SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Sample Presentation


             Macroeconometrics of
         Investment and the User Cost
                  of Capital
                                         Thethach Chuaprapaisilp

                                                  April 14, 2009




Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital,   1
Sample Slides

              Aim: Estimate the long-run user cost elasticity of business
              investment by using a general equilibrium macroeconometric
              model and cointegration technique.
              The Jorgenson (1963) ‘user cost of capital’ as the real rental
              price of capital services or the costs of holding capital:
                                     Ct ≡ Pt−1 rt + δt PtI − PtI − Pt−1
                                           I                        I

              (Interest/opportunity cost + Depreciation cost - Capital gain)
              Long-run neoclassical investment equation from the FOC of
              the optimal capital accumulation problem
                                                     ∞
                    max{Kt−1 ,Lt ,It } V =                (1 + r )−t PtY Qt − wt Lt − PtI It
                                               t=0
                            s.t.   Ft (Kt−1 , Lt ) =        Qt and ∆Kt = It − δKt−1
              implies

                     PtY FK (Kt−1 , Lt ) = (1 + r ) Pt−1 − (1 − δ) PtI (≡ Ct )
                                                     I



Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital,         2
Sample Slides



                              I                                          PtI − Pt−1
                                                                                 I
                        Ct ≡ Pt−1            r + δ − (1 − δ)                  I
                                                                                                .
                                                                             Pt−1

              Can also obtain from a durable goods model of production as
              in Jorgenson and Yun (1991) and Hall and Jorgenson (1967)
              with varying weighted average of rates of return on debt and
              equity, corporate tax rate, investment tax credit and
              depreciation allowances.
              Normalizing investment goods price by the price of output,
              PtY and assuming beginning-of-period gross investment
              (It = ∆Kt+1 + δt Kt ),

                          PtI                              Pt+1 − PtI
                                                            I
                                                                                         1 − ITCt − τt zt
              CtK ≡                rtl + δt − Et                                                            .
                          PtY                                 PtI                             1 − τt


Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital,                          3
Sample Slides

              Assuming a CES production function, Yt = (aKtσ + bLσ )1/σ
                                                                     t
              the first-order condition gives the long-run investment
              equation (in logs),

                                                  1               1
                                        kt =         ln a + yt −    ck
                                                 1−σ             1−σ t

                                       kt = α0 + yt + αR Rt , Rt ≡ ctk
              Many studies using US, UK and Canadian data obtain αR of
              around -0.4 (Chirinko et al., 2007; Ellis and Price, 2004) to
              -0.7 for total private non-residential capital stock and close to
              one for equipment capital (-0.9 in Caballero, 1994; -1.6 in
              Schaller, 2006).
              Tevlin and Whelan (2003): -1.59 for computers, -0.13 for
              noncomputing equipments and -0.18 for equipment capital in
              total.

Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital,   4
Figure: 1 U.S. data. All variables are in logs. kt is the log of capital stock for non-residential business sector
equipment and software calculated from seasonally adjusted real investment series using the perpetual inventory
method and depreciation smoothing technique of Diewert (2008). Rt is the log of the user cost of capital with the
corresponding implicit price index as the purchase price of investment goods. Rt includes after-tax real financial
cost of capital for producers’ durable equipment (a weighted average of 5-year Treasury bond yield and Moody’s
AAA corporate bond rate plus risk premia less expected inflation over 30 years) and tax variables from the FRB/US
model. The log short-term real return measure, rrpt is calculated based on the investment goods price inflation and
                                                                                   I         I   Y
multiplied by the relative investment goods price so that rrpt = [ln(1 + rt ) − πt+1 ] × Pt /Pt where rt is the
3-month CD rate net of federal average marginal income tax on interest received.
Figure: 2 U.S. data in first differences.
Sample Slides



              Estimate αR using a vector error correction model (VECM) of
              a macroeconomy here assuming a tendency for output and
              real interest rates to move towards their long-run natural
              (flexible price equilibrium) values as represented by
              cointegrating relationships.
              Follow the structural cointegrated VAR methodology of
              Garratt, Lee, Pesaran and Shin (2006) and Juselius (2006).
              Expand the two-equation VECM of Ellis and Price (2004) to a
              general equilibrium system.
              Long-run counterpart of the macromonetary framework by
              Gali and Gertler (2007). Concentrate on the long run and use
              the cost of capital instead of Tobin’s q here.



Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital,   7
Long-run reduced form equilibrium conditions provide six cointegrating relations,
     lt = b10 − b11 t + yt − β25 ωt + ξ1,t+1                                    Ld
    kt = b20 + yt − β25 Rt + ξ2,t+1                                             Investment
    yt = b30 + b31 t + β31 lt + β34 kt + ξ3,t+1                                 LRAS
    yt = b40 + β44 kt + β46 ct + β47 nxt + β49 gt + ξ4,t+1                      IS
    ct = b50 + β51 lt + β51 ωt + β54 kt − β58 rrt + ξ5,t+1                      Consumption
    Rt = b60 + b68 rrt + ξ6,t+1                                                 YC
                zt = (lt , yt , wt , kt , Rt , ct , nxt , rrt , gt ) = (yt , gt )
                            ξt = β zt−1 − b0 − b1 (t − 1)
                                                  p−1
                       ∆zt = a0 − αξt +                 Γi ∆zt−i + vt
                                                  i=1
                                                                   p−1
         ∆zt = a0 − α β zt−1 − b0 − b1 (t − 1) +                         Γi ∆zt−i + vt
                                                                   i=1
                                                        p−1
                   ∆zt = a + bt − Πzt−1 +                     Γi ∆zt−i + vt
                                                        i=1
              where a = a0 + α (b0 − b1 ), b = αb1 and Π = αβ .
               ∆yt = ay − Π∗ z∗ + Γy 1 ∆zt−1 + ψ y 0 ∆gt + uyt ,
                              t−1

     z∗ = (zt−1 , t) = (yt−1 , gt−1 , t) and Π∗ = αβ ∗ , β ∗ = (β , −b1 ).
      t−1
                                     r0t = Π∗ r1t + εt
Table: 6.1 Long-run β∗ estimates for the over-identified VECM with rank(Π∗ ) = 5
and p = 2, 1962q4 to 2006q2.

    z∗
     t−1              Labor             Investment           Production                 IS             Consumption


    lt                1.0000                                 −0.85208∗                                  −0.45304∗
                                                             (0.037352)
    yt               −1.0000              −1.0000              1.0000                 1.0000

    wt              0.12922∗                                                                            −0.45304∗
                   (0.032059)                                                                           (0.056240)
    kt                                     1.0000            −0.26361∗             −0.035386            −0.40647∗
                                                             (0.018388)            (0.013755)           (0.024968)
                                                  ∗
    Rt                                    1.9125                                                        −0.22315∗
                                         (0.11895)                                                      (0.017498)
    ct                                                                            −0.77822∗               1.0000
                                                                                   (0.026293)
    nxt           −0.067944∗             −1.0111∗                                 −0.049279∗
                   (0.0093073)           (0.18595)                                (0.0044202)
    rrtp           −0.26586∗             −6.6812∗             0.23153∗            −0.10696∗              0.77444∗
                    (0.057164)            (1.0655)           (0.050414)            (0.019996)           (0.091525)
    gt              0.073148∗                                −0.18590∗            −0.16177∗             −0.23659∗
                    (0.025286)                               (0.025986)            (0.012769)           (0.033603)
    Trend          0.0028339∗                               0.00065454
                  (0.00013614)                              (0.00030597)

  United States data. Standard errors in parentheses. Estimated parameters in bold indicate significance of the t-ratios
  at the 5% level and at 1% level with an asterisk. Likelihood function maximized under general restrictions based on
  Doornik (1995) (scaled linear) switching algorithm under weak convergence criterion of |l (θi+1 ) − l (θi )| ≤ = 0.005.
  Log-likelihood = 5247.98759. −T /2 ln |Ω| = 7234.50154. Beta is identified and 2 over-identifying restrictions are imposed.
  LR test statistics: χ2 (2) = 3.0193 [0.2210]. Number of observations: 175. Number of parameters: 151. The log short-term
  real return measure is calculated based on the investment goods price inflation and multiplied by the relative investment
  goods price so that rrtp = [ln(1 + rt ) − πt+1 ] × PtI /PtY .
                                             I
Table: 6.2 α adjustment coefficient estimates for the over-identified VECM with
rank(Π∗ ) = 5 and p = 2, 1962q4 to 2006q2.

     Equation             Labor               Investment             Production                 IS          Consumption


     ∆lt               −0.066433             0.0095344∗               0.028934               −0.11145         0.090029
                       (0.10738)             (0.0043023)              (0.13117)             (0.093880)       (0.052082)

     ∆yt                0.49876∗              −0.010069               0.47283∗             −0.48830∗         −0.088506
                        (0.15039)            (0.0060257)              (0.18371)            (0.13149)         (0.072945)

     ∆wt                0.078638             −0.0027374              −0.0051453              0.010466         0.017234
                       (0.071941)            (0.0028824)             (0.087881)             (0.062897)       (0.034894)

     ∆kt               0.077271∗            −0.0028891∗              0.087255∗              0.0050440        −0.012648
                       (0.022138)           (0.00088701)             (0.027043)             (0.019355)       (0.010738)

     ∆Rt                −1.9667∗               0.012601               −3.9010∗               1.9932∗           1.3729∗
                        (0.71329)             (0.028579)              (0.87134)             (0.62362)         (0.34597)

     ∆ct                0.34074∗             −0.0035532                0.35063             −0.0013989        −0.091877
                        (0.14455)            (0.0057918)              (0.17658)             (0.12638)        (0.070114)

     ∆nxt                0.73140               0.039095               −0.19918               0.91785          0.83582∗
                        (0.70116)             (0.028093)              (0.85651)             (0.61301)         (0.34008)

     ∆rrtp             −0.077447              0.0058118               −0.12361               0.40675         −0.088550
                       (0.27242)              (0.010915)              (0.33278)             (0.23818)        (0.13213)

   United States data. Standard errors in parentheses. Estimated parameters in bold indicate significance of the t-ratios
   at the 10% level and at 5% level with an asterisk.
Sample Slides


              Long run β ∗ and α estimates obtained from the concentrated
              model: r0t = Π∗ r1t + εt of the conditional VECM:
              ∆yt = ay − Π∗ z∗ + Γy 1 ∆zt−1 + ψ y 0 ∆gt + uyt where
                                t−1
              Π∗ = αβ ∗ .
                                                 ˆ
              Estimated cointegration relations, β ∗ r1 from Table 6.1
              correspond to the following reduced form error correction
                     ˆ∗   ˆ
              terms ξ t = β ∗ z∗ :
                               t−1


       ξ1,t+1 = lt − yt + 0.1292ωt − 0.0679nxt − 0.2659rrtp + 0.0731gt + 0.0028t
       ˆ                                                                                 Labor
       ξ2,t+1 = kt − yt + 1.9125Rt − 1.0111nxt − 6.6812rrtp
       ˆ                                                                                 Invest
       ˆ
       ξ3,t+1 = yt − 0.8521lt − 0.2636kt +           0.2315rrtp   − 0.1859gt + 0.0007t   Product
       ξ4,t+1 = yt − 0.0354kt − 0.7782ct − 0.0493nxt − 0.1070rrtp − 0.1618gt
       ˆ                                                                                 IS
       ξ5,t+1 = ct − 0.4530lt − 0.4530ωt − 0.4065kt − 0.2231Rt + 0.7744rrtp − 0.2366gt
       ˆ                                                                                 Consump




Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital,        11
ˆ
Figure: 6. Reduced form errors for the long-run relations. Estimated −ξt for
the over-identified VECM with rank(Π∗ ) = 5 and p = 2, 1962q4 to 2006q2.
Figure: 8. Generated quarterly stocks of business R&D in billions of chained
(2000) dollars, 1960-2004 compared with the BEA’s annual capital stock data.
Figure: 9. Calculated quarterly stock series for business R&D in billions of
chained (2000) dollars, 1982-2004 from the poisson model with different λ
values compared with that from the depreciation smoothing procedure.
ˆ
Figure: 10. Reduced form errors for the long-run relations. Estimated −ξt for
VECM with R&D capital stock, dt included in the investment relation,
rank(Π∗ ) = 5 and p = 2, 1962q4 to 2004q4.
Table: 16. Summary of elasticity estimates.
Table                           User Cost    Wage                            Variables


Rank 5 VECM with net exports:

(6.1) U.S. data                  -1.9125    -0.1292                          y , k, R, nx, rr
                                                                  [-1, 1, 1.9125, -1.0111, -6.6812]

(12.1) Canadian data             -1.0237     0.1811                           y , k, R, rr
                                                                      [-1, 1, 1.0237, -5.7059]

Rank 4 VECM without net exports:

(8) E&S investment               -0.4587    -0.4207                      y , k, R, rr , g , Trend
                                                              [-1, 1, 0.4587, -1.3768, 0.4990, -0.0070]

(10) Non high-tech investment    -1.2633    -0.2153                         y , k o , R o , rr o
                                                                      [-1, 1, 1.2633, -8.6959]

Dynamic OLS:

U.S. E&S investment              -0.7 to -1.1
U.S. non high-tech investment    -0.3 to -0.5
Canadian E&S investment          -0.9 to -1.1


United States estimates for equipment and software (E&S) investment unless stated otherwise. Variables are
those included in the investment relation with the corresponding cointegration vector at the bottom. The wage
coefficient in the Canadian VECM in Table 12.1 has an opposite sign but is not significantly different from zero.
Table: 16. Summary of elasticity estimates (continued).
Table                                 User Cost    Wage                       Variables


Rank 5 VECM with R&D capital stock:

(14.1) Neutral R&D technology          -0.4870    -0.2858                 y , k, R, rr , g , Trend
                                                               [-1, 1, 0.4870, -1.5182, 0.4992, -0.0069]

(15.1) Capital augmenting R&D tech.    -0.2768    -0.2020                     y , k, R, rr , d
                                                                   [-1, 1, 0.2768, -2.1942, -0.3904]

Dynamic OLS:

U.S. E&S investment                    -0.7 to -1.1
U.S. non high-tech investment          -0.3 to -0.5
Canadian E&S investment                -0.9 to -1.1

Smaller VECM:

(17) Canadian data with investment     -1.3578                                   y , k, R
                                                                            [-1, 1, 1.3578]

(18) U.S. data single equation         -0.2543                              y , k, R, Trend
                                                                       [-1, 1, 0.2543, -0.0052]




United States estimates for equipment and software (E&S) investment unless stated otherwise. Variables are
those included in the investment relation with the corresponding cointegration vector at the bottom.
Conclusion


              According to the estimation results for α adjustment
              coefficients, the user cost of capital is found to be statistically
              significantly adjusting to the long-run reduced form shocks on
              several cointegration relations.
              User cost variable is endogenous to the general equilibrium
              system and responses to macroeconomic shocks including
              external and policy shocks.
              Net exports is also endogenous to the system and needs to be
              included in the investment relation for cointegration.
              Influence of domestic savings and investment on the
              equilibrium long-term real interest hence on the endogenous
              user cost of capital in a large open economy. Large estimated
              user cost elasticities estimates may be biased due to the
              equilibrium current account adjustments (S − I = NX ).


Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital,   18
Conclusion

              Small user cost elasticities for the U.S. obtained in the VECM
              without net exports but with linear time trend (close to -0.4 in
              Chirinko et al., 2007) or with R&D capital-augmenting
              technology dt (close to the wage elasticity of -0.25 in
              Juselius M., 2008).
              Endogeneity of the user cost that is influenced by the demand
              and supply sides of a large economy hence the domestic
              supply of and demand for capital.
              User cost elasticity estimate of around -1.0 for Canadian
              VECM. In a small open economy the interest rates and capital
              goods prices are largely predetermined internationally and
              much less affected by the domestic demand for and supply of
              capital.
              Perfectly elastic supply of capital from abroad so easier to
              identify domestic capital demand in estimation
              (Schaller, 2006; Coulibaly and Millar, 2007).

Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital,   19

More Related Content

PDF
Unexpected Default in an Information based model
PDF
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysis
PDF
Parameter Uncertainty and Learning in Dynamic Financial Decisions
PDF
Common and private ownership of exhaustible resources: theoretical implicat...
PDF
Principal component analysis and matrix factorizations for learning (part 3) ...
PDF
Pclsp ntnu
PDF
CVPR2010: Advanced ITinCVPR in a Nutshell: part 6: Mixtures
PDF
Ceske budevice
Unexpected Default in an Information based model
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysis
Parameter Uncertainty and Learning in Dynamic Financial Decisions
Common and private ownership of exhaustible resources: theoretical implicat...
Principal component analysis and matrix factorizations for learning (part 3) ...
Pclsp ntnu
CVPR2010: Advanced ITinCVPR in a Nutshell: part 6: Mixtures
Ceske budevice

What's hot (20)

PDF
Computational Tools and Techniques for Numerical Macro-Financial Modeling
PDF
A kernel-free particle method: Smile Problem Resolved
PDF
Learning to discover monte carlo algorithm on spin ice manifold
PDF
Paris2012 session2
PDF
Brownian bridges on random intervals
PDF
Bat algorithm for Topology Optimization in Microelectronic Applications
PDF
MM framework for RL
PDF
On the Convergence of Single-Call Stochastic Extra-Gradient Methods
PDF
OPTEX MATHEMATICAL MODELING AND MANAGEMENT SYSTEM
PDF
State Space Model
PDF
Discussion of Faming Liang's talk
PDF
GA Based Multi-Objective Time-Cost Optimization in a Project with Resources C...
PDF
Paper Review: An exact mapping between the Variational Renormalization Group ...
PDF
Paris2012 session1
PDF
RIC-NN: A Robust Transferable Deep Learning Framework for Cross-sectional Inv...
PDF
Self-Learning Systems for Cyber Security
PDF
Interactive Visualization in Human Time -StampedeCon 2015
PDF
Expanding further the universe of exotic options closed pricing formulas in t...
PDF
Fuzzy inventory model with shortages in man power planning
PDF
Lec5 advanced-policy-gradient-methods
Computational Tools and Techniques for Numerical Macro-Financial Modeling
A kernel-free particle method: Smile Problem Resolved
Learning to discover monte carlo algorithm on spin ice manifold
Paris2012 session2
Brownian bridges on random intervals
Bat algorithm for Topology Optimization in Microelectronic Applications
MM framework for RL
On the Convergence of Single-Call Stochastic Extra-Gradient Methods
OPTEX MATHEMATICAL MODELING AND MANAGEMENT SYSTEM
State Space Model
Discussion of Faming Liang's talk
GA Based Multi-Objective Time-Cost Optimization in a Project with Resources C...
Paper Review: An exact mapping between the Variational Renormalization Group ...
Paris2012 session1
RIC-NN: A Robust Transferable Deep Learning Framework for Cross-sectional Inv...
Self-Learning Systems for Cyber Security
Interactive Visualization in Human Time -StampedeCon 2015
Expanding further the universe of exotic options closed pricing formulas in t...
Fuzzy inventory model with shortages in man power planning
Lec5 advanced-policy-gradient-methods
Ad

Viewers also liked (7)

PPTX
Tutor2u - Price Elasticity of Demand
DOCX
direct tax project - income from capital gains detailed study with illustrati...
PPT
Changes in technology affecting Globalisation
PPTX
Capital gain, advance taxes & tds
PPT
Time Series Analysis - Modeling and Forecasting
PPTX
time series analysis
Tutor2u - Price Elasticity of Demand
direct tax project - income from capital gains detailed study with illustrati...
Changes in technology affecting Globalisation
Capital gain, advance taxes & tds
Time Series Analysis - Modeling and Forecasting
time series analysis
Ad

Similar to Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital Presentation Sample (20)

PDF
Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital (article format)
PDF
Lect 02
PDF
Elett02
PDF
1. df tests
PDF
UT Austin - Portugal Lectures on Portfolio Choice
PDF
Lecture on nk [compatibility mode]
PDF
Transaction Costs Made Tractable
PPTX
Towards a ‘Classical Keynesian’ Analysis of Effective Demand in the Long Period
PDF
11.the comparative study of finite difference method and monte carlo method f...
PDF
The comparative study of finite difference method and monte carlo method for ...
PDF
Money, income, and prices in bangladesh a cointegration and causality analysis
PDF
Chapter 1 nonlinear
PDF
Extent3 prognoz practical_approach_lppl_model_2012
PDF
Extent3 prognoz practical_approach_lppl_model_2012
PDF
Optimalpolicyhandout
PDF
20 sameer sharma 186-206
PPTX
PDF
Chapter 5 heterogeneous
PDF
Basic concepts and how to measure price volatility
PDF
Discrete space time option pricing forum fsr
Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital (article format)
Lect 02
Elett02
1. df tests
UT Austin - Portugal Lectures on Portfolio Choice
Lecture on nk [compatibility mode]
Transaction Costs Made Tractable
Towards a ‘Classical Keynesian’ Analysis of Effective Demand in the Long Period
11.the comparative study of finite difference method and monte carlo method f...
The comparative study of finite difference method and monte carlo method for ...
Money, income, and prices in bangladesh a cointegration and causality analysis
Chapter 1 nonlinear
Extent3 prognoz practical_approach_lppl_model_2012
Extent3 prognoz practical_approach_lppl_model_2012
Optimalpolicyhandout
20 sameer sharma 186-206
Chapter 5 heterogeneous
Basic concepts and how to measure price volatility
Discrete space time option pricing forum fsr

Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital Presentation Sample

  • 1. Sample Presentation Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital Thethach Chuaprapaisilp April 14, 2009 Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital, 1
  • 2. Sample Slides Aim: Estimate the long-run user cost elasticity of business investment by using a general equilibrium macroeconometric model and cointegration technique. The Jorgenson (1963) ‘user cost of capital’ as the real rental price of capital services or the costs of holding capital: Ct ≡ Pt−1 rt + δt PtI − PtI − Pt−1 I I (Interest/opportunity cost + Depreciation cost - Capital gain) Long-run neoclassical investment equation from the FOC of the optimal capital accumulation problem ∞ max{Kt−1 ,Lt ,It } V = (1 + r )−t PtY Qt − wt Lt − PtI It t=0 s.t. Ft (Kt−1 , Lt ) = Qt and ∆Kt = It − δKt−1 implies PtY FK (Kt−1 , Lt ) = (1 + r ) Pt−1 − (1 − δ) PtI (≡ Ct ) I Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital, 2
  • 3. Sample Slides I PtI − Pt−1 I Ct ≡ Pt−1 r + δ − (1 − δ) I . Pt−1 Can also obtain from a durable goods model of production as in Jorgenson and Yun (1991) and Hall and Jorgenson (1967) with varying weighted average of rates of return on debt and equity, corporate tax rate, investment tax credit and depreciation allowances. Normalizing investment goods price by the price of output, PtY and assuming beginning-of-period gross investment (It = ∆Kt+1 + δt Kt ), PtI Pt+1 − PtI I 1 − ITCt − τt zt CtK ≡ rtl + δt − Et . PtY PtI 1 − τt Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital, 3
  • 4. Sample Slides Assuming a CES production function, Yt = (aKtσ + bLσ )1/σ t the first-order condition gives the long-run investment equation (in logs), 1 1 kt = ln a + yt − ck 1−σ 1−σ t kt = α0 + yt + αR Rt , Rt ≡ ctk Many studies using US, UK and Canadian data obtain αR of around -0.4 (Chirinko et al., 2007; Ellis and Price, 2004) to -0.7 for total private non-residential capital stock and close to one for equipment capital (-0.9 in Caballero, 1994; -1.6 in Schaller, 2006). Tevlin and Whelan (2003): -1.59 for computers, -0.13 for noncomputing equipments and -0.18 for equipment capital in total. Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital, 4
  • 5. Figure: 1 U.S. data. All variables are in logs. kt is the log of capital stock for non-residential business sector equipment and software calculated from seasonally adjusted real investment series using the perpetual inventory method and depreciation smoothing technique of Diewert (2008). Rt is the log of the user cost of capital with the corresponding implicit price index as the purchase price of investment goods. Rt includes after-tax real financial cost of capital for producers’ durable equipment (a weighted average of 5-year Treasury bond yield and Moody’s AAA corporate bond rate plus risk premia less expected inflation over 30 years) and tax variables from the FRB/US model. The log short-term real return measure, rrpt is calculated based on the investment goods price inflation and I I Y multiplied by the relative investment goods price so that rrpt = [ln(1 + rt ) − πt+1 ] × Pt /Pt where rt is the 3-month CD rate net of federal average marginal income tax on interest received.
  • 6. Figure: 2 U.S. data in first differences.
  • 7. Sample Slides Estimate αR using a vector error correction model (VECM) of a macroeconomy here assuming a tendency for output and real interest rates to move towards their long-run natural (flexible price equilibrium) values as represented by cointegrating relationships. Follow the structural cointegrated VAR methodology of Garratt, Lee, Pesaran and Shin (2006) and Juselius (2006). Expand the two-equation VECM of Ellis and Price (2004) to a general equilibrium system. Long-run counterpart of the macromonetary framework by Gali and Gertler (2007). Concentrate on the long run and use the cost of capital instead of Tobin’s q here. Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital, 7
  • 8. Long-run reduced form equilibrium conditions provide six cointegrating relations, lt = b10 − b11 t + yt − β25 ωt + ξ1,t+1 Ld kt = b20 + yt − β25 Rt + ξ2,t+1 Investment yt = b30 + b31 t + β31 lt + β34 kt + ξ3,t+1 LRAS yt = b40 + β44 kt + β46 ct + β47 nxt + β49 gt + ξ4,t+1 IS ct = b50 + β51 lt + β51 ωt + β54 kt − β58 rrt + ξ5,t+1 Consumption Rt = b60 + b68 rrt + ξ6,t+1 YC zt = (lt , yt , wt , kt , Rt , ct , nxt , rrt , gt ) = (yt , gt ) ξt = β zt−1 − b0 − b1 (t − 1) p−1 ∆zt = a0 − αξt + Γi ∆zt−i + vt i=1 p−1 ∆zt = a0 − α β zt−1 − b0 − b1 (t − 1) + Γi ∆zt−i + vt i=1 p−1 ∆zt = a + bt − Πzt−1 + Γi ∆zt−i + vt i=1 where a = a0 + α (b0 − b1 ), b = αb1 and Π = αβ . ∆yt = ay − Π∗ z∗ + Γy 1 ∆zt−1 + ψ y 0 ∆gt + uyt , t−1 z∗ = (zt−1 , t) = (yt−1 , gt−1 , t) and Π∗ = αβ ∗ , β ∗ = (β , −b1 ). t−1 r0t = Π∗ r1t + εt
  • 9. Table: 6.1 Long-run β∗ estimates for the over-identified VECM with rank(Π∗ ) = 5 and p = 2, 1962q4 to 2006q2. z∗ t−1 Labor Investment Production IS Consumption lt 1.0000 −0.85208∗ −0.45304∗ (0.037352) yt −1.0000 −1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 wt 0.12922∗ −0.45304∗ (0.032059) (0.056240) kt 1.0000 −0.26361∗ −0.035386 −0.40647∗ (0.018388) (0.013755) (0.024968) ∗ Rt 1.9125 −0.22315∗ (0.11895) (0.017498) ct −0.77822∗ 1.0000 (0.026293) nxt −0.067944∗ −1.0111∗ −0.049279∗ (0.0093073) (0.18595) (0.0044202) rrtp −0.26586∗ −6.6812∗ 0.23153∗ −0.10696∗ 0.77444∗ (0.057164) (1.0655) (0.050414) (0.019996) (0.091525) gt 0.073148∗ −0.18590∗ −0.16177∗ −0.23659∗ (0.025286) (0.025986) (0.012769) (0.033603) Trend 0.0028339∗ 0.00065454 (0.00013614) (0.00030597) United States data. Standard errors in parentheses. Estimated parameters in bold indicate significance of the t-ratios at the 5% level and at 1% level with an asterisk. Likelihood function maximized under general restrictions based on Doornik (1995) (scaled linear) switching algorithm under weak convergence criterion of |l (θi+1 ) − l (θi )| ≤ = 0.005. Log-likelihood = 5247.98759. −T /2 ln |Ω| = 7234.50154. Beta is identified and 2 over-identifying restrictions are imposed. LR test statistics: χ2 (2) = 3.0193 [0.2210]. Number of observations: 175. Number of parameters: 151. The log short-term real return measure is calculated based on the investment goods price inflation and multiplied by the relative investment goods price so that rrtp = [ln(1 + rt ) − πt+1 ] × PtI /PtY . I
  • 10. Table: 6.2 α adjustment coefficient estimates for the over-identified VECM with rank(Π∗ ) = 5 and p = 2, 1962q4 to 2006q2. Equation Labor Investment Production IS Consumption ∆lt −0.066433 0.0095344∗ 0.028934 −0.11145 0.090029 (0.10738) (0.0043023) (0.13117) (0.093880) (0.052082) ∆yt 0.49876∗ −0.010069 0.47283∗ −0.48830∗ −0.088506 (0.15039) (0.0060257) (0.18371) (0.13149) (0.072945) ∆wt 0.078638 −0.0027374 −0.0051453 0.010466 0.017234 (0.071941) (0.0028824) (0.087881) (0.062897) (0.034894) ∆kt 0.077271∗ −0.0028891∗ 0.087255∗ 0.0050440 −0.012648 (0.022138) (0.00088701) (0.027043) (0.019355) (0.010738) ∆Rt −1.9667∗ 0.012601 −3.9010∗ 1.9932∗ 1.3729∗ (0.71329) (0.028579) (0.87134) (0.62362) (0.34597) ∆ct 0.34074∗ −0.0035532 0.35063 −0.0013989 −0.091877 (0.14455) (0.0057918) (0.17658) (0.12638) (0.070114) ∆nxt 0.73140 0.039095 −0.19918 0.91785 0.83582∗ (0.70116) (0.028093) (0.85651) (0.61301) (0.34008) ∆rrtp −0.077447 0.0058118 −0.12361 0.40675 −0.088550 (0.27242) (0.010915) (0.33278) (0.23818) (0.13213) United States data. Standard errors in parentheses. Estimated parameters in bold indicate significance of the t-ratios at the 10% level and at 5% level with an asterisk.
  • 11. Sample Slides Long run β ∗ and α estimates obtained from the concentrated model: r0t = Π∗ r1t + εt of the conditional VECM: ∆yt = ay − Π∗ z∗ + Γy 1 ∆zt−1 + ψ y 0 ∆gt + uyt where t−1 Π∗ = αβ ∗ . ˆ Estimated cointegration relations, β ∗ r1 from Table 6.1 correspond to the following reduced form error correction ˆ∗ ˆ terms ξ t = β ∗ z∗ : t−1 ξ1,t+1 = lt − yt + 0.1292ωt − 0.0679nxt − 0.2659rrtp + 0.0731gt + 0.0028t ˆ Labor ξ2,t+1 = kt − yt + 1.9125Rt − 1.0111nxt − 6.6812rrtp ˆ Invest ˆ ξ3,t+1 = yt − 0.8521lt − 0.2636kt + 0.2315rrtp − 0.1859gt + 0.0007t Product ξ4,t+1 = yt − 0.0354kt − 0.7782ct − 0.0493nxt − 0.1070rrtp − 0.1618gt ˆ IS ξ5,t+1 = ct − 0.4530lt − 0.4530ωt − 0.4065kt − 0.2231Rt + 0.7744rrtp − 0.2366gt ˆ Consump Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital, 11
  • 12. ˆ Figure: 6. Reduced form errors for the long-run relations. Estimated −ξt for the over-identified VECM with rank(Π∗ ) = 5 and p = 2, 1962q4 to 2006q2.
  • 13. Figure: 8. Generated quarterly stocks of business R&D in billions of chained (2000) dollars, 1960-2004 compared with the BEA’s annual capital stock data.
  • 14. Figure: 9. Calculated quarterly stock series for business R&D in billions of chained (2000) dollars, 1982-2004 from the poisson model with different λ values compared with that from the depreciation smoothing procedure.
  • 15. ˆ Figure: 10. Reduced form errors for the long-run relations. Estimated −ξt for VECM with R&D capital stock, dt included in the investment relation, rank(Π∗ ) = 5 and p = 2, 1962q4 to 2004q4.
  • 16. Table: 16. Summary of elasticity estimates. Table User Cost Wage Variables Rank 5 VECM with net exports: (6.1) U.S. data -1.9125 -0.1292 y , k, R, nx, rr [-1, 1, 1.9125, -1.0111, -6.6812] (12.1) Canadian data -1.0237 0.1811 y , k, R, rr [-1, 1, 1.0237, -5.7059] Rank 4 VECM without net exports: (8) E&S investment -0.4587 -0.4207 y , k, R, rr , g , Trend [-1, 1, 0.4587, -1.3768, 0.4990, -0.0070] (10) Non high-tech investment -1.2633 -0.2153 y , k o , R o , rr o [-1, 1, 1.2633, -8.6959] Dynamic OLS: U.S. E&S investment -0.7 to -1.1 U.S. non high-tech investment -0.3 to -0.5 Canadian E&S investment -0.9 to -1.1 United States estimates for equipment and software (E&S) investment unless stated otherwise. Variables are those included in the investment relation with the corresponding cointegration vector at the bottom. The wage coefficient in the Canadian VECM in Table 12.1 has an opposite sign but is not significantly different from zero.
  • 17. Table: 16. Summary of elasticity estimates (continued). Table User Cost Wage Variables Rank 5 VECM with R&D capital stock: (14.1) Neutral R&D technology -0.4870 -0.2858 y , k, R, rr , g , Trend [-1, 1, 0.4870, -1.5182, 0.4992, -0.0069] (15.1) Capital augmenting R&D tech. -0.2768 -0.2020 y , k, R, rr , d [-1, 1, 0.2768, -2.1942, -0.3904] Dynamic OLS: U.S. E&S investment -0.7 to -1.1 U.S. non high-tech investment -0.3 to -0.5 Canadian E&S investment -0.9 to -1.1 Smaller VECM: (17) Canadian data with investment -1.3578 y , k, R [-1, 1, 1.3578] (18) U.S. data single equation -0.2543 y , k, R, Trend [-1, 1, 0.2543, -0.0052] United States estimates for equipment and software (E&S) investment unless stated otherwise. Variables are those included in the investment relation with the corresponding cointegration vector at the bottom.
  • 18. Conclusion According to the estimation results for α adjustment coefficients, the user cost of capital is found to be statistically significantly adjusting to the long-run reduced form shocks on several cointegration relations. User cost variable is endogenous to the general equilibrium system and responses to macroeconomic shocks including external and policy shocks. Net exports is also endogenous to the system and needs to be included in the investment relation for cointegration. Influence of domestic savings and investment on the equilibrium long-term real interest hence on the endogenous user cost of capital in a large open economy. Large estimated user cost elasticities estimates may be biased due to the equilibrium current account adjustments (S − I = NX ). Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital, 18
  • 19. Conclusion Small user cost elasticities for the U.S. obtained in the VECM without net exports but with linear time trend (close to -0.4 in Chirinko et al., 2007) or with R&D capital-augmenting technology dt (close to the wage elasticity of -0.25 in Juselius M., 2008). Endogeneity of the user cost that is influenced by the demand and supply sides of a large economy hence the domestic supply of and demand for capital. User cost elasticity estimate of around -1.0 for Canadian VECM. In a small open economy the interest rates and capital goods prices are largely predetermined internationally and much less affected by the domestic demand for and supply of capital. Perfectly elastic supply of capital from abroad so easier to identify domestic capital demand in estimation (Schaller, 2006; Coulibaly and Millar, 2007). Thethach Chuaprapaisilp: Macroeconometrics of Investment and the User Cost of Capital, 19