, about ways to address this issue, and about the promise offered by the clean development mechanism, for developing countries such as Mexico. 5
  • 7. I hope that the information found in this paper will be useful for Mexican policymakers who want to have a better understanding of the clean development mechanism, as an effective environmental policy instrument, that can be used to address the global climate change issue. Before I continue, I would like to explain that this paper’s purpose was to obtain my MA in Global Environmental Policy, from The American University in Washington, D.C., in December 2007. That is why the information you are about to read has not been modified or updated since December 19, 2007. It is my hope to write a follow up paper, where I will be able to update the information about the clean development mechanism and give a current account on the status of the CDM projects mentioned in this paper. With hope for the future and the year 2050… 6
  • 8. Literature Review The following Literature Review has the objective of summarizing the most important characteristics and schools of thought regarding environmental policy instruments. The initial level of classification is between voluntary (eco-labels, eco-audits, and voluntary agreements) and mandatory (market-based taxes, tradable permits, and command-and-control regulation) policy instruments (Hatch 2005, 5-6). In the case of voluntary approaches, the main preoccupation is that they may not be enough to achieve the optimal level of environmental protection (Hatch 2005, 8). On the other hand, it is clear that when dealing with the choice of what is the best type of environmental policy instrument, the relevant debate lies within the mandatory policy instruments, specifically, between regulatory and market-based approaches. The choice of policy instruments is shaped by a host of criteria, including certainty of results, cost and economic efficiency, administrative feasibility (enforcement and compatibility with existing laws), robustness (effectiveness under a variety of circumstances), timeliness (capacity to provide rapid results), dynamic efficiency (impact on incentives to innovate), public acceptance, and compatibility with normative values (Eisner 2007, 16). In an ideal world, regulators would have exhaustive data on the full universe of pollutants, and the scientific knowledge necessary to set specific pollution thresholds. However, in reality, regulators work under conditions of profound information scarcity and uncertainty (Eisner 2007, 16). Environmental policy instruments can be divided into three different schools of thought (Hansjürgens 2005, 1): 1) Those in favor of regulatory approaches. 2) Those in favor of market-based approaches. 3) Those in favor of a mix between traditional regulatory and market-based approaches, as well as, new policy instruments for climate protection (CDM and JI). Regulatory instruments such as licensing, standards, and zoning can be described as institutional measures aimed at directly influencing the environmental performance of polluters, by regulating processes or products used, by abandoning or limiting the discharge of certain pollutants, and/or by restricting activities to certain times and areas (OECD 1994, 12). Command-and-control instruments have the quality of being more conventional, traditional, and direct approaches when dealing with environmental regulation (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 21). 7
  • 9. “Their main feature is that there is no other choice left to the polluter: he has to comply or face penalties in judicial and administrative procedures” (OECD 1994, 12). In the case of command-and-control instruments, the government essentially commands businesses to follow particular forms of behavior by adopting specific standards (technology and/or performance-based) and then controls their behavior through the imposition of negative sanctions. Technology-based standards mandate the use of a particular technology and are usually presented in broad terms that reference the state-of-the-art at the time. Performance-based standards, such as ambient and emission standards, establish maximum levels of pollution compatible with regulator goals. Ambient standards define the maximum levels or concentration of key pollutants that are allowed in a given area. On the other hand, emission standards establish the maximum amounts of pollution that can be discharged from a specific source (Eisner 2007, 13). This approach is based on specific limitations on the allowable discharges of polluting substances from each source, coupled with an administrative and legal system to monitor compliance with the limitations and to impose sanctions or penalties for violations. The pollution control authority must carry out a series of steps for each source: determine the rules and regulations that will achieve the given pollution control targets, establish penalties and sanctions for non-compliance, monitor them, and punish violations (Vig & Kraft 1994, 169). As Jody Freeman and Charles Kolstad point out, “command-and-control approaches tend to force firms to take on similar shares of the pollution control burden, regardless of the cost, by setting uniform standards for firms” (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 19). The advantages of using command-and-control instruments include: direct and visible response to problems, clear policy goals or standards, uniform treatment of sources, and the satisfaction of knowing that each discharger is doing its share (or the most that can be expected) to reduce pollution to desired levels. Its most important weaknesses are: that the technology- based approach is considered simple; that there is a need to collect large amounts of data in order to make judgments about costs, control techniques, and production processes; that they are considered intrusive, inflexible, and inefficient; and that these instruments may discourage innovation, since there is no reward for doing better than directed (Vig & Kraft 1994, 171-176). 8
  • 10. Market-based approaches include instruments based on economic incentives such as: pollution charges, tradable permits, market friction reductions, and government subsidy reductions (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 21). These instruments provide, for the purpose of environmental improvement, monetary incentives for voluntary and non-coerced action by polluters (OECD 1994, 13). Market-based approaches have the objective of solving the defects in the price system more directly, by putting a charge on the use of resources or on the pollution that imposes costs (environmental damage) (Vig & Kraft 1994, 177). When they are working properly, incentive instruments induce companies to respond in different ways, depending on the costs of controls, the age of the facility, the nature of the product, and the degree of economic competitiveness in the regulated industry. The result is a system that equalizes the marginal costs of control across firms and lowers the overall costs of environmental protection to society (Vig & Kraft 1994, 185). Market-based instruments encourage behavior through market signals, rather than through explicit directives regarding pollution control levels or methods. They are often described as ‘harnessing market forces’ because if they are well designed and implemented, they encourage firms (and/or individuals) to undertake pollution control efforts that are in their best interest and that collectively meet policy goals (Eisner 2007, 13). Furthermore, while market- based mechanisms do not offer a panacea, they frequently do offer a practical way to reach environmental goals, by allowing more flexibility. In other words, instead of relying on the regulatory authority to identify the best course of action, the individual agent can select the best way to meet the desired emissions reduction target. As Professor Thomas Tietenberg points out, “this flexibility achieves environmental goals at lower costs, which makes the goals easier to achieve and easier to establish” (Tietenberg 1994, 197-211). The most common market-based instruments are: 1) Pollution taxes: tax charged to a firm based on the amount of pollution it generates. 2) Cap-and-trade programs: regulators determine the acceptable level of pollution (the cap) and issue credits allowing for pollution up to the prescribed level. These credits can be purchased, sold, or saved (the trade). The most relevant advantages of cap-and-trade systems are that regulators can specify a desired level of pollution in advance, and that they can promote greater incentives for firms with a comparative advantage in abatement, 9
  • 11. to go beyond regulatory standards. “Cap-and-trade programs are the most flexible programs for emissions trading to date” (Sterner 2003, 90). Market-based instruments provide a continuing incentive to reduce pollutants, they offer more flexibility for sources, they often complement direct regulation, and they are usually more cost-effective than direct regulation (Vig & Kraft 1994, 171). In spite of these advantages, market-based mechanisms are often surrounded by controversy. Critics may shudder at the thought of purchasing the right to pollute, assuming (incorrectly) that pollution is a completely avoidable act. They are also worried that trading may not be appropriate in some cases, because it could result in higher levels of pollution in certain areas, creating ‘hot spots’ (Eisner 2007, 14). They should be used when the information needed to set source-specific standards is lacking; there is value in giving polluters incentives to develop new technologies or control methods; the marginal costs of complying with uniform standards vary greatly across polluters; the effects of the emissions do not depend much on the location of the sources; the relationship between the time of emission and the environmental effects is not very close; there is a fixed goal to be achieved; and when the number of sources involved is large enough to establish a well-functioning and competitive market with credits available to trade (Vig & Kraft 1994, 187). Unfortunately, “it is common to view regulatory instruments as mutually exclusive – one must select command-and-control instruments or market-based instruments, for example” (Eisner 2007, 15). This characterization obscures the importance of various instrument mixes. After reviewing the literature related to environmental policy instruments, it is clear that regulatory and market-based instruments need to be combined for environmental policies to achieve the desired results. It is not a question of having to choose one or the other. In other words, the most effective environmental policy will be designed using a mix of instruments (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 28). Regardless of their differences, both approaches agree on the fact that their goal is to have cost-effective environmental regulations (Hansjürgens 2005, 3). This performance can be measured by asking: is the policy meeting its goals in a cost-effective manner (Harrington, Morgenstern, & Sterner 2004, 1)? Most authors agree that until recently, command-and-control instruments have predominated because risk-averse politicians and legislators prefer instruments that involve more certain effects. 10
  • 12. The flexibility of market-based instruments creates uncertainty about distributional impacts and local levels of environmental quality. However, they also admit that this trend is changing (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 30). “Market incentives are suited to a new generation of problems and are starting to be used more widely” (Vig & Kraft 1994, 170). “The past three decades have seen a good deal of speculation and dispute over the differences between the two types of instruments” (Harrington, Morgenstern, & Sterner 2004, 10). Most authors and policymakers have agreed on the categories of such differences (Freeman & Kolstad 2007, 20-28; Harrington, Morgenstern, & Sterner 2004, 10-16; Hatch 2005, 1-9). This recognition can be the first step towards a path of mutual cooperation and combination of instruments in environmental policy design. That is, if they know what the differences are between the various policy instruments, they can decide what combination will be more effective to address diverse environmental issues. These differences are: economic efficiency, environmental effectiveness, information requirements, administrative burden, allocation, monitoring and enforcement requirements, adaptability, flexibility, cost revelation, costs of emissions control, pollution abatement costs, environmental targets, degree of pollutant mix, stimulation for technological innovation, effect on international competitiveness, source size and location, performance, and implementation and compliance. “Environmental policy could be improved by paying more attention to the evaluation of the many policy instruments that may be used, their strengths and weaknesses, and the conditions in which they are likely to be most effective” (Vig & Kraft 1994, 188). Now that we have a better understanding of the main characteristics of the available environmental policy instruments, I will now concentrate on my paper’s objective: to describe the potential areas in which the CDM can be used, in combination with other policy instruments, to reduce GHG emissions. And thus, make recommendations for Mexico to continue using the CDM to contribute to the worldwide efforts against global climate change. 11
  • 13. 1. Global Climate Change 1.1 What Is Global Climate Change? There is no turning back. Global climate change is already happening and it will continue to have more drastic effects, unless we start cooperating and working together to try to reverse the damage we have caused. The most sensible approach would be to cut CO2 emissions immediately. However, if the cost of significantly cutting fossil-fuel emissions is too expensive and would severely affect the global economy in the short term, maybe the response of the global economy should be trying to implement CO2 reduction measures, while implementing measures to adapt to the effects caused by climate change (Maslin 2004, 2 & 136). In other words, we cannot pin all our hopes on clean energy and technological fixes (Maslin 2004, 2 & 136). Climate change challenges the way we organize our society, the concept of nation-state vs. global responsibility, and our short-term vs. long-term vision, among others (Maslin 2004, 147). There is every reason to worry about the impacts of the changes now underway in the Earth’s climate system, since the rate of change is unprecedented in the history of human civilization (Barnett & Adger 2007, 640). Climate change is the intensification of the ‘natural’ greenhouse effect from human activities (See 2001, 3). GHGs control the delicate balance between the amount of radiation that is trapped and the amount that is reflected, by creating a natural greenhouse (blanket). This blanket maintains Earth’s average temperature at 35ºC making life on Earth possible (Maslin 2004, 4). The global average surface temperature is expected to increase between 1.5 and 4.5 ºC by 2100 (Frederick 2001, 61). 1.2 What Causes Global Climate Change? There is strong scientific evidence that proves that GHG concentrations have been rising since the beginning of the Industrial Revolution; and that changes in the atmospheric concentrations of such gases, especially CO2, are causing average global temperatures to increase faster than during the past one thousand years (Maslin 2004, 1, 10, & 21). In other words, if levels of GHGs continue to increase, the temperature in the atmosphere will also increase, altering the climate around the world (Maslin 2004, 7). 12
  • 14. The main GHGs are (Maslin 2004, 1 & 11-17; See 2001, 4): Water vapor – it is a naturally occurring GHG, expected to increase in the atmosphere, in response to warmer temperatures. It is entirely produced by natural processes and does not have an anthropogenic component. In other words, human activity does not directly affect its concentration. CO2 – burning fossil fuels, land use change, coal stoves, landfill sites, and deforestation. There is evidence that our actions have increased its atmospheric concentration to the highest level for the last half million years. CH4 – burning fossil fuels and agricultural wastes, rice paddies, waste dumps, land use change, and livestock. N2O – burning fossil fuels, use of fertilizers, refinery operations, and emissions from catalytic converters in transport vehicles. HFCs – refrigerants, vehicle air conditioning, electrical switching gear, and halocarbons. PFCs – aluminum, magnesium, and halocarbons. SF6 – electrical switching gear, aluminum, and magnesium industries. CFC-12 – produced by the use of liquid coolants and foams. O3 – formed by the reaction of sunlight on air containing hydrocarbons and NOx from car engines and industrial operations. 1.3 What Are the Consequences of Global Climate Change? Global climate change will very likely produce negative and positive effects on human and nonhuman worlds. In this case, I will focus on the negative impacts, since the purpose of this paper is to make recommendations to improve Mexico’s climate change mitigation measures. It is important to mention that all of these effects are estimations and predictions made by using the most advanced scientific models possible (Maslin 2004, 2). However, there is always the possibility of “potential surprises that the global climate system might have in store for us” (Maslin 2004, 2). Whatever these economic and human losses might be, the unfortunate reality is that “the poorest people will suffer the most” (Maslin 2004, 3). In other words, those in the weakest economic or political positions will have to face the first effects of global warming: “faltering water supplies, damage to crops, new diseases, and encroaching oceans” (Struck 2007, A03). 13
  • 15. Even though we accept the evidence, predicting climate change is complicated, because the global climate system has different response times and it encompasses many different factors, which respond differently when the atmosphere warms up (Maslin 2004, 21). Some of the potentially devastating effects on human society and on our social, economic, and ecological systems include the following: Global warming - the predicted increase in the global average surface temperature between 1.5 and 4.5 ºC by 2100 is expected to increase the number of fires and heat waves (Frederick 2001, 61). Weather patterns - will become less predictable, causing an increase of extreme climate events such as El Niño, changes in precipitation and wind patterns, and an increase in the number, intensity, frequency, and pathways of storms, monsoons, hurricanes, tornadoes, cyclones, floods, and droughts (Maslin 2004, 91-94). Water stress - it is estimated that approximately five billion people will experience shrinking water supplies and freshwater scarcity by 2025. The potential increase in water evaporation from plants and soil, plus the changes in rainfall, will lead to reduced runoff (Frederick 2001, 67). This will produce desertification of semi-arid lands and droughts, it will reduce crop productivity, and it may substantially affect hydroelectric power generation (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 107; Maslin 2004, 1, 2, & 94-96; Max 2007, 1; See 2001, 3). Increase in the global average ocean temperature - resulting in thermal expansion, sea-level rise, and the release of CH4 reserves (Maslin 2004, 2 & 55). Alteration of the global deep ocean circulation (Great Ocean Conveyor Belt) - causing sea-level rise and extremely cold winters in Europe and a succession of weather repercussions of the same magnitude as the Little Ice Age (Lee 2007, 39; Maslin 2004, 2). Rising global average sea-level - it is estimated that sea-level will increase between 20 and 88 cm. by 2100. This will cause small island nations to sink and become uninhabitable, coastal areas to erode and become unstable, and it will limit tourism (a very important source of income for island nations) (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106; Maslin 2004, 1 & 84-85). Expansion and contraction of ice sheets and glaciers - when polar ice caps melt and are replaced by vegetation or open water, the albedo effect is altered. In other words, the reflection of solar radiation will be reduced (since there is less ice) and more heat will be absorbed (Maslin 2004, 73). 14
  • 16. Melting permafrost - will alter hydrologic processes, increase the release of CO2 and CH4, and trigger erosion, subsidence, avalanches, and sea-level rise (Maslin 2004, 57). Threatened forests - an increase in the rate of deforestation will add CO2 to the atmosphere and will reduce the forests’ capacity to absorb existing atmospheric CO2 (Maslin 2004, 2 & 114). The composition of the forests is likely to change and they will become more vulnerable to disease and insect predation (Sedjo & Sohngen 2001, 75-77). Their weak composition will prevent them from competing against stronger species and so tree species will be lost (Sedjo & Sohngen 2001, 77). Threatened natural habitats - will result in loss of species and biodiversity, migration of species to accommodate warmer air and water, crash of global fish stocks, and the destruction of habitats such as coral reefs, mangroves, wetlands, and marine and mountain ecosystems, among others (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 104; Maslin 2004, 97-98). As a result, “a quarter of all species in these regions may become extinct by the middle of this century” (Maslin 2004, 99). Changes and possible declines in agricultural productivity - will change planting seasons, reduce crop yields, and cause food scarcity and famine (Purvis & Busby 2004, 67). Environmental refugees - the risk from sea-level rise will increase climate refugees fleeing their island nations. This will cause large shifts in human internal and cross-border migration patterns, conflict over resource scarcity in the ‘host’ country, and hostility towards the refugees (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106; Purvis & Busby 2004, 68; See 2001, 3). Human health - the absence of clean water and the extension of the ranges and seasons for mosquitoes and other tropical disease carriers will increase epidemics, outbreaks of infectious diseases such as cholera and malaria, and human mortality rates (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106; Purvis & Busby 2004, 67; See 2001, 3). 15
  • 17. 2. Environmental Policy Instruments Environmental policy instruments are divided into two groups: voluntary policy instruments, which include eco-audits, environmental labeling programs, and voluntary agreements; and mandatory policy instruments, which include command-and-control, emissions trading, green taxes, joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism, among others (Hatch 2005, 5-7). Basically, the elements that differentiate these instruments from each other are: environmental effectiveness, economic and political efficiency, implementation and compliance, administrative efficacy, and their effect on technological innovation (Hatch 2005, 8-9). The following tools represent a large mix of environmental policy instruments. Some of these instruments are already being used to design climate change policies and others are not currently linked to climate change policies. However, they may be used for this purpose sometime in the future. Let me first describe this mix and in the following chapter, I will focus entirely on the clean development mechanism. 2.1 Voluntary Policy Instruments “Voluntary policy instruments are most often non-binding and allow considerable flexibility or discretion” (Hatch 2005, 5). Furthermore, depending on the instrument involved, a different type of political dynamic might develop. They include eco-audits, environmental labeling programs (also known as eco-labels), and voluntary agreements (Hatch 2005, 5). 2.1.1 Eco-Audits Eco-audits are voluntary arrangements that provide consumers information about environmental management practices (Hatch 2005, 6). “For firms that choose to adopt specified standards for environmental management, certified participation in such programs is designed to foster better relations with customers, suppliers, stakeholders, and employees” (Hatch 2005, 6). In other words, the firm’s self-evaluation may help it reduce its ecological footprint by doing things more efficiently 16
  • 18. (Hatch 2005, 6). From the public sector’s perspective, this type of policy instrument offers environmental benefits without the high administrative costs of direct regulation (Hatch 2005, 6). The adoption of ISO 14001 by Japanese corporations is a good example of this environmental management system. The ISO 14001 certification provides significant process and structural change that has positive results for long-term environmental performance (Hatch 2005, 247). “ISO firms are more environmentally active than non-ISO firms” (Hatch 2005, 247). 2.1.2 Environmental Labeling Programs “Environmental labeling programs formulate a set of production or performance criteria products must meet if they desire to carry the eco-label” (Hatch 2005, 5). Products certified with eco-labels represent more environmentally benign production and consumption practices in comparison to non-certified products and offer consumers a choice based on environmental considerations (Hatch 2005, 5). “Eco-labels create incentives for the innovation of more environmentally sound products or production practices, by providing information upon which the environmentally conscious consumer can act” (Hatch 2005, 5). Given their voluntary nature, eco-labels are relatively easy to introduce and implement, since they are “light in terms of the amount of public expenditure, management, and oversight” (Hatch 2005, 5). Their use was recommended during the 1992 Earth Summit and have become very popular worldwide ever since (Hatch 2005, 17). Agenda 21 “explicitly states that governments should encourage the expansion of environmental labeling in order to change consumption patterns” (Hatch 2005, 17). “They seem to fit perfectly into the sustainability strategy, which has the goal of reconciling economic, social, and ecological objectives, by enabling and fostering innovation for more sustainable, resource efficient, and ecologically benign production and consumption patterns” (Hatch 2005, 17). Furthermore, environmental labeling is included in several policy papers written by the Commission on Sustainable Development and the OECD, promoting sustainable consumption patterns (Hatch 2005, 17). They are also accepted around the world as an environmental management tool, within the ISO 14000 family, that “can help accelerate diffusion of technical improvements of products” (Hatch 2005, 18 & 41). The conclusion at the 1998 ‘Berlin 17
  • 19. Conference Eco-labeling for a Sustainable Future’ underlined their role as a policy tool to promote environmentally preferable products and services (Hatch 2005, 18). Germany launched the Blue Angel program in 1978 to reduce the amount of household paint solvents (Hatch 2005, 19). This program is “a voluntary instrument managed in public- private partnership that has proven to be ecologically effective” and is considered the first environmental labeling program in the world (Hatch 2005, 21 & 246). Through the years it has improved products and promoted innovation and the diffusion of the best available technology to reduce product-related environmental problems (Hatch 2005, 40). Today, Germany, Canada, the European Union, Scandinavia, Japan, South Africa, and the United States, among others, have successful eco-labeling programs (World Resources Institute, 2007). They even founded the Global Eco-labeling Network in 1994 to foster information exchange and to represent them in international forums (Hatch 2005, 25). For example: Europe’s ‘flower label’, used by 135 manufacturers, retailers, and flower service providers; the Rainforest Alliance’s Smart Wood program, which has the Forest Stewardship Council’s certification, that the wood comes from a sustainable forest; and the Dolphin Safe label, which certifies that the tuna was caught following U.S. dolphin protection fishing methods and laws (World Resources Institute, 2007). 2.1.3 Voluntary Agreements “Voluntary agreements take a variety of forms ranging from industry covenants that are legally binding to informal declarations of intent” (Hatch 2005, 6). A voluntary agreement is defined as “an agreement between government and industry to facilitate voluntary action with a desirable social outcome, which is encouraged by the government, to be undertaken by the participant based on the participant’s self interest” (Hatch 2005, 6). Since firms voluntarily agree to certain emissions targets, this instrument is more flexible in terms of method and timing, encourages greater efficiency and innovation, and helps achieve environmental objectives at lower costs and in less time (Hatch 2005, 6). Moreover, they further trust and understanding between the government and the industry, which promotes faster implementation and compliance (Hatch 2005, 99). “The voluntary agreements between the German government and the electrical power generation industry have become a centerpiece of Germany’s climate change policy” 18
  • 20. (Hatch 2005, 118). The Netherlands has successfully used voluntary agreements to meet national environmental goals established in the National Environmental Policy Plan (Resource Renewal Institute 1995, 1). For example: the chemical industry negotiated a 90% reduction of SO2 emissions by 2010 (Resource Renewal Institute 1995, 1). In the United States, the Environmental Protection Agency’s (EPA) 33/50 Program uses the Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) data to identify potential participants to reduce 17 pollutants of the Toxic Release Inventory (TRI) (Resource Renewal Institute 1995, 1). Companies such as Intel, 3M, Dow Chemical, DuPont, Xerox, and Patagonia have also shown interest in using this mechanism to comply with environmental regulations and reach environmental goals (Resource Renewal Institute 1995, 3). After analyzing the increase in international energy efficiency due to voluntary agreements, China launched its Shandong Province Enterprise Energy-Efficiency Voluntary Agreement Pilot program in its industrial sector (Resource Renewal Institute 1995, 9). 2.2 Mandatory Policy Instruments The most common mandatory policy instruments are command-and-control regulations, green taxes, emissions trading, joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism (Hatch 2005, 6). Emissions trading, joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism are classified as ‘flexible mechanisms’ in the Kyoto Protocol and “offer market-based approaches for achieving emissions reductions across borders” (Danish 2007, 11). “The rationale for the flexible mechanisms is straightforward” (Danish 2007, 13). Since all emissions of GHGs have the same impact, regardless of their location, and the cost of achieving emissions reduction is quite varied, flexible mechanisms try to ensure that reductions will be implemented wherever they can be achieved at the lowest cost (Danish 2007, 13). It is important to mention that the acquisition of ERUs or CERs when using CDM or JI mechanisms respectively should be supplemental to domestic GHG reduction policies (Albrecht 2002, 17; Hatch 2005, 154). Before describing the characteristics of each instrument, it is important to clarify what is meant by ‘mandatory’ when referring to such environmental policy instruments. For instance, except for green taxes, these instruments are in a sense both voluntary and mandatory. They are adopted voluntarily, but once they have been adopted, the firms must abide by the rules governing each mechanism. For example: developing countries enter clean development 19
  • 21. mechanism agreements voluntarily, but once they enter them, the agreements have the force of a contract that must be honored. In the case of emissions trading schemes, polluters have a choice whether to trade or not, but once they decide to participate in the market, their participation implies contractual and legal obligations. 2.2.1 Command-and-Control Command-and-control policy instruments are divided into two groups: technology-based regulations, which “prescribe the use of specific equipment, processes, or procedures” (Hatch 2005, 7); and performance-based standards, which “specify the level of pollutant emissions allowed” (Hatch 2005, 7). Both are effective in achieving their specified environmental objectives with considerable flexibility (Hatch 2005, 7). Technology-based regulations provide greater flexibility, through the incorporation of principles such as ‘best available technology’ (Hatch 2005, 7). On the other hand, performance-based standards are more flexible, since the regulated entities have considerable discretion to choose the most appropriate method to achieve the prescribed levels of emissions (Hatch 2005, 7). On the other hand, technology-based regulations achieve compliance and oversight much easier than performance-based standards (Hatch 2005, 7). Initially, the efforts to address acid rain pollution in the United States took advantage of the command-and-control regulatory approach. However, once the quality and reliability of the monitoring equipment provided more information regarding air pollution and analytical techniques and capabilities were improved, the use of emissions trading became more feasible (Hatch 2005, 253). 2.2.2 Green Taxes “Green taxes are charges assessed on an amount of pollution that a firm or product generates” (Hatch 2005, 6). Since firms face the direct costs of their polluting activities, they have an incentive to control pollution and to choose the most technologically efficient reduction methods, in order to lower or to avoid the tax (Hatch 2005, 6). “Finding the proper level of taxation, however, is critical to the effectiveness of this instrument, because it is difficult to anticipate exactly how much pollution reduction will result from any given tax” (Hatch 2005, 6). 20
  • 22. Environmental taxes could help achieve environmental goals, foster technological innovation, and internalize externalities even if they “cannot be quantified and environmental targets are set politically” (Hatch 2005, 126). Studies in the United States and Europe have shown that taxes on energy use can improve the overall national economic performance, increase the level of employment, and clean the environment (Robertson 1996, 1). This type of tax is considered regressive, since it affects the poor in a higher degree than the rich. In other words, if the tax on household energy increases the cost of heating and lighting, the poor people would have a hard time finding ways to pay such a higher cost. However, this can be solved by equally distributing the revenue from energy taxes (Robertson 1996, 1). “In Vermont, 98% of carbon emissions come from housing and transportation and only 2% come from fossil-fueled power plants” (Alex C. Walker Foundation 2002, 1). Since the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, which relies on a cap-and-trade system, will not help to reduce Vermont’s carbon emissions, it needs to use green taxes as a more effective environmental policy measure. “Carbon or fossil-fuel energy taxes can begin to effect a gradual reduction of fossil fuel use through increasing prices” (Alex C. Walker Foundation 2002, 1). Germany’s tax reform has an ecological component that includes raising existing taxes on petroleum products (gasoline, diesel fuel, heating oil, and natural gas) and introducing a tax on electricity, as an effort to reduce energy-related GHG emissions (Hatch 2005, 127-128). The Czech Republic has started to design its green tax process in order to drive polluting businesses to switch to healthier energy sources (Bouc 2007, 1). It is hoped that the system will be in place and running by January 2008 (Bouc 2007, 1). The green tax “will affect companies with production or consumption that has a proven negative effect on the environment and health” (Bouc 2007, 1). A higher tax on coal-powered operations will be among the first green taxes implemented in the world (Bouc 2007, 1). This initial phase of the green tax will approximately increase electricity prices by 1%, natural gas prices by 3%, and raw material prices by 10% (Bouc 2007, 1). 21
  • 23. 2.2.3 Emissions Trading This policy instrument “employs the price mechanism to internalize the costs of pollution, thus encouraging both the static and dynamic efficiencies that lead to ongoing pollution reduction” (Hatch 2005, 6-7). In the case of tradable emissions permits, there is no need to predict the appropriate level of taxation required to reach emissions reduction goals (Hatch 2005, 7). Under this system, “policymakers establish an overall target of emissions allowed for an industry, area, or country” (Hatch 2005, 7). “Permits representing allowable shares of the total emissions are then allocated to each company” (Hatch 2005, 7). If firms reduce their emissions below the allotted levels, they can sell their unused permits to firms whose emissions exceed their permits or save (bank) them for future use (Hatch 2005, 7). Thus, if firms exceed their allotted levels, they must purchase permits from other firms or face legal sanctions (Hatch 2005, 7). There are two main approaches or regimes to emissions trading: cap-and-trade and baseline-and-credit. 1- The cap-and-trade (absolute target) approach sets a total cap (absolute quantity of emissions) measured over a specific period of time, on all emissions from the sources covered by the regime. This total is allocated between the sources either freely or by auction, in the form of a right to emit a specific quantity, usually as an allowance. After the initial allocation, sources can choose to reduce their emissions and sell their allowances, maintain their emissions, or increase their emissions, through the purchase of additional allowances. The choice to buy and sell depends on the market price of the allowances and the marginal costs of reducing emissions at the source. At the end of the trading or compliance period, the actual emissions have to be equal to the number of allowances for each source. If the emissions are greater than the allowances, they have to buy more allowances. On the other hand, if emissions are less than the allowances, they can sell their excess allowances. This approach is attractive to both policymakers and environmental groups, since they provide certainty on the environmental outcome of the trading system. The regime’s cap determines the total amount of emissions from the sectors covered by the regime, while the market determines where the necessary reductions in emissions will take place (Yamin 2005, 87). 22
  • 24. 2- The baseline-and-credit (relative target) approach does not set a fixed absolute cap on the emissions from the sectors covered by the regime. The relative target is usually set through defining a baseline, which is expressed in the efficiency of emissions in relation to the activity of the source. The same baseline can be set across a wide range of similar installations. When installations can reduce the emissions more cheaply than the market price of allowances, they will reduce their emissions and obtain allowances, which they can sell. If, on the other hand, the reduction of emissions is more expensive than the market price of allowances, they will maintain or increase their emissions, through the purchase of additional allowances on the market. In this regime, allowances are not allocated up front. Rather, they are allocated when a source demonstrates that it performs better than its baseline. This regime is usually more attractive for regulated sources, as the absolute effects of most abatement techniques are usually dependent on the activity of the installation. Any reduction in emissions caused by the installation of new technology can often easily be outdone by an increase in activity. Industry usually argues that production growth itself should not be punished, but that its efficiency should be increased. Relative targets do exactly this (Yamin 2005, 87). The 1990 Amendments to the 1970 Clean Air Act allowed the first formal public cap-and-trade of acid rain producing SO2 emissions in the United States (May 1992), between three coal-fired power plants: Wisconsin Power and Light Company (one of the cleanest utilities at the time), the Tennessee Valley Authority (one of the dirtiest utilities at the time), and Duquesne Light Co. (utility in Pittsburg) (Hatch 2005, 175). Wisconsin Power and Light Company reduced its emissions of SO2 by 10,000 pounds and sold its emissions permits to the other two utilities, who could not afford to reduce their volume of emissions lower than the legally required level (Allen 1992, A-12). This trade was beneficial because it controlled the production of acid rain and it allowed the polluting utilities to continue generating electricity, while giving them the needed time to install non-polluting technology in their production plants (Allen 1992, A-12). Emissions trading examples around the world include: the Regional Clean Air Incentives Market (RECLAIM) program for trading SOx and NOx emissions from stationary sources in the Los Angeles area, established by Southern California’s South Coast Air Quality Management District (Hatch 2005, 12 & 171); the Stratospheric Ozone Protection Program’s marketable 23
  • 25. permit system for U.S. producers and importers of CFCs (Hatch 2005, 174); Oregon Energy’s program to reduce and trade CO2 emissions in energy generating and non-generating facilities (Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 16); the program in Massachusetts that limits CO2, SO2, and NOx emissions from its largest fossil-fired power plants (Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 16); Chile’s emissions trading permits from industrial point sources of particulate matter in Santiago since 1992 (Sterner 2003, 91); Denmark’s CO2 emissions trading from electricity generators (Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 14); the New South Wales GHG Abatement Scheme (Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 14); the BP Emissions Trading Scheme and the Royal Dutch Shell Tradable Emission Permit System, which regulate internal CO2 and CH4 emissions trading schemes (Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 17); the Chicago Climate Exchange’s voluntary GHG emissions trading program, targeting emissions and offsets in the United States, Canada, Mexico, and Brazil from 2003-2006 (Philibert & Reinaud 2004, 17); the United Kingdom’s Emissions Trading Scheme, considered the world’s first legislative-backed national GHG market, in which emissions from industrial energy users and electricity generators have been voluntarily traded since 2002 (Maslin 2004, 131); and the European Union’s Emissions Trading System, the largest multi-country and multi-sector GHG emissions trading system in the world, in which emissions from electricity generation and from the production of iron, steel, lime, cement, glass, ceramics, pulp, and paper have been traded since 2005 (Mufson 2007, A01). 2.2.4 Joint Implementation International JI projects received attention since the early 1990s (Kuik, Peters, & Schrijver 1994, 73 & 161). This attention increased after the signing of the UNFCCC and the recognition that they can be valuable instruments for cooperation for the reduction of GHG emissions (Kuik, Peters, & Schrijver 1994, 73 & 161). JI is a project-based emissions trading mechanism among countries with Kyoto commitments (Albrecht 2002, 17). In a JI transaction, an Annex I Party (investing country) invests in a project in another Annex I Party (host country) to reduce its GHG emissions, “presumably because the cost of achieving such reduction is lower in the host country than in the investing country” (Danish 2007, 13). In other words, two or more developed countries implement certain policies and measures ‘jointly’ and in agreement for the purpose of reducing GHG emissions with increasing efficiency, cost-effectiveness, and equitability between the 24
  • 26. participating countries (Kuik, Peters, & Schrijver 1994, 161-162). Furthermore, it is very important that the criteria for JI take into account economic, social, and environmental concerns (Kuik, Peters, & Schrijver 1994, 162). In both countries, the government and the State or a privately-owned company within the country is willing to participate in the project (Kuik, Peters, & Schrijver 1994, 73). The ‘receiving country’ transfers a corresponding portion of its assigned amount of ERUs to the ‘investing country’, which adds them to its originally assigned amount. The additionality requirement must be achieved in order for the transaction to be legally valid. This means that ERUs should not be credited to reductions that would have occurred even without the intervention of an investing Annex I Party (Danish 2007, 13). Denmark’s JI program will launch three to five pilot projects in the Baltic States (Hatch 2005, 165). The Swedish Program for an Environmentally Adapted Energy System finances projects on energy efficiency and use of renewable energy in the Baltic Region and Eastern Europe (Hatch 2005, 165). Norway’s business sector is interested in establishing a domestic permit trading system in Eastern Europe (Hatch 2005, 165). Even though ERUs have been obtained since 2000, this mechanism’s official starting date is 2008 (Hatch 2005, 155). 2.2.5 Clean Development Mechanism In the following chapter, there is an extensive review of the CDM’s history and a more detailed explanation of this flexible market-based environmental policy instrument. 25
  • 27. 3. The Clean Development Mechanism Now that we have become familiar with the mix of environmental policy instruments, we can focus our attention on the CDM, since this is the environmental policy scheme that I am proposing, as an excellent tool for Mexico to contribute to the mitigation of global climate change. 3.1 Historical Background The UNEP and the World Meteorological Organization set up the UNFCCC, regarded as the foundation for the international climate change regime (Danish 2007, 10). The UNFCCC, which was adopted in 1992 and entered into force in 1994, set an overall global framework (objectives, guiding principles, commitments, and institutional provisions) for intergovernmental efforts to tackle the challenge posed by climate change; recognized that the climate system is a shared resource whose stability can be affected by GHG emissions; and established guiding principles to balance environmental protection, economic development, and the general divisions of burdens between developed and developing countries (Danish 2007, 10; See 2001, 7). Under the Convention, governments gather and share information on national policies and best practices regarding GHG emissions; launch national strategies for addressing GHG emissions and for adapting to expected impacts, including the provision of financial and technical support for developing countries; and cooperate to find ways to cope with the inevitable effects of climate change (See 2001, 7). The countries, which have ratified the UNFCCC, are divided into three groups: Annex I Parties (developed countries that have been members of the OECD since 1992 and countries with economies in transition); Annex II Parties (Annex I Parties except countries with economies in transition); and non-Annex I Parties (developing countries, including the ‘least developed’ countries) (Danish 2007, 10-11; Echegoyen 2007, 5-6; See 2001, 7). See the Appendix for a detailed list of countries. The COP is the Convention’s main policy-making body (Yamin 2005, xxxix). It meets annually and provides the chief forum for international discussions about climate change (Yamin 2005, xxxix). 26
  • 28. The Kyoto Protocol, which was drafted during COP-3 in Kyoto (1997) and entered into force in 2005, is the most ambitious UNFCCC legally binding international treaty for the limitation of GHG emissions (Hatch 2005, 153; Maslin 2004, 118). The Protocol established differentiated commitments for the Parties (Yamin 2005, xxxix). Annex I Parties are legally bound to adopt quantitative reduction targets for GHG emissions (Albrecht 2002, 1). Specifically, they are required to reduce (cap) the emitted volume of six GHGs (CO2, CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs, and SF6) by an average of 5.2% below 1990 emissions levels (1995 for the last three gases) during the 2008-2012 budget period (Maslin 2004, 118; See 2001, 8). Annex I Parties can meet such targets by reducing domestic emissions from the industrial, energy, services, transportation, household, and agricultural sectors, through technological innovations; by taking action through domestic forest actions such as afforestation (planting trees for commercial purposes on land that is not a forest or has not been one for a long time) and reforestation (reestablishment of existing forests and woodlands which have been depleted); and by using the newly proposed flexible market-based mechanisms: emissions trading, joint implementation, and the clean development mechanism (Albrecht 2002, 1-2; Echegoyen 2007, 7-10). It also established that non-Annex I Parties were not obligated to adopt quantitative commitments for the reduction of GHG emissions (Wiener 2001, 205). However, they must comply with the general commitments of every Party: registration of the inventory of national emissions, the adoption of climate change policies, the development of research projects, and the establishment of global climate change education campaigns (Echegoyen 2007, 7-10). “The negotiation of the Kyoto Protocol to the UNFCCC represented a significant development in international environmental policy” (Toman 2001, 216). Annex I Parties agreed to numerical GHG emissions targets and participants also agreed that the development and implementation of flexibility mechanisms provided an excellent opportunity for reducing overall compliance costs, by investing in cost-effective emissions reduction or sequestration projects in other countries (Danish 2007, 13; See 2001, 7; Toman 2001, 216). Concrete rules and guidelines on the CDM were laid out in 2001 during COP-7 in Marrakesh (Hatch 2005, 151). 27
  • 29. 3.2 Definition The CDM has attracted worldwide interest “since it has become the most globalized element of the Kyoto Protocol” (Baumert & Petkova 2000, 1) to address the reduction and mitigation of global climate change. It is known as the ‘Kyoto surprise’ because the consensus on the final proposal text was reached with unprecedented speed and because it was central for the final outcome of the Kyoto Protocol (Werksman 2000, 218). The CDM, defined in Article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol, is a project-based mechanism that creates CERs through the reduction of GHGs (CO2, CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs, and SF6) against a project baseline of a business-as-usual scenario (Hatch 2005, 153). It allows Annex I Parties to invest in and implement projects that reduce GHG emissions in non-Annex I Parties, creating CERs that are transferred to Annex I Parties, which use them to comply with emissions limits established by the Kyoto Protocol (See 2001, 8; Toman 2001, 216-217). The CDM allows developed and developing countries to become partners and work together to reduce GHG emissions (Echegoyen 2007, 11). Developed countries contribute by investing resources in GHG mitigation projects and developing countries contribute by hosting such projects. CDM projects started in 2000 and are carried out in sectors of great demand and consumption, such as: energy production (improving its efficiency in use and consumption), solid waste management (burning of biogas in the landfills), management of animal manure (capture and burning of methane), and in the destruction of by-product gases from industrial chemical processes (HFC23), among others (Echegoyen 2007, iii; Toman 2001, 217). 3.3 Requirements for CDM Projects The main requirements are the reduction of GHG emissions and the achievement of sustainable development goals in the host Party. The implementation of CDM projects requires the establishment of an appropriate international legal framework with regulations for operating the mechanism. Article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol, the Marrakesh Accords, and the CDM Executive Board have established such a framework, that includes rules for defining, measuring, and certifying CERs; compliance mechanisms and sanctions for the misuse of CERs; and a clear definition of the benefit distribution and the authority of the developing countries (Toman 2001, 218; Wilder 2005, 246). 28
  • 30. In order for CDM projects to be successful, they require public-private partnerships, active participation of local communities, and cooperation with governments (Baumert & Petkova 2000, 1). Additionally, they need to embrace emerging global norms, hold decision makers accountable, include safeguards against corruption, and ensure transparency (Baumert & Petkova 2000, 1). Even before the proper beginning of CDM projects, they must comply with the following requirements (Hatch 2005, 155-156; Toman 2001, 217-218; Werksman 2000, 218, 224, & 225): 1. Participation cannot be forced on any country (Michaelowa 2005, 291). In other words, the degree of participation is voluntary and approved by each Party involved (Danish 2007, 14; Michaelowa 2005, 291). 2. Project participants are encouraged to use pre-approved, transparent, efficient, accountable, and practicable methodologies (Danish 2007, 14). If new methodologies are proposed, the Methodology Panel must review and approve them prior to their implementation (Danish 2007, 14). Moreover, they are required to provide written clarification of their respective roles and of the distribution of CERs arising from the project (Yamin 2005, 31). 3. Host Parties must ratify the Kyoto Protocol, establish an effective institutional and legal framework for approving the projects, and must give affirmation that the project activity meets its own sustainable development goals (Kenber 2005, 265-266). 4. Host Parties must also undertake an environmental impact assessment, if project participants consider it necessary (Kenber 2005, 266). This assessment is needed to guarantee that a basic set of environmental and social serious adverse impacts and major threats to sustainable development will be avoided (Kenber 2005, 266). Usually, NGOs safeguard the environmental and social integrity of the CDM process (Michaelowa 2005, 309). 5. There must be a mandatory process of public consultation (Kenber 2005, 266). This consultation is an opportunity for the public to comment on CDM projects at various stages of the project cycle (Kenber 2005, 267). This way, local communities can influence project design and ensure that their priorities will be met (Kenber 2005, 267). And, at the same time, project developers will be able to recognize community needs and 29
  • 31. gain public support early in the project cycle, avoiding delays and public opposition in the future (Kenber 2005, 267). 6. An equitable geographical spread of projects must be guaranteed (Kenber 2005, 266). In other words, CDM projects must not be concentrated in a few developing countries, with relatively more developed economies, excluding the smaller ones (Kenber 2005, 266). 7. Operation must be supervised by an intergovernment body that includes representatives of the Conference of the Parties (the ultimate authority), an Executive Board, independent auditors, and a DNA (Wilder 2005, 247; Yamin 2005, 33). These institutions should be credible, internally efficient, and adaptable. They should also ensure that the projects do not degenerate into rent-seeking or cater to special interests, without achieving real environmental protection and sustainable development. 8. The Executive Board is the main entity responsible for authorizing validated projects and project participants (Yamin 2005, 34). It must oversee the effective application of the additionality concept, approve new baseline and monitoring methodologies, certify independent auditors, provide information about distribution, financing, technical reports, and norms, monitor procedure compliance, and maintain an updated registration log and project data base (Echegoyen 2007, 17). The Executive Board meets approximately once every two months (at least three times a year) and it is integrated by 10 members from Parties to the Kyoto Protocol (one member from each of the five UN regional groups, two representatives from Annex I and two from non-Annex I Parties, and one member from the developing small island nations) (Echegoyen 2007, 17; Yamin 2005, 35-36). The members must be impartial during the decision making process (Yamin 2005, 35). Decisions are taken by consensus when possible and by a 75% majority in the absence of consensus (Yamin 2005, 38). 9. In order to facilitate and expedite the project cycle, the Executive Board has accredited a number of DOEs and has built a library of standard emissions baseline methodologies for certain types of commonly-implemented projects (Danish 2007, 14). 10. DOEs are private companies that serve as independent project auditors (Echegoyen 2007, 18). They have the responsibility of validating that a proposed CDM project meets all relevant requirements and of verifying that the project has generated reductions on an annual basis (Yamin 2005, 39). They maintain a publicly available list of projects, submit 30
  • 32. annual activity reports to the Executive Board, and provide non-confidential information from CDM projects (Yamin 2005, 41). DOEs specialize in the different sectors in which CDM projects can be developed, such as: renewable energy, hydroelectric, chemical industry, and agriculture, among others (Echegoyen 2007, 18). 11. The DNA is the governmental authority of the Parties participating in the project. It is the entity responsible for issuing the written approval that guarantees the voluntary participation of the Parties in the proposed project and for evaluating the project’s contribution to the host Party’s sustainable development efforts (Yamin 2005, 39). 12. A registry must be established by the Executive Board to ensure the accurate accounting of the issuance, holdings, transfer, and acquisition of CERs by the non-Annex I Parties (Yamin 2005, 31). 13. Since recipient Parties will not have quantified commitments, CERs will be issued when the environmental additionality principle is achieved (Hatch 2005, 155). Additionality is crucial, since “it creates the unit of the transaction for the utilization of the CDM” (Yamin 2005, 38). Thus, “CDM projects must produce real emissions reductions that would not have occurred in the absence of the project”. Moreover, they provide real, measurable, and long-term benefits related to the mitigation of climate change. 14. CERs issued between 2000 and 2008 can be used to achieve compliance during the Kyoto Protocol’s first commitment period. 15. There is no obligation for the COP or governments to provide any financing for the CDM. In other words, any financing is voluntary and may be supplemented by financing from the private sector and development banks in the case of large projects (See 2001, 8). In OECD countries, such financing is limited, since they have quotas on grants for overseas projects (See 2001, 8). 16. Financial and development additionality must be achieved. Financial resources, provided by the investor Party, complement and do not replace existing official development aid and funding through the GEF (operating financial entity responsible for matching eligible projects in developing countries with funds provided by developed countries). (Kenber 2005, 266-267). Furthermore, non-Annex I Parties must be encouraged to follow long-term GHG emissions reduction paths without unacceptably restricting their development path (Kenber 2005, 266-267). 31
  • 33. 17. Parties in non-compliance with these requirements will not be eligible to take advantage of the flexibility mechanisms provided by the Kyoto Protocol. Additionally, non-Annex I Parties must consider the project’s contributions to their countries, before deciding to host a specific CDM project. Such contributions include: global climate change mitigation, sustainability of the local environment, durability of the balance of payments and the macroeconomic plan, development of national technology and technological autonomy, poverty mitigation, and regional, social, and economic development (Kenber 2005, 271; Wilder 2005, 255). 3.4 CDM Project Activity Cycle Each CDM project must go through the following operational stages, defined by the COP (Toman 2001, 216): 1. Identification – identification of a viable project, assessment of its potential net GHG emissions reduction and its economic and social effects, and the determination of its financing source. 2. Development of the Project Design Document – there is a specific template which contains critical information about the project (Danish 2007, 14). This document includes a general description of the project activity; it describes the application of the project’s baseline methodology (the estimated allowable CERs); it specifies the duration of the project activity and its crediting period; it describes the type of monitoring methodology and plan that will be used; it verifies the project’s approval by the receiving Party; it estimates the reduction of GHG emissions by sources and the environmental impacts associated with such reductions; and finally, it contains comments from the participating stakeholders (Echegoyen 2007, Annex F). Project developers are in charge of understanding the technical options for reductions of GHGs and their costs (Echegoyen 2007, 18; Michaelowa 2005, 308). Moreover, they should be able to apply a monitoring methodology once the project starts operating (Echegoyen 2007, 18; Michaelowa 2005, 308). 3. Accreditation and Validation – a DOE independently reviews and evaluates the Project Design Document in order to verify its compliance with CDM requirements and start the 32
  • 34. validation process (Yamin 2005, 31). The DOE must verify that the host Party has ratified the Kyoto Protocol and that the proposed project has the approval of the host Party, that it is voluntary, and that it is aimed at sustainable development goals (Echegoyen 2007, 18). If the project fulfills all the requirements, the DNA formally approves the project by issuing a ‘Host Country Project Approval Letter’, given to the Executive Board (Wilder 2005, 247). 4. Registration – once the Executive Board approves the DOE’s recommendations, it registers the project as a CDM project activity (Danish 2007, 14). This formal acceptance of the validated project ensures that all CDM projects meet the requirements, that they are subject to international scrutiny, and that they have been officially approved by the government in the host and investor countries (Kenber 2005, 270; Yamin 2005, 31). 5. Monitoring – it consists on the identification, collection, and archiving of information necessary to design and implement a monitoring plan (Yamin 2005, 32). The project participant must deliver an annual Monitoring Report quantifying the reduction in GHG emissions generated by the project (Danish 2007, 14). The implementation of the monitoring plan is a condition for the project’s verification and the issuance and certification of CERs (Yamin 2005, 32). 6. Verification – a second DOE (independent from the one that validated the project) delivers a Verification Report to the Executive Board, verifying that the registered project activity has reduced the monitored GHG emissions during the specified time period (Yamin 2005, 33). 7. Issuance and Certification of CERs – once the Executive Board accepts the DOE’s verification that the project has achieved the reduction in GHG emissions, it instructs the CDM Registry Administrator to issue the corresponding CERs into the national registry of the Annex I Party within a 15-day period (Yamin 2005, 33). CERs are calculated by comparing emissions of the CDM project with emissions of a hypothetical ‘baseline scenario’, that reflects the business-as-usual scenario. Baselines can be project specific or standardized and are determined by using three different approaches: actual or historical emissions, emissions of an ‘economically attractive’ course of action, and/or average emissions of similar projects and circumstances undertaken in the previous five years (Michaelowa 2005, 290-291). 33
  • 35. 8. Negotiation – once the project has been validated, lawyers draft the CER Purchase Agreement, in order to certify the transactions of CERs (Michaelowa 2005, 309). CDM projects may obtain CERs for three seven-year periods or for one single ten-year period (Michaelowa 2005, 309). 3.5 CDM Project Activity Status As of December 9, 2007, there were 864 registered Project Activities, 97,699,935 issued CERs, with an annual average of 185,473,153 CERs, and it is expected that approximately 1,130,000,000 CERs will be issued by the end of 2012 (UNFCCC). According to their status, CDM projects are classified into the following groups: 1. Registered (864) 2. Requesting Registration (50) 3. Requesting Review (57) 4. Requesting Corrections (39) 5. Under Review (8) 6. Rejected (46) 7. Withdrawn (8) Table 1 Registered Project Activities by Scale Scale Total Number Percentage Large 458 53.01% Small 406 46.99% Total 864 100% Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007. The Bonn Agreement of 2001 defines the distinction between large-scale and small-scale CDM projects according to the maximum output capacity of the project (UNFCCC). Industrial projects are considered large-scale and community projects are considered small-scale (Department of Sustainable Development 2007, 3). Large-scale CDM projects are defined as activities with output capacities greater than 15 megawatts in renewable energy projects; activities with 15 gigawatt hours per year in energy 34
  • 36. efficiency; or other project activities that both reduce anthropogenic emissions by sources and directly emit 15 or more kilotons of CO2 equivalent annually (Department of Sustainable Development 2007, 3). Small-scale CDM projects are defined as activities with output capacity equivalent up to 15 megawatts (or an appropriate equivalent); activities which reduce energy consumption on the supply and/or demand side, by up to the equivalent of 15 gigawatt hours per year; and other project activities that both reduce anthropogenic emissions by sources and directly emit less than 15 kilotons of CO2 equivalent annually (Thorne 2002, 6). Table 2 Expected Average Annual CERs from Registered Project Activities Host Party Percentage China 48.22% India 15.11% Brazil 9.39% Republic of Korea 7.74% Mexico 3.58% Chile 2.13% Others 13.83% Total 100% Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007. 3.6 CDM Host Parties The countries (Parties) that host CDM projects around the world are: Argentina, Armenia, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Bolivia, Brazil, Cambodia, Chile, China, Colombia, Costa Rica, Cuba, Cyprus, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Fiji, Georgia, Guatemala, Honduras, India, Indonesia, Israel, Jamaica, Lao People’s Democratic Republic, Malaysia, Mexico, Mongolia, Morocco, Nepal, Nicaragua, Nigeria, Pakistan, Panama, Papua New Guinea, Peru, Philippines, Qatar, Republic of Korea, Republic of Moldova, South Africa, Sri Lanka, Thailand, Tunisia, Uganda, United Republic of Tanzania, Uruguay, and Vietnam (UNFCCC). 35
  • 37. Table 3 Registered Project Activities by Host Party Host Party Total Number Percentage India 296 34.26% China 137 15.86% Brazil 113 13.08% Mexico 98 11.34% Chile 21 2.43% Others 199 23.03% Total 864 100% Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007. Table 4 CERs Issued by Host Party Host Party CERs (Percentage) India 32.86% China 25.77% Republic of Korea 18.16% Brazil 15.55% Chile 2.14% Mexico 1.97% Others 3.55% Total 100% Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007. Table 5 Registered Project Activities by Region Region Total Number Percentage non-Annex I Asia and the Pacific 529 61.23% non-Annex I Latin America and the Caribbean 305 35.30% non-Annex I Africa 23 2.66% Other 7 0.81% Total 864 100% Source: http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; December 9, 2007. 36
  • 38. 3.7 Type of CDM Projects If we classify the Registered Project Activities according to the type of economic activity or industry, we observe that about 50% of the projects are related to the energy industry (renewable and non-renewable); followed by projects aimed at reducing CH4 emissions from biomass used to generate electricity, animal waste disposal, and landfill chemical reactions with approximately 24%; 11% of the projects are related to fugitive emissions from fuels and agriculture; and the remaining 15% are projects related to activities such as energy demand, manufacturing and chemical industries, transport, and mining and metal production (Echegoyen 2007, 27). We can also classify CDM projects according to the type of GHG that is targeted (Echegoyen 2007, 24-25): CO2 emissions - renewable energy, industrial and household energy efficiency, carbon capture, and use of biomass to generate electricity. CH4 emissions - biogas capture from landfills and animal waste and reduction of natural gas leaks. N2O emissions - modification of chemical processes in textile production. HFCs and PFCs emissions - manufacture of coolants, fire extinguishers, and air conditioning units. SF6 emissions - manufacture of heat conductors and coolants. 3.8 Advantages of CDM Projects The most important advantages of CDM projects are (Albrecht 2002, 17-19; Danish 2007, 13; Michaelowa 2005, 305-306; Painuly 2002, 192; See 2001, 8 & 182; Werksman 2000, 226-227; and Wiener 2001, 212 & 218-219): 1. Only flexible mechanism that involves developed and developing countries. 2. Considered as the primary mechanism for involvement of developing countries during the Kyoto Protocol’s first commitment period. 3. Facilitate new market penetration or expansion for the investor company and the diversification of domestic risk in overseas markets. 37
  • 39. 4. Reductions of GHG emissions in the host Party can be traded for money or used by the investor Party to meet its own target emissions, at a lower cost, in case its companies are not successful in bidding for CDM projects or cannot afford carbon taxes or permits. 5. The investment needed to reduce GHG emissions in non-Annex I Parties may be smaller than in Annex I Parties, through the installation of advanced pollution reduction technologies. 6. Non-Annex I Parties are beneficiaries of lower fiscal expenditure, inward investments, and transfer of technology. 7. Promotion of foreign investments from Annex I to non-Annex I Parties, specifically for energy efficiency improvement and use of renewable sources of energy. 8. Effective and efficient transfer of technology, capital, and resources, without compromising aid programs to non-energy sectors and sustainability. 9. Annex I Parties can achieve compliance with their quantified emissions limitation and reduction of GHGs without actually reducing their own emissions. 10. Non-Annex I Parties will be able to contribute to the ultimate objective of the UNFCCC (stabilization of GHG concentrations in the atmosphere) through the assistance received from Annex I Parties. 11. In addition to climate change mitigation, these projects assist non-Annex I Parties to achieve sustainable development and adapt to the adverse effects of climate change (Wilder 2005, 247). 12. Provide a meaningful source for adaptation funding. In this case, adaptation is a positive spillover effect from the CDM project. 13. Promote sustainable development in developing countries, while assisting developed countries to reduce their compliance costs, by investing in emissions reduction projects in developing countries. 14. Provide financial and technological assistance, so developing countries will be able to leapfrog dirty technologies. 15. Emerging brokers, accredited monitoring agents, information exchanges, mutual funds, and other means of risk diversification are helping to reduce transaction costs. 16. Developed countries can achieve their commitments to limit or reduce their GHG emissions through cost-effective and flexible means. 38
  • 40. 17. Its innovative aspects have the potential to transform international environmental laws and the climate regime (Danish 2007, 14). 18. Non-compliance will be punished through the imposition of financial penalties, which could provide an additional source of revenue for development assistance for non-Annex I Parties (Danish 2007, 15). 19. Many experts believe that Annex I Parties are likely to rely on CDM projects as a significant strategy for compliance with their Kyoto Protocol commitments, since there is a perception of abundance of low-cost mitigation project opportunities in developing countries. 20. Since CERs are being generated in countries without a quantitative emissions limit, it would seem very possible for such countries to artificially inflate the amount of CERs (Michaelowa 2005, 305). However, this perverse incentive was addressed in the COP-7 where “a stringent body of rules was established and agreed upon to protect the CDM’s environmental credibility” (Michaelowa 2005, 305-306). 3.9 Disadvantages of CDM Projects The most important disadvantages of CDM projects are (Hatch 2005, 152 & 164; Wiener 2001, 212): 1. Potential barriers to participation because of the provisions in agreements under the World Trade Organization. Basically, they must decide if projects can be regarded as additional, even if they are incompatible with the World Trade Organization. 2. Complexity of the procedures for receiving approval by the CDM Executive Board (Kenber 2005, 264). 3. Lack of capital for developing projects in poor rural areas. 4. Lack of management skills among local people. 5. Lack of guidance on how the sustainable components should be assessed (Kenber 2005, 264). 39
  • 41. 6. To preserve environmental integrity, the CDM project cycle inevitably causes transaction costs that are higher than with JI or emissions trading (Michaelowa 2005, 306). In other words, since partners are hard to identify, each negotiation is novel, each project must be approved by both Parties, and each investor needs to monitor its own projects, transaction costs will be high. 7. Do not address the needs of areas of poverty in developing countries. 8. Do not necessarily guarantee environmental and economic prosperity at a global scale. 9. Uncertainty in the development and assessment of baselines. 10. Difficulty in formulating an operational definition of additionality. 11. The fact that host countries need to build competence to master all the steps of the project cycle, in order to be a competitive provider of CERs and avoid costly outsourcing to service providers from developed countries, represents a great challenge for many of them (Michaelowa 2005, 306). 40
  • 42. 4. The Clean Development Mechanism in Mexico Mexico, classified as a non-Annex I Party, signed the UNFCCC in 1992 and ratified it one year later (Echegoyen 2007, 7). Even though Mexico signed the Kyoto Protocol in 1998 and ratified it two years later, the fulfillment of the objectives of the UNFCCC and the development of CDM projects gained importance since February 2005, when the Protocol finally came into force (Echegoyen 2007, iii). The CDM offers developing countries, such as Mexico, a great challenge and opportunity to actively participate in climate change mitigation efforts, while taking advantage of economic, social, and environmental benefits (Echegoyen 2007, ii). Mexico has a great potential to develop CDM projects, in lieu of the fact that the environmental impact of its productive sector is still quite low (compared to developed countries) (Echegoyen 2007, iii). It is important to point out that most projects hosted by Mexico are aimed at mitigating or recovering GHG emissions, CH4 in particular (Echegoyen 2007, 45). Moreover, Mexico has the potential for developing CDM projects in areas such as: reforestation and afforestation, capture of biogas from landfills, waste water treatment, energy efficiency in industrial processes, renewable sources of energy (wind and hydropower), cogeneration of electricity, and conversion to natural gas, among others (Echegoyen 2007, 46). After analyzing the country’s political status, number of developed projects, participation in the CDM Executive Board, and the amount of generated CERs, among other characteristics, Point Carbon (a world-leading provider of consulting services for carbon markets) determined that India, China, Chile, Brazil, and Mexico are the top five non-Annex I Parties with the highest potential for developing CDM projects (Echegoyen 2007, 28). In the words of Miguel Cervantes, the Head of the Climate Change Projects at the Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources, “Mexico has an important potential, since it can take advantage of the opportunity provided by CDM projects in the oil sector and in electricity cogeneration in the private industry” (Sánchez 2007, 1). Mexico’s registered projects in 2007 have the potential of reducing 6.2 million tons of CO2 (Sánchez 2007, 1). This is 50% more than last year’s reduction and it is estimated to double during the next couple of years, with the participation of companies such as PEMEX, Cydsa, Alfa, Minera Antlán, and Mexico’s Federal Electricity Commission (Sánchez 2007, 1). 41
  • 43. 4.1 The Mexican Carbon Fund (FOMECAR) FOMECAR was born from a joint initiative between the Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources (SEMARNAT), the Mario Molina Center, and the Mexican Bank for Foreign Trade (Bancomext, 2007). FOMECAR’s main goal is to provide national companies and public entities with technical and financial support to implement CDM projects and enjoy the additional income offered by the carbon market (Bancomext, 2007). It also aims at taking advantage of the opportunity for sustainable development and environmental benefits to society (Bancomext, 2007). Considering the eligibility of CDM projects, the Mexican Bank for Foreign Trade and Nafin (a Mexican development bank that promotes modernization projects) provide financial resources through lines of credit established with development banks in developed countries, in order to provide the best possible conditions to support CDM projects (Bancomext, 2007). Such conditions include: medium and long term financing, floating and fixed interest rates, loan repayment, according to the project’s specific needs, and maximum financing amount, according to the project’s structure and particular requirements (Bancomext, 2007). In the following sections, I will mention the Mexican Carbon Fund’s objectives, potential participants, and advantages (Bancomext, 2007). 4.1.1 Objectives 1. Develop a culture of reduction of GHG emissions among Mexican businesses and local and state governments. 2. Identify, develop, and promote viable projects to operate under the CDM principles. 3. Encourage the participation of Mexican and foreign financial institutions to support competitive and equitable carbon projects. 4. Organize and carry out seminars, workshops, and training courses to develop PINs. 5. Provide the needed assistance in document preparation during the registration and certification process before the CDM Executive Board. 6. Provide technical assistance on the feasibility of CDM projects. 7. Enhance the country’s capacity to take advantage of the carbon market potential in Mexico. 42
  • 44. 8. Promote new investments in more efficient and cleaner technologies in Mexico, both from domestic and foreign sources. 9. Provide trade advice on carbon internal markets and identify potential CER buyers, in order to maximize the benefits of CDM projects generated in Mexico. 10. Promote national and international investment in sustainable projects and proper environmental management. 11. Work with the Mexican Bank for Foreign Trade, the World Bank, and other commercial banks and international financial institutions, to provide the needed financial resources to fund CDM projects and cover all the expenses related to the development and operation of such projects. 4.1.2 Potential Participants The potential participants in the Mexican Carbon Market can be divided into four groups: 1. Buyers: foreign public and private funds, commercial and institutional funds, multilateral organizations, and companies in Annex I Parties. 2. Sellers: public sector entities (PEMEX and the Federal Electricity Commission), local and state governments, and private companies. 3. Promoters: project developers, suppliers of technology, legal consultants, insurance companies, and DOEs. 4. Financial support: Mexican and foreign financial institutions, the World Bank, export credit agencies, and national and international development banks. 4.1.3 Advantages 1. Increase in the profitability and economic viability of CDM projects. 2. CERs will provide a source of additional income. 3. Direct support for environmental protection policies. 4. FOMECAR is the first North American initiative to achieve the collaboration of an environmental regulatory government entity and a first class financial institution. 43
  • 45. 4.2 CDM Projects in Mexico Even though Mexico currently has 98 registered projects, it needs to better coordinate the CDM culture and implement well organized mechanisms, in order to promote more projects to the Mexican public and private sectors (Bancomext, 2007). Fortunately, FOMECAR has the support of the World Bank’s Carbon Unit to develop methodologies to increase the establishment of CDM projects (Bancomext, 2007). On a similar note, the Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources has international cooperation agreements with Japan, Spain, Italy, Denmark, France, the Netherlands, Austria, Germany, Portugal, and Canada for the promotion and establishment of CDM projects in Mexico (Bancomext, 2007). For Mexico to obtain the Letter of Approval for CDM projects, the project’s environmental, economic, and social performance must be reviewed (Echegoyen 2007, 43). Among other requirements, the project must prove that it will protect biodiversity and reduce the negative impacts on land use, water use, and of waste management and GHG emissions (Echegoyen 2007, 43). Additionally, it must improve the country’s economy, its competitive status, and the population’s quality of life, by promoting profitable investments, generating wealth and employment opportunities, and transferring technology to improve the local infrastructure (Echegoyen 2007, 43). Mexico’s CDM projects can be classified in the following groups (UNFCCC): Animal Waste Management System (AWMS) GHG Mitigation Projects Objective: mitigate animal effluent related GHG emissions and recover CH4 and N2O emissions, resulting from aerobic and anaerobic decomposition processes, in an economically sustainable manner. Benefits: improvements in AWMS practices, improved water quality in and around the site, and reduction in odor. 1) Estado de México - registered on December 2005; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 2) Sonora - registered on December 2005, January 2006, February 2006, March 2006 (3), May 2006, and September 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 3) Baja California - registered on January 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 44
  • 46. 4) Nuevo León - registered on February 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 5) Aguascalientes, Guanajuato, and Querétaro - registered on March 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 6) Jalisco - registered on February 2006 (2), March 2006 (2), and September 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 7) Sinaloa - registered on July 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 8) Sinaloa and Sonora - registered on September 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 9) Aguascalientes and Guanajuato - registered on September 2006; other Party: none. 10) Nuevo León and Tamaulipas - registered on September 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 11) Jalisco and San Luis Potosí - registered on September 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 12) Aguascalientes, Michoacán, and Querétaro - registered in 2007; other Party: none. Animal Waste Management System (AWMS) Methane Recovery Projects Objective: mitigate and recover animal effluent related GHGs by improving AWMS practices. Benefit: reduction of CH4 emissions. 1) Sinaloa and Sonora - registered on October 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 2) Oaxaca and Puebla - registered on October 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 3) Tamaulipas - registered on October 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 4) Guanajuato - registered on November 2006 (2); other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 5) Jalisco and Michoacán - registered on December 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 45
  • 47. 6) Guanajuato, Michoacán, and Querétaro - registered on December 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 7) Coahuila, Durango, and Nuevo León - registered on December 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 8) Veracruz - registered on December 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 9) Coahuila - registered on November 2006 (5) and December 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 10) Puebla - registered on October 2006, December 2006, and March 2007; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 11) Sonora - registered on October 2006, November 2006, March 2007 (2), June 2007, and July 2007; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 12) Durango - registered on November 2006 and June 2007 (2); other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 13) Chiapas - registered on March 2007; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 14) Estado de México and Puebla - registered on June 2007; other Party: none. 15) Chihuahua - registered on June 2007; other Party: none. 16) Coahuila and Durango - registered on June 2007 and July 2007; other Party: none. 17) Nuevo León - registered on July 2007; other Party: none. 18) Aguascalientes, Michoacán, and Querétaro - registered on July 2007; other Party: none. 19) Yucatán - registered on September 2007; other Party: none. EcoMethane Landfill Gas to Energy Projects Objective: capture and destruction of CH4 from sanitary landfills, feed it to a landfill gas flare and a modular electricity generation plant, and dispose of CH4 safely and control the odor nuisance, health risks, and adverse environmental impacts. Benefits: reduction of solid municipal waste and the reduction of CH4 in the atmosphere. 1) Aguascalientes - registered on May 2006 and July 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 46
  • 48. 2) Ecatepec - registered on July 2006; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. 3) Tultitlán – registered on May 2007; other Party: none. 4) Durango - registered on November 2007; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. Methane Recovery and Electricity Generation Project Objective: construction of a covered in-ground anaerobic reactor that will use the organic material produced in the pig farm currently treated in the wastewater ponds, to produce biogas. Benefits: reduction of CO2 and CH4 emissions. 1) Altotonga - registered on September 2006, October 2006 (11), November 2006 (10), December 2006 (3), and April 2007 (4); other Parties: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland and Switzerland. La Venta II Project Objective: construction and use of a wind power plant to generate renewable electricity, which will be supplied to the Interconnected Mexican National Grid. Benefit: reduction of CO2 emissions. 1) Oaxaca - registered on April 2007 and June 2007; other Party: Spain. Eurus Wind Farm Objective: take advantage of the available wind resources to provide renewable energy. Benefits: reduction of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired power plants. 1) Oaxaca – registered on October 2006 and January 2007; other Party: none. Bii Nee Stipa I, II, and III Project Objective: generate renewable energy coming from wind resources. Benefits: reduction of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired power plants. Registered on December 2005, March 2006, and February 2007; other Party: Spain. 47
  • 49. La Ventosa Wind Energy Project Objective: generate electricity from wind. Benefits: increased percentage of renewable sourced power in Mexico’s electricity grid and the reduction in GHG emissions. 1) Oaxaca - registered on June 2007 and October 2007; other Party: Spain. El Gallo Hydroelectric Project Objective: generate renewable electricity using hydroelectric resources. Benefits: reduction of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired power plants. Registered on April 2006 and July 2006; other Party: France. Trojes Hydroelectric Project Objective: generate renewable electricity using hydroelectric resources. Benefits: reduction of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired power plants. 1) Trojes - registered on April 2006; other Party: none. Chilatán Hydroelectric Project Objective: generate renewable electricity using hydroelectric resources. Benefits: reduction of CO2 emissions and the reduction in the utilization of fossil fuel-fired power plants. 1) Chilatán - registered on May 2007 and September 2007; other Party: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. HFC-23 Recovery and Decomposition Project Objective: reduction of HFC-23 emissions by recovering and decomposing this gas. Benefit: reduction of HFC-23 emissions, which is a powerful GHG. 1) Monterrey - registered on May 2006 and June 2006; other Parties: United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland, Netherlands, and Japan. 48
  • 50. Joint Venture Project of Cogeneration of Electricity and Hot Water Objective: utilization of the natural gas and biogas produced from the on-site wastewater biodigesters to produce clean and renewable energy. Benefits: reduction in the use of natural gas, conservation of non-renewable resources, and reduction in GHG emissions. Registered on June 2006 and August 2006; other Party: none. Hasars Landfill Gas Project Objective: capture and flare the landfill gas generated through the decomposition of the organic waste disposed at the landfill site. Benefit: reduction in GHG emissions (CH4 and CO2). Registered on April 2007, July 2007, and October 2007; other Party: none. Reduction of the Average Clinker Content in Cement at the CEMEX Operations Project in Mexico Objective: reduction of the average clinker content in cement. Benefits: reduction of GHG emissions, thermal and electrical energy conservation, and industrial waste utilization. Registered on June 2007 and November 2007; other Party: none. It is estimated that by 2020 municipal solid waste and the CH4 emissions associated with it will have increased by 86% (Bancomext, 2007). Mexico could take advantage of CDM projects to reduce CH4 emissions, by attracting investment opportunities and developing new techniques to use recovered energy for further development (Bancomext, 2007). Moreover, it could take advantage of projects that reduce negative environmental and health effects and the amount of sanitary landfills (Bancomext, 2007). Fortunately, as we can observe from the prior list of CDM projects in Mexico, its current CDM projects are mostly related to GHG (CH4, N2O, and CO2) mitigation projects, that are generated from animal waste and landfills. It is also worth mentioning that Mexico’s main partner (investor Party) is the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland. Hopefully, Mexico will continue expanding its municipal solid waste management in an environmentally friendly way and will expand its scope by accepting CDM projects aimed at other types of objectives and goals. 49
  • 51. Final Comments Scientific research on the relationship between CO2 and the climate began in the th 19 century, when J. Tyndall established that CO2 is a GHG (Oreskes 2007, A15). Then, in the 20th century, S. Arrhenius began to suspect that CO2 could alter the Earth’s climate (Oreskes 2007, A15). This effect was proven by G. Callendar in the 1930s and by C. Keeling and R. Revelle by the 1960s, when they used the Keeling Curve to demonstrate that atmospheric CO2 was steadily rising (Oreskes 2007, A15). As early as 1965, warnings were being reported to governments by the scientific community: “we will modify the heat balance of the atmosphere to such an extent that marked changes in climate … could occur” (Oreskes 2007, A15). The IPCC was formed by the UN in 1988 to determine the state and implications of climate change. It predicted that global warming will trigger enormous physical and social changes, including scientific, environmental, and socio-economic impacts (Maslin 2004, 13; Purvis & Busby 2004, 67; Struck 2007, A03). The IPCC has issued four Assessment Reports: the first (1990) and second (1995) reports “laid the groundwork for the Kyoto Protocol” (Borenstein 2007, 1; Smith, Lennon, & Mix 2007, 96). The third report (2001) provided much stronger evidence of a warming Earth, highlighting the role of GHG emissions, and stating that global warming was “likely caused by human activity” (Borenstein 2007, 1; Smith, Lennon, & Mix 2007, 96). This report predicted that if current trends continued, the concentration of GHGs in the atmosphere would double by the end of the century (Yamin 2005, xxxvi). The fourth report (2007) confirmed that global warming is “very likely man-made” (Borenstein 2007, 1). There is more than 90% certainty that climate change is being caused by an anthropogenic enhanced greenhouse effect (Maslin 2004, 15; Smith, Lennon, & Mix 2007, 96). From this brief historic review, we can conclude that we live in a moment in time when the need to regulate and reduce GHG emissions, especially CO2, has become an urgent task. Global climate change is real and is happening right now. Despite all the scientific evidence collected to support the global warming hypothesis, there is still a great deal of uncertainty regarding the consequences. The degree of uncertainty is enhanced even further since it is not just a scientific issue, but an issue that involves Economics, Sociology, Geopolitics, local Politics, and our choices as consumers and inhabitants of the Earth (Maslin 2004, 1). 50
  • 52. Since global climate change is such a complex issue and it involves the participation of every country, every industry, and every individual in the world, it also needs a varied set of environmental policy instruments. Global climate change will not be solved or mitigated by a single type of policy instrument. We need to use different instruments for different situations and sometimes what is needed is a combination of instruments. That is why it is so important to have a broad view and a wide range of instruments from which to choose. As we have seen throughout this paper, voluntary and mandatory environmental policy instruments have positive and negative characteristics. It is impossible to find an environmental policy instrument that does not have at least one disadvantage. The challenge here is to try to solve as many obstacles as possible and, at the same time, harness the positive elements and start working on their application. It is also important to point out that mandatory and voluntary policy instruments are not exclusive, rather, they complement each other. One of the most immediate issues that must be negotiated and resolved involves the international distribution of responsibility for reducing GHGs and its associated costs (Shogren & Toman 2001, 40). It is generally accepted that developed and developing countries have differentiated responsibilities and capabilities. Developing countries are relatively more vulnerable to global climate change and will generally suffer more from its adverse impacts; have less financial and technical capacity (limited response capacities) for mitigating GHGs; and have more pressing needs (potable water and food supplies) than developed countries (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106; Shogren & Toman 2001, 40). In short, “developing countries will be most affected by the struggle for food, energy, and water as they lack the resources and capacity to quickly adapt to climate change” (Lee 2007, 39). On the other hand, developed countries - which have historically emitted most of the man-made GHGs causing global climate change - “appear better positioned to cope with at least the early consequences of modest climate change” (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106; Maslin 2004, 13). Thus, since developed countries bear a greater historical responsibility for the emission of GHGs and have greater capacity to take action, they are expected to take the lead in combating global climate change (Danish 2007, 10). That is why if developed countries want developing countries to share the burden of reducing GHG emissions, they have the moral and ethical responsibility of assisting them, by providing scientific and technological assistance, so they can 51
  • 53. manage the climate change challenge in an effective and affordable way (Campbell & Weitz 2007, 106). Having said that, it is also true that “even if anthropogenic emissions of CO2 are stabilized or even reduced, the CO2 content in the atmosphere is still expected to increase over the next 100 years” (Maslin 2004, 75). Unfortunately, many countries use this statement as an excuse to avoid taking action, instead of realizing that it underlines the reality that we do not have the luxury of waiting to see the full implication of climate change before taking action (Shogren & Toman 2001, 37). We must put uncertainty aside and act now to do everything possible to reduce GHG emissions and try to lessen the burden of the consequences and the effects on future generations (Maslin 2004, 36). In the words of British economist Sir Nicholas Stern, “the cost of taking tough measures to curb pollution will be repaid in the long run” (Struck 2007, A03). While it is true that industrialized countries are responsible for the greatest share of past and current emissions, increased contributions from developing countries are projected to match the industrialized countries’ current levels somewhere around 2020 (Yamin 2005, xxxvi). The CDM is already being implemented in over 50 developing countries under the legal authority of the COP (Yamin 2005, xxix). Despite the fact that the scale of the CDM market is considerably smaller than originally hoped and expected, it seems likely that the CDM will have an important role in international climate regimes aimed at reducing GHGs emissions in the future (Kenber 2005, 264). Mexico is ranked as the 14th global emitter of GHGs and it has a significant potential for developing policies and using environmental policy instruments to reduce such emissions (Bancomext, 2007). According to the Kyoto Protocol, non-Annex I Parties are not responsible for reducing their GHG emissions during the first period of operation (2008-2012) (Bancomext, 2007). However, it could greatly help the global climate change mitigation efforts if such Parties began taking steps towards reducing their GHG emissions in a voluntary way or through a partnership with Annex I and Annex II Parties. 52
  • 54. I believe that it is in the best interest of the worldwide efforts to mitigate global climate change, for Mexico to continue using the CDM as an environmental policy instrument that will help the country attract foreign investment for development purposes and, at the same time, contribute to the reduction of GHGs. Even though Mexico is a non-Annex I Party and thus is not required to comply with quantitative obligations, it has demonstrated an interest in CDM projects (Echegoyen 2007, 49). Furthermore, it has the political will and the needed financial and governmental institutions to pursue this task (Bancomext, 2007). For instance, Mexico is the first non-Annex I Party that will turn in its Third National Report to the UNFCCC; it is responsible for granting letters of approval for CDM activity projects; the Mexican Bank for Foreign Trade is the first Mexican financial institution to open a line of credit with Japan for the sole purpose of financing CDM projects; and it has the ability of using its business strategy component to identify CDM projects easily and offer solutions for its financing component (Bancomext, 2007). Such positive results in management and promotion of CDM projects provide excellent proof that this mechanism has great potential and promise (Echegoyen 2007, 49). However, Mexico must work hard to improve its institutional deficiencies. While I have not spent time describing Mexico’s institutional deficiencies, I should mention that Mexico needs to address and resolve such deficiencies, for the country to move forward. For instance, it needs to develop specific sustainability criteria for CDM projects (Echegoyen 2007, 49). Additionally, it must also continue to work to remove legal obstacles and diversify the type of projects and partners in CDM projects (Echegoyen 2007, 49). The Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources (SEMARNAT) is directing resources for policies in the Ministries of Energy, Economics, and Social Development in support of the goals of the Climate Change Commission (Echegoyen 2007, 49). This proves Mexico’s commitment to increase the establishment of CDM projects (Echegoyen 2007, 49). It is important to mention that there are many countries that have ratified Kyoto and still have not been able to enjoy the benefits offered by flexible mechanisms, because they lack the structural organization needed for CDM projects to begin operations (Echegoyen 2007, 49). Fortunately, this is not true in Mexico. FOMECAR represents a trustworthy and legitimate entity, since it closely monitors operations to avoid trade offs and special interests to permeate. It coordinates and links the objectives and goals of the Mexican government, Mexican businesses, and international 53
  • 55. businesses, with those of the Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources (SEMARNAT) and the country’s involvement in CDM projects, ensuring honesty and lack of corruption. That is precisely why the partnership between the Mexican government and FOMECAR is crucial for the successful and effective development of CDM projects in Mexico. This partnership will help Mexico become a regional leader of CDM projects, achieve economic growth, reduce unemployment, and provide businesses with the structural and financial investment incentives they need to be willing to participate. As I write my final comments, I am cautiously optimistic about the agreements reached on the final day of COP-13 in Bali. Among other things, representatives from 187 countries have agreed to launch negotiations towards a crucial and strengthened international climate change deal by 2009. This new deal will enter into force in 2013, once the first phase of the Kyoto Protocol expires. However, as a friend of mine pointed out, Bali’s agreements are not that impressive, since countries agreed to continue ‘talking’ about the possible commitments, instead of formally accepting them. In other words, the current climate crisis needs more commitments and fewer conversations! Bali produced a road map, an agenda, a deadline, and the realization that there is a huge task ahead and that time is running out. According to Yvo de Boer, the UNFCCC’s Executive Secretary, “this is a real breakthrough, parties have recognized the urgency of action on climate change and have now provided the political response to what scientists have been telling us in needed” (UNFCCC). The recent UN Climate Change Conference in Bali resulted in agreements that reinforce the importance of the CDM. For example (UNFCCC): - Governments decided that CDM funding for adaptation projects in developing countries would begin under the management of the GEF. This ensures that the Adaptation Fund will become operational in an early stage of the first commitment period of the Kyoto Protocol (2008-2012). - Parties agreed to double the limit in size of small-scale afforestation and reforestation project activities. Expanding the number and geographical reach of the CDM to countries that have been unable to participate in the CDM for this category of project activities. 54
  • 56. Our relationship with the planet “has been utterly transformed in a short period of time” (Gore 2007b, 51). “It is wrong to destroy the habitability of our planet and ruin the prospects of every generation that follows ours” (Gore 2007a, 1). “What is at stake is our ability to live on planet Earth and have a future as a civilization. I believe this is a moral issue” (Gore 2006, 298). 55
  • 57. Appendix Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change 1) Annex I Parties (41). 2) Annex II Parties (25). 3) Non-Annex I Parties (150). Annex I Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change Australia Estonia Italy Norway Switzerland Austria European Japan Poland Turkey Community Belarus Finland Latvia Portugal Ukraine Belgium France Liechtenstein Romania United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland Bulgaria Germany Lithuania Russian United States Federation Canada Greece Luxembourg Slovakia Croatia Hungary Monaco Slovenia Czech Republic Iceland Netherlands Spain Denmark Ireland New Zealand Sweden Source: http://unfccc.int/parties_and_observers/items/2704.php 56
  • 58. Annex II Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change Australia European Iceland Netherlands Sweden Community Austria Finland Ireland New Zealand Switzerland Belgium France Italy Norway Turkey Canada Germany Japan Portugal United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland Denmark Greece Luxembourg Spain United States Source: Echegoyen López, Mónica Paola. La “Convención Marco de las Naciones Unidas sobre el Cambio Climático” de 1992 y la participación de México. Mexico: UNAM, 2007. 57
  • 59. Non-Annex I Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change Afghanistan Congo India Mozambique Seychelles Albania Cook Islands Indonesia Myanmar Sierra Leone Algeria Costa Rica Iran Namibia Singapore Angola Cuba Israel Nauru Solomon Islands Antigua and Cyprus Jamaica Nepal South Africa Barbuda Argentina Cote d’Ivoire Jordan Nicaragua Sri Lanka Armenia Democratic People’s Kazakhstan Niger Sudan Republic of Korea Azerbaijan Dem. Rep. of Congo Kenya Nigeria Suriname Bahamas Djibouti Kiribati Niue Swaziland Bahrain Dominica Kuwait Oman Syria Bangladesh Dominican Republic Kyrgyzstan Pakistan Tajikistan Barbados Ecuador Lao People’s Palau Thailand Democratic Republic Belize Egypt Lebanon Panama Timor-Leste Benin El Salvador Lesotho Papua New Guinea Togo Bhutan Equatorial Guinea Liberia Paraguay Tonga Bolivia Eritrea Libya Peru Trinidad and Tobago Bosnia and Ethiopia Madagascar Philippines Tunisia Herzegovina Botswana Fiji Malawi Qatar Turkmenistan Brazil Former Yugoslav Malaysia Republic of Korea Tuvalu Rep. of Macedonia Burkina Faso Gabon Maldives Republic of Moldova Uganda Burundi Gambia Mali Rwanda U. Arab Emirates Cambodia Georgia Malta Saint Kitts and Nevis U. Republic of Tanzania Cameroon Ghana Marshall Saint Lucia Uruguay Islands Cape Verde Grenada Mauritania St. Vincent and Uzbekistan Grenadines Central African Guatemala Mauritius Samoa Vanuatu Republic Chad Guinea Mexico San Marino Venezuela Chile Guinea-Bissau Micronesia Sao Tome and Viet Nam Principe China Guyana Mongolia Saudi Arabia Yemen Colombia Haiti Montenegro Senegal Zambia Comoros Honduras Morocco Serbia Zimbabwe Source: http://unfccc.int/parties_and_observers/items/2704.php 58
  • 60. References Ahlheim, Michael and Friedrich Schneider. “Allowing for Household Preferences in Emission Trading: A Contribution to the Climate Policy Debate”. Environmental and Resource Economics. Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers, Vol. 21 (4), April 2002. Albrecht, Johan. “Introduction”. In Instruments for Climate Policy: Limited versus Unlimited Flexibility, edited by Albrecht, Johan. Northampton: Edward Elgar, 2002. Allen, F. E. “Tennessee Valley Authority is Buying Pollution Rights from Wisconsin Power”. The Wall Street Journal, Vol. 219 (92), May 1992. Ardavín Ituarte, José Ramón. “How Can Mexico Take Advantage of the Clean Development Mechanism: The Mexican Carbon Fund”. Mexico: Fondo Mexicano de Carbono, November 2006. Barnett, Jon and W. Neil Adger. “Climate Change, Human Security, and Violent Conflict”. Political Geography. Boston: Elsevier, No. 26, 2007. Bate, Roger and Julian Morris. Global Warming: Apocalypse or Hot Air?. London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1994. Baumert, Kevin A. and Elena Petkova. “How Will the Clean Development Mechanism Ensure Transparency, Public Engagement, and Accountability”. Climate Notes. Washington, D.C.: World Resources Institute, November 2000. Borenstein, Seth. “Global Warming is ‘Very Likely’ Man-Made”. The Associated Press. February 2007. Bouc, Frantisek. “Czech Republic Begins Its Green Tax Process”. The Prague Post. January 2007. Campbell, Kurt M. and Richard Weitz. “Summary and Implications of Global Climate Change”. In The Age of Consequences: The Foreign Policy and National Security Implications of Global Climate Change, edited by Campbell, Kurt M., Julianne Smith, and Alexander T. J. Lennon, et-al. Washington, D.C.: Center for Strategic and International Studies, Center for a New American Security, November 2007. Coase, Ronald H. “The Problem of Social Cost”. The Journal of Law and Economics. Chicago: Vol. 3, October 1960. Dales, J. H. Pollution, Property, and Prices: An Essay in Policy-Making and Economics. Canada: University of Toronto Press, 1968. 59
  • 61. Danish, Kyle W. “An Overview of the International Regime Addressing Climate Change”. Sustainable Development Law and Policy. Washington, D.C.: The American University Washington College of Law, Vol. VII (2), Winter 2007. “Driving Business Accountability”. Washington, D.C.: World Resources Institute 2002-2004. Earth Island Institute. “Strongest Official Climate Statement from IPCC”. Earth Island Journal. San Francisco: Vol. 22 (1), Spring 2007. Earth Island Institute. “Viva Sierra Gorda: CO2, Poverty, and Biodiversity”. Earth Island Journal. San Francisco: Vol. 21 (5), Winter 2007. Echegoyen López, Mónica Paola. La “Convención Marco de las Naciones Unidas sobre el Cambio Climático” de 1992 y la participación de México. Mexico: UNAM, 2007. Eisner, Marc Allen. Governing the Environment: The Transformation of Environmental Regulation. Boulder: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2007. Fiorino, Daniel J. Making Environmental Policy. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995. FOMECAR. “Mecanismo de Desarrollo Limpio: utilizando la tecnología japonesa para la eficiencia de energía”. Mexico: Fondo Mexicano de Carbono, 2006. Frederick, Kenneth D. “Water Resources and Climate Change”. In Climate Change Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited by Toman, Michael A. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2001. Freeman, Jody and Charles D. Kolstad. Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience. New York: Oxford University Press, 2007. Fusaro, Peter C. and Marion Yuen. Green Trading Markets: Developing the Second Wave. Boston: Elsevier, 2005. Golub, Jonathan. New Instruments for Environmental Policy in EU. United Kingdom: Routledge, 1998. Gore, Albert. An Inconvenient Truth: The Planetary Emergency of Global Warming and What We Can Do About It. New York: Rodale, 2006. Gore, Albert (a). “Moving Beyond Kyoto”. The New York Times. July 2007. Gore, Albert (b). “The Power of Truth”. Sierra. San Francisco: Sierra Club, May/June 2007. Hansjürgens, Bernd. Emissions Trading for Climate Policy: US and European Perspectives. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005. 60
  • 62. Harrington, Winston, Richard D. Morgenstern, and Thomas Sterner. Choosing Environmental Policy: Comparing Instruments and Outcomes in the United States and Europe. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2004. Hatch, Michael T. Environmental Policymaking: Assessing the Use of Alternative Policy Instruments. Albany: State University of New York Press, 2005. Jackson, Tim, Katie Begg, and Stuart Parkinson. Flexibility in Climate Policy: Making the Kyoto Mechanisms Work. Sterling: Earthscan Publications, 2001. Kenber, Mark. “The Clean Development Mechanism: A Tool for Promoting Long-Term Climate Protection and Sustainable Development?”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005. Klaassen, Ger. Acid Rain and Environmental Degradation: The Economics of Emission Trading. Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1996. Kuik, Onno, Paul Peters, and Nico Schrijver. Joint Implementation to Curb Climate Change: Legal and Economic Aspects. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1994. Lee, Michael K. “The Day After Tomorrow Scenario: What If Global Warming Causes Rapid Climate Change?”. Sustainable Development Law and Policy. Washington, D.C.: The American University Washington College of Law, Vol. VII (2), Winter 2007. Maslin, Mark. Global Warming: A Very Short Introduction. New York: Oxford University Press, 2004. Max, Arthur. “Study: Climate Change is One of History’s Greatest Security Challenges”. The Associated Press. November 2007. Michaelowa, Axel. “Determination of Baselines and Additionality for the CDM: A Crucial Element of Credibility of the Climate Regime”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005. Michaelowa, Axel. “Creating the Foundations for Host Country Participation in the CDM: Experiences and Challenges in CDM Capacity Building”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005. Michaelowa, Axel and Michael Dutschke. Climate Policy and Development: Flexible Instruments in Developing Countries. Northampton: Edward Elgar, 2000. Mol, Arthur, Volkmar Lauber, and Duncan Liefferink. The Voluntary Approach to Environmental Policy: Joint Environmental Policy-Making in Europe. New York: Oxford University Press, 2000. 61
  • 63. Morgenstern, Richard D. and Paul R. Portney. New Approaches on Energy and the Environment: Policy Advice for the President. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2004. Mufson, Steven. “Europe’s Problems Color U.S. Plans to Curb Carbon Gases”. The Washington Post. April 9, 2007. “New Opportunities for Sustainable Energy in Response to Climate Change”. Department of Sustainable Development, Policy Series, No. 11, May 2007. Nordas, Ragnhild and Nils Peter Gleditsch. “Climate Change and Conflict”. Political Geography. Boston: Elsevier, No. 26, 2007. OECD. Climate Change: Designing a Tradable Permit System. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1994. OECD. Economic Instruments for Environmental Protection. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1989. Oreskes, Naomi. “The Long Consensus on Climate Change”. The Washington Post. February 1, 2007. Orford, Margie, Barry Kantor, and Stefan Raubenheimer. Climate Change and the Kyoto Protocol’s Clean Development Mechanism. Practical Action Publishing, 2004. Painuly, Jyoti P. “The Clean Development Mechanism: Potential, Promise, and Limitations”. In Instruments for Climate Policy: Limited versus Unlimited Flexibility, edited by Albrecht, Johan. Northampton: Edward Elgar, 2002. Philibert, Cedric and Julia Reinaud. “Emissions Trading: Taking Stock and Looking Forward”. Working Paper. Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 2004. Piloyan Boudjikanian, Diana. Derechos de contaminación: opción de política económica en la lucha por el mejoramiento del medio ambiente. Mexico: Universidad Iberoamericana, 1995. Purvis, Nigel and Joshua Busby. “The Security Implications of Climate Change for the UN System”. Policy Brief: The UN and Environmental Security. ECSP Report, Issue 10, 2004. Ridley, Michael A. Lowering the Cost of Emission Reduction: Joint Implementation in the Framework Convention on Climate Change. Boston: Kuwer Academic Publishers, 1998. Robertson, James. “A Radical Green Approach to Taxation Could Both Reduce Bureaucracy and Help Save the Environment”. The New Internationalist. United Kingdom, No. 278, April 1996. Sánchez, César and José Manuel López. “Avanza México en bonos verdes”. Reforma. Mexico: August 10, 2007. 62
  • 64. Sedjo, Roger A. and Brent Sohngen. “Forests and Climate Change”. In Climate Change Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited by Toman, Michael A. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2001. See, Michael. Greenhouse Gas Emissions: Global Business Aspects. Germany: Springer, 2001. Shogren, Jason F. and Michael A. Toman. “How Much Climate Change is Too Much? An Economics Perspective”. In Climate Change Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited by Toman, Michael A. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2001. Smith, Julianne, Alexander T. J. Lennon, and Derek Mix. “The Race to Replace Kyoto by 2012”. In The Age of Consequences: The Foreign Policy and National Security Implications of Global Climate Change, edited by Campbell, Kurt M., Julianne Smith, and Alexander T. J. Lennon, et-al. Washington, D.C.: Center for Strategic and International Studies, Center for a New American Security, November 2007. Sorrell, Steve and Jim Skea. Pollution for Sale: Emissions Trading and Joint Implementation. Northampton: Edward Elgar, 1999. Sterner, Thomas. Policy Instruments for Environmental and Natural Resource Management. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2003. Struck, Doug. “UN Global Warming Report Sternly Warns Against Inaction”. The Washington Post. November 17, 2007. Thorne, Steve. “Small-Scale CDM Project Activities: What Is In This for Africa?”. Nairobi: African Negotiators’ Workshop, 2002. Tietenberg, Thomas H. “Economic Instruments for Environmental Regulation”. Economics and Environmental Policy. London: Edward Elgar, 1994. Tietenberg, Thomas H. Environmental Economics and Policy. USA: Pearson, 2004. Toman, Michael A. “Establishing and Operating the Clean Development Mechanism”. In Climate Change Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited by Toman, Michael A. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2001. “Vermont Green Tax and Common Assets Project”. Project Report. Georgia: Alex C. Walker Foundation, 2002. Vig, Norman J. and Michael E. Kraft. Environmental Policy in the 1990s: Toward a New Agenda. Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly, 1994. “Voluntary Agreements: The Dutch Experience”. Green Planning Reports Newsletter. San Francisco: Resource Renewal Institute, Vol. VII, Spring 1995. 63
  • 65. Werksman, Jacob. “The Clean Development Mechanism: Unwrapping the Kyoto Surprise”. In Environmental Markets: Equity and Efficiency, edited by Chichilnisky, Graciela and Geoffrey Heal. New York: Columbia University Press, 2000. Wiener, Jonathan Baert. “Policy Design for International Gas Control”. In Climate Change Economics and Policy: An RFF Anthology, edited by Toman, Michael A. Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 2001. Wilder, Martijn. “Implementing the Clean Development Mechanism and Emissions Trading Beyond Europe”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005. Yamin, Farhana. “Introduction”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005. Yamin, Farhana. “The International Rules on the Kyoto Mechanisms”. In Climate Change and Carbon Markets: A Handbook of Emission Reduction Mechanisms, edited by Yamin, Farhana. United Kingdom: Earthscan, 2005. 64
  • 66. Internet Baker and McKenzie. 2007. Baker and McKenzie online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.bakernet.com; Internet. Bancomext. 2007. Mexican Carbon Fund online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.bancomext.com/Bancomext/publicasecciones/secciones/11348/Financiamiento.htm; Internet. Chicago Climate Exchange. 2007. Chicago Climate Exchange online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.chicagoclimatex.com; Internet. Climate Institute. 2007. Climate Institute online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.climate.org; Internet. Commission of Private Sector Studies for Sustainable Development. 2007. Commission of Private Sector Studies for Sustainable Development online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.cce.org.mx/cespedes; Internet. Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources. 2007. Mexican Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.semarnat.gob.mx; Internet. MGM International. 2007. MGM International online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.mgminter.com; Internet. National Institute of Ecology. 2007. National Institute of Ecology online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.ine.gob.mx; Internet. Point Carbon. 2007. Point Carbon online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.pointcarbon.com; Internet. UNFCCC. 2007. United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change online. Home page on-line. Available from http://cdm.unfccc.int/index.html; Internet. UNFCCC. 2007. United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change online. Home page on-line. Available from http://unfccc.int/parties_and_observers/items/2704.php; Internet. UNFCCC. 2007. “UN Breakthrough on Climate Change Reached in Bali”. United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change online. Home page on-line. Available from http://unfccc.int; Internet. World Resources Institute (WRI). 2007. World Resources Institute online. Home page on-line. Available from http://www.wri.org; Internet. 65