Kelly Criterion (intro)
Pf Quant
15 Jun 2018
A group of roughnecks on an oil rig love to bet on the outcome
of baseball games between two imaginary teams I just made
up:
Team 1) The Stars Team 2) The Stripes
Both teams are equally skilled, so
the rig’s bookie pays even-money,
or, equivalently, 2:1 odds, on either
team winning a game.
Baseball games are played during a 12-hour shift, so the games are
recorded. Everyone watches the recorded games together and places
their bets before the tape is started.
...but a gambler on the rig has a
handheld transistor radio!
Gambler can pick up the results of the game as it happens, during the
shift, and then place a bet later when everyone gathers to watch the tape!
In theory, Gambler would hazard all of his
bankroll on every game since, with this ‘side
information’, the probability of winning is 100%.
𝑉𝑁 = 2 𝑁
𝑉0
Starting with bankroll V0, the gambler’s
expected bankroll V after N games is:
Because he’s certain to win,
Gambler simply bets his entire
bankroll on the outcome of each
game, every time.
...but after a few games (and wins),
the radio is damaged.
Stars?
60%
Stripes?
40%
Because he now stands a non-zero
chance of losing everything if he bets his
bankroll and heard wrong, he now only
wants to bet a fraction of his bankroll.
Gambler is pretty sure he can
understand which team wins…
but not certain.
What fraction should he bet?
What fraction should he bet?
𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑊 1 − 𝑓 𝐿 𝑉0
Every time Gambler wins a bet, he multiplies his bankroll by (1 + f).
𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑉𝑁−1
𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 1 + 𝑓 1 + 𝑓 . . . 𝑉𝑁−...
...which is to say:
...and so on...
Such that if he wins W times, his new bankroll is:
𝑉 𝑊 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑊
𝑉0
Therefore, after N games of W wins and L losses, our gambler’s
bankroll may be written:
Question: Does the order of wins and losses matter, or is the
equation above always right, regardless of order?
𝑉𝐿 = 1 + 𝑓 𝐿
𝑉0
(Same thing for losses.)
No, order does not matter to the end result,
although it does to the path.
1: Win; -1: Loss – 10 bets: 6 wins and 4 losses f: 0.5
Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4 Scenario 5
Bet 1 1 1 1 1 -1
Bet 2 -1 1 1 1 -1
Bet 3 1 1 1 1 -1
Bet 4 -1 -1 1 -1 -1
Bet 5 -1 1 1 -1 1
Bet 6 1 -1 -1 -1 1
Bet 7 1 -1 -1 -1 1
Bet 8 1 1 -1 1 1
Bet 9 -1 1 1 1 1
Bet 10 1 -1 -1 1 1
starting cash: $100.00 $100.00 $100.00 $100.00 $100.00
Bet 1 $150.00 $150.00 $150.00 $150.00 $50.00
Bet 2 $75.00 $225.00 $225.00 $225.00 $25.00
Bet 3 $112.50 $337.50 $337.50 $337.50 $12.50
Bet 4 $56.25 $168.75 $506.25 $168.75 $6.25
Bet 5 $28.13 $253.13 $759.38 $84.38 $9.38
Bet 6 $42.19 $126.56 $379.69 $42.19 $14.06
Bet 7 $63.28 $63.28 $189.84 $21.09 $21.09
Bet 8 $94.92 $94.92 $94.92 $31.64 $31.64
Bet 9 $47.46 $142.38 $142.38 $47.46 $47.46
Bet 10 $71.19 $71.19 $71.19 $71.19 $71.19
if you don’t believe me, consider:
Randomly
typed in 6
wins and 4
losses for
these
columns. Try
your own!
𝑉𝑁 ,
Now we have a formula for The Expected Value of Capital After N
Events, to which we’re going to give the symbol
We don’t really know which baseball game will be a win or a loss
for Gambler, although we can estimate the estimate the fraction of
Ws and Ls we expect to occur over N games.
→ For which, in this case, we have found
𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑊
1 − 𝑓 𝐿
𝑉0.
What Gambler is truly interested in is his expected return per
event; in other words, the quantity
𝐺 = 𝑙𝑖𝑚
𝑁→∞
1
𝑁
𝑙𝑜𝑔2
𝑉𝑁
𝑉0
Why log
base 2?
Base 2 log because:
𝑉𝑁 = 2 𝑁 𝑉0.
In the perfect case (complete certainty), the gambler has
𝐺 = 𝑙𝑖𝑚
𝑁→∞
1
𝑁
𝑙𝑜𝑔2
𝑉𝑁
𝑉0
= 1.
Therefore,
In other words, it will take you 1 event to double your wealth.
This doesn’t NEED to be base 2, but knowing how many events it
takes to double your wealth is very handy and easy to understand!!!
𝐺 = 𝑙𝑖𝑚
𝑁→∞
𝑊
𝑁
𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 + 𝑓 +
𝐿
𝑁
𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 − 𝑓
Putting this definition of expected return per event…
...together with the expected value of capital after N events…
yields:
𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑊
1 − 𝑓 𝐿
𝑉0
𝐺 = 𝑙𝑖𝑚
𝑁→∞
1
𝑁
𝑙𝑜𝑔2
𝑉𝑁
𝑉0
So if we make a couple of simplifying definitions:
𝑙𝑖𝑚
𝑁→∞
𝑊
𝑁
= 𝑞
𝑙𝑖𝑚
𝑁→∞
𝐿
𝑁
= 𝑝
𝑙𝑖𝑚
𝑁→∞
𝑊
𝑁
= 𝑞
The long-term probability that gambler WINS
...and ditto for LOSSES...
𝐺 = 𝑞𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 + 𝑓 + 𝑝𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 − 𝑓
Then we can rewrite G in a much friendlier form:
Expected return per event
Pause for a second...
𝑝
𝑞
: LOSSES.
: WINS.
Keep that in mind.
𝐺 = 𝑞𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 + 𝑓 + 𝑝𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 − 𝑓
Gambler simply wants to maximize his expected return per
baseball game (event).
In other words, he’s happy if he can find some fmax that
maximizes G in the equation from last slide:
𝑙𝑖𝑚
𝑁→∞
𝑊
𝑁
= 𝑞
Lemma: The maximum value with respect to Yi of a quantity of
the form Z = ∑Xi logYi is obtained by using Yi s:
𝑌𝑖,𝑚𝑎𝑥 =
𝑌𝑖
𝑋𝑖
𝑋𝑖.
𝑌𝑖 = 1 + 𝑓 , 1 − 𝑓 ;
To use this handy fact, we simply vectorize G from its original form:
𝑋𝑖 = 𝑞, 𝑝
𝐺 = 𝑞𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 + 𝑓 + 𝑝𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 − 𝑓
… to a vector form
𝐺 = 1 + 𝑓 , 1 − 𝑓 ∗ 𝑞, 𝑝
… and make
substitutions
Lets find Gmax.
From the substitution definitions
𝑙𝑖𝑚
𝑁→∞
𝑊
𝑁
= 𝑞
𝑌𝑖,𝑚𝑎𝑥 =
𝑌𝑖
𝑋𝑖
𝑋𝑖 =
2
1
𝑞, 𝑝 .
Or, more simply:
𝑌𝑖 = 1 + 𝑓 , 1 − 𝑓 ; 𝑋𝑖 = 𝑞, 𝑝 ,
It’s clear that
𝑌𝑖,𝑚𝑎𝑥 = 2 𝑞, 𝑝
Therefore G is maximized by the fraction that makes the substitution
sentence true:
𝐺 𝑚𝑎𝑥 = 1 + 𝑝𝑙𝑜𝑔 𝑝 + 𝑞𝑙𝑜𝑔 𝑞
𝑓𝑚𝑎𝑥 = 2𝑞 − 1 = 1 − 2𝑝
...and betting with this fraction will maximize G at
(In units of bits/event)
Returning to the Gambler -
Stars?
60%
Stripes?
40%
Now that he’s only 60% sure of
winning a particular bet, his
Kelly fraction is 20%
And his expected gain / event is about
0.029 bits/event, which means it’ll
take him about 35 games to double
his wealth.
But that’s not QUITE the
whole story...
Kelly Quant (intro)
Kelly Quant (intro)
Kelly Quant (intro)
Generalized Kelly Fraction:
𝑓 𝑏𝑒𝑠𝑡
=
𝑏𝑝 − 𝑞
𝑏
=
𝑝 𝑏 + 1 − 1
𝑏
𝑓 ∗
=
𝑏𝑞 − 𝑝
𝑏
=
𝑞 𝑏 + 1
𝑏
Wherein:
 f*: how much you should wager
 b: odds ratio (e.g, “2” if 2:1)
 q: probability of winning
 p: probability of losing
 1 = p + q, always
NOTE: In the literature, not everyone chooses to follow Kelly’s
original convention of p: losing, q: winning, so always make
sure you know what the author means by ‘p’ or ‘q’.
edge ≡ 𝑏𝑝 − 𝑞
Point 1: The Edge
Let’s consider what this inequality is really saying.
The Odds Ratio b can be thought of as an engineering parameter that has units of [$
Returned if Successful] / [$ Wagered].
q can be thought of as an engineering parameter that has units of [# of total
wins] / [# of total replications] if you, in a large number of identical parallel
universes, were to observe the outcome of a large number of bets.
Ditto for p: a parameter that has units of [# of total losses] / [# of total
replications] for a sufficiently large sampling of events.
𝑏 > 𝑞 𝑝
The “edge” is the special name given to the numerator of the Kelly fraction.
It’s important to note that – unless you can take a short position – the Kelly fraction
tells us to place a bet ONLY when the edge is positive; equivalently, only when the
following inequality is true:
edge ≡ 𝑏𝑝 − 𝑞;
Point 1: The Edge
With the observations from last slide, let’s do some dimensional analysis:
𝑏 > 𝑞 𝑝
Bet when
𝑏 > 𝑞 𝑝
Has units of: $ Returned if Win
$ Hazarded
$ Returned if Win
$ Hazarded
>
# Wins
# Losses
The dollar payout ratio if
Event happens
-> given to you by BOOKIE
Your own private assessment of
the win-loss ratio
-> comes from YOU
Conclusion:
Kelly says to only take bets in which you believe the bookie has,
mistakenly, underestimated the odds.
𝑓 𝑏𝑒𝑠𝑡
=
𝐸 − 𝑟
𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑚𝑎2
Point 2:
For a stock having expected return E, expected
volatility sigma^2, and risk free rate r:
...but wait… that’s familiar…
𝑓 𝑏𝑒𝑠𝑡 =
𝐸 − 𝑟
𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑚𝑎2
𝑆 =
𝐸 − 𝑟
𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑚𝑎2
...and from Markowitz:
(From last page)
S: Sharpe Ratio, E: Expectecd Return, r: risk-free rate,
sigma^2: expected volatility
Slope of the security market line
for an optimized portfolio:
Not an accident.
Tune in next week :)

More Related Content

PPTX
Poker maths
PPTX
Poker in Numbers
PPTX
Game gg
PPTX
Set 4 quiz of zero-sum games
PDF
Turtle strategyforbj
PPTX
Balancing Fruit - IAPA presentation 26/11/15
PPTX
Game e
DOCX
Houchens jeffrey secret helper gdd
Poker maths
Poker in Numbers
Game gg
Set 4 quiz of zero-sum games
Turtle strategyforbj
Balancing Fruit - IAPA presentation 26/11/15
Game e
Houchens jeffrey secret helper gdd

What's hot (18)

PPT
Basic Poker Strategy
PDF
5 Methods How To Win Casino Roulette
PDF
Casino paper 2
PDF
Bingo
PPTX
Team f
PPTX
Team h
PDF
POWER MATRIX ROULETTE SYSTEM
PDF
Best roulette cheat sheet
PDF
TornadoBrickSmasherUserManual
PPTX
How To Become A Roulette Champion
PPTX
How to play poker
PDF
CIII_FamilyFeud
PDF
DeSocttery
PPTX
Hustle presentation click
PPTX
3. research
PPT
Casino Mathematics
PPTX
General games
Basic Poker Strategy
5 Methods How To Win Casino Roulette
Casino paper 2
Bingo
Team f
Team h
POWER MATRIX ROULETTE SYSTEM
Best roulette cheat sheet
TornadoBrickSmasherUserManual
How To Become A Roulette Champion
How to play poker
CIII_FamilyFeud
DeSocttery
Hustle presentation click
3. research
Casino Mathematics
General games
Ad

Similar to Kelly Quant (intro) (20)

PPT
AufEx4_12_06.ppt
PDF
Price Models
PPT
MMC Math 2009
PPT
Law of large numbers
PDF
Principles of Actuarial Science Chapter 2
PPT
lecture4.ppt
PDF
Upload
PPT
Game Theory
KEY
Jason Arhart: Why Gambling Theory Matters
PDF
stochastic-processes-1.pdf
PPTX
Mathematical Expectation And Variance
PPTX
Mathematical Expectation And Variance
PPT
Talk at the quantopian Boston meetup
PPT
Talk at Quantopian.com quant finance meetup.
PDF
Conditional Expectations Liner algebra
PDF
Dias Da Cruz Steve - Seminar
PDF
13_RL_1.pdf
PDF
Cramton2014a Risk Theory (slides).pdf
PDF
Mark Saroufim - Probability without Measure - It's only a game
AufEx4_12_06.ppt
Price Models
MMC Math 2009
Law of large numbers
Principles of Actuarial Science Chapter 2
lecture4.ppt
Upload
Game Theory
Jason Arhart: Why Gambling Theory Matters
stochastic-processes-1.pdf
Mathematical Expectation And Variance
Mathematical Expectation And Variance
Talk at the quantopian Boston meetup
Talk at Quantopian.com quant finance meetup.
Conditional Expectations Liner algebra
Dias Da Cruz Steve - Seminar
13_RL_1.pdf
Cramton2014a Risk Theory (slides).pdf
Mark Saroufim - Probability without Measure - It's only a game
Ad

Recently uploaded (20)

PDF
01 KEY PROVISIONS on NGPA and PROFESSIONALIZATION.pdf
PPTX
Group Presentation Development Econ and Envi..pptx
PPTX
Q1 PE AND HEALTH 5 WEEK 5 DAY 1 powerpoint template
PPTX
General-Characteristics-of-Microorganisms.pptx
PDF
USS pension Report and Accounts 2025.pdf
PDF
GVCParticipation_Automation_Climate_India
PDF
Truxton Capital: Middle Market Quarterly Review - August 2025
PPTX
Very useful ppt for your banking assignments Banking.pptx
PDF
Pitch Deck.pdf .pdf all about finance in
PPT
features and equilibrium under MONOPOLY 17.11.20.ppt
PPTX
OAT_ORI_Fed Independence_August 2025.pptx
PDF
2018_Simulating Hedge Fund Strategies Generalising Fund Performance Presentat...
DOCX
Final. 150 minutes exercise agrumentative Essay
PDF
5-principles-of-PD-design.pdfvvvhvjvvcjcxhhcjb ggfvjhvjjhbvbbbvccxhgcxzzghjbv...
PDF
THE EFFECT OF FOREIGN AID ON ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ETHIOPIA
PPTX
lesson in englishhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhh
PDF
How to join illuminati agent in Uganda Kampala call 0782561496/0756664682
PDF
Unkipdf.pdf of work in the economy we are
PDF
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
PDF
Buy Verified Stripe Accounts for Sale - Secure and.pdf
01 KEY PROVISIONS on NGPA and PROFESSIONALIZATION.pdf
Group Presentation Development Econ and Envi..pptx
Q1 PE AND HEALTH 5 WEEK 5 DAY 1 powerpoint template
General-Characteristics-of-Microorganisms.pptx
USS pension Report and Accounts 2025.pdf
GVCParticipation_Automation_Climate_India
Truxton Capital: Middle Market Quarterly Review - August 2025
Very useful ppt for your banking assignments Banking.pptx
Pitch Deck.pdf .pdf all about finance in
features and equilibrium under MONOPOLY 17.11.20.ppt
OAT_ORI_Fed Independence_August 2025.pptx
2018_Simulating Hedge Fund Strategies Generalising Fund Performance Presentat...
Final. 150 minutes exercise agrumentative Essay
5-principles-of-PD-design.pdfvvvhvjvvcjcxhhcjb ggfvjhvjjhbvbbbvccxhgcxzzghjbv...
THE EFFECT OF FOREIGN AID ON ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ETHIOPIA
lesson in englishhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhh
How to join illuminati agent in Uganda Kampala call 0782561496/0756664682
Unkipdf.pdf of work in the economy we are
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
Buy Verified Stripe Accounts for Sale - Secure and.pdf

Kelly Quant (intro)

  • 1. Kelly Criterion (intro) Pf Quant 15 Jun 2018
  • 2. A group of roughnecks on an oil rig love to bet on the outcome of baseball games between two imaginary teams I just made up: Team 1) The Stars Team 2) The Stripes Both teams are equally skilled, so the rig’s bookie pays even-money, or, equivalently, 2:1 odds, on either team winning a game. Baseball games are played during a 12-hour shift, so the games are recorded. Everyone watches the recorded games together and places their bets before the tape is started.
  • 3. ...but a gambler on the rig has a handheld transistor radio! Gambler can pick up the results of the game as it happens, during the shift, and then place a bet later when everyone gathers to watch the tape! In theory, Gambler would hazard all of his bankroll on every game since, with this ‘side information’, the probability of winning is 100%. 𝑉𝑁 = 2 𝑁 𝑉0 Starting with bankroll V0, the gambler’s expected bankroll V after N games is: Because he’s certain to win, Gambler simply bets his entire bankroll on the outcome of each game, every time.
  • 4. ...but after a few games (and wins), the radio is damaged. Stars? 60% Stripes? 40% Because he now stands a non-zero chance of losing everything if he bets his bankroll and heard wrong, he now only wants to bet a fraction of his bankroll. Gambler is pretty sure he can understand which team wins… but not certain. What fraction should he bet?
  • 5. What fraction should he bet? 𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑊 1 − 𝑓 𝐿 𝑉0 Every time Gambler wins a bet, he multiplies his bankroll by (1 + f). 𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑉𝑁−1 𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 1 + 𝑓 1 + 𝑓 . . . 𝑉𝑁−... ...which is to say: ...and so on... Such that if he wins W times, his new bankroll is: 𝑉 𝑊 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑊 𝑉0 Therefore, after N games of W wins and L losses, our gambler’s bankroll may be written: Question: Does the order of wins and losses matter, or is the equation above always right, regardless of order? 𝑉𝐿 = 1 + 𝑓 𝐿 𝑉0 (Same thing for losses.)
  • 6. No, order does not matter to the end result, although it does to the path. 1: Win; -1: Loss – 10 bets: 6 wins and 4 losses f: 0.5 Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4 Scenario 5 Bet 1 1 1 1 1 -1 Bet 2 -1 1 1 1 -1 Bet 3 1 1 1 1 -1 Bet 4 -1 -1 1 -1 -1 Bet 5 -1 1 1 -1 1 Bet 6 1 -1 -1 -1 1 Bet 7 1 -1 -1 -1 1 Bet 8 1 1 -1 1 1 Bet 9 -1 1 1 1 1 Bet 10 1 -1 -1 1 1 starting cash: $100.00 $100.00 $100.00 $100.00 $100.00 Bet 1 $150.00 $150.00 $150.00 $150.00 $50.00 Bet 2 $75.00 $225.00 $225.00 $225.00 $25.00 Bet 3 $112.50 $337.50 $337.50 $337.50 $12.50 Bet 4 $56.25 $168.75 $506.25 $168.75 $6.25 Bet 5 $28.13 $253.13 $759.38 $84.38 $9.38 Bet 6 $42.19 $126.56 $379.69 $42.19 $14.06 Bet 7 $63.28 $63.28 $189.84 $21.09 $21.09 Bet 8 $94.92 $94.92 $94.92 $31.64 $31.64 Bet 9 $47.46 $142.38 $142.38 $47.46 $47.46 Bet 10 $71.19 $71.19 $71.19 $71.19 $71.19 if you don’t believe me, consider: Randomly typed in 6 wins and 4 losses for these columns. Try your own!
  • 7. 𝑉𝑁 , Now we have a formula for The Expected Value of Capital After N Events, to which we’re going to give the symbol We don’t really know which baseball game will be a win or a loss for Gambler, although we can estimate the estimate the fraction of Ws and Ls we expect to occur over N games. → For which, in this case, we have found 𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑊 1 − 𝑓 𝐿 𝑉0. What Gambler is truly interested in is his expected return per event; in other words, the quantity 𝐺 = 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑁→∞ 1 𝑁 𝑙𝑜𝑔2 𝑉𝑁 𝑉0 Why log base 2?
  • 8. Base 2 log because: 𝑉𝑁 = 2 𝑁 𝑉0. In the perfect case (complete certainty), the gambler has 𝐺 = 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑁→∞ 1 𝑁 𝑙𝑜𝑔2 𝑉𝑁 𝑉0 = 1. Therefore, In other words, it will take you 1 event to double your wealth. This doesn’t NEED to be base 2, but knowing how many events it takes to double your wealth is very handy and easy to understand!!!
  • 9. 𝐺 = 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑁→∞ 𝑊 𝑁 𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 + 𝑓 + 𝐿 𝑁 𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 − 𝑓 Putting this definition of expected return per event… ...together with the expected value of capital after N events… yields: 𝑉𝑁 = 1 + 𝑓 𝑊 1 − 𝑓 𝐿 𝑉0 𝐺 = 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑁→∞ 1 𝑁 𝑙𝑜𝑔2 𝑉𝑁 𝑉0
  • 10. So if we make a couple of simplifying definitions: 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑁→∞ 𝑊 𝑁 = 𝑞 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑁→∞ 𝐿 𝑁 = 𝑝 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑁→∞ 𝑊 𝑁 = 𝑞 The long-term probability that gambler WINS ...and ditto for LOSSES... 𝐺 = 𝑞𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 + 𝑓 + 𝑝𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 − 𝑓 Then we can rewrite G in a much friendlier form: Expected return per event
  • 11. Pause for a second... 𝑝 𝑞 : LOSSES. : WINS. Keep that in mind.
  • 12. 𝐺 = 𝑞𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 + 𝑓 + 𝑝𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 − 𝑓 Gambler simply wants to maximize his expected return per baseball game (event). In other words, he’s happy if he can find some fmax that maximizes G in the equation from last slide:
  • 13. 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑁→∞ 𝑊 𝑁 = 𝑞 Lemma: The maximum value with respect to Yi of a quantity of the form Z = ∑Xi logYi is obtained by using Yi s: 𝑌𝑖,𝑚𝑎𝑥 = 𝑌𝑖 𝑋𝑖 𝑋𝑖. 𝑌𝑖 = 1 + 𝑓 , 1 − 𝑓 ; To use this handy fact, we simply vectorize G from its original form: 𝑋𝑖 = 𝑞, 𝑝 𝐺 = 𝑞𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 + 𝑓 + 𝑝𝑙𝑜𝑔2 1 − 𝑓 … to a vector form 𝐺 = 1 + 𝑓 , 1 − 𝑓 ∗ 𝑞, 𝑝 … and make substitutions Lets find Gmax.
  • 14. From the substitution definitions 𝑙𝑖𝑚 𝑁→∞ 𝑊 𝑁 = 𝑞 𝑌𝑖,𝑚𝑎𝑥 = 𝑌𝑖 𝑋𝑖 𝑋𝑖 = 2 1 𝑞, 𝑝 . Or, more simply: 𝑌𝑖 = 1 + 𝑓 , 1 − 𝑓 ; 𝑋𝑖 = 𝑞, 𝑝 , It’s clear that 𝑌𝑖,𝑚𝑎𝑥 = 2 𝑞, 𝑝
  • 15. Therefore G is maximized by the fraction that makes the substitution sentence true: 𝐺 𝑚𝑎𝑥 = 1 + 𝑝𝑙𝑜𝑔 𝑝 + 𝑞𝑙𝑜𝑔 𝑞 𝑓𝑚𝑎𝑥 = 2𝑞 − 1 = 1 − 2𝑝 ...and betting with this fraction will maximize G at (In units of bits/event)
  • 16. Returning to the Gambler - Stars? 60% Stripes? 40% Now that he’s only 60% sure of winning a particular bet, his Kelly fraction is 20% And his expected gain / event is about 0.029 bits/event, which means it’ll take him about 35 games to double his wealth. But that’s not QUITE the whole story...
  • 20. Generalized Kelly Fraction: 𝑓 𝑏𝑒𝑠𝑡 = 𝑏𝑝 − 𝑞 𝑏 = 𝑝 𝑏 + 1 − 1 𝑏 𝑓 ∗ = 𝑏𝑞 − 𝑝 𝑏 = 𝑞 𝑏 + 1 𝑏 Wherein:  f*: how much you should wager  b: odds ratio (e.g, “2” if 2:1)  q: probability of winning  p: probability of losing  1 = p + q, always NOTE: In the literature, not everyone chooses to follow Kelly’s original convention of p: losing, q: winning, so always make sure you know what the author means by ‘p’ or ‘q’.
  • 21. edge ≡ 𝑏𝑝 − 𝑞 Point 1: The Edge Let’s consider what this inequality is really saying. The Odds Ratio b can be thought of as an engineering parameter that has units of [$ Returned if Successful] / [$ Wagered]. q can be thought of as an engineering parameter that has units of [# of total wins] / [# of total replications] if you, in a large number of identical parallel universes, were to observe the outcome of a large number of bets. Ditto for p: a parameter that has units of [# of total losses] / [# of total replications] for a sufficiently large sampling of events. 𝑏 > 𝑞 𝑝 The “edge” is the special name given to the numerator of the Kelly fraction. It’s important to note that – unless you can take a short position – the Kelly fraction tells us to place a bet ONLY when the edge is positive; equivalently, only when the following inequality is true:
  • 22. edge ≡ 𝑏𝑝 − 𝑞; Point 1: The Edge With the observations from last slide, let’s do some dimensional analysis: 𝑏 > 𝑞 𝑝 Bet when 𝑏 > 𝑞 𝑝 Has units of: $ Returned if Win $ Hazarded $ Returned if Win $ Hazarded > # Wins # Losses The dollar payout ratio if Event happens -> given to you by BOOKIE Your own private assessment of the win-loss ratio -> comes from YOU Conclusion: Kelly says to only take bets in which you believe the bookie has, mistakenly, underestimated the odds.
  • 23. 𝑓 𝑏𝑒𝑠𝑡 = 𝐸 − 𝑟 𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑚𝑎2 Point 2: For a stock having expected return E, expected volatility sigma^2, and risk free rate r:
  • 24. ...but wait… that’s familiar… 𝑓 𝑏𝑒𝑠𝑡 = 𝐸 − 𝑟 𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑚𝑎2 𝑆 = 𝐸 − 𝑟 𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑚𝑎2 ...and from Markowitz: (From last page) S: Sharpe Ratio, E: Expectecd Return, r: risk-free rate, sigma^2: expected volatility Slope of the security market line for an optimized portfolio:
  • 25. Not an accident. Tune in next week :)