SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Incentive-Based Instruments
for Water Management
December 2015
SYNTHESIS REVIEW
THE
RockefellerFoundation
EVALUATIONOFFICE
Financial support provided by
About the Pacific Institute
The Pacific Institute envisions a world in which society, the economy, and the environment have the
water they need to thrive now and in the future. In pursuit of this vision, the Pacific Institute creates and
advances solutions to the world’s most pressing water challenges, such as unsustainable water manage-
ment and use, climate change, environmental degradation, and basic lack of access to fresh water and
sanitation. Since 1987, the Pacific Institute has cut across traditional areas of study and actively collabo-
rated with a diverse set of stakeholders, including leading policy makers, scientists, corporate leaders,
and international organizations such as the United Nations, advocacy groups, and local communities.
This interdisciplinary and independent approach helps bring diverse groups together to forge effective
real-world solutions.
About the Foundation Center
Established in 1956, Foundation Center is the leading source of information about philanthropy worldwide.
Through data, analysis, and training, it connects people who want to change the world to the resources
they need to succeed. The Foundation Center maintains the most comprehensive database on US and,
increasingly, global grantmakers and their grants – a robust, accessible knowledge bank for the sector. It
also operates research, education, and training programs designed to advance knowledge of philanthro-
py at every level. The Foundation Center’s IssueLab service works to gather, index, and share the collec-
tive intelligence of the social sector more effectively, providing free access to thousands of case studies,
evaluations, white papers, and issue briefs addressing some of the world’s most pressing problems.
About The Rockefeller Foundation
For more than 100 years, The Rockefeller Foundation’s mission has been to promote the well-being
of humanity throughout the world. Today, The Rockefeller Foundation pursues this mission through
dual goals: advancing inclusive economies that expand opportunities for more broadly shared prosper-
ity, and building resilience by helping people, communities, and institutions prepare for, withstand and
emerge stronger from acute shocks and chronic stresses. Committed to supporting learning, account-
ability and performance improvements, the Evaluation Office of The Rockefeller Foundation works with
staff, grantees, and partners to strengthen evaluation practice and to support innovative approaches to
monitoring, evaluation, and learning.
For this synthesis review, The Rockefeller Foundation provided financial support, the Foundation
Center and its IssueLab service were involved in project and technology development, and the Pacific
Institute authored the report. Pacific Institute authors included Heather Cooley, Michael Cohen, Matthew
Heberger, and Heather Rippman.
Cover: Hudson River, NY. Photograph by Daniel Case.
The contents of this report are the views of the authors and do not
necessarily reflect the views or policies of The Rockefeller Foundation.
© 2015, The Rockefeller Foundation
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 License
Incentive-Based Instruments for
Water Management
December 2015
Financial support provided by
THE
RockefellerFoundation
EVALUATIONOFFICE
ChesapeakeBay,Maryland.PhotographbyBossi.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT iii
Table of Contents
Acronyms	 v
Foreword	 vii
Acknowledgements	 ix
Executive summary	 x
Water trading	 x
Payment for ecosystem services	 xiii
Water quality trading	 xv
Conclusions	 xvi
1		 Introduction	 1
2	 Research methodology	 5
3	 Environmental policy instruments	 7
3.1	 Water trading	 10
Description	 10
Application	 12
Environmental, economic, and social performance	 16
Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions	 25
3.2	 Payment for ecosystem services/payment for watershed services	 28
Description	 28
Application	 30
Environmental, economic, and social performance	 31
Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions	 35
3.3	 Water quality trading	 39
Description	 39
Application	 41
Environmental, economic, and social performance	 44
Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions	 48
4 	 Role of the private sector	 53
4.1	 Corporate water stewardship	 53
4.2	 Private sector engagement with incentive-based instruments	 55
5 	 Summary and conclusions	 61
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTiv
Annexes
Annex 1: Demand management	 63
Annex 2: Water trading in Australia: Lessons from the Murray-Darling Basin	 66
Background	 66
MCB and the Colorado River Basin	 66
History	 67
Water trading activity	 69
Enabling conditions	 71
Lessons learned	 71
Glossary	 74
References	 75
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT v
Acronyms
ARP Acid Rain Program (US)
AWS Alliance for Water Stewardship
BIER Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable
BMP Best management practices
CAC Command-and-control
CDP Carbon Disclosure Project (former name)
CRP Conservation Reserve Program (US)
DEG German Investment and Development Corporation
EPA Environmental Protection Agency (US)
EPRI Electric Power Research Institute
GEF The Global Environment Facility
GPCD Gallons per capita daily
IID Imperial Irrigation District (California, US)
IWS Investment in watershed services
MAF Million acre-feet
M&I Municipal and industrial
MDB Murray-Darling Basin
MDBA Murray-Darling Basin Authority
MWD Metropolitan Water District of Southern California (California, US)
MWELO Model Water Efficient Landscape Ordinance
NRC National Research Council (US)
NSWDEC New South Wales Department of Education and Communities (Australia)
NWC National Water Commission (Australia)
PES Payment for ecosystems services
PSAH Programme for Hydrological Environmental Services (Mexico)
PSA Pagos por servicios ambientales (payment for environmental services)
PWS Payment for watershed services
RUPES Rewarding Upland Poor for Environmental Services (Indonesia)
SBP Socio Bosque Program (Ecuador)
SDCWA San Diego County Water Authority
SO2 Sulfur dioxide
SWP State Water Project (California, US)
TMDL Total maximum daily load
TWSTT Transforming Water Scarcity through Trading
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTvi
UCSB University of California at Santa Barbara
UN United Nations
UNDP United Nations Development Programme
UNEP United Nations Environment Programme
USBR United States Bureau of Reclamation
WEF World Economic Forum
WfW Working for Water (South Africa)
WHO World Health Organization
WQT Water quality trading
WRI World Resources Institute
WWF World Wide Fund for Nature
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT vii
Foreword
Human transformation of freshwater ecosystems is rapidly exceeding capacity required to sustain the
conditions we need to survive and thrive. Water crises are already impacting people around the globe –
from river basins in California and China, to the cities of São Palo and Bangkok. Under current population
and growth trends, the 2030 Water Resources Group predicts global water demand will exceed available
supply by 40 percent by 2030.
Humans have used, benefited from, and shaped the natural environment for the whole of human history.
But what we have not done – especially in the course of industrialization and modernization – is find
effective ways to integrate natural ecosystems into our economic and social systems. In response to
these challenges, The Rockefeller Foundation’s work focuses on incentive-based solutions that harness
the importance of ecosystems as an asset for smart development, economic and social progress, and
long-term resilience. In our work on agriculture and food security, climate change, energy, and fisheries,
we seek new approaches to environmental care that will create incentives for the wise use of resources,
and preserve their resilience. And in all of our work we place particular emphasis on the effects of these
solutions on the poor or otherwise vulnerable members of society, who are most directly dependent on
ecosystems to meet their basic needs and are mostly likely to bear the consequences of environmental
degradation.
Freshwater crises are representative of the kind of misaligned incentives we seek to correct. Freshwater
allocation and management systems often place little value on the benefits of functioning ecosystems.
This, in turn, leads to a vicious cycle in which ecosystem degradation and overuse reduce future water
supplies, making even more people vulnerable to water scarcity. As water crises continue to capture
public attention – in January, the World Economic Forum’s Global Risk Report 2015 named water crises
the number one economic risk in terms of impact – and decision makers worldwide scramble for answers,
The Rockefeller Foundation is eager to help support the identification of sound solutions by synthesiz-
ing the knowledge and lessons from past and current water management interventions.
The synthesis report that follows examines several incentive-based instruments for improving freshwa-
ter management for all users, including poor and vulnerable populations and the freshwater ecosystems
themselves. The report examines the economic, social, and environmental performance of three tools,
which were selected because: there is growing interest in applying these instruments in a range of
settings, they are clearly focused on voluntary transactions rather than sanctions or voluntary standards,
they can be applied to improve water quality or quantity, and there is an existing body of literature about
their implementation upon which we can build. However, one of the key findings is that these transac-
tions are often not voluntary. The report highlights the importance of finding a fit between a commu-
nity’s water goals and the water management tool(s) it might choose and, perhaps most importantly, it
characterizes the enabling conditions required for their effective implementation. We hope this synthesis
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTviii
review will serve as an entry point for those exploring opportunities to improve the management of
freshwater, and will spark the development of more robust solutions to improve our management and
maintenance of freshwater systems. 
We hope that you will find this report useful and encourage you to explore the accompanying learning
tool at freshwater.issuelab.org and to share it widely with colleagues.
Dr. Fred Boltz
Managing Director, Ecosystems
The Rockefeller Foundation
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT ix
Acknowledgements
The overall design of this synthesis review was led and managed collaboratively by Gabi Fitz from the
Foundation Center and Alex Martinez from The Rockefeller Foundation.
The research, analysis and written synthesis were undertaken by a freshwater specialist team from the
Pacific Institute led by Heather Cooley and Michael Cohen, and assisted by Matthew Heberger and
Heather Rippman. Their work was further supported by John Berggren, who provided research assistance
and Genevieve Bennett, Roy Brouwer, Jessica Fox, Chuck Howe, Cy Jones, Tony McLeod, Marcus Moench,
and Ina Porras who all provided the team with valuable information and suggested additional readings.
The visualization and special collection were designed and developed by Lisa Brooks and Gabi Fitz from
the Foundation Center and IssueLab, in collaboration with ThreeStory Studio.
Peer review was provided by Dr. Casey Brown of the University of Massachusetts, Matt Elliott, Amy
Dickie, Mark Michelin, Emily Peterson, and James Giampietro of California Environmental Associates,
The Rockefeller Foundation Freshwater Team, and Nancy MacPherson from The Rockefeller Founda-
tion’s Evaluation Office.
Learning from Experience – an ongoing collaboration between the
Foundation Center and The Rockefeller Foundation
This synthesis review, Incentive-based Instruments for Water Management, is part of an ongoing collab-
oration between The Rockefeller Foundation and the Foundation Center, aimed at helping organizations
build more effectively on each other’s knowledge, lessons and experience. With financial support from
The Rockefeller Foundation, the Foundation Center is engaging in synthesis reviews and the develop-
ment of supportive technologies and practices that facilitate the collection, synthesis, and sharing of the
sector’s collective knowledge.
As part of our collaboration, we are committed to sharing all work products from these efforts as public
goods. Too often, systematic and synthesis reviews result in a public report but leave future researchers
having to duplicate search and selection efforts in order to further build on a synthesis. By collecting
and sharing coded search results through an open repository and openly licensing all work products, we
hope other researchers can more freely use and repurpose our findings.
Our goal is to contribute to better programmatic and funding strategies by enabling teams and organizations
to start with a more inclusive and comprehensive understanding of what has worked, what hasn’t, and why.
Gabi Fitz	 Nancy MacPherson
Director of Knowledge Management Initiatives	 Managing Director, Evaluation
Foundation Center	 The Rockefeller Foundation
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTx
Executive summary
Water is one of our most precious and valuable resources and is fundamental for maintaining human
health, economic activity, and critical ecosystem functions. Yet, we can see clear signs of the overexploi-
tation of available freshwater resources and the resultant inability to meet basic human and ecosystem
needs. Already, some iconic rivers, such as the Colorado in the United States and the Yellow in China, no
longer reach the sea. Groundwater withdrawals have tripled over the past 50 years, with groundwater ex-
traction exceeding natural recharge in some areas, causing widespread depletion and declining ground-
water levels. More than 660 million people lack access to an improved drinking water source, predomi-
nantly in sub-Saharan Africa and Oceania, and some 2.4 billion people lack access to basic sanitation.1
At the same time, the world’s water quality is becoming increasingly degraded, with water pollution exac-
erbating the challenges posed by water scarcity. Pressure on water resources is intensifying in response
to challenges such as economic and population growth, and, in turn, is having major impacts on our
social, economic, and environmental well-being.
With traditional approaches to managing water having proven insufficient to address these challenges,
new approaches and policies are needed. Policy makers and water managers are showing increasing
interest in incentive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water resources.
In most regions, laws and regulations have been the primary policy tools employed to improve envi-
ronmental outcomes. However, over the past several decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has
expanded to include incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or indirectly, to
motivate responsible parties to reallocate water, or reduce the health and environmental risks posed by
their facilities, processes, or products.
This report provides a synthesis review of a set of incentive-based instruments that have been employed
to varying degrees around the world. It is part of an effort by The Rockefeller Foundation to improve
understanding of both the potential of these instruments and their limitations. The report is divided into
five sections. Section 1 provides an introduction to the synthesis review. Section 2 describes the research
methodology. Section 3 provides background on policy instruments and detail on three incentive-based
instruments – water trading, payment for ecosystem services, and water quality trading – describing the
application of each, including their environmental, economic, and social performances, and the condi-
tions needed for their implementation. Section 4 highlights the role of the private sector in implementing
these instruments, and Section 5 provides a summary and conclusions.
Water trading
Water trading refers to the temporary or permanent transfer of the right to use water in exchange for
some form of compensation. It is perhaps the best known and most widely used method of reallocating
water. It has proven, in some cases, to be less expensive, more flexible, and less time-consuming than
1	 An “improved” drinking-water source is one that, by nature of its construction and when properly used, adequately protects the source
from outside contamination, particularly fecal matter.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xi
developing new water supplies through, for example, constructing new diversion structures or desali-
nation plants. Similarly, water trading is generally a more accepted method of reallocating water than
state appropriation or revoking of existing water rights. Today, examples of successful water trading
in Australia and other locations – combined with classic economic theory which suggests that market
mechanisms can optimize resource allocation – have heightened interest in this instrument in both
academic literature and popular media.
Water trading occurs within sectors, from agriculture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban, across sectors
and, less frequently, from either of these to the environment. Water trading exists, to varying degrees,
in countries around the world, though the most active water trading markets are in Australia and the
western United States. In Australia, the total value of water trading in fiscal year 2012–13 exceeded
$1.4 billion, with much of that activity concentrated within the Murray-Darling Basin. While the total
volume of water traded via long-term trades within the Murray-Darling Basin decreased slightly in fiscal
year 2012–2013, the volume of water traded via short-term trades increased by 44 percent from the
previous year, from almost 3.5 to 5.0 million acre-feet (MAF), or about 50 percent of the total surface
water use in the basin.2 In the western United States, where the scale of water trading is considerably
lower, there were more than 4,000 water trades between 1987 and 2008. In 2011, the most recent year
for which data are available, more than 1.4 MAF of water were traded in California, representing about
4 percent of the total water use that year. Of that amount, 42 percent of the water traded went to
municipal and industrial users, 37 percent to agricultural users, 17 percent was used for environmental
purposes, and the remainder was for mixed uses.
The actual results of water trading worldwide have been decidedly mixed, due to two key challenges: ex-
ternalities and transaction costs. In Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin, the federal government overcame
some of those challenges by investing more than $3 billion to purchase water for the environment, pro-
tecting ecological resources and directly addressing one of the major challenges to water trading. This
has facilitated trading in the basin and reduced transaction costs by shifting them to national taxpayers.
Over the last 30 years, the federal government also implemented significant institutional changes that
facilitated trading and reduced transaction costs. Short-term water trading within irrigation districts in
the United States, such as within the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, occurs smoothly
and quickly because intra-district trades undergo very limited oversight, and because the third-party
impacts of such trades tend to be small or negligible.
However, these examples of successful water trading regimes are countered by critical arguments and
examples of less-successful trades from various parts of the world. Many authors challenge the applica-
bility and efficacy of water trading, contending that externalities and the unique characteristics of water
itself pose significant obstacles to trading water. Many of these externalities arise from the physical
properties of water: it is heavy, unwieldy, and easily contaminated; varies seasonally and from year to
year; and is readily lost through evaporation, seepage, or runoff. Further, externalities may be borne by
disparate parties, such as the environment or future generations, challenging efforts to compensate
those injured by trading. Questions of externalities, commodification, and the special nature of water
2	 An acre-foot, the conventional unit of water measurement in the western United States, is equivalent to 325,851 gallons or 1,233.48 m3.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxii
itself highlight the challenges faced when seeking to implement or expand water trading. Critics also
highlight the many examples of “buy-and-dry” water trades, where water-rich agricultural areas sell their
water rights, often to wealthier cities, only to find that rural communities as a whole suffer when agricul-
tural production declines. Critics have pointed to examples around the world where wealthy communi-
ties or interests have purchased and withdrawn water from less powerful, poor rural areas.
The environmental performance of water trading has been highly variable, depending on the type of
trade and site-specific conditions. Water trading has been used as a mechanism to obtain water for
ecological purposes, to augment streamflow, and to address water quality concerns (such as tempera-
ture) in threatened reaches. The benefits of voluntary, incentive-based water acquisition include ease
of transaction and greater community support, especially relative to regulatory takings,3 though in most
areas, such activity still represents a tiny fraction of total water use in any given area. In California, in the
last three decades, environmental water purchases averaged 152,000 acre-feet per year, accounting for
about 14 percent of trading activity and less than 0.5 percent of total water use in the state. Conversely,
water trades for other purposes can inadvertently harm the environment. They can, for example, change
the timing, quantity, and quality of return flows, adversely affecting riparian and wetland habitats and the
species that depend upon them.
Water trading has rarely been employed to address equity challenges. Indeed, water trading can exacer-
bate social and economic inequalities, worsening gender and geographic differences. Unequal access to
water markets due to unequal access to information or credit can distort outcomes and reduce market
efficiency. On the other hand, water trading that promotes water-use efficiency rather than fallowing of
agricultural land can improve socio-economic outcomes for both the area of origin and the destination.
Water trading’s social impacts vary based on several factors, including the relative economic health of
the area of origin and the purchasing area, whether or not the water leaves the area of origin, the process
used to trade the water, the relative economic and political power of the parties, gender differences
regarding access to and control of water, the amount of trading activity in the area, and the legitimacy of
the water rights being traded. Impacts often vary within the same community, as those with water rights
or allocations to trade receive compensation, while third parties – such as irrigation equipment suppliers
or farmworkers – may suffer a loss of revenue or income as a result of trading.
Institutional arrangements are among the most important factors that determine the ultimate success or
failure of water trading. Successful water trading requires secure and flexible water rights that recognize
and protect users and others from externalities. Such institutional arrangements also need to be flexible
enough to adapt to changing physical conditions as well as changing social norms, such as the growing
interest in meeting environmental needs and protecting water quality. Some factors, such as access to
timely information about water available to trade, can enable water trading but may not be required.
Other factors, such as legal and transferable rights to use water, may be necessary for water trading to
occur. Still other factors, such as “no injury” regulations and “area of origin” protection, limit water trading
or can function as barriers or obstacles to trading.
3	 A “regulatory taking” occurs when a government regulation limits or infringes upon a private property right to such an extent that it
deprives the owner of some or all of the value of that property” (Fischel, 1995).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xiii
In a limited number of areas with the necessary legal and technical conditions and with sufficient public
investment, water trading has offered a timely, relatively inexpensive, and flexible mechanism to real-
locate water between users, or from water users back to the environment. Building a successful water
market requires decades of determined effort to measure water flows and use, report transactions
publicly, conduct regional water planning, and construct and maintain infrastructure to convey water. In
Australia’s case, it also required more than $3 billion of public funding to acquire water for environmental
purposes, which also called for creating and, in turn, maintaining an environmental baseline above which
trading activity could occur. Such significant institutional changes require broad public support and a
considerable amount of time to implement. Although water trading can be used to reallocate water ef-
fectively, successful implementation requires a clear understanding of existing conditions and a deter-
mined, long-term effort to make the necessary changes and minimize externalities.
Payment for ecosystem services
Payment for ecosystem services is an incentive-based instrument that seeks to monetize the external,
non-market values of environmental services – such as removal of pollutants and regulation of precipita-
tion events – that can then be used as financial incentives for local actors to provide such services. In
practical terms, they involve a series of payments to a land or resource manager in exchange for a guar-
anteed flow of environmental services. Payments are made to the environmental service provider by the
beneficiary of those services, e.g. an individual, a community, a company, or a government. In essence, it
is based on a beneficiary-pays principle, as opposed to a polluter-pays principle.
Payments for ecosystems services (PESs) that focus on watershed services, commonly referred to
as “payments for watershed services” (PWSs), can take a variety of forms. They may be intended to
prevent the degradation of a watershed or to restore a previously degraded one. They may be small, local
schemes covering several hundred hectares or large, national schemes covering millions of hectares.
Programs may be financed directly by the beneficiary or by third parties acting on behalf of the benefi-
ciary, e.g. governments or institutions, or some combination thereof. They may involve cash or in-kind
payments to be paid all at once or periodically.
New York City provides a well-known example. In the late 1990s, New York City was faced with the
prospect of building a $4–$6 billion filtration plant with an additional $250 million in annual operating
costs to meet new federal drinking water standards. An initial analysis suggested that preserving the
upstream rural Catskill watershed would be far less expensive. The city and local farmers came together
to develop a plan that could meet both groups’ interests. A key element of the plan was the Whole Farm
Program, a voluntary effort fully funded by New York City’s Department of Environmental Protection
whereby farmers would work with technical advisors to custom design pollution control measures to
meet an environmental objective while also improving the viability of their farming businesses. By 2006,
the city had spent or committed between $1.4 billion and $1.5 billion in watershed protection projects,
averaging $167 million in expenditures per year – far less than building a water filtration plant. Participa-
tion remains high, with 96 percent of large farms in the watershed participating in the program.
Payments for watershed services are gaining prominence and have been applied in a wide range of
settings. Some of the earliest programs were established in Central America but today, such programs
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxiv
can be found in countries around the world. The United States’ Conservation Reserve Program pays
farmers to take land out of production in order to protect soil and water resources and wildlife habitat. In
northeastern France, Vittel-Nestle Waters paid farmers and provided technical support (and some labor)
to alter local dairy farming practices in order to reduce nitrate pollution of groundwater – the source of
Vittel’s bottled water.
The largest PWS programs are in China. China’s Sloping Land Conversion Programme, piloted in 1999
and fully implemented in 2002, requires farmers to set aside erosion-prone farmland within critical areas
of the watershed of the Yangtze and Yellow Rivers – the two largest rivers in China. In exchange, farmers
receive regular cash payments and grain rations. The program promotes forestry and other economic
endeavors on the land rather than grain production, in order to prevent sediment from washing into
rivers and clogging dams and shipping channels.
The environmental performance of PWS is not well understood. Evaluation of these programs is in-
herently difficult because the connections between land use practice and watershed services are not
always clear, especially as they relate to water quantity, and they are often site-specific. It can also be
difficult to attribute change to the program rather than to external factors (e.g. changing commodity
prices), and programs may not reach threshold levels for measureable impact, or that impact may occur
over a relatively long time period. In addition to these challenges, many programs lack baseline data or
monitoring systems. In the absence of scientific information, performance is often based on perceptions
of local populations and those operating the schemes. But even based on these sources, the available
data suggest that environmental performance of PWS is mixed, with less than 60 percent of programs
reaching their environmental objective. As the field has matured, it has increased emphasis on monitor-
ing, which will inevitably help improve environmental outcomes.
Similarly,limiteddataareavailableonthesocialandeconomicimpactsofpaymentsforwatershedservices.
Most studies have focused on increased income or capacity building rather than broader social impacts,
such as changes in power dynamics. While participation in a PWS program can boost the income of small
farmers, the payments they receive will typically boost their annual incomes only slightly. Several studies
have also suggested that there are important non-financial (or non-income) benefits, such as increasing
land-tenure security, creating human and social capital through internal organization, and improving the
visibility of the community to donors and public entities. Some analysts have argued that because the
programs are mostly voluntary, continued participation provides some indication that the programs are
cost effective, i.e. that benefits exceed costs and participants are satisfied with the outcomes.
While information on broader social outcomes is limited, there is information on the role of these arrange-
ments in alleviating poverty. However, it is important to recognize that payment for watershed services
was conceptualized as a mechanism to improve the efficiency of natural resource management, not as a
mechanism to reduce poverty. Several studies have examined the socio-economic status of participants,
either as buyers or sellers, and have found mixed results, depending to some extent on land and forest
tenure regimes and socio-economic conditions in the targeted areas. While most programs prioritize
areas critical for ecosystem services, some have been tailored to meet social objectives through a variety
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xv
of mechanisms, such as targeting the programs to particular areas or populations, reducing transac-
tion costs, and providing pro-poor premiums and subsidies. While there are often more direct ways of
reducing poverty than payments for watershed services (e.g. education or health programs), there is
little evidence of these schemes actually doing any harm. Few studies have examined gender represen-
tation among program participants.
In general, payments for watershed services are flexible, and the necessary conditions are relatively
modest. Small, self-organized schemes between private entities are based on general legal require-
ments: a legal system recognizing that agreements must be kept and that civil law must provide the
contracting parties with legal remedies in case of non-compliance. Expanding these projects to address
regional or national water problems would require a more developed policy and legal framework along
with incentives or requirements to participate in PES programs, cultural and political acceptance of
markets, trust between ecosystem service providers and beneficiaries, and a supply and demand for
ecosystem services.
Water quality trading
Water quality trading (WQT) is an incentive-based approach for reducing or controlling water pollution.
Under such a system, polluters are granted a permit to pollute, and these permits can be bought and
sold among polluters. The central idea is that trading puts a price on pollution, encouraging cost savings,
efficiency, and innovation. Water quality trading is an adjunct to regulation, not an alternative to it. In fact,
its success depends on the presence of a strong regulatory body to enforce water quality standards, and
monitor and enforce discharge limits.
Water quality markets have drawn inspiration from the success of the Acid Rain Program (ARP) es-
tablished in the United States in the 1990s. The popularity of emissions trading for dealing with water
pollution in the United States is largely a result of the Clean Water Act of 1972, which made it difficult for
governments to handle pollution from farms. Water quality markets have been established in the United
States, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand. There is also interest in China and Europe, although no
programs are currently in place. To date, most water quality trading markets have been used to control
pollution from nutrients that cause excessive algal growth and low dissolved oxygen levels in water
bodies, a process referred to as “eutrophication”. Other water quality trading programs have been set up
to control salinity, heavy metal, sediment, and temperature or thermal pollution.
The largest WQT market in the United States in terms of transactions, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit
Exchange Program, was created in 2002 to reduce nitrogen pollution that came into Long Island Sound
from the Connecticut River. Under the program, which covers 79 sewage treatment plants in the state
of Connecticut, a plant can control pollution in excess of its permit requirement and sell excess nitrogen
allowances to those plants that exceed their allowances. A 2012 review of the program found that in ten
years, the program had helped reduce nitrogen pollution by over 50 percent while controlling costs.
One of the best examples of a successful water quality trading market is on Australia’s Hunter River,
where coal mines and other pollution sources are subject to discharge limits to protect water quality
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxvi
and drinking water sources in downstream cities. Under this system, limited discharge is allowed, but
permitted dischargers must coordinate their activities so that the total salt concentration in the river
never goes above a specified limit. Industries can buy and sell salt credits in real time via a trading
website run by the state government. Several years after it began, the trading program remains popular
among participants and functions smoothly. Perhaps the biggest marker of the program’s success is
that, even though new and potentially high-polluting mines have been established, river water quality
has met standards nearly 100 percent of the time.
Despite the fact that water quality trading markets have existed for three decades in some areas, it is
difficult to determine whether the approach can be considered an overall success. Many of the domestic
WQT markets in the United States have not lived up to expectations, seeing few trades or no trades at
all. This can be explained by a number of factors: high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty about
the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate. However, paradoxically,
despite a lack of trading, the process of creating the market may have contributed to better watershed
management. Bringing stakeholders together around a common goal of improving water quality has
helped lower resistance to new, more stringent water quality regulations.
In other cases, discussion of the use of “market fundamentals” helped convince some political conser-
vatives to implement a form of environmental regulation, paving the way for improved water quality. A
common argument in favor of environmental markets is that they will be smaller, simpler, and lower cost,
because they aim to replace regulation with a free market. However, water quality markets require a
strong and capable regulatory ability to set a cap on pollutants, to monitor pollution, and to verify the le-
gitimacy of water quality credits that are created. Ironically, this often results in the creation of additional
layers of government to perform these functions.
WQT markets are valuable where large price asymmetries exist in water pollution control, and where
certain polluters are beyond the reach of a regulatory agency. This is the case in the United States, where
states are responsible for preserving water quality but have little authority over agriculture and some
other nonpoint sources. On one hand, this has decreased the burden on municipal and industrial sources
of pollution, allowing them to save on the cost of installing expensive treatment technologies. On the
other hand, it has compelled them to fund projects on farms, often hundreds of miles away. We conclude
that water quality trading is not a panacea for solving water pollution problems. However, it can be part
of an effective regulatory approach under certain conditions.
Conclusions
In this report, we analyze the potential for incentive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water
resources. To date, the primary environmental policy tools to address water challenges have been com-
mand-and-control regulations. However, over the past several decades, the environmental policy “toolkit”
has expanded to include a host of incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or
indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their
facilities, processes, or products.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xvii
While regulations and incentive-based instruments are frequently juxtaposed, they also frequently
operate alongside one another. With water quality trading, for example, governments mandate caps on
the allowable pollutant levels and issue tradable permits that allow industry groups to allocate polluting
activities among themselves, governed by market forces. Similarly, with water trading, governments may
allocate water and then institute a framework within which water trading can occur. While incentive-
based instruments may work in tandem, they must be integrated within a broader watershed manage-
ment effort.
Decisions about whether and how to apply a particular instrument depend on the specific objectives,
circumstances, conditions, and needs of a given area. These decisions should be based on an open
and transparent process, with meaningful participation from all affected parties. This approach will help
in crafting a solution that is appropriate for local conditions, and ensure that it is fair and equitable. It
will also help to reduce opposition and promote acceptance from those who will be implementing and
affected by the program. It is important to recognize that those with the least power may not have the
resources to participate, or they may be skeptical of the groups involved. In these cases, there is a need
for consistent and rigorous outreach and, potentially, for engaging a trusted intermediary.
Finally, monitoring and evaluation are essential to the success of any instrument. In particular, moni-
toring and evaluation help ensure outcomes are achieved and allow for adjustments in response to
changing social, economic, or environmental conditions. Monitoring should evaluate the “additionality”
of the program, i.e. whether the program has an effect when compared with some baseline. It should also
examine any potential impacts on surrounding areas (i.e. leakage) and the permanence of the interven-
tion. However, extensive monitoring requirements would increase transaction costs, potentially threat-
ening the viability of the program. Thus, the need for monitoring and evaluation must be balanced with
practical considerations of the ability to maintain the viability of the program.
LimariRiver,Chile.PhotographbyEduardoRobles.
1
Introduction
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 1
Water is one of our most precious and valuable
resources and is fundamental for maintaining human
health, agricultural production, and economic activ-
ity as well as critical ecosystem functions. Even as the
planet’s endowment of water is expected to remain
constant, human appropriation of fresh water, already
at 50 percent by some measures (Postel et al., 1996),
is expected to increase further (Leflaive et al., 2012).
We can already see clear signs of the overexploitation
of available freshwater resources. For example, some
iconic rivers, including the Colorado River in the United
States and the Yellow River in China, no longer reach
the sea. Groundwater withdrawals have tripled over the
past 50 years (UN, 2012), and in some areas, ground-
water extraction exceeds natural recharge, causing
widespread depletion and declining groundwater levels
(Wada et al., 2010; Famiglietti, 2014). Pressures on water
resources are likely to worsen in response to contin-
ued economic and population growth, climate change,
and other challenges. Water pollution exacerbates the
challenges posed by water scarcity as the world’s water
quality is increasingly becoming degraded.
Growing pressures on the availability and quality of
water resources have major impacts on our social, eco-
nomic, and environmental well-being. The failure to
provide safe drinking water and adequate sanitation
services to all people is perhaps the greatest develop-
ment failure of the twentieth century. Improving access
to water and sanitation has been a key focus of the
global development agenda since 2000. Water and
sanitation were goals of the 2000–2015 Millennium
Development Goals, and now, the Sustainable Devel-
opment Goals launched in September 2015, also call for
insuring access to water and sanitation for all.
Yet, despite nearly two decades of international atten-
tion and tens of billions of dollars invested, more than
660 million people still lack access to improved drink-
ing water, predominantly in sub-Saharan Africa and
Oceania, and some 2.4 billion people lack access to
basic sanitation (WHO and UNICEF, 2015).4,5 In even
the wealthiest countries, access to water and sanitation
4	 Improved water sources include household connections, public stand-
pipes, boreholes, protected dug wells, protected springs, and rainwater
collections. Unimproved water sources are unprotected wells, unprotect-
ed springs, vendor-provided water, bottled water (unless water for other
uses is available from an improved source), and tanker truck-provided
water.
5	 Improved sanitation includes connection to public sewers, connection to
septic systems, pour-flush latrines, simple pit latrines, and ventilated im-
proved pit latrines. Service or bucket latrines (where excreta is manually
removed), public latrines and open latrines are not considered improved
sanitation.
“…more than 660 million people still lack
access to an improved drinking water
source…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT2
(2002, 2003), is based on integrating several key prin-
ciples, including improving the overall productivity of
water use, matching water quality to users’ needs, pri-
oritizing basic human and ecosystem water needs, and
seeking meaningful local and community engagement
in water management.
A key element of the soft path for water is shifting from
a near exclusive supply-side orientation to one that
seeks to manage water demand. Numerous studies
have found significant opportunities to reduce water
demand in all sectors using a variety of conservation
and efficiency measures (e.g. Gleick et al., 2003; Cohen
et al., 2013; Heberger et al., 2014). These measures
can be applied in countries at varying levels of eco-
nomic development, although the types of measures
employed and implementation strategies may differ
(Sharma and Vairavamoorthy, 2009). Brooks (2006)
argued that demand management is more than a set
of techniques; rather, it is a governance approach
linked to equity, environmental protection, and public
engagement goals. Additional information on demand
management can be found in Annex 1.
New policy tools are also needed. In most places, regu-
lations have been the primary tool employed to improve
environmental outcomes. However, over the past sev-
eral decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has
expanded to include “incentive-based” instruments.
Incentive-based instruments use financial means,
directly or indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to
reallocate water or reduce the health and environmen-
tal risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products.
These instruments have emerged for several reasons,
but mainly because they are believed to be more cost
effective than regulations, as they provide greater flex-
ibility for the individual or firm to meet the environmen-
tal objective in the least costly manner. Incentive-based
is not universal. A 2011 UN report (de Albuquerque,
2011) highlighted several areas of the United States,
including California, where marginalized populations
(e.g. those living in poverty, communities of color, and
indigenous groups) lacked the basic rights to water
and sanitation. Moreover, access to an improved water
source does not necessarily mean that the water is
affordable or safe to drink. For example, naturally occur-
ring arsenic pollution in groundwater affects nearly
140 million people in 70 countries (United Nations,
2009).
Freshwater ecosystems are among the most exten-
sively altered systems on earth. Rivers, streams, and
lakes have been subjected to chemical, physical, and
biological alteration as a result of large-scale water
diversions, introduction of invasive species, overhar-
vesting, pollution, and climate change (Carpenter
et al., 2011). As a result, an estimated 20 to 35 per-
cent of freshwater fish are vulnerable or endangered
(Cosgrove and Rijsberman, 2000). Likewise, about half
of the world’s wetlands have been lost since 1900, and
much of the remaining wetlands are degraded (Zedler
and Kercher, 2005). Freshwater ecosystem conditions
are likely to continue to decline unless action is taken
to address acute threats and better manage freshwa-
ter resources.
Traditional approaches to managing water supply and
demand are not going to be effective in addressing
these challenges. Throughout much of the twentieth
century, the emphasis was on developing massive dams
and pumping ever increasing amounts of groundwa-
ter to satisfy rising water demands. This approach, as
noted by Sharma and Vairavamoorthy (2009), “has led
to over-use of the resources, over-capitalisation, pollu-
tion and other problems of varying severity.” The soft
path for water has emerged as a promising alternative.
The term “soft energy path”, coined by Amory Lovins
(1977) of the Rocky Mountain Institute, described an
alternative path for energy development that empha-
sized energy efficiency and promoted smaller, decen-
tralized energy systems fueled by renewable sources.
The soft path for water, as described by Peter H. Gleick
“…the environmental policy “toolkit” has
expanded to include “incentive-based”
instruments…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 3
in managing both the quantity and quality of fresh-
water. We have divided this review into five sections.
This Section 1 introduces the synthesis review. Section
2 describes the research methodology. Section 3 pro-
vides background on policy instruments and detail on
three incentive-based instruments that have been used
in the United States and abroad – water trading, pay-
ment for ecosystem services, and water quality trad-
ing. For each instrument, we describe its application, its
environmental, economic, and social performance, and
the conditions needed for its implementation. Section
4 highlights the role of the private sector in implement-
ing these instruments, and Section 5 provides a sum-
mary and conclusions.
instruments are also thought to lower administrative
costs and promote innovation by rewarding those who
exceed their targets (Harrington and Morgenstern,
2004). Furthermore, Koplow (2004) suggests that
these instruments can support self-enforcement by
creating “groups of firms and individuals with vested
interests in the proper use of resources and in emitting
only as much pollution as allowed.”
This report provides a synthesis review of a set of
incentive-based instruments that have been employed
in varying degrees around the world to reduce pressure
on water resources. It is part of an effort to understand
the full potential, and limitations, of these instruments
ColoradoRiver,Texas.PhotographbyLeaflet.
2
Research methodology
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 5
The freshwater synthesis review is based on a five-step
approach to making better use of existing evaluative
knowledge. This approach, modeled by The Rockefeller
Foundation to help inform its investment and program-
matic decisions, has already been used in a review of
success factors in small-scale coastal fisheries man-
agement in developing countries (The Rockefeller
Foundation, 2013). Throughout the project, the proj-
ect team held bi-weekly calls with The Rockefeller
Foundation to review progress on the project, discuss
key findings, and dive into specific case studies that
could further support learning. The following steps
were taken.
1.	 Refine project scope. The first step was to work
with the Foundation Center and The Rockefeller
Foundation to refine the scope of work and develop
research questions.
2.	 Undertake literature search and review. The
second step was to review the peer-reviewed lit-
erature and law reviews on the key topics for the
research. We supplemented this formal literature
search with a review of the gray literature, including
government and other institutional reports, from or-
ganizations working to evaluate or implement these
instruments. To identify the relevant literature, we
used Web of Science (formerly Web of Knowledge)
Internet-based search engines, and institutional
website search engines. The literature on these in-
centive-based instruments is extensive. For example,
a Google Scholar search of “water trading” returned
nearly 1 million results. Given the need to review a
large amount of information in a relatively short time,
we prioritized articles published since 2000. We further
refined our study by limiting our scope to articles and
reports on the state of practice, rather than the state of
theory. In total, we reviewed approximately 500 articles
and reports.
3.	 Conduct expert interviews. The third step was to
obtain the knowledge of experts working to address
the study’s key questions. It was designed to fill in any
gaps in the literature. We developed the interview list
based on the academic and grey literature search and
from the research team’s experience in the sector.
4.	 Compile initial analysis and synthesis. The fourth
step included an initial analysis and synthesis of the
knowledge gained from the first three steps, which was
compiled into a detailed presentation and supporting
materials, and formally presented to the Foundation
Center and The Rockefeller Foundation Team in an
interactive discussion in March 2015. The Rockefeller
Foundation also reviewed the draft report in July 2015,
providing additional input on the synthesis.
5.	 Conduct further analysis and develop final
knowledge product. The fifth step was to conduct
further analysis of the published and expert knowledge
based on the discussions with the Foundation Center,
The Rockefeller Foundation, and other parties. We
worked closely with the Foundation Center to develop
the final knowledge products, including this summary
report and online components, such as a visualization
of key findings and a public collection of cited research.
All of the knowledge products are openly licensed and
free to be used and repurposed.
MurrayRiver,Australia.PhotographbyMattinbgn.
3
Environmental policy instruments
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 7
The objective of environmental policy is “to modify,
slow, or stop resource extraction; to reduce or elimi-
nate emissions of concern; and to shift consumption
and production patterns towards greater sustainability”
(Koplow, 2004). In most places, regulations have tradi-
tionally been the primary environmental policy instru-
ment employed to achieve environmental outcomes.
This approach, often referred to as command-and-
control (CAC), relies on some governmental or similar
body to establish a standard or target (the “command”)
that must then be complied with to avoid negative
sanctions, such as fines or prosecution (the “control”).
Over the past several decades, the environmental pol-
icy “toolkit” has expanded to include incentive-based
instruments, also referred to as economic instruments
or market-based instruments. While definitions vary, we
use the term “incentive-based instruments” to refer to
a set of tools that use financial means, directly or indi-
rectly,tomotivateresponsiblepartiestoreallocatewater
or reduce the health and environmental risks posed by
their facilities, processes, or products. While CAC and
incentive-based instruments are often juxtaposed with
one another, a United Nations Environment Programme
(UNEP) report (Koplow, 2004) noted that “in reality the
two often operate alongside each other. Governments
may, for example, mandate caps on allowable pollu-
tion for a region or country and use market-oriented
approaches such as tradable permits to allocate the
allowable emissions in an efficient manner.”
Figure 1 provides a depiction of the range of environ-
mental policy instruments currently applied around the
world. These include the following.
•	 Regulations and sanctions – mechanisms that
rely on guidelines, permits, or licenses, and often
include a legal or financial penalty for non-compli-
ance. Examples include pollution standards, water
use quotes, and building standards.
•	 Price-based instruments – mechanisms that
impose i) higher costs through fees, charges, or
taxes on pollution or the use of a natural resource,
making them more expensive and discouraging
their production or consumption, or ii) lower costs
through the use of subsidies for environmentally
friendly activities or products. Examples include
abstraction fees, pollution charges, grants, low-in-
terest loans, and favorable tax treatment.
•	 Market creation – mechanisms that include i)
tradable permits whereby user or polluter rights are
assigned according to desirable use levels or his-
torical practices, and compliance can be achieved
by trade, or ii) deposit refund systems that create
a market to buy back inefficient or polluting prod-
ucts. Examples include water trading and water
quality trading.
•	 Information provision – mechanisms that use
the provision and disclosure of information on envi-
ronmental performance to incentivize producers to
reduce their water use or emissions of pollutants,
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT8
As shown in Figure 1, these instruments exist along a
continuum, from “very strict command approaches to
decentralized approaches that rely more on market or
legal mechanisms” (Huber et al., 1998). As noted, there
are varying definitions of incentive-based instruments
and the types of tools that would qualify. All definitions
identify price-based instruments and market creation
as incentive-based instruments. Some, however, use a
broader definition that includes information provision,
voluntary action, and liability instruments (see, e.g.
Stavins, 2001; UNEP, 2001; Anderson, 2004). Product
labeling schemes, such as the United States’ “Energy
Star” or Thailand’s “Green Label”, allow companies
meeting environmental standards to place a recog-
nized label on their product, boosting sales by making
the product more appealing to consumers and provid-
ing a financial incentive to improve environmental per-
formance (Stavins, 2001). These products may also be
sold at a higher price than less environmentally-friendly
or to incentivize consumers to select products with
superior performance. Examples include corporate
reporting, product labeling (e.g. WaterSense),6 and
environmental certification schemes.
•	 Voluntary action – mechanisms that use volun-
tary agreements between the government and pri-
vate firms and/or commitments made independent
of government requirement. Examples include the
UN CEO Water Mandate and the Alliance for Wa-
ter Stewardship’s International Water Stewardship
Standard.
•	 Legal instruments – mechanisms for compen-
sating victims when pollution causes human or
environmental harm, and encouraging compliance
with existing environmental regulations. Examples
include criminal penalties, civil liability statutes, and
performance bonds.
6	 WaterSense is an environmental program designed to encourage water
efficiency in the US, through use of a special label on consumer products.
FIGURE 1. Incentive-based policy instruments
WATER MANAGEMENT EXAMPLES:
Regulations
and sanctions Price based
Market
creation
Information
provision
Voluntary
action Legal
Pollution
standards
Cost recovery
tariffs
Water quality
trading
Eco-labels UN CEO Water
Mandate
Criminal
penalties
Water use
quotas
Pollution taxes Water trading Corporate
reporting
AWS Interna-
tional Water
Stewardship
Standard
Performance
bonds
Building codes Payment for
watershed
services
Environmental
certification
Civil liability
statutes
Source: adapted from Huber et al., 1998; UNEP, 2009.
REGULATIONS
AND SANCTIONS
PRICE BASED MARKET
CREATION
INFORMATION
PROVISION
VOLUNTARY
ACTION
LEGAL
Less flexibility
Maximum government
involvement
Control oriented
More flexibility
Increased private
initiative
Litigation oriented
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 9
of this activity ($11.6 billion, or 94 percent) was associ-
ated with payment for watershed services, and 98 per-
cent of that activity was in China. Collective action
funds – which pool contributions from multiple inves-
tors to support coordinated interventions within a
watershed – had the second highest transaction value
at $563 million. We note, however, that the distinction
between payment for watershed and collective action
programs is sometimes unclear.9 The market activity of
instream buybacks – programs that purchase or lease
water to augment instream flows – was considerably
less ($97 million), followed by water quality trading
($22 million), and voluntary compensation ($320,000).
It is of note that instream buybacks likely represent a
modest fraction of the market activity of water trading
programs, although comprehensive data on the latter
are not readily available.10 While the data suggest a
rapid expansion in the application of these instruments
since 2008, Ecosystem Marketplace’s Genevieve
Bennett (personal communication, 2015) noted that
much of the increase is actually an outcome of better
reporting.
9	 Water funds are sometimes categorized as payment for watershed
services and other times as collective action funds.
10	 California, for example, has an active trading market but no centralized
repository of data on the number and value of transactions.
models. Likewise, voluntary programs may reward
meeting environmental outcomes with, e.g. public rec-
ognition which, in turn, increases sales.
The application and market activity of these instruments
are not well understood. Several organizations track the
application of some of these incentive-based instru-
ments (IIED, 2015 and Forest Trends, 2015a).7 However,
there is no comprehensive list of the programs that have
been implemented globally. Additionally, programs are
sometimes poorly defined, fall into multiple categories, or
change over time. Moreover, data on the activity of these
instruments, including the number and value of transac-
tions, are not collected or made available publicly.
Despite these challenges, Forest Trends has been track-
ing the activity of five market and market-like instru-
ments for watershed investments for several years.8 It
estimates that the market activity of watershed invest-
ments was $12.3 billion in 2013 (Table 1). The majority
7	 See, for example, Watershed Markets (watershedmarkets.org), main-
tained by the London-based International Institute for Environment and
Development, and Watershed Connect (watershedconnect.com), an on-
line platform maintained by the Washington, D.C.-based Forest Trends.
8	 Forest Trends is an international “non-profit organization with three
principal roles: convening market players to advance market transfor-
mations, generating and disseminating critical information to market
players, and facilitating deals between different critical links in the value
chains of new forestry.” See forest-trends.org.
TABLE 1. Transactions (in millions of US$) by type, 2008–2013
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Payment for watershed
services/undefined
$ 7,950 $ 6,950 $ 7,470 $ 8,000 $ 9,600 $11,600
Collective action funds n/a n/a n/a n/a $ 137 $ 563
Voluntary compensation n/a n/a n/a n/a $ 0.230 $ 0.320
Water quality trading $ 10.7 $ 8.30 $ 8.30 $ 7.70 $ 14.9 $ 22.2
Instream buybacks n/a $ 19 $ 390 $ 164 $ 144 $ 97.0
Total $ 7,960 $ 6,980 $ 7,870 $ 8,170 $ 9,890 $ 12,300
Note: Numbers shown are nominal values. All values rounded to three significant figures. Numbers may not add up due to rounding. Based on data provided by Bennett
(personal communication, 2015) and included in Bennett and Carroll (2014).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT10
side of a recognized legal or administrative frame-
work (e.g. the sale of groundwater to an adjacent
irrigator)
•	 water banks – the institutions or agencies that i)
broker or otherwise facilitate water trading (Culp et
al.,2014)orii)areestablishedforaspecificobjective,
such as a trust created to obtain water rights for in-
stream augmentation (Clifford, 2012). Water banks
offer expertise and information for improving com-
munication between buyers and sellers, and often
provide a centralized repository or clearinghouse of
information on current and historical transactions,
including volumes, pricing, and locations.
There is an extensive body of literature suggest-
ing that water trading provides a mechanism to
improve the economic efficiency of water through its
reallocation from lower to higher value uses (Glennon,
2005; Dellapenna, 2000; Bjornlund and McKay, 2002).
The germinal study entitled Water and Choice in the
Colorado Basin (NRC, 1968) recommended that water
in the western United States be transferred from irriga-
tion, which generates relatively low returns per unit of
water, to high-value non-agricultural uses. More recent
researchhascontinuedtoemphasizethepotentialvalue
created by water transfers. For example, models used to
project California’s economic costs under a dry climate
change projection, (Medellín-Azuara et al., 2008) found
significantly increased benefits with market-based real-
locations. Newlin et al. (2002) and Jenkins et al. (2004)
asserted that water trading could dramatically reduce
Southern California’s water scarcity costs.
Water trading is attractive because it tends to minimize
the impact on existing rights holders by providing com-
pensation and, in many cases, additional security, for
existing water rights, while providing opportunities to
those with new or increasing demands (NRC, 1992).
A large number of experts challenge the applicability
and efficacy of water trading. Freyfogle (1996) asserted
that externalities, intrinsic to the very nature of water
itself, pose such an insurmountable obstacle that water
trading does not and cannot work. Many of these
In this review, we evaluate three of the major incentive-
based instruments that have been employed to improve
water management: water trading, payment for ecosys-
tem services, and water quality trading. These instru-
ments are employed in developed and developing
countries, and there is growing interest in expanding
their application.
3.1 Water trading
Description
Water trading is perhaps the best known and most
widely used method of reallocating water. In some
cases, purchasing or leasing water from existing users
has proven to be less expensive, more flexible, and
less time-consuming than developing new water sup-
plies, such as constructing new diversion structures
or desalination plants. Similarly, water trading is gen-
erally a more accepted method for reallocating water
than state appropriation or condemnation of existing
water rights. Successful examples of water trading in
Australia and other locations – combined with classic
economic theory suggesting that market mechanisms
can optimize resource allocation – have heightened
interest in this instrument in both academic literature
and popular media.
As noted in Box 1, the peer-reviewed and gray litera-
ture employ several terms (e.g. water transfers, water
markets, and water banks) to refer to a variety of some-
times overlapping instruments and methods for con-
veying and reallocating water. In this paper, we use the
following terms:
•	 water trading – the temporary or permanent
transfer of the right to use water in exchange for
some form of compensation
•	 informal water trading – the sale of a specified
volume of water for a limited period of time, which
does not involve actual contracts or occurs out-
“…water trading provides a mechanism to
improve the economic efficiency of water…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 11
tradeable commodity. Similarly, Zellmer and Harder
(2007) asserted, “Water is a uniquely essential resource
with uniquely public attributes,” unlike other resources
typically treated as property. Questions of externali-
ties, commodification, and the special nature of water
itself highlight the challenges faced by implementing
or expanding water trading.
In some cases, water trading is effectively zero-sum,
simply shifting water use and economic productivity
from one area or sector to another. In other cases, it can
externalities arise from the physical properties of water:
it is heavy, unwieldy, and easily contaminated; it some-
timeshasdramaticseasonalandyear-to-yearvariability;
and it can be easily lost through evaporation, seepage,
or runoff (Salzman, 2006). Further, these externalities
may be borne by disparate parties, such as the envi-
ronment or future generations, challenging efforts to
compensate those injured by trading (Freyfogle, 1996).
Moreover, Salzman (2006) argued that custom, history,
and religion in many parts of the world treat drinking
water as a common property resource, rather than a
BOX 1
A note on terminology
Water transfers. The National Research Council
(NRC) of the United States National Academies defines
water transfers as changes in the point of diversion,
type of use, or location of water use (NRC et al., 1992).
The term “water transfers” encompasses a broad range
of market-based and non-market water reallocation
mechanisms of varying periods, geographic scales,
and arrangements. Water transfers can range from
short-term leases or conditional arrangements to the
permanent transfer (i.e. sale) of a water right. They
can range in scale from i) change in type of use on
an existing parcel of land, such as when a water right
shifts from irrigation to municipal use when agricultural
land is purchased and converted to housing, to ii)
inter-basin transfers, such as when a city purchases or
leases water from a different watershed.
Water bank. A water bank is a mechanism for
changing the time or location of water use. Water
banking, as with water transfers, can refer to market-
based or non-market activities. The term “water bank”
can refer to an actual institution or to the physical
storage of water. Water banks as institutions may
function as i) brokers that connect buyers and sellers
of water rights or leases, providing an important
communication function; ii) clearinghouses that
directly purchase or lease water from willing sellers
and aggregate supplies for subsequent sale to other
buyers; iii) facilitators that expedite water transfers
using existing storage or conveyance facilities (Culp et
al., 2014); or iv) trusts that hold or otherwise manage
water rights or entitlements for a specific purpose,
such as streamflow augmentation (O’Donnell and
Colby, 2010). When serving as facilitators, water banks
may perform various administrative and technical
functions, including the confirmation of water rights
and screening of potential buyers (Clifford, 2012).
Water banks may also refer to physical storage, either
in surface reservoirs or in aquifers, which, in turn, may
be a component of a larger water transfer or simply
a mechanism enabling an entitlement holder to store
water for its own future use, but we do not use this
definition in this review.
Water market. The term water market refers to a
range of different market-based practices, typically
referring to water trading. According to Brown (2006),
the term water market lacks a precise definition, “but
once a few voluntary trades of water of relatively
common physical and legal characteristics occur, it is
said that a water market exists.” A water market may
also refer to informal transactions involving the direct
sale of water that does not involve the lease or sale of
water rights. Informal water transactions can include
purchasing bottled water or water from a tanker truck,
a common practice in many parts of the developing
world that lack a reliable, piped water supply. While
a “water contract” can refer to a one-time voluntary
water exchange between two actors, a water market
is where many actors come together and make trades;
a market also includes some formalization of the
transactions (Brown et al., 2015).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT12
Application
Water trading exists, to varying degrees, in countries
around the world. When Grafton et al. (2010) assessed
water trading in two wealthy countries (Australia and
theUnitedStates),twolow-tomiddle-incomecountries
(Chile and South Africa), and one poor, rapidly develop-
ing country (China), they found that differing levels of
information availability, legal rights structures, institu-
tional constraints, and management goals had resulted
in very different levels of activity and performance.
ThemostactivewatertradingmarketsoccurinAustralia
and the western United States. Within Australia, water
trading includes both short-term trades (referred to as
allocation trading) and long-term trades (referred to as
entitlement trading). The total value of water trading
in Australia in fiscal year 2012–13 exceeded $1.4 billion
increase system-wide water efficiency, by providing the
area of origin with funds for investing in improved effi-
ciency, maintaining local productivity with lower water
use, and then transferring the conserved water. Water
can be made available for trading from a variety of
activities, including fallowing fields, crop shifting, and
in some cases, a shift from surface water diversions to
groundwater pumping. Water trades can also be linked
to water conservation and efficiency efforts, including
increasing irrigation efficiency and decreasing system
losses that generate surplus water by, e.g. lining canals
or constructing operating reservoirs. However, increas-
ing demand for greater efficiencies in irrigation can
challengetheflexibilityofexistinginstitutions(Hundley,
2001), such as irrigation districts and water courts,
which often do not recognize a legal property right to
this “new” water created by conservation or efficiency.
Additionally, existing institutions often impose signifi-
cantcostsonthoseattemptingtodedicatewatertonon-
traditional uses such as instream flows (Getches, 1985).
These changes have tested the resilience of water insti-
tutions, which have shown some flexibility in adapting
to new values and goals but often impose high transac-
tion costs (Colby et al., 1991).
Water trading can occur within sectors, from agricul-
ture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban, across these
sectors, and, less frequently, from either of these to the
environment (Brewer et al., 2007). Figure 2, from the
California Department of Water Resources, shows the
relative proportions of water trading within and between
differentsectors.Althoughwatertradingisoftenconsid-
ered a means to move water from agriculture to urban
uses, nearly three-quarters of the 270,000 acre-feet
of water traded in California in 2013 occurred between
agricultural users. Interestingly, nearly 25,000 acre-
feet of water were traded from municipal and industrial
(M&I) uses to agriculture, which was nearly half of the
volume of water traded from agriculture to M&I uses.
FIGURE 2. Non-project water transfers within the
Sacramento-San Joaquin watersheds in 2013
Note: Ag – agriculture; FW – fish and wildlife; M&I – municipal and industrial;
AF – acre-foot.
Source: California Department of Water Resources.
Ag to Ag
Ag to M&I
Ag to FW
M&I to Ag9%
(24,577 AF)
TOTAL: 268,370 AF
1%
(1,500 AF)
18%
(49,639 AF)
72%
(192,655 AF)
“The most active water trading markets
occur in Australia and the western United
States.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 13
reports almost 640,000 acre-feet of water traded in
California, through 36 trades with a total value of about
$234 million (all values adjusted to 2014$). More than
80 percent of the water was leased rather than sold.
According to the database, 15 of these trades, account-
ing for about 88,000 acre-feet of total volume, occurred
within one agricultural district. However, the Bren
School database only records the initial year a water
trade is reported, and thus does not reflect the volume
of multiyear trading agreements. That means that a
review of 2009 trading activity does not reflect previ-
ous multi-year trades that may still have been active in
2009, so the values reported above understate trading
activity in 2009.
A comprehensive review of water trading in California
reports about 1.5 MAF of water were traded in 2009,
a dry year (Hanak and Stryjewski, 2012). Volumes
reported for 2011, a wet year and the most recent year
for which data are available, were about 5 percent lower,
at 1.4 MAF. In 2011, 42 percent of the water traded went
to municipal and industrial users, 37 percent to agricul-
tural users, 17 percent for environmental purposes, and
the remainder to mixed uses. Because of limited data,
the study does not include trading activity within irri-
gation districts or similar users associations, although
some estimates suggest that such intra-district activity
accounted for several hundred thousand acre-feet of
water, a third of total water supplies within some of the
larger irrigation districts. Hanak and Stryjewski (2012)
did not provide total dollar values associated with the
California water market, though they noted that prices
of temporary water transfers had increased from an
average of $30–$40 per acre-foot in one region in the
mid-1990s to $180 per acre-foot in 2011, while aver-
age prices in another basin rose to an average of $400
per acre-foot. The authors noted the shifting trend
from short-term to longer-term leases and permanent
trades, pumping restrictions in the Bay-Delta, and ris-
ing transaction costs that had slowed market activity in
the past decade.
California is also home to the largest United States
water trade to date. The San Diego County Water
Authority (SDCWA) entered into a 45-year contract
(NWC, 2013). Trading within the Murray-Darling Basin,
which has an active and well-documented water mar-
ket first established more than 30 years ago (Grafton
et al., 2012), accounts for 98 percent of all allocation
trades and 78 percent of all entitlement trades within
Australia, by volume. Indeed, the Murray-Darling Basin
figures prominently in discussions about water trad-
ing, as an example of a thriving incentive-based sys-
tem that successfully transitioned from a non-market
system (Grafton et al., 2012). In fiscal year 2012–13, the
total volume of short-term (allocation) trading within
the Murray-Darling Basin increased 44  percent from
the previous year, from almost 3.5  million acre-feet
(MAF) to 5 MAF, or about 50 percent of total surface
water use in the basin. The total volume of long-term
trades, however, decreased by about 14 percent over
that period, to about 0.85 MAF. A national study found
that these permanent entitlement trades often offset
the temporary allocation trades, as irrigators planting
perennial crops, such as grapes or almonds, purchased
entitlements to meet expected future demand, but then
sold a portion of the temporary allocations associated
with these entitlements to generate revenue (Frontier
Economics and Australia National Water Commission,
2007). For more information on Australia’s water mar-
ket, see Annex 2.
In the western United States, the scale of water trad-
ing is considerably lower. A database compiled by the
University of California Santa Barbara (UCSB) Bren
School shows notifications for more than 4,000 water
trades in 12 states in the western United States from
the years 1987–2008.11 Brewer et al. (2007) docu-
mented the large variability in the volume, price, and
duration of water trades in the western United States,
both within and between sectors. In 2009, the most
recent year for which data are available, the database
11	 The database summary notes that “The data are drawn from water trans-
actions reported in the monthly trade journal the Water Strategist and its
predecessor the Water Intelligence Monthly from 1987 through February
2010.” These data reflect published reports that in some cases do not
reflect final transfer agreements. For example, the database reports that
the Imperial Irrigation District-San Diego County Water Authority water
transfer began in 1997, although the final transfer agreement was not
actually signed and the transfer did not begin (at different volumes than
the database reports) until October 2003. The Bren School water transfer
database is available at bren.ucsb.edu/news/water_transfers.htm.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT14
in several parts of the country (Thobani, 1997), with
nearly 3,700 registered water transfer requests in 2006
alone (CONAGUA, 2012).
Water markets have also been established in parts of
Europe, Asia, and Africa. In Spain, informal trades, sales,
and short-term exchanges of water are common, while
formal transfers of long-term water rights are generally
limited to groundwater (Albiac et al., 2006). In Spain’s
Alicante basin, several irrigation districts auction their
annual water allocations to district farmers (Albiac et
al., 2006), creating a strong incentive to improve water-
use efficiency and shift toward higher value crops.
England has encouraged water trading for more than a
decade, although only about 60 trades have occurred
to date (TWSTT, 2014).
South Africa has more extensive water markets that
continue to be plagued by conflict and inadequate
institutional support (Grafton et al., 2010). South
Africa’s Water Act of 1998 has provided a framework
for water trading. Historically, agricultural irrigators
traded water rights within their sector, mediated by
the national Department of Water Affairs and Forestry
(Farolfi and Perret, 2002). In 2001, mining companies
seeking to expand operations in northern South Africa
successfully negotiated a temporary trade of some
10,000 acre-feet of water (13 million m3
) from neigh-
boring farmers – representing more than 70 percent of
their annual allocation – in exchange for the current
equivalent of about $1 million. These funds, used to
help rehabilitate the local irrigation infrastructure, rep-
resented less than 0.1 percent of the mines’ develop-
ment costs, reflecting a significant economic disparity
between the two interests (Farolfi and Perret, 2002).
In Asia, India and Pakistan have informal water trad-
ing, in which well-owners may sell some of the water
they extract to neighboring farms or residents (Easter
et al., 1999). In a report published by the Nepal Water
Conservation Foundation and the Institute for Social
in 2003, with an option for a 30-year extension, with
the Imperial Irrigation District (IID), one of the largest
irrigation districts in the country.12 Under the terms of
the agreement, the SDCWA pays the IID to reduce its
diversion of Colorado River water, while the Authority
diverts a like amount farther upstream. After a 15-year
period intended to create time to address ecological
and public health impacts resulting from the trade, the
IID will shift to efficiency-based methods (such as lin-
ing canals and constructing regulating reservoirs) to
generate the water to be conserved. In essence, the
Authority is paying the District to improve the effi-
ciency of its operations and receiving the water con-
served. The trade is ramping up to a maximum volume
of 200,000 acre-feet per year by 2021, representing
about 25 percent of the region’s total water supply. In
2014, the price for the water was $594 per acre-foot,
plus an additional $445 per acre-foot to a different
agency to convey the water through its facilities. This
total, which does not include additional payments to
offset the environmental impacts of the trade, is about
half what the Authority has contracted to pay for water
generated by a new desalination plant on the coast.
In Central and South America, Chile and Mexico
have active water trading markets. Chile’s Limarí
Basin enjoys water rights trading and water transfers,
enabled by three large state-built reservoirs and robust
local water organizations. The actual number of water
trades in Chile’s Limarí Basin has averaged about 33
each year (Romano and Leporati, 2002), although
water trading has been more limited in the rest of the
country (Bauer, 1997). Mexico’s National Water Law of
1992 established a formal water market with tradable
concessions that formed the basis for active markets
12	 With the exception of “water conservancy districts”, to the best of our
knowledge there is no strict naming convention for water agencies. The
ability to create conservancy districts is established by statute, enabling
state district courts or other authorities to establish conservancy
districts with the power to impose property taxes to support district
functions (Howe, 2011). Water authorities tend to serve municipal areas,
and irrigation districts primarily serve agricultural users. However, the
San Diego County Water Authority has agricultural customers (fewer
than before, as they have phased out subsidies for irrigation water),
while the Imperial Irrigation District sells water to all of the cities within
its service area, serving more than 170,000 people. Similarly, water
conservancy districts usually serve agriculture, although some districts
may also serve municipal customers.
“Water banks are generally less widespread
than water trading…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 15
In 2003, nine states in the western United States had
functioning state-operated water banks, although their
level of activity varied dramatically and several are no
longer active. From 1995–2003, for example, Texas’
water bank only reported one transaction (Clifford, 2012).
California’s Drought Water Bank functioned for a limited
period in the early 1990s, providing a mechanism to facil-
itate and expedite water trading between agriculture and
cities during a multi-year drought, while also ensuring
minimum instream flows and providing limited ground-
water recharge. The Drought Water Bank purchased,
held, and sold water, primarily from northern agricultural
users to southern municipal and industrial users, though
about half of the more than 800,000 acre-feet pur-
chased in 1991 was dedicated to instream flows (20 per-
cent) and to recharge aquifers (32 percent) (Dinar et al.,
1997). Idaho operates water banks to manage storage
in reservoirs, and in Oregon, river conservancies oper-
ate as water trusts to purchase or lease water rights to
supplement instream flows (Clifford, 2012). The Northern
Colorado Water Conservancy District maintains a web-
page that functions as an online bulletin board connect-
ing those seeking to acquire water with those who have
water to rent, an example of a brokerage-type water
bank. The very active water trading within the Conser-
vancy District is attributable to the equal volume and
priority of each share available for trade, the absence
of any requirement to preserve return flows or protect
downstream or junior priority users, and the fact that
trading only requires the approval of the district itself,
not a water court, as is the case for most other trades
within Colorado (Howe and Goemans, 2003).
The Colorado River basin, shown in Figure 3, boasts a
large number of creative approaches to water bank-
ing. In 1998, the federal government adopted a new
rule permitting interstate banking agreements within
the basin. To date, Arizona has diverted and stored
more than 600,000 acre-feet of Colorado River water
for southern Nevada, and a southern California water
agency has diverted and stored more than 161,000
acre-feet for southern Nevada, representing creative
methods of skirting state prohibitions of interstate
water trading. In 2007, the seven basin states adopted
a new set of rules for managing the river that, among
and Environmental Transition, Moench et al. (2003)
described an active but largely unregulated water trad-
ing system in Chennai, India, where private companies
meet as much as 35 percent of urban water demand
by delivering raw or purified well water purchased
from farmers in surrounding areas or extracted from
the companies’ wells. This private sector engagement
helps meet a demand for water that the intermittent
municipal water supply cannot meet, though the price
is much higher. Moench et al. (2003) reported that the
price of water for urban customers can be 1,000 times
higher than the price paid to the peri-urban farmers
supplying the water. Also in Asia, in a rare international
water trade, the Bishkek Treaty of 1998 commit-
ted Kyrgyzstan to deliver water via the Syr Darya to
Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan in exchange for compen-
sation (Ambec et al., 2013). China reportedly has small,
local water markets (Grafton et al., 2010). In Oman,
the local falaj irrigation systems purchase short-term
allocations of water based on units of time rather than
volume (e.g. a certain duration of water delivery) in a
village-based auction (Al-Marshudi, 2007).
Water banks are generally less widespread than water
trading because they require additional expertise, fund-
ing, and governance structures. Water banks appear
to be most prevalent in the western United States,
although there are examples in several other coun-
tries. The presence of three reservoirs in Chile’s Limarí
Basin facilitates the large number of water trades in
the region (Bauer, 1997), meaning that, in this case,
the physical storage rather than an institutional bank
facilitates the water trades. In Australia, brokerage-type
water banks are active in both the Murray-Darling Basin
and in northern Victoria, where the banks post informa-
tion about pricing and availability (O’Donnell and Colby,
2010). Mexico’s National Water Commission reported
that the 13 state-based water banks in the country bro-
ker thousands of water trades annually (CONAGUA,
2012). In three basins in Spain, water banks operated
by local water agencies, known as “exchange centers”,
have successfully brokered water trades that have
lessened groundwater overdraft (Garrido and Llamas,
2009).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT16
system as a whole, rather than claiming it for them-
selves. In this instance, the Bureau of Reclamation acts
as a water bank by obtaining water through a reverse
auction process, augmenting system storage for the
benefit of the system as a whole.
Environmental, economic, and social
performance
The primary goal of water trading is usually to pro-
mote economic efficiency by reallocating water from
lower to higher value uses. However, in some cases,
other key developments, permitted entitlement hold-
ers in Arizona, California, and Nevada to invest in vari-
ous water efficiency projects within their own states
and store a percentage of the conserved water in
Lake Mead for later use. To date, more than 1.1 million
acre-feet have been stored in Lake Mead under this
new program. More recently, four large municipal water
agencies in the basin, in cooperation with the federal
Bureau of Reclamation, agreed to invest $11 million in
fallowing and efficiency improvements, and to dedi-
cate the conserved water to the Colorado River Basin
FIGURE 3. The Colorado River Basin
Source: Cohen et al., 2013.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 17
can be an effective means of reallocating water, where
the appropriate conditions exist. The application sec-
tion of 3.1 of this report describes the range of countries
where water trading occurs in general terms. In most of
these regions, limited data precludes detailed assess-
ment of the number or volume of water trading activi-
ties. In several locations, such as the Murray-Darling
Basin and the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy
District, water trades occur frequently, often for small
volumes, suggesting a robust and active market with
low transaction costs (Howe and Goemans, 2003). In
other areas, there tend to be fewer but larger transac-
tions, suggesting higher barriers to trading.
The largest agriculture-to-urban water trade in the
United States has been successful for San Diego
County, which currently receives about 25 percent of
its water supply from the rural Imperial Valley,13 at a
unit cost of water that is less than half the contracted
price of water from a desalination plant that will soon
be operational on the San Diego coastline. The long-
term water trade appears to be cost effective from San
Diego’s perspective but, due to significant externalities,
maynotbefromthebroadersociety’sperspective.Total
transaction costs for this water trade have exceeded
$175 million in attorney fees, plus an additional $171 mil-
lion in mitigation fees to offset public health and envi-
ronmental impacts. In addition, the State of California
agreed to cover all direct mitigation costs in excess
of a pre-determined financial cap for the water trade
parties. The magnitude of these additional mitigation
costs – primarily for managing dust emissions – will not
be known for many years but are expected to run into
the hundreds of millions of dollars (Cohen, 2014). As
suggested by the Imperial Valley-San Diego example,
a narrow focus on direct economic performance may
ignore trading’s broader economic impacts.
Although there are thousands of peer-reviewed
articles on the economic potential of water trading,
robust economic analyses of specific water trades do
13	 Roughly 15 percent of San Diego County’s current water supply comes
from the water trade with the Imperial Valley, while an additional 10 per-
cent comes from water conserved via the lining of the All-American
Canal, a project funded primarily by the state of California.
water trading has been used for environmental or rec-
reational purposes, reflecting the increasing societal
value ascribed to instream flows. In this section, we
evaluate the environmental, social, and economic per-
formance of water trading. While much of the literature
on water trading tends toward theoretical assessments
or recommendations about trading (Newlin et al., 2002)
or specific elements of trading, such as property rights
regimes or institutional capacity (Culp et al., 2014), we
examine the literature on actual impacts to evaluate
the state of practice.
ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Although there are a large number of articles and stud-
ies modeling the potential economic benefits of water
trading, the number of detailed economic assessments
of existing water trades is surprisingly limited. Some
studies on local impacts suggest positive net economic
performance,butthesestudiestypicallydonotdescribe
changes in the distribution of impacts, and they rarely
describe broader economic impacts. Assessing the
economic performance of water trading is frequently
as simple as documenting trading activity and quanti-
fying the number, volume, and value of reported water
trades. A more comprehensive analysis would require
surveys to estimate the number and volume of addi-
tional water trades that users would like to make, as a
means to assess the disparity between availability and
demand. An even more robust analysis would compare
the ability of different instruments – such as water trad-
ing, demand-side management, and supply augmenta-
tion – to meet specific water demands, and the cost
of those instruments. While water agencies seeking to
improve their water supply reliability may perform such
analyses within their service area, these assessments
are often not publicly available.
The large number of trades and the significant volumes
traded,especiallyinAustralia,indicatethatwatertrading
“…the number of detailed economic
assessments of existing water trades is
surprisingly limited.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT18
the trading activity in the district is short term and low
volume, especially in comparison with trading activ-
ity in the same water basin but outside of the district.
Municipal and industrial (M&I) users buy district water
rights to meet expected future demand and then lease
some of this water back to district irrigators. This ris-
ing M&I demand has increased the price of imported
water rights (known as allotments) within the district
(Howe, 2011). Within the relatively prosperous district,
this has improved economic performance. However, in
other regions, particularly in economically depressed
rural areas, selling water out of the area has exacer-
bated economic decline, causing property values to fall
and the local tax base to shrink (Howe, 2011).
In Australia, water trading has enabled the expan-
sion of the wine industry and other high value crops,
such as almonds. Over time, the dairy industry in one
part of the Murray-Darling Basin transitioned from a
small purchaser of water entitlements to a net seller of
entitlements, primarily to the expanding wine and nut
producers in other parts of the basin. These expanding
industries have also exhibited a shift from the former
model of shared irrigation infrastructure (such as com-
mon canals) to direct extraction from the river by indi-
vidual irrigators – in other words, from a communal to a
more flexible individual approach to irrigation (Frontier
Economics and Australia NWC, 2007).
Water trading within the Murray-Darling Basin grew
and matured within the context of the devastating
drought that afflicted the region from 2006 through
2010. The national water trading assessment noted
the challenge of disentangling the economic impacts
of the drought from those of water trading itself, gen-
erally concluding that trading offered irrigators an
additional revenue stream, plus additional flexibility
and resilience within the face of a severely limited
water supply. Without water trading, some sectors,
such as the dairy industry, would have seen even
greater losses. Trading also offered a mechanism to
adjust for historic water apportionments, facilitating
the voluntary sale of water from less productive to
more productive lands and uses (Frontier Economics
and Australia NWC, 2007).
not appear to exist. For example, despite its size and
importance, there do not appear to be any economic
analyses of the Imperial Valley-San Diego County
water trade that assess revenues, agricultural produc-
tion lost due to fallowing, value of transfer payments,
relative value of the water in San Diego, or employ-
ment impacts. There are, however, general regional or
district-level assessments of water trading, as well as
an extensive body of literature on macro-economic
trends, and expected or modeled benefits of water
trading. Yet, assessments of “net” economic benefit at
the state or regional level, expressed in terms of net
increase in employment or revenue, can mask dispari-
ties between areas of origin and importing areas, and
even within the areas of origin themselves.
In one study, the income and employment gains found
in regions in California that imported water via trades
exceeded the net losses (total compensation often
failed to cover foregone crop revenue) in exporting
areas (Howitt, 1998). In 1991, trading activity gener-
ated an average net income loss in water-exporting
areas equivalent to about 5 percent of net agricultural
activity, though this varied within different parts of the
state. However, agricultural areas importing water saw
total gains greater than the losses in exporting areas:
net agricultural water trading activity was positive, as
water moved from lower-value crops to higher-value
crops (Howitt, 1998). In another example, an agricul-
tural community in California exporting water to urban
areas saw a 26  percent decrease in the number of
farms overall, but this masked a 70 percent loss in the
number of small farms and the loss of almost half of
the number of produce firms in the area (Meinzen-Dick
and Pradhan, 2005).
The Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District,
introduced in Section 3.1, has a very active water mar-
ket in part because of low transaction costs. Much of
“In Australia, water trading has enabled the
expansion of the wine industry and other
high value crops, such as almonds.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 19
community support, especially relative to regulatory
takings. However, water trading can also generate large
environmental externalities, adversely affecting either
natural habitats or downstream users, or both (NRC,
1992). For example, when water for trading is generated
by efficiency or by fallowing land, the trade may reduce
the amount of runoff supporting local habitat and may
diminish instream flows.14 On the other hand, some
water trades may improve local instream flows by de-
creasing diversions and contaminant loadings. Where
water is traded to downstream users using the existing
stream as a conveyance, trading could offer measur-
able environmental benefits. Where water is traded out
of the basin or alters the timing and magnitude of flows,
adverse impacts are likely to occur. Unfortunately, there
do not appear to be published assessments of the rela-
tive impacts of water trading on streamflow.15 In the fol-
lowing, we discuss the environmental performance of
several examples of water trading.
Water trading is now used in some areas to return water
to river channels, in order to support listed species or
threatened habitats, and for general ecosystem restora-
tion (Tarlock, 2014). However in most areas, such activ-
ity still represents only a tiny fraction of total water use in
any given area.16 For example, the Colorado Water Trust
(CWT) brokered a lease agreement between two state
14	 In efficiency-based agricultural water trades, the buyer typically pays
the irrigator to install more efficient irrigation equipment or methods,
such as hiring additional irrigation management staff, installing pump-
back systems, lining canals, or constructing new regulatory reservoirs.
The water conserved by these new practices would then be available for
transfer to the buyer/investor. Efficiency-based trades keep agricultural
land in production and can increase total employment in the area of
origin, but they require additional monitoring and measurement to doc-
ument or calculate the volume of water conserved. In fallowing-based
trades, also known as “buy-and-dry”, the buyer simply pays the irrigator
not to irrigate and, in exchange, receives the volume of water historically
used by the parcel. This requires less effort and less time to implement,
but takes land out of production and typically generates significant
adverse impacts on rural communities.
15	 For example, the various water trading agreements between Imperi-
al Valley and urban Southern California will have the direct effect of
reducing the volume of water flowing down the lower Colorado River
between Parker Dam – the new diversion point – and Imperial Dam,
about 150 river miles downstream, by more than 300,000 acre-feet per
year, equivalent to roughly 5 percent of the historic average annual flow
between these two diversion points.
16	 Such instream flows typically require additional legal conditions, such
as explicit recognition of instream flow rights, improved monitoring and
measurement, and the acceptance of local entitlement holders.
The active participation of the Australian government
in water trading increased prices and participation but
may also have increased total water use within the
basin. A large survey (n=520) of those selling entitle-
ments or allocations to the Australian environmental
water program found that sellers believed they received
a higher price from the government than they would
have from other private agents, or that the government
was the only purchaser in the market. The survey also
found that sellers reportedly used 69 to 77 percent of
their water allocations prior to trading it to the govern-
ment (Wheeler and Cheesman, 2013). That is, survey
respondents reported selling portions of their alloca-
tions that they would not have used otherwise. Selling
unused water allocations is not a reallocation so much
as an expansion of total water use.
Water trading occurs in a variety of forms. Howe (2011)
noted that, in practice, many water trades reflect a
change in type of use rather than a change in loca-
tion. For example, in the Northern Colorado Water
Conservancy District, developers have purchased
farmland and its water rights and then converted the
land and water to residential or commercial use, often
generating a significant increase in revenue per unit
of water while limiting some of the social and environ-
mental externalities that would occur if the water were
physically moved to a different location.
ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE
Water trading has been used as a mechanism to obtain
water for ecological purposes, to augment streamflows,
and to address water quality concerns (such as tem-
perature) in threatened reaches. The environmental
performance of water trading is highly variable, de-
pending on the type of trade and site-specific condi-
tions. The benefits of voluntary, incentive-based water
acquisition include ease of transaction and greater
“Water trading can also generate large
environmental externalities, adversely
affecting either natural habitats or
downstream users, or both”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT20
trading activity between 1982 and 2011, but less than
0.5 percent of total water use in the state (Figure 4).
In Australia, the federal government has invested more
than $3 billion to date to purchase entitlements and
allocations for environmental water, protecting eco-
logical resources to enable and expedite water trading
between non-governmental users. In 2008–2009, for
example, the government purchased nearly 880,000
acre-feet of long-term water entitlements and 1.4 mil-
lion acre-feet of short-term allocations, at a total cost of
about $2 billion (adjusted to 2014$). The price for this
water ranged from about $269 to $377 per acre-foot.
Local interest in this environmental water buyback
program, known as “Restoring the Balance”, has been
strong, with the Australian government receiving nearly
7,600 applications to sell water from 2007 to early 2012.
Water entitlement sales for the environment account
agencies, increasing low-season flows in the White River
by 3,000 acre-feet of water three times over a 10-year
period to lower the temperature of river flows and, in
turn, benefit fish (CWT, 2015). Similarly, the Columbia
Basin Water Transactions Program, active for more than
a decade, works with partner organizations in four west-
ern states to acquire and dedicate water for instream
flows within the basin. In 2013, 45 transactions led to the
acquisition of more than 48,000 acre-feet of water, cost-
ing about $13.9 million and benefiting some 276 miles of
streams, the fish and wildlife, and the communities that
depend on them (National Fish and Wildlife Foundation,
2014). Bonneville Power Administration, in cooperation
with the Northwest Power and Conservation Council,
provides some of the funding for the program due,
in part, to concerns about endangered species. In
California, environmental water purchases averaged
152,000 acre-feet, accounting for about 14 percent of
FIGURE 4. Water purchases for the environment in California, 1982–2011
Source: Hanak and Stryjewski, 2012.
1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009
500
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
WaterPurchases(1,000acre-feet)
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 21
resulting in the loss of open water and wetland habitats
that support several hundred species of birds (Cohen
and Hyun, 2006).
Yet water trading occurs in regions of water scarcity,
where water resources in particular have already under-
gone dramatic transformation. Dams, canals, and diver-
sions have already altered the timing and magnitude
of stream flows throughout many of the regions now
turning to water trading (Worster, 1985). Determining
the additional impacts of water trading upon this exist-
ing landscape would be difficult. An alternative basis
for comparison could be the marginal or cumulative
environmental impacts of water trading relative to the
new impacts of additional water development. That is,
water trading may prove to be less environmentally
harmful than the construction of new dams and diver-
sion projects, or even the construction of new desalina-
tion plants.
SOCIAL PERFORMANCE
Water trading is usually characterized as a market-
based mechanism that reduces economic inefficiencies
by reallocating water from lower to higher value uses.
Trading has been used to meet explicit environmen-
tal objectives, but, as described previously, it is rarely
employed to address equity challenges. Indeed, water
trading can exacerbate social and economic inequali-
ties, worsening gender and geographic differences.
In regions with informal water rights and trading that
are functional at the community level, such as rural
Nepal, demands from outlying urban areas for larger
scale trades can overwhelm local water management
institutions. Trades from these rural areas might not
reflect the true value of the many informal uses water
has in the community (such as subsistence fishing or
milling) or the full range of informal ownership and use
for roughly 25  percent of total entitlement trading
activity (Wheeler and Cheesman, 2013). However,
some irrigators and state governments in Australia
oppose the instream buyback program, and it was cut
dramatically when the Labor Party fell from power in
September 2013 (Bennett and Carroll, 2014).
However, water trades not explicitly intended for envi-
ronmental purposes can create a host of adverse envi-
ronmental impacts. They can, for example, change the
timing, quantity, and quality of return flows, adversely
affecting riparian and wetland habitats and the species
that depend upon them. Some trades, such as from
California’s Owens Valley to Los Angeles, adversely
affect public health by increasing the amount of dust
emissions from exposed lakebed and fallowed land,
generating significant externalities (LA DWP, 2013).
Groundwater substitution, in which a user trades sur-
face water and increases groundwater extraction, can
lead to over-extraction, and sinking or caving in of land
surfaces (subsidence), depleting springs and seeps,
and robbing future generations (Brown et al., 2015).
Water trading can also diminish groundwater recharge
rates, whether the water is generated via fallowing or
increased efficiency. In the southern Indian state of
Tamil Nadu, farmers irrigating with groundwater have
increased extraction rates and sold the excess to water
tanker trucks serving urban populations, an example of
informal water trading. Yet this increased groundwater
extraction lowered the water table, increasing pump-
ing costs for other irrigators or drying up their wells
entirely (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005).
Efforts to mitigate the environmental impacts of water
trading have had mixed success. In Spain, a proposal to
add a small environmental mitigation fee to each unit
of water traded was insufficient to overcome the strong
opposition of environmental and social organizations
(Albiac et al., 2006). In California, state commitments to
mitigate the environmental and public health impacts
of the nation’s largest agriculture-to-urban water
trade have yet to result in any actual mitigation efforts,
potentially jeopardizing several listed species and likely
“…water trades not explicitly intended
for environmental purposes can create…
adverse environmental impacts.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT22
water first began flowing to LA, creating the single
largest source of dust pollution in the United States. In
the past decade, after years of litigation, LA has spent
more than $1.4 billion on dust management efforts and
has returned some of the water to Owens Lake.17
San Luis Valley, Colorado. As demonstrated by
efforts to destroy the infrastructure moving water out
of the Owens Valley, local opposition to trading water
can be strong. In the late 1980s, the Canadian owner
of the 97,000-acre Baca Ranch in southern Colorado’s
San Luis Valley began buying water rights from other
farms in San Luis Valley, allegedly to irrigate new crops.
Local residents, who soon discovered that the true pur-
pose of the purchases was to sell the water to Denver
suburbs, 100 miles to the northeast, feared that their
valley would experience the devastation felt in Owens
Valley. Thus, they formed Citizens for San Luis Valley
Water to fight the water trade, working with the local
irrigation district to support a special ballot measure
to raise local taxes to fund litigation against the pro-
posed water sale. The ballot measure prevailed with
92 percent of the vote. In 1991, the locals prevailed in
court, stopping the proposed water trade. After Baca
Ranch was subsequently sold, the new owner also
attempted to sell the water out of the valley, sponsor-
ing two statewide initiatives seen as efforts to support
the water trade. In 1998, both initiatives failed, receiving
less than 5 percent of the vote. With continued pub-
lic pressure, the federal government purchased Baca
Ranch in 2004 – more than a quarter century after
the fight began – to prevent water from leaving the
San Luis Valley. It then parceled the land to the newly
designated Great Sand Dunes National Park, part to a
nearby national forest, and 54,000 acres to the new
Baca National Wildlife Refuge (Reimers, 2013).
Imperial Valley, California. On the other hand, water
trading that promotes efficiency rather than fallowing
of agricultural land can improve socio-economic out-
comes for both the area of origin and the destination.
For example, an ongoing water trade from the Imperial
17	 For information on the dust emissions at Owens Lake and the current
dust management program, see the Great Basin Unified Air Pollution
Control District website.
rights within the community, meaning residents may be
deprived of full compensation (Pant el al., 2008). Even
within the community, the complex web of informal
water-use arrangements can complicate informal trad-
ing agreements and, in turn, generate a range of eco-
nomic impacts on those using the water who had not
been consulted or participated in the trading arrange-
ments (Pant et al., 2008).
Limarí Basin, Chile. Unequal access to water mar-
kets due to unequal access to information or credit can
distort outcomes and reduce market efficiency. Chile’s
Limarí Basin has very high water trading activity, sug-
gesting successful economic performance, but Romano
and Leporati (2002) argued that it suffers from several
market distortions arising from disparities between the
resources available to those trading water. Peasants
fare poorly in trading activity because their water rights
often are not fully recognized, they are not as well-
organized as those purchasing the water, and they lack
access to information on pricing (Romano and Leporati,
2002). Dinar et al. (1997) noted that economic perfor-
mance is affected by disparities in the value of water in
different sectors and by the ability of those with limited
means to participate in water trading.
Southern California. Water generated for trades by
fallowing land can benefit water rights holders at the
expense of farmworkers and equipment suppliers,
potentially devastating rural communities. California’s
Owens Valley provides one of the early examples of
the adverse impacts of trading water away from rural
areas. In the early 1900s, agents secretly representing
the City of Los Angeles (LA) covertly purchased land in
the Owens Valley. In 1908, LA began a 5-year construc-
tion project of a 419-mile pipeline to divert water from
Owens Valley farmland to LA. Although Owens Valley
irrigators had willingly sold their water through market
transactions, they had not contemplated the plight of
the valley as a whole. Over the next several years, agi-
tators from the valley dynamited the pipeline several
times in a vain attempt to protect their water supplies
(Hundley, 2001). In addition to the direct economic and
social impacts on the Owens Valley, the water trade
had desiccated Owens Lake by 1926, just 13 years after
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 23
within households where men have left for new indus-
trial jobs enabled by new water supplies. In places
where rural agriculture, particularly at the household
level, provides subsistence and food security, reduced
access to water can impose significant adverse impacts
(Farolfi and Perret, 2002).
Rural household access to water for domestic uses
and for subsistence agriculture may have only infor-
mal community-level recognition that does not trans-
late into tradable water rights. Water trading that does
not recognize these informal or ad hoc water uses can
adversely affect equity outcomes and prompt ques-
tions of legitimacy (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005).
Formal, state-recognized water rights typically require
the means and ability to register and defend them,
in turn conferring power on those with formal water
rights. In South Asia and other parts of the develop-
ing world, informal water-use arrangements that permit
and enable water use and trading can be disrupted by
formal rights-based trades and command-and-control
reallocations (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005).
Zwarteveen (1997) noted that, as men in Ecuador,
Nepal, and Peru have migrated in search of employ-
ment, women have assumed a disproportionately large
number of agricultural roles, even as formal and infor-
mal water rights continue to be held by the absent men.
These geographic and gender disparities can generate
adverse outcomes as water is traded by absentee own-
ers. Conversely, trading within households – even in the
form of recognition of joint ownership – can encourage
investment in water resource maintenance and pro-
ductivity at the local level (Zwarteveen, 1997). Similarly,
water organizations in the developing world, where
decisions may be made about trading water out of
the community, tend to have limited female participa-
tion, potentially neglecting compensation for impacts
that would have been identified if there were stronger
female roles and participation (Zwarteveen, 1997).
Water trading mechanisms can privilege certain popu-
lations and marginalize others, especially when cultural
practices differ. For example, New Mexico’s cooperative
irrigation systems, known as acequias, usually enjoy
Valley that began in 1989 relies on efficiency-based
measures rather than fallowing to generate water for
trade, creating additional employment while keeping
land in production.18
Water trading’s social impacts vary based on several
factors, including the relative economic health of the
area of origin and the purchasing area, whether or not
the water leaves the area of origin, the process used to
trade the water, and the relative economic and politi-
cal power of the parties (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan,
2005), gender differences regarding access to and
control of water (Zwarteveen, 1997), the amount of
trading activity in the area (Howe, 2011), and the legiti-
macy of the water rights being traded (Meinzen-Dick
and Pradhan, 2005). Impacts often vary within the
same community, as those with water rights or alloca-
tions to trade receive compensation, while third parties
– such as irrigation equipment suppliers or farmwork-
ers – may suffer a loss of revenue or income as a result
of trading (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005).
Water trades within the same region typically have
minimal or no adverse social or equity impacts. Howe
(2011) noted the large number of small-volume, short-
term water trades within an irrigation district as an
example of positive economic and equity outcomes.
Inter-sectoral trades, such as from agricultural to
manufacturing or mining within the same region, may
also generate positive economic and equity outcomes,
as jobs shift from lower income farm employment to
higher income industrial employment (Meinzen-Dick
and Pradhan, 2005). However, Zwarteveen (1997)
noted that even such intra-regional trades can gen-
erate differential impacts based on gender, requiring
additional agricultural and domestic labor for women
18	 The Imperial Irrigation District’s IID/MWD Water Conservation Program
Final Construction Report (2000) documented that 24 separate system
water conservation projects and programs (as opposed to on-farm),
such as lining irrigation canals and installing new headgates, had been
implemented through 1999. The capital cost for these totaled $193
million (2014$), with an additional $8.3 million in annual operations and
maintenance costs. These improvements yield 108,500 acre-feet of
conserved water per year, at a cost of $254 per acre-foot. In addition
to the jobs associated with the initial construction effort, the on-going
water trade supports about 12–13 full-time positions for managing water
deliveries, and for annual operations and maintenance.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT24
trading can increase costs for those who do not sell,
such as operations and maintenance costs associated
with water storage and delivery structures. The eco-
nomic and equity impacts of water traded from rural
areas can accumulate with additional trading activity,
reaching a tipping point where local demand for agri-
cultural services falls below the level necessary to main-
tain operations, creating a cascading set of business
failures and depressing the local tax base (Howe, 2011).
Agricultural areas importing traded water may also suf-
fer from third-party impacts, in the form of increased
competition, extended wait-times for water deliveries
via shared infrastructure, and rising water tables that
may threaten plant roots or require additional drainage
(Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007).
The one key exception to water trading that exacer-
bates social and economic inequalities is in South
Africa. Section 27(1) of South Africa’s 1998 National
Water Act states:
“In issuing a general authorisation or licence a re-
sponsible authority must take into account all
relevant factors, including…
(b) the need to redress the results of past racial and
gender discrimination;…
(d) the socio-economic impact –
(i) of the water use or uses if authorised; or
(ii) of the failure to authorise the water use or
uses.”
While this act explicitly sought to use water trading to
improve socio-economic conditions,19 South Africa’s
Department of Water Affairs and Forestry (now known
as the Department of Water and Sanitation) refused to
permit more than 118 applications for water trades from
2005 through 2008, claiming that the trades failed to
meet the Section 27(1) standards (Coleman, 2008).
South Africa’s Supreme Court found in 2012 that: i) one
proposed trade would create new employment oppor-
tunities for both men and women in a region with high
unemployment, meeting the standard established by
19	 The National Water Act is available at http://www.acts.co.za/national-wa-
ter-act-1998/.
very senior water rights. However, they have fared
poorly when defending their rights or seeking com-
pensation for third-party impacts in state proceedings,
where language and cultural practices favor fluency in
English and legal literacy (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan,
2005). Romano and Leporati (2002) found similar
circumstances in Chile, where less-educated rural
peasants fared poorly in trading water rights to more
powerful non-agricultural interests.
Economic disparities also affect water-trading out-
comes. As with the acequias, wealthy, powerful inter-
ests enjoy disproportionate advantages relative to
many historic water rights holders. In South Africa in
the late 1990s, mining interests sought to increase
their production and activity in rural, water-scarce
regions by purchasing water rights from small irri-
gators, at prices ten times higher than other irriga-
tors were willing to offer. Although the mines offered
employment and generated greater returns per unit
of water, they threatened to dewater local subsis-
tence farms and adversely affect a broad swath of
rural economies beyond the irrigators voluntarily sell-
ing their water (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). A study of
water trading in Chile’s Limarí Valley found a similar
impact, where increasing rural poverty was traced to
water rights sales from peasants to non-agricultural
interests and the general worsening of water-rights
distribution (Romano and Leporati, 2002).
As noted in the examples of the Owens and San Luis
Valleys, those in areas of origin can strongly, sometimes
violently, oppose the sale of water to outside interests.
A national study of water trading in Australia found
that this opposition can extend to local interests that
trade their water rights to external interests (Frontier
Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). In addition to
cultural and social bases for opposing such trades,
“Water trading mechanisms can
privilege certain populations and
marginalize others…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 25
Grafton et al. (2010) wrote that “Legal clarity over
water rights, including what they can be used for and
the rules of water trade, is a cornerstone of functioning
water markets.” Diversion or, better yet, consumptive
use water rights with clear title and quantified alloca-
tions that can be leased or sold can be described as
marketable property rights, a necessary condition for
water trading (Grafton et al., 2012). Culp et al. (2014)
noted that water trading requires legally enforceable
contracts that clearly and completely define the water
right to be traded, an exclusive right to the water, and
the recognized right to trade the water. Government
plays a clear role in establishing these necessary condi-
tions, documenting and, in some cases, allocating water
rights themselves, establishing and maintaining the
legal framework in which trading occurs and, in many
cases, financing the physical infrastructure to store and
convey water and allow water trading to occur (Dinar
et al., 1997). Strong and effective institutions that adju-
dicate and resolve disputes, enforce contracts, and
monitor trading agreements are a necessary element
in successful water markets (Zwarteveen, 1997).
Typically, infrastructure is also required to physically
convey water from a seller to a buyer, or to store or
otherwise manage water availability so that an agreed-
upon volume can be conveyed to the buyer at the
appropriate time. In some cases, creative agreements
have enabled trades from unconnected or remote
sources of water, creating what are known as “in-lieu” or
“paper” trades.21 While these trades can avoid require-
ments for connecting physical infrastructure, they do
require sophisticated legal arrangements, manage-
ment, and monitoring to ensure that the correct vol-
umes of water move at the approved time.
21	 One example of an in-lieu water trade is the agreement between the
Metropolitan Water District of Southern California and the Coachella
Valley Water District and the Desert Water Agency. All three have
contracts with California’s State Water Project (SWP), but because a
direct connection from SWP’s California Aqueduct to Coachella Valley
would have cost the equivalent of more than $1.8 billion, the latter two
agencies agreed to an in-lieu exchange agreement with Metropolitan for
a “bucket-for-bucket” exchange of SWP water for Colorado River water.
That is, Metropolitan takes the other agencies’ allotment of SWP water,
in exchange for giving up an equivalent amount of Colorado River water.
Source: cvwd.org/news/news178.php.
Section 27, and ii) the Department had acted improp-
erly in failing to grant the requested license to trade
the water.20 According to a local source, however, the
responsible authorities in South Africa continue to
delay and deny licenses for water trades, meaning that
South Africa’s water market has been restricted for a
decade (Backeberg, personal communication, 2015).
Necessary, enabling, and
limiting conditions
Institutional arrangements determine the ultimate
success or failure of water trading (Livingston, 1998).
Successful water trading requires secure and flexible
water rights that recognize and protect users and others
from externalities. Such institutional arrangements also
need to be flexible enough to adapt to changing physical
conditions as well as changing social norms, such as the
growing interest in meeting environmental needs and
protecting water quality (Livingston, 1998). Recognizing
and understanding these factors can help explain the
varying successes and even the existence of water trad-
ing in different countries and regions within countries.
Some factors, such as legal and transferable rights to
use water, may be necessary for water trading to occur.
Others, such as access to timely information about water
available to trade, can enable water trading but may not
be required for trading to occur. Still other factors, such
as “no injury” regulations and “area of origin” protections,
limit water trading or function as barriers or obstacles to
trading. The following explains the details of the neces-
sary, enabling and limiting conditions.
Necessary conditions include:
•	 legal, transferable rights to use water
•	 decoupling of water rights from land rights
•	 contract adjudication and enforcement
•	 means for buyers and sellers to communicate
•	 physical infrastructure to move water
•	 mechanisms to monitor and measure water flows
and use.
20	 Makhanya v Goede Wellington Boerdery (Pty) Ltd (230/12) [2012]
ZASCA 205 (30 November 2012).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT26
as precluding trading while the higher end of the scale
can be seen as enabling trading.
Water banks can enable water trading by connecting
buyers and sellers, posting information on availability
and transaction history and, in some cases, by physi-
cally storing water to match availability and demands.
The existence of technically skilled staff and monitor-
ing equipment increases the efficacy of water banks
and can help resolve disputes. Where water banks do
not exist or have limited capacity, water contracting
can enable spot trading (Brown et al., 2015).
The availability of pertinent information can be con-
sidered both a necessary and an enabling condition,
depending on the extent and type of information avail-
able. The availability of information on quantity, quality,
location, and timing of water entitlements or alloca-
tions can enable trading by pairing sellers and buy-
ers. Similarly, clear information about transaction costs
enables trading. Additionally, greater information and
certainty about future conditions, such as the security
of a water right given climate changes, can also enable
water trading (Brown et al., 2015). Clear and timely
information about prices also facilitates trading and
decreases search costs (Levine et al., 2007).
Social cohesion can also enable water trading. Trading
is more likely to occur where informal bonds exist, such
as between neighbors or within an irrigation district or
even between irrigators, relative to trading between
parties with no common history. In some cases, irriga-
tors will accept a lower bid from another irrigator than
a higher bid from a municipal agency, particularly one
from outside the basin or region. Water rights hold-
ers may fear that indicating they have water to trade
could be interpreted to mean that they do not need the
water, jeopardizing the right or imposing political costs
(Albiac et al., 2006).
Water trading can and does occur when necessary con-
ditions are satisfied, but markets are much more robust
and active when additional enabling conditions are met.
Enabling conditions include:
•	 water rights equivalency (as opposed to prioritized
rights)
•	 water banks and contracts
•	 clear, available information
•	 social cohesion
•	 competitive markets with multiple participants of
roughly equivalent economic power.
One of the major factors contributing to Australia’s
successful adoption of water trading in the Murray-
Darling Basin was the absence of prioritized water
rights. This enabled water trading without concern for
impacts on those holding less senior water rights (see
Annex 1 for greater detail). By contrast, in the western
United States and other regions with prioritized water
rights (also known as prior appropriation or seniority),
an entitlement holder with a senior water right (deter-
mined by the date the right was first exercised or “per-
fected”) could only sell or lease water after ensuring
that more junior rights holders receive compensation or
do not otherwise protest the transaction. This distinc-
tion helps explain the frequency of trades within irriga-
tion districts where district members share a common
priority right – such as the Northern Colorado Water
Conservancy District – and the much lower number
of transactions between those with different priorities.
That is, common priority rights or water rights with
equivalent seniority can be traded more readily than
rights with different priority dates.
Dinar and Saleth (2005) proposed a scale from zero
to seven to describe a range of surface water rights
conditions that could be used to evaluate the enabling
conditions for water trading. It spans from a rating of
zero for no water rights, to a rating of five for appropria-
tive rights; six for proportional sharing systems (such
as the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District
and Australia); and seven for water licenses and per-
mits. Under this system, we could categorize no rights
“Social cohesion can also enable water
trading. Trading is more likely to occur
where informal bonds exist…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 27
The anti-speculation doctrine requires buyers to
describe the new location and use of the water, condi-
tioning the trade on these terms and increasing trans-
action costs (Culp et al., 2014). The anti-speculation
doctrine is intended to prevent hoarding and mar-
ket distortion by those with the economic means to
acquire large volumes of water (Grafton et al., 2010). In
some areas, this doctrine is waived for municipal water
agencies, enabling them to acquire water for unspeci-
fied future needs.
The beneficial use doctrine requires that water rights
be exercised, encouraging inefficient or unproductive
uses as rights holders must “use it or lose it.” Some
jurisdictions have amended beneficial use require-
ments to enable rights holders to sell or lease the water
they conserve or save by implementing efficiency mea-
sures, water they would otherwise simply lose to junior
rights holders. Without explicit protection for such
conservation measures, the beneficial use doctrine
precludes water efficiency and hinders trading. In some
areas, laws prohibit users from selling or leasing water
“salvaged” from conservation or efficiency measures
(Culp et al., 2014).
Some kinds of water rights, such as non-consumptive,
appurtenant water rights (common in wetter regions of
the world) do not lend themselves to water trading.22
Examples of such non-consumptive rights include
rights to use or divert water to run mills or generate
hydroelectric power.
Some markets limit participation to existing contractors
or entitlement holders (Albiac et al., 2006). A related
barrier is a limitation on the purpose or use to which
a buyer may apply water. For example, several states
only allow state agencies, and not private individuals or
non-profit organizations, to purchase or lease water for
environmental purposes.
22	 An appurtenant water right is directly tied to the land itself, typically to
lands adjacent to streams.
Levine et al. (2007) argued that successful water trad-
ing requires the participation of multiple buyers and
sellers, with roughly equivalent power. They contended
that, without these factors, market inefficiencies will
result. In Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin and within
several United States irrigation districts, the satisfac-
tion of these criteria has enabled active and successful
water trading. In their absence, as seen in many agricul-
tural-to-urban trades, a small number of economically
powerful buyers have distorted markets and created
significant externalities.
Limiting conditions, which hinder or reduce water
trading, include:
•	 no injury rule
•	 anti-speculation doctrine
•	 beneficial use doctrine
•	 property rights/pre-conditions
•	 high transaction costs
•	 spatial and temporal differences in supply and de-
mand.
In many arid and semi-arid regions, water scarcity and
variability dictate that upstream “return flows” – water
diverted but not consumed that subsequently returns
to the stream – are used and claimed by downstream
users. To protect the rights of these downstream users,
courts or regulators typically require that the quantity
and timing of these return flows be maintained when
upstream water is traded. These and similar protections,
known as “no injury” rules, place the burden of proof that
the trade will not harm or adversely affect other water
rights on those wishing to sell or lease water. The “no
injury” rule is the prevailing law in most of the western
United States, intended to presumptively protect junior
water rights holders from harm that may occur due to
changes in the volume or timing of return flows from
senior appropriators. It dramatically increases transac-
tion costs, requiring sellers to hire attorneys and hydrol-
ogists to prove no injury, or otherwise compensate all
junior entitlement holders, and was a strong disincen-
tive to water trading (Culp et al., 2014).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT28
services (Figure 5). Payments are made to the envi-
ronmental service provider by the beneficiary of those
services, e.g. an individual, a community, a company,
or a government. In essence, it is based on a benefi-
ciary-pays principle, as opposed to a polluter-pays
principle. Environmental services most often included
in PES arrangements include carbon sequestration in
biomass or soils; habitat provision for endangered spe-
cies; protection of landscapes; and various hydrological
functions related to the quality, quantity, or timing of
freshwater flows from upstream areas to downstream
users (Gómez-Baggethun et al., 2010).
PES has no standardized definition. The definition most
commonly used in the literature was developed by
Wunder (2005) and is based on five criteria: i) a volun-
tary transaction where ii) a well-defined environmental
service is iii) purchased by at least one environmental
service buyer from iv) at least one environmental ser-
vice provider, with v) payment conditional on the ser-
vice provided. In reality, few projects actually meet all
of these criteria. For example, money may come from
donors rather than service providers, or participation in
theprogrammaybemandatory.Wunder(2005)argued,
and several reviews confirm, that conditionality is the
hardest criteria to meet because initiatives are often
loosely monitored and payments are made up front or
in good faith. Moreover, in some cases, participation
is not voluntary (e.g. China), and the beneficiaries are
broadly defined and are not directly contributing to the
program. Wunder (2005) concluded that while there
are a considerable number of PES-like arrangements,
there are likely “very few ‘true PES’ conforming to the
theoretical concept developed in the literature.”
PES programs focused on watershed services are
commonly referred to as payment for watershed ser-
vices, or PWS. PWS arrangements, as with all PES
arrangements, can take a variety of forms. They can
be intended to prevent the degradation of a watershed
or to restore a previously degraded watershed. They
can be small, local schemes covering several hundred
hectares or large, national schemes covering millions of
High transactions costs, driven by the various doctrines
noted above as well as by the need to overcome infor-
mation constraints and related factors, can hinder water
trading. Similarly, the time required to complete a trans-
action may limit trading, particularly when buyers seek
to meet a short-term demand such as an additional irri-
gation cycle or to offset a delivery disruption within an
urban system; relatively fast trades will produce greater
trading activity than prolonged approval processes.
Finally, geographic and temporal mismatches between
supply and demand can impose additional barriers to
water trading, especially in the absence of physical
infrastructure to bridge these gaps. Where dams and
conveyances do not exist, those wishing to sell water
may lack the means to physically deliver the water to a
potential buyer, or be unable to deliver the water at the
right time (Bauer, 1997).
3.2 	Payment for ecosystem
services/payment for
watershed services
Description
Payment for ecosystem services (PES) is an incentive-
based instrument that seeks to monetize the external,
non-market values of environmental services, such
as removal of pollutants and regulation of precipita-
tion events, into financial incentives for local actors to
provide such services. In practical terms, PES involves
a series of payments to a land or resource manager
in exchange for a guaranteed flow of environmental
“High transactions costs, driven by the
various doctrines noted above as well
as by the need to overcome information
constraints and related factors, can
hinder water trading.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 29
•	 Service providers. For the vast majority of lo-
cal and national programs, private landowners are
the main watershed service providers, followed by
communal landholders, private reserves, national
parks and, in a very small number of local schemes,
occupiers of public land.
•	 Payment levels. In national programs, payment
levels are mostly determined administratively. In
the local programs, negotiation through an inter-
mediary is more common. Direct negotiations be-
tween supplier and buyer occur in very few cases.
Funds and transfer of payments are in most cases
managed by an intermediary, often in a specially
set up trust fund.
hectares. PWS schemes can be financed directly from
the beneficiary or from third parties acting on behalf
of the beneficiary, e.g. governments or institutions, or
some combination thereof. They can involve cash or
in-kind payments and be paid all at once or periodi-
cally. In a comprehensive review of 50 ongoing PWS
programs in developing countries, Porras et al. (2008)
highlighted the following major trends.
•	 Scale. Most ongoing programs (82 percent) are lo-
cal, operating at watershed level or smaller. The re-
maining 18 percent are national programs. Some of
the local programs are linked to national programs
or international projects.
•	 Scope. Local programs tend to target one or two
watershed services (more commonly water qual-
ity than water quantity), while national programs
tend to target multiple environmental services as
a means of tapping into multiple funding sources.
FIGURE 5. Schematic of a PES arrangement for watershed services
Watershed services
e.g. water purification,
flood risk mitigation,
aquifer recharge,
erosion minimization
Balances upstream and
downstream interests
Upstream community
Stewards and providers
of waterhsed services
Incentives
e.g. cash, assistance,
materials Project
Payments
Downstream water users
Beneficiaries of watershed services
Source: Forest Trends, 2012.
“PWS schemes can be financed directly from
the beneficiary or from third parties…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT30
that preserving the upstream rural Catskill watershed
would be far less expensive. However, New York City
had a long-history of employing eminent domain to
solve such issues. When farmers and rural landowners
voiced immediate concern, the city and local farmers
came together to develop a plan that could meet both
groups’ interests. A key element of the plan was the
Whole Farm Program, a voluntary effort fully funded
by New York City’s Department of Environmental
Protection whereby farmers would work with technical
advisors to custom design point and nonpoint source
pollution control measures to meet an environmen-
tal objective while also improving the viability of their
farming business. By 2006, the city had spent or com-
mitted $1.4–$1.5 billion in watershed protection proj-
ects, averaging $167 million in expenditures per year
(Kenny, 2006). Participation remains high, with 96 per-
cent of large farms in the watershed participating in the
program (Watershed Agricultural Council, 2011).
PWS arrangements have also been established in
developing countries. In Ecuador, for example, the Socio
Bosque Program (SBP), a national program established
in 2008, provides financial incentives to individual and
communal forest landowners to conserve native forest
and Andean tundra ecosystems. The program, which
includes environmental protection and poverty alle-
viation objectives, is largely state funded. Since 2012,
however, additional support has been provided by
the German Development Bank, NGOs, and General
Motors Omnibus BB. Program participation is volun-
tary. Participants are provided a monetary incentive
per hectare of land entered into the program, and in
exchange, must agree to refrain from logging, changing
existing land uses, burning, altering hydrological condi-
tions or reducing carbon storage, and commercial or
sport hunting and fishing for 20 years. By mid-2013,
1.1 million hectares had been conserved through 2,100
individual and 150 communal agreements (Raes and
Mohebalian, 2013).
While PWS programs can be found in a wide range of
settings and, in some cases, have been operating for
decades, comprehensive data on their size or scope are
not available. Ecosystem Marketplace (2013) estimated
•	 Funding sources. Funding sources are varied. Na-
tional programs primarily receive government fund-
ing through the allocation of national budgets and
donor funding, including loans from the World Bank.
Funding for local programs is more varied but is pri-
marily from: domestic and agricultural water fees;
donors, including the Global Environment Facility
(GEF), World Bank, and German Cooperation; the
private sector, including downstream hydroelectric
companies (in some cases, in the form of a dona-
tion); and local government budgets.
•	 Conditionality. Nearly all programs are uncon-
ditional, meaning service providers are paid on a
per unit area basis for land-management practices
“believed to have a high probability of resulting in
provision of the environmental service.” Only one
payment scheme, Indonesia’s Rewarding Upland
Poor for Environmental Services (RUPES) initia-
tive, is conditional on outcomes, such as the level
of sediment reduction achieved.
Application
PWS arrangements are gaining prominence and have
been applied in a wide range of settings. For example,
the US Conservation Reserve Program (CRP), estab-
lished in the 1950s in an effort to reduce erosion on
agricultural lands, became more conservation oriented
in the mid-1980s, making it among the oldest and lon-
gest running PES programs in the world. CRP today
pays farmers to take land out of production in order
to protect soil and water resources, as well as wildlife
habitat (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). In northeastern
France, Vittel-Nestle Waters paid farmers and provided
technical support (and some labor) to alter local dairy
farming practices in order to reduce nitrate pollution
of groundwater – the source of Vittel’s bottled water
(Perrot-Maitre 2006).
New York City provides another well-known example.
In the late 1990s, New York City was faced with the
prospect of building a $4–$6 billion filtration plant with
an additional $250 million in annual operating costs
to meet new federal Safe Drinking Water Act require-
ments – an approach that was “treating symptoms, not
causes” (Appleton, 2010). An initial analysis suggested
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 31
•	 many programs lack baseline data or monitoring
systems
•	 the connections between land-use practice and
watershed services are not always clear, especially
as they relate to water quantity, and are often site
specific
•	 it can be difficult to attribute change to the pro-
gram rather than to external factors (e.g. changing
commodity prices)
•	 programs may not reach threshold levels for mea-
sureable impact, or that impact may occur over a
relatively long time period.
As a result of these challenges, reliance on input-
based indicators (sometimes referred to as behavioral
change) has been borne out of necessity.
Porras (personal communication, 2015) argued that
because of these challenges, monitoring should be
based on input-based, rather than outcome-based,
indicators, as outcome-based indicators shift too much
risk to the ecosystem service provider and may raise
equity concerns. She further noted the need to set
meaningful expectations. For example, conservation
projects may be implemented within a landslide-prone
watershed to reduce the risk of landslides, with the
understanding that, even with a successful program,
a landslide would still likely occur, albeit with reduced
frequency and intensity over the long term. Thus, an
expectation of no landslides is unrealistic and could
threaten the viability of the program.
In the absence of data on project outcomes, Porras
et al. (2008) found that reported impacts are often
based on “perceptions of local populations and those
operating the schemes and/or quick measurements of
what the impacts should be, rather than in-depth sci-
entific evidence drawing from site measurements and
modelling of relationships.” But even based on these
sources, the available data suggest that environmental
performance is mixed. In a review of previous studies
that the total transaction value of PWS programs and
water funds in 2012 was $8.0 billion. Activity in 2013
was considerably higher, with an estimated $11.5 billion
in transaction value for PWS programs in China alone.
While these data suggest dramatic growth, Bennett
(personal communication, 2015) noted that the differ-
ence can largely be explained by better reporting by
a larger number of projects. Case studies of PWS pro-
grams in developing countries are maintained by the
London-based International Institute for Environment
and Development and at Watershed Connect, an online
platform maintained by Forest Trends (2015a).
Environmental, economic, and
social performance
Comprehensive studies on the performance of PWS
programs are limited, although some studies have
been conducted on various aspects of these programs.
Below, we examine the available evidence looking at
how PWS has performed environmentally, economi-
cally, and socially.
ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE
The environmental performance of PWS is not well
understood due to a lack of scientific analysis. In an
analysis of 47 PWS schemes in developing countries,
Brouwer et al. (2011) found that “less than half of the
schemes used quantifiable indicators and monitored
the impact of the schemes on environmental perfor-
mance.” In most cases, the indicators were input-based,
meaning that they, for example, looked at land area with
forest cover, rather the actual impacts and outcomes
of the program. In a review of Costa Rica’s programs,
Pagiola (2008) found it “unfortunately impossible
to determine the extent to which the PSA23 program
has successfully generated environmental services.
Although the PSA program has established a strong
system to monitor land user compliance with payment
contracts, the program remains weak in monitoring its
effectiveness in generating the desired services.”
There are several challenges to evaluating environ-
mental performance:
23	 Pagos por servicios ambientales (payment for environmental services)
“…PWS programs can be found in a wide
range of settings…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT32
applicants for forest protection are prioritized based
on the total number of points they receive, with more
points awarded for forests in indigenous territories or
those protecting water resources. Likewise, applicants
for reforestation projects are awarded more points if
they use native species or reforest degraded areas with
high forestry potential (Porras et al., 2013). The selec-
tion criteria can be tailored to reflect the environmental
(and even social objectives) of the program and altered
as priorities or needs change.
ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Payment structures are generally uniform and untar-
geted, with flat rates per hectare for all sites (Porras et al.,
2008; Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). Despite the preva-
lence of uniform, untargeted payments, program costs
and benefits are spatially heterogeneous. Wunschler et
al. (2006) found that ecosystem service provision varies
spatially according to the ecosystem benefits, the threat
of loss, and the cost of service provision. Several stud-
ies have suggested that untargeted, uniform payments
reduce the cost effectiveness of PES schemes (Dillaha
et al., 2007; Ferraro, 2008), and given likely constraints
on program budgets, reduces the project benefits and
its long-term success (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010).
Reverse auctions (also referred to as procurement auc-
tions) have been put forth as one option for improving
the economic efficiency of PWS schemes (Karousakis
and Brooke, 2010). In an ordinary auction, the buy-
ers compete to obtain a good or service by offering
increasingly higher prices. With reverse auctions, the
sellers compete to obtain business from the buyer,
and prices typically decrease as sellers undercut one
another. The US Conservation Reserve Program, for
example, combines reverse auctions with an environ-
mental benefit index to select land for inclusion in the
program. However, Ferraro (2008) acknowledged that
and surveys of PWS scheme managers, Brouwer et
al. (2011) found that “58 percent of the PWS schemes
were classified as effective in reaching their environ-
mental objectives, while 42 percent were not.” Several
factors, ranging from the number of intermediaries and
mode of participation to the selection of service provid-
ers, level of community participation and type of moni-
toring, were found to improve environmental outcomes:
•	 schemes with fewer intermediaries were more ef-
fective in meeting environmental objectives
•	 mandatory participation increased environmental
effectiveness compared with voluntary schemes
•	 selecting service providers based on a set of crite-
ria, e.g. location, accessibility of land, or parcel size,
tended to have a negative impact on environmen-
tal performance
•	 contracting with the community was more effective
than contracting with a single ecosystem service
provider
•	 programs that monitored progress toward achiev-
ing environmental objectives were more likely to
reach those objectives.
The study also found that schemes for direct payments
by downstream hydropower companies to upstream
land owners to reduce sediment loads were generally
identified as successful, while other factors – includ-
ing the type of watershed service, age of the scheme,
or scale of implementation – had no significant effect
on the outcome. Recognizing this, Brouwer et al. (2011)
called for international monitoring guidelines to com-
pare programs, identify success factors, and support
their future design.
Some have suggested that one way to improve envi-
ronmental outcomes is through better selection of
areas to include within the PWS program, a process
that could be facilitated by the application of new tech-
nologies (e.g. satellite imagery) and modeling efforts.
Porras et al. (2013) identified several criteria suggested
in the literature for targeting efforts, including focus-
ing on areas at high risk of deforestation, large blocks
of land prone to landslides or other natural disasters,
and biological corridors. In Costa Rica, for example,
“…studies have suggested that untargeted,
uniform payments reduce the cost
effectiveness of PES schemes…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 33
rivers in China. Total investment is $4.3 million per year.
Farmers in the Yangtze River Basin are paid yuan 417
per hectare per year ($50), while those in the Yellow
River Basin are paid yuan 290 ($36) per hectare per
year. In addition to the regular cash payments, farm-
ers also receive a one-off cash payment and regular
grain rations (Porras and Neves, 2006a). The program
is designed to promote forestry and other economic
endeavors on the land, rather than grain production.
Given that most programs are voluntary, some have
argued that continued participation provides some indi-
cation that the programs are cost effective, i.e. that the
benefits exceed the costs. The impact of PWS schemes
on ecosystem service providers is generally estimated
by looking at the payment as a fraction of household
income. Using this metric, results are varied. Kosoy et
al. (2007) found that the amount received from the
PWS scheme was less than 2 percent of gross annual
income for most providers in three cases in Costa Rica,
Nicaragua, and Honduras; moreover, most watershed
service providers did not think that the payment was
fair. However, Wunder (2008) found that payments
represented 10 to 16 percent of household income in
schemes in Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Venezuela, and
Vietnam. Even these studies did not examine the trans-
action costs participants incurred in the program or
the opportunity costs. In light of these findings, several
studies have suggested that there are also important
non-financial (or non-income) benefits (Kosoy et al.,
2007; Wunder, 2008). The most commonly cited non-
financial benefits include increasing land-tenure secu-
rity, increasing human and social capital through internal
organization, and increasing the visibility of the commu-
nity to donors and public entities (Wunder, 2008).
SOCIAL PERFORMANCE
Limited data are available on the social outcomes of PES
programs, as studies have been more narrowly focused
on “short- or mid-term outcomes such as increased
income or capacity building since these are much
easier to identify” than broader social impacts, such as
changes in power dynamics (Richards, 2013). In one
notable exception, a review of Mexico’s PES program
auctions introduce their own set of challenges, espe-
cially in low- and middle-income countries. In these
countries, PES schemes may have dual objectives, and
reducing information asymmetries (and thus payments
for the ecosystem service provider) may not be a pri-
ority. Additionally, administrators of these programs
might be less likely to differentiate payment due to
concerns about fairness, and it is unclear whether there
would be institutional capacity to manage these pro-
grams. Moreover, auctions tend to increase transaction
costs, which may already be relatively high in low- and
middle-income countries where buyers of environmen-
tal services are likely to contract with many small, often
semi-literate, landowners, who often have no legal titles
and are in dispersed remote rural areas. Finally, differ-
entiation of payment can make it difficult to identify
corruption and ensure that differentiation is based on
implementation of transparent rules. Alix-Garcia et al.
(2009) suggested another option to reverse auctions
would be “to conduct rigorous contingent valuation
studies in areas targeted by the program.”
Whileuniformpaymentsarestillcommon,therearesev-
eral notable exceptions. Mexico’s National Programme
for Hydrological Environmental Services (PSAH) pro-
vides higher payments for lands that provide greater
benefits. For example, primary forest owners receive
300 pesos per hectare per year (approximately $27).
Cloud forest owners, by contrast, receive 400 pesos
per hectare per year ($36) due to the perceived higher
delivery of hydrological services associated with this
type of forest which has a role in capturing water from
fog and clouds during the dry season (Porras and
Neves, 2006). Payments are made annually, at the end
of the year, once the absence of land use change has
been confirmed.
China’s Sloping Land Conversion Program also pro-
vides targeted payments, although payments are dif-
ferentiated according to the opportunity costs. China’s
program, which began as a pilot in 1999 and was fully
implemented in 2002, requires farmers to set aside ero-
sion-prone farmland within critical areas of the water-
sheds of the Yangtze and Yellow Rivers, the two largest
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT34
broad geographic regions – could be developed to
improve social outcomes. While some have argued that
the pursuit of poverty alleviation objectives is likely to
result in environmental tradeoffs (see, e.g. Huang et al.,
2009), others suggest that this may not always be the
case (Brouwer, personal communication, 2015).
South Africa’s Working for Water (WfW) program is one
of the few programs to have poverty alleviation as its
primary objective. Between its launch in 1995 and 2009,
WfW cleared more than 1 million hectares of invasive
alien plants, which improved the timing and volume
of surface water flows, provided erosion control, and
increased biodiversity (Ferraro, 2009). The program,
administered by the Department of Water Affairs and
Forestry, employs 25,000 to 32,000 people annually,
targeting low skilled, previously unemployed laborers,
with a special focus on rural women, youth, and the dis-
abled (Ferraro, 2009). Social development, an integral
part of the program, includes “skills development, train-
ing, and awareness creation of communities in health
issues, hygiene, environmental health, inoculation,
sexually transmitted diseases, pregnancy and meno-
pause” (Department of Environmental Affairs, 2015).
The vast majority of the program budget is provided by
the central government and the Department of Water
Affairs and Forestry’s general budget, with only very
minor funding from foreign donors, municipalities, and
the private sector. Ferraro (2009) argued that while the
program is effectively the government paying for envi-
ronmental services on government-controlled lands
(and therefore not a true PES program), the program
administrators are actively seeking voluntary payments
from private and municipal actors to remove invasive
plants from within their watersheds.
Several studies have examined the socio-economic
status of participants in PES schemes, either as buyers
or sellers. Porras et al. (2008) found mixed results in
both national and local schemes, depending, to some
extent, on land and forest tenure regimes and socio-
economic conditions in the targeted area. In programs
in Mexico and Nicaragua, for example, the poor were
relatively well represented (Muñoz-Piña et al., 2008;
Pagiola et al., 2005), whereas in Costa Rica, the poor
(Alix-Garcia et al., 2009) found that in most cases, there
were no “obvious” changes in the social dynamics within
a community. However, in two cases, they found a shift
in the relative power of certain groups, whereby small,
private forest holders who held land within or adjacent
to communal lands threatened to cut down their for-
ests if they did not receive some compensation.24 In
two other cases, the program improved environmental
awareness and participation in conservation activities.
Information on broader social outcomes is limited.
However, there is information on the role of PES
arrangements in alleviating poverty. It is important
to recognize that PES schemes were conceptualized
as a mechanism to improve the efficiency of natural
resource management, not as a mechanism to reduce
poverty (Pagiola et al., 2005). While most programs
prioritize areas critical for ecosystem services, some
have been tailored to meet social objectives through
a variety of mechanisms, including by targeting the
programs to particular areas or populations, reducing
transaction costs, and providing pro-poor premiums
and subsidies (Wunder, 2005; Porras et al., 2013). In
Costa Rica, a social development index consisting of 11
health, participation, economics, and education indica-
tors is one of the criteria that is then integrated with
environmental criteria to select participants.25 This par-
ticular social development index has been shown to be
ineffective in targeting payments to low-income popu-
lations because it is biased toward large properties and
is “too spatially coarse to represent the social impact of
the programme at household level” (Porras et al., 2013).
However, it suggests that some sort of criterion – pref-
erably tailored to individual characteristics rather than
24	 In a somewhat unusual situation, this conflict was a result of the fact
that only a small group had rights to the commons and only those with
rights received payment.
25	 The index is used by Costa Rican government institutions to establish
priority for social policy and budget allocations.
“PES schemes were … to improve the
efficiency of natural resource management,
not as a mechanism to reduce poverty…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 35
were not well represented (Zbinden and Lee, 2005).
Wunder (2008) noted that one must typically own or
hold land in order to be a seller, thereby excluding the
“poorest of the poor.” Some schemes have attempted to
recognize informal access to resources (e.g. Indonesia’s
RUPES Program), although this has been difficult to
replicate elsewhere (Porras et al., 2008). A recent
review of ten PWS schemes in developing countries by
Bond and Mayers (2010) found only a small number
of cases where livelihoods had been improved, con-
cluding that “there are significant and positive indirect
effects of PWS – particularly in building social capita
in poor communities.” They acknowledged that while
improving education, health, and nutrition are bet-
ter ways of reducing poverty than PWS, there is little
evidence of these schemes actually doing any harm.
Moreover, they suggested that targeting can make
PWS programs more effective in alleviating poverty.
Additionally, while it is commonly assumed that up-
stream service providers are poorer than downstream
users (Wunder, 2008), the reality may be more com-
plicated. For example, George et al. (2009) found that
downstream and upstream stakeholders were part of
the same community in two watersheds in Thailand and
Lao PDR with no clear distinction between upstream
providers and downstream beneficiaries. In some
cases, according to Porras et al. (2008), downstream
users may, in fact, be poorer, raising concerns about
their ability to pay as well as whether those payments
are equitable. In cases where user fees were used to
compensate ecosystem service providers, the authors
found that the fees were generally found to be accept-
able, with no detectable impact on water use or access
to water. Additionally, some programs had taken steps
to ensure that the poorest users were not impacted by
these fees, e.g. by making payments voluntary or pro-
viding a lifeline supply of water.
Few studies have examined gender representation
among program participants. In a literature review, Ravn-
borg et al. (2007) found that less than 5 percent of the
references addressed gender-specific aspects of impacts
of PES. In a more recent assessment, Richards (2013)
concurred, finding that “Gender effects have not been
monitored, and therefore there is no information about
how women have been affected except some reference
to their low levels of participation.” Porras et al. (2008)
cited two studies indicating low participation levels by
women. However, these studies were more than a decade
old and may not have reflected current conditions.
Necessary, enabling, and
limiting conditions
Some factors, such as contract adjudication and
enforcement, may be necessary for establishing a PWS
program. Other factors, such as appropriate inventories
and analyses and government support, can enable but
may not be required for PES programs to be estab-
lished. Still other factors, such as legal prohibitions, limit
watershed PES or function as barriers or obstacles.
Necessary conditions include:
•	 a legal system recognizing that agreements must
be kept
•	 a civil law providing contract parties with legal rem-
edies to enforce contract rights in cases of non-
compliance with contract obligations
•	 general respect for the rule of law.
In general, PES schemes are flexible and the necessary
conditions are relatively modest. However, Calvache
et al. (2012) determined that they must be designed
within the legal context of a particular area. Greiber
(2009) provided additional detail on the legal frame-
work for PWS implementation, noting that the frame-
work will differ depending on the type of scheme
implemented. For example, private schemes, defined
as self-organized schemes between private entities,
require the least government intervention and depend
on only general legal requirements: e.g. a legal system
recognizing that agreements must be kept, and civil
law providing contract parties with legal remedies in
case of non-compliance. However, if only these condi-
tions are in place, Greiber (2009) asserted that these
“Few studies have examined … gender-
specific aspects of impacts of PES.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT36
•	 methodologies for measuring, monitoring, report-
ing, and verifying progress toward achieving proj-
ect outcomes.
Several studies have developed guides highlighting the
technical requirements (Hawkins, 2011; Calvache et al.,
2012; Smith et al., 2013). In addition to these require-
ments, methodologies for measuring, monitoring,
reporting, and verifying progress toward achieving out-
comes are also needed. Monitoring and evaluation are
fundamental to the success of PES schemes because
the information they provide gives assurance to the
buyer that ecosystem services are delivered as prom-
ised and allows for adjustments to the program based
on better information and changing conditions. Porras
et al. (2013) made a distinction between monitoring for
compliance and monitoring for environmental effective-
ness. The former “seeks to ensure that the conditional-
ity inherent in a PWS scheme is put into practice, and
that the project is implemented effectively.” The latter,
by contrast, seeks to ensure that the scheme achieves
its overall objectives and is needed to demonstrate
additionality, i.e. that changes in watershed ecosystem
services can be attributed to the program. While com-
pliance and effectiveness monitoring are often linked, “a
high degree of compliance does not necessarily ensure
that a scheme is effective, as a poorly designed scheme
may target the wrong land managers and land that is at
least risk, meaning that the payments may not generate
the desired hydro-ecological or conservation benefits.”
Despite some of the challenges to monitoring (described
in the application section of 3.2), Brouwer et al. (2011)
pointed to the need for international monitoring guide-
lines to identify the relationship between the design of
theprogramanditsenvironmentaleffectivenessbecause
understanding these relationships is “paramount to the
future design of cost-effective PWS schemes.” A recent
Science article by a large team of scientists and prac-
titioners in the PES field (Naeem et al., 2015) noted
that “many projects are based on weak scientific foun-
dations, and effectiveness is rarely evaluated with the
rigor necessary for scaling up and understanding the
importance of these approaches as policy instruments
and conservation tools.” In an effort to advance the field,
programs would “mostly develop at a small scale with
the objective to solve a specific local water problem,”
and expanding these projects to address regional or
national water problems would require a more devel-
oped policy and legal framework.
By contrast, public schemes are government-driven
schemes that, by definition, require far greater gov-
ernment involvement, as local, regional, or national
governments are involved as either watershed service
providers or buyers, and payment may be done through
user fees, taxes, or subsidies. However, many of these
schemes have evolved on an ad hoc basis from initia-
tives of NGOs and overseas development corporations
and, as a result, they typically lack comprehensive or
coherent legislation. Greiber (2009) also noted that
these conditions limit “the real potential of PES as
an innovative instrument that might be applied more
often, more efficiently, and at a larger scale to combat
prevailing water problems.” He argued that a specific
legal and policy framework would stimulate PES devel-
opment by creating greater legal certainty and helping
to promote good governance practices.
While necessary conditions establish the minimum
requirements for the implementation of a PES program,
there is a set of enabling conditions that promotes the
success and long-term viability of these programs.
While some of the enabling conditions are technical in
nature, others are legal, institutional, social, and political.
Technical enabling conditions include:
•	 an inventory of the value of hydrological services,
including assessments of baseline conditions, and
of how these values may change in response to
land use alterations, infrastructure development,
and climate
•	 an analysis of program costs, including implemen-
tation, opportunity, and transaction costs
•	 a registry of names, transactions, project data,
credit issuance, or other information related to PES
activities
•	 technical support from the government, civil soci-
ety, or the private sector through trainings, infor-
mation, or direct technical assistance
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 37
TABLE 2. Natural-science principles and guidelines for PES programs
Principle: Dynamics
Objective: Ensure project capacity to adapt to dynamic
natural and anthropogenic processes.
Principle: Monitoring
Objective: Track factors necessary for management,
trade, forecasting, and assessment.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
identify key services for each service type beyond
target services
identify spatiotemporal scales of targeted services
identify data needs, resources, and gaps
identify stressors and their spatiotemporal variability
identify and forecast trends in endogenous and
exogenous threats
identify services’ production and functions and
sensitivities
determine trade-offs and synergies among services
determine how functional diversity influences resilience.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
quantify deliverables associated with target services
identify spatiotemporal scales in advance of
implementation
use established methods/protocols and best practices
for monitoring
estimate uncertainties
monitoring should inform decision-making
monitoring should detect potential changes in
baseline conditions
monitor non-target services that influence
target services.
Principle: Baseline
Objective: Document and initial conditions
Principle: Metrics
Objective: Robust, efficient, and versatile methods
for procuring data.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
measure influences of interventions on
services
measure status and trends of non-target
services
ensure that measurements are feasible
given resources
assess initial state of exogenous and endogenous
threats to services
measure factors important for forecasting
service trends.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
must be relevant, reliable, and appropriate in scale
should comply with voluntary standards, certification,
and regulations
should reflect spatiotemporal scales as identified
in dynamics
optimize balance between precision and simplicity
assess progress (in conjunction with baseline
and monitoring)
should measure both absolute changes and changes
in trends
preferentially selected to allow comparisons across
service types
assess how services influence each other.
Principle: Multiple services
Objective: Recognize trade-offs and synergies
among services
Principle: Ecological sustainability
Objective: Insure project durability and sustainability
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
assess how intervention influences the other services
avoid “double counting”
assess impacts of intervention on non-target services.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
estimate short-term and long-term project or program
performance.
Note: The scientific guidelines shown in bold font are intended to indicate “essential” guidelines that must be followed for a successful intervention.
Guidelines shown in regular font are considered “desirable”.
Source: Naeem et al., 2015.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT38
of ecosystem services, while Colombia went even fur-
ther by requiring departments and municipalities to
invest at least 1  percent of annual revenues toward
either PES to landowners or direct land acquisition in
source water areas (Bennett et al., 2014). Enabling leg-
islation can occur at various levels (e.g. local, provincial,
or national) and take a variety of forms. However, the
appropriate level and form will depend on the prevail-
ing governance system in a particular area.
A variety of social and political conditions increases
the likelihood of the successful implementation of PES
schemes. For example, cultural and political acceptance
of markets in general, and of commercializing rights to
land use and land management practices, creates an
enabling environment. Dillaha et al. (2007) noted that
PES activity is generally strong in Latin America, but
that development tends to lag in areas with strong
indigenous cultures (such as the Bolivian highlands) or
closed economies (such as Venezuela). It is important
to note that in areas where the natural environment has
historically been used for free, “actually paying for envi-
ronmental services in response to mounting resource
scarcity represents a major change in attitude, which
necessarily will take time” (Dillaha et al., 2007).
Trust is also a key element for an effective PES pro-
gram, as it helps to ensure that there are willing buy-
ers and sellers, and reduces transaction costs. Dillaha
et al. (2007) noted that service providers might fear
that PES is a first-step toward appropriation of their
resources, while service users “might suspect that they
are or will be the victims of ‘environmental blackmail’.”
Based on several cases in Asia, Neef and Thomas
(2009) argued that “Lack of trust between poten-
tial buyers and providers of environmental services is
probably one of the most constraining factors in set-
ting up viable PES schemes.” One way to facilitate the
trust-building process is through stakeholder engage-
ment, especially during the initial stages of the project.
Likewise, transparency and access to information are
also essential. Intermediaries, such as NGOs, can some-
times play a role in building and maintaining trust while
also providing technical, legal, and financial support. As
the authors put forth a set of natural science principles
and guidelines for PES efforts that they felt were appli-
cable to local-, regional-, and national-level programs in
developed and developing countries (Table 2). A set of
scientific guidelines for four of the principles – dynamics,
monitoring, baseline, and metrics – were deemed “essen-
tial” for a successful intervention, whereas the remainder
were deemed “desirable”. While specific to PES arrange-
ments, they argued that the principles and guidelines
could be applicable to market-based conservation
instruments more broadly. In a review of 118 active PES
projects, however, the authors found that 60 percent did
not adhere to the four essential principles, highlighting
considerable room for improvement in the development
and implementation of PES projects.
In addition to the more technical aspects of PES, there
are a number of enabling legal, institutional, social, and
political conditions that also improve the effectiveness
of PES.
Enabling legal, institutional, social, and political
conditions include:
•	 a policy and legal framework for PES
•	 incentives and/or requirements to participate in
PES programs
•	 cultural and political acceptance of markets
•	 trust between ecosystem service providers and
beneficiaries
•	 a supply and demand for ecosystem services.
Governments, for example, can pass laws or institute
policies that enable the development of PES pro-
grams. In Costa Rica, participants of PES programs
are exempt from paying property taxes (Porras et al.,
2013). Likewise, the Peruvian government unanimously
passed a law providing a legal framework for voluntary
PES programs between land stewards and beneficiaries
“Governments, for example, can pass
laws or institute policies that enable the
development of PES programs.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 39
whether these rights also include “the right to receive
income from the ecosystem services provided by the
transferred natural resource.” Likewise, in Asia, most
forested and agricultural land is state-owned. Thus,
individuals and communities have weak land rights,
making it difficult for them to sign a contract and pro-
vide a legal guarantee of future land management
practices (Huang et al., 2009).
3.3 Water quality trading
Description
Water quality trading (WQT) is a market-based
approach for reducing or controlling water pollution. It
allows permitted dischargers in a watershed to trade
water quality credits, or pollution allowances, in order to
meet water quality standards. Markets in water quality
differ from conventional markets in that they are not
based on an actual physical commodity. Rather, they
are based on trading a license or a permit to pollute.
The primary goal of water quality trading is to reduce
the costs of water pollution control, often following the
imposition of a cap on pollutant emissions by regula-
tors. Secondary goals are to reduce compliance costs
and spur innovative solutions to pollution control.
Water quality trading is an adjunct to regulation, and
not an alternative to it. In fact, its success depends on
the presence of a strong regulatory body to enforce
water quality standards, and monitor and enforce dis-
charge limits.
Water quality markets draw inspiration from the suc-
cess of the Acid Rain Program (ARP) in the United
States in the 1990s. At the time, most environmental
groups and government agency staff favored a “com-
mand-and-control” approach to pollution control that
Bond and Mayers (2010) acknowledged, trust “is hard
to build and easy to lose.”
Finally, there must be a supply of, and demand for, eco-
system services. On the supply side, payments must be
big enough relative to other opportunities to create a
real incentive for change. On the demand side, benefi-
ciaries must have the ability to pay. For example, Huang
et al. (2009) posited that by increasing incomes, rapid
economic growth in Asia could increase demand for
watershed services because there is greater willing-
ness and ability to pay for amenities such as clean
water and recreation. At the same time, rapid economic
growth could increase demand for goods and services
produced on the land, thereby increasing the oppor-
tunity cost of the land. In a regional review of PWS
programs in sub-Saharan Africa, Ferraro (2009) sug-
gested that demand for watershed services is relatively
low, as there are relatively few formal water systems,
and even those with formal systems may lack reliable
access – which means there are few people who could
be easily charged a water fee to pay for watershed ser-
vices. Moreover, high poverty rates suggest that many
would not be able to afford higher water costs.
There is also a set of conditions that can hinder or limit
the development of PES schemes.
Limiting conditions can include:
•	 any legal provision prohibiting watershed PES con-
tracts
•	 poorly defined property rights.
Greiber (2009) noted that “clearly defined property
rights enable parties to enter into PES contracts and
ensure the sustainability of PES schemes.” Several
challenges associated with property rights arise when
implementing PES schemes. For example, ecosystem
services are a relatively new concept and may not be
recognized by the existing legal framework. In Peru,
the state is the owner of natural resources and holds
the property rights over ecosystem services. While the
state can transfer certain property rights over natural
resources to individuals, it has not yet been determined
“Water quality markets draw inspiration from
the success of the Acid Rain Program in the
US in the 1990s.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT40
levels in water bodies, a process referred to as “eutro-
phication”. Other water quality trading programs have
been set up to control salinity, heavy metal, sediment,
and temperature or thermal pollution (Morgan and
Wolverton, 2005). These programs are typically based
around specific watersheds or receiving waters, such
as the Chesapeake Bay or Wisconsin’s Fox River. WQT
markets are different from other emissions trading
schemes, in that trading is used between sources in
the same area of impact, e.g. a watershed that drains
to a particular water body, such as a lake, estuary, or
river. The geography of trading contrasts starkly with
other well-known cap-and-trade-style environmental
markets, such as national and international markets
for carbon offsets, where emission reductions can take
place even in remote parts of the world.
Trading within water quality markets can take several
different forms. The most common arrangement in
the United States is a bilateral market, where buyers
negotiate trades directly with potential sellers, discuss-
ing their quantity and price. Often, a regulator will get
involved by, for example, approving the terms of the
agreement, or facilitating monitoring to ensure that
actual discharge reductions take place. This arrange-
ment makes transactions slow and costly, and has
been partially blamed for the moribund trading activ-
ity in most US WQT markets (Woodward et al., 2002).
In clearinghouse-style markets, a middleman such as
a brokerage firm facilitates trades by connecting will-
ing buyers and sellers, as has been done in the Tar-
Pamlico River Basin Nutrient Trading Program in North
Carolina. On the opposite extreme, exchanges are a
form of trading where allowances are turned into stan-
dardized commodities and are freely traded. For exam-
ple, in the United States, SO2 allowances are traded
on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange. The Hunter
River Salinity Trading Scheme in Australia may also
be considered an example of an exchange, although
in this case, the government is responsible for trades
(NSWDEC, 2003).
Water quality markets can be classified in a number of
ways. One useful way to categorize markets is based on
would have required all power plants to install scrub-
bers on their smokestacks to remove sulfur diox-
ide (SO2). Lawmakers instead opted for a bold policy
experiment, setting a cap on total SO2 emissions, and
allowing polluters to buy and sell pollution allowances.
Under this system, emissions from individual sources
could rise or fall, as long as the total annual emissions
stayed the same. The central idea was that allowing
trading puts a price on pollution, and, in turn, encour-
ages cost savings, efficiency, and innovation.
In most WQT markets, a cap is put on water pollutants.
In the United States, the cap is usually set by state gov-
ernments, which are responsible for regulating water
quality in rivers, lakes, and estuaries. The cap should
be based on a scientific analysis of how much pollutant
a water body can assimilate without being excessively
degraded, which is referred to as a total maximum daily
load (TMDL). Government regulators issue pollution
allowances, often referred to as “credits”, to existing
polluters. For example, a credit may allow a facility to
discharge one pound of phosphorus to a river. A facility
manager may choose to install pollution-control tech-
nologies that limit emissions. If a facility’s emissions
decrease to below its permitted level, this frees up
additional credits that managers may then sell to other
polluters. There typically may be two types of buyers
that create a demand for credits: i) new entrants to the
market, such as a new factory in the watershed, or ii)
existing polluters that may wish to or need to increase
their emissions, e.g. a factory that wishes to increase
output, or a sewage plant serving a growing commu-
nity. Trading allows the industry greater freedom to
operate as it sees fit. A low-performing facility may
continue to pollute more heavily, but it will be required
to purchase credits, making the cost of doing business
more expensive. High-performers that can reduce their
pollution levels create valuable pollution credits that
they can sell, and this creates an incentive to invest in
pollution controls, at least according to theory.
To date, most water quality trading markets have been
used to control pollution from nutrients that cause
excessive algal growth and low dissolved oxygen
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 41
right to discharge pollutants. Markets are also thought
to foster innovation – where “innovative, entrepreneur-
ial companies can profit from low-cost reductions in
emissions. Slower, less innovative firms can benefit as
well by having the opportunity to purchase needed
emission allowances for less than it would cost them
to comply internally” (Anderson, 2004). Moreover, cap-
and-trade programs may provide greater certainty in
the outcome. With a fixed or declining cap, policy mak-
ers can be more certain of the environmental improve-
ment that will be achieved, compared with alternative
approaches such as best management practices or a
pollution tax.
Application
A survey conducted by Bennett and Carroll (2014)
for Forest Trends found that activity for WQT mar-
kets is still relatively small, although it has shown large
increases in the past several years. In 2013, the trading
value of WQT markets was about $22.2 million. Much
of that activity was concentrated in the United States,
where WQT markets had a trading value of $11.1 mil-
lion in 2013, with a cumulative total of $95 million since
2000. While there are currently over 30 water quality
markets in place in the United States, some have seen
no trading or only a few trades, even two decades after
their establishment. Among the reasons cited for the
lack of trading activity are high transaction costs, lack
of trust, uncertainty about the future of the market, or
simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate in
the market (Shortle and Horan, 2008). While some of
the longest-running markets are getting smaller, new
programs in Oregon, Virginia, and Maryland have kept
overall transaction values high. Indeed, in 2013, United
States market activity was at its highest level ever
recorded, although Bennet and Carroll (2014) posited
that this likely represented recovery from the eco-
nomic downturn rather than new growth. It is of note
that New Zealand’s Lake Taupo Trading Program, a
relatively new program, has rapidly become the largest
in the world, with at least $10.2 million in transactions
in 2013. However, the future of that market is uncertain
because “that market’s biggest buyer, the Lake Taupo
Protection Trust, announced in June 2013 it would
the regulatory system that drives the demand for trad-
ing and whether it includes a cap on total emissions
(Anderson, 2004). This includes both cap-and-trade
systems and credit systems.
Cap-and-trade systems put a limit on the total
amount of allowed releases of pollution. They seek
a specific environmental result (a cap), and trading
allowances to release pollution are simply an option to
minimize the cost of achieving the emission reductions
specified in the regulatory cap. In the cap-and-trade
approach, allowances for future emissions are sold or
granted to existing sources.
Credit systems, on the other hand, do not establish
any fixed ceiling on total emissions. Total emissions can
increase if new sources of pollution enter the market, or
if existing sources increase their outputs. In uncapped
systems, tradable credits are earned for controlling pol-
lution beyond what is specified in one’s permit.
The literature is full of descriptions of the potential
benefits of water quality trading compared with the
more conventional “command-and-control” approach,
where regulators allocate the right to pollute by impos-
ing limits on individual polluters (Shortle and Horan,
2005). In particular, WQT markets are thought to be a
less-costly, more-efficient alternative. When the total
amount of pollutant emissions in a region is capped,
the right to pollute becomes a scarce commodity and,
as many economists assert, markets are the most effi-
cient way of allocating a scarce commodity.26 WQT
programs allow polluters to interact in the marketplace
and decide among themselves how to allocate the
26	 While economic theory says that trading will lead to the most efficient
allocation of a resource, it says little about distributional effects, i.e. who
pays and who benefits, or other market “externalities”.
“WQT programs allow polluters to interact
in the marketplace and decide among
themselves how to allocate the right to
discharge pollutants.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT42
in the Reagan, George H.W. Bush, and George W. Bush
administrations, “and were once strongly condemned
by liberals and environmentalists” (Schmalensee and
Stavins, 2012). The key element for overcoming con-
servative politicians’ resistance to the policy was to
replace regulation with a free market; the market would
operate on its own with no intervention by the govern-
ment, a step that would “radically disempower the reg-
ulators” (Conniff, 2009). However, this has not been the
reality with most environmental markets, which have
been designed with additional layers of government
that oversee the market, monitor and enforce emis-
sions limits, and facilitate and verify trades. By contrast,
there are alternative pollution control policies that are
simpler and require less government involvement, such
as mandating the use of pollution-limiting technology
or taxing pollution. There is some irony here, prompting
one scholar to observe, “a putative form of rationaliza-
tion or deregulation is in fact a case of ‘reregulation’”
(Mariola 2009).
As an example of how WQT markets work, consider
the example of the Chesapeake Bay. To reduce nutri-
ent discharge into the bay, regulators had the option
of requiring wastewater plants to install expensive and
technologically advanced treatment systems. Nitrogen
removal costs for these systems are typically about
$200 per pound per year (Jones et al., 2010). However,
farms in the watershed are an even larger source of
nitrogen, and removal costs are much lower, at $1 to $5
per pound per year. As a result, permitted dischargers
have negotiated the ability to fulfill their permit require-
ments by funding pollution control projects on farms
in the watershed, such as planting winter cover crops,
planting vegetation around streams (called riparian
buffers), or installing permeable filter strips around
animal feedlots. These agricultural “best management
practices” reduce soil erosion and sediment runoff
from farms, reducing the amount of nutrients washed
into local waterways. Because they use soil and veg-
etation to filter water and sediment, they are gener-
ally low-tech and relatively inexpensive to install and
maintain. The Chesapeake Bay WQT program was set
up specifically to encourage these kinds of exchanges.
withdraw from future trading, having made arrange-
ments to achieve its remaining nitrogen reduction
goals by purchasing and managing land in the catch-
ment” (Bennett et al., 2014).
The popularity of emissions trading for dealing with
water pollution in the United States is largely a result
of the Clean Water Act of 1972. The specifics of how
the law was written and implemented have made it dif-
ficult for governments to handle pollution from farms.
In particular, the law made it illegal for “point source”
dischargers, such as factories or wastewater treatment
plants, to release pollutants into waterways without a
permit, but did not attempt to regulate pollution from
“nonpoint sources”, such as agriculture or urban run-
off, since these were considered minor sources of pol-
lution and believed to be difficult to regulate. In many
watersheds, however, farms and feedlots are the larg-
est source of pollutants. These nonpoint sources are
exempt from most water pollution regulations, and
there appears to be insufficient will to remedy this.
Forty years after passage of the landmark law, some
40 percent of America’s surface water fails to meet its
water quality goals (Faeth, 2000). Further, a set of stud-
ies in the 1990s showed that reducing nutrient pollution
from agriculture could be 65 times more cost effective
than imposing further controls on municipal or indus-
trial sources. As a result, water quality regulators in the
United States use WQT markets primarily as a tool to
encourage point dischargers to fund nonpoint source
pollution controls, largely because regulators lack the
authority to deal with these sources of pollution.
One factor contributing to the popularity of emis-
sions trading is its appeal to conservative politicians
due to their invocation of the “power of the market”
(Conniff, 2009). The original cap-and-trade programs
were policy innovations developed by conservatives
“40 percent of America’s surface water fails
to meet its water quality goals.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 43
(Olszowa et al., 1998). Further, on-farm nutrient con-
trols will do little to control other toxins that are present
in coal ash, such as arsenic, lead, mercury, and heavy
metals. However, the program is notable as it is the
first program in the United States that has allowed the
purchase of pollution control credits across state lines
(Fox, 2014).
In addition to the many markets in the United States,
there are also examples of WQT markets in other
regions, especially in Oceania:
•	 Lake Taupo Nitrogen Trading Program (New Zea-
land)
•	 South Creek Bubble Licensing Scheme (Australia)
•	 Murray-Darling Basin Salinity Credits Scheme
(Australia)
•	 South Nation River Watershed Trading Program
(Canada)
•	 Chao Lake Nutrient Trading Program (China, under
consideration)
Several European countries have shown interest in
WQT. A literature review by Wind (2012) summarized
14 studies of the concept within the European Union.
Despite this interest, no markets have been created to
date, and it appears that EU directives limit the ability
of states to set up markets.
Perhaps the best example of a successful operating
WQT market is on Australia’s Hunter River, where coal
mines and other sources are subject to discharge lim-
its to protect water quality and drinking water sources
in downstream cities. Saline soils are present through-
out Australia, and during coal mining, salty water col-
lects in mine pits and shafts and has to be pumped
out to allow mining operations to continue (NSWDEC,
2003). The Hunter River Basin had a history of conflict
among users, with mining activities making the water
unsuitable for irrigation, and new mine proposals facing
extremely high costs. The state government, following
years of study and collaboration with stakeholders, set
a cap on salinity levels in the river, and put a system of
tradable discharge credits in place.
Trading allows regulated polluters to meet their per-
mitted discharge requirement at a much lower cost
than with technology. Further, it helps to finance pollu-
tion reduction from the agricultural sector, which gen-
erates about 44 percent of the nutrients entering the
bay. A recent assessment concluded that controlling
discharges from agriculture is necessary to restore the
bay (Steinzor et al., 2012).
A second noteworthy example of a domestic WQT
market is the relatively new Ohio River Basin Water
Quality Trading Project developed by the Electric
Power Research Institute, the research arm of the
United States electric power industry. Coal-fired power
plants in the Ohio River Basin are a major source of
nitrogen pollution in rivers, due to their using water
in scrubbers for air pollution control and to sluice the
coal ash out of reactors (US EPA, 2009). The ash and
water slurry most often goes into storage and treat-
ment ponds that provide only a minimal level of treat-
ment and where spills and illicit discharges have been
common (Zucchino, 2015). Under the pilot program,
power plants and other interested parties can pay for
nonpoint source pollution reductions on farms, another
major source of pollution in the watershed. Because
on-farm improvements are much less expensive than
installing wastewater treatment facilities, power plants
stand to save $500,000 to $800,000 per year (EPRI,
2010).
The first projects are creating nutrient reduction credits
through “activities like planting cover crops and creat-
ing treatment wetlands for animal wastes” (Ecosystem
Marketplace, 2015). The program is notable for its thor-
oughness in documenting projects, posting a descrip-
tion and photos of every project on the Electric Power
Research Institute (EPRI) website, and using a stan-
dard methodology for calculating the reduced pollution
in farm runoff. The program is credited with reducing
pollution by 100,000 pounds of nutrients between 2013
and 2015 (Barrett 2015). While commendable, this proj-
ect is a small pilot, and pollutant reductions are small
compared with the estimates of over 3 million pounds
of nitrogen entering the watershed’s rivers every day
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT44
at how WQT markets have performed environmentally,
economically, and socially.
ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE
While there are no comprehensive analyses of the envi-
ronmental performance of WQT programs in general,
there are several examples of successful programs.
In the application section of 3.3, we cited Australia’s
Hunter River as one example. Indeed, since formation
of the program, river water quality has met standards
nearly 100 percent of the time, protecting water sup-
plies to downstream irrigators and cities. This hap-
pened despite the establishment of new, potentially
highly polluting mines in the watershed. The Alpine
Cheese Company Nutrient Trading Program in Ohio is
another notable success. As a part of this program, the
company helped fund pollution reduction projects on
local farms, paying 25 farmers to install 91 conserva-
tion measures that resulted in a 3,000-pound-per-year
phosphorus reduction (US EPA, 2010).
A United States Environmental Protection Agency
(US EPA) 2010 evaluation of the program found that
it exceeded its nutrient reduction goals, and estimated
that “conservation measures would reduce up to three
times more nutrients than if equal funds were used for
wastewater treatment upgrades.” It is noteworthy that
the project has also been praised by the local chapter
of the Sierra Club, which has strongly opposed the cre-
ation of larger WQT schemes in other areas that could
allow industry to continue implementing poor practices
by purchasing offsets (Marida, 2010).
Likewise, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit Exchange
Program – currently the largest in the United States
– was created in 2002 to reduce nitrogen pollution to
Long Island Sound from the Connecticut River. Under
the program, which covers 79 sewage treatment plants
in the state of Connecticut, a plant can control pollu-
tion in excess of its permit requirement and sell excess
nitrogen allowances to those plants that exceed their
allowances. A 2012 review of the program suggested
that the program had helped the state meet its environ-
mental goals while lowering overall costs (Stacey et al.,
2012). The program helped reduce nitrogen loading by
Under this system, no discharges of salty water are
allowed when the river is in low flow. When the river
is in high flow and its capacity to dilute salty inflows
is greater, limited discharge is allowed, controlled by
a system of salt credits. Permitted dischargers coor-
dinate their activities so that the total salt concen-
tration in the river never goes above a specified limit.
Industries can buy and sell salt credits in real time via
a trading website run by the state government. Several
years after the program began, the trading program is
popular among participants and functioning smoothly.
The state government has set up real-time monitor-
ing to make sure the river water quality meets stan-
dards, and to monitor for permit violations. Perhaps the
biggest marker of the program’s success is that new,
potentially highly polluting mines have been estab-
lished, but river water quality has met standards nearly
100 percent of the time.
Environmental, economic, and
social performance
Despite the fact that water quality trading markets
have existed for three decades in some areas, it is
difficult to state whether they can be considered an
overall success. In making such an evaluation, we must
determine whether desired pollution reductions were
achieved and water quality targets attained. We must
also examine how the result compared with what would
have occurred under another form of management:
were the pollution reductions greater, did they occur
more quickly, or at a lower cost?
Moreover, there is a great deal of literature about water
quality trading and market-based solutions to water
pollution but few real-world evaluations of existing
WQT markets. Much of the literature about markets is
theoretical and oriented toward “making the case” for
WQT, e.g. describing how a market can or should be set
up. Below, we examine the available evidence looking
“…there is a great deal of literature … but
few real-world evaluations of existing
WQT markets.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 45
In an assessment of three mature WQT programs in
the United States, one scholar concluded that there
had been very little benefit as a direct result of trades.
However, the programs had an unexpected benefit: they
broughttogetherwatershedstakeholdersandincreased
“the institutional capacity for watershed management”
(Wallace, 2007). Stakeholders coming together around
a common goal of improving water quality also helped
lower resistance to new, more stringent water quality
regulations. Wallace concluded that the markets them-
selves were not important mechanisms for reducing
pollution. Rather, their presence contributed to “unin-
tended contributions to increased pollution regulation
and management on a watershed scale.” So, on the one
hand, these markets could be considered failures by
some observers because many of them had seen no
trading even decades after their creation.
The lack of trades can be explained by a number of fac-
tors: high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty
about the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity
and unwillingness to participate in the market. On the
other hand, even where little or no trading occurred,
water quality and governance had improved in the
three watersheds evaluated by Wallace (2007). It is not
always possible to disentangle how much of a role the
market played in bringing about these improvements.
On the one hand, financial transactions have not played
a large role, tempting us to conclude that the markets
were relatively unimportant. However, if discussion of
the use of “market fundamentals” helped overcome
resistance to environmental regulation and paved the
way toward decreased pollution, then we may conclude
that markets were a key feature in improving water
quality, albeit indirectly.
ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
It is difficult to assess the economic performance of
WQT markets and how their economic performance
compares with alternative forms of pollution control.
To date, the size and impact of water quality markets is
relatively small. There is some information in the litera-
ture on the number of trades that have occurred, and
the prices paid for water quality credits. In the applica-
tion section of 3.3, we cited a Forest Trends study that
over 50 percent over 10 years, and was on track to meet
water quality goals by 2014. As a result, the area of Long
Island Sound suffering from hypoxia (low dissolved oxy-
gen which is fatal to wildlife) had steadily declined.
Despite these examples, most water quality trading
programs in the United States are either too small or
have seen too little trading to make a meaningful dif-
ference on water quality. For example, a 2012 evalua-
tion of Ohio’s Great Miami Nutrient Trading Program
called it “one of the most successful programs to date”
(Newburn and Woodward, 2012). In 2009, the trading
program attracted $1.3 million in trades and helped fund
100 projects that reduced nutrient pollution by 800,000
pounds per year. Proposed projects submitted by farm-
ers in the watershed covered a variety of agricultural
“best management practices” designed to prevent sedi-
ment and nutrients from entering waterways. Evaluators
concluded that the program “has been successful in
developing both supply and ensuring funding for agri-
cultural pollution abatement projects compared to
other WQT programs” (Newburn and Woodward, 2012).
Despite this, they found that the program had not likely
had a significant effect on regional water quality due to
the “relatively minor role that the trading program has
had on nutrient management in the watershed to date.”
To date, the projects have simply been too small and
too few to have a major impact. The Great Miami River
watershed drains 748 square miles, the majority of
which is cultivated, so a much larger investment would
be needed to meaningfully improve water quality in the
basin. This example highlights the caution needed when
interpreting large numbers cited by market proponents.
While 800,000 pounds sounds like a lot (and is indeed
a worthwhile accomplishment), it pales in comparison
with the estimated 1 trillion pounds of nitrogen enter-
ing the Ohio River watershed each year (Olszowa et al.,
1998). Like most WQT markets in the United States, the
Greater Miami Basin program did not emerge from a cap
on pollutants. Rather, it was created as a way to allow
regulated point-source dischargers, such as factories
and sewage plants, to lower their costs by paying for
pollution controls on farms rather than installing expen-
sive pollution control measures at their own facilities.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT46
improving the environment and supporting the local
economy, and also experienced other indirect benefits
from the project, “by fencing cows out of streams, bac-
teria levels in milk were decreased, giving the farmers
a premium price for milk and reducing costs for Alpine
[Cheese Company]” (Marida, 2010).
As described previously, the Connecticut Nitrogen
Credit Exchange Program is currently one of the larg-
est WQT programs in operation. An evaluation of the
program in 2012 suggested that the program has
helped the state meet its environmental goal of reduc-
ing nitrogen loading to Long Island Sound while lower-
ing overall costs. The state estimated that, in the first
10 years of the program, trading had lowered costs by
$300 to $400 million below what individual facilities
would have had to pay for equivalent pollution reduc-
tions (Stacey et al., 2012).
SOCIAL PERFORMANCE
There is little research on the social impacts of WQT,
and much of what we describe in this section is based
on anecdotal evidence. Critics of environmental mar-
kets have raised questions about their fairness and
justice. A specific concern relates to how regulators
distribute pollution permits at the outset of market cre-
ation. Under a market system, pollution permits become
valuable commodities to be bought and sold. In many
cases, as in SO2 trading in the United States, the gov-
ernment grants allowances to industries for free, based
on their historic emissions. Critics point out that such
“grandfathering” of permits rewards those polluters
most responsible for environmental problems in the
first place. It may also unfairly burden more recent mar-
ket entrants, because they have no history of polluting
and no “free” permits, yet would be required to purchase
credits to offset 100 percent of their emissions. There
are, however, different ways of issuing credits that help
mitigate these concerns. For example, rather than giv-
ing away credits, they could be sold to polluters in an
auction, as has been proposed in carbon markets.
Critics have also raised concerns about the fairness of
water quality markets to potential sellers of water qual-
ity credits. Consider a farmer who installed pollution
estimated the value of the United States water quality
tradingmarketas$11.1millionin2013,intermsofthetotal
value of payments. To put these numbers in perspec-
tive, state and local governments in the United States
spent $70 billion on sanitation and sewerage in 2008
(US Census Bureau, 2012). Despite these investments,
many argue that the United States should be spending
much more to control water pollution. Researchers at
Kansas State found that nutrient pollution from nitro-
gen and phosphorus cost the United States $2.2 bil-
lion in 2008, due to losses in recreational water usage,
waterfront real estate, spending on recovery of threat-
ened and endangered species, and increased treatment
for drinking water (Dodds et al., 2008).
While limited data are available, advocates for WQT
markets cite the lower overall cost of improving water
quality as their main advantage, as compared with more
conventional means of water pollution control. There
is local evidence for this, especially in smaller markets.
Take the case of the Alpine Cheese Company, in Ohio’s
Sugar Creek watershed. The plant was faced with
expensive wastewater treatment upgrades to satisfy
Clean Water Act permit requirements (US EPA, 2010).
These upgrades would likely have cost over $1 million
to install, plus ongoing costs for operation and mainte-
nance.Instead,thecompanycollaboratedwithothersto
reduce pollution through projects at farms in the water-
shed that have a much lower cost per pound of phos-
phorus prevented from entering streams, and which
are expected to last 15 to 20 years (Moore, 2012). The
company worked with universities, regulators, and local
agricultural extension services, providing $800,000
over five years for planning, technical assistance, and
outreach. In addition, these measures allowed the plant
to expand, creating 12 new jobs. Further, the project
provided funding to chronically cash-strapped local
soil and water conservation districts and to the local
agricultural economy. Local dairy farmers took pride in
“…advocates for WQT markets cite the lower
overall cost of improving water quality as
their main advantage…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 47
communal ownership makes it slower and more diffi-
cult to develop land. In a sense, those most responsible
for past pollution have been rewarded with large (and
valuable) pollution permits, while the Maori community
will face higher costs to develop their lands economi-
cally. In response to these concerns, regulators altered
the market design by relaxing the cap somewhat “to
ease the restrictive nature of historical allocation on
Tuwharetoa [Maori] and other forest owners” (Duhon
et al., 2011).
In the New Zealand case study, program managers
realized the importance of dealing with issues of race
and historical justice in order to make the program suc-
cessful. In the United States, some program managers
have also sought to address issues related to age and
gender. For example, the Ohio River Basin Water Quality
Trading Project directs money from the electric power
industry to farmers to support on-farm improvements
to reduce runoff and pollution. A concern was raised
early on that the early adopters would be all younger,
male farmers (Jessica Fox, EPRI, personal communica-
tion, 2015) because they would be more open to new
ideas. Also, there are fewer woman-owned farms in the
region compared with those owned by men. As a result,
the managers of this program have made a particular
effort to involve women farmers and older farmers.
Some critics have suggested that WQT programs could
perpetuate or worsen environmental justice problems.
The environmental justice movement in the United
States has focused on the fact that pollution often
occurs in areas where many poor and minority people
live or work, and that disadvantaged communities bear
an unfair burden of exposure to pollution. There is a
possibility that trading could allow pollution “hot spots”
to continue, with accompanying environmental jus-
tice concerns. For example, a polluter could purchase
credits instead of making onsite pollution reductions.
controls before a WQT program was established. Unlike
his (polluting) neighbors, he would not be eligible for
financing under the program. Thus, the program would
reward “notorious polluters” rather than the good stew-
ards, “because the good steward had already reduced
pollution” (Ruppert, 2004). Despite these criticisms,
there are several examples of WQT markets that have
been considered successful, and earned support from
industry, famers, regulators, and environmentalists.
As was discussed previously, the Alpine Cheese
Company Trading Program in Ohio was a very small
market that involved the purchase of credits from 25
farmers by a local cheese company. Many of the farm-
ers already did business with Alpine Cheese, selling
milk from their dairy herds, and have a strong inter-
est in maintaining a strong agricultural economy. One
observer wrote that, “socially, community has been
built with the farmers taking pride in working together,
their more sustainable farming practices and in seeing
the success of the factory” (Marida, 2010). One sees a
similar outcome in an evaluation of the Hunter River
Salinity Trading Scheme in Australia. Where there was
once “significant conflict between primary producers
and mining operators,” today, “agriculture, mining and
electricity generation operate side by side, sharing the
use of the river” (NSWDEC, 2003). Here, a history of
conflict has been replaced by cooperation. This did not
happen overnight, and required many years of pains-
taking consultation and negotiation.
In New Zealand, concerns have been raised about how
the Lake Taupo Nutrient Trading Scheme affects differ-
ent types of landowners, particularly indigenous Maori
people. In this area, dairy farms and grazing were cre-
ating polluted runoff, negatively impacting a freshwa-
ter lake important for fishing and tourism. Regulators
instituted a cap on nitrogen pollution seeking to main-
tain water quality at year 2000 levels. Larger corpo-
rate landowners were given more pollution credits
based on their historical use of the land, while Maori
landowners had not yet fully developed their lands
(MOTU, 2009). There are historical and cultural rea-
sons why Maoris have been slower to develop their
lands: they did not own some lands until recently, and
“Some critics have suggested that WQT
programs could perpetuate or worsen
environmental justice problems.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT48
States, the Clean Water Act established the concept of
“designated use” for waterways (i.e. swimmable, boat-
able, or fishable), with water quality standards then
developed based on the designated use. The process
of developing a standard requires understanding the
basic physical, environmental, and human elements of
the watershed. Generally, scientists or engineers collect
data and use computer models to determine the natu-
ral and human pollution sources (i.e. diffuse nonpoint
sources and point discharges). They also use models
to determine how much of a pollutant a water body can
assimilate while restoring or maintaining beneficial uses.
The second necessary condition is that polluters have
the ability to create water quality improvements, or
reduce pollutant discharge through technology or
management. Further, the regulator must be able to
verify that these pollution reductions are real and likely
to last. Verification of credits can be cumbersome and
time consuming, which can inhibit trading. Regulators
may require field visits or photos to show that on-
farm improvements have been properly installed and
maintained. In the case of the Alpine Cheese Trading
Program, soil conservation agents ensure that pollu-
tion control measures installed on farms meet “strin-
gent engineering specifications” (Mariola, 2009).
Implementation requires up to eight visits to a farm
from project start to finish, and a full-time agent is
required to coordinate a program involving one credit
buyer and 25 farmers. In some cases, however, the role
of verification falls to a trusted intermediary, as in the
case of the South Nation River Program in Canada,
where a conservation nonprofit hires local farmers to
conduct field inspections (O’Grady, 2011). More often
however, inspections and record-keeping are con-
ducted by state or local governments. According to
the US EPA, “mechanisms for determining and ensur-
ing compliance may include a combination of record
This was the subject of a 2013 lawsuit by Food & Water
Watch against the Chesapeake Bay Nutrient Trading
Program, which was later dismissed by a federal judge
(Hauter, 2013).
Trading programs are most effective when they cover
pollutants with “far-field” impacts, meaning their effects
are felt over a large area or over a long time period.
Indeed, a thriving market under a cap could allow pollu-
tion hot spots to continue unchecked, and thus would
be inappropriate for regulating pollutants which have
acute local impacts. “This is the reason no one has seri-
ously contemplated a market for toxics,” according to
Cy Jones, a World Resources Institute (WRI) senior
fellow (personal communication, 2015). This issue is
less important when trading operates within discrete
basins. The larger the basin in which trading is allowed,
the more chance there is to exacerbate hotspots. For
this reason, some programs have rules restricting trad-
ing to smaller sub-watersheds, as has been done in the
Ohio River program described above.
Necessary, enabling, and
limiting conditions
In this section, we discuss the minimum conditions that
are necessary for the creation and successful opera-
tion of a water quality market, followed by a discussion
of conditions that can enable WQT markets. These
enabling factors will increase the market’s likelihood of
succeeding but may not be required for it to be estab-
lished. Finally, we discuss factors which may limit WQT
markets by acting as barriers or obstacles.
Necessary conditions for a successful water quality
trading program include the following three circum-
stances. The first is the presence of a regulator and
its ability to set a cap on pollutants, monitor pollution,
and verify the legitimacy of water quality credits that
are created. Thus, the regulator must have the scien-
tific and technical capacity to set water quality goals,
and monitor water quality to ensure that those goals
are being met. To do so first requires a set of “desired
future conditions” for a particular waterbody. This may
be set by law, custom, or local preferences. In the United
“It is one thing to set up a water quality
market; it is another for active trading to
take place.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 49
Enabling conditions required for creation of a water
quality trading program go beyond these basics. First,
the government regulator must have the authority
to set discharge limits to protect waterways. Second,
the regulator needs the power to issue and enforce
water pollution discharge permits. Enforcement, with
the threat of meaningful fines or criminal penalties, is
especially important. As Abraham Lincoln famously
noted, “laws without enforcement are just good advice.”
Finally, there must be a legal framework by which trad-
ing can take place.
It is one thing to set up a water quality market; it is
another for active trading to take place. As we have
shown, many United States markets have been largely
moribund. The following presents what we consider
enabling conditions – meaning governments can set
up a market without them, but there may be little or
no trading. It would be tempting to classify an idle mar-
ket as a failure, but as we have also seen, some United
States markets have seen little trading, but they have
been accompanied by an improvement in watershed
stewardship and improvements to the environment.
There must be a demand for water quality credits.
Demand is the first and foremost enabling condition for
trades to take place. Generally, such demand is created
by a strong regulatory or non-regulatory driver.27 In the
case of the Alpine Cheese Nutrient Trading Program
described above, factory owners wished to expand pro-
duction, but were unable to do so because of a restric-
tive discharge permit. Violating the permit could have
resulted in fines or criminal charges. The factory own-
ers faced otherwise undesirable options: they could
27	 An example of a non-regulatory driver could be where industrial
emitters decide among themselves to voluntarily limit pollution to gain
goodwill or in an attempt to pre-empt regulation. This is the case in
the Ohio River study discussed above, where electric power companies
have funded projects to reduce pollution from farms in their watersheds.
These activities are not compulsory, so why would a for-profit corpora-
tion do it? Their motivation, as put forth by the program’s manager in
Congressional testimony is “to meet corporate sustainability goals and
their voluntary participation may also be considered by the state permit-
ting agencies when determining the need for flexible permit compliance
options in the future” (Fox 2014). In other words, she was saying that
companies hope that their activities today will buy them goodwill with
regulators and that future regulation will be less burdensome as a result.
keeping, monitoring, reporting and inspections” (US
EPA, 2003). There are other aspects of regulatory
oversight necessary to ensure accountability on behalf
of both buyers and sellers of credits. This oversight
includes many aspects of a trading program:
•	 establishing trading eligibility
•	 tracking of trades
•	 verification of credit generation
•	 compliance and enforcement
•	 monitoring of results
•	 program assessment.
It is especially difficult and usually impractical to mea-
sure nonpoint source pollution reductions, for example,
from projects designed to reduce polluted runoff from
farms. The pollution source is usually spread out, and
there is no obvious place to measure the discharge (as
there would be at the outfall of a factory). Nonpoint
source pollution also tends to be “episodic”, occur-
ring when rainfall flushes pollutants into waterways,
further thwarting measurement efforts. Regulators
have adopted several approaches to deal with these
issues. Nonpoint source pollution reductions are most
often estimated based on prior studies or modeling.
To address the uncertainty associated with these esti-
mates, regulators may place a higher burden for pol-
lution reductions on nonpoint sources. Indeed, some
markets have been designed with “trading ratios”
where nonpoint source reductions trade against point
sources at a ratio of 2:1 or 3:1.
The third necessary condition is an appropriate legal
framework enabling trading. Some of the legal require-
ments for water quality trading are similar to those for
other market-based instruments. Broadly, programs
require a legal environment that will uphold the rights
of buyers and sellers. Some basics, as outlined by
Greiber (2009), include:
•	 a legal system that recognizes agreements must
be kept
•	 a civil law providing contract parties with legal rem-
edies to enforce contract rights in cases of non-
compliance with contract obligations
•	 general respect for the rule of law.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT50
(2013), economists from MIT and Harvard who studied
the program, concluded that, by all accounts, it was a
major success: following its launch in 1995, the market
performed “exceptionally well along all relevant dimen-
sions” and helped the United States reach emissions
goals in 2006.
However, the market’s collapse should be a cautionary
tale: “When the government creates a market, it can
also destroy it, possibly fostering a legacy of increased
regulatory uncertainty and reduced investor confi-
dence in future cap-and-trade regimes, and hence
reduced credibility of pollution markets more broadly”
(Schmalensee and Stavins, 2013).
Trust among market participants is a key element of
any WQT program. In the United States, most water
quality markets involve point sources purchasing pol-
lution reduction credits from farms, or less frequently,
from forests or other nonpoint sources. Controlling
nonpoint source pollution from agriculture faces
unique obstacles. Farmers often distrust regulators,
and worry that participation in a trading program may
open the door to future regulation. Some pilot pro-
grams in the United States have worked through local
soil and water conservation districts, or made use of
agricultural extension services, because the farmers
know and trust these agents. In fact, Mariola (2009)
found the most important factor for program success
was “the use of a local, trusted, embedded intermediary
as the link between programs and farmers emerges as
the most important explanatory variable for program
success.”
Canadian WQT managers have come to similar conclu-
sions. In the South Nation River watershed, wastewater
dischargers face a cap on phosphorus discharge, and
new wastewater systems are purchasing phosphorus
relocate the factory, install expensive onsite wastewater
treatment, or stop production altogether. In Australia’s
Hunter River, salty discharge from mines was affecting
the drinking water supplies for downstream cities, and
an inflexible basin cap would have meant that existing
mines could not expand and new industries could not
develop. In other cases, industries are interested in mit-
igating their own pollution to create goodwill or to help
lessen the burden of future regulation. This is the case
for power companies in the Ohio River Basin. At pres-
ent, large power companies such as Duke Energy, the
largest electric power holding company in the United
States with some 7.3 million customers, and American
Electric Power, which has over 5 million customers, pur-
chase credits “to meet corporate sustainability goals
and their voluntary participation may also be consid-
ered by the state permitting agencies when determin-
ing the need for flexible permit compliance options in
the future” (Fox, 2014).
In addition to demand, there must be willingness
to engage in trade among buyers and sellers. One
observer cited the most frequent roadblock to estab-
lishing a WQT program as the “simple absence of
willing buyers and sellers” (O’Grady, 2011). In WQT
markets, demand for the commodity (pollution credits)
“is artificially created by regulatory decree and which
cannot be seen or felt or even measured with preci-
sion” (Mariola, 2009). Because the market is entirely
dependent on a regulatory driver, it can be fragile and
susceptible to interference by politicians or the courts.
For example, the United States Acid Rain Program
(ARP), the nation’s first national cap-and-trade pro-
gram, suffered a series of legal challenges beginning
in 2008, culminating in new rules in 2011 that severely
limited trading between states. As a result, the market,
which relied heavily on interstate trading, collapsed. In
2012, the market value of a credit to emit a ton of sulfur
dioxide was less than $1. Previously, these same credits
had sold for $100 to $200 for most of the last decade
and peaked at $1,200 per ton in 2005 (Schmalensee
and Stavins, 2013). The ARP’s collapse is worth paus-
ing to consider, as it was the model for all subsequent
environmental markets. Schmalensee and Stavins
“In addition to demand, there must be
willingness to engage in trade among
buyers and sellers.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 51
The ability to trade water quality credits across regional
borders may be an important enabling condition,
depending on the geography of the watershed. Many
important watersheds extend across multiple states, or
across international boundaries. When trades can only
take place within a single state or country, it reduces
the potential for trading and for water quality improve-
ments (Fisher-Vanden and Olmstead, 2013). In 2012,
the pilot Ohio River Basin Trading Program became
the first program in the United States to allow trad-
ing across state borders, with an agreement signed by
the states of Ohio, Kentucky, and Indiana (Fox, 2014).
Lessons learned from the Acid Rain Program sug-
gest that legislation may be necessary for interstate
programs: “the series of regulations, court rulings, and
regulatory responses ... affirmed that EPA cannot set up
an interstate trading system under the Clean Air Act in
the absence of specific legislation” (Schmalensee and
Stavins, 2013).
Limiting conditions for water quality trading may be
created by existing laws, policies, and institutions in
some regions. Greiber (2009) described a number of
possible concerns related to the legal and institutional
frameworks for environmental markets. Unrelated laws
may contradict the aims of a market by, for example,
providing perverse incentives to polluting industries or
restricting innovative ways of funding environmental
projects. Land tenure is a key concern in some coun-
tries, as farmers without tenure may have little incen-
tive to participate in programs if they do not own land
and their futures are more uncertain.
credits from rural landowners, mainly farmers. Initially,
the agricultural community had reservations about the
program. One of the main concerns raised by farmers
during the design of the South Nation program was their
future liability.
Organizers confronted this concern during a series of
public meetings and then added a key phrase to their
final document that addressed the farmers’ concerns
and allowed trading to begin (O’Grady, 2011) – the
phrase was: “Landowners are not bound, legally or
otherwise, to attain the predicted phosphorus offset
through the establishment of a BMP [best manage-
ment practice, another term for an on-farm pollution
control measure] on their property.” Further, control of
the program was granted to South Nation Conservation,
a community-based watershed organization that was
trusted by farmers. In addition, the program is run by a
multi-stakeholder committee, “and all project field visits
are done by farmers and not paid professionals.” As a
result, the program has been able to overcome much of
the early resistance. An independent evaluation showed
that most farmers had a high opinion of the program
and have recommend the program to other farmers in
their community (O’Grady, 2011).
“When trades can only take place within
a single state or country, it reduces the
potential for … water quality improvements.”
IrrigationnearCastroville,CA.PhotographbyGwendolynStansbury.
4
Role of the private sector
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 53
The private sector participates to some degree in all
of the instruments described in the previous section.
For example, in Michigan’s Paw Paw River Watershed,
Coca-Cola North America and other stakeholders
recently developed and implemented a performance-
based PWS program to compensate farmers for imple-
menting practices that reduce soil loss and enhance
groundwater recharge (Forest Trends, 2015b). The pri-
vate sector also participates as a buyer or seller in water
quality trading programs to comply with water quality
regulations, or buys or sells water rights through water
trading programs. In addition to these incentive-based
instruments, the private sector may participate in a
range of voluntary initiatives to, for example, restore or
protect a watershed or provide water service to local
communities. Moreover, they may employ incentives
within their direct operations or supply chains to pro-
mote water stewardship. In this section, we describe
some of the drivers for private sector engagement in
water stewardship, provide examples of their participa-
tion in incentive-based programs, and provide an initial
estimate of their investment in these programs.
4.1 Corporate water stewardship
To produce goods and services, most companies rely
on a consistent supply of adequate quality source
water and permission to discharge wastewater. As
population growth and economic development push
the limits of renewable freshwater supplies and busi-
ness-as-usual resource management strategies, and as
rapid urbanization, water pollution, groundwater deple-
tion, and climate change introduce new water-related
risks, companies face increasing urgency to respond.
Companies typically come to understand their relation-
ship to water in terms of their water footprint and their
water-related business risk. A water footprint assess-
ment – which estimates the volume of water consumed
and polluted in the production of a material or a prod-
uct, or in the operation of an entire business, industry,
or nation – can help managers more fully understand
the nature and extent of a company’s dependence
and impact on water resources. It is also appealing as
a basis for setting targets to reduce water use related
to, for example, manufacturing processes or production
of agricultural raw materials. While a water footprint
assessment can inform a risk assessment, a volumetric
footprint measurement omits the local context neces-
sary to characterize the risks related to water use, and
obscures the difference in impact between using water
“Companies … understand their relationship
to water in terms of their water footprint and
their water-related business risk.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT54
Effective water resource management systems and
regulatory frameworks, the performance of which can
be enhanced by incentive-based instruments, benefit
companies in a number of ways.
•	 As water users, companies benefit from a more reli-
able and higher quality supply of water.
•	 As polluters, businesses benefit from opportunities
to manage the cost of compliance over time, and to
seek innovative approaches to improve the quality
and reduce the volume of wastewater.
•	 As ratepayers and taxpayers, companies benefit by
avoiding the cost of adding new or expanding ex-
isting supply.
Efforts to reduce water-related business risks typically
occur at three scales: within direct operations, in supply
chain agricultural or manufacturing operations that are
not within a company’s direct control, or outside the
fenceline of both owned and supply chain properties,
where water-related risks are driven more by sociopo-
litical, hydrological, or ecological conditions than by the
actions of the company or its suppliers.
from a source that’s plentiful and using the same vol-
ume of water from a source that’s overexploited or not
readily replenished.28
Water-related business risks generally fall into three
broad and interrelated categories:
•	 physical risks include scarcity, degraded source
water quality, and flooding
•	 regulatory risks relate to inconsistent, ineffective,
or poorly enforced public policy, particularly when
a change in regulation or enforcement could dis-
rupt production or lead to an unexpected cost of
compliance
•	 reputational risks are faced by companies that
overexploit or are perceived to overexploit water
resources – including inefficient use, water pollu-
tion, excessive withdrawal, competition with other
users, or other negligent water-related activities.
All three categories of risk include financial impacts
from increased operating costs, fines or unplanned
capital expenditures, supply chain disruptions, damage
to the value of a brand, or lost access to markets.
Increasingly, businesses are taking steps to identify,
characterize, and mitigate these risks. For example, the
Aqueduct Water Risk Atlas, a web-based tool produced
by the World Resources Institute, identifies which and
how many locations in a company’s operations or sup-
ply chain face water-related risk in 12 dimensions, as
shown in Figure 7. The Water Risk Filter, an online
tool launched by the World Wide Fund for Nature
(WWF) and the German Investment and Development
Corporation (DEG), assigns each water-using location
a score that incorporates both location-specific and
company-specific risks, based on criteria such as the
average water intensity or typical level of water pol-
lution generated by suppliers to a particular industry
sector (WWF and DEG, 2014).
28	 Water “neutrality” or “offsets” are related concepts, similar to carbon
neutrality or carbon offsets. They imply that a company can compen-
sate for the negative impacts of its water footprint. However, there is no
standard for measuring negative impacts or defining which types and
how much of any given activity is sufficient compensation (Hoekstra et
al., 2011).
Baseline water
stress
Inter-annual
variability
Seasonal
variability
Flood occurence
Droughtseverity
Upstream storage
Groundwater
Stress
Return flow ratio
Upstream
protected land
Media coverage
Access to water
Threatened
amphibians
Physical Risk
Quantity
Physical Risk
Quality
Regulatory and
Reputational Risk
OVERALL WATER RISK
FIGURE 7. Water risk indicators
Source: Gassert et al., 2013.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 55
Another recent development is the idea of engag-
ing outside the fenceline. Leading companies under-
stand that collective action with other stakeholders at
the watershed scale may be required to address root
causes of resource scarcity, accessibility, or source
water quality, which can increase costs or disrupt
operations. The Beverage Industry Environmental
Roundtable (BIER), a coalition of business leaders in
an industry that faces substantial water-related repu-
tational risk, has acknowledged that in some locations,
watershed-level interventions may in fact be more
effective at mitigating water-related risk than facility-
level water-use efficiency or other activities (BIER,
2015). To assist companies in prioritizing their efforts,
BIER has proposed developing a decision support tool
that could give more priority to intervention outside
the fenceline than to internal efficiency or water quality
improvements.
4.2 Private sector engagement with
incentive-based instruments
Private sector participation in incentive-based instru-
ments, such as PWS and water quality trading, has been
relatively modest but is growing. Bennett and Carroll
(2014) found that in 2013, the private sector invested
US$41 million in watershed services that supported
“watershed restoration or protection that delivers ben-
efits to society.” While this represents more than twice
the estimated private sector investment of $19 million
to $26 million in 2011, it is still a very small portion of the
overall $12.3 billion invested collectively in watersheds
by governments, business, and individual donors in
2013. Most private sector watershed investment activ-
ity (about 95  percent) took place in North America,
Europe, and Africa (Bennett and Carroll, 2014).
•	 Direct operations. Companies that recognize wa-
ter-relatedbusinessrisksoftenbeginworkingvolun-
tarily with direct operations – owned and operated
offices, distribution or retail facilities, manufacturing
facilities, farms or other means of production – to
mitigate those risks. In direct operations, companies
can plan and manage implementation internally and
realize cost savings related to obtaining, pumping,
heating, or treating smaller volumes of water when
operational efficiencies are achieved.
•	 Supply chains. From agricultural raw materials to
water- and chemical-intensive manufacturing pro-
cesses, most companies face challenges managing
water-related business risks in their supply chains,
including those with advanced water stewardship
practices in their direct operations. In many cases,
complex business models and limited traceability
are significant obstacles to quantifying corporate
water footprints and identifying water-related busi-
ness risks that exist in global supply chains.
•	 Outside the fenceline. Facilities that maintain
industry average or better water efficiency and
wastewater quality may not be immune to all wa-
ter-related risks. The term “outside the fenceline”
refers to conditions and activities outside the phys-
ical footprint of a production site. Water-related risk
is said to originate outside the fenceline in regions
where, for example, source water is scarce or pol-
luted, projected demand exceeds renewable sup-
ply, regulations are inconsistent or nonexistent, or
lack of access to water and sanitation damages
public health. While internal process or policy
changes are easier to implement, they would not
necessarily mitigate these risks.
The private sector increasingly recognizes the need
to evaluate site-level water use in the context of its
local watershed characteristics, in order to inform and
prioritize efficiency targets for different locations. For
example, companies can manage risk more effectively
by giving higher priority to efficiency improvements for
water-intensive locations in drought-prone locations
than for similar facilities where water resources are
more plentiful.
“Most private sector watershed investment
activity … took place in North America,
Europe, and Africa.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT56
provide opportunities for projects within the corpo-
rate replenish initiative to directly mitigate risks in the
global supply chain. Other projects’ impacts, such as
those related to access to water and sanitation or ones
where Coca-Cola contributed to a collective action
together with other companies, are estimated differ-
ently (Rozza et al., 2013).
Disincentives for private sector investments.
There are also disincentives for private sector invest-
ments in public goods, including watershed services.
The benefits must be shared with others that did not
contribute to the investment, and the benefits could
be exhausted by other actors that did not participate
in the collective action or investment (Meißner, 2013).
However, when the consequences of inaction are sig-
nificant, there is a compelling case in favor of policy
engagement, collective action, and investment in
water-related initiatives outside the fenceline, includ-
ing preservation of resources or delivery of ecosystem
services via incentive-based instruments.
Among the barriers that prevent the private sector
from participating more fully in watershed investments
are three critical core competencies needed to achieve
measureable outcomes with specific benefits for at-risk
locations, which most companies do not possess:
•	 scientific and environmental engineering expertise
to identify, design, and implement watershed-level
solutions
•	 a nuanced understanding of the local environment
and culture in the watershed where they seek to
have a positive environmental outcome
•	 experience with partnerships involving diverse
stakeholders outside the fenceline.
Therefore, in cases where companies identify risk and
choose to take action at the watershed level, particu-
larly if they choose to do so in more than one location
across diverse global operations or an extended supply
chain, it is helpful and sometimes necessary to involve
an intermediary. Stanton et al. (2010) defined an inter-
mediary as “any party other than the buyer or seller who
Incentives for private sector investments. Industry
sectors with the highest levels of investment in water-
shed services (IWS) were energy utilities, water utilities,
and the food and beverage industry, with investments
of US$9.3 million, $8.9 million, and $8.8 million, respec-
tively. The primary reported motivation for spending
on watershed services was regulatory compliance,
followed by water availability risks, water quality risks,
corporate social responsibility and reputational risk,
and biodiversity protection (Bennett and Carroll, 2014).
The food and beverage sector, which accounted for
nearly one-quarter of the total corporate investment in
watersheds, is unlike other sectors in that it is driven
primarily by water availability and water risks, rather
than regulatory compliance. Bennett and Carroll (2014)
found that 88 percent of buyers in the food and bever-
age industry acted voluntarily, compared with the pri-
vate sector average of 31 percent.
For example, in 2012–2013, the Coca-Cola Company
and its global bottling partners were involved in 20
projects around the world, buying at least $2.2 mil-
lion in watershed services (Bennett and Carroll, 2014).
Separately, the company publishes annual reports
detailing its involvement in hundreds of other projects
(LimnoTech, 2013). Indeed, the Coca-Cola Company
is among a handful of private companies with a public
commitment to “replenish” the water it uses.29 However,
as Coca-Cola acknowledges, the impacts of water use
are specific and local, making it impossible for a multi-
national corporation to offset water use at the enter-
prise level. Rozza et al. (2013) described a detailed
methodology for quantifying the value of Coca-Cola’s
replenish projects, including source water protection,
water reuse for conservation or productive uses, and
community-level sustainability projects. The company
also requires its bottling plants to complete source
water vulnerability assessments and to engage in the
development of source water protection plans, which
29	 Specifically, Coca-Cola is “Collaborating to replenish the water we use”,
pledging that by 2020, it will “safely return to communities and nature
an amount of water equal to what we use in our finished beverages and
their production.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 57
are driving increased adoption of water risk assess-
ment across the business community. For example, in
its annual survey of leaders and decision makers about
perceptions of global risks, the World Economic Forum
(WEF, 2015) found that water crises have the greatest
potential for impact and are the eighth most likely to
occur, as shown in Figure 8. Moreover, WEF has consid-
ered water among the top three global risks since 2012
(WEF, 2012; 2013; 2014).
CDP, formerly known as the Carbon Disclosure Project,
operates a water program that surveys companies
helps facilitate some aspect of the transaction or imple-
mentation of the overall program. This role is commonly
played by NGOs, consultants, or academic institutions.”
Indeed, Coca-Cola has had to coordinate large-scale
bilateral partnerships with more than one intermediary
in order to achieve progress toward its global replen-
ish objective, including The Nature Conservancy, WWF,
and the  United Nations Development Programme
(UNDP). Table 3 illustrates increasing complexity and
differences in motivation that companies face as they
move from addressing efficiency in direct operations to
engaging in collective action intended to create more
sustainable operating conditions in watersheds where
they do business.
Future investments by the private sector are uncertain.
However, consumer preference for more sustainable
products and investor concern about unmitigated risk
TABLE 3. Private sector activities, scale, drivers
ACTIVITIES, COMPLEXITY, INCLUSIVITY
Operational efficiency
Wastewater quality
Owned facilities
Codes of conduct
Social/environmental indices
Voluntary sustainability standards
Industry sector/association
Policy engagement
Collective action
Diverse stakeholders
SCALE
Site-specific
Small business
Supply chain
Small to medium enterprise
Landscape
Multinational
TIME/VALUE
Near-term, return on investment Medium-term, possible value capture Long-term, sustainability
DRIVERS
Financial self-interest
Regulatory compliance
Externalities
License to operate
Reputation
Access to markets
EXTERNAL CONDITIONS
Strong governance and enforcement Inconsistent local regulation and
enforcement
Weak governance
Negative externalities of other actors
“…there is increasing awareness of water-
specific issues and of best practices in
corporate water stewardship…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT58
Figure 1: The Global Risks Landscape 2015
4.54.03.5 5.0 5.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
4.82
average
average
4.74
Likelihood
Impact
Top 10 risks in terms of
Likelihood
Categories
Interstate conflict
Extreme weather events
Failure of national governance
State collapse or crisis
Unemployment or underemployment
Natural catastrophes
Failure of climate-change adaptation
Water crises
Data fraud or theft
Cyber attacks
Top 10 risks in terms of
Impact
Water crises
Weapons of mass destruction
Interstate conflict
Energy price shock
Failure of climate-change adaptation
Fiscal crises
Unemployment or underemployment
Biodiversity loss and ecosystem collapse
Spread of infectious diseases
Critical information infrastructure breakdown
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
7.0
1.0 7.0
plotted
area
Economic
Geopolitical
Environmental
Societal
Technological
Misuse of
technologies Data fraud
or theft
Cyber
attacks
Critical information
infrastructure breakdown
Water crises
Spread of
infectious diseases
Profound social instability
Large-scale
involuntary migration
Food crises
Failure of urban planning
Weapons of
mass destruction
Terrorist
attacks
State collapse
or crisis
Interstate
conflict
Failure of
national governance
Natural catastrophes
Man-made environmental
catastrophes
Failure of
climate-change
adaptation
Biodiversity loss and
ecosystem collapse
Unmanageable
inflation
Unemployment
or underemployment
Fiscal crises
Failure of
critical infrastructure
Energy price
shock
Deflation
Asset bubble
Extreme
weather events
Failure of financial
mechanism or institution
Source: Global Risks Perception Survey 2014.
Note: Survey respondents were asked to assess the likelihood and impact of the individual risks on a scale of 1 to 7, 1 representing a risk that is not likely to happen or have
impact, and 7 a risk very likely to occur and with massive and devastating impacts. See Appendix B for more details. To ensure legibility, the names of the global risks are
abbreviated. Also see Appendix A for the full name and description.
FIGURE 8: Global risks landscape, 2015
Note: Taken from 2014 Global Risks Perception Survey. Survey respondents were asked to assess the likelihood and impact of the
individual risks on a scale of 1 to 7, 1 representing a risk that is not likely to happen or have impact, and 7 a risk very likely to occur
and with massive and devastating impacts. See Appendix B for more details. To ensure legibility, the names of the global risks are
abbreviated. Also see Appendix A for the full name and description.
Source: World Economic Forum, 2015.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 59
Concurrently, there is increasing awareness of water-
specific issues and of best practices in corporate water
stewardship, so there will likely be demand for mecha-
nisms that can deliver quantifiable outcomes to ben-
efit specific corporate assets or at-risk strategic supply
chain locations. Increased understanding of water-
related risks and opportunities could similarly drive an
increase in private sector engagement in incentive-
based instruments for watershed services.
in order to reveal water-related risk in institutional
investment portfolios. CDP’s 2014 Global Water Report
revealed that, of nearly 1,100 responding companies,
74  percent had evaluated how water quantity and
quality could affect their growth strategy. However, of
these, only 38 percent assessed water-related risk in
both owned operations and their supply chain, and only
25 percent conducted detailed water risk assessments
at the watershed level (CDP, 2014).
HunterRiver,Australia.PhotographbyAussieLegend.
5
Summary and conclusions
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 61
Growing pressure on the availability and quality of
water resources is having a major impact on our social,
economic, and environmental well-being. These pres-
sures are likely to worsen in response to continued
population and economic growth, climate change, and
other challenges. As water pollution exacerbates the
challenges posed by water scarcity, and the world’s
water quality becomes increasingly degraded, new
approaches and strategies are needed.
One key area of interest is the potential for incen-
tive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water
resources. To date, the primary environmental pol-
icy tool to address water challenges has been com-
mand-and-control regulations. Over the past several
decades, however, the environmental policy “toolkit”
has expanded to include a host of incentive-based
instruments that use financial means, directly or indi-
rectly, to motivate responsible parties to reduce the
health and environmental risks posed by their facili-
ties, processes, or products. While regulations and
incentive-based instruments are often juxtaposed, “in
reality the two often operate alongside each other”
(UNEP, 2004). With water quality trading, for example,
governments mandate caps on the allowable pollut-
ant levels and issue tradable permits that allow those
in the industry to allocate polluting activities among
themselves, incentivized by market forces. Similarly,
with water trading, governments may allocate water
and then institute a framework by which water trad-
ing can occur. While incentive-based instruments
may work in tandem, they must be integrated within
a broader watershed management effort. In a recent
review of PWS programs, Bond and Mayers (2010)
cautioned that:
“PWS is a tool that will fail, or become irrelevant, if it
is not integrated with wider regulatory approaches,
broaderwatershedmanagementefforts,andexplicit
attention to governance influences that shape
what is possible. Policy makers need to consider
the opportunities to ensure that future policy and
legislation allow for a mix of both incentives and
regulations to ensure the effective management of
land and water resources.”
The choice of whether and which instrument to apply
depends on the specific circumstances, conditions, and
needs of a given area. It is important to avoid “the law
of the instrument”, i.e. the tendency to gravitate toward
a particular tool and then look for applications of that
tool. UNEP (2004) found that:
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT62
for consistent and rigorous outreach and, potentially, a
need for engaging a trusted intermediary.
Finally, monitoring and evaluation are essential to the
success of any instrument. In particular, they help
ensure outcomes are achieved and allow for adjust-
ments in response to changing social, economic, or
environmental conditions. Monitoring should evaluate
the additionality of the program, i.e. whether the pro-
gram has an effect when compared with baseline con-
ditions. It should also examine any potential impacts on
surrounding areas (e.g. leakage) and the permanence
of the intervention. However, it is important to recog-
nize that extensive monitoring requirements would
increase transaction costs. Thus, the need for moni-
toring and evaluation must be balanced with practical
considerations about the ability to maintain the viability
of the program.
“Prior to designing and applying any policy instrument
for environmental protection, the policy context must
be understood, including the existing institutional,
legal and economic conditions in which these tools
are meant to function. Choosing an effective policy
package that will both address the environmental
problem policy makers are faced with and fit in with the
institutional capabilities and existing policy framework
remains one of the most difficult challenges.”
This process should be open and transparent, with
meaningful participation from all affected parties. This
will enable crafting a solution that not only is appropri-
ate for local conditions, it will help reduce opposition
and promote buy-in from those who will be imple-
menting and affected by the program. It is important
to recognize that those with the least power may not
have the resources to participate or be skeptical of the
groups involved. In these cases, there will be a need
ANNEX 1
Demand management
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 63
A key way to reduce pressure on limited water supplies
is through demand management, commonly referred
to as water conservation and efficiency. In many cases,
reducing demand is equivalent to augmenting or real-
locating water supply. Demand management is typi-
cally less expensive and faster to implement than water
supply augmentation, and often results in reduced
energy demand and water and wastewater treatment
costs. For example, a recent study in Westminster,
Colorado, found that water conservation and efficiency
since 1980 had reduced water use in the city, reduc-
ing tap fees by 80 percent and reducing customers’
bills by 91  percent relative to what they would have
been without these efforts (Feinglas, Gray, and Mayer
2013). In major cities, such as San Francisco and Los
Angeles, total water use has decreased since the late
1970s despite population and economic growth. At a
larger scale, a recent United States federal study found
that water conservation and efficiency efforts have
reduced annual demand for water from the Colorado
River basin by more than 1.7 million acre-feet, a tremen-
dous savings in an over-allocated basin (US Bureau of
Reclamation 2015). In the United States, we have made
considerable progress in managing the nation’s water,
with total water use less than it was in 1970, despite
continued population and economic growth. Indeed,
every sector, from agriculture to thermoelectric power
generation, shows reductions in water use. Likewise,
in Australia, a severe drought in the middle of the last
decade prompted an intensive effort to reduce water
demand. In response, total urban demand, including
losses and non-residential consumption, fell from about
130 gallons per capita daily (gpcd) in 2005 to about 80
gpcd in 2010 (Queensland Water Commission, 2010).
There are many tools available to reduce water demand
– some of which rely on an incentive-based approach,
e.g. pricing and rebates, while others are based on a
more traditional command-and-control approach.
Numerous studies have shown that significant conser-
vation and efficiency opportunities exist in urban and
agricultural areas (see, e.g. Gleick et al., 2003; Heberger,
Cooley, and Gleick 2014). Below, we provide additional
detail on the major demand management tools, includ-
ing pricing, direct financial incentives, regulations, and
education and outreach.
Water pricing. Well-designed tariff structures can
meet multiple policy objectives, including supporting
the financial stability of the utility, the affordability of
water for low-income customers, the efficient alloca-
tion of water and other resources, and environmental
sustainability. Most water utilities use some form of
volumetric tariffs to achieve these objectives. There
are several types of volumetric tariffs in use around the
world:
•	 uniform tariffs in which the volumetric tariff ($/m3)
is constant regardless of the quantity used;
•	 inclining block tariffs in which the volumetric tariff
increases as the quantity used increases; and
•	 declining block tariffs in which the volumetric tariff
decreases as the quantity used increases.
Uniform tariffs are the most common tariff structure
in OECD and in developing countries (OECD 2009).
Inclining block rates are becoming increasingly com-
mon (OECD 2009), as there is recognition that when
designed properly, this approach can provide a strong
financial incentive to conserve while ensuring that
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT64
Instead of providing rebates to cover a portion of the
cost, some utilities have opted to institute direct-install
programs that cover the entire cost of the device and
the installation costs. In the mid-1990s, for example, the
New York City Department of Environmental Protection
launched a massive toilet rebate program to replace
one-third of all water-wasting toilets in New York City
with low-flow models. For this effort, property owners
contracted directly with private licensed plumbers for
the installation of the toilet, and after completion of
the work, the City provided the property owner with a
$240 rebate for the first toilet and $150 for the second
toilet. Where possible, the plumber would also install
low-flow showerheads and faucet aerators. The pro-
gram was a huge success. Between 1994 and 1997, 1.3
million low-flow toilets were installed, saving 70 - 90
million gallons per day. Customers saw their water and
wastewater bills drop 20 percent to 40 percent (EPA
2002). Additionally, the City was able to defer the need
to develop new supply sources and expand wastewater
treatment capacity, saving the community even more
money.
Regulations. In addition to financial incentives, reg-
ulations are key demand management strategies.
Regulations can take a variety of forms, ranging from
a prescriptive approach focused on a particular appli-
ance to a performance-based approach for outdoor
water use. For example, the International Plumbing
Code, which is widely used in the United States and
forms the basis for plumbing codes in several other
countries, specifies maximum flow rates for kitchen
and lavatory faucets. Likewise, communities in the Las
Vegas area have restricted lawn installation in new
developments. California has also passed an ordinance
to reduce outdoor water use, although the state opted
for a performance-based approach. Landscape irriga-
tion typically accounts for more than half of residen-
tial demand in the state, and in an effort to promote
outdoor efficiency, the state adopted the Model Water
Efficient Landscape Ordinance (MWELO). MWELO
lower-income consumers are able to meet their basic
water needs at a reduced cost. A 2003 survey of cities
in the southwest United States found that per-capita
water use is typically lower in cities with dramatically
increasing block tariffs, such as Tucson and El Paso
(WRA 2003).
Although less frequently employed, pricing has also
been shown to be effective in reducing agricultural
water use. For example, the Broadview Water District,
a small district in California’s San Joaquin Valley, imple-
mented increasing block rates in 1988 to reduce the
volume of contaminated drainage water flowing into
the San Joaquin River. The rate was set at $16 per
acre-foot ($0.013 per m3) for the first 90 percent of
average water use during the 1986 to 1988 period and
$40 per acre-foot ($0.032 per m3) for any additional
water. By 1991, the district’s average water use declined
by 19 percent due to efficiency improvements and crop
shifting (MacDougall et al., 1992).
Direct financial incentives. Rebate programs are
commonly used to encourage customers to make
investments in water conservation and efficiency
improvements. Residents and business owners pur-
chase new devices as the old devices wear out. While
most new standard devices use less water than older
models, there are many new high-efficiency devices
available that use even less water. While efficient
devices are often cheaper over their lifetimes due to
lower water, energy, and wastewater bills, users may be
put off by the higher up-front costs. As a result, water
utilities may provide their customers with a rebate to
defray the additional cost of the more efficient device.
There are several examples of water utilities partner-
ing with local energy utilities to augment those rebates
because of the energy savings (Cooley and Donnelly
2013). Additionally, utilities may partner with retailers
to offer rebates at the point of sale, giving customers
an immediate incentive to purchase the more efficient
device.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 65
Education and outreach. Education and outreach
programs can also be effective for promoting water
conservation and efficiency. The US Environmental
Protection Agency (EPA), for example, launched the
WaterSense labeling program in 2006 to promote
water-conserving devices that are 20  percent more
efficient than standard products on the market and
meet rigorous performance criteria. Social market-
ing has also gained prominence in recent years, with
some programs tapping into new metering technolo-
gies and web-based platforms. For example, a recent
study found that home water reports - which provide
customers information on their current water use and
comparisons to their past use, use by similar house-
holds, and efficient use - reduce water by 5 percent and
were especially effective in reaching the highest water
users (Mitchell and Chesnutt 2013).
establishes a water budget for new construction and
rehabilitated landscapes that are at least 2,500 square
feet and require a building or landscaping permit (the
size threshold is likely to be reduced to 500 square
feet in response to the current drought). In addition,
the ordinance requires mulching for most plantings;
promotes the use of techniques to increase storm-
water retention and infiltration; and requires new and
refurbished landscapes to install irrigation systems run
by weather, soil moisture, or other self-adjusting con-
trollers. Also in California, Governor Schwarzenegger
signed SBx7-7 in 2009, requiring urban water suppliers
to reduce per-capita water use by 20 percent by 2020.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT66
The MDB includes parts of four states (Queensland,
New South Wales, Victoria, and South Australia) and the
Australian Capital Territory. The MDB supplies water to
about three million people, including the national capi-
tal (Canberra) and Adelaide, outside of the basin near
the river’s mouth. According to the MDBA, the basin
contains some 70 percent of the nation’s irrigated acre-
age, producing a third of the country’s food supply. The
MDBA reports the gross value of irrigated agriculture in
the basin in 2012-13 at approximately $6.8 Billion. The
MDB generates almost all of Australia’s rice and cotton
and 75 percent of its grapes, as well as roughly half of
the nation’s hay, fruit, livestock, and dairy production.
The construction of dams and canals and the diver-
sion and depletion of MDB rivers has endangered the
survival of at least 35 bird species and 16 mammal spe-
cies within the basin. Many fish species, including the
Murray cod, are also threatened. Wetlands have dried
up or reached critically low levels, exacerbated by the
Millennium drought, prompting public concern.
MDB and the Colorado
River Basin
The MDB and the Colorado River Basin share many
common traits: both are highly variable rivers in arid
basins, where rapidly-growing urban populations have
imposed new demands on limited, climate-stressed
rivers. Basin size and runoff are similar. And, interest-
ingly, the two basins share a common figure: Elwood
Mead (namesake of Lake Mead), the Wyoming State
Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin (MDB) figures promi-
nently in discussions about water trading as an example
of a thriving incentive-based system that successfully
transitioned from a non-market system (Grafton et al.,
2012). The total value of water trading in Australia in
fiscal year 2012-13 exceeded $1.4 billion (NWC 2013).
Water trading in Australia includes both short-term
trades, known as allocation trading, and long-term
trades, known as entitlement trading. In fiscal year
2012-13, the most recent period for which comprehen-
sive data are available, the total volume of short-term
trading increased 44 percent from the previous year,
from almost 3.5 million acre-feet to 5 million acre-feet,
or roughly 50 percent of total surface water use in the
MDB. This is an extremely active water market.
Background
The MDB covers some 390,000 square miles in south-
eastern Australia, comprising roughly 14 percent of that
country’s land area. Most of the basin is very arid, with
86 percent of the basin contributing little or no flow to
rivers that drain the basin. The Murray-Darling Basin
Authority (MDBA) estimates that total runoff within the
basin is less than 26 million acre-feet annually, yield-
ing an estimated long-term annual average 19 MAF
of total river flow. As shown in Figure A-1, the system
displays very high seasonal and annual variability. For
example, flows in the southern Murray basin typically
are much higher than in the northern Darling basin.
Pre-development, an estimated 10 million acre-feet ran
into the ocean; in 2009, during the historic Millennium
drought, this had decreased to 4 million acre-feet.
ANNEX 2
Water trading in Australia:
Lessons from the Murray-Darling Basin
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 67
subsequently changing the water rights structure to
facilitate trading and protect environmental resources.
In Australia, water rights typically refer to either entitle-
ments or allocations.30 The National Water Initiative of
2004 defines these as:
•	 Water access entitlement – a perpetual or ongo-
ing entitlement to exclusive access to a share of
water from a specified consumptive pool as defined
in the relevant water plan.
•	 Water allocation – the specific volume of water
allocated to water access entitlements in a given
season, defined according to rules established in
the relevant water plan. (Young, 2010).
Australian water rights are typically defined as the right
todivertaspecificvolume,asopposedtoaconsumptive
use right that is more typical with prior appropriation
30	 Additional water rights include: Water use license – a non-tradable
use or condition linked to the place of use; and Delivery right – may be
required to ensure that an allocation is delivered, typically associated
with irrigation infrastructure, such as canals and headgates (Grafton and
Horne 2014).
Irrigation Engineer from 1888-99, went on to serve as
the Chairman of Victoria (Australia)’s State Rivers 
Water Supply Commission (1907–15), prior to return-
ing to the US and serving as the Commissioner of the
Bureau of Reclamation from 1924-36 (McLeod 2014).
However, Australia avoided Mead’s legacy of prior
appropriation and hierarchical water rights to embrace
a very different system that promotes and facilitates
water trading, as described in the following sections.
History
Australia has promoted and developed water trading
over a period of more than 30 years (Grafton et al.,
2012), in a process that initially attempted to activate
markets prior to recognizing that the water rights struc-
ture itself needed to be altered to encourage active
trading and minimize transaction costs (Young, 2015).
Table A-1 lists some of the major steps taken to cre-
ate the current water trading structure. These changes
have occurred over several decades and often reflect
corrections to previous policies. Young (2010, 2015)
asserts that Australia implemented water trading from
the wrong direction, by first promoting trading and
FIGURE A-1. Historical river flows within the Murray-Darling Basin
1900s 1910s 1920s 1930s 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s
30,000
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
Flow(GLperyear)
Northern basin annual flows
Flow measured on Darling River at Bourke
Southern basin annual flows
Flow measured on River Murray at Euston
Average annual flow levels
1895
Startofthe
‘FederationDrought’
whichlastsfor7years
1909
Floodinthe
Murrayand
Wimmerarivers
1914
Severedrought
leadstotheend
ofcommercial
navigationonthe
Murrayand
Darlingrivers
1917
Floodingalong
theRiverMurray
1921
Floodingacross
theentireBasin
1931
Floodingalong
theRiverMurray
1944
Severedrought
throughoutNSW,
VicandSA.
Murrayceasesto
flowinsomeareas
1950
Recordrainfall
causeswidespread
floodinginCondamine
andWarregorivers
1952
Floodinginthe
RiverMurray
1956
HighestBasininflows
inrecordedhistory
causewidespread
flooding
1968
Duetosevere
drought,HumeDam
fallsto1%ofcapacity
1974
Widespreadflooding
acrosstheBasin,
knownasthe‘bigwet’
1981
Droughtforces
Adelaidetotake
90%ofitswater
fromtheMurray.
TheMurrayMouth
closesforthefirst
timeinrecorded
history
1993
Floodingacross
QLD,NSW
andVictoria
1997
Beginningoflongestdrought
inAustralia’srecordedhistory
2000MurrayMouthclosesand
requiresdredging
2010-11Widespreadflooding
throughouttheBasin
2006
Lowest water
inflowsonrecord
Extremedryin
NorthernBasin
2013-15
Note: Volumes in the figure shown in gigaliters, with 1000 GL = 0.8 million acre-feet.
Source: Australia’s MDBA.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT68
the land. Transforming these general land-based rights
to discrete volumes then required determining his-
toric usage patterns and water requirements for crops
grown on that land. Several MDB states initially allowed
water trading within individual irrigation districts, using
shared infrastructure to trade water to different parcels
within the district. These volumetric rights were subse-
quently “unbundled” from the land, enabling water to
be traded between different irrigation districts. Despite
these changes, restrictions on trading between dif-
ferent sub-basins often took years to revoke, due to
concerns about adverse economic and equity impacts
that trading could cause in areas of origin (Grafton and
Horne 2014).
regimes (Connor and Kaczan, 2013). Diversions can
be measured (and subsequently traded) more readily
than consumptive use, which requires measurement
of both diversions and surface and sub-surface return
flows. Return flows often lag diversions, sometimes by
weeks or months in the case of sub-surface returns,
requiring more complicated measurements and esti-
mates, challenging efforts to evaluate and quantify the
full impacts (especially environmental impacts) of the
trade, hindering transactions.
Initially, Australian water rights were linked to a spe-
cific land parcel. In many cases, the water right simply
entitled the landowner to sufficient water to irrigate
TABLE A-1. Policy and legislative milestones
YEAR ACTION DESCRIPTION
1960s Volumetric water licenses
Start of conversion of land-based water entitlements to volumetric
entitlements
1983 Water trading w/in districts Allowed in New South Wales and South Australia
1987 1st
MDB Agreement Established the MDB Commission, to coordinate management
1991 Inter-district water trading Allowed in New South Wales
1994 “Unbundling”
Council of Australian Governments agrees to separate statutory land
rights from water rights, facilitating trading
1995 Diversion CAP implemented Limits surface water diversions in the MDB; limits water rights
1995 National Competition Policy Requires development of water markets and full-cost pricing
2000 Water Management Act “Unbundles” diversion and use rights
2004 National Water Initiative Promotes cohesive water planning and trading efforts
2004 Living Murray Initiative Authorizes purchase and dedication of 0.4 MAF to the river
2007 Water Act Promotes management of MDB
2008 Water Amendment Act Establishes MDB Authority, replacing the Commission
2008 Water for the Future Commits $3.1 billion to purchase water entitlements for the env.
2012 MD Basin Plan
Caps total MDB surface diversions at 8.8 MAF, coordinates basin
management including water quality (esp. salinity)
Sources: MDBA, Young, 2010; Grafton and Horne, 2014.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 69
uses. New South Wales has attempted to limit federal
purchases of water for the environment to no more than
3 percent of total entitlements, though this appears to
contravene trading rules within the Basin Plan, which
seek to minimize restrictions on trading (Grafton and
Horne 2014).
State water plans allocate water entitlements into one
or two “pools,” known as a high security pool and a gen-
eral or low security pool. The high security pool is allo-
cated to those entitlement holders proportional to the
size of their entitlement. For example, if a system only
has two entitlement holders and one right is for nine
units and the other is for one unit, the former would
receive 90  percent of the pool’s allocation and the
latter would receive 10 percent. If additional water is
available for the general pool, that volume is allocated
to those entitlement holders. Every season, the state
determines the total volume available for allocation for
each pool. During drought, the general pool might not
receive any water at all (Young, 2010).
Water trading activity
Australia’s water trading activity is largely concentrated
in the MDB, which represents as much as 94 percent of
all such activity in Australia despite being only one of
twelve surface water management areas (Figure A-2).
Trading is very high as measured by the total volume
of water traded (as much as 5 million acre-feet), the
percentage of all diversions that are traded (as much
as 50 percent), the number of farmers trading water
(roughly half, in 2008-09), and the total number of
trades (11,000, in 2011-12). The number of short-term
(allocation) interstate trades also appears to be rising,
reaching 20 percent of the total number of such trades
in 2011/12 (Grafton and Horne 2014). Not surprisingly,
the number of short-term (allocation) trades is much
higher, in terms of numbers and volumes, than the
number of entitlement trades. As the federal govern-
ment has exercised its commitment to ensure minimum
Unlike the doctrine of prior appropriation in the west-
ern United States, water rights in Australia did not
have priority dates or a seniority system for satisfy-
ing demands: all rights were considered equivalent.
Additionally, Australian water rights did not have to
be exercised on an annual or periodic basis to demon-
strate possession (again, unlike the prior appropriation
system); many rights holders maintained their rights
for periodic or infrequent use (known as “dozer” rights)
or never exercised their water rights (known as “sleep-
ers”), perhaps in the expectation that they might be
needed in the future.
The 1995 imposition of the diversion CAP limiting
surface water diversions and rights within the MDBA
explicitly recognized the continuing validity of dozer
and sleeper rights and incorporated the volumes of
these rights into the general calculation of the propor-
tional shares of the new water rights regime. However,
the result of recognizing dozer and sleeper rights within
the context of water trading was to increase the finan-
cial value of these unexercised rights, leading to new
diversions and greater strain on water supply, in turn
reducing water reliability (Grafton and Horne 2014).
Tony McLeod, General Manager for Water Planning at
MDBA, explained that the recognition of these dozer
and sleeper rights was intentional, to reduce resistance
to the imposition of the CAP and smooth the transition
to the new system of proportional sharing (McLeod,
personal communication, 2014).
In response, the Australian government implemented
several initiatives to purchase existing water entitle-
ments and dedicate these to the environment, both to
offset reservoir evaporation and other system losses
(known as maintenance rights) and explicitly to ensure
minimum instream flow volumes in designated reaches.
The government has invested more than $3 Billion to
date to purchase entitlements for environmental water.
However, the relative priority of this environmental
water remains contentious, with some states contend-
ing that such rights receive lower priority than human
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT70
about $54 per acre-foot in the drier 2012/13.31 Similarly,
trading in drier years tends to see water move from lower
value uses, such as pasture and forage, to higher value
wine and vegetable crops. Connor and Kaczan (2013)
reported that many livestock operations irrigate pasture
and forage crops in wet years but tend to trade away
their allocations in drier years, when the price of water
rises due to scarcity, using the profits to purchase feed
from other areas. These trends also manifest regionally,
aswatertendstomoveacrossstatelinesfromNewSouth
Wales into South Australia, which has more high-value
31	 These prices are about an order of magnitude lower than prices for
short-term transfers in California in the 2014 drought year, but are
comparable to prices paid for short-term rentals in the active Northern
Colorado Water Conservancy district water market.
environmental flows by purchasing entitlements, such
purchases have risen to 37 percent of the total number
of entitlement trades in 2011/12. Only about 5 percent
of farmers traded water entitlements, either to other
farmers or to cities or to the government for augment-
ing environmental flows, in 2008/09, or about 10 per-
cent of the number that reported trading allocations
that year (Grafton and Horne 2014).
As expected, the number of allocation trades appears
to be inversely correlated with precipitation and runoff,
rising in drought years and falling when allocations are
higher due to wetter conditions. Prices similarly vary in
response to water availability, rising from the equivalent
of about $22 per acre-foot in 2011/12 to the equivalent of
81 0.NT
426.K
426.A
426.B
426.I
507.A
426.G
426.D
41 4.SAC
239.SAA
81 0.WA
809.WA
808
807
806
805
804
803
802
801
71 0709
708
707
706
705
704
703
702
701
61 9
61 8
61 7
61 6 61 5
61 461 3
61 2
611
61 0
609
608
607
606
605
604
602
601
026.WA
025
024
023.WA
022.WA
41 5
41 4.VIC
408
407
406
405
404
403
402
409.VIC
239.VIC
238
237
236
235
234
233
232
231
230
229
225
224
223
222.VIC
221 .VIC
31 4.I
31 4.H
31 2
31131 0
302.G
301
31 9.E
31 9.D
302.F
302.E
31 9.B
307.B
31 8.F
31 6
31 8.E
31 7
31 8.B
31 8.A
302.D
309
302.C
302.A
303 304.E
304.B
304.A
308
306
31 4.A
31 3
307.A
021 .D 004.A
023.SAB
51 3.D
51 3.C
51 3.B
51 3.A
426.C
023.SAA
503.C
501
003.SA
505.A
005.SA
021 .B
41 4.SAD
021 .C
026.SA
51 2
507.B
506.A
007.SA
426.F
506.B
021 .A
509
51 0
004.B
001 .SA
508.A
022.SA
511
508.B
239.SAC
239.SAE
41 4.SAA
002
41 6.QLD
11 7
11 0
924
1 23
1 22.B
925
923
1 34
1 29
423.A
11 3
1 27
1 44.B
1 04
91 5
1 28
11 8
1 22.A
922
1 261 25
424.QLD
1 02
1 24
1 05
422.A
11 4
111
91 3
928
1 43
41 7
91 9
1 38
1 03
11 2
1 06
927
1 01
1 44.A
921
11 5
11 6
1 46
001 .QLD
1 39
1 30
1 07
926
1 21
1 09
1 08
1 31
003.QLD
422.B
920
1 32
1 36
1 20
011
1 33
929
91 2
91 0
909
908
907
906
905
904
903
902
901
826
825824
823
822
821
820
81 9
81 8
81 7
81 6
81 5.B
81 5.A
81 4
81 3
81 2
811
809.NT
029
028
027
026.NT
023.NT
007.NT
006
005.NT
001 .NT
499
425.URB425.URA
425.R
421 .UR
421 .R
420
41 9.UR
41 9.R
41 8.UR
41 8.R
41 6.NSWR
41 6.NSWUR
41 2.UR
41 2.R
411
41 0.NSWUR
41 0.NSWR
409.NSW
401 .NSW
222.NSW
221 .NSW
220
21 9.UR
21 9.R
21 8
21 7
21 6
21 5
21 4
21 3
21 2 211
21 0.UR
21 0.R
208 207
206 205
204
203.UR
203.R
202
201
01 2
424.NSW
004.NSW
003.NSW
41 0.ACT
503.B
502
426.J
426.H
426.L
239.SAB
603
228
227
226
31 9.C
31 9.A
31 8.C
31 8.D
304.F
302.B
305
304.D
304.C
31 4.G
31 4.F31 4.E
31 4.D
31 4.C
31 5
31 4.B
505.C
503.A
504.B
504.C
505.E
504.A
505.G
505.F
505.B
426.E
505.D
41 4.SAB
239.SAD
1 45
209
PERTH
HOBART
SYDNEY
DARWIN
CANBERRA
ADELAIDE
BRISBANE
MELBOURNE
0 250 5001 25
Kilometres
Legend
Surface water
management areas
Drainage division
North-East Coast
South-East Coast
Tasmania
Murray-Darling
South Australia Gulf
South-West Coast
Indian Ocean
Timor Sea
Gulf of Carpentaria
Lake Eyre
Bulloo-Bancannia
Western Plateau
CommonwealthofAustralia© MapID: WA_L1_SWMA_28
WaterAustralian Resources 2005
FIGURE A-2. Surface water management areas in Australia
Source: Australia National Water Commission.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 71
market activity while protecting environmental values
by participating directly in the market, purchasing enti-
tlements from willing sellers and dedicating this water
to preserve threatened ecosystems and river reaches.
This approach has come at great expense to the gov-
ernment (and taxpayers) but has been justified by the
reported increase in economic activity and benefits
arising from trading activity. In a robust assessment
of water trading in Victoria’s Murray Valley, Frontier
Economics (2007) found strong local opposition to
permanently trading water out of local areas, to the
extent that some irrigators selling entitlements have
been ostracized, but also found a combination of posi-
tive and negative socio-economic impacts from such
trades. For example, the authors found that trading
ameliorated the impacts of the Millennium Drought on
dairy farmers in the region, who otherwise would have
fared much worse. Additionally, water trading facili-
tated the expansion of the wine industry in the region.
Several researchers have compiled extensive lists of
lessons learned. Two of these are reproduced below.
Young (2010) writes:
Lesson 1: Unless carefully managed, the legacy
of prior licensing decisions can result in markets
causing over-allocation problems to emerge in a
manner that erodes the health of rivers, aquifer and
the water dependent ecosystems associated with
them.
Lesson 2: Transaction and administrative costs
are lower when entitlements are defined using a
unit share structure and not as an entitlement to a
volume of water. One of the simplest ways of pre-
venting over-allocation problems from emerging is
to assign the risks of adverse climate change and/
or the emergence of long dry periods to entitlement
holders and define entitlements as an entitlement
to a share of the water defined as being available
for use.
Lesson 3: Market efficiency is improved by using
separate structures to define entitlements, manage
allocations and control the use of water.
crops. In response, New South Wales and Victoria have
imposed restrictions on the volume of water that may be
exported from the state (Grafton and Horne 2014).
Enabling conditions
A large number of necessary and enabling conditions
help explain Australia’s water trading success. Key
among these is the development of a proportional
water sharing regime, in which the state, rather than
administrative or water courts, determines total annual
water availability, rather than granting rights holders
an absolute or priority-based right to a fixed volume
of water. The Australian experience also shows that
water trading is more active when allocation pools
encompass a large number of entitlement holders with
a diverse range of uses (Young, 2010).
Grafton and Horne (2014) found that infrastructure,
such as dams and canals, can facilitate water trading by
storing water until needed and providing conveyances
to deliver where needed. Similarly, access to accurate
and timely information on water prices and availability
facilitates water trading. In Australia, brokerage-type
water banks are active in both the Murray-Darling Basin
and in northern Victoria, where the banks post informa-
tion about pricing and availability (O’Donnell and Colby
2010). Underpinning this information exchange is an
extensive, credible, verifiable registry of entitlements and
allocations and mechanism to quickly record, measure
and monitor trades, as well as sufficient sanctions on
those violating agreements (Connor and Kaczan 2013).
Lessons learned
Connor and Kaczan highlighted the classic dilemma
facing those attempting to implement a water trading
system: the tradeoff between protecting third parties
with high transaction costs versus promoting trades
with low transaction costs, with less concern for third
parties. Australia has adopted the latter approach,
choosing to minimize transaction costs and promote
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT72
Lesson 11: Water use and investment will be more
efficient if all users are exposed to at least the
full lower bound cost and preferably the upper
bound cost of supplying water to them. One way of
achieving this outcome is to transfer ownership of
the supply system to these users.
Lesson 12: Manage environmental externalities
using separate instruments so that the costs of
avoiding them are reflected in the costs of produc-
tion and use in a manner that encourages water
users to avoid creating them.
Lesson 13: Removal of administrative impediments
to inter-regional trade and inter-state trade is difficult
but necessary for the development of efficient water
markets. Australia has taken the approach of ap-
pointing an independent agency to develop rules
designed to remove unnecessary barriers to water
trade. Amongst other things, this has required the
setting of guidelines that prevent water supply
companies from setting charges and adopting
practices that discriminate against people who wish
to trade water out of a region.
Lesson 14: Markets will be more efficient and the
volume of trade greater if entitlements are allocated
to individual users rather than to irrigator controlled
water supply companies and cooperatives. Whilst
opposed by water supply companies and coopera-
tives, it is the Australian experience that willingness
to trade and market depth typically is much greater
when entitlements are allocated to individuals rather
than to water supply companies or associations as
they are called in other countries. The reason for
this is that when allocations are issued to individu-
als they do not have to obtain the permission of the
board of a water supply company or association to
sell water out of a region.
Lesson 15: Equity and fairness principles require
careful attention to and discipline in the way
that allocation decisions and policy changes are
announced.
Lesson 16: Water markets are more effective when
information about the prices being paid and offered
is made available to all participants in a timely
manner.
Lesson 4: Early attention to the development of
accurate license registers is critical and a necessary
precondition to the development of low-cost entitle-
ment trading systems.
Lesson 5: Unless water market and allocation pro-
cedures allow unused water to be carried forward
from year to year, trading may increase the severity
of droughts.
Lesson 6: Early installation of meters and conver-
sion from area based licenses to a volumetric man-
agement system is a necessary precursor to the
development of low cost allocation trading systems.
Metering and conversion to a volumetric allocation
system is a necessary precursor to the development
of efficient water trading systems. In order to facili-
tate the more efficient management of the available
resource and trading, Australia has spent many
years converting area-based licenses to volumetric
licenses and installing meters. Typically, conversion
involves estimation of the amount of water used
by crop type and the development of conversion
factors.
Lesson 7: It is difficult for communities to plan for
an adverse climate shift and develop water sharing
plans that deal adequately with a climatic shift to
a drier regime. More robust planning and water en-
titlement systems are needed.
Lesson 8: The allocation regime for the provision of
water necessary to maintain minimum flows, provide
for conveyance and cover evaporative losses need
to be more secure than that used to allocate water
for environmental and other purposes.
Lesson 9: Unless all forms of water use are
accounted for entitlement reliability will be eroded
by expansion of un-metered uses like plantation
forestry and farm dam development, increases in ir-
rigation efficiency, etc. and place the integrity of the
allocation system at risk.
Lesson 10: Unless connected ground and surface
water systems are managed as a single integrated
resource, groundwater development will reduce the
amount of water available that can be allocated to
surface water users.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 73
7.	 Statutory rights offer flexibility but carry risks
- can be modified without recourse to the courts.
Developments to unbundle water rights have facili-
tated trade. A potential downside of statutory rights
is sovereign risk, or the possibility that the value of
existing water rights can be degraded by changes
in regulation and discretionary behaviour by state
governments.
8.	 Markets can promote environmental outcomes -
Trading should always be subject to a public interest
test. Where there are important public interests,
such as flow volumes at key locations or the need
to ensure minimum levels of water quality, trade may
need to be constrained for environmental reasons.
An example of this approach is the Basin Salinity
Management Strategy that seeks to reduce salinity:
actions that reduce salinity are treated as credits
and actions that increase salinity as debits on state
salinity registers.
9.	 Acquiring water for the environment through
buybacks has proved effective.
10.	Prices contain information on scarcity and risk.
11.	Basin-wide and local perspectives have roles to
play – local input can also prevent or undermine the
emergence of strong water markets. … Governments
need to see through short-term and some-times
parochial interests to facilitate optimal use in the
longer term.
12.	Effective monitoring and control of extractions
are critical for sustainability – Farmers made
substantial investments to increase their on-farm
retention of water that might otherwise have flowed
to the Basin’s streams and rivers. Similarly, ground-
water extractions increased by about half over the
period 2000–2001 to 2007–2008 (from about 1
MAF to 1.4 MAF) as market users sought access to
other cost effective water supplies.
Lesson 17: Develop brokering industry and avoid
government involvement in the provision of water
brokering services.
GRAFTON AND HORNE (2014) WRITE:
1.	 Crises may facilitate reform - As the focus on the
crisis fades, so may do the reform zeal. This ‘stop
and go’ reform process suggests that determination
is required to make consistent progress, but that a
crisis can facilitate reform.
2.	 Water markets support regional resilience - The
geographical distribution of markets has meant
these benefits have been concentrated in areas of
greatest connectivity of the resource (the southern
Murray-Darling Basin) where there is also the widest
cross-section of users. An example is the signifi-
cance of selling water by opportunistic commodity
producers (such as rice growers) to perennial crop
producers (such as citrus growers).
3.	 Political and administrative leadership is critical
- This involves teams with a range of skills, much
broader than the engineering-based specialists that
have traditionally managed water resources.
4.	 Capping extractions promotes effective use and
sustainability - any cap should be comprehen-
sive and all water sources should be included to
avoid substitution to uncontrolled or inadequately
measured sources.
5.	 Regulated water framework facilitates water
trading - entitlements delivered via regulated water
storages account for about 90 percent of the water
entitlements traded in the Southern MDB.
6.	 Reliable, accessible and timely market informa-
tion promotes effective decision-making - the
Australian government is investing over half a billion
Australian dollars in improved water information and
regulations.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT74
Payment for ecosystem services (PES) – an incen-
tive-based instrument that seeks to translate external,
non-market values of environment services into financial
incentives for local actors to provide such services. In
practical terms, PES involves a series of payments to a
land or resource manager in exchange for a guaranteed
flow of environmental services.
Payment for watershed services (PWS) – a type of
PES arrangement that is focused on watershed services.
Water bank – may refer to the physical storage of water,
typically in a reservoir or an aquifer, to an institution that
facilitates or brokers a water transfer or serves as an
information clearinghouse, or to any agency that holds
water rights in trust for a specified purpose such as
streamflow augmentation.
Water market – Often used interchangeably with water
transfer, a water market can also refer to informal
transactions involving the sale of water, e.g. from water
tankers, that do not involve the lease or sale of water
rights or concessions.
Water option – a type of conditional water transfer.
Under dry-year options a buyer will pay the seller an
annual fee to be able to exercise an option to purchase a
pre-determined volume of water under a specific set of
circumstances.
Water transfer – a change in the point of diversion,
type of use, or location of water use. May refer to a
temporary or permanent exchange of water rights (see
water market), or to a non-market conveyance of water
from one location to another.
Aquifer – an underground layer of water-bearing
materials, such as sandstone or gravel or other
permeable material.
Command-and-control regulation – an environmental
regulatory policy that is often contrasted with “incentive-
based mechanisms” in the literature. A command and
control (CAC) regulation can be defined as the direct
regulation of an industry or activity that states what is
permitted and what is illegal.
Economic Efficiency – generally, a state or condition
with optimal resource use, allocation, or productivity. May
or may not be consistent with equity considerations.
Equity – refers to fairness, justice, impartiality, such as
in the allocation of resources or treatment of different
classes of people. May or may not be consistent with
economic efficiency considerations.
Eutrophication – excessive richness of nutrients in a
lake or other body of water, frequently due to runoff from
the land, which causes a dense growth of plant life and
death of animal life from lack of oxygen.
Incentive-based instrument – a broad set of tools that
use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate re-
sponsible parties to reduce the health and environmental
risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products.
Nonpoint source (NPS) pollution – water pollution
from diffuse sources such as runoff from urbanized areas
or farm fields.
Nutrients – nitrogen or phosphorus-containing water
pollutants that can cause water quality problems. See
eutrophication.
Paper water – the legal right to use a given volume
of water, contrasted with “wet” or “real” water. In many
basins, more paper water exists than wet water.
Glossary
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT74
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 75
Bennett, G.  N. Carroll. 2014. “Gaining Depth: State of Wa-
tershed Investment 2014.” Forest Trends, Ecosystem
Marketplace. Available at forest-trends.org/documents/
files/SOWI2014.pdf.
Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER). 2015.
“Performance in Watershed Context Concept Paper.” Bev-
erage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER). http://
www.bieroundtable.com/#!/c16n5.
Bjornlund, H.  J. McKay. 2002. “Aspects of Water Markets
for Developing Countries: Experiences from Australia,
Chile, and the US.” Environment and Development Eco-
nomics 7 (04). doi:10.1017/S1355770X02000463.
Bond, I., and J. Mayers. 2010. “Fair Deals for Watershed Ser-
vices: Lessons from a Multi-Country Action-Learning
Project.” No. 13. Natural Resources Issues. London, UK:
International Institute for Environment and Development.
Available at pubs.iied.org/pdfs/13535IIED.pdf.
Brewer, J., R. Glennon, A. Ker  G.D. Libecap. 2007. “Water
Markets in the West: Prices, Trading, and Contractual
Forms.” National Bureau of Economic Research.
Brooks, D.B. 2006. “An Operational Definition of Water De-
mand Management.” Intenational Journal of Water Re-
sources Development 22 (4): 521–28.
Brouwer, R., A. Tesfaye  P. Pauw. 2011. “Meta-Analysis of
Institutional-Economic Factors Explaining the Environ-
mental Performance of Payments for Watershed Ser-
vices.” Environmental Conservation 38 (04): 380–92.
doi:10.1017/S0376892911000543.
Brown, C., U. Lall  F.A. Souza Filho. 2015. “Allocating Water
in a Changing World: Incentive-Based Mechanisms for
Climate Adaptation.”
Calvache, A., S. Benitez  A. Ramos. 2012. “Fondo de Agua:
Conservando La Infraestructura Verde. Guia de Diseno,
Creacio, Y Operacion.” Bogota, Columbia: The Nature
Conservancy, Fundacion FEMSA, y Banco Interamericano
de Desarrollo. Available at conservationgateway.org/
Documents/LAWFP-ENG-low-050312_0.pdf.
Carpenter, S.R., E.H. Stanley  M. J. Vander Zanden. 2011.
“State of the World’s Freshwater Ecosystems: Physical,
Chemical, and Biological Changes.” Annual Review of
Environment and Resources 36 (1): 75–99. doi:10.1146/
annurev-environ-021810-094524.
CDP. 2014. “From Water Risk to Value Creation, CDP Global
Water Report 2014.” CDP. Available at cdp.net/CDPRe-
sults/CDP-Global-Water-Report-2014.pdf.
Albiac, J., M. Hanemann, J. Calatrava, J. Uche  J. Tapia.
2006. “The Rise and Fall of the Ebro Water Transfer.”
Natural Resources Journal 46: 729–57.
Alix-Garcia, J., A. de Janvry, E. Sadoulet  J. Manuel. 2009.
“Lessons Learned from Mexico’s Payment for Environ-
mental Services Program.” In Payment for Environmental
Services in Agricultural Landscapes, edited by Leslie Lip-
per, Takumi Sakuyama, Randy Stringer, and David Zilber-
man, 163–88. Natural Resource Management and Policy
31. Springer New York. Available at link.springer.com/
chapter/10.1007/978-0-387-72971-8_8.
Al-Marshudi, A.S. 2007. “The Falaj Irrigation System and
Water Allocation Markets in Northern Oman.” Agricul-
tural Water Management 91 (1–3): 71–77. doi:10.1016/j.
agwat.2007.04.008.
Ambec, S., A. Dinar  D. McKinney. 2013. “Water Sharing
Agreements Sustainable to Reduced Flows.” Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management 66 (3):
639–55. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2013.06.003.
Anderson, R.C. 2004. “International Experiences with
Economic Incentives for Protecting the Environment.”
EPA-236-R-04-001. Washington, DC: US Environmental
Protection Agency, National Center for Environmental
Economics. Available at yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/eerm.
nsf/vwAN/EE-0487-01.pdf/$file/EE-0487-01.pdf.
Appleton, A.F. 2010. “How New York City Used an Ecosystem
Services Strategy Carried out through an Urban-Rural
Partnership to Preserve the Pristine Quality of Its Drink-
ing Water and Save Billions of Dollars.” New York, NY: A
Paper for Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarket-
place.com/documents/cms_documents/NYC_H2O_Eco-
system_Services.pdf.
Backeberg, G. 2015. “Water Markets in South Africa,” July 24.
Barrett, K. 2015. “A Different Kind of Sale: April Auction Of-
fers Stewardship Credits to Meet Sustainability Goals.”
Ecosystem Marketplace. February 12. Available at eco-
systemmarketplace.com/pages/dynamic/article.page.
php?page_id=10792section=news_articleseod=1.
Bauer, C.J. 1997. “Bringing Water Markets down to Earth: The
Political Economy of Water Rights in Chile, 1976–1995.”
World Development 25 (5): 639–56.
Bennett, G., N. Carroll  K. Hamilton. (2012) Charting New
Waters: State of Watershed Payments 2012. Washington,
DC: Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.
com/reports/sowp2012.
References
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT76
at ohchr.org/english/bodies/hrcouncil/docs/18session/A-
HRC-18-33-Add4_en.pdf.
Dellapenna, J. 2000. “The Importance of Getting Names
Right: The Myth of Markets for Water.” William  Mary
Environmental Law and Policy Review 25 (2): 317.
Department of Environmental Affairs. 2015. “Social Develop-
ment | Department of Environmental Affairs.” Accessed
September 10. Available at environment.gov.za/proj-
ectsprogrammes/wfw/socialdevelopment.
Dillaha, T., P. Ferraro, M. Huang, D. Southgate, S. Upadhyaya
 S. Wunder. 2007. “Payment for Watershed Services
Regional Syntheses.” USAID. Available at sanrem.cals.
vt.edu/1010/Dillaha2007_PWS_regional_syntheses.pdf.
Dinar, A., M.W. Rosegrant  R. Meinzen-Dick. 1997. “Wa-
ter Allocation Mechanisms: Principles and Examples.”
Policy Research Working Paper Series 1779. The World
Bank. Available at econpapers.repec.org/paper/wbkw-
brwps/1779.htm.
Dinar, A.  R.M. Saleth. 2005. “Can Water Institutions Be
Cured? A Water Institutions Health Index.” Water Supply
5: 17–40.
Dodds, W.K., W.W. Bouska, J.L. Eitzmann, T.J. Pilger, K.L. Pitts,
A.J. Riley, J.T. Schloesser  D.J. Thornbrugh. 2008. “Eu-
trophication of US Freshwaters: Analysis of Potential Eco-
nomic Damages.” Environmental Science  Technology
43 (1): 12–19.
Duhon, M., J. Young  S. Kerr. 2011. “Nitrogen Trading in Lake
Taupo: An Analysis and Evaluation of an Innovative Water
Management Strategy.” In New Zealand Agricultural and
Resource Economics Society 2011 Conference. Nelson,
New Zealand. Available at ageconsearch.umn.edu/bit-
stream/115353/2/Duhon%20Paper.pdf.
Easter, K.W., M.W. Rosegrant  A. Dinar. 1999. “Formal and
Informal Markets for Water: Institutions, Performance, and
Constraints.” The World Bank Research Observer 14 (1):
99–116.
Ecosystem Marketplace. 2013. “Innovative Markets and
Market Like Instruments for Ecosystem Services.” Forest
Trends. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.com/docu-
ments/acrobat/the_matrix.pdf.
———. 2015. “This Week In Water: The Art Of The Nutrient
Credit Sale.” Watershed Connect. February 27. Available
at watershedconnect.com/news/this_week_in_water_the_
art_of_the_nutrient_credit_sale_.
Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI). 2010. “Program on
Technology Innovation: Ohio River Water Quality Trading
Pilot Program: Business Case for Power Company Partici-
pation.” Available at epri.com/abstracts/Pages/ProductA-
bstract.aspx?ProductId=000000000001018861.
Clifford, P. 2012. “Water Banking in Washington State: 2012
Report to the Legislature.” Report to Legislature 12-11-
055. Washington State Department of Ecology. https://
fortress.wa.gov/ecy/publications/SummaryPages/1211055.
html.
Cohen, M.J., J. Christian-Smith  J. Berggren. 2013. “Water
to Supply the Land: Irrigated Agriculture in the Colorado
River Basin.” Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/
publication/water-to-supply-the-land-irrigated-agricul-
ture-in-the-colorado-river-basin/.
Cohen, M.J. 2014. “Hazard’s Toll: The Costs of Inaction at the
Salton Sea.” Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/pub-
lication/hazards-toll/.
Cohen, M.J.  K.H. Hyun. 2006. “Hazard: The Future of the
Salton Sea With No Restoration Plan.” Oakland, Calif.: Pa-
cific Institute. http://pacinst.org/publication/restoration-
project-critical-to-salton-seas-future/.
Colby, B.G., M.A. McGinnis  K.A. Rait. 1991. “Mitigating Envi-
ronmental Externalities through Voluntary and Involun-
tary Water Reallocation: Nevada’s Truckee-Carson River
Basin.” Natural Resources Journal 31: 757.
Coleman, A. 2008. “Farmers to Sue DWAF for Water Rights
Transfers.” Farmer’s Weekly, September 12.
Conagua. 2012. “Water Banks in Mexico.” National Water
Commission. Available at conagua.gob.mx/bancos-
delagua/.
Connor, J.D.  D. Kaczan. 2013. “Principles for Economically
Efficient and Environmentally Sustainable Water Mar-
kets: The Australian Experience.” In Drought in Arid and
Semi-Arid Regions, edited by Kurt Schwabe, Jose Albiac,
Jeffery D. Connor, Rashid M. Hassan, and Liliana Meza
González, 357–74. Springer Netherlands. Available at
dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-6636-5_20.
Cosgrove, W.S.  F.R. Rijsberman. 2000. “World Water Vision:
Making Water Everybody’s Business.” World Water Coun-
cil. Available at worldwatercouncil.org/index.php?id=961.
Culp, P., R. Glennon  G. Libecap. 2014. “Shopping for Wa-
ter: How the Market Can Mitigate Water Shortages in
the American West.” 2014-05. Discussion Paper. The
Brookings Institute. Available at hamiltonproject.org/
files/downloads_and_links/market_mitigate_water_short-
age_in_west_paper_glennon_final.pdf.
Colorado Water Trust (CWT). 2015. Colorado Water Trust Big
Beaver Creek Reservoir / Big Beaver Creek  White River.
Available at coloradowatertrust.org/our-work/projects/
lake-avery-big-beaver-creek-white-river/#sthash.I3vg-
PjZL.dpuf.
de Albuquerque, C. 2011. “Special Rapporteur on the Human
Right to Safe Drinking Water and Sanitation, Mission to
the United States of America.” United Nations. Available
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 77
Victorian Murray Valley / Frontier Economics. PANDORA
Electronic Collection. Canberra, A.C.T: National Water Com-
mission. Available at nla.gov.au/nla.arc-79821.
Garrido, A.  M.R. Llamas. 2009. “Water Management in
Spain: An Example of Changing Paradigms.” Policy and
Strategic Behaviour in Water Resource Management 125.
Gassert, F., M. Landis, P. Reig, M. Luck  T. Shiao. 2013. “Aq-
ueduct Metadata Document, Aqueduct Global Maps 2.0.”
World Resources Institute (WRI). Available at wri.org/sites/
default/files/pdf/aqueduct_metadata_global.pdf.
Genevieve B., N. Carroll, M. Bennett, A. Leonardi  K. Moull.
2014. “Gaining Depth: State of Watershed Investment
2014.” Washington, D.C: Forest Trends. Available at.forest-
trends.org/documents/files/SOWI2014.pdf.
George, A., A. Pierret, A. Boonsaner, V. Christian  O. Planchon.
2009. “Potential and Limitations of Payments for Environ-
mental Services (PES) as a Means to Manage Watershed
Services in Mainland Southeast Asia.” International Jour-
nal of the Commons 3 (1): 16–40.
Getches, D.H. 1985. “Competing Demands for the Colorado
River.” University of Colorado Law Review 56: 413.
Gleick, P.H. 2002. “Water Management: Soft Water Paths.”
Nature 418: 373.
———. 2003. “Global Freshwater Resources: Soft-Path Solu-
tions for the 21st Century.” Science 302 (5650): 1524–28.
Gleick, P.H., D. Haasz, C. Henges-Jeck, V. Srinivasan, G. Wolff,
K. Kao Cushing  A. Mann. 2003. “Waste Not, Want Not:
The Potential for Urban Water Conservation in California.”
Oakland CA: Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/wp-
content/uploads/sites/21/2013/02/waste_not_want_not_
full_report3.pdf.
Glennon, R. 2005. “Water Scarcity, Marketing, and Privatiza-
tion.” Texas Law Review 83 (7): 1873–1902.
Gómez-Baggethun, E., R. de Groot, P.L. Lomas  C. Montes.
2010. “The History of Ecosystem Services in Economic
Theory and Practice: From Early Notions to Markets and
Payment Schemes.” Ecological Economics, Special Sec-
tion - Payments for Environmental Services: Reconciling
Theory and Practice, 69 (6): 1209–18. doi:10.1016/j.ecole-
con.2009.11.007.
Grafton, R.Q.  J. Horne. 2014. “Water Markets in the Murray-
Darling Basin.” Agricultural Water Management 145 (No-
vember): 61–71. doi:10.1016/j.agwat.2013.12.001.
Grafton, R.Q., C. Landry, G.D. Libecap, S. McGlennon  R.
O’Brien. 2010. “An Integrated Assessment of Water Mar-
kets: Australia, Chile, China, South Africa and the USA.”
ICER Working Paper 32-2010. ICER - International Centre
for Economic Research. Available at ideas.repec.org/p/icr/
wpicer/32-2010.html.
Faeth, P. 2000. Fertile Ground: Nutrient Trading’s Potential
to Cost-Effectively Improve Water Quality. Washington,
D.C.: World Resources Institute. Available at wri.org/sites/
default/files/pdf/fertile_ground.pdf.
Famiglietti, J.S. 2014. “The Global Groundwater Crisis.” Na-
ture Climate Change 4: 945–48.
Farolfi, St.  S. Perret. 2002. “Inter-Sectoral Competition for
Water Allocation in Rural South Africa : Analysing a Case
Study through a Standard Environmental Economics
Approach.” Paper without proceedings Working paper:
2002-23. Department of Agricultural Economics, Exten-
sion and Rural Development: University of Pretoria. http://
agritrop.cirad.fr/511263/.
Feinglas, S., C. Gray  P. Mayer. 2013. “Conservation Helps
Limit Rate Increases for a Colorado Utility.” Alliance for
Water Efficiency. Available at financingsustainablewater.
org/resource-search/conservation-helps-limit-rate-
increases-colorado-utility.
Ferraro, P.J. 2008. “Asymmetric Information and Contract
Design for Payments for Environmental Services.” Eco-
logical Economics, Payments for Environmental Services
in Developing and Developed Countries, 65 (4): 810–21.
doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.029.
———. 2009. “Regional Review of Payments for Wa-
tershed Services: Sub-Saharan Africa.” Jour-
nal of Sustainable Forestry 28 (3-5): 525–50.
doi:10.1080/10549810802701234.
Fischel, W.A. 1995. Regulatory Takings: Law, Economics, and
Politics. Harvard University Press.
Fisher-Vanden, K.  S. Olmstead. 2013. “Moving Pollution
Trading from Air to Water: Potential, Problems, and Prog-
nosis.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 147–71.
Forest Trends. 2015a. Watershed Connect. Available at wa-
tershedconnect.com/
Forest Trends. 2015b. “Paw Paw River Watershed.” Program
Inventory. Paw Paw River Watershed. Available at water-
shedconnect.com/programs/Paw-Paw-River-Watershed.
Fox, J. 2014. “The Role of Trading in Achieving Water Qual-
ity Objectives.” presented at the United States House
of Representatives, Committee on Transportation and
Infrastructure, Subcommittee on Water Resources and
Environment, Washington, DC, April 17. Available at wqt.
epri.com/pdf/EPRI%20Testimony%20WQT%20Final%20
4-17-14.pdf.
Freyfogle, E.T. 1996. “Water Rights and the Commonwealth.”
Environmental Law 26: 27.
Frontier Economics, and Australia National Water Commis-
sion. 2007. The Economic and Social Impacts of Water
Trading [electronic Resource] : Case Studies in the
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT78
rent Initiatives.” Journal of Sustainable Forestry 28 (3-5):
551–75. doi:10.1080/10549810902794287.
Huber, R.M., J. Ruitenbeek  R.S. da Motta. 1998. “Market-
Based Instruments for Environmental Policymaking in
Latin America and the Caribbean - Lessons from Eleven
Countries.” WDP381. The World Bank. Available at docu-
ments.worldbank.org/curated/en/1998/11/438776/market-
based-instruments-environmental-policymaking-latin-
america-caribbean-lessons-eleven-countries.
Hundley, N., Jr. 2001. The Great Thirst: Californians and
Water—A History, Revised Edition. 2001 (revised). Un-
versity of California Press. Available at ucpress.edu/book.
php?isbn=9780520224568.
International Institute for Environment and Development
(IIED). 2015. Watershed Markets. Available at watershed-
markets.org/
Jenkins, M.W., J.R. Lund, R.E. Howitt, A.J. Draper, S.M. Msangi,
S.K. Tanaka, R.S. Ritzema  G.F. Marques. 2004. “Optimi-
zation of California’s Water Supply System: Results and
Insights.” Journal of Water Resources Planning and
Management 130 (4): 271–80. doi:10.1061/(ASCE)0733-
9496(2004)130:4(271).
Jones, C., E. Branosky, M. Selman  M. Perez. 2010. “How Nu-
trient Trading Could Help Restore the Chesapeake Bay.”
Washington, DC: World Resources Institute. Available
at wri.org/working_papers/how_nutrient_trading_could_
help_restore_the_chesapeake_bay.pdf.
Karousakis, K.  Q. Brooke. 2010. Paying for Biodiversity:
Enhancing the Cost-Effectiveness of Payments for Eco-
system Services. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-
operation and Development. Available at oecd-ilibrary.
org/content/book/9789264090279-en.
Kenny, A. 2006. “Ecosystem Marketplace - Ecosystem Ser-
vices in the New York City Watershed.” Ecosystem Mar-
ketplace. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.com/pages/
dynamic/article.page.php?page_id=4130section=home.
Koplow, D. 2004. The Use of Economic Instruments in Envi-
ronmental Policy: Opportunties and Challenges. United
Nations Environment Programme. Available at unep.ch/
etb/publication/EconInst/econInstruOppChnaFin.pdf.
Kosoy, N., M. Martinez-Tuna, R. Muradian  J. Martinez-Alier.
2007. “Payments for Environmental Services in Water-
sheds: Insights from a Comparative Study of Three Cases
in Central America.” Ecological Economics 61 (2–3):
446–55. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.03.016.
Los Angeles Department of Water and Power (LA DWP).
2013. “Owens Lake Master Project.” Los Angeles, CA:
Los Angeles Department of Water and Power. Available
at ladwp.com/ladwp/faces/ladwp/aboutus/a-water/a-w-
losangelesaqueduct/a-w-laa-owenslake.
Grafton, R.Q., G. Libecap, E. Edwards, R O’Brien  C. Landry.
2012. “Comparative Assessment of Water Markets: In-
sights from the Murray-Darling Basin of Australia and the
Western USA.” Water Policy 14: 175–93.
Greiber, T., ed. 2009. Payments for Ecosystem Services: Le-
gal and Institutional Frameworks. IUCN Environmental
Policy and Law Paper, No. 78. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN, in
collaboration with the IUCN Environmental Law Centre,
Bonn, Germany. Available at cmsdata.iucn.org/downloads/
eplp_78_1.pdf.
Hanak, E.  E. Stryjewski. 2012. “California’s Water Market,
By the Numbers: Update 2012.” Public Policy Institute
of California. Available at wee.ppic.org/content/pubs/
report/R_1112EHR.pdf.
Harrington, W.  R.D. Morgenstern. 2004. “Economic Incen-
tives Versus Command and Control: What’s the Best Ap-
proach for Solving Environmental Problems?” Resources
for the Future. Available at rff.org/Publications/Resources/
Documents/152/RFF_Resources_152_ecoincentives.pdf.
Hauter, W. 2013. “D.C. District Court Fails on Pollution Trad-
ing: Clean Water Act Trading Lawsuit Dismissed Due to
Burden of Proof.” Food and Water Watch. December 16.
Available at foodandwaterwatch.org/pressreleases/d-c-
district-court-fails-on-pollution-trading-clean-water-act-
trading-lawsuit-dismissed-due-to-burden-of-proof/.
Hawkins, S. 2011. “Laying the Foundation: An Analytical Tool
for Assessing Legal and Institutional Readiness for PES.”
Forest Trends. Available at forest-trends.org/documents/
files/doc_3014.pdf.
Heberger, M., H. Cooley  P.H. Gleick. 2014. “Urban Water
Conservation and Efficiency Potential in California.” Oak-
land, CA: Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/wp-
content/uploads/sites/21/2014/06/ca-water-urban.pdf.
Howe, C.W. 2011. “The Efficient Water Market of the Northern
Colorado Water Conservancy. District: Colorado, USA.”
IBE Review reports CS22. WP6 IBE EX-POST Case Stud-
ies. EPI Water. Available at feem-project.net/epiwater/
docs/d32-d6-1/CS22_Colorado.pdf.
Howe, C.W.  C. Goemans. 2003. “Water Transfers and Their
Impacts: Lessons from Three Colorado Water Markets.”
JAWRA Journal of the American Water Resources
Association 39 (5): 1055–65. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2003.
tb03692.x.
Howitt, R.E. 1998. “Spot Prices, Option Prices, and Water
Markets: An Analysis of Emerging Markets in California.”
In Markets for Water, edited by K. William Easter, Mark
W. Rosegrant, and Ariel Dinar, 119–40. Natural Resource
Management and Policy 15. Springer US.
Huang, M., S.K. Upadhyaya, R. Jindal  J. Kerr. 2009. “Pay-
ments for Watershed Services in Asia: A Review of Cur-
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 79
Moench, M., A. Dixit, S. Janakarajan, M.S. Rathore  S. Mudra-
kartha. 2003. The Fluid Mosaic: Water Governance in
the Context of Variability, Uncertainty and Change: A
Synthesis Paper. Nepal Water Conservation Foundation,
Kathmandu, and the Institute for Social and Environmen-
tal Transition, Boulder, Colorado, US.
Moore, R.H. 2012. “Reaching the Potential of Water-Quality
Trading.” In Water Sustainability in Agriculture, 73–81.
Ithaca, New York: National Agriculutural Biotechnology
Council. Available at nabc.cals.cornell.edu/Publications/
Reports/nabc_24/24_2_1_Moore.pdf.
Morgan, C.  A. Wolverton. 2005. “Water Quality Trading in
the United States.” 05-07. Working Paper. National Cen-
ter for Environmental Economics. Available at yosemite.
epa.gov/ee/epa/eed.nsf/be6bc67216ab9f5d85256e460
07b104d/3e026cbb6a9956918525702f005e383c/$FI
LE/2005-07.pdf.
MOTU. 2009. “Lake Rotorua Short Films.” Motu Economic
and Public Policy Research. Available at motu.org.nz/
research/detail/rotorua_films.
Muñoz-Piña, C., A. Guevara, J.M. Torres  J. Braña. 2008.
“Paying for the Hydrological Services of Mexico’s Forests:
Analysis, Negotiations and Results.” Ecological Econom-
ics, Payments for Environmental Services in Developing
and Developed Countries, 65 (4): 725–36. doi:10.1016/j.
ecolecon.2007.07.031.
Naeem, S., J. C. Ingram, A. Varga, T. Agardy, P. Barten, G. Ben-
nett, E. Bloomgarden, et al., 2015. “Get the Science Right
When Paying for Nature’s Services.” Science 347 (6227):
1206–7. doi:10.1126/science.aaa1403.
National Fish and Wildlife Foundation. 2014. “FY 2013 Annual
Report: Columbia Basin Water Transactions Program.”
Portland, Oregon: National Fish and Wildlife Foundation.
Available at cbwtp.org/jsp/cbwtp/library/documents/
NLB_CBWTP_Annual13_R8.pdf.
National Research Council. 1968. Water and Choice in the
Colorado Basin: An Example of Alternatives in Water
Management: A Report. National Academies.
———. 1992. Water Transfers in the West:: Efficiency, Eq-
uity, and the Environment. National Academies Press.
Neef, A.  D. Thomas. 2009. “Rewarding the Upland Poor for
Saving the Commons? Evidence from Southeast Asia.”
International Journal of the Commons 3 (1): 1–15.
Newburn, D.A.  R.T. Woodward. 2012. “An Ex Post Evalu-
ation of Ohio’s Great Miami Water Quality Trading
Program1.” JAWRA Journal of the American Water
Resources Association 48 (1): 156–69. doi:10.1111/j.1752-
1688.2011.00601.x.
Raes, L.  P. Mohebalian. 2013. “The Socio Bosque Pro-
gram for Rainforest and Paramo Conservation, Ecuado.”
Geneva Switzerland: The Economics of Ecosystems
and Biodiversity. Available at teebweb.org/wp-content/
uploads/2014/07/The-Socio-Bosque-Programme-for-
rainforest-and-Paramo-Conservation-Ecuador-.pdf.
Leflaive, X., M. Witmer, R. Martin-Hurtado, M. Bakker, T. Kram,
L. Bouwman, H. Visser, A. Bouwman, H. Hilderink  K.
Kim. 2012. “Water.” In OECD Environmental Outlook,
275–332. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development. Available at oecd-ilibrary.org/content/
chapter/env_outlook-2012-8-en.
Levine, G., R. Barker  C.C. Huang. 2007. “Water Transfer
from Agriculture to Urban Uses: Lessons Learned, with
Policy Considerations.” Paddy and Water Environment 5
(4): 213–22. doi:10.1007/s10333-007-0092-8.
LimnoTech  The Nature Conservancy. 2013. “Quantifying
Replenish Benefits in Community Water Partnership
Projects, Final Report for 2012.” The Coca-Cola Com-
pany. Available at assets.coca-colacompany.com/2f/cb/
e5d2ca1e4c58a38adbe8586d06db/final-quanitification-
report-water-pdf.pdf.
Livingston, M.L. 1998. “Institutional Requisites for Efficient
Water Markets.” In Markets for Water: Potential and Per-
formance, 19–33. Springer. Available at link.springer.com/
chapter/10.1007/978-0-585-32088-5_2.
Lovins, A. 1977. Soft energy paths: Toward a durable peace.
Ballinger Publishing Co., Cambridge, Massachusetts, US.
Marida, P. 2010. “Ohio’s Water Quality Trading Programs - To
Be Taken Over by Coal?” The Ohio Sierran, A Publica-
tion of the Ohio Chapter of the Sierra Club.
Mariola, M.J. 2009. “Are Markets the Solution to Water Pollu-
tion? A Sociological Investigation of Water Quality Trad-
ing.” Ph.D. Dissertation, Columbus, Ohio: The Ohio State
University. Available at rave.ohiolink.edu/etdc/view?acc_
num=osu1250015222.
Medellín-Azuara, J., J.J. Harou, M.A. Olivares, K. Madani,
J.R. Lund, R.E. Howitt, S.K. Tanaka, M.W. Jenkins  T.
Zhu. 2008. “Adaptability and Adaptations of California’s
Water Supply System to Dry Climate Warming.” Climatic
Change 87 (1): 75–90.
Meinzen-Dick, R.  R. Pradhan. 2005. “Recognizing Multiple
Water Uses in Intersectoral Water Transfers.” In Asian
Irrigation in Transition: Responding to Challenges, 178–
205. Asian Institute of Technology, Bangkok, Thailand.
Richards, M. 2013. “What Do We Know about Gender and
Other Social Impacts of IWS Projects?: A Literature Re-
view.” Forest Trends. Available at forest-trends.org/docu-
ments/files/doc_4089.pdf.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT80
Porras, I., B. Aylward  J. Dengel. 2013. “Monitoring Pay-
ments for Watershed Services Schemes in Developing
Countries.” London, UK: International Institute for Envi-
ronment and Development. Available at pubs.iied.org/
pdfs/16525IIED.pdf.
Porras, I., D.N. Barton, A. Chacon-Cascante  M. Miranda.
2013. “Learning from 20 Years of Payments for Ecosys-
tem Services in Costa Rica.” London, UK: International
Institute for Environment and Development. Available at
pubs.iied.org/pdfs/16514IIED.pdf.
Porras, I.  N. Neves. 2006a. “China - Sloping Lands Con-
version Programme.” Markets for Watershed Services
- Country Profile. International Institute for Environment
and Development. Available at watershedmarkets.org/
documents/China_SLCP_eng.pdf.
———. 2006b. “Mexico - National PSAH Programme.” Mar-
ket for Watershed Services - Country Profile. International
Institute for Environment and Development. Available
at watershedmarkets.org/documents/Mexico_National_
PSAH_eng.pdf.
Porras, I.T., M. Grieg-Gran  N. Neves. 2008. All That Glit-
ters: A Review of Payments for Watershed Services in
Developing Countries. IIED. Available at pubs.iied.org/
pdfs/13542IIED.pdf.
Postel, S.L., G.C. Daily  P.R. Ehrlich. 1996. “Appropriation of
Renewable Fresh Water.” Science 271 (5250): 785–88.
Queensland Water Commission. 2010. “South East
Queensland Water Strategy 2010.” 29229. Queensland
Water Commission. Available at qwc.qld.gov.au.
Ravnborg, H.M., M.G. Damsgaard  K. Raben. 2007. “Pay-
ments for Ecosystem Services - Issues and Pro-Poor
Opportunities for Development Assistance.” Copenhagen,
Denmark: Danish Institute for International Studies.
Reimers, F. 2013. “Shifting Ground.” Nature Conservancy,
June.
Rockefeller Foundation. 2013. Key Factors Supporting Small-
Scale Coastal Fisheries Management.
Romano, D.  M. Leporati. 2002. “The Distributive Impact
of the Water Market in Chile: A Case Study in Limari
Province, 1981- 1997.” Quarterly Journal of International
Agriculture 41 (1): 41–58.
Rozza, J.P., B.D. Richter, W.M. Larson, T. Redder, K. Vigerstol 
P. Bowen P. 2013. “Corporate Water Stewardship: Achiev-
ing a Sustainable Balance.” Journal of Management and
Sustainability 3 (4). Available at dx.doi.org/10.5539/jms.
v3n4p41.
Newlin, B.D., M.W. Jenkins, J.R. Lund  R.E. Howitt. 2002.
“Southern California Water Markets: Potential and Limita-
tions.” Journal of Water Resources Planning and Man-
agement 128 (1): 21–32.
NSWDEC. 2003. Hunter River Salinity Trading Scheme:
Working Together to Protect River Quality and Sustain
Economic Development. Sydney, Australia: Department
of Environment and Conservation, New South Wales.
Available at epa.nsw.gov.au/resources/licensing/hrsts/
hrsts.pdf.
NWC. 2013. Australian National Water Commission Markets
Report 2012-2013. Canberra. Available at nwc.gov.au/pub-
lications/topic/water-industry/australian-water-markets-
report-2012-13.
O’Donnell, M.  B. Colby. 2010. “Water Banks: A Tool for En-
hancing Water Supply Reliability.” Guidebook. University
of Arizona. Available at ag.arizona.edu/arec/pubs/faculty-
pubs/ewsr-Banks-final-5-12-10.pdf.
O’Grady, D. 2011. “Sociopolitical Conditions for Success-
ful Water Quality Trading in the South Nation River
Watershed, Ontario, Canada1.” JAWRA Journal of the
American Water Resources Association 47 (1): 39–51.
doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2010.00511.x.
Olszowa, D.M., J.P. Heath  P.A. Tennant. 1998. “Evalua-
tion of Nutrient Loads and Sources in the Ohio River
Basin.” In . Ohio River Valley Water Sanitation Com-
mission (ORSANCO). http://acwi.gov/monitoring/
conference/98proceedings/Papers/54-OLSZ.html.
Pagiola, S. 2008. “Payments for Environmental Services in
Costa Rica.” Ecological Economics, Payments for Envi-
ronmental Services in Developing and Developed Coun-
tries, 65 (4): 712–24. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.033.
Pagiola, S., A. Arcenas  G. Platais. 2005. “Can Payments for
Environmental Services Help Reduce Poverty? An Explo-
ration of the Issues and the Evidence to Date from Latin
America.” World Development, Institutional arrange-
ments for rural poverty reduction and resource conserva-
tion, 33 (2): 237–53. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.011.
Pant, D., M. Bhattarai  G. Basnet. 2008. “Implications Of Bulk
Water Transfer On Local Water Management Institutions:
A Case Study of the Melamchi Water Supply Project in
Nepal.” Working Paper 78. Consultative Group on Interna-
tional Agricultural Research (CGIAR). Available at indiae-
nvironmentportal.org.in/files/capriwp78.pdf.
Perrot-Maitre, D. 2006. “The Vittel Payments for Ecosystem
Services: A ‘Perfect’ PES Case?” London, UK: International
Institute for Environment and Development. Available
at katoombagroup.org/~katoomba/documents/tools/
TheVittelpaymentsforecosystemservices.pdf.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 81
Thobani, M. 1997. “Formal Water Markets: Why, When, and
How to Introduce Tradable Water Rights.” World Bank
Research Observer 12 (2): 161–79.
TWSST, 2014. Transforming water scarcity through trading,
2012–2015, Final report.
United Nations. 2009. “World Water Development Report 3:
Water in a Changing World.” Available at webworld.unes-
co.org/water/wwap/wwdr/wwdr3/tableofcontents.shtml.
———. 2012. “World Water Development Report 4:
Managing Water under Uncertainty and Risk.” Paris,
France: United Nations. http://unesdoc.unesco.org/
images/0021/002156/215644e.pdf.
UNEP. 2009. “Training Resource Manual: The Use of Eco-
nomic Instruments for Environmental and Natural Re-
source Management.” Available at unep.ch/etb/publica-
tions/EI%20manual%202009/Training%20Resource%20
Manual.pdf.
UNEP. 2004. “The Use of Economic Instruments in Environ-
mental Policy: Opportunities and Challenges.” Available
at unep.ch/etb/publication/EconInst/econInstruOppCh-
naFin.pdf.
US Bureau of Reclamation. 2015. “Moving Forward, Phase 1
Report.” Bureau of Reclamation, US Department of the In-
terior. Available at usbr.gov/lc/region/programs/crbstudy/
MovingForward/Phase1Report.html.
US Census Bureau. 2012. “The Statistical Abstract of the
United States, Table 435: State and Local Governments-
-Summary of Finances.” Washington, DC. Available at
census.gov/compendia/statab/2012/tables/12s0435.pdf.
US EPA. 2001. “The United States Experiences with Eco-
nomic Incentives for Protecting the Environment.” EPA-
240-R-01-001. Available at yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/
eerm.nsf/vwAN/EE-0216B-13.pdf/$file/EE-0216B-13.pdf.
US EPA. 2003. “Final Water Quality Trading Policy.” January
13. http://water.epa.gov/type/watersheds/trading/finalpo-
licy2003.cfm.
———. 2009. “Steam Electric Power Generation Point
Source Category: Final Detailed Study Report.” United
States Environmental Protection Agency. Available at
water.epa.gov/scitech/wastetech/guide/steam-electric/
upload/Steam-Electric_Detailed-Study-Report_2009.pdf.
———. 2010. “How Water Quality (Nutrient) Trading Enables
Alpine Cheese Company to Improve Water Quality and
Increase Economic Development in the Region.” US.
Available at water.epa.gov/type/watersheds/named/ms-
basin/oh_03.cfm.
Ruppert, T.K. 2004. “Water Quality Trading and Agricultural
Nonpoint Source Pollution: An Analysis of the Effective-
ness and Fairness of EPA’s Policy on Water Quality Trad-
ing.” Villanova Environmental Law Journal 15: 1.
Salzman, J. 2006. “Thirst: A Short History of Drinking Water.”
Yale Journal of Law and the Humanities 17 (3). Avail-
able at lsr.nellco.org/duke_fs/31.
Schmalensee, R  R.N. Stavins. 2013. “The SO2 Allowance
Trading System: The Ironic History of a Grand Policy
Experiment.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 27 (1):
103–22. doi:10.1257/jep.27.1.103.
Sharma, S.K.  K. Vairavamoorthy. 2009. “Urban Water De-
mand Management: Prospects and Challenges for the
Developing Countries.” Water and Environment Journal
23 (3): 210–18. doi:10.1111/j.1747-6593.2008.00134.x.
Shortle, J.S.  R.D. Horan. 2005. “Water Quality Trading.”
Penn State Environmental Law Review 14: 231.
———. 2008. “The Economics of Water Quality Trading.”
International Review of Environmental and Resource
Economics 2 (2): 101–33.
Smith, S., P. Rowcroft, M. Everard, L. Couldrick, M. Reed, H.
Rogers, T. Quick, C. Eves  C. White. 2013. “Payments
for Ecosystem Services: A Best Practice Guide.” Defra,
London: Department for Environment, Food, and Rural
Affairs. Available at gov.uk/government/uploads/system/
uploads/attachment_data/file/200920/pb13932-pes-
bestpractice-20130522.pdf.
Stacey, P.E., T. Haze  I. Raffa. 2012. “Meeting the Nitrogen
Wasteload Allocation in Connecticut: Connecticut’s Nitro-
gen Credit Exchange After 10 Years of Operation as the
Nation’s Most Significant Water Quality Trading Program.”
presented at the 36th annual Meeting of the New Eng-
land Association of Environmental Biologists, Falmouth,
Massachusetts, March 22. Available at epa.gov/region1/
neaeb2012/pdfs/0930_BR2_PaulStacey.pdf.
Stanton, T., M. Echavarria, K. Hamilton  C. Ott. 2010. “State
of Watershed Payments: An Emerging Marketplace.”
Ecosystem Marketplace. Available at watershedconnect.
com/documents/files/state_of_watershed_payments_an_
emerging_marketplace.pdf.
Stavins, R.N. 2001. “Experience with Market-Based Environ-
mental Policy Instruments.” Resources for the Future.
Available at rff.org/documents/rff-dp-01-58.pdf.
Tarlock, A.D. 2014. “Mexico and the United States Assume a
Legal Duty to Provide Colorado River Delta Restoration
Flows: An Important International Environmental and
Water Law Precedent.” Review of European, Compara-
tive  International Environmental Law 23 (1): 76–87.
doi:10.1111/reel.12066.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT82
Worster, D. 1985. Rivers of Empire: Water, Aridity, and the
Growth of the American West. Oxford University Press.
Wunder, S. 2005. “Payments for Environmental Services:
Some Nuts and Bolts.” CIFOR Occasional Paper No. 42.
Jakarta, Indonesia: Center for Internatioanl Forestry Re-
search. Available at theredddesk.org/sites/default/files/
resources/pdf/2012/payment-ecosystem-services-02.pdf.
———. 2008. “Payments for Environmental Services and
the Poor: Concepts and Preliminary Evidence.” Environ-
ment and Development Economics 13 (03): 279–97.
doi:10.1017/S1355770X08004282.
Young, M.D. 2010. “Environmental Effectiveness and Eco-
nomic Efficiency of Water Use in Agriculture: The Experi-
ence of and Lessons from the Australian Water Reform
Programme.” Background Report. Sustainable Manage-
ment of Water Resources in Agriculture. OECD. Available
at dx.doi.org/10.1787/786732081512.
Young, M. 2015. “Tricks of the Trade: Learning From Austra-
lia’s Water Reform Experience.” Waterfront 1 (1): 10–12.
Zbinden, S.  D.R. Lee. 2005. “Paying for Environmental Ser-
vices: An Analysis of Participation in Costa Rica’s PSA
Program.” World Development, Institutional arrange-
ments for rural poverty reduction and resource conserva-
tion, 33 (2): 255–72. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.012.
Zedler, J.B.  S. Kercher. 2005. “WETLAND RESOURCES:
Status, Trends, Ecosystem Services, and Restorability.”
Annual Review of Environment and Resources 30 (1):
39–74. doi:10.1146/annurev.energy.30.050504.144248.
Zellmer, S.B.  J. Harder. 2007. “Unbundling Property in
Water.” Alabama Law Review 59: 679.
Zucchino, D. 2015. “Duke Energy Fined $102 Million for Pol-
luting Rivers with Coal Ash.” Los Angeles Times, May 14.
Available at latimes.com/nation/la-na-duke-energy-coal-
ash-20150514-story.html#page=1.
Zwarteveen, M.Z. 1997. “Water: From Basic Need to Com-
modity: A Discussion on Gender and Water Rights in
the Context of Irrigation.” World Development 25 (8):
1335–49.
Wada, Y., L.P.H. van Beek, C.M. van Kempen, J.W.T.M. Reck-
man, S. Vasak  M.F.P. Bierkens. 2010. “Global Depletion of
Groundwater Resources.” Geophysical Research Letters
37 (20): L20402. doi:10.1029/2010GL044571.
Wallace, K.H. 2007. “Trading Pollution for Water Quality:
Assessing the Effects of Market-Based Instruments in
Three Basins.” Master’s Thesis, Cambridge, Massachu-
setts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Available at
dspace.mit.edu/handle/1721.1/39938.
Watershed Agricultural Council. 2011. “Strategic Plan: 2011-
2014.” Walton, New York. Available at nycwatershed.org/
pdfs/Strategic_Plan_2011-2014.pdf.
Wheeler, S.A.  J. Cheesman. 2013. “Key Findings from a Sur-
vey of Sellers to the Restoring the Balance Programme.”
Economic Papers: A Journal of Applied Economics
and Policy 32 (3): 340–52. doi:10.1111/1759-3441.12038.
Wind, M.H.A. 2012. “Water Emissions Trading in Europe - A
Literature Overview and Discussion of Opportunities.”
Eco-consult Environmental Economics. http://www.eco-
consult.nl/images/pdf/WET_in_Europe_v3.pdf.
Woodward, R.T., R.A. Kaiser  A.B. Wicks. 2002. “The Struc-
ture and Practice of Water Quality Trading Markets.”
Journal of the American Water Resources Association
38 (4): 967–79. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2002.tb05538.x.
World Economic Forum (WEF). 2012. “Global Risks 2012,
Seventh Edition.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic
Forum (WEF). Available at weforum.org/docs/WEF_Glo-
balRisks_Report_2012.pdf.
———. 2013. “Global Risks 2013, Eighth Edition.” Geneva,
Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available
at.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalRisks_Report_2013.pdf.
———. 2014. “Global Risks 2014, Ninth Edition.” Geneva,
Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at
weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalRisks_Report_2014.pdf.
———. 2015. “Global Risks 2015, 10th Edition.” Geneva, Swit-
zerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at wefo-
rum.org/docs/WEF_Global_Risks_2015_Report15.pdf.
World Health Organization and UNICEF. 2015. “Progress on
Sanitation and Drinking Water - 2015 Update and MDG
Assessment.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Health Orga-
nization. Available at wssinfo.org/fileadmin/user_upload/
resources/JMP-Update-report-2015_English.pdf.
OhioRiver,Indiana.PhotographbyRavenonhealth.
www.rockefellerfoundation.org
Financial support provided by
Incentive-Based Instruments
for Water Management
December 2015
SYNTHESIS REVIEW
THE
RockefellerFoundation
EVALUATIONOFFICE
Financial support provided by
About the Pacific Institute
The Pacific Institute envisions a world in which society, the economy, and the environment have the
water they need to thrive now and in the future. In pursuit of this vision, the Pacific Institute creates and
advances solutions to the world’s most pressing water challenges, such as unsustainable water manage-
ment and use, climate change, environmental degradation, and basic lack of access to fresh water and
sanitation. Since 1987, the Pacific Institute has cut across traditional areas of study and actively collabo-
rated with a diverse set of stakeholders, including leading policy makers, scientists, corporate leaders,
and international organizations such as the United Nations, advocacy groups, and local communities.
This interdisciplinary and independent approach helps bring diverse groups together to forge effective
real-world solutions.
About the Foundation Center
Established in 1956, Foundation Center is the leading source of information about philanthropy worldwide.
Through data, analysis, and training, it connects people who want to change the world to the resources
they need to succeed. The Foundation Center maintains the most comprehensive database on US and,
increasingly, global grantmakers and their grants – a robust, accessible knowledge bank for the sector. It
also operates research, education, and training programs designed to advance knowledge of philanthro-
py at every level. The Foundation Center’s IssueLab service works to gather, index, and share the collec-
tive intelligence of the social sector more effectively, providing free access to thousands of case studies,
evaluations, white papers, and issue briefs addressing some of the world’s most pressing problems.
About The Rockefeller Foundation
For more than 100 years, The Rockefeller Foundation’s mission has been to promote the well-being
of humanity throughout the world. Today, The Rockefeller Foundation pursues this mission through
dual goals: advancing inclusive economies that expand opportunities for more broadly shared prosper-
ity, and building resilience by helping people, communities, and institutions prepare for, withstand and
emerge stronger from acute shocks and chronic stresses. Committed to supporting learning, account-
ability and performance improvements, the Evaluation Office of The Rockefeller Foundation works with
staff, grantees, and partners to strengthen evaluation practice and to support innovative approaches to
monitoring, evaluation, and learning.
For this synthesis review, The Rockefeller Foundation provided financial support, the Foundation
Center and its IssueLab service were involved in project and technology development, and the Pacific
Institute authored the report. Pacific Institute authors included Heather Cooley, Michael Cohen, Matthew
Heberger, and Heather Rippman.
Cover: Hudson River, NY. Photograph by Daniel Case.
The contents of this report are the views of the authors and do not
necessarily reflect the views or policies of The Rockefeller Foundation.
© 2015, The Rockefeller Foundation
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 License
Incentive-Based Instruments for
Water Management
December 2015
Financial support provided by
THE
RockefellerFoundation
EVALUATIONOFFICE
ChesapeakeBay,Maryland.PhotographbyBossi.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT iii
Table of Contents
Acronyms	 v
Foreword	 vii
Acknowledgements	 ix
Executive summary	 x
Water trading	 x
Payment for ecosystem services	 xiii
Water quality trading	 xv
Conclusions	 xvi
1		 Introduction	 1
2	 Research methodology	 5
3	 Environmental policy instruments	 7
3.1	 Water trading	 10
Description	 10
Application	 12
Environmental, economic, and social performance	 16
Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions	 25
3.2	 Payment for ecosystem services/payment for watershed services	 28
Description	 28
Application	 30
Environmental, economic, and social performance	 31
Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions	 35
3.3	 Water quality trading	 39
Description	 39
Application	 41
Environmental, economic, and social performance	 44
Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions	 48
4 	 Role of the private sector	 53
4.1	 Corporate water stewardship	 53
4.2	 Private sector engagement with incentive-based instruments	 55
5 	 Summary and conclusions	 61
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTiv
Annexes
Annex 1: Demand management	 63
Annex 2: Water trading in Australia: Lessons from the Murray-Darling Basin	 66
Background	 66
MCB and the Colorado River Basin	 66
History	 67
Water trading activity	 69
Enabling conditions	 71
Lessons learned	 71
Glossary	 74
References	 75
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT v
Acronyms
ARP Acid Rain Program (US)
AWS Alliance for Water Stewardship
BIER Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable
BMP Best management practices
CAC Command-and-control
CDP Carbon Disclosure Project (former name)
CRP Conservation Reserve Program (US)
DEG German Investment and Development Corporation
EPA Environmental Protection Agency (US)
EPRI Electric Power Research Institute
GEF The Global Environment Facility
GPCD Gallons per capita daily
IID Imperial Irrigation District (California, US)
IWS Investment in watershed services
MAF Million acre-feet
MI Municipal and industrial
MDB Murray-Darling Basin
MDBA Murray-Darling Basin Authority
MWD Metropolitan Water District of Southern California (California, US)
MWELO Model Water Efficient Landscape Ordinance
NRC National Research Council (US)
NSWDEC New South Wales Department of Education and Communities (Australia)
NWC National Water Commission (Australia)
PES Payment for ecosystems services
PSAH Programme for Hydrological Environmental Services (Mexico)
PSA Pagos por servicios ambientales (payment for environmental services)
PWS Payment for watershed services
RUPES Rewarding Upland Poor for Environmental Services (Indonesia)
SBP Socio Bosque Program (Ecuador)
SDCWA San Diego County Water Authority
SO2 Sulfur dioxide
SWP State Water Project (California, US)
TMDL Total maximum daily load
TWSTT Transforming Water Scarcity through Trading
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTvi
UCSB University of California at Santa Barbara
UN United Nations
UNDP United Nations Development Programme
UNEP United Nations Environment Programme
USBR United States Bureau of Reclamation
WEF World Economic Forum
WfW Working for Water (South Africa)
WHO World Health Organization
WQT Water quality trading
WRI World Resources Institute
WWF World Wide Fund for Nature
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT vii
Foreword
Human transformation of freshwater ecosystems is rapidly exceeding capacity required to sustain the
conditions we need to survive and thrive. Water crises are already impacting people around the globe –
from river basins in California and China, to the cities of São Palo and Bangkok. Under current population
and growth trends, the 2030 Water Resources Group predicts global water demand will exceed available
supply by 40 percent by 2030.
Humans have used, benefited from, and shaped the natural environment for the whole of human history.
But what we have not done – especially in the course of industrialization and modernization – is find
effective ways to integrate natural ecosystems into our economic and social systems. In response to
these challenges, The Rockefeller Foundation’s work focuses on incentive-based solutions that harness
the importance of ecosystems as an asset for smart development, economic and social progress, and
long-term resilience. In our work on agriculture and food security, climate change, energy, and fisheries,
we seek new approaches to environmental care that will create incentives for the wise use of resources,
and preserve their resilience. And in all of our work we place particular emphasis on the effects of these
solutions on the poor or otherwise vulnerable members of society, who are most directly dependent on
ecosystems to meet their basic needs and are mostly likely to bear the consequences of environmental
degradation.
Freshwater crises are representative of the kind of misaligned incentives we seek to correct. Freshwater
allocation and management systems often place little value on the benefits of functioning ecosystems.
This, in turn, leads to a vicious cycle in which ecosystem degradation and overuse reduce future water
supplies, making even more people vulnerable to water scarcity. As water crises continue to capture
public attention – in January, the World Economic Forum’s Global Risk Report 2015 named water crises
the number one economic risk in terms of impact – and decision makers worldwide scramble for answers,
The Rockefeller Foundation is eager to help support the identification of sound solutions by synthesiz-
ing the knowledge and lessons from past and current water management interventions.
The synthesis report that follows examines several incentive-based instruments for improving freshwa-
ter management for all users, including poor and vulnerable populations and the freshwater ecosystems
themselves. The report examines the economic, social, and environmental performance of three tools,
which were selected because: there is growing interest in applying these instruments in a range of
settings, they are clearly focused on voluntary transactions rather than sanctions or voluntary standards,
they can be applied to improve water quality or quantity, and there is an existing body of literature about
their implementation upon which we can build. However, one of the key findings is that these transac-
tions are often not voluntary. The report highlights the importance of finding a fit between a commu-
nity’s water goals and the water management tool(s) it might choose and, perhaps most importantly, it
characterizes the enabling conditions required for their effective implementation. We hope this synthesis
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTviii
review will serve as an entry point for those exploring opportunities to improve the management of
freshwater, and will spark the development of more robust solutions to improve our management and
maintenance of freshwater systems. 
We hope that you will find this report useful and encourage you to explore the accompanying learning
tool at freshwater.issuelab.org and to share it widely with colleagues.
Dr. Fred Boltz
Managing Director, Ecosystems
The Rockefeller Foundation
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT ix
Acknowledgements
The overall design of this synthesis review was led and managed collaboratively by Gabi Fitz from the
Foundation Center and Alex Martinez from The Rockefeller Foundation.
The research, analysis and written synthesis were undertaken by a freshwater specialist team from the
Pacific Institute led by Heather Cooley and Michael Cohen, and assisted by Matthew Heberger and
Heather Rippman. Their work was further supported by John Berggren, who provided research assistance
and Genevieve Bennett, Roy Brouwer, Jessica Fox, Chuck Howe, Cy Jones, Tony McLeod, Marcus Moench,
and Ina Porras who all provided the team with valuable information and suggested additional readings.
The visualization and special collection were designed and developed by Lisa Brooks and Gabi Fitz from
the Foundation Center and IssueLab, in collaboration with ThreeStory Studio.
Peer review was provided by Dr. Casey Brown of the University of Massachusetts, Matt Elliott, Amy
Dickie, Mark Michelin, Emily Peterson, and James Giampietro of California Environmental Associates,
The Rockefeller Foundation Freshwater Team, and Nancy MacPherson from The Rockefeller Founda-
tion’s Evaluation Office.
Learning from Experience – an ongoing collaboration between the
Foundation Center and The Rockefeller Foundation
This synthesis review, Incentive-based Instruments for Water Management, is part of an ongoing collab-
oration between The Rockefeller Foundation and the Foundation Center, aimed at helping organizations
build more effectively on each other’s knowledge, lessons and experience. With financial support from
The Rockefeller Foundation, the Foundation Center is engaging in synthesis reviews and the develop-
ment of supportive technologies and practices that facilitate the collection, synthesis, and sharing of the
sector’s collective knowledge.
As part of our collaboration, we are committed to sharing all work products from these efforts as public
goods. Too often, systematic and synthesis reviews result in a public report but leave future researchers
having to duplicate search and selection efforts in order to further build on a synthesis. By collecting
and sharing coded search results through an open repository and openly licensing all work products, we
hope other researchers can more freely use and repurpose our findings.
Our goal is to contribute to better programmatic and funding strategies by enabling teams and organizations
to start with a more inclusive and comprehensive understanding of what has worked, what hasn’t, and why.
Gabi Fitz	 Nancy MacPherson
Director of Knowledge Management Initiatives	 Managing Director, Evaluation
Foundation Center	 The Rockefeller Foundation
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTx
Executive summary
Water is one of our most precious and valuable resources and is fundamental for maintaining human
health, economic activity, and critical ecosystem functions. Yet, we can see clear signs of the overexploi-
tation of available freshwater resources and the resultant inability to meet basic human and ecosystem
needs. Already, some iconic rivers, such as the Colorado in the United States and the Yellow in China, no
longer reach the sea. Groundwater withdrawals have tripled over the past 50 years, with groundwater ex-
traction exceeding natural recharge in some areas, causing widespread depletion and declining ground-
water levels. More than 660 million people lack access to an improved drinking water source, predomi-
nantly in sub-Saharan Africa and Oceania, and some 2.4 billion people lack access to basic sanitation.1
At the same time, the world’s water quality is becoming increasingly degraded, with water pollution exac-
erbating the challenges posed by water scarcity. Pressure on water resources is intensifying in response
to challenges such as economic and population growth, and, in turn, is having major impacts on our
social, economic, and environmental well-being.
With traditional approaches to managing water having proven insufficient to address these challenges,
new approaches and policies are needed. Policy makers and water managers are showing increasing
interest in incentive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water resources.
In most regions, laws and regulations have been the primary policy tools employed to improve envi-
ronmental outcomes. However, over the past several decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has
expanded to include incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or indirectly, to
motivate responsible parties to reallocate water, or reduce the health and environmental risks posed by
their facilities, processes, or products.
This report provides a synthesis review of a set of incentive-based instruments that have been employed
to varying degrees around the world. It is part of an effort by The Rockefeller Foundation to improve
understanding of both the potential of these instruments and their limitations. The report is divided into
five sections. Section 1 provides an introduction to the synthesis review. Section 2 describes the research
methodology. Section 3 provides background on policy instruments and detail on three incentive-based
instruments – water trading, payment for ecosystem services, and water quality trading – describing the
application of each, including their environmental, economic, and social performances, and the condi-
tions needed for their implementation. Section 4 highlights the role of the private sector in implementing
these instruments, and Section 5 provides a summary and conclusions.
Water trading
Water trading refers to the temporary or permanent transfer of the right to use water in exchange for
some form of compensation. It is perhaps the best known and most widely used method of reallocating
water. It has proven, in some cases, to be less expensive, more flexible, and less time-consuming than
1	 An “improved” drinking-water source is one that, by nature of its construction and when properly used, adequately protects the source
from outside contamination, particularly fecal matter.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xi
developing new water supplies through, for example, constructing new diversion structures or desali-
nation plants. Similarly, water trading is generally a more accepted method of reallocating water than
state appropriation or revoking of existing water rights. Today, examples of successful water trading
in Australia and other locations – combined with classic economic theory which suggests that market
mechanisms can optimize resource allocation – have heightened interest in this instrument in both
academic literature and popular media.
Water trading occurs within sectors, from agriculture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban, across sectors
and, less frequently, from either of these to the environment. Water trading exists, to varying degrees,
in countries around the world, though the most active water trading markets are in Australia and the
western United States. In Australia, the total value of water trading in fiscal year 2012–13 exceeded
$1.4 billion, with much of that activity concentrated within the Murray-Darling Basin. While the total
volume of water traded via long-term trades within the Murray-Darling Basin decreased slightly in fiscal
year 2012–2013, the volume of water traded via short-term trades increased by 44 percent from the
previous year, from almost 3.5 to 5.0 million acre-feet (MAF), or about 50 percent of the total surface
water use in the basin.2 In the western United States, where the scale of water trading is considerably
lower, there were more than 4,000 water trades between 1987 and 2008. In 2011, the most recent year
for which data are available, more than 1.4 MAF of water were traded in California, representing about
4 percent of the total water use that year. Of that amount, 42 percent of the water traded went to
municipal and industrial users, 37 percent to agricultural users, 17 percent was used for environmental
purposes, and the remainder was for mixed uses.
The actual results of water trading worldwide have been decidedly mixed, due to two key challenges: ex-
ternalities and transaction costs. In Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin, the federal government overcame
some of those challenges by investing more than $3 billion to purchase water for the environment, pro-
tecting ecological resources and directly addressing one of the major challenges to water trading. This
has facilitated trading in the basin and reduced transaction costs by shifting them to national taxpayers.
Over the last 30 years, the federal government also implemented significant institutional changes that
facilitated trading and reduced transaction costs. Short-term water trading within irrigation districts in
the United States, such as within the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, occurs smoothly
and quickly because intra-district trades undergo very limited oversight, and because the third-party
impacts of such trades tend to be small or negligible.
However, these examples of successful water trading regimes are countered by critical arguments and
examples of less-successful trades from various parts of the world. Many authors challenge the applica-
bility and efficacy of water trading, contending that externalities and the unique characteristics of water
itself pose significant obstacles to trading water. Many of these externalities arise from the physical
properties of water: it is heavy, unwieldy, and easily contaminated; varies seasonally and from year to
year; and is readily lost through evaporation, seepage, or runoff. Further, externalities may be borne by
disparate parties, such as the environment or future generations, challenging efforts to compensate
those injured by trading. Questions of externalities, commodification, and the special nature of water
2	 An acre-foot, the conventional unit of water measurement in the western United States, is equivalent to 325,851 gallons or 1,233.48 m3.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxii
itself highlight the challenges faced when seeking to implement or expand water trading. Critics also
highlight the many examples of “buy-and-dry” water trades, where water-rich agricultural areas sell their
water rights, often to wealthier cities, only to find that rural communities as a whole suffer when agricul-
tural production declines. Critics have pointed to examples around the world where wealthy communi-
ties or interests have purchased and withdrawn water from less powerful, poor rural areas.
The environmental performance of water trading has been highly variable, depending on the type of
trade and site-specific conditions. Water trading has been used as a mechanism to obtain water for
ecological purposes, to augment streamflow, and to address water quality concerns (such as tempera-
ture) in threatened reaches. The benefits of voluntary, incentive-based water acquisition include ease
of transaction and greater community support, especially relative to regulatory takings,3 though in most
areas, such activity still represents a tiny fraction of total water use in any given area. In California, in the
last three decades, environmental water purchases averaged 152,000 acre-feet per year, accounting for
about 14 percent of trading activity and less than 0.5 percent of total water use in the state. Conversely,
water trades for other purposes can inadvertently harm the environment. They can, for example, change
the timing, quantity, and quality of return flows, adversely affecting riparian and wetland habitats and the
species that depend upon them.
Water trading has rarely been employed to address equity challenges. Indeed, water trading can exacer-
bate social and economic inequalities, worsening gender and geographic differences. Unequal access to
water markets due to unequal access to information or credit can distort outcomes and reduce market
efficiency. On the other hand, water trading that promotes water-use efficiency rather than fallowing of
agricultural land can improve socio-economic outcomes for both the area of origin and the destination.
Water trading’s social impacts vary based on several factors, including the relative economic health of
the area of origin and the purchasing area, whether or not the water leaves the area of origin, the process
used to trade the water, the relative economic and political power of the parties, gender differences
regarding access to and control of water, the amount of trading activity in the area, and the legitimacy of
the water rights being traded. Impacts often vary within the same community, as those with water rights
or allocations to trade receive compensation, while third parties – such as irrigation equipment suppliers
or farmworkers – may suffer a loss of revenue or income as a result of trading.
Institutional arrangements are among the most important factors that determine the ultimate success or
failure of water trading. Successful water trading requires secure and flexible water rights that recognize
and protect users and others from externalities. Such institutional arrangements also need to be flexible
enough to adapt to changing physical conditions as well as changing social norms, such as the growing
interest in meeting environmental needs and protecting water quality. Some factors, such as access to
timely information about water available to trade, can enable water trading but may not be required.
Other factors, such as legal and transferable rights to use water, may be necessary for water trading to
occur. Still other factors, such as “no injury” regulations and “area of origin” protection, limit water trading
or can function as barriers or obstacles to trading.
3	 A “regulatory taking” occurs when a government regulation limits or infringes upon a private property right to such an extent that it
deprives the owner of some or all of the value of that property” (Fischel, 1995).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xiii
In a limited number of areas with the necessary legal and technical conditions and with sufficient public
investment, water trading has offered a timely, relatively inexpensive, and flexible mechanism to real-
locate water between users, or from water users back to the environment. Building a successful water
market requires decades of determined effort to measure water flows and use, report transactions
publicly, conduct regional water planning, and construct and maintain infrastructure to convey water. In
Australia’s case, it also required more than $3 billion of public funding to acquire water for environmental
purposes, which also called for creating and, in turn, maintaining an environmental baseline above which
trading activity could occur. Such significant institutional changes require broad public support and a
considerable amount of time to implement. Although water trading can be used to reallocate water ef-
fectively, successful implementation requires a clear understanding of existing conditions and a deter-
mined, long-term effort to make the necessary changes and minimize externalities.
Payment for ecosystem services
Payment for ecosystem services is an incentive-based instrument that seeks to monetize the external,
non-market values of environmental services – such as removal of pollutants and regulation of precipita-
tion events – that can then be used as financial incentives for local actors to provide such services. In
practical terms, they involve a series of payments to a land or resource manager in exchange for a guar-
anteed flow of environmental services. Payments are made to the environmental service provider by the
beneficiary of those services, e.g. an individual, a community, a company, or a government. In essence, it
is based on a beneficiary-pays principle, as opposed to a polluter-pays principle.
Payments for ecosystems services (PESs) that focus on watershed services, commonly referred to
as “payments for watershed services” (PWSs), can take a variety of forms. They may be intended to
prevent the degradation of a watershed or to restore a previously degraded one. They may be small, local
schemes covering several hundred hectares or large, national schemes covering millions of hectares.
Programs may be financed directly by the beneficiary or by third parties acting on behalf of the benefi-
ciary, e.g. governments or institutions, or some combination thereof. They may involve cash or in-kind
payments to be paid all at once or periodically.
New York City provides a well-known example. In the late 1990s, New York City was faced with the
prospect of building a $4–$6 billion filtration plant with an additional $250 million in annual operating
costs to meet new federal drinking water standards. An initial analysis suggested that preserving the
upstream rural Catskill watershed would be far less expensive. The city and local farmers came together
to develop a plan that could meet both groups’ interests. A key element of the plan was the Whole Farm
Program, a voluntary effort fully funded by New York City’s Department of Environmental Protection
whereby farmers would work with technical advisors to custom design pollution control measures to
meet an environmental objective while also improving the viability of their farming businesses. By 2006,
the city had spent or committed between $1.4 billion and $1.5 billion in watershed protection projects,
averaging $167 million in expenditures per year – far less than building a water filtration plant. Participa-
tion remains high, with 96 percent of large farms in the watershed participating in the program.
Payments for watershed services are gaining prominence and have been applied in a wide range of
settings. Some of the earliest programs were established in Central America but today, such programs
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxiv
can be found in countries around the world. The United States’ Conservation Reserve Program pays
farmers to take land out of production in order to protect soil and water resources and wildlife habitat. In
northeastern France, Vittel-Nestle Waters paid farmers and provided technical support (and some labor)
to alter local dairy farming practices in order to reduce nitrate pollution of groundwater – the source of
Vittel’s bottled water.
The largest PWS programs are in China. China’s Sloping Land Conversion Programme, piloted in 1999
and fully implemented in 2002, requires farmers to set aside erosion-prone farmland within critical areas
of the watershed of the Yangtze and Yellow Rivers – the two largest rivers in China. In exchange, farmers
receive regular cash payments and grain rations. The program promotes forestry and other economic
endeavors on the land rather than grain production, in order to prevent sediment from washing into
rivers and clogging dams and shipping channels.
The environmental performance of PWS is not well understood. Evaluation of these programs is in-
herently difficult because the connections between land use practice and watershed services are not
always clear, especially as they relate to water quantity, and they are often site-specific. It can also be
difficult to attribute change to the program rather than to external factors (e.g. changing commodity
prices), and programs may not reach threshold levels for measureable impact, or that impact may occur
over a relatively long time period. In addition to these challenges, many programs lack baseline data or
monitoring systems. In the absence of scientific information, performance is often based on perceptions
of local populations and those operating the schemes. But even based on these sources, the available
data suggest that environmental performance of PWS is mixed, with less than 60 percent of programs
reaching their environmental objective. As the field has matured, it has increased emphasis on monitor-
ing, which will inevitably help improve environmental outcomes.
Similarly,limiteddataareavailableonthesocialandeconomicimpactsofpaymentsforwatershedservices.
Most studies have focused on increased income or capacity building rather than broader social impacts,
such as changes in power dynamics. While participation in a PWS program can boost the income of small
farmers, the payments they receive will typically boost their annual incomes only slightly. Several studies
have also suggested that there are important non-financial (or non-income) benefits, such as increasing
land-tenure security, creating human and social capital through internal organization, and improving the
visibility of the community to donors and public entities. Some analysts have argued that because the
programs are mostly voluntary, continued participation provides some indication that the programs are
cost effective, i.e. that benefits exceed costs and participants are satisfied with the outcomes.
While information on broader social outcomes is limited, there is information on the role of these arrange-
ments in alleviating poverty. However, it is important to recognize that payment for watershed services
was conceptualized as a mechanism to improve the efficiency of natural resource management, not as a
mechanism to reduce poverty. Several studies have examined the socio-economic status of participants,
either as buyers or sellers, and have found mixed results, depending to some extent on land and forest
tenure regimes and socio-economic conditions in the targeted areas. While most programs prioritize
areas critical for ecosystem services, some have been tailored to meet social objectives through a variety
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xv
of mechanisms, such as targeting the programs to particular areas or populations, reducing transac-
tion costs, and providing pro-poor premiums and subsidies. While there are often more direct ways of
reducing poverty than payments for watershed services (e.g. education or health programs), there is
little evidence of these schemes actually doing any harm. Few studies have examined gender represen-
tation among program participants.
In general, payments for watershed services are flexible, and the necessary conditions are relatively
modest. Small, self-organized schemes between private entities are based on general legal require-
ments: a legal system recognizing that agreements must be kept and that civil law must provide the
contracting parties with legal remedies in case of non-compliance. Expanding these projects to address
regional or national water problems would require a more developed policy and legal framework along
with incentives or requirements to participate in PES programs, cultural and political acceptance of
markets, trust between ecosystem service providers and beneficiaries, and a supply and demand for
ecosystem services.
Water quality trading
Water quality trading (WQT) is an incentive-based approach for reducing or controlling water pollution.
Under such a system, polluters are granted a permit to pollute, and these permits can be bought and
sold among polluters. The central idea is that trading puts a price on pollution, encouraging cost savings,
efficiency, and innovation. Water quality trading is an adjunct to regulation, not an alternative to it. In fact,
its success depends on the presence of a strong regulatory body to enforce water quality standards, and
monitor and enforce discharge limits.
Water quality markets have drawn inspiration from the success of the Acid Rain Program (ARP) es-
tablished in the United States in the 1990s. The popularity of emissions trading for dealing with water
pollution in the United States is largely a result of the Clean Water Act of 1972, which made it difficult for
governments to handle pollution from farms. Water quality markets have been established in the United
States, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand. There is also interest in China and Europe, although no
programs are currently in place. To date, most water quality trading markets have been used to control
pollution from nutrients that cause excessive algal growth and low dissolved oxygen levels in water
bodies, a process referred to as “eutrophication”. Other water quality trading programs have been set up
to control salinity, heavy metal, sediment, and temperature or thermal pollution.
The largest WQT market in the United States in terms of transactions, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit
Exchange Program, was created in 2002 to reduce nitrogen pollution that came into Long Island Sound
from the Connecticut River. Under the program, which covers 79 sewage treatment plants in the state
of Connecticut, a plant can control pollution in excess of its permit requirement and sell excess nitrogen
allowances to those plants that exceed their allowances. A 2012 review of the program found that in ten
years, the program had helped reduce nitrogen pollution by over 50 percent while controlling costs.
One of the best examples of a successful water quality trading market is on Australia’s Hunter River,
where coal mines and other pollution sources are subject to discharge limits to protect water quality
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxvi
and drinking water sources in downstream cities. Under this system, limited discharge is allowed, but
permitted dischargers must coordinate their activities so that the total salt concentration in the river
never goes above a specified limit. Industries can buy and sell salt credits in real time via a trading
website run by the state government. Several years after it began, the trading program remains popular
among participants and functions smoothly. Perhaps the biggest marker of the program’s success is
that, even though new and potentially high-polluting mines have been established, river water quality
has met standards nearly 100 percent of the time.
Despite the fact that water quality trading markets have existed for three decades in some areas, it is
difficult to determine whether the approach can be considered an overall success. Many of the domestic
WQT markets in the United States have not lived up to expectations, seeing few trades or no trades at
all. This can be explained by a number of factors: high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty about
the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate. However, paradoxically,
despite a lack of trading, the process of creating the market may have contributed to better watershed
management. Bringing stakeholders together around a common goal of improving water quality has
helped lower resistance to new, more stringent water quality regulations.
In other cases, discussion of the use of “market fundamentals” helped convince some political conser-
vatives to implement a form of environmental regulation, paving the way for improved water quality. A
common argument in favor of environmental markets is that they will be smaller, simpler, and lower cost,
because they aim to replace regulation with a free market. However, water quality markets require a
strong and capable regulatory ability to set a cap on pollutants, to monitor pollution, and to verify the le-
gitimacy of water quality credits that are created. Ironically, this often results in the creation of additional
layers of government to perform these functions.
WQT markets are valuable where large price asymmetries exist in water pollution control, and where
certain polluters are beyond the reach of a regulatory agency. This is the case in the United States, where
states are responsible for preserving water quality but have little authority over agriculture and some
other nonpoint sources. On one hand, this has decreased the burden on municipal and industrial sources
of pollution, allowing them to save on the cost of installing expensive treatment technologies. On the
other hand, it has compelled them to fund projects on farms, often hundreds of miles away. We conclude
that water quality trading is not a panacea for solving water pollution problems. However, it can be part
of an effective regulatory approach under certain conditions.
Conclusions
In this report, we analyze the potential for incentive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water
resources. To date, the primary environmental policy tools to address water challenges have been com-
mand-and-control regulations. However, over the past several decades, the environmental policy “toolkit”
has expanded to include a host of incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or
indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their
facilities, processes, or products.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xvii
While regulations and incentive-based instruments are frequently juxtaposed, they also frequently
operate alongside one another. With water quality trading, for example, governments mandate caps on
the allowable pollutant levels and issue tradable permits that allow industry groups to allocate polluting
activities among themselves, governed by market forces. Similarly, with water trading, governments may
allocate water and then institute a framework within which water trading can occur. While incentive-
based instruments may work in tandem, they must be integrated within a broader watershed manage-
ment effort.
Decisions about whether and how to apply a particular instrument depend on the specific objectives,
circumstances, conditions, and needs of a given area. These decisions should be based on an open
and transparent process, with meaningful participation from all affected parties. This approach will help
in crafting a solution that is appropriate for local conditions, and ensure that it is fair and equitable. It
will also help to reduce opposition and promote acceptance from those who will be implementing and
affected by the program. It is important to recognize that those with the least power may not have the
resources to participate, or they may be skeptical of the groups involved. In these cases, there is a need
for consistent and rigorous outreach and, potentially, for engaging a trusted intermediary.
Finally, monitoring and evaluation are essential to the success of any instrument. In particular, moni-
toring and evaluation help ensure outcomes are achieved and allow for adjustments in response to
changing social, economic, or environmental conditions. Monitoring should evaluate the “additionality”
of the program, i.e. whether the program has an effect when compared with some baseline. It should also
examine any potential impacts on surrounding areas (i.e. leakage) and the permanence of the interven-
tion. However, extensive monitoring requirements would increase transaction costs, potentially threat-
ening the viability of the program. Thus, the need for monitoring and evaluation must be balanced with
practical considerations of the ability to maintain the viability of the program.
LimariRiver,Chile.PhotographbyEduardoRobles.
1
Introduction
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 1
Water is one of our most precious and valuable
resources and is fundamental for maintaining human
health, agricultural production, and economic activ-
ity as well as critical ecosystem functions. Even as the
planet’s endowment of water is expected to remain
constant, human appropriation of fresh water, already
at 50 percent by some measures (Postel et al., 1996),
is expected to increase further (Leflaive et al., 2012).
We can already see clear signs of the overexploitation
of available freshwater resources. For example, some
iconic rivers, including the Colorado River in the United
States and the Yellow River in China, no longer reach
the sea. Groundwater withdrawals have tripled over the
past 50 years (UN, 2012), and in some areas, ground-
water extraction exceeds natural recharge, causing
widespread depletion and declining groundwater levels
(Wada et al., 2010; Famiglietti, 2014). Pressures on water
resources are likely to worsen in response to contin-
ued economic and population growth, climate change,
and other challenges. Water pollution exacerbates the
challenges posed by water scarcity as the world’s water
quality is increasingly becoming degraded.
Growing pressures on the availability and quality of
water resources have major impacts on our social, eco-
nomic, and environmental well-being. The failure to
provide safe drinking water and adequate sanitation
services to all people is perhaps the greatest develop-
ment failure of the twentieth century. Improving access
to water and sanitation has been a key focus of the
global development agenda since 2000. Water and
sanitation were goals of the 2000–2015 Millennium
Development Goals, and now, the Sustainable Devel-
opment Goals launched in September 2015, also call for
insuring access to water and sanitation for all.
Yet, despite nearly two decades of international atten-
tion and tens of billions of dollars invested, more than
660 million people still lack access to improved drink-
ing water, predominantly in sub-Saharan Africa and
Oceania, and some 2.4 billion people lack access to
basic sanitation (WHO and UNICEF, 2015).4,5 In even
the wealthiest countries, access to water and sanitation
4	 Improved water sources include household connections, public stand-
pipes, boreholes, protected dug wells, protected springs, and rainwater
collections. Unimproved water sources are unprotected wells, unprotect-
ed springs, vendor-provided water, bottled water (unless water for other
uses is available from an improved source), and tanker truck-provided
water.
5	 Improved sanitation includes connection to public sewers, connection to
septic systems, pour-flush latrines, simple pit latrines, and ventilated im-
proved pit latrines. Service or bucket latrines (where excreta is manually
removed), public latrines and open latrines are not considered improved
sanitation.
“…more than 660 million people still lack
access to an improved drinking water
source…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT2
(2002, 2003), is based on integrating several key prin-
ciples, including improving the overall productivity of
water use, matching water quality to users’ needs, pri-
oritizing basic human and ecosystem water needs, and
seeking meaningful local and community engagement
in water management.
A key element of the soft path for water is shifting from
a near exclusive supply-side orientation to one that
seeks to manage water demand. Numerous studies
have found significant opportunities to reduce water
demand in all sectors using a variety of conservation
and efficiency measures (e.g. Gleick et al., 2003; Cohen
et al., 2013; Heberger et al., 2014). These measures
can be applied in countries at varying levels of eco-
nomic development, although the types of measures
employed and implementation strategies may differ
(Sharma and Vairavamoorthy, 2009). Brooks (2006)
argued that demand management is more than a set
of techniques; rather, it is a governance approach
linked to equity, environmental protection, and public
engagement goals. Additional information on demand
management can be found in Annex 1.
New policy tools are also needed. In most places, regu-
lations have been the primary tool employed to improve
environmental outcomes. However, over the past sev-
eral decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has
expanded to include “incentive-based” instruments.
Incentive-based instruments use financial means,
directly or indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to
reallocate water or reduce the health and environmen-
tal risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products.
These instruments have emerged for several reasons,
but mainly because they are believed to be more cost
effective than regulations, as they provide greater flex-
ibility for the individual or firm to meet the environmen-
tal objective in the least costly manner. Incentive-based
is not universal. A 2011 UN report (de Albuquerque,
2011) highlighted several areas of the United States,
including California, where marginalized populations
(e.g. those living in poverty, communities of color, and
indigenous groups) lacked the basic rights to water
and sanitation. Moreover, access to an improved water
source does not necessarily mean that the water is
affordable or safe to drink. For example, naturally occur-
ring arsenic pollution in groundwater affects nearly
140 million people in 70 countries (United Nations,
2009).
Freshwater ecosystems are among the most exten-
sively altered systems on earth. Rivers, streams, and
lakes have been subjected to chemical, physical, and
biological alteration as a result of large-scale water
diversions, introduction of invasive species, overhar-
vesting, pollution, and climate change (Carpenter
et al., 2011). As a result, an estimated 20 to 35 per-
cent of freshwater fish are vulnerable or endangered
(Cosgrove and Rijsberman, 2000). Likewise, about half
of the world’s wetlands have been lost since 1900, and
much of the remaining wetlands are degraded (Zedler
and Kercher, 2005). Freshwater ecosystem conditions
are likely to continue to decline unless action is taken
to address acute threats and better manage freshwa-
ter resources.
Traditional approaches to managing water supply and
demand are not going to be effective in addressing
these challenges. Throughout much of the twentieth
century, the emphasis was on developing massive dams
and pumping ever increasing amounts of groundwa-
ter to satisfy rising water demands. This approach, as
noted by Sharma and Vairavamoorthy (2009), “has led
to over-use of the resources, over-capitalisation, pollu-
tion and other problems of varying severity.” The soft
path for water has emerged as a promising alternative.
The term “soft energy path”, coined by Amory Lovins
(1977) of the Rocky Mountain Institute, described an
alternative path for energy development that empha-
sized energy efficiency and promoted smaller, decen-
tralized energy systems fueled by renewable sources.
The soft path for water, as described by Peter H. Gleick
“…the environmental policy “toolkit” has
expanded to include “incentive-based”
instruments…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 3
in managing both the quantity and quality of fresh-
water. We have divided this review into five sections.
This Section 1 introduces the synthesis review. Section
2 describes the research methodology. Section 3 pro-
vides background on policy instruments and detail on
three incentive-based instruments that have been used
in the United States and abroad – water trading, pay-
ment for ecosystem services, and water quality trad-
ing. For each instrument, we describe its application, its
environmental, economic, and social performance, and
the conditions needed for its implementation. Section
4 highlights the role of the private sector in implement-
ing these instruments, and Section 5 provides a sum-
mary and conclusions.
instruments are also thought to lower administrative
costs and promote innovation by rewarding those who
exceed their targets (Harrington and Morgenstern,
2004). Furthermore, Koplow (2004) suggests that
these instruments can support self-enforcement by
creating “groups of firms and individuals with vested
interests in the proper use of resources and in emitting
only as much pollution as allowed.”
This report provides a synthesis review of a set of
incentive-based instruments that have been employed
in varying degrees around the world to reduce pressure
on water resources. It is part of an effort to understand
the full potential, and limitations, of these instruments
ColoradoRiver,Texas.PhotographbyLeaflet.
2
Research methodology
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 5
The freshwater synthesis review is based on a five-step
approach to making better use of existing evaluative
knowledge. This approach, modeled by The Rockefeller
Foundation to help inform its investment and program-
matic decisions, has already been used in a review of
success factors in small-scale coastal fisheries man-
agement in developing countries (The Rockefeller
Foundation, 2013). Throughout the project, the proj-
ect team held bi-weekly calls with The Rockefeller
Foundation to review progress on the project, discuss
key findings, and dive into specific case studies that
could further support learning. The following steps
were taken.
1.	 Refine project scope. The first step was to work
with the Foundation Center and The Rockefeller
Foundation to refine the scope of work and develop
research questions.
2.	 Undertake literature search and review. The
second step was to review the peer-reviewed lit-
erature and law reviews on the key topics for the
research. We supplemented this formal literature
search with a review of the gray literature, including
government and other institutional reports, from or-
ganizations working to evaluate or implement these
instruments. To identify the relevant literature, we
used Web of Science (formerly Web of Knowledge)
Internet-based search engines, and institutional
website search engines. The literature on these in-
centive-based instruments is extensive. For example,
a Google Scholar search of “water trading” returned
nearly 1 million results. Given the need to review a
large amount of information in a relatively short time,
we prioritized articles published since 2000. We further
refined our study by limiting our scope to articles and
reports on the state of practice, rather than the state of
theory. In total, we reviewed approximately 500 articles
and reports.
3.	 Conduct expert interviews. The third step was to
obtain the knowledge of experts working to address
the study’s key questions. It was designed to fill in any
gaps in the literature. We developed the interview list
based on the academic and grey literature search and
from the research team’s experience in the sector.
4.	 Compile initial analysis and synthesis. The fourth
step included an initial analysis and synthesis of the
knowledge gained from the first three steps, which was
compiled into a detailed presentation and supporting
materials, and formally presented to the Foundation
Center and The Rockefeller Foundation Team in an
interactive discussion in March 2015. The Rockefeller
Foundation also reviewed the draft report in July 2015,
providing additional input on the synthesis.
5.	 Conduct further analysis and develop final
knowledge product. The fifth step was to conduct
further analysis of the published and expert knowledge
based on the discussions with the Foundation Center,
The Rockefeller Foundation, and other parties. We
worked closely with the Foundation Center to develop
the final knowledge products, including this summary
report and online components, such as a visualization
of key findings and a public collection of cited research.
All of the knowledge products are openly licensed and
free to be used and repurposed.
MurrayRiver,Australia.PhotographbyMattinbgn.
3
Environmental policy instruments
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 7
The objective of environmental policy is “to modify,
slow, or stop resource extraction; to reduce or elimi-
nate emissions of concern; and to shift consumption
and production patterns towards greater sustainability”
(Koplow, 2004). In most places, regulations have tradi-
tionally been the primary environmental policy instru-
ment employed to achieve environmental outcomes.
This approach, often referred to as command-and-
control (CAC), relies on some governmental or similar
body to establish a standard or target (the “command”)
that must then be complied with to avoid negative
sanctions, such as fines or prosecution (the “control”).
Over the past several decades, the environmental pol-
icy “toolkit” has expanded to include incentive-based
instruments, also referred to as economic instruments
or market-based instruments. While definitions vary, we
use the term “incentive-based instruments” to refer to
a set of tools that use financial means, directly or indi-
rectly,tomotivateresponsiblepartiestoreallocatewater
or reduce the health and environmental risks posed by
their facilities, processes, or products. While CAC and
incentive-based instruments are often juxtaposed with
one another, a United Nations Environment Programme
(UNEP) report (Koplow, 2004) noted that “in reality the
two often operate alongside each other. Governments
may, for example, mandate caps on allowable pollu-
tion for a region or country and use market-oriented
approaches such as tradable permits to allocate the
allowable emissions in an efficient manner.”
Figure 1 provides a depiction of the range of environ-
mental policy instruments currently applied around the
world. These include the following.
•	 Regulations and sanctions – mechanisms that
rely on guidelines, permits, or licenses, and often
include a legal or financial penalty for non-compli-
ance. Examples include pollution standards, water
use quotes, and building standards.
•	 Price-based instruments – mechanisms that
impose i) higher costs through fees, charges, or
taxes on pollution or the use of a natural resource,
making them more expensive and discouraging
their production or consumption, or ii) lower costs
through the use of subsidies for environmentally
friendly activities or products. Examples include
abstraction fees, pollution charges, grants, low-in-
terest loans, and favorable tax treatment.
•	 Market creation – mechanisms that include i)
tradable permits whereby user or polluter rights are
assigned according to desirable use levels or his-
torical practices, and compliance can be achieved
by trade, or ii) deposit refund systems that create
a market to buy back inefficient or polluting prod-
ucts. Examples include water trading and water
quality trading.
•	 Information provision – mechanisms that use
the provision and disclosure of information on envi-
ronmental performance to incentivize producers to
reduce their water use or emissions of pollutants,
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT8
As shown in Figure 1, these instruments exist along a
continuum, from “very strict command approaches to
decentralized approaches that rely more on market or
legal mechanisms” (Huber et al., 1998). As noted, there
are varying definitions of incentive-based instruments
and the types of tools that would qualify. All definitions
identify price-based instruments and market creation
as incentive-based instruments. Some, however, use a
broader definition that includes information provision,
voluntary action, and liability instruments (see, e.g.
Stavins, 2001; UNEP, 2001; Anderson, 2004). Product
labeling schemes, such as the United States’ “Energy
Star” or Thailand’s “Green Label”, allow companies
meeting environmental standards to place a recog-
nized label on their product, boosting sales by making
the product more appealing to consumers and provid-
ing a financial incentive to improve environmental per-
formance (Stavins, 2001). These products may also be
sold at a higher price than less environmentally-friendly
or to incentivize consumers to select products with
superior performance. Examples include corporate
reporting, product labeling (e.g. WaterSense),6 and
environmental certification schemes.
•	 Voluntary action – mechanisms that use volun-
tary agreements between the government and pri-
vate firms and/or commitments made independent
of government requirement. Examples include the
UN CEO Water Mandate and the Alliance for Wa-
ter Stewardship’s International Water Stewardship
Standard.
•	 Legal instruments – mechanisms for compen-
sating victims when pollution causes human or
environmental harm, and encouraging compliance
with existing environmental regulations. Examples
include criminal penalties, civil liability statutes, and
performance bonds.
6	 WaterSense is an environmental program designed to encourage water
efficiency in the US, through use of a special label on consumer products.
FIGURE 1. Incentive-based policy instruments
WATER MANAGEMENT EXAMPLES:
Regulations
and sanctions Price based
Market
creation
Information
provision
Voluntary
action Legal
Pollution
standards
Cost recovery
tariffs
Water quality
trading
Eco-labels UN CEO Water
Mandate
Criminal
penalties
Water use
quotas
Pollution taxes Water trading Corporate
reporting
AWS Interna-
tional Water
Stewardship
Standard
Performance
bonds
Building codes Payment for
watershed
services
Environmental
certification
Civil liability
statutes
Source: adapted from Huber et al., 1998; UNEP, 2009.
REGULATIONS
AND SANCTIONS
PRICE BASED MARKET
CREATION
INFORMATION
PROVISION
VOLUNTARY
ACTION
LEGAL
Less flexibility
Maximum government
involvement
Control oriented
More flexibility
Increased private
initiative
Litigation oriented
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 9
of this activity ($11.6 billion, or 94 percent) was associ-
ated with payment for watershed services, and 98 per-
cent of that activity was in China. Collective action
funds – which pool contributions from multiple inves-
tors to support coordinated interventions within a
watershed – had the second highest transaction value
at $563 million. We note, however, that the distinction
between payment for watershed and collective action
programs is sometimes unclear.9 The market activity of
instream buybacks – programs that purchase or lease
water to augment instream flows – was considerably
less ($97 million), followed by water quality trading
($22 million), and voluntary compensation ($320,000).
It is of note that instream buybacks likely represent a
modest fraction of the market activity of water trading
programs, although comprehensive data on the latter
are not readily available.10 While the data suggest a
rapid expansion in the application of these instruments
since 2008, Ecosystem Marketplace’s Genevieve
Bennett (personal communication, 2015) noted that
much of the increase is actually an outcome of better
reporting.
9	 Water funds are sometimes categorized as payment for watershed
services and other times as collective action funds.
10	 California, for example, has an active trading market but no centralized
repository of data on the number and value of transactions.
models. Likewise, voluntary programs may reward
meeting environmental outcomes with, e.g. public rec-
ognition which, in turn, increases sales.
The application and market activity of these instruments
are not well understood. Several organizations track the
application of some of these incentive-based instru-
ments (IIED, 2015 and Forest Trends, 2015a).7 However,
there is no comprehensive list of the programs that have
been implemented globally. Additionally, programs are
sometimes poorly defined, fall into multiple categories, or
change over time. Moreover, data on the activity of these
instruments, including the number and value of transac-
tions, are not collected or made available publicly.
Despite these challenges, Forest Trends has been track-
ing the activity of five market and market-like instru-
ments for watershed investments for several years.8 It
estimates that the market activity of watershed invest-
ments was $12.3 billion in 2013 (Table 1). The majority
7	 See, for example, Watershed Markets (watershedmarkets.org), main-
tained by the London-based International Institute for Environment and
Development, and Watershed Connect (watershedconnect.com), an on-
line platform maintained by the Washington, D.C.-based Forest Trends.
8	 Forest Trends is an international “non-profit organization with three
principal roles: convening market players to advance market transfor-
mations, generating and disseminating critical information to market
players, and facilitating deals between different critical links in the value
chains of new forestry.” See forest-trends.org.
TABLE 1. Transactions (in millions of US$) by type, 2008–2013
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Payment for watershed
services/undefined
$ 7,950 $ 6,950 $ 7,470 $ 8,000 $ 9,600 $11,600
Collective action funds n/a n/a n/a n/a $ 137 $ 563
Voluntary compensation n/a n/a n/a n/a $ 0.230 $ 0.320
Water quality trading $ 10.7 $ 8.30 $ 8.30 $ 7.70 $ 14.9 $ 22.2
Instream buybacks n/a $ 19 $ 390 $ 164 $ 144 $ 97.0
Total $ 7,960 $ 6,980 $ 7,870 $ 8,170 $ 9,890 $ 12,300
Note: Numbers shown are nominal values. All values rounded to three significant figures. Numbers may not add up due to rounding. Based on data provided by Bennett
(personal communication, 2015) and included in Bennett and Carroll (2014).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT10
side of a recognized legal or administrative frame-
work (e.g. the sale of groundwater to an adjacent
irrigator)
•	 water banks – the institutions or agencies that i)
broker or otherwise facilitate water trading (Culp et
al.,2014)orii)areestablishedforaspecificobjective,
such as a trust created to obtain water rights for in-
stream augmentation (Clifford, 2012). Water banks
offer expertise and information for improving com-
munication between buyers and sellers, and often
provide a centralized repository or clearinghouse of
information on current and historical transactions,
including volumes, pricing, and locations.
There is an extensive body of literature suggest-
ing that water trading provides a mechanism to
improve the economic efficiency of water through its
reallocation from lower to higher value uses (Glennon,
2005; Dellapenna, 2000; Bjornlund and McKay, 2002).
The germinal study entitled Water and Choice in the
Colorado Basin (NRC, 1968) recommended that water
in the western United States be transferred from irriga-
tion, which generates relatively low returns per unit of
water, to high-value non-agricultural uses. More recent
researchhascontinuedtoemphasizethepotentialvalue
created by water transfers. For example, models used to
project California’s economic costs under a dry climate
change projection, (Medellín-Azuara et al., 2008) found
significantly increased benefits with market-based real-
locations. Newlin et al. (2002) and Jenkins et al. (2004)
asserted that water trading could dramatically reduce
Southern California’s water scarcity costs.
Water trading is attractive because it tends to minimize
the impact on existing rights holders by providing com-
pensation and, in many cases, additional security, for
existing water rights, while providing opportunities to
those with new or increasing demands (NRC, 1992).
A large number of experts challenge the applicability
and efficacy of water trading. Freyfogle (1996) asserted
that externalities, intrinsic to the very nature of water
itself, pose such an insurmountable obstacle that water
trading does not and cannot work. Many of these
In this review, we evaluate three of the major incentive-
based instruments that have been employed to improve
water management: water trading, payment for ecosys-
tem services, and water quality trading. These instru-
ments are employed in developed and developing
countries, and there is growing interest in expanding
their application.
3.1 Water trading
Description
Water trading is perhaps the best known and most
widely used method of reallocating water. In some
cases, purchasing or leasing water from existing users
has proven to be less expensive, more flexible, and
less time-consuming than developing new water sup-
plies, such as constructing new diversion structures
or desalination plants. Similarly, water trading is gen-
erally a more accepted method for reallocating water
than state appropriation or condemnation of existing
water rights. Successful examples of water trading in
Australia and other locations – combined with classic
economic theory suggesting that market mechanisms
can optimize resource allocation – have heightened
interest in this instrument in both academic literature
and popular media.
As noted in Box 1, the peer-reviewed and gray litera-
ture employ several terms (e.g. water transfers, water
markets, and water banks) to refer to a variety of some-
times overlapping instruments and methods for con-
veying and reallocating water. In this paper, we use the
following terms:
•	 water trading – the temporary or permanent
transfer of the right to use water in exchange for
some form of compensation
•	 informal water trading – the sale of a specified
volume of water for a limited period of time, which
does not involve actual contracts or occurs out-
“…water trading provides a mechanism to
improve the economic efficiency of water…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 11
tradeable commodity. Similarly, Zellmer and Harder
(2007) asserted, “Water is a uniquely essential resource
with uniquely public attributes,” unlike other resources
typically treated as property. Questions of externali-
ties, commodification, and the special nature of water
itself highlight the challenges faced by implementing
or expanding water trading.
In some cases, water trading is effectively zero-sum,
simply shifting water use and economic productivity
from one area or sector to another. In other cases, it can
externalities arise from the physical properties of water:
it is heavy, unwieldy, and easily contaminated; it some-
timeshasdramaticseasonalandyear-to-yearvariability;
and it can be easily lost through evaporation, seepage,
or runoff (Salzman, 2006). Further, these externalities
may be borne by disparate parties, such as the envi-
ronment or future generations, challenging efforts to
compensate those injured by trading (Freyfogle, 1996).
Moreover, Salzman (2006) argued that custom, history,
and religion in many parts of the world treat drinking
water as a common property resource, rather than a
BOX 1
A note on terminology
Water transfers. The National Research Council
(NRC) of the United States National Academies defines
water transfers as changes in the point of diversion,
type of use, or location of water use (NRC et al., 1992).
The term “water transfers” encompasses a broad range
of market-based and non-market water reallocation
mechanisms of varying periods, geographic scales,
and arrangements. Water transfers can range from
short-term leases or conditional arrangements to the
permanent transfer (i.e. sale) of a water right. They
can range in scale from i) change in type of use on
an existing parcel of land, such as when a water right
shifts from irrigation to municipal use when agricultural
land is purchased and converted to housing, to ii)
inter-basin transfers, such as when a city purchases or
leases water from a different watershed.
Water bank. A water bank is a mechanism for
changing the time or location of water use. Water
banking, as with water transfers, can refer to market-
based or non-market activities. The term “water bank”
can refer to an actual institution or to the physical
storage of water. Water banks as institutions may
function as i) brokers that connect buyers and sellers
of water rights or leases, providing an important
communication function; ii) clearinghouses that
directly purchase or lease water from willing sellers
and aggregate supplies for subsequent sale to other
buyers; iii) facilitators that expedite water transfers
using existing storage or conveyance facilities (Culp et
al., 2014); or iv) trusts that hold or otherwise manage
water rights or entitlements for a specific purpose,
such as streamflow augmentation (O’Donnell and
Colby, 2010). When serving as facilitators, water banks
may perform various administrative and technical
functions, including the confirmation of water rights
and screening of potential buyers (Clifford, 2012).
Water banks may also refer to physical storage, either
in surface reservoirs or in aquifers, which, in turn, may
be a component of a larger water transfer or simply
a mechanism enabling an entitlement holder to store
water for its own future use, but we do not use this
definition in this review.
Water market. The term water market refers to a
range of different market-based practices, typically
referring to water trading. According to Brown (2006),
the term water market lacks a precise definition, “but
once a few voluntary trades of water of relatively
common physical and legal characteristics occur, it is
said that a water market exists.” A water market may
also refer to informal transactions involving the direct
sale of water that does not involve the lease or sale of
water rights. Informal water transactions can include
purchasing bottled water or water from a tanker truck,
a common practice in many parts of the developing
world that lack a reliable, piped water supply. While
a “water contract” can refer to a one-time voluntary
water exchange between two actors, a water market
is where many actors come together and make trades;
a market also includes some formalization of the
transactions (Brown et al., 2015).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT12
Application
Water trading exists, to varying degrees, in countries
around the world. When Grafton et al. (2010) assessed
water trading in two wealthy countries (Australia and
theUnitedStates),twolow-tomiddle-incomecountries
(Chile and South Africa), and one poor, rapidly develop-
ing country (China), they found that differing levels of
information availability, legal rights structures, institu-
tional constraints, and management goals had resulted
in very different levels of activity and performance.
ThemostactivewatertradingmarketsoccurinAustralia
and the western United States. Within Australia, water
trading includes both short-term trades (referred to as
allocation trading) and long-term trades (referred to as
entitlement trading). The total value of water trading
in Australia in fiscal year 2012–13 exceeded $1.4 billion
increase system-wide water efficiency, by providing the
area of origin with funds for investing in improved effi-
ciency, maintaining local productivity with lower water
use, and then transferring the conserved water. Water
can be made available for trading from a variety of
activities, including fallowing fields, crop shifting, and
in some cases, a shift from surface water diversions to
groundwater pumping. Water trades can also be linked
to water conservation and efficiency efforts, including
increasing irrigation efficiency and decreasing system
losses that generate surplus water by, e.g. lining canals
or constructing operating reservoirs. However, increas-
ing demand for greater efficiencies in irrigation can
challengetheflexibilityofexistinginstitutions(Hundley,
2001), such as irrigation districts and water courts,
which often do not recognize a legal property right to
this “new” water created by conservation or efficiency.
Additionally, existing institutions often impose signifi-
cantcostsonthoseattemptingtodedicatewatertonon-
traditional uses such as instream flows (Getches, 1985).
These changes have tested the resilience of water insti-
tutions, which have shown some flexibility in adapting
to new values and goals but often impose high transac-
tion costs (Colby et al., 1991).
Water trading can occur within sectors, from agricul-
ture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban, across these
sectors, and, less frequently, from either of these to the
environment (Brewer et al., 2007). Figure 2, from the
California Department of Water Resources, shows the
relative proportions of water trading within and between
differentsectors.Althoughwatertradingisoftenconsid-
ered a means to move water from agriculture to urban
uses, nearly three-quarters of the 270,000 acre-feet
of water traded in California in 2013 occurred between
agricultural users. Interestingly, nearly 25,000 acre-
feet of water were traded from municipal and industrial
(MI) uses to agriculture, which was nearly half of the
volume of water traded from agriculture to MI uses.
FIGURE 2. Non-project water transfers within the
Sacramento-San Joaquin watersheds in 2013
Note: Ag – agriculture; FW – fish and wildlife; MI – municipal and industrial;
AF – acre-foot.
Source: California Department of Water Resources.
Ag to Ag
Ag to MI
Ag to FW
MI to Ag9%
(24,577 AF)
TOTAL: 268,370 AF
1%
(1,500 AF)
18%
(49,639 AF)
72%
(192,655 AF)
“The most active water trading markets
occur in Australia and the western United
States.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 13
reports almost 640,000 acre-feet of water traded in
California, through 36 trades with a total value of about
$234 million (all values adjusted to 2014$). More than
80 percent of the water was leased rather than sold.
According to the database, 15 of these trades, account-
ing for about 88,000 acre-feet of total volume, occurred
within one agricultural district. However, the Bren
School database only records the initial year a water
trade is reported, and thus does not reflect the volume
of multiyear trading agreements. That means that a
review of 2009 trading activity does not reflect previ-
ous multi-year trades that may still have been active in
2009, so the values reported above understate trading
activity in 2009.
A comprehensive review of water trading in California
reports about 1.5 MAF of water were traded in 2009,
a dry year (Hanak and Stryjewski, 2012). Volumes
reported for 2011, a wet year and the most recent year
for which data are available, were about 5 percent lower,
at 1.4 MAF. In 2011, 42 percent of the water traded went
to municipal and industrial users, 37 percent to agricul-
tural users, 17 percent for environmental purposes, and
the remainder to mixed uses. Because of limited data,
the study does not include trading activity within irri-
gation districts or similar users associations, although
some estimates suggest that such intra-district activity
accounted for several hundred thousand acre-feet of
water, a third of total water supplies within some of the
larger irrigation districts. Hanak and Stryjewski (2012)
did not provide total dollar values associated with the
California water market, though they noted that prices
of temporary water transfers had increased from an
average of $30–$40 per acre-foot in one region in the
mid-1990s to $180 per acre-foot in 2011, while aver-
age prices in another basin rose to an average of $400
per acre-foot. The authors noted the shifting trend
from short-term to longer-term leases and permanent
trades, pumping restrictions in the Bay-Delta, and ris-
ing transaction costs that had slowed market activity in
the past decade.
California is also home to the largest United States
water trade to date. The San Diego County Water
Authority (SDCWA) entered into a 45-year contract
(NWC, 2013). Trading within the Murray-Darling Basin,
which has an active and well-documented water mar-
ket first established more than 30 years ago (Grafton
et al., 2012), accounts for 98 percent of all allocation
trades and 78 percent of all entitlement trades within
Australia, by volume. Indeed, the Murray-Darling Basin
figures prominently in discussions about water trad-
ing, as an example of a thriving incentive-based sys-
tem that successfully transitioned from a non-market
system (Grafton et al., 2012). In fiscal year 2012–13, the
total volume of short-term (allocation) trading within
the Murray-Darling Basin increased 44  percent from
the previous year, from almost 3.5  million acre-feet
(MAF) to 5 MAF, or about 50 percent of total surface
water use in the basin. The total volume of long-term
trades, however, decreased by about 14 percent over
that period, to about 0.85 MAF. A national study found
that these permanent entitlement trades often offset
the temporary allocation trades, as irrigators planting
perennial crops, such as grapes or almonds, purchased
entitlements to meet expected future demand, but then
sold a portion of the temporary allocations associated
with these entitlements to generate revenue (Frontier
Economics and Australia National Water Commission,
2007). For more information on Australia’s water mar-
ket, see Annex 2.
In the western United States, the scale of water trad-
ing is considerably lower. A database compiled by the
University of California Santa Barbara (UCSB) Bren
School shows notifications for more than 4,000 water
trades in 12 states in the western United States from
the years 1987–2008.11 Brewer et al. (2007) docu-
mented the large variability in the volume, price, and
duration of water trades in the western United States,
both within and between sectors. In 2009, the most
recent year for which data are available, the database
11	 The database summary notes that “The data are drawn from water trans-
actions reported in the monthly trade journal the Water Strategist and its
predecessor the Water Intelligence Monthly from 1987 through February
2010.” These data reflect published reports that in some cases do not
reflect final transfer agreements. For example, the database reports that
the Imperial Irrigation District-San Diego County Water Authority water
transfer began in 1997, although the final transfer agreement was not
actually signed and the transfer did not begin (at different volumes than
the database reports) until October 2003. The Bren School water transfer
database is available at bren.ucsb.edu/news/water_transfers.htm.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT14
in several parts of the country (Thobani, 1997), with
nearly 3,700 registered water transfer requests in 2006
alone (CONAGUA, 2012).
Water markets have also been established in parts of
Europe, Asia, and Africa. In Spain, informal trades, sales,
and short-term exchanges of water are common, while
formal transfers of long-term water rights are generally
limited to groundwater (Albiac et al., 2006). In Spain’s
Alicante basin, several irrigation districts auction their
annual water allocations to district farmers (Albiac et
al., 2006), creating a strong incentive to improve water-
use efficiency and shift toward higher value crops.
England has encouraged water trading for more than a
decade, although only about 60 trades have occurred
to date (TWSTT, 2014).
South Africa has more extensive water markets that
continue to be plagued by conflict and inadequate
institutional support (Grafton et al., 2010). South
Africa’s Water Act of 1998 has provided a framework
for water trading. Historically, agricultural irrigators
traded water rights within their sector, mediated by
the national Department of Water Affairs and Forestry
(Farolfi and Perret, 2002). In 2001, mining companies
seeking to expand operations in northern South Africa
successfully negotiated a temporary trade of some
10,000 acre-feet of water (13 million m3
) from neigh-
boring farmers – representing more than 70 percent of
their annual allocation – in exchange for the current
equivalent of about $1 million. These funds, used to
help rehabilitate the local irrigation infrastructure, rep-
resented less than 0.1 percent of the mines’ develop-
ment costs, reflecting a significant economic disparity
between the two interests (Farolfi and Perret, 2002).
In Asia, India and Pakistan have informal water trad-
ing, in which well-owners may sell some of the water
they extract to neighboring farms or residents (Easter
et al., 1999). In a report published by the Nepal Water
Conservation Foundation and the Institute for Social
in 2003, with an option for a 30-year extension, with
the Imperial Irrigation District (IID), one of the largest
irrigation districts in the country.12 Under the terms of
the agreement, the SDCWA pays the IID to reduce its
diversion of Colorado River water, while the Authority
diverts a like amount farther upstream. After a 15-year
period intended to create time to address ecological
and public health impacts resulting from the trade, the
IID will shift to efficiency-based methods (such as lin-
ing canals and constructing regulating reservoirs) to
generate the water to be conserved. In essence, the
Authority is paying the District to improve the effi-
ciency of its operations and receiving the water con-
served. The trade is ramping up to a maximum volume
of 200,000 acre-feet per year by 2021, representing
about 25 percent of the region’s total water supply. In
2014, the price for the water was $594 per acre-foot,
plus an additional $445 per acre-foot to a different
agency to convey the water through its facilities. This
total, which does not include additional payments to
offset the environmental impacts of the trade, is about
half what the Authority has contracted to pay for water
generated by a new desalination plant on the coast.
In Central and South America, Chile and Mexico
have active water trading markets. Chile’s Limarí
Basin enjoys water rights trading and water transfers,
enabled by three large state-built reservoirs and robust
local water organizations. The actual number of water
trades in Chile’s Limarí Basin has averaged about 33
each year (Romano and Leporati, 2002), although
water trading has been more limited in the rest of the
country (Bauer, 1997). Mexico’s National Water Law of
1992 established a formal water market with tradable
concessions that formed the basis for active markets
12	 With the exception of “water conservancy districts”, to the best of our
knowledge there is no strict naming convention for water agencies. The
ability to create conservancy districts is established by statute, enabling
state district courts or other authorities to establish conservancy
districts with the power to impose property taxes to support district
functions (Howe, 2011). Water authorities tend to serve municipal areas,
and irrigation districts primarily serve agricultural users. However, the
San Diego County Water Authority has agricultural customers (fewer
than before, as they have phased out subsidies for irrigation water),
while the Imperial Irrigation District sells water to all of the cities within
its service area, serving more than 170,000 people. Similarly, water
conservancy districts usually serve agriculture, although some districts
may also serve municipal customers.
“Water banks are generally less widespread
than water trading…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 15
In 2003, nine states in the western United States had
functioning state-operated water banks, although their
level of activity varied dramatically and several are no
longer active. From 1995–2003, for example, Texas’
water bank only reported one transaction (Clifford, 2012).
California’s Drought Water Bank functioned for a limited
period in the early 1990s, providing a mechanism to facil-
itate and expedite water trading between agriculture and
cities during a multi-year drought, while also ensuring
minimum instream flows and providing limited ground-
water recharge. The Drought Water Bank purchased,
held, and sold water, primarily from northern agricultural
users to southern municipal and industrial users, though
about half of the more than 800,000 acre-feet pur-
chased in 1991 was dedicated to instream flows (20 per-
cent) and to recharge aquifers (32 percent) (Dinar et al.,
1997). Idaho operates water banks to manage storage
in reservoirs, and in Oregon, river conservancies oper-
ate as water trusts to purchase or lease water rights to
supplement instream flows (Clifford, 2012). The Northern
Colorado Water Conservancy District maintains a web-
page that functions as an online bulletin board connect-
ing those seeking to acquire water with those who have
water to rent, an example of a brokerage-type water
bank. The very active water trading within the Conser-
vancy District is attributable to the equal volume and
priority of each share available for trade, the absence
of any requirement to preserve return flows or protect
downstream or junior priority users, and the fact that
trading only requires the approval of the district itself,
not a water court, as is the case for most other trades
within Colorado (Howe and Goemans, 2003).
The Colorado River basin, shown in Figure 3, boasts a
large number of creative approaches to water bank-
ing. In 1998, the federal government adopted a new
rule permitting interstate banking agreements within
the basin. To date, Arizona has diverted and stored
more than 600,000 acre-feet of Colorado River water
for southern Nevada, and a southern California water
agency has diverted and stored more than 161,000
acre-feet for southern Nevada, representing creative
methods of skirting state prohibitions of interstate
water trading. In 2007, the seven basin states adopted
a new set of rules for managing the river that, among
and Environmental Transition, Moench et al. (2003)
described an active but largely unregulated water trad-
ing system in Chennai, India, where private companies
meet as much as 35 percent of urban water demand
by delivering raw or purified well water purchased
from farmers in surrounding areas or extracted from
the companies’ wells. This private sector engagement
helps meet a demand for water that the intermittent
municipal water supply cannot meet, though the price
is much higher. Moench et al. (2003) reported that the
price of water for urban customers can be 1,000 times
higher than the price paid to the peri-urban farmers
supplying the water. Also in Asia, in a rare international
water trade, the Bishkek Treaty of 1998 commit-
ted Kyrgyzstan to deliver water via the Syr Darya to
Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan in exchange for compen-
sation (Ambec et al., 2013). China reportedly has small,
local water markets (Grafton et al., 2010). In Oman,
the local falaj irrigation systems purchase short-term
allocations of water based on units of time rather than
volume (e.g. a certain duration of water delivery) in a
village-based auction (Al-Marshudi, 2007).
Water banks are generally less widespread than water
trading because they require additional expertise, fund-
ing, and governance structures. Water banks appear
to be most prevalent in the western United States,
although there are examples in several other coun-
tries. The presence of three reservoirs in Chile’s Limarí
Basin facilitates the large number of water trades in
the region (Bauer, 1997), meaning that, in this case,
the physical storage rather than an institutional bank
facilitates the water trades. In Australia, brokerage-type
water banks are active in both the Murray-Darling Basin
and in northern Victoria, where the banks post informa-
tion about pricing and availability (O’Donnell and Colby,
2010). Mexico’s National Water Commission reported
that the 13 state-based water banks in the country bro-
ker thousands of water trades annually (CONAGUA,
2012). In three basins in Spain, water banks operated
by local water agencies, known as “exchange centers”,
have successfully brokered water trades that have
lessened groundwater overdraft (Garrido and Llamas,
2009).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT16
system as a whole, rather than claiming it for them-
selves. In this instance, the Bureau of Reclamation acts
as a water bank by obtaining water through a reverse
auction process, augmenting system storage for the
benefit of the system as a whole.
Environmental, economic, and social
performance
The primary goal of water trading is usually to pro-
mote economic efficiency by reallocating water from
lower to higher value uses. However, in some cases,
other key developments, permitted entitlement hold-
ers in Arizona, California, and Nevada to invest in vari-
ous water efficiency projects within their own states
and store a percentage of the conserved water in
Lake Mead for later use. To date, more than 1.1 million
acre-feet have been stored in Lake Mead under this
new program. More recently, four large municipal water
agencies in the basin, in cooperation with the federal
Bureau of Reclamation, agreed to invest $11 million in
fallowing and efficiency improvements, and to dedi-
cate the conserved water to the Colorado River Basin
FIGURE 3. The Colorado River Basin
Source: Cohen et al., 2013.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 17
can be an effective means of reallocating water, where
the appropriate conditions exist. The application sec-
tion of 3.1 of this report describes the range of countries
where water trading occurs in general terms. In most of
these regions, limited data precludes detailed assess-
ment of the number or volume of water trading activi-
ties. In several locations, such as the Murray-Darling
Basin and the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy
District, water trades occur frequently, often for small
volumes, suggesting a robust and active market with
low transaction costs (Howe and Goemans, 2003). In
other areas, there tend to be fewer but larger transac-
tions, suggesting higher barriers to trading.
The largest agriculture-to-urban water trade in the
United States has been successful for San Diego
County, which currently receives about 25 percent of
its water supply from the rural Imperial Valley,13 at a
unit cost of water that is less than half the contracted
price of water from a desalination plant that will soon
be operational on the San Diego coastline. The long-
term water trade appears to be cost effective from San
Diego’s perspective but, due to significant externalities,
maynotbefromthebroadersociety’sperspective.Total
transaction costs for this water trade have exceeded
$175 million in attorney fees, plus an additional $171 mil-
lion in mitigation fees to offset public health and envi-
ronmental impacts. In addition, the State of California
agreed to cover all direct mitigation costs in excess
of a pre-determined financial cap for the water trade
parties. The magnitude of these additional mitigation
costs – primarily for managing dust emissions – will not
be known for many years but are expected to run into
the hundreds of millions of dollars (Cohen, 2014). As
suggested by the Imperial Valley-San Diego example,
a narrow focus on direct economic performance may
ignore trading’s broader economic impacts.
Although there are thousands of peer-reviewed
articles on the economic potential of water trading,
robust economic analyses of specific water trades do
13	 Roughly 15 percent of San Diego County’s current water supply comes
from the water trade with the Imperial Valley, while an additional 10 per-
cent comes from water conserved via the lining of the All-American
Canal, a project funded primarily by the state of California.
water trading has been used for environmental or rec-
reational purposes, reflecting the increasing societal
value ascribed to instream flows. In this section, we
evaluate the environmental, social, and economic per-
formance of water trading. While much of the literature
on water trading tends toward theoretical assessments
or recommendations about trading (Newlin et al., 2002)
or specific elements of trading, such as property rights
regimes or institutional capacity (Culp et al., 2014), we
examine the literature on actual impacts to evaluate
the state of practice.
ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Although there are a large number of articles and stud-
ies modeling the potential economic benefits of water
trading, the number of detailed economic assessments
of existing water trades is surprisingly limited. Some
studies on local impacts suggest positive net economic
performance,butthesestudiestypicallydonotdescribe
changes in the distribution of impacts, and they rarely
describe broader economic impacts. Assessing the
economic performance of water trading is frequently
as simple as documenting trading activity and quanti-
fying the number, volume, and value of reported water
trades. A more comprehensive analysis would require
surveys to estimate the number and volume of addi-
tional water trades that users would like to make, as a
means to assess the disparity between availability and
demand. An even more robust analysis would compare
the ability of different instruments – such as water trad-
ing, demand-side management, and supply augmenta-
tion – to meet specific water demands, and the cost
of those instruments. While water agencies seeking to
improve their water supply reliability may perform such
analyses within their service area, these assessments
are often not publicly available.
The large number of trades and the significant volumes
traded,especiallyinAustralia,indicatethatwatertrading
“…the number of detailed economic
assessments of existing water trades is
surprisingly limited.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT18
the trading activity in the district is short term and low
volume, especially in comparison with trading activ-
ity in the same water basin but outside of the district.
Municipal and industrial (MI) users buy district water
rights to meet expected future demand and then lease
some of this water back to district irrigators. This ris-
ing MI demand has increased the price of imported
water rights (known as allotments) within the district
(Howe, 2011). Within the relatively prosperous district,
this has improved economic performance. However, in
other regions, particularly in economically depressed
rural areas, selling water out of the area has exacer-
bated economic decline, causing property values to fall
and the local tax base to shrink (Howe, 2011).
In Australia, water trading has enabled the expan-
sion of the wine industry and other high value crops,
such as almonds. Over time, the dairy industry in one
part of the Murray-Darling Basin transitioned from a
small purchaser of water entitlements to a net seller of
entitlements, primarily to the expanding wine and nut
producers in other parts of the basin. These expanding
industries have also exhibited a shift from the former
model of shared irrigation infrastructure (such as com-
mon canals) to direct extraction from the river by indi-
vidual irrigators – in other words, from a communal to a
more flexible individual approach to irrigation (Frontier
Economics and Australia NWC, 2007).
Water trading within the Murray-Darling Basin grew
and matured within the context of the devastating
drought that afflicted the region from 2006 through
2010. The national water trading assessment noted
the challenge of disentangling the economic impacts
of the drought from those of water trading itself, gen-
erally concluding that trading offered irrigators an
additional revenue stream, plus additional flexibility
and resilience within the face of a severely limited
water supply. Without water trading, some sectors,
such as the dairy industry, would have seen even
greater losses. Trading also offered a mechanism to
adjust for historic water apportionments, facilitating
the voluntary sale of water from less productive to
more productive lands and uses (Frontier Economics
and Australia NWC, 2007).
not appear to exist. For example, despite its size and
importance, there do not appear to be any economic
analyses of the Imperial Valley-San Diego County
water trade that assess revenues, agricultural produc-
tion lost due to fallowing, value of transfer payments,
relative value of the water in San Diego, or employ-
ment impacts. There are, however, general regional or
district-level assessments of water trading, as well as
an extensive body of literature on macro-economic
trends, and expected or modeled benefits of water
trading. Yet, assessments of “net” economic benefit at
the state or regional level, expressed in terms of net
increase in employment or revenue, can mask dispari-
ties between areas of origin and importing areas, and
even within the areas of origin themselves.
In one study, the income and employment gains found
in regions in California that imported water via trades
exceeded the net losses (total compensation often
failed to cover foregone crop revenue) in exporting
areas (Howitt, 1998). In 1991, trading activity gener-
ated an average net income loss in water-exporting
areas equivalent to about 5 percent of net agricultural
activity, though this varied within different parts of the
state. However, agricultural areas importing water saw
total gains greater than the losses in exporting areas:
net agricultural water trading activity was positive, as
water moved from lower-value crops to higher-value
crops (Howitt, 1998). In another example, an agricul-
tural community in California exporting water to urban
areas saw a 26  percent decrease in the number of
farms overall, but this masked a 70 percent loss in the
number of small farms and the loss of almost half of
the number of produce firms in the area (Meinzen-Dick
and Pradhan, 2005).
The Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District,
introduced in Section 3.1, has a very active water mar-
ket in part because of low transaction costs. Much of
“In Australia, water trading has enabled the
expansion of the wine industry and other
high value crops, such as almonds.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 19
community support, especially relative to regulatory
takings. However, water trading can also generate large
environmental externalities, adversely affecting either
natural habitats or downstream users, or both (NRC,
1992). For example, when water for trading is generated
by efficiency or by fallowing land, the trade may reduce
the amount of runoff supporting local habitat and may
diminish instream flows.14 On the other hand, some
water trades may improve local instream flows by de-
creasing diversions and contaminant loadings. Where
water is traded to downstream users using the existing
stream as a conveyance, trading could offer measur-
able environmental benefits. Where water is traded out
of the basin or alters the timing and magnitude of flows,
adverse impacts are likely to occur. Unfortunately, there
do not appear to be published assessments of the rela-
tive impacts of water trading on streamflow.15 In the fol-
lowing, we discuss the environmental performance of
several examples of water trading.
Water trading is now used in some areas to return water
to river channels, in order to support listed species or
threatened habitats, and for general ecosystem restora-
tion (Tarlock, 2014). However in most areas, such activ-
ity still represents only a tiny fraction of total water use in
any given area.16 For example, the Colorado Water Trust
(CWT) brokered a lease agreement between two state
14	 In efficiency-based agricultural water trades, the buyer typically pays
the irrigator to install more efficient irrigation equipment or methods,
such as hiring additional irrigation management staff, installing pump-
back systems, lining canals, or constructing new regulatory reservoirs.
The water conserved by these new practices would then be available for
transfer to the buyer/investor. Efficiency-based trades keep agricultural
land in production and can increase total employment in the area of
origin, but they require additional monitoring and measurement to doc-
ument or calculate the volume of water conserved. In fallowing-based
trades, also known as “buy-and-dry”, the buyer simply pays the irrigator
not to irrigate and, in exchange, receives the volume of water historically
used by the parcel. This requires less effort and less time to implement,
but takes land out of production and typically generates significant
adverse impacts on rural communities.
15	 For example, the various water trading agreements between Imperi-
al Valley and urban Southern California will have the direct effect of
reducing the volume of water flowing down the lower Colorado River
between Parker Dam – the new diversion point – and Imperial Dam,
about 150 river miles downstream, by more than 300,000 acre-feet per
year, equivalent to roughly 5 percent of the historic average annual flow
between these two diversion points.
16	 Such instream flows typically require additional legal conditions, such
as explicit recognition of instream flow rights, improved monitoring and
measurement, and the acceptance of local entitlement holders.
The active participation of the Australian government
in water trading increased prices and participation but
may also have increased total water use within the
basin. A large survey (n=520) of those selling entitle-
ments or allocations to the Australian environmental
water program found that sellers believed they received
a higher price from the government than they would
have from other private agents, or that the government
was the only purchaser in the market. The survey also
found that sellers reportedly used 69 to 77 percent of
their water allocations prior to trading it to the govern-
ment (Wheeler and Cheesman, 2013). That is, survey
respondents reported selling portions of their alloca-
tions that they would not have used otherwise. Selling
unused water allocations is not a reallocation so much
as an expansion of total water use.
Water trading occurs in a variety of forms. Howe (2011)
noted that, in practice, many water trades reflect a
change in type of use rather than a change in loca-
tion. For example, in the Northern Colorado Water
Conservancy District, developers have purchased
farmland and its water rights and then converted the
land and water to residential or commercial use, often
generating a significant increase in revenue per unit
of water while limiting some of the social and environ-
mental externalities that would occur if the water were
physically moved to a different location.
ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE
Water trading has been used as a mechanism to obtain
water for ecological purposes, to augment streamflows,
and to address water quality concerns (such as tem-
perature) in threatened reaches. The environmental
performance of water trading is highly variable, de-
pending on the type of trade and site-specific condi-
tions. The benefits of voluntary, incentive-based water
acquisition include ease of transaction and greater
“Water trading can also generate large
environmental externalities, adversely
affecting either natural habitats or
downstream users, or both”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT20
trading activity between 1982 and 2011, but less than
0.5 percent of total water use in the state (Figure 4).
In Australia, the federal government has invested more
than $3 billion to date to purchase entitlements and
allocations for environmental water, protecting eco-
logical resources to enable and expedite water trading
between non-governmental users. In 2008–2009, for
example, the government purchased nearly 880,000
acre-feet of long-term water entitlements and 1.4 mil-
lion acre-feet of short-term allocations, at a total cost of
about $2 billion (adjusted to 2014$). The price for this
water ranged from about $269 to $377 per acre-foot.
Local interest in this environmental water buyback
program, known as “Restoring the Balance”, has been
strong, with the Australian government receiving nearly
7,600 applications to sell water from 2007 to early 2012.
Water entitlement sales for the environment account
agencies, increasing low-season flows in the White River
by 3,000 acre-feet of water three times over a 10-year
period to lower the temperature of river flows and, in
turn, benefit fish (CWT, 2015). Similarly, the Columbia
Basin Water Transactions Program, active for more than
a decade, works with partner organizations in four west-
ern states to acquire and dedicate water for instream
flows within the basin. In 2013, 45 transactions led to the
acquisition of more than 48,000 acre-feet of water, cost-
ing about $13.9 million and benefiting some 276 miles of
streams, the fish and wildlife, and the communities that
depend on them (National Fish and Wildlife Foundation,
2014). Bonneville Power Administration, in cooperation
with the Northwest Power and Conservation Council,
provides some of the funding for the program due,
in part, to concerns about endangered species. In
California, environmental water purchases averaged
152,000 acre-feet, accounting for about 14 percent of
FIGURE 4. Water purchases for the environment in California, 1982–2011
Source: Hanak and Stryjewski, 2012.
1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009
500
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
WaterPurchases(1,000acre-feet)
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 21
resulting in the loss of open water and wetland habitats
that support several hundred species of birds (Cohen
and Hyun, 2006).
Yet water trading occurs in regions of water scarcity,
where water resources in particular have already under-
gone dramatic transformation. Dams, canals, and diver-
sions have already altered the timing and magnitude
of stream flows throughout many of the regions now
turning to water trading (Worster, 1985). Determining
the additional impacts of water trading upon this exist-
ing landscape would be difficult. An alternative basis
for comparison could be the marginal or cumulative
environmental impacts of water trading relative to the
new impacts of additional water development. That is,
water trading may prove to be less environmentally
harmful than the construction of new dams and diver-
sion projects, or even the construction of new desalina-
tion plants.
SOCIAL PERFORMANCE
Water trading is usually characterized as a market-
based mechanism that reduces economic inefficiencies
by reallocating water from lower to higher value uses.
Trading has been used to meet explicit environmen-
tal objectives, but, as described previously, it is rarely
employed to address equity challenges. Indeed, water
trading can exacerbate social and economic inequali-
ties, worsening gender and geographic differences.
In regions with informal water rights and trading that
are functional at the community level, such as rural
Nepal, demands from outlying urban areas for larger
scale trades can overwhelm local water management
institutions. Trades from these rural areas might not
reflect the true value of the many informal uses water
has in the community (such as subsistence fishing or
milling) or the full range of informal ownership and use
for roughly 25  percent of total entitlement trading
activity (Wheeler and Cheesman, 2013). However,
some irrigators and state governments in Australia
oppose the instream buyback program, and it was cut
dramatically when the Labor Party fell from power in
September 2013 (Bennett and Carroll, 2014).
However, water trades not explicitly intended for envi-
ronmental purposes can create a host of adverse envi-
ronmental impacts. They can, for example, change the
timing, quantity, and quality of return flows, adversely
affecting riparian and wetland habitats and the species
that depend upon them. Some trades, such as from
California’s Owens Valley to Los Angeles, adversely
affect public health by increasing the amount of dust
emissions from exposed lakebed and fallowed land,
generating significant externalities (LA DWP, 2013).
Groundwater substitution, in which a user trades sur-
face water and increases groundwater extraction, can
lead to over-extraction, and sinking or caving in of land
surfaces (subsidence), depleting springs and seeps,
and robbing future generations (Brown et al., 2015).
Water trading can also diminish groundwater recharge
rates, whether the water is generated via fallowing or
increased efficiency. In the southern Indian state of
Tamil Nadu, farmers irrigating with groundwater have
increased extraction rates and sold the excess to water
tanker trucks serving urban populations, an example of
informal water trading. Yet this increased groundwater
extraction lowered the water table, increasing pump-
ing costs for other irrigators or drying up their wells
entirely (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005).
Efforts to mitigate the environmental impacts of water
trading have had mixed success. In Spain, a proposal to
add a small environmental mitigation fee to each unit
of water traded was insufficient to overcome the strong
opposition of environmental and social organizations
(Albiac et al., 2006). In California, state commitments to
mitigate the environmental and public health impacts
of the nation’s largest agriculture-to-urban water
trade have yet to result in any actual mitigation efforts,
potentially jeopardizing several listed species and likely
“…water trades not explicitly intended
for environmental purposes can create…
adverse environmental impacts.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT22
water first began flowing to LA, creating the single
largest source of dust pollution in the United States. In
the past decade, after years of litigation, LA has spent
more than $1.4 billion on dust management efforts and
has returned some of the water to Owens Lake.17
San Luis Valley, Colorado. As demonstrated by
efforts to destroy the infrastructure moving water out
of the Owens Valley, local opposition to trading water
can be strong. In the late 1980s, the Canadian owner
of the 97,000-acre Baca Ranch in southern Colorado’s
San Luis Valley began buying water rights from other
farms in San Luis Valley, allegedly to irrigate new crops.
Local residents, who soon discovered that the true pur-
pose of the purchases was to sell the water to Denver
suburbs, 100 miles to the northeast, feared that their
valley would experience the devastation felt in Owens
Valley. Thus, they formed Citizens for San Luis Valley
Water to fight the water trade, working with the local
irrigation district to support a special ballot measure
to raise local taxes to fund litigation against the pro-
posed water sale. The ballot measure prevailed with
92 percent of the vote. In 1991, the locals prevailed in
court, stopping the proposed water trade. After Baca
Ranch was subsequently sold, the new owner also
attempted to sell the water out of the valley, sponsor-
ing two statewide initiatives seen as efforts to support
the water trade. In 1998, both initiatives failed, receiving
less than 5 percent of the vote. With continued pub-
lic pressure, the federal government purchased Baca
Ranch in 2004 – more than a quarter century after
the fight began – to prevent water from leaving the
San Luis Valley. It then parceled the land to the newly
designated Great Sand Dunes National Park, part to a
nearby national forest, and 54,000 acres to the new
Baca National Wildlife Refuge (Reimers, 2013).
Imperial Valley, California. On the other hand, water
trading that promotes efficiency rather than fallowing
of agricultural land can improve socio-economic out-
comes for both the area of origin and the destination.
For example, an ongoing water trade from the Imperial
17	 For information on the dust emissions at Owens Lake and the current
dust management program, see the Great Basin Unified Air Pollution
Control District website.
rights within the community, meaning residents may be
deprived of full compensation (Pant el al., 2008). Even
within the community, the complex web of informal
water-use arrangements can complicate informal trad-
ing agreements and, in turn, generate a range of eco-
nomic impacts on those using the water who had not
been consulted or participated in the trading arrange-
ments (Pant et al., 2008).
Limarí Basin, Chile. Unequal access to water mar-
kets due to unequal access to information or credit can
distort outcomes and reduce market efficiency. Chile’s
Limarí Basin has very high water trading activity, sug-
gesting successful economic performance, but Romano
and Leporati (2002) argued that it suffers from several
market distortions arising from disparities between the
resources available to those trading water. Peasants
fare poorly in trading activity because their water rights
often are not fully recognized, they are not as well-
organized as those purchasing the water, and they lack
access to information on pricing (Romano and Leporati,
2002). Dinar et al. (1997) noted that economic perfor-
mance is affected by disparities in the value of water in
different sectors and by the ability of those with limited
means to participate in water trading.
Southern California. Water generated for trades by
fallowing land can benefit water rights holders at the
expense of farmworkers and equipment suppliers,
potentially devastating rural communities. California’s
Owens Valley provides one of the early examples of
the adverse impacts of trading water away from rural
areas. In the early 1900s, agents secretly representing
the City of Los Angeles (LA) covertly purchased land in
the Owens Valley. In 1908, LA began a 5-year construc-
tion project of a 419-mile pipeline to divert water from
Owens Valley farmland to LA. Although Owens Valley
irrigators had willingly sold their water through market
transactions, they had not contemplated the plight of
the valley as a whole. Over the next several years, agi-
tators from the valley dynamited the pipeline several
times in a vain attempt to protect their water supplies
(Hundley, 2001). In addition to the direct economic and
social impacts on the Owens Valley, the water trade
had desiccated Owens Lake by 1926, just 13 years after
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 23
within households where men have left for new indus-
trial jobs enabled by new water supplies. In places
where rural agriculture, particularly at the household
level, provides subsistence and food security, reduced
access to water can impose significant adverse impacts
(Farolfi and Perret, 2002).
Rural household access to water for domestic uses
and for subsistence agriculture may have only infor-
mal community-level recognition that does not trans-
late into tradable water rights. Water trading that does
not recognize these informal or ad hoc water uses can
adversely affect equity outcomes and prompt ques-
tions of legitimacy (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005).
Formal, state-recognized water rights typically require
the means and ability to register and defend them,
in turn conferring power on those with formal water
rights. In South Asia and other parts of the develop-
ing world, informal water-use arrangements that permit
and enable water use and trading can be disrupted by
formal rights-based trades and command-and-control
reallocations (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005).
Zwarteveen (1997) noted that, as men in Ecuador,
Nepal, and Peru have migrated in search of employ-
ment, women have assumed a disproportionately large
number of agricultural roles, even as formal and infor-
mal water rights continue to be held by the absent men.
These geographic and gender disparities can generate
adverse outcomes as water is traded by absentee own-
ers. Conversely, trading within households – even in the
form of recognition of joint ownership – can encourage
investment in water resource maintenance and pro-
ductivity at the local level (Zwarteveen, 1997). Similarly,
water organizations in the developing world, where
decisions may be made about trading water out of
the community, tend to have limited female participa-
tion, potentially neglecting compensation for impacts
that would have been identified if there were stronger
female roles and participation (Zwarteveen, 1997).
Water trading mechanisms can privilege certain popu-
lations and marginalize others, especially when cultural
practices differ. For example, New Mexico’s cooperative
irrigation systems, known as acequias, usually enjoy
Valley that began in 1989 relies on efficiency-based
measures rather than fallowing to generate water for
trade, creating additional employment while keeping
land in production.18
Water trading’s social impacts vary based on several
factors, including the relative economic health of the
area of origin and the purchasing area, whether or not
the water leaves the area of origin, the process used to
trade the water, and the relative economic and politi-
cal power of the parties (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan,
2005), gender differences regarding access to and
control of water (Zwarteveen, 1997), the amount of
trading activity in the area (Howe, 2011), and the legiti-
macy of the water rights being traded (Meinzen-Dick
and Pradhan, 2005). Impacts often vary within the
same community, as those with water rights or alloca-
tions to trade receive compensation, while third parties
– such as irrigation equipment suppliers or farmwork-
ers – may suffer a loss of revenue or income as a result
of trading (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005).
Water trades within the same region typically have
minimal or no adverse social or equity impacts. Howe
(2011) noted the large number of small-volume, short-
term water trades within an irrigation district as an
example of positive economic and equity outcomes.
Inter-sectoral trades, such as from agricultural to
manufacturing or mining within the same region, may
also generate positive economic and equity outcomes,
as jobs shift from lower income farm employment to
higher income industrial employment (Meinzen-Dick
and Pradhan, 2005). However, Zwarteveen (1997)
noted that even such intra-regional trades can gen-
erate differential impacts based on gender, requiring
additional agricultural and domestic labor for women
18	 The Imperial Irrigation District’s IID/MWD Water Conservation Program
Final Construction Report (2000) documented that 24 separate system
water conservation projects and programs (as opposed to on-farm),
such as lining irrigation canals and installing new headgates, had been
implemented through 1999. The capital cost for these totaled $193
million (2014$), with an additional $8.3 million in annual operations and
maintenance costs. These improvements yield 108,500 acre-feet of
conserved water per year, at a cost of $254 per acre-foot. In addition
to the jobs associated with the initial construction effort, the on-going
water trade supports about 12–13 full-time positions for managing water
deliveries, and for annual operations and maintenance.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT24
trading can increase costs for those who do not sell,
such as operations and maintenance costs associated
with water storage and delivery structures. The eco-
nomic and equity impacts of water traded from rural
areas can accumulate with additional trading activity,
reaching a tipping point where local demand for agri-
cultural services falls below the level necessary to main-
tain operations, creating a cascading set of business
failures and depressing the local tax base (Howe, 2011).
Agricultural areas importing traded water may also suf-
fer from third-party impacts, in the form of increased
competition, extended wait-times for water deliveries
via shared infrastructure, and rising water tables that
may threaten plant roots or require additional drainage
(Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007).
The one key exception to water trading that exacer-
bates social and economic inequalities is in South
Africa. Section 27(1) of South Africa’s 1998 National
Water Act states:
“In issuing a general authorisation or licence a re-
sponsible authority must take into account all
relevant factors, including…
(b) the need to redress the results of past racial and
gender discrimination;…
(d) the socio-economic impact –
(i) of the water use or uses if authorised; or
(ii) of the failure to authorise the water use or
uses.”
While this act explicitly sought to use water trading to
improve socio-economic conditions,19 South Africa’s
Department of Water Affairs and Forestry (now known
as the Department of Water and Sanitation) refused to
permit more than 118 applications for water trades from
2005 through 2008, claiming that the trades failed to
meet the Section 27(1) standards (Coleman, 2008).
South Africa’s Supreme Court found in 2012 that: i) one
proposed trade would create new employment oppor-
tunities for both men and women in a region with high
unemployment, meeting the standard established by
19	 The National Water Act is available at http://www.acts.co.za/national-wa-
ter-act-1998/.
very senior water rights. However, they have fared
poorly when defending their rights or seeking com-
pensation for third-party impacts in state proceedings,
where language and cultural practices favor fluency in
English and legal literacy (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan,
2005). Romano and Leporati (2002) found similar
circumstances in Chile, where less-educated rural
peasants fared poorly in trading water rights to more
powerful non-agricultural interests.
Economic disparities also affect water-trading out-
comes. As with the acequias, wealthy, powerful inter-
ests enjoy disproportionate advantages relative to
many historic water rights holders. In South Africa in
the late 1990s, mining interests sought to increase
their production and activity in rural, water-scarce
regions by purchasing water rights from small irri-
gators, at prices ten times higher than other irriga-
tors were willing to offer. Although the mines offered
employment and generated greater returns per unit
of water, they threatened to dewater local subsis-
tence farms and adversely affect a broad swath of
rural economies beyond the irrigators voluntarily sell-
ing their water (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). A study of
water trading in Chile’s Limarí Valley found a similar
impact, where increasing rural poverty was traced to
water rights sales from peasants to non-agricultural
interests and the general worsening of water-rights
distribution (Romano and Leporati, 2002).
As noted in the examples of the Owens and San Luis
Valleys, those in areas of origin can strongly, sometimes
violently, oppose the sale of water to outside interests.
A national study of water trading in Australia found
that this opposition can extend to local interests that
trade their water rights to external interests (Frontier
Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). In addition to
cultural and social bases for opposing such trades,
“Water trading mechanisms can
privilege certain populations and
marginalize others…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 25
Grafton et al. (2010) wrote that “Legal clarity over
water rights, including what they can be used for and
the rules of water trade, is a cornerstone of functioning
water markets.” Diversion or, better yet, consumptive
use water rights with clear title and quantified alloca-
tions that can be leased or sold can be described as
marketable property rights, a necessary condition for
water trading (Grafton et al., 2012). Culp et al. (2014)
noted that water trading requires legally enforceable
contracts that clearly and completely define the water
right to be traded, an exclusive right to the water, and
the recognized right to trade the water. Government
plays a clear role in establishing these necessary condi-
tions, documenting and, in some cases, allocating water
rights themselves, establishing and maintaining the
legal framework in which trading occurs and, in many
cases, financing the physical infrastructure to store and
convey water and allow water trading to occur (Dinar
et al., 1997). Strong and effective institutions that adju-
dicate and resolve disputes, enforce contracts, and
monitor trading agreements are a necessary element
in successful water markets (Zwarteveen, 1997).
Typically, infrastructure is also required to physically
convey water from a seller to a buyer, or to store or
otherwise manage water availability so that an agreed-
upon volume can be conveyed to the buyer at the
appropriate time. In some cases, creative agreements
have enabled trades from unconnected or remote
sources of water, creating what are known as “in-lieu” or
“paper” trades.21 While these trades can avoid require-
ments for connecting physical infrastructure, they do
require sophisticated legal arrangements, manage-
ment, and monitoring to ensure that the correct vol-
umes of water move at the approved time.
21	 One example of an in-lieu water trade is the agreement between the
Metropolitan Water District of Southern California and the Coachella
Valley Water District and the Desert Water Agency. All three have
contracts with California’s State Water Project (SWP), but because a
direct connection from SWP’s California Aqueduct to Coachella Valley
would have cost the equivalent of more than $1.8 billion, the latter two
agencies agreed to an in-lieu exchange agreement with Metropolitan for
a “bucket-for-bucket” exchange of SWP water for Colorado River water.
That is, Metropolitan takes the other agencies’ allotment of SWP water,
in exchange for giving up an equivalent amount of Colorado River water.
Source: cvwd.org/news/news178.php.
Section 27, and ii) the Department had acted improp-
erly in failing to grant the requested license to trade
the water.20 According to a local source, however, the
responsible authorities in South Africa continue to
delay and deny licenses for water trades, meaning that
South Africa’s water market has been restricted for a
decade (Backeberg, personal communication, 2015).
Necessary, enabling, and
limiting conditions
Institutional arrangements determine the ultimate
success or failure of water trading (Livingston, 1998).
Successful water trading requires secure and flexible
water rights that recognize and protect users and others
from externalities. Such institutional arrangements also
need to be flexible enough to adapt to changing physical
conditions as well as changing social norms, such as the
growing interest in meeting environmental needs and
protecting water quality (Livingston, 1998). Recognizing
and understanding these factors can help explain the
varying successes and even the existence of water trad-
ing in different countries and regions within countries.
Some factors, such as legal and transferable rights to
use water, may be necessary for water trading to occur.
Others, such as access to timely information about water
available to trade, can enable water trading but may not
be required for trading to occur. Still other factors, such
as “no injury” regulations and “area of origin” protections,
limit water trading or function as barriers or obstacles to
trading. The following explains the details of the neces-
sary, enabling and limiting conditions.
Necessary conditions include:
•	 legal, transferable rights to use water
•	 decoupling of water rights from land rights
•	 contract adjudication and enforcement
•	 means for buyers and sellers to communicate
•	 physical infrastructure to move water
•	 mechanisms to monitor and measure water flows
and use.
20	 Makhanya v Goede Wellington Boerdery (Pty) Ltd (230/12) [2012]
ZASCA 205 (30 November 2012).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT26
as precluding trading while the higher end of the scale
can be seen as enabling trading.
Water banks can enable water trading by connecting
buyers and sellers, posting information on availability
and transaction history and, in some cases, by physi-
cally storing water to match availability and demands.
The existence of technically skilled staff and monitor-
ing equipment increases the efficacy of water banks
and can help resolve disputes. Where water banks do
not exist or have limited capacity, water contracting
can enable spot trading (Brown et al., 2015).
The availability of pertinent information can be con-
sidered both a necessary and an enabling condition,
depending on the extent and type of information avail-
able. The availability of information on quantity, quality,
location, and timing of water entitlements or alloca-
tions can enable trading by pairing sellers and buy-
ers. Similarly, clear information about transaction costs
enables trading. Additionally, greater information and
certainty about future conditions, such as the security
of a water right given climate changes, can also enable
water trading (Brown et al., 2015). Clear and timely
information about prices also facilitates trading and
decreases search costs (Levine et al., 2007).
Social cohesion can also enable water trading. Trading
is more likely to occur where informal bonds exist, such
as between neighbors or within an irrigation district or
even between irrigators, relative to trading between
parties with no common history. In some cases, irriga-
tors will accept a lower bid from another irrigator than
a higher bid from a municipal agency, particularly one
from outside the basin or region. Water rights hold-
ers may fear that indicating they have water to trade
could be interpreted to mean that they do not need the
water, jeopardizing the right or imposing political costs
(Albiac et al., 2006).
Water trading can and does occur when necessary con-
ditions are satisfied, but markets are much more robust
and active when additional enabling conditions are met.
Enabling conditions include:
•	 water rights equivalency (as opposed to prioritized
rights)
•	 water banks and contracts
•	 clear, available information
•	 social cohesion
•	 competitive markets with multiple participants of
roughly equivalent economic power.
One of the major factors contributing to Australia’s
successful adoption of water trading in the Murray-
Darling Basin was the absence of prioritized water
rights. This enabled water trading without concern for
impacts on those holding less senior water rights (see
Annex 1 for greater detail). By contrast, in the western
United States and other regions with prioritized water
rights (also known as prior appropriation or seniority),
an entitlement holder with a senior water right (deter-
mined by the date the right was first exercised or “per-
fected”) could only sell or lease water after ensuring
that more junior rights holders receive compensation or
do not otherwise protest the transaction. This distinc-
tion helps explain the frequency of trades within irriga-
tion districts where district members share a common
priority right – such as the Northern Colorado Water
Conservancy District – and the much lower number
of transactions between those with different priorities.
That is, common priority rights or water rights with
equivalent seniority can be traded more readily than
rights with different priority dates.
Dinar and Saleth (2005) proposed a scale from zero
to seven to describe a range of surface water rights
conditions that could be used to evaluate the enabling
conditions for water trading. It spans from a rating of
zero for no water rights, to a rating of five for appropria-
tive rights; six for proportional sharing systems (such
as the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District
and Australia); and seven for water licenses and per-
mits. Under this system, we could categorize no rights
“Social cohesion can also enable water
trading. Trading is more likely to occur
where informal bonds exist…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 27
The anti-speculation doctrine requires buyers to
describe the new location and use of the water, condi-
tioning the trade on these terms and increasing trans-
action costs (Culp et al., 2014). The anti-speculation
doctrine is intended to prevent hoarding and mar-
ket distortion by those with the economic means to
acquire large volumes of water (Grafton et al., 2010). In
some areas, this doctrine is waived for municipal water
agencies, enabling them to acquire water for unspeci-
fied future needs.
The beneficial use doctrine requires that water rights
be exercised, encouraging inefficient or unproductive
uses as rights holders must “use it or lose it.” Some
jurisdictions have amended beneficial use require-
ments to enable rights holders to sell or lease the water
they conserve or save by implementing efficiency mea-
sures, water they would otherwise simply lose to junior
rights holders. Without explicit protection for such
conservation measures, the beneficial use doctrine
precludes water efficiency and hinders trading. In some
areas, laws prohibit users from selling or leasing water
“salvaged” from conservation or efficiency measures
(Culp et al., 2014).
Some kinds of water rights, such as non-consumptive,
appurtenant water rights (common in wetter regions of
the world) do not lend themselves to water trading.22
Examples of such non-consumptive rights include
rights to use or divert water to run mills or generate
hydroelectric power.
Some markets limit participation to existing contractors
or entitlement holders (Albiac et al., 2006). A related
barrier is a limitation on the purpose or use to which
a buyer may apply water. For example, several states
only allow state agencies, and not private individuals or
non-profit organizations, to purchase or lease water for
environmental purposes.
22	 An appurtenant water right is directly tied to the land itself, typically to
lands adjacent to streams.
Levine et al. (2007) argued that successful water trad-
ing requires the participation of multiple buyers and
sellers, with roughly equivalent power. They contended
that, without these factors, market inefficiencies will
result. In Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin and within
several United States irrigation districts, the satisfac-
tion of these criteria has enabled active and successful
water trading. In their absence, as seen in many agricul-
tural-to-urban trades, a small number of economically
powerful buyers have distorted markets and created
significant externalities.
Limiting conditions, which hinder or reduce water
trading, include:
•	 no injury rule
•	 anti-speculation doctrine
•	 beneficial use doctrine
•	 property rights/pre-conditions
•	 high transaction costs
•	 spatial and temporal differences in supply and de-
mand.
In many arid and semi-arid regions, water scarcity and
variability dictate that upstream “return flows” – water
diverted but not consumed that subsequently returns
to the stream – are used and claimed by downstream
users. To protect the rights of these downstream users,
courts or regulators typically require that the quantity
and timing of these return flows be maintained when
upstream water is traded. These and similar protections,
known as “no injury” rules, place the burden of proof that
the trade will not harm or adversely affect other water
rights on those wishing to sell or lease water. The “no
injury” rule is the prevailing law in most of the western
United States, intended to presumptively protect junior
water rights holders from harm that may occur due to
changes in the volume or timing of return flows from
senior appropriators. It dramatically increases transac-
tion costs, requiring sellers to hire attorneys and hydrol-
ogists to prove no injury, or otherwise compensate all
junior entitlement holders, and was a strong disincen-
tive to water trading (Culp et al., 2014).
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT28
services (Figure 5). Payments are made to the envi-
ronmental service provider by the beneficiary of those
services, e.g. an individual, a community, a company,
or a government. In essence, it is based on a benefi-
ciary-pays principle, as opposed to a polluter-pays
principle. Environmental services most often included
in PES arrangements include carbon sequestration in
biomass or soils; habitat provision for endangered spe-
cies; protection of landscapes; and various hydrological
functions related to the quality, quantity, or timing of
freshwater flows from upstream areas to downstream
users (Gómez-Baggethun et al., 2010).
PES has no standardized definition. The definition most
commonly used in the literature was developed by
Wunder (2005) and is based on five criteria: i) a volun-
tary transaction where ii) a well-defined environmental
service is iii) purchased by at least one environmental
service buyer from iv) at least one environmental ser-
vice provider, with v) payment conditional on the ser-
vice provided. In reality, few projects actually meet all
of these criteria. For example, money may come from
donors rather than service providers, or participation in
theprogrammaybemandatory.Wunder(2005)argued,
and several reviews confirm, that conditionality is the
hardest criteria to meet because initiatives are often
loosely monitored and payments are made up front or
in good faith. Moreover, in some cases, participation
is not voluntary (e.g. China), and the beneficiaries are
broadly defined and are not directly contributing to the
program. Wunder (2005) concluded that while there
are a considerable number of PES-like arrangements,
there are likely “very few ‘true PES’ conforming to the
theoretical concept developed in the literature.”
PES programs focused on watershed services are
commonly referred to as payment for watershed ser-
vices, or PWS. PWS arrangements, as with all PES
arrangements, can take a variety of forms. They can
be intended to prevent the degradation of a watershed
or to restore a previously degraded watershed. They
can be small, local schemes covering several hundred
hectares or large, national schemes covering millions of
High transactions costs, driven by the various doctrines
noted above as well as by the need to overcome infor-
mation constraints and related factors, can hinder water
trading. Similarly, the time required to complete a trans-
action may limit trading, particularly when buyers seek
to meet a short-term demand such as an additional irri-
gation cycle or to offset a delivery disruption within an
urban system; relatively fast trades will produce greater
trading activity than prolonged approval processes.
Finally, geographic and temporal mismatches between
supply and demand can impose additional barriers to
water trading, especially in the absence of physical
infrastructure to bridge these gaps. Where dams and
conveyances do not exist, those wishing to sell water
may lack the means to physically deliver the water to a
potential buyer, or be unable to deliver the water at the
right time (Bauer, 1997).
3.2 	Payment for ecosystem
services/payment for
watershed services
Description
Payment for ecosystem services (PES) is an incentive-
based instrument that seeks to monetize the external,
non-market values of environmental services, such
as removal of pollutants and regulation of precipita-
tion events, into financial incentives for local actors to
provide such services. In practical terms, PES involves
a series of payments to a land or resource manager
in exchange for a guaranteed flow of environmental
“High transactions costs, driven by the
various doctrines noted above as well
as by the need to overcome information
constraints and related factors, can
hinder water trading.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 29
•	 Service providers. For the vast majority of lo-
cal and national programs, private landowners are
the main watershed service providers, followed by
communal landholders, private reserves, national
parks and, in a very small number of local schemes,
occupiers of public land.
•	 Payment levels. In national programs, payment
levels are mostly determined administratively. In
the local programs, negotiation through an inter-
mediary is more common. Direct negotiations be-
tween supplier and buyer occur in very few cases.
Funds and transfer of payments are in most cases
managed by an intermediary, often in a specially
set up trust fund.
hectares. PWS schemes can be financed directly from
the beneficiary or from third parties acting on behalf
of the beneficiary, e.g. governments or institutions, or
some combination thereof. They can involve cash or
in-kind payments and be paid all at once or periodi-
cally. In a comprehensive review of 50 ongoing PWS
programs in developing countries, Porras et al. (2008)
highlighted the following major trends.
•	 Scale. Most ongoing programs (82 percent) are lo-
cal, operating at watershed level or smaller. The re-
maining 18 percent are national programs. Some of
the local programs are linked to national programs
or international projects.
•	 Scope. Local programs tend to target one or two
watershed services (more commonly water qual-
ity than water quantity), while national programs
tend to target multiple environmental services as
a means of tapping into multiple funding sources.
FIGURE 5. Schematic of a PES arrangement for watershed services
Watershed services
e.g. water purification,
flood risk mitigation,
aquifer recharge,
erosion minimization
Balances upstream and
downstream interests
Upstream community
Stewards and providers
of waterhsed services
Incentives
e.g. cash, assistance,
materials Project
Payments
Downstream water users
Beneficiaries of watershed services
Source: Forest Trends, 2012.
“PWS schemes can be financed directly from
the beneficiary or from third parties…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT30
that preserving the upstream rural Catskill watershed
would be far less expensive. However, New York City
had a long-history of employing eminent domain to
solve such issues. When farmers and rural landowners
voiced immediate concern, the city and local farmers
came together to develop a plan that could meet both
groups’ interests. A key element of the plan was the
Whole Farm Program, a voluntary effort fully funded
by New York City’s Department of Environmental
Protection whereby farmers would work with technical
advisors to custom design point and nonpoint source
pollution control measures to meet an environmen-
tal objective while also improving the viability of their
farming business. By 2006, the city had spent or com-
mitted $1.4–$1.5 billion in watershed protection proj-
ects, averaging $167 million in expenditures per year
(Kenny, 2006). Participation remains high, with 96 per-
cent of large farms in the watershed participating in the
program (Watershed Agricultural Council, 2011).
PWS arrangements have also been established in
developing countries. In Ecuador, for example, the Socio
Bosque Program (SBP), a national program established
in 2008, provides financial incentives to individual and
communal forest landowners to conserve native forest
and Andean tundra ecosystems. The program, which
includes environmental protection and poverty alle-
viation objectives, is largely state funded. Since 2012,
however, additional support has been provided by
the German Development Bank, NGOs, and General
Motors Omnibus BB. Program participation is volun-
tary. Participants are provided a monetary incentive
per hectare of land entered into the program, and in
exchange, must agree to refrain from logging, changing
existing land uses, burning, altering hydrological condi-
tions or reducing carbon storage, and commercial or
sport hunting and fishing for 20 years. By mid-2013,
1.1 million hectares had been conserved through 2,100
individual and 150 communal agreements (Raes and
Mohebalian, 2013).
While PWS programs can be found in a wide range of
settings and, in some cases, have been operating for
decades, comprehensive data on their size or scope are
not available. Ecosystem Marketplace (2013) estimated
•	 Funding sources. Funding sources are varied. Na-
tional programs primarily receive government fund-
ing through the allocation of national budgets and
donor funding, including loans from the World Bank.
Funding for local programs is more varied but is pri-
marily from: domestic and agricultural water fees;
donors, including the Global Environment Facility
(GEF), World Bank, and German Cooperation; the
private sector, including downstream hydroelectric
companies (in some cases, in the form of a dona-
tion); and local government budgets.
•	 Conditionality. Nearly all programs are uncon-
ditional, meaning service providers are paid on a
per unit area basis for land-management practices
“believed to have a high probability of resulting in
provision of the environmental service.” Only one
payment scheme, Indonesia’s Rewarding Upland
Poor for Environmental Services (RUPES) initia-
tive, is conditional on outcomes, such as the level
of sediment reduction achieved.
Application
PWS arrangements are gaining prominence and have
been applied in a wide range of settings. For example,
the US Conservation Reserve Program (CRP), estab-
lished in the 1950s in an effort to reduce erosion on
agricultural lands, became more conservation oriented
in the mid-1980s, making it among the oldest and lon-
gest running PES programs in the world. CRP today
pays farmers to take land out of production in order
to protect soil and water resources, as well as wildlife
habitat (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). In northeastern
France, Vittel-Nestle Waters paid farmers and provided
technical support (and some labor) to alter local dairy
farming practices in order to reduce nitrate pollution
of groundwater – the source of Vittel’s bottled water
(Perrot-Maitre 2006).
New York City provides another well-known example.
In the late 1990s, New York City was faced with the
prospect of building a $4–$6 billion filtration plant with
an additional $250 million in annual operating costs
to meet new federal Safe Drinking Water Act require-
ments – an approach that was “treating symptoms, not
causes” (Appleton, 2010). An initial analysis suggested
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 31
•	 many programs lack baseline data or monitoring
systems
•	 the connections between land-use practice and
watershed services are not always clear, especially
as they relate to water quantity, and are often site
specific
•	 it can be difficult to attribute change to the pro-
gram rather than to external factors (e.g. changing
commodity prices)
•	 programs may not reach threshold levels for mea-
sureable impact, or that impact may occur over a
relatively long time period.
As a result of these challenges, reliance on input-
based indicators (sometimes referred to as behavioral
change) has been borne out of necessity.
Porras (personal communication, 2015) argued that
because of these challenges, monitoring should be
based on input-based, rather than outcome-based,
indicators, as outcome-based indicators shift too much
risk to the ecosystem service provider and may raise
equity concerns. She further noted the need to set
meaningful expectations. For example, conservation
projects may be implemented within a landslide-prone
watershed to reduce the risk of landslides, with the
understanding that, even with a successful program,
a landslide would still likely occur, albeit with reduced
frequency and intensity over the long term. Thus, an
expectation of no landslides is unrealistic and could
threaten the viability of the program.
In the absence of data on project outcomes, Porras
et al. (2008) found that reported impacts are often
based on “perceptions of local populations and those
operating the schemes and/or quick measurements of
what the impacts should be, rather than in-depth sci-
entific evidence drawing from site measurements and
modelling of relationships.” But even based on these
sources, the available data suggest that environmental
performance is mixed. In a review of previous studies
that the total transaction value of PWS programs and
water funds in 2012 was $8.0 billion. Activity in 2013
was considerably higher, with an estimated $11.5 billion
in transaction value for PWS programs in China alone.
While these data suggest dramatic growth, Bennett
(personal communication, 2015) noted that the differ-
ence can largely be explained by better reporting by
a larger number of projects. Case studies of PWS pro-
grams in developing countries are maintained by the
London-based International Institute for Environment
and Development and at Watershed Connect, an online
platform maintained by Forest Trends (2015a).
Environmental, economic, and
social performance
Comprehensive studies on the performance of PWS
programs are limited, although some studies have
been conducted on various aspects of these programs.
Below, we examine the available evidence looking at
how PWS has performed environmentally, economi-
cally, and socially.
ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE
The environmental performance of PWS is not well
understood due to a lack of scientific analysis. In an
analysis of 47 PWS schemes in developing countries,
Brouwer et al. (2011) found that “less than half of the
schemes used quantifiable indicators and monitored
the impact of the schemes on environmental perfor-
mance.” In most cases, the indicators were input-based,
meaning that they, for example, looked at land area with
forest cover, rather the actual impacts and outcomes
of the program. In a review of Costa Rica’s programs,
Pagiola (2008) found it “unfortunately impossible
to determine the extent to which the PSA23 program
has successfully generated environmental services.
Although the PSA program has established a strong
system to monitor land user compliance with payment
contracts, the program remains weak in monitoring its
effectiveness in generating the desired services.”
There are several challenges to evaluating environ-
mental performance:
23	 Pagos por servicios ambientales (payment for environmental services)
“…PWS programs can be found in a wide
range of settings…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT32
applicants for forest protection are prioritized based
on the total number of points they receive, with more
points awarded for forests in indigenous territories or
those protecting water resources. Likewise, applicants
for reforestation projects are awarded more points if
they use native species or reforest degraded areas with
high forestry potential (Porras et al., 2013). The selec-
tion criteria can be tailored to reflect the environmental
(and even social objectives) of the program and altered
as priorities or needs change.
ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
Payment structures are generally uniform and untar-
geted, with flat rates per hectare for all sites (Porras et al.,
2008; Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). Despite the preva-
lence of uniform, untargeted payments, program costs
and benefits are spatially heterogeneous. Wunschler et
al. (2006) found that ecosystem service provision varies
spatially according to the ecosystem benefits, the threat
of loss, and the cost of service provision. Several stud-
ies have suggested that untargeted, uniform payments
reduce the cost effectiveness of PES schemes (Dillaha
et al., 2007; Ferraro, 2008), and given likely constraints
on program budgets, reduces the project benefits and
its long-term success (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010).
Reverse auctions (also referred to as procurement auc-
tions) have been put forth as one option for improving
the economic efficiency of PWS schemes (Karousakis
and Brooke, 2010). In an ordinary auction, the buy-
ers compete to obtain a good or service by offering
increasingly higher prices. With reverse auctions, the
sellers compete to obtain business from the buyer,
and prices typically decrease as sellers undercut one
another. The US Conservation Reserve Program, for
example, combines reverse auctions with an environ-
mental benefit index to select land for inclusion in the
program. However, Ferraro (2008) acknowledged that
and surveys of PWS scheme managers, Brouwer et
al. (2011) found that “58 percent of the PWS schemes
were classified as effective in reaching their environ-
mental objectives, while 42 percent were not.” Several
factors, ranging from the number of intermediaries and
mode of participation to the selection of service provid-
ers, level of community participation and type of moni-
toring, were found to improve environmental outcomes:
•	 schemes with fewer intermediaries were more ef-
fective in meeting environmental objectives
•	 mandatory participation increased environmental
effectiveness compared with voluntary schemes
•	 selecting service providers based on a set of crite-
ria, e.g. location, accessibility of land, or parcel size,
tended to have a negative impact on environmen-
tal performance
•	 contracting with the community was more effective
than contracting with a single ecosystem service
provider
•	 programs that monitored progress toward achiev-
ing environmental objectives were more likely to
reach those objectives.
The study also found that schemes for direct payments
by downstream hydropower companies to upstream
land owners to reduce sediment loads were generally
identified as successful, while other factors – includ-
ing the type of watershed service, age of the scheme,
or scale of implementation – had no significant effect
on the outcome. Recognizing this, Brouwer et al. (2011)
called for international monitoring guidelines to com-
pare programs, identify success factors, and support
their future design.
Some have suggested that one way to improve envi-
ronmental outcomes is through better selection of
areas to include within the PWS program, a process
that could be facilitated by the application of new tech-
nologies (e.g. satellite imagery) and modeling efforts.
Porras et al. (2013) identified several criteria suggested
in the literature for targeting efforts, including focus-
ing on areas at high risk of deforestation, large blocks
of land prone to landslides or other natural disasters,
and biological corridors. In Costa Rica, for example,
“…studies have suggested that untargeted,
uniform payments reduce the cost
effectiveness of PES schemes…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 33
rivers in China. Total investment is $4.3 million per year.
Farmers in the Yangtze River Basin are paid yuan 417
per hectare per year ($50), while those in the Yellow
River Basin are paid yuan 290 ($36) per hectare per
year. In addition to the regular cash payments, farm-
ers also receive a one-off cash payment and regular
grain rations (Porras and Neves, 2006a). The program
is designed to promote forestry and other economic
endeavors on the land, rather than grain production.
Given that most programs are voluntary, some have
argued that continued participation provides some indi-
cation that the programs are cost effective, i.e. that the
benefits exceed the costs. The impact of PWS schemes
on ecosystem service providers is generally estimated
by looking at the payment as a fraction of household
income. Using this metric, results are varied. Kosoy et
al. (2007) found that the amount received from the
PWS scheme was less than 2 percent of gross annual
income for most providers in three cases in Costa Rica,
Nicaragua, and Honduras; moreover, most watershed
service providers did not think that the payment was
fair. However, Wunder (2008) found that payments
represented 10 to 16 percent of household income in
schemes in Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Venezuela, and
Vietnam. Even these studies did not examine the trans-
action costs participants incurred in the program or
the opportunity costs. In light of these findings, several
studies have suggested that there are also important
non-financial (or non-income) benefits (Kosoy et al.,
2007; Wunder, 2008). The most commonly cited non-
financial benefits include increasing land-tenure secu-
rity, increasing human and social capital through internal
organization, and increasing the visibility of the commu-
nity to donors and public entities (Wunder, 2008).
SOCIAL PERFORMANCE
Limited data are available on the social outcomes of PES
programs, as studies have been more narrowly focused
on “short- or mid-term outcomes such as increased
income or capacity building since these are much
easier to identify” than broader social impacts, such as
changes in power dynamics (Richards, 2013). In one
notable exception, a review of Mexico’s PES program
auctions introduce their own set of challenges, espe-
cially in low- and middle-income countries. In these
countries, PES schemes may have dual objectives, and
reducing information asymmetries (and thus payments
for the ecosystem service provider) may not be a pri-
ority. Additionally, administrators of these programs
might be less likely to differentiate payment due to
concerns about fairness, and it is unclear whether there
would be institutional capacity to manage these pro-
grams. Moreover, auctions tend to increase transaction
costs, which may already be relatively high in low- and
middle-income countries where buyers of environmen-
tal services are likely to contract with many small, often
semi-literate, landowners, who often have no legal titles
and are in dispersed remote rural areas. Finally, differ-
entiation of payment can make it difficult to identify
corruption and ensure that differentiation is based on
implementation of transparent rules. Alix-Garcia et al.
(2009) suggested another option to reverse auctions
would be “to conduct rigorous contingent valuation
studies in areas targeted by the program.”
Whileuniformpaymentsarestillcommon,therearesev-
eral notable exceptions. Mexico’s National Programme
for Hydrological Environmental Services (PSAH) pro-
vides higher payments for lands that provide greater
benefits. For example, primary forest owners receive
300 pesos per hectare per year (approximately $27).
Cloud forest owners, by contrast, receive 400 pesos
per hectare per year ($36) due to the perceived higher
delivery of hydrological services associated with this
type of forest which has a role in capturing water from
fog and clouds during the dry season (Porras and
Neves, 2006). Payments are made annually, at the end
of the year, once the absence of land use change has
been confirmed.
China’s Sloping Land Conversion Program also pro-
vides targeted payments, although payments are dif-
ferentiated according to the opportunity costs. China’s
program, which began as a pilot in 1999 and was fully
implemented in 2002, requires farmers to set aside ero-
sion-prone farmland within critical areas of the water-
sheds of the Yangtze and Yellow Rivers, the two largest
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT34
broad geographic regions – could be developed to
improve social outcomes. While some have argued that
the pursuit of poverty alleviation objectives is likely to
result in environmental tradeoffs (see, e.g. Huang et al.,
2009), others suggest that this may not always be the
case (Brouwer, personal communication, 2015).
South Africa’s Working for Water (WfW) program is one
of the few programs to have poverty alleviation as its
primary objective. Between its launch in 1995 and 2009,
WfW cleared more than 1 million hectares of invasive
alien plants, which improved the timing and volume
of surface water flows, provided erosion control, and
increased biodiversity (Ferraro, 2009). The program,
administered by the Department of Water Affairs and
Forestry, employs 25,000 to 32,000 people annually,
targeting low skilled, previously unemployed laborers,
with a special focus on rural women, youth, and the dis-
abled (Ferraro, 2009). Social development, an integral
part of the program, includes “skills development, train-
ing, and awareness creation of communities in health
issues, hygiene, environmental health, inoculation,
sexually transmitted diseases, pregnancy and meno-
pause” (Department of Environmental Affairs, 2015).
The vast majority of the program budget is provided by
the central government and the Department of Water
Affairs and Forestry’s general budget, with only very
minor funding from foreign donors, municipalities, and
the private sector. Ferraro (2009) argued that while the
program is effectively the government paying for envi-
ronmental services on government-controlled lands
(and therefore not a true PES program), the program
administrators are actively seeking voluntary payments
from private and municipal actors to remove invasive
plants from within their watersheds.
Several studies have examined the socio-economic
status of participants in PES schemes, either as buyers
or sellers. Porras et al. (2008) found mixed results in
both national and local schemes, depending, to some
extent, on land and forest tenure regimes and socio-
economic conditions in the targeted area. In programs
in Mexico and Nicaragua, for example, the poor were
relatively well represented (Muñoz-Piña et al., 2008;
Pagiola et al., 2005), whereas in Costa Rica, the poor
(Alix-Garcia et al., 2009) found that in most cases, there
were no “obvious” changes in the social dynamics within
a community. However, in two cases, they found a shift
in the relative power of certain groups, whereby small,
private forest holders who held land within or adjacent
to communal lands threatened to cut down their for-
ests if they did not receive some compensation.24 In
two other cases, the program improved environmental
awareness and participation in conservation activities.
Information on broader social outcomes is limited.
However, there is information on the role of PES
arrangements in alleviating poverty. It is important
to recognize that PES schemes were conceptualized
as a mechanism to improve the efficiency of natural
resource management, not as a mechanism to reduce
poverty (Pagiola et al., 2005). While most programs
prioritize areas critical for ecosystem services, some
have been tailored to meet social objectives through
a variety of mechanisms, including by targeting the
programs to particular areas or populations, reducing
transaction costs, and providing pro-poor premiums
and subsidies (Wunder, 2005; Porras et al., 2013). In
Costa Rica, a social development index consisting of 11
health, participation, economics, and education indica-
tors is one of the criteria that is then integrated with
environmental criteria to select participants.25 This par-
ticular social development index has been shown to be
ineffective in targeting payments to low-income popu-
lations because it is biased toward large properties and
is “too spatially coarse to represent the social impact of
the programme at household level” (Porras et al., 2013).
However, it suggests that some sort of criterion – pref-
erably tailored to individual characteristics rather than
24	 In a somewhat unusual situation, this conflict was a result of the fact
that only a small group had rights to the commons and only those with
rights received payment.
25	 The index is used by Costa Rican government institutions to establish
priority for social policy and budget allocations.
“PES schemes were … to improve the
efficiency of natural resource management,
not as a mechanism to reduce poverty…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 35
were not well represented (Zbinden and Lee, 2005).
Wunder (2008) noted that one must typically own or
hold land in order to be a seller, thereby excluding the
“poorest of the poor.” Some schemes have attempted to
recognize informal access to resources (e.g. Indonesia’s
RUPES Program), although this has been difficult to
replicate elsewhere (Porras et al., 2008). A recent
review of ten PWS schemes in developing countries by
Bond and Mayers (2010) found only a small number
of cases where livelihoods had been improved, con-
cluding that “there are significant and positive indirect
effects of PWS – particularly in building social capita
in poor communities.” They acknowledged that while
improving education, health, and nutrition are bet-
ter ways of reducing poverty than PWS, there is little
evidence of these schemes actually doing any harm.
Moreover, they suggested that targeting can make
PWS programs more effective in alleviating poverty.
Additionally, while it is commonly assumed that up-
stream service providers are poorer than downstream
users (Wunder, 2008), the reality may be more com-
plicated. For example, George et al. (2009) found that
downstream and upstream stakeholders were part of
the same community in two watersheds in Thailand and
Lao PDR with no clear distinction between upstream
providers and downstream beneficiaries. In some
cases, according to Porras et al. (2008), downstream
users may, in fact, be poorer, raising concerns about
their ability to pay as well as whether those payments
are equitable. In cases where user fees were used to
compensate ecosystem service providers, the authors
found that the fees were generally found to be accept-
able, with no detectable impact on water use or access
to water. Additionally, some programs had taken steps
to ensure that the poorest users were not impacted by
these fees, e.g. by making payments voluntary or pro-
viding a lifeline supply of water.
Few studies have examined gender representation
among program participants. In a literature review, Ravn-
borg et al. (2007) found that less than 5 percent of the
references addressed gender-specific aspects of impacts
of PES. In a more recent assessment, Richards (2013)
concurred, finding that “Gender effects have not been
monitored, and therefore there is no information about
how women have been affected except some reference
to their low levels of participation.” Porras et al. (2008)
cited two studies indicating low participation levels by
women. However, these studies were more than a decade
old and may not have reflected current conditions.
Necessary, enabling, and
limiting conditions
Some factors, such as contract adjudication and
enforcement, may be necessary for establishing a PWS
program. Other factors, such as appropriate inventories
and analyses and government support, can enable but
may not be required for PES programs to be estab-
lished. Still other factors, such as legal prohibitions, limit
watershed PES or function as barriers or obstacles.
Necessary conditions include:
•	 a legal system recognizing that agreements must
be kept
•	 a civil law providing contract parties with legal rem-
edies to enforce contract rights in cases of non-
compliance with contract obligations
•	 general respect for the rule of law.
In general, PES schemes are flexible and the necessary
conditions are relatively modest. However, Calvache
et al. (2012) determined that they must be designed
within the legal context of a particular area. Greiber
(2009) provided additional detail on the legal frame-
work for PWS implementation, noting that the frame-
work will differ depending on the type of scheme
implemented. For example, private schemes, defined
as self-organized schemes between private entities,
require the least government intervention and depend
on only general legal requirements: e.g. a legal system
recognizing that agreements must be kept, and civil
law providing contract parties with legal remedies in
case of non-compliance. However, if only these condi-
tions are in place, Greiber (2009) asserted that these
“Few studies have examined … gender-
specific aspects of impacts of PES.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT36
•	 methodologies for measuring, monitoring, report-
ing, and verifying progress toward achieving proj-
ect outcomes.
Several studies have developed guides highlighting the
technical requirements (Hawkins, 2011; Calvache et al.,
2012; Smith et al., 2013). In addition to these require-
ments, methodologies for measuring, monitoring,
reporting, and verifying progress toward achieving out-
comes are also needed. Monitoring and evaluation are
fundamental to the success of PES schemes because
the information they provide gives assurance to the
buyer that ecosystem services are delivered as prom-
ised and allows for adjustments to the program based
on better information and changing conditions. Porras
et al. (2013) made a distinction between monitoring for
compliance and monitoring for environmental effective-
ness. The former “seeks to ensure that the conditional-
ity inherent in a PWS scheme is put into practice, and
that the project is implemented effectively.” The latter,
by contrast, seeks to ensure that the scheme achieves
its overall objectives and is needed to demonstrate
additionality, i.e. that changes in watershed ecosystem
services can be attributed to the program. While com-
pliance and effectiveness monitoring are often linked, “a
high degree of compliance does not necessarily ensure
that a scheme is effective, as a poorly designed scheme
may target the wrong land managers and land that is at
least risk, meaning that the payments may not generate
the desired hydro-ecological or conservation benefits.”
Despite some of the challenges to monitoring (described
in the application section of 3.2), Brouwer et al. (2011)
pointed to the need for international monitoring guide-
lines to identify the relationship between the design of
theprogramanditsenvironmentaleffectivenessbecause
understanding these relationships is “paramount to the
future design of cost-effective PWS schemes.” A recent
Science article by a large team of scientists and prac-
titioners in the PES field (Naeem et al., 2015) noted
that “many projects are based on weak scientific foun-
dations, and effectiveness is rarely evaluated with the
rigor necessary for scaling up and understanding the
importance of these approaches as policy instruments
and conservation tools.” In an effort to advance the field,
programs would “mostly develop at a small scale with
the objective to solve a specific local water problem,”
and expanding these projects to address regional or
national water problems would require a more devel-
oped policy and legal framework.
By contrast, public schemes are government-driven
schemes that, by definition, require far greater gov-
ernment involvement, as local, regional, or national
governments are involved as either watershed service
providers or buyers, and payment may be done through
user fees, taxes, or subsidies. However, many of these
schemes have evolved on an ad hoc basis from initia-
tives of NGOs and overseas development corporations
and, as a result, they typically lack comprehensive or
coherent legislation. Greiber (2009) also noted that
these conditions limit “the real potential of PES as
an innovative instrument that might be applied more
often, more efficiently, and at a larger scale to combat
prevailing water problems.” He argued that a specific
legal and policy framework would stimulate PES devel-
opment by creating greater legal certainty and helping
to promote good governance practices.
While necessary conditions establish the minimum
requirements for the implementation of a PES program,
there is a set of enabling conditions that promotes the
success and long-term viability of these programs.
While some of the enabling conditions are technical in
nature, others are legal, institutional, social, and political.
Technical enabling conditions include:
•	 an inventory of the value of hydrological services,
including assessments of baseline conditions, and
of how these values may change in response to
land use alterations, infrastructure development,
and climate
•	 an analysis of program costs, including implemen-
tation, opportunity, and transaction costs
•	 a registry of names, transactions, project data,
credit issuance, or other information related to PES
activities
•	 technical support from the government, civil soci-
ety, or the private sector through trainings, infor-
mation, or direct technical assistance
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 37
TABLE 2. Natural-science principles and guidelines for PES programs
Principle: Dynamics
Objective: Ensure project capacity to adapt to dynamic
natural and anthropogenic processes.
Principle: Monitoring
Objective: Track factors necessary for management,
trade, forecasting, and assessment.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
identify key services for each service type beyond
target services
identify spatiotemporal scales of targeted services
identify data needs, resources, and gaps
identify stressors and their spatiotemporal variability
identify and forecast trends in endogenous and
exogenous threats
identify services’ production and functions and
sensitivities
determine trade-offs and synergies among services
determine how functional diversity influences resilience.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
quantify deliverables associated with target services
identify spatiotemporal scales in advance of
implementation
use established methods/protocols and best practices
for monitoring
estimate uncertainties
monitoring should inform decision-making
monitoring should detect potential changes in
baseline conditions
monitor non-target services that influence
target services.
Principle: Baseline
Objective: Document and initial conditions
Principle: Metrics
Objective: Robust, efficient, and versatile methods
for procuring data.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
measure influences of interventions on
services
measure status and trends of non-target
services
ensure that measurements are feasible
given resources
assess initial state of exogenous and endogenous
threats to services
measure factors important for forecasting
service trends.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
must be relevant, reliable, and appropriate in scale
should comply with voluntary standards, certification,
and regulations
should reflect spatiotemporal scales as identified
in dynamics
optimize balance between precision and simplicity
assess progress (in conjunction with baseline
and monitoring)
should measure both absolute changes and changes
in trends
preferentially selected to allow comparisons across
service types
assess how services influence each other.
Principle: Multiple services
Objective: Recognize trade-offs and synergies
among services
Principle: Ecological sustainability
Objective: Insure project durability and sustainability
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
assess how intervention influences the other services
avoid “double counting”
assess impacts of intervention on non-target services.
SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES:
estimate short-term and long-term project or program
performance.
Note: The scientific guidelines shown in bold font are intended to indicate “essential” guidelines that must be followed for a successful intervention.
Guidelines shown in regular font are considered “desirable”.
Source: Naeem et al., 2015.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT38
of ecosystem services, while Colombia went even fur-
ther by requiring departments and municipalities to
invest at least 1  percent of annual revenues toward
either PES to landowners or direct land acquisition in
source water areas (Bennett et al., 2014). Enabling leg-
islation can occur at various levels (e.g. local, provincial,
or national) and take a variety of forms. However, the
appropriate level and form will depend on the prevail-
ing governance system in a particular area.
A variety of social and political conditions increases
the likelihood of the successful implementation of PES
schemes. For example, cultural and political acceptance
of markets in general, and of commercializing rights to
land use and land management practices, creates an
enabling environment. Dillaha et al. (2007) noted that
PES activity is generally strong in Latin America, but
that development tends to lag in areas with strong
indigenous cultures (such as the Bolivian highlands) or
closed economies (such as Venezuela). It is important
to note that in areas where the natural environment has
historically been used for free, “actually paying for envi-
ronmental services in response to mounting resource
scarcity represents a major change in attitude, which
necessarily will take time” (Dillaha et al., 2007).
Trust is also a key element for an effective PES pro-
gram, as it helps to ensure that there are willing buy-
ers and sellers, and reduces transaction costs. Dillaha
et al. (2007) noted that service providers might fear
that PES is a first-step toward appropriation of their
resources, while service users “might suspect that they
are or will be the victims of ‘environmental blackmail’.”
Based on several cases in Asia, Neef and Thomas
(2009) argued that “Lack of trust between poten-
tial buyers and providers of environmental services is
probably one of the most constraining factors in set-
ting up viable PES schemes.” One way to facilitate the
trust-building process is through stakeholder engage-
ment, especially during the initial stages of the project.
Likewise, transparency and access to information are
also essential. Intermediaries, such as NGOs, can some-
times play a role in building and maintaining trust while
also providing technical, legal, and financial support. As
the authors put forth a set of natural science principles
and guidelines for PES efforts that they felt were appli-
cable to local-, regional-, and national-level programs in
developed and developing countries (Table 2). A set of
scientific guidelines for four of the principles – dynamics,
monitoring, baseline, and metrics – were deemed “essen-
tial” for a successful intervention, whereas the remainder
were deemed “desirable”. While specific to PES arrange-
ments, they argued that the principles and guidelines
could be applicable to market-based conservation
instruments more broadly. In a review of 118 active PES
projects, however, the authors found that 60 percent did
not adhere to the four essential principles, highlighting
considerable room for improvement in the development
and implementation of PES projects.
In addition to the more technical aspects of PES, there
are a number of enabling legal, institutional, social, and
political conditions that also improve the effectiveness
of PES.
Enabling legal, institutional, social, and political
conditions include:
•	 a policy and legal framework for PES
•	 incentives and/or requirements to participate in
PES programs
•	 cultural and political acceptance of markets
•	 trust between ecosystem service providers and
beneficiaries
•	 a supply and demand for ecosystem services.
Governments, for example, can pass laws or institute
policies that enable the development of PES pro-
grams. In Costa Rica, participants of PES programs
are exempt from paying property taxes (Porras et al.,
2013). Likewise, the Peruvian government unanimously
passed a law providing a legal framework for voluntary
PES programs between land stewards and beneficiaries
“Governments, for example, can pass
laws or institute policies that enable the
development of PES programs.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 39
whether these rights also include “the right to receive
income from the ecosystem services provided by the
transferred natural resource.” Likewise, in Asia, most
forested and agricultural land is state-owned. Thus,
individuals and communities have weak land rights,
making it difficult for them to sign a contract and pro-
vide a legal guarantee of future land management
practices (Huang et al., 2009).
3.3 Water quality trading
Description
Water quality trading (WQT) is a market-based
approach for reducing or controlling water pollution. It
allows permitted dischargers in a watershed to trade
water quality credits, or pollution allowances, in order to
meet water quality standards. Markets in water quality
differ from conventional markets in that they are not
based on an actual physical commodity. Rather, they
are based on trading a license or a permit to pollute.
The primary goal of water quality trading is to reduce
the costs of water pollution control, often following the
imposition of a cap on pollutant emissions by regula-
tors. Secondary goals are to reduce compliance costs
and spur innovative solutions to pollution control.
Water quality trading is an adjunct to regulation, and
not an alternative to it. In fact, its success depends on
the presence of a strong regulatory body to enforce
water quality standards, and monitor and enforce dis-
charge limits.
Water quality markets draw inspiration from the suc-
cess of the Acid Rain Program (ARP) in the United
States in the 1990s. At the time, most environmental
groups and government agency staff favored a “com-
mand-and-control” approach to pollution control that
Bond and Mayers (2010) acknowledged, trust “is hard
to build and easy to lose.”
Finally, there must be a supply of, and demand for, eco-
system services. On the supply side, payments must be
big enough relative to other opportunities to create a
real incentive for change. On the demand side, benefi-
ciaries must have the ability to pay. For example, Huang
et al. (2009) posited that by increasing incomes, rapid
economic growth in Asia could increase demand for
watershed services because there is greater willing-
ness and ability to pay for amenities such as clean
water and recreation. At the same time, rapid economic
growth could increase demand for goods and services
produced on the land, thereby increasing the oppor-
tunity cost of the land. In a regional review of PWS
programs in sub-Saharan Africa, Ferraro (2009) sug-
gested that demand for watershed services is relatively
low, as there are relatively few formal water systems,
and even those with formal systems may lack reliable
access – which means there are few people who could
be easily charged a water fee to pay for watershed ser-
vices. Moreover, high poverty rates suggest that many
would not be able to afford higher water costs.
There is also a set of conditions that can hinder or limit
the development of PES schemes.
Limiting conditions can include:
•	 any legal provision prohibiting watershed PES con-
tracts
•	 poorly defined property rights.
Greiber (2009) noted that “clearly defined property
rights enable parties to enter into PES contracts and
ensure the sustainability of PES schemes.” Several
challenges associated with property rights arise when
implementing PES schemes. For example, ecosystem
services are a relatively new concept and may not be
recognized by the existing legal framework. In Peru,
the state is the owner of natural resources and holds
the property rights over ecosystem services. While the
state can transfer certain property rights over natural
resources to individuals, it has not yet been determined
“Water quality markets draw inspiration from
the success of the Acid Rain Program in the
US in the 1990s.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT40
levels in water bodies, a process referred to as “eutro-
phication”. Other water quality trading programs have
been set up to control salinity, heavy metal, sediment,
and temperature or thermal pollution (Morgan and
Wolverton, 2005). These programs are typically based
around specific watersheds or receiving waters, such
as the Chesapeake Bay or Wisconsin’s Fox River. WQT
markets are different from other emissions trading
schemes, in that trading is used between sources in
the same area of impact, e.g. a watershed that drains
to a particular water body, such as a lake, estuary, or
river. The geography of trading contrasts starkly with
other well-known cap-and-trade-style environmental
markets, such as national and international markets
for carbon offsets, where emission reductions can take
place even in remote parts of the world.
Trading within water quality markets can take several
different forms. The most common arrangement in
the United States is a bilateral market, where buyers
negotiate trades directly with potential sellers, discuss-
ing their quantity and price. Often, a regulator will get
involved by, for example, approving the terms of the
agreement, or facilitating monitoring to ensure that
actual discharge reductions take place. This arrange-
ment makes transactions slow and costly, and has
been partially blamed for the moribund trading activ-
ity in most US WQT markets (Woodward et al., 2002).
In clearinghouse-style markets, a middleman such as
a brokerage firm facilitates trades by connecting will-
ing buyers and sellers, as has been done in the Tar-
Pamlico River Basin Nutrient Trading Program in North
Carolina. On the opposite extreme, exchanges are a
form of trading where allowances are turned into stan-
dardized commodities and are freely traded. For exam-
ple, in the United States, SO2 allowances are traded
on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange. The Hunter
River Salinity Trading Scheme in Australia may also
be considered an example of an exchange, although
in this case, the government is responsible for trades
(NSWDEC, 2003).
Water quality markets can be classified in a number of
ways. One useful way to categorize markets is based on
would have required all power plants to install scrub-
bers on their smokestacks to remove sulfur diox-
ide (SO2). Lawmakers instead opted for a bold policy
experiment, setting a cap on total SO2 emissions, and
allowing polluters to buy and sell pollution allowances.
Under this system, emissions from individual sources
could rise or fall, as long as the total annual emissions
stayed the same. The central idea was that allowing
trading puts a price on pollution, and, in turn, encour-
ages cost savings, efficiency, and innovation.
In most WQT markets, a cap is put on water pollutants.
In the United States, the cap is usually set by state gov-
ernments, which are responsible for regulating water
quality in rivers, lakes, and estuaries. The cap should
be based on a scientific analysis of how much pollutant
a water body can assimilate without being excessively
degraded, which is referred to as a total maximum daily
load (TMDL). Government regulators issue pollution
allowances, often referred to as “credits”, to existing
polluters. For example, a credit may allow a facility to
discharge one pound of phosphorus to a river. A facility
manager may choose to install pollution-control tech-
nologies that limit emissions. If a facility’s emissions
decrease to below its permitted level, this frees up
additional credits that managers may then sell to other
polluters. There typically may be two types of buyers
that create a demand for credits: i) new entrants to the
market, such as a new factory in the watershed, or ii)
existing polluters that may wish to or need to increase
their emissions, e.g. a factory that wishes to increase
output, or a sewage plant serving a growing commu-
nity. Trading allows the industry greater freedom to
operate as it sees fit. A low-performing facility may
continue to pollute more heavily, but it will be required
to purchase credits, making the cost of doing business
more expensive. High-performers that can reduce their
pollution levels create valuable pollution credits that
they can sell, and this creates an incentive to invest in
pollution controls, at least according to theory.
To date, most water quality trading markets have been
used to control pollution from nutrients that cause
excessive algal growth and low dissolved oxygen
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 41
right to discharge pollutants. Markets are also thought
to foster innovation – where “innovative, entrepreneur-
ial companies can profit from low-cost reductions in
emissions. Slower, less innovative firms can benefit as
well by having the opportunity to purchase needed
emission allowances for less than it would cost them
to comply internally” (Anderson, 2004). Moreover, cap-
and-trade programs may provide greater certainty in
the outcome. With a fixed or declining cap, policy mak-
ers can be more certain of the environmental improve-
ment that will be achieved, compared with alternative
approaches such as best management practices or a
pollution tax.
Application
A survey conducted by Bennett and Carroll (2014)
for Forest Trends found that activity for WQT mar-
kets is still relatively small, although it has shown large
increases in the past several years. In 2013, the trading
value of WQT markets was about $22.2 million. Much
of that activity was concentrated in the United States,
where WQT markets had a trading value of $11.1 mil-
lion in 2013, with a cumulative total of $95 million since
2000. While there are currently over 30 water quality
markets in place in the United States, some have seen
no trading or only a few trades, even two decades after
their establishment. Among the reasons cited for the
lack of trading activity are high transaction costs, lack
of trust, uncertainty about the future of the market, or
simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate in
the market (Shortle and Horan, 2008). While some of
the longest-running markets are getting smaller, new
programs in Oregon, Virginia, and Maryland have kept
overall transaction values high. Indeed, in 2013, United
States market activity was at its highest level ever
recorded, although Bennet and Carroll (2014) posited
that this likely represented recovery from the eco-
nomic downturn rather than new growth. It is of note
that New Zealand’s Lake Taupo Trading Program, a
relatively new program, has rapidly become the largest
in the world, with at least $10.2 million in transactions
in 2013. However, the future of that market is uncertain
because “that market’s biggest buyer, the Lake Taupo
Protection Trust, announced in June 2013 it would
the regulatory system that drives the demand for trad-
ing and whether it includes a cap on total emissions
(Anderson, 2004). This includes both cap-and-trade
systems and credit systems.
Cap-and-trade systems put a limit on the total
amount of allowed releases of pollution. They seek
a specific environmental result (a cap), and trading
allowances to release pollution are simply an option to
minimize the cost of achieving the emission reductions
specified in the regulatory cap. In the cap-and-trade
approach, allowances for future emissions are sold or
granted to existing sources.
Credit systems, on the other hand, do not establish
any fixed ceiling on total emissions. Total emissions can
increase if new sources of pollution enter the market, or
if existing sources increase their outputs. In uncapped
systems, tradable credits are earned for controlling pol-
lution beyond what is specified in one’s permit.
The literature is full of descriptions of the potential
benefits of water quality trading compared with the
more conventional “command-and-control” approach,
where regulators allocate the right to pollute by impos-
ing limits on individual polluters (Shortle and Horan,
2005). In particular, WQT markets are thought to be a
less-costly, more-efficient alternative. When the total
amount of pollutant emissions in a region is capped,
the right to pollute becomes a scarce commodity and,
as many economists assert, markets are the most effi-
cient way of allocating a scarce commodity.26 WQT
programs allow polluters to interact in the marketplace
and decide among themselves how to allocate the
26	 While economic theory says that trading will lead to the most efficient
allocation of a resource, it says little about distributional effects, i.e. who
pays and who benefits, or other market “externalities”.
“WQT programs allow polluters to interact
in the marketplace and decide among
themselves how to allocate the right to
discharge pollutants.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT42
in the Reagan, George H.W. Bush, and George W. Bush
administrations, “and were once strongly condemned
by liberals and environmentalists” (Schmalensee and
Stavins, 2012). The key element for overcoming con-
servative politicians’ resistance to the policy was to
replace regulation with a free market; the market would
operate on its own with no intervention by the govern-
ment, a step that would “radically disempower the reg-
ulators” (Conniff, 2009). However, this has not been the
reality with most environmental markets, which have
been designed with additional layers of government
that oversee the market, monitor and enforce emis-
sions limits, and facilitate and verify trades. By contrast,
there are alternative pollution control policies that are
simpler and require less government involvement, such
as mandating the use of pollution-limiting technology
or taxing pollution. There is some irony here, prompting
one scholar to observe, “a putative form of rationaliza-
tion or deregulation is in fact a case of ‘reregulation’”
(Mariola 2009).
As an example of how WQT markets work, consider
the example of the Chesapeake Bay. To reduce nutri-
ent discharge into the bay, regulators had the option
of requiring wastewater plants to install expensive and
technologically advanced treatment systems. Nitrogen
removal costs for these systems are typically about
$200 per pound per year (Jones et al., 2010). However,
farms in the watershed are an even larger source of
nitrogen, and removal costs are much lower, at $1 to $5
per pound per year. As a result, permitted dischargers
have negotiated the ability to fulfill their permit require-
ments by funding pollution control projects on farms
in the watershed, such as planting winter cover crops,
planting vegetation around streams (called riparian
buffers), or installing permeable filter strips around
animal feedlots. These agricultural “best management
practices” reduce soil erosion and sediment runoff
from farms, reducing the amount of nutrients washed
into local waterways. Because they use soil and veg-
etation to filter water and sediment, they are gener-
ally low-tech and relatively inexpensive to install and
maintain. The Chesapeake Bay WQT program was set
up specifically to encourage these kinds of exchanges.
withdraw from future trading, having made arrange-
ments to achieve its remaining nitrogen reduction
goals by purchasing and managing land in the catch-
ment” (Bennett et al., 2014).
The popularity of emissions trading for dealing with
water pollution in the United States is largely a result
of the Clean Water Act of 1972. The specifics of how
the law was written and implemented have made it dif-
ficult for governments to handle pollution from farms.
In particular, the law made it illegal for “point source”
dischargers, such as factories or wastewater treatment
plants, to release pollutants into waterways without a
permit, but did not attempt to regulate pollution from
“nonpoint sources”, such as agriculture or urban run-
off, since these were considered minor sources of pol-
lution and believed to be difficult to regulate. In many
watersheds, however, farms and feedlots are the larg-
est source of pollutants. These nonpoint sources are
exempt from most water pollution regulations, and
there appears to be insufficient will to remedy this.
Forty years after passage of the landmark law, some
40 percent of America’s surface water fails to meet its
water quality goals (Faeth, 2000). Further, a set of stud-
ies in the 1990s showed that reducing nutrient pollution
from agriculture could be 65 times more cost effective
than imposing further controls on municipal or indus-
trial sources. As a result, water quality regulators in the
United States use WQT markets primarily as a tool to
encourage point dischargers to fund nonpoint source
pollution controls, largely because regulators lack the
authority to deal with these sources of pollution.
One factor contributing to the popularity of emis-
sions trading is its appeal to conservative politicians
due to their invocation of the “power of the market”
(Conniff, 2009). The original cap-and-trade programs
were policy innovations developed by conservatives
“40 percent of America’s surface water fails
to meet its water quality goals.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 43
(Olszowa et al., 1998). Further, on-farm nutrient con-
trols will do little to control other toxins that are present
in coal ash, such as arsenic, lead, mercury, and heavy
metals. However, the program is notable as it is the
first program in the United States that has allowed the
purchase of pollution control credits across state lines
(Fox, 2014).
In addition to the many markets in the United States,
there are also examples of WQT markets in other
regions, especially in Oceania:
•	 Lake Taupo Nitrogen Trading Program (New Zea-
land)
•	 South Creek Bubble Licensing Scheme (Australia)
•	 Murray-Darling Basin Salinity Credits Scheme
(Australia)
•	 South Nation River Watershed Trading Program
(Canada)
•	 Chao Lake Nutrient Trading Program (China, under
consideration)
Several European countries have shown interest in
WQT. A literature review by Wind (2012) summarized
14 studies of the concept within the European Union.
Despite this interest, no markets have been created to
date, and it appears that EU directives limit the ability
of states to set up markets.
Perhaps the best example of a successful operating
WQT market is on Australia’s Hunter River, where coal
mines and other sources are subject to discharge lim-
its to protect water quality and drinking water sources
in downstream cities. Saline soils are present through-
out Australia, and during coal mining, salty water col-
lects in mine pits and shafts and has to be pumped
out to allow mining operations to continue (NSWDEC,
2003). The Hunter River Basin had a history of conflict
among users, with mining activities making the water
unsuitable for irrigation, and new mine proposals facing
extremely high costs. The state government, following
years of study and collaboration with stakeholders, set
a cap on salinity levels in the river, and put a system of
tradable discharge credits in place.
Trading allows regulated polluters to meet their per-
mitted discharge requirement at a much lower cost
than with technology. Further, it helps to finance pollu-
tion reduction from the agricultural sector, which gen-
erates about 44 percent of the nutrients entering the
bay. A recent assessment concluded that controlling
discharges from agriculture is necessary to restore the
bay (Steinzor et al., 2012).
A second noteworthy example of a domestic WQT
market is the relatively new Ohio River Basin Water
Quality Trading Project developed by the Electric
Power Research Institute, the research arm of the
United States electric power industry. Coal-fired power
plants in the Ohio River Basin are a major source of
nitrogen pollution in rivers, due to their using water
in scrubbers for air pollution control and to sluice the
coal ash out of reactors (US EPA, 2009). The ash and
water slurry most often goes into storage and treat-
ment ponds that provide only a minimal level of treat-
ment and where spills and illicit discharges have been
common (Zucchino, 2015). Under the pilot program,
power plants and other interested parties can pay for
nonpoint source pollution reductions on farms, another
major source of pollution in the watershed. Because
on-farm improvements are much less expensive than
installing wastewater treatment facilities, power plants
stand to save $500,000 to $800,000 per year (EPRI,
2010).
The first projects are creating nutrient reduction credits
through “activities like planting cover crops and creat-
ing treatment wetlands for animal wastes” (Ecosystem
Marketplace, 2015). The program is notable for its thor-
oughness in documenting projects, posting a descrip-
tion and photos of every project on the Electric Power
Research Institute (EPRI) website, and using a stan-
dard methodology for calculating the reduced pollution
in farm runoff. The program is credited with reducing
pollution by 100,000 pounds of nutrients between 2013
and 2015 (Barrett 2015). While commendable, this proj-
ect is a small pilot, and pollutant reductions are small
compared with the estimates of over 3 million pounds
of nitrogen entering the watershed’s rivers every day
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT44
at how WQT markets have performed environmentally,
economically, and socially.
ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE
While there are no comprehensive analyses of the envi-
ronmental performance of WQT programs in general,
there are several examples of successful programs.
In the application section of 3.3, we cited Australia’s
Hunter River as one example. Indeed, since formation
of the program, river water quality has met standards
nearly 100 percent of the time, protecting water sup-
plies to downstream irrigators and cities. This hap-
pened despite the establishment of new, potentially
highly polluting mines in the watershed. The Alpine
Cheese Company Nutrient Trading Program in Ohio is
another notable success. As a part of this program, the
company helped fund pollution reduction projects on
local farms, paying 25 farmers to install 91 conserva-
tion measures that resulted in a 3,000-pound-per-year
phosphorus reduction (US EPA, 2010).
A United States Environmental Protection Agency
(US EPA) 2010 evaluation of the program found that
it exceeded its nutrient reduction goals, and estimated
that “conservation measures would reduce up to three
times more nutrients than if equal funds were used for
wastewater treatment upgrades.” It is noteworthy that
the project has also been praised by the local chapter
of the Sierra Club, which has strongly opposed the cre-
ation of larger WQT schemes in other areas that could
allow industry to continue implementing poor practices
by purchasing offsets (Marida, 2010).
Likewise, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit Exchange
Program – currently the largest in the United States
– was created in 2002 to reduce nitrogen pollution to
Long Island Sound from the Connecticut River. Under
the program, which covers 79 sewage treatment plants
in the state of Connecticut, a plant can control pollu-
tion in excess of its permit requirement and sell excess
nitrogen allowances to those plants that exceed their
allowances. A 2012 review of the program suggested
that the program had helped the state meet its environ-
mental goals while lowering overall costs (Stacey et al.,
2012). The program helped reduce nitrogen loading by
Under this system, no discharges of salty water are
allowed when the river is in low flow. When the river
is in high flow and its capacity to dilute salty inflows
is greater, limited discharge is allowed, controlled by
a system of salt credits. Permitted dischargers coor-
dinate their activities so that the total salt concen-
tration in the river never goes above a specified limit.
Industries can buy and sell salt credits in real time via
a trading website run by the state government. Several
years after the program began, the trading program is
popular among participants and functioning smoothly.
The state government has set up real-time monitor-
ing to make sure the river water quality meets stan-
dards, and to monitor for permit violations. Perhaps the
biggest marker of the program’s success is that new,
potentially highly polluting mines have been estab-
lished, but river water quality has met standards nearly
100 percent of the time.
Environmental, economic, and
social performance
Despite the fact that water quality trading markets
have existed for three decades in some areas, it is
difficult to state whether they can be considered an
overall success. In making such an evaluation, we must
determine whether desired pollution reductions were
achieved and water quality targets attained. We must
also examine how the result compared with what would
have occurred under another form of management:
were the pollution reductions greater, did they occur
more quickly, or at a lower cost?
Moreover, there is a great deal of literature about water
quality trading and market-based solutions to water
pollution but few real-world evaluations of existing
WQT markets. Much of the literature about markets is
theoretical and oriented toward “making the case” for
WQT, e.g. describing how a market can or should be set
up. Below, we examine the available evidence looking
“…there is a great deal of literature … but
few real-world evaluations of existing
WQT markets.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 45
In an assessment of three mature WQT programs in
the United States, one scholar concluded that there
had been very little benefit as a direct result of trades.
However, the programs had an unexpected benefit: they
broughttogetherwatershedstakeholdersandincreased
“the institutional capacity for watershed management”
(Wallace, 2007). Stakeholders coming together around
a common goal of improving water quality also helped
lower resistance to new, more stringent water quality
regulations. Wallace concluded that the markets them-
selves were not important mechanisms for reducing
pollution. Rather, their presence contributed to “unin-
tended contributions to increased pollution regulation
and management on a watershed scale.” So, on the one
hand, these markets could be considered failures by
some observers because many of them had seen no
trading even decades after their creation.
The lack of trades can be explained by a number of fac-
tors: high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty
about the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity
and unwillingness to participate in the market. On the
other hand, even where little or no trading occurred,
water quality and governance had improved in the
three watersheds evaluated by Wallace (2007). It is not
always possible to disentangle how much of a role the
market played in bringing about these improvements.
On the one hand, financial transactions have not played
a large role, tempting us to conclude that the markets
were relatively unimportant. However, if discussion of
the use of “market fundamentals” helped overcome
resistance to environmental regulation and paved the
way toward decreased pollution, then we may conclude
that markets were a key feature in improving water
quality, albeit indirectly.
ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE
It is difficult to assess the economic performance of
WQT markets and how their economic performance
compares with alternative forms of pollution control.
To date, the size and impact of water quality markets is
relatively small. There is some information in the litera-
ture on the number of trades that have occurred, and
the prices paid for water quality credits. In the applica-
tion section of 3.3, we cited a Forest Trends study that
over 50 percent over 10 years, and was on track to meet
water quality goals by 2014. As a result, the area of Long
Island Sound suffering from hypoxia (low dissolved oxy-
gen which is fatal to wildlife) had steadily declined.
Despite these examples, most water quality trading
programs in the United States are either too small or
have seen too little trading to make a meaningful dif-
ference on water quality. For example, a 2012 evalua-
tion of Ohio’s Great Miami Nutrient Trading Program
called it “one of the most successful programs to date”
(Newburn and Woodward, 2012). In 2009, the trading
program attracted $1.3 million in trades and helped fund
100 projects that reduced nutrient pollution by 800,000
pounds per year. Proposed projects submitted by farm-
ers in the watershed covered a variety of agricultural
“best management practices” designed to prevent sedi-
ment and nutrients from entering waterways. Evaluators
concluded that the program “has been successful in
developing both supply and ensuring funding for agri-
cultural pollution abatement projects compared to
other WQT programs” (Newburn and Woodward, 2012).
Despite this, they found that the program had not likely
had a significant effect on regional water quality due to
the “relatively minor role that the trading program has
had on nutrient management in the watershed to date.”
To date, the projects have simply been too small and
too few to have a major impact. The Great Miami River
watershed drains 748 square miles, the majority of
which is cultivated, so a much larger investment would
be needed to meaningfully improve water quality in the
basin. This example highlights the caution needed when
interpreting large numbers cited by market proponents.
While 800,000 pounds sounds like a lot (and is indeed
a worthwhile accomplishment), it pales in comparison
with the estimated 1 trillion pounds of nitrogen enter-
ing the Ohio River watershed each year (Olszowa et al.,
1998). Like most WQT markets in the United States, the
Greater Miami Basin program did not emerge from a cap
on pollutants. Rather, it was created as a way to allow
regulated point-source dischargers, such as factories
and sewage plants, to lower their costs by paying for
pollution controls on farms rather than installing expen-
sive pollution control measures at their own facilities.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT46
improving the environment and supporting the local
economy, and also experienced other indirect benefits
from the project, “by fencing cows out of streams, bac-
teria levels in milk were decreased, giving the farmers
a premium price for milk and reducing costs for Alpine
[Cheese Company]” (Marida, 2010).
As described previously, the Connecticut Nitrogen
Credit Exchange Program is currently one of the larg-
est WQT programs in operation. An evaluation of the
program in 2012 suggested that the program has
helped the state meet its environmental goal of reduc-
ing nitrogen loading to Long Island Sound while lower-
ing overall costs. The state estimated that, in the first
10 years of the program, trading had lowered costs by
$300 to $400 million below what individual facilities
would have had to pay for equivalent pollution reduc-
tions (Stacey et al., 2012).
SOCIAL PERFORMANCE
There is little research on the social impacts of WQT,
and much of what we describe in this section is based
on anecdotal evidence. Critics of environmental mar-
kets have raised questions about their fairness and
justice. A specific concern relates to how regulators
distribute pollution permits at the outset of market cre-
ation. Under a market system, pollution permits become
valuable commodities to be bought and sold. In many
cases, as in SO2 trading in the United States, the gov-
ernment grants allowances to industries for free, based
on their historic emissions. Critics point out that such
“grandfathering” of permits rewards those polluters
most responsible for environmental problems in the
first place. It may also unfairly burden more recent mar-
ket entrants, because they have no history of polluting
and no “free” permits, yet would be required to purchase
credits to offset 100 percent of their emissions. There
are, however, different ways of issuing credits that help
mitigate these concerns. For example, rather than giv-
ing away credits, they could be sold to polluters in an
auction, as has been proposed in carbon markets.
Critics have also raised concerns about the fairness of
water quality markets to potential sellers of water qual-
ity credits. Consider a farmer who installed pollution
estimated the value of the United States water quality
tradingmarketas$11.1millionin2013,intermsofthetotal
value of payments. To put these numbers in perspec-
tive, state and local governments in the United States
spent $70 billion on sanitation and sewerage in 2008
(US Census Bureau, 2012). Despite these investments,
many argue that the United States should be spending
much more to control water pollution. Researchers at
Kansas State found that nutrient pollution from nitro-
gen and phosphorus cost the United States $2.2 bil-
lion in 2008, due to losses in recreational water usage,
waterfront real estate, spending on recovery of threat-
ened and endangered species, and increased treatment
for drinking water (Dodds et al., 2008).
While limited data are available, advocates for WQT
markets cite the lower overall cost of improving water
quality as their main advantage, as compared with more
conventional means of water pollution control. There
is local evidence for this, especially in smaller markets.
Take the case of the Alpine Cheese Company, in Ohio’s
Sugar Creek watershed. The plant was faced with
expensive wastewater treatment upgrades to satisfy
Clean Water Act permit requirements (US EPA, 2010).
These upgrades would likely have cost over $1 million
to install, plus ongoing costs for operation and mainte-
nance.Instead,thecompanycollaboratedwithothersto
reduce pollution through projects at farms in the water-
shed that have a much lower cost per pound of phos-
phorus prevented from entering streams, and which
are expected to last 15 to 20 years (Moore, 2012). The
company worked with universities, regulators, and local
agricultural extension services, providing $800,000
over five years for planning, technical assistance, and
outreach. In addition, these measures allowed the plant
to expand, creating 12 new jobs. Further, the project
provided funding to chronically cash-strapped local
soil and water conservation districts and to the local
agricultural economy. Local dairy farmers took pride in
“…advocates for WQT markets cite the lower
overall cost of improving water quality as
their main advantage…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 47
communal ownership makes it slower and more diffi-
cult to develop land. In a sense, those most responsible
for past pollution have been rewarded with large (and
valuable) pollution permits, while the Maori community
will face higher costs to develop their lands economi-
cally. In response to these concerns, regulators altered
the market design by relaxing the cap somewhat “to
ease the restrictive nature of historical allocation on
Tuwharetoa [Maori] and other forest owners” (Duhon
et al., 2011).
In the New Zealand case study, program managers
realized the importance of dealing with issues of race
and historical justice in order to make the program suc-
cessful. In the United States, some program managers
have also sought to address issues related to age and
gender. For example, the Ohio River Basin Water Quality
Trading Project directs money from the electric power
industry to farmers to support on-farm improvements
to reduce runoff and pollution. A concern was raised
early on that the early adopters would be all younger,
male farmers (Jessica Fox, EPRI, personal communica-
tion, 2015) because they would be more open to new
ideas. Also, there are fewer woman-owned farms in the
region compared with those owned by men. As a result,
the managers of this program have made a particular
effort to involve women farmers and older farmers.
Some critics have suggested that WQT programs could
perpetuate or worsen environmental justice problems.
The environmental justice movement in the United
States has focused on the fact that pollution often
occurs in areas where many poor and minority people
live or work, and that disadvantaged communities bear
an unfair burden of exposure to pollution. There is a
possibility that trading could allow pollution “hot spots”
to continue, with accompanying environmental jus-
tice concerns. For example, a polluter could purchase
credits instead of making onsite pollution reductions.
controls before a WQT program was established. Unlike
his (polluting) neighbors, he would not be eligible for
financing under the program. Thus, the program would
reward “notorious polluters” rather than the good stew-
ards, “because the good steward had already reduced
pollution” (Ruppert, 2004). Despite these criticisms,
there are several examples of WQT markets that have
been considered successful, and earned support from
industry, famers, regulators, and environmentalists.
As was discussed previously, the Alpine Cheese
Company Trading Program in Ohio was a very small
market that involved the purchase of credits from 25
farmers by a local cheese company. Many of the farm-
ers already did business with Alpine Cheese, selling
milk from their dairy herds, and have a strong inter-
est in maintaining a strong agricultural economy. One
observer wrote that, “socially, community has been
built with the farmers taking pride in working together,
their more sustainable farming practices and in seeing
the success of the factory” (Marida, 2010). One sees a
similar outcome in an evaluation of the Hunter River
Salinity Trading Scheme in Australia. Where there was
once “significant conflict between primary producers
and mining operators,” today, “agriculture, mining and
electricity generation operate side by side, sharing the
use of the river” (NSWDEC, 2003). Here, a history of
conflict has been replaced by cooperation. This did not
happen overnight, and required many years of pains-
taking consultation and negotiation.
In New Zealand, concerns have been raised about how
the Lake Taupo Nutrient Trading Scheme affects differ-
ent types of landowners, particularly indigenous Maori
people. In this area, dairy farms and grazing were cre-
ating polluted runoff, negatively impacting a freshwa-
ter lake important for fishing and tourism. Regulators
instituted a cap on nitrogen pollution seeking to main-
tain water quality at year 2000 levels. Larger corpo-
rate landowners were given more pollution credits
based on their historical use of the land, while Maori
landowners had not yet fully developed their lands
(MOTU, 2009). There are historical and cultural rea-
sons why Maoris have been slower to develop their
lands: they did not own some lands until recently, and
“Some critics have suggested that WQT
programs could perpetuate or worsen
environmental justice problems.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT48
States, the Clean Water Act established the concept of
“designated use” for waterways (i.e. swimmable, boat-
able, or fishable), with water quality standards then
developed based on the designated use. The process
of developing a standard requires understanding the
basic physical, environmental, and human elements of
the watershed. Generally, scientists or engineers collect
data and use computer models to determine the natu-
ral and human pollution sources (i.e. diffuse nonpoint
sources and point discharges). They also use models
to determine how much of a pollutant a water body can
assimilate while restoring or maintaining beneficial uses.
The second necessary condition is that polluters have
the ability to create water quality improvements, or
reduce pollutant discharge through technology or
management. Further, the regulator must be able to
verify that these pollution reductions are real and likely
to last. Verification of credits can be cumbersome and
time consuming, which can inhibit trading. Regulators
may require field visits or photos to show that on-
farm improvements have been properly installed and
maintained. In the case of the Alpine Cheese Trading
Program, soil conservation agents ensure that pollu-
tion control measures installed on farms meet “strin-
gent engineering specifications” (Mariola, 2009).
Implementation requires up to eight visits to a farm
from project start to finish, and a full-time agent is
required to coordinate a program involving one credit
buyer and 25 farmers. In some cases, however, the role
of verification falls to a trusted intermediary, as in the
case of the South Nation River Program in Canada,
where a conservation nonprofit hires local farmers to
conduct field inspections (O’Grady, 2011). More often
however, inspections and record-keeping are con-
ducted by state or local governments. According to
the US EPA, “mechanisms for determining and ensur-
ing compliance may include a combination of record
This was the subject of a 2013 lawsuit by Food  Water
Watch against the Chesapeake Bay Nutrient Trading
Program, which was later dismissed by a federal judge
(Hauter, 2013).
Trading programs are most effective when they cover
pollutants with “far-field” impacts, meaning their effects
are felt over a large area or over a long time period.
Indeed, a thriving market under a cap could allow pollu-
tion hot spots to continue unchecked, and thus would
be inappropriate for regulating pollutants which have
acute local impacts. “This is the reason no one has seri-
ously contemplated a market for toxics,” according to
Cy Jones, a World Resources Institute (WRI) senior
fellow (personal communication, 2015). This issue is
less important when trading operates within discrete
basins. The larger the basin in which trading is allowed,
the more chance there is to exacerbate hotspots. For
this reason, some programs have rules restricting trad-
ing to smaller sub-watersheds, as has been done in the
Ohio River program described above.
Necessary, enabling, and
limiting conditions
In this section, we discuss the minimum conditions that
are necessary for the creation and successful opera-
tion of a water quality market, followed by a discussion
of conditions that can enable WQT markets. These
enabling factors will increase the market’s likelihood of
succeeding but may not be required for it to be estab-
lished. Finally, we discuss factors which may limit WQT
markets by acting as barriers or obstacles.
Necessary conditions for a successful water quality
trading program include the following three circum-
stances. The first is the presence of a regulator and
its ability to set a cap on pollutants, monitor pollution,
and verify the legitimacy of water quality credits that
are created. Thus, the regulator must have the scien-
tific and technical capacity to set water quality goals,
and monitor water quality to ensure that those goals
are being met. To do so first requires a set of “desired
future conditions” for a particular waterbody. This may
be set by law, custom, or local preferences. In the United
“It is one thing to set up a water quality
market; it is another for active trading to
take place.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 49
Enabling conditions required for creation of a water
quality trading program go beyond these basics. First,
the government regulator must have the authority
to set discharge limits to protect waterways. Second,
the regulator needs the power to issue and enforce
water pollution discharge permits. Enforcement, with
the threat of meaningful fines or criminal penalties, is
especially important. As Abraham Lincoln famously
noted, “laws without enforcement are just good advice.”
Finally, there must be a legal framework by which trad-
ing can take place.
It is one thing to set up a water quality market; it is
another for active trading to take place. As we have
shown, many United States markets have been largely
moribund. The following presents what we consider
enabling conditions – meaning governments can set
up a market without them, but there may be little or
no trading. It would be tempting to classify an idle mar-
ket as a failure, but as we have also seen, some United
States markets have seen little trading, but they have
been accompanied by an improvement in watershed
stewardship and improvements to the environment.
There must be a demand for water quality credits.
Demand is the first and foremost enabling condition for
trades to take place. Generally, such demand is created
by a strong regulatory or non-regulatory driver.27 In the
case of the Alpine Cheese Nutrient Trading Program
described above, factory owners wished to expand pro-
duction, but were unable to do so because of a restric-
tive discharge permit. Violating the permit could have
resulted in fines or criminal charges. The factory own-
ers faced otherwise undesirable options: they could
27	 An example of a non-regulatory driver could be where industrial
emitters decide among themselves to voluntarily limit pollution to gain
goodwill or in an attempt to pre-empt regulation. This is the case in
the Ohio River study discussed above, where electric power companies
have funded projects to reduce pollution from farms in their watersheds.
These activities are not compulsory, so why would a for-profit corpora-
tion do it? Their motivation, as put forth by the program’s manager in
Congressional testimony is “to meet corporate sustainability goals and
their voluntary participation may also be considered by the state permit-
ting agencies when determining the need for flexible permit compliance
options in the future” (Fox 2014). In other words, she was saying that
companies hope that their activities today will buy them goodwill with
regulators and that future regulation will be less burdensome as a result.
keeping, monitoring, reporting and inspections” (US
EPA, 2003). There are other aspects of regulatory
oversight necessary to ensure accountability on behalf
of both buyers and sellers of credits. This oversight
includes many aspects of a trading program:
•	 establishing trading eligibility
•	 tracking of trades
•	 verification of credit generation
•	 compliance and enforcement
•	 monitoring of results
•	 program assessment.
It is especially difficult and usually impractical to mea-
sure nonpoint source pollution reductions, for example,
from projects designed to reduce polluted runoff from
farms. The pollution source is usually spread out, and
there is no obvious place to measure the discharge (as
there would be at the outfall of a factory). Nonpoint
source pollution also tends to be “episodic”, occur-
ring when rainfall flushes pollutants into waterways,
further thwarting measurement efforts. Regulators
have adopted several approaches to deal with these
issues. Nonpoint source pollution reductions are most
often estimated based on prior studies or modeling.
To address the uncertainty associated with these esti-
mates, regulators may place a higher burden for pol-
lution reductions on nonpoint sources. Indeed, some
markets have been designed with “trading ratios”
where nonpoint source reductions trade against point
sources at a ratio of 2:1 or 3:1.
The third necessary condition is an appropriate legal
framework enabling trading. Some of the legal require-
ments for water quality trading are similar to those for
other market-based instruments. Broadly, programs
require a legal environment that will uphold the rights
of buyers and sellers. Some basics, as outlined by
Greiber (2009), include:
•	 a legal system that recognizes agreements must
be kept
•	 a civil law providing contract parties with legal rem-
edies to enforce contract rights in cases of non-
compliance with contract obligations
•	 general respect for the rule of law.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT50
(2013), economists from MIT and Harvard who studied
the program, concluded that, by all accounts, it was a
major success: following its launch in 1995, the market
performed “exceptionally well along all relevant dimen-
sions” and helped the United States reach emissions
goals in 2006.
However, the market’s collapse should be a cautionary
tale: “When the government creates a market, it can
also destroy it, possibly fostering a legacy of increased
regulatory uncertainty and reduced investor confi-
dence in future cap-and-trade regimes, and hence
reduced credibility of pollution markets more broadly”
(Schmalensee and Stavins, 2013).
Trust among market participants is a key element of
any WQT program. In the United States, most water
quality markets involve point sources purchasing pol-
lution reduction credits from farms, or less frequently,
from forests or other nonpoint sources. Controlling
nonpoint source pollution from agriculture faces
unique obstacles. Farmers often distrust regulators,
and worry that participation in a trading program may
open the door to future regulation. Some pilot pro-
grams in the United States have worked through local
soil and water conservation districts, or made use of
agricultural extension services, because the farmers
know and trust these agents. In fact, Mariola (2009)
found the most important factor for program success
was “the use of a local, trusted, embedded intermediary
as the link between programs and farmers emerges as
the most important explanatory variable for program
success.”
Canadian WQT managers have come to similar conclu-
sions. In the South Nation River watershed, wastewater
dischargers face a cap on phosphorus discharge, and
new wastewater systems are purchasing phosphorus
relocate the factory, install expensive onsite wastewater
treatment, or stop production altogether. In Australia’s
Hunter River, salty discharge from mines was affecting
the drinking water supplies for downstream cities, and
an inflexible basin cap would have meant that existing
mines could not expand and new industries could not
develop. In other cases, industries are interested in mit-
igating their own pollution to create goodwill or to help
lessen the burden of future regulation. This is the case
for power companies in the Ohio River Basin. At pres-
ent, large power companies such as Duke Energy, the
largest electric power holding company in the United
States with some 7.3 million customers, and American
Electric Power, which has over 5 million customers, pur-
chase credits “to meet corporate sustainability goals
and their voluntary participation may also be consid-
ered by the state permitting agencies when determin-
ing the need for flexible permit compliance options in
the future” (Fox, 2014).
In addition to demand, there must be willingness
to engage in trade among buyers and sellers. One
observer cited the most frequent roadblock to estab-
lishing a WQT program as the “simple absence of
willing buyers and sellers” (O’Grady, 2011). In WQT
markets, demand for the commodity (pollution credits)
“is artificially created by regulatory decree and which
cannot be seen or felt or even measured with preci-
sion” (Mariola, 2009). Because the market is entirely
dependent on a regulatory driver, it can be fragile and
susceptible to interference by politicians or the courts.
For example, the United States Acid Rain Program
(ARP), the nation’s first national cap-and-trade pro-
gram, suffered a series of legal challenges beginning
in 2008, culminating in new rules in 2011 that severely
limited trading between states. As a result, the market,
which relied heavily on interstate trading, collapsed. In
2012, the market value of a credit to emit a ton of sulfur
dioxide was less than $1. Previously, these same credits
had sold for $100 to $200 for most of the last decade
and peaked at $1,200 per ton in 2005 (Schmalensee
and Stavins, 2013). The ARP’s collapse is worth paus-
ing to consider, as it was the model for all subsequent
environmental markets. Schmalensee and Stavins
“In addition to demand, there must be
willingness to engage in trade among
buyers and sellers.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 51
The ability to trade water quality credits across regional
borders may be an important enabling condition,
depending on the geography of the watershed. Many
important watersheds extend across multiple states, or
across international boundaries. When trades can only
take place within a single state or country, it reduces
the potential for trading and for water quality improve-
ments (Fisher-Vanden and Olmstead, 2013). In 2012,
the pilot Ohio River Basin Trading Program became
the first program in the United States to allow trad-
ing across state borders, with an agreement signed by
the states of Ohio, Kentucky, and Indiana (Fox, 2014).
Lessons learned from the Acid Rain Program sug-
gest that legislation may be necessary for interstate
programs: “the series of regulations, court rulings, and
regulatory responses ... affirmed that EPA cannot set up
an interstate trading system under the Clean Air Act in
the absence of specific legislation” (Schmalensee and
Stavins, 2013).
Limiting conditions for water quality trading may be
created by existing laws, policies, and institutions in
some regions. Greiber (2009) described a number of
possible concerns related to the legal and institutional
frameworks for environmental markets. Unrelated laws
may contradict the aims of a market by, for example,
providing perverse incentives to polluting industries or
restricting innovative ways of funding environmental
projects. Land tenure is a key concern in some coun-
tries, as farmers without tenure may have little incen-
tive to participate in programs if they do not own land
and their futures are more uncertain.
credits from rural landowners, mainly farmers. Initially,
the agricultural community had reservations about the
program. One of the main concerns raised by farmers
during the design of the South Nation program was their
future liability.
Organizers confronted this concern during a series of
public meetings and then added a key phrase to their
final document that addressed the farmers’ concerns
and allowed trading to begin (O’Grady, 2011) – the
phrase was: “Landowners are not bound, legally or
otherwise, to attain the predicted phosphorus offset
through the establishment of a BMP [best manage-
ment practice, another term for an on-farm pollution
control measure] on their property.” Further, control of
the program was granted to South Nation Conservation,
a community-based watershed organization that was
trusted by farmers. In addition, the program is run by a
multi-stakeholder committee, “and all project field visits
are done by farmers and not paid professionals.” As a
result, the program has been able to overcome much of
the early resistance. An independent evaluation showed
that most farmers had a high opinion of the program
and have recommend the program to other farmers in
their community (O’Grady, 2011).
“When trades can only take place within
a single state or country, it reduces the
potential for … water quality improvements.”
IrrigationnearCastroville,CA.PhotographbyGwendolynStansbury.
4
Role of the private sector
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 53
The private sector participates to some degree in all
of the instruments described in the previous section.
For example, in Michigan’s Paw Paw River Watershed,
Coca-Cola North America and other stakeholders
recently developed and implemented a performance-
based PWS program to compensate farmers for imple-
menting practices that reduce soil loss and enhance
groundwater recharge (Forest Trends, 2015b). The pri-
vate sector also participates as a buyer or seller in water
quality trading programs to comply with water quality
regulations, or buys or sells water rights through water
trading programs. In addition to these incentive-based
instruments, the private sector may participate in a
range of voluntary initiatives to, for example, restore or
protect a watershed or provide water service to local
communities. Moreover, they may employ incentives
within their direct operations or supply chains to pro-
mote water stewardship. In this section, we describe
some of the drivers for private sector engagement in
water stewardship, provide examples of their participa-
tion in incentive-based programs, and provide an initial
estimate of their investment in these programs.
4.1 Corporate water stewardship
To produce goods and services, most companies rely
on a consistent supply of adequate quality source
water and permission to discharge wastewater. As
population growth and economic development push
the limits of renewable freshwater supplies and busi-
ness-as-usual resource management strategies, and as
rapid urbanization, water pollution, groundwater deple-
tion, and climate change introduce new water-related
risks, companies face increasing urgency to respond.
Companies typically come to understand their relation-
ship to water in terms of their water footprint and their
water-related business risk. A water footprint assess-
ment – which estimates the volume of water consumed
and polluted in the production of a material or a prod-
uct, or in the operation of an entire business, industry,
or nation – can help managers more fully understand
the nature and extent of a company’s dependence
and impact on water resources. It is also appealing as
a basis for setting targets to reduce water use related
to, for example, manufacturing processes or production
of agricultural raw materials. While a water footprint
assessment can inform a risk assessment, a volumetric
footprint measurement omits the local context neces-
sary to characterize the risks related to water use, and
obscures the difference in impact between using water
“Companies … understand their relationship
to water in terms of their water footprint and
their water-related business risk.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT54
Effective water resource management systems and
regulatory frameworks, the performance of which can
be enhanced by incentive-based instruments, benefit
companies in a number of ways.
•	 As water users, companies benefit from a more reli-
able and higher quality supply of water.
•	 As polluters, businesses benefit from opportunities
to manage the cost of compliance over time, and to
seek innovative approaches to improve the quality
and reduce the volume of wastewater.
•	 As ratepayers and taxpayers, companies benefit by
avoiding the cost of adding new or expanding ex-
isting supply.
Efforts to reduce water-related business risks typically
occur at three scales: within direct operations, in supply
chain agricultural or manufacturing operations that are
not within a company’s direct control, or outside the
fenceline of both owned and supply chain properties,
where water-related risks are driven more by sociopo-
litical, hydrological, or ecological conditions than by the
actions of the company or its suppliers.
from a source that’s plentiful and using the same vol-
ume of water from a source that’s overexploited or not
readily replenished.28
Water-related business risks generally fall into three
broad and interrelated categories:
•	 physical risks include scarcity, degraded source
water quality, and flooding
•	 regulatory risks relate to inconsistent, ineffective,
or poorly enforced public policy, particularly when
a change in regulation or enforcement could dis-
rupt production or lead to an unexpected cost of
compliance
•	 reputational risks are faced by companies that
overexploit or are perceived to overexploit water
resources – including inefficient use, water pollu-
tion, excessive withdrawal, competition with other
users, or other negligent water-related activities.
All three categories of risk include financial impacts
from increased operating costs, fines or unplanned
capital expenditures, supply chain disruptions, damage
to the value of a brand, or lost access to markets.
Increasingly, businesses are taking steps to identify,
characterize, and mitigate these risks. For example, the
Aqueduct Water Risk Atlas, a web-based tool produced
by the World Resources Institute, identifies which and
how many locations in a company’s operations or sup-
ply chain face water-related risk in 12 dimensions, as
shown in Figure 7. The Water Risk Filter, an online
tool launched by the World Wide Fund for Nature
(WWF) and the German Investment and Development
Corporation (DEG), assigns each water-using location
a score that incorporates both location-specific and
company-specific risks, based on criteria such as the
average water intensity or typical level of water pol-
lution generated by suppliers to a particular industry
sector (WWF and DEG, 2014).
28	 Water “neutrality” or “offsets” are related concepts, similar to carbon
neutrality or carbon offsets. They imply that a company can compen-
sate for the negative impacts of its water footprint. However, there is no
standard for measuring negative impacts or defining which types and
how much of any given activity is sufficient compensation (Hoekstra et
al., 2011).
Baseline water
stress
Inter-annual
variability
Seasonal
variability
Flood occurence
Droughtseverity
Upstream storage
Groundwater
Stress
Return flow ratio
Upstream
protected land
Media coverage
Access to water
Threatened
amphibians
Physical Risk
Quantity
Physical Risk
Quality
Regulatory and
Reputational Risk
OVERALL WATER RISK
FIGURE 7. Water risk indicators
Source: Gassert et al., 2013.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 55
Another recent development is the idea of engag-
ing outside the fenceline. Leading companies under-
stand that collective action with other stakeholders at
the watershed scale may be required to address root
causes of resource scarcity, accessibility, or source
water quality, which can increase costs or disrupt
operations. The Beverage Industry Environmental
Roundtable (BIER), a coalition of business leaders in
an industry that faces substantial water-related repu-
tational risk, has acknowledged that in some locations,
watershed-level interventions may in fact be more
effective at mitigating water-related risk than facility-
level water-use efficiency or other activities (BIER,
2015). To assist companies in prioritizing their efforts,
BIER has proposed developing a decision support tool
that could give more priority to intervention outside
the fenceline than to internal efficiency or water quality
improvements.
4.2 Private sector engagement with
incentive-based instruments
Private sector participation in incentive-based instru-
ments, such as PWS and water quality trading, has been
relatively modest but is growing. Bennett and Carroll
(2014) found that in 2013, the private sector invested
US$41 million in watershed services that supported
“watershed restoration or protection that delivers ben-
efits to society.” While this represents more than twice
the estimated private sector investment of $19 million
to $26 million in 2011, it is still a very small portion of the
overall $12.3 billion invested collectively in watersheds
by governments, business, and individual donors in
2013. Most private sector watershed investment activ-
ity (about 95  percent) took place in North America,
Europe, and Africa (Bennett and Carroll, 2014).
•	 Direct operations. Companies that recognize wa-
ter-relatedbusinessrisksoftenbeginworkingvolun-
tarily with direct operations – owned and operated
offices, distribution or retail facilities, manufacturing
facilities, farms or other means of production – to
mitigate those risks. In direct operations, companies
can plan and manage implementation internally and
realize cost savings related to obtaining, pumping,
heating, or treating smaller volumes of water when
operational efficiencies are achieved.
•	 Supply chains. From agricultural raw materials to
water- and chemical-intensive manufacturing pro-
cesses, most companies face challenges managing
water-related business risks in their supply chains,
including those with advanced water stewardship
practices in their direct operations. In many cases,
complex business models and limited traceability
are significant obstacles to quantifying corporate
water footprints and identifying water-related busi-
ness risks that exist in global supply chains.
•	 Outside the fenceline. Facilities that maintain
industry average or better water efficiency and
wastewater quality may not be immune to all wa-
ter-related risks. The term “outside the fenceline”
refers to conditions and activities outside the phys-
ical footprint of a production site. Water-related risk
is said to originate outside the fenceline in regions
where, for example, source water is scarce or pol-
luted, projected demand exceeds renewable sup-
ply, regulations are inconsistent or nonexistent, or
lack of access to water and sanitation damages
public health. While internal process or policy
changes are easier to implement, they would not
necessarily mitigate these risks.
The private sector increasingly recognizes the need
to evaluate site-level water use in the context of its
local watershed characteristics, in order to inform and
prioritize efficiency targets for different locations. For
example, companies can manage risk more effectively
by giving higher priority to efficiency improvements for
water-intensive locations in drought-prone locations
than for similar facilities where water resources are
more plentiful.
“Most private sector watershed investment
activity … took place in North America,
Europe, and Africa.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT56
provide opportunities for projects within the corpo-
rate replenish initiative to directly mitigate risks in the
global supply chain. Other projects’ impacts, such as
those related to access to water and sanitation or ones
where Coca-Cola contributed to a collective action
together with other companies, are estimated differ-
ently (Rozza et al., 2013).
Disincentives for private sector investments.
There are also disincentives for private sector invest-
ments in public goods, including watershed services.
The benefits must be shared with others that did not
contribute to the investment, and the benefits could
be exhausted by other actors that did not participate
in the collective action or investment (Meißner, 2013).
However, when the consequences of inaction are sig-
nificant, there is a compelling case in favor of policy
engagement, collective action, and investment in
water-related initiatives outside the fenceline, includ-
ing preservation of resources or delivery of ecosystem
services via incentive-based instruments.
Among the barriers that prevent the private sector
from participating more fully in watershed investments
are three critical core competencies needed to achieve
measureable outcomes with specific benefits for at-risk
locations, which most companies do not possess:
•	 scientific and environmental engineering expertise
to identify, design, and implement watershed-level
solutions
•	 a nuanced understanding of the local environment
and culture in the watershed where they seek to
have a positive environmental outcome
•	 experience with partnerships involving diverse
stakeholders outside the fenceline.
Therefore, in cases where companies identify risk and
choose to take action at the watershed level, particu-
larly if they choose to do so in more than one location
across diverse global operations or an extended supply
chain, it is helpful and sometimes necessary to involve
an intermediary. Stanton et al. (2010) defined an inter-
mediary as “any party other than the buyer or seller who
Incentives for private sector investments. Industry
sectors with the highest levels of investment in water-
shed services (IWS) were energy utilities, water utilities,
and the food and beverage industry, with investments
of US$9.3 million, $8.9 million, and $8.8 million, respec-
tively. The primary reported motivation for spending
on watershed services was regulatory compliance,
followed by water availability risks, water quality risks,
corporate social responsibility and reputational risk,
and biodiversity protection (Bennett and Carroll, 2014).
The food and beverage sector, which accounted for
nearly one-quarter of the total corporate investment in
watersheds, is unlike other sectors in that it is driven
primarily by water availability and water risks, rather
than regulatory compliance. Bennett and Carroll (2014)
found that 88 percent of buyers in the food and bever-
age industry acted voluntarily, compared with the pri-
vate sector average of 31 percent.
For example, in 2012–2013, the Coca-Cola Company
and its global bottling partners were involved in 20
projects around the world, buying at least $2.2 mil-
lion in watershed services (Bennett and Carroll, 2014).
Separately, the company publishes annual reports
detailing its involvement in hundreds of other projects
(LimnoTech, 2013). Indeed, the Coca-Cola Company
is among a handful of private companies with a public
commitment to “replenish” the water it uses.29 However,
as Coca-Cola acknowledges, the impacts of water use
are specific and local, making it impossible for a multi-
national corporation to offset water use at the enter-
prise level. Rozza et al. (2013) described a detailed
methodology for quantifying the value of Coca-Cola’s
replenish projects, including source water protection,
water reuse for conservation or productive uses, and
community-level sustainability projects. The company
also requires its bottling plants to complete source
water vulnerability assessments and to engage in the
development of source water protection plans, which
29	 Specifically, Coca-Cola is “Collaborating to replenish the water we use”,
pledging that by 2020, it will “safely return to communities and nature
an amount of water equal to what we use in our finished beverages and
their production.”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 57
are driving increased adoption of water risk assess-
ment across the business community. For example, in
its annual survey of leaders and decision makers about
perceptions of global risks, the World Economic Forum
(WEF, 2015) found that water crises have the greatest
potential for impact and are the eighth most likely to
occur, as shown in Figure 8. Moreover, WEF has consid-
ered water among the top three global risks since 2012
(WEF, 2012; 2013; 2014).
CDP, formerly known as the Carbon Disclosure Project,
operates a water program that surveys companies
helps facilitate some aspect of the transaction or imple-
mentation of the overall program. This role is commonly
played by NGOs, consultants, or academic institutions.”
Indeed, Coca-Cola has had to coordinate large-scale
bilateral partnerships with more than one intermediary
in order to achieve progress toward its global replen-
ish objective, including The Nature Conservancy, WWF,
and the  United Nations Development Programme
(UNDP). Table 3 illustrates increasing complexity and
differences in motivation that companies face as they
move from addressing efficiency in direct operations to
engaging in collective action intended to create more
sustainable operating conditions in watersheds where
they do business.
Future investments by the private sector are uncertain.
However, consumer preference for more sustainable
products and investor concern about unmitigated risk
TABLE 3. Private sector activities, scale, drivers
ACTIVITIES, COMPLEXITY, INCLUSIVITY
Operational efficiency
Wastewater quality
Owned facilities
Codes of conduct
Social/environmental indices
Voluntary sustainability standards
Industry sector/association
Policy engagement
Collective action
Diverse stakeholders
SCALE
Site-specific
Small business
Supply chain
Small to medium enterprise
Landscape
Multinational
TIME/VALUE
Near-term, return on investment Medium-term, possible value capture Long-term, sustainability
DRIVERS
Financial self-interest
Regulatory compliance
Externalities
License to operate
Reputation
Access to markets
EXTERNAL CONDITIONS
Strong governance and enforcement Inconsistent local regulation and
enforcement
Weak governance
Negative externalities of other actors
“…there is increasing awareness of water-
specific issues and of best practices in
corporate water stewardship…”
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT58
Figure 1: The Global Risks Landscape 2015
4.54.03.5 5.0 5.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
4.82
average
average
4.74
Likelihood
Impact
Top 10 risks in terms of
Likelihood
Categories
Interstate conflict
Extreme weather events
Failure of national governance
State collapse or crisis
Unemployment or underemployment
Natural catastrophes
Failure of climate-change adaptation
Water crises
Data fraud or theft
Cyber attacks
Top 10 risks in terms of
Impact
Water crises
Weapons of mass destruction
Interstate conflict
Energy price shock
Failure of climate-change adaptation
Fiscal crises
Unemployment or underemployment
Biodiversity loss and ecosystem collapse
Spread of infectious diseases
Critical information infrastructure breakdown
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
7.0
1.0 7.0
plotted
area
Economic
Geopolitical
Environmental
Societal
Technological
Misuse of
technologies Data fraud
or theft
Cyber
attacks
Critical information
infrastructure breakdown
Water crises
Spread of
infectious diseases
Profound social instability
Large-scale
involuntary migration
Food crises
Failure of urban planning
Weapons of
mass destruction
Terrorist
attacks
State collapse
or crisis
Interstate
conflict
Failure of
national governance
Natural catastrophes
Man-made environmental
catastrophes
Failure of
climate-change
adaptation
Biodiversity loss and
ecosystem collapse
Unmanageable
inflation
Unemployment
or underemployment
Fiscal crises
Failure of
critical infrastructure
Energy price
shock
Deflation
Asset bubble
Extreme
weather events
Failure of financial
mechanism or institution
Source: Global Risks Perception Survey 2014.
Note: Survey respondents were asked to assess the likelihood and impact of the individual risks on a scale of 1 to 7, 1 representing a risk that is not likely to happen or have
impact, and 7 a risk very likely to occur and with massive and devastating impacts. See Appendix B for more details. To ensure legibility, the names of the global risks are
abbreviated. Also see Appendix A for the full name and description.
FIGURE 8: Global risks landscape, 2015
Note: Taken from 2014 Global Risks Perception Survey. Survey respondents were asked to assess the likelihood and impact of the
individual risks on a scale of 1 to 7, 1 representing a risk that is not likely to happen or have impact, and 7 a risk very likely to occur
and with massive and devastating impacts. See Appendix B for more details. To ensure legibility, the names of the global risks are
abbreviated. Also see Appendix A for the full name and description.
Source: World Economic Forum, 2015.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 59
Concurrently, there is increasing awareness of water-
specific issues and of best practices in corporate water
stewardship, so there will likely be demand for mecha-
nisms that can deliver quantifiable outcomes to ben-
efit specific corporate assets or at-risk strategic supply
chain locations. Increased understanding of water-
related risks and opportunities could similarly drive an
increase in private sector engagement in incentive-
based instruments for watershed services.
in order to reveal water-related risk in institutional
investment portfolios. CDP’s 2014 Global Water Report
revealed that, of nearly 1,100 responding companies,
74  percent had evaluated how water quantity and
quality could affect their growth strategy. However, of
these, only 38 percent assessed water-related risk in
both owned operations and their supply chain, and only
25 percent conducted detailed water risk assessments
at the watershed level (CDP, 2014).
HunterRiver,Australia.PhotographbyAussieLegend.
5
Summary and conclusions
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 61
Growing pressure on the availability and quality of
water resources is having a major impact on our social,
economic, and environmental well-being. These pres-
sures are likely to worsen in response to continued
population and economic growth, climate change, and
other challenges. As water pollution exacerbates the
challenges posed by water scarcity, and the world’s
water quality becomes increasingly degraded, new
approaches and strategies are needed.
One key area of interest is the potential for incen-
tive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water
resources. To date, the primary environmental pol-
icy tool to address water challenges has been com-
mand-and-control regulations. Over the past several
decades, however, the environmental policy “toolkit”
has expanded to include a host of incentive-based
instruments that use financial means, directly or indi-
rectly, to motivate responsible parties to reduce the
health and environmental risks posed by their facili-
ties, processes, or products. While regulations and
incentive-based instruments are often juxtaposed, “in
reality the two often operate alongside each other”
(UNEP, 2004). With water quality trading, for example,
governments mandate caps on the allowable pollut-
ant levels and issue tradable permits that allow those
in the industry to allocate polluting activities among
themselves, incentivized by market forces. Similarly,
with water trading, governments may allocate water
and then institute a framework by which water trad-
ing can occur. While incentive-based instruments
may work in tandem, they must be integrated within
a broader watershed management effort. In a recent
review of PWS programs, Bond and Mayers (2010)
cautioned that:
“PWS is a tool that will fail, or become irrelevant, if it
is not integrated with wider regulatory approaches,
broaderwatershedmanagementefforts,andexplicit
attention to governance influences that shape
what is possible. Policy makers need to consider
the opportunities to ensure that future policy and
legislation allow for a mix of both incentives and
regulations to ensure the effective management of
land and water resources.”
The choice of whether and which instrument to apply
depends on the specific circumstances, conditions, and
needs of a given area. It is important to avoid “the law
of the instrument”, i.e. the tendency to gravitate toward
a particular tool and then look for applications of that
tool. UNEP (2004) found that:
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT62
for consistent and rigorous outreach and, potentially, a
need for engaging a trusted intermediary.
Finally, monitoring and evaluation are essential to the
success of any instrument. In particular, they help
ensure outcomes are achieved and allow for adjust-
ments in response to changing social, economic, or
environmental conditions. Monitoring should evaluate
the additionality of the program, i.e. whether the pro-
gram has an effect when compared with baseline con-
ditions. It should also examine any potential impacts on
surrounding areas (e.g. leakage) and the permanence
of the intervention. However, it is important to recog-
nize that extensive monitoring requirements would
increase transaction costs. Thus, the need for moni-
toring and evaluation must be balanced with practical
considerations about the ability to maintain the viability
of the program.
“Prior to designing and applying any policy instrument
for environmental protection, the policy context must
be understood, including the existing institutional,
legal and economic conditions in which these tools
are meant to function. Choosing an effective policy
package that will both address the environmental
problem policy makers are faced with and fit in with the
institutional capabilities and existing policy framework
remains one of the most difficult challenges.”
This process should be open and transparent, with
meaningful participation from all affected parties. This
will enable crafting a solution that not only is appropri-
ate for local conditions, it will help reduce opposition
and promote buy-in from those who will be imple-
menting and affected by the program. It is important
to recognize that those with the least power may not
have the resources to participate or be skeptical of the
groups involved. In these cases, there will be a need
ANNEX 1
Demand management
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 63
A key way to reduce pressure on limited water supplies
is through demand management, commonly referred
to as water conservation and efficiency. In many cases,
reducing demand is equivalent to augmenting or real-
locating water supply. Demand management is typi-
cally less expensive and faster to implement than water
supply augmentation, and often results in reduced
energy demand and water and wastewater treatment
costs. For example, a recent study in Westminster,
Colorado, found that water conservation and efficiency
since 1980 had reduced water use in the city, reduc-
ing tap fees by 80 percent and reducing customers’
bills by 91  percent relative to what they would have
been without these efforts (Feinglas, Gray, and Mayer
2013). In major cities, such as San Francisco and Los
Angeles, total water use has decreased since the late
1970s despite population and economic growth. At a
larger scale, a recent United States federal study found
that water conservation and efficiency efforts have
reduced annual demand for water from the Colorado
River basin by more than 1.7 million acre-feet, a tremen-
dous savings in an over-allocated basin (US Bureau of
Reclamation 2015). In the United States, we have made
considerable progress in managing the nation’s water,
with total water use less than it was in 1970, despite
continued population and economic growth. Indeed,
every sector, from agriculture to thermoelectric power
generation, shows reductions in water use. Likewise,
in Australia, a severe drought in the middle of the last
decade prompted an intensive effort to reduce water
demand. In response, total urban demand, including
losses and non-residential consumption, fell from about
130 gallons per capita daily (gpcd) in 2005 to about 80
gpcd in 2010 (Queensland Water Commission, 2010).
There are many tools available to reduce water demand
– some of which rely on an incentive-based approach,
e.g. pricing and rebates, while others are based on a
more traditional command-and-control approach.
Numerous studies have shown that significant conser-
vation and efficiency opportunities exist in urban and
agricultural areas (see, e.g. Gleick et al., 2003; Heberger,
Cooley, and Gleick 2014). Below, we provide additional
detail on the major demand management tools, includ-
ing pricing, direct financial incentives, regulations, and
education and outreach.
Water pricing. Well-designed tariff structures can
meet multiple policy objectives, including supporting
the financial stability of the utility, the affordability of
water for low-income customers, the efficient alloca-
tion of water and other resources, and environmental
sustainability. Most water utilities use some form of
volumetric tariffs to achieve these objectives. There
are several types of volumetric tariffs in use around the
world:
•	 uniform tariffs in which the volumetric tariff ($/m3)
is constant regardless of the quantity used;
•	 inclining block tariffs in which the volumetric tariff
increases as the quantity used increases; and
•	 declining block tariffs in which the volumetric tariff
decreases as the quantity used increases.
Uniform tariffs are the most common tariff structure
in OECD and in developing countries (OECD 2009).
Inclining block rates are becoming increasingly com-
mon (OECD 2009), as there is recognition that when
designed properly, this approach can provide a strong
financial incentive to conserve while ensuring that
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT64
Instead of providing rebates to cover a portion of the
cost, some utilities have opted to institute direct-install
programs that cover the entire cost of the device and
the installation costs. In the mid-1990s, for example, the
New York City Department of Environmental Protection
launched a massive toilet rebate program to replace
one-third of all water-wasting toilets in New York City
with low-flow models. For this effort, property owners
contracted directly with private licensed plumbers for
the installation of the toilet, and after completion of
the work, the City provided the property owner with a
$240 rebate for the first toilet and $150 for the second
toilet. Where possible, the plumber would also install
low-flow showerheads and faucet aerators. The pro-
gram was a huge success. Between 1994 and 1997, 1.3
million low-flow toilets were installed, saving 70 - 90
million gallons per day. Customers saw their water and
wastewater bills drop 20 percent to 40 percent (EPA
2002). Additionally, the City was able to defer the need
to develop new supply sources and expand wastewater
treatment capacity, saving the community even more
money.
Regulations. In addition to financial incentives, reg-
ulations are key demand management strategies.
Regulations can take a variety of forms, ranging from
a prescriptive approach focused on a particular appli-
ance to a performance-based approach for outdoor
water use. For example, the International Plumbing
Code, which is widely used in the United States and
forms the basis for plumbing codes in several other
countries, specifies maximum flow rates for kitchen
and lavatory faucets. Likewise, communities in the Las
Vegas area have restricted lawn installation in new
developments. California has also passed an ordinance
to reduce outdoor water use, although the state opted
for a performance-based approach. Landscape irriga-
tion typically accounts for more than half of residen-
tial demand in the state, and in an effort to promote
outdoor efficiency, the state adopted the Model Water
Efficient Landscape Ordinance (MWELO). MWELO
lower-income consumers are able to meet their basic
water needs at a reduced cost. A 2003 survey of cities
in the southwest United States found that per-capita
water use is typically lower in cities with dramatically
increasing block tariffs, such as Tucson and El Paso
(WRA 2003).
Although less frequently employed, pricing has also
been shown to be effective in reducing agricultural
water use. For example, the Broadview Water District,
a small district in California’s San Joaquin Valley, imple-
mented increasing block rates in 1988 to reduce the
volume of contaminated drainage water flowing into
the San Joaquin River. The rate was set at $16 per
acre-foot ($0.013 per m3) for the first 90 percent of
average water use during the 1986 to 1988 period and
$40 per acre-foot ($0.032 per m3) for any additional
water. By 1991, the district’s average water use declined
by 19 percent due to efficiency improvements and crop
shifting (MacDougall et al., 1992).
Direct financial incentives. Rebate programs are
commonly used to encourage customers to make
investments in water conservation and efficiency
improvements. Residents and business owners pur-
chase new devices as the old devices wear out. While
most new standard devices use less water than older
models, there are many new high-efficiency devices
available that use even less water. While efficient
devices are often cheaper over their lifetimes due to
lower water, energy, and wastewater bills, users may be
put off by the higher up-front costs. As a result, water
utilities may provide their customers with a rebate to
defray the additional cost of the more efficient device.
There are several examples of water utilities partner-
ing with local energy utilities to augment those rebates
because of the energy savings (Cooley and Donnelly
2013). Additionally, utilities may partner with retailers
to offer rebates at the point of sale, giving customers
an immediate incentive to purchase the more efficient
device.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 65
Education and outreach. Education and outreach
programs can also be effective for promoting water
conservation and efficiency. The US Environmental
Protection Agency (EPA), for example, launched the
WaterSense labeling program in 2006 to promote
water-conserving devices that are 20  percent more
efficient than standard products on the market and
meet rigorous performance criteria. Social market-
ing has also gained prominence in recent years, with
some programs tapping into new metering technolo-
gies and web-based platforms. For example, a recent
study found that home water reports - which provide
customers information on their current water use and
comparisons to their past use, use by similar house-
holds, and efficient use - reduce water by 5 percent and
were especially effective in reaching the highest water
users (Mitchell and Chesnutt 2013).
establishes a water budget for new construction and
rehabilitated landscapes that are at least 2,500 square
feet and require a building or landscaping permit (the
size threshold is likely to be reduced to 500 square
feet in response to the current drought). In addition,
the ordinance requires mulching for most plantings;
promotes the use of techniques to increase storm-
water retention and infiltration; and requires new and
refurbished landscapes to install irrigation systems run
by weather, soil moisture, or other self-adjusting con-
trollers. Also in California, Governor Schwarzenegger
signed SBx7-7 in 2009, requiring urban water suppliers
to reduce per-capita water use by 20 percent by 2020.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT66
The MDB includes parts of four states (Queensland,
New South Wales, Victoria, and South Australia) and the
Australian Capital Territory. The MDB supplies water to
about three million people, including the national capi-
tal (Canberra) and Adelaide, outside of the basin near
the river’s mouth. According to the MDBA, the basin
contains some 70 percent of the nation’s irrigated acre-
age, producing a third of the country’s food supply. The
MDBA reports the gross value of irrigated agriculture in
the basin in 2012-13 at approximately $6.8 Billion. The
MDB generates almost all of Australia’s rice and cotton
and 75 percent of its grapes, as well as roughly half of
the nation’s hay, fruit, livestock, and dairy production.
The construction of dams and canals and the diver-
sion and depletion of MDB rivers has endangered the
survival of at least 35 bird species and 16 mammal spe-
cies within the basin. Many fish species, including the
Murray cod, are also threatened. Wetlands have dried
up or reached critically low levels, exacerbated by the
Millennium drought, prompting public concern.
MDB and the Colorado
River Basin
The MDB and the Colorado River Basin share many
common traits: both are highly variable rivers in arid
basins, where rapidly-growing urban populations have
imposed new demands on limited, climate-stressed
rivers. Basin size and runoff are similar. And, interest-
ingly, the two basins share a common figure: Elwood
Mead (namesake of Lake Mead), the Wyoming State
Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin (MDB) figures promi-
nently in discussions about water trading as an example
of a thriving incentive-based system that successfully
transitioned from a non-market system (Grafton et al.,
2012). The total value of water trading in Australia in
fiscal year 2012-13 exceeded $1.4 billion (NWC 2013).
Water trading in Australia includes both short-term
trades, known as allocation trading, and long-term
trades, known as entitlement trading. In fiscal year
2012-13, the most recent period for which comprehen-
sive data are available, the total volume of short-term
trading increased 44 percent from the previous year,
from almost 3.5 million acre-feet to 5 million acre-feet,
or roughly 50 percent of total surface water use in the
MDB. This is an extremely active water market.
Background
The MDB covers some 390,000 square miles in south-
eastern Australia, comprising roughly 14 percent of that
country’s land area. Most of the basin is very arid, with
86 percent of the basin contributing little or no flow to
rivers that drain the basin. The Murray-Darling Basin
Authority (MDBA) estimates that total runoff within the
basin is less than 26 million acre-feet annually, yield-
ing an estimated long-term annual average 19 MAF
of total river flow. As shown in Figure A-1, the system
displays very high seasonal and annual variability. For
example, flows in the southern Murray basin typically
are much higher than in the northern Darling basin.
Pre-development, an estimated 10 million acre-feet ran
into the ocean; in 2009, during the historic Millennium
drought, this had decreased to 4 million acre-feet.
ANNEX 2
Water trading in Australia:
Lessons from the Murray-Darling Basin
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 67
subsequently changing the water rights structure to
facilitate trading and protect environmental resources.
In Australia, water rights typically refer to either entitle-
ments or allocations.30 The National Water Initiative of
2004 defines these as:
•	 Water access entitlement – a perpetual or ongo-
ing entitlement to exclusive access to a share of
water from a specified consumptive pool as defined
in the relevant water plan.
•	 Water allocation – the specific volume of water
allocated to water access entitlements in a given
season, defined according to rules established in
the relevant water plan. (Young, 2010).
Australian water rights are typically defined as the right
todivertaspecificvolume,asopposedtoaconsumptive
use right that is more typical with prior appropriation
30	 Additional water rights include: Water use license – a non-tradable
use or condition linked to the place of use; and Delivery right – may be
required to ensure that an allocation is delivered, typically associated
with irrigation infrastructure, such as canals and headgates (Grafton and
Horne 2014).
Irrigation Engineer from 1888-99, went on to serve as
the Chairman of Victoria (Australia)’s State Rivers 
Water Supply Commission (1907–15), prior to return-
ing to the US and serving as the Commissioner of the
Bureau of Reclamation from 1924-36 (McLeod 2014).
However, Australia avoided Mead’s legacy of prior
appropriation and hierarchical water rights to embrace
a very different system that promotes and facilitates
water trading, as described in the following sections.
History
Australia has promoted and developed water trading
over a period of more than 30 years (Grafton et al.,
2012), in a process that initially attempted to activate
markets prior to recognizing that the water rights struc-
ture itself needed to be altered to encourage active
trading and minimize transaction costs (Young, 2015).
Table A-1 lists some of the major steps taken to cre-
ate the current water trading structure. These changes
have occurred over several decades and often reflect
corrections to previous policies. Young (2010, 2015)
asserts that Australia implemented water trading from
the wrong direction, by first promoting trading and
FIGURE A-1. Historical river flows within the Murray-Darling Basin
1900s 1910s 1920s 1930s 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s
30,000
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
Flow(GLperyear)
Northern basin annual flows
Flow measured on Darling River at Bourke
Southern basin annual flows
Flow measured on River Murray at Euston
Average annual flow levels
1895
Startofthe
‘FederationDrought’
whichlastsfor7years
1909
Floodinthe
Murrayand
Wimmerarivers
1914
Severedrought
leadstotheend
ofcommercial
navigationonthe
Murrayand
Darlingrivers
1917
Floodingalong
theRiverMurray
1921
Floodingacross
theentireBasin
1931
Floodingalong
theRiverMurray
1944
Severedrought
throughoutNSW,
VicandSA.
Murrayceasesto
flowinsomeareas
1950
Recordrainfall
causeswidespread
floodinginCondamine
andWarregorivers
1952
Floodinginthe
RiverMurray
1956
HighestBasininflows
inrecordedhistory
causewidespread
flooding
1968
Duetosevere
drought,HumeDam
fallsto1%ofcapacity
1974
Widespreadflooding
acrosstheBasin,
knownasthe‘bigwet’
1981
Droughtforces
Adelaidetotake
90%ofitswater
fromtheMurray.
TheMurrayMouth
closesforthefirst
timeinrecorded
history
1993
Floodingacross
QLD,NSW
andVictoria
1997
Beginningoflongestdrought
inAustralia’srecordedhistory
2000MurrayMouthclosesand
requiresdredging
2010-11Widespreadflooding
throughouttheBasin
2006
Lowest water
inflowsonrecord
Extremedryin
NorthernBasin
2013-15
Note: Volumes in the figure shown in gigaliters, with 1000 GL = 0.8 million acre-feet.
Source: Australia’s MDBA.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT68
the land. Transforming these general land-based rights
to discrete volumes then required determining his-
toric usage patterns and water requirements for crops
grown on that land. Several MDB states initially allowed
water trading within individual irrigation districts, using
shared infrastructure to trade water to different parcels
within the district. These volumetric rights were subse-
quently “unbundled” from the land, enabling water to
be traded between different irrigation districts. Despite
these changes, restrictions on trading between dif-
ferent sub-basins often took years to revoke, due to
concerns about adverse economic and equity impacts
that trading could cause in areas of origin (Grafton and
Horne 2014).
regimes (Connor and Kaczan, 2013). Diversions can
be measured (and subsequently traded) more readily
than consumptive use, which requires measurement
of both diversions and surface and sub-surface return
flows. Return flows often lag diversions, sometimes by
weeks or months in the case of sub-surface returns,
requiring more complicated measurements and esti-
mates, challenging efforts to evaluate and quantify the
full impacts (especially environmental impacts) of the
trade, hindering transactions.
Initially, Australian water rights were linked to a spe-
cific land parcel. In many cases, the water right simply
entitled the landowner to sufficient water to irrigate
TABLE A-1. Policy and legislative milestones
YEAR ACTION DESCRIPTION
1960s Volumetric water licenses
Start of conversion of land-based water entitlements to volumetric
entitlements
1983 Water trading w/in districts Allowed in New South Wales and South Australia
1987 1st
MDB Agreement Established the MDB Commission, to coordinate management
1991 Inter-district water trading Allowed in New South Wales
1994 “Unbundling”
Council of Australian Governments agrees to separate statutory land
rights from water rights, facilitating trading
1995 Diversion CAP implemented Limits surface water diversions in the MDB; limits water rights
1995 National Competition Policy Requires development of water markets and full-cost pricing
2000 Water Management Act “Unbundles” diversion and use rights
2004 National Water Initiative Promotes cohesive water planning and trading efforts
2004 Living Murray Initiative Authorizes purchase and dedication of 0.4 MAF to the river
2007 Water Act Promotes management of MDB
2008 Water Amendment Act Establishes MDB Authority, replacing the Commission
2008 Water for the Future Commits $3.1 billion to purchase water entitlements for the env.
2012 MD Basin Plan
Caps total MDB surface diversions at 8.8 MAF, coordinates basin
management including water quality (esp. salinity)
Sources: MDBA, Young, 2010; Grafton and Horne, 2014.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 69
uses. New South Wales has attempted to limit federal
purchases of water for the environment to no more than
3 percent of total entitlements, though this appears to
contravene trading rules within the Basin Plan, which
seek to minimize restrictions on trading (Grafton and
Horne 2014).
State water plans allocate water entitlements into one
or two “pools,” known as a high security pool and a gen-
eral or low security pool. The high security pool is allo-
cated to those entitlement holders proportional to the
size of their entitlement. For example, if a system only
has two entitlement holders and one right is for nine
units and the other is for one unit, the former would
receive 90  percent of the pool’s allocation and the
latter would receive 10 percent. If additional water is
available for the general pool, that volume is allocated
to those entitlement holders. Every season, the state
determines the total volume available for allocation for
each pool. During drought, the general pool might not
receive any water at all (Young, 2010).
Water trading activity
Australia’s water trading activity is largely concentrated
in the MDB, which represents as much as 94 percent of
all such activity in Australia despite being only one of
twelve surface water management areas (Figure A-2).
Trading is very high as measured by the total volume
of water traded (as much as 5 million acre-feet), the
percentage of all diversions that are traded (as much
as 50 percent), the number of farmers trading water
(roughly half, in 2008-09), and the total number of
trades (11,000, in 2011-12). The number of short-term
(allocation) interstate trades also appears to be rising,
reaching 20 percent of the total number of such trades
in 2011/12 (Grafton and Horne 2014). Not surprisingly,
the number of short-term (allocation) trades is much
higher, in terms of numbers and volumes, than the
number of entitlement trades. As the federal govern-
ment has exercised its commitment to ensure minimum
Unlike the doctrine of prior appropriation in the west-
ern United States, water rights in Australia did not
have priority dates or a seniority system for satisfy-
ing demands: all rights were considered equivalent.
Additionally, Australian water rights did not have to
be exercised on an annual or periodic basis to demon-
strate possession (again, unlike the prior appropriation
system); many rights holders maintained their rights
for periodic or infrequent use (known as “dozer” rights)
or never exercised their water rights (known as “sleep-
ers”), perhaps in the expectation that they might be
needed in the future.
The 1995 imposition of the diversion CAP limiting
surface water diversions and rights within the MDBA
explicitly recognized the continuing validity of dozer
and sleeper rights and incorporated the volumes of
these rights into the general calculation of the propor-
tional shares of the new water rights regime. However,
the result of recognizing dozer and sleeper rights within
the context of water trading was to increase the finan-
cial value of these unexercised rights, leading to new
diversions and greater strain on water supply, in turn
reducing water reliability (Grafton and Horne 2014).
Tony McLeod, General Manager for Water Planning at
MDBA, explained that the recognition of these dozer
and sleeper rights was intentional, to reduce resistance
to the imposition of the CAP and smooth the transition
to the new system of proportional sharing (McLeod,
personal communication, 2014).
In response, the Australian government implemented
several initiatives to purchase existing water entitle-
ments and dedicate these to the environment, both to
offset reservoir evaporation and other system losses
(known as maintenance rights) and explicitly to ensure
minimum instream flow volumes in designated reaches.
The government has invested more than $3 Billion to
date to purchase entitlements for environmental water.
However, the relative priority of this environmental
water remains contentious, with some states contend-
ing that such rights receive lower priority than human
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT70
about $54 per acre-foot in the drier 2012/13.31 Similarly,
trading in drier years tends to see water move from lower
value uses, such as pasture and forage, to higher value
wine and vegetable crops. Connor and Kaczan (2013)
reported that many livestock operations irrigate pasture
and forage crops in wet years but tend to trade away
their allocations in drier years, when the price of water
rises due to scarcity, using the profits to purchase feed
from other areas. These trends also manifest regionally,
aswatertendstomoveacrossstatelinesfromNewSouth
Wales into South Australia, which has more high-value
31	 These prices are about an order of magnitude lower than prices for
short-term transfers in California in the 2014 drought year, but are
comparable to prices paid for short-term rentals in the active Northern
Colorado Water Conservancy district water market.
environmental flows by purchasing entitlements, such
purchases have risen to 37 percent of the total number
of entitlement trades in 2011/12. Only about 5 percent
of farmers traded water entitlements, either to other
farmers or to cities or to the government for augment-
ing environmental flows, in 2008/09, or about 10 per-
cent of the number that reported trading allocations
that year (Grafton and Horne 2014).
As expected, the number of allocation trades appears
to be inversely correlated with precipitation and runoff,
rising in drought years and falling when allocations are
higher due to wetter conditions. Prices similarly vary in
response to water availability, rising from the equivalent
of about $22 per acre-foot in 2011/12 to the equivalent of
81 0.NT
426.K
426.A
426.B
426.I
507.A
426.G
426.D
41 4.SAC
239.SAA
81 0.WA
809.WA
808
807
806
805
804
803
802
801
71 0709
708
707
706
705
704
703
702
701
61 9
61 8
61 7
61 6 61 5
61 461 3
61 2
611
61 0
609
608
607
606
605
604
602
601
026.WA
025
024
023.WA
022.WA
41 5
41 4.VIC
408
407
406
405
404
403
402
409.VIC
239.VIC
238
237
236
235
234
233
232
231
230
229
225
224
223
222.VIC
221 .VIC
31 4.I
31 4.H
31 2
31131 0
302.G
301
31 9.E
31 9.D
302.F
302.E
31 9.B
307.B
31 8.F
31 6
31 8.E
31 7
31 8.B
31 8.A
302.D
309
302.C
302.A
303 304.E
304.B
304.A
308
306
31 4.A
31 3
307.A
021 .D 004.A
023.SAB
51 3.D
51 3.C
51 3.B
51 3.A
426.C
023.SAA
503.C
501
003.SA
505.A
005.SA
021 .B
41 4.SAD
021 .C
026.SA
51 2
507.B
506.A
007.SA
426.F
506.B
021 .A
509
51 0
004.B
001 .SA
508.A
022.SA
511
508.B
239.SAC
239.SAE
41 4.SAA
002
41 6.QLD
11 7
11 0
924
1 23
1 22.B
925
923
1 34
1 29
423.A
11 3
1 27
1 44.B
1 04
91 5
1 28
11 8
1 22.A
922
1 261 25
424.QLD
1 02
1 24
1 05
422.A
11 4
111
91 3
928
1 43
41 7
91 9
1 38
1 03
11 2
1 06
927
1 01
1 44.A
921
11 5
11 6
1 46
001 .QLD
1 39
1 30
1 07
926
1 21
1 09
1 08
1 31
003.QLD
422.B
920
1 32
1 36
1 20
011
1 33
929
91 2
91 0
909
908
907
906
905
904
903
902
901
826
825824
823
822
821
820
81 9
81 8
81 7
81 6
81 5.B
81 5.A
81 4
81 3
81 2
811
809.NT
029
028
027
026.NT
023.NT
007.NT
006
005.NT
001 .NT
499
425.URB425.URA
425.R
421 .UR
421 .R
420
41 9.UR
41 9.R
41 8.UR
41 8.R
41 6.NSWR
41 6.NSWUR
41 2.UR
41 2.R
411
41 0.NSWUR
41 0.NSWR
409.NSW
401 .NSW
222.NSW
221 .NSW
220
21 9.UR
21 9.R
21 8
21 7
21 6
21 5
21 4
21 3
21 2 211
21 0.UR
21 0.R
208 207
206 205
204
203.UR
203.R
202
201
01 2
424.NSW
004.NSW
003.NSW
41 0.ACT
503.B
502
426.J
426.H
426.L
239.SAB
603
228
227
226
31 9.C
31 9.A
31 8.C
31 8.D
304.F
302.B
305
304.D
304.C
31 4.G
31 4.F31 4.E
31 4.D
31 4.C
31 5
31 4.B
505.C
503.A
504.B
504.C
505.E
504.A
505.G
505.F
505.B
426.E
505.D
41 4.SAB
239.SAD
1 45
209
PERTH
HOBART
SYDNEY
DARWIN
CANBERRA
ADELAIDE
BRISBANE
MELBOURNE
0 250 5001 25
Kilometres
Legend
Surface water
management areas
Drainage division
North-East Coast
South-East Coast
Tasmania
Murray-Darling
South Australia Gulf
South-West Coast
Indian Ocean
Timor Sea
Gulf of Carpentaria
Lake Eyre
Bulloo-Bancannia
Western Plateau
CommonwealthofAustralia© MapID: WA_L1_SWMA_28
WaterAustralian Resources 2005
FIGURE A-2. Surface water management areas in Australia
Source: Australia National Water Commission.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 71
market activity while protecting environmental values
by participating directly in the market, purchasing enti-
tlements from willing sellers and dedicating this water
to preserve threatened ecosystems and river reaches.
This approach has come at great expense to the gov-
ernment (and taxpayers) but has been justified by the
reported increase in economic activity and benefits
arising from trading activity. In a robust assessment
of water trading in Victoria’s Murray Valley, Frontier
Economics (2007) found strong local opposition to
permanently trading water out of local areas, to the
extent that some irrigators selling entitlements have
been ostracized, but also found a combination of posi-
tive and negative socio-economic impacts from such
trades. For example, the authors found that trading
ameliorated the impacts of the Millennium Drought on
dairy farmers in the region, who otherwise would have
fared much worse. Additionally, water trading facili-
tated the expansion of the wine industry in the region.
Several researchers have compiled extensive lists of
lessons learned. Two of these are reproduced below.
Young (2010) writes:
Lesson 1: Unless carefully managed, the legacy
of prior licensing decisions can result in markets
causing over-allocation problems to emerge in a
manner that erodes the health of rivers, aquifer and
the water dependent ecosystems associated with
them.
Lesson 2: Transaction and administrative costs
are lower when entitlements are defined using a
unit share structure and not as an entitlement to a
volume of water. One of the simplest ways of pre-
venting over-allocation problems from emerging is
to assign the risks of adverse climate change and/
or the emergence of long dry periods to entitlement
holders and define entitlements as an entitlement
to a share of the water defined as being available
for use.
Lesson 3: Market efficiency is improved by using
separate structures to define entitlements, manage
allocations and control the use of water.
crops. In response, New South Wales and Victoria have
imposed restrictions on the volume of water that may be
exported from the state (Grafton and Horne 2014).
Enabling conditions
A large number of necessary and enabling conditions
help explain Australia’s water trading success. Key
among these is the development of a proportional
water sharing regime, in which the state, rather than
administrative or water courts, determines total annual
water availability, rather than granting rights holders
an absolute or priority-based right to a fixed volume
of water. The Australian experience also shows that
water trading is more active when allocation pools
encompass a large number of entitlement holders with
a diverse range of uses (Young, 2010).
Grafton and Horne (2014) found that infrastructure,
such as dams and canals, can facilitate water trading by
storing water until needed and providing conveyances
to deliver where needed. Similarly, access to accurate
and timely information on water prices and availability
facilitates water trading. In Australia, brokerage-type
water banks are active in both the Murray-Darling Basin
and in northern Victoria, where the banks post informa-
tion about pricing and availability (O’Donnell and Colby
2010). Underpinning this information exchange is an
extensive, credible, verifiable registry of entitlements and
allocations and mechanism to quickly record, measure
and monitor trades, as well as sufficient sanctions on
those violating agreements (Connor and Kaczan 2013).
Lessons learned
Connor and Kaczan highlighted the classic dilemma
facing those attempting to implement a water trading
system: the tradeoff between protecting third parties
with high transaction costs versus promoting trades
with low transaction costs, with less concern for third
parties. Australia has adopted the latter approach,
choosing to minimize transaction costs and promote
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT72
Lesson 11: Water use and investment will be more
efficient if all users are exposed to at least the
full lower bound cost and preferably the upper
bound cost of supplying water to them. One way of
achieving this outcome is to transfer ownership of
the supply system to these users.
Lesson 12: Manage environmental externalities
using separate instruments so that the costs of
avoiding them are reflected in the costs of produc-
tion and use in a manner that encourages water
users to avoid creating them.
Lesson 13: Removal of administrative impediments
to inter-regional trade and inter-state trade is difficult
but necessary for the development of efficient water
markets. Australia has taken the approach of ap-
pointing an independent agency to develop rules
designed to remove unnecessary barriers to water
trade. Amongst other things, this has required the
setting of guidelines that prevent water supply
companies from setting charges and adopting
practices that discriminate against people who wish
to trade water out of a region.
Lesson 14: Markets will be more efficient and the
volume of trade greater if entitlements are allocated
to individual users rather than to irrigator controlled
water supply companies and cooperatives. Whilst
opposed by water supply companies and coopera-
tives, it is the Australian experience that willingness
to trade and market depth typically is much greater
when entitlements are allocated to individuals rather
than to water supply companies or associations as
they are called in other countries. The reason for
this is that when allocations are issued to individu-
als they do not have to obtain the permission of the
board of a water supply company or association to
sell water out of a region.
Lesson 15: Equity and fairness principles require
careful attention to and discipline in the way
that allocation decisions and policy changes are
announced.
Lesson 16: Water markets are more effective when
information about the prices being paid and offered
is made available to all participants in a timely
manner.
Lesson 4: Early attention to the development of
accurate license registers is critical and a necessary
precondition to the development of low-cost entitle-
ment trading systems.
Lesson 5: Unless water market and allocation pro-
cedures allow unused water to be carried forward
from year to year, trading may increase the severity
of droughts.
Lesson 6: Early installation of meters and conver-
sion from area based licenses to a volumetric man-
agement system is a necessary precursor to the
development of low cost allocation trading systems.
Metering and conversion to a volumetric allocation
system is a necessary precursor to the development
of efficient water trading systems. In order to facili-
tate the more efficient management of the available
resource and trading, Australia has spent many
years converting area-based licenses to volumetric
licenses and installing meters. Typically, conversion
involves estimation of the amount of water used
by crop type and the development of conversion
factors.
Lesson 7: It is difficult for communities to plan for
an adverse climate shift and develop water sharing
plans that deal adequately with a climatic shift to
a drier regime. More robust planning and water en-
titlement systems are needed.
Lesson 8: The allocation regime for the provision of
water necessary to maintain minimum flows, provide
for conveyance and cover evaporative losses need
to be more secure than that used to allocate water
for environmental and other purposes.
Lesson 9: Unless all forms of water use are
accounted for entitlement reliability will be eroded
by expansion of un-metered uses like plantation
forestry and farm dam development, increases in ir-
rigation efficiency, etc. and place the integrity of the
allocation system at risk.
Lesson 10: Unless connected ground and surface
water systems are managed as a single integrated
resource, groundwater development will reduce the
amount of water available that can be allocated to
surface water users.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 73
7.	 Statutory rights offer flexibility but carry risks
- can be modified without recourse to the courts.
Developments to unbundle water rights have facili-
tated trade. A potential downside of statutory rights
is sovereign risk, or the possibility that the value of
existing water rights can be degraded by changes
in regulation and discretionary behaviour by state
governments.
8.	 Markets can promote environmental outcomes -
Trading should always be subject to a public interest
test. Where there are important public interests,
such as flow volumes at key locations or the need
to ensure minimum levels of water quality, trade may
need to be constrained for environmental reasons.
An example of this approach is the Basin Salinity
Management Strategy that seeks to reduce salinity:
actions that reduce salinity are treated as credits
and actions that increase salinity as debits on state
salinity registers.
9.	 Acquiring water for the environment through
buybacks has proved effective.
10.	Prices contain information on scarcity and risk.
11.	Basin-wide and local perspectives have roles to
play – local input can also prevent or undermine the
emergence of strong water markets. … Governments
need to see through short-term and some-times
parochial interests to facilitate optimal use in the
longer term.
12.	Effective monitoring and control of extractions
are critical for sustainability – Farmers made
substantial investments to increase their on-farm
retention of water that might otherwise have flowed
to the Basin’s streams and rivers. Similarly, ground-
water extractions increased by about half over the
period 2000–2001 to 2007–2008 (from about 1
MAF to 1.4 MAF) as market users sought access to
other cost effective water supplies.
Lesson 17: Develop brokering industry and avoid
government involvement in the provision of water
brokering services.
GRAFTON AND HORNE (2014) WRITE:
1.	 Crises may facilitate reform - As the focus on the
crisis fades, so may do the reform zeal. This ‘stop
and go’ reform process suggests that determination
is required to make consistent progress, but that a
crisis can facilitate reform.
2.	 Water markets support regional resilience - The
geographical distribution of markets has meant
these benefits have been concentrated in areas of
greatest connectivity of the resource (the southern
Murray-Darling Basin) where there is also the widest
cross-section of users. An example is the signifi-
cance of selling water by opportunistic commodity
producers (such as rice growers) to perennial crop
producers (such as citrus growers).
3.	 Political and administrative leadership is critical
- This involves teams with a range of skills, much
broader than the engineering-based specialists that
have traditionally managed water resources.
4.	 Capping extractions promotes effective use and
sustainability - any cap should be comprehen-
sive and all water sources should be included to
avoid substitution to uncontrolled or inadequately
measured sources.
5.	 Regulated water framework facilitates water
trading - entitlements delivered via regulated water
storages account for about 90 percent of the water
entitlements traded in the Southern MDB.
6.	 Reliable, accessible and timely market informa-
tion promotes effective decision-making - the
Australian government is investing over half a billion
Australian dollars in improved water information and
regulations.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT74
Payment for ecosystem services (PES) – an incen-
tive-based instrument that seeks to translate external,
non-market values of environment services into financial
incentives for local actors to provide such services. In
practical terms, PES involves a series of payments to a
land or resource manager in exchange for a guaranteed
flow of environmental services.
Payment for watershed services (PWS) – a type of
PES arrangement that is focused on watershed services.
Water bank – may refer to the physical storage of water,
typically in a reservoir or an aquifer, to an institution that
facilitates or brokers a water transfer or serves as an
information clearinghouse, or to any agency that holds
water rights in trust for a specified purpose such as
streamflow augmentation.
Water market – Often used interchangeably with water
transfer, a water market can also refer to informal
transactions involving the sale of water, e.g. from water
tankers, that do not involve the lease or sale of water
rights or concessions.
Water option – a type of conditional water transfer.
Under dry-year options a buyer will pay the seller an
annual fee to be able to exercise an option to purchase a
pre-determined volume of water under a specific set of
circumstances.
Water transfer – a change in the point of diversion,
type of use, or location of water use. May refer to a
temporary or permanent exchange of water rights (see
water market), or to a non-market conveyance of water
from one location to another.
Aquifer – an underground layer of water-bearing
materials, such as sandstone or gravel or other
permeable material.
Command-and-control regulation – an environmental
regulatory policy that is often contrasted with “incentive-
based mechanisms” in the literature. A command and
control (CAC) regulation can be defined as the direct
regulation of an industry or activity that states what is
permitted and what is illegal.
Economic Efficiency – generally, a state or condition
with optimal resource use, allocation, or productivity. May
or may not be consistent with equity considerations.
Equity – refers to fairness, justice, impartiality, such as
in the allocation of resources or treatment of different
classes of people. May or may not be consistent with
economic efficiency considerations.
Eutrophication – excessive richness of nutrients in a
lake or other body of water, frequently due to runoff from
the land, which causes a dense growth of plant life and
death of animal life from lack of oxygen.
Incentive-based instrument – a broad set of tools that
use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate re-
sponsible parties to reduce the health and environmental
risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products.
Nonpoint source (NPS) pollution – water pollution
from diffuse sources such as runoff from urbanized areas
or farm fields.
Nutrients – nitrogen or phosphorus-containing water
pollutants that can cause water quality problems. See
eutrophication.
Paper water – the legal right to use a given volume
of water, contrasted with “wet” or “real” water. In many
basins, more paper water exists than wet water.
Glossary
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT74
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 75
Bennett, G.  N. Carroll. 2014. “Gaining Depth: State of Wa-
tershed Investment 2014.” Forest Trends, Ecosystem
Marketplace. Available at forest-trends.org/documents/
files/SOWI2014.pdf.
Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER). 2015.
“Performance in Watershed Context Concept Paper.” Bev-
erage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER). http://
www.bieroundtable.com/#!/c16n5.
Bjornlund, H.  J. McKay. 2002. “Aspects of Water Markets
for Developing Countries: Experiences from Australia,
Chile, and the US.” Environment and Development Eco-
nomics 7 (04). doi:10.1017/S1355770X02000463.
Bond, I., and J. Mayers. 2010. “Fair Deals for Watershed Ser-
vices: Lessons from a Multi-Country Action-Learning
Project.” No. 13. Natural Resources Issues. London, UK:
International Institute for Environment and Development.
Available at pubs.iied.org/pdfs/13535IIED.pdf.
Brewer, J., R. Glennon, A. Ker  G.D. Libecap. 2007. “Water
Markets in the West: Prices, Trading, and Contractual
Forms.” National Bureau of Economic Research.
Brooks, D.B. 2006. “An Operational Definition of Water De-
mand Management.” Intenational Journal of Water Re-
sources Development 22 (4): 521–28.
Brouwer, R., A. Tesfaye  P. Pauw. 2011. “Meta-Analysis of
Institutional-Economic Factors Explaining the Environ-
mental Performance of Payments for Watershed Ser-
vices.” Environmental Conservation 38 (04): 380–92.
doi:10.1017/S0376892911000543.
Brown, C., U. Lall  F.A. Souza Filho. 2015. “Allocating Water
in a Changing World: Incentive-Based Mechanisms for
Climate Adaptation.”
Calvache, A., S. Benitez  A. Ramos. 2012. “Fondo de Agua:
Conservando La Infraestructura Verde. Guia de Diseno,
Creacio, Y Operacion.” Bogota, Columbia: The Nature
Conservancy, Fundacion FEMSA, y Banco Interamericano
de Desarrollo. Available at conservationgateway.org/
Documents/LAWFP-ENG-low-050312_0.pdf.
Carpenter, S.R., E.H. Stanley  M. J. Vander Zanden. 2011.
“State of the World’s Freshwater Ecosystems: Physical,
Chemical, and Biological Changes.” Annual Review of
Environment and Resources 36 (1): 75–99. doi:10.1146/
annurev-environ-021810-094524.
CDP. 2014. “From Water Risk to Value Creation, CDP Global
Water Report 2014.” CDP. Available at cdp.net/CDPRe-
sults/CDP-Global-Water-Report-2014.pdf.
Albiac, J., M. Hanemann, J. Calatrava, J. Uche  J. Tapia.
2006. “The Rise and Fall of the Ebro Water Transfer.”
Natural Resources Journal 46: 729–57.
Alix-Garcia, J., A. de Janvry, E. Sadoulet  J. Manuel. 2009.
“Lessons Learned from Mexico’s Payment for Environ-
mental Services Program.” In Payment for Environmental
Services in Agricultural Landscapes, edited by Leslie Lip-
per, Takumi Sakuyama, Randy Stringer, and David Zilber-
man, 163–88. Natural Resource Management and Policy
31. Springer New York. Available at link.springer.com/
chapter/10.1007/978-0-387-72971-8_8.
Al-Marshudi, A.S. 2007. “The Falaj Irrigation System and
Water Allocation Markets in Northern Oman.” Agricul-
tural Water Management 91 (1–3): 71–77. doi:10.1016/j.
agwat.2007.04.008.
Ambec, S., A. Dinar  D. McKinney. 2013. “Water Sharing
Agreements Sustainable to Reduced Flows.” Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management 66 (3):
639–55. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2013.06.003.
Anderson, R.C. 2004. “International Experiences with
Economic Incentives for Protecting the Environment.”
EPA-236-R-04-001. Washington, DC: US Environmental
Protection Agency, National Center for Environmental
Economics. Available at yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/eerm.
nsf/vwAN/EE-0487-01.pdf/$file/EE-0487-01.pdf.
Appleton, A.F. 2010. “How New York City Used an Ecosystem
Services Strategy Carried out through an Urban-Rural
Partnership to Preserve the Pristine Quality of Its Drink-
ing Water and Save Billions of Dollars.” New York, NY: A
Paper for Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarket-
place.com/documents/cms_documents/NYC_H2O_Eco-
system_Services.pdf.
Backeberg, G. 2015. “Water Markets in South Africa,” July 24.
Barrett, K. 2015. “A Different Kind of Sale: April Auction Of-
fers Stewardship Credits to Meet Sustainability Goals.”
Ecosystem Marketplace. February 12. Available at eco-
systemmarketplace.com/pages/dynamic/article.page.
php?page_id=10792section=news_articleseod=1.
Bauer, C.J. 1997. “Bringing Water Markets down to Earth: The
Political Economy of Water Rights in Chile, 1976–1995.”
World Development 25 (5): 639–56.
Bennett, G., N. Carroll  K. Hamilton. (2012) Charting New
Waters: State of Watershed Payments 2012. Washington,
DC: Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.
com/reports/sowp2012.
References
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT76
at ohchr.org/english/bodies/hrcouncil/docs/18session/A-
HRC-18-33-Add4_en.pdf.
Dellapenna, J. 2000. “The Importance of Getting Names
Right: The Myth of Markets for Water.” William  Mary
Environmental Law and Policy Review 25 (2): 317.
Department of Environmental Affairs. 2015. “Social Develop-
ment | Department of Environmental Affairs.” Accessed
September 10. Available at environment.gov.za/proj-
ectsprogrammes/wfw/socialdevelopment.
Dillaha, T., P. Ferraro, M. Huang, D. Southgate, S. Upadhyaya
 S. Wunder. 2007. “Payment for Watershed Services
Regional Syntheses.” USAID. Available at sanrem.cals.
vt.edu/1010/Dillaha2007_PWS_regional_syntheses.pdf.
Dinar, A., M.W. Rosegrant  R. Meinzen-Dick. 1997. “Wa-
ter Allocation Mechanisms: Principles and Examples.”
Policy Research Working Paper Series 1779. The World
Bank. Available at econpapers.repec.org/paper/wbkw-
brwps/1779.htm.
Dinar, A.  R.M. Saleth. 2005. “Can Water Institutions Be
Cured? A Water Institutions Health Index.” Water Supply
5: 17–40.
Dodds, W.K., W.W. Bouska, J.L. Eitzmann, T.J. Pilger, K.L. Pitts,
A.J. Riley, J.T. Schloesser  D.J. Thornbrugh. 2008. “Eu-
trophication of US Freshwaters: Analysis of Potential Eco-
nomic Damages.” Environmental Science  Technology
43 (1): 12–19.
Duhon, M., J. Young  S. Kerr. 2011. “Nitrogen Trading in Lake
Taupo: An Analysis and Evaluation of an Innovative Water
Management Strategy.” In New Zealand Agricultural and
Resource Economics Society 2011 Conference. Nelson,
New Zealand. Available at ageconsearch.umn.edu/bit-
stream/115353/2/Duhon%20Paper.pdf.
Easter, K.W., M.W. Rosegrant  A. Dinar. 1999. “Formal and
Informal Markets for Water: Institutions, Performance, and
Constraints.” The World Bank Research Observer 14 (1):
99–116.
Ecosystem Marketplace. 2013. “Innovative Markets and
Market Like Instruments for Ecosystem Services.” Forest
Trends. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.com/docu-
ments/acrobat/the_matrix.pdf.
———. 2015. “This Week In Water: The Art Of The Nutrient
Credit Sale.” Watershed Connect. February 27. Available
at watershedconnect.com/news/this_week_in_water_the_
art_of_the_nutrient_credit_sale_.
Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI). 2010. “Program on
Technology Innovation: Ohio River Water Quality Trading
Pilot Program: Business Case for Power Company Partici-
pation.” Available at epri.com/abstracts/Pages/ProductA-
bstract.aspx?ProductId=000000000001018861.
Clifford, P. 2012. “Water Banking in Washington State: 2012
Report to the Legislature.” Report to Legislature 12-11-
055. Washington State Department of Ecology. https://
fortress.wa.gov/ecy/publications/SummaryPages/1211055.
html.
Cohen, M.J., J. Christian-Smith  J. Berggren. 2013. “Water
to Supply the Land: Irrigated Agriculture in the Colorado
River Basin.” Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/
publication/water-to-supply-the-land-irrigated-agricul-
ture-in-the-colorado-river-basin/.
Cohen, M.J. 2014. “Hazard’s Toll: The Costs of Inaction at the
Salton Sea.” Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/pub-
lication/hazards-toll/.
Cohen, M.J.  K.H. Hyun. 2006. “Hazard: The Future of the
Salton Sea With No Restoration Plan.” Oakland, Calif.: Pa-
cific Institute. http://pacinst.org/publication/restoration-
project-critical-to-salton-seas-future/.
Colby, B.G., M.A. McGinnis  K.A. Rait. 1991. “Mitigating Envi-
ronmental Externalities through Voluntary and Involun-
tary Water Reallocation: Nevada’s Truckee-Carson River
Basin.” Natural Resources Journal 31: 757.
Coleman, A. 2008. “Farmers to Sue DWAF for Water Rights
Transfers.” Farmer’s Weekly, September 12.
Conagua. 2012. “Water Banks in Mexico.” National Water
Commission. Available at conagua.gob.mx/bancos-
delagua/.
Connor, J.D.  D. Kaczan. 2013. “Principles for Economically
Efficient and Environmentally Sustainable Water Mar-
kets: The Australian Experience.” In Drought in Arid and
Semi-Arid Regions, edited by Kurt Schwabe, Jose Albiac,
Jeffery D. Connor, Rashid M. Hassan, and Liliana Meza
González, 357–74. Springer Netherlands. Available at
dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-6636-5_20.
Cosgrove, W.S.  F.R. Rijsberman. 2000. “World Water Vision:
Making Water Everybody’s Business.” World Water Coun-
cil. Available at worldwatercouncil.org/index.php?id=961.
Culp, P., R. Glennon  G. Libecap. 2014. “Shopping for Wa-
ter: How the Market Can Mitigate Water Shortages in
the American West.” 2014-05. Discussion Paper. The
Brookings Institute. Available at hamiltonproject.org/
files/downloads_and_links/market_mitigate_water_short-
age_in_west_paper_glennon_final.pdf.
Colorado Water Trust (CWT). 2015. Colorado Water Trust Big
Beaver Creek Reservoir / Big Beaver Creek  White River.
Available at coloradowatertrust.org/our-work/projects/
lake-avery-big-beaver-creek-white-river/#sthash.I3vg-
PjZL.dpuf.
de Albuquerque, C. 2011. “Special Rapporteur on the Human
Right to Safe Drinking Water and Sanitation, Mission to
the United States of America.” United Nations. Available
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 77
Victorian Murray Valley / Frontier Economics. PANDORA
Electronic Collection. Canberra, A.C.T: National Water Com-
mission. Available at nla.gov.au/nla.arc-79821.
Garrido, A.  M.R. Llamas. 2009. “Water Management in
Spain: An Example of Changing Paradigms.” Policy and
Strategic Behaviour in Water Resource Management 125.
Gassert, F., M. Landis, P. Reig, M. Luck  T. Shiao. 2013. “Aq-
ueduct Metadata Document, Aqueduct Global Maps 2.0.”
World Resources Institute (WRI). Available at wri.org/sites/
default/files/pdf/aqueduct_metadata_global.pdf.
Genevieve B., N. Carroll, M. Bennett, A. Leonardi  K. Moull.
2014. “Gaining Depth: State of Watershed Investment
2014.” Washington, D.C: Forest Trends. Available at.forest-
trends.org/documents/files/SOWI2014.pdf.
George, A., A. Pierret, A. Boonsaner, V. Christian  O. Planchon.
2009. “Potential and Limitations of Payments for Environ-
mental Services (PES) as a Means to Manage Watershed
Services in Mainland Southeast Asia.” International Jour-
nal of the Commons 3 (1): 16–40.
Getches, D.H. 1985. “Competing Demands for the Colorado
River.” University of Colorado Law Review 56: 413.
Gleick, P.H. 2002. “Water Management: Soft Water Paths.”
Nature 418: 373.
———. 2003. “Global Freshwater Resources: Soft-Path Solu-
tions for the 21st Century.” Science 302 (5650): 1524–28.
Gleick, P.H., D. Haasz, C. Henges-Jeck, V. Srinivasan, G. Wolff,
K. Kao Cushing  A. Mann. 2003. “Waste Not, Want Not:
The Potential for Urban Water Conservation in California.”
Oakland CA: Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/wp-
content/uploads/sites/21/2013/02/waste_not_want_not_
full_report3.pdf.
Glennon, R. 2005. “Water Scarcity, Marketing, and Privatiza-
tion.” Texas Law Review 83 (7): 1873–1902.
Gómez-Baggethun, E., R. de Groot, P.L. Lomas  C. Montes.
2010. “The History of Ecosystem Services in Economic
Theory and Practice: From Early Notions to Markets and
Payment Schemes.” Ecological Economics, Special Sec-
tion - Payments for Environmental Services: Reconciling
Theory and Practice, 69 (6): 1209–18. doi:10.1016/j.ecole-
con.2009.11.007.
Grafton, R.Q.  J. Horne. 2014. “Water Markets in the Murray-
Darling Basin.” Agricultural Water Management 145 (No-
vember): 61–71. doi:10.1016/j.agwat.2013.12.001.
Grafton, R.Q., C. Landry, G.D. Libecap, S. McGlennon  R.
O’Brien. 2010. “An Integrated Assessment of Water Mar-
kets: Australia, Chile, China, South Africa and the USA.”
ICER Working Paper 32-2010. ICER - International Centre
for Economic Research. Available at ideas.repec.org/p/icr/
wpicer/32-2010.html.
Faeth, P. 2000. Fertile Ground: Nutrient Trading’s Potential
to Cost-Effectively Improve Water Quality. Washington,
D.C.: World Resources Institute. Available at wri.org/sites/
default/files/pdf/fertile_ground.pdf.
Famiglietti, J.S. 2014. “The Global Groundwater Crisis.” Na-
ture Climate Change 4: 945–48.
Farolfi, St.  S. Perret. 2002. “Inter-Sectoral Competition for
Water Allocation in Rural South Africa : Analysing a Case
Study through a Standard Environmental Economics
Approach.” Paper without proceedings Working paper:
2002-23. Department of Agricultural Economics, Exten-
sion and Rural Development: University of Pretoria. http://
agritrop.cirad.fr/511263/.
Feinglas, S., C. Gray  P. Mayer. 2013. “Conservation Helps
Limit Rate Increases for a Colorado Utility.” Alliance for
Water Efficiency. Available at financingsustainablewater.
org/resource-search/conservation-helps-limit-rate-
increases-colorado-utility.
Ferraro, P.J. 2008. “Asymmetric Information and Contract
Design for Payments for Environmental Services.” Eco-
logical Economics, Payments for Environmental Services
in Developing and Developed Countries, 65 (4): 810–21.
doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.029.
———. 2009. “Regional Review of Payments for Wa-
tershed Services: Sub-Saharan Africa.” Jour-
nal of Sustainable Forestry 28 (3-5): 525–50.
doi:10.1080/10549810802701234.
Fischel, W.A. 1995. Regulatory Takings: Law, Economics, and
Politics. Harvard University Press.
Fisher-Vanden, K.  S. Olmstead. 2013. “Moving Pollution
Trading from Air to Water: Potential, Problems, and Prog-
nosis.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 147–71.
Forest Trends. 2015a. Watershed Connect. Available at wa-
tershedconnect.com/
Forest Trends. 2015b. “Paw Paw River Watershed.” Program
Inventory. Paw Paw River Watershed. Available at water-
shedconnect.com/programs/Paw-Paw-River-Watershed.
Fox, J. 2014. “The Role of Trading in Achieving Water Qual-
ity Objectives.” presented at the United States House
of Representatives, Committee on Transportation and
Infrastructure, Subcommittee on Water Resources and
Environment, Washington, DC, April 17. Available at wqt.
epri.com/pdf/EPRI%20Testimony%20WQT%20Final%20
4-17-14.pdf.
Freyfogle, E.T. 1996. “Water Rights and the Commonwealth.”
Environmental Law 26: 27.
Frontier Economics, and Australia National Water Commis-
sion. 2007. The Economic and Social Impacts of Water
Trading [electronic Resource] : Case Studies in the
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT78
rent Initiatives.” Journal of Sustainable Forestry 28 (3-5):
551–75. doi:10.1080/10549810902794287.
Huber, R.M., J. Ruitenbeek  R.S. da Motta. 1998. “Market-
Based Instruments for Environmental Policymaking in
Latin America and the Caribbean - Lessons from Eleven
Countries.” WDP381. The World Bank. Available at docu-
ments.worldbank.org/curated/en/1998/11/438776/market-
based-instruments-environmental-policymaking-latin-
america-caribbean-lessons-eleven-countries.
Hundley, N., Jr. 2001. The Great Thirst: Californians and
Water—A History, Revised Edition. 2001 (revised). Un-
versity of California Press. Available at ucpress.edu/book.
php?isbn=9780520224568.
International Institute for Environment and Development
(IIED). 2015. Watershed Markets. Available at watershed-
markets.org/
Jenkins, M.W., J.R. Lund, R.E. Howitt, A.J. Draper, S.M. Msangi,
S.K. Tanaka, R.S. Ritzema  G.F. Marques. 2004. “Optimi-
zation of California’s Water Supply System: Results and
Insights.” Journal of Water Resources Planning and
Management 130 (4): 271–80. doi:10.1061/(ASCE)0733-
9496(2004)130:4(271).
Jones, C., E. Branosky, M. Selman  M. Perez. 2010. “How Nu-
trient Trading Could Help Restore the Chesapeake Bay.”
Washington, DC: World Resources Institute. Available
at wri.org/working_papers/how_nutrient_trading_could_
help_restore_the_chesapeake_bay.pdf.
Karousakis, K.  Q. Brooke. 2010. Paying for Biodiversity:
Enhancing the Cost-Effectiveness of Payments for Eco-
system Services. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-
operation and Development. Available at oecd-ilibrary.
org/content/book/9789264090279-en.
Kenny, A. 2006. “Ecosystem Marketplace - Ecosystem Ser-
vices in the New York City Watershed.” Ecosystem Mar-
ketplace. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.com/pages/
dynamic/article.page.php?page_id=4130section=home.
Koplow, D. 2004. The Use of Economic Instruments in Envi-
ronmental Policy: Opportunties and Challenges. United
Nations Environment Programme. Available at unep.ch/
etb/publication/EconInst/econInstruOppChnaFin.pdf.
Kosoy, N., M. Martinez-Tuna, R. Muradian  J. Martinez-Alier.
2007. “Payments for Environmental Services in Water-
sheds: Insights from a Comparative Study of Three Cases
in Central America.” Ecological Economics 61 (2–3):
446–55. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.03.016.
Los Angeles Department of Water and Power (LA DWP).
2013. “Owens Lake Master Project.” Los Angeles, CA:
Los Angeles Department of Water and Power. Available
at ladwp.com/ladwp/faces/ladwp/aboutus/a-water/a-w-
losangelesaqueduct/a-w-laa-owenslake.
Grafton, R.Q., G. Libecap, E. Edwards, R O’Brien  C. Landry.
2012. “Comparative Assessment of Water Markets: In-
sights from the Murray-Darling Basin of Australia and the
Western USA.” Water Policy 14: 175–93.
Greiber, T., ed. 2009. Payments for Ecosystem Services: Le-
gal and Institutional Frameworks. IUCN Environmental
Policy and Law Paper, No. 78. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN, in
collaboration with the IUCN Environmental Law Centre,
Bonn, Germany. Available at cmsdata.iucn.org/downloads/
eplp_78_1.pdf.
Hanak, E.  E. Stryjewski. 2012. “California’s Water Market,
By the Numbers: Update 2012.” Public Policy Institute
of California. Available at wee.ppic.org/content/pubs/
report/R_1112EHR.pdf.
Harrington, W.  R.D. Morgenstern. 2004. “Economic Incen-
tives Versus Command and Control: What’s the Best Ap-
proach for Solving Environmental Problems?” Resources
for the Future. Available at rff.org/Publications/Resources/
Documents/152/RFF_Resources_152_ecoincentives.pdf.
Hauter, W. 2013. “D.C. District Court Fails on Pollution Trad-
ing: Clean Water Act Trading Lawsuit Dismissed Due to
Burden of Proof.” Food and Water Watch. December 16.
Available at foodandwaterwatch.org/pressreleases/d-c-
district-court-fails-on-pollution-trading-clean-water-act-
trading-lawsuit-dismissed-due-to-burden-of-proof/.
Hawkins, S. 2011. “Laying the Foundation: An Analytical Tool
for Assessing Legal and Institutional Readiness for PES.”
Forest Trends. Available at forest-trends.org/documents/
files/doc_3014.pdf.
Heberger, M., H. Cooley  P.H. Gleick. 2014. “Urban Water
Conservation and Efficiency Potential in California.” Oak-
land, CA: Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/wp-
content/uploads/sites/21/2014/06/ca-water-urban.pdf.
Howe, C.W. 2011. “The Efficient Water Market of the Northern
Colorado Water Conservancy. District: Colorado, USA.”
IBE Review reports CS22. WP6 IBE EX-POST Case Stud-
ies. EPI Water. Available at feem-project.net/epiwater/
docs/d32-d6-1/CS22_Colorado.pdf.
Howe, C.W.  C. Goemans. 2003. “Water Transfers and Their
Impacts: Lessons from Three Colorado Water Markets.”
JAWRA Journal of the American Water Resources
Association 39 (5): 1055–65. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2003.
tb03692.x.
Howitt, R.E. 1998. “Spot Prices, Option Prices, and Water
Markets: An Analysis of Emerging Markets in California.”
In Markets for Water, edited by K. William Easter, Mark
W. Rosegrant, and Ariel Dinar, 119–40. Natural Resource
Management and Policy 15. Springer US.
Huang, M., S.K. Upadhyaya, R. Jindal  J. Kerr. 2009. “Pay-
ments for Watershed Services in Asia: A Review of Cur-
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 79
Moench, M., A. Dixit, S. Janakarajan, M.S. Rathore  S. Mudra-
kartha. 2003. The Fluid Mosaic: Water Governance in
the Context of Variability, Uncertainty and Change: A
Synthesis Paper. Nepal Water Conservation Foundation,
Kathmandu, and the Institute for Social and Environmen-
tal Transition, Boulder, Colorado, US.
Moore, R.H. 2012. “Reaching the Potential of Water-Quality
Trading.” In Water Sustainability in Agriculture, 73–81.
Ithaca, New York: National Agriculutural Biotechnology
Council. Available at nabc.cals.cornell.edu/Publications/
Reports/nabc_24/24_2_1_Moore.pdf.
Morgan, C.  A. Wolverton. 2005. “Water Quality Trading in
the United States.” 05-07. Working Paper. National Cen-
ter for Environmental Economics. Available at yosemite.
epa.gov/ee/epa/eed.nsf/be6bc67216ab9f5d85256e460
07b104d/3e026cbb6a9956918525702f005e383c/$FI
LE/2005-07.pdf.
MOTU. 2009. “Lake Rotorua Short Films.” Motu Economic
and Public Policy Research. Available at motu.org.nz/
research/detail/rotorua_films.
Muñoz-Piña, C., A. Guevara, J.M. Torres  J. Braña. 2008.
“Paying for the Hydrological Services of Mexico’s Forests:
Analysis, Negotiations and Results.” Ecological Econom-
ics, Payments for Environmental Services in Developing
and Developed Countries, 65 (4): 725–36. doi:10.1016/j.
ecolecon.2007.07.031.
Naeem, S., J. C. Ingram, A. Varga, T. Agardy, P. Barten, G. Ben-
nett, E. Bloomgarden, et al., 2015. “Get the Science Right
When Paying for Nature’s Services.” Science 347 (6227):
1206–7. doi:10.1126/science.aaa1403.
National Fish and Wildlife Foundation. 2014. “FY 2013 Annual
Report: Columbia Basin Water Transactions Program.”
Portland, Oregon: National Fish and Wildlife Foundation.
Available at cbwtp.org/jsp/cbwtp/library/documents/
NLB_CBWTP_Annual13_R8.pdf.
National Research Council. 1968. Water and Choice in the
Colorado Basin: An Example of Alternatives in Water
Management: A Report. National Academies.
———. 1992. Water Transfers in the West:: Efficiency, Eq-
uity, and the Environment. National Academies Press.
Neef, A.  D. Thomas. 2009. “Rewarding the Upland Poor for
Saving the Commons? Evidence from Southeast Asia.”
International Journal of the Commons 3 (1): 1–15.
Newburn, D.A.  R.T. Woodward. 2012. “An Ex Post Evalu-
ation of Ohio’s Great Miami Water Quality Trading
Program1.” JAWRA Journal of the American Water
Resources Association 48 (1): 156–69. doi:10.1111/j.1752-
1688.2011.00601.x.
Raes, L.  P. Mohebalian. 2013. “The Socio Bosque Pro-
gram for Rainforest and Paramo Conservation, Ecuado.”
Geneva Switzerland: The Economics of Ecosystems
and Biodiversity. Available at teebweb.org/wp-content/
uploads/2014/07/The-Socio-Bosque-Programme-for-
rainforest-and-Paramo-Conservation-Ecuador-.pdf.
Leflaive, X., M. Witmer, R. Martin-Hurtado, M. Bakker, T. Kram,
L. Bouwman, H. Visser, A. Bouwman, H. Hilderink  K.
Kim. 2012. “Water.” In OECD Environmental Outlook,
275–332. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development. Available at oecd-ilibrary.org/content/
chapter/env_outlook-2012-8-en.
Levine, G., R. Barker  C.C. Huang. 2007. “Water Transfer
from Agriculture to Urban Uses: Lessons Learned, with
Policy Considerations.” Paddy and Water Environment 5
(4): 213–22. doi:10.1007/s10333-007-0092-8.
LimnoTech  The Nature Conservancy. 2013. “Quantifying
Replenish Benefits in Community Water Partnership
Projects, Final Report for 2012.” The Coca-Cola Com-
pany. Available at assets.coca-colacompany.com/2f/cb/
e5d2ca1e4c58a38adbe8586d06db/final-quanitification-
report-water-pdf.pdf.
Livingston, M.L. 1998. “Institutional Requisites for Efficient
Water Markets.” In Markets for Water: Potential and Per-
formance, 19–33. Springer. Available at link.springer.com/
chapter/10.1007/978-0-585-32088-5_2.
Lovins, A. 1977. Soft energy paths: Toward a durable peace.
Ballinger Publishing Co., Cambridge, Massachusetts, US.
Marida, P. 2010. “Ohio’s Water Quality Trading Programs - To
Be Taken Over by Coal?” The Ohio Sierran, A Publica-
tion of the Ohio Chapter of the Sierra Club.
Mariola, M.J. 2009. “Are Markets the Solution to Water Pollu-
tion? A Sociological Investigation of Water Quality Trad-
ing.” Ph.D. Dissertation, Columbus, Ohio: The Ohio State
University. Available at rave.ohiolink.edu/etdc/view?acc_
num=osu1250015222.
Medellín-Azuara, J., J.J. Harou, M.A. Olivares, K. Madani,
J.R. Lund, R.E. Howitt, S.K. Tanaka, M.W. Jenkins  T.
Zhu. 2008. “Adaptability and Adaptations of California’s
Water Supply System to Dry Climate Warming.” Climatic
Change 87 (1): 75–90.
Meinzen-Dick, R.  R. Pradhan. 2005. “Recognizing Multiple
Water Uses in Intersectoral Water Transfers.” In Asian
Irrigation in Transition: Responding to Challenges, 178–
205. Asian Institute of Technology, Bangkok, Thailand.
Richards, M. 2013. “What Do We Know about Gender and
Other Social Impacts of IWS Projects?: A Literature Re-
view.” Forest Trends. Available at forest-trends.org/docu-
ments/files/doc_4089.pdf.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT80
Porras, I., B. Aylward  J. Dengel. 2013. “Monitoring Pay-
ments for Watershed Services Schemes in Developing
Countries.” London, UK: International Institute for Envi-
ronment and Development. Available at pubs.iied.org/
pdfs/16525IIED.pdf.
Porras, I., D.N. Barton, A. Chacon-Cascante  M. Miranda.
2013. “Learning from 20 Years of Payments for Ecosys-
tem Services in Costa Rica.” London, UK: International
Institute for Environment and Development. Available at
pubs.iied.org/pdfs/16514IIED.pdf.
Porras, I.  N. Neves. 2006a. “China - Sloping Lands Con-
version Programme.” Markets for Watershed Services
- Country Profile. International Institute for Environment
and Development. Available at watershedmarkets.org/
documents/China_SLCP_eng.pdf.
———. 2006b. “Mexico - National PSAH Programme.” Mar-
ket for Watershed Services - Country Profile. International
Institute for Environment and Development. Available
at watershedmarkets.org/documents/Mexico_National_
PSAH_eng.pdf.
Porras, I.T., M. Grieg-Gran  N. Neves. 2008. All That Glit-
ters: A Review of Payments for Watershed Services in
Developing Countries. IIED. Available at pubs.iied.org/
pdfs/13542IIED.pdf.
Postel, S.L., G.C. Daily  P.R. Ehrlich. 1996. “Appropriation of
Renewable Fresh Water.” Science 271 (5250): 785–88.
Queensland Water Commission. 2010. “South East
Queensland Water Strategy 2010.” 29229. Queensland
Water Commission. Available at qwc.qld.gov.au.
Ravnborg, H.M., M.G. Damsgaard  K. Raben. 2007. “Pay-
ments for Ecosystem Services - Issues and Pro-Poor
Opportunities for Development Assistance.” Copenhagen,
Denmark: Danish Institute for International Studies.
Reimers, F. 2013. “Shifting Ground.” Nature Conservancy,
June.
Rockefeller Foundation. 2013. Key Factors Supporting Small-
Scale Coastal Fisheries Management.
Romano, D.  M. Leporati. 2002. “The Distributive Impact
of the Water Market in Chile: A Case Study in Limari
Province, 1981- 1997.” Quarterly Journal of International
Agriculture 41 (1): 41–58.
Rozza, J.P., B.D. Richter, W.M. Larson, T. Redder, K. Vigerstol 
P. Bowen P. 2013. “Corporate Water Stewardship: Achiev-
ing a Sustainable Balance.” Journal of Management and
Sustainability 3 (4). Available at dx.doi.org/10.5539/jms.
v3n4p41.
Newlin, B.D., M.W. Jenkins, J.R. Lund  R.E. Howitt. 2002.
“Southern California Water Markets: Potential and Limita-
tions.” Journal of Water Resources Planning and Man-
agement 128 (1): 21–32.
NSWDEC. 2003. Hunter River Salinity Trading Scheme:
Working Together to Protect River Quality and Sustain
Economic Development. Sydney, Australia: Department
of Environment and Conservation, New South Wales.
Available at epa.nsw.gov.au/resources/licensing/hrsts/
hrsts.pdf.
NWC. 2013. Australian National Water Commission Markets
Report 2012-2013. Canberra. Available at nwc.gov.au/pub-
lications/topic/water-industry/australian-water-markets-
report-2012-13.
O’Donnell, M.  B. Colby. 2010. “Water Banks: A Tool for En-
hancing Water Supply Reliability.” Guidebook. University
of Arizona. Available at ag.arizona.edu/arec/pubs/faculty-
pubs/ewsr-Banks-final-5-12-10.pdf.
O’Grady, D. 2011. “Sociopolitical Conditions for Success-
ful Water Quality Trading in the South Nation River
Watershed, Ontario, Canada1.” JAWRA Journal of the
American Water Resources Association 47 (1): 39–51.
doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2010.00511.x.
Olszowa, D.M., J.P. Heath  P.A. Tennant. 1998. “Evalua-
tion of Nutrient Loads and Sources in the Ohio River
Basin.” In . Ohio River Valley Water Sanitation Com-
mission (ORSANCO). http://acwi.gov/monitoring/
conference/98proceedings/Papers/54-OLSZ.html.
Pagiola, S. 2008. “Payments for Environmental Services in
Costa Rica.” Ecological Economics, Payments for Envi-
ronmental Services in Developing and Developed Coun-
tries, 65 (4): 712–24. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.033.
Pagiola, S., A. Arcenas  G. Platais. 2005. “Can Payments for
Environmental Services Help Reduce Poverty? An Explo-
ration of the Issues and the Evidence to Date from Latin
America.” World Development, Institutional arrange-
ments for rural poverty reduction and resource conserva-
tion, 33 (2): 237–53. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.011.
Pant, D., M. Bhattarai  G. Basnet. 2008. “Implications Of Bulk
Water Transfer On Local Water Management Institutions:
A Case Study of the Melamchi Water Supply Project in
Nepal.” Working Paper 78. Consultative Group on Interna-
tional Agricultural Research (CGIAR). Available at indiae-
nvironmentportal.org.in/files/capriwp78.pdf.
Perrot-Maitre, D. 2006. “The Vittel Payments for Ecosystem
Services: A ‘Perfect’ PES Case?” London, UK: International
Institute for Environment and Development. Available
at katoombagroup.org/~katoomba/documents/tools/
TheVittelpaymentsforecosystemservices.pdf.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 81
Thobani, M. 1997. “Formal Water Markets: Why, When, and
How to Introduce Tradable Water Rights.” World Bank
Research Observer 12 (2): 161–79.
TWSST, 2014. Transforming water scarcity through trading,
2012–2015, Final report.
United Nations. 2009. “World Water Development Report 3:
Water in a Changing World.” Available at webworld.unes-
co.org/water/wwap/wwdr/wwdr3/tableofcontents.shtml.
———. 2012. “World Water Development Report 4:
Managing Water under Uncertainty and Risk.” Paris,
France: United Nations. http://unesdoc.unesco.org/
images/0021/002156/215644e.pdf.
UNEP. 2009. “Training Resource Manual: The Use of Eco-
nomic Instruments for Environmental and Natural Re-
source Management.” Available at unep.ch/etb/publica-
tions/EI%20manual%202009/Training%20Resource%20
Manual.pdf.
UNEP. 2004. “The Use of Economic Instruments in Environ-
mental Policy: Opportunities and Challenges.” Available
at unep.ch/etb/publication/EconInst/econInstruOppCh-
naFin.pdf.
US Bureau of Reclamation. 2015. “Moving Forward, Phase 1
Report.” Bureau of Reclamation, US Department of the In-
terior. Available at usbr.gov/lc/region/programs/crbstudy/
MovingForward/Phase1Report.html.
US Census Bureau. 2012. “The Statistical Abstract of the
United States, Table 435: State and Local Governments-
-Summary of Finances.” Washington, DC. Available at
census.gov/compendia/statab/2012/tables/12s0435.pdf.
US EPA. 2001. “The United States Experiences with Eco-
nomic Incentives for Protecting the Environment.” EPA-
240-R-01-001. Available at yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/
eerm.nsf/vwAN/EE-0216B-13.pdf/$file/EE-0216B-13.pdf.
US EPA. 2003. “Final Water Quality Trading Policy.” January
13. http://water.epa.gov/type/watersheds/trading/finalpo-
licy2003.cfm.
———. 2009. “Steam Electric Power Generation Point
Source Category: Final Detailed Study Report.” United
States Environmental Protection Agency. Available at
water.epa.gov/scitech/wastetech/guide/steam-electric/
upload/Steam-Electric_Detailed-Study-Report_2009.pdf.
———. 2010. “How Water Quality (Nutrient) Trading Enables
Alpine Cheese Company to Improve Water Quality and
Increase Economic Development in the Region.” US.
Available at water.epa.gov/type/watersheds/named/ms-
basin/oh_03.cfm.
Ruppert, T.K. 2004. “Water Quality Trading and Agricultural
Nonpoint Source Pollution: An Analysis of the Effective-
ness and Fairness of EPA’s Policy on Water Quality Trad-
ing.” Villanova Environmental Law Journal 15: 1.
Salzman, J. 2006. “Thirst: A Short History of Drinking Water.”
Yale Journal of Law and the Humanities 17 (3). Avail-
able at lsr.nellco.org/duke_fs/31.
Schmalensee, R  R.N. Stavins. 2013. “The SO2 Allowance
Trading System: The Ironic History of a Grand Policy
Experiment.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 27 (1):
103–22. doi:10.1257/jep.27.1.103.
Sharma, S.K.  K. Vairavamoorthy. 2009. “Urban Water De-
mand Management: Prospects and Challenges for the
Developing Countries.” Water and Environment Journal
23 (3): 210–18. doi:10.1111/j.1747-6593.2008.00134.x.
Shortle, J.S.  R.D. Horan. 2005. “Water Quality Trading.”
Penn State Environmental Law Review 14: 231.
———. 2008. “The Economics of Water Quality Trading.”
International Review of Environmental and Resource
Economics 2 (2): 101–33.
Smith, S., P. Rowcroft, M. Everard, L. Couldrick, M. Reed, H.
Rogers, T. Quick, C. Eves  C. White. 2013. “Payments
for Ecosystem Services: A Best Practice Guide.” Defra,
London: Department for Environment, Food, and Rural
Affairs. Available at gov.uk/government/uploads/system/
uploads/attachment_data/file/200920/pb13932-pes-
bestpractice-20130522.pdf.
Stacey, P.E., T. Haze  I. Raffa. 2012. “Meeting the Nitrogen
Wasteload Allocation in Connecticut: Connecticut’s Nitro-
gen Credit Exchange After 10 Years of Operation as the
Nation’s Most Significant Water Quality Trading Program.”
presented at the 36th annual Meeting of the New Eng-
land Association of Environmental Biologists, Falmouth,
Massachusetts, March 22. Available at epa.gov/region1/
neaeb2012/pdfs/0930_BR2_PaulStacey.pdf.
Stanton, T., M. Echavarria, K. Hamilton  C. Ott. 2010. “State
of Watershed Payments: An Emerging Marketplace.”
Ecosystem Marketplace. Available at watershedconnect.
com/documents/files/state_of_watershed_payments_an_
emerging_marketplace.pdf.
Stavins, R.N. 2001. “Experience with Market-Based Environ-
mental Policy Instruments.” Resources for the Future.
Available at rff.org/documents/rff-dp-01-58.pdf.
Tarlock, A.D. 2014. “Mexico and the United States Assume a
Legal Duty to Provide Colorado River Delta Restoration
Flows: An Important International Environmental and
Water Law Precedent.” Review of European, Compara-
tive  International Environmental Law 23 (1): 76–87.
doi:10.1111/reel.12066.
INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT82
Worster, D. 1985. Rivers of Empire: Water, Aridity, and the
Growth of the American West. Oxford University Press.
Wunder, S. 2005. “Payments for Environmental Services:
Some Nuts and Bolts.” CIFOR Occasional Paper No. 42.
Jakarta, Indonesia: Center for Internatioanl Forestry Re-
search. Available at theredddesk.org/sites/default/files/
resources/pdf/2012/payment-ecosystem-services-02.pdf.
———. 2008. “Payments for Environmental Services and
the Poor: Concepts and Preliminary Evidence.” Environ-
ment and Development Economics 13 (03): 279–97.
doi:10.1017/S1355770X08004282.
Young, M.D. 2010. “Environmental Effectiveness and Eco-
nomic Efficiency of Water Use in Agriculture: The Experi-
ence of and Lessons from the Australian Water Reform
Programme.” Background Report. Sustainable Manage-
ment of Water Resources in Agriculture. OECD. Available
at dx.doi.org/10.1787/786732081512.
Young, M. 2015. “Tricks of the Trade: Learning From Austra-
lia’s Water Reform Experience.” Waterfront 1 (1): 10–12.
Zbinden, S.  D.R. Lee. 2005. “Paying for Environmental Ser-
vices: An Analysis of Participation in Costa Rica’s PSA
Program.” World Development, Institutional arrange-
ments for rural poverty reduction and resource conserva-
tion, 33 (2): 255–72. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.012.
Zedler, J.B.  S. Kercher. 2005. “WETLAND RESOURCES:
Status, Trends, Ecosystem Services, and Restorability.”
Annual Review of Environment and Resources 30 (1):
39–74. doi:10.1146/annurev.energy.30.050504.144248.
Zellmer, S.B.  J. Harder. 2007. “Unbundling Property in
Water.” Alabama Law Review 59: 679.
Zucchino, D. 2015. “Duke Energy Fined $102 Million for Pol-
luting Rivers with Coal Ash.” Los Angeles Times, May 14.
Available at latimes.com/nation/la-na-duke-energy-coal-
ash-20150514-story.html#page=1.
Zwarteveen, M.Z. 1997. “Water: From Basic Need to Com-
modity: A Discussion on Gender and Water Rights in
the Context of Irrigation.” World Development 25 (8):
1335–49.
Wada, Y., L.P.H. van Beek, C.M. van Kempen, J.W.T.M. Reck-
man, S. Vasak  M.F.P. Bierkens. 2010. “Global Depletion of
Groundwater Resources.” Geophysical Research Letters
37 (20): L20402. doi:10.1029/2010GL044571.
Wallace, K.H. 2007. “Trading Pollution for Water Quality:
Assessing the Effects of Market-Based Instruments in
Three Basins.” Master’s Thesis, Cambridge, Massachu-
setts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Available at
dspace.mit.edu/handle/1721.1/39938.
Watershed Agricultural Council. 2011. “Strategic Plan: 2011-
2014.” Walton, New York. Available at nycwatershed.org/
pdfs/Strategic_Plan_2011-2014.pdf.
Wheeler, S.A.  J. Cheesman. 2013. “Key Findings from a Sur-
vey of Sellers to the Restoring the Balance Programme.”
Economic Papers: A Journal of Applied Economics
and Policy 32 (3): 340–52. doi:10.1111/1759-3441.12038.
Wind, M.H.A. 2012. “Water Emissions Trading in Europe - A
Literature Overview and Discussion of Opportunities.”
Eco-consult Environmental Economics. http://www.eco-
consult.nl/images/pdf/WET_in_Europe_v3.pdf.
Woodward, R.T., R.A. Kaiser  A.B. Wicks. 2002. “The Struc-
ture and Practice of Water Quality Trading Markets.”
Journal of the American Water Resources Association
38 (4): 967–79. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2002.tb05538.x.
World Economic Forum (WEF). 2012. “Global Risks 2012,
Seventh Edition.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic
Forum (WEF). Available at weforum.org/docs/WEF_Glo-
balRisks_Report_2012.pdf.
———. 2013. “Global Risks 2013, Eighth Edition.” Geneva,
Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available
at.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalRisks_Report_2013.pdf.
———. 2014. “Global Risks 2014, Ninth Edition.” Geneva,
Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at
weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalRisks_Report_2014.pdf.
———. 2015. “Global Risks 2015, 10th Edition.” Geneva, Swit-
zerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at wefo-
rum.org/docs/WEF_Global_Risks_2015_Report15.pdf.
World Health Organization and UNICEF. 2015. “Progress on
Sanitation and Drinking Water - 2015 Update and MDG
Assessment.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Health Orga-
nization. Available at wssinfo.org/fileadmin/user_upload/
resources/JMP-Update-report-2015_English.pdf.
OhioRiver,Indiana.PhotographbyRavenonhealth.
www.rockefellerfoundation.org
Financial support provided by
Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management
Publisher(s): Foundation Center; Pacific Institute; Rockefeller Foundation
Author(s): Michael Cohen; Heather Cooley; Matthew Heberger; Heather Rippman
Date Published: 2015-12-01
Rights: Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 International
Subject(s): Energy and Environment
IssueLab Permalink: http://www.issuelab.org/permalink/resource/23697
_______________________________________________________________________________________________________________
This social sector resource is permanently archived with IssueLab.
IssueLab permalink: http://www.issuelab.org/permalink/resource/23697
Metadata last modified: 2016-01-26
Date file archived: 2016-01-20
Date this page generated to accompany file download: 2016-02-08
IssueLab, a service of the Foundation Center, works to more effectively gather, index, and share the
collective intelligence of the social sector. We provide free access to thousands of case studies, evaluations,
white papers, and issue briefs published by foundations, nonprofits, and academic research centers that
address some of the world's most pressing social problems. Visit www.issuelab.org where you can search,
browse, access, and share social sector resources.

More Related Content

PDF
Exploring Incentive- based Solutions for Freshwater Management
PDF
Degradation and Loss of Peri-Urban Ecosystems
PDF
The Evaluation of the Design Competition of Rebuild by Design
PDF
Rebuild by Design Phase 1 Evaluation Report
PDF
ACCCRN Cities Projects 2014
PDF
Rebound: Building a More Resilient World
PDF
Planetary Health: A Special Edition of the Economist Magazine
PDF
A critical scan of four key topics for the philanthropic sector
Exploring Incentive- based Solutions for Freshwater Management
Degradation and Loss of Peri-Urban Ecosystems
The Evaluation of the Design Competition of Rebuild by Design
Rebuild by Design Phase 1 Evaluation Report
ACCCRN Cities Projects 2014
Rebound: Building a More Resilient World
Planetary Health: A Special Edition of the Economist Magazine
A critical scan of four key topics for the philanthropic sector

What's hot (20)

PDF
Global Resilience Partnership – Overview
PPTX
Resilience By Design: The Future of Coastal Cities
PDF
Effective Public Health Communication in an Interconnected World: Enhancing R...
PDF
A Roadmap to Reduce U.S. Food Waste by 20 Percent
PDF
Key Factors Supporting Small Scale Coastal Fisheries Management
PDF
What is a resilient health system? Lessons from Ebola | The Lancet
PDF
City Resilience Framework
PPTX
Mitigation Of What And By What Presentationfinal
PDF
Taking Stock of Our Natural Capital by Tess Bacalla
PDF
Situating the Next Generation of Impact Measurement and Evaluation for Impact...
PDF
World Bank promotional brochure about natural capital accounting
PDF
Scanning the landscape by Ryan Rosauro
PPTX
Who should value nature. Rethiking Capitals conference December 2014 at ICAEW...
PDF
Urban resilience
PPT
GWP & IWRM
PDF
GroundworkScientificAssessment
PDF
2015 WWW report-Chapter 12
PDF
Our Goal: Lasting human well-being by Conservation International
PDF
Determinants of Households Willingness to Pay for Conservation of Natural Koo...
PDF
Newsletter 205
Global Resilience Partnership – Overview
Resilience By Design: The Future of Coastal Cities
Effective Public Health Communication in an Interconnected World: Enhancing R...
A Roadmap to Reduce U.S. Food Waste by 20 Percent
Key Factors Supporting Small Scale Coastal Fisheries Management
What is a resilient health system? Lessons from Ebola | The Lancet
City Resilience Framework
Mitigation Of What And By What Presentationfinal
Taking Stock of Our Natural Capital by Tess Bacalla
Situating the Next Generation of Impact Measurement and Evaluation for Impact...
World Bank promotional brochure about natural capital accounting
Scanning the landscape by Ryan Rosauro
Who should value nature. Rethiking Capitals conference December 2014 at ICAEW...
Urban resilience
GWP & IWRM
GroundworkScientificAssessment
2015 WWW report-Chapter 12
Our Goal: Lasting human well-being by Conservation International
Determinants of Households Willingness to Pay for Conservation of Natural Koo...
Newsletter 205
Ad

Similar to Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management (20)

PPTX
Green infrastructure finance
PDF
SWaRMA_IRBM_Module1_#1, Principles of IWRM and IRBM: Challenges for the Himal...
PDF
Funding Water Projects Whitepaper
PDF
Toward Water Sustainability: a blueprint for philanthropy
PDF
Presentations_LAC water beam_TNC_Sep16_2013
PPT
Corporate Water Stewardship and Collective Action: The Water Action Hub
PPT
Enabling environment.ppt:Enabling environment
PDF
Presentation - 9th Roundtable on Financing water - Amgad Elmahdi
PPTX
The UN Global Compact: CEO Water Mandate and the Water Action Hub
PPTX
Building national water and sanitation monitoring capacity in Haiti
PPTX
Innovative financial mechanisms and water related collective action for wate...
PPT
Chapter 2 from_water_related_issues_to_e&f_instruments
PPT
Nicholas Parker - BEI
PDF
Making Sustainable Commitments An Environment Strategy For The World Bank Wor...
PDF
IWRM LECRURE TWO.pdfIWRM LECRURE TWO.pdf
PDF
Water Security The Water Food Energy Climate Nexus 1st Edition The World Econ...
PDF
Financing Investment in Water Security: Recent Developments and Perspectives ...
PDF
Water Resource Economics The Analysis Of Scarcity Policies And Projects Ronal...
Green infrastructure finance
SWaRMA_IRBM_Module1_#1, Principles of IWRM and IRBM: Challenges for the Himal...
Funding Water Projects Whitepaper
Toward Water Sustainability: a blueprint for philanthropy
Presentations_LAC water beam_TNC_Sep16_2013
Corporate Water Stewardship and Collective Action: The Water Action Hub
Enabling environment.ppt:Enabling environment
Presentation - 9th Roundtable on Financing water - Amgad Elmahdi
The UN Global Compact: CEO Water Mandate and the Water Action Hub
Building national water and sanitation monitoring capacity in Haiti
Innovative financial mechanisms and water related collective action for wate...
Chapter 2 from_water_related_issues_to_e&f_instruments
Nicholas Parker - BEI
Making Sustainable Commitments An Environment Strategy For The World Bank Wor...
IWRM LECRURE TWO.pdfIWRM LECRURE TWO.pdf
Water Security The Water Food Energy Climate Nexus 1st Edition The World Econ...
Financing Investment in Water Security: Recent Developments and Perspectives ...
Water Resource Economics The Analysis Of Scarcity Policies And Projects Ronal...
Ad

More from The Rockefeller Foundation (20)

PDF
Transforming Health Systems Final Evaluation
PDF
Thinking Strategically About Networks for Change
PDF
Putting “Impact” at the Center of Impact Investing: A Case Study of How Green...
PDF
Integrating mini grids with india's evolving electricity system may 2017
PDF
Smart Power Connect May 2017
PDF
Expanding Opportunities for Renewable Energy-Based Mini-Grids in Rural India
PDF
Implementation Models - Synthesis of Findings
PDF
Smart Power Impact Report
PDF
THS Joint Learning Network Case Study Brief
PDF
THS Joint Learning Network Case Study
PDF
Reducing food waste by changing the way consumers interact with food
PDF
Impact hiring survey results
PDF
National Disaster Resilience Competition's Resilience Academies - Emerging In...
PDF
NDRC Resilience Academies Evaluation Report 2016
PDF
Resilience Week 2016 Hosted by The Rockefeller Foundation
PDF
Asian Cities Climate Change Resilience Network Initiative Final Evaluation
PDF
Inclusive Economy Indicators Full Report Dec 2016
PDF
Inclusive Economy Indicators Exec Summary
PDF
100x25 CEO & Gender Media Audit Infographic
PDF
Equity and inclusive growth background paper - sept 2016
Transforming Health Systems Final Evaluation
Thinking Strategically About Networks for Change
Putting “Impact” at the Center of Impact Investing: A Case Study of How Green...
Integrating mini grids with india's evolving electricity system may 2017
Smart Power Connect May 2017
Expanding Opportunities for Renewable Energy-Based Mini-Grids in Rural India
Implementation Models - Synthesis of Findings
Smart Power Impact Report
THS Joint Learning Network Case Study Brief
THS Joint Learning Network Case Study
Reducing food waste by changing the way consumers interact with food
Impact hiring survey results
National Disaster Resilience Competition's Resilience Academies - Emerging In...
NDRC Resilience Academies Evaluation Report 2016
Resilience Week 2016 Hosted by The Rockefeller Foundation
Asian Cities Climate Change Resilience Network Initiative Final Evaluation
Inclusive Economy Indicators Full Report Dec 2016
Inclusive Economy Indicators Exec Summary
100x25 CEO & Gender Media Audit Infographic
Equity and inclusive growth background paper - sept 2016

Recently uploaded (20)

PPTX
sustainable-development in tech-ppt[1].pptx
PDF
Urban Hub 50: Spirits of Place - & the Souls' of Places
DOCX
Double Membrane Roofs for Biogas Tanks Securely store produced biogas.docx
DOCX
D-360 ESG Series: Sustainable Hospitality Strategies for a Greener Future
PPTX
FIRE SAFETY SEMINAR SAMPLE FOR EVERYONE.pptx
PPTX
Disposal Of Wastes.pptx according to community medicine
PDF
Ornithology-Basic-Concepts.pdf..........
PPT
Environmental pollution for educational study
PPTX
Biodiversity of nature in environmental studies.pptx
PPTX
Concept of Safe and Wholesome Water.pptx
PDF
FMM Slides For OSH Management Requirement
PDF
2-Reqerwsrhfdfsfgtdrttddjdiuiversion 2.pdf
PPT
PPTPresentation3 jhsvdasvdjhavsdhsvjcksjbc.jasb..ppt
PDF
Effect of salinity on biochimical and anatomical characteristics of sweet pep...
DOCX
Epoxy Coated Steel Bolted Tanks for Dairy Farm Water Ensures Clean Water for ...
PPTX
Green and Cream Aesthetic Group Project Presentation.pptx
PPTX
Environmental Ethics: issues and possible solutions
PPTX
NSTP1 NSTP1NSTP1NSTP1NSTP1NSTP1NSTP1NSTP
DOCX
Epoxy Coated Steel Bolted Tanks for Beverage Wastewater Storage Manages Liqui...
PPTX
Green Modern Sustainable Living Nature Presentation_20250226_230231_0000.pptx
sustainable-development in tech-ppt[1].pptx
Urban Hub 50: Spirits of Place - & the Souls' of Places
Double Membrane Roofs for Biogas Tanks Securely store produced biogas.docx
D-360 ESG Series: Sustainable Hospitality Strategies for a Greener Future
FIRE SAFETY SEMINAR SAMPLE FOR EVERYONE.pptx
Disposal Of Wastes.pptx according to community medicine
Ornithology-Basic-Concepts.pdf..........
Environmental pollution for educational study
Biodiversity of nature in environmental studies.pptx
Concept of Safe and Wholesome Water.pptx
FMM Slides For OSH Management Requirement
2-Reqerwsrhfdfsfgtdrttddjdiuiversion 2.pdf
PPTPresentation3 jhsvdasvdjhavsdhsvjcksjbc.jasb..ppt
Effect of salinity on biochimical and anatomical characteristics of sweet pep...
Epoxy Coated Steel Bolted Tanks for Dairy Farm Water Ensures Clean Water for ...
Green and Cream Aesthetic Group Project Presentation.pptx
Environmental Ethics: issues and possible solutions
NSTP1 NSTP1NSTP1NSTP1NSTP1NSTP1NSTP1NSTP
Epoxy Coated Steel Bolted Tanks for Beverage Wastewater Storage Manages Liqui...
Green Modern Sustainable Living Nature Presentation_20250226_230231_0000.pptx

Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management

  • 1. Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management December 2015 SYNTHESIS REVIEW THE RockefellerFoundation EVALUATIONOFFICE Financial support provided by
  • 2. About the Pacific Institute The Pacific Institute envisions a world in which society, the economy, and the environment have the water they need to thrive now and in the future. In pursuit of this vision, the Pacific Institute creates and advances solutions to the world’s most pressing water challenges, such as unsustainable water manage- ment and use, climate change, environmental degradation, and basic lack of access to fresh water and sanitation. Since 1987, the Pacific Institute has cut across traditional areas of study and actively collabo- rated with a diverse set of stakeholders, including leading policy makers, scientists, corporate leaders, and international organizations such as the United Nations, advocacy groups, and local communities. This interdisciplinary and independent approach helps bring diverse groups together to forge effective real-world solutions. About the Foundation Center Established in 1956, Foundation Center is the leading source of information about philanthropy worldwide. Through data, analysis, and training, it connects people who want to change the world to the resources they need to succeed. The Foundation Center maintains the most comprehensive database on US and, increasingly, global grantmakers and their grants – a robust, accessible knowledge bank for the sector. It also operates research, education, and training programs designed to advance knowledge of philanthro- py at every level. The Foundation Center’s IssueLab service works to gather, index, and share the collec- tive intelligence of the social sector more effectively, providing free access to thousands of case studies, evaluations, white papers, and issue briefs addressing some of the world’s most pressing problems. About The Rockefeller Foundation For more than 100 years, The Rockefeller Foundation’s mission has been to promote the well-being of humanity throughout the world. Today, The Rockefeller Foundation pursues this mission through dual goals: advancing inclusive economies that expand opportunities for more broadly shared prosper- ity, and building resilience by helping people, communities, and institutions prepare for, withstand and emerge stronger from acute shocks and chronic stresses. Committed to supporting learning, account- ability and performance improvements, the Evaluation Office of The Rockefeller Foundation works with staff, grantees, and partners to strengthen evaluation practice and to support innovative approaches to monitoring, evaluation, and learning. For this synthesis review, The Rockefeller Foundation provided financial support, the Foundation Center and its IssueLab service were involved in project and technology development, and the Pacific Institute authored the report. Pacific Institute authors included Heather Cooley, Michael Cohen, Matthew Heberger, and Heather Rippman. Cover: Hudson River, NY. Photograph by Daniel Case.
  • 3. The contents of this report are the views of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of The Rockefeller Foundation. © 2015, The Rockefeller Foundation This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 License Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management December 2015 Financial support provided by THE RockefellerFoundation EVALUATIONOFFICE
  • 5. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT iii Table of Contents Acronyms v Foreword vii Acknowledgements ix Executive summary x Water trading x Payment for ecosystem services xiii Water quality trading xv Conclusions xvi 1 Introduction 1 2 Research methodology 5 3 Environmental policy instruments 7 3.1 Water trading 10 Description 10 Application 12 Environmental, economic, and social performance 16 Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions 25 3.2 Payment for ecosystem services/payment for watershed services 28 Description 28 Application 30 Environmental, economic, and social performance 31 Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions 35 3.3 Water quality trading 39 Description 39 Application 41 Environmental, economic, and social performance 44 Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions 48 4 Role of the private sector 53 4.1 Corporate water stewardship 53 4.2 Private sector engagement with incentive-based instruments 55 5 Summary and conclusions 61
  • 6. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTiv Annexes Annex 1: Demand management 63 Annex 2: Water trading in Australia: Lessons from the Murray-Darling Basin 66 Background 66 MCB and the Colorado River Basin 66 History 67 Water trading activity 69 Enabling conditions 71 Lessons learned 71 Glossary 74 References 75
  • 7. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT v Acronyms ARP Acid Rain Program (US) AWS Alliance for Water Stewardship BIER Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable BMP Best management practices CAC Command-and-control CDP Carbon Disclosure Project (former name) CRP Conservation Reserve Program (US) DEG German Investment and Development Corporation EPA Environmental Protection Agency (US) EPRI Electric Power Research Institute GEF The Global Environment Facility GPCD Gallons per capita daily IID Imperial Irrigation District (California, US) IWS Investment in watershed services MAF Million acre-feet M&I Municipal and industrial MDB Murray-Darling Basin MDBA Murray-Darling Basin Authority MWD Metropolitan Water District of Southern California (California, US) MWELO Model Water Efficient Landscape Ordinance NRC National Research Council (US) NSWDEC New South Wales Department of Education and Communities (Australia) NWC National Water Commission (Australia) PES Payment for ecosystems services PSAH Programme for Hydrological Environmental Services (Mexico) PSA Pagos por servicios ambientales (payment for environmental services) PWS Payment for watershed services RUPES Rewarding Upland Poor for Environmental Services (Indonesia) SBP Socio Bosque Program (Ecuador) SDCWA San Diego County Water Authority SO2 Sulfur dioxide SWP State Water Project (California, US) TMDL Total maximum daily load TWSTT Transforming Water Scarcity through Trading
  • 8. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTvi UCSB University of California at Santa Barbara UN United Nations UNDP United Nations Development Programme UNEP United Nations Environment Programme USBR United States Bureau of Reclamation WEF World Economic Forum WfW Working for Water (South Africa) WHO World Health Organization WQT Water quality trading WRI World Resources Institute WWF World Wide Fund for Nature
  • 9. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT vii Foreword Human transformation of freshwater ecosystems is rapidly exceeding capacity required to sustain the conditions we need to survive and thrive. Water crises are already impacting people around the globe – from river basins in California and China, to the cities of São Palo and Bangkok. Under current population and growth trends, the 2030 Water Resources Group predicts global water demand will exceed available supply by 40 percent by 2030. Humans have used, benefited from, and shaped the natural environment for the whole of human history. But what we have not done – especially in the course of industrialization and modernization – is find effective ways to integrate natural ecosystems into our economic and social systems. In response to these challenges, The Rockefeller Foundation’s work focuses on incentive-based solutions that harness the importance of ecosystems as an asset for smart development, economic and social progress, and long-term resilience. In our work on agriculture and food security, climate change, energy, and fisheries, we seek new approaches to environmental care that will create incentives for the wise use of resources, and preserve their resilience. And in all of our work we place particular emphasis on the effects of these solutions on the poor or otherwise vulnerable members of society, who are most directly dependent on ecosystems to meet their basic needs and are mostly likely to bear the consequences of environmental degradation. Freshwater crises are representative of the kind of misaligned incentives we seek to correct. Freshwater allocation and management systems often place little value on the benefits of functioning ecosystems. This, in turn, leads to a vicious cycle in which ecosystem degradation and overuse reduce future water supplies, making even more people vulnerable to water scarcity. As water crises continue to capture public attention – in January, the World Economic Forum’s Global Risk Report 2015 named water crises the number one economic risk in terms of impact – and decision makers worldwide scramble for answers, The Rockefeller Foundation is eager to help support the identification of sound solutions by synthesiz- ing the knowledge and lessons from past and current water management interventions. The synthesis report that follows examines several incentive-based instruments for improving freshwa- ter management for all users, including poor and vulnerable populations and the freshwater ecosystems themselves. The report examines the economic, social, and environmental performance of three tools, which were selected because: there is growing interest in applying these instruments in a range of settings, they are clearly focused on voluntary transactions rather than sanctions or voluntary standards, they can be applied to improve water quality or quantity, and there is an existing body of literature about their implementation upon which we can build. However, one of the key findings is that these transac- tions are often not voluntary. The report highlights the importance of finding a fit between a commu- nity’s water goals and the water management tool(s) it might choose and, perhaps most importantly, it characterizes the enabling conditions required for their effective implementation. We hope this synthesis
  • 10. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTviii review will serve as an entry point for those exploring opportunities to improve the management of freshwater, and will spark the development of more robust solutions to improve our management and maintenance of freshwater systems.  We hope that you will find this report useful and encourage you to explore the accompanying learning tool at freshwater.issuelab.org and to share it widely with colleagues. Dr. Fred Boltz Managing Director, Ecosystems The Rockefeller Foundation
  • 11. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT ix Acknowledgements The overall design of this synthesis review was led and managed collaboratively by Gabi Fitz from the Foundation Center and Alex Martinez from The Rockefeller Foundation. The research, analysis and written synthesis were undertaken by a freshwater specialist team from the Pacific Institute led by Heather Cooley and Michael Cohen, and assisted by Matthew Heberger and Heather Rippman. Their work was further supported by John Berggren, who provided research assistance and Genevieve Bennett, Roy Brouwer, Jessica Fox, Chuck Howe, Cy Jones, Tony McLeod, Marcus Moench, and Ina Porras who all provided the team with valuable information and suggested additional readings. The visualization and special collection were designed and developed by Lisa Brooks and Gabi Fitz from the Foundation Center and IssueLab, in collaboration with ThreeStory Studio. Peer review was provided by Dr. Casey Brown of the University of Massachusetts, Matt Elliott, Amy Dickie, Mark Michelin, Emily Peterson, and James Giampietro of California Environmental Associates, The Rockefeller Foundation Freshwater Team, and Nancy MacPherson from The Rockefeller Founda- tion’s Evaluation Office. Learning from Experience – an ongoing collaboration between the Foundation Center and The Rockefeller Foundation This synthesis review, Incentive-based Instruments for Water Management, is part of an ongoing collab- oration between The Rockefeller Foundation and the Foundation Center, aimed at helping organizations build more effectively on each other’s knowledge, lessons and experience. With financial support from The Rockefeller Foundation, the Foundation Center is engaging in synthesis reviews and the develop- ment of supportive technologies and practices that facilitate the collection, synthesis, and sharing of the sector’s collective knowledge. As part of our collaboration, we are committed to sharing all work products from these efforts as public goods. Too often, systematic and synthesis reviews result in a public report but leave future researchers having to duplicate search and selection efforts in order to further build on a synthesis. By collecting and sharing coded search results through an open repository and openly licensing all work products, we hope other researchers can more freely use and repurpose our findings. Our goal is to contribute to better programmatic and funding strategies by enabling teams and organizations to start with a more inclusive and comprehensive understanding of what has worked, what hasn’t, and why. Gabi Fitz Nancy MacPherson Director of Knowledge Management Initiatives Managing Director, Evaluation Foundation Center The Rockefeller Foundation
  • 12. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTx Executive summary Water is one of our most precious and valuable resources and is fundamental for maintaining human health, economic activity, and critical ecosystem functions. Yet, we can see clear signs of the overexploi- tation of available freshwater resources and the resultant inability to meet basic human and ecosystem needs. Already, some iconic rivers, such as the Colorado in the United States and the Yellow in China, no longer reach the sea. Groundwater withdrawals have tripled over the past 50 years, with groundwater ex- traction exceeding natural recharge in some areas, causing widespread depletion and declining ground- water levels. More than 660 million people lack access to an improved drinking water source, predomi- nantly in sub-Saharan Africa and Oceania, and some 2.4 billion people lack access to basic sanitation.1 At the same time, the world’s water quality is becoming increasingly degraded, with water pollution exac- erbating the challenges posed by water scarcity. Pressure on water resources is intensifying in response to challenges such as economic and population growth, and, in turn, is having major impacts on our social, economic, and environmental well-being. With traditional approaches to managing water having proven insufficient to address these challenges, new approaches and policies are needed. Policy makers and water managers are showing increasing interest in incentive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water resources. In most regions, laws and regulations have been the primary policy tools employed to improve envi- ronmental outcomes. However, over the past several decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to reallocate water, or reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products. This report provides a synthesis review of a set of incentive-based instruments that have been employed to varying degrees around the world. It is part of an effort by The Rockefeller Foundation to improve understanding of both the potential of these instruments and their limitations. The report is divided into five sections. Section 1 provides an introduction to the synthesis review. Section 2 describes the research methodology. Section 3 provides background on policy instruments and detail on three incentive-based instruments – water trading, payment for ecosystem services, and water quality trading – describing the application of each, including their environmental, economic, and social performances, and the condi- tions needed for their implementation. Section 4 highlights the role of the private sector in implementing these instruments, and Section 5 provides a summary and conclusions. Water trading Water trading refers to the temporary or permanent transfer of the right to use water in exchange for some form of compensation. It is perhaps the best known and most widely used method of reallocating water. It has proven, in some cases, to be less expensive, more flexible, and less time-consuming than 1 An “improved” drinking-water source is one that, by nature of its construction and when properly used, adequately protects the source from outside contamination, particularly fecal matter.
  • 13. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xi developing new water supplies through, for example, constructing new diversion structures or desali- nation plants. Similarly, water trading is generally a more accepted method of reallocating water than state appropriation or revoking of existing water rights. Today, examples of successful water trading in Australia and other locations – combined with classic economic theory which suggests that market mechanisms can optimize resource allocation – have heightened interest in this instrument in both academic literature and popular media. Water trading occurs within sectors, from agriculture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban, across sectors and, less frequently, from either of these to the environment. Water trading exists, to varying degrees, in countries around the world, though the most active water trading markets are in Australia and the western United States. In Australia, the total value of water trading in fiscal year 2012–13 exceeded $1.4 billion, with much of that activity concentrated within the Murray-Darling Basin. While the total volume of water traded via long-term trades within the Murray-Darling Basin decreased slightly in fiscal year 2012–2013, the volume of water traded via short-term trades increased by 44 percent from the previous year, from almost 3.5 to 5.0 million acre-feet (MAF), or about 50 percent of the total surface water use in the basin.2 In the western United States, where the scale of water trading is considerably lower, there were more than 4,000 water trades between 1987 and 2008. In 2011, the most recent year for which data are available, more than 1.4 MAF of water were traded in California, representing about 4 percent of the total water use that year. Of that amount, 42 percent of the water traded went to municipal and industrial users, 37 percent to agricultural users, 17 percent was used for environmental purposes, and the remainder was for mixed uses. The actual results of water trading worldwide have been decidedly mixed, due to two key challenges: ex- ternalities and transaction costs. In Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin, the federal government overcame some of those challenges by investing more than $3 billion to purchase water for the environment, pro- tecting ecological resources and directly addressing one of the major challenges to water trading. This has facilitated trading in the basin and reduced transaction costs by shifting them to national taxpayers. Over the last 30 years, the federal government also implemented significant institutional changes that facilitated trading and reduced transaction costs. Short-term water trading within irrigation districts in the United States, such as within the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, occurs smoothly and quickly because intra-district trades undergo very limited oversight, and because the third-party impacts of such trades tend to be small or negligible. However, these examples of successful water trading regimes are countered by critical arguments and examples of less-successful trades from various parts of the world. Many authors challenge the applica- bility and efficacy of water trading, contending that externalities and the unique characteristics of water itself pose significant obstacles to trading water. Many of these externalities arise from the physical properties of water: it is heavy, unwieldy, and easily contaminated; varies seasonally and from year to year; and is readily lost through evaporation, seepage, or runoff. Further, externalities may be borne by disparate parties, such as the environment or future generations, challenging efforts to compensate those injured by trading. Questions of externalities, commodification, and the special nature of water 2 An acre-foot, the conventional unit of water measurement in the western United States, is equivalent to 325,851 gallons or 1,233.48 m3.
  • 14. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxii itself highlight the challenges faced when seeking to implement or expand water trading. Critics also highlight the many examples of “buy-and-dry” water trades, where water-rich agricultural areas sell their water rights, often to wealthier cities, only to find that rural communities as a whole suffer when agricul- tural production declines. Critics have pointed to examples around the world where wealthy communi- ties or interests have purchased and withdrawn water from less powerful, poor rural areas. The environmental performance of water trading has been highly variable, depending on the type of trade and site-specific conditions. Water trading has been used as a mechanism to obtain water for ecological purposes, to augment streamflow, and to address water quality concerns (such as tempera- ture) in threatened reaches. The benefits of voluntary, incentive-based water acquisition include ease of transaction and greater community support, especially relative to regulatory takings,3 though in most areas, such activity still represents a tiny fraction of total water use in any given area. In California, in the last three decades, environmental water purchases averaged 152,000 acre-feet per year, accounting for about 14 percent of trading activity and less than 0.5 percent of total water use in the state. Conversely, water trades for other purposes can inadvertently harm the environment. They can, for example, change the timing, quantity, and quality of return flows, adversely affecting riparian and wetland habitats and the species that depend upon them. Water trading has rarely been employed to address equity challenges. Indeed, water trading can exacer- bate social and economic inequalities, worsening gender and geographic differences. Unequal access to water markets due to unequal access to information or credit can distort outcomes and reduce market efficiency. On the other hand, water trading that promotes water-use efficiency rather than fallowing of agricultural land can improve socio-economic outcomes for both the area of origin and the destination. Water trading’s social impacts vary based on several factors, including the relative economic health of the area of origin and the purchasing area, whether or not the water leaves the area of origin, the process used to trade the water, the relative economic and political power of the parties, gender differences regarding access to and control of water, the amount of trading activity in the area, and the legitimacy of the water rights being traded. Impacts often vary within the same community, as those with water rights or allocations to trade receive compensation, while third parties – such as irrigation equipment suppliers or farmworkers – may suffer a loss of revenue or income as a result of trading. Institutional arrangements are among the most important factors that determine the ultimate success or failure of water trading. Successful water trading requires secure and flexible water rights that recognize and protect users and others from externalities. Such institutional arrangements also need to be flexible enough to adapt to changing physical conditions as well as changing social norms, such as the growing interest in meeting environmental needs and protecting water quality. Some factors, such as access to timely information about water available to trade, can enable water trading but may not be required. Other factors, such as legal and transferable rights to use water, may be necessary for water trading to occur. Still other factors, such as “no injury” regulations and “area of origin” protection, limit water trading or can function as barriers or obstacles to trading. 3 A “regulatory taking” occurs when a government regulation limits or infringes upon a private property right to such an extent that it deprives the owner of some or all of the value of that property” (Fischel, 1995).
  • 15. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xiii In a limited number of areas with the necessary legal and technical conditions and with sufficient public investment, water trading has offered a timely, relatively inexpensive, and flexible mechanism to real- locate water between users, or from water users back to the environment. Building a successful water market requires decades of determined effort to measure water flows and use, report transactions publicly, conduct regional water planning, and construct and maintain infrastructure to convey water. In Australia’s case, it also required more than $3 billion of public funding to acquire water for environmental purposes, which also called for creating and, in turn, maintaining an environmental baseline above which trading activity could occur. Such significant institutional changes require broad public support and a considerable amount of time to implement. Although water trading can be used to reallocate water ef- fectively, successful implementation requires a clear understanding of existing conditions and a deter- mined, long-term effort to make the necessary changes and minimize externalities. Payment for ecosystem services Payment for ecosystem services is an incentive-based instrument that seeks to monetize the external, non-market values of environmental services – such as removal of pollutants and regulation of precipita- tion events – that can then be used as financial incentives for local actors to provide such services. In practical terms, they involve a series of payments to a land or resource manager in exchange for a guar- anteed flow of environmental services. Payments are made to the environmental service provider by the beneficiary of those services, e.g. an individual, a community, a company, or a government. In essence, it is based on a beneficiary-pays principle, as opposed to a polluter-pays principle. Payments for ecosystems services (PESs) that focus on watershed services, commonly referred to as “payments for watershed services” (PWSs), can take a variety of forms. They may be intended to prevent the degradation of a watershed or to restore a previously degraded one. They may be small, local schemes covering several hundred hectares or large, national schemes covering millions of hectares. Programs may be financed directly by the beneficiary or by third parties acting on behalf of the benefi- ciary, e.g. governments or institutions, or some combination thereof. They may involve cash or in-kind payments to be paid all at once or periodically. New York City provides a well-known example. In the late 1990s, New York City was faced with the prospect of building a $4–$6 billion filtration plant with an additional $250 million in annual operating costs to meet new federal drinking water standards. An initial analysis suggested that preserving the upstream rural Catskill watershed would be far less expensive. The city and local farmers came together to develop a plan that could meet both groups’ interests. A key element of the plan was the Whole Farm Program, a voluntary effort fully funded by New York City’s Department of Environmental Protection whereby farmers would work with technical advisors to custom design pollution control measures to meet an environmental objective while also improving the viability of their farming businesses. By 2006, the city had spent or committed between $1.4 billion and $1.5 billion in watershed protection projects, averaging $167 million in expenditures per year – far less than building a water filtration plant. Participa- tion remains high, with 96 percent of large farms in the watershed participating in the program. Payments for watershed services are gaining prominence and have been applied in a wide range of settings. Some of the earliest programs were established in Central America but today, such programs
  • 16. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxiv can be found in countries around the world. The United States’ Conservation Reserve Program pays farmers to take land out of production in order to protect soil and water resources and wildlife habitat. In northeastern France, Vittel-Nestle Waters paid farmers and provided technical support (and some labor) to alter local dairy farming practices in order to reduce nitrate pollution of groundwater – the source of Vittel’s bottled water. The largest PWS programs are in China. China’s Sloping Land Conversion Programme, piloted in 1999 and fully implemented in 2002, requires farmers to set aside erosion-prone farmland within critical areas of the watershed of the Yangtze and Yellow Rivers – the two largest rivers in China. In exchange, farmers receive regular cash payments and grain rations. The program promotes forestry and other economic endeavors on the land rather than grain production, in order to prevent sediment from washing into rivers and clogging dams and shipping channels. The environmental performance of PWS is not well understood. Evaluation of these programs is in- herently difficult because the connections between land use practice and watershed services are not always clear, especially as they relate to water quantity, and they are often site-specific. It can also be difficult to attribute change to the program rather than to external factors (e.g. changing commodity prices), and programs may not reach threshold levels for measureable impact, or that impact may occur over a relatively long time period. In addition to these challenges, many programs lack baseline data or monitoring systems. In the absence of scientific information, performance is often based on perceptions of local populations and those operating the schemes. But even based on these sources, the available data suggest that environmental performance of PWS is mixed, with less than 60 percent of programs reaching their environmental objective. As the field has matured, it has increased emphasis on monitor- ing, which will inevitably help improve environmental outcomes. Similarly,limiteddataareavailableonthesocialandeconomicimpactsofpaymentsforwatershedservices. Most studies have focused on increased income or capacity building rather than broader social impacts, such as changes in power dynamics. While participation in a PWS program can boost the income of small farmers, the payments they receive will typically boost their annual incomes only slightly. Several studies have also suggested that there are important non-financial (or non-income) benefits, such as increasing land-tenure security, creating human and social capital through internal organization, and improving the visibility of the community to donors and public entities. Some analysts have argued that because the programs are mostly voluntary, continued participation provides some indication that the programs are cost effective, i.e. that benefits exceed costs and participants are satisfied with the outcomes. While information on broader social outcomes is limited, there is information on the role of these arrange- ments in alleviating poverty. However, it is important to recognize that payment for watershed services was conceptualized as a mechanism to improve the efficiency of natural resource management, not as a mechanism to reduce poverty. Several studies have examined the socio-economic status of participants, either as buyers or sellers, and have found mixed results, depending to some extent on land and forest tenure regimes and socio-economic conditions in the targeted areas. While most programs prioritize areas critical for ecosystem services, some have been tailored to meet social objectives through a variety
  • 17. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xv of mechanisms, such as targeting the programs to particular areas or populations, reducing transac- tion costs, and providing pro-poor premiums and subsidies. While there are often more direct ways of reducing poverty than payments for watershed services (e.g. education or health programs), there is little evidence of these schemes actually doing any harm. Few studies have examined gender represen- tation among program participants. In general, payments for watershed services are flexible, and the necessary conditions are relatively modest. Small, self-organized schemes between private entities are based on general legal require- ments: a legal system recognizing that agreements must be kept and that civil law must provide the contracting parties with legal remedies in case of non-compliance. Expanding these projects to address regional or national water problems would require a more developed policy and legal framework along with incentives or requirements to participate in PES programs, cultural and political acceptance of markets, trust between ecosystem service providers and beneficiaries, and a supply and demand for ecosystem services. Water quality trading Water quality trading (WQT) is an incentive-based approach for reducing or controlling water pollution. Under such a system, polluters are granted a permit to pollute, and these permits can be bought and sold among polluters. The central idea is that trading puts a price on pollution, encouraging cost savings, efficiency, and innovation. Water quality trading is an adjunct to regulation, not an alternative to it. In fact, its success depends on the presence of a strong regulatory body to enforce water quality standards, and monitor and enforce discharge limits. Water quality markets have drawn inspiration from the success of the Acid Rain Program (ARP) es- tablished in the United States in the 1990s. The popularity of emissions trading for dealing with water pollution in the United States is largely a result of the Clean Water Act of 1972, which made it difficult for governments to handle pollution from farms. Water quality markets have been established in the United States, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand. There is also interest in China and Europe, although no programs are currently in place. To date, most water quality trading markets have been used to control pollution from nutrients that cause excessive algal growth and low dissolved oxygen levels in water bodies, a process referred to as “eutrophication”. Other water quality trading programs have been set up to control salinity, heavy metal, sediment, and temperature or thermal pollution. The largest WQT market in the United States in terms of transactions, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit Exchange Program, was created in 2002 to reduce nitrogen pollution that came into Long Island Sound from the Connecticut River. Under the program, which covers 79 sewage treatment plants in the state of Connecticut, a plant can control pollution in excess of its permit requirement and sell excess nitrogen allowances to those plants that exceed their allowances. A 2012 review of the program found that in ten years, the program had helped reduce nitrogen pollution by over 50 percent while controlling costs. One of the best examples of a successful water quality trading market is on Australia’s Hunter River, where coal mines and other pollution sources are subject to discharge limits to protect water quality
  • 18. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxvi and drinking water sources in downstream cities. Under this system, limited discharge is allowed, but permitted dischargers must coordinate their activities so that the total salt concentration in the river never goes above a specified limit. Industries can buy and sell salt credits in real time via a trading website run by the state government. Several years after it began, the trading program remains popular among participants and functions smoothly. Perhaps the biggest marker of the program’s success is that, even though new and potentially high-polluting mines have been established, river water quality has met standards nearly 100 percent of the time. Despite the fact that water quality trading markets have existed for three decades in some areas, it is difficult to determine whether the approach can be considered an overall success. Many of the domestic WQT markets in the United States have not lived up to expectations, seeing few trades or no trades at all. This can be explained by a number of factors: high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty about the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate. However, paradoxically, despite a lack of trading, the process of creating the market may have contributed to better watershed management. Bringing stakeholders together around a common goal of improving water quality has helped lower resistance to new, more stringent water quality regulations. In other cases, discussion of the use of “market fundamentals” helped convince some political conser- vatives to implement a form of environmental regulation, paving the way for improved water quality. A common argument in favor of environmental markets is that they will be smaller, simpler, and lower cost, because they aim to replace regulation with a free market. However, water quality markets require a strong and capable regulatory ability to set a cap on pollutants, to monitor pollution, and to verify the le- gitimacy of water quality credits that are created. Ironically, this often results in the creation of additional layers of government to perform these functions. WQT markets are valuable where large price asymmetries exist in water pollution control, and where certain polluters are beyond the reach of a regulatory agency. This is the case in the United States, where states are responsible for preserving water quality but have little authority over agriculture and some other nonpoint sources. On one hand, this has decreased the burden on municipal and industrial sources of pollution, allowing them to save on the cost of installing expensive treatment technologies. On the other hand, it has compelled them to fund projects on farms, often hundreds of miles away. We conclude that water quality trading is not a panacea for solving water pollution problems. However, it can be part of an effective regulatory approach under certain conditions. Conclusions In this report, we analyze the potential for incentive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water resources. To date, the primary environmental policy tools to address water challenges have been com- mand-and-control regulations. However, over the past several decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include a host of incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products.
  • 19. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xvii While regulations and incentive-based instruments are frequently juxtaposed, they also frequently operate alongside one another. With water quality trading, for example, governments mandate caps on the allowable pollutant levels and issue tradable permits that allow industry groups to allocate polluting activities among themselves, governed by market forces. Similarly, with water trading, governments may allocate water and then institute a framework within which water trading can occur. While incentive- based instruments may work in tandem, they must be integrated within a broader watershed manage- ment effort. Decisions about whether and how to apply a particular instrument depend on the specific objectives, circumstances, conditions, and needs of a given area. These decisions should be based on an open and transparent process, with meaningful participation from all affected parties. This approach will help in crafting a solution that is appropriate for local conditions, and ensure that it is fair and equitable. It will also help to reduce opposition and promote acceptance from those who will be implementing and affected by the program. It is important to recognize that those with the least power may not have the resources to participate, or they may be skeptical of the groups involved. In these cases, there is a need for consistent and rigorous outreach and, potentially, for engaging a trusted intermediary. Finally, monitoring and evaluation are essential to the success of any instrument. In particular, moni- toring and evaluation help ensure outcomes are achieved and allow for adjustments in response to changing social, economic, or environmental conditions. Monitoring should evaluate the “additionality” of the program, i.e. whether the program has an effect when compared with some baseline. It should also examine any potential impacts on surrounding areas (i.e. leakage) and the permanence of the interven- tion. However, extensive monitoring requirements would increase transaction costs, potentially threat- ening the viability of the program. Thus, the need for monitoring and evaluation must be balanced with practical considerations of the ability to maintain the viability of the program.
  • 21. 1 Introduction INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 1 Water is one of our most precious and valuable resources and is fundamental for maintaining human health, agricultural production, and economic activ- ity as well as critical ecosystem functions. Even as the planet’s endowment of water is expected to remain constant, human appropriation of fresh water, already at 50 percent by some measures (Postel et al., 1996), is expected to increase further (Leflaive et al., 2012). We can already see clear signs of the overexploitation of available freshwater resources. For example, some iconic rivers, including the Colorado River in the United States and the Yellow River in China, no longer reach the sea. Groundwater withdrawals have tripled over the past 50 years (UN, 2012), and in some areas, ground- water extraction exceeds natural recharge, causing widespread depletion and declining groundwater levels (Wada et al., 2010; Famiglietti, 2014). Pressures on water resources are likely to worsen in response to contin- ued economic and population growth, climate change, and other challenges. Water pollution exacerbates the challenges posed by water scarcity as the world’s water quality is increasingly becoming degraded. Growing pressures on the availability and quality of water resources have major impacts on our social, eco- nomic, and environmental well-being. The failure to provide safe drinking water and adequate sanitation services to all people is perhaps the greatest develop- ment failure of the twentieth century. Improving access to water and sanitation has been a key focus of the global development agenda since 2000. Water and sanitation were goals of the 2000–2015 Millennium Development Goals, and now, the Sustainable Devel- opment Goals launched in September 2015, also call for insuring access to water and sanitation for all. Yet, despite nearly two decades of international atten- tion and tens of billions of dollars invested, more than 660 million people still lack access to improved drink- ing water, predominantly in sub-Saharan Africa and Oceania, and some 2.4 billion people lack access to basic sanitation (WHO and UNICEF, 2015).4,5 In even the wealthiest countries, access to water and sanitation 4 Improved water sources include household connections, public stand- pipes, boreholes, protected dug wells, protected springs, and rainwater collections. Unimproved water sources are unprotected wells, unprotect- ed springs, vendor-provided water, bottled water (unless water for other uses is available from an improved source), and tanker truck-provided water. 5 Improved sanitation includes connection to public sewers, connection to septic systems, pour-flush latrines, simple pit latrines, and ventilated im- proved pit latrines. Service or bucket latrines (where excreta is manually removed), public latrines and open latrines are not considered improved sanitation. “…more than 660 million people still lack access to an improved drinking water source…”
  • 22. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT2 (2002, 2003), is based on integrating several key prin- ciples, including improving the overall productivity of water use, matching water quality to users’ needs, pri- oritizing basic human and ecosystem water needs, and seeking meaningful local and community engagement in water management. A key element of the soft path for water is shifting from a near exclusive supply-side orientation to one that seeks to manage water demand. Numerous studies have found significant opportunities to reduce water demand in all sectors using a variety of conservation and efficiency measures (e.g. Gleick et al., 2003; Cohen et al., 2013; Heberger et al., 2014). These measures can be applied in countries at varying levels of eco- nomic development, although the types of measures employed and implementation strategies may differ (Sharma and Vairavamoorthy, 2009). Brooks (2006) argued that demand management is more than a set of techniques; rather, it is a governance approach linked to equity, environmental protection, and public engagement goals. Additional information on demand management can be found in Annex 1. New policy tools are also needed. In most places, regu- lations have been the primary tool employed to improve environmental outcomes. However, over the past sev- eral decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include “incentive-based” instruments. Incentive-based instruments use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to reallocate water or reduce the health and environmen- tal risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products. These instruments have emerged for several reasons, but mainly because they are believed to be more cost effective than regulations, as they provide greater flex- ibility for the individual or firm to meet the environmen- tal objective in the least costly manner. Incentive-based is not universal. A 2011 UN report (de Albuquerque, 2011) highlighted several areas of the United States, including California, where marginalized populations (e.g. those living in poverty, communities of color, and indigenous groups) lacked the basic rights to water and sanitation. Moreover, access to an improved water source does not necessarily mean that the water is affordable or safe to drink. For example, naturally occur- ring arsenic pollution in groundwater affects nearly 140 million people in 70 countries (United Nations, 2009). Freshwater ecosystems are among the most exten- sively altered systems on earth. Rivers, streams, and lakes have been subjected to chemical, physical, and biological alteration as a result of large-scale water diversions, introduction of invasive species, overhar- vesting, pollution, and climate change (Carpenter et al., 2011). As a result, an estimated 20 to 35 per- cent of freshwater fish are vulnerable or endangered (Cosgrove and Rijsberman, 2000). Likewise, about half of the world’s wetlands have been lost since 1900, and much of the remaining wetlands are degraded (Zedler and Kercher, 2005). Freshwater ecosystem conditions are likely to continue to decline unless action is taken to address acute threats and better manage freshwa- ter resources. Traditional approaches to managing water supply and demand are not going to be effective in addressing these challenges. Throughout much of the twentieth century, the emphasis was on developing massive dams and pumping ever increasing amounts of groundwa- ter to satisfy rising water demands. This approach, as noted by Sharma and Vairavamoorthy (2009), “has led to over-use of the resources, over-capitalisation, pollu- tion and other problems of varying severity.” The soft path for water has emerged as a promising alternative. The term “soft energy path”, coined by Amory Lovins (1977) of the Rocky Mountain Institute, described an alternative path for energy development that empha- sized energy efficiency and promoted smaller, decen- tralized energy systems fueled by renewable sources. The soft path for water, as described by Peter H. Gleick “…the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include “incentive-based” instruments…”
  • 23. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 3 in managing both the quantity and quality of fresh- water. We have divided this review into five sections. This Section 1 introduces the synthesis review. Section 2 describes the research methodology. Section 3 pro- vides background on policy instruments and detail on three incentive-based instruments that have been used in the United States and abroad – water trading, pay- ment for ecosystem services, and water quality trad- ing. For each instrument, we describe its application, its environmental, economic, and social performance, and the conditions needed for its implementation. Section 4 highlights the role of the private sector in implement- ing these instruments, and Section 5 provides a sum- mary and conclusions. instruments are also thought to lower administrative costs and promote innovation by rewarding those who exceed their targets (Harrington and Morgenstern, 2004). Furthermore, Koplow (2004) suggests that these instruments can support self-enforcement by creating “groups of firms and individuals with vested interests in the proper use of resources and in emitting only as much pollution as allowed.” This report provides a synthesis review of a set of incentive-based instruments that have been employed in varying degrees around the world to reduce pressure on water resources. It is part of an effort to understand the full potential, and limitations, of these instruments
  • 25. 2 Research methodology INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 5 The freshwater synthesis review is based on a five-step approach to making better use of existing evaluative knowledge. This approach, modeled by The Rockefeller Foundation to help inform its investment and program- matic decisions, has already been used in a review of success factors in small-scale coastal fisheries man- agement in developing countries (The Rockefeller Foundation, 2013). Throughout the project, the proj- ect team held bi-weekly calls with The Rockefeller Foundation to review progress on the project, discuss key findings, and dive into specific case studies that could further support learning. The following steps were taken. 1. Refine project scope. The first step was to work with the Foundation Center and The Rockefeller Foundation to refine the scope of work and develop research questions. 2. Undertake literature search and review. The second step was to review the peer-reviewed lit- erature and law reviews on the key topics for the research. We supplemented this formal literature search with a review of the gray literature, including government and other institutional reports, from or- ganizations working to evaluate or implement these instruments. To identify the relevant literature, we used Web of Science (formerly Web of Knowledge) Internet-based search engines, and institutional website search engines. The literature on these in- centive-based instruments is extensive. For example, a Google Scholar search of “water trading” returned nearly 1 million results. Given the need to review a large amount of information in a relatively short time, we prioritized articles published since 2000. We further refined our study by limiting our scope to articles and reports on the state of practice, rather than the state of theory. In total, we reviewed approximately 500 articles and reports. 3. Conduct expert interviews. The third step was to obtain the knowledge of experts working to address the study’s key questions. It was designed to fill in any gaps in the literature. We developed the interview list based on the academic and grey literature search and from the research team’s experience in the sector. 4. Compile initial analysis and synthesis. The fourth step included an initial analysis and synthesis of the knowledge gained from the first three steps, which was compiled into a detailed presentation and supporting materials, and formally presented to the Foundation Center and The Rockefeller Foundation Team in an interactive discussion in March 2015. The Rockefeller Foundation also reviewed the draft report in July 2015, providing additional input on the synthesis. 5. Conduct further analysis and develop final knowledge product. The fifth step was to conduct further analysis of the published and expert knowledge based on the discussions with the Foundation Center, The Rockefeller Foundation, and other parties. We worked closely with the Foundation Center to develop the final knowledge products, including this summary report and online components, such as a visualization of key findings and a public collection of cited research. All of the knowledge products are openly licensed and free to be used and repurposed.
  • 27. 3 Environmental policy instruments INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 7 The objective of environmental policy is “to modify, slow, or stop resource extraction; to reduce or elimi- nate emissions of concern; and to shift consumption and production patterns towards greater sustainability” (Koplow, 2004). In most places, regulations have tradi- tionally been the primary environmental policy instru- ment employed to achieve environmental outcomes. This approach, often referred to as command-and- control (CAC), relies on some governmental or similar body to establish a standard or target (the “command”) that must then be complied with to avoid negative sanctions, such as fines or prosecution (the “control”). Over the past several decades, the environmental pol- icy “toolkit” has expanded to include incentive-based instruments, also referred to as economic instruments or market-based instruments. While definitions vary, we use the term “incentive-based instruments” to refer to a set of tools that use financial means, directly or indi- rectly,tomotivateresponsiblepartiestoreallocatewater or reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products. While CAC and incentive-based instruments are often juxtaposed with one another, a United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) report (Koplow, 2004) noted that “in reality the two often operate alongside each other. Governments may, for example, mandate caps on allowable pollu- tion for a region or country and use market-oriented approaches such as tradable permits to allocate the allowable emissions in an efficient manner.” Figure 1 provides a depiction of the range of environ- mental policy instruments currently applied around the world. These include the following. • Regulations and sanctions – mechanisms that rely on guidelines, permits, or licenses, and often include a legal or financial penalty for non-compli- ance. Examples include pollution standards, water use quotes, and building standards. • Price-based instruments – mechanisms that impose i) higher costs through fees, charges, or taxes on pollution or the use of a natural resource, making them more expensive and discouraging their production or consumption, or ii) lower costs through the use of subsidies for environmentally friendly activities or products. Examples include abstraction fees, pollution charges, grants, low-in- terest loans, and favorable tax treatment. • Market creation – mechanisms that include i) tradable permits whereby user or polluter rights are assigned according to desirable use levels or his- torical practices, and compliance can be achieved by trade, or ii) deposit refund systems that create a market to buy back inefficient or polluting prod- ucts. Examples include water trading and water quality trading. • Information provision – mechanisms that use the provision and disclosure of information on envi- ronmental performance to incentivize producers to reduce their water use or emissions of pollutants,
  • 28. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT8 As shown in Figure 1, these instruments exist along a continuum, from “very strict command approaches to decentralized approaches that rely more on market or legal mechanisms” (Huber et al., 1998). As noted, there are varying definitions of incentive-based instruments and the types of tools that would qualify. All definitions identify price-based instruments and market creation as incentive-based instruments. Some, however, use a broader definition that includes information provision, voluntary action, and liability instruments (see, e.g. Stavins, 2001; UNEP, 2001; Anderson, 2004). Product labeling schemes, such as the United States’ “Energy Star” or Thailand’s “Green Label”, allow companies meeting environmental standards to place a recog- nized label on their product, boosting sales by making the product more appealing to consumers and provid- ing a financial incentive to improve environmental per- formance (Stavins, 2001). These products may also be sold at a higher price than less environmentally-friendly or to incentivize consumers to select products with superior performance. Examples include corporate reporting, product labeling (e.g. WaterSense),6 and environmental certification schemes. • Voluntary action – mechanisms that use volun- tary agreements between the government and pri- vate firms and/or commitments made independent of government requirement. Examples include the UN CEO Water Mandate and the Alliance for Wa- ter Stewardship’s International Water Stewardship Standard. • Legal instruments – mechanisms for compen- sating victims when pollution causes human or environmental harm, and encouraging compliance with existing environmental regulations. Examples include criminal penalties, civil liability statutes, and performance bonds. 6 WaterSense is an environmental program designed to encourage water efficiency in the US, through use of a special label on consumer products. FIGURE 1. Incentive-based policy instruments WATER MANAGEMENT EXAMPLES: Regulations and sanctions Price based Market creation Information provision Voluntary action Legal Pollution standards Cost recovery tariffs Water quality trading Eco-labels UN CEO Water Mandate Criminal penalties Water use quotas Pollution taxes Water trading Corporate reporting AWS Interna- tional Water Stewardship Standard Performance bonds Building codes Payment for watershed services Environmental certification Civil liability statutes Source: adapted from Huber et al., 1998; UNEP, 2009. REGULATIONS AND SANCTIONS PRICE BASED MARKET CREATION INFORMATION PROVISION VOLUNTARY ACTION LEGAL Less flexibility Maximum government involvement Control oriented More flexibility Increased private initiative Litigation oriented
  • 29. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 9 of this activity ($11.6 billion, or 94 percent) was associ- ated with payment for watershed services, and 98 per- cent of that activity was in China. Collective action funds – which pool contributions from multiple inves- tors to support coordinated interventions within a watershed – had the second highest transaction value at $563 million. We note, however, that the distinction between payment for watershed and collective action programs is sometimes unclear.9 The market activity of instream buybacks – programs that purchase or lease water to augment instream flows – was considerably less ($97 million), followed by water quality trading ($22 million), and voluntary compensation ($320,000). It is of note that instream buybacks likely represent a modest fraction of the market activity of water trading programs, although comprehensive data on the latter are not readily available.10 While the data suggest a rapid expansion in the application of these instruments since 2008, Ecosystem Marketplace’s Genevieve Bennett (personal communication, 2015) noted that much of the increase is actually an outcome of better reporting. 9 Water funds are sometimes categorized as payment for watershed services and other times as collective action funds. 10 California, for example, has an active trading market but no centralized repository of data on the number and value of transactions. models. Likewise, voluntary programs may reward meeting environmental outcomes with, e.g. public rec- ognition which, in turn, increases sales. The application and market activity of these instruments are not well understood. Several organizations track the application of some of these incentive-based instru- ments (IIED, 2015 and Forest Trends, 2015a).7 However, there is no comprehensive list of the programs that have been implemented globally. Additionally, programs are sometimes poorly defined, fall into multiple categories, or change over time. Moreover, data on the activity of these instruments, including the number and value of transac- tions, are not collected or made available publicly. Despite these challenges, Forest Trends has been track- ing the activity of five market and market-like instru- ments for watershed investments for several years.8 It estimates that the market activity of watershed invest- ments was $12.3 billion in 2013 (Table 1). The majority 7 See, for example, Watershed Markets (watershedmarkets.org), main- tained by the London-based International Institute for Environment and Development, and Watershed Connect (watershedconnect.com), an on- line platform maintained by the Washington, D.C.-based Forest Trends. 8 Forest Trends is an international “non-profit organization with three principal roles: convening market players to advance market transfor- mations, generating and disseminating critical information to market players, and facilitating deals between different critical links in the value chains of new forestry.” See forest-trends.org. TABLE 1. Transactions (in millions of US$) by type, 2008–2013 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Payment for watershed services/undefined $ 7,950 $ 6,950 $ 7,470 $ 8,000 $ 9,600 $11,600 Collective action funds n/a n/a n/a n/a $ 137 $ 563 Voluntary compensation n/a n/a n/a n/a $ 0.230 $ 0.320 Water quality trading $ 10.7 $ 8.30 $ 8.30 $ 7.70 $ 14.9 $ 22.2 Instream buybacks n/a $ 19 $ 390 $ 164 $ 144 $ 97.0 Total $ 7,960 $ 6,980 $ 7,870 $ 8,170 $ 9,890 $ 12,300 Note: Numbers shown are nominal values. All values rounded to three significant figures. Numbers may not add up due to rounding. Based on data provided by Bennett (personal communication, 2015) and included in Bennett and Carroll (2014).
  • 30. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT10 side of a recognized legal or administrative frame- work (e.g. the sale of groundwater to an adjacent irrigator) • water banks – the institutions or agencies that i) broker or otherwise facilitate water trading (Culp et al.,2014)orii)areestablishedforaspecificobjective, such as a trust created to obtain water rights for in- stream augmentation (Clifford, 2012). Water banks offer expertise and information for improving com- munication between buyers and sellers, and often provide a centralized repository or clearinghouse of information on current and historical transactions, including volumes, pricing, and locations. There is an extensive body of literature suggest- ing that water trading provides a mechanism to improve the economic efficiency of water through its reallocation from lower to higher value uses (Glennon, 2005; Dellapenna, 2000; Bjornlund and McKay, 2002). The germinal study entitled Water and Choice in the Colorado Basin (NRC, 1968) recommended that water in the western United States be transferred from irriga- tion, which generates relatively low returns per unit of water, to high-value non-agricultural uses. More recent researchhascontinuedtoemphasizethepotentialvalue created by water transfers. For example, models used to project California’s economic costs under a dry climate change projection, (Medellín-Azuara et al., 2008) found significantly increased benefits with market-based real- locations. Newlin et al. (2002) and Jenkins et al. (2004) asserted that water trading could dramatically reduce Southern California’s water scarcity costs. Water trading is attractive because it tends to minimize the impact on existing rights holders by providing com- pensation and, in many cases, additional security, for existing water rights, while providing opportunities to those with new or increasing demands (NRC, 1992). A large number of experts challenge the applicability and efficacy of water trading. Freyfogle (1996) asserted that externalities, intrinsic to the very nature of water itself, pose such an insurmountable obstacle that water trading does not and cannot work. Many of these In this review, we evaluate three of the major incentive- based instruments that have been employed to improve water management: water trading, payment for ecosys- tem services, and water quality trading. These instru- ments are employed in developed and developing countries, and there is growing interest in expanding their application. 3.1 Water trading Description Water trading is perhaps the best known and most widely used method of reallocating water. In some cases, purchasing or leasing water from existing users has proven to be less expensive, more flexible, and less time-consuming than developing new water sup- plies, such as constructing new diversion structures or desalination plants. Similarly, water trading is gen- erally a more accepted method for reallocating water than state appropriation or condemnation of existing water rights. Successful examples of water trading in Australia and other locations – combined with classic economic theory suggesting that market mechanisms can optimize resource allocation – have heightened interest in this instrument in both academic literature and popular media. As noted in Box 1, the peer-reviewed and gray litera- ture employ several terms (e.g. water transfers, water markets, and water banks) to refer to a variety of some- times overlapping instruments and methods for con- veying and reallocating water. In this paper, we use the following terms: • water trading – the temporary or permanent transfer of the right to use water in exchange for some form of compensation • informal water trading – the sale of a specified volume of water for a limited period of time, which does not involve actual contracts or occurs out- “…water trading provides a mechanism to improve the economic efficiency of water…”
  • 31. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 11 tradeable commodity. Similarly, Zellmer and Harder (2007) asserted, “Water is a uniquely essential resource with uniquely public attributes,” unlike other resources typically treated as property. Questions of externali- ties, commodification, and the special nature of water itself highlight the challenges faced by implementing or expanding water trading. In some cases, water trading is effectively zero-sum, simply shifting water use and economic productivity from one area or sector to another. In other cases, it can externalities arise from the physical properties of water: it is heavy, unwieldy, and easily contaminated; it some- timeshasdramaticseasonalandyear-to-yearvariability; and it can be easily lost through evaporation, seepage, or runoff (Salzman, 2006). Further, these externalities may be borne by disparate parties, such as the envi- ronment or future generations, challenging efforts to compensate those injured by trading (Freyfogle, 1996). Moreover, Salzman (2006) argued that custom, history, and religion in many parts of the world treat drinking water as a common property resource, rather than a BOX 1 A note on terminology Water transfers. The National Research Council (NRC) of the United States National Academies defines water transfers as changes in the point of diversion, type of use, or location of water use (NRC et al., 1992). The term “water transfers” encompasses a broad range of market-based and non-market water reallocation mechanisms of varying periods, geographic scales, and arrangements. Water transfers can range from short-term leases or conditional arrangements to the permanent transfer (i.e. sale) of a water right. They can range in scale from i) change in type of use on an existing parcel of land, such as when a water right shifts from irrigation to municipal use when agricultural land is purchased and converted to housing, to ii) inter-basin transfers, such as when a city purchases or leases water from a different watershed. Water bank. A water bank is a mechanism for changing the time or location of water use. Water banking, as with water transfers, can refer to market- based or non-market activities. The term “water bank” can refer to an actual institution or to the physical storage of water. Water banks as institutions may function as i) brokers that connect buyers and sellers of water rights or leases, providing an important communication function; ii) clearinghouses that directly purchase or lease water from willing sellers and aggregate supplies for subsequent sale to other buyers; iii) facilitators that expedite water transfers using existing storage or conveyance facilities (Culp et al., 2014); or iv) trusts that hold or otherwise manage water rights or entitlements for a specific purpose, such as streamflow augmentation (O’Donnell and Colby, 2010). When serving as facilitators, water banks may perform various administrative and technical functions, including the confirmation of water rights and screening of potential buyers (Clifford, 2012). Water banks may also refer to physical storage, either in surface reservoirs or in aquifers, which, in turn, may be a component of a larger water transfer or simply a mechanism enabling an entitlement holder to store water for its own future use, but we do not use this definition in this review. Water market. The term water market refers to a range of different market-based practices, typically referring to water trading. According to Brown (2006), the term water market lacks a precise definition, “but once a few voluntary trades of water of relatively common physical and legal characteristics occur, it is said that a water market exists.” A water market may also refer to informal transactions involving the direct sale of water that does not involve the lease or sale of water rights. Informal water transactions can include purchasing bottled water or water from a tanker truck, a common practice in many parts of the developing world that lack a reliable, piped water supply. While a “water contract” can refer to a one-time voluntary water exchange between two actors, a water market is where many actors come together and make trades; a market also includes some formalization of the transactions (Brown et al., 2015).
  • 32. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT12 Application Water trading exists, to varying degrees, in countries around the world. When Grafton et al. (2010) assessed water trading in two wealthy countries (Australia and theUnitedStates),twolow-tomiddle-incomecountries (Chile and South Africa), and one poor, rapidly develop- ing country (China), they found that differing levels of information availability, legal rights structures, institu- tional constraints, and management goals had resulted in very different levels of activity and performance. ThemostactivewatertradingmarketsoccurinAustralia and the western United States. Within Australia, water trading includes both short-term trades (referred to as allocation trading) and long-term trades (referred to as entitlement trading). The total value of water trading in Australia in fiscal year 2012–13 exceeded $1.4 billion increase system-wide water efficiency, by providing the area of origin with funds for investing in improved effi- ciency, maintaining local productivity with lower water use, and then transferring the conserved water. Water can be made available for trading from a variety of activities, including fallowing fields, crop shifting, and in some cases, a shift from surface water diversions to groundwater pumping. Water trades can also be linked to water conservation and efficiency efforts, including increasing irrigation efficiency and decreasing system losses that generate surplus water by, e.g. lining canals or constructing operating reservoirs. However, increas- ing demand for greater efficiencies in irrigation can challengetheflexibilityofexistinginstitutions(Hundley, 2001), such as irrigation districts and water courts, which often do not recognize a legal property right to this “new” water created by conservation or efficiency. Additionally, existing institutions often impose signifi- cantcostsonthoseattemptingtodedicatewatertonon- traditional uses such as instream flows (Getches, 1985). These changes have tested the resilience of water insti- tutions, which have shown some flexibility in adapting to new values and goals but often impose high transac- tion costs (Colby et al., 1991). Water trading can occur within sectors, from agricul- ture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban, across these sectors, and, less frequently, from either of these to the environment (Brewer et al., 2007). Figure 2, from the California Department of Water Resources, shows the relative proportions of water trading within and between differentsectors.Althoughwatertradingisoftenconsid- ered a means to move water from agriculture to urban uses, nearly three-quarters of the 270,000 acre-feet of water traded in California in 2013 occurred between agricultural users. Interestingly, nearly 25,000 acre- feet of water were traded from municipal and industrial (M&I) uses to agriculture, which was nearly half of the volume of water traded from agriculture to M&I uses. FIGURE 2. Non-project water transfers within the Sacramento-San Joaquin watersheds in 2013 Note: Ag – agriculture; FW – fish and wildlife; M&I – municipal and industrial; AF – acre-foot. Source: California Department of Water Resources. Ag to Ag Ag to M&I Ag to FW M&I to Ag9% (24,577 AF) TOTAL: 268,370 AF 1% (1,500 AF) 18% (49,639 AF) 72% (192,655 AF) “The most active water trading markets occur in Australia and the western United States.”
  • 33. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 13 reports almost 640,000 acre-feet of water traded in California, through 36 trades with a total value of about $234 million (all values adjusted to 2014$). More than 80 percent of the water was leased rather than sold. According to the database, 15 of these trades, account- ing for about 88,000 acre-feet of total volume, occurred within one agricultural district. However, the Bren School database only records the initial year a water trade is reported, and thus does not reflect the volume of multiyear trading agreements. That means that a review of 2009 trading activity does not reflect previ- ous multi-year trades that may still have been active in 2009, so the values reported above understate trading activity in 2009. A comprehensive review of water trading in California reports about 1.5 MAF of water were traded in 2009, a dry year (Hanak and Stryjewski, 2012). Volumes reported for 2011, a wet year and the most recent year for which data are available, were about 5 percent lower, at 1.4 MAF. In 2011, 42 percent of the water traded went to municipal and industrial users, 37 percent to agricul- tural users, 17 percent for environmental purposes, and the remainder to mixed uses. Because of limited data, the study does not include trading activity within irri- gation districts or similar users associations, although some estimates suggest that such intra-district activity accounted for several hundred thousand acre-feet of water, a third of total water supplies within some of the larger irrigation districts. Hanak and Stryjewski (2012) did not provide total dollar values associated with the California water market, though they noted that prices of temporary water transfers had increased from an average of $30–$40 per acre-foot in one region in the mid-1990s to $180 per acre-foot in 2011, while aver- age prices in another basin rose to an average of $400 per acre-foot. The authors noted the shifting trend from short-term to longer-term leases and permanent trades, pumping restrictions in the Bay-Delta, and ris- ing transaction costs that had slowed market activity in the past decade. California is also home to the largest United States water trade to date. The San Diego County Water Authority (SDCWA) entered into a 45-year contract (NWC, 2013). Trading within the Murray-Darling Basin, which has an active and well-documented water mar- ket first established more than 30 years ago (Grafton et al., 2012), accounts for 98 percent of all allocation trades and 78 percent of all entitlement trades within Australia, by volume. Indeed, the Murray-Darling Basin figures prominently in discussions about water trad- ing, as an example of a thriving incentive-based sys- tem that successfully transitioned from a non-market system (Grafton et al., 2012). In fiscal year 2012–13, the total volume of short-term (allocation) trading within the Murray-Darling Basin increased 44  percent from the previous year, from almost 3.5  million acre-feet (MAF) to 5 MAF, or about 50 percent of total surface water use in the basin. The total volume of long-term trades, however, decreased by about 14 percent over that period, to about 0.85 MAF. A national study found that these permanent entitlement trades often offset the temporary allocation trades, as irrigators planting perennial crops, such as grapes or almonds, purchased entitlements to meet expected future demand, but then sold a portion of the temporary allocations associated with these entitlements to generate revenue (Frontier Economics and Australia National Water Commission, 2007). For more information on Australia’s water mar- ket, see Annex 2. In the western United States, the scale of water trad- ing is considerably lower. A database compiled by the University of California Santa Barbara (UCSB) Bren School shows notifications for more than 4,000 water trades in 12 states in the western United States from the years 1987–2008.11 Brewer et al. (2007) docu- mented the large variability in the volume, price, and duration of water trades in the western United States, both within and between sectors. In 2009, the most recent year for which data are available, the database 11 The database summary notes that “The data are drawn from water trans- actions reported in the monthly trade journal the Water Strategist and its predecessor the Water Intelligence Monthly from 1987 through February 2010.” These data reflect published reports that in some cases do not reflect final transfer agreements. For example, the database reports that the Imperial Irrigation District-San Diego County Water Authority water transfer began in 1997, although the final transfer agreement was not actually signed and the transfer did not begin (at different volumes than the database reports) until October 2003. The Bren School water transfer database is available at bren.ucsb.edu/news/water_transfers.htm.
  • 34. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT14 in several parts of the country (Thobani, 1997), with nearly 3,700 registered water transfer requests in 2006 alone (CONAGUA, 2012). Water markets have also been established in parts of Europe, Asia, and Africa. In Spain, informal trades, sales, and short-term exchanges of water are common, while formal transfers of long-term water rights are generally limited to groundwater (Albiac et al., 2006). In Spain’s Alicante basin, several irrigation districts auction their annual water allocations to district farmers (Albiac et al., 2006), creating a strong incentive to improve water- use efficiency and shift toward higher value crops. England has encouraged water trading for more than a decade, although only about 60 trades have occurred to date (TWSTT, 2014). South Africa has more extensive water markets that continue to be plagued by conflict and inadequate institutional support (Grafton et al., 2010). South Africa’s Water Act of 1998 has provided a framework for water trading. Historically, agricultural irrigators traded water rights within their sector, mediated by the national Department of Water Affairs and Forestry (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). In 2001, mining companies seeking to expand operations in northern South Africa successfully negotiated a temporary trade of some 10,000 acre-feet of water (13 million m3 ) from neigh- boring farmers – representing more than 70 percent of their annual allocation – in exchange for the current equivalent of about $1 million. These funds, used to help rehabilitate the local irrigation infrastructure, rep- resented less than 0.1 percent of the mines’ develop- ment costs, reflecting a significant economic disparity between the two interests (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). In Asia, India and Pakistan have informal water trad- ing, in which well-owners may sell some of the water they extract to neighboring farms or residents (Easter et al., 1999). In a report published by the Nepal Water Conservation Foundation and the Institute for Social in 2003, with an option for a 30-year extension, with the Imperial Irrigation District (IID), one of the largest irrigation districts in the country.12 Under the terms of the agreement, the SDCWA pays the IID to reduce its diversion of Colorado River water, while the Authority diverts a like amount farther upstream. After a 15-year period intended to create time to address ecological and public health impacts resulting from the trade, the IID will shift to efficiency-based methods (such as lin- ing canals and constructing regulating reservoirs) to generate the water to be conserved. In essence, the Authority is paying the District to improve the effi- ciency of its operations and receiving the water con- served. The trade is ramping up to a maximum volume of 200,000 acre-feet per year by 2021, representing about 25 percent of the region’s total water supply. In 2014, the price for the water was $594 per acre-foot, plus an additional $445 per acre-foot to a different agency to convey the water through its facilities. This total, which does not include additional payments to offset the environmental impacts of the trade, is about half what the Authority has contracted to pay for water generated by a new desalination plant on the coast. In Central and South America, Chile and Mexico have active water trading markets. Chile’s Limarí Basin enjoys water rights trading and water transfers, enabled by three large state-built reservoirs and robust local water organizations. The actual number of water trades in Chile’s Limarí Basin has averaged about 33 each year (Romano and Leporati, 2002), although water trading has been more limited in the rest of the country (Bauer, 1997). Mexico’s National Water Law of 1992 established a formal water market with tradable concessions that formed the basis for active markets 12 With the exception of “water conservancy districts”, to the best of our knowledge there is no strict naming convention for water agencies. The ability to create conservancy districts is established by statute, enabling state district courts or other authorities to establish conservancy districts with the power to impose property taxes to support district functions (Howe, 2011). Water authorities tend to serve municipal areas, and irrigation districts primarily serve agricultural users. However, the San Diego County Water Authority has agricultural customers (fewer than before, as they have phased out subsidies for irrigation water), while the Imperial Irrigation District sells water to all of the cities within its service area, serving more than 170,000 people. Similarly, water conservancy districts usually serve agriculture, although some districts may also serve municipal customers. “Water banks are generally less widespread than water trading…”
  • 35. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 15 In 2003, nine states in the western United States had functioning state-operated water banks, although their level of activity varied dramatically and several are no longer active. From 1995–2003, for example, Texas’ water bank only reported one transaction (Clifford, 2012). California’s Drought Water Bank functioned for a limited period in the early 1990s, providing a mechanism to facil- itate and expedite water trading between agriculture and cities during a multi-year drought, while also ensuring minimum instream flows and providing limited ground- water recharge. The Drought Water Bank purchased, held, and sold water, primarily from northern agricultural users to southern municipal and industrial users, though about half of the more than 800,000 acre-feet pur- chased in 1991 was dedicated to instream flows (20 per- cent) and to recharge aquifers (32 percent) (Dinar et al., 1997). Idaho operates water banks to manage storage in reservoirs, and in Oregon, river conservancies oper- ate as water trusts to purchase or lease water rights to supplement instream flows (Clifford, 2012). The Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District maintains a web- page that functions as an online bulletin board connect- ing those seeking to acquire water with those who have water to rent, an example of a brokerage-type water bank. The very active water trading within the Conser- vancy District is attributable to the equal volume and priority of each share available for trade, the absence of any requirement to preserve return flows or protect downstream or junior priority users, and the fact that trading only requires the approval of the district itself, not a water court, as is the case for most other trades within Colorado (Howe and Goemans, 2003). The Colorado River basin, shown in Figure 3, boasts a large number of creative approaches to water bank- ing. In 1998, the federal government adopted a new rule permitting interstate banking agreements within the basin. To date, Arizona has diverted and stored more than 600,000 acre-feet of Colorado River water for southern Nevada, and a southern California water agency has diverted and stored more than 161,000 acre-feet for southern Nevada, representing creative methods of skirting state prohibitions of interstate water trading. In 2007, the seven basin states adopted a new set of rules for managing the river that, among and Environmental Transition, Moench et al. (2003) described an active but largely unregulated water trad- ing system in Chennai, India, where private companies meet as much as 35 percent of urban water demand by delivering raw or purified well water purchased from farmers in surrounding areas or extracted from the companies’ wells. This private sector engagement helps meet a demand for water that the intermittent municipal water supply cannot meet, though the price is much higher. Moench et al. (2003) reported that the price of water for urban customers can be 1,000 times higher than the price paid to the peri-urban farmers supplying the water. Also in Asia, in a rare international water trade, the Bishkek Treaty of 1998 commit- ted Kyrgyzstan to deliver water via the Syr Darya to Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan in exchange for compen- sation (Ambec et al., 2013). China reportedly has small, local water markets (Grafton et al., 2010). In Oman, the local falaj irrigation systems purchase short-term allocations of water based on units of time rather than volume (e.g. a certain duration of water delivery) in a village-based auction (Al-Marshudi, 2007). Water banks are generally less widespread than water trading because they require additional expertise, fund- ing, and governance structures. Water banks appear to be most prevalent in the western United States, although there are examples in several other coun- tries. The presence of three reservoirs in Chile’s Limarí Basin facilitates the large number of water trades in the region (Bauer, 1997), meaning that, in this case, the physical storage rather than an institutional bank facilitates the water trades. In Australia, brokerage-type water banks are active in both the Murray-Darling Basin and in northern Victoria, where the banks post informa- tion about pricing and availability (O’Donnell and Colby, 2010). Mexico’s National Water Commission reported that the 13 state-based water banks in the country bro- ker thousands of water trades annually (CONAGUA, 2012). In three basins in Spain, water banks operated by local water agencies, known as “exchange centers”, have successfully brokered water trades that have lessened groundwater overdraft (Garrido and Llamas, 2009).
  • 36. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT16 system as a whole, rather than claiming it for them- selves. In this instance, the Bureau of Reclamation acts as a water bank by obtaining water through a reverse auction process, augmenting system storage for the benefit of the system as a whole. Environmental, economic, and social performance The primary goal of water trading is usually to pro- mote economic efficiency by reallocating water from lower to higher value uses. However, in some cases, other key developments, permitted entitlement hold- ers in Arizona, California, and Nevada to invest in vari- ous water efficiency projects within their own states and store a percentage of the conserved water in Lake Mead for later use. To date, more than 1.1 million acre-feet have been stored in Lake Mead under this new program. More recently, four large municipal water agencies in the basin, in cooperation with the federal Bureau of Reclamation, agreed to invest $11 million in fallowing and efficiency improvements, and to dedi- cate the conserved water to the Colorado River Basin FIGURE 3. The Colorado River Basin Source: Cohen et al., 2013.
  • 37. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 17 can be an effective means of reallocating water, where the appropriate conditions exist. The application sec- tion of 3.1 of this report describes the range of countries where water trading occurs in general terms. In most of these regions, limited data precludes detailed assess- ment of the number or volume of water trading activi- ties. In several locations, such as the Murray-Darling Basin and the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, water trades occur frequently, often for small volumes, suggesting a robust and active market with low transaction costs (Howe and Goemans, 2003). In other areas, there tend to be fewer but larger transac- tions, suggesting higher barriers to trading. The largest agriculture-to-urban water trade in the United States has been successful for San Diego County, which currently receives about 25 percent of its water supply from the rural Imperial Valley,13 at a unit cost of water that is less than half the contracted price of water from a desalination plant that will soon be operational on the San Diego coastline. The long- term water trade appears to be cost effective from San Diego’s perspective but, due to significant externalities, maynotbefromthebroadersociety’sperspective.Total transaction costs for this water trade have exceeded $175 million in attorney fees, plus an additional $171 mil- lion in mitigation fees to offset public health and envi- ronmental impacts. In addition, the State of California agreed to cover all direct mitigation costs in excess of a pre-determined financial cap for the water trade parties. The magnitude of these additional mitigation costs – primarily for managing dust emissions – will not be known for many years but are expected to run into the hundreds of millions of dollars (Cohen, 2014). As suggested by the Imperial Valley-San Diego example, a narrow focus on direct economic performance may ignore trading’s broader economic impacts. Although there are thousands of peer-reviewed articles on the economic potential of water trading, robust economic analyses of specific water trades do 13 Roughly 15 percent of San Diego County’s current water supply comes from the water trade with the Imperial Valley, while an additional 10 per- cent comes from water conserved via the lining of the All-American Canal, a project funded primarily by the state of California. water trading has been used for environmental or rec- reational purposes, reflecting the increasing societal value ascribed to instream flows. In this section, we evaluate the environmental, social, and economic per- formance of water trading. While much of the literature on water trading tends toward theoretical assessments or recommendations about trading (Newlin et al., 2002) or specific elements of trading, such as property rights regimes or institutional capacity (Culp et al., 2014), we examine the literature on actual impacts to evaluate the state of practice. ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Although there are a large number of articles and stud- ies modeling the potential economic benefits of water trading, the number of detailed economic assessments of existing water trades is surprisingly limited. Some studies on local impacts suggest positive net economic performance,butthesestudiestypicallydonotdescribe changes in the distribution of impacts, and they rarely describe broader economic impacts. Assessing the economic performance of water trading is frequently as simple as documenting trading activity and quanti- fying the number, volume, and value of reported water trades. A more comprehensive analysis would require surveys to estimate the number and volume of addi- tional water trades that users would like to make, as a means to assess the disparity between availability and demand. An even more robust analysis would compare the ability of different instruments – such as water trad- ing, demand-side management, and supply augmenta- tion – to meet specific water demands, and the cost of those instruments. While water agencies seeking to improve their water supply reliability may perform such analyses within their service area, these assessments are often not publicly available. The large number of trades and the significant volumes traded,especiallyinAustralia,indicatethatwatertrading “…the number of detailed economic assessments of existing water trades is surprisingly limited.”
  • 38. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT18 the trading activity in the district is short term and low volume, especially in comparison with trading activ- ity in the same water basin but outside of the district. Municipal and industrial (M&I) users buy district water rights to meet expected future demand and then lease some of this water back to district irrigators. This ris- ing M&I demand has increased the price of imported water rights (known as allotments) within the district (Howe, 2011). Within the relatively prosperous district, this has improved economic performance. However, in other regions, particularly in economically depressed rural areas, selling water out of the area has exacer- bated economic decline, causing property values to fall and the local tax base to shrink (Howe, 2011). In Australia, water trading has enabled the expan- sion of the wine industry and other high value crops, such as almonds. Over time, the dairy industry in one part of the Murray-Darling Basin transitioned from a small purchaser of water entitlements to a net seller of entitlements, primarily to the expanding wine and nut producers in other parts of the basin. These expanding industries have also exhibited a shift from the former model of shared irrigation infrastructure (such as com- mon canals) to direct extraction from the river by indi- vidual irrigators – in other words, from a communal to a more flexible individual approach to irrigation (Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). Water trading within the Murray-Darling Basin grew and matured within the context of the devastating drought that afflicted the region from 2006 through 2010. The national water trading assessment noted the challenge of disentangling the economic impacts of the drought from those of water trading itself, gen- erally concluding that trading offered irrigators an additional revenue stream, plus additional flexibility and resilience within the face of a severely limited water supply. Without water trading, some sectors, such as the dairy industry, would have seen even greater losses. Trading also offered a mechanism to adjust for historic water apportionments, facilitating the voluntary sale of water from less productive to more productive lands and uses (Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). not appear to exist. For example, despite its size and importance, there do not appear to be any economic analyses of the Imperial Valley-San Diego County water trade that assess revenues, agricultural produc- tion lost due to fallowing, value of transfer payments, relative value of the water in San Diego, or employ- ment impacts. There are, however, general regional or district-level assessments of water trading, as well as an extensive body of literature on macro-economic trends, and expected or modeled benefits of water trading. Yet, assessments of “net” economic benefit at the state or regional level, expressed in terms of net increase in employment or revenue, can mask dispari- ties between areas of origin and importing areas, and even within the areas of origin themselves. In one study, the income and employment gains found in regions in California that imported water via trades exceeded the net losses (total compensation often failed to cover foregone crop revenue) in exporting areas (Howitt, 1998). In 1991, trading activity gener- ated an average net income loss in water-exporting areas equivalent to about 5 percent of net agricultural activity, though this varied within different parts of the state. However, agricultural areas importing water saw total gains greater than the losses in exporting areas: net agricultural water trading activity was positive, as water moved from lower-value crops to higher-value crops (Howitt, 1998). In another example, an agricul- tural community in California exporting water to urban areas saw a 26  percent decrease in the number of farms overall, but this masked a 70 percent loss in the number of small farms and the loss of almost half of the number of produce firms in the area (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). The Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, introduced in Section 3.1, has a very active water mar- ket in part because of low transaction costs. Much of “In Australia, water trading has enabled the expansion of the wine industry and other high value crops, such as almonds.”
  • 39. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 19 community support, especially relative to regulatory takings. However, water trading can also generate large environmental externalities, adversely affecting either natural habitats or downstream users, or both (NRC, 1992). For example, when water for trading is generated by efficiency or by fallowing land, the trade may reduce the amount of runoff supporting local habitat and may diminish instream flows.14 On the other hand, some water trades may improve local instream flows by de- creasing diversions and contaminant loadings. Where water is traded to downstream users using the existing stream as a conveyance, trading could offer measur- able environmental benefits. Where water is traded out of the basin or alters the timing and magnitude of flows, adverse impacts are likely to occur. Unfortunately, there do not appear to be published assessments of the rela- tive impacts of water trading on streamflow.15 In the fol- lowing, we discuss the environmental performance of several examples of water trading. Water trading is now used in some areas to return water to river channels, in order to support listed species or threatened habitats, and for general ecosystem restora- tion (Tarlock, 2014). However in most areas, such activ- ity still represents only a tiny fraction of total water use in any given area.16 For example, the Colorado Water Trust (CWT) brokered a lease agreement between two state 14 In efficiency-based agricultural water trades, the buyer typically pays the irrigator to install more efficient irrigation equipment or methods, such as hiring additional irrigation management staff, installing pump- back systems, lining canals, or constructing new regulatory reservoirs. The water conserved by these new practices would then be available for transfer to the buyer/investor. Efficiency-based trades keep agricultural land in production and can increase total employment in the area of origin, but they require additional monitoring and measurement to doc- ument or calculate the volume of water conserved. In fallowing-based trades, also known as “buy-and-dry”, the buyer simply pays the irrigator not to irrigate and, in exchange, receives the volume of water historically used by the parcel. This requires less effort and less time to implement, but takes land out of production and typically generates significant adverse impacts on rural communities. 15 For example, the various water trading agreements between Imperi- al Valley and urban Southern California will have the direct effect of reducing the volume of water flowing down the lower Colorado River between Parker Dam – the new diversion point – and Imperial Dam, about 150 river miles downstream, by more than 300,000 acre-feet per year, equivalent to roughly 5 percent of the historic average annual flow between these two diversion points. 16 Such instream flows typically require additional legal conditions, such as explicit recognition of instream flow rights, improved monitoring and measurement, and the acceptance of local entitlement holders. The active participation of the Australian government in water trading increased prices and participation but may also have increased total water use within the basin. A large survey (n=520) of those selling entitle- ments or allocations to the Australian environmental water program found that sellers believed they received a higher price from the government than they would have from other private agents, or that the government was the only purchaser in the market. The survey also found that sellers reportedly used 69 to 77 percent of their water allocations prior to trading it to the govern- ment (Wheeler and Cheesman, 2013). That is, survey respondents reported selling portions of their alloca- tions that they would not have used otherwise. Selling unused water allocations is not a reallocation so much as an expansion of total water use. Water trading occurs in a variety of forms. Howe (2011) noted that, in practice, many water trades reflect a change in type of use rather than a change in loca- tion. For example, in the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, developers have purchased farmland and its water rights and then converted the land and water to residential or commercial use, often generating a significant increase in revenue per unit of water while limiting some of the social and environ- mental externalities that would occur if the water were physically moved to a different location. ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE Water trading has been used as a mechanism to obtain water for ecological purposes, to augment streamflows, and to address water quality concerns (such as tem- perature) in threatened reaches. The environmental performance of water trading is highly variable, de- pending on the type of trade and site-specific condi- tions. The benefits of voluntary, incentive-based water acquisition include ease of transaction and greater “Water trading can also generate large environmental externalities, adversely affecting either natural habitats or downstream users, or both”
  • 40. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT20 trading activity between 1982 and 2011, but less than 0.5 percent of total water use in the state (Figure 4). In Australia, the federal government has invested more than $3 billion to date to purchase entitlements and allocations for environmental water, protecting eco- logical resources to enable and expedite water trading between non-governmental users. In 2008–2009, for example, the government purchased nearly 880,000 acre-feet of long-term water entitlements and 1.4 mil- lion acre-feet of short-term allocations, at a total cost of about $2 billion (adjusted to 2014$). The price for this water ranged from about $269 to $377 per acre-foot. Local interest in this environmental water buyback program, known as “Restoring the Balance”, has been strong, with the Australian government receiving nearly 7,600 applications to sell water from 2007 to early 2012. Water entitlement sales for the environment account agencies, increasing low-season flows in the White River by 3,000 acre-feet of water three times over a 10-year period to lower the temperature of river flows and, in turn, benefit fish (CWT, 2015). Similarly, the Columbia Basin Water Transactions Program, active for more than a decade, works with partner organizations in four west- ern states to acquire and dedicate water for instream flows within the basin. In 2013, 45 transactions led to the acquisition of more than 48,000 acre-feet of water, cost- ing about $13.9 million and benefiting some 276 miles of streams, the fish and wildlife, and the communities that depend on them (National Fish and Wildlife Foundation, 2014). Bonneville Power Administration, in cooperation with the Northwest Power and Conservation Council, provides some of the funding for the program due, in part, to concerns about endangered species. In California, environmental water purchases averaged 152,000 acre-feet, accounting for about 14 percent of FIGURE 4. Water purchases for the environment in California, 1982–2011 Source: Hanak and Stryjewski, 2012. 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 500 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 WaterPurchases(1,000acre-feet)
  • 41. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 21 resulting in the loss of open water and wetland habitats that support several hundred species of birds (Cohen and Hyun, 2006). Yet water trading occurs in regions of water scarcity, where water resources in particular have already under- gone dramatic transformation. Dams, canals, and diver- sions have already altered the timing and magnitude of stream flows throughout many of the regions now turning to water trading (Worster, 1985). Determining the additional impacts of water trading upon this exist- ing landscape would be difficult. An alternative basis for comparison could be the marginal or cumulative environmental impacts of water trading relative to the new impacts of additional water development. That is, water trading may prove to be less environmentally harmful than the construction of new dams and diver- sion projects, or even the construction of new desalina- tion plants. SOCIAL PERFORMANCE Water trading is usually characterized as a market- based mechanism that reduces economic inefficiencies by reallocating water from lower to higher value uses. Trading has been used to meet explicit environmen- tal objectives, but, as described previously, it is rarely employed to address equity challenges. Indeed, water trading can exacerbate social and economic inequali- ties, worsening gender and geographic differences. In regions with informal water rights and trading that are functional at the community level, such as rural Nepal, demands from outlying urban areas for larger scale trades can overwhelm local water management institutions. Trades from these rural areas might not reflect the true value of the many informal uses water has in the community (such as subsistence fishing or milling) or the full range of informal ownership and use for roughly 25  percent of total entitlement trading activity (Wheeler and Cheesman, 2013). However, some irrigators and state governments in Australia oppose the instream buyback program, and it was cut dramatically when the Labor Party fell from power in September 2013 (Bennett and Carroll, 2014). However, water trades not explicitly intended for envi- ronmental purposes can create a host of adverse envi- ronmental impacts. They can, for example, change the timing, quantity, and quality of return flows, adversely affecting riparian and wetland habitats and the species that depend upon them. Some trades, such as from California’s Owens Valley to Los Angeles, adversely affect public health by increasing the amount of dust emissions from exposed lakebed and fallowed land, generating significant externalities (LA DWP, 2013). Groundwater substitution, in which a user trades sur- face water and increases groundwater extraction, can lead to over-extraction, and sinking or caving in of land surfaces (subsidence), depleting springs and seeps, and robbing future generations (Brown et al., 2015). Water trading can also diminish groundwater recharge rates, whether the water is generated via fallowing or increased efficiency. In the southern Indian state of Tamil Nadu, farmers irrigating with groundwater have increased extraction rates and sold the excess to water tanker trucks serving urban populations, an example of informal water trading. Yet this increased groundwater extraction lowered the water table, increasing pump- ing costs for other irrigators or drying up their wells entirely (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Efforts to mitigate the environmental impacts of water trading have had mixed success. In Spain, a proposal to add a small environmental mitigation fee to each unit of water traded was insufficient to overcome the strong opposition of environmental and social organizations (Albiac et al., 2006). In California, state commitments to mitigate the environmental and public health impacts of the nation’s largest agriculture-to-urban water trade have yet to result in any actual mitigation efforts, potentially jeopardizing several listed species and likely “…water trades not explicitly intended for environmental purposes can create… adverse environmental impacts.”
  • 42. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT22 water first began flowing to LA, creating the single largest source of dust pollution in the United States. In the past decade, after years of litigation, LA has spent more than $1.4 billion on dust management efforts and has returned some of the water to Owens Lake.17 San Luis Valley, Colorado. As demonstrated by efforts to destroy the infrastructure moving water out of the Owens Valley, local opposition to trading water can be strong. In the late 1980s, the Canadian owner of the 97,000-acre Baca Ranch in southern Colorado’s San Luis Valley began buying water rights from other farms in San Luis Valley, allegedly to irrigate new crops. Local residents, who soon discovered that the true pur- pose of the purchases was to sell the water to Denver suburbs, 100 miles to the northeast, feared that their valley would experience the devastation felt in Owens Valley. Thus, they formed Citizens for San Luis Valley Water to fight the water trade, working with the local irrigation district to support a special ballot measure to raise local taxes to fund litigation against the pro- posed water sale. The ballot measure prevailed with 92 percent of the vote. In 1991, the locals prevailed in court, stopping the proposed water trade. After Baca Ranch was subsequently sold, the new owner also attempted to sell the water out of the valley, sponsor- ing two statewide initiatives seen as efforts to support the water trade. In 1998, both initiatives failed, receiving less than 5 percent of the vote. With continued pub- lic pressure, the federal government purchased Baca Ranch in 2004 – more than a quarter century after the fight began – to prevent water from leaving the San Luis Valley. It then parceled the land to the newly designated Great Sand Dunes National Park, part to a nearby national forest, and 54,000 acres to the new Baca National Wildlife Refuge (Reimers, 2013). Imperial Valley, California. On the other hand, water trading that promotes efficiency rather than fallowing of agricultural land can improve socio-economic out- comes for both the area of origin and the destination. For example, an ongoing water trade from the Imperial 17 For information on the dust emissions at Owens Lake and the current dust management program, see the Great Basin Unified Air Pollution Control District website. rights within the community, meaning residents may be deprived of full compensation (Pant el al., 2008). Even within the community, the complex web of informal water-use arrangements can complicate informal trad- ing agreements and, in turn, generate a range of eco- nomic impacts on those using the water who had not been consulted or participated in the trading arrange- ments (Pant et al., 2008). Limarí Basin, Chile. Unequal access to water mar- kets due to unequal access to information or credit can distort outcomes and reduce market efficiency. Chile’s Limarí Basin has very high water trading activity, sug- gesting successful economic performance, but Romano and Leporati (2002) argued that it suffers from several market distortions arising from disparities between the resources available to those trading water. Peasants fare poorly in trading activity because their water rights often are not fully recognized, they are not as well- organized as those purchasing the water, and they lack access to information on pricing (Romano and Leporati, 2002). Dinar et al. (1997) noted that economic perfor- mance is affected by disparities in the value of water in different sectors and by the ability of those with limited means to participate in water trading. Southern California. Water generated for trades by fallowing land can benefit water rights holders at the expense of farmworkers and equipment suppliers, potentially devastating rural communities. California’s Owens Valley provides one of the early examples of the adverse impacts of trading water away from rural areas. In the early 1900s, agents secretly representing the City of Los Angeles (LA) covertly purchased land in the Owens Valley. In 1908, LA began a 5-year construc- tion project of a 419-mile pipeline to divert water from Owens Valley farmland to LA. Although Owens Valley irrigators had willingly sold their water through market transactions, they had not contemplated the plight of the valley as a whole. Over the next several years, agi- tators from the valley dynamited the pipeline several times in a vain attempt to protect their water supplies (Hundley, 2001). In addition to the direct economic and social impacts on the Owens Valley, the water trade had desiccated Owens Lake by 1926, just 13 years after
  • 43. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 23 within households where men have left for new indus- trial jobs enabled by new water supplies. In places where rural agriculture, particularly at the household level, provides subsistence and food security, reduced access to water can impose significant adverse impacts (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). Rural household access to water for domestic uses and for subsistence agriculture may have only infor- mal community-level recognition that does not trans- late into tradable water rights. Water trading that does not recognize these informal or ad hoc water uses can adversely affect equity outcomes and prompt ques- tions of legitimacy (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Formal, state-recognized water rights typically require the means and ability to register and defend them, in turn conferring power on those with formal water rights. In South Asia and other parts of the develop- ing world, informal water-use arrangements that permit and enable water use and trading can be disrupted by formal rights-based trades and command-and-control reallocations (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Zwarteveen (1997) noted that, as men in Ecuador, Nepal, and Peru have migrated in search of employ- ment, women have assumed a disproportionately large number of agricultural roles, even as formal and infor- mal water rights continue to be held by the absent men. These geographic and gender disparities can generate adverse outcomes as water is traded by absentee own- ers. Conversely, trading within households – even in the form of recognition of joint ownership – can encourage investment in water resource maintenance and pro- ductivity at the local level (Zwarteveen, 1997). Similarly, water organizations in the developing world, where decisions may be made about trading water out of the community, tend to have limited female participa- tion, potentially neglecting compensation for impacts that would have been identified if there were stronger female roles and participation (Zwarteveen, 1997). Water trading mechanisms can privilege certain popu- lations and marginalize others, especially when cultural practices differ. For example, New Mexico’s cooperative irrigation systems, known as acequias, usually enjoy Valley that began in 1989 relies on efficiency-based measures rather than fallowing to generate water for trade, creating additional employment while keeping land in production.18 Water trading’s social impacts vary based on several factors, including the relative economic health of the area of origin and the purchasing area, whether or not the water leaves the area of origin, the process used to trade the water, and the relative economic and politi- cal power of the parties (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005), gender differences regarding access to and control of water (Zwarteveen, 1997), the amount of trading activity in the area (Howe, 2011), and the legiti- macy of the water rights being traded (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Impacts often vary within the same community, as those with water rights or alloca- tions to trade receive compensation, while third parties – such as irrigation equipment suppliers or farmwork- ers – may suffer a loss of revenue or income as a result of trading (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Water trades within the same region typically have minimal or no adverse social or equity impacts. Howe (2011) noted the large number of small-volume, short- term water trades within an irrigation district as an example of positive economic and equity outcomes. Inter-sectoral trades, such as from agricultural to manufacturing or mining within the same region, may also generate positive economic and equity outcomes, as jobs shift from lower income farm employment to higher income industrial employment (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). However, Zwarteveen (1997) noted that even such intra-regional trades can gen- erate differential impacts based on gender, requiring additional agricultural and domestic labor for women 18 The Imperial Irrigation District’s IID/MWD Water Conservation Program Final Construction Report (2000) documented that 24 separate system water conservation projects and programs (as opposed to on-farm), such as lining irrigation canals and installing new headgates, had been implemented through 1999. The capital cost for these totaled $193 million (2014$), with an additional $8.3 million in annual operations and maintenance costs. These improvements yield 108,500 acre-feet of conserved water per year, at a cost of $254 per acre-foot. In addition to the jobs associated with the initial construction effort, the on-going water trade supports about 12–13 full-time positions for managing water deliveries, and for annual operations and maintenance.
  • 44. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT24 trading can increase costs for those who do not sell, such as operations and maintenance costs associated with water storage and delivery structures. The eco- nomic and equity impacts of water traded from rural areas can accumulate with additional trading activity, reaching a tipping point where local demand for agri- cultural services falls below the level necessary to main- tain operations, creating a cascading set of business failures and depressing the local tax base (Howe, 2011). Agricultural areas importing traded water may also suf- fer from third-party impacts, in the form of increased competition, extended wait-times for water deliveries via shared infrastructure, and rising water tables that may threaten plant roots or require additional drainage (Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). The one key exception to water trading that exacer- bates social and economic inequalities is in South Africa. Section 27(1) of South Africa’s 1998 National Water Act states: “In issuing a general authorisation or licence a re- sponsible authority must take into account all relevant factors, including… (b) the need to redress the results of past racial and gender discrimination;… (d) the socio-economic impact – (i) of the water use or uses if authorised; or (ii) of the failure to authorise the water use or uses.” While this act explicitly sought to use water trading to improve socio-economic conditions,19 South Africa’s Department of Water Affairs and Forestry (now known as the Department of Water and Sanitation) refused to permit more than 118 applications for water trades from 2005 through 2008, claiming that the trades failed to meet the Section 27(1) standards (Coleman, 2008). South Africa’s Supreme Court found in 2012 that: i) one proposed trade would create new employment oppor- tunities for both men and women in a region with high unemployment, meeting the standard established by 19 The National Water Act is available at http://www.acts.co.za/national-wa- ter-act-1998/. very senior water rights. However, they have fared poorly when defending their rights or seeking com- pensation for third-party impacts in state proceedings, where language and cultural practices favor fluency in English and legal literacy (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Romano and Leporati (2002) found similar circumstances in Chile, where less-educated rural peasants fared poorly in trading water rights to more powerful non-agricultural interests. Economic disparities also affect water-trading out- comes. As with the acequias, wealthy, powerful inter- ests enjoy disproportionate advantages relative to many historic water rights holders. In South Africa in the late 1990s, mining interests sought to increase their production and activity in rural, water-scarce regions by purchasing water rights from small irri- gators, at prices ten times higher than other irriga- tors were willing to offer. Although the mines offered employment and generated greater returns per unit of water, they threatened to dewater local subsis- tence farms and adversely affect a broad swath of rural economies beyond the irrigators voluntarily sell- ing their water (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). A study of water trading in Chile’s Limarí Valley found a similar impact, where increasing rural poverty was traced to water rights sales from peasants to non-agricultural interests and the general worsening of water-rights distribution (Romano and Leporati, 2002). As noted in the examples of the Owens and San Luis Valleys, those in areas of origin can strongly, sometimes violently, oppose the sale of water to outside interests. A national study of water trading in Australia found that this opposition can extend to local interests that trade their water rights to external interests (Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). In addition to cultural and social bases for opposing such trades, “Water trading mechanisms can privilege certain populations and marginalize others…”
  • 45. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 25 Grafton et al. (2010) wrote that “Legal clarity over water rights, including what they can be used for and the rules of water trade, is a cornerstone of functioning water markets.” Diversion or, better yet, consumptive use water rights with clear title and quantified alloca- tions that can be leased or sold can be described as marketable property rights, a necessary condition for water trading (Grafton et al., 2012). Culp et al. (2014) noted that water trading requires legally enforceable contracts that clearly and completely define the water right to be traded, an exclusive right to the water, and the recognized right to trade the water. Government plays a clear role in establishing these necessary condi- tions, documenting and, in some cases, allocating water rights themselves, establishing and maintaining the legal framework in which trading occurs and, in many cases, financing the physical infrastructure to store and convey water and allow water trading to occur (Dinar et al., 1997). Strong and effective institutions that adju- dicate and resolve disputes, enforce contracts, and monitor trading agreements are a necessary element in successful water markets (Zwarteveen, 1997). Typically, infrastructure is also required to physically convey water from a seller to a buyer, or to store or otherwise manage water availability so that an agreed- upon volume can be conveyed to the buyer at the appropriate time. In some cases, creative agreements have enabled trades from unconnected or remote sources of water, creating what are known as “in-lieu” or “paper” trades.21 While these trades can avoid require- ments for connecting physical infrastructure, they do require sophisticated legal arrangements, manage- ment, and monitoring to ensure that the correct vol- umes of water move at the approved time. 21 One example of an in-lieu water trade is the agreement between the Metropolitan Water District of Southern California and the Coachella Valley Water District and the Desert Water Agency. All three have contracts with California’s State Water Project (SWP), but because a direct connection from SWP’s California Aqueduct to Coachella Valley would have cost the equivalent of more than $1.8 billion, the latter two agencies agreed to an in-lieu exchange agreement with Metropolitan for a “bucket-for-bucket” exchange of SWP water for Colorado River water. That is, Metropolitan takes the other agencies’ allotment of SWP water, in exchange for giving up an equivalent amount of Colorado River water. Source: cvwd.org/news/news178.php. Section 27, and ii) the Department had acted improp- erly in failing to grant the requested license to trade the water.20 According to a local source, however, the responsible authorities in South Africa continue to delay and deny licenses for water trades, meaning that South Africa’s water market has been restricted for a decade (Backeberg, personal communication, 2015). Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions Institutional arrangements determine the ultimate success or failure of water trading (Livingston, 1998). Successful water trading requires secure and flexible water rights that recognize and protect users and others from externalities. Such institutional arrangements also need to be flexible enough to adapt to changing physical conditions as well as changing social norms, such as the growing interest in meeting environmental needs and protecting water quality (Livingston, 1998). Recognizing and understanding these factors can help explain the varying successes and even the existence of water trad- ing in different countries and regions within countries. Some factors, such as legal and transferable rights to use water, may be necessary for water trading to occur. Others, such as access to timely information about water available to trade, can enable water trading but may not be required for trading to occur. Still other factors, such as “no injury” regulations and “area of origin” protections, limit water trading or function as barriers or obstacles to trading. The following explains the details of the neces- sary, enabling and limiting conditions. Necessary conditions include: • legal, transferable rights to use water • decoupling of water rights from land rights • contract adjudication and enforcement • means for buyers and sellers to communicate • physical infrastructure to move water • mechanisms to monitor and measure water flows and use. 20 Makhanya v Goede Wellington Boerdery (Pty) Ltd (230/12) [2012] ZASCA 205 (30 November 2012).
  • 46. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT26 as precluding trading while the higher end of the scale can be seen as enabling trading. Water banks can enable water trading by connecting buyers and sellers, posting information on availability and transaction history and, in some cases, by physi- cally storing water to match availability and demands. The existence of technically skilled staff and monitor- ing equipment increases the efficacy of water banks and can help resolve disputes. Where water banks do not exist or have limited capacity, water contracting can enable spot trading (Brown et al., 2015). The availability of pertinent information can be con- sidered both a necessary and an enabling condition, depending on the extent and type of information avail- able. The availability of information on quantity, quality, location, and timing of water entitlements or alloca- tions can enable trading by pairing sellers and buy- ers. Similarly, clear information about transaction costs enables trading. Additionally, greater information and certainty about future conditions, such as the security of a water right given climate changes, can also enable water trading (Brown et al., 2015). Clear and timely information about prices also facilitates trading and decreases search costs (Levine et al., 2007). Social cohesion can also enable water trading. Trading is more likely to occur where informal bonds exist, such as between neighbors or within an irrigation district or even between irrigators, relative to trading between parties with no common history. In some cases, irriga- tors will accept a lower bid from another irrigator than a higher bid from a municipal agency, particularly one from outside the basin or region. Water rights hold- ers may fear that indicating they have water to trade could be interpreted to mean that they do not need the water, jeopardizing the right or imposing political costs (Albiac et al., 2006). Water trading can and does occur when necessary con- ditions are satisfied, but markets are much more robust and active when additional enabling conditions are met. Enabling conditions include: • water rights equivalency (as opposed to prioritized rights) • water banks and contracts • clear, available information • social cohesion • competitive markets with multiple participants of roughly equivalent economic power. One of the major factors contributing to Australia’s successful adoption of water trading in the Murray- Darling Basin was the absence of prioritized water rights. This enabled water trading without concern for impacts on those holding less senior water rights (see Annex 1 for greater detail). By contrast, in the western United States and other regions with prioritized water rights (also known as prior appropriation or seniority), an entitlement holder with a senior water right (deter- mined by the date the right was first exercised or “per- fected”) could only sell or lease water after ensuring that more junior rights holders receive compensation or do not otherwise protest the transaction. This distinc- tion helps explain the frequency of trades within irriga- tion districts where district members share a common priority right – such as the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District – and the much lower number of transactions between those with different priorities. That is, common priority rights or water rights with equivalent seniority can be traded more readily than rights with different priority dates. Dinar and Saleth (2005) proposed a scale from zero to seven to describe a range of surface water rights conditions that could be used to evaluate the enabling conditions for water trading. It spans from a rating of zero for no water rights, to a rating of five for appropria- tive rights; six for proportional sharing systems (such as the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District and Australia); and seven for water licenses and per- mits. Under this system, we could categorize no rights “Social cohesion can also enable water trading. Trading is more likely to occur where informal bonds exist…”
  • 47. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 27 The anti-speculation doctrine requires buyers to describe the new location and use of the water, condi- tioning the trade on these terms and increasing trans- action costs (Culp et al., 2014). The anti-speculation doctrine is intended to prevent hoarding and mar- ket distortion by those with the economic means to acquire large volumes of water (Grafton et al., 2010). In some areas, this doctrine is waived for municipal water agencies, enabling them to acquire water for unspeci- fied future needs. The beneficial use doctrine requires that water rights be exercised, encouraging inefficient or unproductive uses as rights holders must “use it or lose it.” Some jurisdictions have amended beneficial use require- ments to enable rights holders to sell or lease the water they conserve or save by implementing efficiency mea- sures, water they would otherwise simply lose to junior rights holders. Without explicit protection for such conservation measures, the beneficial use doctrine precludes water efficiency and hinders trading. In some areas, laws prohibit users from selling or leasing water “salvaged” from conservation or efficiency measures (Culp et al., 2014). Some kinds of water rights, such as non-consumptive, appurtenant water rights (common in wetter regions of the world) do not lend themselves to water trading.22 Examples of such non-consumptive rights include rights to use or divert water to run mills or generate hydroelectric power. Some markets limit participation to existing contractors or entitlement holders (Albiac et al., 2006). A related barrier is a limitation on the purpose or use to which a buyer may apply water. For example, several states only allow state agencies, and not private individuals or non-profit organizations, to purchase or lease water for environmental purposes. 22 An appurtenant water right is directly tied to the land itself, typically to lands adjacent to streams. Levine et al. (2007) argued that successful water trad- ing requires the participation of multiple buyers and sellers, with roughly equivalent power. They contended that, without these factors, market inefficiencies will result. In Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin and within several United States irrigation districts, the satisfac- tion of these criteria has enabled active and successful water trading. In their absence, as seen in many agricul- tural-to-urban trades, a small number of economically powerful buyers have distorted markets and created significant externalities. Limiting conditions, which hinder or reduce water trading, include: • no injury rule • anti-speculation doctrine • beneficial use doctrine • property rights/pre-conditions • high transaction costs • spatial and temporal differences in supply and de- mand. In many arid and semi-arid regions, water scarcity and variability dictate that upstream “return flows” – water diverted but not consumed that subsequently returns to the stream – are used and claimed by downstream users. To protect the rights of these downstream users, courts or regulators typically require that the quantity and timing of these return flows be maintained when upstream water is traded. These and similar protections, known as “no injury” rules, place the burden of proof that the trade will not harm or adversely affect other water rights on those wishing to sell or lease water. The “no injury” rule is the prevailing law in most of the western United States, intended to presumptively protect junior water rights holders from harm that may occur due to changes in the volume or timing of return flows from senior appropriators. It dramatically increases transac- tion costs, requiring sellers to hire attorneys and hydrol- ogists to prove no injury, or otherwise compensate all junior entitlement holders, and was a strong disincen- tive to water trading (Culp et al., 2014).
  • 48. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT28 services (Figure 5). Payments are made to the envi- ronmental service provider by the beneficiary of those services, e.g. an individual, a community, a company, or a government. In essence, it is based on a benefi- ciary-pays principle, as opposed to a polluter-pays principle. Environmental services most often included in PES arrangements include carbon sequestration in biomass or soils; habitat provision for endangered spe- cies; protection of landscapes; and various hydrological functions related to the quality, quantity, or timing of freshwater flows from upstream areas to downstream users (Gómez-Baggethun et al., 2010). PES has no standardized definition. The definition most commonly used in the literature was developed by Wunder (2005) and is based on five criteria: i) a volun- tary transaction where ii) a well-defined environmental service is iii) purchased by at least one environmental service buyer from iv) at least one environmental ser- vice provider, with v) payment conditional on the ser- vice provided. In reality, few projects actually meet all of these criteria. For example, money may come from donors rather than service providers, or participation in theprogrammaybemandatory.Wunder(2005)argued, and several reviews confirm, that conditionality is the hardest criteria to meet because initiatives are often loosely monitored and payments are made up front or in good faith. Moreover, in some cases, participation is not voluntary (e.g. China), and the beneficiaries are broadly defined and are not directly contributing to the program. Wunder (2005) concluded that while there are a considerable number of PES-like arrangements, there are likely “very few ‘true PES’ conforming to the theoretical concept developed in the literature.” PES programs focused on watershed services are commonly referred to as payment for watershed ser- vices, or PWS. PWS arrangements, as with all PES arrangements, can take a variety of forms. They can be intended to prevent the degradation of a watershed or to restore a previously degraded watershed. They can be small, local schemes covering several hundred hectares or large, national schemes covering millions of High transactions costs, driven by the various doctrines noted above as well as by the need to overcome infor- mation constraints and related factors, can hinder water trading. Similarly, the time required to complete a trans- action may limit trading, particularly when buyers seek to meet a short-term demand such as an additional irri- gation cycle or to offset a delivery disruption within an urban system; relatively fast trades will produce greater trading activity than prolonged approval processes. Finally, geographic and temporal mismatches between supply and demand can impose additional barriers to water trading, especially in the absence of physical infrastructure to bridge these gaps. Where dams and conveyances do not exist, those wishing to sell water may lack the means to physically deliver the water to a potential buyer, or be unable to deliver the water at the right time (Bauer, 1997). 3.2 Payment for ecosystem services/payment for watershed services Description Payment for ecosystem services (PES) is an incentive- based instrument that seeks to monetize the external, non-market values of environmental services, such as removal of pollutants and regulation of precipita- tion events, into financial incentives for local actors to provide such services. In practical terms, PES involves a series of payments to a land or resource manager in exchange for a guaranteed flow of environmental “High transactions costs, driven by the various doctrines noted above as well as by the need to overcome information constraints and related factors, can hinder water trading.”
  • 49. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 29 • Service providers. For the vast majority of lo- cal and national programs, private landowners are the main watershed service providers, followed by communal landholders, private reserves, national parks and, in a very small number of local schemes, occupiers of public land. • Payment levels. In national programs, payment levels are mostly determined administratively. In the local programs, negotiation through an inter- mediary is more common. Direct negotiations be- tween supplier and buyer occur in very few cases. Funds and transfer of payments are in most cases managed by an intermediary, often in a specially set up trust fund. hectares. PWS schemes can be financed directly from the beneficiary or from third parties acting on behalf of the beneficiary, e.g. governments or institutions, or some combination thereof. They can involve cash or in-kind payments and be paid all at once or periodi- cally. In a comprehensive review of 50 ongoing PWS programs in developing countries, Porras et al. (2008) highlighted the following major trends. • Scale. Most ongoing programs (82 percent) are lo- cal, operating at watershed level or smaller. The re- maining 18 percent are national programs. Some of the local programs are linked to national programs or international projects. • Scope. Local programs tend to target one or two watershed services (more commonly water qual- ity than water quantity), while national programs tend to target multiple environmental services as a means of tapping into multiple funding sources. FIGURE 5. Schematic of a PES arrangement for watershed services Watershed services e.g. water purification, flood risk mitigation, aquifer recharge, erosion minimization Balances upstream and downstream interests Upstream community Stewards and providers of waterhsed services Incentives e.g. cash, assistance, materials Project Payments Downstream water users Beneficiaries of watershed services Source: Forest Trends, 2012. “PWS schemes can be financed directly from the beneficiary or from third parties…”
  • 50. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT30 that preserving the upstream rural Catskill watershed would be far less expensive. However, New York City had a long-history of employing eminent domain to solve such issues. When farmers and rural landowners voiced immediate concern, the city and local farmers came together to develop a plan that could meet both groups’ interests. A key element of the plan was the Whole Farm Program, a voluntary effort fully funded by New York City’s Department of Environmental Protection whereby farmers would work with technical advisors to custom design point and nonpoint source pollution control measures to meet an environmen- tal objective while also improving the viability of their farming business. By 2006, the city had spent or com- mitted $1.4–$1.5 billion in watershed protection proj- ects, averaging $167 million in expenditures per year (Kenny, 2006). Participation remains high, with 96 per- cent of large farms in the watershed participating in the program (Watershed Agricultural Council, 2011). PWS arrangements have also been established in developing countries. In Ecuador, for example, the Socio Bosque Program (SBP), a national program established in 2008, provides financial incentives to individual and communal forest landowners to conserve native forest and Andean tundra ecosystems. The program, which includes environmental protection and poverty alle- viation objectives, is largely state funded. Since 2012, however, additional support has been provided by the German Development Bank, NGOs, and General Motors Omnibus BB. Program participation is volun- tary. Participants are provided a monetary incentive per hectare of land entered into the program, and in exchange, must agree to refrain from logging, changing existing land uses, burning, altering hydrological condi- tions or reducing carbon storage, and commercial or sport hunting and fishing for 20 years. By mid-2013, 1.1 million hectares had been conserved through 2,100 individual and 150 communal agreements (Raes and Mohebalian, 2013). While PWS programs can be found in a wide range of settings and, in some cases, have been operating for decades, comprehensive data on their size or scope are not available. Ecosystem Marketplace (2013) estimated • Funding sources. Funding sources are varied. Na- tional programs primarily receive government fund- ing through the allocation of national budgets and donor funding, including loans from the World Bank. Funding for local programs is more varied but is pri- marily from: domestic and agricultural water fees; donors, including the Global Environment Facility (GEF), World Bank, and German Cooperation; the private sector, including downstream hydroelectric companies (in some cases, in the form of a dona- tion); and local government budgets. • Conditionality. Nearly all programs are uncon- ditional, meaning service providers are paid on a per unit area basis for land-management practices “believed to have a high probability of resulting in provision of the environmental service.” Only one payment scheme, Indonesia’s Rewarding Upland Poor for Environmental Services (RUPES) initia- tive, is conditional on outcomes, such as the level of sediment reduction achieved. Application PWS arrangements are gaining prominence and have been applied in a wide range of settings. For example, the US Conservation Reserve Program (CRP), estab- lished in the 1950s in an effort to reduce erosion on agricultural lands, became more conservation oriented in the mid-1980s, making it among the oldest and lon- gest running PES programs in the world. CRP today pays farmers to take land out of production in order to protect soil and water resources, as well as wildlife habitat (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). In northeastern France, Vittel-Nestle Waters paid farmers and provided technical support (and some labor) to alter local dairy farming practices in order to reduce nitrate pollution of groundwater – the source of Vittel’s bottled water (Perrot-Maitre 2006). New York City provides another well-known example. In the late 1990s, New York City was faced with the prospect of building a $4–$6 billion filtration plant with an additional $250 million in annual operating costs to meet new federal Safe Drinking Water Act require- ments – an approach that was “treating symptoms, not causes” (Appleton, 2010). An initial analysis suggested
  • 51. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 31 • many programs lack baseline data or monitoring systems • the connections between land-use practice and watershed services are not always clear, especially as they relate to water quantity, and are often site specific • it can be difficult to attribute change to the pro- gram rather than to external factors (e.g. changing commodity prices) • programs may not reach threshold levels for mea- sureable impact, or that impact may occur over a relatively long time period. As a result of these challenges, reliance on input- based indicators (sometimes referred to as behavioral change) has been borne out of necessity. Porras (personal communication, 2015) argued that because of these challenges, monitoring should be based on input-based, rather than outcome-based, indicators, as outcome-based indicators shift too much risk to the ecosystem service provider and may raise equity concerns. She further noted the need to set meaningful expectations. For example, conservation projects may be implemented within a landslide-prone watershed to reduce the risk of landslides, with the understanding that, even with a successful program, a landslide would still likely occur, albeit with reduced frequency and intensity over the long term. Thus, an expectation of no landslides is unrealistic and could threaten the viability of the program. In the absence of data on project outcomes, Porras et al. (2008) found that reported impacts are often based on “perceptions of local populations and those operating the schemes and/or quick measurements of what the impacts should be, rather than in-depth sci- entific evidence drawing from site measurements and modelling of relationships.” But even based on these sources, the available data suggest that environmental performance is mixed. In a review of previous studies that the total transaction value of PWS programs and water funds in 2012 was $8.0 billion. Activity in 2013 was considerably higher, with an estimated $11.5 billion in transaction value for PWS programs in China alone. While these data suggest dramatic growth, Bennett (personal communication, 2015) noted that the differ- ence can largely be explained by better reporting by a larger number of projects. Case studies of PWS pro- grams in developing countries are maintained by the London-based International Institute for Environment and Development and at Watershed Connect, an online platform maintained by Forest Trends (2015a). Environmental, economic, and social performance Comprehensive studies on the performance of PWS programs are limited, although some studies have been conducted on various aspects of these programs. Below, we examine the available evidence looking at how PWS has performed environmentally, economi- cally, and socially. ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE The environmental performance of PWS is not well understood due to a lack of scientific analysis. In an analysis of 47 PWS schemes in developing countries, Brouwer et al. (2011) found that “less than half of the schemes used quantifiable indicators and monitored the impact of the schemes on environmental perfor- mance.” In most cases, the indicators were input-based, meaning that they, for example, looked at land area with forest cover, rather the actual impacts and outcomes of the program. In a review of Costa Rica’s programs, Pagiola (2008) found it “unfortunately impossible to determine the extent to which the PSA23 program has successfully generated environmental services. Although the PSA program has established a strong system to monitor land user compliance with payment contracts, the program remains weak in monitoring its effectiveness in generating the desired services.” There are several challenges to evaluating environ- mental performance: 23 Pagos por servicios ambientales (payment for environmental services) “…PWS programs can be found in a wide range of settings…”
  • 52. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT32 applicants for forest protection are prioritized based on the total number of points they receive, with more points awarded for forests in indigenous territories or those protecting water resources. Likewise, applicants for reforestation projects are awarded more points if they use native species or reforest degraded areas with high forestry potential (Porras et al., 2013). The selec- tion criteria can be tailored to reflect the environmental (and even social objectives) of the program and altered as priorities or needs change. ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Payment structures are generally uniform and untar- geted, with flat rates per hectare for all sites (Porras et al., 2008; Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). Despite the preva- lence of uniform, untargeted payments, program costs and benefits are spatially heterogeneous. Wunschler et al. (2006) found that ecosystem service provision varies spatially according to the ecosystem benefits, the threat of loss, and the cost of service provision. Several stud- ies have suggested that untargeted, uniform payments reduce the cost effectiveness of PES schemes (Dillaha et al., 2007; Ferraro, 2008), and given likely constraints on program budgets, reduces the project benefits and its long-term success (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). Reverse auctions (also referred to as procurement auc- tions) have been put forth as one option for improving the economic efficiency of PWS schemes (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). In an ordinary auction, the buy- ers compete to obtain a good or service by offering increasingly higher prices. With reverse auctions, the sellers compete to obtain business from the buyer, and prices typically decrease as sellers undercut one another. The US Conservation Reserve Program, for example, combines reverse auctions with an environ- mental benefit index to select land for inclusion in the program. However, Ferraro (2008) acknowledged that and surveys of PWS scheme managers, Brouwer et al. (2011) found that “58 percent of the PWS schemes were classified as effective in reaching their environ- mental objectives, while 42 percent were not.” Several factors, ranging from the number of intermediaries and mode of participation to the selection of service provid- ers, level of community participation and type of moni- toring, were found to improve environmental outcomes: • schemes with fewer intermediaries were more ef- fective in meeting environmental objectives • mandatory participation increased environmental effectiveness compared with voluntary schemes • selecting service providers based on a set of crite- ria, e.g. location, accessibility of land, or parcel size, tended to have a negative impact on environmen- tal performance • contracting with the community was more effective than contracting with a single ecosystem service provider • programs that monitored progress toward achiev- ing environmental objectives were more likely to reach those objectives. The study also found that schemes for direct payments by downstream hydropower companies to upstream land owners to reduce sediment loads were generally identified as successful, while other factors – includ- ing the type of watershed service, age of the scheme, or scale of implementation – had no significant effect on the outcome. Recognizing this, Brouwer et al. (2011) called for international monitoring guidelines to com- pare programs, identify success factors, and support their future design. Some have suggested that one way to improve envi- ronmental outcomes is through better selection of areas to include within the PWS program, a process that could be facilitated by the application of new tech- nologies (e.g. satellite imagery) and modeling efforts. Porras et al. (2013) identified several criteria suggested in the literature for targeting efforts, including focus- ing on areas at high risk of deforestation, large blocks of land prone to landslides or other natural disasters, and biological corridors. In Costa Rica, for example, “…studies have suggested that untargeted, uniform payments reduce the cost effectiveness of PES schemes…”
  • 53. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 33 rivers in China. Total investment is $4.3 million per year. Farmers in the Yangtze River Basin are paid yuan 417 per hectare per year ($50), while those in the Yellow River Basin are paid yuan 290 ($36) per hectare per year. In addition to the regular cash payments, farm- ers also receive a one-off cash payment and regular grain rations (Porras and Neves, 2006a). The program is designed to promote forestry and other economic endeavors on the land, rather than grain production. Given that most programs are voluntary, some have argued that continued participation provides some indi- cation that the programs are cost effective, i.e. that the benefits exceed the costs. The impact of PWS schemes on ecosystem service providers is generally estimated by looking at the payment as a fraction of household income. Using this metric, results are varied. Kosoy et al. (2007) found that the amount received from the PWS scheme was less than 2 percent of gross annual income for most providers in three cases in Costa Rica, Nicaragua, and Honduras; moreover, most watershed service providers did not think that the payment was fair. However, Wunder (2008) found that payments represented 10 to 16 percent of household income in schemes in Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Venezuela, and Vietnam. Even these studies did not examine the trans- action costs participants incurred in the program or the opportunity costs. In light of these findings, several studies have suggested that there are also important non-financial (or non-income) benefits (Kosoy et al., 2007; Wunder, 2008). The most commonly cited non- financial benefits include increasing land-tenure secu- rity, increasing human and social capital through internal organization, and increasing the visibility of the commu- nity to donors and public entities (Wunder, 2008). SOCIAL PERFORMANCE Limited data are available on the social outcomes of PES programs, as studies have been more narrowly focused on “short- or mid-term outcomes such as increased income or capacity building since these are much easier to identify” than broader social impacts, such as changes in power dynamics (Richards, 2013). In one notable exception, a review of Mexico’s PES program auctions introduce their own set of challenges, espe- cially in low- and middle-income countries. In these countries, PES schemes may have dual objectives, and reducing information asymmetries (and thus payments for the ecosystem service provider) may not be a pri- ority. Additionally, administrators of these programs might be less likely to differentiate payment due to concerns about fairness, and it is unclear whether there would be institutional capacity to manage these pro- grams. Moreover, auctions tend to increase transaction costs, which may already be relatively high in low- and middle-income countries where buyers of environmen- tal services are likely to contract with many small, often semi-literate, landowners, who often have no legal titles and are in dispersed remote rural areas. Finally, differ- entiation of payment can make it difficult to identify corruption and ensure that differentiation is based on implementation of transparent rules. Alix-Garcia et al. (2009) suggested another option to reverse auctions would be “to conduct rigorous contingent valuation studies in areas targeted by the program.” Whileuniformpaymentsarestillcommon,therearesev- eral notable exceptions. Mexico’s National Programme for Hydrological Environmental Services (PSAH) pro- vides higher payments for lands that provide greater benefits. For example, primary forest owners receive 300 pesos per hectare per year (approximately $27). Cloud forest owners, by contrast, receive 400 pesos per hectare per year ($36) due to the perceived higher delivery of hydrological services associated with this type of forest which has a role in capturing water from fog and clouds during the dry season (Porras and Neves, 2006). Payments are made annually, at the end of the year, once the absence of land use change has been confirmed. China’s Sloping Land Conversion Program also pro- vides targeted payments, although payments are dif- ferentiated according to the opportunity costs. China’s program, which began as a pilot in 1999 and was fully implemented in 2002, requires farmers to set aside ero- sion-prone farmland within critical areas of the water- sheds of the Yangtze and Yellow Rivers, the two largest
  • 54. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT34 broad geographic regions – could be developed to improve social outcomes. While some have argued that the pursuit of poverty alleviation objectives is likely to result in environmental tradeoffs (see, e.g. Huang et al., 2009), others suggest that this may not always be the case (Brouwer, personal communication, 2015). South Africa’s Working for Water (WfW) program is one of the few programs to have poverty alleviation as its primary objective. Between its launch in 1995 and 2009, WfW cleared more than 1 million hectares of invasive alien plants, which improved the timing and volume of surface water flows, provided erosion control, and increased biodiversity (Ferraro, 2009). The program, administered by the Department of Water Affairs and Forestry, employs 25,000 to 32,000 people annually, targeting low skilled, previously unemployed laborers, with a special focus on rural women, youth, and the dis- abled (Ferraro, 2009). Social development, an integral part of the program, includes “skills development, train- ing, and awareness creation of communities in health issues, hygiene, environmental health, inoculation, sexually transmitted diseases, pregnancy and meno- pause” (Department of Environmental Affairs, 2015). The vast majority of the program budget is provided by the central government and the Department of Water Affairs and Forestry’s general budget, with only very minor funding from foreign donors, municipalities, and the private sector. Ferraro (2009) argued that while the program is effectively the government paying for envi- ronmental services on government-controlled lands (and therefore not a true PES program), the program administrators are actively seeking voluntary payments from private and municipal actors to remove invasive plants from within their watersheds. Several studies have examined the socio-economic status of participants in PES schemes, either as buyers or sellers. Porras et al. (2008) found mixed results in both national and local schemes, depending, to some extent, on land and forest tenure regimes and socio- economic conditions in the targeted area. In programs in Mexico and Nicaragua, for example, the poor were relatively well represented (Muñoz-Piña et al., 2008; Pagiola et al., 2005), whereas in Costa Rica, the poor (Alix-Garcia et al., 2009) found that in most cases, there were no “obvious” changes in the social dynamics within a community. However, in two cases, they found a shift in the relative power of certain groups, whereby small, private forest holders who held land within or adjacent to communal lands threatened to cut down their for- ests if they did not receive some compensation.24 In two other cases, the program improved environmental awareness and participation in conservation activities. Information on broader social outcomes is limited. However, there is information on the role of PES arrangements in alleviating poverty. It is important to recognize that PES schemes were conceptualized as a mechanism to improve the efficiency of natural resource management, not as a mechanism to reduce poverty (Pagiola et al., 2005). While most programs prioritize areas critical for ecosystem services, some have been tailored to meet social objectives through a variety of mechanisms, including by targeting the programs to particular areas or populations, reducing transaction costs, and providing pro-poor premiums and subsidies (Wunder, 2005; Porras et al., 2013). In Costa Rica, a social development index consisting of 11 health, participation, economics, and education indica- tors is one of the criteria that is then integrated with environmental criteria to select participants.25 This par- ticular social development index has been shown to be ineffective in targeting payments to low-income popu- lations because it is biased toward large properties and is “too spatially coarse to represent the social impact of the programme at household level” (Porras et al., 2013). However, it suggests that some sort of criterion – pref- erably tailored to individual characteristics rather than 24 In a somewhat unusual situation, this conflict was a result of the fact that only a small group had rights to the commons and only those with rights received payment. 25 The index is used by Costa Rican government institutions to establish priority for social policy and budget allocations. “PES schemes were … to improve the efficiency of natural resource management, not as a mechanism to reduce poverty…”
  • 55. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 35 were not well represented (Zbinden and Lee, 2005). Wunder (2008) noted that one must typically own or hold land in order to be a seller, thereby excluding the “poorest of the poor.” Some schemes have attempted to recognize informal access to resources (e.g. Indonesia’s RUPES Program), although this has been difficult to replicate elsewhere (Porras et al., 2008). A recent review of ten PWS schemes in developing countries by Bond and Mayers (2010) found only a small number of cases where livelihoods had been improved, con- cluding that “there are significant and positive indirect effects of PWS – particularly in building social capita in poor communities.” They acknowledged that while improving education, health, and nutrition are bet- ter ways of reducing poverty than PWS, there is little evidence of these schemes actually doing any harm. Moreover, they suggested that targeting can make PWS programs more effective in alleviating poverty. Additionally, while it is commonly assumed that up- stream service providers are poorer than downstream users (Wunder, 2008), the reality may be more com- plicated. For example, George et al. (2009) found that downstream and upstream stakeholders were part of the same community in two watersheds in Thailand and Lao PDR with no clear distinction between upstream providers and downstream beneficiaries. In some cases, according to Porras et al. (2008), downstream users may, in fact, be poorer, raising concerns about their ability to pay as well as whether those payments are equitable. In cases where user fees were used to compensate ecosystem service providers, the authors found that the fees were generally found to be accept- able, with no detectable impact on water use or access to water. Additionally, some programs had taken steps to ensure that the poorest users were not impacted by these fees, e.g. by making payments voluntary or pro- viding a lifeline supply of water. Few studies have examined gender representation among program participants. In a literature review, Ravn- borg et al. (2007) found that less than 5 percent of the references addressed gender-specific aspects of impacts of PES. In a more recent assessment, Richards (2013) concurred, finding that “Gender effects have not been monitored, and therefore there is no information about how women have been affected except some reference to their low levels of participation.” Porras et al. (2008) cited two studies indicating low participation levels by women. However, these studies were more than a decade old and may not have reflected current conditions. Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions Some factors, such as contract adjudication and enforcement, may be necessary for establishing a PWS program. Other factors, such as appropriate inventories and analyses and government support, can enable but may not be required for PES programs to be estab- lished. Still other factors, such as legal prohibitions, limit watershed PES or function as barriers or obstacles. Necessary conditions include: • a legal system recognizing that agreements must be kept • a civil law providing contract parties with legal rem- edies to enforce contract rights in cases of non- compliance with contract obligations • general respect for the rule of law. In general, PES schemes are flexible and the necessary conditions are relatively modest. However, Calvache et al. (2012) determined that they must be designed within the legal context of a particular area. Greiber (2009) provided additional detail on the legal frame- work for PWS implementation, noting that the frame- work will differ depending on the type of scheme implemented. For example, private schemes, defined as self-organized schemes between private entities, require the least government intervention and depend on only general legal requirements: e.g. a legal system recognizing that agreements must be kept, and civil law providing contract parties with legal remedies in case of non-compliance. However, if only these condi- tions are in place, Greiber (2009) asserted that these “Few studies have examined … gender- specific aspects of impacts of PES.”
  • 56. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT36 • methodologies for measuring, monitoring, report- ing, and verifying progress toward achieving proj- ect outcomes. Several studies have developed guides highlighting the technical requirements (Hawkins, 2011; Calvache et al., 2012; Smith et al., 2013). In addition to these require- ments, methodologies for measuring, monitoring, reporting, and verifying progress toward achieving out- comes are also needed. Monitoring and evaluation are fundamental to the success of PES schemes because the information they provide gives assurance to the buyer that ecosystem services are delivered as prom- ised and allows for adjustments to the program based on better information and changing conditions. Porras et al. (2013) made a distinction between monitoring for compliance and monitoring for environmental effective- ness. The former “seeks to ensure that the conditional- ity inherent in a PWS scheme is put into practice, and that the project is implemented effectively.” The latter, by contrast, seeks to ensure that the scheme achieves its overall objectives and is needed to demonstrate additionality, i.e. that changes in watershed ecosystem services can be attributed to the program. While com- pliance and effectiveness monitoring are often linked, “a high degree of compliance does not necessarily ensure that a scheme is effective, as a poorly designed scheme may target the wrong land managers and land that is at least risk, meaning that the payments may not generate the desired hydro-ecological or conservation benefits.” Despite some of the challenges to monitoring (described in the application section of 3.2), Brouwer et al. (2011) pointed to the need for international monitoring guide- lines to identify the relationship between the design of theprogramanditsenvironmentaleffectivenessbecause understanding these relationships is “paramount to the future design of cost-effective PWS schemes.” A recent Science article by a large team of scientists and prac- titioners in the PES field (Naeem et al., 2015) noted that “many projects are based on weak scientific foun- dations, and effectiveness is rarely evaluated with the rigor necessary for scaling up and understanding the importance of these approaches as policy instruments and conservation tools.” In an effort to advance the field, programs would “mostly develop at a small scale with the objective to solve a specific local water problem,” and expanding these projects to address regional or national water problems would require a more devel- oped policy and legal framework. By contrast, public schemes are government-driven schemes that, by definition, require far greater gov- ernment involvement, as local, regional, or national governments are involved as either watershed service providers or buyers, and payment may be done through user fees, taxes, or subsidies. However, many of these schemes have evolved on an ad hoc basis from initia- tives of NGOs and overseas development corporations and, as a result, they typically lack comprehensive or coherent legislation. Greiber (2009) also noted that these conditions limit “the real potential of PES as an innovative instrument that might be applied more often, more efficiently, and at a larger scale to combat prevailing water problems.” He argued that a specific legal and policy framework would stimulate PES devel- opment by creating greater legal certainty and helping to promote good governance practices. While necessary conditions establish the minimum requirements for the implementation of a PES program, there is a set of enabling conditions that promotes the success and long-term viability of these programs. While some of the enabling conditions are technical in nature, others are legal, institutional, social, and political. Technical enabling conditions include: • an inventory of the value of hydrological services, including assessments of baseline conditions, and of how these values may change in response to land use alterations, infrastructure development, and climate • an analysis of program costs, including implemen- tation, opportunity, and transaction costs • a registry of names, transactions, project data, credit issuance, or other information related to PES activities • technical support from the government, civil soci- ety, or the private sector through trainings, infor- mation, or direct technical assistance
  • 57. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 37 TABLE 2. Natural-science principles and guidelines for PES programs Principle: Dynamics Objective: Ensure project capacity to adapt to dynamic natural and anthropogenic processes. Principle: Monitoring Objective: Track factors necessary for management, trade, forecasting, and assessment. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: identify key services for each service type beyond target services identify spatiotemporal scales of targeted services identify data needs, resources, and gaps identify stressors and their spatiotemporal variability identify and forecast trends in endogenous and exogenous threats identify services’ production and functions and sensitivities determine trade-offs and synergies among services determine how functional diversity influences resilience. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: quantify deliverables associated with target services identify spatiotemporal scales in advance of implementation use established methods/protocols and best practices for monitoring estimate uncertainties monitoring should inform decision-making monitoring should detect potential changes in baseline conditions monitor non-target services that influence target services. Principle: Baseline Objective: Document and initial conditions Principle: Metrics Objective: Robust, efficient, and versatile methods for procuring data. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: measure influences of interventions on services measure status and trends of non-target services ensure that measurements are feasible given resources assess initial state of exogenous and endogenous threats to services measure factors important for forecasting service trends. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: must be relevant, reliable, and appropriate in scale should comply with voluntary standards, certification, and regulations should reflect spatiotemporal scales as identified in dynamics optimize balance between precision and simplicity assess progress (in conjunction with baseline and monitoring) should measure both absolute changes and changes in trends preferentially selected to allow comparisons across service types assess how services influence each other. Principle: Multiple services Objective: Recognize trade-offs and synergies among services Principle: Ecological sustainability Objective: Insure project durability and sustainability SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: assess how intervention influences the other services avoid “double counting” assess impacts of intervention on non-target services. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: estimate short-term and long-term project or program performance. Note: The scientific guidelines shown in bold font are intended to indicate “essential” guidelines that must be followed for a successful intervention. Guidelines shown in regular font are considered “desirable”. Source: Naeem et al., 2015.
  • 58. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT38 of ecosystem services, while Colombia went even fur- ther by requiring departments and municipalities to invest at least 1  percent of annual revenues toward either PES to landowners or direct land acquisition in source water areas (Bennett et al., 2014). Enabling leg- islation can occur at various levels (e.g. local, provincial, or national) and take a variety of forms. However, the appropriate level and form will depend on the prevail- ing governance system in a particular area. A variety of social and political conditions increases the likelihood of the successful implementation of PES schemes. For example, cultural and political acceptance of markets in general, and of commercializing rights to land use and land management practices, creates an enabling environment. Dillaha et al. (2007) noted that PES activity is generally strong in Latin America, but that development tends to lag in areas with strong indigenous cultures (such as the Bolivian highlands) or closed economies (such as Venezuela). It is important to note that in areas where the natural environment has historically been used for free, “actually paying for envi- ronmental services in response to mounting resource scarcity represents a major change in attitude, which necessarily will take time” (Dillaha et al., 2007). Trust is also a key element for an effective PES pro- gram, as it helps to ensure that there are willing buy- ers and sellers, and reduces transaction costs. Dillaha et al. (2007) noted that service providers might fear that PES is a first-step toward appropriation of their resources, while service users “might suspect that they are or will be the victims of ‘environmental blackmail’.” Based on several cases in Asia, Neef and Thomas (2009) argued that “Lack of trust between poten- tial buyers and providers of environmental services is probably one of the most constraining factors in set- ting up viable PES schemes.” One way to facilitate the trust-building process is through stakeholder engage- ment, especially during the initial stages of the project. Likewise, transparency and access to information are also essential. Intermediaries, such as NGOs, can some- times play a role in building and maintaining trust while also providing technical, legal, and financial support. As the authors put forth a set of natural science principles and guidelines for PES efforts that they felt were appli- cable to local-, regional-, and national-level programs in developed and developing countries (Table 2). A set of scientific guidelines for four of the principles – dynamics, monitoring, baseline, and metrics – were deemed “essen- tial” for a successful intervention, whereas the remainder were deemed “desirable”. While specific to PES arrange- ments, they argued that the principles and guidelines could be applicable to market-based conservation instruments more broadly. In a review of 118 active PES projects, however, the authors found that 60 percent did not adhere to the four essential principles, highlighting considerable room for improvement in the development and implementation of PES projects. In addition to the more technical aspects of PES, there are a number of enabling legal, institutional, social, and political conditions that also improve the effectiveness of PES. Enabling legal, institutional, social, and political conditions include: • a policy and legal framework for PES • incentives and/or requirements to participate in PES programs • cultural and political acceptance of markets • trust between ecosystem service providers and beneficiaries • a supply and demand for ecosystem services. Governments, for example, can pass laws or institute policies that enable the development of PES pro- grams. In Costa Rica, participants of PES programs are exempt from paying property taxes (Porras et al., 2013). Likewise, the Peruvian government unanimously passed a law providing a legal framework for voluntary PES programs between land stewards and beneficiaries “Governments, for example, can pass laws or institute policies that enable the development of PES programs.”
  • 59. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 39 whether these rights also include “the right to receive income from the ecosystem services provided by the transferred natural resource.” Likewise, in Asia, most forested and agricultural land is state-owned. Thus, individuals and communities have weak land rights, making it difficult for them to sign a contract and pro- vide a legal guarantee of future land management practices (Huang et al., 2009). 3.3 Water quality trading Description Water quality trading (WQT) is a market-based approach for reducing or controlling water pollution. It allows permitted dischargers in a watershed to trade water quality credits, or pollution allowances, in order to meet water quality standards. Markets in water quality differ from conventional markets in that they are not based on an actual physical commodity. Rather, they are based on trading a license or a permit to pollute. The primary goal of water quality trading is to reduce the costs of water pollution control, often following the imposition of a cap on pollutant emissions by regula- tors. Secondary goals are to reduce compliance costs and spur innovative solutions to pollution control. Water quality trading is an adjunct to regulation, and not an alternative to it. In fact, its success depends on the presence of a strong regulatory body to enforce water quality standards, and monitor and enforce dis- charge limits. Water quality markets draw inspiration from the suc- cess of the Acid Rain Program (ARP) in the United States in the 1990s. At the time, most environmental groups and government agency staff favored a “com- mand-and-control” approach to pollution control that Bond and Mayers (2010) acknowledged, trust “is hard to build and easy to lose.” Finally, there must be a supply of, and demand for, eco- system services. On the supply side, payments must be big enough relative to other opportunities to create a real incentive for change. On the demand side, benefi- ciaries must have the ability to pay. For example, Huang et al. (2009) posited that by increasing incomes, rapid economic growth in Asia could increase demand for watershed services because there is greater willing- ness and ability to pay for amenities such as clean water and recreation. At the same time, rapid economic growth could increase demand for goods and services produced on the land, thereby increasing the oppor- tunity cost of the land. In a regional review of PWS programs in sub-Saharan Africa, Ferraro (2009) sug- gested that demand for watershed services is relatively low, as there are relatively few formal water systems, and even those with formal systems may lack reliable access – which means there are few people who could be easily charged a water fee to pay for watershed ser- vices. Moreover, high poverty rates suggest that many would not be able to afford higher water costs. There is also a set of conditions that can hinder or limit the development of PES schemes. Limiting conditions can include: • any legal provision prohibiting watershed PES con- tracts • poorly defined property rights. Greiber (2009) noted that “clearly defined property rights enable parties to enter into PES contracts and ensure the sustainability of PES schemes.” Several challenges associated with property rights arise when implementing PES schemes. For example, ecosystem services are a relatively new concept and may not be recognized by the existing legal framework. In Peru, the state is the owner of natural resources and holds the property rights over ecosystem services. While the state can transfer certain property rights over natural resources to individuals, it has not yet been determined “Water quality markets draw inspiration from the success of the Acid Rain Program in the US in the 1990s.”
  • 60. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT40 levels in water bodies, a process referred to as “eutro- phication”. Other water quality trading programs have been set up to control salinity, heavy metal, sediment, and temperature or thermal pollution (Morgan and Wolverton, 2005). These programs are typically based around specific watersheds or receiving waters, such as the Chesapeake Bay or Wisconsin’s Fox River. WQT markets are different from other emissions trading schemes, in that trading is used between sources in the same area of impact, e.g. a watershed that drains to a particular water body, such as a lake, estuary, or river. The geography of trading contrasts starkly with other well-known cap-and-trade-style environmental markets, such as national and international markets for carbon offsets, where emission reductions can take place even in remote parts of the world. Trading within water quality markets can take several different forms. The most common arrangement in the United States is a bilateral market, where buyers negotiate trades directly with potential sellers, discuss- ing their quantity and price. Often, a regulator will get involved by, for example, approving the terms of the agreement, or facilitating monitoring to ensure that actual discharge reductions take place. This arrange- ment makes transactions slow and costly, and has been partially blamed for the moribund trading activ- ity in most US WQT markets (Woodward et al., 2002). In clearinghouse-style markets, a middleman such as a brokerage firm facilitates trades by connecting will- ing buyers and sellers, as has been done in the Tar- Pamlico River Basin Nutrient Trading Program in North Carolina. On the opposite extreme, exchanges are a form of trading where allowances are turned into stan- dardized commodities and are freely traded. For exam- ple, in the United States, SO2 allowances are traded on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange. The Hunter River Salinity Trading Scheme in Australia may also be considered an example of an exchange, although in this case, the government is responsible for trades (NSWDEC, 2003). Water quality markets can be classified in a number of ways. One useful way to categorize markets is based on would have required all power plants to install scrub- bers on their smokestacks to remove sulfur diox- ide (SO2). Lawmakers instead opted for a bold policy experiment, setting a cap on total SO2 emissions, and allowing polluters to buy and sell pollution allowances. Under this system, emissions from individual sources could rise or fall, as long as the total annual emissions stayed the same. The central idea was that allowing trading puts a price on pollution, and, in turn, encour- ages cost savings, efficiency, and innovation. In most WQT markets, a cap is put on water pollutants. In the United States, the cap is usually set by state gov- ernments, which are responsible for regulating water quality in rivers, lakes, and estuaries. The cap should be based on a scientific analysis of how much pollutant a water body can assimilate without being excessively degraded, which is referred to as a total maximum daily load (TMDL). Government regulators issue pollution allowances, often referred to as “credits”, to existing polluters. For example, a credit may allow a facility to discharge one pound of phosphorus to a river. A facility manager may choose to install pollution-control tech- nologies that limit emissions. If a facility’s emissions decrease to below its permitted level, this frees up additional credits that managers may then sell to other polluters. There typically may be two types of buyers that create a demand for credits: i) new entrants to the market, such as a new factory in the watershed, or ii) existing polluters that may wish to or need to increase their emissions, e.g. a factory that wishes to increase output, or a sewage plant serving a growing commu- nity. Trading allows the industry greater freedom to operate as it sees fit. A low-performing facility may continue to pollute more heavily, but it will be required to purchase credits, making the cost of doing business more expensive. High-performers that can reduce their pollution levels create valuable pollution credits that they can sell, and this creates an incentive to invest in pollution controls, at least according to theory. To date, most water quality trading markets have been used to control pollution from nutrients that cause excessive algal growth and low dissolved oxygen
  • 61. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 41 right to discharge pollutants. Markets are also thought to foster innovation – where “innovative, entrepreneur- ial companies can profit from low-cost reductions in emissions. Slower, less innovative firms can benefit as well by having the opportunity to purchase needed emission allowances for less than it would cost them to comply internally” (Anderson, 2004). Moreover, cap- and-trade programs may provide greater certainty in the outcome. With a fixed or declining cap, policy mak- ers can be more certain of the environmental improve- ment that will be achieved, compared with alternative approaches such as best management practices or a pollution tax. Application A survey conducted by Bennett and Carroll (2014) for Forest Trends found that activity for WQT mar- kets is still relatively small, although it has shown large increases in the past several years. In 2013, the trading value of WQT markets was about $22.2 million. Much of that activity was concentrated in the United States, where WQT markets had a trading value of $11.1 mil- lion in 2013, with a cumulative total of $95 million since 2000. While there are currently over 30 water quality markets in place in the United States, some have seen no trading or only a few trades, even two decades after their establishment. Among the reasons cited for the lack of trading activity are high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty about the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate in the market (Shortle and Horan, 2008). While some of the longest-running markets are getting smaller, new programs in Oregon, Virginia, and Maryland have kept overall transaction values high. Indeed, in 2013, United States market activity was at its highest level ever recorded, although Bennet and Carroll (2014) posited that this likely represented recovery from the eco- nomic downturn rather than new growth. It is of note that New Zealand’s Lake Taupo Trading Program, a relatively new program, has rapidly become the largest in the world, with at least $10.2 million in transactions in 2013. However, the future of that market is uncertain because “that market’s biggest buyer, the Lake Taupo Protection Trust, announced in June 2013 it would the regulatory system that drives the demand for trad- ing and whether it includes a cap on total emissions (Anderson, 2004). This includes both cap-and-trade systems and credit systems. Cap-and-trade systems put a limit on the total amount of allowed releases of pollution. They seek a specific environmental result (a cap), and trading allowances to release pollution are simply an option to minimize the cost of achieving the emission reductions specified in the regulatory cap. In the cap-and-trade approach, allowances for future emissions are sold or granted to existing sources. Credit systems, on the other hand, do not establish any fixed ceiling on total emissions. Total emissions can increase if new sources of pollution enter the market, or if existing sources increase their outputs. In uncapped systems, tradable credits are earned for controlling pol- lution beyond what is specified in one’s permit. The literature is full of descriptions of the potential benefits of water quality trading compared with the more conventional “command-and-control” approach, where regulators allocate the right to pollute by impos- ing limits on individual polluters (Shortle and Horan, 2005). In particular, WQT markets are thought to be a less-costly, more-efficient alternative. When the total amount of pollutant emissions in a region is capped, the right to pollute becomes a scarce commodity and, as many economists assert, markets are the most effi- cient way of allocating a scarce commodity.26 WQT programs allow polluters to interact in the marketplace and decide among themselves how to allocate the 26 While economic theory says that trading will lead to the most efficient allocation of a resource, it says little about distributional effects, i.e. who pays and who benefits, or other market “externalities”. “WQT programs allow polluters to interact in the marketplace and decide among themselves how to allocate the right to discharge pollutants.”
  • 62. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT42 in the Reagan, George H.W. Bush, and George W. Bush administrations, “and were once strongly condemned by liberals and environmentalists” (Schmalensee and Stavins, 2012). The key element for overcoming con- servative politicians’ resistance to the policy was to replace regulation with a free market; the market would operate on its own with no intervention by the govern- ment, a step that would “radically disempower the reg- ulators” (Conniff, 2009). However, this has not been the reality with most environmental markets, which have been designed with additional layers of government that oversee the market, monitor and enforce emis- sions limits, and facilitate and verify trades. By contrast, there are alternative pollution control policies that are simpler and require less government involvement, such as mandating the use of pollution-limiting technology or taxing pollution. There is some irony here, prompting one scholar to observe, “a putative form of rationaliza- tion or deregulation is in fact a case of ‘reregulation’” (Mariola 2009). As an example of how WQT markets work, consider the example of the Chesapeake Bay. To reduce nutri- ent discharge into the bay, regulators had the option of requiring wastewater plants to install expensive and technologically advanced treatment systems. Nitrogen removal costs for these systems are typically about $200 per pound per year (Jones et al., 2010). However, farms in the watershed are an even larger source of nitrogen, and removal costs are much lower, at $1 to $5 per pound per year. As a result, permitted dischargers have negotiated the ability to fulfill their permit require- ments by funding pollution control projects on farms in the watershed, such as planting winter cover crops, planting vegetation around streams (called riparian buffers), or installing permeable filter strips around animal feedlots. These agricultural “best management practices” reduce soil erosion and sediment runoff from farms, reducing the amount of nutrients washed into local waterways. Because they use soil and veg- etation to filter water and sediment, they are gener- ally low-tech and relatively inexpensive to install and maintain. The Chesapeake Bay WQT program was set up specifically to encourage these kinds of exchanges. withdraw from future trading, having made arrange- ments to achieve its remaining nitrogen reduction goals by purchasing and managing land in the catch- ment” (Bennett et al., 2014). The popularity of emissions trading for dealing with water pollution in the United States is largely a result of the Clean Water Act of 1972. The specifics of how the law was written and implemented have made it dif- ficult for governments to handle pollution from farms. In particular, the law made it illegal for “point source” dischargers, such as factories or wastewater treatment plants, to release pollutants into waterways without a permit, but did not attempt to regulate pollution from “nonpoint sources”, such as agriculture or urban run- off, since these were considered minor sources of pol- lution and believed to be difficult to regulate. In many watersheds, however, farms and feedlots are the larg- est source of pollutants. These nonpoint sources are exempt from most water pollution regulations, and there appears to be insufficient will to remedy this. Forty years after passage of the landmark law, some 40 percent of America’s surface water fails to meet its water quality goals (Faeth, 2000). Further, a set of stud- ies in the 1990s showed that reducing nutrient pollution from agriculture could be 65 times more cost effective than imposing further controls on municipal or indus- trial sources. As a result, water quality regulators in the United States use WQT markets primarily as a tool to encourage point dischargers to fund nonpoint source pollution controls, largely because regulators lack the authority to deal with these sources of pollution. One factor contributing to the popularity of emis- sions trading is its appeal to conservative politicians due to their invocation of the “power of the market” (Conniff, 2009). The original cap-and-trade programs were policy innovations developed by conservatives “40 percent of America’s surface water fails to meet its water quality goals.”
  • 63. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 43 (Olszowa et al., 1998). Further, on-farm nutrient con- trols will do little to control other toxins that are present in coal ash, such as arsenic, lead, mercury, and heavy metals. However, the program is notable as it is the first program in the United States that has allowed the purchase of pollution control credits across state lines (Fox, 2014). In addition to the many markets in the United States, there are also examples of WQT markets in other regions, especially in Oceania: • Lake Taupo Nitrogen Trading Program (New Zea- land) • South Creek Bubble Licensing Scheme (Australia) • Murray-Darling Basin Salinity Credits Scheme (Australia) • South Nation River Watershed Trading Program (Canada) • Chao Lake Nutrient Trading Program (China, under consideration) Several European countries have shown interest in WQT. A literature review by Wind (2012) summarized 14 studies of the concept within the European Union. Despite this interest, no markets have been created to date, and it appears that EU directives limit the ability of states to set up markets. Perhaps the best example of a successful operating WQT market is on Australia’s Hunter River, where coal mines and other sources are subject to discharge lim- its to protect water quality and drinking water sources in downstream cities. Saline soils are present through- out Australia, and during coal mining, salty water col- lects in mine pits and shafts and has to be pumped out to allow mining operations to continue (NSWDEC, 2003). The Hunter River Basin had a history of conflict among users, with mining activities making the water unsuitable for irrigation, and new mine proposals facing extremely high costs. The state government, following years of study and collaboration with stakeholders, set a cap on salinity levels in the river, and put a system of tradable discharge credits in place. Trading allows regulated polluters to meet their per- mitted discharge requirement at a much lower cost than with technology. Further, it helps to finance pollu- tion reduction from the agricultural sector, which gen- erates about 44 percent of the nutrients entering the bay. A recent assessment concluded that controlling discharges from agriculture is necessary to restore the bay (Steinzor et al., 2012). A second noteworthy example of a domestic WQT market is the relatively new Ohio River Basin Water Quality Trading Project developed by the Electric Power Research Institute, the research arm of the United States electric power industry. Coal-fired power plants in the Ohio River Basin are a major source of nitrogen pollution in rivers, due to their using water in scrubbers for air pollution control and to sluice the coal ash out of reactors (US EPA, 2009). The ash and water slurry most often goes into storage and treat- ment ponds that provide only a minimal level of treat- ment and where spills and illicit discharges have been common (Zucchino, 2015). Under the pilot program, power plants and other interested parties can pay for nonpoint source pollution reductions on farms, another major source of pollution in the watershed. Because on-farm improvements are much less expensive than installing wastewater treatment facilities, power plants stand to save $500,000 to $800,000 per year (EPRI, 2010). The first projects are creating nutrient reduction credits through “activities like planting cover crops and creat- ing treatment wetlands for animal wastes” (Ecosystem Marketplace, 2015). The program is notable for its thor- oughness in documenting projects, posting a descrip- tion and photos of every project on the Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI) website, and using a stan- dard methodology for calculating the reduced pollution in farm runoff. The program is credited with reducing pollution by 100,000 pounds of nutrients between 2013 and 2015 (Barrett 2015). While commendable, this proj- ect is a small pilot, and pollutant reductions are small compared with the estimates of over 3 million pounds of nitrogen entering the watershed’s rivers every day
  • 64. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT44 at how WQT markets have performed environmentally, economically, and socially. ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE While there are no comprehensive analyses of the envi- ronmental performance of WQT programs in general, there are several examples of successful programs. In the application section of 3.3, we cited Australia’s Hunter River as one example. Indeed, since formation of the program, river water quality has met standards nearly 100 percent of the time, protecting water sup- plies to downstream irrigators and cities. This hap- pened despite the establishment of new, potentially highly polluting mines in the watershed. The Alpine Cheese Company Nutrient Trading Program in Ohio is another notable success. As a part of this program, the company helped fund pollution reduction projects on local farms, paying 25 farmers to install 91 conserva- tion measures that resulted in a 3,000-pound-per-year phosphorus reduction (US EPA, 2010). A United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA) 2010 evaluation of the program found that it exceeded its nutrient reduction goals, and estimated that “conservation measures would reduce up to three times more nutrients than if equal funds were used for wastewater treatment upgrades.” It is noteworthy that the project has also been praised by the local chapter of the Sierra Club, which has strongly opposed the cre- ation of larger WQT schemes in other areas that could allow industry to continue implementing poor practices by purchasing offsets (Marida, 2010). Likewise, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit Exchange Program – currently the largest in the United States – was created in 2002 to reduce nitrogen pollution to Long Island Sound from the Connecticut River. Under the program, which covers 79 sewage treatment plants in the state of Connecticut, a plant can control pollu- tion in excess of its permit requirement and sell excess nitrogen allowances to those plants that exceed their allowances. A 2012 review of the program suggested that the program had helped the state meet its environ- mental goals while lowering overall costs (Stacey et al., 2012). The program helped reduce nitrogen loading by Under this system, no discharges of salty water are allowed when the river is in low flow. When the river is in high flow and its capacity to dilute salty inflows is greater, limited discharge is allowed, controlled by a system of salt credits. Permitted dischargers coor- dinate their activities so that the total salt concen- tration in the river never goes above a specified limit. Industries can buy and sell salt credits in real time via a trading website run by the state government. Several years after the program began, the trading program is popular among participants and functioning smoothly. The state government has set up real-time monitor- ing to make sure the river water quality meets stan- dards, and to monitor for permit violations. Perhaps the biggest marker of the program’s success is that new, potentially highly polluting mines have been estab- lished, but river water quality has met standards nearly 100 percent of the time. Environmental, economic, and social performance Despite the fact that water quality trading markets have existed for three decades in some areas, it is difficult to state whether they can be considered an overall success. In making such an evaluation, we must determine whether desired pollution reductions were achieved and water quality targets attained. We must also examine how the result compared with what would have occurred under another form of management: were the pollution reductions greater, did they occur more quickly, or at a lower cost? Moreover, there is a great deal of literature about water quality trading and market-based solutions to water pollution but few real-world evaluations of existing WQT markets. Much of the literature about markets is theoretical and oriented toward “making the case” for WQT, e.g. describing how a market can or should be set up. Below, we examine the available evidence looking “…there is a great deal of literature … but few real-world evaluations of existing WQT markets.”
  • 65. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 45 In an assessment of three mature WQT programs in the United States, one scholar concluded that there had been very little benefit as a direct result of trades. However, the programs had an unexpected benefit: they broughttogetherwatershedstakeholdersandincreased “the institutional capacity for watershed management” (Wallace, 2007). Stakeholders coming together around a common goal of improving water quality also helped lower resistance to new, more stringent water quality regulations. Wallace concluded that the markets them- selves were not important mechanisms for reducing pollution. Rather, their presence contributed to “unin- tended contributions to increased pollution regulation and management on a watershed scale.” So, on the one hand, these markets could be considered failures by some observers because many of them had seen no trading even decades after their creation. The lack of trades can be explained by a number of fac- tors: high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty about the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate in the market. On the other hand, even where little or no trading occurred, water quality and governance had improved in the three watersheds evaluated by Wallace (2007). It is not always possible to disentangle how much of a role the market played in bringing about these improvements. On the one hand, financial transactions have not played a large role, tempting us to conclude that the markets were relatively unimportant. However, if discussion of the use of “market fundamentals” helped overcome resistance to environmental regulation and paved the way toward decreased pollution, then we may conclude that markets were a key feature in improving water quality, albeit indirectly. ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE It is difficult to assess the economic performance of WQT markets and how their economic performance compares with alternative forms of pollution control. To date, the size and impact of water quality markets is relatively small. There is some information in the litera- ture on the number of trades that have occurred, and the prices paid for water quality credits. In the applica- tion section of 3.3, we cited a Forest Trends study that over 50 percent over 10 years, and was on track to meet water quality goals by 2014. As a result, the area of Long Island Sound suffering from hypoxia (low dissolved oxy- gen which is fatal to wildlife) had steadily declined. Despite these examples, most water quality trading programs in the United States are either too small or have seen too little trading to make a meaningful dif- ference on water quality. For example, a 2012 evalua- tion of Ohio’s Great Miami Nutrient Trading Program called it “one of the most successful programs to date” (Newburn and Woodward, 2012). In 2009, the trading program attracted $1.3 million in trades and helped fund 100 projects that reduced nutrient pollution by 800,000 pounds per year. Proposed projects submitted by farm- ers in the watershed covered a variety of agricultural “best management practices” designed to prevent sedi- ment and nutrients from entering waterways. Evaluators concluded that the program “has been successful in developing both supply and ensuring funding for agri- cultural pollution abatement projects compared to other WQT programs” (Newburn and Woodward, 2012). Despite this, they found that the program had not likely had a significant effect on regional water quality due to the “relatively minor role that the trading program has had on nutrient management in the watershed to date.” To date, the projects have simply been too small and too few to have a major impact. The Great Miami River watershed drains 748 square miles, the majority of which is cultivated, so a much larger investment would be needed to meaningfully improve water quality in the basin. This example highlights the caution needed when interpreting large numbers cited by market proponents. While 800,000 pounds sounds like a lot (and is indeed a worthwhile accomplishment), it pales in comparison with the estimated 1 trillion pounds of nitrogen enter- ing the Ohio River watershed each year (Olszowa et al., 1998). Like most WQT markets in the United States, the Greater Miami Basin program did not emerge from a cap on pollutants. Rather, it was created as a way to allow regulated point-source dischargers, such as factories and sewage plants, to lower their costs by paying for pollution controls on farms rather than installing expen- sive pollution control measures at their own facilities.
  • 66. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT46 improving the environment and supporting the local economy, and also experienced other indirect benefits from the project, “by fencing cows out of streams, bac- teria levels in milk were decreased, giving the farmers a premium price for milk and reducing costs for Alpine [Cheese Company]” (Marida, 2010). As described previously, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit Exchange Program is currently one of the larg- est WQT programs in operation. An evaluation of the program in 2012 suggested that the program has helped the state meet its environmental goal of reduc- ing nitrogen loading to Long Island Sound while lower- ing overall costs. The state estimated that, in the first 10 years of the program, trading had lowered costs by $300 to $400 million below what individual facilities would have had to pay for equivalent pollution reduc- tions (Stacey et al., 2012). SOCIAL PERFORMANCE There is little research on the social impacts of WQT, and much of what we describe in this section is based on anecdotal evidence. Critics of environmental mar- kets have raised questions about their fairness and justice. A specific concern relates to how regulators distribute pollution permits at the outset of market cre- ation. Under a market system, pollution permits become valuable commodities to be bought and sold. In many cases, as in SO2 trading in the United States, the gov- ernment grants allowances to industries for free, based on their historic emissions. Critics point out that such “grandfathering” of permits rewards those polluters most responsible for environmental problems in the first place. It may also unfairly burden more recent mar- ket entrants, because they have no history of polluting and no “free” permits, yet would be required to purchase credits to offset 100 percent of their emissions. There are, however, different ways of issuing credits that help mitigate these concerns. For example, rather than giv- ing away credits, they could be sold to polluters in an auction, as has been proposed in carbon markets. Critics have also raised concerns about the fairness of water quality markets to potential sellers of water qual- ity credits. Consider a farmer who installed pollution estimated the value of the United States water quality tradingmarketas$11.1millionin2013,intermsofthetotal value of payments. To put these numbers in perspec- tive, state and local governments in the United States spent $70 billion on sanitation and sewerage in 2008 (US Census Bureau, 2012). Despite these investments, many argue that the United States should be spending much more to control water pollution. Researchers at Kansas State found that nutrient pollution from nitro- gen and phosphorus cost the United States $2.2 bil- lion in 2008, due to losses in recreational water usage, waterfront real estate, spending on recovery of threat- ened and endangered species, and increased treatment for drinking water (Dodds et al., 2008). While limited data are available, advocates for WQT markets cite the lower overall cost of improving water quality as their main advantage, as compared with more conventional means of water pollution control. There is local evidence for this, especially in smaller markets. Take the case of the Alpine Cheese Company, in Ohio’s Sugar Creek watershed. The plant was faced with expensive wastewater treatment upgrades to satisfy Clean Water Act permit requirements (US EPA, 2010). These upgrades would likely have cost over $1 million to install, plus ongoing costs for operation and mainte- nance.Instead,thecompanycollaboratedwithothersto reduce pollution through projects at farms in the water- shed that have a much lower cost per pound of phos- phorus prevented from entering streams, and which are expected to last 15 to 20 years (Moore, 2012). The company worked with universities, regulators, and local agricultural extension services, providing $800,000 over five years for planning, technical assistance, and outreach. In addition, these measures allowed the plant to expand, creating 12 new jobs. Further, the project provided funding to chronically cash-strapped local soil and water conservation districts and to the local agricultural economy. Local dairy farmers took pride in “…advocates for WQT markets cite the lower overall cost of improving water quality as their main advantage…”
  • 67. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 47 communal ownership makes it slower and more diffi- cult to develop land. In a sense, those most responsible for past pollution have been rewarded with large (and valuable) pollution permits, while the Maori community will face higher costs to develop their lands economi- cally. In response to these concerns, regulators altered the market design by relaxing the cap somewhat “to ease the restrictive nature of historical allocation on Tuwharetoa [Maori] and other forest owners” (Duhon et al., 2011). In the New Zealand case study, program managers realized the importance of dealing with issues of race and historical justice in order to make the program suc- cessful. In the United States, some program managers have also sought to address issues related to age and gender. For example, the Ohio River Basin Water Quality Trading Project directs money from the electric power industry to farmers to support on-farm improvements to reduce runoff and pollution. A concern was raised early on that the early adopters would be all younger, male farmers (Jessica Fox, EPRI, personal communica- tion, 2015) because they would be more open to new ideas. Also, there are fewer woman-owned farms in the region compared with those owned by men. As a result, the managers of this program have made a particular effort to involve women farmers and older farmers. Some critics have suggested that WQT programs could perpetuate or worsen environmental justice problems. The environmental justice movement in the United States has focused on the fact that pollution often occurs in areas where many poor and minority people live or work, and that disadvantaged communities bear an unfair burden of exposure to pollution. There is a possibility that trading could allow pollution “hot spots” to continue, with accompanying environmental jus- tice concerns. For example, a polluter could purchase credits instead of making onsite pollution reductions. controls before a WQT program was established. Unlike his (polluting) neighbors, he would not be eligible for financing under the program. Thus, the program would reward “notorious polluters” rather than the good stew- ards, “because the good steward had already reduced pollution” (Ruppert, 2004). Despite these criticisms, there are several examples of WQT markets that have been considered successful, and earned support from industry, famers, regulators, and environmentalists. As was discussed previously, the Alpine Cheese Company Trading Program in Ohio was a very small market that involved the purchase of credits from 25 farmers by a local cheese company. Many of the farm- ers already did business with Alpine Cheese, selling milk from their dairy herds, and have a strong inter- est in maintaining a strong agricultural economy. One observer wrote that, “socially, community has been built with the farmers taking pride in working together, their more sustainable farming practices and in seeing the success of the factory” (Marida, 2010). One sees a similar outcome in an evaluation of the Hunter River Salinity Trading Scheme in Australia. Where there was once “significant conflict between primary producers and mining operators,” today, “agriculture, mining and electricity generation operate side by side, sharing the use of the river” (NSWDEC, 2003). Here, a history of conflict has been replaced by cooperation. This did not happen overnight, and required many years of pains- taking consultation and negotiation. In New Zealand, concerns have been raised about how the Lake Taupo Nutrient Trading Scheme affects differ- ent types of landowners, particularly indigenous Maori people. In this area, dairy farms and grazing were cre- ating polluted runoff, negatively impacting a freshwa- ter lake important for fishing and tourism. Regulators instituted a cap on nitrogen pollution seeking to main- tain water quality at year 2000 levels. Larger corpo- rate landowners were given more pollution credits based on their historical use of the land, while Maori landowners had not yet fully developed their lands (MOTU, 2009). There are historical and cultural rea- sons why Maoris have been slower to develop their lands: they did not own some lands until recently, and “Some critics have suggested that WQT programs could perpetuate or worsen environmental justice problems.”
  • 68. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT48 States, the Clean Water Act established the concept of “designated use” for waterways (i.e. swimmable, boat- able, or fishable), with water quality standards then developed based on the designated use. The process of developing a standard requires understanding the basic physical, environmental, and human elements of the watershed. Generally, scientists or engineers collect data and use computer models to determine the natu- ral and human pollution sources (i.e. diffuse nonpoint sources and point discharges). They also use models to determine how much of a pollutant a water body can assimilate while restoring or maintaining beneficial uses. The second necessary condition is that polluters have the ability to create water quality improvements, or reduce pollutant discharge through technology or management. Further, the regulator must be able to verify that these pollution reductions are real and likely to last. Verification of credits can be cumbersome and time consuming, which can inhibit trading. Regulators may require field visits or photos to show that on- farm improvements have been properly installed and maintained. In the case of the Alpine Cheese Trading Program, soil conservation agents ensure that pollu- tion control measures installed on farms meet “strin- gent engineering specifications” (Mariola, 2009). Implementation requires up to eight visits to a farm from project start to finish, and a full-time agent is required to coordinate a program involving one credit buyer and 25 farmers. In some cases, however, the role of verification falls to a trusted intermediary, as in the case of the South Nation River Program in Canada, where a conservation nonprofit hires local farmers to conduct field inspections (O’Grady, 2011). More often however, inspections and record-keeping are con- ducted by state or local governments. According to the US EPA, “mechanisms for determining and ensur- ing compliance may include a combination of record This was the subject of a 2013 lawsuit by Food & Water Watch against the Chesapeake Bay Nutrient Trading Program, which was later dismissed by a federal judge (Hauter, 2013). Trading programs are most effective when they cover pollutants with “far-field” impacts, meaning their effects are felt over a large area or over a long time period. Indeed, a thriving market under a cap could allow pollu- tion hot spots to continue unchecked, and thus would be inappropriate for regulating pollutants which have acute local impacts. “This is the reason no one has seri- ously contemplated a market for toxics,” according to Cy Jones, a World Resources Institute (WRI) senior fellow (personal communication, 2015). This issue is less important when trading operates within discrete basins. The larger the basin in which trading is allowed, the more chance there is to exacerbate hotspots. For this reason, some programs have rules restricting trad- ing to smaller sub-watersheds, as has been done in the Ohio River program described above. Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions In this section, we discuss the minimum conditions that are necessary for the creation and successful opera- tion of a water quality market, followed by a discussion of conditions that can enable WQT markets. These enabling factors will increase the market’s likelihood of succeeding but may not be required for it to be estab- lished. Finally, we discuss factors which may limit WQT markets by acting as barriers or obstacles. Necessary conditions for a successful water quality trading program include the following three circum- stances. The first is the presence of a regulator and its ability to set a cap on pollutants, monitor pollution, and verify the legitimacy of water quality credits that are created. Thus, the regulator must have the scien- tific and technical capacity to set water quality goals, and monitor water quality to ensure that those goals are being met. To do so first requires a set of “desired future conditions” for a particular waterbody. This may be set by law, custom, or local preferences. In the United “It is one thing to set up a water quality market; it is another for active trading to take place.”
  • 69. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 49 Enabling conditions required for creation of a water quality trading program go beyond these basics. First, the government regulator must have the authority to set discharge limits to protect waterways. Second, the regulator needs the power to issue and enforce water pollution discharge permits. Enforcement, with the threat of meaningful fines or criminal penalties, is especially important. As Abraham Lincoln famously noted, “laws without enforcement are just good advice.” Finally, there must be a legal framework by which trad- ing can take place. It is one thing to set up a water quality market; it is another for active trading to take place. As we have shown, many United States markets have been largely moribund. The following presents what we consider enabling conditions – meaning governments can set up a market without them, but there may be little or no trading. It would be tempting to classify an idle mar- ket as a failure, but as we have also seen, some United States markets have seen little trading, but they have been accompanied by an improvement in watershed stewardship and improvements to the environment. There must be a demand for water quality credits. Demand is the first and foremost enabling condition for trades to take place. Generally, such demand is created by a strong regulatory or non-regulatory driver.27 In the case of the Alpine Cheese Nutrient Trading Program described above, factory owners wished to expand pro- duction, but were unable to do so because of a restric- tive discharge permit. Violating the permit could have resulted in fines or criminal charges. The factory own- ers faced otherwise undesirable options: they could 27 An example of a non-regulatory driver could be where industrial emitters decide among themselves to voluntarily limit pollution to gain goodwill or in an attempt to pre-empt regulation. This is the case in the Ohio River study discussed above, where electric power companies have funded projects to reduce pollution from farms in their watersheds. These activities are not compulsory, so why would a for-profit corpora- tion do it? Their motivation, as put forth by the program’s manager in Congressional testimony is “to meet corporate sustainability goals and their voluntary participation may also be considered by the state permit- ting agencies when determining the need for flexible permit compliance options in the future” (Fox 2014). In other words, she was saying that companies hope that their activities today will buy them goodwill with regulators and that future regulation will be less burdensome as a result. keeping, monitoring, reporting and inspections” (US EPA, 2003). There are other aspects of regulatory oversight necessary to ensure accountability on behalf of both buyers and sellers of credits. This oversight includes many aspects of a trading program: • establishing trading eligibility • tracking of trades • verification of credit generation • compliance and enforcement • monitoring of results • program assessment. It is especially difficult and usually impractical to mea- sure nonpoint source pollution reductions, for example, from projects designed to reduce polluted runoff from farms. The pollution source is usually spread out, and there is no obvious place to measure the discharge (as there would be at the outfall of a factory). Nonpoint source pollution also tends to be “episodic”, occur- ring when rainfall flushes pollutants into waterways, further thwarting measurement efforts. Regulators have adopted several approaches to deal with these issues. Nonpoint source pollution reductions are most often estimated based on prior studies or modeling. To address the uncertainty associated with these esti- mates, regulators may place a higher burden for pol- lution reductions on nonpoint sources. Indeed, some markets have been designed with “trading ratios” where nonpoint source reductions trade against point sources at a ratio of 2:1 or 3:1. The third necessary condition is an appropriate legal framework enabling trading. Some of the legal require- ments for water quality trading are similar to those for other market-based instruments. Broadly, programs require a legal environment that will uphold the rights of buyers and sellers. Some basics, as outlined by Greiber (2009), include: • a legal system that recognizes agreements must be kept • a civil law providing contract parties with legal rem- edies to enforce contract rights in cases of non- compliance with contract obligations • general respect for the rule of law.
  • 70. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT50 (2013), economists from MIT and Harvard who studied the program, concluded that, by all accounts, it was a major success: following its launch in 1995, the market performed “exceptionally well along all relevant dimen- sions” and helped the United States reach emissions goals in 2006. However, the market’s collapse should be a cautionary tale: “When the government creates a market, it can also destroy it, possibly fostering a legacy of increased regulatory uncertainty and reduced investor confi- dence in future cap-and-trade regimes, and hence reduced credibility of pollution markets more broadly” (Schmalensee and Stavins, 2013). Trust among market participants is a key element of any WQT program. In the United States, most water quality markets involve point sources purchasing pol- lution reduction credits from farms, or less frequently, from forests or other nonpoint sources. Controlling nonpoint source pollution from agriculture faces unique obstacles. Farmers often distrust regulators, and worry that participation in a trading program may open the door to future regulation. Some pilot pro- grams in the United States have worked through local soil and water conservation districts, or made use of agricultural extension services, because the farmers know and trust these agents. In fact, Mariola (2009) found the most important factor for program success was “the use of a local, trusted, embedded intermediary as the link between programs and farmers emerges as the most important explanatory variable for program success.” Canadian WQT managers have come to similar conclu- sions. In the South Nation River watershed, wastewater dischargers face a cap on phosphorus discharge, and new wastewater systems are purchasing phosphorus relocate the factory, install expensive onsite wastewater treatment, or stop production altogether. In Australia’s Hunter River, salty discharge from mines was affecting the drinking water supplies for downstream cities, and an inflexible basin cap would have meant that existing mines could not expand and new industries could not develop. In other cases, industries are interested in mit- igating their own pollution to create goodwill or to help lessen the burden of future regulation. This is the case for power companies in the Ohio River Basin. At pres- ent, large power companies such as Duke Energy, the largest electric power holding company in the United States with some 7.3 million customers, and American Electric Power, which has over 5 million customers, pur- chase credits “to meet corporate sustainability goals and their voluntary participation may also be consid- ered by the state permitting agencies when determin- ing the need for flexible permit compliance options in the future” (Fox, 2014). In addition to demand, there must be willingness to engage in trade among buyers and sellers. One observer cited the most frequent roadblock to estab- lishing a WQT program as the “simple absence of willing buyers and sellers” (O’Grady, 2011). In WQT markets, demand for the commodity (pollution credits) “is artificially created by regulatory decree and which cannot be seen or felt or even measured with preci- sion” (Mariola, 2009). Because the market is entirely dependent on a regulatory driver, it can be fragile and susceptible to interference by politicians or the courts. For example, the United States Acid Rain Program (ARP), the nation’s first national cap-and-trade pro- gram, suffered a series of legal challenges beginning in 2008, culminating in new rules in 2011 that severely limited trading between states. As a result, the market, which relied heavily on interstate trading, collapsed. In 2012, the market value of a credit to emit a ton of sulfur dioxide was less than $1. Previously, these same credits had sold for $100 to $200 for most of the last decade and peaked at $1,200 per ton in 2005 (Schmalensee and Stavins, 2013). The ARP’s collapse is worth paus- ing to consider, as it was the model for all subsequent environmental markets. Schmalensee and Stavins “In addition to demand, there must be willingness to engage in trade among buyers and sellers.”
  • 71. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 51 The ability to trade water quality credits across regional borders may be an important enabling condition, depending on the geography of the watershed. Many important watersheds extend across multiple states, or across international boundaries. When trades can only take place within a single state or country, it reduces the potential for trading and for water quality improve- ments (Fisher-Vanden and Olmstead, 2013). In 2012, the pilot Ohio River Basin Trading Program became the first program in the United States to allow trad- ing across state borders, with an agreement signed by the states of Ohio, Kentucky, and Indiana (Fox, 2014). Lessons learned from the Acid Rain Program sug- gest that legislation may be necessary for interstate programs: “the series of regulations, court rulings, and regulatory responses ... affirmed that EPA cannot set up an interstate trading system under the Clean Air Act in the absence of specific legislation” (Schmalensee and Stavins, 2013). Limiting conditions for water quality trading may be created by existing laws, policies, and institutions in some regions. Greiber (2009) described a number of possible concerns related to the legal and institutional frameworks for environmental markets. Unrelated laws may contradict the aims of a market by, for example, providing perverse incentives to polluting industries or restricting innovative ways of funding environmental projects. Land tenure is a key concern in some coun- tries, as farmers without tenure may have little incen- tive to participate in programs if they do not own land and their futures are more uncertain. credits from rural landowners, mainly farmers. Initially, the agricultural community had reservations about the program. One of the main concerns raised by farmers during the design of the South Nation program was their future liability. Organizers confronted this concern during a series of public meetings and then added a key phrase to their final document that addressed the farmers’ concerns and allowed trading to begin (O’Grady, 2011) – the phrase was: “Landowners are not bound, legally or otherwise, to attain the predicted phosphorus offset through the establishment of a BMP [best manage- ment practice, another term for an on-farm pollution control measure] on their property.” Further, control of the program was granted to South Nation Conservation, a community-based watershed organization that was trusted by farmers. In addition, the program is run by a multi-stakeholder committee, “and all project field visits are done by farmers and not paid professionals.” As a result, the program has been able to overcome much of the early resistance. An independent evaluation showed that most farmers had a high opinion of the program and have recommend the program to other farmers in their community (O’Grady, 2011). “When trades can only take place within a single state or country, it reduces the potential for … water quality improvements.”
  • 73. 4 Role of the private sector INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 53 The private sector participates to some degree in all of the instruments described in the previous section. For example, in Michigan’s Paw Paw River Watershed, Coca-Cola North America and other stakeholders recently developed and implemented a performance- based PWS program to compensate farmers for imple- menting practices that reduce soil loss and enhance groundwater recharge (Forest Trends, 2015b). The pri- vate sector also participates as a buyer or seller in water quality trading programs to comply with water quality regulations, or buys or sells water rights through water trading programs. In addition to these incentive-based instruments, the private sector may participate in a range of voluntary initiatives to, for example, restore or protect a watershed or provide water service to local communities. Moreover, they may employ incentives within their direct operations or supply chains to pro- mote water stewardship. In this section, we describe some of the drivers for private sector engagement in water stewardship, provide examples of their participa- tion in incentive-based programs, and provide an initial estimate of their investment in these programs. 4.1 Corporate water stewardship To produce goods and services, most companies rely on a consistent supply of adequate quality source water and permission to discharge wastewater. As population growth and economic development push the limits of renewable freshwater supplies and busi- ness-as-usual resource management strategies, and as rapid urbanization, water pollution, groundwater deple- tion, and climate change introduce new water-related risks, companies face increasing urgency to respond. Companies typically come to understand their relation- ship to water in terms of their water footprint and their water-related business risk. A water footprint assess- ment – which estimates the volume of water consumed and polluted in the production of a material or a prod- uct, or in the operation of an entire business, industry, or nation – can help managers more fully understand the nature and extent of a company’s dependence and impact on water resources. It is also appealing as a basis for setting targets to reduce water use related to, for example, manufacturing processes or production of agricultural raw materials. While a water footprint assessment can inform a risk assessment, a volumetric footprint measurement omits the local context neces- sary to characterize the risks related to water use, and obscures the difference in impact between using water “Companies … understand their relationship to water in terms of their water footprint and their water-related business risk.”
  • 74. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT54 Effective water resource management systems and regulatory frameworks, the performance of which can be enhanced by incentive-based instruments, benefit companies in a number of ways. • As water users, companies benefit from a more reli- able and higher quality supply of water. • As polluters, businesses benefit from opportunities to manage the cost of compliance over time, and to seek innovative approaches to improve the quality and reduce the volume of wastewater. • As ratepayers and taxpayers, companies benefit by avoiding the cost of adding new or expanding ex- isting supply. Efforts to reduce water-related business risks typically occur at three scales: within direct operations, in supply chain agricultural or manufacturing operations that are not within a company’s direct control, or outside the fenceline of both owned and supply chain properties, where water-related risks are driven more by sociopo- litical, hydrological, or ecological conditions than by the actions of the company or its suppliers. from a source that’s plentiful and using the same vol- ume of water from a source that’s overexploited or not readily replenished.28 Water-related business risks generally fall into three broad and interrelated categories: • physical risks include scarcity, degraded source water quality, and flooding • regulatory risks relate to inconsistent, ineffective, or poorly enforced public policy, particularly when a change in regulation or enforcement could dis- rupt production or lead to an unexpected cost of compliance • reputational risks are faced by companies that overexploit or are perceived to overexploit water resources – including inefficient use, water pollu- tion, excessive withdrawal, competition with other users, or other negligent water-related activities. All three categories of risk include financial impacts from increased operating costs, fines or unplanned capital expenditures, supply chain disruptions, damage to the value of a brand, or lost access to markets. Increasingly, businesses are taking steps to identify, characterize, and mitigate these risks. For example, the Aqueduct Water Risk Atlas, a web-based tool produced by the World Resources Institute, identifies which and how many locations in a company’s operations or sup- ply chain face water-related risk in 12 dimensions, as shown in Figure 7. The Water Risk Filter, an online tool launched by the World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF) and the German Investment and Development Corporation (DEG), assigns each water-using location a score that incorporates both location-specific and company-specific risks, based on criteria such as the average water intensity or typical level of water pol- lution generated by suppliers to a particular industry sector (WWF and DEG, 2014). 28 Water “neutrality” or “offsets” are related concepts, similar to carbon neutrality or carbon offsets. They imply that a company can compen- sate for the negative impacts of its water footprint. However, there is no standard for measuring negative impacts or defining which types and how much of any given activity is sufficient compensation (Hoekstra et al., 2011). Baseline water stress Inter-annual variability Seasonal variability Flood occurence Droughtseverity Upstream storage Groundwater Stress Return flow ratio Upstream protected land Media coverage Access to water Threatened amphibians Physical Risk Quantity Physical Risk Quality Regulatory and Reputational Risk OVERALL WATER RISK FIGURE 7. Water risk indicators Source: Gassert et al., 2013.
  • 75. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 55 Another recent development is the idea of engag- ing outside the fenceline. Leading companies under- stand that collective action with other stakeholders at the watershed scale may be required to address root causes of resource scarcity, accessibility, or source water quality, which can increase costs or disrupt operations. The Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER), a coalition of business leaders in an industry that faces substantial water-related repu- tational risk, has acknowledged that in some locations, watershed-level interventions may in fact be more effective at mitigating water-related risk than facility- level water-use efficiency or other activities (BIER, 2015). To assist companies in prioritizing their efforts, BIER has proposed developing a decision support tool that could give more priority to intervention outside the fenceline than to internal efficiency or water quality improvements. 4.2 Private sector engagement with incentive-based instruments Private sector participation in incentive-based instru- ments, such as PWS and water quality trading, has been relatively modest but is growing. Bennett and Carroll (2014) found that in 2013, the private sector invested US$41 million in watershed services that supported “watershed restoration or protection that delivers ben- efits to society.” While this represents more than twice the estimated private sector investment of $19 million to $26 million in 2011, it is still a very small portion of the overall $12.3 billion invested collectively in watersheds by governments, business, and individual donors in 2013. Most private sector watershed investment activ- ity (about 95  percent) took place in North America, Europe, and Africa (Bennett and Carroll, 2014). • Direct operations. Companies that recognize wa- ter-relatedbusinessrisksoftenbeginworkingvolun- tarily with direct operations – owned and operated offices, distribution or retail facilities, manufacturing facilities, farms or other means of production – to mitigate those risks. In direct operations, companies can plan and manage implementation internally and realize cost savings related to obtaining, pumping, heating, or treating smaller volumes of water when operational efficiencies are achieved. • Supply chains. From agricultural raw materials to water- and chemical-intensive manufacturing pro- cesses, most companies face challenges managing water-related business risks in their supply chains, including those with advanced water stewardship practices in their direct operations. In many cases, complex business models and limited traceability are significant obstacles to quantifying corporate water footprints and identifying water-related busi- ness risks that exist in global supply chains. • Outside the fenceline. Facilities that maintain industry average or better water efficiency and wastewater quality may not be immune to all wa- ter-related risks. The term “outside the fenceline” refers to conditions and activities outside the phys- ical footprint of a production site. Water-related risk is said to originate outside the fenceline in regions where, for example, source water is scarce or pol- luted, projected demand exceeds renewable sup- ply, regulations are inconsistent or nonexistent, or lack of access to water and sanitation damages public health. While internal process or policy changes are easier to implement, they would not necessarily mitigate these risks. The private sector increasingly recognizes the need to evaluate site-level water use in the context of its local watershed characteristics, in order to inform and prioritize efficiency targets for different locations. For example, companies can manage risk more effectively by giving higher priority to efficiency improvements for water-intensive locations in drought-prone locations than for similar facilities where water resources are more plentiful. “Most private sector watershed investment activity … took place in North America, Europe, and Africa.”
  • 76. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT56 provide opportunities for projects within the corpo- rate replenish initiative to directly mitigate risks in the global supply chain. Other projects’ impacts, such as those related to access to water and sanitation or ones where Coca-Cola contributed to a collective action together with other companies, are estimated differ- ently (Rozza et al., 2013). Disincentives for private sector investments. There are also disincentives for private sector invest- ments in public goods, including watershed services. The benefits must be shared with others that did not contribute to the investment, and the benefits could be exhausted by other actors that did not participate in the collective action or investment (Meißner, 2013). However, when the consequences of inaction are sig- nificant, there is a compelling case in favor of policy engagement, collective action, and investment in water-related initiatives outside the fenceline, includ- ing preservation of resources or delivery of ecosystem services via incentive-based instruments. Among the barriers that prevent the private sector from participating more fully in watershed investments are three critical core competencies needed to achieve measureable outcomes with specific benefits for at-risk locations, which most companies do not possess: • scientific and environmental engineering expertise to identify, design, and implement watershed-level solutions • a nuanced understanding of the local environment and culture in the watershed where they seek to have a positive environmental outcome • experience with partnerships involving diverse stakeholders outside the fenceline. Therefore, in cases where companies identify risk and choose to take action at the watershed level, particu- larly if they choose to do so in more than one location across diverse global operations or an extended supply chain, it is helpful and sometimes necessary to involve an intermediary. Stanton et al. (2010) defined an inter- mediary as “any party other than the buyer or seller who Incentives for private sector investments. Industry sectors with the highest levels of investment in water- shed services (IWS) were energy utilities, water utilities, and the food and beverage industry, with investments of US$9.3 million, $8.9 million, and $8.8 million, respec- tively. The primary reported motivation for spending on watershed services was regulatory compliance, followed by water availability risks, water quality risks, corporate social responsibility and reputational risk, and biodiversity protection (Bennett and Carroll, 2014). The food and beverage sector, which accounted for nearly one-quarter of the total corporate investment in watersheds, is unlike other sectors in that it is driven primarily by water availability and water risks, rather than regulatory compliance. Bennett and Carroll (2014) found that 88 percent of buyers in the food and bever- age industry acted voluntarily, compared with the pri- vate sector average of 31 percent. For example, in 2012–2013, the Coca-Cola Company and its global bottling partners were involved in 20 projects around the world, buying at least $2.2 mil- lion in watershed services (Bennett and Carroll, 2014). Separately, the company publishes annual reports detailing its involvement in hundreds of other projects (LimnoTech, 2013). Indeed, the Coca-Cola Company is among a handful of private companies with a public commitment to “replenish” the water it uses.29 However, as Coca-Cola acknowledges, the impacts of water use are specific and local, making it impossible for a multi- national corporation to offset water use at the enter- prise level. Rozza et al. (2013) described a detailed methodology for quantifying the value of Coca-Cola’s replenish projects, including source water protection, water reuse for conservation or productive uses, and community-level sustainability projects. The company also requires its bottling plants to complete source water vulnerability assessments and to engage in the development of source water protection plans, which 29 Specifically, Coca-Cola is “Collaborating to replenish the water we use”, pledging that by 2020, it will “safely return to communities and nature an amount of water equal to what we use in our finished beverages and their production.”
  • 77. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 57 are driving increased adoption of water risk assess- ment across the business community. For example, in its annual survey of leaders and decision makers about perceptions of global risks, the World Economic Forum (WEF, 2015) found that water crises have the greatest potential for impact and are the eighth most likely to occur, as shown in Figure 8. Moreover, WEF has consid- ered water among the top three global risks since 2012 (WEF, 2012; 2013; 2014). CDP, formerly known as the Carbon Disclosure Project, operates a water program that surveys companies helps facilitate some aspect of the transaction or imple- mentation of the overall program. This role is commonly played by NGOs, consultants, or academic institutions.” Indeed, Coca-Cola has had to coordinate large-scale bilateral partnerships with more than one intermediary in order to achieve progress toward its global replen- ish objective, including The Nature Conservancy, WWF, and the  United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). Table 3 illustrates increasing complexity and differences in motivation that companies face as they move from addressing efficiency in direct operations to engaging in collective action intended to create more sustainable operating conditions in watersheds where they do business. Future investments by the private sector are uncertain. However, consumer preference for more sustainable products and investor concern about unmitigated risk TABLE 3. Private sector activities, scale, drivers ACTIVITIES, COMPLEXITY, INCLUSIVITY Operational efficiency Wastewater quality Owned facilities Codes of conduct Social/environmental indices Voluntary sustainability standards Industry sector/association Policy engagement Collective action Diverse stakeholders SCALE Site-specific Small business Supply chain Small to medium enterprise Landscape Multinational TIME/VALUE Near-term, return on investment Medium-term, possible value capture Long-term, sustainability DRIVERS Financial self-interest Regulatory compliance Externalities License to operate Reputation Access to markets EXTERNAL CONDITIONS Strong governance and enforcement Inconsistent local regulation and enforcement Weak governance Negative externalities of other actors “…there is increasing awareness of water- specific issues and of best practices in corporate water stewardship…”
  • 78. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT58 Figure 1: The Global Risks Landscape 2015 4.54.03.5 5.0 5.5 4.0 4.5 5.0 4.82 average average 4.74 Likelihood Impact Top 10 risks in terms of Likelihood Categories Interstate conflict Extreme weather events Failure of national governance State collapse or crisis Unemployment or underemployment Natural catastrophes Failure of climate-change adaptation Water crises Data fraud or theft Cyber attacks Top 10 risks in terms of Impact Water crises Weapons of mass destruction Interstate conflict Energy price shock Failure of climate-change adaptation Fiscal crises Unemployment or underemployment Biodiversity loss and ecosystem collapse Spread of infectious diseases Critical information infrastructure breakdown 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 7.0 1.0 7.0 plotted area Economic Geopolitical Environmental Societal Technological Misuse of technologies Data fraud or theft Cyber attacks Critical information infrastructure breakdown Water crises Spread of infectious diseases Profound social instability Large-scale involuntary migration Food crises Failure of urban planning Weapons of mass destruction Terrorist attacks State collapse or crisis Interstate conflict Failure of national governance Natural catastrophes Man-made environmental catastrophes Failure of climate-change adaptation Biodiversity loss and ecosystem collapse Unmanageable inflation Unemployment or underemployment Fiscal crises Failure of critical infrastructure Energy price shock Deflation Asset bubble Extreme weather events Failure of financial mechanism or institution Source: Global Risks Perception Survey 2014. Note: Survey respondents were asked to assess the likelihood and impact of the individual risks on a scale of 1 to 7, 1 representing a risk that is not likely to happen or have impact, and 7 a risk very likely to occur and with massive and devastating impacts. See Appendix B for more details. To ensure legibility, the names of the global risks are abbreviated. Also see Appendix A for the full name and description. FIGURE 8: Global risks landscape, 2015 Note: Taken from 2014 Global Risks Perception Survey. Survey respondents were asked to assess the likelihood and impact of the individual risks on a scale of 1 to 7, 1 representing a risk that is not likely to happen or have impact, and 7 a risk very likely to occur and with massive and devastating impacts. See Appendix B for more details. To ensure legibility, the names of the global risks are abbreviated. Also see Appendix A for the full name and description. Source: World Economic Forum, 2015.
  • 79. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 59 Concurrently, there is increasing awareness of water- specific issues and of best practices in corporate water stewardship, so there will likely be demand for mecha- nisms that can deliver quantifiable outcomes to ben- efit specific corporate assets or at-risk strategic supply chain locations. Increased understanding of water- related risks and opportunities could similarly drive an increase in private sector engagement in incentive- based instruments for watershed services. in order to reveal water-related risk in institutional investment portfolios. CDP’s 2014 Global Water Report revealed that, of nearly 1,100 responding companies, 74  percent had evaluated how water quantity and quality could affect their growth strategy. However, of these, only 38 percent assessed water-related risk in both owned operations and their supply chain, and only 25 percent conducted detailed water risk assessments at the watershed level (CDP, 2014).
  • 81. 5 Summary and conclusions INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 61 Growing pressure on the availability and quality of water resources is having a major impact on our social, economic, and environmental well-being. These pres- sures are likely to worsen in response to continued population and economic growth, climate change, and other challenges. As water pollution exacerbates the challenges posed by water scarcity, and the world’s water quality becomes increasingly degraded, new approaches and strategies are needed. One key area of interest is the potential for incen- tive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water resources. To date, the primary environmental pol- icy tool to address water challenges has been com- mand-and-control regulations. Over the past several decades, however, the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include a host of incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or indi- rectly, to motivate responsible parties to reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facili- ties, processes, or products. While regulations and incentive-based instruments are often juxtaposed, “in reality the two often operate alongside each other” (UNEP, 2004). With water quality trading, for example, governments mandate caps on the allowable pollut- ant levels and issue tradable permits that allow those in the industry to allocate polluting activities among themselves, incentivized by market forces. Similarly, with water trading, governments may allocate water and then institute a framework by which water trad- ing can occur. While incentive-based instruments may work in tandem, they must be integrated within a broader watershed management effort. In a recent review of PWS programs, Bond and Mayers (2010) cautioned that: “PWS is a tool that will fail, or become irrelevant, if it is not integrated with wider regulatory approaches, broaderwatershedmanagementefforts,andexplicit attention to governance influences that shape what is possible. Policy makers need to consider the opportunities to ensure that future policy and legislation allow for a mix of both incentives and regulations to ensure the effective management of land and water resources.” The choice of whether and which instrument to apply depends on the specific circumstances, conditions, and needs of a given area. It is important to avoid “the law of the instrument”, i.e. the tendency to gravitate toward a particular tool and then look for applications of that tool. UNEP (2004) found that:
  • 82. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT62 for consistent and rigorous outreach and, potentially, a need for engaging a trusted intermediary. Finally, monitoring and evaluation are essential to the success of any instrument. In particular, they help ensure outcomes are achieved and allow for adjust- ments in response to changing social, economic, or environmental conditions. Monitoring should evaluate the additionality of the program, i.e. whether the pro- gram has an effect when compared with baseline con- ditions. It should also examine any potential impacts on surrounding areas (e.g. leakage) and the permanence of the intervention. However, it is important to recog- nize that extensive monitoring requirements would increase transaction costs. Thus, the need for moni- toring and evaluation must be balanced with practical considerations about the ability to maintain the viability of the program. “Prior to designing and applying any policy instrument for environmental protection, the policy context must be understood, including the existing institutional, legal and economic conditions in which these tools are meant to function. Choosing an effective policy package that will both address the environmental problem policy makers are faced with and fit in with the institutional capabilities and existing policy framework remains one of the most difficult challenges.” This process should be open and transparent, with meaningful participation from all affected parties. This will enable crafting a solution that not only is appropri- ate for local conditions, it will help reduce opposition and promote buy-in from those who will be imple- menting and affected by the program. It is important to recognize that those with the least power may not have the resources to participate or be skeptical of the groups involved. In these cases, there will be a need
  • 83. ANNEX 1 Demand management INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 63 A key way to reduce pressure on limited water supplies is through demand management, commonly referred to as water conservation and efficiency. In many cases, reducing demand is equivalent to augmenting or real- locating water supply. Demand management is typi- cally less expensive and faster to implement than water supply augmentation, and often results in reduced energy demand and water and wastewater treatment costs. For example, a recent study in Westminster, Colorado, found that water conservation and efficiency since 1980 had reduced water use in the city, reduc- ing tap fees by 80 percent and reducing customers’ bills by 91  percent relative to what they would have been without these efforts (Feinglas, Gray, and Mayer 2013). In major cities, such as San Francisco and Los Angeles, total water use has decreased since the late 1970s despite population and economic growth. At a larger scale, a recent United States federal study found that water conservation and efficiency efforts have reduced annual demand for water from the Colorado River basin by more than 1.7 million acre-feet, a tremen- dous savings in an over-allocated basin (US Bureau of Reclamation 2015). In the United States, we have made considerable progress in managing the nation’s water, with total water use less than it was in 1970, despite continued population and economic growth. Indeed, every sector, from agriculture to thermoelectric power generation, shows reductions in water use. Likewise, in Australia, a severe drought in the middle of the last decade prompted an intensive effort to reduce water demand. In response, total urban demand, including losses and non-residential consumption, fell from about 130 gallons per capita daily (gpcd) in 2005 to about 80 gpcd in 2010 (Queensland Water Commission, 2010). There are many tools available to reduce water demand – some of which rely on an incentive-based approach, e.g. pricing and rebates, while others are based on a more traditional command-and-control approach. Numerous studies have shown that significant conser- vation and efficiency opportunities exist in urban and agricultural areas (see, e.g. Gleick et al., 2003; Heberger, Cooley, and Gleick 2014). Below, we provide additional detail on the major demand management tools, includ- ing pricing, direct financial incentives, regulations, and education and outreach. Water pricing. Well-designed tariff structures can meet multiple policy objectives, including supporting the financial stability of the utility, the affordability of water for low-income customers, the efficient alloca- tion of water and other resources, and environmental sustainability. Most water utilities use some form of volumetric tariffs to achieve these objectives. There are several types of volumetric tariffs in use around the world: • uniform tariffs in which the volumetric tariff ($/m3) is constant regardless of the quantity used; • inclining block tariffs in which the volumetric tariff increases as the quantity used increases; and • declining block tariffs in which the volumetric tariff decreases as the quantity used increases. Uniform tariffs are the most common tariff structure in OECD and in developing countries (OECD 2009). Inclining block rates are becoming increasingly com- mon (OECD 2009), as there is recognition that when designed properly, this approach can provide a strong financial incentive to conserve while ensuring that
  • 84. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT64 Instead of providing rebates to cover a portion of the cost, some utilities have opted to institute direct-install programs that cover the entire cost of the device and the installation costs. In the mid-1990s, for example, the New York City Department of Environmental Protection launched a massive toilet rebate program to replace one-third of all water-wasting toilets in New York City with low-flow models. For this effort, property owners contracted directly with private licensed plumbers for the installation of the toilet, and after completion of the work, the City provided the property owner with a $240 rebate for the first toilet and $150 for the second toilet. Where possible, the plumber would also install low-flow showerheads and faucet aerators. The pro- gram was a huge success. Between 1994 and 1997, 1.3 million low-flow toilets were installed, saving 70 - 90 million gallons per day. Customers saw their water and wastewater bills drop 20 percent to 40 percent (EPA 2002). Additionally, the City was able to defer the need to develop new supply sources and expand wastewater treatment capacity, saving the community even more money. Regulations. In addition to financial incentives, reg- ulations are key demand management strategies. Regulations can take a variety of forms, ranging from a prescriptive approach focused on a particular appli- ance to a performance-based approach for outdoor water use. For example, the International Plumbing Code, which is widely used in the United States and forms the basis for plumbing codes in several other countries, specifies maximum flow rates for kitchen and lavatory faucets. Likewise, communities in the Las Vegas area have restricted lawn installation in new developments. California has also passed an ordinance to reduce outdoor water use, although the state opted for a performance-based approach. Landscape irriga- tion typically accounts for more than half of residen- tial demand in the state, and in an effort to promote outdoor efficiency, the state adopted the Model Water Efficient Landscape Ordinance (MWELO). MWELO lower-income consumers are able to meet their basic water needs at a reduced cost. A 2003 survey of cities in the southwest United States found that per-capita water use is typically lower in cities with dramatically increasing block tariffs, such as Tucson and El Paso (WRA 2003). Although less frequently employed, pricing has also been shown to be effective in reducing agricultural water use. For example, the Broadview Water District, a small district in California’s San Joaquin Valley, imple- mented increasing block rates in 1988 to reduce the volume of contaminated drainage water flowing into the San Joaquin River. The rate was set at $16 per acre-foot ($0.013 per m3) for the first 90 percent of average water use during the 1986 to 1988 period and $40 per acre-foot ($0.032 per m3) for any additional water. By 1991, the district’s average water use declined by 19 percent due to efficiency improvements and crop shifting (MacDougall et al., 1992). Direct financial incentives. Rebate programs are commonly used to encourage customers to make investments in water conservation and efficiency improvements. Residents and business owners pur- chase new devices as the old devices wear out. While most new standard devices use less water than older models, there are many new high-efficiency devices available that use even less water. While efficient devices are often cheaper over their lifetimes due to lower water, energy, and wastewater bills, users may be put off by the higher up-front costs. As a result, water utilities may provide their customers with a rebate to defray the additional cost of the more efficient device. There are several examples of water utilities partner- ing with local energy utilities to augment those rebates because of the energy savings (Cooley and Donnelly 2013). Additionally, utilities may partner with retailers to offer rebates at the point of sale, giving customers an immediate incentive to purchase the more efficient device.
  • 85. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 65 Education and outreach. Education and outreach programs can also be effective for promoting water conservation and efficiency. The US Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), for example, launched the WaterSense labeling program in 2006 to promote water-conserving devices that are 20  percent more efficient than standard products on the market and meet rigorous performance criteria. Social market- ing has also gained prominence in recent years, with some programs tapping into new metering technolo- gies and web-based platforms. For example, a recent study found that home water reports - which provide customers information on their current water use and comparisons to their past use, use by similar house- holds, and efficient use - reduce water by 5 percent and were especially effective in reaching the highest water users (Mitchell and Chesnutt 2013). establishes a water budget for new construction and rehabilitated landscapes that are at least 2,500 square feet and require a building or landscaping permit (the size threshold is likely to be reduced to 500 square feet in response to the current drought). In addition, the ordinance requires mulching for most plantings; promotes the use of techniques to increase storm- water retention and infiltration; and requires new and refurbished landscapes to install irrigation systems run by weather, soil moisture, or other self-adjusting con- trollers. Also in California, Governor Schwarzenegger signed SBx7-7 in 2009, requiring urban water suppliers to reduce per-capita water use by 20 percent by 2020.
  • 86. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT66 The MDB includes parts of four states (Queensland, New South Wales, Victoria, and South Australia) and the Australian Capital Territory. The MDB supplies water to about three million people, including the national capi- tal (Canberra) and Adelaide, outside of the basin near the river’s mouth. According to the MDBA, the basin contains some 70 percent of the nation’s irrigated acre- age, producing a third of the country’s food supply. The MDBA reports the gross value of irrigated agriculture in the basin in 2012-13 at approximately $6.8 Billion. The MDB generates almost all of Australia’s rice and cotton and 75 percent of its grapes, as well as roughly half of the nation’s hay, fruit, livestock, and dairy production. The construction of dams and canals and the diver- sion and depletion of MDB rivers has endangered the survival of at least 35 bird species and 16 mammal spe- cies within the basin. Many fish species, including the Murray cod, are also threatened. Wetlands have dried up or reached critically low levels, exacerbated by the Millennium drought, prompting public concern. MDB and the Colorado River Basin The MDB and the Colorado River Basin share many common traits: both are highly variable rivers in arid basins, where rapidly-growing urban populations have imposed new demands on limited, climate-stressed rivers. Basin size and runoff are similar. And, interest- ingly, the two basins share a common figure: Elwood Mead (namesake of Lake Mead), the Wyoming State Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin (MDB) figures promi- nently in discussions about water trading as an example of a thriving incentive-based system that successfully transitioned from a non-market system (Grafton et al., 2012). The total value of water trading in Australia in fiscal year 2012-13 exceeded $1.4 billion (NWC 2013). Water trading in Australia includes both short-term trades, known as allocation trading, and long-term trades, known as entitlement trading. In fiscal year 2012-13, the most recent period for which comprehen- sive data are available, the total volume of short-term trading increased 44 percent from the previous year, from almost 3.5 million acre-feet to 5 million acre-feet, or roughly 50 percent of total surface water use in the MDB. This is an extremely active water market. Background The MDB covers some 390,000 square miles in south- eastern Australia, comprising roughly 14 percent of that country’s land area. Most of the basin is very arid, with 86 percent of the basin contributing little or no flow to rivers that drain the basin. The Murray-Darling Basin Authority (MDBA) estimates that total runoff within the basin is less than 26 million acre-feet annually, yield- ing an estimated long-term annual average 19 MAF of total river flow. As shown in Figure A-1, the system displays very high seasonal and annual variability. For example, flows in the southern Murray basin typically are much higher than in the northern Darling basin. Pre-development, an estimated 10 million acre-feet ran into the ocean; in 2009, during the historic Millennium drought, this had decreased to 4 million acre-feet. ANNEX 2 Water trading in Australia: Lessons from the Murray-Darling Basin
  • 87. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 67 subsequently changing the water rights structure to facilitate trading and protect environmental resources. In Australia, water rights typically refer to either entitle- ments or allocations.30 The National Water Initiative of 2004 defines these as: • Water access entitlement – a perpetual or ongo- ing entitlement to exclusive access to a share of water from a specified consumptive pool as defined in the relevant water plan. • Water allocation – the specific volume of water allocated to water access entitlements in a given season, defined according to rules established in the relevant water plan. (Young, 2010). Australian water rights are typically defined as the right todivertaspecificvolume,asopposedtoaconsumptive use right that is more typical with prior appropriation 30 Additional water rights include: Water use license – a non-tradable use or condition linked to the place of use; and Delivery right – may be required to ensure that an allocation is delivered, typically associated with irrigation infrastructure, such as canals and headgates (Grafton and Horne 2014). Irrigation Engineer from 1888-99, went on to serve as the Chairman of Victoria (Australia)’s State Rivers Water Supply Commission (1907–15), prior to return- ing to the US and serving as the Commissioner of the Bureau of Reclamation from 1924-36 (McLeod 2014). However, Australia avoided Mead’s legacy of prior appropriation and hierarchical water rights to embrace a very different system that promotes and facilitates water trading, as described in the following sections. History Australia has promoted and developed water trading over a period of more than 30 years (Grafton et al., 2012), in a process that initially attempted to activate markets prior to recognizing that the water rights struc- ture itself needed to be altered to encourage active trading and minimize transaction costs (Young, 2015). Table A-1 lists some of the major steps taken to cre- ate the current water trading structure. These changes have occurred over several decades and often reflect corrections to previous policies. Young (2010, 2015) asserts that Australia implemented water trading from the wrong direction, by first promoting trading and FIGURE A-1. Historical river flows within the Murray-Darling Basin 1900s 1910s 1920s 1930s 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s 30,000 25,000 20,000 15,000 10,000 5,000 0 Flow(GLperyear) Northern basin annual flows Flow measured on Darling River at Bourke Southern basin annual flows Flow measured on River Murray at Euston Average annual flow levels 1895 Startofthe ‘FederationDrought’ whichlastsfor7years 1909 Floodinthe Murrayand Wimmerarivers 1914 Severedrought leadstotheend ofcommercial navigationonthe Murrayand Darlingrivers 1917 Floodingalong theRiverMurray 1921 Floodingacross theentireBasin 1931 Floodingalong theRiverMurray 1944 Severedrought throughoutNSW, VicandSA. Murrayceasesto flowinsomeareas 1950 Recordrainfall causeswidespread floodinginCondamine andWarregorivers 1952 Floodinginthe RiverMurray 1956 HighestBasininflows inrecordedhistory causewidespread flooding 1968 Duetosevere drought,HumeDam fallsto1%ofcapacity 1974 Widespreadflooding acrosstheBasin, knownasthe‘bigwet’ 1981 Droughtforces Adelaidetotake 90%ofitswater fromtheMurray. TheMurrayMouth closesforthefirst timeinrecorded history 1993 Floodingacross QLD,NSW andVictoria 1997 Beginningoflongestdrought inAustralia’srecordedhistory 2000MurrayMouthclosesand requiresdredging 2010-11Widespreadflooding throughouttheBasin 2006 Lowest water inflowsonrecord Extremedryin NorthernBasin 2013-15 Note: Volumes in the figure shown in gigaliters, with 1000 GL = 0.8 million acre-feet. Source: Australia’s MDBA.
  • 88. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT68 the land. Transforming these general land-based rights to discrete volumes then required determining his- toric usage patterns and water requirements for crops grown on that land. Several MDB states initially allowed water trading within individual irrigation districts, using shared infrastructure to trade water to different parcels within the district. These volumetric rights were subse- quently “unbundled” from the land, enabling water to be traded between different irrigation districts. Despite these changes, restrictions on trading between dif- ferent sub-basins often took years to revoke, due to concerns about adverse economic and equity impacts that trading could cause in areas of origin (Grafton and Horne 2014). regimes (Connor and Kaczan, 2013). Diversions can be measured (and subsequently traded) more readily than consumptive use, which requires measurement of both diversions and surface and sub-surface return flows. Return flows often lag diversions, sometimes by weeks or months in the case of sub-surface returns, requiring more complicated measurements and esti- mates, challenging efforts to evaluate and quantify the full impacts (especially environmental impacts) of the trade, hindering transactions. Initially, Australian water rights were linked to a spe- cific land parcel. In many cases, the water right simply entitled the landowner to sufficient water to irrigate TABLE A-1. Policy and legislative milestones YEAR ACTION DESCRIPTION 1960s Volumetric water licenses Start of conversion of land-based water entitlements to volumetric entitlements 1983 Water trading w/in districts Allowed in New South Wales and South Australia 1987 1st MDB Agreement Established the MDB Commission, to coordinate management 1991 Inter-district water trading Allowed in New South Wales 1994 “Unbundling” Council of Australian Governments agrees to separate statutory land rights from water rights, facilitating trading 1995 Diversion CAP implemented Limits surface water diversions in the MDB; limits water rights 1995 National Competition Policy Requires development of water markets and full-cost pricing 2000 Water Management Act “Unbundles” diversion and use rights 2004 National Water Initiative Promotes cohesive water planning and trading efforts 2004 Living Murray Initiative Authorizes purchase and dedication of 0.4 MAF to the river 2007 Water Act Promotes management of MDB 2008 Water Amendment Act Establishes MDB Authority, replacing the Commission 2008 Water for the Future Commits $3.1 billion to purchase water entitlements for the env. 2012 MD Basin Plan Caps total MDB surface diversions at 8.8 MAF, coordinates basin management including water quality (esp. salinity) Sources: MDBA, Young, 2010; Grafton and Horne, 2014.
  • 89. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 69 uses. New South Wales has attempted to limit federal purchases of water for the environment to no more than 3 percent of total entitlements, though this appears to contravene trading rules within the Basin Plan, which seek to minimize restrictions on trading (Grafton and Horne 2014). State water plans allocate water entitlements into one or two “pools,” known as a high security pool and a gen- eral or low security pool. The high security pool is allo- cated to those entitlement holders proportional to the size of their entitlement. For example, if a system only has two entitlement holders and one right is for nine units and the other is for one unit, the former would receive 90  percent of the pool’s allocation and the latter would receive 10 percent. If additional water is available for the general pool, that volume is allocated to those entitlement holders. Every season, the state determines the total volume available for allocation for each pool. During drought, the general pool might not receive any water at all (Young, 2010). Water trading activity Australia’s water trading activity is largely concentrated in the MDB, which represents as much as 94 percent of all such activity in Australia despite being only one of twelve surface water management areas (Figure A-2). Trading is very high as measured by the total volume of water traded (as much as 5 million acre-feet), the percentage of all diversions that are traded (as much as 50 percent), the number of farmers trading water (roughly half, in 2008-09), and the total number of trades (11,000, in 2011-12). The number of short-term (allocation) interstate trades also appears to be rising, reaching 20 percent of the total number of such trades in 2011/12 (Grafton and Horne 2014). Not surprisingly, the number of short-term (allocation) trades is much higher, in terms of numbers and volumes, than the number of entitlement trades. As the federal govern- ment has exercised its commitment to ensure minimum Unlike the doctrine of prior appropriation in the west- ern United States, water rights in Australia did not have priority dates or a seniority system for satisfy- ing demands: all rights were considered equivalent. Additionally, Australian water rights did not have to be exercised on an annual or periodic basis to demon- strate possession (again, unlike the prior appropriation system); many rights holders maintained their rights for periodic or infrequent use (known as “dozer” rights) or never exercised their water rights (known as “sleep- ers”), perhaps in the expectation that they might be needed in the future. The 1995 imposition of the diversion CAP limiting surface water diversions and rights within the MDBA explicitly recognized the continuing validity of dozer and sleeper rights and incorporated the volumes of these rights into the general calculation of the propor- tional shares of the new water rights regime. However, the result of recognizing dozer and sleeper rights within the context of water trading was to increase the finan- cial value of these unexercised rights, leading to new diversions and greater strain on water supply, in turn reducing water reliability (Grafton and Horne 2014). Tony McLeod, General Manager for Water Planning at MDBA, explained that the recognition of these dozer and sleeper rights was intentional, to reduce resistance to the imposition of the CAP and smooth the transition to the new system of proportional sharing (McLeod, personal communication, 2014). In response, the Australian government implemented several initiatives to purchase existing water entitle- ments and dedicate these to the environment, both to offset reservoir evaporation and other system losses (known as maintenance rights) and explicitly to ensure minimum instream flow volumes in designated reaches. The government has invested more than $3 Billion to date to purchase entitlements for environmental water. However, the relative priority of this environmental water remains contentious, with some states contend- ing that such rights receive lower priority than human
  • 90. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT70 about $54 per acre-foot in the drier 2012/13.31 Similarly, trading in drier years tends to see water move from lower value uses, such as pasture and forage, to higher value wine and vegetable crops. Connor and Kaczan (2013) reported that many livestock operations irrigate pasture and forage crops in wet years but tend to trade away their allocations in drier years, when the price of water rises due to scarcity, using the profits to purchase feed from other areas. These trends also manifest regionally, aswatertendstomoveacrossstatelinesfromNewSouth Wales into South Australia, which has more high-value 31 These prices are about an order of magnitude lower than prices for short-term transfers in California in the 2014 drought year, but are comparable to prices paid for short-term rentals in the active Northern Colorado Water Conservancy district water market. environmental flows by purchasing entitlements, such purchases have risen to 37 percent of the total number of entitlement trades in 2011/12. Only about 5 percent of farmers traded water entitlements, either to other farmers or to cities or to the government for augment- ing environmental flows, in 2008/09, or about 10 per- cent of the number that reported trading allocations that year (Grafton and Horne 2014). As expected, the number of allocation trades appears to be inversely correlated with precipitation and runoff, rising in drought years and falling when allocations are higher due to wetter conditions. Prices similarly vary in response to water availability, rising from the equivalent of about $22 per acre-foot in 2011/12 to the equivalent of 81 0.NT 426.K 426.A 426.B 426.I 507.A 426.G 426.D 41 4.SAC 239.SAA 81 0.WA 809.WA 808 807 806 805 804 803 802 801 71 0709 708 707 706 705 704 703 702 701 61 9 61 8 61 7 61 6 61 5 61 461 3 61 2 611 61 0 609 608 607 606 605 604 602 601 026.WA 025 024 023.WA 022.WA 41 5 41 4.VIC 408 407 406 405 404 403 402 409.VIC 239.VIC 238 237 236 235 234 233 232 231 230 229 225 224 223 222.VIC 221 .VIC 31 4.I 31 4.H 31 2 31131 0 302.G 301 31 9.E 31 9.D 302.F 302.E 31 9.B 307.B 31 8.F 31 6 31 8.E 31 7 31 8.B 31 8.A 302.D 309 302.C 302.A 303 304.E 304.B 304.A 308 306 31 4.A 31 3 307.A 021 .D 004.A 023.SAB 51 3.D 51 3.C 51 3.B 51 3.A 426.C 023.SAA 503.C 501 003.SA 505.A 005.SA 021 .B 41 4.SAD 021 .C 026.SA 51 2 507.B 506.A 007.SA 426.F 506.B 021 .A 509 51 0 004.B 001 .SA 508.A 022.SA 511 508.B 239.SAC 239.SAE 41 4.SAA 002 41 6.QLD 11 7 11 0 924 1 23 1 22.B 925 923 1 34 1 29 423.A 11 3 1 27 1 44.B 1 04 91 5 1 28 11 8 1 22.A 922 1 261 25 424.QLD 1 02 1 24 1 05 422.A 11 4 111 91 3 928 1 43 41 7 91 9 1 38 1 03 11 2 1 06 927 1 01 1 44.A 921 11 5 11 6 1 46 001 .QLD 1 39 1 30 1 07 926 1 21 1 09 1 08 1 31 003.QLD 422.B 920 1 32 1 36 1 20 011 1 33 929 91 2 91 0 909 908 907 906 905 904 903 902 901 826 825824 823 822 821 820 81 9 81 8 81 7 81 6 81 5.B 81 5.A 81 4 81 3 81 2 811 809.NT 029 028 027 026.NT 023.NT 007.NT 006 005.NT 001 .NT 499 425.URB425.URA 425.R 421 .UR 421 .R 420 41 9.UR 41 9.R 41 8.UR 41 8.R 41 6.NSWR 41 6.NSWUR 41 2.UR 41 2.R 411 41 0.NSWUR 41 0.NSWR 409.NSW 401 .NSW 222.NSW 221 .NSW 220 21 9.UR 21 9.R 21 8 21 7 21 6 21 5 21 4 21 3 21 2 211 21 0.UR 21 0.R 208 207 206 205 204 203.UR 203.R 202 201 01 2 424.NSW 004.NSW 003.NSW 41 0.ACT 503.B 502 426.J 426.H 426.L 239.SAB 603 228 227 226 31 9.C 31 9.A 31 8.C 31 8.D 304.F 302.B 305 304.D 304.C 31 4.G 31 4.F31 4.E 31 4.D 31 4.C 31 5 31 4.B 505.C 503.A 504.B 504.C 505.E 504.A 505.G 505.F 505.B 426.E 505.D 41 4.SAB 239.SAD 1 45 209 PERTH HOBART SYDNEY DARWIN CANBERRA ADELAIDE BRISBANE MELBOURNE 0 250 5001 25 Kilometres Legend Surface water management areas Drainage division North-East Coast South-East Coast Tasmania Murray-Darling South Australia Gulf South-West Coast Indian Ocean Timor Sea Gulf of Carpentaria Lake Eyre Bulloo-Bancannia Western Plateau CommonwealthofAustralia© MapID: WA_L1_SWMA_28 WaterAustralian Resources 2005 FIGURE A-2. Surface water management areas in Australia Source: Australia National Water Commission.
  • 91. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 71 market activity while protecting environmental values by participating directly in the market, purchasing enti- tlements from willing sellers and dedicating this water to preserve threatened ecosystems and river reaches. This approach has come at great expense to the gov- ernment (and taxpayers) but has been justified by the reported increase in economic activity and benefits arising from trading activity. In a robust assessment of water trading in Victoria’s Murray Valley, Frontier Economics (2007) found strong local opposition to permanently trading water out of local areas, to the extent that some irrigators selling entitlements have been ostracized, but also found a combination of posi- tive and negative socio-economic impacts from such trades. For example, the authors found that trading ameliorated the impacts of the Millennium Drought on dairy farmers in the region, who otherwise would have fared much worse. Additionally, water trading facili- tated the expansion of the wine industry in the region. Several researchers have compiled extensive lists of lessons learned. Two of these are reproduced below. Young (2010) writes: Lesson 1: Unless carefully managed, the legacy of prior licensing decisions can result in markets causing over-allocation problems to emerge in a manner that erodes the health of rivers, aquifer and the water dependent ecosystems associated with them. Lesson 2: Transaction and administrative costs are lower when entitlements are defined using a unit share structure and not as an entitlement to a volume of water. One of the simplest ways of pre- venting over-allocation problems from emerging is to assign the risks of adverse climate change and/ or the emergence of long dry periods to entitlement holders and define entitlements as an entitlement to a share of the water defined as being available for use. Lesson 3: Market efficiency is improved by using separate structures to define entitlements, manage allocations and control the use of water. crops. In response, New South Wales and Victoria have imposed restrictions on the volume of water that may be exported from the state (Grafton and Horne 2014). Enabling conditions A large number of necessary and enabling conditions help explain Australia’s water trading success. Key among these is the development of a proportional water sharing regime, in which the state, rather than administrative or water courts, determines total annual water availability, rather than granting rights holders an absolute or priority-based right to a fixed volume of water. The Australian experience also shows that water trading is more active when allocation pools encompass a large number of entitlement holders with a diverse range of uses (Young, 2010). Grafton and Horne (2014) found that infrastructure, such as dams and canals, can facilitate water trading by storing water until needed and providing conveyances to deliver where needed. Similarly, access to accurate and timely information on water prices and availability facilitates water trading. In Australia, brokerage-type water banks are active in both the Murray-Darling Basin and in northern Victoria, where the banks post informa- tion about pricing and availability (O’Donnell and Colby 2010). Underpinning this information exchange is an extensive, credible, verifiable registry of entitlements and allocations and mechanism to quickly record, measure and monitor trades, as well as sufficient sanctions on those violating agreements (Connor and Kaczan 2013). Lessons learned Connor and Kaczan highlighted the classic dilemma facing those attempting to implement a water trading system: the tradeoff between protecting third parties with high transaction costs versus promoting trades with low transaction costs, with less concern for third parties. Australia has adopted the latter approach, choosing to minimize transaction costs and promote
  • 92. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT72 Lesson 11: Water use and investment will be more efficient if all users are exposed to at least the full lower bound cost and preferably the upper bound cost of supplying water to them. One way of achieving this outcome is to transfer ownership of the supply system to these users. Lesson 12: Manage environmental externalities using separate instruments so that the costs of avoiding them are reflected in the costs of produc- tion and use in a manner that encourages water users to avoid creating them. Lesson 13: Removal of administrative impediments to inter-regional trade and inter-state trade is difficult but necessary for the development of efficient water markets. Australia has taken the approach of ap- pointing an independent agency to develop rules designed to remove unnecessary barriers to water trade. Amongst other things, this has required the setting of guidelines that prevent water supply companies from setting charges and adopting practices that discriminate against people who wish to trade water out of a region. Lesson 14: Markets will be more efficient and the volume of trade greater if entitlements are allocated to individual users rather than to irrigator controlled water supply companies and cooperatives. Whilst opposed by water supply companies and coopera- tives, it is the Australian experience that willingness to trade and market depth typically is much greater when entitlements are allocated to individuals rather than to water supply companies or associations as they are called in other countries. The reason for this is that when allocations are issued to individu- als they do not have to obtain the permission of the board of a water supply company or association to sell water out of a region. Lesson 15: Equity and fairness principles require careful attention to and discipline in the way that allocation decisions and policy changes are announced. Lesson 16: Water markets are more effective when information about the prices being paid and offered is made available to all participants in a timely manner. Lesson 4: Early attention to the development of accurate license registers is critical and a necessary precondition to the development of low-cost entitle- ment trading systems. Lesson 5: Unless water market and allocation pro- cedures allow unused water to be carried forward from year to year, trading may increase the severity of droughts. Lesson 6: Early installation of meters and conver- sion from area based licenses to a volumetric man- agement system is a necessary precursor to the development of low cost allocation trading systems. Metering and conversion to a volumetric allocation system is a necessary precursor to the development of efficient water trading systems. In order to facili- tate the more efficient management of the available resource and trading, Australia has spent many years converting area-based licenses to volumetric licenses and installing meters. Typically, conversion involves estimation of the amount of water used by crop type and the development of conversion factors. Lesson 7: It is difficult for communities to plan for an adverse climate shift and develop water sharing plans that deal adequately with a climatic shift to a drier regime. More robust planning and water en- titlement systems are needed. Lesson 8: The allocation regime for the provision of water necessary to maintain minimum flows, provide for conveyance and cover evaporative losses need to be more secure than that used to allocate water for environmental and other purposes. Lesson 9: Unless all forms of water use are accounted for entitlement reliability will be eroded by expansion of un-metered uses like plantation forestry and farm dam development, increases in ir- rigation efficiency, etc. and place the integrity of the allocation system at risk. Lesson 10: Unless connected ground and surface water systems are managed as a single integrated resource, groundwater development will reduce the amount of water available that can be allocated to surface water users.
  • 93. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 73 7. Statutory rights offer flexibility but carry risks - can be modified without recourse to the courts. Developments to unbundle water rights have facili- tated trade. A potential downside of statutory rights is sovereign risk, or the possibility that the value of existing water rights can be degraded by changes in regulation and discretionary behaviour by state governments. 8. Markets can promote environmental outcomes - Trading should always be subject to a public interest test. Where there are important public interests, such as flow volumes at key locations or the need to ensure minimum levels of water quality, trade may need to be constrained for environmental reasons. An example of this approach is the Basin Salinity Management Strategy that seeks to reduce salinity: actions that reduce salinity are treated as credits and actions that increase salinity as debits on state salinity registers. 9. Acquiring water for the environment through buybacks has proved effective. 10. Prices contain information on scarcity and risk. 11. Basin-wide and local perspectives have roles to play – local input can also prevent or undermine the emergence of strong water markets. … Governments need to see through short-term and some-times parochial interests to facilitate optimal use in the longer term. 12. Effective monitoring and control of extractions are critical for sustainability – Farmers made substantial investments to increase their on-farm retention of water that might otherwise have flowed to the Basin’s streams and rivers. Similarly, ground- water extractions increased by about half over the period 2000–2001 to 2007–2008 (from about 1 MAF to 1.4 MAF) as market users sought access to other cost effective water supplies. Lesson 17: Develop brokering industry and avoid government involvement in the provision of water brokering services. GRAFTON AND HORNE (2014) WRITE: 1. Crises may facilitate reform - As the focus on the crisis fades, so may do the reform zeal. This ‘stop and go’ reform process suggests that determination is required to make consistent progress, but that a crisis can facilitate reform. 2. Water markets support regional resilience - The geographical distribution of markets has meant these benefits have been concentrated in areas of greatest connectivity of the resource (the southern Murray-Darling Basin) where there is also the widest cross-section of users. An example is the signifi- cance of selling water by opportunistic commodity producers (such as rice growers) to perennial crop producers (such as citrus growers). 3. Political and administrative leadership is critical - This involves teams with a range of skills, much broader than the engineering-based specialists that have traditionally managed water resources. 4. Capping extractions promotes effective use and sustainability - any cap should be comprehen- sive and all water sources should be included to avoid substitution to uncontrolled or inadequately measured sources. 5. Regulated water framework facilitates water trading - entitlements delivered via regulated water storages account for about 90 percent of the water entitlements traded in the Southern MDB. 6. Reliable, accessible and timely market informa- tion promotes effective decision-making - the Australian government is investing over half a billion Australian dollars in improved water information and regulations.
  • 94. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT74 Payment for ecosystem services (PES) – an incen- tive-based instrument that seeks to translate external, non-market values of environment services into financial incentives for local actors to provide such services. In practical terms, PES involves a series of payments to a land or resource manager in exchange for a guaranteed flow of environmental services. Payment for watershed services (PWS) – a type of PES arrangement that is focused on watershed services. Water bank – may refer to the physical storage of water, typically in a reservoir or an aquifer, to an institution that facilitates or brokers a water transfer or serves as an information clearinghouse, or to any agency that holds water rights in trust for a specified purpose such as streamflow augmentation. Water market – Often used interchangeably with water transfer, a water market can also refer to informal transactions involving the sale of water, e.g. from water tankers, that do not involve the lease or sale of water rights or concessions. Water option – a type of conditional water transfer. Under dry-year options a buyer will pay the seller an annual fee to be able to exercise an option to purchase a pre-determined volume of water under a specific set of circumstances. Water transfer – a change in the point of diversion, type of use, or location of water use. May refer to a temporary or permanent exchange of water rights (see water market), or to a non-market conveyance of water from one location to another. Aquifer – an underground layer of water-bearing materials, such as sandstone or gravel or other permeable material. Command-and-control regulation – an environmental regulatory policy that is often contrasted with “incentive- based mechanisms” in the literature. A command and control (CAC) regulation can be defined as the direct regulation of an industry or activity that states what is permitted and what is illegal. Economic Efficiency – generally, a state or condition with optimal resource use, allocation, or productivity. May or may not be consistent with equity considerations. Equity – refers to fairness, justice, impartiality, such as in the allocation of resources or treatment of different classes of people. May or may not be consistent with economic efficiency considerations. Eutrophication – excessive richness of nutrients in a lake or other body of water, frequently due to runoff from the land, which causes a dense growth of plant life and death of animal life from lack of oxygen. Incentive-based instrument – a broad set of tools that use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate re- sponsible parties to reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products. Nonpoint source (NPS) pollution – water pollution from diffuse sources such as runoff from urbanized areas or farm fields. Nutrients – nitrogen or phosphorus-containing water pollutants that can cause water quality problems. See eutrophication. Paper water – the legal right to use a given volume of water, contrasted with “wet” or “real” water. In many basins, more paper water exists than wet water. Glossary INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT74
  • 95. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 75 Bennett, G. N. Carroll. 2014. “Gaining Depth: State of Wa- tershed Investment 2014.” Forest Trends, Ecosystem Marketplace. Available at forest-trends.org/documents/ files/SOWI2014.pdf. Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER). 2015. “Performance in Watershed Context Concept Paper.” Bev- erage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER). http:// www.bieroundtable.com/#!/c16n5. Bjornlund, H. J. McKay. 2002. “Aspects of Water Markets for Developing Countries: Experiences from Australia, Chile, and the US.” Environment and Development Eco- nomics 7 (04). doi:10.1017/S1355770X02000463. Bond, I., and J. Mayers. 2010. “Fair Deals for Watershed Ser- vices: Lessons from a Multi-Country Action-Learning Project.” No. 13. Natural Resources Issues. London, UK: International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at pubs.iied.org/pdfs/13535IIED.pdf. Brewer, J., R. Glennon, A. Ker G.D. Libecap. 2007. “Water Markets in the West: Prices, Trading, and Contractual Forms.” National Bureau of Economic Research. Brooks, D.B. 2006. “An Operational Definition of Water De- mand Management.” Intenational Journal of Water Re- sources Development 22 (4): 521–28. Brouwer, R., A. Tesfaye P. Pauw. 2011. “Meta-Analysis of Institutional-Economic Factors Explaining the Environ- mental Performance of Payments for Watershed Ser- vices.” Environmental Conservation 38 (04): 380–92. doi:10.1017/S0376892911000543. Brown, C., U. Lall F.A. Souza Filho. 2015. “Allocating Water in a Changing World: Incentive-Based Mechanisms for Climate Adaptation.” Calvache, A., S. Benitez A. Ramos. 2012. “Fondo de Agua: Conservando La Infraestructura Verde. Guia de Diseno, Creacio, Y Operacion.” Bogota, Columbia: The Nature Conservancy, Fundacion FEMSA, y Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo. Available at conservationgateway.org/ Documents/LAWFP-ENG-low-050312_0.pdf. Carpenter, S.R., E.H. Stanley M. J. Vander Zanden. 2011. “State of the World’s Freshwater Ecosystems: Physical, Chemical, and Biological Changes.” Annual Review of Environment and Resources 36 (1): 75–99. doi:10.1146/ annurev-environ-021810-094524. CDP. 2014. “From Water Risk to Value Creation, CDP Global Water Report 2014.” CDP. Available at cdp.net/CDPRe- sults/CDP-Global-Water-Report-2014.pdf. Albiac, J., M. Hanemann, J. Calatrava, J. Uche J. Tapia. 2006. “The Rise and Fall of the Ebro Water Transfer.” Natural Resources Journal 46: 729–57. Alix-Garcia, J., A. de Janvry, E. Sadoulet J. Manuel. 2009. “Lessons Learned from Mexico’s Payment for Environ- mental Services Program.” In Payment for Environmental Services in Agricultural Landscapes, edited by Leslie Lip- per, Takumi Sakuyama, Randy Stringer, and David Zilber- man, 163–88. Natural Resource Management and Policy 31. Springer New York. Available at link.springer.com/ chapter/10.1007/978-0-387-72971-8_8. Al-Marshudi, A.S. 2007. “The Falaj Irrigation System and Water Allocation Markets in Northern Oman.” Agricul- tural Water Management 91 (1–3): 71–77. doi:10.1016/j. agwat.2007.04.008. Ambec, S., A. Dinar D. McKinney. 2013. “Water Sharing Agreements Sustainable to Reduced Flows.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 66 (3): 639–55. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2013.06.003. Anderson, R.C. 2004. “International Experiences with Economic Incentives for Protecting the Environment.” EPA-236-R-04-001. Washington, DC: US Environmental Protection Agency, National Center for Environmental Economics. Available at yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/eerm. nsf/vwAN/EE-0487-01.pdf/$file/EE-0487-01.pdf. Appleton, A.F. 2010. “How New York City Used an Ecosystem Services Strategy Carried out through an Urban-Rural Partnership to Preserve the Pristine Quality of Its Drink- ing Water and Save Billions of Dollars.” New York, NY: A Paper for Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarket- place.com/documents/cms_documents/NYC_H2O_Eco- system_Services.pdf. Backeberg, G. 2015. “Water Markets in South Africa,” July 24. Barrett, K. 2015. “A Different Kind of Sale: April Auction Of- fers Stewardship Credits to Meet Sustainability Goals.” Ecosystem Marketplace. February 12. Available at eco- systemmarketplace.com/pages/dynamic/article.page. php?page_id=10792section=news_articleseod=1. Bauer, C.J. 1997. “Bringing Water Markets down to Earth: The Political Economy of Water Rights in Chile, 1976–1995.” World Development 25 (5): 639–56. Bennett, G., N. Carroll K. Hamilton. (2012) Charting New Waters: State of Watershed Payments 2012. Washington, DC: Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarketplace. com/reports/sowp2012. References
  • 96. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT76 at ohchr.org/english/bodies/hrcouncil/docs/18session/A- HRC-18-33-Add4_en.pdf. Dellapenna, J. 2000. “The Importance of Getting Names Right: The Myth of Markets for Water.” William Mary Environmental Law and Policy Review 25 (2): 317. Department of Environmental Affairs. 2015. “Social Develop- ment | Department of Environmental Affairs.” Accessed September 10. Available at environment.gov.za/proj- ectsprogrammes/wfw/socialdevelopment. Dillaha, T., P. Ferraro, M. Huang, D. Southgate, S. Upadhyaya S. Wunder. 2007. “Payment for Watershed Services Regional Syntheses.” USAID. Available at sanrem.cals. vt.edu/1010/Dillaha2007_PWS_regional_syntheses.pdf. Dinar, A., M.W. Rosegrant R. Meinzen-Dick. 1997. “Wa- ter Allocation Mechanisms: Principles and Examples.” Policy Research Working Paper Series 1779. The World Bank. Available at econpapers.repec.org/paper/wbkw- brwps/1779.htm. Dinar, A. R.M. Saleth. 2005. “Can Water Institutions Be Cured? A Water Institutions Health Index.” Water Supply 5: 17–40. Dodds, W.K., W.W. Bouska, J.L. Eitzmann, T.J. Pilger, K.L. Pitts, A.J. Riley, J.T. Schloesser D.J. Thornbrugh. 2008. “Eu- trophication of US Freshwaters: Analysis of Potential Eco- nomic Damages.” Environmental Science Technology 43 (1): 12–19. Duhon, M., J. Young S. Kerr. 2011. “Nitrogen Trading in Lake Taupo: An Analysis and Evaluation of an Innovative Water Management Strategy.” In New Zealand Agricultural and Resource Economics Society 2011 Conference. Nelson, New Zealand. Available at ageconsearch.umn.edu/bit- stream/115353/2/Duhon%20Paper.pdf. Easter, K.W., M.W. Rosegrant A. Dinar. 1999. “Formal and Informal Markets for Water: Institutions, Performance, and Constraints.” The World Bank Research Observer 14 (1): 99–116. Ecosystem Marketplace. 2013. “Innovative Markets and Market Like Instruments for Ecosystem Services.” Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.com/docu- ments/acrobat/the_matrix.pdf. ———. 2015. “This Week In Water: The Art Of The Nutrient Credit Sale.” Watershed Connect. February 27. Available at watershedconnect.com/news/this_week_in_water_the_ art_of_the_nutrient_credit_sale_. Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI). 2010. “Program on Technology Innovation: Ohio River Water Quality Trading Pilot Program: Business Case for Power Company Partici- pation.” Available at epri.com/abstracts/Pages/ProductA- bstract.aspx?ProductId=000000000001018861. Clifford, P. 2012. “Water Banking in Washington State: 2012 Report to the Legislature.” Report to Legislature 12-11- 055. Washington State Department of Ecology. https:// fortress.wa.gov/ecy/publications/SummaryPages/1211055. html. Cohen, M.J., J. Christian-Smith J. Berggren. 2013. “Water to Supply the Land: Irrigated Agriculture in the Colorado River Basin.” Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/ publication/water-to-supply-the-land-irrigated-agricul- ture-in-the-colorado-river-basin/. Cohen, M.J. 2014. “Hazard’s Toll: The Costs of Inaction at the Salton Sea.” Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/pub- lication/hazards-toll/. Cohen, M.J. K.H. Hyun. 2006. “Hazard: The Future of the Salton Sea With No Restoration Plan.” Oakland, Calif.: Pa- cific Institute. http://pacinst.org/publication/restoration- project-critical-to-salton-seas-future/. Colby, B.G., M.A. McGinnis K.A. Rait. 1991. “Mitigating Envi- ronmental Externalities through Voluntary and Involun- tary Water Reallocation: Nevada’s Truckee-Carson River Basin.” Natural Resources Journal 31: 757. Coleman, A. 2008. “Farmers to Sue DWAF for Water Rights Transfers.” Farmer’s Weekly, September 12. Conagua. 2012. “Water Banks in Mexico.” National Water Commission. Available at conagua.gob.mx/bancos- delagua/. Connor, J.D. D. Kaczan. 2013. “Principles for Economically Efficient and Environmentally Sustainable Water Mar- kets: The Australian Experience.” In Drought in Arid and Semi-Arid Regions, edited by Kurt Schwabe, Jose Albiac, Jeffery D. Connor, Rashid M. Hassan, and Liliana Meza González, 357–74. Springer Netherlands. Available at dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-6636-5_20. Cosgrove, W.S. F.R. Rijsberman. 2000. “World Water Vision: Making Water Everybody’s Business.” World Water Coun- cil. Available at worldwatercouncil.org/index.php?id=961. Culp, P., R. Glennon G. Libecap. 2014. “Shopping for Wa- ter: How the Market Can Mitigate Water Shortages in the American West.” 2014-05. Discussion Paper. The Brookings Institute. Available at hamiltonproject.org/ files/downloads_and_links/market_mitigate_water_short- age_in_west_paper_glennon_final.pdf. Colorado Water Trust (CWT). 2015. Colorado Water Trust Big Beaver Creek Reservoir / Big Beaver Creek White River. Available at coloradowatertrust.org/our-work/projects/ lake-avery-big-beaver-creek-white-river/#sthash.I3vg- PjZL.dpuf. de Albuquerque, C. 2011. “Special Rapporteur on the Human Right to Safe Drinking Water and Sanitation, Mission to the United States of America.” United Nations. Available
  • 97. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 77 Victorian Murray Valley / Frontier Economics. PANDORA Electronic Collection. Canberra, A.C.T: National Water Com- mission. Available at nla.gov.au/nla.arc-79821. Garrido, A. M.R. Llamas. 2009. “Water Management in Spain: An Example of Changing Paradigms.” Policy and Strategic Behaviour in Water Resource Management 125. Gassert, F., M. Landis, P. Reig, M. Luck T. Shiao. 2013. “Aq- ueduct Metadata Document, Aqueduct Global Maps 2.0.” World Resources Institute (WRI). Available at wri.org/sites/ default/files/pdf/aqueduct_metadata_global.pdf. Genevieve B., N. Carroll, M. Bennett, A. Leonardi K. Moull. 2014. “Gaining Depth: State of Watershed Investment 2014.” Washington, D.C: Forest Trends. Available at.forest- trends.org/documents/files/SOWI2014.pdf. George, A., A. Pierret, A. Boonsaner, V. Christian O. Planchon. 2009. “Potential and Limitations of Payments for Environ- mental Services (PES) as a Means to Manage Watershed Services in Mainland Southeast Asia.” International Jour- nal of the Commons 3 (1): 16–40. Getches, D.H. 1985. “Competing Demands for the Colorado River.” University of Colorado Law Review 56: 413. Gleick, P.H. 2002. “Water Management: Soft Water Paths.” Nature 418: 373. ———. 2003. “Global Freshwater Resources: Soft-Path Solu- tions for the 21st Century.” Science 302 (5650): 1524–28. Gleick, P.H., D. Haasz, C. Henges-Jeck, V. Srinivasan, G. Wolff, K. Kao Cushing A. Mann. 2003. “Waste Not, Want Not: The Potential for Urban Water Conservation in California.” Oakland CA: Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/wp- content/uploads/sites/21/2013/02/waste_not_want_not_ full_report3.pdf. Glennon, R. 2005. “Water Scarcity, Marketing, and Privatiza- tion.” Texas Law Review 83 (7): 1873–1902. Gómez-Baggethun, E., R. de Groot, P.L. Lomas C. Montes. 2010. “The History of Ecosystem Services in Economic Theory and Practice: From Early Notions to Markets and Payment Schemes.” Ecological Economics, Special Sec- tion - Payments for Environmental Services: Reconciling Theory and Practice, 69 (6): 1209–18. doi:10.1016/j.ecole- con.2009.11.007. Grafton, R.Q. J. Horne. 2014. “Water Markets in the Murray- Darling Basin.” Agricultural Water Management 145 (No- vember): 61–71. doi:10.1016/j.agwat.2013.12.001. Grafton, R.Q., C. Landry, G.D. Libecap, S. McGlennon R. O’Brien. 2010. “An Integrated Assessment of Water Mar- kets: Australia, Chile, China, South Africa and the USA.” ICER Working Paper 32-2010. ICER - International Centre for Economic Research. Available at ideas.repec.org/p/icr/ wpicer/32-2010.html. Faeth, P. 2000. Fertile Ground: Nutrient Trading’s Potential to Cost-Effectively Improve Water Quality. Washington, D.C.: World Resources Institute. Available at wri.org/sites/ default/files/pdf/fertile_ground.pdf. Famiglietti, J.S. 2014. “The Global Groundwater Crisis.” Na- ture Climate Change 4: 945–48. Farolfi, St. S. Perret. 2002. “Inter-Sectoral Competition for Water Allocation in Rural South Africa : Analysing a Case Study through a Standard Environmental Economics Approach.” Paper without proceedings Working paper: 2002-23. Department of Agricultural Economics, Exten- sion and Rural Development: University of Pretoria. http:// agritrop.cirad.fr/511263/. Feinglas, S., C. Gray P. Mayer. 2013. “Conservation Helps Limit Rate Increases for a Colorado Utility.” Alliance for Water Efficiency. Available at financingsustainablewater. org/resource-search/conservation-helps-limit-rate- increases-colorado-utility. Ferraro, P.J. 2008. “Asymmetric Information and Contract Design for Payments for Environmental Services.” Eco- logical Economics, Payments for Environmental Services in Developing and Developed Countries, 65 (4): 810–21. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.029. ———. 2009. “Regional Review of Payments for Wa- tershed Services: Sub-Saharan Africa.” Jour- nal of Sustainable Forestry 28 (3-5): 525–50. doi:10.1080/10549810802701234. Fischel, W.A. 1995. Regulatory Takings: Law, Economics, and Politics. Harvard University Press. Fisher-Vanden, K. S. Olmstead. 2013. “Moving Pollution Trading from Air to Water: Potential, Problems, and Prog- nosis.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 147–71. Forest Trends. 2015a. Watershed Connect. Available at wa- tershedconnect.com/ Forest Trends. 2015b. “Paw Paw River Watershed.” Program Inventory. Paw Paw River Watershed. Available at water- shedconnect.com/programs/Paw-Paw-River-Watershed. Fox, J. 2014. “The Role of Trading in Achieving Water Qual- ity Objectives.” presented at the United States House of Representatives, Committee on Transportation and Infrastructure, Subcommittee on Water Resources and Environment, Washington, DC, April 17. Available at wqt. epri.com/pdf/EPRI%20Testimony%20WQT%20Final%20 4-17-14.pdf. Freyfogle, E.T. 1996. “Water Rights and the Commonwealth.” Environmental Law 26: 27. Frontier Economics, and Australia National Water Commis- sion. 2007. The Economic and Social Impacts of Water Trading [electronic Resource] : Case Studies in the
  • 98. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT78 rent Initiatives.” Journal of Sustainable Forestry 28 (3-5): 551–75. doi:10.1080/10549810902794287. Huber, R.M., J. Ruitenbeek R.S. da Motta. 1998. “Market- Based Instruments for Environmental Policymaking in Latin America and the Caribbean - Lessons from Eleven Countries.” WDP381. The World Bank. Available at docu- ments.worldbank.org/curated/en/1998/11/438776/market- based-instruments-environmental-policymaking-latin- america-caribbean-lessons-eleven-countries. Hundley, N., Jr. 2001. The Great Thirst: Californians and Water—A History, Revised Edition. 2001 (revised). Un- versity of California Press. Available at ucpress.edu/book. php?isbn=9780520224568. International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED). 2015. Watershed Markets. Available at watershed- markets.org/ Jenkins, M.W., J.R. Lund, R.E. Howitt, A.J. Draper, S.M. Msangi, S.K. Tanaka, R.S. Ritzema G.F. Marques. 2004. “Optimi- zation of California’s Water Supply System: Results and Insights.” Journal of Water Resources Planning and Management 130 (4): 271–80. doi:10.1061/(ASCE)0733- 9496(2004)130:4(271). Jones, C., E. Branosky, M. Selman M. Perez. 2010. “How Nu- trient Trading Could Help Restore the Chesapeake Bay.” Washington, DC: World Resources Institute. Available at wri.org/working_papers/how_nutrient_trading_could_ help_restore_the_chesapeake_bay.pdf. Karousakis, K. Q. Brooke. 2010. Paying for Biodiversity: Enhancing the Cost-Effectiveness of Payments for Eco- system Services. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development. Available at oecd-ilibrary. org/content/book/9789264090279-en. Kenny, A. 2006. “Ecosystem Marketplace - Ecosystem Ser- vices in the New York City Watershed.” Ecosystem Mar- ketplace. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.com/pages/ dynamic/article.page.php?page_id=4130section=home. Koplow, D. 2004. The Use of Economic Instruments in Envi- ronmental Policy: Opportunties and Challenges. United Nations Environment Programme. Available at unep.ch/ etb/publication/EconInst/econInstruOppChnaFin.pdf. Kosoy, N., M. Martinez-Tuna, R. Muradian J. Martinez-Alier. 2007. “Payments for Environmental Services in Water- sheds: Insights from a Comparative Study of Three Cases in Central America.” Ecological Economics 61 (2–3): 446–55. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.03.016. Los Angeles Department of Water and Power (LA DWP). 2013. “Owens Lake Master Project.” Los Angeles, CA: Los Angeles Department of Water and Power. Available at ladwp.com/ladwp/faces/ladwp/aboutus/a-water/a-w- losangelesaqueduct/a-w-laa-owenslake. Grafton, R.Q., G. Libecap, E. Edwards, R O’Brien C. Landry. 2012. “Comparative Assessment of Water Markets: In- sights from the Murray-Darling Basin of Australia and the Western USA.” Water Policy 14: 175–93. Greiber, T., ed. 2009. Payments for Ecosystem Services: Le- gal and Institutional Frameworks. IUCN Environmental Policy and Law Paper, No. 78. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN, in collaboration with the IUCN Environmental Law Centre, Bonn, Germany. Available at cmsdata.iucn.org/downloads/ eplp_78_1.pdf. Hanak, E. E. Stryjewski. 2012. “California’s Water Market, By the Numbers: Update 2012.” Public Policy Institute of California. Available at wee.ppic.org/content/pubs/ report/R_1112EHR.pdf. Harrington, W. R.D. Morgenstern. 2004. “Economic Incen- tives Versus Command and Control: What’s the Best Ap- proach for Solving Environmental Problems?” Resources for the Future. Available at rff.org/Publications/Resources/ Documents/152/RFF_Resources_152_ecoincentives.pdf. Hauter, W. 2013. “D.C. District Court Fails on Pollution Trad- ing: Clean Water Act Trading Lawsuit Dismissed Due to Burden of Proof.” Food and Water Watch. December 16. Available at foodandwaterwatch.org/pressreleases/d-c- district-court-fails-on-pollution-trading-clean-water-act- trading-lawsuit-dismissed-due-to-burden-of-proof/. Hawkins, S. 2011. “Laying the Foundation: An Analytical Tool for Assessing Legal and Institutional Readiness for PES.” Forest Trends. Available at forest-trends.org/documents/ files/doc_3014.pdf. Heberger, M., H. Cooley P.H. Gleick. 2014. “Urban Water Conservation and Efficiency Potential in California.” Oak- land, CA: Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/wp- content/uploads/sites/21/2014/06/ca-water-urban.pdf. Howe, C.W. 2011. “The Efficient Water Market of the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy. District: Colorado, USA.” IBE Review reports CS22. WP6 IBE EX-POST Case Stud- ies. EPI Water. Available at feem-project.net/epiwater/ docs/d32-d6-1/CS22_Colorado.pdf. Howe, C.W. C. Goemans. 2003. “Water Transfers and Their Impacts: Lessons from Three Colorado Water Markets.” JAWRA Journal of the American Water Resources Association 39 (5): 1055–65. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2003. tb03692.x. Howitt, R.E. 1998. “Spot Prices, Option Prices, and Water Markets: An Analysis of Emerging Markets in California.” In Markets for Water, edited by K. William Easter, Mark W. Rosegrant, and Ariel Dinar, 119–40. Natural Resource Management and Policy 15. Springer US. Huang, M., S.K. Upadhyaya, R. Jindal J. Kerr. 2009. “Pay- ments for Watershed Services in Asia: A Review of Cur-
  • 99. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 79 Moench, M., A. Dixit, S. Janakarajan, M.S. Rathore S. Mudra- kartha. 2003. The Fluid Mosaic: Water Governance in the Context of Variability, Uncertainty and Change: A Synthesis Paper. Nepal Water Conservation Foundation, Kathmandu, and the Institute for Social and Environmen- tal Transition, Boulder, Colorado, US. Moore, R.H. 2012. “Reaching the Potential of Water-Quality Trading.” In Water Sustainability in Agriculture, 73–81. Ithaca, New York: National Agriculutural Biotechnology Council. Available at nabc.cals.cornell.edu/Publications/ Reports/nabc_24/24_2_1_Moore.pdf. Morgan, C. A. Wolverton. 2005. “Water Quality Trading in the United States.” 05-07. Working Paper. National Cen- ter for Environmental Economics. Available at yosemite. epa.gov/ee/epa/eed.nsf/be6bc67216ab9f5d85256e460 07b104d/3e026cbb6a9956918525702f005e383c/$FI LE/2005-07.pdf. MOTU. 2009. “Lake Rotorua Short Films.” Motu Economic and Public Policy Research. Available at motu.org.nz/ research/detail/rotorua_films. Muñoz-Piña, C., A. Guevara, J.M. Torres J. Braña. 2008. “Paying for the Hydrological Services of Mexico’s Forests: Analysis, Negotiations and Results.” Ecological Econom- ics, Payments for Environmental Services in Developing and Developed Countries, 65 (4): 725–36. doi:10.1016/j. ecolecon.2007.07.031. Naeem, S., J. C. Ingram, A. Varga, T. Agardy, P. Barten, G. Ben- nett, E. Bloomgarden, et al., 2015. “Get the Science Right When Paying for Nature’s Services.” Science 347 (6227): 1206–7. doi:10.1126/science.aaa1403. National Fish and Wildlife Foundation. 2014. “FY 2013 Annual Report: Columbia Basin Water Transactions Program.” Portland, Oregon: National Fish and Wildlife Foundation. Available at cbwtp.org/jsp/cbwtp/library/documents/ NLB_CBWTP_Annual13_R8.pdf. National Research Council. 1968. Water and Choice in the Colorado Basin: An Example of Alternatives in Water Management: A Report. National Academies. ———. 1992. Water Transfers in the West:: Efficiency, Eq- uity, and the Environment. National Academies Press. Neef, A. D. Thomas. 2009. “Rewarding the Upland Poor for Saving the Commons? Evidence from Southeast Asia.” International Journal of the Commons 3 (1): 1–15. Newburn, D.A. R.T. Woodward. 2012. “An Ex Post Evalu- ation of Ohio’s Great Miami Water Quality Trading Program1.” JAWRA Journal of the American Water Resources Association 48 (1): 156–69. doi:10.1111/j.1752- 1688.2011.00601.x. Raes, L. P. Mohebalian. 2013. “The Socio Bosque Pro- gram for Rainforest and Paramo Conservation, Ecuado.” Geneva Switzerland: The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity. Available at teebweb.org/wp-content/ uploads/2014/07/The-Socio-Bosque-Programme-for- rainforest-and-Paramo-Conservation-Ecuador-.pdf. Leflaive, X., M. Witmer, R. Martin-Hurtado, M. Bakker, T. Kram, L. Bouwman, H. Visser, A. Bouwman, H. Hilderink K. Kim. 2012. “Water.” In OECD Environmental Outlook, 275–332. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Available at oecd-ilibrary.org/content/ chapter/env_outlook-2012-8-en. Levine, G., R. Barker C.C. Huang. 2007. “Water Transfer from Agriculture to Urban Uses: Lessons Learned, with Policy Considerations.” Paddy and Water Environment 5 (4): 213–22. doi:10.1007/s10333-007-0092-8. LimnoTech The Nature Conservancy. 2013. “Quantifying Replenish Benefits in Community Water Partnership Projects, Final Report for 2012.” The Coca-Cola Com- pany. Available at assets.coca-colacompany.com/2f/cb/ e5d2ca1e4c58a38adbe8586d06db/final-quanitification- report-water-pdf.pdf. Livingston, M.L. 1998. “Institutional Requisites for Efficient Water Markets.” In Markets for Water: Potential and Per- formance, 19–33. Springer. Available at link.springer.com/ chapter/10.1007/978-0-585-32088-5_2. Lovins, A. 1977. Soft energy paths: Toward a durable peace. Ballinger Publishing Co., Cambridge, Massachusetts, US. Marida, P. 2010. “Ohio’s Water Quality Trading Programs - To Be Taken Over by Coal?” The Ohio Sierran, A Publica- tion of the Ohio Chapter of the Sierra Club. Mariola, M.J. 2009. “Are Markets the Solution to Water Pollu- tion? A Sociological Investigation of Water Quality Trad- ing.” Ph.D. Dissertation, Columbus, Ohio: The Ohio State University. Available at rave.ohiolink.edu/etdc/view?acc_ num=osu1250015222. Medellín-Azuara, J., J.J. Harou, M.A. Olivares, K. Madani, J.R. Lund, R.E. Howitt, S.K. Tanaka, M.W. Jenkins T. Zhu. 2008. “Adaptability and Adaptations of California’s Water Supply System to Dry Climate Warming.” Climatic Change 87 (1): 75–90. Meinzen-Dick, R. R. Pradhan. 2005. “Recognizing Multiple Water Uses in Intersectoral Water Transfers.” In Asian Irrigation in Transition: Responding to Challenges, 178– 205. Asian Institute of Technology, Bangkok, Thailand. Richards, M. 2013. “What Do We Know about Gender and Other Social Impacts of IWS Projects?: A Literature Re- view.” Forest Trends. Available at forest-trends.org/docu- ments/files/doc_4089.pdf.
  • 100. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT80 Porras, I., B. Aylward J. Dengel. 2013. “Monitoring Pay- ments for Watershed Services Schemes in Developing Countries.” London, UK: International Institute for Envi- ronment and Development. Available at pubs.iied.org/ pdfs/16525IIED.pdf. Porras, I., D.N. Barton, A. Chacon-Cascante M. Miranda. 2013. “Learning from 20 Years of Payments for Ecosys- tem Services in Costa Rica.” London, UK: International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at pubs.iied.org/pdfs/16514IIED.pdf. Porras, I. N. Neves. 2006a. “China - Sloping Lands Con- version Programme.” Markets for Watershed Services - Country Profile. International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at watershedmarkets.org/ documents/China_SLCP_eng.pdf. ———. 2006b. “Mexico - National PSAH Programme.” Mar- ket for Watershed Services - Country Profile. International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at watershedmarkets.org/documents/Mexico_National_ PSAH_eng.pdf. Porras, I.T., M. Grieg-Gran N. Neves. 2008. All That Glit- ters: A Review of Payments for Watershed Services in Developing Countries. IIED. Available at pubs.iied.org/ pdfs/13542IIED.pdf. Postel, S.L., G.C. Daily P.R. Ehrlich. 1996. “Appropriation of Renewable Fresh Water.” Science 271 (5250): 785–88. Queensland Water Commission. 2010. “South East Queensland Water Strategy 2010.” 29229. Queensland Water Commission. Available at qwc.qld.gov.au. Ravnborg, H.M., M.G. Damsgaard K. Raben. 2007. “Pay- ments for Ecosystem Services - Issues and Pro-Poor Opportunities for Development Assistance.” Copenhagen, Denmark: Danish Institute for International Studies. Reimers, F. 2013. “Shifting Ground.” Nature Conservancy, June. Rockefeller Foundation. 2013. Key Factors Supporting Small- Scale Coastal Fisheries Management. Romano, D. M. Leporati. 2002. “The Distributive Impact of the Water Market in Chile: A Case Study in Limari Province, 1981- 1997.” Quarterly Journal of International Agriculture 41 (1): 41–58. Rozza, J.P., B.D. Richter, W.M. Larson, T. Redder, K. Vigerstol P. Bowen P. 2013. “Corporate Water Stewardship: Achiev- ing a Sustainable Balance.” Journal of Management and Sustainability 3 (4). Available at dx.doi.org/10.5539/jms. v3n4p41. Newlin, B.D., M.W. Jenkins, J.R. Lund R.E. Howitt. 2002. “Southern California Water Markets: Potential and Limita- tions.” Journal of Water Resources Planning and Man- agement 128 (1): 21–32. NSWDEC. 2003. Hunter River Salinity Trading Scheme: Working Together to Protect River Quality and Sustain Economic Development. Sydney, Australia: Department of Environment and Conservation, New South Wales. Available at epa.nsw.gov.au/resources/licensing/hrsts/ hrsts.pdf. NWC. 2013. Australian National Water Commission Markets Report 2012-2013. Canberra. Available at nwc.gov.au/pub- lications/topic/water-industry/australian-water-markets- report-2012-13. O’Donnell, M. B. Colby. 2010. “Water Banks: A Tool for En- hancing Water Supply Reliability.” Guidebook. University of Arizona. Available at ag.arizona.edu/arec/pubs/faculty- pubs/ewsr-Banks-final-5-12-10.pdf. O’Grady, D. 2011. “Sociopolitical Conditions for Success- ful Water Quality Trading in the South Nation River Watershed, Ontario, Canada1.” JAWRA Journal of the American Water Resources Association 47 (1): 39–51. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2010.00511.x. Olszowa, D.M., J.P. Heath P.A. Tennant. 1998. “Evalua- tion of Nutrient Loads and Sources in the Ohio River Basin.” In . Ohio River Valley Water Sanitation Com- mission (ORSANCO). http://acwi.gov/monitoring/ conference/98proceedings/Papers/54-OLSZ.html. Pagiola, S. 2008. “Payments for Environmental Services in Costa Rica.” Ecological Economics, Payments for Envi- ronmental Services in Developing and Developed Coun- tries, 65 (4): 712–24. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.033. Pagiola, S., A. Arcenas G. Platais. 2005. “Can Payments for Environmental Services Help Reduce Poverty? An Explo- ration of the Issues and the Evidence to Date from Latin America.” World Development, Institutional arrange- ments for rural poverty reduction and resource conserva- tion, 33 (2): 237–53. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.011. Pant, D., M. Bhattarai G. Basnet. 2008. “Implications Of Bulk Water Transfer On Local Water Management Institutions: A Case Study of the Melamchi Water Supply Project in Nepal.” Working Paper 78. Consultative Group on Interna- tional Agricultural Research (CGIAR). Available at indiae- nvironmentportal.org.in/files/capriwp78.pdf. Perrot-Maitre, D. 2006. “The Vittel Payments for Ecosystem Services: A ‘Perfect’ PES Case?” London, UK: International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at katoombagroup.org/~katoomba/documents/tools/ TheVittelpaymentsforecosystemservices.pdf.
  • 101. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 81 Thobani, M. 1997. “Formal Water Markets: Why, When, and How to Introduce Tradable Water Rights.” World Bank Research Observer 12 (2): 161–79. TWSST, 2014. Transforming water scarcity through trading, 2012–2015, Final report. United Nations. 2009. “World Water Development Report 3: Water in a Changing World.” Available at webworld.unes- co.org/water/wwap/wwdr/wwdr3/tableofcontents.shtml. ———. 2012. “World Water Development Report 4: Managing Water under Uncertainty and Risk.” Paris, France: United Nations. http://unesdoc.unesco.org/ images/0021/002156/215644e.pdf. UNEP. 2009. “Training Resource Manual: The Use of Eco- nomic Instruments for Environmental and Natural Re- source Management.” Available at unep.ch/etb/publica- tions/EI%20manual%202009/Training%20Resource%20 Manual.pdf. UNEP. 2004. “The Use of Economic Instruments in Environ- mental Policy: Opportunities and Challenges.” Available at unep.ch/etb/publication/EconInst/econInstruOppCh- naFin.pdf. US Bureau of Reclamation. 2015. “Moving Forward, Phase 1 Report.” Bureau of Reclamation, US Department of the In- terior. Available at usbr.gov/lc/region/programs/crbstudy/ MovingForward/Phase1Report.html. US Census Bureau. 2012. “The Statistical Abstract of the United States, Table 435: State and Local Governments- -Summary of Finances.” Washington, DC. Available at census.gov/compendia/statab/2012/tables/12s0435.pdf. US EPA. 2001. “The United States Experiences with Eco- nomic Incentives for Protecting the Environment.” EPA- 240-R-01-001. Available at yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/ eerm.nsf/vwAN/EE-0216B-13.pdf/$file/EE-0216B-13.pdf. US EPA. 2003. “Final Water Quality Trading Policy.” January 13. http://water.epa.gov/type/watersheds/trading/finalpo- licy2003.cfm. ———. 2009. “Steam Electric Power Generation Point Source Category: Final Detailed Study Report.” United States Environmental Protection Agency. Available at water.epa.gov/scitech/wastetech/guide/steam-electric/ upload/Steam-Electric_Detailed-Study-Report_2009.pdf. ———. 2010. “How Water Quality (Nutrient) Trading Enables Alpine Cheese Company to Improve Water Quality and Increase Economic Development in the Region.” US. Available at water.epa.gov/type/watersheds/named/ms- basin/oh_03.cfm. Ruppert, T.K. 2004. “Water Quality Trading and Agricultural Nonpoint Source Pollution: An Analysis of the Effective- ness and Fairness of EPA’s Policy on Water Quality Trad- ing.” Villanova Environmental Law Journal 15: 1. Salzman, J. 2006. “Thirst: A Short History of Drinking Water.” Yale Journal of Law and the Humanities 17 (3). Avail- able at lsr.nellco.org/duke_fs/31. Schmalensee, R R.N. Stavins. 2013. “The SO2 Allowance Trading System: The Ironic History of a Grand Policy Experiment.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 27 (1): 103–22. doi:10.1257/jep.27.1.103. Sharma, S.K. K. Vairavamoorthy. 2009. “Urban Water De- mand Management: Prospects and Challenges for the Developing Countries.” Water and Environment Journal 23 (3): 210–18. doi:10.1111/j.1747-6593.2008.00134.x. Shortle, J.S. R.D. Horan. 2005. “Water Quality Trading.” Penn State Environmental Law Review 14: 231. ———. 2008. “The Economics of Water Quality Trading.” International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics 2 (2): 101–33. Smith, S., P. Rowcroft, M. Everard, L. Couldrick, M. Reed, H. Rogers, T. Quick, C. Eves C. White. 2013. “Payments for Ecosystem Services: A Best Practice Guide.” Defra, London: Department for Environment, Food, and Rural Affairs. Available at gov.uk/government/uploads/system/ uploads/attachment_data/file/200920/pb13932-pes- bestpractice-20130522.pdf. Stacey, P.E., T. Haze I. Raffa. 2012. “Meeting the Nitrogen Wasteload Allocation in Connecticut: Connecticut’s Nitro- gen Credit Exchange After 10 Years of Operation as the Nation’s Most Significant Water Quality Trading Program.” presented at the 36th annual Meeting of the New Eng- land Association of Environmental Biologists, Falmouth, Massachusetts, March 22. Available at epa.gov/region1/ neaeb2012/pdfs/0930_BR2_PaulStacey.pdf. Stanton, T., M. Echavarria, K. Hamilton C. Ott. 2010. “State of Watershed Payments: An Emerging Marketplace.” Ecosystem Marketplace. Available at watershedconnect. com/documents/files/state_of_watershed_payments_an_ emerging_marketplace.pdf. Stavins, R.N. 2001. “Experience with Market-Based Environ- mental Policy Instruments.” Resources for the Future. Available at rff.org/documents/rff-dp-01-58.pdf. Tarlock, A.D. 2014. “Mexico and the United States Assume a Legal Duty to Provide Colorado River Delta Restoration Flows: An Important International Environmental and Water Law Precedent.” Review of European, Compara- tive International Environmental Law 23 (1): 76–87. doi:10.1111/reel.12066.
  • 102. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT82 Worster, D. 1985. Rivers of Empire: Water, Aridity, and the Growth of the American West. Oxford University Press. Wunder, S. 2005. “Payments for Environmental Services: Some Nuts and Bolts.” CIFOR Occasional Paper No. 42. Jakarta, Indonesia: Center for Internatioanl Forestry Re- search. Available at theredddesk.org/sites/default/files/ resources/pdf/2012/payment-ecosystem-services-02.pdf. ———. 2008. “Payments for Environmental Services and the Poor: Concepts and Preliminary Evidence.” Environ- ment and Development Economics 13 (03): 279–97. doi:10.1017/S1355770X08004282. Young, M.D. 2010. “Environmental Effectiveness and Eco- nomic Efficiency of Water Use in Agriculture: The Experi- ence of and Lessons from the Australian Water Reform Programme.” Background Report. Sustainable Manage- ment of Water Resources in Agriculture. OECD. Available at dx.doi.org/10.1787/786732081512. Young, M. 2015. “Tricks of the Trade: Learning From Austra- lia’s Water Reform Experience.” Waterfront 1 (1): 10–12. Zbinden, S. D.R. Lee. 2005. “Paying for Environmental Ser- vices: An Analysis of Participation in Costa Rica’s PSA Program.” World Development, Institutional arrange- ments for rural poverty reduction and resource conserva- tion, 33 (2): 255–72. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.012. Zedler, J.B. S. Kercher. 2005. “WETLAND RESOURCES: Status, Trends, Ecosystem Services, and Restorability.” Annual Review of Environment and Resources 30 (1): 39–74. doi:10.1146/annurev.energy.30.050504.144248. Zellmer, S.B. J. Harder. 2007. “Unbundling Property in Water.” Alabama Law Review 59: 679. Zucchino, D. 2015. “Duke Energy Fined $102 Million for Pol- luting Rivers with Coal Ash.” Los Angeles Times, May 14. Available at latimes.com/nation/la-na-duke-energy-coal- ash-20150514-story.html#page=1. Zwarteveen, M.Z. 1997. “Water: From Basic Need to Com- modity: A Discussion on Gender and Water Rights in the Context of Irrigation.” World Development 25 (8): 1335–49. Wada, Y., L.P.H. van Beek, C.M. van Kempen, J.W.T.M. Reck- man, S. Vasak M.F.P. Bierkens. 2010. “Global Depletion of Groundwater Resources.” Geophysical Research Letters 37 (20): L20402. doi:10.1029/2010GL044571. Wallace, K.H. 2007. “Trading Pollution for Water Quality: Assessing the Effects of Market-Based Instruments in Three Basins.” Master’s Thesis, Cambridge, Massachu- setts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Available at dspace.mit.edu/handle/1721.1/39938. Watershed Agricultural Council. 2011. “Strategic Plan: 2011- 2014.” Walton, New York. Available at nycwatershed.org/ pdfs/Strategic_Plan_2011-2014.pdf. Wheeler, S.A. J. Cheesman. 2013. “Key Findings from a Sur- vey of Sellers to the Restoring the Balance Programme.” Economic Papers: A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 32 (3): 340–52. doi:10.1111/1759-3441.12038. Wind, M.H.A. 2012. “Water Emissions Trading in Europe - A Literature Overview and Discussion of Opportunities.” Eco-consult Environmental Economics. http://www.eco- consult.nl/images/pdf/WET_in_Europe_v3.pdf. Woodward, R.T., R.A. Kaiser A.B. Wicks. 2002. “The Struc- ture and Practice of Water Quality Trading Markets.” Journal of the American Water Resources Association 38 (4): 967–79. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2002.tb05538.x. World Economic Forum (WEF). 2012. “Global Risks 2012, Seventh Edition.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at weforum.org/docs/WEF_Glo- balRisks_Report_2012.pdf. ———. 2013. “Global Risks 2013, Eighth Edition.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalRisks_Report_2013.pdf. ———. 2014. “Global Risks 2014, Ninth Edition.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalRisks_Report_2014.pdf. ———. 2015. “Global Risks 2015, 10th Edition.” Geneva, Swit- zerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at wefo- rum.org/docs/WEF_Global_Risks_2015_Report15.pdf. World Health Organization and UNICEF. 2015. “Progress on Sanitation and Drinking Water - 2015 Update and MDG Assessment.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Health Orga- nization. Available at wssinfo.org/fileadmin/user_upload/ resources/JMP-Update-report-2015_English.pdf.
  • 105. Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management December 2015 SYNTHESIS REVIEW THE RockefellerFoundation EVALUATIONOFFICE Financial support provided by
  • 106. About the Pacific Institute The Pacific Institute envisions a world in which society, the economy, and the environment have the water they need to thrive now and in the future. In pursuit of this vision, the Pacific Institute creates and advances solutions to the world’s most pressing water challenges, such as unsustainable water manage- ment and use, climate change, environmental degradation, and basic lack of access to fresh water and sanitation. Since 1987, the Pacific Institute has cut across traditional areas of study and actively collabo- rated with a diverse set of stakeholders, including leading policy makers, scientists, corporate leaders, and international organizations such as the United Nations, advocacy groups, and local communities. This interdisciplinary and independent approach helps bring diverse groups together to forge effective real-world solutions. About the Foundation Center Established in 1956, Foundation Center is the leading source of information about philanthropy worldwide. Through data, analysis, and training, it connects people who want to change the world to the resources they need to succeed. The Foundation Center maintains the most comprehensive database on US and, increasingly, global grantmakers and their grants – a robust, accessible knowledge bank for the sector. It also operates research, education, and training programs designed to advance knowledge of philanthro- py at every level. The Foundation Center’s IssueLab service works to gather, index, and share the collec- tive intelligence of the social sector more effectively, providing free access to thousands of case studies, evaluations, white papers, and issue briefs addressing some of the world’s most pressing problems. About The Rockefeller Foundation For more than 100 years, The Rockefeller Foundation’s mission has been to promote the well-being of humanity throughout the world. Today, The Rockefeller Foundation pursues this mission through dual goals: advancing inclusive economies that expand opportunities for more broadly shared prosper- ity, and building resilience by helping people, communities, and institutions prepare for, withstand and emerge stronger from acute shocks and chronic stresses. Committed to supporting learning, account- ability and performance improvements, the Evaluation Office of The Rockefeller Foundation works with staff, grantees, and partners to strengthen evaluation practice and to support innovative approaches to monitoring, evaluation, and learning. For this synthesis review, The Rockefeller Foundation provided financial support, the Foundation Center and its IssueLab service were involved in project and technology development, and the Pacific Institute authored the report. Pacific Institute authors included Heather Cooley, Michael Cohen, Matthew Heberger, and Heather Rippman. Cover: Hudson River, NY. Photograph by Daniel Case.
  • 107. The contents of this report are the views of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of The Rockefeller Foundation. © 2015, The Rockefeller Foundation This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 License Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management December 2015 Financial support provided by THE RockefellerFoundation EVALUATIONOFFICE
  • 109. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT iii Table of Contents Acronyms v Foreword vii Acknowledgements ix Executive summary x Water trading x Payment for ecosystem services xiii Water quality trading xv Conclusions xvi 1 Introduction 1 2 Research methodology 5 3 Environmental policy instruments 7 3.1 Water trading 10 Description 10 Application 12 Environmental, economic, and social performance 16 Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions 25 3.2 Payment for ecosystem services/payment for watershed services 28 Description 28 Application 30 Environmental, economic, and social performance 31 Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions 35 3.3 Water quality trading 39 Description 39 Application 41 Environmental, economic, and social performance 44 Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions 48 4 Role of the private sector 53 4.1 Corporate water stewardship 53 4.2 Private sector engagement with incentive-based instruments 55 5 Summary and conclusions 61
  • 110. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTiv Annexes Annex 1: Demand management 63 Annex 2: Water trading in Australia: Lessons from the Murray-Darling Basin 66 Background 66 MCB and the Colorado River Basin 66 History 67 Water trading activity 69 Enabling conditions 71 Lessons learned 71 Glossary 74 References 75
  • 111. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT v Acronyms ARP Acid Rain Program (US) AWS Alliance for Water Stewardship BIER Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable BMP Best management practices CAC Command-and-control CDP Carbon Disclosure Project (former name) CRP Conservation Reserve Program (US) DEG German Investment and Development Corporation EPA Environmental Protection Agency (US) EPRI Electric Power Research Institute GEF The Global Environment Facility GPCD Gallons per capita daily IID Imperial Irrigation District (California, US) IWS Investment in watershed services MAF Million acre-feet MI Municipal and industrial MDB Murray-Darling Basin MDBA Murray-Darling Basin Authority MWD Metropolitan Water District of Southern California (California, US) MWELO Model Water Efficient Landscape Ordinance NRC National Research Council (US) NSWDEC New South Wales Department of Education and Communities (Australia) NWC National Water Commission (Australia) PES Payment for ecosystems services PSAH Programme for Hydrological Environmental Services (Mexico) PSA Pagos por servicios ambientales (payment for environmental services) PWS Payment for watershed services RUPES Rewarding Upland Poor for Environmental Services (Indonesia) SBP Socio Bosque Program (Ecuador) SDCWA San Diego County Water Authority SO2 Sulfur dioxide SWP State Water Project (California, US) TMDL Total maximum daily load TWSTT Transforming Water Scarcity through Trading
  • 112. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTvi UCSB University of California at Santa Barbara UN United Nations UNDP United Nations Development Programme UNEP United Nations Environment Programme USBR United States Bureau of Reclamation WEF World Economic Forum WfW Working for Water (South Africa) WHO World Health Organization WQT Water quality trading WRI World Resources Institute WWF World Wide Fund for Nature
  • 113. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT vii Foreword Human transformation of freshwater ecosystems is rapidly exceeding capacity required to sustain the conditions we need to survive and thrive. Water crises are already impacting people around the globe – from river basins in California and China, to the cities of São Palo and Bangkok. Under current population and growth trends, the 2030 Water Resources Group predicts global water demand will exceed available supply by 40 percent by 2030. Humans have used, benefited from, and shaped the natural environment for the whole of human history. But what we have not done – especially in the course of industrialization and modernization – is find effective ways to integrate natural ecosystems into our economic and social systems. In response to these challenges, The Rockefeller Foundation’s work focuses on incentive-based solutions that harness the importance of ecosystems as an asset for smart development, economic and social progress, and long-term resilience. In our work on agriculture and food security, climate change, energy, and fisheries, we seek new approaches to environmental care that will create incentives for the wise use of resources, and preserve their resilience. And in all of our work we place particular emphasis on the effects of these solutions on the poor or otherwise vulnerable members of society, who are most directly dependent on ecosystems to meet their basic needs and are mostly likely to bear the consequences of environmental degradation. Freshwater crises are representative of the kind of misaligned incentives we seek to correct. Freshwater allocation and management systems often place little value on the benefits of functioning ecosystems. This, in turn, leads to a vicious cycle in which ecosystem degradation and overuse reduce future water supplies, making even more people vulnerable to water scarcity. As water crises continue to capture public attention – in January, the World Economic Forum’s Global Risk Report 2015 named water crises the number one economic risk in terms of impact – and decision makers worldwide scramble for answers, The Rockefeller Foundation is eager to help support the identification of sound solutions by synthesiz- ing the knowledge and lessons from past and current water management interventions. The synthesis report that follows examines several incentive-based instruments for improving freshwa- ter management for all users, including poor and vulnerable populations and the freshwater ecosystems themselves. The report examines the economic, social, and environmental performance of three tools, which were selected because: there is growing interest in applying these instruments in a range of settings, they are clearly focused on voluntary transactions rather than sanctions or voluntary standards, they can be applied to improve water quality or quantity, and there is an existing body of literature about their implementation upon which we can build. However, one of the key findings is that these transac- tions are often not voluntary. The report highlights the importance of finding a fit between a commu- nity’s water goals and the water management tool(s) it might choose and, perhaps most importantly, it characterizes the enabling conditions required for their effective implementation. We hope this synthesis
  • 114. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTviii review will serve as an entry point for those exploring opportunities to improve the management of freshwater, and will spark the development of more robust solutions to improve our management and maintenance of freshwater systems.  We hope that you will find this report useful and encourage you to explore the accompanying learning tool at freshwater.issuelab.org and to share it widely with colleagues. Dr. Fred Boltz Managing Director, Ecosystems The Rockefeller Foundation
  • 115. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT ix Acknowledgements The overall design of this synthesis review was led and managed collaboratively by Gabi Fitz from the Foundation Center and Alex Martinez from The Rockefeller Foundation. The research, analysis and written synthesis were undertaken by a freshwater specialist team from the Pacific Institute led by Heather Cooley and Michael Cohen, and assisted by Matthew Heberger and Heather Rippman. Their work was further supported by John Berggren, who provided research assistance and Genevieve Bennett, Roy Brouwer, Jessica Fox, Chuck Howe, Cy Jones, Tony McLeod, Marcus Moench, and Ina Porras who all provided the team with valuable information and suggested additional readings. The visualization and special collection were designed and developed by Lisa Brooks and Gabi Fitz from the Foundation Center and IssueLab, in collaboration with ThreeStory Studio. Peer review was provided by Dr. Casey Brown of the University of Massachusetts, Matt Elliott, Amy Dickie, Mark Michelin, Emily Peterson, and James Giampietro of California Environmental Associates, The Rockefeller Foundation Freshwater Team, and Nancy MacPherson from The Rockefeller Founda- tion’s Evaluation Office. Learning from Experience – an ongoing collaboration between the Foundation Center and The Rockefeller Foundation This synthesis review, Incentive-based Instruments for Water Management, is part of an ongoing collab- oration between The Rockefeller Foundation and the Foundation Center, aimed at helping organizations build more effectively on each other’s knowledge, lessons and experience. With financial support from The Rockefeller Foundation, the Foundation Center is engaging in synthesis reviews and the develop- ment of supportive technologies and practices that facilitate the collection, synthesis, and sharing of the sector’s collective knowledge. As part of our collaboration, we are committed to sharing all work products from these efforts as public goods. Too often, systematic and synthesis reviews result in a public report but leave future researchers having to duplicate search and selection efforts in order to further build on a synthesis. By collecting and sharing coded search results through an open repository and openly licensing all work products, we hope other researchers can more freely use and repurpose our findings. Our goal is to contribute to better programmatic and funding strategies by enabling teams and organizations to start with a more inclusive and comprehensive understanding of what has worked, what hasn’t, and why. Gabi Fitz Nancy MacPherson Director of Knowledge Management Initiatives Managing Director, Evaluation Foundation Center The Rockefeller Foundation
  • 116. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTx Executive summary Water is one of our most precious and valuable resources and is fundamental for maintaining human health, economic activity, and critical ecosystem functions. Yet, we can see clear signs of the overexploi- tation of available freshwater resources and the resultant inability to meet basic human and ecosystem needs. Already, some iconic rivers, such as the Colorado in the United States and the Yellow in China, no longer reach the sea. Groundwater withdrawals have tripled over the past 50 years, with groundwater ex- traction exceeding natural recharge in some areas, causing widespread depletion and declining ground- water levels. More than 660 million people lack access to an improved drinking water source, predomi- nantly in sub-Saharan Africa and Oceania, and some 2.4 billion people lack access to basic sanitation.1 At the same time, the world’s water quality is becoming increasingly degraded, with water pollution exac- erbating the challenges posed by water scarcity. Pressure on water resources is intensifying in response to challenges such as economic and population growth, and, in turn, is having major impacts on our social, economic, and environmental well-being. With traditional approaches to managing water having proven insufficient to address these challenges, new approaches and policies are needed. Policy makers and water managers are showing increasing interest in incentive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water resources. In most regions, laws and regulations have been the primary policy tools employed to improve envi- ronmental outcomes. However, over the past several decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to reallocate water, or reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products. This report provides a synthesis review of a set of incentive-based instruments that have been employed to varying degrees around the world. It is part of an effort by The Rockefeller Foundation to improve understanding of both the potential of these instruments and their limitations. The report is divided into five sections. Section 1 provides an introduction to the synthesis review. Section 2 describes the research methodology. Section 3 provides background on policy instruments and detail on three incentive-based instruments – water trading, payment for ecosystem services, and water quality trading – describing the application of each, including their environmental, economic, and social performances, and the condi- tions needed for their implementation. Section 4 highlights the role of the private sector in implementing these instruments, and Section 5 provides a summary and conclusions. Water trading Water trading refers to the temporary or permanent transfer of the right to use water in exchange for some form of compensation. It is perhaps the best known and most widely used method of reallocating water. It has proven, in some cases, to be less expensive, more flexible, and less time-consuming than 1 An “improved” drinking-water source is one that, by nature of its construction and when properly used, adequately protects the source from outside contamination, particularly fecal matter.
  • 117. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xi developing new water supplies through, for example, constructing new diversion structures or desali- nation plants. Similarly, water trading is generally a more accepted method of reallocating water than state appropriation or revoking of existing water rights. Today, examples of successful water trading in Australia and other locations – combined with classic economic theory which suggests that market mechanisms can optimize resource allocation – have heightened interest in this instrument in both academic literature and popular media. Water trading occurs within sectors, from agriculture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban, across sectors and, less frequently, from either of these to the environment. Water trading exists, to varying degrees, in countries around the world, though the most active water trading markets are in Australia and the western United States. In Australia, the total value of water trading in fiscal year 2012–13 exceeded $1.4 billion, with much of that activity concentrated within the Murray-Darling Basin. While the total volume of water traded via long-term trades within the Murray-Darling Basin decreased slightly in fiscal year 2012–2013, the volume of water traded via short-term trades increased by 44 percent from the previous year, from almost 3.5 to 5.0 million acre-feet (MAF), or about 50 percent of the total surface water use in the basin.2 In the western United States, where the scale of water trading is considerably lower, there were more than 4,000 water trades between 1987 and 2008. In 2011, the most recent year for which data are available, more than 1.4 MAF of water were traded in California, representing about 4 percent of the total water use that year. Of that amount, 42 percent of the water traded went to municipal and industrial users, 37 percent to agricultural users, 17 percent was used for environmental purposes, and the remainder was for mixed uses. The actual results of water trading worldwide have been decidedly mixed, due to two key challenges: ex- ternalities and transaction costs. In Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin, the federal government overcame some of those challenges by investing more than $3 billion to purchase water for the environment, pro- tecting ecological resources and directly addressing one of the major challenges to water trading. This has facilitated trading in the basin and reduced transaction costs by shifting them to national taxpayers. Over the last 30 years, the federal government also implemented significant institutional changes that facilitated trading and reduced transaction costs. Short-term water trading within irrigation districts in the United States, such as within the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, occurs smoothly and quickly because intra-district trades undergo very limited oversight, and because the third-party impacts of such trades tend to be small or negligible. However, these examples of successful water trading regimes are countered by critical arguments and examples of less-successful trades from various parts of the world. Many authors challenge the applica- bility and efficacy of water trading, contending that externalities and the unique characteristics of water itself pose significant obstacles to trading water. Many of these externalities arise from the physical properties of water: it is heavy, unwieldy, and easily contaminated; varies seasonally and from year to year; and is readily lost through evaporation, seepage, or runoff. Further, externalities may be borne by disparate parties, such as the environment or future generations, challenging efforts to compensate those injured by trading. Questions of externalities, commodification, and the special nature of water 2 An acre-foot, the conventional unit of water measurement in the western United States, is equivalent to 325,851 gallons or 1,233.48 m3.
  • 118. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxii itself highlight the challenges faced when seeking to implement or expand water trading. Critics also highlight the many examples of “buy-and-dry” water trades, where water-rich agricultural areas sell their water rights, often to wealthier cities, only to find that rural communities as a whole suffer when agricul- tural production declines. Critics have pointed to examples around the world where wealthy communi- ties or interests have purchased and withdrawn water from less powerful, poor rural areas. The environmental performance of water trading has been highly variable, depending on the type of trade and site-specific conditions. Water trading has been used as a mechanism to obtain water for ecological purposes, to augment streamflow, and to address water quality concerns (such as tempera- ture) in threatened reaches. The benefits of voluntary, incentive-based water acquisition include ease of transaction and greater community support, especially relative to regulatory takings,3 though in most areas, such activity still represents a tiny fraction of total water use in any given area. In California, in the last three decades, environmental water purchases averaged 152,000 acre-feet per year, accounting for about 14 percent of trading activity and less than 0.5 percent of total water use in the state. Conversely, water trades for other purposes can inadvertently harm the environment. They can, for example, change the timing, quantity, and quality of return flows, adversely affecting riparian and wetland habitats and the species that depend upon them. Water trading has rarely been employed to address equity challenges. Indeed, water trading can exacer- bate social and economic inequalities, worsening gender and geographic differences. Unequal access to water markets due to unequal access to information or credit can distort outcomes and reduce market efficiency. On the other hand, water trading that promotes water-use efficiency rather than fallowing of agricultural land can improve socio-economic outcomes for both the area of origin and the destination. Water trading’s social impacts vary based on several factors, including the relative economic health of the area of origin and the purchasing area, whether or not the water leaves the area of origin, the process used to trade the water, the relative economic and political power of the parties, gender differences regarding access to and control of water, the amount of trading activity in the area, and the legitimacy of the water rights being traded. Impacts often vary within the same community, as those with water rights or allocations to trade receive compensation, while third parties – such as irrigation equipment suppliers or farmworkers – may suffer a loss of revenue or income as a result of trading. Institutional arrangements are among the most important factors that determine the ultimate success or failure of water trading. Successful water trading requires secure and flexible water rights that recognize and protect users and others from externalities. Such institutional arrangements also need to be flexible enough to adapt to changing physical conditions as well as changing social norms, such as the growing interest in meeting environmental needs and protecting water quality. Some factors, such as access to timely information about water available to trade, can enable water trading but may not be required. Other factors, such as legal and transferable rights to use water, may be necessary for water trading to occur. Still other factors, such as “no injury” regulations and “area of origin” protection, limit water trading or can function as barriers or obstacles to trading. 3 A “regulatory taking” occurs when a government regulation limits or infringes upon a private property right to such an extent that it deprives the owner of some or all of the value of that property” (Fischel, 1995).
  • 119. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xiii In a limited number of areas with the necessary legal and technical conditions and with sufficient public investment, water trading has offered a timely, relatively inexpensive, and flexible mechanism to real- locate water between users, or from water users back to the environment. Building a successful water market requires decades of determined effort to measure water flows and use, report transactions publicly, conduct regional water planning, and construct and maintain infrastructure to convey water. In Australia’s case, it also required more than $3 billion of public funding to acquire water for environmental purposes, which also called for creating and, in turn, maintaining an environmental baseline above which trading activity could occur. Such significant institutional changes require broad public support and a considerable amount of time to implement. Although water trading can be used to reallocate water ef- fectively, successful implementation requires a clear understanding of existing conditions and a deter- mined, long-term effort to make the necessary changes and minimize externalities. Payment for ecosystem services Payment for ecosystem services is an incentive-based instrument that seeks to monetize the external, non-market values of environmental services – such as removal of pollutants and regulation of precipita- tion events – that can then be used as financial incentives for local actors to provide such services. In practical terms, they involve a series of payments to a land or resource manager in exchange for a guar- anteed flow of environmental services. Payments are made to the environmental service provider by the beneficiary of those services, e.g. an individual, a community, a company, or a government. In essence, it is based on a beneficiary-pays principle, as opposed to a polluter-pays principle. Payments for ecosystems services (PESs) that focus on watershed services, commonly referred to as “payments for watershed services” (PWSs), can take a variety of forms. They may be intended to prevent the degradation of a watershed or to restore a previously degraded one. They may be small, local schemes covering several hundred hectares or large, national schemes covering millions of hectares. Programs may be financed directly by the beneficiary or by third parties acting on behalf of the benefi- ciary, e.g. governments or institutions, or some combination thereof. They may involve cash or in-kind payments to be paid all at once or periodically. New York City provides a well-known example. In the late 1990s, New York City was faced with the prospect of building a $4–$6 billion filtration plant with an additional $250 million in annual operating costs to meet new federal drinking water standards. An initial analysis suggested that preserving the upstream rural Catskill watershed would be far less expensive. The city and local farmers came together to develop a plan that could meet both groups’ interests. A key element of the plan was the Whole Farm Program, a voluntary effort fully funded by New York City’s Department of Environmental Protection whereby farmers would work with technical advisors to custom design pollution control measures to meet an environmental objective while also improving the viability of their farming businesses. By 2006, the city had spent or committed between $1.4 billion and $1.5 billion in watershed protection projects, averaging $167 million in expenditures per year – far less than building a water filtration plant. Participa- tion remains high, with 96 percent of large farms in the watershed participating in the program. Payments for watershed services are gaining prominence and have been applied in a wide range of settings. Some of the earliest programs were established in Central America but today, such programs
  • 120. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxiv can be found in countries around the world. The United States’ Conservation Reserve Program pays farmers to take land out of production in order to protect soil and water resources and wildlife habitat. In northeastern France, Vittel-Nestle Waters paid farmers and provided technical support (and some labor) to alter local dairy farming practices in order to reduce nitrate pollution of groundwater – the source of Vittel’s bottled water. The largest PWS programs are in China. China’s Sloping Land Conversion Programme, piloted in 1999 and fully implemented in 2002, requires farmers to set aside erosion-prone farmland within critical areas of the watershed of the Yangtze and Yellow Rivers – the two largest rivers in China. In exchange, farmers receive regular cash payments and grain rations. The program promotes forestry and other economic endeavors on the land rather than grain production, in order to prevent sediment from washing into rivers and clogging dams and shipping channels. The environmental performance of PWS is not well understood. Evaluation of these programs is in- herently difficult because the connections between land use practice and watershed services are not always clear, especially as they relate to water quantity, and they are often site-specific. It can also be difficult to attribute change to the program rather than to external factors (e.g. changing commodity prices), and programs may not reach threshold levels for measureable impact, or that impact may occur over a relatively long time period. In addition to these challenges, many programs lack baseline data or monitoring systems. In the absence of scientific information, performance is often based on perceptions of local populations and those operating the schemes. But even based on these sources, the available data suggest that environmental performance of PWS is mixed, with less than 60 percent of programs reaching their environmental objective. As the field has matured, it has increased emphasis on monitor- ing, which will inevitably help improve environmental outcomes. Similarly,limiteddataareavailableonthesocialandeconomicimpactsofpaymentsforwatershedservices. Most studies have focused on increased income or capacity building rather than broader social impacts, such as changes in power dynamics. While participation in a PWS program can boost the income of small farmers, the payments they receive will typically boost their annual incomes only slightly. Several studies have also suggested that there are important non-financial (or non-income) benefits, such as increasing land-tenure security, creating human and social capital through internal organization, and improving the visibility of the community to donors and public entities. Some analysts have argued that because the programs are mostly voluntary, continued participation provides some indication that the programs are cost effective, i.e. that benefits exceed costs and participants are satisfied with the outcomes. While information on broader social outcomes is limited, there is information on the role of these arrange- ments in alleviating poverty. However, it is important to recognize that payment for watershed services was conceptualized as a mechanism to improve the efficiency of natural resource management, not as a mechanism to reduce poverty. Several studies have examined the socio-economic status of participants, either as buyers or sellers, and have found mixed results, depending to some extent on land and forest tenure regimes and socio-economic conditions in the targeted areas. While most programs prioritize areas critical for ecosystem services, some have been tailored to meet social objectives through a variety
  • 121. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xv of mechanisms, such as targeting the programs to particular areas or populations, reducing transac- tion costs, and providing pro-poor premiums and subsidies. While there are often more direct ways of reducing poverty than payments for watershed services (e.g. education or health programs), there is little evidence of these schemes actually doing any harm. Few studies have examined gender represen- tation among program participants. In general, payments for watershed services are flexible, and the necessary conditions are relatively modest. Small, self-organized schemes between private entities are based on general legal require- ments: a legal system recognizing that agreements must be kept and that civil law must provide the contracting parties with legal remedies in case of non-compliance. Expanding these projects to address regional or national water problems would require a more developed policy and legal framework along with incentives or requirements to participate in PES programs, cultural and political acceptance of markets, trust between ecosystem service providers and beneficiaries, and a supply and demand for ecosystem services. Water quality trading Water quality trading (WQT) is an incentive-based approach for reducing or controlling water pollution. Under such a system, polluters are granted a permit to pollute, and these permits can be bought and sold among polluters. The central idea is that trading puts a price on pollution, encouraging cost savings, efficiency, and innovation. Water quality trading is an adjunct to regulation, not an alternative to it. In fact, its success depends on the presence of a strong regulatory body to enforce water quality standards, and monitor and enforce discharge limits. Water quality markets have drawn inspiration from the success of the Acid Rain Program (ARP) es- tablished in the United States in the 1990s. The popularity of emissions trading for dealing with water pollution in the United States is largely a result of the Clean Water Act of 1972, which made it difficult for governments to handle pollution from farms. Water quality markets have been established in the United States, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand. There is also interest in China and Europe, although no programs are currently in place. To date, most water quality trading markets have been used to control pollution from nutrients that cause excessive algal growth and low dissolved oxygen levels in water bodies, a process referred to as “eutrophication”. Other water quality trading programs have been set up to control salinity, heavy metal, sediment, and temperature or thermal pollution. The largest WQT market in the United States in terms of transactions, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit Exchange Program, was created in 2002 to reduce nitrogen pollution that came into Long Island Sound from the Connecticut River. Under the program, which covers 79 sewage treatment plants in the state of Connecticut, a plant can control pollution in excess of its permit requirement and sell excess nitrogen allowances to those plants that exceed their allowances. A 2012 review of the program found that in ten years, the program had helped reduce nitrogen pollution by over 50 percent while controlling costs. One of the best examples of a successful water quality trading market is on Australia’s Hunter River, where coal mines and other pollution sources are subject to discharge limits to protect water quality
  • 122. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENTxvi and drinking water sources in downstream cities. Under this system, limited discharge is allowed, but permitted dischargers must coordinate their activities so that the total salt concentration in the river never goes above a specified limit. Industries can buy and sell salt credits in real time via a trading website run by the state government. Several years after it began, the trading program remains popular among participants and functions smoothly. Perhaps the biggest marker of the program’s success is that, even though new and potentially high-polluting mines have been established, river water quality has met standards nearly 100 percent of the time. Despite the fact that water quality trading markets have existed for three decades in some areas, it is difficult to determine whether the approach can be considered an overall success. Many of the domestic WQT markets in the United States have not lived up to expectations, seeing few trades or no trades at all. This can be explained by a number of factors: high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty about the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate. However, paradoxically, despite a lack of trading, the process of creating the market may have contributed to better watershed management. Bringing stakeholders together around a common goal of improving water quality has helped lower resistance to new, more stringent water quality regulations. In other cases, discussion of the use of “market fundamentals” helped convince some political conser- vatives to implement a form of environmental regulation, paving the way for improved water quality. A common argument in favor of environmental markets is that they will be smaller, simpler, and lower cost, because they aim to replace regulation with a free market. However, water quality markets require a strong and capable regulatory ability to set a cap on pollutants, to monitor pollution, and to verify the le- gitimacy of water quality credits that are created. Ironically, this often results in the creation of additional layers of government to perform these functions. WQT markets are valuable where large price asymmetries exist in water pollution control, and where certain polluters are beyond the reach of a regulatory agency. This is the case in the United States, where states are responsible for preserving water quality but have little authority over agriculture and some other nonpoint sources. On one hand, this has decreased the burden on municipal and industrial sources of pollution, allowing them to save on the cost of installing expensive treatment technologies. On the other hand, it has compelled them to fund projects on farms, often hundreds of miles away. We conclude that water quality trading is not a panacea for solving water pollution problems. However, it can be part of an effective regulatory approach under certain conditions. Conclusions In this report, we analyze the potential for incentive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water resources. To date, the primary environmental policy tools to address water challenges have been com- mand-and-control regulations. However, over the past several decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include a host of incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products.
  • 123. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT xvii While regulations and incentive-based instruments are frequently juxtaposed, they also frequently operate alongside one another. With water quality trading, for example, governments mandate caps on the allowable pollutant levels and issue tradable permits that allow industry groups to allocate polluting activities among themselves, governed by market forces. Similarly, with water trading, governments may allocate water and then institute a framework within which water trading can occur. While incentive- based instruments may work in tandem, they must be integrated within a broader watershed manage- ment effort. Decisions about whether and how to apply a particular instrument depend on the specific objectives, circumstances, conditions, and needs of a given area. These decisions should be based on an open and transparent process, with meaningful participation from all affected parties. This approach will help in crafting a solution that is appropriate for local conditions, and ensure that it is fair and equitable. It will also help to reduce opposition and promote acceptance from those who will be implementing and affected by the program. It is important to recognize that those with the least power may not have the resources to participate, or they may be skeptical of the groups involved. In these cases, there is a need for consistent and rigorous outreach and, potentially, for engaging a trusted intermediary. Finally, monitoring and evaluation are essential to the success of any instrument. In particular, moni- toring and evaluation help ensure outcomes are achieved and allow for adjustments in response to changing social, economic, or environmental conditions. Monitoring should evaluate the “additionality” of the program, i.e. whether the program has an effect when compared with some baseline. It should also examine any potential impacts on surrounding areas (i.e. leakage) and the permanence of the interven- tion. However, extensive monitoring requirements would increase transaction costs, potentially threat- ening the viability of the program. Thus, the need for monitoring and evaluation must be balanced with practical considerations of the ability to maintain the viability of the program.
  • 125. 1 Introduction INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 1 Water is one of our most precious and valuable resources and is fundamental for maintaining human health, agricultural production, and economic activ- ity as well as critical ecosystem functions. Even as the planet’s endowment of water is expected to remain constant, human appropriation of fresh water, already at 50 percent by some measures (Postel et al., 1996), is expected to increase further (Leflaive et al., 2012). We can already see clear signs of the overexploitation of available freshwater resources. For example, some iconic rivers, including the Colorado River in the United States and the Yellow River in China, no longer reach the sea. Groundwater withdrawals have tripled over the past 50 years (UN, 2012), and in some areas, ground- water extraction exceeds natural recharge, causing widespread depletion and declining groundwater levels (Wada et al., 2010; Famiglietti, 2014). Pressures on water resources are likely to worsen in response to contin- ued economic and population growth, climate change, and other challenges. Water pollution exacerbates the challenges posed by water scarcity as the world’s water quality is increasingly becoming degraded. Growing pressures on the availability and quality of water resources have major impacts on our social, eco- nomic, and environmental well-being. The failure to provide safe drinking water and adequate sanitation services to all people is perhaps the greatest develop- ment failure of the twentieth century. Improving access to water and sanitation has been a key focus of the global development agenda since 2000. Water and sanitation were goals of the 2000–2015 Millennium Development Goals, and now, the Sustainable Devel- opment Goals launched in September 2015, also call for insuring access to water and sanitation for all. Yet, despite nearly two decades of international atten- tion and tens of billions of dollars invested, more than 660 million people still lack access to improved drink- ing water, predominantly in sub-Saharan Africa and Oceania, and some 2.4 billion people lack access to basic sanitation (WHO and UNICEF, 2015).4,5 In even the wealthiest countries, access to water and sanitation 4 Improved water sources include household connections, public stand- pipes, boreholes, protected dug wells, protected springs, and rainwater collections. Unimproved water sources are unprotected wells, unprotect- ed springs, vendor-provided water, bottled water (unless water for other uses is available from an improved source), and tanker truck-provided water. 5 Improved sanitation includes connection to public sewers, connection to septic systems, pour-flush latrines, simple pit latrines, and ventilated im- proved pit latrines. Service or bucket latrines (where excreta is manually removed), public latrines and open latrines are not considered improved sanitation. “…more than 660 million people still lack access to an improved drinking water source…”
  • 126. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT2 (2002, 2003), is based on integrating several key prin- ciples, including improving the overall productivity of water use, matching water quality to users’ needs, pri- oritizing basic human and ecosystem water needs, and seeking meaningful local and community engagement in water management. A key element of the soft path for water is shifting from a near exclusive supply-side orientation to one that seeks to manage water demand. Numerous studies have found significant opportunities to reduce water demand in all sectors using a variety of conservation and efficiency measures (e.g. Gleick et al., 2003; Cohen et al., 2013; Heberger et al., 2014). These measures can be applied in countries at varying levels of eco- nomic development, although the types of measures employed and implementation strategies may differ (Sharma and Vairavamoorthy, 2009). Brooks (2006) argued that demand management is more than a set of techniques; rather, it is a governance approach linked to equity, environmental protection, and public engagement goals. Additional information on demand management can be found in Annex 1. New policy tools are also needed. In most places, regu- lations have been the primary tool employed to improve environmental outcomes. However, over the past sev- eral decades, the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include “incentive-based” instruments. Incentive-based instruments use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate responsible parties to reallocate water or reduce the health and environmen- tal risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products. These instruments have emerged for several reasons, but mainly because they are believed to be more cost effective than regulations, as they provide greater flex- ibility for the individual or firm to meet the environmen- tal objective in the least costly manner. Incentive-based is not universal. A 2011 UN report (de Albuquerque, 2011) highlighted several areas of the United States, including California, where marginalized populations (e.g. those living in poverty, communities of color, and indigenous groups) lacked the basic rights to water and sanitation. Moreover, access to an improved water source does not necessarily mean that the water is affordable or safe to drink. For example, naturally occur- ring arsenic pollution in groundwater affects nearly 140 million people in 70 countries (United Nations, 2009). Freshwater ecosystems are among the most exten- sively altered systems on earth. Rivers, streams, and lakes have been subjected to chemical, physical, and biological alteration as a result of large-scale water diversions, introduction of invasive species, overhar- vesting, pollution, and climate change (Carpenter et al., 2011). As a result, an estimated 20 to 35 per- cent of freshwater fish are vulnerable or endangered (Cosgrove and Rijsberman, 2000). Likewise, about half of the world’s wetlands have been lost since 1900, and much of the remaining wetlands are degraded (Zedler and Kercher, 2005). Freshwater ecosystem conditions are likely to continue to decline unless action is taken to address acute threats and better manage freshwa- ter resources. Traditional approaches to managing water supply and demand are not going to be effective in addressing these challenges. Throughout much of the twentieth century, the emphasis was on developing massive dams and pumping ever increasing amounts of groundwa- ter to satisfy rising water demands. This approach, as noted by Sharma and Vairavamoorthy (2009), “has led to over-use of the resources, over-capitalisation, pollu- tion and other problems of varying severity.” The soft path for water has emerged as a promising alternative. The term “soft energy path”, coined by Amory Lovins (1977) of the Rocky Mountain Institute, described an alternative path for energy development that empha- sized energy efficiency and promoted smaller, decen- tralized energy systems fueled by renewable sources. The soft path for water, as described by Peter H. Gleick “…the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include “incentive-based” instruments…”
  • 127. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 3 in managing both the quantity and quality of fresh- water. We have divided this review into five sections. This Section 1 introduces the synthesis review. Section 2 describes the research methodology. Section 3 pro- vides background on policy instruments and detail on three incentive-based instruments that have been used in the United States and abroad – water trading, pay- ment for ecosystem services, and water quality trad- ing. For each instrument, we describe its application, its environmental, economic, and social performance, and the conditions needed for its implementation. Section 4 highlights the role of the private sector in implement- ing these instruments, and Section 5 provides a sum- mary and conclusions. instruments are also thought to lower administrative costs and promote innovation by rewarding those who exceed their targets (Harrington and Morgenstern, 2004). Furthermore, Koplow (2004) suggests that these instruments can support self-enforcement by creating “groups of firms and individuals with vested interests in the proper use of resources and in emitting only as much pollution as allowed.” This report provides a synthesis review of a set of incentive-based instruments that have been employed in varying degrees around the world to reduce pressure on water resources. It is part of an effort to understand the full potential, and limitations, of these instruments
  • 129. 2 Research methodology INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 5 The freshwater synthesis review is based on a five-step approach to making better use of existing evaluative knowledge. This approach, modeled by The Rockefeller Foundation to help inform its investment and program- matic decisions, has already been used in a review of success factors in small-scale coastal fisheries man- agement in developing countries (The Rockefeller Foundation, 2013). Throughout the project, the proj- ect team held bi-weekly calls with The Rockefeller Foundation to review progress on the project, discuss key findings, and dive into specific case studies that could further support learning. The following steps were taken. 1. Refine project scope. The first step was to work with the Foundation Center and The Rockefeller Foundation to refine the scope of work and develop research questions. 2. Undertake literature search and review. The second step was to review the peer-reviewed lit- erature and law reviews on the key topics for the research. We supplemented this formal literature search with a review of the gray literature, including government and other institutional reports, from or- ganizations working to evaluate or implement these instruments. To identify the relevant literature, we used Web of Science (formerly Web of Knowledge) Internet-based search engines, and institutional website search engines. The literature on these in- centive-based instruments is extensive. For example, a Google Scholar search of “water trading” returned nearly 1 million results. Given the need to review a large amount of information in a relatively short time, we prioritized articles published since 2000. We further refined our study by limiting our scope to articles and reports on the state of practice, rather than the state of theory. In total, we reviewed approximately 500 articles and reports. 3. Conduct expert interviews. The third step was to obtain the knowledge of experts working to address the study’s key questions. It was designed to fill in any gaps in the literature. We developed the interview list based on the academic and grey literature search and from the research team’s experience in the sector. 4. Compile initial analysis and synthesis. The fourth step included an initial analysis and synthesis of the knowledge gained from the first three steps, which was compiled into a detailed presentation and supporting materials, and formally presented to the Foundation Center and The Rockefeller Foundation Team in an interactive discussion in March 2015. The Rockefeller Foundation also reviewed the draft report in July 2015, providing additional input on the synthesis. 5. Conduct further analysis and develop final knowledge product. The fifth step was to conduct further analysis of the published and expert knowledge based on the discussions with the Foundation Center, The Rockefeller Foundation, and other parties. We worked closely with the Foundation Center to develop the final knowledge products, including this summary report and online components, such as a visualization of key findings and a public collection of cited research. All of the knowledge products are openly licensed and free to be used and repurposed.
  • 131. 3 Environmental policy instruments INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 7 The objective of environmental policy is “to modify, slow, or stop resource extraction; to reduce or elimi- nate emissions of concern; and to shift consumption and production patterns towards greater sustainability” (Koplow, 2004). In most places, regulations have tradi- tionally been the primary environmental policy instru- ment employed to achieve environmental outcomes. This approach, often referred to as command-and- control (CAC), relies on some governmental or similar body to establish a standard or target (the “command”) that must then be complied with to avoid negative sanctions, such as fines or prosecution (the “control”). Over the past several decades, the environmental pol- icy “toolkit” has expanded to include incentive-based instruments, also referred to as economic instruments or market-based instruments. While definitions vary, we use the term “incentive-based instruments” to refer to a set of tools that use financial means, directly or indi- rectly,tomotivateresponsiblepartiestoreallocatewater or reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products. While CAC and incentive-based instruments are often juxtaposed with one another, a United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) report (Koplow, 2004) noted that “in reality the two often operate alongside each other. Governments may, for example, mandate caps on allowable pollu- tion for a region or country and use market-oriented approaches such as tradable permits to allocate the allowable emissions in an efficient manner.” Figure 1 provides a depiction of the range of environ- mental policy instruments currently applied around the world. These include the following. • Regulations and sanctions – mechanisms that rely on guidelines, permits, or licenses, and often include a legal or financial penalty for non-compli- ance. Examples include pollution standards, water use quotes, and building standards. • Price-based instruments – mechanisms that impose i) higher costs through fees, charges, or taxes on pollution or the use of a natural resource, making them more expensive and discouraging their production or consumption, or ii) lower costs through the use of subsidies for environmentally friendly activities or products. Examples include abstraction fees, pollution charges, grants, low-in- terest loans, and favorable tax treatment. • Market creation – mechanisms that include i) tradable permits whereby user or polluter rights are assigned according to desirable use levels or his- torical practices, and compliance can be achieved by trade, or ii) deposit refund systems that create a market to buy back inefficient or polluting prod- ucts. Examples include water trading and water quality trading. • Information provision – mechanisms that use the provision and disclosure of information on envi- ronmental performance to incentivize producers to reduce their water use or emissions of pollutants,
  • 132. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT8 As shown in Figure 1, these instruments exist along a continuum, from “very strict command approaches to decentralized approaches that rely more on market or legal mechanisms” (Huber et al., 1998). As noted, there are varying definitions of incentive-based instruments and the types of tools that would qualify. All definitions identify price-based instruments and market creation as incentive-based instruments. Some, however, use a broader definition that includes information provision, voluntary action, and liability instruments (see, e.g. Stavins, 2001; UNEP, 2001; Anderson, 2004). Product labeling schemes, such as the United States’ “Energy Star” or Thailand’s “Green Label”, allow companies meeting environmental standards to place a recog- nized label on their product, boosting sales by making the product more appealing to consumers and provid- ing a financial incentive to improve environmental per- formance (Stavins, 2001). These products may also be sold at a higher price than less environmentally-friendly or to incentivize consumers to select products with superior performance. Examples include corporate reporting, product labeling (e.g. WaterSense),6 and environmental certification schemes. • Voluntary action – mechanisms that use volun- tary agreements between the government and pri- vate firms and/or commitments made independent of government requirement. Examples include the UN CEO Water Mandate and the Alliance for Wa- ter Stewardship’s International Water Stewardship Standard. • Legal instruments – mechanisms for compen- sating victims when pollution causes human or environmental harm, and encouraging compliance with existing environmental regulations. Examples include criminal penalties, civil liability statutes, and performance bonds. 6 WaterSense is an environmental program designed to encourage water efficiency in the US, through use of a special label on consumer products. FIGURE 1. Incentive-based policy instruments WATER MANAGEMENT EXAMPLES: Regulations and sanctions Price based Market creation Information provision Voluntary action Legal Pollution standards Cost recovery tariffs Water quality trading Eco-labels UN CEO Water Mandate Criminal penalties Water use quotas Pollution taxes Water trading Corporate reporting AWS Interna- tional Water Stewardship Standard Performance bonds Building codes Payment for watershed services Environmental certification Civil liability statutes Source: adapted from Huber et al., 1998; UNEP, 2009. REGULATIONS AND SANCTIONS PRICE BASED MARKET CREATION INFORMATION PROVISION VOLUNTARY ACTION LEGAL Less flexibility Maximum government involvement Control oriented More flexibility Increased private initiative Litigation oriented
  • 133. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 9 of this activity ($11.6 billion, or 94 percent) was associ- ated with payment for watershed services, and 98 per- cent of that activity was in China. Collective action funds – which pool contributions from multiple inves- tors to support coordinated interventions within a watershed – had the second highest transaction value at $563 million. We note, however, that the distinction between payment for watershed and collective action programs is sometimes unclear.9 The market activity of instream buybacks – programs that purchase or lease water to augment instream flows – was considerably less ($97 million), followed by water quality trading ($22 million), and voluntary compensation ($320,000). It is of note that instream buybacks likely represent a modest fraction of the market activity of water trading programs, although comprehensive data on the latter are not readily available.10 While the data suggest a rapid expansion in the application of these instruments since 2008, Ecosystem Marketplace’s Genevieve Bennett (personal communication, 2015) noted that much of the increase is actually an outcome of better reporting. 9 Water funds are sometimes categorized as payment for watershed services and other times as collective action funds. 10 California, for example, has an active trading market but no centralized repository of data on the number and value of transactions. models. Likewise, voluntary programs may reward meeting environmental outcomes with, e.g. public rec- ognition which, in turn, increases sales. The application and market activity of these instruments are not well understood. Several organizations track the application of some of these incentive-based instru- ments (IIED, 2015 and Forest Trends, 2015a).7 However, there is no comprehensive list of the programs that have been implemented globally. Additionally, programs are sometimes poorly defined, fall into multiple categories, or change over time. Moreover, data on the activity of these instruments, including the number and value of transac- tions, are not collected or made available publicly. Despite these challenges, Forest Trends has been track- ing the activity of five market and market-like instru- ments for watershed investments for several years.8 It estimates that the market activity of watershed invest- ments was $12.3 billion in 2013 (Table 1). The majority 7 See, for example, Watershed Markets (watershedmarkets.org), main- tained by the London-based International Institute for Environment and Development, and Watershed Connect (watershedconnect.com), an on- line platform maintained by the Washington, D.C.-based Forest Trends. 8 Forest Trends is an international “non-profit organization with three principal roles: convening market players to advance market transfor- mations, generating and disseminating critical information to market players, and facilitating deals between different critical links in the value chains of new forestry.” See forest-trends.org. TABLE 1. Transactions (in millions of US$) by type, 2008–2013 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Payment for watershed services/undefined $ 7,950 $ 6,950 $ 7,470 $ 8,000 $ 9,600 $11,600 Collective action funds n/a n/a n/a n/a $ 137 $ 563 Voluntary compensation n/a n/a n/a n/a $ 0.230 $ 0.320 Water quality trading $ 10.7 $ 8.30 $ 8.30 $ 7.70 $ 14.9 $ 22.2 Instream buybacks n/a $ 19 $ 390 $ 164 $ 144 $ 97.0 Total $ 7,960 $ 6,980 $ 7,870 $ 8,170 $ 9,890 $ 12,300 Note: Numbers shown are nominal values. All values rounded to three significant figures. Numbers may not add up due to rounding. Based on data provided by Bennett (personal communication, 2015) and included in Bennett and Carroll (2014).
  • 134. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT10 side of a recognized legal or administrative frame- work (e.g. the sale of groundwater to an adjacent irrigator) • water banks – the institutions or agencies that i) broker or otherwise facilitate water trading (Culp et al.,2014)orii)areestablishedforaspecificobjective, such as a trust created to obtain water rights for in- stream augmentation (Clifford, 2012). Water banks offer expertise and information for improving com- munication between buyers and sellers, and often provide a centralized repository or clearinghouse of information on current and historical transactions, including volumes, pricing, and locations. There is an extensive body of literature suggest- ing that water trading provides a mechanism to improve the economic efficiency of water through its reallocation from lower to higher value uses (Glennon, 2005; Dellapenna, 2000; Bjornlund and McKay, 2002). The germinal study entitled Water and Choice in the Colorado Basin (NRC, 1968) recommended that water in the western United States be transferred from irriga- tion, which generates relatively low returns per unit of water, to high-value non-agricultural uses. More recent researchhascontinuedtoemphasizethepotentialvalue created by water transfers. For example, models used to project California’s economic costs under a dry climate change projection, (Medellín-Azuara et al., 2008) found significantly increased benefits with market-based real- locations. Newlin et al. (2002) and Jenkins et al. (2004) asserted that water trading could dramatically reduce Southern California’s water scarcity costs. Water trading is attractive because it tends to minimize the impact on existing rights holders by providing com- pensation and, in many cases, additional security, for existing water rights, while providing opportunities to those with new or increasing demands (NRC, 1992). A large number of experts challenge the applicability and efficacy of water trading. Freyfogle (1996) asserted that externalities, intrinsic to the very nature of water itself, pose such an insurmountable obstacle that water trading does not and cannot work. Many of these In this review, we evaluate three of the major incentive- based instruments that have been employed to improve water management: water trading, payment for ecosys- tem services, and water quality trading. These instru- ments are employed in developed and developing countries, and there is growing interest in expanding their application. 3.1 Water trading Description Water trading is perhaps the best known and most widely used method of reallocating water. In some cases, purchasing or leasing water from existing users has proven to be less expensive, more flexible, and less time-consuming than developing new water sup- plies, such as constructing new diversion structures or desalination plants. Similarly, water trading is gen- erally a more accepted method for reallocating water than state appropriation or condemnation of existing water rights. Successful examples of water trading in Australia and other locations – combined with classic economic theory suggesting that market mechanisms can optimize resource allocation – have heightened interest in this instrument in both academic literature and popular media. As noted in Box 1, the peer-reviewed and gray litera- ture employ several terms (e.g. water transfers, water markets, and water banks) to refer to a variety of some- times overlapping instruments and methods for con- veying and reallocating water. In this paper, we use the following terms: • water trading – the temporary or permanent transfer of the right to use water in exchange for some form of compensation • informal water trading – the sale of a specified volume of water for a limited period of time, which does not involve actual contracts or occurs out- “…water trading provides a mechanism to improve the economic efficiency of water…”
  • 135. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 11 tradeable commodity. Similarly, Zellmer and Harder (2007) asserted, “Water is a uniquely essential resource with uniquely public attributes,” unlike other resources typically treated as property. Questions of externali- ties, commodification, and the special nature of water itself highlight the challenges faced by implementing or expanding water trading. In some cases, water trading is effectively zero-sum, simply shifting water use and economic productivity from one area or sector to another. In other cases, it can externalities arise from the physical properties of water: it is heavy, unwieldy, and easily contaminated; it some- timeshasdramaticseasonalandyear-to-yearvariability; and it can be easily lost through evaporation, seepage, or runoff (Salzman, 2006). Further, these externalities may be borne by disparate parties, such as the envi- ronment or future generations, challenging efforts to compensate those injured by trading (Freyfogle, 1996). Moreover, Salzman (2006) argued that custom, history, and religion in many parts of the world treat drinking water as a common property resource, rather than a BOX 1 A note on terminology Water transfers. The National Research Council (NRC) of the United States National Academies defines water transfers as changes in the point of diversion, type of use, or location of water use (NRC et al., 1992). The term “water transfers” encompasses a broad range of market-based and non-market water reallocation mechanisms of varying periods, geographic scales, and arrangements. Water transfers can range from short-term leases or conditional arrangements to the permanent transfer (i.e. sale) of a water right. They can range in scale from i) change in type of use on an existing parcel of land, such as when a water right shifts from irrigation to municipal use when agricultural land is purchased and converted to housing, to ii) inter-basin transfers, such as when a city purchases or leases water from a different watershed. Water bank. A water bank is a mechanism for changing the time or location of water use. Water banking, as with water transfers, can refer to market- based or non-market activities. The term “water bank” can refer to an actual institution or to the physical storage of water. Water banks as institutions may function as i) brokers that connect buyers and sellers of water rights or leases, providing an important communication function; ii) clearinghouses that directly purchase or lease water from willing sellers and aggregate supplies for subsequent sale to other buyers; iii) facilitators that expedite water transfers using existing storage or conveyance facilities (Culp et al., 2014); or iv) trusts that hold or otherwise manage water rights or entitlements for a specific purpose, such as streamflow augmentation (O’Donnell and Colby, 2010). When serving as facilitators, water banks may perform various administrative and technical functions, including the confirmation of water rights and screening of potential buyers (Clifford, 2012). Water banks may also refer to physical storage, either in surface reservoirs or in aquifers, which, in turn, may be a component of a larger water transfer or simply a mechanism enabling an entitlement holder to store water for its own future use, but we do not use this definition in this review. Water market. The term water market refers to a range of different market-based practices, typically referring to water trading. According to Brown (2006), the term water market lacks a precise definition, “but once a few voluntary trades of water of relatively common physical and legal characteristics occur, it is said that a water market exists.” A water market may also refer to informal transactions involving the direct sale of water that does not involve the lease or sale of water rights. Informal water transactions can include purchasing bottled water or water from a tanker truck, a common practice in many parts of the developing world that lack a reliable, piped water supply. While a “water contract” can refer to a one-time voluntary water exchange between two actors, a water market is where many actors come together and make trades; a market also includes some formalization of the transactions (Brown et al., 2015).
  • 136. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT12 Application Water trading exists, to varying degrees, in countries around the world. When Grafton et al. (2010) assessed water trading in two wealthy countries (Australia and theUnitedStates),twolow-tomiddle-incomecountries (Chile and South Africa), and one poor, rapidly develop- ing country (China), they found that differing levels of information availability, legal rights structures, institu- tional constraints, and management goals had resulted in very different levels of activity and performance. ThemostactivewatertradingmarketsoccurinAustralia and the western United States. Within Australia, water trading includes both short-term trades (referred to as allocation trading) and long-term trades (referred to as entitlement trading). The total value of water trading in Australia in fiscal year 2012–13 exceeded $1.4 billion increase system-wide water efficiency, by providing the area of origin with funds for investing in improved effi- ciency, maintaining local productivity with lower water use, and then transferring the conserved water. Water can be made available for trading from a variety of activities, including fallowing fields, crop shifting, and in some cases, a shift from surface water diversions to groundwater pumping. Water trades can also be linked to water conservation and efficiency efforts, including increasing irrigation efficiency and decreasing system losses that generate surplus water by, e.g. lining canals or constructing operating reservoirs. However, increas- ing demand for greater efficiencies in irrigation can challengetheflexibilityofexistinginstitutions(Hundley, 2001), such as irrigation districts and water courts, which often do not recognize a legal property right to this “new” water created by conservation or efficiency. Additionally, existing institutions often impose signifi- cantcostsonthoseattemptingtodedicatewatertonon- traditional uses such as instream flows (Getches, 1985). These changes have tested the resilience of water insti- tutions, which have shown some flexibility in adapting to new values and goals but often impose high transac- tion costs (Colby et al., 1991). Water trading can occur within sectors, from agricul- ture-to-agriculture and urban-to-urban, across these sectors, and, less frequently, from either of these to the environment (Brewer et al., 2007). Figure 2, from the California Department of Water Resources, shows the relative proportions of water trading within and between differentsectors.Althoughwatertradingisoftenconsid- ered a means to move water from agriculture to urban uses, nearly three-quarters of the 270,000 acre-feet of water traded in California in 2013 occurred between agricultural users. Interestingly, nearly 25,000 acre- feet of water were traded from municipal and industrial (MI) uses to agriculture, which was nearly half of the volume of water traded from agriculture to MI uses. FIGURE 2. Non-project water transfers within the Sacramento-San Joaquin watersheds in 2013 Note: Ag – agriculture; FW – fish and wildlife; MI – municipal and industrial; AF – acre-foot. Source: California Department of Water Resources. Ag to Ag Ag to MI Ag to FW MI to Ag9% (24,577 AF) TOTAL: 268,370 AF 1% (1,500 AF) 18% (49,639 AF) 72% (192,655 AF) “The most active water trading markets occur in Australia and the western United States.”
  • 137. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 13 reports almost 640,000 acre-feet of water traded in California, through 36 trades with a total value of about $234 million (all values adjusted to 2014$). More than 80 percent of the water was leased rather than sold. According to the database, 15 of these trades, account- ing for about 88,000 acre-feet of total volume, occurred within one agricultural district. However, the Bren School database only records the initial year a water trade is reported, and thus does not reflect the volume of multiyear trading agreements. That means that a review of 2009 trading activity does not reflect previ- ous multi-year trades that may still have been active in 2009, so the values reported above understate trading activity in 2009. A comprehensive review of water trading in California reports about 1.5 MAF of water were traded in 2009, a dry year (Hanak and Stryjewski, 2012). Volumes reported for 2011, a wet year and the most recent year for which data are available, were about 5 percent lower, at 1.4 MAF. In 2011, 42 percent of the water traded went to municipal and industrial users, 37 percent to agricul- tural users, 17 percent for environmental purposes, and the remainder to mixed uses. Because of limited data, the study does not include trading activity within irri- gation districts or similar users associations, although some estimates suggest that such intra-district activity accounted for several hundred thousand acre-feet of water, a third of total water supplies within some of the larger irrigation districts. Hanak and Stryjewski (2012) did not provide total dollar values associated with the California water market, though they noted that prices of temporary water transfers had increased from an average of $30–$40 per acre-foot in one region in the mid-1990s to $180 per acre-foot in 2011, while aver- age prices in another basin rose to an average of $400 per acre-foot. The authors noted the shifting trend from short-term to longer-term leases and permanent trades, pumping restrictions in the Bay-Delta, and ris- ing transaction costs that had slowed market activity in the past decade. California is also home to the largest United States water trade to date. The San Diego County Water Authority (SDCWA) entered into a 45-year contract (NWC, 2013). Trading within the Murray-Darling Basin, which has an active and well-documented water mar- ket first established more than 30 years ago (Grafton et al., 2012), accounts for 98 percent of all allocation trades and 78 percent of all entitlement trades within Australia, by volume. Indeed, the Murray-Darling Basin figures prominently in discussions about water trad- ing, as an example of a thriving incentive-based sys- tem that successfully transitioned from a non-market system (Grafton et al., 2012). In fiscal year 2012–13, the total volume of short-term (allocation) trading within the Murray-Darling Basin increased 44  percent from the previous year, from almost 3.5  million acre-feet (MAF) to 5 MAF, or about 50 percent of total surface water use in the basin. The total volume of long-term trades, however, decreased by about 14 percent over that period, to about 0.85 MAF. A national study found that these permanent entitlement trades often offset the temporary allocation trades, as irrigators planting perennial crops, such as grapes or almonds, purchased entitlements to meet expected future demand, but then sold a portion of the temporary allocations associated with these entitlements to generate revenue (Frontier Economics and Australia National Water Commission, 2007). For more information on Australia’s water mar- ket, see Annex 2. In the western United States, the scale of water trad- ing is considerably lower. A database compiled by the University of California Santa Barbara (UCSB) Bren School shows notifications for more than 4,000 water trades in 12 states in the western United States from the years 1987–2008.11 Brewer et al. (2007) docu- mented the large variability in the volume, price, and duration of water trades in the western United States, both within and between sectors. In 2009, the most recent year for which data are available, the database 11 The database summary notes that “The data are drawn from water trans- actions reported in the monthly trade journal the Water Strategist and its predecessor the Water Intelligence Monthly from 1987 through February 2010.” These data reflect published reports that in some cases do not reflect final transfer agreements. For example, the database reports that the Imperial Irrigation District-San Diego County Water Authority water transfer began in 1997, although the final transfer agreement was not actually signed and the transfer did not begin (at different volumes than the database reports) until October 2003. The Bren School water transfer database is available at bren.ucsb.edu/news/water_transfers.htm.
  • 138. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT14 in several parts of the country (Thobani, 1997), with nearly 3,700 registered water transfer requests in 2006 alone (CONAGUA, 2012). Water markets have also been established in parts of Europe, Asia, and Africa. In Spain, informal trades, sales, and short-term exchanges of water are common, while formal transfers of long-term water rights are generally limited to groundwater (Albiac et al., 2006). In Spain’s Alicante basin, several irrigation districts auction their annual water allocations to district farmers (Albiac et al., 2006), creating a strong incentive to improve water- use efficiency and shift toward higher value crops. England has encouraged water trading for more than a decade, although only about 60 trades have occurred to date (TWSTT, 2014). South Africa has more extensive water markets that continue to be plagued by conflict and inadequate institutional support (Grafton et al., 2010). South Africa’s Water Act of 1998 has provided a framework for water trading. Historically, agricultural irrigators traded water rights within their sector, mediated by the national Department of Water Affairs and Forestry (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). In 2001, mining companies seeking to expand operations in northern South Africa successfully negotiated a temporary trade of some 10,000 acre-feet of water (13 million m3 ) from neigh- boring farmers – representing more than 70 percent of their annual allocation – in exchange for the current equivalent of about $1 million. These funds, used to help rehabilitate the local irrigation infrastructure, rep- resented less than 0.1 percent of the mines’ develop- ment costs, reflecting a significant economic disparity between the two interests (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). In Asia, India and Pakistan have informal water trad- ing, in which well-owners may sell some of the water they extract to neighboring farms or residents (Easter et al., 1999). In a report published by the Nepal Water Conservation Foundation and the Institute for Social in 2003, with an option for a 30-year extension, with the Imperial Irrigation District (IID), one of the largest irrigation districts in the country.12 Under the terms of the agreement, the SDCWA pays the IID to reduce its diversion of Colorado River water, while the Authority diverts a like amount farther upstream. After a 15-year period intended to create time to address ecological and public health impacts resulting from the trade, the IID will shift to efficiency-based methods (such as lin- ing canals and constructing regulating reservoirs) to generate the water to be conserved. In essence, the Authority is paying the District to improve the effi- ciency of its operations and receiving the water con- served. The trade is ramping up to a maximum volume of 200,000 acre-feet per year by 2021, representing about 25 percent of the region’s total water supply. In 2014, the price for the water was $594 per acre-foot, plus an additional $445 per acre-foot to a different agency to convey the water through its facilities. This total, which does not include additional payments to offset the environmental impacts of the trade, is about half what the Authority has contracted to pay for water generated by a new desalination plant on the coast. In Central and South America, Chile and Mexico have active water trading markets. Chile’s Limarí Basin enjoys water rights trading and water transfers, enabled by three large state-built reservoirs and robust local water organizations. The actual number of water trades in Chile’s Limarí Basin has averaged about 33 each year (Romano and Leporati, 2002), although water trading has been more limited in the rest of the country (Bauer, 1997). Mexico’s National Water Law of 1992 established a formal water market with tradable concessions that formed the basis for active markets 12 With the exception of “water conservancy districts”, to the best of our knowledge there is no strict naming convention for water agencies. The ability to create conservancy districts is established by statute, enabling state district courts or other authorities to establish conservancy districts with the power to impose property taxes to support district functions (Howe, 2011). Water authorities tend to serve municipal areas, and irrigation districts primarily serve agricultural users. However, the San Diego County Water Authority has agricultural customers (fewer than before, as they have phased out subsidies for irrigation water), while the Imperial Irrigation District sells water to all of the cities within its service area, serving more than 170,000 people. Similarly, water conservancy districts usually serve agriculture, although some districts may also serve municipal customers. “Water banks are generally less widespread than water trading…”
  • 139. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 15 In 2003, nine states in the western United States had functioning state-operated water banks, although their level of activity varied dramatically and several are no longer active. From 1995–2003, for example, Texas’ water bank only reported one transaction (Clifford, 2012). California’s Drought Water Bank functioned for a limited period in the early 1990s, providing a mechanism to facil- itate and expedite water trading between agriculture and cities during a multi-year drought, while also ensuring minimum instream flows and providing limited ground- water recharge. The Drought Water Bank purchased, held, and sold water, primarily from northern agricultural users to southern municipal and industrial users, though about half of the more than 800,000 acre-feet pur- chased in 1991 was dedicated to instream flows (20 per- cent) and to recharge aquifers (32 percent) (Dinar et al., 1997). Idaho operates water banks to manage storage in reservoirs, and in Oregon, river conservancies oper- ate as water trusts to purchase or lease water rights to supplement instream flows (Clifford, 2012). The Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District maintains a web- page that functions as an online bulletin board connect- ing those seeking to acquire water with those who have water to rent, an example of a brokerage-type water bank. The very active water trading within the Conser- vancy District is attributable to the equal volume and priority of each share available for trade, the absence of any requirement to preserve return flows or protect downstream or junior priority users, and the fact that trading only requires the approval of the district itself, not a water court, as is the case for most other trades within Colorado (Howe and Goemans, 2003). The Colorado River basin, shown in Figure 3, boasts a large number of creative approaches to water bank- ing. In 1998, the federal government adopted a new rule permitting interstate banking agreements within the basin. To date, Arizona has diverted and stored more than 600,000 acre-feet of Colorado River water for southern Nevada, and a southern California water agency has diverted and stored more than 161,000 acre-feet for southern Nevada, representing creative methods of skirting state prohibitions of interstate water trading. In 2007, the seven basin states adopted a new set of rules for managing the river that, among and Environmental Transition, Moench et al. (2003) described an active but largely unregulated water trad- ing system in Chennai, India, where private companies meet as much as 35 percent of urban water demand by delivering raw or purified well water purchased from farmers in surrounding areas or extracted from the companies’ wells. This private sector engagement helps meet a demand for water that the intermittent municipal water supply cannot meet, though the price is much higher. Moench et al. (2003) reported that the price of water for urban customers can be 1,000 times higher than the price paid to the peri-urban farmers supplying the water. Also in Asia, in a rare international water trade, the Bishkek Treaty of 1998 commit- ted Kyrgyzstan to deliver water via the Syr Darya to Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan in exchange for compen- sation (Ambec et al., 2013). China reportedly has small, local water markets (Grafton et al., 2010). In Oman, the local falaj irrigation systems purchase short-term allocations of water based on units of time rather than volume (e.g. a certain duration of water delivery) in a village-based auction (Al-Marshudi, 2007). Water banks are generally less widespread than water trading because they require additional expertise, fund- ing, and governance structures. Water banks appear to be most prevalent in the western United States, although there are examples in several other coun- tries. The presence of three reservoirs in Chile’s Limarí Basin facilitates the large number of water trades in the region (Bauer, 1997), meaning that, in this case, the physical storage rather than an institutional bank facilitates the water trades. In Australia, brokerage-type water banks are active in both the Murray-Darling Basin and in northern Victoria, where the banks post informa- tion about pricing and availability (O’Donnell and Colby, 2010). Mexico’s National Water Commission reported that the 13 state-based water banks in the country bro- ker thousands of water trades annually (CONAGUA, 2012). In three basins in Spain, water banks operated by local water agencies, known as “exchange centers”, have successfully brokered water trades that have lessened groundwater overdraft (Garrido and Llamas, 2009).
  • 140. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT16 system as a whole, rather than claiming it for them- selves. In this instance, the Bureau of Reclamation acts as a water bank by obtaining water through a reverse auction process, augmenting system storage for the benefit of the system as a whole. Environmental, economic, and social performance The primary goal of water trading is usually to pro- mote economic efficiency by reallocating water from lower to higher value uses. However, in some cases, other key developments, permitted entitlement hold- ers in Arizona, California, and Nevada to invest in vari- ous water efficiency projects within their own states and store a percentage of the conserved water in Lake Mead for later use. To date, more than 1.1 million acre-feet have been stored in Lake Mead under this new program. More recently, four large municipal water agencies in the basin, in cooperation with the federal Bureau of Reclamation, agreed to invest $11 million in fallowing and efficiency improvements, and to dedi- cate the conserved water to the Colorado River Basin FIGURE 3. The Colorado River Basin Source: Cohen et al., 2013.
  • 141. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 17 can be an effective means of reallocating water, where the appropriate conditions exist. The application sec- tion of 3.1 of this report describes the range of countries where water trading occurs in general terms. In most of these regions, limited data precludes detailed assess- ment of the number or volume of water trading activi- ties. In several locations, such as the Murray-Darling Basin and the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, water trades occur frequently, often for small volumes, suggesting a robust and active market with low transaction costs (Howe and Goemans, 2003). In other areas, there tend to be fewer but larger transac- tions, suggesting higher barriers to trading. The largest agriculture-to-urban water trade in the United States has been successful for San Diego County, which currently receives about 25 percent of its water supply from the rural Imperial Valley,13 at a unit cost of water that is less than half the contracted price of water from a desalination plant that will soon be operational on the San Diego coastline. The long- term water trade appears to be cost effective from San Diego’s perspective but, due to significant externalities, maynotbefromthebroadersociety’sperspective.Total transaction costs for this water trade have exceeded $175 million in attorney fees, plus an additional $171 mil- lion in mitigation fees to offset public health and envi- ronmental impacts. In addition, the State of California agreed to cover all direct mitigation costs in excess of a pre-determined financial cap for the water trade parties. The magnitude of these additional mitigation costs – primarily for managing dust emissions – will not be known for many years but are expected to run into the hundreds of millions of dollars (Cohen, 2014). As suggested by the Imperial Valley-San Diego example, a narrow focus on direct economic performance may ignore trading’s broader economic impacts. Although there are thousands of peer-reviewed articles on the economic potential of water trading, robust economic analyses of specific water trades do 13 Roughly 15 percent of San Diego County’s current water supply comes from the water trade with the Imperial Valley, while an additional 10 per- cent comes from water conserved via the lining of the All-American Canal, a project funded primarily by the state of California. water trading has been used for environmental or rec- reational purposes, reflecting the increasing societal value ascribed to instream flows. In this section, we evaluate the environmental, social, and economic per- formance of water trading. While much of the literature on water trading tends toward theoretical assessments or recommendations about trading (Newlin et al., 2002) or specific elements of trading, such as property rights regimes or institutional capacity (Culp et al., 2014), we examine the literature on actual impacts to evaluate the state of practice. ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Although there are a large number of articles and stud- ies modeling the potential economic benefits of water trading, the number of detailed economic assessments of existing water trades is surprisingly limited. Some studies on local impacts suggest positive net economic performance,butthesestudiestypicallydonotdescribe changes in the distribution of impacts, and they rarely describe broader economic impacts. Assessing the economic performance of water trading is frequently as simple as documenting trading activity and quanti- fying the number, volume, and value of reported water trades. A more comprehensive analysis would require surveys to estimate the number and volume of addi- tional water trades that users would like to make, as a means to assess the disparity between availability and demand. An even more robust analysis would compare the ability of different instruments – such as water trad- ing, demand-side management, and supply augmenta- tion – to meet specific water demands, and the cost of those instruments. While water agencies seeking to improve their water supply reliability may perform such analyses within their service area, these assessments are often not publicly available. The large number of trades and the significant volumes traded,especiallyinAustralia,indicatethatwatertrading “…the number of detailed economic assessments of existing water trades is surprisingly limited.”
  • 142. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT18 the trading activity in the district is short term and low volume, especially in comparison with trading activ- ity in the same water basin but outside of the district. Municipal and industrial (MI) users buy district water rights to meet expected future demand and then lease some of this water back to district irrigators. This ris- ing MI demand has increased the price of imported water rights (known as allotments) within the district (Howe, 2011). Within the relatively prosperous district, this has improved economic performance. However, in other regions, particularly in economically depressed rural areas, selling water out of the area has exacer- bated economic decline, causing property values to fall and the local tax base to shrink (Howe, 2011). In Australia, water trading has enabled the expan- sion of the wine industry and other high value crops, such as almonds. Over time, the dairy industry in one part of the Murray-Darling Basin transitioned from a small purchaser of water entitlements to a net seller of entitlements, primarily to the expanding wine and nut producers in other parts of the basin. These expanding industries have also exhibited a shift from the former model of shared irrigation infrastructure (such as com- mon canals) to direct extraction from the river by indi- vidual irrigators – in other words, from a communal to a more flexible individual approach to irrigation (Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). Water trading within the Murray-Darling Basin grew and matured within the context of the devastating drought that afflicted the region from 2006 through 2010. The national water trading assessment noted the challenge of disentangling the economic impacts of the drought from those of water trading itself, gen- erally concluding that trading offered irrigators an additional revenue stream, plus additional flexibility and resilience within the face of a severely limited water supply. Without water trading, some sectors, such as the dairy industry, would have seen even greater losses. Trading also offered a mechanism to adjust for historic water apportionments, facilitating the voluntary sale of water from less productive to more productive lands and uses (Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). not appear to exist. For example, despite its size and importance, there do not appear to be any economic analyses of the Imperial Valley-San Diego County water trade that assess revenues, agricultural produc- tion lost due to fallowing, value of transfer payments, relative value of the water in San Diego, or employ- ment impacts. There are, however, general regional or district-level assessments of water trading, as well as an extensive body of literature on macro-economic trends, and expected or modeled benefits of water trading. Yet, assessments of “net” economic benefit at the state or regional level, expressed in terms of net increase in employment or revenue, can mask dispari- ties between areas of origin and importing areas, and even within the areas of origin themselves. In one study, the income and employment gains found in regions in California that imported water via trades exceeded the net losses (total compensation often failed to cover foregone crop revenue) in exporting areas (Howitt, 1998). In 1991, trading activity gener- ated an average net income loss in water-exporting areas equivalent to about 5 percent of net agricultural activity, though this varied within different parts of the state. However, agricultural areas importing water saw total gains greater than the losses in exporting areas: net agricultural water trading activity was positive, as water moved from lower-value crops to higher-value crops (Howitt, 1998). In another example, an agricul- tural community in California exporting water to urban areas saw a 26  percent decrease in the number of farms overall, but this masked a 70 percent loss in the number of small farms and the loss of almost half of the number of produce firms in the area (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). The Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, introduced in Section 3.1, has a very active water mar- ket in part because of low transaction costs. Much of “In Australia, water trading has enabled the expansion of the wine industry and other high value crops, such as almonds.”
  • 143. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 19 community support, especially relative to regulatory takings. However, water trading can also generate large environmental externalities, adversely affecting either natural habitats or downstream users, or both (NRC, 1992). For example, when water for trading is generated by efficiency or by fallowing land, the trade may reduce the amount of runoff supporting local habitat and may diminish instream flows.14 On the other hand, some water trades may improve local instream flows by de- creasing diversions and contaminant loadings. Where water is traded to downstream users using the existing stream as a conveyance, trading could offer measur- able environmental benefits. Where water is traded out of the basin or alters the timing and magnitude of flows, adverse impacts are likely to occur. Unfortunately, there do not appear to be published assessments of the rela- tive impacts of water trading on streamflow.15 In the fol- lowing, we discuss the environmental performance of several examples of water trading. Water trading is now used in some areas to return water to river channels, in order to support listed species or threatened habitats, and for general ecosystem restora- tion (Tarlock, 2014). However in most areas, such activ- ity still represents only a tiny fraction of total water use in any given area.16 For example, the Colorado Water Trust (CWT) brokered a lease agreement between two state 14 In efficiency-based agricultural water trades, the buyer typically pays the irrigator to install more efficient irrigation equipment or methods, such as hiring additional irrigation management staff, installing pump- back systems, lining canals, or constructing new regulatory reservoirs. The water conserved by these new practices would then be available for transfer to the buyer/investor. Efficiency-based trades keep agricultural land in production and can increase total employment in the area of origin, but they require additional monitoring and measurement to doc- ument or calculate the volume of water conserved. In fallowing-based trades, also known as “buy-and-dry”, the buyer simply pays the irrigator not to irrigate and, in exchange, receives the volume of water historically used by the parcel. This requires less effort and less time to implement, but takes land out of production and typically generates significant adverse impacts on rural communities. 15 For example, the various water trading agreements between Imperi- al Valley and urban Southern California will have the direct effect of reducing the volume of water flowing down the lower Colorado River between Parker Dam – the new diversion point – and Imperial Dam, about 150 river miles downstream, by more than 300,000 acre-feet per year, equivalent to roughly 5 percent of the historic average annual flow between these two diversion points. 16 Such instream flows typically require additional legal conditions, such as explicit recognition of instream flow rights, improved monitoring and measurement, and the acceptance of local entitlement holders. The active participation of the Australian government in water trading increased prices and participation but may also have increased total water use within the basin. A large survey (n=520) of those selling entitle- ments or allocations to the Australian environmental water program found that sellers believed they received a higher price from the government than they would have from other private agents, or that the government was the only purchaser in the market. The survey also found that sellers reportedly used 69 to 77 percent of their water allocations prior to trading it to the govern- ment (Wheeler and Cheesman, 2013). That is, survey respondents reported selling portions of their alloca- tions that they would not have used otherwise. Selling unused water allocations is not a reallocation so much as an expansion of total water use. Water trading occurs in a variety of forms. Howe (2011) noted that, in practice, many water trades reflect a change in type of use rather than a change in loca- tion. For example, in the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District, developers have purchased farmland and its water rights and then converted the land and water to residential or commercial use, often generating a significant increase in revenue per unit of water while limiting some of the social and environ- mental externalities that would occur if the water were physically moved to a different location. ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE Water trading has been used as a mechanism to obtain water for ecological purposes, to augment streamflows, and to address water quality concerns (such as tem- perature) in threatened reaches. The environmental performance of water trading is highly variable, de- pending on the type of trade and site-specific condi- tions. The benefits of voluntary, incentive-based water acquisition include ease of transaction and greater “Water trading can also generate large environmental externalities, adversely affecting either natural habitats or downstream users, or both”
  • 144. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT20 trading activity between 1982 and 2011, but less than 0.5 percent of total water use in the state (Figure 4). In Australia, the federal government has invested more than $3 billion to date to purchase entitlements and allocations for environmental water, protecting eco- logical resources to enable and expedite water trading between non-governmental users. In 2008–2009, for example, the government purchased nearly 880,000 acre-feet of long-term water entitlements and 1.4 mil- lion acre-feet of short-term allocations, at a total cost of about $2 billion (adjusted to 2014$). The price for this water ranged from about $269 to $377 per acre-foot. Local interest in this environmental water buyback program, known as “Restoring the Balance”, has been strong, with the Australian government receiving nearly 7,600 applications to sell water from 2007 to early 2012. Water entitlement sales for the environment account agencies, increasing low-season flows in the White River by 3,000 acre-feet of water three times over a 10-year period to lower the temperature of river flows and, in turn, benefit fish (CWT, 2015). Similarly, the Columbia Basin Water Transactions Program, active for more than a decade, works with partner organizations in four west- ern states to acquire and dedicate water for instream flows within the basin. In 2013, 45 transactions led to the acquisition of more than 48,000 acre-feet of water, cost- ing about $13.9 million and benefiting some 276 miles of streams, the fish and wildlife, and the communities that depend on them (National Fish and Wildlife Foundation, 2014). Bonneville Power Administration, in cooperation with the Northwest Power and Conservation Council, provides some of the funding for the program due, in part, to concerns about endangered species. In California, environmental water purchases averaged 152,000 acre-feet, accounting for about 14 percent of FIGURE 4. Water purchases for the environment in California, 1982–2011 Source: Hanak and Stryjewski, 2012. 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 500 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 WaterPurchases(1,000acre-feet)
  • 145. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 21 resulting in the loss of open water and wetland habitats that support several hundred species of birds (Cohen and Hyun, 2006). Yet water trading occurs in regions of water scarcity, where water resources in particular have already under- gone dramatic transformation. Dams, canals, and diver- sions have already altered the timing and magnitude of stream flows throughout many of the regions now turning to water trading (Worster, 1985). Determining the additional impacts of water trading upon this exist- ing landscape would be difficult. An alternative basis for comparison could be the marginal or cumulative environmental impacts of water trading relative to the new impacts of additional water development. That is, water trading may prove to be less environmentally harmful than the construction of new dams and diver- sion projects, or even the construction of new desalina- tion plants. SOCIAL PERFORMANCE Water trading is usually characterized as a market- based mechanism that reduces economic inefficiencies by reallocating water from lower to higher value uses. Trading has been used to meet explicit environmen- tal objectives, but, as described previously, it is rarely employed to address equity challenges. Indeed, water trading can exacerbate social and economic inequali- ties, worsening gender and geographic differences. In regions with informal water rights and trading that are functional at the community level, such as rural Nepal, demands from outlying urban areas for larger scale trades can overwhelm local water management institutions. Trades from these rural areas might not reflect the true value of the many informal uses water has in the community (such as subsistence fishing or milling) or the full range of informal ownership and use for roughly 25  percent of total entitlement trading activity (Wheeler and Cheesman, 2013). However, some irrigators and state governments in Australia oppose the instream buyback program, and it was cut dramatically when the Labor Party fell from power in September 2013 (Bennett and Carroll, 2014). However, water trades not explicitly intended for envi- ronmental purposes can create a host of adverse envi- ronmental impacts. They can, for example, change the timing, quantity, and quality of return flows, adversely affecting riparian and wetland habitats and the species that depend upon them. Some trades, such as from California’s Owens Valley to Los Angeles, adversely affect public health by increasing the amount of dust emissions from exposed lakebed and fallowed land, generating significant externalities (LA DWP, 2013). Groundwater substitution, in which a user trades sur- face water and increases groundwater extraction, can lead to over-extraction, and sinking or caving in of land surfaces (subsidence), depleting springs and seeps, and robbing future generations (Brown et al., 2015). Water trading can also diminish groundwater recharge rates, whether the water is generated via fallowing or increased efficiency. In the southern Indian state of Tamil Nadu, farmers irrigating with groundwater have increased extraction rates and sold the excess to water tanker trucks serving urban populations, an example of informal water trading. Yet this increased groundwater extraction lowered the water table, increasing pump- ing costs for other irrigators or drying up their wells entirely (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Efforts to mitigate the environmental impacts of water trading have had mixed success. In Spain, a proposal to add a small environmental mitigation fee to each unit of water traded was insufficient to overcome the strong opposition of environmental and social organizations (Albiac et al., 2006). In California, state commitments to mitigate the environmental and public health impacts of the nation’s largest agriculture-to-urban water trade have yet to result in any actual mitigation efforts, potentially jeopardizing several listed species and likely “…water trades not explicitly intended for environmental purposes can create… adverse environmental impacts.”
  • 146. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT22 water first began flowing to LA, creating the single largest source of dust pollution in the United States. In the past decade, after years of litigation, LA has spent more than $1.4 billion on dust management efforts and has returned some of the water to Owens Lake.17 San Luis Valley, Colorado. As demonstrated by efforts to destroy the infrastructure moving water out of the Owens Valley, local opposition to trading water can be strong. In the late 1980s, the Canadian owner of the 97,000-acre Baca Ranch in southern Colorado’s San Luis Valley began buying water rights from other farms in San Luis Valley, allegedly to irrigate new crops. Local residents, who soon discovered that the true pur- pose of the purchases was to sell the water to Denver suburbs, 100 miles to the northeast, feared that their valley would experience the devastation felt in Owens Valley. Thus, they formed Citizens for San Luis Valley Water to fight the water trade, working with the local irrigation district to support a special ballot measure to raise local taxes to fund litigation against the pro- posed water sale. The ballot measure prevailed with 92 percent of the vote. In 1991, the locals prevailed in court, stopping the proposed water trade. After Baca Ranch was subsequently sold, the new owner also attempted to sell the water out of the valley, sponsor- ing two statewide initiatives seen as efforts to support the water trade. In 1998, both initiatives failed, receiving less than 5 percent of the vote. With continued pub- lic pressure, the federal government purchased Baca Ranch in 2004 – more than a quarter century after the fight began – to prevent water from leaving the San Luis Valley. It then parceled the land to the newly designated Great Sand Dunes National Park, part to a nearby national forest, and 54,000 acres to the new Baca National Wildlife Refuge (Reimers, 2013). Imperial Valley, California. On the other hand, water trading that promotes efficiency rather than fallowing of agricultural land can improve socio-economic out- comes for both the area of origin and the destination. For example, an ongoing water trade from the Imperial 17 For information on the dust emissions at Owens Lake and the current dust management program, see the Great Basin Unified Air Pollution Control District website. rights within the community, meaning residents may be deprived of full compensation (Pant el al., 2008). Even within the community, the complex web of informal water-use arrangements can complicate informal trad- ing agreements and, in turn, generate a range of eco- nomic impacts on those using the water who had not been consulted or participated in the trading arrange- ments (Pant et al., 2008). Limarí Basin, Chile. Unequal access to water mar- kets due to unequal access to information or credit can distort outcomes and reduce market efficiency. Chile’s Limarí Basin has very high water trading activity, sug- gesting successful economic performance, but Romano and Leporati (2002) argued that it suffers from several market distortions arising from disparities between the resources available to those trading water. Peasants fare poorly in trading activity because their water rights often are not fully recognized, they are not as well- organized as those purchasing the water, and they lack access to information on pricing (Romano and Leporati, 2002). Dinar et al. (1997) noted that economic perfor- mance is affected by disparities in the value of water in different sectors and by the ability of those with limited means to participate in water trading. Southern California. Water generated for trades by fallowing land can benefit water rights holders at the expense of farmworkers and equipment suppliers, potentially devastating rural communities. California’s Owens Valley provides one of the early examples of the adverse impacts of trading water away from rural areas. In the early 1900s, agents secretly representing the City of Los Angeles (LA) covertly purchased land in the Owens Valley. In 1908, LA began a 5-year construc- tion project of a 419-mile pipeline to divert water from Owens Valley farmland to LA. Although Owens Valley irrigators had willingly sold their water through market transactions, they had not contemplated the plight of the valley as a whole. Over the next several years, agi- tators from the valley dynamited the pipeline several times in a vain attempt to protect their water supplies (Hundley, 2001). In addition to the direct economic and social impacts on the Owens Valley, the water trade had desiccated Owens Lake by 1926, just 13 years after
  • 147. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 23 within households where men have left for new indus- trial jobs enabled by new water supplies. In places where rural agriculture, particularly at the household level, provides subsistence and food security, reduced access to water can impose significant adverse impacts (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). Rural household access to water for domestic uses and for subsistence agriculture may have only infor- mal community-level recognition that does not trans- late into tradable water rights. Water trading that does not recognize these informal or ad hoc water uses can adversely affect equity outcomes and prompt ques- tions of legitimacy (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Formal, state-recognized water rights typically require the means and ability to register and defend them, in turn conferring power on those with formal water rights. In South Asia and other parts of the develop- ing world, informal water-use arrangements that permit and enable water use and trading can be disrupted by formal rights-based trades and command-and-control reallocations (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Zwarteveen (1997) noted that, as men in Ecuador, Nepal, and Peru have migrated in search of employ- ment, women have assumed a disproportionately large number of agricultural roles, even as formal and infor- mal water rights continue to be held by the absent men. These geographic and gender disparities can generate adverse outcomes as water is traded by absentee own- ers. Conversely, trading within households – even in the form of recognition of joint ownership – can encourage investment in water resource maintenance and pro- ductivity at the local level (Zwarteveen, 1997). Similarly, water organizations in the developing world, where decisions may be made about trading water out of the community, tend to have limited female participa- tion, potentially neglecting compensation for impacts that would have been identified if there were stronger female roles and participation (Zwarteveen, 1997). Water trading mechanisms can privilege certain popu- lations and marginalize others, especially when cultural practices differ. For example, New Mexico’s cooperative irrigation systems, known as acequias, usually enjoy Valley that began in 1989 relies on efficiency-based measures rather than fallowing to generate water for trade, creating additional employment while keeping land in production.18 Water trading’s social impacts vary based on several factors, including the relative economic health of the area of origin and the purchasing area, whether or not the water leaves the area of origin, the process used to trade the water, and the relative economic and politi- cal power of the parties (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005), gender differences regarding access to and control of water (Zwarteveen, 1997), the amount of trading activity in the area (Howe, 2011), and the legiti- macy of the water rights being traded (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Impacts often vary within the same community, as those with water rights or alloca- tions to trade receive compensation, while third parties – such as irrigation equipment suppliers or farmwork- ers – may suffer a loss of revenue or income as a result of trading (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Water trades within the same region typically have minimal or no adverse social or equity impacts. Howe (2011) noted the large number of small-volume, short- term water trades within an irrigation district as an example of positive economic and equity outcomes. Inter-sectoral trades, such as from agricultural to manufacturing or mining within the same region, may also generate positive economic and equity outcomes, as jobs shift from lower income farm employment to higher income industrial employment (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). However, Zwarteveen (1997) noted that even such intra-regional trades can gen- erate differential impacts based on gender, requiring additional agricultural and domestic labor for women 18 The Imperial Irrigation District’s IID/MWD Water Conservation Program Final Construction Report (2000) documented that 24 separate system water conservation projects and programs (as opposed to on-farm), such as lining irrigation canals and installing new headgates, had been implemented through 1999. The capital cost for these totaled $193 million (2014$), with an additional $8.3 million in annual operations and maintenance costs. These improvements yield 108,500 acre-feet of conserved water per year, at a cost of $254 per acre-foot. In addition to the jobs associated with the initial construction effort, the on-going water trade supports about 12–13 full-time positions for managing water deliveries, and for annual operations and maintenance.
  • 148. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT24 trading can increase costs for those who do not sell, such as operations and maintenance costs associated with water storage and delivery structures. The eco- nomic and equity impacts of water traded from rural areas can accumulate with additional trading activity, reaching a tipping point where local demand for agri- cultural services falls below the level necessary to main- tain operations, creating a cascading set of business failures and depressing the local tax base (Howe, 2011). Agricultural areas importing traded water may also suf- fer from third-party impacts, in the form of increased competition, extended wait-times for water deliveries via shared infrastructure, and rising water tables that may threaten plant roots or require additional drainage (Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). The one key exception to water trading that exacer- bates social and economic inequalities is in South Africa. Section 27(1) of South Africa’s 1998 National Water Act states: “In issuing a general authorisation or licence a re- sponsible authority must take into account all relevant factors, including… (b) the need to redress the results of past racial and gender discrimination;… (d) the socio-economic impact – (i) of the water use or uses if authorised; or (ii) of the failure to authorise the water use or uses.” While this act explicitly sought to use water trading to improve socio-economic conditions,19 South Africa’s Department of Water Affairs and Forestry (now known as the Department of Water and Sanitation) refused to permit more than 118 applications for water trades from 2005 through 2008, claiming that the trades failed to meet the Section 27(1) standards (Coleman, 2008). South Africa’s Supreme Court found in 2012 that: i) one proposed trade would create new employment oppor- tunities for both men and women in a region with high unemployment, meeting the standard established by 19 The National Water Act is available at http://www.acts.co.za/national-wa- ter-act-1998/. very senior water rights. However, they have fared poorly when defending their rights or seeking com- pensation for third-party impacts in state proceedings, where language and cultural practices favor fluency in English and legal literacy (Meinzen-Dick and Pradhan, 2005). Romano and Leporati (2002) found similar circumstances in Chile, where less-educated rural peasants fared poorly in trading water rights to more powerful non-agricultural interests. Economic disparities also affect water-trading out- comes. As with the acequias, wealthy, powerful inter- ests enjoy disproportionate advantages relative to many historic water rights holders. In South Africa in the late 1990s, mining interests sought to increase their production and activity in rural, water-scarce regions by purchasing water rights from small irri- gators, at prices ten times higher than other irriga- tors were willing to offer. Although the mines offered employment and generated greater returns per unit of water, they threatened to dewater local subsis- tence farms and adversely affect a broad swath of rural economies beyond the irrigators voluntarily sell- ing their water (Farolfi and Perret, 2002). A study of water trading in Chile’s Limarí Valley found a similar impact, where increasing rural poverty was traced to water rights sales from peasants to non-agricultural interests and the general worsening of water-rights distribution (Romano and Leporati, 2002). As noted in the examples of the Owens and San Luis Valleys, those in areas of origin can strongly, sometimes violently, oppose the sale of water to outside interests. A national study of water trading in Australia found that this opposition can extend to local interests that trade their water rights to external interests (Frontier Economics and Australia NWC, 2007). In addition to cultural and social bases for opposing such trades, “Water trading mechanisms can privilege certain populations and marginalize others…”
  • 149. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 25 Grafton et al. (2010) wrote that “Legal clarity over water rights, including what they can be used for and the rules of water trade, is a cornerstone of functioning water markets.” Diversion or, better yet, consumptive use water rights with clear title and quantified alloca- tions that can be leased or sold can be described as marketable property rights, a necessary condition for water trading (Grafton et al., 2012). Culp et al. (2014) noted that water trading requires legally enforceable contracts that clearly and completely define the water right to be traded, an exclusive right to the water, and the recognized right to trade the water. Government plays a clear role in establishing these necessary condi- tions, documenting and, in some cases, allocating water rights themselves, establishing and maintaining the legal framework in which trading occurs and, in many cases, financing the physical infrastructure to store and convey water and allow water trading to occur (Dinar et al., 1997). Strong and effective institutions that adju- dicate and resolve disputes, enforce contracts, and monitor trading agreements are a necessary element in successful water markets (Zwarteveen, 1997). Typically, infrastructure is also required to physically convey water from a seller to a buyer, or to store or otherwise manage water availability so that an agreed- upon volume can be conveyed to the buyer at the appropriate time. In some cases, creative agreements have enabled trades from unconnected or remote sources of water, creating what are known as “in-lieu” or “paper” trades.21 While these trades can avoid require- ments for connecting physical infrastructure, they do require sophisticated legal arrangements, manage- ment, and monitoring to ensure that the correct vol- umes of water move at the approved time. 21 One example of an in-lieu water trade is the agreement between the Metropolitan Water District of Southern California and the Coachella Valley Water District and the Desert Water Agency. All three have contracts with California’s State Water Project (SWP), but because a direct connection from SWP’s California Aqueduct to Coachella Valley would have cost the equivalent of more than $1.8 billion, the latter two agencies agreed to an in-lieu exchange agreement with Metropolitan for a “bucket-for-bucket” exchange of SWP water for Colorado River water. That is, Metropolitan takes the other agencies’ allotment of SWP water, in exchange for giving up an equivalent amount of Colorado River water. Source: cvwd.org/news/news178.php. Section 27, and ii) the Department had acted improp- erly in failing to grant the requested license to trade the water.20 According to a local source, however, the responsible authorities in South Africa continue to delay and deny licenses for water trades, meaning that South Africa’s water market has been restricted for a decade (Backeberg, personal communication, 2015). Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions Institutional arrangements determine the ultimate success or failure of water trading (Livingston, 1998). Successful water trading requires secure and flexible water rights that recognize and protect users and others from externalities. Such institutional arrangements also need to be flexible enough to adapt to changing physical conditions as well as changing social norms, such as the growing interest in meeting environmental needs and protecting water quality (Livingston, 1998). Recognizing and understanding these factors can help explain the varying successes and even the existence of water trad- ing in different countries and regions within countries. Some factors, such as legal and transferable rights to use water, may be necessary for water trading to occur. Others, such as access to timely information about water available to trade, can enable water trading but may not be required for trading to occur. Still other factors, such as “no injury” regulations and “area of origin” protections, limit water trading or function as barriers or obstacles to trading. The following explains the details of the neces- sary, enabling and limiting conditions. Necessary conditions include: • legal, transferable rights to use water • decoupling of water rights from land rights • contract adjudication and enforcement • means for buyers and sellers to communicate • physical infrastructure to move water • mechanisms to monitor and measure water flows and use. 20 Makhanya v Goede Wellington Boerdery (Pty) Ltd (230/12) [2012] ZASCA 205 (30 November 2012).
  • 150. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT26 as precluding trading while the higher end of the scale can be seen as enabling trading. Water banks can enable water trading by connecting buyers and sellers, posting information on availability and transaction history and, in some cases, by physi- cally storing water to match availability and demands. The existence of technically skilled staff and monitor- ing equipment increases the efficacy of water banks and can help resolve disputes. Where water banks do not exist or have limited capacity, water contracting can enable spot trading (Brown et al., 2015). The availability of pertinent information can be con- sidered both a necessary and an enabling condition, depending on the extent and type of information avail- able. The availability of information on quantity, quality, location, and timing of water entitlements or alloca- tions can enable trading by pairing sellers and buy- ers. Similarly, clear information about transaction costs enables trading. Additionally, greater information and certainty about future conditions, such as the security of a water right given climate changes, can also enable water trading (Brown et al., 2015). Clear and timely information about prices also facilitates trading and decreases search costs (Levine et al., 2007). Social cohesion can also enable water trading. Trading is more likely to occur where informal bonds exist, such as between neighbors or within an irrigation district or even between irrigators, relative to trading between parties with no common history. In some cases, irriga- tors will accept a lower bid from another irrigator than a higher bid from a municipal agency, particularly one from outside the basin or region. Water rights hold- ers may fear that indicating they have water to trade could be interpreted to mean that they do not need the water, jeopardizing the right or imposing political costs (Albiac et al., 2006). Water trading can and does occur when necessary con- ditions are satisfied, but markets are much more robust and active when additional enabling conditions are met. Enabling conditions include: • water rights equivalency (as opposed to prioritized rights) • water banks and contracts • clear, available information • social cohesion • competitive markets with multiple participants of roughly equivalent economic power. One of the major factors contributing to Australia’s successful adoption of water trading in the Murray- Darling Basin was the absence of prioritized water rights. This enabled water trading without concern for impacts on those holding less senior water rights (see Annex 1 for greater detail). By contrast, in the western United States and other regions with prioritized water rights (also known as prior appropriation or seniority), an entitlement holder with a senior water right (deter- mined by the date the right was first exercised or “per- fected”) could only sell or lease water after ensuring that more junior rights holders receive compensation or do not otherwise protest the transaction. This distinc- tion helps explain the frequency of trades within irriga- tion districts where district members share a common priority right – such as the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District – and the much lower number of transactions between those with different priorities. That is, common priority rights or water rights with equivalent seniority can be traded more readily than rights with different priority dates. Dinar and Saleth (2005) proposed a scale from zero to seven to describe a range of surface water rights conditions that could be used to evaluate the enabling conditions for water trading. It spans from a rating of zero for no water rights, to a rating of five for appropria- tive rights; six for proportional sharing systems (such as the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy District and Australia); and seven for water licenses and per- mits. Under this system, we could categorize no rights “Social cohesion can also enable water trading. Trading is more likely to occur where informal bonds exist…”
  • 151. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 27 The anti-speculation doctrine requires buyers to describe the new location and use of the water, condi- tioning the trade on these terms and increasing trans- action costs (Culp et al., 2014). The anti-speculation doctrine is intended to prevent hoarding and mar- ket distortion by those with the economic means to acquire large volumes of water (Grafton et al., 2010). In some areas, this doctrine is waived for municipal water agencies, enabling them to acquire water for unspeci- fied future needs. The beneficial use doctrine requires that water rights be exercised, encouraging inefficient or unproductive uses as rights holders must “use it or lose it.” Some jurisdictions have amended beneficial use require- ments to enable rights holders to sell or lease the water they conserve or save by implementing efficiency mea- sures, water they would otherwise simply lose to junior rights holders. Without explicit protection for such conservation measures, the beneficial use doctrine precludes water efficiency and hinders trading. In some areas, laws prohibit users from selling or leasing water “salvaged” from conservation or efficiency measures (Culp et al., 2014). Some kinds of water rights, such as non-consumptive, appurtenant water rights (common in wetter regions of the world) do not lend themselves to water trading.22 Examples of such non-consumptive rights include rights to use or divert water to run mills or generate hydroelectric power. Some markets limit participation to existing contractors or entitlement holders (Albiac et al., 2006). A related barrier is a limitation on the purpose or use to which a buyer may apply water. For example, several states only allow state agencies, and not private individuals or non-profit organizations, to purchase or lease water for environmental purposes. 22 An appurtenant water right is directly tied to the land itself, typically to lands adjacent to streams. Levine et al. (2007) argued that successful water trad- ing requires the participation of multiple buyers and sellers, with roughly equivalent power. They contended that, without these factors, market inefficiencies will result. In Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin and within several United States irrigation districts, the satisfac- tion of these criteria has enabled active and successful water trading. In their absence, as seen in many agricul- tural-to-urban trades, a small number of economically powerful buyers have distorted markets and created significant externalities. Limiting conditions, which hinder or reduce water trading, include: • no injury rule • anti-speculation doctrine • beneficial use doctrine • property rights/pre-conditions • high transaction costs • spatial and temporal differences in supply and de- mand. In many arid and semi-arid regions, water scarcity and variability dictate that upstream “return flows” – water diverted but not consumed that subsequently returns to the stream – are used and claimed by downstream users. To protect the rights of these downstream users, courts or regulators typically require that the quantity and timing of these return flows be maintained when upstream water is traded. These and similar protections, known as “no injury” rules, place the burden of proof that the trade will not harm or adversely affect other water rights on those wishing to sell or lease water. The “no injury” rule is the prevailing law in most of the western United States, intended to presumptively protect junior water rights holders from harm that may occur due to changes in the volume or timing of return flows from senior appropriators. It dramatically increases transac- tion costs, requiring sellers to hire attorneys and hydrol- ogists to prove no injury, or otherwise compensate all junior entitlement holders, and was a strong disincen- tive to water trading (Culp et al., 2014).
  • 152. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT28 services (Figure 5). Payments are made to the envi- ronmental service provider by the beneficiary of those services, e.g. an individual, a community, a company, or a government. In essence, it is based on a benefi- ciary-pays principle, as opposed to a polluter-pays principle. Environmental services most often included in PES arrangements include carbon sequestration in biomass or soils; habitat provision for endangered spe- cies; protection of landscapes; and various hydrological functions related to the quality, quantity, or timing of freshwater flows from upstream areas to downstream users (Gómez-Baggethun et al., 2010). PES has no standardized definition. The definition most commonly used in the literature was developed by Wunder (2005) and is based on five criteria: i) a volun- tary transaction where ii) a well-defined environmental service is iii) purchased by at least one environmental service buyer from iv) at least one environmental ser- vice provider, with v) payment conditional on the ser- vice provided. In reality, few projects actually meet all of these criteria. For example, money may come from donors rather than service providers, or participation in theprogrammaybemandatory.Wunder(2005)argued, and several reviews confirm, that conditionality is the hardest criteria to meet because initiatives are often loosely monitored and payments are made up front or in good faith. Moreover, in some cases, participation is not voluntary (e.g. China), and the beneficiaries are broadly defined and are not directly contributing to the program. Wunder (2005) concluded that while there are a considerable number of PES-like arrangements, there are likely “very few ‘true PES’ conforming to the theoretical concept developed in the literature.” PES programs focused on watershed services are commonly referred to as payment for watershed ser- vices, or PWS. PWS arrangements, as with all PES arrangements, can take a variety of forms. They can be intended to prevent the degradation of a watershed or to restore a previously degraded watershed. They can be small, local schemes covering several hundred hectares or large, national schemes covering millions of High transactions costs, driven by the various doctrines noted above as well as by the need to overcome infor- mation constraints and related factors, can hinder water trading. Similarly, the time required to complete a trans- action may limit trading, particularly when buyers seek to meet a short-term demand such as an additional irri- gation cycle or to offset a delivery disruption within an urban system; relatively fast trades will produce greater trading activity than prolonged approval processes. Finally, geographic and temporal mismatches between supply and demand can impose additional barriers to water trading, especially in the absence of physical infrastructure to bridge these gaps. Where dams and conveyances do not exist, those wishing to sell water may lack the means to physically deliver the water to a potential buyer, or be unable to deliver the water at the right time (Bauer, 1997). 3.2 Payment for ecosystem services/payment for watershed services Description Payment for ecosystem services (PES) is an incentive- based instrument that seeks to monetize the external, non-market values of environmental services, such as removal of pollutants and regulation of precipita- tion events, into financial incentives for local actors to provide such services. In practical terms, PES involves a series of payments to a land or resource manager in exchange for a guaranteed flow of environmental “High transactions costs, driven by the various doctrines noted above as well as by the need to overcome information constraints and related factors, can hinder water trading.”
  • 153. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 29 • Service providers. For the vast majority of lo- cal and national programs, private landowners are the main watershed service providers, followed by communal landholders, private reserves, national parks and, in a very small number of local schemes, occupiers of public land. • Payment levels. In national programs, payment levels are mostly determined administratively. In the local programs, negotiation through an inter- mediary is more common. Direct negotiations be- tween supplier and buyer occur in very few cases. Funds and transfer of payments are in most cases managed by an intermediary, often in a specially set up trust fund. hectares. PWS schemes can be financed directly from the beneficiary or from third parties acting on behalf of the beneficiary, e.g. governments or institutions, or some combination thereof. They can involve cash or in-kind payments and be paid all at once or periodi- cally. In a comprehensive review of 50 ongoing PWS programs in developing countries, Porras et al. (2008) highlighted the following major trends. • Scale. Most ongoing programs (82 percent) are lo- cal, operating at watershed level or smaller. The re- maining 18 percent are national programs. Some of the local programs are linked to national programs or international projects. • Scope. Local programs tend to target one or two watershed services (more commonly water qual- ity than water quantity), while national programs tend to target multiple environmental services as a means of tapping into multiple funding sources. FIGURE 5. Schematic of a PES arrangement for watershed services Watershed services e.g. water purification, flood risk mitigation, aquifer recharge, erosion minimization Balances upstream and downstream interests Upstream community Stewards and providers of waterhsed services Incentives e.g. cash, assistance, materials Project Payments Downstream water users Beneficiaries of watershed services Source: Forest Trends, 2012. “PWS schemes can be financed directly from the beneficiary or from third parties…”
  • 154. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT30 that preserving the upstream rural Catskill watershed would be far less expensive. However, New York City had a long-history of employing eminent domain to solve such issues. When farmers and rural landowners voiced immediate concern, the city and local farmers came together to develop a plan that could meet both groups’ interests. A key element of the plan was the Whole Farm Program, a voluntary effort fully funded by New York City’s Department of Environmental Protection whereby farmers would work with technical advisors to custom design point and nonpoint source pollution control measures to meet an environmen- tal objective while also improving the viability of their farming business. By 2006, the city had spent or com- mitted $1.4–$1.5 billion in watershed protection proj- ects, averaging $167 million in expenditures per year (Kenny, 2006). Participation remains high, with 96 per- cent of large farms in the watershed participating in the program (Watershed Agricultural Council, 2011). PWS arrangements have also been established in developing countries. In Ecuador, for example, the Socio Bosque Program (SBP), a national program established in 2008, provides financial incentives to individual and communal forest landowners to conserve native forest and Andean tundra ecosystems. The program, which includes environmental protection and poverty alle- viation objectives, is largely state funded. Since 2012, however, additional support has been provided by the German Development Bank, NGOs, and General Motors Omnibus BB. Program participation is volun- tary. Participants are provided a monetary incentive per hectare of land entered into the program, and in exchange, must agree to refrain from logging, changing existing land uses, burning, altering hydrological condi- tions or reducing carbon storage, and commercial or sport hunting and fishing for 20 years. By mid-2013, 1.1 million hectares had been conserved through 2,100 individual and 150 communal agreements (Raes and Mohebalian, 2013). While PWS programs can be found in a wide range of settings and, in some cases, have been operating for decades, comprehensive data on their size or scope are not available. Ecosystem Marketplace (2013) estimated • Funding sources. Funding sources are varied. Na- tional programs primarily receive government fund- ing through the allocation of national budgets and donor funding, including loans from the World Bank. Funding for local programs is more varied but is pri- marily from: domestic and agricultural water fees; donors, including the Global Environment Facility (GEF), World Bank, and German Cooperation; the private sector, including downstream hydroelectric companies (in some cases, in the form of a dona- tion); and local government budgets. • Conditionality. Nearly all programs are uncon- ditional, meaning service providers are paid on a per unit area basis for land-management practices “believed to have a high probability of resulting in provision of the environmental service.” Only one payment scheme, Indonesia’s Rewarding Upland Poor for Environmental Services (RUPES) initia- tive, is conditional on outcomes, such as the level of sediment reduction achieved. Application PWS arrangements are gaining prominence and have been applied in a wide range of settings. For example, the US Conservation Reserve Program (CRP), estab- lished in the 1950s in an effort to reduce erosion on agricultural lands, became more conservation oriented in the mid-1980s, making it among the oldest and lon- gest running PES programs in the world. CRP today pays farmers to take land out of production in order to protect soil and water resources, as well as wildlife habitat (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). In northeastern France, Vittel-Nestle Waters paid farmers and provided technical support (and some labor) to alter local dairy farming practices in order to reduce nitrate pollution of groundwater – the source of Vittel’s bottled water (Perrot-Maitre 2006). New York City provides another well-known example. In the late 1990s, New York City was faced with the prospect of building a $4–$6 billion filtration plant with an additional $250 million in annual operating costs to meet new federal Safe Drinking Water Act require- ments – an approach that was “treating symptoms, not causes” (Appleton, 2010). An initial analysis suggested
  • 155. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 31 • many programs lack baseline data or monitoring systems • the connections between land-use practice and watershed services are not always clear, especially as they relate to water quantity, and are often site specific • it can be difficult to attribute change to the pro- gram rather than to external factors (e.g. changing commodity prices) • programs may not reach threshold levels for mea- sureable impact, or that impact may occur over a relatively long time period. As a result of these challenges, reliance on input- based indicators (sometimes referred to as behavioral change) has been borne out of necessity. Porras (personal communication, 2015) argued that because of these challenges, monitoring should be based on input-based, rather than outcome-based, indicators, as outcome-based indicators shift too much risk to the ecosystem service provider and may raise equity concerns. She further noted the need to set meaningful expectations. For example, conservation projects may be implemented within a landslide-prone watershed to reduce the risk of landslides, with the understanding that, even with a successful program, a landslide would still likely occur, albeit with reduced frequency and intensity over the long term. Thus, an expectation of no landslides is unrealistic and could threaten the viability of the program. In the absence of data on project outcomes, Porras et al. (2008) found that reported impacts are often based on “perceptions of local populations and those operating the schemes and/or quick measurements of what the impacts should be, rather than in-depth sci- entific evidence drawing from site measurements and modelling of relationships.” But even based on these sources, the available data suggest that environmental performance is mixed. In a review of previous studies that the total transaction value of PWS programs and water funds in 2012 was $8.0 billion. Activity in 2013 was considerably higher, with an estimated $11.5 billion in transaction value for PWS programs in China alone. While these data suggest dramatic growth, Bennett (personal communication, 2015) noted that the differ- ence can largely be explained by better reporting by a larger number of projects. Case studies of PWS pro- grams in developing countries are maintained by the London-based International Institute for Environment and Development and at Watershed Connect, an online platform maintained by Forest Trends (2015a). Environmental, economic, and social performance Comprehensive studies on the performance of PWS programs are limited, although some studies have been conducted on various aspects of these programs. Below, we examine the available evidence looking at how PWS has performed environmentally, economi- cally, and socially. ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE The environmental performance of PWS is not well understood due to a lack of scientific analysis. In an analysis of 47 PWS schemes in developing countries, Brouwer et al. (2011) found that “less than half of the schemes used quantifiable indicators and monitored the impact of the schemes on environmental perfor- mance.” In most cases, the indicators were input-based, meaning that they, for example, looked at land area with forest cover, rather the actual impacts and outcomes of the program. In a review of Costa Rica’s programs, Pagiola (2008) found it “unfortunately impossible to determine the extent to which the PSA23 program has successfully generated environmental services. Although the PSA program has established a strong system to monitor land user compliance with payment contracts, the program remains weak in monitoring its effectiveness in generating the desired services.” There are several challenges to evaluating environ- mental performance: 23 Pagos por servicios ambientales (payment for environmental services) “…PWS programs can be found in a wide range of settings…”
  • 156. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT32 applicants for forest protection are prioritized based on the total number of points they receive, with more points awarded for forests in indigenous territories or those protecting water resources. Likewise, applicants for reforestation projects are awarded more points if they use native species or reforest degraded areas with high forestry potential (Porras et al., 2013). The selec- tion criteria can be tailored to reflect the environmental (and even social objectives) of the program and altered as priorities or needs change. ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Payment structures are generally uniform and untar- geted, with flat rates per hectare for all sites (Porras et al., 2008; Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). Despite the preva- lence of uniform, untargeted payments, program costs and benefits are spatially heterogeneous. Wunschler et al. (2006) found that ecosystem service provision varies spatially according to the ecosystem benefits, the threat of loss, and the cost of service provision. Several stud- ies have suggested that untargeted, uniform payments reduce the cost effectiveness of PES schemes (Dillaha et al., 2007; Ferraro, 2008), and given likely constraints on program budgets, reduces the project benefits and its long-term success (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). Reverse auctions (also referred to as procurement auc- tions) have been put forth as one option for improving the economic efficiency of PWS schemes (Karousakis and Brooke, 2010). In an ordinary auction, the buy- ers compete to obtain a good or service by offering increasingly higher prices. With reverse auctions, the sellers compete to obtain business from the buyer, and prices typically decrease as sellers undercut one another. The US Conservation Reserve Program, for example, combines reverse auctions with an environ- mental benefit index to select land for inclusion in the program. However, Ferraro (2008) acknowledged that and surveys of PWS scheme managers, Brouwer et al. (2011) found that “58 percent of the PWS schemes were classified as effective in reaching their environ- mental objectives, while 42 percent were not.” Several factors, ranging from the number of intermediaries and mode of participation to the selection of service provid- ers, level of community participation and type of moni- toring, were found to improve environmental outcomes: • schemes with fewer intermediaries were more ef- fective in meeting environmental objectives • mandatory participation increased environmental effectiveness compared with voluntary schemes • selecting service providers based on a set of crite- ria, e.g. location, accessibility of land, or parcel size, tended to have a negative impact on environmen- tal performance • contracting with the community was more effective than contracting with a single ecosystem service provider • programs that monitored progress toward achiev- ing environmental objectives were more likely to reach those objectives. The study also found that schemes for direct payments by downstream hydropower companies to upstream land owners to reduce sediment loads were generally identified as successful, while other factors – includ- ing the type of watershed service, age of the scheme, or scale of implementation – had no significant effect on the outcome. Recognizing this, Brouwer et al. (2011) called for international monitoring guidelines to com- pare programs, identify success factors, and support their future design. Some have suggested that one way to improve envi- ronmental outcomes is through better selection of areas to include within the PWS program, a process that could be facilitated by the application of new tech- nologies (e.g. satellite imagery) and modeling efforts. Porras et al. (2013) identified several criteria suggested in the literature for targeting efforts, including focus- ing on areas at high risk of deforestation, large blocks of land prone to landslides or other natural disasters, and biological corridors. In Costa Rica, for example, “…studies have suggested that untargeted, uniform payments reduce the cost effectiveness of PES schemes…”
  • 157. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 33 rivers in China. Total investment is $4.3 million per year. Farmers in the Yangtze River Basin are paid yuan 417 per hectare per year ($50), while those in the Yellow River Basin are paid yuan 290 ($36) per hectare per year. In addition to the regular cash payments, farm- ers also receive a one-off cash payment and regular grain rations (Porras and Neves, 2006a). The program is designed to promote forestry and other economic endeavors on the land, rather than grain production. Given that most programs are voluntary, some have argued that continued participation provides some indi- cation that the programs are cost effective, i.e. that the benefits exceed the costs. The impact of PWS schemes on ecosystem service providers is generally estimated by looking at the payment as a fraction of household income. Using this metric, results are varied. Kosoy et al. (2007) found that the amount received from the PWS scheme was less than 2 percent of gross annual income for most providers in three cases in Costa Rica, Nicaragua, and Honduras; moreover, most watershed service providers did not think that the payment was fair. However, Wunder (2008) found that payments represented 10 to 16 percent of household income in schemes in Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Venezuela, and Vietnam. Even these studies did not examine the trans- action costs participants incurred in the program or the opportunity costs. In light of these findings, several studies have suggested that there are also important non-financial (or non-income) benefits (Kosoy et al., 2007; Wunder, 2008). The most commonly cited non- financial benefits include increasing land-tenure secu- rity, increasing human and social capital through internal organization, and increasing the visibility of the commu- nity to donors and public entities (Wunder, 2008). SOCIAL PERFORMANCE Limited data are available on the social outcomes of PES programs, as studies have been more narrowly focused on “short- or mid-term outcomes such as increased income or capacity building since these are much easier to identify” than broader social impacts, such as changes in power dynamics (Richards, 2013). In one notable exception, a review of Mexico’s PES program auctions introduce their own set of challenges, espe- cially in low- and middle-income countries. In these countries, PES schemes may have dual objectives, and reducing information asymmetries (and thus payments for the ecosystem service provider) may not be a pri- ority. Additionally, administrators of these programs might be less likely to differentiate payment due to concerns about fairness, and it is unclear whether there would be institutional capacity to manage these pro- grams. Moreover, auctions tend to increase transaction costs, which may already be relatively high in low- and middle-income countries where buyers of environmen- tal services are likely to contract with many small, often semi-literate, landowners, who often have no legal titles and are in dispersed remote rural areas. Finally, differ- entiation of payment can make it difficult to identify corruption and ensure that differentiation is based on implementation of transparent rules. Alix-Garcia et al. (2009) suggested another option to reverse auctions would be “to conduct rigorous contingent valuation studies in areas targeted by the program.” Whileuniformpaymentsarestillcommon,therearesev- eral notable exceptions. Mexico’s National Programme for Hydrological Environmental Services (PSAH) pro- vides higher payments for lands that provide greater benefits. For example, primary forest owners receive 300 pesos per hectare per year (approximately $27). Cloud forest owners, by contrast, receive 400 pesos per hectare per year ($36) due to the perceived higher delivery of hydrological services associated with this type of forest which has a role in capturing water from fog and clouds during the dry season (Porras and Neves, 2006). Payments are made annually, at the end of the year, once the absence of land use change has been confirmed. China’s Sloping Land Conversion Program also pro- vides targeted payments, although payments are dif- ferentiated according to the opportunity costs. China’s program, which began as a pilot in 1999 and was fully implemented in 2002, requires farmers to set aside ero- sion-prone farmland within critical areas of the water- sheds of the Yangtze and Yellow Rivers, the two largest
  • 158. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT34 broad geographic regions – could be developed to improve social outcomes. While some have argued that the pursuit of poverty alleviation objectives is likely to result in environmental tradeoffs (see, e.g. Huang et al., 2009), others suggest that this may not always be the case (Brouwer, personal communication, 2015). South Africa’s Working for Water (WfW) program is one of the few programs to have poverty alleviation as its primary objective. Between its launch in 1995 and 2009, WfW cleared more than 1 million hectares of invasive alien plants, which improved the timing and volume of surface water flows, provided erosion control, and increased biodiversity (Ferraro, 2009). The program, administered by the Department of Water Affairs and Forestry, employs 25,000 to 32,000 people annually, targeting low skilled, previously unemployed laborers, with a special focus on rural women, youth, and the dis- abled (Ferraro, 2009). Social development, an integral part of the program, includes “skills development, train- ing, and awareness creation of communities in health issues, hygiene, environmental health, inoculation, sexually transmitted diseases, pregnancy and meno- pause” (Department of Environmental Affairs, 2015). The vast majority of the program budget is provided by the central government and the Department of Water Affairs and Forestry’s general budget, with only very minor funding from foreign donors, municipalities, and the private sector. Ferraro (2009) argued that while the program is effectively the government paying for envi- ronmental services on government-controlled lands (and therefore not a true PES program), the program administrators are actively seeking voluntary payments from private and municipal actors to remove invasive plants from within their watersheds. Several studies have examined the socio-economic status of participants in PES schemes, either as buyers or sellers. Porras et al. (2008) found mixed results in both national and local schemes, depending, to some extent, on land and forest tenure regimes and socio- economic conditions in the targeted area. In programs in Mexico and Nicaragua, for example, the poor were relatively well represented (Muñoz-Piña et al., 2008; Pagiola et al., 2005), whereas in Costa Rica, the poor (Alix-Garcia et al., 2009) found that in most cases, there were no “obvious” changes in the social dynamics within a community. However, in two cases, they found a shift in the relative power of certain groups, whereby small, private forest holders who held land within or adjacent to communal lands threatened to cut down their for- ests if they did not receive some compensation.24 In two other cases, the program improved environmental awareness and participation in conservation activities. Information on broader social outcomes is limited. However, there is information on the role of PES arrangements in alleviating poverty. It is important to recognize that PES schemes were conceptualized as a mechanism to improve the efficiency of natural resource management, not as a mechanism to reduce poverty (Pagiola et al., 2005). While most programs prioritize areas critical for ecosystem services, some have been tailored to meet social objectives through a variety of mechanisms, including by targeting the programs to particular areas or populations, reducing transaction costs, and providing pro-poor premiums and subsidies (Wunder, 2005; Porras et al., 2013). In Costa Rica, a social development index consisting of 11 health, participation, economics, and education indica- tors is one of the criteria that is then integrated with environmental criteria to select participants.25 This par- ticular social development index has been shown to be ineffective in targeting payments to low-income popu- lations because it is biased toward large properties and is “too spatially coarse to represent the social impact of the programme at household level” (Porras et al., 2013). However, it suggests that some sort of criterion – pref- erably tailored to individual characteristics rather than 24 In a somewhat unusual situation, this conflict was a result of the fact that only a small group had rights to the commons and only those with rights received payment. 25 The index is used by Costa Rican government institutions to establish priority for social policy and budget allocations. “PES schemes were … to improve the efficiency of natural resource management, not as a mechanism to reduce poverty…”
  • 159. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 35 were not well represented (Zbinden and Lee, 2005). Wunder (2008) noted that one must typically own or hold land in order to be a seller, thereby excluding the “poorest of the poor.” Some schemes have attempted to recognize informal access to resources (e.g. Indonesia’s RUPES Program), although this has been difficult to replicate elsewhere (Porras et al., 2008). A recent review of ten PWS schemes in developing countries by Bond and Mayers (2010) found only a small number of cases where livelihoods had been improved, con- cluding that “there are significant and positive indirect effects of PWS – particularly in building social capita in poor communities.” They acknowledged that while improving education, health, and nutrition are bet- ter ways of reducing poverty than PWS, there is little evidence of these schemes actually doing any harm. Moreover, they suggested that targeting can make PWS programs more effective in alleviating poverty. Additionally, while it is commonly assumed that up- stream service providers are poorer than downstream users (Wunder, 2008), the reality may be more com- plicated. For example, George et al. (2009) found that downstream and upstream stakeholders were part of the same community in two watersheds in Thailand and Lao PDR with no clear distinction between upstream providers and downstream beneficiaries. In some cases, according to Porras et al. (2008), downstream users may, in fact, be poorer, raising concerns about their ability to pay as well as whether those payments are equitable. In cases where user fees were used to compensate ecosystem service providers, the authors found that the fees were generally found to be accept- able, with no detectable impact on water use or access to water. Additionally, some programs had taken steps to ensure that the poorest users were not impacted by these fees, e.g. by making payments voluntary or pro- viding a lifeline supply of water. Few studies have examined gender representation among program participants. In a literature review, Ravn- borg et al. (2007) found that less than 5 percent of the references addressed gender-specific aspects of impacts of PES. In a more recent assessment, Richards (2013) concurred, finding that “Gender effects have not been monitored, and therefore there is no information about how women have been affected except some reference to their low levels of participation.” Porras et al. (2008) cited two studies indicating low participation levels by women. However, these studies were more than a decade old and may not have reflected current conditions. Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions Some factors, such as contract adjudication and enforcement, may be necessary for establishing a PWS program. Other factors, such as appropriate inventories and analyses and government support, can enable but may not be required for PES programs to be estab- lished. Still other factors, such as legal prohibitions, limit watershed PES or function as barriers or obstacles. Necessary conditions include: • a legal system recognizing that agreements must be kept • a civil law providing contract parties with legal rem- edies to enforce contract rights in cases of non- compliance with contract obligations • general respect for the rule of law. In general, PES schemes are flexible and the necessary conditions are relatively modest. However, Calvache et al. (2012) determined that they must be designed within the legal context of a particular area. Greiber (2009) provided additional detail on the legal frame- work for PWS implementation, noting that the frame- work will differ depending on the type of scheme implemented. For example, private schemes, defined as self-organized schemes between private entities, require the least government intervention and depend on only general legal requirements: e.g. a legal system recognizing that agreements must be kept, and civil law providing contract parties with legal remedies in case of non-compliance. However, if only these condi- tions are in place, Greiber (2009) asserted that these “Few studies have examined … gender- specific aspects of impacts of PES.”
  • 160. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT36 • methodologies for measuring, monitoring, report- ing, and verifying progress toward achieving proj- ect outcomes. Several studies have developed guides highlighting the technical requirements (Hawkins, 2011; Calvache et al., 2012; Smith et al., 2013). In addition to these require- ments, methodologies for measuring, monitoring, reporting, and verifying progress toward achieving out- comes are also needed. Monitoring and evaluation are fundamental to the success of PES schemes because the information they provide gives assurance to the buyer that ecosystem services are delivered as prom- ised and allows for adjustments to the program based on better information and changing conditions. Porras et al. (2013) made a distinction between monitoring for compliance and monitoring for environmental effective- ness. The former “seeks to ensure that the conditional- ity inherent in a PWS scheme is put into practice, and that the project is implemented effectively.” The latter, by contrast, seeks to ensure that the scheme achieves its overall objectives and is needed to demonstrate additionality, i.e. that changes in watershed ecosystem services can be attributed to the program. While com- pliance and effectiveness monitoring are often linked, “a high degree of compliance does not necessarily ensure that a scheme is effective, as a poorly designed scheme may target the wrong land managers and land that is at least risk, meaning that the payments may not generate the desired hydro-ecological or conservation benefits.” Despite some of the challenges to monitoring (described in the application section of 3.2), Brouwer et al. (2011) pointed to the need for international monitoring guide- lines to identify the relationship between the design of theprogramanditsenvironmentaleffectivenessbecause understanding these relationships is “paramount to the future design of cost-effective PWS schemes.” A recent Science article by a large team of scientists and prac- titioners in the PES field (Naeem et al., 2015) noted that “many projects are based on weak scientific foun- dations, and effectiveness is rarely evaluated with the rigor necessary for scaling up and understanding the importance of these approaches as policy instruments and conservation tools.” In an effort to advance the field, programs would “mostly develop at a small scale with the objective to solve a specific local water problem,” and expanding these projects to address regional or national water problems would require a more devel- oped policy and legal framework. By contrast, public schemes are government-driven schemes that, by definition, require far greater gov- ernment involvement, as local, regional, or national governments are involved as either watershed service providers or buyers, and payment may be done through user fees, taxes, or subsidies. However, many of these schemes have evolved on an ad hoc basis from initia- tives of NGOs and overseas development corporations and, as a result, they typically lack comprehensive or coherent legislation. Greiber (2009) also noted that these conditions limit “the real potential of PES as an innovative instrument that might be applied more often, more efficiently, and at a larger scale to combat prevailing water problems.” He argued that a specific legal and policy framework would stimulate PES devel- opment by creating greater legal certainty and helping to promote good governance practices. While necessary conditions establish the minimum requirements for the implementation of a PES program, there is a set of enabling conditions that promotes the success and long-term viability of these programs. While some of the enabling conditions are technical in nature, others are legal, institutional, social, and political. Technical enabling conditions include: • an inventory of the value of hydrological services, including assessments of baseline conditions, and of how these values may change in response to land use alterations, infrastructure development, and climate • an analysis of program costs, including implemen- tation, opportunity, and transaction costs • a registry of names, transactions, project data, credit issuance, or other information related to PES activities • technical support from the government, civil soci- ety, or the private sector through trainings, infor- mation, or direct technical assistance
  • 161. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 37 TABLE 2. Natural-science principles and guidelines for PES programs Principle: Dynamics Objective: Ensure project capacity to adapt to dynamic natural and anthropogenic processes. Principle: Monitoring Objective: Track factors necessary for management, trade, forecasting, and assessment. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: identify key services for each service type beyond target services identify spatiotemporal scales of targeted services identify data needs, resources, and gaps identify stressors and their spatiotemporal variability identify and forecast trends in endogenous and exogenous threats identify services’ production and functions and sensitivities determine trade-offs and synergies among services determine how functional diversity influences resilience. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: quantify deliverables associated with target services identify spatiotemporal scales in advance of implementation use established methods/protocols and best practices for monitoring estimate uncertainties monitoring should inform decision-making monitoring should detect potential changes in baseline conditions monitor non-target services that influence target services. Principle: Baseline Objective: Document and initial conditions Principle: Metrics Objective: Robust, efficient, and versatile methods for procuring data. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: measure influences of interventions on services measure status and trends of non-target services ensure that measurements are feasible given resources assess initial state of exogenous and endogenous threats to services measure factors important for forecasting service trends. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: must be relevant, reliable, and appropriate in scale should comply with voluntary standards, certification, and regulations should reflect spatiotemporal scales as identified in dynamics optimize balance between precision and simplicity assess progress (in conjunction with baseline and monitoring) should measure both absolute changes and changes in trends preferentially selected to allow comparisons across service types assess how services influence each other. Principle: Multiple services Objective: Recognize trade-offs and synergies among services Principle: Ecological sustainability Objective: Insure project durability and sustainability SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: assess how intervention influences the other services avoid “double counting” assess impacts of intervention on non-target services. SCIENTIFIC GUIDELINES: estimate short-term and long-term project or program performance. Note: The scientific guidelines shown in bold font are intended to indicate “essential” guidelines that must be followed for a successful intervention. Guidelines shown in regular font are considered “desirable”. Source: Naeem et al., 2015.
  • 162. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT38 of ecosystem services, while Colombia went even fur- ther by requiring departments and municipalities to invest at least 1  percent of annual revenues toward either PES to landowners or direct land acquisition in source water areas (Bennett et al., 2014). Enabling leg- islation can occur at various levels (e.g. local, provincial, or national) and take a variety of forms. However, the appropriate level and form will depend on the prevail- ing governance system in a particular area. A variety of social and political conditions increases the likelihood of the successful implementation of PES schemes. For example, cultural and political acceptance of markets in general, and of commercializing rights to land use and land management practices, creates an enabling environment. Dillaha et al. (2007) noted that PES activity is generally strong in Latin America, but that development tends to lag in areas with strong indigenous cultures (such as the Bolivian highlands) or closed economies (such as Venezuela). It is important to note that in areas where the natural environment has historically been used for free, “actually paying for envi- ronmental services in response to mounting resource scarcity represents a major change in attitude, which necessarily will take time” (Dillaha et al., 2007). Trust is also a key element for an effective PES pro- gram, as it helps to ensure that there are willing buy- ers and sellers, and reduces transaction costs. Dillaha et al. (2007) noted that service providers might fear that PES is a first-step toward appropriation of their resources, while service users “might suspect that they are or will be the victims of ‘environmental blackmail’.” Based on several cases in Asia, Neef and Thomas (2009) argued that “Lack of trust between poten- tial buyers and providers of environmental services is probably one of the most constraining factors in set- ting up viable PES schemes.” One way to facilitate the trust-building process is through stakeholder engage- ment, especially during the initial stages of the project. Likewise, transparency and access to information are also essential. Intermediaries, such as NGOs, can some- times play a role in building and maintaining trust while also providing technical, legal, and financial support. As the authors put forth a set of natural science principles and guidelines for PES efforts that they felt were appli- cable to local-, regional-, and national-level programs in developed and developing countries (Table 2). A set of scientific guidelines for four of the principles – dynamics, monitoring, baseline, and metrics – were deemed “essen- tial” for a successful intervention, whereas the remainder were deemed “desirable”. While specific to PES arrange- ments, they argued that the principles and guidelines could be applicable to market-based conservation instruments more broadly. In a review of 118 active PES projects, however, the authors found that 60 percent did not adhere to the four essential principles, highlighting considerable room for improvement in the development and implementation of PES projects. In addition to the more technical aspects of PES, there are a number of enabling legal, institutional, social, and political conditions that also improve the effectiveness of PES. Enabling legal, institutional, social, and political conditions include: • a policy and legal framework for PES • incentives and/or requirements to participate in PES programs • cultural and political acceptance of markets • trust between ecosystem service providers and beneficiaries • a supply and demand for ecosystem services. Governments, for example, can pass laws or institute policies that enable the development of PES pro- grams. In Costa Rica, participants of PES programs are exempt from paying property taxes (Porras et al., 2013). Likewise, the Peruvian government unanimously passed a law providing a legal framework for voluntary PES programs between land stewards and beneficiaries “Governments, for example, can pass laws or institute policies that enable the development of PES programs.”
  • 163. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 39 whether these rights also include “the right to receive income from the ecosystem services provided by the transferred natural resource.” Likewise, in Asia, most forested and agricultural land is state-owned. Thus, individuals and communities have weak land rights, making it difficult for them to sign a contract and pro- vide a legal guarantee of future land management practices (Huang et al., 2009). 3.3 Water quality trading Description Water quality trading (WQT) is a market-based approach for reducing or controlling water pollution. It allows permitted dischargers in a watershed to trade water quality credits, or pollution allowances, in order to meet water quality standards. Markets in water quality differ from conventional markets in that they are not based on an actual physical commodity. Rather, they are based on trading a license or a permit to pollute. The primary goal of water quality trading is to reduce the costs of water pollution control, often following the imposition of a cap on pollutant emissions by regula- tors. Secondary goals are to reduce compliance costs and spur innovative solutions to pollution control. Water quality trading is an adjunct to regulation, and not an alternative to it. In fact, its success depends on the presence of a strong regulatory body to enforce water quality standards, and monitor and enforce dis- charge limits. Water quality markets draw inspiration from the suc- cess of the Acid Rain Program (ARP) in the United States in the 1990s. At the time, most environmental groups and government agency staff favored a “com- mand-and-control” approach to pollution control that Bond and Mayers (2010) acknowledged, trust “is hard to build and easy to lose.” Finally, there must be a supply of, and demand for, eco- system services. On the supply side, payments must be big enough relative to other opportunities to create a real incentive for change. On the demand side, benefi- ciaries must have the ability to pay. For example, Huang et al. (2009) posited that by increasing incomes, rapid economic growth in Asia could increase demand for watershed services because there is greater willing- ness and ability to pay for amenities such as clean water and recreation. At the same time, rapid economic growth could increase demand for goods and services produced on the land, thereby increasing the oppor- tunity cost of the land. In a regional review of PWS programs in sub-Saharan Africa, Ferraro (2009) sug- gested that demand for watershed services is relatively low, as there are relatively few formal water systems, and even those with formal systems may lack reliable access – which means there are few people who could be easily charged a water fee to pay for watershed ser- vices. Moreover, high poverty rates suggest that many would not be able to afford higher water costs. There is also a set of conditions that can hinder or limit the development of PES schemes. Limiting conditions can include: • any legal provision prohibiting watershed PES con- tracts • poorly defined property rights. Greiber (2009) noted that “clearly defined property rights enable parties to enter into PES contracts and ensure the sustainability of PES schemes.” Several challenges associated with property rights arise when implementing PES schemes. For example, ecosystem services are a relatively new concept and may not be recognized by the existing legal framework. In Peru, the state is the owner of natural resources and holds the property rights over ecosystem services. While the state can transfer certain property rights over natural resources to individuals, it has not yet been determined “Water quality markets draw inspiration from the success of the Acid Rain Program in the US in the 1990s.”
  • 164. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT40 levels in water bodies, a process referred to as “eutro- phication”. Other water quality trading programs have been set up to control salinity, heavy metal, sediment, and temperature or thermal pollution (Morgan and Wolverton, 2005). These programs are typically based around specific watersheds or receiving waters, such as the Chesapeake Bay or Wisconsin’s Fox River. WQT markets are different from other emissions trading schemes, in that trading is used between sources in the same area of impact, e.g. a watershed that drains to a particular water body, such as a lake, estuary, or river. The geography of trading contrasts starkly with other well-known cap-and-trade-style environmental markets, such as national and international markets for carbon offsets, where emission reductions can take place even in remote parts of the world. Trading within water quality markets can take several different forms. The most common arrangement in the United States is a bilateral market, where buyers negotiate trades directly with potential sellers, discuss- ing their quantity and price. Often, a regulator will get involved by, for example, approving the terms of the agreement, or facilitating monitoring to ensure that actual discharge reductions take place. This arrange- ment makes transactions slow and costly, and has been partially blamed for the moribund trading activ- ity in most US WQT markets (Woodward et al., 2002). In clearinghouse-style markets, a middleman such as a brokerage firm facilitates trades by connecting will- ing buyers and sellers, as has been done in the Tar- Pamlico River Basin Nutrient Trading Program in North Carolina. On the opposite extreme, exchanges are a form of trading where allowances are turned into stan- dardized commodities and are freely traded. For exam- ple, in the United States, SO2 allowances are traded on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange. The Hunter River Salinity Trading Scheme in Australia may also be considered an example of an exchange, although in this case, the government is responsible for trades (NSWDEC, 2003). Water quality markets can be classified in a number of ways. One useful way to categorize markets is based on would have required all power plants to install scrub- bers on their smokestacks to remove sulfur diox- ide (SO2). Lawmakers instead opted for a bold policy experiment, setting a cap on total SO2 emissions, and allowing polluters to buy and sell pollution allowances. Under this system, emissions from individual sources could rise or fall, as long as the total annual emissions stayed the same. The central idea was that allowing trading puts a price on pollution, and, in turn, encour- ages cost savings, efficiency, and innovation. In most WQT markets, a cap is put on water pollutants. In the United States, the cap is usually set by state gov- ernments, which are responsible for regulating water quality in rivers, lakes, and estuaries. The cap should be based on a scientific analysis of how much pollutant a water body can assimilate without being excessively degraded, which is referred to as a total maximum daily load (TMDL). Government regulators issue pollution allowances, often referred to as “credits”, to existing polluters. For example, a credit may allow a facility to discharge one pound of phosphorus to a river. A facility manager may choose to install pollution-control tech- nologies that limit emissions. If a facility’s emissions decrease to below its permitted level, this frees up additional credits that managers may then sell to other polluters. There typically may be two types of buyers that create a demand for credits: i) new entrants to the market, such as a new factory in the watershed, or ii) existing polluters that may wish to or need to increase their emissions, e.g. a factory that wishes to increase output, or a sewage plant serving a growing commu- nity. Trading allows the industry greater freedom to operate as it sees fit. A low-performing facility may continue to pollute more heavily, but it will be required to purchase credits, making the cost of doing business more expensive. High-performers that can reduce their pollution levels create valuable pollution credits that they can sell, and this creates an incentive to invest in pollution controls, at least according to theory. To date, most water quality trading markets have been used to control pollution from nutrients that cause excessive algal growth and low dissolved oxygen
  • 165. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 41 right to discharge pollutants. Markets are also thought to foster innovation – where “innovative, entrepreneur- ial companies can profit from low-cost reductions in emissions. Slower, less innovative firms can benefit as well by having the opportunity to purchase needed emission allowances for less than it would cost them to comply internally” (Anderson, 2004). Moreover, cap- and-trade programs may provide greater certainty in the outcome. With a fixed or declining cap, policy mak- ers can be more certain of the environmental improve- ment that will be achieved, compared with alternative approaches such as best management practices or a pollution tax. Application A survey conducted by Bennett and Carroll (2014) for Forest Trends found that activity for WQT mar- kets is still relatively small, although it has shown large increases in the past several years. In 2013, the trading value of WQT markets was about $22.2 million. Much of that activity was concentrated in the United States, where WQT markets had a trading value of $11.1 mil- lion in 2013, with a cumulative total of $95 million since 2000. While there are currently over 30 water quality markets in place in the United States, some have seen no trading or only a few trades, even two decades after their establishment. Among the reasons cited for the lack of trading activity are high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty about the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate in the market (Shortle and Horan, 2008). While some of the longest-running markets are getting smaller, new programs in Oregon, Virginia, and Maryland have kept overall transaction values high. Indeed, in 2013, United States market activity was at its highest level ever recorded, although Bennet and Carroll (2014) posited that this likely represented recovery from the eco- nomic downturn rather than new growth. It is of note that New Zealand’s Lake Taupo Trading Program, a relatively new program, has rapidly become the largest in the world, with at least $10.2 million in transactions in 2013. However, the future of that market is uncertain because “that market’s biggest buyer, the Lake Taupo Protection Trust, announced in June 2013 it would the regulatory system that drives the demand for trad- ing and whether it includes a cap on total emissions (Anderson, 2004). This includes both cap-and-trade systems and credit systems. Cap-and-trade systems put a limit on the total amount of allowed releases of pollution. They seek a specific environmental result (a cap), and trading allowances to release pollution are simply an option to minimize the cost of achieving the emission reductions specified in the regulatory cap. In the cap-and-trade approach, allowances for future emissions are sold or granted to existing sources. Credit systems, on the other hand, do not establish any fixed ceiling on total emissions. Total emissions can increase if new sources of pollution enter the market, or if existing sources increase their outputs. In uncapped systems, tradable credits are earned for controlling pol- lution beyond what is specified in one’s permit. The literature is full of descriptions of the potential benefits of water quality trading compared with the more conventional “command-and-control” approach, where regulators allocate the right to pollute by impos- ing limits on individual polluters (Shortle and Horan, 2005). In particular, WQT markets are thought to be a less-costly, more-efficient alternative. When the total amount of pollutant emissions in a region is capped, the right to pollute becomes a scarce commodity and, as many economists assert, markets are the most effi- cient way of allocating a scarce commodity.26 WQT programs allow polluters to interact in the marketplace and decide among themselves how to allocate the 26 While economic theory says that trading will lead to the most efficient allocation of a resource, it says little about distributional effects, i.e. who pays and who benefits, or other market “externalities”. “WQT programs allow polluters to interact in the marketplace and decide among themselves how to allocate the right to discharge pollutants.”
  • 166. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT42 in the Reagan, George H.W. Bush, and George W. Bush administrations, “and were once strongly condemned by liberals and environmentalists” (Schmalensee and Stavins, 2012). The key element for overcoming con- servative politicians’ resistance to the policy was to replace regulation with a free market; the market would operate on its own with no intervention by the govern- ment, a step that would “radically disempower the reg- ulators” (Conniff, 2009). However, this has not been the reality with most environmental markets, which have been designed with additional layers of government that oversee the market, monitor and enforce emis- sions limits, and facilitate and verify trades. By contrast, there are alternative pollution control policies that are simpler and require less government involvement, such as mandating the use of pollution-limiting technology or taxing pollution. There is some irony here, prompting one scholar to observe, “a putative form of rationaliza- tion or deregulation is in fact a case of ‘reregulation’” (Mariola 2009). As an example of how WQT markets work, consider the example of the Chesapeake Bay. To reduce nutri- ent discharge into the bay, regulators had the option of requiring wastewater plants to install expensive and technologically advanced treatment systems. Nitrogen removal costs for these systems are typically about $200 per pound per year (Jones et al., 2010). However, farms in the watershed are an even larger source of nitrogen, and removal costs are much lower, at $1 to $5 per pound per year. As a result, permitted dischargers have negotiated the ability to fulfill their permit require- ments by funding pollution control projects on farms in the watershed, such as planting winter cover crops, planting vegetation around streams (called riparian buffers), or installing permeable filter strips around animal feedlots. These agricultural “best management practices” reduce soil erosion and sediment runoff from farms, reducing the amount of nutrients washed into local waterways. Because they use soil and veg- etation to filter water and sediment, they are gener- ally low-tech and relatively inexpensive to install and maintain. The Chesapeake Bay WQT program was set up specifically to encourage these kinds of exchanges. withdraw from future trading, having made arrange- ments to achieve its remaining nitrogen reduction goals by purchasing and managing land in the catch- ment” (Bennett et al., 2014). The popularity of emissions trading for dealing with water pollution in the United States is largely a result of the Clean Water Act of 1972. The specifics of how the law was written and implemented have made it dif- ficult for governments to handle pollution from farms. In particular, the law made it illegal for “point source” dischargers, such as factories or wastewater treatment plants, to release pollutants into waterways without a permit, but did not attempt to regulate pollution from “nonpoint sources”, such as agriculture or urban run- off, since these were considered minor sources of pol- lution and believed to be difficult to regulate. In many watersheds, however, farms and feedlots are the larg- est source of pollutants. These nonpoint sources are exempt from most water pollution regulations, and there appears to be insufficient will to remedy this. Forty years after passage of the landmark law, some 40 percent of America’s surface water fails to meet its water quality goals (Faeth, 2000). Further, a set of stud- ies in the 1990s showed that reducing nutrient pollution from agriculture could be 65 times more cost effective than imposing further controls on municipal or indus- trial sources. As a result, water quality regulators in the United States use WQT markets primarily as a tool to encourage point dischargers to fund nonpoint source pollution controls, largely because regulators lack the authority to deal with these sources of pollution. One factor contributing to the popularity of emis- sions trading is its appeal to conservative politicians due to their invocation of the “power of the market” (Conniff, 2009). The original cap-and-trade programs were policy innovations developed by conservatives “40 percent of America’s surface water fails to meet its water quality goals.”
  • 167. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 43 (Olszowa et al., 1998). Further, on-farm nutrient con- trols will do little to control other toxins that are present in coal ash, such as arsenic, lead, mercury, and heavy metals. However, the program is notable as it is the first program in the United States that has allowed the purchase of pollution control credits across state lines (Fox, 2014). In addition to the many markets in the United States, there are also examples of WQT markets in other regions, especially in Oceania: • Lake Taupo Nitrogen Trading Program (New Zea- land) • South Creek Bubble Licensing Scheme (Australia) • Murray-Darling Basin Salinity Credits Scheme (Australia) • South Nation River Watershed Trading Program (Canada) • Chao Lake Nutrient Trading Program (China, under consideration) Several European countries have shown interest in WQT. A literature review by Wind (2012) summarized 14 studies of the concept within the European Union. Despite this interest, no markets have been created to date, and it appears that EU directives limit the ability of states to set up markets. Perhaps the best example of a successful operating WQT market is on Australia’s Hunter River, where coal mines and other sources are subject to discharge lim- its to protect water quality and drinking water sources in downstream cities. Saline soils are present through- out Australia, and during coal mining, salty water col- lects in mine pits and shafts and has to be pumped out to allow mining operations to continue (NSWDEC, 2003). The Hunter River Basin had a history of conflict among users, with mining activities making the water unsuitable for irrigation, and new mine proposals facing extremely high costs. The state government, following years of study and collaboration with stakeholders, set a cap on salinity levels in the river, and put a system of tradable discharge credits in place. Trading allows regulated polluters to meet their per- mitted discharge requirement at a much lower cost than with technology. Further, it helps to finance pollu- tion reduction from the agricultural sector, which gen- erates about 44 percent of the nutrients entering the bay. A recent assessment concluded that controlling discharges from agriculture is necessary to restore the bay (Steinzor et al., 2012). A second noteworthy example of a domestic WQT market is the relatively new Ohio River Basin Water Quality Trading Project developed by the Electric Power Research Institute, the research arm of the United States electric power industry. Coal-fired power plants in the Ohio River Basin are a major source of nitrogen pollution in rivers, due to their using water in scrubbers for air pollution control and to sluice the coal ash out of reactors (US EPA, 2009). The ash and water slurry most often goes into storage and treat- ment ponds that provide only a minimal level of treat- ment and where spills and illicit discharges have been common (Zucchino, 2015). Under the pilot program, power plants and other interested parties can pay for nonpoint source pollution reductions on farms, another major source of pollution in the watershed. Because on-farm improvements are much less expensive than installing wastewater treatment facilities, power plants stand to save $500,000 to $800,000 per year (EPRI, 2010). The first projects are creating nutrient reduction credits through “activities like planting cover crops and creat- ing treatment wetlands for animal wastes” (Ecosystem Marketplace, 2015). The program is notable for its thor- oughness in documenting projects, posting a descrip- tion and photos of every project on the Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI) website, and using a stan- dard methodology for calculating the reduced pollution in farm runoff. The program is credited with reducing pollution by 100,000 pounds of nutrients between 2013 and 2015 (Barrett 2015). While commendable, this proj- ect is a small pilot, and pollutant reductions are small compared with the estimates of over 3 million pounds of nitrogen entering the watershed’s rivers every day
  • 168. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT44 at how WQT markets have performed environmentally, economically, and socially. ENVIRONMENTAL PERFORMANCE While there are no comprehensive analyses of the envi- ronmental performance of WQT programs in general, there are several examples of successful programs. In the application section of 3.3, we cited Australia’s Hunter River as one example. Indeed, since formation of the program, river water quality has met standards nearly 100 percent of the time, protecting water sup- plies to downstream irrigators and cities. This hap- pened despite the establishment of new, potentially highly polluting mines in the watershed. The Alpine Cheese Company Nutrient Trading Program in Ohio is another notable success. As a part of this program, the company helped fund pollution reduction projects on local farms, paying 25 farmers to install 91 conserva- tion measures that resulted in a 3,000-pound-per-year phosphorus reduction (US EPA, 2010). A United States Environmental Protection Agency (US EPA) 2010 evaluation of the program found that it exceeded its nutrient reduction goals, and estimated that “conservation measures would reduce up to three times more nutrients than if equal funds were used for wastewater treatment upgrades.” It is noteworthy that the project has also been praised by the local chapter of the Sierra Club, which has strongly opposed the cre- ation of larger WQT schemes in other areas that could allow industry to continue implementing poor practices by purchasing offsets (Marida, 2010). Likewise, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit Exchange Program – currently the largest in the United States – was created in 2002 to reduce nitrogen pollution to Long Island Sound from the Connecticut River. Under the program, which covers 79 sewage treatment plants in the state of Connecticut, a plant can control pollu- tion in excess of its permit requirement and sell excess nitrogen allowances to those plants that exceed their allowances. A 2012 review of the program suggested that the program had helped the state meet its environ- mental goals while lowering overall costs (Stacey et al., 2012). The program helped reduce nitrogen loading by Under this system, no discharges of salty water are allowed when the river is in low flow. When the river is in high flow and its capacity to dilute salty inflows is greater, limited discharge is allowed, controlled by a system of salt credits. Permitted dischargers coor- dinate their activities so that the total salt concen- tration in the river never goes above a specified limit. Industries can buy and sell salt credits in real time via a trading website run by the state government. Several years after the program began, the trading program is popular among participants and functioning smoothly. The state government has set up real-time monitor- ing to make sure the river water quality meets stan- dards, and to monitor for permit violations. Perhaps the biggest marker of the program’s success is that new, potentially highly polluting mines have been estab- lished, but river water quality has met standards nearly 100 percent of the time. Environmental, economic, and social performance Despite the fact that water quality trading markets have existed for three decades in some areas, it is difficult to state whether they can be considered an overall success. In making such an evaluation, we must determine whether desired pollution reductions were achieved and water quality targets attained. We must also examine how the result compared with what would have occurred under another form of management: were the pollution reductions greater, did they occur more quickly, or at a lower cost? Moreover, there is a great deal of literature about water quality trading and market-based solutions to water pollution but few real-world evaluations of existing WQT markets. Much of the literature about markets is theoretical and oriented toward “making the case” for WQT, e.g. describing how a market can or should be set up. Below, we examine the available evidence looking “…there is a great deal of literature … but few real-world evaluations of existing WQT markets.”
  • 169. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 45 In an assessment of three mature WQT programs in the United States, one scholar concluded that there had been very little benefit as a direct result of trades. However, the programs had an unexpected benefit: they broughttogetherwatershedstakeholdersandincreased “the institutional capacity for watershed management” (Wallace, 2007). Stakeholders coming together around a common goal of improving water quality also helped lower resistance to new, more stringent water quality regulations. Wallace concluded that the markets them- selves were not important mechanisms for reducing pollution. Rather, their presence contributed to “unin- tended contributions to increased pollution regulation and management on a watershed scale.” So, on the one hand, these markets could be considered failures by some observers because many of them had seen no trading even decades after their creation. The lack of trades can be explained by a number of fac- tors: high transaction costs, lack of trust, uncertainty about the future of the market, or simply unfamiliarity and unwillingness to participate in the market. On the other hand, even where little or no trading occurred, water quality and governance had improved in the three watersheds evaluated by Wallace (2007). It is not always possible to disentangle how much of a role the market played in bringing about these improvements. On the one hand, financial transactions have not played a large role, tempting us to conclude that the markets were relatively unimportant. However, if discussion of the use of “market fundamentals” helped overcome resistance to environmental regulation and paved the way toward decreased pollution, then we may conclude that markets were a key feature in improving water quality, albeit indirectly. ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE It is difficult to assess the economic performance of WQT markets and how their economic performance compares with alternative forms of pollution control. To date, the size and impact of water quality markets is relatively small. There is some information in the litera- ture on the number of trades that have occurred, and the prices paid for water quality credits. In the applica- tion section of 3.3, we cited a Forest Trends study that over 50 percent over 10 years, and was on track to meet water quality goals by 2014. As a result, the area of Long Island Sound suffering from hypoxia (low dissolved oxy- gen which is fatal to wildlife) had steadily declined. Despite these examples, most water quality trading programs in the United States are either too small or have seen too little trading to make a meaningful dif- ference on water quality. For example, a 2012 evalua- tion of Ohio’s Great Miami Nutrient Trading Program called it “one of the most successful programs to date” (Newburn and Woodward, 2012). In 2009, the trading program attracted $1.3 million in trades and helped fund 100 projects that reduced nutrient pollution by 800,000 pounds per year. Proposed projects submitted by farm- ers in the watershed covered a variety of agricultural “best management practices” designed to prevent sedi- ment and nutrients from entering waterways. Evaluators concluded that the program “has been successful in developing both supply and ensuring funding for agri- cultural pollution abatement projects compared to other WQT programs” (Newburn and Woodward, 2012). Despite this, they found that the program had not likely had a significant effect on regional water quality due to the “relatively minor role that the trading program has had on nutrient management in the watershed to date.” To date, the projects have simply been too small and too few to have a major impact. The Great Miami River watershed drains 748 square miles, the majority of which is cultivated, so a much larger investment would be needed to meaningfully improve water quality in the basin. This example highlights the caution needed when interpreting large numbers cited by market proponents. While 800,000 pounds sounds like a lot (and is indeed a worthwhile accomplishment), it pales in comparison with the estimated 1 trillion pounds of nitrogen enter- ing the Ohio River watershed each year (Olszowa et al., 1998). Like most WQT markets in the United States, the Greater Miami Basin program did not emerge from a cap on pollutants. Rather, it was created as a way to allow regulated point-source dischargers, such as factories and sewage plants, to lower their costs by paying for pollution controls on farms rather than installing expen- sive pollution control measures at their own facilities.
  • 170. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT46 improving the environment and supporting the local economy, and also experienced other indirect benefits from the project, “by fencing cows out of streams, bac- teria levels in milk were decreased, giving the farmers a premium price for milk and reducing costs for Alpine [Cheese Company]” (Marida, 2010). As described previously, the Connecticut Nitrogen Credit Exchange Program is currently one of the larg- est WQT programs in operation. An evaluation of the program in 2012 suggested that the program has helped the state meet its environmental goal of reduc- ing nitrogen loading to Long Island Sound while lower- ing overall costs. The state estimated that, in the first 10 years of the program, trading had lowered costs by $300 to $400 million below what individual facilities would have had to pay for equivalent pollution reduc- tions (Stacey et al., 2012). SOCIAL PERFORMANCE There is little research on the social impacts of WQT, and much of what we describe in this section is based on anecdotal evidence. Critics of environmental mar- kets have raised questions about their fairness and justice. A specific concern relates to how regulators distribute pollution permits at the outset of market cre- ation. Under a market system, pollution permits become valuable commodities to be bought and sold. In many cases, as in SO2 trading in the United States, the gov- ernment grants allowances to industries for free, based on their historic emissions. Critics point out that such “grandfathering” of permits rewards those polluters most responsible for environmental problems in the first place. It may also unfairly burden more recent mar- ket entrants, because they have no history of polluting and no “free” permits, yet would be required to purchase credits to offset 100 percent of their emissions. There are, however, different ways of issuing credits that help mitigate these concerns. For example, rather than giv- ing away credits, they could be sold to polluters in an auction, as has been proposed in carbon markets. Critics have also raised concerns about the fairness of water quality markets to potential sellers of water qual- ity credits. Consider a farmer who installed pollution estimated the value of the United States water quality tradingmarketas$11.1millionin2013,intermsofthetotal value of payments. To put these numbers in perspec- tive, state and local governments in the United States spent $70 billion on sanitation and sewerage in 2008 (US Census Bureau, 2012). Despite these investments, many argue that the United States should be spending much more to control water pollution. Researchers at Kansas State found that nutrient pollution from nitro- gen and phosphorus cost the United States $2.2 bil- lion in 2008, due to losses in recreational water usage, waterfront real estate, spending on recovery of threat- ened and endangered species, and increased treatment for drinking water (Dodds et al., 2008). While limited data are available, advocates for WQT markets cite the lower overall cost of improving water quality as their main advantage, as compared with more conventional means of water pollution control. There is local evidence for this, especially in smaller markets. Take the case of the Alpine Cheese Company, in Ohio’s Sugar Creek watershed. The plant was faced with expensive wastewater treatment upgrades to satisfy Clean Water Act permit requirements (US EPA, 2010). These upgrades would likely have cost over $1 million to install, plus ongoing costs for operation and mainte- nance.Instead,thecompanycollaboratedwithothersto reduce pollution through projects at farms in the water- shed that have a much lower cost per pound of phos- phorus prevented from entering streams, and which are expected to last 15 to 20 years (Moore, 2012). The company worked with universities, regulators, and local agricultural extension services, providing $800,000 over five years for planning, technical assistance, and outreach. In addition, these measures allowed the plant to expand, creating 12 new jobs. Further, the project provided funding to chronically cash-strapped local soil and water conservation districts and to the local agricultural economy. Local dairy farmers took pride in “…advocates for WQT markets cite the lower overall cost of improving water quality as their main advantage…”
  • 171. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 47 communal ownership makes it slower and more diffi- cult to develop land. In a sense, those most responsible for past pollution have been rewarded with large (and valuable) pollution permits, while the Maori community will face higher costs to develop their lands economi- cally. In response to these concerns, regulators altered the market design by relaxing the cap somewhat “to ease the restrictive nature of historical allocation on Tuwharetoa [Maori] and other forest owners” (Duhon et al., 2011). In the New Zealand case study, program managers realized the importance of dealing with issues of race and historical justice in order to make the program suc- cessful. In the United States, some program managers have also sought to address issues related to age and gender. For example, the Ohio River Basin Water Quality Trading Project directs money from the electric power industry to farmers to support on-farm improvements to reduce runoff and pollution. A concern was raised early on that the early adopters would be all younger, male farmers (Jessica Fox, EPRI, personal communica- tion, 2015) because they would be more open to new ideas. Also, there are fewer woman-owned farms in the region compared with those owned by men. As a result, the managers of this program have made a particular effort to involve women farmers and older farmers. Some critics have suggested that WQT programs could perpetuate or worsen environmental justice problems. The environmental justice movement in the United States has focused on the fact that pollution often occurs in areas where many poor and minority people live or work, and that disadvantaged communities bear an unfair burden of exposure to pollution. There is a possibility that trading could allow pollution “hot spots” to continue, with accompanying environmental jus- tice concerns. For example, a polluter could purchase credits instead of making onsite pollution reductions. controls before a WQT program was established. Unlike his (polluting) neighbors, he would not be eligible for financing under the program. Thus, the program would reward “notorious polluters” rather than the good stew- ards, “because the good steward had already reduced pollution” (Ruppert, 2004). Despite these criticisms, there are several examples of WQT markets that have been considered successful, and earned support from industry, famers, regulators, and environmentalists. As was discussed previously, the Alpine Cheese Company Trading Program in Ohio was a very small market that involved the purchase of credits from 25 farmers by a local cheese company. Many of the farm- ers already did business with Alpine Cheese, selling milk from their dairy herds, and have a strong inter- est in maintaining a strong agricultural economy. One observer wrote that, “socially, community has been built with the farmers taking pride in working together, their more sustainable farming practices and in seeing the success of the factory” (Marida, 2010). One sees a similar outcome in an evaluation of the Hunter River Salinity Trading Scheme in Australia. Where there was once “significant conflict between primary producers and mining operators,” today, “agriculture, mining and electricity generation operate side by side, sharing the use of the river” (NSWDEC, 2003). Here, a history of conflict has been replaced by cooperation. This did not happen overnight, and required many years of pains- taking consultation and negotiation. In New Zealand, concerns have been raised about how the Lake Taupo Nutrient Trading Scheme affects differ- ent types of landowners, particularly indigenous Maori people. In this area, dairy farms and grazing were cre- ating polluted runoff, negatively impacting a freshwa- ter lake important for fishing and tourism. Regulators instituted a cap on nitrogen pollution seeking to main- tain water quality at year 2000 levels. Larger corpo- rate landowners were given more pollution credits based on their historical use of the land, while Maori landowners had not yet fully developed their lands (MOTU, 2009). There are historical and cultural rea- sons why Maoris have been slower to develop their lands: they did not own some lands until recently, and “Some critics have suggested that WQT programs could perpetuate or worsen environmental justice problems.”
  • 172. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT48 States, the Clean Water Act established the concept of “designated use” for waterways (i.e. swimmable, boat- able, or fishable), with water quality standards then developed based on the designated use. The process of developing a standard requires understanding the basic physical, environmental, and human elements of the watershed. Generally, scientists or engineers collect data and use computer models to determine the natu- ral and human pollution sources (i.e. diffuse nonpoint sources and point discharges). They also use models to determine how much of a pollutant a water body can assimilate while restoring or maintaining beneficial uses. The second necessary condition is that polluters have the ability to create water quality improvements, or reduce pollutant discharge through technology or management. Further, the regulator must be able to verify that these pollution reductions are real and likely to last. Verification of credits can be cumbersome and time consuming, which can inhibit trading. Regulators may require field visits or photos to show that on- farm improvements have been properly installed and maintained. In the case of the Alpine Cheese Trading Program, soil conservation agents ensure that pollu- tion control measures installed on farms meet “strin- gent engineering specifications” (Mariola, 2009). Implementation requires up to eight visits to a farm from project start to finish, and a full-time agent is required to coordinate a program involving one credit buyer and 25 farmers. In some cases, however, the role of verification falls to a trusted intermediary, as in the case of the South Nation River Program in Canada, where a conservation nonprofit hires local farmers to conduct field inspections (O’Grady, 2011). More often however, inspections and record-keeping are con- ducted by state or local governments. According to the US EPA, “mechanisms for determining and ensur- ing compliance may include a combination of record This was the subject of a 2013 lawsuit by Food Water Watch against the Chesapeake Bay Nutrient Trading Program, which was later dismissed by a federal judge (Hauter, 2013). Trading programs are most effective when they cover pollutants with “far-field” impacts, meaning their effects are felt over a large area or over a long time period. Indeed, a thriving market under a cap could allow pollu- tion hot spots to continue unchecked, and thus would be inappropriate for regulating pollutants which have acute local impacts. “This is the reason no one has seri- ously contemplated a market for toxics,” according to Cy Jones, a World Resources Institute (WRI) senior fellow (personal communication, 2015). This issue is less important when trading operates within discrete basins. The larger the basin in which trading is allowed, the more chance there is to exacerbate hotspots. For this reason, some programs have rules restricting trad- ing to smaller sub-watersheds, as has been done in the Ohio River program described above. Necessary, enabling, and limiting conditions In this section, we discuss the minimum conditions that are necessary for the creation and successful opera- tion of a water quality market, followed by a discussion of conditions that can enable WQT markets. These enabling factors will increase the market’s likelihood of succeeding but may not be required for it to be estab- lished. Finally, we discuss factors which may limit WQT markets by acting as barriers or obstacles. Necessary conditions for a successful water quality trading program include the following three circum- stances. The first is the presence of a regulator and its ability to set a cap on pollutants, monitor pollution, and verify the legitimacy of water quality credits that are created. Thus, the regulator must have the scien- tific and technical capacity to set water quality goals, and monitor water quality to ensure that those goals are being met. To do so first requires a set of “desired future conditions” for a particular waterbody. This may be set by law, custom, or local preferences. In the United “It is one thing to set up a water quality market; it is another for active trading to take place.”
  • 173. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 49 Enabling conditions required for creation of a water quality trading program go beyond these basics. First, the government regulator must have the authority to set discharge limits to protect waterways. Second, the regulator needs the power to issue and enforce water pollution discharge permits. Enforcement, with the threat of meaningful fines or criminal penalties, is especially important. As Abraham Lincoln famously noted, “laws without enforcement are just good advice.” Finally, there must be a legal framework by which trad- ing can take place. It is one thing to set up a water quality market; it is another for active trading to take place. As we have shown, many United States markets have been largely moribund. The following presents what we consider enabling conditions – meaning governments can set up a market without them, but there may be little or no trading. It would be tempting to classify an idle mar- ket as a failure, but as we have also seen, some United States markets have seen little trading, but they have been accompanied by an improvement in watershed stewardship and improvements to the environment. There must be a demand for water quality credits. Demand is the first and foremost enabling condition for trades to take place. Generally, such demand is created by a strong regulatory or non-regulatory driver.27 In the case of the Alpine Cheese Nutrient Trading Program described above, factory owners wished to expand pro- duction, but were unable to do so because of a restric- tive discharge permit. Violating the permit could have resulted in fines or criminal charges. The factory own- ers faced otherwise undesirable options: they could 27 An example of a non-regulatory driver could be where industrial emitters decide among themselves to voluntarily limit pollution to gain goodwill or in an attempt to pre-empt regulation. This is the case in the Ohio River study discussed above, where electric power companies have funded projects to reduce pollution from farms in their watersheds. These activities are not compulsory, so why would a for-profit corpora- tion do it? Their motivation, as put forth by the program’s manager in Congressional testimony is “to meet corporate sustainability goals and their voluntary participation may also be considered by the state permit- ting agencies when determining the need for flexible permit compliance options in the future” (Fox 2014). In other words, she was saying that companies hope that their activities today will buy them goodwill with regulators and that future regulation will be less burdensome as a result. keeping, monitoring, reporting and inspections” (US EPA, 2003). There are other aspects of regulatory oversight necessary to ensure accountability on behalf of both buyers and sellers of credits. This oversight includes many aspects of a trading program: • establishing trading eligibility • tracking of trades • verification of credit generation • compliance and enforcement • monitoring of results • program assessment. It is especially difficult and usually impractical to mea- sure nonpoint source pollution reductions, for example, from projects designed to reduce polluted runoff from farms. The pollution source is usually spread out, and there is no obvious place to measure the discharge (as there would be at the outfall of a factory). Nonpoint source pollution also tends to be “episodic”, occur- ring when rainfall flushes pollutants into waterways, further thwarting measurement efforts. Regulators have adopted several approaches to deal with these issues. Nonpoint source pollution reductions are most often estimated based on prior studies or modeling. To address the uncertainty associated with these esti- mates, regulators may place a higher burden for pol- lution reductions on nonpoint sources. Indeed, some markets have been designed with “trading ratios” where nonpoint source reductions trade against point sources at a ratio of 2:1 or 3:1. The third necessary condition is an appropriate legal framework enabling trading. Some of the legal require- ments for water quality trading are similar to those for other market-based instruments. Broadly, programs require a legal environment that will uphold the rights of buyers and sellers. Some basics, as outlined by Greiber (2009), include: • a legal system that recognizes agreements must be kept • a civil law providing contract parties with legal rem- edies to enforce contract rights in cases of non- compliance with contract obligations • general respect for the rule of law.
  • 174. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT50 (2013), economists from MIT and Harvard who studied the program, concluded that, by all accounts, it was a major success: following its launch in 1995, the market performed “exceptionally well along all relevant dimen- sions” and helped the United States reach emissions goals in 2006. However, the market’s collapse should be a cautionary tale: “When the government creates a market, it can also destroy it, possibly fostering a legacy of increased regulatory uncertainty and reduced investor confi- dence in future cap-and-trade regimes, and hence reduced credibility of pollution markets more broadly” (Schmalensee and Stavins, 2013). Trust among market participants is a key element of any WQT program. In the United States, most water quality markets involve point sources purchasing pol- lution reduction credits from farms, or less frequently, from forests or other nonpoint sources. Controlling nonpoint source pollution from agriculture faces unique obstacles. Farmers often distrust regulators, and worry that participation in a trading program may open the door to future regulation. Some pilot pro- grams in the United States have worked through local soil and water conservation districts, or made use of agricultural extension services, because the farmers know and trust these agents. In fact, Mariola (2009) found the most important factor for program success was “the use of a local, trusted, embedded intermediary as the link between programs and farmers emerges as the most important explanatory variable for program success.” Canadian WQT managers have come to similar conclu- sions. In the South Nation River watershed, wastewater dischargers face a cap on phosphorus discharge, and new wastewater systems are purchasing phosphorus relocate the factory, install expensive onsite wastewater treatment, or stop production altogether. In Australia’s Hunter River, salty discharge from mines was affecting the drinking water supplies for downstream cities, and an inflexible basin cap would have meant that existing mines could not expand and new industries could not develop. In other cases, industries are interested in mit- igating their own pollution to create goodwill or to help lessen the burden of future regulation. This is the case for power companies in the Ohio River Basin. At pres- ent, large power companies such as Duke Energy, the largest electric power holding company in the United States with some 7.3 million customers, and American Electric Power, which has over 5 million customers, pur- chase credits “to meet corporate sustainability goals and their voluntary participation may also be consid- ered by the state permitting agencies when determin- ing the need for flexible permit compliance options in the future” (Fox, 2014). In addition to demand, there must be willingness to engage in trade among buyers and sellers. One observer cited the most frequent roadblock to estab- lishing a WQT program as the “simple absence of willing buyers and sellers” (O’Grady, 2011). In WQT markets, demand for the commodity (pollution credits) “is artificially created by regulatory decree and which cannot be seen or felt or even measured with preci- sion” (Mariola, 2009). Because the market is entirely dependent on a regulatory driver, it can be fragile and susceptible to interference by politicians or the courts. For example, the United States Acid Rain Program (ARP), the nation’s first national cap-and-trade pro- gram, suffered a series of legal challenges beginning in 2008, culminating in new rules in 2011 that severely limited trading between states. As a result, the market, which relied heavily on interstate trading, collapsed. In 2012, the market value of a credit to emit a ton of sulfur dioxide was less than $1. Previously, these same credits had sold for $100 to $200 for most of the last decade and peaked at $1,200 per ton in 2005 (Schmalensee and Stavins, 2013). The ARP’s collapse is worth paus- ing to consider, as it was the model for all subsequent environmental markets. Schmalensee and Stavins “In addition to demand, there must be willingness to engage in trade among buyers and sellers.”
  • 175. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 51 The ability to trade water quality credits across regional borders may be an important enabling condition, depending on the geography of the watershed. Many important watersheds extend across multiple states, or across international boundaries. When trades can only take place within a single state or country, it reduces the potential for trading and for water quality improve- ments (Fisher-Vanden and Olmstead, 2013). In 2012, the pilot Ohio River Basin Trading Program became the first program in the United States to allow trad- ing across state borders, with an agreement signed by the states of Ohio, Kentucky, and Indiana (Fox, 2014). Lessons learned from the Acid Rain Program sug- gest that legislation may be necessary for interstate programs: “the series of regulations, court rulings, and regulatory responses ... affirmed that EPA cannot set up an interstate trading system under the Clean Air Act in the absence of specific legislation” (Schmalensee and Stavins, 2013). Limiting conditions for water quality trading may be created by existing laws, policies, and institutions in some regions. Greiber (2009) described a number of possible concerns related to the legal and institutional frameworks for environmental markets. Unrelated laws may contradict the aims of a market by, for example, providing perverse incentives to polluting industries or restricting innovative ways of funding environmental projects. Land tenure is a key concern in some coun- tries, as farmers without tenure may have little incen- tive to participate in programs if they do not own land and their futures are more uncertain. credits from rural landowners, mainly farmers. Initially, the agricultural community had reservations about the program. One of the main concerns raised by farmers during the design of the South Nation program was their future liability. Organizers confronted this concern during a series of public meetings and then added a key phrase to their final document that addressed the farmers’ concerns and allowed trading to begin (O’Grady, 2011) – the phrase was: “Landowners are not bound, legally or otherwise, to attain the predicted phosphorus offset through the establishment of a BMP [best manage- ment practice, another term for an on-farm pollution control measure] on their property.” Further, control of the program was granted to South Nation Conservation, a community-based watershed organization that was trusted by farmers. In addition, the program is run by a multi-stakeholder committee, “and all project field visits are done by farmers and not paid professionals.” As a result, the program has been able to overcome much of the early resistance. An independent evaluation showed that most farmers had a high opinion of the program and have recommend the program to other farmers in their community (O’Grady, 2011). “When trades can only take place within a single state or country, it reduces the potential for … water quality improvements.”
  • 177. 4 Role of the private sector INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 53 The private sector participates to some degree in all of the instruments described in the previous section. For example, in Michigan’s Paw Paw River Watershed, Coca-Cola North America and other stakeholders recently developed and implemented a performance- based PWS program to compensate farmers for imple- menting practices that reduce soil loss and enhance groundwater recharge (Forest Trends, 2015b). The pri- vate sector also participates as a buyer or seller in water quality trading programs to comply with water quality regulations, or buys or sells water rights through water trading programs. In addition to these incentive-based instruments, the private sector may participate in a range of voluntary initiatives to, for example, restore or protect a watershed or provide water service to local communities. Moreover, they may employ incentives within their direct operations or supply chains to pro- mote water stewardship. In this section, we describe some of the drivers for private sector engagement in water stewardship, provide examples of their participa- tion in incentive-based programs, and provide an initial estimate of their investment in these programs. 4.1 Corporate water stewardship To produce goods and services, most companies rely on a consistent supply of adequate quality source water and permission to discharge wastewater. As population growth and economic development push the limits of renewable freshwater supplies and busi- ness-as-usual resource management strategies, and as rapid urbanization, water pollution, groundwater deple- tion, and climate change introduce new water-related risks, companies face increasing urgency to respond. Companies typically come to understand their relation- ship to water in terms of their water footprint and their water-related business risk. A water footprint assess- ment – which estimates the volume of water consumed and polluted in the production of a material or a prod- uct, or in the operation of an entire business, industry, or nation – can help managers more fully understand the nature and extent of a company’s dependence and impact on water resources. It is also appealing as a basis for setting targets to reduce water use related to, for example, manufacturing processes or production of agricultural raw materials. While a water footprint assessment can inform a risk assessment, a volumetric footprint measurement omits the local context neces- sary to characterize the risks related to water use, and obscures the difference in impact between using water “Companies … understand their relationship to water in terms of their water footprint and their water-related business risk.”
  • 178. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT54 Effective water resource management systems and regulatory frameworks, the performance of which can be enhanced by incentive-based instruments, benefit companies in a number of ways. • As water users, companies benefit from a more reli- able and higher quality supply of water. • As polluters, businesses benefit from opportunities to manage the cost of compliance over time, and to seek innovative approaches to improve the quality and reduce the volume of wastewater. • As ratepayers and taxpayers, companies benefit by avoiding the cost of adding new or expanding ex- isting supply. Efforts to reduce water-related business risks typically occur at three scales: within direct operations, in supply chain agricultural or manufacturing operations that are not within a company’s direct control, or outside the fenceline of both owned and supply chain properties, where water-related risks are driven more by sociopo- litical, hydrological, or ecological conditions than by the actions of the company or its suppliers. from a source that’s plentiful and using the same vol- ume of water from a source that’s overexploited or not readily replenished.28 Water-related business risks generally fall into three broad and interrelated categories: • physical risks include scarcity, degraded source water quality, and flooding • regulatory risks relate to inconsistent, ineffective, or poorly enforced public policy, particularly when a change in regulation or enforcement could dis- rupt production or lead to an unexpected cost of compliance • reputational risks are faced by companies that overexploit or are perceived to overexploit water resources – including inefficient use, water pollu- tion, excessive withdrawal, competition with other users, or other negligent water-related activities. All three categories of risk include financial impacts from increased operating costs, fines or unplanned capital expenditures, supply chain disruptions, damage to the value of a brand, or lost access to markets. Increasingly, businesses are taking steps to identify, characterize, and mitigate these risks. For example, the Aqueduct Water Risk Atlas, a web-based tool produced by the World Resources Institute, identifies which and how many locations in a company’s operations or sup- ply chain face water-related risk in 12 dimensions, as shown in Figure 7. The Water Risk Filter, an online tool launched by the World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF) and the German Investment and Development Corporation (DEG), assigns each water-using location a score that incorporates both location-specific and company-specific risks, based on criteria such as the average water intensity or typical level of water pol- lution generated by suppliers to a particular industry sector (WWF and DEG, 2014). 28 Water “neutrality” or “offsets” are related concepts, similar to carbon neutrality or carbon offsets. They imply that a company can compen- sate for the negative impacts of its water footprint. However, there is no standard for measuring negative impacts or defining which types and how much of any given activity is sufficient compensation (Hoekstra et al., 2011). Baseline water stress Inter-annual variability Seasonal variability Flood occurence Droughtseverity Upstream storage Groundwater Stress Return flow ratio Upstream protected land Media coverage Access to water Threatened amphibians Physical Risk Quantity Physical Risk Quality Regulatory and Reputational Risk OVERALL WATER RISK FIGURE 7. Water risk indicators Source: Gassert et al., 2013.
  • 179. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 55 Another recent development is the idea of engag- ing outside the fenceline. Leading companies under- stand that collective action with other stakeholders at the watershed scale may be required to address root causes of resource scarcity, accessibility, or source water quality, which can increase costs or disrupt operations. The Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER), a coalition of business leaders in an industry that faces substantial water-related repu- tational risk, has acknowledged that in some locations, watershed-level interventions may in fact be more effective at mitigating water-related risk than facility- level water-use efficiency or other activities (BIER, 2015). To assist companies in prioritizing their efforts, BIER has proposed developing a decision support tool that could give more priority to intervention outside the fenceline than to internal efficiency or water quality improvements. 4.2 Private sector engagement with incentive-based instruments Private sector participation in incentive-based instru- ments, such as PWS and water quality trading, has been relatively modest but is growing. Bennett and Carroll (2014) found that in 2013, the private sector invested US$41 million in watershed services that supported “watershed restoration or protection that delivers ben- efits to society.” While this represents more than twice the estimated private sector investment of $19 million to $26 million in 2011, it is still a very small portion of the overall $12.3 billion invested collectively in watersheds by governments, business, and individual donors in 2013. Most private sector watershed investment activ- ity (about 95  percent) took place in North America, Europe, and Africa (Bennett and Carroll, 2014). • Direct operations. Companies that recognize wa- ter-relatedbusinessrisksoftenbeginworkingvolun- tarily with direct operations – owned and operated offices, distribution or retail facilities, manufacturing facilities, farms or other means of production – to mitigate those risks. In direct operations, companies can plan and manage implementation internally and realize cost savings related to obtaining, pumping, heating, or treating smaller volumes of water when operational efficiencies are achieved. • Supply chains. From agricultural raw materials to water- and chemical-intensive manufacturing pro- cesses, most companies face challenges managing water-related business risks in their supply chains, including those with advanced water stewardship practices in their direct operations. In many cases, complex business models and limited traceability are significant obstacles to quantifying corporate water footprints and identifying water-related busi- ness risks that exist in global supply chains. • Outside the fenceline. Facilities that maintain industry average or better water efficiency and wastewater quality may not be immune to all wa- ter-related risks. The term “outside the fenceline” refers to conditions and activities outside the phys- ical footprint of a production site. Water-related risk is said to originate outside the fenceline in regions where, for example, source water is scarce or pol- luted, projected demand exceeds renewable sup- ply, regulations are inconsistent or nonexistent, or lack of access to water and sanitation damages public health. While internal process or policy changes are easier to implement, they would not necessarily mitigate these risks. The private sector increasingly recognizes the need to evaluate site-level water use in the context of its local watershed characteristics, in order to inform and prioritize efficiency targets for different locations. For example, companies can manage risk more effectively by giving higher priority to efficiency improvements for water-intensive locations in drought-prone locations than for similar facilities where water resources are more plentiful. “Most private sector watershed investment activity … took place in North America, Europe, and Africa.”
  • 180. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT56 provide opportunities for projects within the corpo- rate replenish initiative to directly mitigate risks in the global supply chain. Other projects’ impacts, such as those related to access to water and sanitation or ones where Coca-Cola contributed to a collective action together with other companies, are estimated differ- ently (Rozza et al., 2013). Disincentives for private sector investments. There are also disincentives for private sector invest- ments in public goods, including watershed services. The benefits must be shared with others that did not contribute to the investment, and the benefits could be exhausted by other actors that did not participate in the collective action or investment (Meißner, 2013). However, when the consequences of inaction are sig- nificant, there is a compelling case in favor of policy engagement, collective action, and investment in water-related initiatives outside the fenceline, includ- ing preservation of resources or delivery of ecosystem services via incentive-based instruments. Among the barriers that prevent the private sector from participating more fully in watershed investments are three critical core competencies needed to achieve measureable outcomes with specific benefits for at-risk locations, which most companies do not possess: • scientific and environmental engineering expertise to identify, design, and implement watershed-level solutions • a nuanced understanding of the local environment and culture in the watershed where they seek to have a positive environmental outcome • experience with partnerships involving diverse stakeholders outside the fenceline. Therefore, in cases where companies identify risk and choose to take action at the watershed level, particu- larly if they choose to do so in more than one location across diverse global operations or an extended supply chain, it is helpful and sometimes necessary to involve an intermediary. Stanton et al. (2010) defined an inter- mediary as “any party other than the buyer or seller who Incentives for private sector investments. Industry sectors with the highest levels of investment in water- shed services (IWS) were energy utilities, water utilities, and the food and beverage industry, with investments of US$9.3 million, $8.9 million, and $8.8 million, respec- tively. The primary reported motivation for spending on watershed services was regulatory compliance, followed by water availability risks, water quality risks, corporate social responsibility and reputational risk, and biodiversity protection (Bennett and Carroll, 2014). The food and beverage sector, which accounted for nearly one-quarter of the total corporate investment in watersheds, is unlike other sectors in that it is driven primarily by water availability and water risks, rather than regulatory compliance. Bennett and Carroll (2014) found that 88 percent of buyers in the food and bever- age industry acted voluntarily, compared with the pri- vate sector average of 31 percent. For example, in 2012–2013, the Coca-Cola Company and its global bottling partners were involved in 20 projects around the world, buying at least $2.2 mil- lion in watershed services (Bennett and Carroll, 2014). Separately, the company publishes annual reports detailing its involvement in hundreds of other projects (LimnoTech, 2013). Indeed, the Coca-Cola Company is among a handful of private companies with a public commitment to “replenish” the water it uses.29 However, as Coca-Cola acknowledges, the impacts of water use are specific and local, making it impossible for a multi- national corporation to offset water use at the enter- prise level. Rozza et al. (2013) described a detailed methodology for quantifying the value of Coca-Cola’s replenish projects, including source water protection, water reuse for conservation or productive uses, and community-level sustainability projects. The company also requires its bottling plants to complete source water vulnerability assessments and to engage in the development of source water protection plans, which 29 Specifically, Coca-Cola is “Collaborating to replenish the water we use”, pledging that by 2020, it will “safely return to communities and nature an amount of water equal to what we use in our finished beverages and their production.”
  • 181. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 57 are driving increased adoption of water risk assess- ment across the business community. For example, in its annual survey of leaders and decision makers about perceptions of global risks, the World Economic Forum (WEF, 2015) found that water crises have the greatest potential for impact and are the eighth most likely to occur, as shown in Figure 8. Moreover, WEF has consid- ered water among the top three global risks since 2012 (WEF, 2012; 2013; 2014). CDP, formerly known as the Carbon Disclosure Project, operates a water program that surveys companies helps facilitate some aspect of the transaction or imple- mentation of the overall program. This role is commonly played by NGOs, consultants, or academic institutions.” Indeed, Coca-Cola has had to coordinate large-scale bilateral partnerships with more than one intermediary in order to achieve progress toward its global replen- ish objective, including The Nature Conservancy, WWF, and the  United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). Table 3 illustrates increasing complexity and differences in motivation that companies face as they move from addressing efficiency in direct operations to engaging in collective action intended to create more sustainable operating conditions in watersheds where they do business. Future investments by the private sector are uncertain. However, consumer preference for more sustainable products and investor concern about unmitigated risk TABLE 3. Private sector activities, scale, drivers ACTIVITIES, COMPLEXITY, INCLUSIVITY Operational efficiency Wastewater quality Owned facilities Codes of conduct Social/environmental indices Voluntary sustainability standards Industry sector/association Policy engagement Collective action Diverse stakeholders SCALE Site-specific Small business Supply chain Small to medium enterprise Landscape Multinational TIME/VALUE Near-term, return on investment Medium-term, possible value capture Long-term, sustainability DRIVERS Financial self-interest Regulatory compliance Externalities License to operate Reputation Access to markets EXTERNAL CONDITIONS Strong governance and enforcement Inconsistent local regulation and enforcement Weak governance Negative externalities of other actors “…there is increasing awareness of water- specific issues and of best practices in corporate water stewardship…”
  • 182. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT58 Figure 1: The Global Risks Landscape 2015 4.54.03.5 5.0 5.5 4.0 4.5 5.0 4.82 average average 4.74 Likelihood Impact Top 10 risks in terms of Likelihood Categories Interstate conflict Extreme weather events Failure of national governance State collapse or crisis Unemployment or underemployment Natural catastrophes Failure of climate-change adaptation Water crises Data fraud or theft Cyber attacks Top 10 risks in terms of Impact Water crises Weapons of mass destruction Interstate conflict Energy price shock Failure of climate-change adaptation Fiscal crises Unemployment or underemployment Biodiversity loss and ecosystem collapse Spread of infectious diseases Critical information infrastructure breakdown 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 7.0 1.0 7.0 plotted area Economic Geopolitical Environmental Societal Technological Misuse of technologies Data fraud or theft Cyber attacks Critical information infrastructure breakdown Water crises Spread of infectious diseases Profound social instability Large-scale involuntary migration Food crises Failure of urban planning Weapons of mass destruction Terrorist attacks State collapse or crisis Interstate conflict Failure of national governance Natural catastrophes Man-made environmental catastrophes Failure of climate-change adaptation Biodiversity loss and ecosystem collapse Unmanageable inflation Unemployment or underemployment Fiscal crises Failure of critical infrastructure Energy price shock Deflation Asset bubble Extreme weather events Failure of financial mechanism or institution Source: Global Risks Perception Survey 2014. Note: Survey respondents were asked to assess the likelihood and impact of the individual risks on a scale of 1 to 7, 1 representing a risk that is not likely to happen or have impact, and 7 a risk very likely to occur and with massive and devastating impacts. See Appendix B for more details. To ensure legibility, the names of the global risks are abbreviated. Also see Appendix A for the full name and description. FIGURE 8: Global risks landscape, 2015 Note: Taken from 2014 Global Risks Perception Survey. Survey respondents were asked to assess the likelihood and impact of the individual risks on a scale of 1 to 7, 1 representing a risk that is not likely to happen or have impact, and 7 a risk very likely to occur and with massive and devastating impacts. See Appendix B for more details. To ensure legibility, the names of the global risks are abbreviated. Also see Appendix A for the full name and description. Source: World Economic Forum, 2015.
  • 183. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 59 Concurrently, there is increasing awareness of water- specific issues and of best practices in corporate water stewardship, so there will likely be demand for mecha- nisms that can deliver quantifiable outcomes to ben- efit specific corporate assets or at-risk strategic supply chain locations. Increased understanding of water- related risks and opportunities could similarly drive an increase in private sector engagement in incentive- based instruments for watershed services. in order to reveal water-related risk in institutional investment portfolios. CDP’s 2014 Global Water Report revealed that, of nearly 1,100 responding companies, 74  percent had evaluated how water quantity and quality could affect their growth strategy. However, of these, only 38 percent assessed water-related risk in both owned operations and their supply chain, and only 25 percent conducted detailed water risk assessments at the watershed level (CDP, 2014).
  • 185. 5 Summary and conclusions INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 61 Growing pressure on the availability and quality of water resources is having a major impact on our social, economic, and environmental well-being. These pres- sures are likely to worsen in response to continued population and economic growth, climate change, and other challenges. As water pollution exacerbates the challenges posed by water scarcity, and the world’s water quality becomes increasingly degraded, new approaches and strategies are needed. One key area of interest is the potential for incen- tive-based instruments to reduce pressure on water resources. To date, the primary environmental pol- icy tool to address water challenges has been com- mand-and-control regulations. Over the past several decades, however, the environmental policy “toolkit” has expanded to include a host of incentive-based instruments that use financial means, directly or indi- rectly, to motivate responsible parties to reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facili- ties, processes, or products. While regulations and incentive-based instruments are often juxtaposed, “in reality the two often operate alongside each other” (UNEP, 2004). With water quality trading, for example, governments mandate caps on the allowable pollut- ant levels and issue tradable permits that allow those in the industry to allocate polluting activities among themselves, incentivized by market forces. Similarly, with water trading, governments may allocate water and then institute a framework by which water trad- ing can occur. While incentive-based instruments may work in tandem, they must be integrated within a broader watershed management effort. In a recent review of PWS programs, Bond and Mayers (2010) cautioned that: “PWS is a tool that will fail, or become irrelevant, if it is not integrated with wider regulatory approaches, broaderwatershedmanagementefforts,andexplicit attention to governance influences that shape what is possible. Policy makers need to consider the opportunities to ensure that future policy and legislation allow for a mix of both incentives and regulations to ensure the effective management of land and water resources.” The choice of whether and which instrument to apply depends on the specific circumstances, conditions, and needs of a given area. It is important to avoid “the law of the instrument”, i.e. the tendency to gravitate toward a particular tool and then look for applications of that tool. UNEP (2004) found that:
  • 186. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT62 for consistent and rigorous outreach and, potentially, a need for engaging a trusted intermediary. Finally, monitoring and evaluation are essential to the success of any instrument. In particular, they help ensure outcomes are achieved and allow for adjust- ments in response to changing social, economic, or environmental conditions. Monitoring should evaluate the additionality of the program, i.e. whether the pro- gram has an effect when compared with baseline con- ditions. It should also examine any potential impacts on surrounding areas (e.g. leakage) and the permanence of the intervention. However, it is important to recog- nize that extensive monitoring requirements would increase transaction costs. Thus, the need for moni- toring and evaluation must be balanced with practical considerations about the ability to maintain the viability of the program. “Prior to designing and applying any policy instrument for environmental protection, the policy context must be understood, including the existing institutional, legal and economic conditions in which these tools are meant to function. Choosing an effective policy package that will both address the environmental problem policy makers are faced with and fit in with the institutional capabilities and existing policy framework remains one of the most difficult challenges.” This process should be open and transparent, with meaningful participation from all affected parties. This will enable crafting a solution that not only is appropri- ate for local conditions, it will help reduce opposition and promote buy-in from those who will be imple- menting and affected by the program. It is important to recognize that those with the least power may not have the resources to participate or be skeptical of the groups involved. In these cases, there will be a need
  • 187. ANNEX 1 Demand management INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 63 A key way to reduce pressure on limited water supplies is through demand management, commonly referred to as water conservation and efficiency. In many cases, reducing demand is equivalent to augmenting or real- locating water supply. Demand management is typi- cally less expensive and faster to implement than water supply augmentation, and often results in reduced energy demand and water and wastewater treatment costs. For example, a recent study in Westminster, Colorado, found that water conservation and efficiency since 1980 had reduced water use in the city, reduc- ing tap fees by 80 percent and reducing customers’ bills by 91  percent relative to what they would have been without these efforts (Feinglas, Gray, and Mayer 2013). In major cities, such as San Francisco and Los Angeles, total water use has decreased since the late 1970s despite population and economic growth. At a larger scale, a recent United States federal study found that water conservation and efficiency efforts have reduced annual demand for water from the Colorado River basin by more than 1.7 million acre-feet, a tremen- dous savings in an over-allocated basin (US Bureau of Reclamation 2015). In the United States, we have made considerable progress in managing the nation’s water, with total water use less than it was in 1970, despite continued population and economic growth. Indeed, every sector, from agriculture to thermoelectric power generation, shows reductions in water use. Likewise, in Australia, a severe drought in the middle of the last decade prompted an intensive effort to reduce water demand. In response, total urban demand, including losses and non-residential consumption, fell from about 130 gallons per capita daily (gpcd) in 2005 to about 80 gpcd in 2010 (Queensland Water Commission, 2010). There are many tools available to reduce water demand – some of which rely on an incentive-based approach, e.g. pricing and rebates, while others are based on a more traditional command-and-control approach. Numerous studies have shown that significant conser- vation and efficiency opportunities exist in urban and agricultural areas (see, e.g. Gleick et al., 2003; Heberger, Cooley, and Gleick 2014). Below, we provide additional detail on the major demand management tools, includ- ing pricing, direct financial incentives, regulations, and education and outreach. Water pricing. Well-designed tariff structures can meet multiple policy objectives, including supporting the financial stability of the utility, the affordability of water for low-income customers, the efficient alloca- tion of water and other resources, and environmental sustainability. Most water utilities use some form of volumetric tariffs to achieve these objectives. There are several types of volumetric tariffs in use around the world: • uniform tariffs in which the volumetric tariff ($/m3) is constant regardless of the quantity used; • inclining block tariffs in which the volumetric tariff increases as the quantity used increases; and • declining block tariffs in which the volumetric tariff decreases as the quantity used increases. Uniform tariffs are the most common tariff structure in OECD and in developing countries (OECD 2009). Inclining block rates are becoming increasingly com- mon (OECD 2009), as there is recognition that when designed properly, this approach can provide a strong financial incentive to conserve while ensuring that
  • 188. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT64 Instead of providing rebates to cover a portion of the cost, some utilities have opted to institute direct-install programs that cover the entire cost of the device and the installation costs. In the mid-1990s, for example, the New York City Department of Environmental Protection launched a massive toilet rebate program to replace one-third of all water-wasting toilets in New York City with low-flow models. For this effort, property owners contracted directly with private licensed plumbers for the installation of the toilet, and after completion of the work, the City provided the property owner with a $240 rebate for the first toilet and $150 for the second toilet. Where possible, the plumber would also install low-flow showerheads and faucet aerators. The pro- gram was a huge success. Between 1994 and 1997, 1.3 million low-flow toilets were installed, saving 70 - 90 million gallons per day. Customers saw their water and wastewater bills drop 20 percent to 40 percent (EPA 2002). Additionally, the City was able to defer the need to develop new supply sources and expand wastewater treatment capacity, saving the community even more money. Regulations. In addition to financial incentives, reg- ulations are key demand management strategies. Regulations can take a variety of forms, ranging from a prescriptive approach focused on a particular appli- ance to a performance-based approach for outdoor water use. For example, the International Plumbing Code, which is widely used in the United States and forms the basis for plumbing codes in several other countries, specifies maximum flow rates for kitchen and lavatory faucets. Likewise, communities in the Las Vegas area have restricted lawn installation in new developments. California has also passed an ordinance to reduce outdoor water use, although the state opted for a performance-based approach. Landscape irriga- tion typically accounts for more than half of residen- tial demand in the state, and in an effort to promote outdoor efficiency, the state adopted the Model Water Efficient Landscape Ordinance (MWELO). MWELO lower-income consumers are able to meet their basic water needs at a reduced cost. A 2003 survey of cities in the southwest United States found that per-capita water use is typically lower in cities with dramatically increasing block tariffs, such as Tucson and El Paso (WRA 2003). Although less frequently employed, pricing has also been shown to be effective in reducing agricultural water use. For example, the Broadview Water District, a small district in California’s San Joaquin Valley, imple- mented increasing block rates in 1988 to reduce the volume of contaminated drainage water flowing into the San Joaquin River. The rate was set at $16 per acre-foot ($0.013 per m3) for the first 90 percent of average water use during the 1986 to 1988 period and $40 per acre-foot ($0.032 per m3) for any additional water. By 1991, the district’s average water use declined by 19 percent due to efficiency improvements and crop shifting (MacDougall et al., 1992). Direct financial incentives. Rebate programs are commonly used to encourage customers to make investments in water conservation and efficiency improvements. Residents and business owners pur- chase new devices as the old devices wear out. While most new standard devices use less water than older models, there are many new high-efficiency devices available that use even less water. While efficient devices are often cheaper over their lifetimes due to lower water, energy, and wastewater bills, users may be put off by the higher up-front costs. As a result, water utilities may provide their customers with a rebate to defray the additional cost of the more efficient device. There are several examples of water utilities partner- ing with local energy utilities to augment those rebates because of the energy savings (Cooley and Donnelly 2013). Additionally, utilities may partner with retailers to offer rebates at the point of sale, giving customers an immediate incentive to purchase the more efficient device.
  • 189. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 65 Education and outreach. Education and outreach programs can also be effective for promoting water conservation and efficiency. The US Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), for example, launched the WaterSense labeling program in 2006 to promote water-conserving devices that are 20  percent more efficient than standard products on the market and meet rigorous performance criteria. Social market- ing has also gained prominence in recent years, with some programs tapping into new metering technolo- gies and web-based platforms. For example, a recent study found that home water reports - which provide customers information on their current water use and comparisons to their past use, use by similar house- holds, and efficient use - reduce water by 5 percent and were especially effective in reaching the highest water users (Mitchell and Chesnutt 2013). establishes a water budget for new construction and rehabilitated landscapes that are at least 2,500 square feet and require a building or landscaping permit (the size threshold is likely to be reduced to 500 square feet in response to the current drought). In addition, the ordinance requires mulching for most plantings; promotes the use of techniques to increase storm- water retention and infiltration; and requires new and refurbished landscapes to install irrigation systems run by weather, soil moisture, or other self-adjusting con- trollers. Also in California, Governor Schwarzenegger signed SBx7-7 in 2009, requiring urban water suppliers to reduce per-capita water use by 20 percent by 2020.
  • 190. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT66 The MDB includes parts of four states (Queensland, New South Wales, Victoria, and South Australia) and the Australian Capital Territory. The MDB supplies water to about three million people, including the national capi- tal (Canberra) and Adelaide, outside of the basin near the river’s mouth. According to the MDBA, the basin contains some 70 percent of the nation’s irrigated acre- age, producing a third of the country’s food supply. The MDBA reports the gross value of irrigated agriculture in the basin in 2012-13 at approximately $6.8 Billion. The MDB generates almost all of Australia’s rice and cotton and 75 percent of its grapes, as well as roughly half of the nation’s hay, fruit, livestock, and dairy production. The construction of dams and canals and the diver- sion and depletion of MDB rivers has endangered the survival of at least 35 bird species and 16 mammal spe- cies within the basin. Many fish species, including the Murray cod, are also threatened. Wetlands have dried up or reached critically low levels, exacerbated by the Millennium drought, prompting public concern. MDB and the Colorado River Basin The MDB and the Colorado River Basin share many common traits: both are highly variable rivers in arid basins, where rapidly-growing urban populations have imposed new demands on limited, climate-stressed rivers. Basin size and runoff are similar. And, interest- ingly, the two basins share a common figure: Elwood Mead (namesake of Lake Mead), the Wyoming State Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin (MDB) figures promi- nently in discussions about water trading as an example of a thriving incentive-based system that successfully transitioned from a non-market system (Grafton et al., 2012). The total value of water trading in Australia in fiscal year 2012-13 exceeded $1.4 billion (NWC 2013). Water trading in Australia includes both short-term trades, known as allocation trading, and long-term trades, known as entitlement trading. In fiscal year 2012-13, the most recent period for which comprehen- sive data are available, the total volume of short-term trading increased 44 percent from the previous year, from almost 3.5 million acre-feet to 5 million acre-feet, or roughly 50 percent of total surface water use in the MDB. This is an extremely active water market. Background The MDB covers some 390,000 square miles in south- eastern Australia, comprising roughly 14 percent of that country’s land area. Most of the basin is very arid, with 86 percent of the basin contributing little or no flow to rivers that drain the basin. The Murray-Darling Basin Authority (MDBA) estimates that total runoff within the basin is less than 26 million acre-feet annually, yield- ing an estimated long-term annual average 19 MAF of total river flow. As shown in Figure A-1, the system displays very high seasonal and annual variability. For example, flows in the southern Murray basin typically are much higher than in the northern Darling basin. Pre-development, an estimated 10 million acre-feet ran into the ocean; in 2009, during the historic Millennium drought, this had decreased to 4 million acre-feet. ANNEX 2 Water trading in Australia: Lessons from the Murray-Darling Basin
  • 191. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 67 subsequently changing the water rights structure to facilitate trading and protect environmental resources. In Australia, water rights typically refer to either entitle- ments or allocations.30 The National Water Initiative of 2004 defines these as: • Water access entitlement – a perpetual or ongo- ing entitlement to exclusive access to a share of water from a specified consumptive pool as defined in the relevant water plan. • Water allocation – the specific volume of water allocated to water access entitlements in a given season, defined according to rules established in the relevant water plan. (Young, 2010). Australian water rights are typically defined as the right todivertaspecificvolume,asopposedtoaconsumptive use right that is more typical with prior appropriation 30 Additional water rights include: Water use license – a non-tradable use or condition linked to the place of use; and Delivery right – may be required to ensure that an allocation is delivered, typically associated with irrigation infrastructure, such as canals and headgates (Grafton and Horne 2014). Irrigation Engineer from 1888-99, went on to serve as the Chairman of Victoria (Australia)’s State Rivers Water Supply Commission (1907–15), prior to return- ing to the US and serving as the Commissioner of the Bureau of Reclamation from 1924-36 (McLeod 2014). However, Australia avoided Mead’s legacy of prior appropriation and hierarchical water rights to embrace a very different system that promotes and facilitates water trading, as described in the following sections. History Australia has promoted and developed water trading over a period of more than 30 years (Grafton et al., 2012), in a process that initially attempted to activate markets prior to recognizing that the water rights struc- ture itself needed to be altered to encourage active trading and minimize transaction costs (Young, 2015). Table A-1 lists some of the major steps taken to cre- ate the current water trading structure. These changes have occurred over several decades and often reflect corrections to previous policies. Young (2010, 2015) asserts that Australia implemented water trading from the wrong direction, by first promoting trading and FIGURE A-1. Historical river flows within the Murray-Darling Basin 1900s 1910s 1920s 1930s 1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s 30,000 25,000 20,000 15,000 10,000 5,000 0 Flow(GLperyear) Northern basin annual flows Flow measured on Darling River at Bourke Southern basin annual flows Flow measured on River Murray at Euston Average annual flow levels 1895 Startofthe ‘FederationDrought’ whichlastsfor7years 1909 Floodinthe Murrayand Wimmerarivers 1914 Severedrought leadstotheend ofcommercial navigationonthe Murrayand Darlingrivers 1917 Floodingalong theRiverMurray 1921 Floodingacross theentireBasin 1931 Floodingalong theRiverMurray 1944 Severedrought throughoutNSW, VicandSA. Murrayceasesto flowinsomeareas 1950 Recordrainfall causeswidespread floodinginCondamine andWarregorivers 1952 Floodinginthe RiverMurray 1956 HighestBasininflows inrecordedhistory causewidespread flooding 1968 Duetosevere drought,HumeDam fallsto1%ofcapacity 1974 Widespreadflooding acrosstheBasin, knownasthe‘bigwet’ 1981 Droughtforces Adelaidetotake 90%ofitswater fromtheMurray. TheMurrayMouth closesforthefirst timeinrecorded history 1993 Floodingacross QLD,NSW andVictoria 1997 Beginningoflongestdrought inAustralia’srecordedhistory 2000MurrayMouthclosesand requiresdredging 2010-11Widespreadflooding throughouttheBasin 2006 Lowest water inflowsonrecord Extremedryin NorthernBasin 2013-15 Note: Volumes in the figure shown in gigaliters, with 1000 GL = 0.8 million acre-feet. Source: Australia’s MDBA.
  • 192. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT68 the land. Transforming these general land-based rights to discrete volumes then required determining his- toric usage patterns and water requirements for crops grown on that land. Several MDB states initially allowed water trading within individual irrigation districts, using shared infrastructure to trade water to different parcels within the district. These volumetric rights were subse- quently “unbundled” from the land, enabling water to be traded between different irrigation districts. Despite these changes, restrictions on trading between dif- ferent sub-basins often took years to revoke, due to concerns about adverse economic and equity impacts that trading could cause in areas of origin (Grafton and Horne 2014). regimes (Connor and Kaczan, 2013). Diversions can be measured (and subsequently traded) more readily than consumptive use, which requires measurement of both diversions and surface and sub-surface return flows. Return flows often lag diversions, sometimes by weeks or months in the case of sub-surface returns, requiring more complicated measurements and esti- mates, challenging efforts to evaluate and quantify the full impacts (especially environmental impacts) of the trade, hindering transactions. Initially, Australian water rights were linked to a spe- cific land parcel. In many cases, the water right simply entitled the landowner to sufficient water to irrigate TABLE A-1. Policy and legislative milestones YEAR ACTION DESCRIPTION 1960s Volumetric water licenses Start of conversion of land-based water entitlements to volumetric entitlements 1983 Water trading w/in districts Allowed in New South Wales and South Australia 1987 1st MDB Agreement Established the MDB Commission, to coordinate management 1991 Inter-district water trading Allowed in New South Wales 1994 “Unbundling” Council of Australian Governments agrees to separate statutory land rights from water rights, facilitating trading 1995 Diversion CAP implemented Limits surface water diversions in the MDB; limits water rights 1995 National Competition Policy Requires development of water markets and full-cost pricing 2000 Water Management Act “Unbundles” diversion and use rights 2004 National Water Initiative Promotes cohesive water planning and trading efforts 2004 Living Murray Initiative Authorizes purchase and dedication of 0.4 MAF to the river 2007 Water Act Promotes management of MDB 2008 Water Amendment Act Establishes MDB Authority, replacing the Commission 2008 Water for the Future Commits $3.1 billion to purchase water entitlements for the env. 2012 MD Basin Plan Caps total MDB surface diversions at 8.8 MAF, coordinates basin management including water quality (esp. salinity) Sources: MDBA, Young, 2010; Grafton and Horne, 2014.
  • 193. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 69 uses. New South Wales has attempted to limit federal purchases of water for the environment to no more than 3 percent of total entitlements, though this appears to contravene trading rules within the Basin Plan, which seek to minimize restrictions on trading (Grafton and Horne 2014). State water plans allocate water entitlements into one or two “pools,” known as a high security pool and a gen- eral or low security pool. The high security pool is allo- cated to those entitlement holders proportional to the size of their entitlement. For example, if a system only has two entitlement holders and one right is for nine units and the other is for one unit, the former would receive 90  percent of the pool’s allocation and the latter would receive 10 percent. If additional water is available for the general pool, that volume is allocated to those entitlement holders. Every season, the state determines the total volume available for allocation for each pool. During drought, the general pool might not receive any water at all (Young, 2010). Water trading activity Australia’s water trading activity is largely concentrated in the MDB, which represents as much as 94 percent of all such activity in Australia despite being only one of twelve surface water management areas (Figure A-2). Trading is very high as measured by the total volume of water traded (as much as 5 million acre-feet), the percentage of all diversions that are traded (as much as 50 percent), the number of farmers trading water (roughly half, in 2008-09), and the total number of trades (11,000, in 2011-12). The number of short-term (allocation) interstate trades also appears to be rising, reaching 20 percent of the total number of such trades in 2011/12 (Grafton and Horne 2014). Not surprisingly, the number of short-term (allocation) trades is much higher, in terms of numbers and volumes, than the number of entitlement trades. As the federal govern- ment has exercised its commitment to ensure minimum Unlike the doctrine of prior appropriation in the west- ern United States, water rights in Australia did not have priority dates or a seniority system for satisfy- ing demands: all rights were considered equivalent. Additionally, Australian water rights did not have to be exercised on an annual or periodic basis to demon- strate possession (again, unlike the prior appropriation system); many rights holders maintained their rights for periodic or infrequent use (known as “dozer” rights) or never exercised their water rights (known as “sleep- ers”), perhaps in the expectation that they might be needed in the future. The 1995 imposition of the diversion CAP limiting surface water diversions and rights within the MDBA explicitly recognized the continuing validity of dozer and sleeper rights and incorporated the volumes of these rights into the general calculation of the propor- tional shares of the new water rights regime. However, the result of recognizing dozer and sleeper rights within the context of water trading was to increase the finan- cial value of these unexercised rights, leading to new diversions and greater strain on water supply, in turn reducing water reliability (Grafton and Horne 2014). Tony McLeod, General Manager for Water Planning at MDBA, explained that the recognition of these dozer and sleeper rights was intentional, to reduce resistance to the imposition of the CAP and smooth the transition to the new system of proportional sharing (McLeod, personal communication, 2014). In response, the Australian government implemented several initiatives to purchase existing water entitle- ments and dedicate these to the environment, both to offset reservoir evaporation and other system losses (known as maintenance rights) and explicitly to ensure minimum instream flow volumes in designated reaches. The government has invested more than $3 Billion to date to purchase entitlements for environmental water. However, the relative priority of this environmental water remains contentious, with some states contend- ing that such rights receive lower priority than human
  • 194. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT70 about $54 per acre-foot in the drier 2012/13.31 Similarly, trading in drier years tends to see water move from lower value uses, such as pasture and forage, to higher value wine and vegetable crops. Connor and Kaczan (2013) reported that many livestock operations irrigate pasture and forage crops in wet years but tend to trade away their allocations in drier years, when the price of water rises due to scarcity, using the profits to purchase feed from other areas. These trends also manifest regionally, aswatertendstomoveacrossstatelinesfromNewSouth Wales into South Australia, which has more high-value 31 These prices are about an order of magnitude lower than prices for short-term transfers in California in the 2014 drought year, but are comparable to prices paid for short-term rentals in the active Northern Colorado Water Conservancy district water market. environmental flows by purchasing entitlements, such purchases have risen to 37 percent of the total number of entitlement trades in 2011/12. Only about 5 percent of farmers traded water entitlements, either to other farmers or to cities or to the government for augment- ing environmental flows, in 2008/09, or about 10 per- cent of the number that reported trading allocations that year (Grafton and Horne 2014). As expected, the number of allocation trades appears to be inversely correlated with precipitation and runoff, rising in drought years and falling when allocations are higher due to wetter conditions. Prices similarly vary in response to water availability, rising from the equivalent of about $22 per acre-foot in 2011/12 to the equivalent of 81 0.NT 426.K 426.A 426.B 426.I 507.A 426.G 426.D 41 4.SAC 239.SAA 81 0.WA 809.WA 808 807 806 805 804 803 802 801 71 0709 708 707 706 705 704 703 702 701 61 9 61 8 61 7 61 6 61 5 61 461 3 61 2 611 61 0 609 608 607 606 605 604 602 601 026.WA 025 024 023.WA 022.WA 41 5 41 4.VIC 408 407 406 405 404 403 402 409.VIC 239.VIC 238 237 236 235 234 233 232 231 230 229 225 224 223 222.VIC 221 .VIC 31 4.I 31 4.H 31 2 31131 0 302.G 301 31 9.E 31 9.D 302.F 302.E 31 9.B 307.B 31 8.F 31 6 31 8.E 31 7 31 8.B 31 8.A 302.D 309 302.C 302.A 303 304.E 304.B 304.A 308 306 31 4.A 31 3 307.A 021 .D 004.A 023.SAB 51 3.D 51 3.C 51 3.B 51 3.A 426.C 023.SAA 503.C 501 003.SA 505.A 005.SA 021 .B 41 4.SAD 021 .C 026.SA 51 2 507.B 506.A 007.SA 426.F 506.B 021 .A 509 51 0 004.B 001 .SA 508.A 022.SA 511 508.B 239.SAC 239.SAE 41 4.SAA 002 41 6.QLD 11 7 11 0 924 1 23 1 22.B 925 923 1 34 1 29 423.A 11 3 1 27 1 44.B 1 04 91 5 1 28 11 8 1 22.A 922 1 261 25 424.QLD 1 02 1 24 1 05 422.A 11 4 111 91 3 928 1 43 41 7 91 9 1 38 1 03 11 2 1 06 927 1 01 1 44.A 921 11 5 11 6 1 46 001 .QLD 1 39 1 30 1 07 926 1 21 1 09 1 08 1 31 003.QLD 422.B 920 1 32 1 36 1 20 011 1 33 929 91 2 91 0 909 908 907 906 905 904 903 902 901 826 825824 823 822 821 820 81 9 81 8 81 7 81 6 81 5.B 81 5.A 81 4 81 3 81 2 811 809.NT 029 028 027 026.NT 023.NT 007.NT 006 005.NT 001 .NT 499 425.URB425.URA 425.R 421 .UR 421 .R 420 41 9.UR 41 9.R 41 8.UR 41 8.R 41 6.NSWR 41 6.NSWUR 41 2.UR 41 2.R 411 41 0.NSWUR 41 0.NSWR 409.NSW 401 .NSW 222.NSW 221 .NSW 220 21 9.UR 21 9.R 21 8 21 7 21 6 21 5 21 4 21 3 21 2 211 21 0.UR 21 0.R 208 207 206 205 204 203.UR 203.R 202 201 01 2 424.NSW 004.NSW 003.NSW 41 0.ACT 503.B 502 426.J 426.H 426.L 239.SAB 603 228 227 226 31 9.C 31 9.A 31 8.C 31 8.D 304.F 302.B 305 304.D 304.C 31 4.G 31 4.F31 4.E 31 4.D 31 4.C 31 5 31 4.B 505.C 503.A 504.B 504.C 505.E 504.A 505.G 505.F 505.B 426.E 505.D 41 4.SAB 239.SAD 1 45 209 PERTH HOBART SYDNEY DARWIN CANBERRA ADELAIDE BRISBANE MELBOURNE 0 250 5001 25 Kilometres Legend Surface water management areas Drainage division North-East Coast South-East Coast Tasmania Murray-Darling South Australia Gulf South-West Coast Indian Ocean Timor Sea Gulf of Carpentaria Lake Eyre Bulloo-Bancannia Western Plateau CommonwealthofAustralia© MapID: WA_L1_SWMA_28 WaterAustralian Resources 2005 FIGURE A-2. Surface water management areas in Australia Source: Australia National Water Commission.
  • 195. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 71 market activity while protecting environmental values by participating directly in the market, purchasing enti- tlements from willing sellers and dedicating this water to preserve threatened ecosystems and river reaches. This approach has come at great expense to the gov- ernment (and taxpayers) but has been justified by the reported increase in economic activity and benefits arising from trading activity. In a robust assessment of water trading in Victoria’s Murray Valley, Frontier Economics (2007) found strong local opposition to permanently trading water out of local areas, to the extent that some irrigators selling entitlements have been ostracized, but also found a combination of posi- tive and negative socio-economic impacts from such trades. For example, the authors found that trading ameliorated the impacts of the Millennium Drought on dairy farmers in the region, who otherwise would have fared much worse. Additionally, water trading facili- tated the expansion of the wine industry in the region. Several researchers have compiled extensive lists of lessons learned. Two of these are reproduced below. Young (2010) writes: Lesson 1: Unless carefully managed, the legacy of prior licensing decisions can result in markets causing over-allocation problems to emerge in a manner that erodes the health of rivers, aquifer and the water dependent ecosystems associated with them. Lesson 2: Transaction and administrative costs are lower when entitlements are defined using a unit share structure and not as an entitlement to a volume of water. One of the simplest ways of pre- venting over-allocation problems from emerging is to assign the risks of adverse climate change and/ or the emergence of long dry periods to entitlement holders and define entitlements as an entitlement to a share of the water defined as being available for use. Lesson 3: Market efficiency is improved by using separate structures to define entitlements, manage allocations and control the use of water. crops. In response, New South Wales and Victoria have imposed restrictions on the volume of water that may be exported from the state (Grafton and Horne 2014). Enabling conditions A large number of necessary and enabling conditions help explain Australia’s water trading success. Key among these is the development of a proportional water sharing regime, in which the state, rather than administrative or water courts, determines total annual water availability, rather than granting rights holders an absolute or priority-based right to a fixed volume of water. The Australian experience also shows that water trading is more active when allocation pools encompass a large number of entitlement holders with a diverse range of uses (Young, 2010). Grafton and Horne (2014) found that infrastructure, such as dams and canals, can facilitate water trading by storing water until needed and providing conveyances to deliver where needed. Similarly, access to accurate and timely information on water prices and availability facilitates water trading. In Australia, brokerage-type water banks are active in both the Murray-Darling Basin and in northern Victoria, where the banks post informa- tion about pricing and availability (O’Donnell and Colby 2010). Underpinning this information exchange is an extensive, credible, verifiable registry of entitlements and allocations and mechanism to quickly record, measure and monitor trades, as well as sufficient sanctions on those violating agreements (Connor and Kaczan 2013). Lessons learned Connor and Kaczan highlighted the classic dilemma facing those attempting to implement a water trading system: the tradeoff between protecting third parties with high transaction costs versus promoting trades with low transaction costs, with less concern for third parties. Australia has adopted the latter approach, choosing to minimize transaction costs and promote
  • 196. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT72 Lesson 11: Water use and investment will be more efficient if all users are exposed to at least the full lower bound cost and preferably the upper bound cost of supplying water to them. One way of achieving this outcome is to transfer ownership of the supply system to these users. Lesson 12: Manage environmental externalities using separate instruments so that the costs of avoiding them are reflected in the costs of produc- tion and use in a manner that encourages water users to avoid creating them. Lesson 13: Removal of administrative impediments to inter-regional trade and inter-state trade is difficult but necessary for the development of efficient water markets. Australia has taken the approach of ap- pointing an independent agency to develop rules designed to remove unnecessary barriers to water trade. Amongst other things, this has required the setting of guidelines that prevent water supply companies from setting charges and adopting practices that discriminate against people who wish to trade water out of a region. Lesson 14: Markets will be more efficient and the volume of trade greater if entitlements are allocated to individual users rather than to irrigator controlled water supply companies and cooperatives. Whilst opposed by water supply companies and coopera- tives, it is the Australian experience that willingness to trade and market depth typically is much greater when entitlements are allocated to individuals rather than to water supply companies or associations as they are called in other countries. The reason for this is that when allocations are issued to individu- als they do not have to obtain the permission of the board of a water supply company or association to sell water out of a region. Lesson 15: Equity and fairness principles require careful attention to and discipline in the way that allocation decisions and policy changes are announced. Lesson 16: Water markets are more effective when information about the prices being paid and offered is made available to all participants in a timely manner. Lesson 4: Early attention to the development of accurate license registers is critical and a necessary precondition to the development of low-cost entitle- ment trading systems. Lesson 5: Unless water market and allocation pro- cedures allow unused water to be carried forward from year to year, trading may increase the severity of droughts. Lesson 6: Early installation of meters and conver- sion from area based licenses to a volumetric man- agement system is a necessary precursor to the development of low cost allocation trading systems. Metering and conversion to a volumetric allocation system is a necessary precursor to the development of efficient water trading systems. In order to facili- tate the more efficient management of the available resource and trading, Australia has spent many years converting area-based licenses to volumetric licenses and installing meters. Typically, conversion involves estimation of the amount of water used by crop type and the development of conversion factors. Lesson 7: It is difficult for communities to plan for an adverse climate shift and develop water sharing plans that deal adequately with a climatic shift to a drier regime. More robust planning and water en- titlement systems are needed. Lesson 8: The allocation regime for the provision of water necessary to maintain minimum flows, provide for conveyance and cover evaporative losses need to be more secure than that used to allocate water for environmental and other purposes. Lesson 9: Unless all forms of water use are accounted for entitlement reliability will be eroded by expansion of un-metered uses like plantation forestry and farm dam development, increases in ir- rigation efficiency, etc. and place the integrity of the allocation system at risk. Lesson 10: Unless connected ground and surface water systems are managed as a single integrated resource, groundwater development will reduce the amount of water available that can be allocated to surface water users.
  • 197. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 73 7. Statutory rights offer flexibility but carry risks - can be modified without recourse to the courts. Developments to unbundle water rights have facili- tated trade. A potential downside of statutory rights is sovereign risk, or the possibility that the value of existing water rights can be degraded by changes in regulation and discretionary behaviour by state governments. 8. Markets can promote environmental outcomes - Trading should always be subject to a public interest test. Where there are important public interests, such as flow volumes at key locations or the need to ensure minimum levels of water quality, trade may need to be constrained for environmental reasons. An example of this approach is the Basin Salinity Management Strategy that seeks to reduce salinity: actions that reduce salinity are treated as credits and actions that increase salinity as debits on state salinity registers. 9. Acquiring water for the environment through buybacks has proved effective. 10. Prices contain information on scarcity and risk. 11. Basin-wide and local perspectives have roles to play – local input can also prevent or undermine the emergence of strong water markets. … Governments need to see through short-term and some-times parochial interests to facilitate optimal use in the longer term. 12. Effective monitoring and control of extractions are critical for sustainability – Farmers made substantial investments to increase their on-farm retention of water that might otherwise have flowed to the Basin’s streams and rivers. Similarly, ground- water extractions increased by about half over the period 2000–2001 to 2007–2008 (from about 1 MAF to 1.4 MAF) as market users sought access to other cost effective water supplies. Lesson 17: Develop brokering industry and avoid government involvement in the provision of water brokering services. GRAFTON AND HORNE (2014) WRITE: 1. Crises may facilitate reform - As the focus on the crisis fades, so may do the reform zeal. This ‘stop and go’ reform process suggests that determination is required to make consistent progress, but that a crisis can facilitate reform. 2. Water markets support regional resilience - The geographical distribution of markets has meant these benefits have been concentrated in areas of greatest connectivity of the resource (the southern Murray-Darling Basin) where there is also the widest cross-section of users. An example is the signifi- cance of selling water by opportunistic commodity producers (such as rice growers) to perennial crop producers (such as citrus growers). 3. Political and administrative leadership is critical - This involves teams with a range of skills, much broader than the engineering-based specialists that have traditionally managed water resources. 4. Capping extractions promotes effective use and sustainability - any cap should be comprehen- sive and all water sources should be included to avoid substitution to uncontrolled or inadequately measured sources. 5. Regulated water framework facilitates water trading - entitlements delivered via regulated water storages account for about 90 percent of the water entitlements traded in the Southern MDB. 6. Reliable, accessible and timely market informa- tion promotes effective decision-making - the Australian government is investing over half a billion Australian dollars in improved water information and regulations.
  • 198. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT74 Payment for ecosystem services (PES) – an incen- tive-based instrument that seeks to translate external, non-market values of environment services into financial incentives for local actors to provide such services. In practical terms, PES involves a series of payments to a land or resource manager in exchange for a guaranteed flow of environmental services. Payment for watershed services (PWS) – a type of PES arrangement that is focused on watershed services. Water bank – may refer to the physical storage of water, typically in a reservoir or an aquifer, to an institution that facilitates or brokers a water transfer or serves as an information clearinghouse, or to any agency that holds water rights in trust for a specified purpose such as streamflow augmentation. Water market – Often used interchangeably with water transfer, a water market can also refer to informal transactions involving the sale of water, e.g. from water tankers, that do not involve the lease or sale of water rights or concessions. Water option – a type of conditional water transfer. Under dry-year options a buyer will pay the seller an annual fee to be able to exercise an option to purchase a pre-determined volume of water under a specific set of circumstances. Water transfer – a change in the point of diversion, type of use, or location of water use. May refer to a temporary or permanent exchange of water rights (see water market), or to a non-market conveyance of water from one location to another. Aquifer – an underground layer of water-bearing materials, such as sandstone or gravel or other permeable material. Command-and-control regulation – an environmental regulatory policy that is often contrasted with “incentive- based mechanisms” in the literature. A command and control (CAC) regulation can be defined as the direct regulation of an industry or activity that states what is permitted and what is illegal. Economic Efficiency – generally, a state or condition with optimal resource use, allocation, or productivity. May or may not be consistent with equity considerations. Equity – refers to fairness, justice, impartiality, such as in the allocation of resources or treatment of different classes of people. May or may not be consistent with economic efficiency considerations. Eutrophication – excessive richness of nutrients in a lake or other body of water, frequently due to runoff from the land, which causes a dense growth of plant life and death of animal life from lack of oxygen. Incentive-based instrument – a broad set of tools that use financial means, directly or indirectly, to motivate re- sponsible parties to reduce the health and environmental risks posed by their facilities, processes, or products. Nonpoint source (NPS) pollution – water pollution from diffuse sources such as runoff from urbanized areas or farm fields. Nutrients – nitrogen or phosphorus-containing water pollutants that can cause water quality problems. See eutrophication. Paper water – the legal right to use a given volume of water, contrasted with “wet” or “real” water. In many basins, more paper water exists than wet water. Glossary INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT74
  • 199. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 75 Bennett, G. N. Carroll. 2014. “Gaining Depth: State of Wa- tershed Investment 2014.” Forest Trends, Ecosystem Marketplace. Available at forest-trends.org/documents/ files/SOWI2014.pdf. Beverage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER). 2015. “Performance in Watershed Context Concept Paper.” Bev- erage Industry Environmental Roundtable (BIER). http:// www.bieroundtable.com/#!/c16n5. Bjornlund, H. J. McKay. 2002. “Aspects of Water Markets for Developing Countries: Experiences from Australia, Chile, and the US.” Environment and Development Eco- nomics 7 (04). doi:10.1017/S1355770X02000463. Bond, I., and J. Mayers. 2010. “Fair Deals for Watershed Ser- vices: Lessons from a Multi-Country Action-Learning Project.” No. 13. Natural Resources Issues. London, UK: International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at pubs.iied.org/pdfs/13535IIED.pdf. Brewer, J., R. Glennon, A. Ker G.D. Libecap. 2007. “Water Markets in the West: Prices, Trading, and Contractual Forms.” National Bureau of Economic Research. Brooks, D.B. 2006. “An Operational Definition of Water De- mand Management.” Intenational Journal of Water Re- sources Development 22 (4): 521–28. Brouwer, R., A. Tesfaye P. Pauw. 2011. “Meta-Analysis of Institutional-Economic Factors Explaining the Environ- mental Performance of Payments for Watershed Ser- vices.” Environmental Conservation 38 (04): 380–92. doi:10.1017/S0376892911000543. Brown, C., U. Lall F.A. Souza Filho. 2015. “Allocating Water in a Changing World: Incentive-Based Mechanisms for Climate Adaptation.” Calvache, A., S. Benitez A. Ramos. 2012. “Fondo de Agua: Conservando La Infraestructura Verde. Guia de Diseno, Creacio, Y Operacion.” Bogota, Columbia: The Nature Conservancy, Fundacion FEMSA, y Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo. Available at conservationgateway.org/ Documents/LAWFP-ENG-low-050312_0.pdf. Carpenter, S.R., E.H. Stanley M. J. Vander Zanden. 2011. “State of the World’s Freshwater Ecosystems: Physical, Chemical, and Biological Changes.” Annual Review of Environment and Resources 36 (1): 75–99. doi:10.1146/ annurev-environ-021810-094524. CDP. 2014. “From Water Risk to Value Creation, CDP Global Water Report 2014.” CDP. Available at cdp.net/CDPRe- sults/CDP-Global-Water-Report-2014.pdf. Albiac, J., M. Hanemann, J. Calatrava, J. Uche J. Tapia. 2006. “The Rise and Fall of the Ebro Water Transfer.” Natural Resources Journal 46: 729–57. Alix-Garcia, J., A. de Janvry, E. Sadoulet J. Manuel. 2009. “Lessons Learned from Mexico’s Payment for Environ- mental Services Program.” In Payment for Environmental Services in Agricultural Landscapes, edited by Leslie Lip- per, Takumi Sakuyama, Randy Stringer, and David Zilber- man, 163–88. Natural Resource Management and Policy 31. Springer New York. Available at link.springer.com/ chapter/10.1007/978-0-387-72971-8_8. Al-Marshudi, A.S. 2007. “The Falaj Irrigation System and Water Allocation Markets in Northern Oman.” Agricul- tural Water Management 91 (1–3): 71–77. doi:10.1016/j. agwat.2007.04.008. Ambec, S., A. Dinar D. McKinney. 2013. “Water Sharing Agreements Sustainable to Reduced Flows.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 66 (3): 639–55. doi:10.1016/j.jeem.2013.06.003. Anderson, R.C. 2004. “International Experiences with Economic Incentives for Protecting the Environment.” EPA-236-R-04-001. Washington, DC: US Environmental Protection Agency, National Center for Environmental Economics. Available at yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/eerm. nsf/vwAN/EE-0487-01.pdf/$file/EE-0487-01.pdf. Appleton, A.F. 2010. “How New York City Used an Ecosystem Services Strategy Carried out through an Urban-Rural Partnership to Preserve the Pristine Quality of Its Drink- ing Water and Save Billions of Dollars.” New York, NY: A Paper for Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarket- place.com/documents/cms_documents/NYC_H2O_Eco- system_Services.pdf. Backeberg, G. 2015. “Water Markets in South Africa,” July 24. Barrett, K. 2015. “A Different Kind of Sale: April Auction Of- fers Stewardship Credits to Meet Sustainability Goals.” Ecosystem Marketplace. February 12. Available at eco- systemmarketplace.com/pages/dynamic/article.page. php?page_id=10792section=news_articleseod=1. Bauer, C.J. 1997. “Bringing Water Markets down to Earth: The Political Economy of Water Rights in Chile, 1976–1995.” World Development 25 (5): 639–56. Bennett, G., N. Carroll K. Hamilton. (2012) Charting New Waters: State of Watershed Payments 2012. Washington, DC: Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarketplace. com/reports/sowp2012. References
  • 200. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT76 at ohchr.org/english/bodies/hrcouncil/docs/18session/A- HRC-18-33-Add4_en.pdf. Dellapenna, J. 2000. “The Importance of Getting Names Right: The Myth of Markets for Water.” William Mary Environmental Law and Policy Review 25 (2): 317. Department of Environmental Affairs. 2015. “Social Develop- ment | Department of Environmental Affairs.” Accessed September 10. Available at environment.gov.za/proj- ectsprogrammes/wfw/socialdevelopment. Dillaha, T., P. Ferraro, M. Huang, D. Southgate, S. Upadhyaya S. Wunder. 2007. “Payment for Watershed Services Regional Syntheses.” USAID. Available at sanrem.cals. vt.edu/1010/Dillaha2007_PWS_regional_syntheses.pdf. Dinar, A., M.W. Rosegrant R. Meinzen-Dick. 1997. “Wa- ter Allocation Mechanisms: Principles and Examples.” Policy Research Working Paper Series 1779. The World Bank. Available at econpapers.repec.org/paper/wbkw- brwps/1779.htm. Dinar, A. R.M. Saleth. 2005. “Can Water Institutions Be Cured? A Water Institutions Health Index.” Water Supply 5: 17–40. Dodds, W.K., W.W. Bouska, J.L. Eitzmann, T.J. Pilger, K.L. Pitts, A.J. Riley, J.T. Schloesser D.J. Thornbrugh. 2008. “Eu- trophication of US Freshwaters: Analysis of Potential Eco- nomic Damages.” Environmental Science Technology 43 (1): 12–19. Duhon, M., J. Young S. Kerr. 2011. “Nitrogen Trading in Lake Taupo: An Analysis and Evaluation of an Innovative Water Management Strategy.” In New Zealand Agricultural and Resource Economics Society 2011 Conference. Nelson, New Zealand. Available at ageconsearch.umn.edu/bit- stream/115353/2/Duhon%20Paper.pdf. Easter, K.W., M.W. Rosegrant A. Dinar. 1999. “Formal and Informal Markets for Water: Institutions, Performance, and Constraints.” The World Bank Research Observer 14 (1): 99–116. Ecosystem Marketplace. 2013. “Innovative Markets and Market Like Instruments for Ecosystem Services.” Forest Trends. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.com/docu- ments/acrobat/the_matrix.pdf. ———. 2015. “This Week In Water: The Art Of The Nutrient Credit Sale.” Watershed Connect. February 27. Available at watershedconnect.com/news/this_week_in_water_the_ art_of_the_nutrient_credit_sale_. Electric Power Research Institute (EPRI). 2010. “Program on Technology Innovation: Ohio River Water Quality Trading Pilot Program: Business Case for Power Company Partici- pation.” Available at epri.com/abstracts/Pages/ProductA- bstract.aspx?ProductId=000000000001018861. Clifford, P. 2012. “Water Banking in Washington State: 2012 Report to the Legislature.” Report to Legislature 12-11- 055. Washington State Department of Ecology. https:// fortress.wa.gov/ecy/publications/SummaryPages/1211055. html. Cohen, M.J., J. Christian-Smith J. Berggren. 2013. “Water to Supply the Land: Irrigated Agriculture in the Colorado River Basin.” Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/ publication/water-to-supply-the-land-irrigated-agricul- ture-in-the-colorado-river-basin/. Cohen, M.J. 2014. “Hazard’s Toll: The Costs of Inaction at the Salton Sea.” Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/pub- lication/hazards-toll/. Cohen, M.J. K.H. Hyun. 2006. “Hazard: The Future of the Salton Sea With No Restoration Plan.” Oakland, Calif.: Pa- cific Institute. http://pacinst.org/publication/restoration- project-critical-to-salton-seas-future/. Colby, B.G., M.A. McGinnis K.A. Rait. 1991. “Mitigating Envi- ronmental Externalities through Voluntary and Involun- tary Water Reallocation: Nevada’s Truckee-Carson River Basin.” Natural Resources Journal 31: 757. Coleman, A. 2008. “Farmers to Sue DWAF for Water Rights Transfers.” Farmer’s Weekly, September 12. Conagua. 2012. “Water Banks in Mexico.” National Water Commission. Available at conagua.gob.mx/bancos- delagua/. Connor, J.D. D. Kaczan. 2013. “Principles for Economically Efficient and Environmentally Sustainable Water Mar- kets: The Australian Experience.” In Drought in Arid and Semi-Arid Regions, edited by Kurt Schwabe, Jose Albiac, Jeffery D. Connor, Rashid M. Hassan, and Liliana Meza González, 357–74. Springer Netherlands. Available at dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-6636-5_20. Cosgrove, W.S. F.R. Rijsberman. 2000. “World Water Vision: Making Water Everybody’s Business.” World Water Coun- cil. Available at worldwatercouncil.org/index.php?id=961. Culp, P., R. Glennon G. Libecap. 2014. “Shopping for Wa- ter: How the Market Can Mitigate Water Shortages in the American West.” 2014-05. Discussion Paper. The Brookings Institute. Available at hamiltonproject.org/ files/downloads_and_links/market_mitigate_water_short- age_in_west_paper_glennon_final.pdf. Colorado Water Trust (CWT). 2015. Colorado Water Trust Big Beaver Creek Reservoir / Big Beaver Creek White River. Available at coloradowatertrust.org/our-work/projects/ lake-avery-big-beaver-creek-white-river/#sthash.I3vg- PjZL.dpuf. de Albuquerque, C. 2011. “Special Rapporteur on the Human Right to Safe Drinking Water and Sanitation, Mission to the United States of America.” United Nations. Available
  • 201. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 77 Victorian Murray Valley / Frontier Economics. PANDORA Electronic Collection. Canberra, A.C.T: National Water Com- mission. Available at nla.gov.au/nla.arc-79821. Garrido, A. M.R. Llamas. 2009. “Water Management in Spain: An Example of Changing Paradigms.” Policy and Strategic Behaviour in Water Resource Management 125. Gassert, F., M. Landis, P. Reig, M. Luck T. Shiao. 2013. “Aq- ueduct Metadata Document, Aqueduct Global Maps 2.0.” World Resources Institute (WRI). Available at wri.org/sites/ default/files/pdf/aqueduct_metadata_global.pdf. Genevieve B., N. Carroll, M. Bennett, A. Leonardi K. Moull. 2014. “Gaining Depth: State of Watershed Investment 2014.” Washington, D.C: Forest Trends. Available at.forest- trends.org/documents/files/SOWI2014.pdf. George, A., A. Pierret, A. Boonsaner, V. Christian O. Planchon. 2009. “Potential and Limitations of Payments for Environ- mental Services (PES) as a Means to Manage Watershed Services in Mainland Southeast Asia.” International Jour- nal of the Commons 3 (1): 16–40. Getches, D.H. 1985. “Competing Demands for the Colorado River.” University of Colorado Law Review 56: 413. Gleick, P.H. 2002. “Water Management: Soft Water Paths.” Nature 418: 373. ———. 2003. “Global Freshwater Resources: Soft-Path Solu- tions for the 21st Century.” Science 302 (5650): 1524–28. Gleick, P.H., D. Haasz, C. Henges-Jeck, V. Srinivasan, G. Wolff, K. Kao Cushing A. Mann. 2003. “Waste Not, Want Not: The Potential for Urban Water Conservation in California.” Oakland CA: Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/wp- content/uploads/sites/21/2013/02/waste_not_want_not_ full_report3.pdf. Glennon, R. 2005. “Water Scarcity, Marketing, and Privatiza- tion.” Texas Law Review 83 (7): 1873–1902. Gómez-Baggethun, E., R. de Groot, P.L. Lomas C. Montes. 2010. “The History of Ecosystem Services in Economic Theory and Practice: From Early Notions to Markets and Payment Schemes.” Ecological Economics, Special Sec- tion - Payments for Environmental Services: Reconciling Theory and Practice, 69 (6): 1209–18. doi:10.1016/j.ecole- con.2009.11.007. Grafton, R.Q. J. Horne. 2014. “Water Markets in the Murray- Darling Basin.” Agricultural Water Management 145 (No- vember): 61–71. doi:10.1016/j.agwat.2013.12.001. Grafton, R.Q., C. Landry, G.D. Libecap, S. McGlennon R. O’Brien. 2010. “An Integrated Assessment of Water Mar- kets: Australia, Chile, China, South Africa and the USA.” ICER Working Paper 32-2010. ICER - International Centre for Economic Research. Available at ideas.repec.org/p/icr/ wpicer/32-2010.html. Faeth, P. 2000. Fertile Ground: Nutrient Trading’s Potential to Cost-Effectively Improve Water Quality. Washington, D.C.: World Resources Institute. Available at wri.org/sites/ default/files/pdf/fertile_ground.pdf. Famiglietti, J.S. 2014. “The Global Groundwater Crisis.” Na- ture Climate Change 4: 945–48. Farolfi, St. S. Perret. 2002. “Inter-Sectoral Competition for Water Allocation in Rural South Africa : Analysing a Case Study through a Standard Environmental Economics Approach.” Paper without proceedings Working paper: 2002-23. Department of Agricultural Economics, Exten- sion and Rural Development: University of Pretoria. http:// agritrop.cirad.fr/511263/. Feinglas, S., C. Gray P. Mayer. 2013. “Conservation Helps Limit Rate Increases for a Colorado Utility.” Alliance for Water Efficiency. Available at financingsustainablewater. org/resource-search/conservation-helps-limit-rate- increases-colorado-utility. Ferraro, P.J. 2008. “Asymmetric Information and Contract Design for Payments for Environmental Services.” Eco- logical Economics, Payments for Environmental Services in Developing and Developed Countries, 65 (4): 810–21. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.029. ———. 2009. “Regional Review of Payments for Wa- tershed Services: Sub-Saharan Africa.” Jour- nal of Sustainable Forestry 28 (3-5): 525–50. doi:10.1080/10549810802701234. Fischel, W.A. 1995. Regulatory Takings: Law, Economics, and Politics. Harvard University Press. Fisher-Vanden, K. S. Olmstead. 2013. “Moving Pollution Trading from Air to Water: Potential, Problems, and Prog- nosis.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 147–71. Forest Trends. 2015a. Watershed Connect. Available at wa- tershedconnect.com/ Forest Trends. 2015b. “Paw Paw River Watershed.” Program Inventory. Paw Paw River Watershed. Available at water- shedconnect.com/programs/Paw-Paw-River-Watershed. Fox, J. 2014. “The Role of Trading in Achieving Water Qual- ity Objectives.” presented at the United States House of Representatives, Committee on Transportation and Infrastructure, Subcommittee on Water Resources and Environment, Washington, DC, April 17. Available at wqt. epri.com/pdf/EPRI%20Testimony%20WQT%20Final%20 4-17-14.pdf. Freyfogle, E.T. 1996. “Water Rights and the Commonwealth.” Environmental Law 26: 27. Frontier Economics, and Australia National Water Commis- sion. 2007. The Economic and Social Impacts of Water Trading [electronic Resource] : Case Studies in the
  • 202. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT78 rent Initiatives.” Journal of Sustainable Forestry 28 (3-5): 551–75. doi:10.1080/10549810902794287. Huber, R.M., J. Ruitenbeek R.S. da Motta. 1998. “Market- Based Instruments for Environmental Policymaking in Latin America and the Caribbean - Lessons from Eleven Countries.” WDP381. The World Bank. Available at docu- ments.worldbank.org/curated/en/1998/11/438776/market- based-instruments-environmental-policymaking-latin- america-caribbean-lessons-eleven-countries. Hundley, N., Jr. 2001. The Great Thirst: Californians and Water—A History, Revised Edition. 2001 (revised). Un- versity of California Press. Available at ucpress.edu/book. php?isbn=9780520224568. International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED). 2015. Watershed Markets. Available at watershed- markets.org/ Jenkins, M.W., J.R. Lund, R.E. Howitt, A.J. Draper, S.M. Msangi, S.K. Tanaka, R.S. Ritzema G.F. Marques. 2004. “Optimi- zation of California’s Water Supply System: Results and Insights.” Journal of Water Resources Planning and Management 130 (4): 271–80. doi:10.1061/(ASCE)0733- 9496(2004)130:4(271). Jones, C., E. Branosky, M. Selman M. Perez. 2010. “How Nu- trient Trading Could Help Restore the Chesapeake Bay.” Washington, DC: World Resources Institute. Available at wri.org/working_papers/how_nutrient_trading_could_ help_restore_the_chesapeake_bay.pdf. Karousakis, K. Q. Brooke. 2010. Paying for Biodiversity: Enhancing the Cost-Effectiveness of Payments for Eco- system Services. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development. Available at oecd-ilibrary. org/content/book/9789264090279-en. Kenny, A. 2006. “Ecosystem Marketplace - Ecosystem Ser- vices in the New York City Watershed.” Ecosystem Mar- ketplace. Available at ecosystemmarketplace.com/pages/ dynamic/article.page.php?page_id=4130section=home. Koplow, D. 2004. The Use of Economic Instruments in Envi- ronmental Policy: Opportunties and Challenges. United Nations Environment Programme. Available at unep.ch/ etb/publication/EconInst/econInstruOppChnaFin.pdf. Kosoy, N., M. Martinez-Tuna, R. Muradian J. Martinez-Alier. 2007. “Payments for Environmental Services in Water- sheds: Insights from a Comparative Study of Three Cases in Central America.” Ecological Economics 61 (2–3): 446–55. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.03.016. Los Angeles Department of Water and Power (LA DWP). 2013. “Owens Lake Master Project.” Los Angeles, CA: Los Angeles Department of Water and Power. Available at ladwp.com/ladwp/faces/ladwp/aboutus/a-water/a-w- losangelesaqueduct/a-w-laa-owenslake. Grafton, R.Q., G. Libecap, E. Edwards, R O’Brien C. Landry. 2012. “Comparative Assessment of Water Markets: In- sights from the Murray-Darling Basin of Australia and the Western USA.” Water Policy 14: 175–93. Greiber, T., ed. 2009. Payments for Ecosystem Services: Le- gal and Institutional Frameworks. IUCN Environmental Policy and Law Paper, No. 78. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN, in collaboration with the IUCN Environmental Law Centre, Bonn, Germany. Available at cmsdata.iucn.org/downloads/ eplp_78_1.pdf. Hanak, E. E. Stryjewski. 2012. “California’s Water Market, By the Numbers: Update 2012.” Public Policy Institute of California. Available at wee.ppic.org/content/pubs/ report/R_1112EHR.pdf. Harrington, W. R.D. Morgenstern. 2004. “Economic Incen- tives Versus Command and Control: What’s the Best Ap- proach for Solving Environmental Problems?” Resources for the Future. Available at rff.org/Publications/Resources/ Documents/152/RFF_Resources_152_ecoincentives.pdf. Hauter, W. 2013. “D.C. District Court Fails on Pollution Trad- ing: Clean Water Act Trading Lawsuit Dismissed Due to Burden of Proof.” Food and Water Watch. December 16. Available at foodandwaterwatch.org/pressreleases/d-c- district-court-fails-on-pollution-trading-clean-water-act- trading-lawsuit-dismissed-due-to-burden-of-proof/. Hawkins, S. 2011. “Laying the Foundation: An Analytical Tool for Assessing Legal and Institutional Readiness for PES.” Forest Trends. Available at forest-trends.org/documents/ files/doc_3014.pdf. Heberger, M., H. Cooley P.H. Gleick. 2014. “Urban Water Conservation and Efficiency Potential in California.” Oak- land, CA: Pacific Institute. Available at pacinst.org/wp- content/uploads/sites/21/2014/06/ca-water-urban.pdf. Howe, C.W. 2011. “The Efficient Water Market of the Northern Colorado Water Conservancy. District: Colorado, USA.” IBE Review reports CS22. WP6 IBE EX-POST Case Stud- ies. EPI Water. Available at feem-project.net/epiwater/ docs/d32-d6-1/CS22_Colorado.pdf. Howe, C.W. C. Goemans. 2003. “Water Transfers and Their Impacts: Lessons from Three Colorado Water Markets.” JAWRA Journal of the American Water Resources Association 39 (5): 1055–65. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2003. tb03692.x. Howitt, R.E. 1998. “Spot Prices, Option Prices, and Water Markets: An Analysis of Emerging Markets in California.” In Markets for Water, edited by K. William Easter, Mark W. Rosegrant, and Ariel Dinar, 119–40. Natural Resource Management and Policy 15. Springer US. Huang, M., S.K. Upadhyaya, R. Jindal J. Kerr. 2009. “Pay- ments for Watershed Services in Asia: A Review of Cur-
  • 203. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 79 Moench, M., A. Dixit, S. Janakarajan, M.S. Rathore S. Mudra- kartha. 2003. The Fluid Mosaic: Water Governance in the Context of Variability, Uncertainty and Change: A Synthesis Paper. Nepal Water Conservation Foundation, Kathmandu, and the Institute for Social and Environmen- tal Transition, Boulder, Colorado, US. Moore, R.H. 2012. “Reaching the Potential of Water-Quality Trading.” In Water Sustainability in Agriculture, 73–81. Ithaca, New York: National Agriculutural Biotechnology Council. Available at nabc.cals.cornell.edu/Publications/ Reports/nabc_24/24_2_1_Moore.pdf. Morgan, C. A. Wolverton. 2005. “Water Quality Trading in the United States.” 05-07. Working Paper. National Cen- ter for Environmental Economics. Available at yosemite. epa.gov/ee/epa/eed.nsf/be6bc67216ab9f5d85256e460 07b104d/3e026cbb6a9956918525702f005e383c/$FI LE/2005-07.pdf. MOTU. 2009. “Lake Rotorua Short Films.” Motu Economic and Public Policy Research. Available at motu.org.nz/ research/detail/rotorua_films. Muñoz-Piña, C., A. Guevara, J.M. Torres J. Braña. 2008. “Paying for the Hydrological Services of Mexico’s Forests: Analysis, Negotiations and Results.” Ecological Econom- ics, Payments for Environmental Services in Developing and Developed Countries, 65 (4): 725–36. doi:10.1016/j. ecolecon.2007.07.031. Naeem, S., J. C. Ingram, A. Varga, T. Agardy, P. Barten, G. Ben- nett, E. Bloomgarden, et al., 2015. “Get the Science Right When Paying for Nature’s Services.” Science 347 (6227): 1206–7. doi:10.1126/science.aaa1403. National Fish and Wildlife Foundation. 2014. “FY 2013 Annual Report: Columbia Basin Water Transactions Program.” Portland, Oregon: National Fish and Wildlife Foundation. Available at cbwtp.org/jsp/cbwtp/library/documents/ NLB_CBWTP_Annual13_R8.pdf. National Research Council. 1968. Water and Choice in the Colorado Basin: An Example of Alternatives in Water Management: A Report. National Academies. ———. 1992. Water Transfers in the West:: Efficiency, Eq- uity, and the Environment. National Academies Press. Neef, A. D. Thomas. 2009. “Rewarding the Upland Poor for Saving the Commons? Evidence from Southeast Asia.” International Journal of the Commons 3 (1): 1–15. Newburn, D.A. R.T. Woodward. 2012. “An Ex Post Evalu- ation of Ohio’s Great Miami Water Quality Trading Program1.” JAWRA Journal of the American Water Resources Association 48 (1): 156–69. doi:10.1111/j.1752- 1688.2011.00601.x. Raes, L. P. Mohebalian. 2013. “The Socio Bosque Pro- gram for Rainforest and Paramo Conservation, Ecuado.” Geneva Switzerland: The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity. Available at teebweb.org/wp-content/ uploads/2014/07/The-Socio-Bosque-Programme-for- rainforest-and-Paramo-Conservation-Ecuador-.pdf. Leflaive, X., M. Witmer, R. Martin-Hurtado, M. Bakker, T. Kram, L. Bouwman, H. Visser, A. Bouwman, H. Hilderink K. Kim. 2012. “Water.” In OECD Environmental Outlook, 275–332. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Available at oecd-ilibrary.org/content/ chapter/env_outlook-2012-8-en. Levine, G., R. Barker C.C. Huang. 2007. “Water Transfer from Agriculture to Urban Uses: Lessons Learned, with Policy Considerations.” Paddy and Water Environment 5 (4): 213–22. doi:10.1007/s10333-007-0092-8. LimnoTech The Nature Conservancy. 2013. “Quantifying Replenish Benefits in Community Water Partnership Projects, Final Report for 2012.” The Coca-Cola Com- pany. Available at assets.coca-colacompany.com/2f/cb/ e5d2ca1e4c58a38adbe8586d06db/final-quanitification- report-water-pdf.pdf. Livingston, M.L. 1998. “Institutional Requisites for Efficient Water Markets.” In Markets for Water: Potential and Per- formance, 19–33. Springer. Available at link.springer.com/ chapter/10.1007/978-0-585-32088-5_2. Lovins, A. 1977. Soft energy paths: Toward a durable peace. Ballinger Publishing Co., Cambridge, Massachusetts, US. Marida, P. 2010. “Ohio’s Water Quality Trading Programs - To Be Taken Over by Coal?” The Ohio Sierran, A Publica- tion of the Ohio Chapter of the Sierra Club. Mariola, M.J. 2009. “Are Markets the Solution to Water Pollu- tion? A Sociological Investigation of Water Quality Trad- ing.” Ph.D. Dissertation, Columbus, Ohio: The Ohio State University. Available at rave.ohiolink.edu/etdc/view?acc_ num=osu1250015222. Medellín-Azuara, J., J.J. Harou, M.A. Olivares, K. Madani, J.R. Lund, R.E. Howitt, S.K. Tanaka, M.W. Jenkins T. Zhu. 2008. “Adaptability and Adaptations of California’s Water Supply System to Dry Climate Warming.” Climatic Change 87 (1): 75–90. Meinzen-Dick, R. R. Pradhan. 2005. “Recognizing Multiple Water Uses in Intersectoral Water Transfers.” In Asian Irrigation in Transition: Responding to Challenges, 178– 205. Asian Institute of Technology, Bangkok, Thailand. Richards, M. 2013. “What Do We Know about Gender and Other Social Impacts of IWS Projects?: A Literature Re- view.” Forest Trends. Available at forest-trends.org/docu- ments/files/doc_4089.pdf.
  • 204. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT80 Porras, I., B. Aylward J. Dengel. 2013. “Monitoring Pay- ments for Watershed Services Schemes in Developing Countries.” London, UK: International Institute for Envi- ronment and Development. Available at pubs.iied.org/ pdfs/16525IIED.pdf. Porras, I., D.N. Barton, A. Chacon-Cascante M. Miranda. 2013. “Learning from 20 Years of Payments for Ecosys- tem Services in Costa Rica.” London, UK: International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at pubs.iied.org/pdfs/16514IIED.pdf. Porras, I. N. Neves. 2006a. “China - Sloping Lands Con- version Programme.” Markets for Watershed Services - Country Profile. International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at watershedmarkets.org/ documents/China_SLCP_eng.pdf. ———. 2006b. “Mexico - National PSAH Programme.” Mar- ket for Watershed Services - Country Profile. International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at watershedmarkets.org/documents/Mexico_National_ PSAH_eng.pdf. Porras, I.T., M. Grieg-Gran N. Neves. 2008. All That Glit- ters: A Review of Payments for Watershed Services in Developing Countries. IIED. Available at pubs.iied.org/ pdfs/13542IIED.pdf. Postel, S.L., G.C. Daily P.R. Ehrlich. 1996. “Appropriation of Renewable Fresh Water.” Science 271 (5250): 785–88. Queensland Water Commission. 2010. “South East Queensland Water Strategy 2010.” 29229. Queensland Water Commission. Available at qwc.qld.gov.au. Ravnborg, H.M., M.G. Damsgaard K. Raben. 2007. “Pay- ments for Ecosystem Services - Issues and Pro-Poor Opportunities for Development Assistance.” Copenhagen, Denmark: Danish Institute for International Studies. Reimers, F. 2013. “Shifting Ground.” Nature Conservancy, June. Rockefeller Foundation. 2013. Key Factors Supporting Small- Scale Coastal Fisheries Management. Romano, D. M. Leporati. 2002. “The Distributive Impact of the Water Market in Chile: A Case Study in Limari Province, 1981- 1997.” Quarterly Journal of International Agriculture 41 (1): 41–58. Rozza, J.P., B.D. Richter, W.M. Larson, T. Redder, K. Vigerstol P. Bowen P. 2013. “Corporate Water Stewardship: Achiev- ing a Sustainable Balance.” Journal of Management and Sustainability 3 (4). Available at dx.doi.org/10.5539/jms. v3n4p41. Newlin, B.D., M.W. Jenkins, J.R. Lund R.E. Howitt. 2002. “Southern California Water Markets: Potential and Limita- tions.” Journal of Water Resources Planning and Man- agement 128 (1): 21–32. NSWDEC. 2003. Hunter River Salinity Trading Scheme: Working Together to Protect River Quality and Sustain Economic Development. Sydney, Australia: Department of Environment and Conservation, New South Wales. Available at epa.nsw.gov.au/resources/licensing/hrsts/ hrsts.pdf. NWC. 2013. Australian National Water Commission Markets Report 2012-2013. Canberra. Available at nwc.gov.au/pub- lications/topic/water-industry/australian-water-markets- report-2012-13. O’Donnell, M. B. Colby. 2010. “Water Banks: A Tool for En- hancing Water Supply Reliability.” Guidebook. University of Arizona. Available at ag.arizona.edu/arec/pubs/faculty- pubs/ewsr-Banks-final-5-12-10.pdf. O’Grady, D. 2011. “Sociopolitical Conditions for Success- ful Water Quality Trading in the South Nation River Watershed, Ontario, Canada1.” JAWRA Journal of the American Water Resources Association 47 (1): 39–51. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2010.00511.x. Olszowa, D.M., J.P. Heath P.A. Tennant. 1998. “Evalua- tion of Nutrient Loads and Sources in the Ohio River Basin.” In . Ohio River Valley Water Sanitation Com- mission (ORSANCO). http://acwi.gov/monitoring/ conference/98proceedings/Papers/54-OLSZ.html. Pagiola, S. 2008. “Payments for Environmental Services in Costa Rica.” Ecological Economics, Payments for Envi- ronmental Services in Developing and Developed Coun- tries, 65 (4): 712–24. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.033. Pagiola, S., A. Arcenas G. Platais. 2005. “Can Payments for Environmental Services Help Reduce Poverty? An Explo- ration of the Issues and the Evidence to Date from Latin America.” World Development, Institutional arrange- ments for rural poverty reduction and resource conserva- tion, 33 (2): 237–53. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.011. Pant, D., M. Bhattarai G. Basnet. 2008. “Implications Of Bulk Water Transfer On Local Water Management Institutions: A Case Study of the Melamchi Water Supply Project in Nepal.” Working Paper 78. Consultative Group on Interna- tional Agricultural Research (CGIAR). Available at indiae- nvironmentportal.org.in/files/capriwp78.pdf. Perrot-Maitre, D. 2006. “The Vittel Payments for Ecosystem Services: A ‘Perfect’ PES Case?” London, UK: International Institute for Environment and Development. Available at katoombagroup.org/~katoomba/documents/tools/ TheVittelpaymentsforecosystemservices.pdf.
  • 205. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT 81 Thobani, M. 1997. “Formal Water Markets: Why, When, and How to Introduce Tradable Water Rights.” World Bank Research Observer 12 (2): 161–79. TWSST, 2014. Transforming water scarcity through trading, 2012–2015, Final report. United Nations. 2009. “World Water Development Report 3: Water in a Changing World.” Available at webworld.unes- co.org/water/wwap/wwdr/wwdr3/tableofcontents.shtml. ———. 2012. “World Water Development Report 4: Managing Water under Uncertainty and Risk.” Paris, France: United Nations. http://unesdoc.unesco.org/ images/0021/002156/215644e.pdf. UNEP. 2009. “Training Resource Manual: The Use of Eco- nomic Instruments for Environmental and Natural Re- source Management.” Available at unep.ch/etb/publica- tions/EI%20manual%202009/Training%20Resource%20 Manual.pdf. UNEP. 2004. “The Use of Economic Instruments in Environ- mental Policy: Opportunities and Challenges.” Available at unep.ch/etb/publication/EconInst/econInstruOppCh- naFin.pdf. US Bureau of Reclamation. 2015. “Moving Forward, Phase 1 Report.” Bureau of Reclamation, US Department of the In- terior. Available at usbr.gov/lc/region/programs/crbstudy/ MovingForward/Phase1Report.html. US Census Bureau. 2012. “The Statistical Abstract of the United States, Table 435: State and Local Governments- -Summary of Finances.” Washington, DC. Available at census.gov/compendia/statab/2012/tables/12s0435.pdf. US EPA. 2001. “The United States Experiences with Eco- nomic Incentives for Protecting the Environment.” EPA- 240-R-01-001. Available at yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/ eerm.nsf/vwAN/EE-0216B-13.pdf/$file/EE-0216B-13.pdf. US EPA. 2003. “Final Water Quality Trading Policy.” January 13. http://water.epa.gov/type/watersheds/trading/finalpo- licy2003.cfm. ———. 2009. “Steam Electric Power Generation Point Source Category: Final Detailed Study Report.” United States Environmental Protection Agency. Available at water.epa.gov/scitech/wastetech/guide/steam-electric/ upload/Steam-Electric_Detailed-Study-Report_2009.pdf. ———. 2010. “How Water Quality (Nutrient) Trading Enables Alpine Cheese Company to Improve Water Quality and Increase Economic Development in the Region.” US. Available at water.epa.gov/type/watersheds/named/ms- basin/oh_03.cfm. Ruppert, T.K. 2004. “Water Quality Trading and Agricultural Nonpoint Source Pollution: An Analysis of the Effective- ness and Fairness of EPA’s Policy on Water Quality Trad- ing.” Villanova Environmental Law Journal 15: 1. Salzman, J. 2006. “Thirst: A Short History of Drinking Water.” Yale Journal of Law and the Humanities 17 (3). Avail- able at lsr.nellco.org/duke_fs/31. Schmalensee, R R.N. Stavins. 2013. “The SO2 Allowance Trading System: The Ironic History of a Grand Policy Experiment.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 27 (1): 103–22. doi:10.1257/jep.27.1.103. Sharma, S.K. K. Vairavamoorthy. 2009. “Urban Water De- mand Management: Prospects and Challenges for the Developing Countries.” Water and Environment Journal 23 (3): 210–18. doi:10.1111/j.1747-6593.2008.00134.x. Shortle, J.S. R.D. Horan. 2005. “Water Quality Trading.” Penn State Environmental Law Review 14: 231. ———. 2008. “The Economics of Water Quality Trading.” International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics 2 (2): 101–33. Smith, S., P. Rowcroft, M. Everard, L. Couldrick, M. Reed, H. Rogers, T. Quick, C. Eves C. White. 2013. “Payments for Ecosystem Services: A Best Practice Guide.” Defra, London: Department for Environment, Food, and Rural Affairs. Available at gov.uk/government/uploads/system/ uploads/attachment_data/file/200920/pb13932-pes- bestpractice-20130522.pdf. Stacey, P.E., T. Haze I. Raffa. 2012. “Meeting the Nitrogen Wasteload Allocation in Connecticut: Connecticut’s Nitro- gen Credit Exchange After 10 Years of Operation as the Nation’s Most Significant Water Quality Trading Program.” presented at the 36th annual Meeting of the New Eng- land Association of Environmental Biologists, Falmouth, Massachusetts, March 22. Available at epa.gov/region1/ neaeb2012/pdfs/0930_BR2_PaulStacey.pdf. Stanton, T., M. Echavarria, K. Hamilton C. Ott. 2010. “State of Watershed Payments: An Emerging Marketplace.” Ecosystem Marketplace. Available at watershedconnect. com/documents/files/state_of_watershed_payments_an_ emerging_marketplace.pdf. Stavins, R.N. 2001. “Experience with Market-Based Environ- mental Policy Instruments.” Resources for the Future. Available at rff.org/documents/rff-dp-01-58.pdf. Tarlock, A.D. 2014. “Mexico and the United States Assume a Legal Duty to Provide Colorado River Delta Restoration Flows: An Important International Environmental and Water Law Precedent.” Review of European, Compara- tive International Environmental Law 23 (1): 76–87. doi:10.1111/reel.12066.
  • 206. INCENTIVE-BASED INSTRUMENTS FOR WATER MANAGEMENT82 Worster, D. 1985. Rivers of Empire: Water, Aridity, and the Growth of the American West. Oxford University Press. Wunder, S. 2005. “Payments for Environmental Services: Some Nuts and Bolts.” CIFOR Occasional Paper No. 42. Jakarta, Indonesia: Center for Internatioanl Forestry Re- search. Available at theredddesk.org/sites/default/files/ resources/pdf/2012/payment-ecosystem-services-02.pdf. ———. 2008. “Payments for Environmental Services and the Poor: Concepts and Preliminary Evidence.” Environ- ment and Development Economics 13 (03): 279–97. doi:10.1017/S1355770X08004282. Young, M.D. 2010. “Environmental Effectiveness and Eco- nomic Efficiency of Water Use in Agriculture: The Experi- ence of and Lessons from the Australian Water Reform Programme.” Background Report. Sustainable Manage- ment of Water Resources in Agriculture. OECD. Available at dx.doi.org/10.1787/786732081512. Young, M. 2015. “Tricks of the Trade: Learning From Austra- lia’s Water Reform Experience.” Waterfront 1 (1): 10–12. Zbinden, S. D.R. Lee. 2005. “Paying for Environmental Ser- vices: An Analysis of Participation in Costa Rica’s PSA Program.” World Development, Institutional arrange- ments for rural poverty reduction and resource conserva- tion, 33 (2): 255–72. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.012. Zedler, J.B. S. Kercher. 2005. “WETLAND RESOURCES: Status, Trends, Ecosystem Services, and Restorability.” Annual Review of Environment and Resources 30 (1): 39–74. doi:10.1146/annurev.energy.30.050504.144248. Zellmer, S.B. J. Harder. 2007. “Unbundling Property in Water.” Alabama Law Review 59: 679. Zucchino, D. 2015. “Duke Energy Fined $102 Million for Pol- luting Rivers with Coal Ash.” Los Angeles Times, May 14. Available at latimes.com/nation/la-na-duke-energy-coal- ash-20150514-story.html#page=1. Zwarteveen, M.Z. 1997. “Water: From Basic Need to Com- modity: A Discussion on Gender and Water Rights in the Context of Irrigation.” World Development 25 (8): 1335–49. Wada, Y., L.P.H. van Beek, C.M. van Kempen, J.W.T.M. Reck- man, S. Vasak M.F.P. Bierkens. 2010. “Global Depletion of Groundwater Resources.” Geophysical Research Letters 37 (20): L20402. doi:10.1029/2010GL044571. Wallace, K.H. 2007. “Trading Pollution for Water Quality: Assessing the Effects of Market-Based Instruments in Three Basins.” Master’s Thesis, Cambridge, Massachu- setts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Available at dspace.mit.edu/handle/1721.1/39938. Watershed Agricultural Council. 2011. “Strategic Plan: 2011- 2014.” Walton, New York. Available at nycwatershed.org/ pdfs/Strategic_Plan_2011-2014.pdf. Wheeler, S.A. J. Cheesman. 2013. “Key Findings from a Sur- vey of Sellers to the Restoring the Balance Programme.” Economic Papers: A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 32 (3): 340–52. doi:10.1111/1759-3441.12038. Wind, M.H.A. 2012. “Water Emissions Trading in Europe - A Literature Overview and Discussion of Opportunities.” Eco-consult Environmental Economics. http://www.eco- consult.nl/images/pdf/WET_in_Europe_v3.pdf. Woodward, R.T., R.A. Kaiser A.B. Wicks. 2002. “The Struc- ture and Practice of Water Quality Trading Markets.” Journal of the American Water Resources Association 38 (4): 967–79. doi:10.1111/j.1752-1688.2002.tb05538.x. World Economic Forum (WEF). 2012. “Global Risks 2012, Seventh Edition.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at weforum.org/docs/WEF_Glo- balRisks_Report_2012.pdf. ———. 2013. “Global Risks 2013, Eighth Edition.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalRisks_Report_2013.pdf. ———. 2014. “Global Risks 2014, Ninth Edition.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at weforum.org/docs/WEF_GlobalRisks_Report_2014.pdf. ———. 2015. “Global Risks 2015, 10th Edition.” Geneva, Swit- zerland: World Economic Forum (WEF). Available at wefo- rum.org/docs/WEF_Global_Risks_2015_Report15.pdf. World Health Organization and UNICEF. 2015. “Progress on Sanitation and Drinking Water - 2015 Update and MDG Assessment.” Geneva, Switzerland: World Health Orga- nization. Available at wssinfo.org/fileadmin/user_upload/ resources/JMP-Update-report-2015_English.pdf.
  • 209. Incentive-Based Instruments for Water Management Publisher(s): Foundation Center; Pacific Institute; Rockefeller Foundation Author(s): Michael Cohen; Heather Cooley; Matthew Heberger; Heather Rippman Date Published: 2015-12-01 Rights: Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 International Subject(s): Energy and Environment IssueLab Permalink: http://www.issuelab.org/permalink/resource/23697 _______________________________________________________________________________________________________________ This social sector resource is permanently archived with IssueLab. IssueLab permalink: http://www.issuelab.org/permalink/resource/23697 Metadata last modified: 2016-01-26 Date file archived: 2016-01-20 Date this page generated to accompany file download: 2016-02-08 IssueLab, a service of the Foundation Center, works to more effectively gather, index, and share the collective intelligence of the social sector. We provide free access to thousands of case studies, evaluations, white papers, and issue briefs published by foundations, nonprofits, and academic research centers that address some of the world's most pressing social problems. Visit www.issuelab.org where you can search, browse, access, and share social sector resources.