Conference Version
Mf in inia 2007
Microfinance in India
               A State of the Sector Report, 2007




                                              By
                                       Prabhu Ghate

                                      Sai Gunaranjan
                                      Vijay Mahajan
                                      Prasanth Regy
                                       Frances Sinha
                                        Sanjay Sinha




                                     Microfinance India
                             28 Hauz Khas Village, New Delhi 110 016




This report represents the personal views of the chapter authors. It does not represent the
views of Microfinance India, or of its sponsors, or of the Microfinance India Advisory Group.

                                                                                            1
2
Contents
Chapter                                                                 Page No
Foreword                                                                     5
Preface and Acknowledgments                                                  6
Abbreviations                                                                8
1   Overview                                                                11
    Prabhu Ghate
2   Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme                           35
    Prabhu Ghate
3   SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers?                               49
    Prabhu Ghate
4   MFI Performance: Efficiency with Growth                                 73
    Sanjay Sinha
5   Urban Microfinance                                                      83
    Prabhu Ghate
6   Social Performance in Indian Microfinance                              105
    Frances Sinha
7   Micro Insurance                                                        119
    Sai Gunaranjan
8   Microfinance and Technology                                            131
    Prasanth V Regy and Vijay Mahajan
9   Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost?          149
    Prabhu Ghate


List of Tables                                                          Page No
Table 2.1    Growth trends in the SBLP                                       36
Table 2.2    Growth of linked SHGs in 13 Priority States                     37
Table 2.3    Growth trends in the SBLP for 2006-07, by state                 43
Table 2.4    Growth of linked SHGs in the regions                            38
Table 2.5    Agency- wise number of SHGs financed                            38
Table 4.1    Regional distribution of Indian MFIs rated by M-CRIL            74
Table 4.2    Distribution of sample Indian MFIs by microfinance model        75
Table 4.3    Distribution of sample MFIs by legal form                       75
Table 4.4    Operating expense ratios of Indian MFIs                         78
Table 4.5    Capital adequacy ratios of Indian MFIs                          80
Table 4.6    Portfolio yield relative to APR                                 81
Table 4.7    Outreach of efficient microfinance institutions                 82
Table 9.1    Successive versions of the microfinance bill                   163
Table 9.2    MFOs and MFIs                                                  164

                                                                                  3
Appendix Tables                                                                    Page No
Table A.1    Fact Sheet on coverage and growth of India microfinance, 2006-07             179
Table A.2    Information on 129 MFIs covered in Sa-Dhan's Quick Report 2007               180
Table A.3    Lending by selected apex financing institutions and banks to MFIs            188
Table A.4    Salient features of India-oriented equity investors                          189
Table A.5    Insurance coverage by selected MFIs                                          191
Table A.6    List of selected transformations                                             192

List of Boxes                                                                      Page No
Box 1.1      Cashpor: Stoppage of Partnership Funding                                      14
Box 1.2      The challenges of raising capital: Inside the entrepreneur’s mind             26
Box 3.1      “The SHG Revolution: What Next?”                                              50
Box 3.2      MYRADA’s Community Managed Resource Centres (CMRCs)                           53
Box 3.3      DHAN Foundation federations: changing with the times                          55
Box 3.4      Making non-financial federations viable: PRADAN’s experience                  57
Box 3.5      Roshan Vikas: An urban SHG federation                                         62
Box 3.6      Swayanshree at the crossroads: To borrow or to facilitate direct linkages?    63
Box 5.1      The uses and abuses of moneylenders                                           86
Box 5.2      The ubiquity of moneylenders in Bangalore                                     87
Box 5.3      Mobility in a Delhi slum                                                      89
Box 5.4      Segmentation by loan purpose                                                  90
Box 5.5      Ujjivan’s approach to urban housing microfinance:
             helping customers climb the housing ladder                                    92
Box 5.6      Individual loans and product diversification at SEWA Bank                    94
Box 6.1      Dimensions of social performance                                             106
Box 7.1      Providing sustainable and competitive
             insurance products to rural customers                                        121
Box 7.2      SEWA and rainfall insurance                                                  127
Box 8.1      The evolution of MIS in Basix                                                135
Box 8.2      A hosted solution: FINO                                                      137
Box 8.3      TAFI: Putting mobile phone technology to work as a BC for remittances        145
Box 9.1:     The microfinance bill: a case study in dilution                              162
Box 9.2      Misunderstandings about savings                                              165
Box 9.3      Grameen II and flexible, voluntary savings                                   166
Box 9.4      Sa-Dhan’s Voluntary Mutual Code of Conduct                                   167
Box 9.5      A bit of history: Self-regulation backed by legal sanctions                  168


List of Figures                                                                    Page No
Figure 4.1   Membership of sample MFIs                                                     76
Figure 4.2   Average savings per member by model                                           77
Figure 4.3   OER by loan size                                                              78
Figure 4.4   Relationship of portfolio size with efficiency                                79
Figure 4.5   Sources of funds for microfinance operations                                  79
Figure 6.1   Assessing social performance                                                 108

4
Foreword
This is the second of a series of Annual Reports on the microfinance sector in India, prepared for presentation
to the annual Microfinance India conference organized by ACCESS Development Services. The Microfinance
India Conference, over the last four years, has become established as perhaps the most recognized sector
event, and attracts large-scale interest from diverse stakeholders from the sector, and interested observers
from within and outside the country, and has become known for insightful discussions and debates of key
issues challenging the sector. This year's conference, the fourth in the series, is being held on October 9-
10. Among others, a specific significant contribution of Microfinance India, in addition to the conference,
has been the publication of the State of the Sector Report annually released at the time of the Conference.
Like last year, the State of the Sector Report contains two chapters on progress under each of the two main
models of microfinance in India viz. linkage banking and MFIs. These two chapters are proposed to be
carried every year and carry the most updated review of how the two models have progressed during the
year. In addition, the Report includes five chapters on "new" topics and themes that could not be covered
in the last State of the Sector Report, but continue to be of current and future significance to the Sector.
These topics relate to SHG federations, evaluation of social performance, urban microfinance, developments
in technology, and perspectives on regulatory issues, including the pending microfinance bill. A few
topics such as developments in commercial bank lending to MFIs, equity investments, and issues relating
to the mounting challenge of the growing need for quality human resource for the sector could not be
covered again in this year's report for reasons of space, but are proposed to be taken up in subsequent
years. In future years, we also hope to include themes, which have yet to be covered, such as livelihoods
finance, financial inclusion, financial literacy, et al. The abundance of additional information collated by
the author may necessitate a second edition of the report.
In order to broad-base participation in preparation of the report and take fullest advantage of the rich
expertise available in the sector, four of the chapters contained in this year's report have been contributed
by well known sector experts. I am personally grateful to them for taking valuable time off from their
other responsibilities. I acknowledge support extended for one of these chapters, that on the MFI
model, by the MIX. All of them have been equally ambitious to continue to support this ACCESS -
Microfinance initiative to make the State of the Sector Report as valuable to the sector as possible.
To ensure widespread distribution of last year's State of the Sector Report, it has been brought out as
book under the title of Microfinance in India: The Challenges of Rapid Growth. The book has been
published by Sage Publications as a paperback so as to enhance affordability.
I am also grateful to our sponsors Swiss Development Cooperation and Ford Foundation and the close
association of both Adrian and Ajit at all stages of the Report's progress. And finally, I am immensely
grateful to Prabhu, who, exhausted from the first effort, with some persuasion, agreed to author the
2007 report. I also would like to thank my team at ACCESS for the support provided to this effort. Most
importantly, I am grateful to the sector at large for their very positive response to last year's report,
which encouraged us to raise our ambition for the current year's report, and to persist with the idea of
bringing it out annually.
I hope the sector will find the State of the Sector Report 2007 equally valuable as last year and continue
to support the effort through sharing information, contributing experiences from the field and bringing
in their perspectives on the sector.


                                                                            Vipin Sharma
                                              CEO, ACCESS Development Services, New Delhi
                                                                                                              5
Preface and
                Acknowledgements
Like last year's report on the state of the Indian microfinance sector, this year's seeks to
document developments, clarify issues, publicize studies, stimulate research, identify policy
choices, generate understanding, and enhance support for the sector. Given the increasing
complexity and diversity of the sector, each annual edition of the report can try, but is
unlikely to succeed, in being a comprehensive record of everything that happened during the
year. In its choice of topics this year's report tries to complement last year's. Thus it covers
five topics not covered last year, two of them contained in chapters by practitioners (those
on technology and social performance) and three of them in chapters by the lead author
(those on SHG federations, urban microfinance, and regulation). A third chapter on insurance
is also by a practitioner. I am grateful to Vijay Mahajan, Sai Gunaranjan and Prasanth Regy for
giving the report a more practical flavour by drawing on the experience of BASIX, an industry
leader in the adoption (and adaptation) of both technology and micro insurance. Frances
Sinha leads M-CRIL's pioneering efforts in introducing social performance assessment to India
(and indeed to many other countries), and Sanjay Sinha is one of India's leading analysts of
the MFI model through M-CRIL's rating work and the periodic M-CRIL Reviews.

Many of the people whose help I gratefully acknowledged last year were generous again in
sharing their time and understanding. I hope they will understand if I do not thank them
individually again. Among those I had not managed to contact last year but were an invaluable
source of information and guidance this year were Vikram Akula, Ramesh Arunachalam, Anjali
Banthia, Mukti Bosco, Arabdha Das, T Dhanaraj, BR Diwakar, Malini Eden , Aloysius Fernandez,
Suvarna Rani Gandham, Aseem Gandhi, Chandra Shekhar Ghosh, Samit Ghosh, Gita Goel, Marie-
Luise Haberberger, Pradeep Jena, Mohd Ali Karim, KG Karmakar, Jugal Kataria, S. Kathiresan,
Manish Khera, Sudha Kothari, Aparna Krishnan, Ajit Kumar Maity, Veena Mankar, Jan Meissner,
Amulya Mohanty, Nayana Mohanty, R Murali, Ravi Narasimhan, Venky Natarajan, Anant Natu,
Parashuram Nayak, LB Prakash, Vidya Ramachandran, RV Ramakrishna, S Ramamurthy, Abhijit
Ray, Chinappa Reddy, Rama Reddy, Suma Reddy, Shubhankar Sengupta, HP Singh, Jaipal Singh,
Usha Somasundaram, Girija Srinivasan, Mark Straub, Yusuke Taishi,Usha Thorat, and Srikrishna.
My apologies to the many others who have been left out. My thanks to all of you.

I would like to thank the following institutions for their support: Sa-Dhan for coming out in
such timely fashion with this year's "Quick Report 2007: A Snapshot of MFIs in India" which
forms the basis of an important table in the statistical appendix; the Center for Micro Finance,
Chennai, for useful interactions over the year: and M2i through Deepak Alok and Avishek



6
Sarcar, who helped put together the statistical appendix, brief though it is because of the
paucity of time and the scattered nature of the data available.

I would like to thank the sponsors for giving me this opportunity to immerse myself for
another year in a sector peopled by so many creative and inspiring individuals. I am grateful
also to Vipin Sharma of ACCESS India for his encouragement, and the freedom and flexibility
he gave me while I tried to put together the various pieces of the complicated puzzle that is
Indian microfinance; to his team consisting of Nishant Tirath and Yeshu Bansal and other
colleagues for help provided; and to Malcolm Harper and Brij Mohan, two of our resource
persons, for being on tap once again with a constant flow of good advice and stimulating
comments.

In order to establish continuity and avoid duplication, I refer back frequently to "last year's
report", which is now conveniently available as a paperback. While I have attempted to consult
as many sector participants as possible, I am conscious that a number of significant
developments and materials relevant to the topics covered may have escaped my attention. I
would request readers to bring them to my attention, as well as any other comments or
corrections, so that they can be taken into account while preparing the report for final
publication. I am sure the other chapter authors would also welcome feedback. The intention
is to make these reports as collaborative an effort as possible. Needless to say, the views
expressed in our respective chapters are entirely our own.



                                                                          Prabhu Ghate
                                                                          pghate1@gmail.com




                                                                                              7
Abbreviations

AIDS      Acquired Immune Deficiency Syndrome
ALW       A Little World
AMMACTS   Acts Mahila Mutually Aided Cooperative Thrift Society
AMUL      Anand Milk-producers Union Limited
AP        Andhra Pradesh
APMACS    Andhra Pradesh Mutually Aided Cooperative Societies
APMAS     Andhra Pradesh Mahila Abhivruddhi Society
APR       Annualised Percentage Rate
ASP       Ankuram Sanghamam Poram
ATM       Automated Teller Machine
AWA       Assistant Anganwadi Worker
AWW       Anganwadi Worker
BC        Business Correspodent
BDS       Business Development service
CASHE     Credit and Savings for Household Enterprise
CASHPOR   Credit and Savings for the Hardcore Poor
CBHI      Central Bureau of Health Intelligence
CBMFI     Community Based MFI
CBO       Capacity Building Organisation
CBS       Core Banking Solution
CDF       Cooperative Development Foundation
CGAP      Consultative Group to Assist the Poor
CIF        Community Investment Funds
CM        Computer Munshi
CMF       Center for Microfinance
CMRC      Community Managed Resource Centres
CRAR      Capital to Risk Weighted Assets Ratio
DCCB      District Central Cooperative Bank
DF        DHAN Foundation
DFID      Department for International Development+B1
DRDA      District Rural Development Authority
DWCD      Department of Women and Child Development
EIR       Effective Interest Rate
EWI       Equated Weekly Installment
FAMIS     Financial Accounting and Management Information System
FGD       Focussed Group Discussion
FINO      Financial Information Network & Operations Ltd
FLDG      First Loss Deficiency Guarantee
FWWB      Friends of Women’s World Banking
8
GCC       General Purpose Credit Cards
GNI       Gross National Income
GRADES    G stands for governance, R for resources, A for asset quality, D for design of
          systems, E for efficiency and profitability, and S for services to member SHGs
          and their performance.
GTZ       Deutsche Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit
HDFC      Housing Development Finance Corporation
HIV       Human Immunodeficiency Virus
HO        Head Office
HR        Human Resources
HUDCO     Housing Urban Development Corporation
IB        Individual Banking
ICT       Information Communication Technology
IFAD      International Fund for Agricultural Development
IGS       Indian Grameen Services
IKP       Indira Kranti Patham
ILO       International Labour Organisation
IPO       Initial Public Offering
IRDA      Insurance Regulatory and Development Authority
IT        Information Technology
JLG       Joint Liability Group
KBSLAB    Krishna Bhima Samruddhi Local Area Bank
KDFS       Kalanjiam Development and Financial Services
KSDF      Kalighat Society for Development Facilitation
KVK       Krishi Vigyan Kendras
KYC       Know Your Customer
LAB       Local Area Bank
LAN       Local Area Network
LSS       "Lights and Shades" Study
MACS      Mutually Aided Cooperative Society
MBT       Mutual Benefit Trust
MCRA      Micro Credit Regulatory Authority
M-CRIL    Micro-credit Ratings International Ltd
MFDC      Microfinance Development Council
MFDEF     Micro Finance Development and Equity Fund
MFI       Microfinance Institution
MFO       Microfinance Organisations
MIFOS     Microfinance Open Source
MIS       Management Information System
MIX       Microfinance Information Exchange
MSDF      Michael & Susan Dell Foundation
NABARD    National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development
NABFINS   Nabard Financial Services
NBFC      Non-Banking Financial Company
NBJK      Nav Bharat Jagriti Kendra
NCAER     National Council for Applied Economic Research (NCAER
NDA       National Democratic Alliance
NDDB      National Dairy Development Board
NE        North East
NFC       Near Field Communication
NGO       Non Governmental Organization
NOF       Net Owned Fund
NPA       Non Performing Assets
                                                                                       9
NREGA         National Rural Employment Guarantee Act
 NSSO          National Sample Survey Organisation
 OER           Operating Expense Ratio
 OSS           Operating Self Sufficiency
 PACS          Primary Agricultural Credit Societies
 PAR           Portfolio At Risk
 PC            Personal Computer
 PDA           Personal Digital Assistant
 PHC           Public Health Centre
 PLR           Prime Lending Rate
 POS           Point of Sale
 PPP           Purchasing Power Parity
 PRADAN        Professional Assistance for Development Action
 PSS           Pragathi Sewa Samithi
 PWMACTS       The Payakaraopta Women’s Mutually Aided Cooperative Thrift And Credit Society Ltd
 RBI           Reserve Bank of India
 RGVN          Rashtriya Grameen Vikas Nidhi
 RMK           Rashtriya Mahila Kosh
 RRB           Regional Rural Bank
 RSRO          Recognised Self Regulatory Authority
 RV            Roshan Vikas
 SBLP          SHG Bank Linkage Program
 SC            Scheduled Caste
 SCB           State Cooperative Bank
 SEEP          Small Enterprise Education and Promotion
 SERP          The Society for Elimination of Rural Poverty
 SEWA          Self-Employed Women's Association
 SGSY          Swarna Jayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojna
 SHG           Self Help Group
 SHPA          Self Help Promotion Agency
 SHPI          Self Help Promoting Institution
 SIDBI         Small Industries Development Bank of India
 SIM           Subscriber Identity Module
 SKDRDP        Shri Kshetra Dhamrmasthala Rural Development Project
 SKS           Swayam Krishi Sangam
 SNFL          Sarvodaya Nano Finance Limited
 SPM           Social Performance Management
 SPMS          Sri Padmavathy Mahila Abyudaya Sangh
 SPOT          Specified Point of Transaction
 SQL           Structured Query Language
 SRO           Self Regulatory Authority
 ST            Scheduled Tribe
 STEP          Strategies and Tools against social Exlusion and Poverty
 SWAWS         Sharadas Women’s Association for Weaker Section
 TAFI          Technology Assisted Financial Inclusion
 TNCDW         Tamil Nadu Corporation for the Development of Women
 UCB           Urban Cooperative Bank
 UNDP          United Nations Development Program
 UPS           Uninterruptible Power Supply
 USP           Unique Selling Proposition
 VO            Village Organization
 VWS           Village Welfare Society



       NOTE: 1 CRORE = 10 MILLION, 1 LAKH = 10,000, US$1 = RS 40 APPROXIMATELY

10
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                                Overview




                                          CHAPTER 1

                                   Overview


Growth of the sector continues to be rapid...
The SHG-Bank Linkage Programme (SBLP) covered a further 9.6 million persons in 2006-07, over 90
percent of them women, and about them half of them poor (Fact Sheet, Table A.1). The total number of
SHG members who have ever received credit through the programme has grown therefore to 41 million
persons. Microfinance Institutions, (MFIs), the other model of microfinance in India, grew even more
strongly, and added an estimated 3 million new borrowers to reach a total coverage of about 10.5
million borrowers. Both programmes taken together have therefore reached about 50 million households.
Only 36.8 million of these are being currently being served, however. (Table A.1)


However, not all microfinance borrowers are poor
About half of SHG members, and only 30 percent of MFI members are estimated to be below the         Indicate the
poverty line.1 Thus about 22 percent of all poor households (about 75 million) are currently        sector
                                                                                                    continues to
receiving microfinance services, or at least microcredit. Given limitations in the data base        make strong
that continue to afflict the sector, these are only rough estimates, but they indicate the          progress
                                                                                                    towards the
sector continues to make strong progress towards the goal of extending financial inclusion to       goal of
the roughly fourth-fifths of the population who do not receive credit from the banks, although extending
there is still a long way to go. Slower progress is being made in reaching out to poor households.2 financial
                                                                                                    inclusion to the
                                                                                                    roughly fourth-
MFI borrowers receive larger first loans than SHG members, but since (i) the average duration fifths of the
of MFI loans is shorter (generally one year instead of two), (ii) MFIs have been expanding population who
                                                                                                    do not receive
rapidly, bringing down average MFI loan size (Chapter 4), and (iii) the size of repeat loans to
                                                                                                    credit from the
SHGs has been growing even faster than first loans (Chapter 2), the difference in average loans banks, although
outstanding per borrower in the two models no longer appears to be significant.3                    there is still a
                                                                                                    long way to go.
                                                                                                    Slower progress
The sector needs to pay more attention to depth of                                                  is being made
                                                                                                    in reaching out
outreach and other quality issues                                                                   to poor
                                                                                                    households

Both models continue to do relatively well on loan repayment performance4 and on empowering
women by improving their economic status in the household. The SHG model has the additional
empowerment benefit of bringing almost a million SHG leaders into direct contact with the
banks, and in a few states giving them an opportunity to represent their groups in SHGs
federations at the village and higher levels. While SHG federations are still being formed in

                                                                                                    11
most states, in a few states such as AP they have started playing an increasingly active role in
                    delivering economic and social services (Chapter 3). Last year's report made the point that now
                    that the goal of making a significant dent on the challenge of financial inclusion seems attainable,
                    the sector should pay more attention to quality issues. It expressed the concern that growth in
                    the SBLP in particular was running ahead of the programme's capacity to ensure quality. The
                    programme has decelerated only slightly this year in terms of new groups linked, and not at all
                    in respect of loans disbursed (which now amount to a cumulative amount of Rs 18,000 crores
                    (Chapter 2). Indeed the SBLP is now growing under its own momentum.

                    There is of course a need to accelerate growth in the underserved states which are mostly in
 Although there     the central and eastern regions, and slower growth in the programme as a whole will not in
  are some well
           known    itself lead to higher quality in terms of depth of outreach (the proportion of SHG members
     exceptions,    below the poverty line), or in book-keeping capacity, which is crucial for a whole range of
 including MFIs     performance variables such as the drop-out rate, the equity of loan distribution within groups,
     who rely on
  methods such      and indeed of the longevity of groups themselves. There have been no reported new approaches
 as an easy-to-     by NGOs promoting SHGs, or by NABARD, in tackling the phenomenon of self-exclusion, by
     use housing
index to target
                    introducing lower and more flexible monthly savings requirements in keeping with the variable
the poor, most      and uncertain incomes of the poor. Assistance to promoting NGOs remains inadequate to
     MFIs, while    enable them to provide training inputs for long enough to ensure group sustainability. Studies
contributing to
    the financial   show that groups promoted by field level government functionaries who are given targets in
        inclusion   addition to their regular duties, tend to be the weakest, and receive the lowest hand-holding
  objective, are
                    inputs after the groups have been formed. While progress is being made in expanding the
      making no
 special efforts    programme in 13 priority states as discussed in Chapter 2, it is being achieved on the basis of
   to target the    government-promoted groups, since these are the states where good NGOs tend be thinnest
             poor
                    on the ground. It would enhance quality consciousness at all levels of the programme if
                    NABARD could include in its annual report on the programme, information on the quality of
                    groups. A grading system has already been prescribed for purposes of loan appraisal by the
                    banks, but it is not being used in monitoring of the programme. Grading would of course have
                    to be done on a sample basis given the immensity of the task of grading all groups.

                    Increasing the depth of outreach is equally urgent for MFIs,5 although it could be argued that
                    as the SHG programme expands to all parts of the country SHGs should attempt to meet the
                    demand for household consumption and emergency loans and for relatively small investment
                    loans for income generation activities, while allowing MFIs to cater to the market for larger
                    loans, which is growing rapidly in the rural areas. The emergence of some such division of
                    labour will help reduce MFI transactions costs and therefore interest charged to MFI borrowers.
                    SHGs are designed to internalize these costs. Although they do so, they end up charging their
                    borrowers about the same rates as MFIs, in order to build up group capital. The modal SHG
                    charges 2 percent per month, or 24 percent per annum, as against average MFI rates for the
                    country as a whole of 21 percent as self-reported by 129 MFIs in Sa-Dhan 2007, or about 25
                    percent according to a smaller M-CRIL sample (Chapter 4).6

                    However, until some such division of labour takes place it would be unfortunate if MFIs in
                    their urge to expand and reduce unit costs increasingly neglect the poorest borrowers, as
                    seems to be already happening. Although there are some well known exceptions, including
                    MFIs who rely on methods such as an easy-to-use housing index to target the poor,7 most
                    MFIs, while contributing to the financial inclusion objective, are making no special efforts to
                    target the poor. For many of them, lending to the poorest borrowers is increasingly becoming
                12
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                              Overview




a niche activity, assigned to special projects. Many of them are increasingly describing their
target group in such terms as the "the sub-prime market", the "missing middle", "low income
groups" etc.8

Depth of outreach is one of the social performance variables that the new social rating tools
being developed in India and elsewhere seek to monitor (Chapter 6). Client satisfaction and
client protection issues are other social performance quality variables that have come to the
fore in India after last year's Krishna district episode (Chapter 4 of last year's report).


The on-lending funds constraint makes a reappearance
As last year's report points out, there was a time when MFI managers had to devote most of
their time and energy to dealing with the uncertainty of where the next loan for on-lending
funds was going to come from. However the rapid expansion of commercial bank lending to
the sector from 2004 led to the happy situation in which this was no longer the case. MFI
lending grew rapidly, both through the expansion of existing MFIs and the incubation of new
ones, and the Indian microfinance sector became one the most highly leveraged in the world
(Chapter 3, last year's report).

However, developments during the year have made it more difficult to be as sanguine as before
                                                                                                       The partnership
that the onlending funds constraint on continued growth of MFI's has for once and all been
                                                                                                       model in effect
removed. The rapid expansion of lending to MFIs was due largely to the introduction by ICICI           removed both
Bank of its "partnership model", under which loans to borrowers remained on the books of the           the equity and
                                                                                                       the on-lending
bank, off the balance sheet of the MFI partner, which only undertook loan origination, monitoring      funds
and collection services for a fee. Thus the MFI performed the role of a social intermediary, while     constraints at
credit risk was borne largely by the bank, although the MFI had to share the risk of default up to     one stroke...
                                                                                                       This major
a specified level, by providing a "first loss guarantee". This greatly reduced the amount of equity    innovation
with which an MFI required to support its borrowings, and the partnership model in effect              unfortunately
                                                                                                       came unstuck
removed both the equity and the on-lending funds constraints at one stroke.                            during the year

This major innovation unfortunately came unstuck during the year, initially due to the AP
crisis in March 2006 and regulatory concerns about KYC (Know Your Customer) requirements,
but thereafter because ICICI changed its own requirements under the partnership model, and
indeed its whole vision of the nature of the relationship it wants to have with its partners. By
March 2006, ICICI Bank's lending had grown to constitute about two-thirds of total lending
to the sector, with about 60 percent of its lending coming under the partnership model.9
However, instead of increasing sharply again as in previous years, ICICI's lending has declined
in 2006-07, and is likely to stay relatively low in the current year. One of the concerns raised
by the AP crisis was the possibility of multiple borrowing by MFI customers from both the
major MFIs in the district concerned, both of who were major partners of the bank under the
partnership model. While there is no evidence that this led to over-lending as reflected in an
inability to repay loans,10 ICICI was urged by the RBI to strengthen its KYC procedures now
that the loans were on the bank's own books and not on those of the partner.11

It took some time for ICICI's partners to furnish the relevant information, during which time
fresh lending under the partnership model was suspended. It was partly substituted by term
loans, but not in sufficient amounts to alleviate the stress being experienced by partners who
were now strapped for funds. While other banks increased their lending, it was mostly to

                                                                                                  13
existing partners, although some switching may have taken place. Box 1.1 describes the loan
 fund stringency caused to a major partner of the bank, an experience not untypical of that
 undergone by a number of former partners, especially the smaller ones.12

                 Box 1.1      Cashpor: Stoppage of Partnership Funding

 This was an unexpected and major challenge for the Company during the last Fiscal. Funds
 stopped flowing, suddenly and without notice, from our major off-balance sheet funder in
 early September. As about half (47%) of our total portfolio was under Partnership, and it
 amounted to Rs. 29.2 crore, danger signals started flashing. To make things worse, we could
 not get a clear explanation from the Bank, nor any indication as to when the funds would flow
 again. Normally under Partnership, our portfolio grows over-time according to demand from
 clients, as the funds are on tap. For efficient fund management the practice is to contra due
 repayments against new loan disbursement. If there are no longer any funds for new
 disbursement, however, due repayments still have to be made - taking funds out of circulation
 in the field. With the stoppage of funds, not only did we have to find new funds for new
 clients but also for subsequent loans of existing clients. Suddenly we needed about Rs.6 crore
 of new funds, every month! Fortunately we had been negotiating with two other banks to
 provide funding under Partnership, so as to diversify our sources of that important category
 of funding. They agreed to start funding under Partnership, and we transferred 4 of the 6
 Districts funded under partnership to them. One of them got cold feet, however, at the last
 moment, as there were rumours circulating that the RBI was not happy with Partnership
 funding, and had directed the major bank involved to stop it. Similar rumours have continued
 to circulate and have even appeared in the press; but RBI has not issued any public clarification.
 Meanwhile, after a month and a half, our original Partner Bank, offered a term loan to replace
 its Partnership funding, which the Company accepted. Then in December, funds started flowing
 again under Partnership. Then, just as suddenly and without notice, the flow stopped again
 in early January. It had not resumed by end of the Fiscal; but the Bank has made an additional
 term loan available. Nevertheless, the irregularity and uncertainty over the flow of Partnership
 funds have caused considerable delay and confusion on the ground among clients and staff of
 the Company. The continuing failure of the Bank and RBI to inform the MFIs and the public as
 to the reasons for the stoppage and if and how the flow of funds could be resumed is creating
 uncertainty which is unhealthy for the financial system…Partnership funding was a break-
 through to reaching increasing numbers of BPL households with financial services. Its stoppage
 removes economic opportunity from them.
 Informally we have discovered that the proximate reason for the stoppages in Partnership
 funding last Fiscal was strict new guidelines that RBI insisted for it. It seems that the main
 Bank involved was slow to meet these requirements, did not inform its partner MFIs clearly
 about them and their deadlines, and finally was instructed by their own legal department that
 they were in violation and had to stop.
 We are now clear that Partnership funding can resume when RBI KYC (Know Your Client)
 requirements are fully-met and compliance is maintained, and when the banks involved receive
 day-end transaction information for clients under Partnership. KYC requirements are being
 fully complied with by CMC; and we will soon test the FINO technological solution for providing
 day-end transaction information to the banks. Partnership funding is expected to resume as
 the new technology spreads.
 It might be asked as to why the Company wishes to resume Partnership funding, when it and
 the main Bank involved have been unreliable? The answer is simple. Our overriding objective
 is increase in our outreach to BPL households. Partnership funding, as imperfect as it has
 been, enables us to expand that outreach twice as much as we could without it.
 Extract from "Highlights from the Chairman", in "CASHPOR Annual Report, 2006-07:
 Crossing Two Lac BPL Clients", CASHPOR, Varanasi, 2007


14
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                                Overview




And technology makes an entry
During this period it seems ICICI's own thinking underwent a change as it gained a better
understanding of the limitations of the MIS systems of most of its partners. Many MFIs are still
putting in place computerized information systems that can track ever-larger number of
transactions and branch accounts. MIS systems are the foundation of other technology
applications, and are discussed in Chapter 8. It came around to the view that without major
reliance on technology (and renewed inputs of capacity-building) most partners would not be
available to furnish KYC (Know Your Customer) information in a timely fashion, and certainly
not by the "end of day", as required under the guidelines of the business correspondent model
(see below). However, there was an even more important reason for why ICICI Bank came to
feel the need to reflect all transactions in its books on a real time basis, which had to do with
the bank's own rethinking of its stance towards microfinance.

The bank has always been interested in developing what it has called the "missing markets" of           Many MFIs are
complementary infrastructure, including shared borrower information systems. It is making a             still putting in
                                                                                                        place
major effort to introduce smart cards bearing unique ID numbers and biometric information               computerized
(finger prints) that will help identify customers, track service usage, and build up customer           information
                                                                                                        systems that
histories. In the longer term this will be an essential element in the creation of credit information
                                                                                                        can track ever-
systems such as credit bureaus. The "front-end" technology will have to be supported however            larger number
by "back-end" "core banking" infrastructure consisting of "hosted" or centralized software,             of transactions
                                                                                                        and branch
which can be shared by several customers, and which can communicate with hand held devices              accounts. MIS
(or POS or "point of sale" terminals) in the field, which read and record transaction information       systems are the
                                                                                                        foundation of
on the customer's smart cards. If internet connectivity is available, the smart cards can be
                                                                                                        other
used on a real time basis, enabling real-time sharing of credit information across the branch           technology
network. ICICI is supporting such a system through FINO, a company which seeks to provide               applications
a core banking solution, not just to MFIs but to other banks and financial institutions and
even state governments (Chapter 8).13

Partnership loans are being extended only to existing or new partners who are willing to sign
up for FINO, or any alternative core banking system.14 Only a small proportion of the bank's
former 100 odd partners are reported to have joined so far.15 As we have seen, for those former
partners who have decided not to join, lending flows have declined because term loans are
not intended to fully substitute for the former level of partnership flows.

While ICICI Bank continued to make term loans as an interim measure to alleviate distress, it
has veered around to a strong preference for partnership lending supported by technology for
the long-term advantage the combination of partnership lending and ICT holds out of being
able to generate customer information, not just on credit, but also on savings, insurance,
remittance and other transactions, built up through the use of smart cards. Smart cards are
being issued through partners to all borrowers. ICICI has also launched pilots to collect
savings through smart cards and point of sale devices through several partners around the
country under the business correspondent scheme, and expects eventually to be able to make
individual loans to the same customers on the basis of the customer information built up.16
Conversely it has lost interest in making term loans to MFIs conducting group lending along
traditional minimalist lines.

Given the radically changed perspective on the part of the major lender it is possible we are

                                                                                                    15
Given the    likely to be in the midst of at least a temporary hiccup in the growth rate of lending under the
         radically   MFI model, especially to medium sized and small MFIs, until other banks and bulk lenders such
          changed
 perspective on      as SIDBI, FWWB, and others can step in to fill the breach.17 While banks other than ICICI have
the part of the      been increasing their lending quite sharply, they are doing so from a relatively small base.18
major lender it
                     Independently of these developments, the World Bank is reported to be considering making a
  is possible we
are likely to be     loan to SIDBI which would enable SIDBI to further step up its lending, and make longer term
in the midst of      loans with the grace periods necessary to finance MFI deficits in the initial years. Demand for
        at least a
       temporary     such loans is certainly likely to strengthen, especially on the part of smaller MFIs who may not
    hiccup in the    be able to attract the equity investments which could temporarily alleviate credit stringency
 growth rate of
                     for larger MFIs. A greater diversity of lenders will reduce unhealthy dependence on a single
   lending under
the MFI model,       large lender. Another possible source of funds are member savings which in Bangladesh
    especially to    contribute about a third of the funding base, while lowering at the same time the average
   medium sized
and small MFIs,      cost of funds (Chapter 9). However this option is not proposed to be made available to the
      until other    bulk of the sector consisting of NBFCs and S 25 companies by the emerging regulatory regime
 banks and bulk      for the sector, as discussed below.
lenders such as
  SIDBI, FWWB,
 and others can
   step in to fill
                     Private equity also makes an entry, but what are the
       the breach    implications?
                     Two landmark private equity investments in Indian MFIs took place in the first part of the year;
                     a $ 11.5 million investment in SKS, led by Sequoia Capital, at the end of March, followed soon
                     after by a $25 million investment in SHARE, by Legatum Capital. Hyderabad-based SKS is the
                     third largest MFI in India (Table A.2), and is growing perhaps the most rapidly, hoping to end
                     the current financial year with an outreach of about 1.5 million borrowers in 11 states. Sequoia
                     was joined by Unitus equity fund, which already has 2 equity investment partners in India and
                     8 other "capacity building" partners through an associated foundation with offices in Bangalore,
                     as well as by Vinod Khosla and other investors. This infusion of fresh equity enabled SKS to
                     leverage a Rs 180 crore financial arrangement with Citibank India to finance its expansion
                     plans. Under the deal, Citibank will purchase loans originated by SKS under a limited guarantee
                     provided by US-based Grameen Foundation, which also has an office in India.19

                     SHARE is India's largest MFI with over 1 million clients and has plans to grow to 6 million over
                     the next five years. When lending under ICICI Bank's partnership model was suspended at the
                     beginning of the year until partners could fulfill KYC requirements SHARE found itself strapped
                     not just for lending funds, but short of the equity capital with which to borrow them as term
                     loans from the banks. Legatum's investment gives it majority control of SHARE. It was
                     accompanied by a $2 million investment by Aavishkaar Goodwell Microfinance Development
                     Company, an Indo-Dutch joint venture,20 which becomes the fifth social venture capital company
                     to have a presence in India (Table A.4, and Chapter 7B, last year's report).

                     The size of these investments is unusual even by Latin American standards. One came just
                     before, and the other just after Banco Compartamos, a Mexican bank specializing in
                     microfinance, that had started life as an NGO, made an initial public offering of 30 percent of
                     its stocks on Wall Street, in April. The success of the Compartamos floatation, and the size of
                     the SKS and SHARE private placements occasioned considerable excitement world-wide. These
                     were investments by mainstream commercial (as opposed to socially-motivated) investors,
                     whose support would accelerate the mobilization of private capital for massive expansion of

                 16
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                              Overview




outreach. They were seen as heralding the beginning of large private placements in microfinance
as "investors now have a clear line of sight towards an exit" (Satterthwaite 2007).

However, the huge profits made by the shareholders of Compartamos also stirred world-wide
debate about "whether this was what microfinance was all about". The IPO was oversubscribed
13 times and the share price surged by 22 percent on the first day of trading alone. Two-
thirds of the shares were held by public-purpose institutions and a third were held by private
individuals, including the co-founders of the NGO.21 The issues raised by Compartamos have
been discussed comprehensively in a CGAP study. It points out the extremely high profitability
of Banco (resulting in a return to equity of over 50 percent a year) was based on interest rates
that were high even by Mexican standards (CGAP 2007). The study felt that that as long as
Compartamos was an NGO, its strategy of funding growth on the basis of unusually high profits         The study felt
and retained earnings so as to expand coverage rapidly to new borrowers, was justified. But           that that as
                                                                                                      long as
once it commercialized in 2000,22 and private investors stood to benefit, it should have              Compartamos
funded further growth by tapping into the rapidly expanding flow of funds from socially-              was an NGO, its
                                                                                                      strategy of
minded investors and development-oriented lenders. This would have enabled it to decrease             funding growth
interest rates considerably. As the report says "it seems to us at CGAP that after 2000 there         on the basis of
was a direct conflict between the profits of private investors and the financial interest of          unusually high
                                                                                                      profits and
Compartamos borrowers. We don't think that Compartamos and its pro-bono majority                      retained
shareholders gave enough weight to borrowers when setting its prices"                                 earnings so as
                                                                                                      to expand
                                                                                                      coverage
It pointed out further that the high IPO prices sets in place expectations and alters the
                                                                                                      rapidly to new
ownership structure of Compartamos in such a way that will make it even harder for the                borrowers, was
company to balance social and commercial objectives in the future. The not-for-profit                 justified. But
                                                                                                      once it
institutional shareholders are now in a minority by a tiny margin, although they can still            commercialized
exercise effective control if they vote together. However, the "…practical implication is that        in 2000, and
                                                                                                      private
new purchasers cannot realize a respectable return on their investment unless future profitability
                                                                                                      investors stood
is considerably higher than it already was in 2006…new investors…will have little sympathy            to benefit, it
for interest rate policies that do not stretch profits to the maximum …"                              should have
                                                                                                      funded further
                                                                                                      growth by
The report is candid enough to admit that "those of us who are involved in MFI transformations        tapping into
may need to be clearer about the inevitable governance consequences of those transformations…         the rapidly
since our founding in 1995, CGAP has been vocal about the need for interest rates that are high       expanding flow
                                                                                                      of funds from
enough to cover costs, but we have been less emphatic about the loss to clients when interest         socially-minded
rates are driven by inefficiency or exorbitant profits. We never made concrete predictions about      investors and
                                                                                                      development-
how quickly competition would fix these problems, but we were probably too optimistic on this         oriented
score. The Compartamos IPO gives all of us an opportunity to take another look at these questions."   lenders

Some of the issues raised in the Compartamos debate were reflected in India too, for example
in the debate carried by Microfinance Insights, a quarterly publication by Intellecap, the
microfinance consultingancy company, between the founders of SKS, SHARE and the Basix
group of companies. The flavour of the debate is conveyed by extracts in Box 1.2. The key
question is what is the impact of large commercial investments likely to be on the Indian
microfinance sector and the borrower? India already has a group of microfinance venture
capital funds driven by a mix of social and commercial objectives23 and they have been active
during the year, investing both in "transformees" (see below) and start-ups. As a group, they
have longer time horizons and probably lower-return expectations than the new private equity
investors.24 However, they cannot hope to match the scale of investments required by the

                                                                                                  17
larger MFIs or the sector as a whole, especially after the sharp decline in the number of MFIs
                     under the partnership model.

                     The pressure to maximize returns by the new PE investors is unlikely to result in upward
                     pressure on interest rates, as was the case with Compartamos, although it could dampen the
                     decline of rates that should come with further growth. Public, political and regulator
                     acceptability will not allow high rates in India. With this option cut off, the pressure to
                     maximize returns is likely to take the form of the desire to reach massive scale. This portends
                     well for financial inclusion, and for better regional balance of MFI lending, since the large
                     MFIs are stepping out of their base in Andhra, but it does not portend as well for the quality
                     of growth. The problems in AP in 2006 were caused by "the rush to grow". Moreover, since
                     organic growth yields slower increases in scale than mergers and acquisitions, it is widely
                     expected that the sector will witness mergers between MFIs.25 Further large investments by
                     private equity are also expected, with the possibility of IPOs.26

The pressure to      Recent developments on the equity front have been welcomed by most observers as the only
       maximize
returns is likely    means of meeting the huge equity requirements of a rapidly expanding, but increasingly
     to take the     capital inadequate sector (Chapter 4). The Indian sector is now seen to be attracting the
     form of the     whole spectrum of funding from purely commercial private equity at one end to grants at the
 desire to reach
  massive scale.     other, although the latter are much less important than in other countries. It is too early to
   This portends     say whether the concerns of the pessimists will materialize. There is little doubt that there is
          well for
        financial
                     considerable interest among new investors in entering the sector, despite declining margins
  inclusion, and     being squeezed by rising costs and limits to acceptable interest rate increases (Chapter 4).27
       for better    There is no dearth of potential investees either, as more and more non-profits are lining up to
         regional
  balance of MFI     transform to NBFCs, a phenomenon driven primarily by capital adequacy concerns, but also by
  lending, since     the enhanced sense of vulnerability induced by the AP crisis. The new bill which seeks to
  the large MFIs
                     confer a modicum of legitimacy to non-profits does not seem to be stemming the flow of non-
    are stepping
     out of their    profits voting with their feet. An active market has developed in NBFC licenses not being used
base in Andhra,      by the original owners which are being brought up for a premium by transforming NGOs.28 Thus
 but it does not
 portend as well     the chain of consequences set in motion by the Andhra crisis is still playing itself out. By
 for the quality     putting an end to partnership lending in the form we knew it, it has increased the demand for
       of growth
                     term loans, which in turn have increased the demand for equity, and have led to a spate of
                     transformations to NBFC status. The new microfinance bill is out of tune with these
                     developments, as discussed next.


                     The new microfinance bill takes a small but important
                     step forward in allowing NGO-MFIs to mobilize savings,
                     but limits savings to "thrift"
                     The absence of savings in Indian microfinance has distinguished it till now from microfinance
                     in most other countries, and has been likened to "walking on one leg" since without savings
                     microfinance is not microfinance at all but microcredit. There is a widespread misconception
                     that the poor are too poor to save, and that they need credit, not savings facilities. On the
                     contrary, as Chapter 9 points out, savings is probably a more widely felt need than credit, and
                     takes place through a variety of savings mechanisms and institutions in the informal sector.29
                     Like the rest of us, the poor are looking for savings services which are convenient, safe,
                     liquid, and can preferably be used to leverage loans.
                 18
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                             Overview




By allowing at least what it call micro finance organizations (MFOs) to meet this need, the
draft microfinance bill takes an important step forward. However, ironically, it is this aspect
of the bill that has been the most widely misunderstood by critics. India's attitude to
savings mobilization by non-banks has been more restrictive than elsewhere, an attitude
influenced by exaggerated perceptions of fraud in the informal and cooperative sectors,
and strengthened by periodic scams which affect the savings of the urban middle classes
and which therefore receive widespread publicity in the press. Most of the countries of
South Asia, which share the same legal heritage, now expressly allow savings to registered
MFIs in their microfinance legislation. Bangladesh, where conditions are closest to India,
and where the MFI model originated, has recently passed the Micro Credit Regulatory Authority
(MCRA) Act 2006, which allows the MCRA to allow registered MFIs to offer savings withdrawable
on demand.

Unfortunately, the bill limits permissible savings to what it calls thrift, or the small, Indeed,
                                                                                          recognizing the
compulsory savings of uniform size for all members. While the proposal to allow thrift is
                                                                                                    liquidity
welcome and long overdue, it is important to note it is only the first small step forward in        preference of
introducing savings. While many savers welcome the discipline of compulsory savings,                the poor for
                                                                                                    many although
they tend to belong to the better-off among the poor, or to the "near-poor" above the               not all savings
poverty line. On the other hand many of the poorer members of SHGs (and most of the                 purposes,
                                                                                                    several MFIs in
self-excluded non-members), who have highly uncertain and variable incomes, would prefer
                                                                                                    Bangladesh, and
to save small variable amounts, with variable frequency. Several surveys have found that the        indeed world-
main reason for why only half the members of SHGs are below the poverty line is the                 wide, who have
                                                                                                    the requisite
inability of BPL persons to commit themselves to the required mandatory savings amounts             accounting
and periodicities. Uniform mandatory savings are also the most frequent reason cited by             systems, are
drop-outs for leaving SHGs.                                                                         moving to a
                                                                                                    system of
                                                                                                    voluntary
A concomitant of mandatory savings products is their illiquidity. While illiquid savings protect    savings in
the savings of the poor from daily demands, and are suited to accumulating lump-sums for            which the saver
                                                                                                    has some choice
expected purposes such as life-cycle events or school fees or adding a new room to the hut,         over the timing
they are unsuited to coping with unexpected emergencies including sickness and disease, or          and amount of
consumption smoothening in the lean season, or replacing a leaky roof in the middle of the          savings and
                                                                                                    withdrawals
monsoons. Indeed, recognizing the liquidity preference of the poor for many although not all
savings purposes, several MFIs in Bangladesh, and indeed world-wide, who have the requisite
accounting systems, are moving to a system of voluntary savings in which the saver has some
choice over the timing and amount of savings and withdrawals. It is not being suggested that
most small Indian NGO-MFIs have developed the requisite systems to be able to able to offer
such a savings product yet, or that mandatory savings do not have their advantages for
certain purposes.

However, provision should be made for the day when a larger number of NGO-MFIs have developed
the requisites systems and capacity to offer voluntary savings. Also, there is a possibility that
the bill may be amended to include NBFCs and S 25 companies, who do have such capacities.
Since voluntary savings are more conveniently offered as individual savings (because voluntary
savings amounts and frequency will always vary from individual to individual), it would seem
essential to allow the regulator the option to approve individual, voluntary, savings products
in appropriate cases after due diligence by the regulator on a case by case basis.



                                                                                                19
Moreover, the microfinance bill excludes the larger,
                    and more rapidly growing part of the sector
                    One of the major omissions in the bill is that it excludes MFIs registered as NBFCs and S 25
                    companies, which account for nearly all the large MFIs, and the larger part of total microcredit
                    in the country. Their number is steadily increasing, as more and NGO-MFIs transform themselves
                    into companies for the reasons discussed above. The argument usually adduced for keeping
                    NBFCs outside the purview of the bill is that they are already regulated by the RBI. However,
                    the argument applies equally to district, state and urban cooperative banks which are governed
                    by the Banking Regulation Act in respect of banking activities, while conforming to the
                    cooperative law in other respects. Like them, NBFCs would be governed by the microfinance
                    bill in respect of thrift activities, without any dilution of their capital, reserve, or liquidity
                    requirements as NBFCs.

         There is   The irony is that not only can NBFC-MFIs not accept public deposits, by virtue of being
 understandable
                    excluded from the bill they will not be able to accept the savings of their own borrower-
   reluctance to
   allow MFIs to    members either,30 who will continue to have to rely on less convenient, riskier lower yielding,
 mobilize public    and often socially less productive savings instruments (such as ornaments). There is
        deposits,
without putting     understandable reluctance to allow MFIs to mobilize public deposits, without putting in place
     in place the   the necessary safequards, for sound prudential reasons. But the vast majority of MFI members
        necessary
                    are net borrowers of the MFI at any one time. They borrow to finance their larger investment
 safequards, for
            sound   requirements, but simultaneously save small amounts regularly to finance their liquidity
       prudential   requirements, provide for emergencies, build up a cushion to tide over the lean season when
    reasons. But
         the vast   agricultural wage employment is scarce, and aggregate savings into amounts large enough to
majority of MFI     make useful investments, repair the hut, send a daughter to high school, or a son to the big
    members are     city to look for work. Since they are net borrowers, prudential concerns are much less pressing.
  net borrowers
   of the MFI at
   any one time     So are we missing an important opportunity with the
                    microfinance bill?
                    In excluding NBFCs and S 25 companies, the act will also deprive more than half of borrowers
                    from the protection of the ombudsman envisaged under the bill, and the sector as a whole
                    from the benefits of universal performance standards in respect of microfinance activities,
                    and a much needed data base. The bill confers a modicum of legitimacy on the most vulnerable
                    part of the sector, the NGO-MFIs, but is careful not to step on the toes of the states by failing
                    to assert that the principle of cost-recovering interest rates takes precedence over caps on
                    interest rates under state moneylender acts.

                    The bill violates the spirit and intent of the new MACS acts in reducing the role of government
                    in cooperation. It is true that the registrars under the new acts are not performing supervisory,
                    data gathering and consumer protection functions any better than the old ones, but will the
                    new regulator be able to do a better job for thousands of thrift cooperatives all over the
                    country? In any case cooperation is a state subject, and the states will have to sign on,
                    unless the courts take the narrow view that accepting thrift even from one's own member-
                    borrowers constitutes "banking", which is a central subject.

                    The bill does not provide the sector with a form of registration uniquely suited to microfinance.

                20
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                                 Overview




It leaves NGO-MFIs with no alternative between remaining NGOs and having to raise enough the envisaged
                                                                                                         Microfinance
capital to become NBFCs. Societies and trusts were not designed as vehicles for financial                Development
operations, and although NGO-MFIs are non-profits, they have a hard time convincing the                  Council will be a
                                                                                                         government
local income tax authorities that their surpluses are intended for expansion and leverage of
                                                                                                         dominated body
borrowed funds. "Special-window" MFIs, with lower entry capital but higher capital adequacy              with a purely
requirements, as a unique legal form under the act, would have constituted a valuable                    advisory role.
                                                                                                         Given the fact
intermediate stage of incorporation between remaining an NGO and becoming a full-fledged                 that the
NBFC.                                                                                                    microfinance
                                                                                                         sector, like the
                                                                                                         IT sector, has
Finally, as Chapter 9 points out, the envisaged Microfinance Development Council will be a
                                                                                                         grown so rapidly
government dominated body with a purely advisory role. Given the fact that the microfinance              and in many
sector, like the IT sector, has grown so rapidly and in many ways creatively, precisely because          ways creatively,
                                                                                                         precisely
it was outside the government, one would have thought that sector representation on the                  because it was
council would be higher, and that it would be given much greater autonomy. For all these                 outside the
reasons, discussed at greater length in Chapter 9, the bill, as it presently stands, may be              government,
                                                                                                         one would have
missing an important opportunity.                                                                        thought that
                                                                                                         sector
Why has commercial microfinance been excluded from                                                       representation
                                                                                                         on the council
the bill? Three alternatives views of the role of                                                        would be higher,
                                                                                                         and that it
microfinance                                                                                             would be given
                                                                                                         much greater
                                                                                                         autonomy
The exclusion of MFIs has brought into sharper focus three different visions of the role of the
sector. The first accords an important place to financial intermediation as a means of offering
savings as an essential financial service to the poor, since MFIs under the group lending
model meet their borrowers once a week anyway, and therefore enjoy economies of scope in
being able to collect savings cheaply and conveniently along with loan repayment installments.
Most savers at any one time remain net borrowers of the MFI, which fund the bulk of their on-
lending requirement initially from donors and apex financial institutions with access to soft
funds, and then from more commercial sources. As NGO-MFIs strengthen their capacity and
profitability and transform into for-profit entities they apply for licenses to mobilize the
savings also of non-members, or the public. This is essentially the path along which microfinance
has developed in most countries where the Grameen bank group lending model is dominant, as
it is Asia and in countries in many other regions.

In India, however, MFIs have not been allowed to mobilize savings even from their borrower
members. They have had to rely exclusively on borrowings to fund their growth, acting as
retailers of whole sale funds borrowed from the banks and financial institutions. They have
been valued primarily as retailers of "last mile" services in delivering credit to borrowers the
banks are not in a position to reach directly. The microfinance bill seeks to allow NGO-MFIs to
conduct limited financial intermediation but only in the form of thrift or small, weekly,
compulsory savings. By excluding NBFC and S 25 companies from the purview of the bill it
denies this limited savings opportunity to their members, as well as cheaper funds to the MFIs
themselves, which might enable them to reduce their interest rates.

However there is a third view of the role of MFIs purely as facilitators of credit and other financial
service,s and providers of credit-plus services. The partnership model as noted above has always
envisaged the MFI as playing the role of a social intermediary, identifying and monitoring

                                                                                                     21
borrowers and servicing collections for a fee. The major lender to the sector seems to be
                veering round to the view that new developments in technology have strengthened the
                suitability of the model to the extent that in the long run it may be able to dispense with the
                services of MFIs altogether, relying instead on a range of business facilitators and correspondents
                such as internet kiosks, post offices, merchant vendors (when the guidelines allow it) or even
                trustworthy local individuals, to provide essential local knowledge and information on borrowers,
                and enable it, on the basis of credit histories on such borrowers built up through their
                savings and other behaviour, to eventually lend to them directly (just as MFIs do, with
                graduates of group lending).

                This third view, which might be called the facilitator or agent view, is also the view that the RBI
                seems to be veering around to. It was first articulated in the RBI's business facilitator and
                business correspondent circular of January 2006.31 The Deputy Governor of the RBI responsible
                for regulatory issues enunciated it most recently at a Sa-Dhan meeting when she envisaged
                financial inclusion depending not just on technology but also on the "credit plus services
                that community based organizations are able to provide because of enjoying the trust of local
                persons, having knowledge of the local community and being able to facilitate financial
This third view,
which might be  literacy, credit counseling, and garner credit information…" (Thorat 2007). This view of the
                role of MFIs was expressed even more explicitly in a recent speech in which she said "… the
       called the
   facilitator or
                real value of NGOs and MFIs lies in their role as providing "credit plus" services and not just
  agent view, is
   also the viewfunctioning as an intermediary for onlending. Banks with their resources and scale have
    that the RBI greater cost advantages, but linking with local community based organizations and local
    seems to be
 veering around
                  persons/entities would help them get over the information gap and access barriers" (Thorat
               to 2007).

                Efforts at extending financial inclusions by the banks in India have focused so far largely on
                savings products. The greatest progress had been made in opening "no-frills" zero-balance
                savings accounts which numbered 6 lakhs by March 2007. In mobilizing savings, banks have
                an advantage over MFIs in that the savings are insured. In her Sa-Dhan speech the Deputy
                Governor referred to another advantage bank savings have over MFI savings, that of "being
                able to obtain access to the national payments systems through bank accounts - or in countries
                where the regulatory system allows, through electronic accounts with such service providers
                facilitated by mobile phones. In South Africa and Brazil, for example, efforts at financial
                inclusion are targeted at enabling easier and low cost access to payments systems for money
                transfers, utility payments, and other daily transactions" (Thorat 2007). The financial inclusion
                movements seeks to remove the disadvantages the banks have traditionally suffered from in
                respect of access, and the liquidity of their savings for the poor.32 However until it succeeds
                in doing so, it is the regulatory prohibition that restricts MFIs in India to contributing to
                financial inclusion through the remaining three financial services - credit, insurance and
                money transfers.

                Credit, with the contraction of the partnership model, has reverted for the time being to
                being provided by MFIs almost entirely as intermediaries retailing funds wholesaled by the
                banks. Insurance services however are being provided mostly in an agency role (Chapter 7).
                The provision of remittance services has been rudimentary so far, but for regulatory reasons
                will also have to be provided in the agency role.33 An example of a pilot project being
                implemented by BASIX in partnership with Axisbank and the technology provider, A Little
                World, that provides a remittance service using mobile phones, is described in Box 8.3.
              22
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                              Overview




MFIs have not succeeded (or shown much interest for that matter) in providing credit under
the BC scheme because of the interest rate cap on small loans which has rendered the BC
scheme dysfunctional as far as credit is concerned (Chapter 9)34 Even if there were no cap
however, and even after the full development of the ICT applications discussed above, there is
no presumption that the BC role is more suited to MFI credit than the financial intermediary
or last-mile retailer role.35 MFIs will always have a comparative advantage over banks in being
able to originate, monitor and collect micro loans. This advantage also derives form technology,
but from a technology of a softer kind, the technology of group lending pioneered by the
Grameen Bank. While group lending does have well known disadvantages, and while alternative
channels to reach the borrower will and should develop, it is difficult to see how MFIs, with
their field presence, will lose their comparative advantage in identifying creditworthy borrowers,
providing them with hand-holding support, and dealing with delinquencies. This advantage
can be put to use in any of the three roles, but MFIs have shown a distinct preference so far
for the first two. This may be for non-financial reasons as much as financial.36 It is perhaps no
                                                                                           MFIs will always
coincidence that even in Brazil the services that are being provided by agents (including  have a
merchant outlets such as shops, who are not eligible under India's BC scheme) are mostly   comparative
                                                                                           advantage over
remittances, bill payments, and savings services, but not credit. The stance the RBI appears
                                                                                           banks in being
to be developing on the other hand is that in the long run MFIs should function as banking able to
                                                                                           originate,
correspondents and agents for all services, including credit, although last mile retailing will
                                                                                           monitor and
continue to be allowed. It is this vision of the long run role of MFIs that appears to explain
                                                                                           collect micro
the exclusion of NBFCs MFIs from the microfinance bill, even more than concerns about dual loans
regulation of microfinance NBFCs.


Early experience with the new urban microfinance
A major development during the last couple of years has been the upsurge of interest in urban
microfinance (Chapter 5). The urban areas have remained virtually uncharted territory, except by
a few prominent exceptions such as SEWA Bank, despite the prospects of (i) huge loan demand,
(ii) larger average loan size and higher population density making for lower costs, (iii) the need
to reach the growing numbers of the urban poor, and (iv) the example of Latin America where
microfinance is predominantly urban. The rate of urbanization in India has increased sharply in
the 1990s to almost twice the rural population growth rate, the difference being driven by
migration from the rural areas.37 Moreover, while urban poverty is declining in relative terms, it
is increasing in absolute terms.38 India's metros and large towns have some of the most congested
slums in the world and are "home" to some of the worst living conditions anywhere.39

One of the main reasons why MFIs were reluctant to initiate operations in the urban areas was
their apprehension that the Grameen-style group lending model, which was proving so successful
in the rural areas, was too dependent on peer-pressure and mutual trust, based on long-
standing neighbourhood and kinship ties, to be successful in the urban slums. Also the one-
size-fits-all standardization (of loan size and duration) and the borrower- time requirements
(attendance at weekly meetings) of the group-lending model might prove a handicap in the
much more heterogenous and time-constrained environment of urban slum-dwellers.

However mobility and transience have proved to be much less of a problem than was originally
feared, and the new urban MFIs are finding that many slum dwellers have been living in the same
location for a generation or more, and that even if they go home to their villages for a couple of
months a year they come back to the same area because of proximity to a known livelihood.
                                                                                                 23
More of a problem it turns out is that as many as a third of borrowers have no formal documentation
                      to establish either identity or address. More of a problem, also, than mobility per se, is what
                      might be called "involuntary mobility", caused by the ongoing drive in many cities to demolish
                      slums and relocate them elsewhere, and by the widening of roads, etc. Also, even in slums where
                      a significant proportion of residents are transient, MFIs have to achieve a very high level of
                      penetration before running out of prospective borrower from among permanent residents. The
                      trick, they are learning, is a high success rate in spotting them.

                      As with many other generalizations, the obstacle posed by mobility and transience depends on
                      which income segment and location one is looking at. Many of the new urban MFIs intend to
                      cater primarily to the vast majority of permanent urban residents who are still unserved by the
                      banks, and depend largely on the informal sector for their financial needs. Reaching the transient
                      poor is not a primary goal, at least initially. For example, while MFIs in Kolkata would like to
                      serve the huge population of mostly day visitors who flood into the middle-class areas of South
                      Kolkata from the rural hinterland as day labourers and maids etc, or rickshaw drivers who park by
                      the wayside to sleep in their rickshaws at night, they are unlikely to be able to do so unless they
                      extend their operations to the peripheral rural areas, as many of them are in fact doing.

         It is well   It is well accepted that microfinance is best suited to reaching the economically active poor. It is
   accepted that
                      ill-suited to solving the problem of chronic income deficits. However it is also the case that there
 microfinance is
   best suited to     are many potential borrowers whose income deficits could be removed by credit if they were
     reaching the     combined with other inputs.40 The challenge is to identify such persons, and arrange for the
     economically
  active poor. It     provision of the other inputs by some other agency if necessary. While urban MFIs are cognizant of
  is ill-suited to    the need to offer a full set of financial services including savings, insurance and remittances, they
       solving the    intend to meet non-financial needs such as health and vocational training through partnerships
        problem of
  chronic income      with NGOs, other civil society organizations, and socially minded corporations.
          deficits.
    However it is     Some of the recent start-ups in the metros are promoted by professionals who have a proven
    also the case
   that there are
                      track record of successful careers in banking and other fields. Their backgrounds have been
 many potential       very successful in attracting lenders and investors. The new urban start-ups are growing
borrowers whose       particularly strongly in Bangalore and Kolkata, but are still nascent in Mumbai and Delhi. In
 income deficits
          could be    locations such as Hyderabad and other towns across the country existing rural MFIs are
      removed by      moving into contiguous urban and peri-urban areas. They are being joined by several NBFCs
    credit if they
                      who have already been operating in the urban areas but are now experimenting with
  were combined
        with other    "downscaling" to smaller loans. Banks in India have in effect been excluded from the small
            inputs    loans market by regulatory fiat. They are not allowed to make loans of less than Rs 200,000 at
                      a rate any higher than their PLR (their lending rate to prime customers) for the loans to
                      qualify as priority sector loans. Despite this cap, Yes Bank is pioneering individual loans in
                      urban microfinance. The Microsate branch of Indian Bank is successfully doing SHG-bank
                      linkage in Chennai (Chapter 5).

                      While the MFI human resources challenge - not just training, but attracting and retaining
                      staff - has been engaging the attention of the MFI community generally in the last few years
                      (Chapter 6 of last year's report), its severity in the urban areas has taken the new urban MFIs
                      by surprise. Nearly all of them are finding it difficult to recruit and retain staff in conditions
                      of a tightening job market, especially in cities like Bangalore where attrition rates are as high
                      as 20 to 30 percent a year. The skills field workers acquire are turning out to be in high
                      demand in other parts of the financial sector, and in marketing.

                  24
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                               Overview




The sector's infrastructure of support services is
gradually strengthening
Given its rate of growth, the human resource challenge remains the most important facing the
sector. It has not been possible to include a chapter this year on developments in training
and capacity building, but apart from the activities of the older, more established service
providers, the year saw several new initiatives, such as Intellecap's Microfinance Franchise Package
which seeks to incubate start-ups by providing training, manuals, and a complete business
plan and financial model combined with operational exposure in group formation, lending
processes, and branch and head office management at CASHPOR in Varanasi.41

With a view to channeling start-up and capacity building support to MFIs in underserved
regions, MicroSave relocated itself in the North, with a view to creating a centre of excellence
in microfinance at the IIM-Lucknow with links to SIDBI. In line with its plans to create a
cadre of 50-60 "low cost-high capacity" consultants spread out across India, it continued to
impart training in specialized areas such as loan portfolio audits, process mapping and new
product development. Work on running training workshops, and developing action research
partnerships and toolkits continued.

The amount of timely information and analysis on the sector on the sector is increasing
through publications such as Intellecap's quarterly Microfinance Insights which devotes
each issue to a special topic, and online publications such as the monthly Microfinance Focus.
Sa-Dhan achieved a major breakthrough by publishing “Quick Report 2007: A Snapshot of
Microfinance Institutions in India”, within just over four months of the closing of the financial
year. The report carries core data on the bulk of its membership. Although it based on self-
reported data prepared without waiting for audited annual reports, the report greatly enhances
the cause of transparency and timely public reporting.

A few, but not enough, extremely educative MFI annual reports are also being prepared which            A few, but not
                                                                                                       enough,
convey more than just the numbers but deal with the nitty-girtty issues facing the sector.42
                                                                                                       extremely
The MIX continues to contribute to the cause of transparency by expanding its reporting on             educative MFI
the performance indicators of the larger Indian MFIs in collaboration with M-CRIL. One of the          annual reports
                                                                                                       are also being
most useful developments in the last year has been UNDP's email-based Solutions Exchange
                                                                                                       prepared which
service which carries an active, high quality and widely-used exchange of views and information        convey more
on Indian microfinance. There is still a need however for greater timeliness and coverage in           than just the
                                                                                                       numbers but
the reports of some of the financial institutions, and for a timely annual statistical compendium,
                                                                                                       deal with the
which perhaps the new regulator will bring out. There continues to be a dearth of good case            nitty-girtty
studies, and the research effort remains insufficient to the needs of the sector. Here too the         issues facing
                                                                                                       the sector
new regulator will hopefully make a difference.

Finally, although it is not part of the infrastructure of support services, a new product
introduced recently by MFIs deserves special mention, and that is participation in UTI's
Retirement Benefit Pension Fund which accepts monthly contributions of as low as Rs 50 a
month for individual retirement accounts. The fund is approved to invest up to 40 percent of
collections in the Indian stock market. SEWA and SHEPHERD (in Trichy, Tamil Nadu) are the
first two MFIs to have distributed participation to their members. Subscribers are not required
to pay any initiation fees, and are sent monthly statements. Monthly pension payments start
at the age of 58, and are paid into bank accounts. In the event of the death of a member
accumulated contributions with interest are paid to a nominee.

                                                                                                   25
Box 1.2    The challenges of raising capital: Inside the entrepreneur's mind

 MICROFINANCE INSIGHTS: As the Share deal showed, microfinance is becoming more and more
 accepted by mainstream investors. Do you have any personal concerns about the pressure for
 financial performance and its possible impact on the social mission of MFIs?

 UDAIA KUMAR: Actually there is no conflict between both of them... what we are trying to do
 at Share is focus on the poorest of the poor, trying to help them come out of poverty. In the
 process, we run a viable program where we cover all costs, make reasonable profits, service all
 investors, and also pay the right price to banks we borrow money from.

 Everybody is in a win-win situation. If we are able to use this model, then we will be able to
 channel bigger money into the sector and we'll also be able to increase our scale. We will be
 able to get into the capital markets, offer IPOs and so on.

 I don't think anybody would have given us those 26 million dollars as a grant…

 VIKRAM AKULA: …I do not feel that the two interests are separate. In our case, we strive to
 be profitable and increase our investments because it enables us to reach out to more poor;
 we plough our profits into expansion efforts throughout India. Also, the majority share of SKS
 is held by members; thus, the interests of our investors and of our clients are aligned. As a
 response to the concerns that microfinance is not reaching the poorest of the poor, SKS has
 developed a pilot ultra poor program to target the needs of destitute populations, those too
 poor to qualify for traditional microfinance.

 VIJAY MAHAJAN: Yes, I am concerned about the impact of extreme profit seeking investors on
 the mission of MFIs. Such investors might say that reaching the poor is not their problem and
 that they are just investing in a company which is doing microcredit as a commercial service.
 To such investors I would say, please stay out of this field. The sector has not been built by
 commercial investors; it has been built by the sweat equity of development workers, by funding
 from public and philanthropic institutions and accumulation of capital of the poor themselves.
 Globally perhaps some 3 or 4 billion dollars have been spent to bring the field to where it has
 reached now. For extreme profit-seeking investors to now cherry pick that part of this field
 which gives a high return, without any care as to what it does to the poor, is not acceptable.
 If they still insist on coming in, as they are free to do, they will soon find a rise of popular
 revulsion against MFIs and political actions to curb interest rates, etc, which will not only kill
 the extreme profits, but also shut down other MFIs who are trying to be sustainable. Net
 result, the poor will be back to the clutches of moneylenders and government doles.

 MICROFINANCE INSIGHTS: If a decision to move towards commercial funding is taken, what are
 the key obstacles that MFIs face? How have these changed in recent years?

 UDAIA KUMAR: In our case, there are two parts to the fundraising effort: one is equity, the
 other is debt funds. The debt funds were quite difficult because of the limited capital and
 surplus we had...I never thought that we would require such huge investment because of the
 changes that took place in the banking sector: funding microfinance institutions, stopping
 partnership arrangements and so on.

 VIJAY MAHAJAN: The key obstacle that an MFI faces in raising commercial equity is what it
 does to the poor… For example, let us take the recent case of Compartamos …Its founders
 have personally become multimillionaires … Presumably, this will attract more capital, but on
 what terms to the ultimate users? Is this what we set up this sector for?...If this is microfinance,

26
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                            Overview




then I repudiate the field: I don't want to be part of this. In BASIX we don't want to deal with
any investor who thinks this is what they are for in microfinance. Instead, we'll raise money
from the community, as we did in our sister company Sarvodaya Nano Finance and from
development finance institutions and from philanthropic foundations.

MICROFINANCE INSIGHTS: What effect do you think the upcoming microfinance bill will have
on the sector? Is there an actual need for stronger regulation?

UDAIA KUMAR…The new bill will bring visibility and legitimacy to the sector and … support
from the government as well as from the state governments….

VIJAY MAHAJAN: The upcoming bill is a mixed blessing. It is positive in as much as microfinance
is being recognized for the first time, but on the down side, it does not extend its scope to
NBFC MFIs, which are the main players in the sector…The problem is that if we leave it to
complete self regulation, opportunism will take off. In Andhra Pradesh last year this led the
government to shut down branches of two MFIs because these institutions were seen to be
making excessive profits, charging high rates of interest. Those interest rates were right when
they started because they were not breaking even. But when the institutions grew to scale,
they did nothing to bring those interest rates down, they just kept raking in those profits
until it became an issue. And so they got the treatment that they deserved. The question is:
at what stage, do you really expect the regulator to be looking at your quarterly result, and
thinking now you are making too much profit? There is a simple way to do it. Look at the
Return on Assets. World over, we know that a healthy commercial bank makes ROA of 1.5% to
2.5%, at best. So why do we want a microfinance institution to make 20% ROA? I think we
need a sectoral cap. I think something like 4% ROA after tax is the upper limit to ensure that
we are providing enough incentive to investors. Even with a 1:5 leveraging, this would mean
an ROE of 20%.

Extracts from of an interview by Microfinance Insights with three leading Indian
microfinance entrepreneurs: Udaia Kumar of Share Microfin, Vikram Akula of SKS and
Vijay Mahajan of BASIX (Microfinance Insights, Volume 3, June 2007)




                                                                                               27
Endnotes


 1 Thirty percent is the estimate of the proportion of poor borrowers in MFIs in the second or endline
     survey in the seven year longitudinal study of SIDBI-partnered MFIs undertaken by EDA (baseline) and
     the Agricultural Finance Corporation, (endline, conducted in 2006, but not yet released) as well as the
     finding from the social performance assessment of 12 MFIs conducted by M-CRIL reported in Chapter 6.
     The proportion of poor SHG members was found in EDA and APMAS 2006 to be 51 percent.

 2 For the assumptions see Table A.1.

 3 Chapter 4 estimates that because of rapid expansion of outreach by MFIs, average loans outstanding
     of sample MFIs is only Rs 3400. The average size of the first loan received by SHGs members has gone
     up this year to Rs 3167 (Table 2.1, assuming 14 members per SHG). However, because the average size
     of repeat loans is even higher (Rs 5650, Table 2.1) and because the average tenor of SHG loans is
     generally two years, average loans outstanding may be about the same in the two models. Using the
     ratio reported in Chapter 2 of loans outstanding being 59% of cumulative bank loans disbursed, one
     derives a rough estimate of SHG loans outstanding per member of about Rs 4000 (Table A.1)

 4 See however Chapter 4, which estimates that PARs have increased since the last M-CRIL Review, especially
     sharply for large MFIs, partly because of the deterioration of the credit culture that occurred after the
     AP crisis. Loan portfolio audits that have been conducted by MicroSave and others often reveal a less
     rosy picture than the financial statements claim.

 5 Thirty percent is the estimate of the proportion of poor borrowers in MFIs in the second or endline
     survey in the seven year longitudinal study of SIDBI-partnered MFIs undertaken by EDA (baseline) and
     the Agricultural Finance Corporation, (endline, conducted in 2006, but not yet released) as well as the
     finding from the social performance assessment of 12 MFIs reported in Chapter 6.

 6 The average interest rate of the 129 MFIs in the Sa-Dhan Quick Report was 21.I percent and came down
     for large MFIs in the sample to 19.7 percent from 20.8 percent last year. Not surprisingly it was the
     small MFIs that had the higher rates (22 percent) than the large and medium sized MFIs (both 19.7
     percent). Chapter 4 reports higher rates of up to 25 percent, probably because it includes fees etc to
     the nominal rates to work out the effective interest rate. Although on average, the interest rates of
     Indian MFIs are slightly higher than that for other South Asian countries, the South Asian region has
     the lowest average rates of all regions in the world according to MIX data.

 7 Thus CASHPOR restricts its lending to BPL families and identifies likely BPL families as those scoring less
     than 3 points i.e. those living in small houses with mud walls of less than 8 feet in height. These
     candidates then have to satisfy three further criteria (not less than half of household income from
     seasonal agricultural labour, no irrigated land, and no large farm animals or any other significant
     productive assets)

 8 Bandhan and SKS are two MFIs that have special programmes for the poorest of the poor. Bandhan's
     Targeting the Hard Core project, based on the experience of BRAC in Bangladesh, focuses on skill
     training, asset creation through grants, hand-holding for 1.5 to 2 years to ensure productive utilization

28
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                                      Overview




   of the assets, and regular savings, before participants join the mainstream credit programme. SKS
   runs a similar programme for the "ultra-poor" through an associated NGO.

9 Chapter 7A, last year's report.

10 The issues involved are discussed in Chapter 4 of last year's report.

11 Although KYC norms were motivated internationally mostly by anti-money laundering and anti-terrorism
   concerns, the KYC guidelines issued by RBI make it clear that they are also designed to serve a risk
   management and transparency enhancing role. The RBI in November 2006 advised the banks that
   "they, as principal financiers of MFIs, needed to engage MFIs with regard to their systems, practices
   and lending policies with a view to ensuring better transparency and adherence to best practices (Usha
   Thorat 2007)

12 Some of them are reported to have suffered declines in their repayment rates, as borrowers were not
   assured of getting fresh loans on time, and consequents shrinkages in their portfolios. Despite this
   however, the sector as a whole has shown surprising resilience, with few reported cases of partners
   going under.

13 The AP government has distributed smart cards in Warangal district to receive NREGA and pension
   payments.

14 ICICI Bank is a partner in FINO.

15 Uptake has been slow for several reasons. One of them is the perception that FINO is expensive. Its
   charges are levied on a per transactions basis with no discount for higher usage, and larger MFIs are
   concerned that above a certain level of transactions, it would be cheaper for them to go it alone
   through their own stand-alone systems. Joining FINO or some other core banking solution would seem
   to be much more attractive for start-ups and small MFIs, and for MFIs functioning as business
   correspondents where the front-end and back-end are equally important (Chapter 8). Also, some
   partners are reported to be experiencing problems in customizing FINOs software to their unique
   requirements, especially as it was developed originally for banking operations.

16 It is also becoming more interested in supporting the livelihoods of its customers by tailoring loan
   products to the specific size, cash flow and other requirements of different activities and supporting
   enterprises that will buy their products.

17 SIDBI is expecting to double its portfolio to about Rs 1000 crores from Rs 548 crores in March 2007
   (see Table A.3) New players such as Fullerton, a newly set up finance company could also add to loan
   supply in a few years. Fullerton has ambitious plans to set up rural branches all over the country and
   and get into both direct, and indirect microfinance through intermediaries.

18 Table A.3 contains data on the growth of lending by selected commercial banks, financial institutions,
   and other bulk lenders to MFIs in 2006-07. Several large loans have been made by banks other than
   ICICI in the current year, but these include relatively large loans to the newly capital rich MFIs which
   have received equity investments. One of them is a portfolio buyout of Rs 180 crores by Citibank (see
   below). Table A.3 is incomplete and contains fewer banks than Table 7.1 in last year's report, because
   banks are under no obligation to furnish information on their MFI lending, and several of them were
   unable or unwilling to do so.


                                                                                                          29
19 While arrangements such as this are often referred to as securitizations, they are more correctly
     regarded as portfolio buyouts, with the purchaser of the loans having the option of securitizing them
     by pooling them with other assets, getting them rated, and selling them in the capital markets. See
     Chapter 7B of last year's report.

 20 Legatum's financial advisor on the transactions was Intellecap, a microfinance consulting firm and
     social investment adviser, which is closely associated with Aavishkaar Goodwell.

 21 The private shareholders received $150 million for an investment of $6 million, or a return of over 100
     percent a year compounded over an eight year period. They received more than 12 times the book
     value of their shares, resulting in a valuation of Banco Compartamos of over $1.5 billion (CGAP 2007).

 22 It first became a regulated finance company and then in 2006 a full-service bank)

 23 See Chapter 7B of last year's report, and Table A.4.

 24 The new investors in SKS seek, according to Satterthwaite 2007, to "cash out within 3-5 years", which
     if true is more aggressive than the stated time horizons of the India-dedicated funds.

     Dubai-based Legatum Capital has investments of over $1 billion in India's financial sector. Its President,
     Mark Stoleson is reported as saying "Legatum is a global investor that seems extraordinary opportunities
     without regard to sector or geography". However, the press note dated May 15, 2007 quotes him as
     also saying that "… we will seek to support SHARE in setting new standards for best practice and
     governance…"

 25 Another reason to expect mergers is competition from the large MFIs expanding to other states. The
     borrowers and staff of the smaller existing MFIs may not be able to resist the attraction of switching
     to a larger, more rapidly expanding MFI. The only reported merger so far is that between Sonata
     (referred to in Chapter 5 as a new start-up partly urban MFI and a smaller MFI, also in UP, but this was
     reportedly at the behest of a social venture capital company).

 26 It is possible also that some existing large MFIs may themselves be acquired by the large corporate
     houses that have recently made a foray into agri marketing as a means of financing their producers
     and suppliers. Yet another possible impact of fresh capital and borrowings may be to accelerate the
     trend towards increasing the share of the more profitable larger loans in the portfolios of the larger
     MFIs, and could lead even to their gradually exiting the sector as they move up-market, making room
     for the others.

 27 Average return of assets in the M-CRIL sample has been reduced to zero. This is not to say some
     individual MFIs do not offer highly profitable prospects. SKS earned an ROA of 3.3 in 2006 and ROE of
     23.9

 28 The licenses of thousands of such non-functioning NBFCs are said to be for a sale, at a premium over
     their net worth given demand by transforming NGO-MFIs, but they still cost much less than raising Rs
     2 crores to seek a new NBFC. The entry capital requirement was earlier Rs 25 lakhs. Besides, not all MFI
     applicants have succeeded in getting new NBFC licenses, of which only about 5 have been issued since
     around 2000.

 29 Such as itinerant deposit collectors, small community chit funds, informal credit unions (such as the
     bishis of Maharashta), investments in livestock or ornaments (which can later be liquefied through the

30
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                                        Overview




   pawnbroker and moneylender), or through "reciprocal finance", that is, lending to a friend in need so
   that the lender can borrow reciprocally when required. The phenomenal growth of the SHG movement, in
   which rural women meet with unfailing regularity once a month to save small sums ranging from Rs 10
   to 50, and the fact that poor urban slum dwellers, far from earning interest on their savings, are willing
   to pay to have their deposits collected at the doorstep and stored safely until they amount to a useful
   sum, and countless other examples, attest to the importance of the almost universal need to save.

30 Quite apart from benefits to members, the cost of funds MFIs will come down. Because Indian MFIs
   have had to rely exclusively on funds borrowed from the banks, their financial expense ratios (cost of
   funds as a proportion of total costs) are the highest in the world (see Chapter 4 of last year's report).
   In Bangladesh, on the other hand, interest rates are slightly lower than in India, because as much as
   a third of the funds base comes from member savings. Many Bangladeshi MFIs also pay a slightly
   higher rate to savers than the banks, because of the cost efficiencies that ensue from economies of
   scope in being able to use existing field staff, who have to meet borrowers once a week anyway to
   collect loan repayment installments and disburse fresh loans. Grameen Bank mobilizes in fact more
   savings than it disburses as credit (as does Bank Rakyat Indonesia, further examples of how savings are
   as valued by poor clients as credit).

31 For details and a discussion see Chapter 7A of last year's report.

32 Especially with the use of smart cards, as in the pilots referred to above, where the BC's field agent
   travels to the doorstep to collects savings and dispense withdrawals. The frequency of withdrawals,
   minimum accounts that can be deposited etc are still being worked out.

33 MFIs can not accept cash for remittances since these are treated as savings. In the UK, in order to
   encourage ease of entry and competition among money transfer operators so as to lower the costs
   of remittances, regulators allow an MTO to hold money for up to 3 days before it is treated as
   savings. Adhikar (see Chapter 5B of last year's report) is talking to banks to continue its operations
   as a BC.

34 There are no similar caps on the maximum rate that can be paid on savings or remittance services.

35 The one argument that can be made against the latter is that it represents an inefficient use of equity.

36 Perhaps MFIs value the autonomy and psychic satisfactions of being autonomous (the equivalent of
   "being one's own boss" in preferring self-employment to salaried employment) and do not want to be
   anyone's agent

37 The share of the urban population, although still lower than the global and Asian average, had grown
   to 31 percent by 2001.

38 In the three decades since 1970 the number of poor went up from 52 to 67 million. Rural poverty is
   declining both in relative and absolute terms. However the number of rural poor is still three times
   higher than that of the urban poor.

39 Thus the extent of "human poverty" and deprivation is much worse than the "income" poverty
   measured and reported in the statistics. In cities like Delhi the income poverty ratio is as low as low as
   8.23 percent in 1999

40 It is important to be able to assess whether the deficit is merely temporary, or likely to remain

                                                                                                            31
permanent in the absence of the provision of other inputs. Defining the target group too conservatively
     finesses this challenges.

 41 The package includes periodic visits and handholding for 9 months and assistance with the installation
     of a computerized MIS. Equity can be provided by sister company Aavishkaar Goodwell and loans by
     ICICI Bank which is expected to play the role of lead banker to the institutions.. Three start ups have
     signed on so far. Apart from an upfront fee, partners are charged a part of the margin between their
     borrowing and lending rates.

 42 An example is CASHPOR's, from which Box 1.1 is excerpted, and which discusses the problem of the
     increasing frequency and size of frauds and steps being taken to combat it. Sa-Dhan should institute
     an annual award for the each of the three most informative annual reports and websites.




32
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                        Overview




References


CGAP, 2007, "CGAP Reflections on the Compartamos Initial Public Offering: A Case Study on
Microfinance Interest Rates and Profits, Focus Note No. 42, Washington DC

EDA Rural Systems and APMAS, 2006, "Self Help Groups in India: A Study of the Lights and
Shades" for CRS, USAID, CARE and GTZ/NABARD, Microfinance India, New Delhi

Sa-Dhan, 2007, "Quick Report 2007: A Snapshot of Microfinance Institutions in India", New
Delhi

Satterthwaite, David, 2007, "MicroCapital Equity Report: 2007 Starts Strong" in Microfinance
Insights, Vol. 3, June 2007, Intellecap, Mumbai

Thorat, Usha, 2006, "Financial Inclusion for Sustainable Development : Role of IT and
Intermediaries" speech, as circulated at the Annual Bankers' Conference 2006, November 4,
Hyderabad.

Thorat, Usha, 2007, "Microfinance and financial inclusion", speech at Sa-Dhan function to
release "Quick Report, 2007", Chennai, August 10

World Bank, 2007, "Microfinance in South Asia: Toward Financial Inclusion for the Poor",
Washington DC




                                                                                           33
34
CHAPTER 2
                                                                                                    Progress Under the SHG Bank
                                                                                                    Linkage Programme




                                           CHAPTER 2


Progress Under the SHG Bank
     Linkage Programme
Growth continues to be rapid…
A further 686,408 SHGs were linked during the year, bringing the cumulative number of SHGs that had
ever been linked (provided with bank loans) to 2.92 million by March 2007 (Table 2.1). Assuming
average group size of 14 members1 this translates into coverage during the year of another 9.6 million
persons, over 90 percent of them women, and the total number of SHG members who have ever benefited
from the programme to about 41 million. Since some households have more than one member in the
programme, the number of families benefited is slightly smaller than these numbers imply.2 About half of
them are below the poverty line. In addition to first loans to new SHGs, 457,410 SHGs received repeat
loans.

The number of new SHGs linked this year represents an increase of about 11 percent over those linked         Reporting under
                                                                                                             the programme
last year. This represents only a slight deceleration of the rate of growth of loans to new SHGs from 15
                                                                                                             has until now
percent last year. The increase in the number of repeat loans however, was exactly the same, at 33           been carried
percent. Lending under the programme grew by Rs 6643 crores, or an increase of 48 percent over last          out entirely in
                                                                                                             terms of
year's new lending, which had grown by 50 percent over the previous year. The average size of first loans    disbursements,
made to new SHGs went up by 18 percent to about Rs 44,300 per group, or to an average of about Rs            both annual and
3200 per member. The average size of repeat loans, on the other hand, grew by 25 percent to almost Rs        cumulative,
                                                                                                             rather than
79,000 per group, or Rs 5650 per member.3                                                                    loans
                                                                                                             outstanding at
We now have an estimate of the total size of the programme                                                   the end of year


Reporting under the programme has until now been carried out entirely in terms of disbursements,
both annual and cumulative, rather than loans outstanding at the end of year. The latter is a
stock measure of size, as compared to a flow, and provides a better basis for comparison with
the size of lending under the MFI model, or with bank lending to other categories of borrowers
such as marginal farmers, since it standardizes for loan tenor.4 In an important study based on
a survey of participating banks under the programme conducted by GTZ/NABARD in 2005
(Ramakrishna 2006), loans outstanding under the programme as of March 2005 were established
for the first time as amounting to 59 percent of cumulative lending till that date. Moreover,
of the SHGs that had been linked till that date, 71 percent had loans outstanding.5 These
ratios had been the subject of conjecture until now.

NABARD had been unable to report exposure (loans outstanding) figures under the programme
because of the inability of the participating banks to furnish them in a timely fashion.

                                                                                                        35
Table 2.1 Growth trends in the SBLP
                                          2001    2002    2003     2004      2005      2006      2007
 1    No. of new SHGs provided           263,825 461,478 717,360 1,079,091 1,618,456 2,238,565 2,924,973
      with bank loans (cumulative)
 1a   Of which in Southern region                                                   938,941 1,214,431 1,522,144
      (cumulative)
 1b   Percent in Southern region                                                       58        54         52
      (percent)
 2    No. of new SHGs financed           149,650 197,653 255,882 361,731 539,365 620,109 686,408
      during the year
 2a   Of which in Southern region                                                             275,490 307,713
 2b   Percent in Southern region                                                                44      45
 2c   Rate of growth of loans to                      32         29         41         49       15      11
      new SHGs (percent)
 3    No. of SHGs receiving repeat       21,630     41,413    102,391 171,669 258,092 344,502 457,410
      loans
 3a   Rate of growth of repeat                        91        147         68         50        33         33
      loans
 3b   Proportion of repeat loans in                   17         29         40         32        36         40
      total loans
 4    Bank loan disbursed                  481       1,026     2,049      3,904      6,896     11,398     18,040
      cumulative (Rs. crore)
 4a   Bank loan disbursed during            NA        545      1,023      1,855      2,994      4,499     6,643
      year (Rs crore)
 4b   Of which, disbursed to new           290        453       691       1,158      1,727      2,330     3,044
      groups (Rs crore)
 4c   Of which, disbursed as repeat         NA        92        332        698       1,268      2,169     3,599
      loans (Rs crore)
 4d   Proportion of repeat loans in                   17         33         38         42        48         54
      total disbursed (percent)
 5a   Average loan sizes - New           19,379     22,919     27,005     32,013    32,019     37,574     44,343
 5b   Repeat                                        22,215     32,425     40,660    49,130     62,960     78,682

Source: NABARD annual reports and Table 2.3


     The RBI has    Fortunately, the RBI has now made it mandatory for all banks to report exposure and NPA
    now made it
                    figures to it every six months, and the NABARD annual report on the programme should be in
  mandatory for
     all banks to   a position to report at least the former for the year ending March 2008. Until then, these
report exposure     estimates are a great step forward in strengthening the statistical base of the programme (and
and NPA figures
 to it every six    are used in the Fact Sheet).
    months, and
    the NABARD      …and of its savings outreach
   annual report
           on the
      programme     The GTZ study also carried important new information of savings under the programme, which
  should be in a    were reported by the survey participants as amounting to Rs 2391 crores as of March 2005.
      position to   RRBs and cooperative banks have a higher share of total savings accounts and savings
 report at least
  the former for    outstanding than of total loan accounts and loans outstanding. One would like to think this
the year ending     is because of greater ease of access to these institutions than to the commercial banks, but it
    March 2008
                    turns out that as with loans (discussed below, under Operations), savings performance is
                    highly concentrated in a few institutions around the country, especially in the case of RRBs.6


                36
CHAPTER 2
                                                                                            Progress Under the SHG Bank
                                                                                            Linkage Programme




Since loans outstanding were Rs 4205 crores, the credit-deposit ratio was 1.76. In other
words a little more than half of linkage loans are financed by the SHGs themselves. However,
since 29 percent of SHGs are not currently linked, and the total savings figure includes their
savings, the ratio would be higher for those SHGs that are linked.

Rectifying regional skew
The SBLP expanded by 37 percent in 13 priority states which account for 67 percent of the           The two regions
                                                                                                    which have the
rural poor (Table 2.2). These states were identified by NABARD in 2005 for special efforts and
                                                                                                    most catching
location-specific strategies. Growth was particularly rapid in Maharashtra (Table 2.3) As a         up to do are
result, the western region experienced the fastest growth (63 percent) of all the regions, and      the central and
                                                                                                    eastern
its share in the total number of groups linked is now only 5 percentage points behind its           regions, whose
share of the total number of poor (Table 2.4). The two regions which have the most catching         share of groups
                                                                                                    lag behind their
up to do are the central and eastern regions, whose share of groups lag behind their share of
                                                                                                    share of the
the poor by 21 and 11 percentage points respectively. Growth in the East was 33 percent,            poor by 21 and
about the same as overall national growth of 31 percent, and well below the previous year's         11 percentage
                                                                                                    points
growth of 48 percent. Growth in the central region was only 24 percent.



                Table 2.2 Growth of linked SHG's in 13 Priority States
  State                 2003        2004        2005        2006        2007       Percent
                                                                                   growth

  Assam                 3,477      10,706      31,234       56,449      81454         44

  Bihar                 8,161      16,246      28,015       46,221      72339         57

  Chhatisgarh           6,763       9,796      18,569       31,291      41703         33

  Gujarat              13,875      15,974      24,712       34,160      43572         28

  Himachal Pradesh      8,875      13,228      17,798       22,920      27799         21

  Jharkhand             7,765      12,647      21,531       30,819      37317         21

  Maharashtra          28,065      38,535      71,146      131,470     225856         72

  Madhya Pradesh       15,271      27,095      45,105       57,125      70912         24

  Orissa               42,272      77,588      123,256     180,896     234451         30

  Rajasthan            22,742      33,846      60,006       98,171     137837         40

  Uttar Pradesh        53,696      79,210      119,648     161,911     198587         23

  Uttaranchal           5,853      10,908      14,043       17,588      21527         22

  West Bengal          32,647      51,685      92,698      136,251     181563         33

  Total               249,462      397,464     667,761    1,005,272 1374917            37

  Percent increase                    59          68          51          37

Source: NABARD annual reports and Table 2.3




                                                                                               37
Table 2.4 Growth of linked SHG's in the regions

  Region       Mar-04        Mar-05      Mar-06     Percent     Mar-07     Percent Share of          Share of
                                                     2006                   2007 population            BPL
                                                                                                    population

Northern         52,396       86018      133097         6       182018         6            13%         7%
North            12278        34238       62517         3       91754          3             4%         3%
Eastern
Region
Eastern        158237        265628      394351        18       525881        18            22%         29%
Region
Central        127009        197365      267915        12       332729        11            25%         32%
Region
Western          54815        96266      166254         7       270447         9            15%         14%
Region
Southern       674356        939941      1214431       54       1522144       52            21%         15%
Region
All India    1079091         1618456     2238565      100       2924973     100.00          100%        100%

Source: Poverty Estimates for 2004-05, Press Information Bureau, Government of India, New Delhi, March, 2007


                   Despite relatively rapid growth in the priority states, the programme continues to remains
                   heavily skewed in favour of the South. While the share of the South in linked groups came
                   down marginally during the year (Table 2.1) lending in the South still accounted for 75
                   percent of total lending during the year, and an even higher share of repeat lending (88
                   percent), indicating both higher average initial loan size, and even higher average repeat
                   loan size on account of the seniority of groups in the southern Region. In Andhra Pradesh,
                   the number of new loans remained about the same but the number of repeat loans increased
                   by 31 percent year. Given relatively high loan size in the state APs share of total and repeat
                   lending during the year constituted as much as 42 and 65 percent respectively of that for the
                   country as a whole.

                   Operations
                                       Table 2.5 Agency-wise share of SHGs financed

                                       During 2005-06                                During 2006-07
      Agency
                                SHGs                    Loans                  SHGs                 Loans
                            No.          %         Amount        %          No.        %       Amount      %
 CBs                      344567        56         28284        63        406707      59       44101      66
 RRBs                     176178        28         12226        27        170783      25       17089      26
 Co-operatives             99364        16          4481        10        108878      16        5242       8
 Total                    620,109       100        44,991       100       686368      100      66432      100

Source: NABARD annual reports

                   Table 2.5 shows the respective share of commercial banks, RRBs and cooperatives in financing
                   SHGs. The share of commercial banks has gone up in 2006-07, both in respect of number of
                   loans and amounts disbursed, at the expense mostly of the of RRBs in respect of share of
                   number of loans and of the cooperatives in respect of share of loans disbursed. In 2005-06,7
                   twenty-seven public sector banks accounted for 93 percent of commercial bank financing and
                 38
CHAPTER 2
                                                                                             Progress Under the SHG Bank
                                                                                             Linkage Programme




20 private banks for 7 percent. Among public sector banks, the SBI linked by far the highest
number of SHGs during the year (142,034)8 followed by Indian Bank (30,632) and Canara
Bank (18,445). We know from the GTZ/NABARD study that in March 2005 SBI accounted for 40
percent of all active clients (i.e. those in currently linked SHGs) and the top five lenders
accounted for more than two-thirds of them.9 Similarly, 20 out of the total of 196 participating
RRBs served 50 percent of active clients, and cooperative banks in three states (Tamil Nadu,
Karnataka and West Bengal) accounted for 82 percent of those served by the cooperative
banks.10 ICICI accounted for half the SHGs linked by the private banks.

          The share of the three models of linkage remained roughly the same, with Model II
(SHGs formed by agencies other than banks, mainly NGOs, but also farmer clubs, and individual
rural volunteers who are paid a fee) increasing its share from 74 to 75 percent of cumulative
linkages at the expense of the share Model I, in which SHGs are formed by the banks themselves.
In Model III, NGOs and SHG federations act as credit intermediaries, or in other words as MFIs,
borrowing at their own risk to onlend to SHGs.11

An interesting addition to the intermediaries being used under Model III was made during             An interesting
                                                                                                     addition to the
the year through a pilot project in 5 districts of Tamil Nadu to lend through post offices. Post
                                                                                                     intermediaries
offices have huge potential outreach, with about 155,000 branches, and have close local              being used
knowledge. They will borrow at 6 percent from NABARD and on-lend to SHGs at 9 percent. Like          under Model III
                                                                                                     was made
the banks, they will use NGOs to form and train groups, and the NGOs will be eligible for the        during the year
grants NABARD pays NGOs to defray their costs (but only partially)12.                                through a pilot
                                                                                                     project in 5
                                                                                                     districts of
SHG lifespans                                                                                        Tamil Nadu to
                                                                                                     lend through
In perhaps the first rigorous academic study of an aspect of the SHG movement, using                 post offices.
sophisticated econometric methods; Micro-finance Lifespans: A Study of Attrition and Exclusion       Post offices
                                                                                                     have huge
in Self-Help Groups in India by Jean-Marie Baland, Rohini Somanathan and Lore Vandewalle             potential
(Baland et al 2007), welcome confirmation was found for two of the "lights", or reassuring           outreach, with
                                                                                                     about 155,000
findings, of the SHG "Lights and Shades"study (LSS) discussed at length in last year's report
                                                                                                     branches, and
(EDA and APMAS 2006). These relate to the longevity groups and the drop-out rate. In a               have close local
sample of 1102 PRADAN promoted groups in three tribal districts of Orissa and Chattisgarh,           knowledge

only 10 percent of groups formed between 1998 and 2006 were found by the survey carried
out in early 2007, to be no longer active. This is comparable with the estimated proportion of
defunct and broken groups of 7 percent, in groups of average age of 6 years, in the much
smaller 214-SHG, LSS sample taken across 4 states.

The drop-out rate of individual members was found to be almost identical, at 14 percent.13
The study found that the factors behind group survival were different from those behind
member longevity. The former was strongly associated with the presence of an educated member
in the group, perhaps because this facilitates transactions, interaction with bank officials,
and the accuracy of book-keeping. A second factor was the presence of other groups in the
village. Since PRADAN organizes groups in the same village into clusters, this is the first
empirical finding in support of the potential role of higher-level formations such as clusters of
SHGs and their federations in enhancing SHG quality and sustainability. On the other hand, a
third possible factor, social heterogeneity, measured by the number of different castes
represented in the group, does not have systematic effects on group survival.


                                                                                                39
However, the study found that social heterogeneity does increase the probability of individual
                    member exit from the group (or of dropping out), presumably by increasing the probability of
                    personal conflict with other members, which was the single most important reason for departures
                    in Chattisgarh, and the second most important one in Orissa, where difficulties in meeting
                    loan repayment and monthly savings obligations were twice as important. This last reason for
                    member departures may also explain the finding of the study that tribal and SC women have
                    shorter SHG lifespans than groups that lie higher in the social hierarchy.

                    On the other hand higher levels of education, bigger landholdings and more relatives within
                    the groups are associated with a lower probability of exit. The finding about land-holdings is
                    interesting, because it is well-known that an important use of SHG loans is to finance crop
                    inputs and the other recurrent costs of family agriculture. Since a large proportion of SHG
                    members, both above the below the poverty line, are farmers' wives, the SHG programme, as it
                    expands, is beginning to become increasingly important as a source of crop credit. It already
                    supplies close to one-fifth of total agricultural lending by the banks to marginal farmers with
                    less than 2.5 acres of land.14

                    Quality remains the major problem, and may be growing: a case
                    study of the programme in a priority state
The report finds    Another important recent study, "Quality Issues of SHGs in Rajasthan", conducted recently by
         that the
                    the Centre for Microfinance, Jaipur and APMAS, gives us a much more differentiated picture of
"overall quality
of groups is low    the programme in a particular state than is usually possible in a multi-state study.15 It
   and there are    provides a useful corrective to any complacency that might be engendered by the impressive
 startling inter-
     district and   macro numbers for the country as a whole. It also serves as a useful reminder that while it is
 intra-promoter     important for the programme to grow in the 13 priority states (Rajasthan is one of them)
       variations   long-run growth will be much more rapid if it takes place on the basis of strong foundations.
       across the
    groups". The    The report finds that the "overall quality of groups is low and there are startling inter-district
 proportion of A    and intra-promoter variations across the groups". The proportion of A groups was 30 percent
  groups was 30
                    as against 66 percent found by APMAS 2005 in AP.
      percent as
      against 66
   percent found    The study was carried out in 5 districts based on a sample of 202 SHGs, a little more than half
by APMAS 2005       of which were of less than 3 years old given the age of the programme in Rajasthan. However
            in AP
                    a third were between 3 and 5 years old. Interestingly, the number of BPL members were almost
                    exactly the same as the number of poor members as defined in LSS (49 percent as against 51
                    percent respectively). While the study agrees with other studies that SHGs have a significant
                    impact on women's empowerment, a medium impact on household income, and that overdues
                    and defaults on bank loans are not a serious problem, it found the dropout rate to be considerably
                    higher (30 percent for groups older than 5 years, with a disproportionate share of them being
                    BPL members). Regarding the quality of governance, at least a tenth of all groups had held no
                    meetings at all during the year, and more than 20 percent has carried out all transactions
                    outside the meetings.

                    Savings per member were an average of Rs 40 a month, but two-thirds of the amount saved
                    had accumulated as idle funds parked in the banks, instead of being lent out to members. The
                    report is critical of the fact that these funds constituted 44 percent of bank loans outstanding
                    to the groups, on which they were paying much higher interest than they received on their


                40
CHAPTER 2
                                                                                            Progress Under the SHG Bank
                                                                                            Linkage Programme




savings balances. It is not clear however what part of these funds belonged to groups with
loans outstanding.16

The study observed several other symptoms of weak loan demand, such as the fact that only 59
percent of members borrowed, of which 14 percent were group leaders,17 and that 12 percent
of the groups received first loans of less than Rs 5000.18 It also notes some extreme instances
of the deleterious effects of targetitis, with cases in one district of small loans being forced
on groups who were told to repay within two months. Although, on average, groups received
1.6 loans each, the average amount of loans received including repeat loans was only Rs
27,000.19

With two-thirds of sample groups organized by government functionaries, primarily anganwadi        The study
                                                                                                   proposes that
workers from the DWCD,20 which is also the nodal coordinating agency, as it is in many other
                                                                                                   monitoring of
states, the Rajasthan programme is particularly vulnerable to the distortions introduced by        the programme
targets. The study proposes that monitoring of the programme should henceforth be in terms         should
                                                                                                   henceforth be in
of the respective numbers of A, B, and C grade groups, as well as in respect of repeat loans and   terms of the
size of loans, which is a useful suggestion for the programme at the national level too. It        respective
                                                                                                   numbers of A,
suggests that the 50 percent of groups in the B category need to brought up to the A
                                                                                                   B, and C grade
category with extra inputs of training, hand-holding support, and exposure visits. The DCWD,       groups, as well
which receives inadequate funds as the main SHPI, needs to enhance its own capacity in order       as in respect of
                                                                                                   repeat loans
to accomplish this.                                                                                and size of
                                                                                                   loans, which is
The report makes the important point that although it is claimed that the programme has            a useful
achieved an important paradigm shift from a loan-centred to a savings- centred strategy, "the      suggestion for
                                                                                                   the programme
sample groups, by and large, are functioning around loans if not subsidies.21 Savings are          at the national
nominal at times."22 But because they are compulsory they exclude a large number of the poor,      level too
whose incomes fluctuate. Several other studies have shown that reluctance to commit themselves
to fixed monthly savings in the face of uncertain and fluctuating incomes is the single most
important reason for why only half the membership of the movement is poor, and for dropping
out. The report recommends introducing therefore some flexibility in savings and repayments
to overcome the effects, which are particularly strong in Rajasthan, both because of seasonality
in agriculture,23 and of migration. Second, it proposes distribution of at least part of the
accumulated corpus of groups from time to time as "dividends", both as an incentive to save,
and so as to ensure that the accounting is timely and accurate enough to ensure allocability
of the corpus between members. It recommends that at the very least, all groups prepare,
discuss and approve the balance sheet of the group once a year, which is yet another reminder
of the importance of good bookkeeping (and training for it) in the programme.

All in all, the study provides a much more nuanced view of how the programme actually
operates in one priority state, and draws attention to the urgency of tackling quality related
issues if the programme is to grow sustainably. We need many more state level studies before
deciding how representative the problems identified are, but anecdotal experience suggests
they are widespread, and a "vision document" prepared by the Government of Orissa itself says
the "mushrooming growth of groups in the state and lack of adequate monitoring has resulted
in irregular savings, irregular meetings, improper book-keeping, lack of solidarity and peer
pressure in the groups…"(Government of Orissa 2005).24




                                                                                               41
As the Rajasthan study points out, the programme suffers from several "structural" constraints
                      which are particularly acute in Rajasthan, with its low population density and widely dispersed
                      habitats,25 high female illiteracy,26 cultural tradition of female seclusion,27 predominance of
                      agriculture, and high incidence of migration.28 One suspects however that the most important
                      factor explaining differences in programme quality across states is the quality of grass-roots
                      governance in a state. It is important also that such studies be carried out by neutral observers
                      such as state level resource agencies whose independence is not fettered by any assistance
                      they may receive from the state government or interested donors.
   Since NABARD
       is likely to   Statistics
      become the
 regulator under      As noted earlier, the biggest gap in the statistical foundations of the programme, the lack of
           the new
     microfinance
                      exposure (loans outstanding) data, is about to be filled. But the others identified in last
  bill pending in     year's report remain: (i) the lack of disaggregated data on repeat loans (separating them into
  partliament, a      second, third and subsequent loans) so that loan size progression can be observed, (ii) data
major objective
   of which is to     on savings balances and CD ratios (although we now have an estimate for March 2005), (iii)
     improve the      reported data on institution-wise and state-wise NPAs under the programme, although, again,
    national data
                      we do have one-time information on NPAs as of March 2005 from the GTZ report. A further
  base, it needs
    to set a good     suggestion, as noted above, is a tabulation of the quality of the groups in terms of the mix of
      example by      their A, B, and C grades.
        presenting
       timely and
  comprehensive       Since NABARD is likely to become the regulator under the new microfinance bill pending in
      data on the     partliament, a major objective of which is to improve the national data base, it needs to set
       programme
                      a good example by presenting timely and comprehensive data on the programme under its
   under its own
direct oversight      own direct oversight.




                  42
CHAPTER 2
                                                                                                         Progress Under the SHG Bank
                                                                                                         Linkage Programme




                          Table 2.3 Growth trends in the SBLP for 2006-07, by state
  S.          Region/State      Cumulative No. of new      No. of  Cumulative Cumulative Bank Loan Of Col.8, Cumulative
                                No. of SHGs   SHGs       existing  No. of SHGs bank loan     during    repeat bank bank loan
 No.
                                  provided  provided       SHGs     provided     upto      2006-07       loan to        upto
                                 with bank with bank    provided    with bank 31 March                   existing    31 March
                                 loan upto loan during with repeat loan upto     2006                     SHGs      2007 (7+8)
                                 31 March   2006-07     bank loan   31 March
                                   2006                   during  2007 (3+4) (Rs million) (Rs million) (Rs million) (Rs million)
                                                        2006-07

   1    2                            3           4           5           6           7            8            9          10
   A    Northern Region
   1    Himachal Pradesh          22,920       4,879       2,282       27,799      863.98      388.27       153.60      1,252.25
   2    Rajasthan                 98,171      39,666       3,692      137,837     2,447.94    1,447.40      191.53      3,895.34
   3    Haryana                    4,867       1,966       1,821       6,833       316.01      183.31        69.86      499.32
   4    Punjab                     4,561       1,893        517        6,454       238.86      117.74        29.24      356.60
   5    Jammu & Kashmir            2,354        405         199        2,759       100.48       44.25        15.83      144.73
   6    New Delhi                   224         112                     336        18.58        8.65                     27.23
        T O T A L (A)             133,097     48,921       8,511      182,018     3,985.85    2,189.62      460.05      6,175.47


   B    North Eastern Region
   7    Assam                     56,449      25,005        160        81,454     1,423.98     794.40        2.91       2,218.38
   8    Meghalaya                   735         476          0         1,211       16.19        17.40        0.00        33.59
   9    Tripura                    1,996        910         57         2,906       31.12        18.40        1.48        49.52
  10    Sikkim                      127         33           0          160         1.86        1.12         0.00        2.98
  11    Manipur                    1,468       1,215         0         2,683       71.85        40.80        0.00       112.65
  12    Arunachal Pradesh           346         101          0          447        13.49        5.72         0.00        19.21
  13    Nagaland                    422         576         10          998        34.38        33.50        2.97        67.88
  14    Mizoram                     974         921          0         1,895       64.14        70.56        0.00       134.70
        T O T A L (B)             62,517      29,237        227        91,754     1,657.01     981.89        7.36       2,638.90


   C    Eastern Region
  15    Orissa                    180,896     53,555       28,806     234,451     4,754.65    3,274.27      1,409.33    8,028.92
  16    Bihar                     46,221      26,118       1,306       72,339     1,052.19     960.28       211.15      2,012.47
  17    Jharkhand                 30,819       6,498       1,153       37,317     1,114.60     391.96        84.21      1,506.56
  18    West Bengal               136,251     45,312       22,014     181,563     2,424.52    2,060.64      888.40      4,485.16
  19    UT of A & N Islands         164         47          30          211         8.23        4.58         3.40        12.81
        T O T A L (C)             394,351     131,530      53,309     525,881     9,354.19    6,691.72      2,596.50   16,045.91


   D    Central Region
  20    Madhya Pradesh            57,125      13,787       1,726       70,912     1,666.86     499.23        65.12      2,166.09
  21    Chhatisgarh               31,291      10,412       1,330       41,703      337.81      218.44        27.51      556.25
  22    Uttar Pradesh             161,911     36,676       2,873      198,587     5,153.54    1,778.48      192.43      6,932.02
  23    Uttarakhand               17,588       3,939       1,288       21,527      891.86      382.69       225.64      1,274.55
        T O T A L (D)             267,915     64,814       7,217      332,729     8,050.07    2,878.84      510.69     10,928.91


   E    Western Region
  24    Gujarat                   34,160       9,412        64         43,572     1,244.51     885.46        4.69       2,129.97
  25    Maharashtra               131,470     94,386       19,382     225,856     3,951.67    2,983.86      841.01      6,935.53
  26    Goa                         624         395         142        1,019       55.21        28.28        9.03        83.49
        T O T A L (E)             166,254     104,193      19,588     270,447     5,251.39    3,897.60      854.72      9,148.99


   F    Southern Region
  27    Andhra Pradesh            587,238     96,381      262,895     683,619    43,455.18    27,754.55    23,536.74   71,209.73
  28    Karnataka                 224,928     92,708       56,717     317,636     9,927.53    8,163.89      3,239.26   18,091.42
  29    Kerala                    86,988      30,925       13,559     117,913     4,821.48    2,889.40      1,067.68    7,710.88
  30    Tamil Nadu                312,778     87,699       35,387     400,477    27,121.87    10,984.48     3,721.55   38,106.35
  31    UT of Pondicherry          2,499                               2,499       350.86                               350.86
        T O T A L (F)            1,214,431    307,713     368,558    1,522,144   85,676.92    49,792.32    31,565.24   135,469.24
        GRAND TOTAL              2,238,565    686,408     457,410    2,924,973   113,975.43   66,431.99    35,994.56   180,407.42

Source: www.nabard.org
                                                                                                            43
Endnotes


 1 This is the average size for the overall sample reported in the most recent large scale survey of SHGs,
     "Self Help Groups in India: A Study of the Lights and Shades" (EDA and APMAS 2006), discussed in
     last year's State of the Sector, and hereafter referred to as LSS. For a national average this is probably
     on the low side, given that the average age of the groups was 6 years, and the dropout rate 10
     percent. In its annual reports on the programme NABARD uses a higher figure (15 in 2004-05 and
     14.7 in 2005-06).

 2 A recent estimate of the percentage of members who have at least one relative in the group is about
     10 percent (Baland et al 07). If they had only one relative each, the number of families benefited
     would have to adjusted downwards by 5 percent.

 3 The corresponding increases last year were 17 and 28 percent respectively. Data on repeat loans are for
     an unreported, and probably unknown, mix of second, third and further loans.

 4 Thus two six monthly seasonal crop loans will show twice the disbursement level of a one-year loan of
     the same size.

 5 Table 1 of Ramakrishna 2006. Responses were received from all the 27 public sector commercial banks
     participating in the programme, 192 out of the 196 RRBs, and 114 cooperative credit institutions
     from the five major states who hold 95 percent of the share of the cooperative banks in the SHG
     programme.

 6 Thus in terms of savings outstanding, 10 percent of RRBs in the country account for 83 percent of total
     savings outstanding. The situation is better with the DCCBs where 20 percent of the institutions account
     for 45 percent of total savings outstanding.

 7 NABARD's annual report on the SBLP, and hence the corresponding data for 2006-07, were not
     available at the time of writing this chapter in late September 2007.

 8 The SBI has announced a goal of linking 1 million SHGs by March 2008.

 9 These are the State Bank of India, Andhra Bank, State Bank of Hyderabad, Indian Overseas Bank and
     Indian Bank (Table 1 of Ramakrishna 2006). Most of AP's programme is served by the second two.

 10 Tables 6 and 7 in Ramakrishna 2006.

 11 The share of Model I declined from 20 to 17 percent, unlike last year when it increased, and that of
     Model III increased from 6 to 8 percent, after declining steadily for the last few years.

 12 Thus the post offices under the pilot are in a sense being given special treatment since intermediaries
     under Model III are expected to defray the costs of group promotion through the margin. The most
     common estimate used for the actual cost of forming and "hand-holding" groups is Rs 10,000,
     incurred over the few years necessary, but NABARD treats the incentive as an add-on, meant to
     supplement grants from other sources. See last year's report for a fuller discussion. An increase in the

44
CHAPTER 2
                                                                                                      Progress Under the SHG Bank
                                                                                                      Linkage Programme




   incentive from Rs 3000 to Rs 4000 is reportedly under consideration (The incentive is already higher in
   the Northeast, where it is Rs 5,000 per SHG).

13 The rate in LSS was 10 percent, but some of the drop-outs among the 14 percent went on to join other
   groups. Overall, the study estimated that about 20 percent of SHG members who had joined a group
   had left the SHG network within the 8-year period.

14 A comparison of loans outstanding in 2003-04 against marginal farmers, shown in Table 59 of the RBI
   Handbook of Statistics on the Indian Economy (on short-term and long-term direct finance to farmers
   in various land-holding classes) with the amount of SHG loans outstanding in that year (estimated, as
   discussed above, by assuming it was 70 percent of cumulative lending in that year), shows that SHG
   lending constituted 18.5 percent of total lending to farmers. (It is assumed that the figures in Table
   59 include SHG lending, which is classified as agricultural).

15 Although LSS provided extensive tabulation and analysis on state-wise performance in the four states
   it studied (AP, Karnataka, Orissa and Rajasthan) it looked at 214 SHGs in the four states as against the
   202 in a single state in this study. The state that has been studied the most extensively is AP, largely
   because of the presence in that state of the first and largest SHG resource institution, APMAS. Last
   year's Report carries in Chapter 2 a section describing the findings of APMAS 2005, a comprehensive
   summary of several studies on SHGs in AP, conducted by APMAS since 2003.

16 To the extent they were, one reason could be mismanagement by group leaders, made possible by the
   fact that many members had no clear picture of "where the savings is, how it is being used and for
   what purpose…" Another reason could be the reported practice by the banks of impounding the
   savings of the group as collateral, against both the letter and spirit of the linkage programme.
   Impounding of part of the loan amount is also reported to have been in vogue, with no interest paid
   on the deducted amount. To the extent savings belonged to surplus groups with no bank loans
   outstanding, the "balancing" of funds between surplus and deficit groups is one of the functions
   proposed for federations performing financial intermediation, as discussed in Chapter 3.

17 In this sense loan distribution was less equitable than in LSS. On the other hand, need based borrowing
   is clearly preferable to loans being distributed between all group members equally, which is another
   symptom of weak loan demand (and in some cases also lack of trust within a group) and happened in
   the case of 13 percent of all loans, with another 16 percent being distributed on the basis of "need
   plus equal basis".

18 The banks lend at between 8 to 12 percent as in other parts of the country but onlending rates range
   from as low as 8 percent (the rate at which funds are borrowed) to 36 percent. The on-lending rate is
   the lowest in the district in which the leaders receive the highest proportion of loans.

19 Instances were noted of first loans of Rs 1000, a second loan of Rs 2000, and 3rd loans of Rs 5000.
   Evidence of the emergence of a significant loan absorption constraint has been found in many other
   studies. However the solution lies not within the SHG programme but enhancing the effectiveness of the
   general development programme in increasing the productive opportunities open to the poor.

20 These are the Anganwadi Worker (AWW) and Assistant Anganwadi Worker (AWA), who not only organized
   groups, but in most groups promoted by them also became the leaders of the groups, and sometimes
   of more than one group. The report notes that groups have failed to internalize the norms of the
   programme, and tend to be perpetually dependent on SHG staff for their day to day activities. Also,

                                                                                                          45
meeting dates, venues and timing tend to be fixed at the convenience of SHPI field staff and leaders.
     Thus group meetings are fixed in the afternoons, which is a convenient time for the AWW and field staff
     of NGOs, but not for members, who are free only by late evening.

 21 The reference to subsidies is to the 10 SGSY groups. Apart from subsidies these groups had received
     average loans of Rs 300,000, which is ten times higher than the average received by the 151 groups
     linked under the regular programme. 51 groups in the sample of 202 groups had not yet been linked.

 22 Although average savings were Rs 40 a month, about 50 percent of groups had saving of Rs 20 or less
     a month.

 23 Over 85 percent of the female work force in employed in agriculture, either as cultivators or labourers.

 24 Orissa along with Rajasthan is one of the 13 Priority States where the programme is growing relatively
     rapidly. With the assistance of CARE India, Orissa prepared a "vision" document released by the Chief
     Minister for Mission Shakti, which lays down the goal of forming 300,000 groups by the end of 2008,
     of which 80 percent would be credit linked, and would be of grade A. Repeat linkage would be ensured
     in the case of 50 percent of the groups and average lending per group would be Rs 40,000. Every
     revenue village in the state would have at least one SHG. Top priority would be given to the formation
     of cluster and block level federations in every panchayat and block respectively, as well as "activity
     based federations" and cooperatives (See Chapter 3). The government would facilitate the setting up
     of a Capacity Building Institute to meet the capacity building demands of stakeholders (Government of
     Orissa 2005).

     Unfortunately the Department of Women and Child Development does not publish statistics on progress
     towards these goals, although the target for credit linked groups is likely to be 90 percent reached as
     can be seen from Table 2.2. Also, 6065 panchayat level clusters and 208 block level federations had
     been formed by March 2007, a coverage of 95 percent of the goal, although mostly only on paper.
     According to NABARD statistics the proportion of repeat loans was only 12 percent by March 2007
     (Table 2.3). Since a capacity building and resource institute for the programme has not been set up
     yet, no quality assessment study exists yet similar to the present one being discussed for Rajasthan,
     although a rating exercise was carried out in 2003 which found that the number of A, B, and C groups
     constituted 29, 14, and 57 percent of the total, respectively.

 25 These partly explain relatively low average group size of 12 and irregularities in meetings and attendance.

 26 At about 75 percent on of the lowest in the country.

 27 Rajasthan is one of the most conservative states in the country, with high discrimination against
     women. A high proportion of members are elderly women who are subjected to less seclusion.

 28 Migration is one of the most important livelihood strategies in the state. Those women who are left
     behind are unable to participate in meetings because of heavier workloads caused by the absence of
     the male family members.




46
CHAPTER 2
                                                                                           Progress Under the SHG Bank
                                                                                           Linkage Programme




References


Baland, Jean-Marie, Rohini Somanathan and Lore Vandewalle, 2007, "Micro-finance Lifespans:
A Study of Attrition and Exlusion in Self-Help Groups in India, paper prepared for presentation
at the Brookings-NCAER India Policy Forum 2007, July 17-18, New Delhi

EDA Rural Systems and APMAS, 2006, "Self Help Groups in India: A Study of the Lights and
Shades" for CRS, USAID, CARE and GTZ/NABARD, Microfinace India, New Delhi

Government of Orissa, 2005, "Empowered Woman: A Vision Document for micro-Finance in
Orissa", Women and Child Development Department, Bhubaneshwar

Centre for Microfinance and APMAS, 2006, "Quality Issues of SHGs in Rajasthan", CMF, Jaipur

Ramakrishna, RV, 2006, "Management Information System (MIS): SHG Bank Linkage Programme"
mimeo, GTZ, New Delhi




                                                                                              47
48
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                             SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                             or Nurturers?




                                        CHAPTER 3

  SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                     1
        or Nurturers?
A few years ago a chapter such as this might have started with the question "are federations
necessary", but today, whatever the answer to that question, federations seem to be a fait
accompli, with a 2005 estimate of at least 66,000 in the country as a whole (Reddy et al
2007). This number has increased since then, propelled both by a variety of push factors, with
donors, governments, and several banks supporting them for various reasons, as well as by the       A number of
                                                                                                    state
pull factor of the demand for credit that remains unsatisfied by the SBLP. Several multilateral
                                                                                                    governments,
and bilateral donor-sponsored projects have included federations as an important component          AP being the
of their SHG-based livelihoods projects, primarily as a means of ensuring the long run              most important
                                                                                                    of them,
institutional sustainability of the SHG programme.2 More communitarian-minded donors, mainly        accounting for
international and local NGOs, have promoted federations for the stronger organized identity,        almost half the
and greater possibilities for collective action, they offer SHG women, much more than a single      federations in
                                                                                                    the country
SHG could ever do3.                                                                                 through the IKP
                                                                                                    programme, are
A number of state governments, AP being the most important of them, accounting for almost           attracted by
                                                                                                    federations as a
half the federations in the country through the IKP programme, are attracted by federations
                                                                                                    convenient
as a convenient means of offering a variety of economic and social services in the rural areas,     means of
as well as for their empowerment and potential political advantages. West Bengal for instance       offering a
                                                                                                    variety of
has a minister for SHGs, who is reported to oversee 13600 panchayat level federations and 350       economic and
block level federations, and Kerala implements the Kudumbasree programme consisting of              social services
                                                                                                    in the rural
about 15,000 federations through local bodies.4 Banks are interested in the federations for
                                                                                                    areas, as well
the economies of scale they promise, and SHGs are attracted by the greater sense of efficacy        as for their
they experience through belonging to a larger fraternity, referred to often as "being able to       empowerment
                                                                                                    and potential
walk into the Collector's office". Finally, in areas or pockets where credit demand is high, many   political
of them are impatient with the quantum and timeliness of credit available under the SBLP,           advantages
despite rapid expansion of the programme in recent years.5

While the estimate of 66,000 federations needs to be updated, it is important to note that
the numbers come mostly from a few states in which government-sponsored programmes have
set up federations in every panchayat or block. Except in AP and Kerala, many of these have
yet to be registered, and the vast majority are still inactive. The number of federations set up
by NGOs and NGO-networks is much smaller, and probably below 2 to 3 thousand.6 Even for
them, details on distribution by level (whether cluster or higher), size, type, major programme
under which promoted, etc. are lacking. The sheer heterogeneity of federations,7 the fact that
many of them are still nascent and inchoate, and the dearth of case studies all complicate the
effort of coming up with a satisfactory typology, a necessary step in building a meaningfully
differentiated data base.8
                                                                                               49
It is important to note also, that despite their obvious appeal, the "are they necessary"
                    question is still being asked by the main actor in the SHG movement - NABARD - and by others
                    who argue that in a situation of limited promotional resources (promoter capacity and the
                    long-term commitment required) it is more efficient to devote these scarce resources to
                    improving the quality of SHGs and therefore the flow of resources from the banks to SHGs
                    directly, which after all is likely to remain by far the larger source of funds to SHGs than bulk
                    funding through federations. Thus although many federations have already been formed, this
                    argument goes, they are not entirely a "sunk cost" in the context of the further huge growth
                    of the SBLP envisaged.

   The tentative    The tentative hypothesis put forward in this chapter is that we should still be very interested in
  hypothesis put
                    federations primarily as a cost-effective means (but not the only one) of enhancing the prospects
  forward in this
 chapter is that    of sustainability of the SBLP and individual SHG quality.9 We need a greatly stepped up programme
  we should still   of coordinated action research to fully investigate the potential of federations in this respect.
          be very
    interested in   Moreover as discussed below, there appear to be situations where they are needed for their
      federations   financial services too, as in bridge financing, as DHAN Foundation seems to have concluded, or
   primarily as a
                    where federations have become so strong and efficient that lenders are genuinely persuaded
   cost-effective
 means (but not     about the scale advantages of lending to them directly, adding a third channel to the two main
the only one) of    existing channels of microfinance in the country, or what have been called community based
   enhancing the
     prospects of   MFIs (CBMFIs). Third, federations offer the prospect of very real empowerment benefits. Ultimately,
   sustainability   and quite apart from their benefits as aggregators of services, it is these benefits, of experiencing
of the SBLP and     a sense of efficacy through advocacy and collective action, that drives SHGs and many promoters
  individual SHG
          quality   to federate. It is this aspect of the SHG "revolution" that attracts many observers the most. As
                    Jairam Ramesh points out, financial services are only part of the success story. "More fundamental
                    has been voice, identity and empowerment" (Box 3.1)

                                         Box 3.1. "The SHG Revolution: What Next?"

                     "Today, in some parts of the country, SHGs are taking on new roles and responsibilities that lie
                     at the very core of livelihood security for the poor. Indeed, as institutions of social capital,
                     they offer great potential…The SHG network in Andhra has gone beyond credit…

                     First, it has taken up the marketing of commodities like maize, neem, soybean, coffee, lac and
                     red gram. Last year, the value of procurement was in the region of Rs 130 crores. The big
                     challenge here is to go beyond traditional marketing and get into value-addition in meaningful
                     measure and develop linkages with exporters and processors directly.

                     Second, it is being used to distribute old-age pensions-in 2006/07, over Rs 700 crores was
                     distributed to around 3 million beneficiaries through the SHGs. Timely disbursement of pensions
                     and disbursements without a "consideration" are the hallmark of SHG involvement.

                     Third, the elements of a community-based food security system are being put in place. At the
                     moment, it consists almost entirely of a rice credit line but the goal seems to be paddy
                     purchase and milling by the SHG network at the village and mandal level itself.

                     Fourth, dairy interventions have started with livestock being purchased through SHG-bank
                     linkages and with the SHG network setting up bulk milk coolers and milk procurement centres.
                     My own involvement has been to try and ensure that there are links established between the
                     network of SHGs and the traditional NDDB procurement network… Dairying is very important
                     as an income-augmenting occupation to crop agriculture.

                50
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                              SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                              or Nurturers?




There is one more somewhat unusual intervention through the SHG network. This relates to
non-pesticide management in agriculture, particularly cotton… Cotton lies at the heart of
the suicide tragedies that have stalked the state over the past decade and so this particular
initiative has great significance. So far, something like 2 lakh acres have been covered and by
the end of the decade about 10% of the net sown area in the state will be covered.

In my capacity as Minister of State of Commerce, I am particularly interested in exports of
spices. Today, about 25% of the $ 600 million of spice exports is accounted for by chillies
that are grown predominantly in Andhra Pradesh. We have discovered that chillies without
pesticide residue command a premium in world markets. I will distinguish here between non-
pesticide agriculture where fertilizers are still used and organic farming where yields may turn
out to be lower but net returns to farmers could actually increase. NPM agriculture is, in my
view, the first step to organic farming that has relevance in certain situations and niche
regions.

I want to mention another important initiative … About 2 million ha.of government land has
been assigned to the landless poor in Andhra Pradesh over the past decades. But as is well
known, the productivity of these assigned lands is very low-perhaps, that is why they were
"assigned" in the first place. Against this background, the state government has launched a
comprehensive land development project that takes up about 10% of this area to be brought
under productive use in four years time.                                                              … it is critical
                                                                                                      to see SHGs not
The Andhra SHG story has undoubtedly been government-driven. … What it shows is that                  as just networks
                                                                                                      for confidence-
government can innovate, that government can demonstrate commitment and concern.
                                                                                                      building and
Efficiency is not the monopoly of the private sector nor is sensitivity the preserve of civil         empowerment
society. Within the government system, there are people who are motivated and who, given              but also as
                                                                                                      networks that
political support, can and will deliver…
                                                                                                      must have
                                                                                                      access to new
To be sure, over time the SHG network must become self-sustaining. Indeed, that is the true           economic
test of whether the government has succeeded or not. When will this happen? I have been               opportunities
asking this question of my colleagues in Andhra Pradesh and the answer they have come up is
the following. A Mandal Samakhya will have the capacity to be on its own feet when it has a
monthly net income of Rs 50,000. Today, while a detailed financial analysis is still being
done, it appears that of the 1000 Mandal Samakhyas, perhaps just about 10-15% meet this
criteria. Clearly, there is a long way to go yet. Further, even in these 100-odd Mandal Samakhyas,
the bulk of the monthly income-around three-fourths-is really interest income. This proportion
has to reduce.

… it is critical to see SHGs not as just networks for confidence-building and empowerment
but also as networks that must have access to new economic opportunities. One of the
initiatives taken by the Ministry of Commerce in recent months is to link export promotion
councils with SHGs so that the benefits of export expansion can accrue directly to the poor
where they have skills. A beginning has been made in leather in Tamil Nadu and in shellac in
Andhra Pradesh. The export promotion councils are working with SHGs to provide design and
marketing assistance, while the SHGs are responsible for production. Another example is how
the SHG-run lace export park in Narsapur in West Godavari district of Andhra Pradesh is being
facilitated to establish global linkages. A recent breakthrough has been obtained with Ikea.

…SHGs are not panaceas for every situation. In India, there have been many instances of
innovative initiatives have been taken and pretty soon these initiatives degenerating into


                                                                                                 51
"solutions in search of problems" … Since the state administrative machinery has collapsed in
                      so many areas, there is a temptation to give the SHG network an ever expanding role.

                      … Proponents of SHGs have raised the possibility of SHGs managing PHCs, for instance. When
                      there is a good thing going, exaggerated expectations can and do set in, especially when
                      there is political mileage to be derived as well. Drawing a Lakshman Rekha around the SHG
                      network so that it does not spread itself very thin is very essential. At the same time, I do
                      recognize that there has to be some room for responding to new challenges. For instance, now
                      that Andhra Pradesh has emerged as number 1 in HIV/AIDS prevalence in the country, public
                      health planners should use the extensive SHG network for combating this scourge.

                      I had alluded to MFIs earlier… I believe that both are have important roles to play. The
                      separation of the social organization to be performed by the IKP and capital mobilization and
                      disbursement to be performed by the MFIs is the starting point of a cooperative approach. In
                      such an approach, the regulation of the industry will be driven by the market and community,
                      rather than by legislation.

  The separation      …the panchayat revolution … has swept India, thanks to the 73rd Amendment to the
     of the social    Constitution. While much remains to be done, over 30 lakh elected representatives now all
 organization to
be performed by       over rural India with over 12 lakh of them being women is a visible manifestation of this
      the IKP and     momentous change.
           capital
     mobilization     …Simultaneously, there has been the SHG upsurge, an upsurge that is uniquely Indian. Over 3
              and     crore women are now linked to banks through over 22 lakh SHGs and as I have shown, financial
disbursement to
be performed by       services is only a small part of their success story. More fundamental has been voice, identity
 the MFIs is the      and empowerment.
   starting point
of a cooperative      …The relationship between SHG institutions and panchayat bodies needs greater
         approach
                      attention…There is really no conflict between the two. SHG institutions can and must play a
                      supporting role in social mobilization and in social audit, like, for instance, in the NREGA.

                      ...Over time, as SHG members gain in voice and self-confidence, they can be expected to
                      contest panchayat elections on their own. In the recent local body elections, about 9-10% of
                      those elected to mandal and zilla panchayats were "SHG women", something that was unheard
                      of before.

                      …For inclusive growth which has become the mantra these days, India needs not just
                      globalization as traditionally understood but actually glocalisation which ensures that economic
                      growth is more broad-based, equitable and sustainable than it has been so far. Panchayats are
                      institutions of representation. SHGs are institutions of participation. These are the twin
                      pillars on which India's glocalisation strategy should rest."

                      Excerpts from Silver Jubilee Lecture at the Society for the Promotion of Wastelands
                      Development, New Delhi, May 5, 2007 by Jairam Ramesh, Minister of State for Commerce
                      (with a shortened version in the Economic and Political Weekly, September 8-14, 2007).


                      Non-financial support services to SHGs
                      It is useful to discuss the experience with federations according to three broad sets of
                      objectives they could serve. These are (i) non-financial support services designed to strengthen
                      the quality of member SHGs (ii) financial services and (iii) non-credit related economic and
                      social activities.

                     52
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                              SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                              or Nurturers?




Between the first two of these at any rate, most observers would regard the first as more
important. While credit can be accessed through direct linkages, and that too relatively easily
judging by the pace of expansion of SHG Bank Linkage Programme, studies show that the
long-run health of SHGs and the very sustainability of the programme depends crucially on
strengthening SHG capacity.10 Federations are an important means of doing so, although it is
important to note that they are not the only ones.

Other approaches are (i) institutions such as MYRADA's Community Managed Resource Centres
(CMRCs) (Box 3.2) (ii) accounting system innovations such as Computer Munshi, (iii) greater
capacity building of the capacity builders themselves, strengthening SHPAs to provide more
effective and longer-term hand-holding of SHGs directly, financed if necessary by higher and
longer-term promotional assistance from government, (iv) bank branches insisting of better
account keeping and playing a stronger role in capacity building of linked SHGs, either
directly or though outsourcing (as SBI is doing), (v) DRDAs and government programmes
eschewing targets, and preferably direct group formation by government functionaries
altogether, or at least improving their own capacity building efforts, and (vi) induction of
technology11.

       Box 3.2 MYRADA's Community Managed Resource Centres (CMRCs)

MYRADA had set up 89 CMRCs with 303 full-time workers by December 2006, each covering 100-
200 SHGs, watershed institutions and other CBOs, to provide training, support and information
on a variety of government schemes, insurance and legal matters, and equipped with telephone
and internet facilities to access information and download forms etc. The major activity is
training (about 6000 trainings a year) not just on SHG related skills such as book keeping, but
in other areas too such as awareness of health, veterinary care, disability, and legal issues. Eye,
blood-donation, and animal health camps are also organized. All services are paid for. 15 CMRCs
had reached self-sufficiency by Sept 2005, including payment for the services of the Manager
and other staff, both full-time and community volunteers.

CMRCs play a key role in MYRADA's withdrawal strategy after 6 to 8 years in an area. The centres
are strictly speaking not representative organizations (and are unlike federations in this respect)
but are run by management committees comprising representatives of member CBOs. MYRADA
also has federations through which representatives to the CMRCs are chosen, but these are
cluster level groups of only 10-15 SHGs, kept small so as to maximize participation, and are paid
for by one-time admission fees and monthly membership fees from the SHGs. Unlike in many
other parts of the country, the availability of local book-keepers does not seem to be a major
issue in MYRADA's areas, and book keeping is handled by the SHGs themselves, with the assistance
of training offered by the CMRCs. Facilitation in availing of linkage loans from the bank branches,
and in getting loans from Sanghamitra, is offered by the CMRCs and not by the federations,
whose task is essentially to offer audit services, review the functioning of member SHGs, resolve
any conflicts, and organize trainings and exposure visits through the CMRC.

                                           Based on discussions with Al Fernandez, MYRADA


However these approaches are not alternatives to federations,12 or to each other. The main
non-financial services federations can provide to develop capacity are (i) training and hand-
holding in book-keeping and accounting, (ii) direct provision of accounting services, (iii)
ongoing quality monitoring, (iv) periodic grading or quality assessment and (v) annual

                                                                                                  53
auditing. Other non-financial services they can provide, although not directly related to
                    capacity-building are (i) conflict resolution and problem solving within and between groups
                    (ii) promoting new groups (iii) awareness building and advocacy of social issues and (iv)
                    livelihood promotion activities if the funding is available.

                    We need much more action research to get a feel for how federations can provide such services
                    effectively and sustainably. APMAS's 2006 quality assessment report found the provision of
                    services to be the weakest aspect of federation performance across the six indicators in
                GRADES.13 One of the best known cases of a federation providing non-financial services along
                with limited financial intermediation (but no bulk borrowing14 from external sources) is that
                of Sakhi Samiti in Alwar district, Rajasthan, which was promoted by PRADAN. After supporting
                it for about ten years PRADAN exited Sakhi Samiti six years ago. Since then Sakhi Samiti has
                been successfully providing book-keeping services to about 250 SHGs on its own, through a
      Anecdotal small staff of field workers at the federation level, and one munshi (accountant) based at each
       evidence of three clusters. Sakhi Samiti charges member SHGs 2 per Rs 1000 of cumulative group
  suggests that
            once
                    savings a month, so that a typical group pays about Rs 200 a month. It also facilitates
federations get     linkages of new groups with the local banks, for which it charges half a percent of the loan
        into the    amount. A third source of revenue is lending from an associated fund called Sakhi Suvidha, to
     business of
 accessing bulk     which each group makes a one-time contribution or Rs 1000, and each group member Rs 50.
      funds, the    Loans from the fund are meant to tide groups over periods when they are waiting for loans
  preoccupation
                    from the banks, and the fund lends much less than the banks. It seems these sources of
            with
  sustainability    income15 are insufficient to recover costs fully, which are met through cross-subsidization
      leads to a    from other activities. It is not known how much higher fees, (and interest on Sakhi Suvidha
neglect of non-
        financial   loans, or its scale of operations) would have to be for Sakhi Samiti as a whole to achieve self-
         services   sufficiency.16

                    A question that often arises is whether it helps to separate non-financial from financial
                    service provision (i.e for federations to do one or the other) Anecdotal evidence suggests
                    that once federations get into the business of accessing bulk funds, the preoccupation with
                    sustainability leads to a neglect of non-financial services, given limitations on field worker
                    time and managerial energy and attention-span. Also, it has been pointed out that the
                    balance of power within federations tends to shift away from the primaries towards the higher
                    tiers, with the former becoming more dependent on the latter, and the federation becoming
                    less responsive to the primaries and their non-financial needs and interests. Shashi Rajgopalan
                    in particular has in various writings described the dynamics involved.17

                    It could be argued, on the other hand, that a bulk funder would itself be expected to exercise
                    pressure for maintaining group quality out of prudential self-interest. However there is little
                    evidence to support this hypothesis One district level federation visited by the author that
                    was borrowing from the banks to on-lend to its middle-tier secondaries, widely referred to as
                    MACS in AP after their form of incorporation, relied for its high recoveries by the MACS from
                    their groups more on the informal personal responsibility each MACS member took for the
                    geographical set of SHGs she represented in the MACs, than on the inherent good quality of
                    the groups. Moreover, the accounting assistance that the MACS level accountants provided to
                    the groups was restricted to the loan ledgers relating to the MACS loan and not to the rest of
                    the group's books. (The groups were free to borrow also from the large government-sponsored
                    SHG federation programme, IKP, formerly called Velugu). In this respect, the federation was
                    functioning more as an MFI than a federation set up to strengthen its primaries.18 Indeed
                54
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                             SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                             or Nurturers?




APMAS 2006 and a number of other studies point out that recoveries within groups are much
poorer than those from groups to the secondaries, so that each level is drawing at least
temporarily on its own funds (savings deposits and accumulated surpluses from operations), a
process which in the long run is not sustainable. It would be useful to gather empirical
material on how real these concerns are, and the other dynamics involved.

If the case studies were to show that the fee-for-service concept has not usually worked in If the case
                                                                                            studies were to
purely non-financial federations, then one argument against separating financial from non-
                                                                                                show that the
financial service provision is that the former might be able to pay for the latter. An example of
                                                                                                fee-for-service
a federation that has been successful in doing so is KVK sponsored by the DHAN Foundation.      concept has not
                                                                                                usually worked
KVK is one of the few federations which have been studied carefully through a case-study        in purely non-
(Srinivasan 2005) KVK offered credit through bulk borrowing and on-lending services, apart      financial
                                                                                                federations,
from providing non-financial services to its members, and the margin of 3 percent added on
                                                                                                then one
by both the apex level as well as the cluster level sufficed to pay not just for accounting     argument
assistance costs, but for total operating costs including all staff. From 2002-03, however, KVK against
                                                                                                separating
switched from financing support costs from lending margins to a system of sharing total costs financial from
determined once a year (at the AGM) by all SHG members equally. The switch to this system non-financial
was made to ensure greater accountability to the SHGs, and was in keeping with DHAN service
                                                                                                provision is that
Foundation's new policy of moving away from bulk borrowing for all its federations as discussed the former
in Box 3.3.                                                                                     might be able to
                                                                                                pay for the
                                                                                                latter
        Box 3.3 DHAN Foundation federations: changing with the times

DHAN Foundation's policy towards bulk borrowing by federations has evolved through several
stages. In the first stage, as an increasing number of SHGs were formed under the Kalanjiam
banking programme, the demand for linkage loans could not keep pace with supply from the
SBLP, which was still gathering pace. In order to increase the quantum of credit available to
SHGs, capture scale economies, and earn much needed revenue to support non-financial
services to the clusters and groups through the spread, several federations initiated bulk
borrowing from the banks and financial institutions. SPMS and KVK are prominent examples,
the former being located, unusually, in an urban area (Tirupati). Cumulatively, 25 federations
are reported to have mobilized 24 crores from this source, as against Rs 134 crores through
linkage lending. (Vasimalai and Narender 2007).

However, as it became apparent that building up truly member controlled federations with the
specialized financial skills to manage bulk borrowing was going to take an unacceptably long
time, the Kalanjium community banking programme decided to centralize bulk borrowing in a
S 25 company, the Kalanjiam Development and Financial Services (KDFS), which was registered
in 2001 and had borrowed Rs 14 crores from SIDBI, ABN-Amro and others by March 2004.
(DHAN Foundation 2004). The company is owned by the federations but professionally managed
by employees. Direct bulk borrowing by the federations was increasingly restricted thereafter
to specialized purposes such as housing, where the lending institutions were themselves
wholesale institutions without branches, such as HUDCO, HDFC, and NHB, and could not make
small loans to individual SHGs. It is important to note that for the same capacity-related
reasons affecting bulk borrowing (with a few prominent exceptions such as KVK and SPMS)
KDFS decided to lend directly to the groups and not to the federations.

According to the booklet "Catalysing Linkages:SHGs and Banks: the KDFS Experience 2001-
2004" (DHAN Foundation 2004), the demonstration effect of KDFS lending has been partly

                                                                                                 55
responsible for growth of direct linkage lending from the banks and the improvement in the
                      overall proportion of groups linked (to 75 percent) and the leverage ratio, or loan amount to
                      own savings, (to about 1:1) The booklet is very clear that "KDFS needs to maintain its role and
                      identity as an enabler and for bridging the gap. It should guard against becoming another
                      microfinance agency providing credit services."

                      Of the 130 odd locations in which DF currently has operations, it has so far registered
                      federations in about 80 (20 in AP, 10 in Karnataka, 2-3 in Orissa, 1 in MP and the rest in Tamil
                      Nadu). Several of these are in urban areas such as Madurai, Vishakapatnam, and Salem.
                      Federations are registered as societies and trusts so that SHGs can become primary members.
                      Of the 80 federations only about 10 are currently involved in bulk borrowing, and that too at
                      a reducing level. The primary mode of group financing is through direct linkages with the
                      federation acting as facilitator for a fee (as in Karnataka where the SBI pays the federations 1
                      percent of the interest rate charged the groups).

      It has been     Even SPMS, which is possibly the first SHG federation registered in the country, in 1992, as a
      pointed out     society, and which relied primarily on bulk borrowing in the first few years after receiving
 that one factor
           driving    loans from SIDBI, HUDCO and HDFC in the mid-1990s, has with the growth of the SBLP for the
      federations     last few years been encouraging direct linkages. These increased rapidly after 2002 and finally
          towards     overtook bulk borrowing in 2005. One of the major lenders was the Venkateshwara Grameen
     provision of
         financial    Bank, with SHG lending accounting for 10 percent of its business. Unlike institutions in
       services is    cities, those in towns can operated in the surrounding peri-urban areas with access to public
    precisely this
                      sector branch banks. Apart from a major emphasis on housing, which it shares with urban
 scope for cross-
   subsidization,     microfinance generally SPMS has like other DF federations branched increasingly into economic
     and if grant     and social initiatives such as insurance, health programmes, slum improvement, reproductive
funds were more
                      and child heath and even consumer stores (DHAN Foundation 2005). This is in accordance
            readily
     available to     with DF's philosophy of seeking to provide critical missing services, based on core competencies
    finance their     at each level.
    non-financial
         services,    Contrary to the hypothesis that bulk borrowing would increase self-sufficiency, federations
      federations
                      that have not got into financing (as noted above, the majority now) are more often cost
      would more
 often resist the     recovering than those which do bulk borrow. Roughly 35 to 40 of Dhan's 80 federations are
  temptation to       reported to be fully cost recovering.
    get into bulk
           funding                                      Based on discussion with K. Narender, DHAN Foundation



                      It has been pointed out that one factor driving federations towards provision of financial
                      services is precisely this scope for cross-subsidization, and if grant funds were more readily
                      available to finance their non-financial services, federations would more often resist the
                      temptation to get into bulk funding. Another issue that arises therefore is whether there is
                      a case for greater use of grant money to enable federations to undertake non-financial services
                      without getting into bulk funding.19

                      However too much should not be made of the cross-subsidization benefits of bulk financing.
                      Data contained in comments on this chapter received from PRADAN (Box 3.4) show how
                      viability might be achieved without bulk borrowing but with assistance from economic
                      activities. Some federations such as Shramik Bharti in UP have actually got out of bulk
                      borrowing because they felt they were was losing sight of their objectives as peoples
                      organizations, and are now facilitating direct linkages through the local banks.20 Several

                  56
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                             SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                             or Nurturers?




SHPAs promoting federations at a recent Sa-Dhan consultation on federations said that revenues
from fees manage to pay for a substantial part of expenditures on training, accounting
assistance, auditing and other support services offered by their federations21.

   Box 3.4      Making non-financial federations viable: PRADAN's experience

Federations are needed to provide support to SHGs in maintaining quality by providing
appropriate services. Groups are complicated phenomena, however small they are. It is not
wise to expect them to survive on their own without support from some mechanism external
to the group. That is where the peerage created through clusters and the federation comes
into play. But then, clusters and federations are also groups. So we have to create an integrated
prototype, with SHGs, clusters and the federation as the different levels, and a set of community
resource persons housed in it. It has to be a financially sustainable model, the revenue being
generated by different services that the different levels provide.

The clusters and federation also need to evolve as independent entities of their own, each            Federations are
with a clear vision and agenda of its own. This evolves over a period of time. The clusters are       needed to
                                                                                                      provide support
for peer monitoring and learning, collective action at the local level and sharing resources at       to SHGs in
the local level when needed, such as a cluster accountant. The federation provides identity to        maintaining
the women, plays the role of a people's organization dealing with poor peoples' agenda, and           quality by
                                                                                                      providing
provides a set of services relevant to the SHGs - hosting the Computer Munshi, the MIS                appropriate
system, as many livelihood support services as can be managed, and building solidarity and            services. Groups
empowerment. Clusters and federations have to be built around the skills and resources of the         are complicated
                                                                                                      phenomena,
SHG women and not on that of the NGO professional.                                                    however small
                                                                                                      they are. It is
If there are 200 SHGs and 3000 members in a federation, the income and expenditure will look          not wise to
like this                                                                                             expect them to
                                                                                                      survive on their
12 staff @ Rs 1500 per month - 12 months                                               216000         own without
Computer Munshi - 2000 pm                                                               24000         support from
                                                                                                      some mechanism
Federation manager - 2000 pm                                                            24000         external to the
Stationery - 2000 pm                                                                    24000         group
Admin - rent electricity, computer
Maintenance etc - Rs 3000 pm                                                             36000
Local travel @ Rs 2000 pm (board meeting monthly)                                        24000
Contingencies                                                                            10000

TOTAL                                                                                358000
This works out to about Rs 120 per member per year, which is on the high side. Thus the
federation will have to get into livelihood support activities such as collective purchase of
inputs or collective marketing which can earn it a surplus of about Rs 50-60 thousand, and
can help maintain the member contribution at about Rs 100/- per member per year. In Kesla
last year the federation mobilized a surplus of Rs 70000/- by trading in agri inputs. So it is
possible. We can further reduce the member contribution by mobilizing grant funds if available,
or building up a corpus from start up grants.

The services that the member gets are regular group monitoring support, in situ training,
periodic audit, MIS, and problem solving support. In addition to the Rs 100 contribution
made to the federation by each member, the group pays the group accountant Rs 30 to 50
every month for writing accounts, from their interest surplus. We need to do more action
research on this before we surmise anything… What we need are inputs from the behavioural

                                                                                                 57
sciences. They are the ones to can tell us about groups, group dynamics, and institutions etc.
                    Action research is required with inputs not just from bankers and economists, and NGO-
                    wallahs, but from people who understand groups from the most basic psychological, human
                    processes point of view. Institutions are after not about services but about people..

                    One of the reasons PRADAN is against financial services by federations is because it requires a
                    lot of sophistication to run a MFI especially when volumes are large, and it has to be done by
                    professionals which introduces its own kind of information asymmetry. When finances are
                    made available though the SBLP it does not make the women dependent on the professionals.
                    At the same time, the women have other kinds of skills - political skills, skills of mobilizing,
                    human skills, leadership skills etc. That is what needs to be used and nurtured, we are
                    unnecessarily burdening the women by making them run MFIs.

                    I would even go so far as to say that even if financial and non-financial services are unviable
                    or ineffective, the empowerment benefits still make federations worthwhile I think it is even
                    possible to have a viable organization only involved in empowerment related issues The question
                    is - will people pay for empowerment and dignity? Intuitively yes. If people are willing to give
                    up lives for such issues, surely they would pay 100 rupees a year to have an organization of
                    their own which gives them an enhanced sense of dignity! But how do we bring it to life?
                    There might be need to really look around for examples- there is a need to document some
                    best cases from across the country in understanding these issues. Today we are all talking with
                    very inadequate understanding of what is happening At least I am.

                                                            Comments received from D Narendranath, PRADAN


                    Financial services
                    Bulk funding
Bulk funding (of    Among financial services, the most important one is clearly bulk funding.22 Bulk funding (of a
          a truly
                    truly commercial nature)23 is driven by the prospect of scale economies for the lender and
      commercial
       nature) is   greater access to funds by the borrower. Private banks (such as ICICI, HDFC ABN-AMRO, UTI,),
   driven by the    wholesale lenders (HUDCO, FWWB, SIDBI, NABARD), public commercial banks (SBI, Canara Bank,
      prospect of
            scale   Bank of India, Indian Bank and Bank of Maharashtra), RRBs, and Basix (through both its NBFC
   economies for    and LAB) are all current or erstwhile lenders.24 The most recent phase of bulk lending to
  the lender and
                    federations took place by private banks to NGO-promoted federations, mostly in AP. Lending by
  greater access
 to funds by the    the public commercial banks took place mostly in Tamil Nadu to DHAN Foundation promoted
        borrower    federations when DHAN Foundation was actively encouraging its federations to borrow. It has
                    since changed its policy as discussed below, and has set up a S 25 company to centralize bulk
                    borrowing, but only to supplement direct linkages in a "bridge financing" role. This is because
                    the SBLP is now judged to have reached the stage where the argument for bulk borrowing
                    (credit stringency) is no longer valid. Several other NGOs have recently set up similar S 25
                    companies to play the same role. Finally, there has been some nascent RRB lending to Village
                    Organizations, the second-level tier in the IKP programme in AP, propelled largely by moral
                    suasion from the state government.

                    A documented example of bulk borrowing is an ICICI loan for SHGs in 19 MACS organized by
                    Pragati Seva Samiti, an MFI in Warangal district, AP (described in Harper and Kirsten 2006).
                    The loans to the SHGs, while more expensive than the loans the SHGs received when sourced

                58
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                                  SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                                  or Nurturers?




from the local RRB, were for a larger amount, and part of the difference in price was offset by
lower borrower transactions costs.25 The case does not provide information on the relative importance
of the bulk funder as a source of loans as against direct linkages, if any. Some federations discourage
or even prohibit constituent groups from borrowing directly from the banks, which are usually
cheaper despite higher transactions costs. What should the policy be here?

Another issue is the distribution of functions between various levels. Although many federations
have three levels, in some cases the apex or intermediate level performs only non-financial or
economic and social activities services so that the intermediating tiers are in effect only two.
The distribution of the total spread between the various levels depends largely on the
distribution of functions, respective staff complements, and which level pays for them. Thus
in MARI, also in Warangal district and also a former CASHE partner, the MACS managers are paid
for by the apex level and are transferable.26

MARI borrows in bulk from ICICI, on behalf of a district level apex, Sangatitha. A UTI loan was In a sense, the
                                                                                                real test (for
borrowed by Sangatitha directly. Accessed funds are on-lent at 16 percent to the MACS which
                                                                                                  the economies of
on-lend to the SHGs at 19 percent. Kakatia Grameen Bank has made housing loans to the MACS        scale argument)
directly. Total membership is expected to grow to about 50,000 borrowers by March 2008,           is whether banks
                                                                                                  with rural branch
with loans outstanding of Rs 35 to 40 crores. The MACS are graded monthly according to            networks such as
certain parameters, have all been rated by APMAS, are audited annually, and there is an           SBI see it as
                                                                                                  cheaper to make
incentive component to field and HO staff pay. The average operational self-sufficiency (OSS)
                                                                                                  bulk loans to
of all the MACSs was 149 percent in August 2006, and that of the Sangatitha, the district level   federations
apex, 118 percent. An urgent need (in this as in other federations) is the induction of one or rather than
                                                                                                  conduct direct
more professionals at the apex level, for which the federation will have to be willing to pay the linkages
going market rate.27 MACS promoted by the AP NGO, GRAM, are reported to be even larger than
MARI's. Indur MACS promoted by GRAM has received convertible debt from Bellwether, the
social venture capital fund.28

A third AP federation, Ankuram Sanghamam Poram (ASP), which borrows from the commercial
banks29 constitutes in a sense a unique model for federations in AP because it is a state level
federation, and was not promoted by any particular NGO, but grew out of the Dalit movement30.
ASP is the subject of a detailed case study full of insights into the relationship between the
three levels by Rewa Misra, who refers to it as "a massive combination of a trade union
movement, a Dalit movement, and an NGO" (Misra 2007). ASP now has about 150,000 members
at the base level and has received considerable grant funding from donors in view of its
uniqueness. The case shows that while ASP absorbed the initial risks and costs associated with
outreach to remote areas and marginalized communities, it is facing competition from new
entrants at the primary level, and further growth will have to depend less on member loyalty
than the ability to deliver timely and adequate loans. The sample SHGs in the case now have a
choice of borrowing not just from the banks and IKP's Village Organizations, but some of them
even belong to more than one federation (other than IKP).31

Bulk funding as we have seen has come so far mostly from the private banks who in the
absence of extensive rural branch networks have an incentive to lend to SHGs through federations
in order to meet their priority sector targets. Indeed, banks like HDFC have also been lending
to urban SHGs through their federations, such as Roshan Vikas (Box 3.5) for the same reason.
Seven private banks currently have loans outstanding to the largest bulk borrowing federation
in the country, Sarvodaya Nano Finance Corporation.32 In a sense, the real test (for the economies

                                                                                                      59
of scale argument) is whether banks with rural branch networks such as SBI see it as cheaper
                        to make bulk loans to federations rather than conduct direct linkages, and whether scale
                        economies will ever offset the perception of higher risk in making say one Rs 50 lakh loan
                        rather than 50 Rs one lakh loans. This test has not really been met yet, although there
                        continue to be cases of public sector banks lending to federations, such as the recent cash-
                        credit loan extended by the Bank of Maharashtra to Chaitanya in Maharashtra.

                        As noted earlier, there has also been sporadic RRB lending to VOs in AP, especially in Mahbubnagar
                        district where a concerted effort was made in 2005 at the urging of the IKP programme, to
                        lend to VOs in accordance with guidelines issued few years ago by the Hyderabad office of
                        NABARD. It was reported at a recent workshop on financing federations in AP that about 150
                        VOs have been financed in the district by several banks to the extent of about Rs 10 crores.
                        While the workshop favoured the concept of lending to VOs, bankers urged the need to
                        proceed cautiously as several VOs had been defaulting for more than a year. Among the prior
                        steps necessary was a clear strategy for training raters, bankers, SHPI staff and federation
                        leaders especially in VO financial management.

  Insurance is less     The dominant trend currently is for mostly public sector banks to lend to S 25 companies being
 extensive among        set up by SHPIs such as MYRADA, DHAN Foundation and several others, which lend directly to
     SHG members
           than MFI     SHGs rather than to their federations. The first of these was Sanghamitra Rural Financial
 members. If this       Services incorporated by MYRADA in 1995 (see Fernandez 2007) followed by Kalanjiam
         is because
                        Development and Financial Services (KDFS), which was registered by DHAN in 2001. More
   individual SHGs
   are too small to     recently CYSD has promoted Swayanshree Micro Credit Services in Orissa, with loans outstanding
 access insurance,      to SHGs of Rs 7.5 crores in July 2007, borrowings from SBI and HDFC, and quasi-equity from
federations would
 seem to offer an       Bellwether, and SEARCH has set up KOPSA in Tamil Nadu33.
    opportunity to
        rectify the     It is important to note that DHAN Foundation's rationale for centralizing bulk borrowing and
          situation.
                        on-lending into a community owned but professionally managed S 25 company, was that
  Insurance is one
     service where      building up truly member controlled federations with the specialized financial skills to manage
                large   bulk borrowing was turning out to much more difficult than was originally anticipated and
      government-
          sponsored     was taking an unacceptably long time. For the same capacity-related reasons, KDFS decided to
         federation     lend directly to the groups and not to the federations. DHAN Foundation is very clear that
   programs should      "KDFS needs to maintain its role and identity as an enabler, and for bridging the gap (in
             have an
 advantage, since       direct linkage loans). It should guard against becoming another microfinance agency providing
           they can     credit services." (DHAN Foundation 2004).
   aggregate huge
            numbers
                        An important issue for both types of federations (non-financial as well as financial) is how high
                        are promotional costs, and who is to bear them? Promotional costs have been borne so far (and
                        continue to be borne)34 largely by donors, including international NGOs with an ideological
                        leaning towards federations. One of the few estimates we have for promotion cost per SHG is for
                        the DHAN foundation in Srinivasan 2005 ($150 to $200) and Nair 2005 (also about $150).35

                        Insurance
                        A second increasingly important financial service is insurance36 According to EDA's evaluation
                        of 20 SIDBI MFIs (EDA 2005), insurance is less extensive among SHG members than MFI
                        members. If this is because individual SHGs are too small to access insurance, federations
                        would seem to offer an opportunity to rectify the situation. Insurance is one service where
                        large government-sponsored federation programs should have an advantage, since they can
                    60
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                                SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                                or Nurturers?




aggregate huge numbers. IKP is reported to have 1.8 million of its members insured. Banks
too can play a useful role. Some banks such as Andhra Bank is reported to insist that 15
percent of its linkage loans be used to avail of insurance.37 An area calling for field investigation
is how extensive insurance is through federations, how it is organized, and how it could it be
increased. It should be noted though that insurance can be provided just as well by non-
financial federations.

Rotating liquidity between groups
A third financial service is the movement of surplus funds from surplus to deficit SHGs, or what        To the extent
                                                                                                        the option of
is commonly referred to by practitioners as the "balancing" role. This liquidity balancing role
                                                                                                        depositing
seems to be fairly common. At least two promoters in the Sa-Dhan consultation, Roshan Vikas             surplus funds in
(Box 3.5) and Chaitanya said their federations "balance" funds, as does ASP.38 To the extent            a higher tier
                                                                                                        increases choice,
the option of depositing surplus funds in a higher tier increases choice, and SHGs and MACS             and SHGs and
remain free to deposit them in the banks instead, the balancing role could be extremely useful          MACS remain
in well managed federations. Idle funds with SHGs crop up as a concern in many APMAS                    free to deposit
                                                                                                        them in the
studies, but they seem to be a problem at the federation level too. It would be useful to               banks instead,
investigate why this is, if they can be routed to deficit SHGs.                                         the balancing
                                                                                                        role could be
                                                                                                        extremely useful
Facilitating linkages                                                                                   in well managed
                                                                                                        federations
While we have already counted this service as non-financial, it could be regarded as financial
if it is backed by guarantees from the higher tier. Federations often render assistance to new
groups by helping banks appraise loan applications, and setting up counters at a bank on a
fixed day of the week to assist groups with repayments and new applications. Federations and
SHPI staff seek to improve their leverage with banks by promising exclusive banking relationships
with them, and making deposits of their own idle/surplus funds. Again, except for providing
guarantees, all these services can be provided by non-financial federations too.

Savings services
These too need to be studied and described in greater detail. Many federations require SHGs
to share their monthly savings with the higher tier compulsorily (an example being Swayanshree
described in Box 3.6) and many offer voluntary savings too (for instance Roshan Vikas,
described in Box 3.5)39 Security deposits or margin money payments are also often required to
be placed in the higher level on receipt of a loan, as in the case of MARI above. On the face of
it a federation should be able to offer a higher rate on savings than a bank if it is intermediating
to deficit units at lower cost or higher interest than the banks. An issue here is how much
incremental savings take place as a result of a federation's savings service and how much of it
represents diversion from bank savings. Another issue (discussed below) is that of appropriate
regulation and supervision to ensure the safety of savings. Finally, some federations are
reported to be offering pensions, such as some of those promoted by DHAN Foundation,
although for most others this would seem a bit a bit futuristic.




                                                                                                    61
Box 3.5     Roshan Vikas: An urban SHG federation

 Roshan Vikas is an urban cooperative SHG federation operating in Hyderabad's old city, with
 plans to expand into roughly a third of the city's 40-50 municipal wards by 2010. It started
 off as a two-tier structure (SHGs federated into a ward level MACS) in the late 1990s, with an
 emphasis on linking its SHGs to health and other government programmes, but as its groups
 started accumulating idle funds it commenced the activity of inter-lending, or "balancing"
 funds, by paying surplus groups 12 percent on their deposits and lending them to deficit
 groups at 18 percent, at a 5:1 ratio on their savings (only those deposited with the federation
 or on total savings?). There was also a requirement that the SHGs, whether surplus or not,
 would pool 25 percent of their savings in RV for lending to deficit groups.

 In 2006 Roshan Vikas (RV) decided to augment the supply of loans to its groups by linking
 them to the banks, starting with a 3 year term loan of Rs 2.5 crores from HDFC Bank. To prepare
 for the large planned expansion into a number of new wards, it also decided to decentralize to
 a three-tier structure, with ward-level federations, also registered as MACS, taking on the
 accounting functions handled till now by RV. The HDFC loan, at 8 percent, which can be used
 for IG purposes only, reaches the SHGs at 14 percent, with each of RV and the ward federations
 taking a margin of 3 percent. Although documentation is prepared by the federation, the loan
 documents are signed directly with the groups at a gearing of 6 to 8 times of the group's
 surpluses.

 The groups (who on-lend at 24 percent) decide on the allocation of loans among members.
 Only about a fifth of the total membership have taken bank or federation loans, the rest being
 happy to take positions as net savers (the savings requirement is Rs 30 a month). Maximum
 loan size is Rs 50,000. Each accountant employed at the ward level visits up to 35 group
 meetings a month to help with the book-keeping, and returns with an audit report showing
 the group's latest position at the next monthly meeting. Group share capital in the ward level
 MACS is Rs 100 per member, and membership fees Rs 10 per member. The system of banking a
 minimum of 25 percent of savings with the higher tiers continues, with three-quarters going
 to the ward MACS and one-quarter going to RV. Group surpluses above this can be parked with
 RV in savings accounts, fixed deposits or recurring deposits.

 To meet the heavy demand for funds, and to have the flexibility to introduce new products
 such as housing and gold loans, RV is negotiating with several private banks to lend to RV
 directly. As a prelude to housing loans, RV is planning to assist members in registering their
 homes, with the cost being recovered as a loan.

 RV is functioning as a truly representative structure, and at the bottom level the SHGs are
 genuine autonomous SHGs. The loan is a single loan to the group with the SHG deciding who
 the loan should be given to, for what purposes, on what terms and with what schedule of
 recovery (bank loans are typically recovered in less than 36 months and recycled). As in the
 rural areas though, an SHG federation is less likely to reach down to the poorest of the urban
 poor as compared to an MFI that can target the poor actively it wants to (SHGs are in theory
 at least self-selected). Members would seem to enjoy more empowerment than in urban MFIs
 using JLGs, however, through opportunities to participate in the federation structure.

                                      Based on discussion with Mohd Kareem, Roshan Vikas




62
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                             SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                             or Nurturers?




              Box 3.6     Swayanshree at the crossroads: To borrow or to
                              facilitate direct linkages?

Swayanshree, a member owned and controlled but professionally managed urban federation
serving the slums of Cuttack, has grown steadily over the last 12 years to attain its present
size of almost 9000 members distributed over 670 SHGs and 80 JLGs. The primary groups are
clustered into zonal bodies each of which elects a director to the governing body. On joining
the federation an SHG pays Rs 100 per member as share capital, Rs 10 as membership fees and
Rs 20 to go into a fund to provide legal services to members in cases of domestic violence,
dowry deaths and other forms of gender discrimination. SHG members save an average of Rs 40
a month, Rs 30 of which goes to the federation to fund various loan products and Rs 10 of
which remains in the SHG to fund emergency loans. Until 2006 the federation had idle funds,
partly on account of grant funds received to subsidize operational funds from the CASHE
project. But by 2007, with the general process of urban growth, the termination of CASHE, an
increase in the maximum loans granted for various purposes and a decrease in the interest rate
on loans from 24 to 18 percent, loan demand began to exceed the supply. In response to
increasing loan demand from non-members Swayanshree also started organizing 5 member
JLGs, whose members have to save only Rs 10 per month and can start borrowing immediately
(although at a higher interest than older SHG members) without going through the mandatory
6 months savings requirement for SHGs.

Swayanshree is faced with an important strategic decision. Should it meet growing loan
demand by encouraging member SHGs to borrow from the banks, and facilitating the process
by assisting in loan appraisal and monitoring for a fee, or should it start bulk borrowing on its
own account to on-lend to member SHGs and JLGs. The banks have become much more
interested in the last year or so in lending to urban SHGs (although not to JLGs). Thus SBI
recently made loans to four SHGs, and like some other private banks HDFC Bank is willing to
lend to them along the same lines it lends to Roshan Vikas in Hyderabad (see Box 3) HDFC is
willing to share 3 percent with Swayanshree out of the 12 percent loans it proposes to charge
SHGs. However it does want a letter of comfort from Swayanshree backing the loans.

Swayanshree is inclined to prefer the alternative of borrowing itself from the banks and
organizations like Swayanshree MCS, the S 25 company, since it stands to earn more from the
intermediation margin (of about 6 percent) in on-lending to SHGs, and more in the case of
JLGs. It will be interesting to see which way it goes, and why.

                                   Based on discussion with Nayana Mohanty, Swayanshree



Social and economic activities
A seemingly huge variety of social and economic activities and services are being undertaken
by federations in AP, some of them described in Box 3.1, and increasingly in other states, and
it would be useful to categorize them meaningfully and identify issues with respect to each of
them that need to be looked into further. Among economic activities and services being undertaken
by federations (some of them as agents, others on own behalf) are foodgrain procurement,
marketing, input supply, ration shops, other retailing, food security activities such as grain
banks, works under the watershed programme, preparing mid-day meals Second, potentially at
least, federations provide a forum for viably aggregating business development services for
livelihood promotion and microfinance plus activities (such as veterinary care, skills training,

                                                                                                63
marketing support, milk chilling plants, design up-gradation in e.g. crafts activities, etc).

                        Social services include distribution of pensions and payments under the rural employment
                        guarantee scheme, running crèches, supervising the implementation of social programmes,
                        participating in health education, sanitation, drinking water, nutrition and family planning
                        activities and serving as a conduit for development information generally. A fourth set of
                        activities relates to social causes and advocacy relating to domestic violence, alcoholism,
                        child labour, gender sensitization etc. A fifth entails political participation and representation
                        activities, both formally through the gram panchayat and higher level echelon elections, and
                        informally by constituting a pro-poor pressure group for rights and entitlements.

    The processes       The processes and dynamics through which "empowerment" accrues through participation in
     and dynamics
                        these activities is still only hazily understood and needs to be researched further. However
    through which
 "empowerment"          SHG federations constitute an important vehicle for promoting grass-roots democracy and
  accrues through       participation, and for the women themselves a vehicle for experiencing and asserting a much
  participation in
  these activities      stronger collective identity and solidarity. They have led to the emergence a new kind of elite
        is still only   in rural Andhra Pradesh, who have been given an opportunity "to elect, be elected, make
               hazily
                        policies and take decisions" (Misra 2007).40 A less benign political effect of federations is
   understood and
       needs to be      that they have become a potential vote bloc and an attractive target of "capture" by political
         researched     parties through inducements and subsidies, including credit subsidies as in AP's pavla vaddi
further. However
 SHG federations        scheme. It would be interesting to look at the effects these are having, quite apart from their
     constitute an      cost.41 Thus there is anecdotal evidence that hitherto defunct groups of the non-poor are
          important     getting revived in order to avail of the pavla vadi scheme.42
         vehicle for
promoting grass-
 roots democracy        Another issue is the interplay between this third category of functions of federations (economic
                 and    and social activities) and the first two. It has been pointed out that they can pre-empt scarce
    participation,
        and for the
                        managerial talent and energy to the detriment of the first two functions (the provision of
              women     financial and non-financial services). Is this true, or do they more often enhance the skills
     themselves a       and sense of ownership that strengthens those functions too, increasing credit absorption
         vehicle for
experiencing and        capacity and repayment discipline? Also, activities like bulk purchase have in cases contributed
asserting a much        revenue to pay for non-financial support services (an example of which is contained in
            stronger
                        Box 3.4). On the other hand, unless all the groups in a federation participate in an economic
           collective
      identity and      activity equally, losses can put non-participating (or reluctantly participating) groups at risk.
           solidarity   A related issue is whether federations should first focus on achieving institutional and financial
                        viability before branching into economic activities?43


                        Regulation and supervision
                        SHG federations registered as MACS have become important players in the sector in AP, where
                        the two tiers of SHG federations at the mandal and village level, have either already been, or
                        are slated to be, registered as MACS (Chapter 9). In Orissa panchayat level federations are
                        being registered under the The Orissa Self Help Cooperatives Act (the equivalent of the MACS
                        act in the state).44 Tamil Nadu does not have a parallel cooperative law, where panchayat and
                        block level federations are being registered as societies.

                        The MACS Act was a major step towards building more member owned and accountable
                        institutions. However, the new microfinance bill is proposing to supplant the registrars of
                        cooperative societies, whether under the new or old acts, by a new regulator, NABARD, for the

                    64
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                              SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                              or Nurturers?




regulation of thrift services. There is some question whether federations (the two tiers above ... it will
                                                                                                become all the
the SHG level) fall within the purview of the bill. Chapter 9 argues that it would seem more    more important
practicable (and certainly more in accordance of the spirit of cooperation) for the bill to leave
                                                                                                for the states to
                                                                                                energize their
out cooperatives altogether, whether thrift cooperatives at the primary level or their federations.
                                                                                                state registrars,
If the bill is amended accordingly, and even it is not, if it is clarified that federations do not
                                                                                                and ensure they
fall under its purview, it will become all the more important for the states to energize their  carry out their
                                                                                                supervisory
state registrars, and ensure they carry out their supervisory obligations towards cooperative   obligations
thrift societies, whether primary or higher level, much more diligently. At present, according towards
to one observer, the relationship of most federations with the MACS act ends as soon as they cooperative
                                                                                                thrift societies,
have been registered, and they simply exist in the books of the district registrar.45           whether primary
                                                                                                or higher level,
A second alternative is for MACS conducting microfinance to set up a system of self-regulation, much more
                                                                                                diligently
a possible solution being studied by APMAS, with the right to suspend, merge or close non-
compliant federations to be vested in a state-level body. A third solution is much stronger
self-supervision by federations themselves. However this requires a foundation of strong
management and record keeping. Some of the difficulties that stand in the way of relying
entirely on more effective self-supervision especially in large state-wide federations such as
ASP are (i) the high cost of on-site supervision (ii) the lack of stringent standards (iii)
relatively weak staff capacity (iv) the lack of regular rating and (v) good book-keeping. The
difficulties may be a little less intractable for smaller federations, but are still formidable. A
combination of all three alternatives (energizing the registrars, self-regulation by the
microfinance MACS community, and stronger self-supervision) is likely to be required.


Conclusion
In stating a preference for the non-financial over the financial role of federations it is not the
intention of this chapter to be prescriptive. Despite the expansion of the SBLP there may well
be circumstances and areas where financial federations are called for, and not just because the
SHG women themselves "want their own bank" as is often claimed by promoters. Such areas will
generally have a higher demand for credit than the SBLP can satisfy, unlike areas where the
carrying capacity of the community is low, as in tribal belts, dry and rain fed farming areas.
They could also be areas where the demand for credit is high but branch branches are sparsely
distributed, as in the northern hill states.

Also, in using a three fold classification of functions for analytical reasons it is not being
implied that federations must choose between one or the other. Thus non-financial support
services aimed at enhancing SHG quality can, and usually are, combined with activities from
the third category from very inception, such as addressing gender and other social issues,
accessing and seeking convergence for members of ongoing government programmes, and
perhaps providing what are referred to in the jargon as "business development services" or
BDS.

As Girija Srinivasan points out,46 federation building needs to be carefully sequenced, with
each phase responding to a real need, and carefully monitored. The first stage is social
mobilisation of groups, providing non financial services, and institutionalising the fee-for-
services concept. After 3 or 4 years the federation could intensify the provision of BDS in
order to improve credit absorption capacity, as well as introduce specialised bulk loans for
housing, etc. which are not catered to by SBLP. Finally, after 5 or 6 years it could start

                                                                                                  65
Endnotes

 1 The purpose of this chapter is to raise issues, stimulate discussion, and suggest further field work and
     case studies. Given limitations of space the issues discussed are mainly policy issues centering on the
     problem of financial sustainability, since there is some existing literature on institutional sustainability
     issues (governance, representative structure, systems, training, number of levels, the distribution of
     functions between levels etc) as well as what were referred to as "non-negotiables" at two workshops
     held in December 2002 and June 2003, based on an extensive Sa-Dhan study of 27 federations
     Examples of these are (i) promotion of federations should be process rather than blue-print oriented,
     (ii) it should be undertaken only after strong primaries are in place and (iii) should add value without
     competing with the primaries (Sa-Dhan 2004). The study categorized federations into four quadrants
     depending on the whether they were member of promoter controlled, and whether they offered only
     microfinance or microfinance "plus", that is, also social and livelihood interventions. The consensus
     was that federations with an internal locus of control and microfinance plus had the best chance of
     developing into true institutions of the poor. A financial analysis of 7 out of the 27 federations in the
     study by Ramesh Arunachalam found that from the point of view of financial sustainability however,
     federations with high member control but offering microfinance only had the highest sustainability
     (because they relied primarily on member savings, a low cost source capital, had lean organizational
     structures, good asset quality, and minimal idle cash). Unfortunately this was the last nationwide
     empirical study based on extensive field work. More recent documents include Sa-Dhan, 2004, and
     several APMAS's quality assessment reports, the latest being APMAS 2006. One of the best shorter
     studies on federations remains that Ajai Nair 2005 and for a highly readable account of the history
     and rationale of the federation movement in Tamil Nadu, full of practical programmatic detail,
     Gariyali 2007. I am grateful to CS Reddy, LB Prakash, Girija Srinivasan, and the participants at the
     Sa-Dhan consultation in Delhi on May 30, 2007 for useful discussions and comments.

 2 Thus IFAD, UNDP and the World Bank have all promoted federations, as have bilateral donors such as
     DFID though the CASHE project. The World Bank is reported to be preparing further projects. containing
     federations for Bihar, Jharkhand and the Northeast.

 3 Some donors and international NGOs with an interest in federations are NOVIB, HIVOS, Christian Aid,
     and CRS.

 4 More than the programme in other states, Kudumashree emphasizes collective as well as individual
     activities, and convergence with government services.

 5 These areas, ironically, tend to be those where the SBLP is longest established, since the demand for
     credit is probably correlated with the presence of good promoting NGOs, both of them being associated
     with the general state of development, and largely explaining the regional skew of the SBLP.

 6 Some of the the leading NGO federation promoters have been PRADAN, DHAN Foundation, MYRADA,
     CDS, SEWA, PREM, Chaitanya, Gram Vikas, ASA, and YCO.

 7 As a further example, the Tamil Nadu Corporation for the Development of Women (TNCDW) sponsors
     urban federations at the ward level, and AP is piloting them too (for an example see Box 5).


66
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                                       SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                                       or Nurturers?




8 Thus, in AP most of the 29,000 federations (estimated at the time) belong to the World Bank-assisted
   IKP programme's three tier federation structure. Tamil Nadu's 14104 federations consist mostly of the
   12527 panchayat level federations that were formed under the leadership of the TN Corportation for
   the Development of Women in accordance with orders issued by the state government in 2002. Till
   2000 there were only 645 cluster level federations in Tamil Nadu that had been set up under an IFAD
   sponsored project (Gariyali 2007). Similarly, the 5429 federations reported from Orissa in the estimate
   consist of panchayat and block level federations set up under Mission Shakti. Their number has now
   gone up to 6278 (March 2007) or 95 percent of the total number of panchayats and blocks. As in
   Tamil Nadu, most of these have yet to be registered, and are still inactive. The numbers for two other
   states, Kerala and West Bengal have already been mentioned above.

9 There is consensus that the focus should be on the constituent SHGs, whose interests the federations
   should always serve rather than the other way round, although best practice towards the goal of
   federation systems being self-managed is still evolving. The situation is one of a thousand flowers
   blooming, which is what makes the field particularly fascinating, but also challenging to document
   and distill lessons from.

10 Many of these are discussed in the Chapter 2 of last year's report. APMAS 2005 finds a disquieting
   tendency for SHGs to deteriorate with age. Of concern is the apparent tendency of the doctor to
   succumb to the same desease - APMAS 2006 finds that federations too generally weaken with age.

11 Such as data transmission by mobile phones to a centralized MIS being developed by Ekgaon Technologies
   ( Chapter 8), etc.

12 Indeed CMRCs provide representation to federations in their area along with other CBOs, and the
   Computer Munshi system uses cluster level federations to discuss monthly trial balances of member
   groups (see Box 2.1 of last year's report).

13 G stands for governance, R for resources, A for asset quality, D for design of systems, E for efficiency
   and profitability, and S for services to member SHGs and their performance. Only 3.6 percent of the
   federations assessed were providing quality services overall, of which only 17 percent were providing
   quality support services as against 93 percent providing quality financial services (APMAS 2006).

14 We use the term bulk borrowing in this chapter to distinguish outside borrowing from collecting and
   lending out savings within the federation, although the latter term is usually used as a generic term
   that covers both.

15 A fourth source of income is Rs 500 charged numerous visitors from nearby Delhi!

16 Sakhi Suvidha is reported to be the most profitable of the four federations studied in Part I of CGAP
   2007.

17 See Rajagopalan 2004, but she has written many other discussion papers available unfortunately only
   in mimeo form.

18 For semantic purposes, the distinction between an MFI lending through SHGs on one the one hand, and
   a federation accessing bulk funds on the other, would seem to lie in whether the institution has at least
   one layer of autonomous organizations above the SHG. If the institution accesses bulk funds to lend
   directly to SHGs it should be regarded as an MFI, but if it has autonomous secondaries even if they
   provide only support services or undertake social and economic activities, the institution should be

                                                                                                           67
regarded as a federation, even if loan funds flow directly from the apex to the SHGs as is sometimes
     the case. On this definition SNFL would be defined as a federation rather than an MFI.

 19 Some questions of interest are how much grant money is already available under the major programmes
     (state womens' development corporations, DRDAs, Velugu, Swashakti, etc and how well is the money
     being used? NGO-promoted SHGs in AP used to pay for accounting services directly. Now that many of
     them have joined Velugu, and their accountants have become "government" employees, are the latter
     as conscientious?

 20 It has paid off its former bulk lenders such as SIDBI, HUDCO and RMK (Rakesh Kumar Pandey at the Sa-
     Dhan consultation, see endnote 1). It is hopeful that its federations will be able to recover their
     accounting-support, auditing and account-book costs through fees, and is planning to introduce the
     Computer Munshi system, and get into livelihood support once the federations have been strengthened
     further. Many federations have scaled down the financial intermediation role. Other federations that
     are reported to have scaled down financial intermediation are those that have been promoted by SSP
     in Mahrashtra, and by CCD in Tamil Nadu.

 21 PRADAN said that in Jharkhand, its federations manage to recover the entire cost (approximately Rs 75
     per member a year) either through a once-a-year contribution per member or in installments over the
     year. Box 4 contains a slightly higher estimate. Participants pointed out however that grant money
     played a crucial role initially, although it was often inherited from previous programme activities, such
     as grants for revolving funds, watershed development and health.

 22 We use the term bulk funding to distinguish it from the broader term financial intermediation because the
     latter includes borrowing from members. Bulk funding is of course indirectly intermediating the savings of
     savers in the formal sector. Of the 129 MFIs covered by Sa-Dhan's Quick Report, 21 were MACS with 1.6
     percent of the total number of borrowers, and 4 of them cooperatives not registered as MACS (such as Sewa
     Bank), with 3.9 percent. In addition, many federations are registered as societies rather than cooperatives,
     such as those in Tamil Nadu. The Quick Report contains data on borrowings for each MFI.

 23 Commercial, as opposed to donor funding of on-lending funds such as Velugu's Community Investment
     Fund, or CASHE's revolving fund, which has now been inherited by ACCESS to support their incubation
     of new MFIs.

 24 However there is no estimate of total lending to federations.

 25 In the case of direct linkages, all the SHG members had to travel to the Kakatiya Grameen Bank to
     collect their loans, costing them bus fares as well as lost wages. The Grameen Bank also conducted bulk
     lending to the groups, and the groups received these loans at 18 percent. The case does not include
     information on margins retained by the MACS and PSS, or say whether any deposits had to be made
     by the SHGs in the MACS and by the MACS in PSS to fund the deposit of 15 percent of the loan amount
     PSS had to make as an FLDG deposit with ICICI earning 5.5 percent interest.

 26 The pros and cons of this arrangement - better control over possible malfeasance at the MACS level but
     less autonomy for the MAC - also need to be analyzed.

 27 A topic that generates much heat in sector conclaves is the need to manage the relationship between
     professionals and the representative governance structure sensitively. The following comment received
     on this chapter is frequently heard. "Another very frustrating observation I have made during my field


68
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                                        SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                                        or Nurturers?




   visits and interactions with promoting agencies' staff and federation leaders is that most of the time
   professionals who manage the entire show on behalf of federations are too intimidating, over-powering,
   and lack sensitivity and patience. They are unable to understand the limitations and unique strengths
   of these women. As a result, the vibrant leaders of federations are reduced to good accountants and
   obedient workers of promoting agencies. Given a choice, federation leaders would not like to go
   through that route …in most cases it is the promoting agencies' agenda that push federations into a
   provider role. Given a choice, women would like to keep out of this game. Federations might have
   proved their utility for the promoting agency, but we need to check whether the same applies when it
   comes to SHGs." The view taken here is that if the relationship is successfully managed (and it can be)
   a community based institution can be community or member owned without necessarily having to be
   entirely community managed. The best known example is AMUL, and among federations, SIFFS, a
   federation of fishermen's cooperatives, and SNFL, both in Tamil Nadu.

28 This is something of a first. An equity investment is ruled out however by the cooperative principle of
   one man one vote.

29 Currently, Syndicate Bank, ICICI,Canara Bank and the State Bank of Hyderabad.

30 Apart from NGO-promoted federations and ASP, the third federation model in AP is the ubiquitous IKP,
   which does not borrow from the banks but does on-lend Community Investment Funds (CIF) it has
   received from the World Bank. These funds are on-lent down the three tier structure with each tier
   earning a margin. Finally there is the well-known fourth model in AP of the two tier federations of
   thrift cooperatives, also in Warangal district, promoted by CDF (Chapter 9). This however is a special
   case since the primaries here are not SHGs but much larger thrift cooperatives or in effect credit
   unions, with credit activities funded almost entirely by savings and with little outside borrowing as a
   matter of philosophy.

31 ASP's operational sustainability is only 25 percent, partly because of the relatively large staff required
   to support state wide operations, and also because in keeping with its respect for the autonomy of
   each level, ASP's relationship with member MACS is loosely defined. Its strategic plan lays down that
   "the standardization of systems and procedures that are required for taking advantages of economies
   of scale will be realized through processes of consensus building" (Misra 2007).

32 SNFL is in a sense a unique case since it is an NBFC at the apex level which on-lends to federations
   registered as mutual benefit trusts at the secondary level. Although the CEO and two board members of
   each MBT are appointed by the apex, they otherwise enjoy substantial autonomy, and the apex itself is
   owned by the MBTs. Thus SNFL is professionally managed but community owned. It is the largest
   federation in India, with loans outstanding of Rs 64 crores in March 2007 and an outreach of 126,000
   SHG members organized in 25140 SHGs belonging to 108 MBTs in six states.

33 KOPSA, in three districts of Tamil Nadu, borrows from SBI at 8 percent and on-lends at 12 percent,
   directly to SHG groups. It also has a loan from ING Vysya Bank.

34 For instance in the new World Bank IKP-type project in Bihar.

35 Presumably this includes the historical costs that were incurred on promoting the individual SHGs.
   Ultimately it is the total promotional cost at both levels that is relevant. Federations, once formed,
   offer the prospect of bringing down the average cost per SHG formed as they get into the business of
   promoting new SHGs themselves.

                                                                                                            69
36 It is usually provided by the federation as an agent for an insurance company, but sometimes also
     through the in-house model, as with life and health insurance in DHAN, although DHAN kalanjiams are
     reported to be switching to the former model, at least for life insurance (Chapter 5A of last year's
     report).

 37 The commission payment of 20 percent of the premium payable to the agent is an incentive to the
     banks.

 38 However, it is only the apex that balances the surpluses of its MACS, since SHG prefer the safety of
     depositing their funds in the banks or leaving them idle.

 39 The distinction between the liquidity balancing and savings services role can be thought of as the
     former applying only to group as opposed to individual savings, and being shorter term.

 40 She points out also that new elites can fall into old habits, leading to issues of elite domination at the
     second tier, dominating the agenda at general assemblies, "deciding which entitlements and schemes
     to opt for, which members to pull up for non repayment and which loans to sanction without any form
     of active engagement even with the SHG leaders".

 41 Assuming an interest subsidy of 9 percent (the bank rate minus the pavla vadi rate of 3 percent) on
     about Rs 3500 crores of loans outstanding in AP in March 2007 (or 60 percent of cumulative
     disbursements of Rs 5889 crores using the assumptions discussed in Chapter 2), the bill to the state
     government could come to Rs 300 crores at current levels of lending.

 42 At the Microfinance India conference in October 2006, a Rajya Sabha member from Orissa credited the
     SHG programme for getting his party re-elected in the last elections.

 43 Economic, because social activities do not preempt scarce skills to the same extent.

 44 The Orissa act allows membership to the primaries or SHGs unlike the AP MACS Act which only allows
     membership to individuals or cooperatives, so that SHGs have to be represented by representatives
     acting formally in an individual capacity. This is the reason DHAN Foundation prefers to register
     federations as societies or trusts.

 45 As Rama Reddy points out "Neither the SHG Federation, nor the promoting GO, nor the promoting NGO,
     nor the registering DCO is interested in the functioning of the village organisation as a Macs cooperative.
     They do not need any supervision and/or regulation since they themselves are part and parcel of the
     governmental organisations or of the non-governmental organisations. On the one hand, as a policy,
     the State Government is interested in getting village organisations registered as macs cooperatives and
     on the other hand, again as a matter of policy, the same government puts a ban on the registration
     of citizen-promoted genuine thrift cooperatives and dairy cooperatives under the Macs Act" (Personal
     communication).

 46 This paragraph is based on comments received from Girija Srinivasan.




70
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                            SHG Federations: Financiers
                                                                                            or Nurturers?




References


APMAS, 2006, "Status of SHG Federations in Andhra Pradesh: Quality Assessment:2nd Report",
Hyderabad

Christen, Bob, and Guatam Ivatury, 2005, "A Systemic View of the SHG Bank-Linkage System:
Four Sustainable Models" paper presented at World Bank conference in New Delhi, December

CGAP, 2007, Sustainability of Self-Help Groups in India: Two Analyses" Occasional Paper, World
Bank, DC

Dhan Foundation, 2004, "Catalysing Linkages: SHGs and Banks: the KDFS Experience 2001-
2004".

DHAN Foundation, 2005, "Impacting Urban Poverty Through Microfinance: The SPMS
Experience", DHAN Foundation, Madurai.

EDA Rural Systems, 2005, "The Maturing of Indian Microfinance", study done for SIDBI, Gurgaon

Fernandez, Aloysius, 207, "A Microfinance Institution with a Difference", Economic and Political
Weekly, March 31, Mumbai

Gariyali, CK, 2007, "Climbing Higher: Federations of Women Self-Help Groups at the Panchayat
Level", Vetri Publications, New Delhi

Harper, Malcolm and Marie Kirsten 2006 "ICICI Bank and microfinance linkages in India", Small
Enterprise Development, Volume 17, Number 1, March.

Misra, Rewa, 2007, "Case of Mutually Aided Cooperative Societies, India: SHG federations as a
model for remote outreach of financial services", study commissioned by Ford Foundation,
Coady International Institute, Antigonish, NS

Nair, Ajay, 2005, "Sustainability of Microfinance Self-Help Groups in India: Would Federating
Help", Policy Working Research Paper 3516, South Asia Region, Finance and Private Sector
Development Unit, World Bank, D.C.

Rajagopalan, Shashi, 2004, "Do federations have a role in financial intermediation?", paper
written for "Microfinance India 2008" conference, 24-26 February, New Delhi

Ramesh, Jairam, 2007, "The SHG Revolution: What Next?, Silver Jubilee Lecture at the Society
for the Promotion of Wastelands Development, New Delhi, May 5,

Reddy, CS, N Tirupathaiah, and S Ramalakshmi, 2007, "Emerging SHG Federations and
Challenges", International Conference on Andhra Pradesh Experience with Member-Based
Organizations of the Poor, Mimeo, CESS, Hyderabad, June 5-6.

Sa-Dhan, 2004, "SHG Federations in India: Emerging Structures and Practices"

Srinivasan, R, 2005, "Canara Bank, Allanganallur branch, Madurai district, Tamil Nadu, India"
in Harper and Arora, eds. "Small Customers, Big Markets:Commercial Banks in Microfinance",
Practical Action Group, London.

Vasimalai, MP, and K Narender, 2007, "Microfinance for Poverty Reduction: the Kalanjiam
Way", Economic and Political Weekly, March 31, 2007.

                                                                                               71
72
CHAPTER 4
                                                                                              MFI Performance:
                                                                                              Efficiency with Growth




                                        CHAPTER 4


              MFI Performance:
           Efficiency with Growth
                                                                      Sanjay Sinha1
Overview
The past two years have seen a series of critical developments in the Indian MFI sector. These       The past two
are both positive and negative. On the positive side, MFIs have started to leverage their new        years have seen
                                                                                                     a series of
found management expertise to achieve scale and to spread their operations well beyond their         critical
traditional operational areas. Thus, rating data from a large sample of the leading MFIs shows       developments in
                                                                                                     the Indian MFI
that these have recorded high growth rates of the order of 80% per annum in terms of                 sector. These
numbers of borrowers and around 40% per annum in terms of portfolio reaching from 300,000            are both
to one million clients each. Also positive is that a significant part of that expansion has been     positive and
                                                                                                     negative. On
either to less developed areas of the country - Orissa, Jharkhand, Rajasthan, Madhya Pradesh,        the positive
Tripura, Assam - or to areas such as Maharashtra that also have substantial numbers of low           side, MFIs have
                                                                                                     started to
income families in some regions even if their overall development indicators are not as low as
                                                                                                     leverage their
those for the other states.                                                                          new found
                                                                                                     management
On the negative side, MFIs have been under attack from politicians and bureaucrats in some           expertise to
                                                                                                     achieve scale
of their traditional operational areas in Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka (with questions even          and to spread
being asked in Orissa). Their loan recovery practices have been questioned and their interest        their operations
                                                                                                     well beyond
rates described as exorbitant. The related publicity has vitiated the credit culture in the
                                                                                                     their traditional
traditional microfinance states forcing a lowering of interest rates and increasing the necessary    operational
level of loan loss reserves and provisioning. Operationally, the increase in costs has been          areas
compounded by the spread of the operations of individual MFIs simultaneously (and
inorganically) to a number of non-traditional states. This has put pressure on operating
efficiency and resulted in slowing the trend to lowering unit costs.

The growth of the microfinance sector has been fuelled by continuing interest from banks in
increasing their exposure to microfinance resulting in a highly leveraged industry with capital
adequacy ratios down below 10% and debt-to-equity ratios of the order of 11:1. Given the
pressure on margins (which has already reduced the collective return on assets of the sector to
negligible, if still positive, levels) it is unclear for how long such high leverage ratios can be
sustained.

The increased coverage of clients made possible by the high growth rates of Indian MFIs is
laudable. Even as it increases outreach, the industry continues to be amongst the most

                                                                                                 73
efficient in the world. But, high growth brings with it possible dangers of mission drift as
                    many MFIs emphasise commercial behaviour and may not strategically balance this with their
                    original social mission, or with social values expected in microfinance. As the discussion in
                    this chapter and that on social rating shows, it is apparent that while MFIs have learnt much
                    in terms of operational efficiency a substantial effort is required in the areas of clarifying
                    social objectives, poverty targeting, product development and client orientation. The challenge
                    for MFIs over the next few years is to achieve growth with equity as well as efficiency.

                    This chapter presents a summary analysis of the information obtained by M-CRIL during its
                    ratings of 58 Indian MFIs over the 18 month period January 2006 to June 2007. The overview
                    of the performance of Indian MFIs emerging from this analysis is placed in perspective by a
                    comparison with the benchmarks emerging from the database of the MIX's latest set of 37
                    reporting MFIs (for March 2007). The India Microfinance Review, published separately by
                    M-CRIL and the MIX, presents the detailed analysis.


                    1 Characteristics of MFIs covered by this analysis
   By and large,    Regionally, this analysis provides a comprehensive picture of microfinance in India. The
however, Indian
MFIs have been      samples used contain a large number of MFIs from South India.
     innovating,
 experimenting      This is de facto recognition of the fact that South India MFIs provide a substantial portion of
        with and    client coverage in Indian microfinance. Table 4.1 presents a broad regional analysis of the
 growing out of
              the   samples.
   conventional
   mould of SHG
   and Grameen              Table 4.1 Regional distribution of Indian MFIs rated by M-CRIL
 operations, to
    cater to the    Regions                  M-CRIL MFIs                    Update                MIX dataset
  needs of their                                                            sample
  markets more                    Rated      Sample     % of sample                      2005-06         2006-07
      effectively
                    South           27          24            24             18 (62%)        28        24 (64.9%)
                    East & NE       24          20            20              8 (28%)        8         10 (27.0%)
                    West            10          6              6               1 (3%)        0           1 (2.7%)
                    North           11          8              8               2 (7%)        2           2 (5.4%)
                    India           72          58            58            29 (100%)        38        37 (100.0%)


                     There are many SHG-based microfinance programmes but, in recent years, most of the new
                     MFIs have been established using the Grameen model. There has been a tendency for MFIs
                     increasingly to adopt the Grameen model since this is seen by many as a means of accelerating
                     their growth and progress towards sustainability. By and large, however, Indian MFIs have
                     been innovating, experimenting with and growing out of the conventional mould of SHG and
                     Grameen operations, to cater to the needs of their markets more effectively. The distribution
                     of sample Indian MFIs based on microfinance models is shown in Table 4.2. This distribution
                     is a broad reflection of the pattern of microfinance undertaken through microfinance
                     institutions (as opposed to the SHG-bank linkage programme) in India.




                74
CHAPTER 4
                                                                                              MFI Performance:
                                                                                              Efficiency with Growth




     Table 4.2 Distribution of sample Indian MFIs by microfinance model
Models                   M-CRIL Sample                                      MIX dataset
                 2005          2007         Top 10       Updates       2005-06       2006-07

G                 19              23            7           16            19            21
IB                15               8            1            6            14            15
SHG               50              27            2           10            25            21
Total MFIs        84              58          10            32            38            37


Though there is a trend, India-wide, towards for-profit and formal registration of MFIs as
finance companies, not-for-profit institutions continue to dominate by numbers of
organisations in the provision of microfinance services. Table 4.3 shows the distribution of
sample MFIs across legal forms. The 15 for-profit companies in the M-CRIL sample of 58
includes 5 institutions that were still registered as not-for-profit institutions (when rated)
but are either in the process of transforming or have already transformed to companies (at the
time of writing).

Of the 10 best institutions selected for the purpose of comparison with the overall sample,         There are
                                                                                                    relatively few
just two in this group have been replaced since the last review. However, while earlier six of
                                                                                                    MFIs in the
the 10 were non-bank finance companies (NBFCs), all but one of the Top 10 MFIs in India is          West. Grameen
now legally registered as such.                                                                     MFIs with over
                                                                                                    130,000 clients
                                                                                                    each are the
                                                                                                    largest in the
             Table 4.3 Distribution of sample MFIs by legal form                                    country and
Form of registration                                     M-CRIL         Top 10      MIX, 2006       together serve
                                                                                                    over 50% of
Not-for-profit                                                                                      the total
                                                                                                    number of
                                   societies & trusts       34             1            22          clients covered
                                       Cooperatives          4                            1
                             Section 25 companies            5                            2
Non-bank finance companies/bank                             15             9            12
Total MFIs                                                  58            10            37



2 Client outreach & services
The microfinance outreach of sample MFIs amounts to some 5.6 million clients (M-CRIL,
September 2006) to 6.6 million clients (for the MIX dataset, March 2007). Around three-
quarters of these are based in South India and another 20% in the East. Most of the remainder
are in North India. There are relatively few MFIs in the West. Grameen MFIs with over 130,000
clients each are the largest in the country and together serve over 50% of the total number of
clients covered. Though extensive government support for SHG programmes has resulted in
the establishment of a large number of MFIs using the SHG methodology, these are around
half the size of Grameen MFIs and, as a result, provide outreach to only about one-third of the
total number of clients covered (Figure 4.1). From the perspective of the legal framework, the
proposed new microfinance law does not cover nearly 80% of these clients since 73% are

                                                                                                 75
served by NBFCs (or MFIs on the verge of transformation to NBFCs) and another 6% by Section
 25 (not-for-proft) companies. Such institutions fall outside the ambit of the proposed law.

                        Figure 4.1 Membership of sample MFIs

                          (a)…by microfinance methodology




                                    (b) …by legal form




 Indian MFIs have minuscule outstandings Rs3,400 ($82) compared to the international average
 Rs19,200 ($468) and has not grown over the past couple of years. The Grameen clients have
 the smallest loan balances Rs2,700 ($65). This has happened despite a high growth rate of
 MFI portfolios (40%) because client outreach has expanded even faster (84%). Large numbers
 of new MFI clients inevitably means small loan sizes.

 At an average loan balance that is just 9.9% of GNI per capita, depth of outreach is apparently
 substantial. However, field experience shows that significant numbers of not-so-poor women
 join microfinance groups - often for social reasons - so the loan balance-GNI ratio is not a
 good indicator of poverty outreach (at least for India).

 A highly restrictive legal framework for deposit taking has severely constrained the offering of
 thrift services so client savings form just 8.1% of outstanding loan balances. As Figure 4.2
 indicates, all the methodologies have low average savings per member except for the individual
 banking model. Each of the bars reflects the nature of the methodologies and the legal
 framework in which the organisations operate.

76
CHAPTER 4
                                                                                              MFI Performance:
                                                                                              Efficiency with Growth




          Figure 4.2 Average savings per member by model, Rupees




SHG programmes, usually have voluntary deposit schemes in which the members themselves               Staff
determine the amount of the recurring savings deposit. Since disposition of this amount is           productivity in
                                                                                                     India is now
determined by the group rather than by the individual saver, this often results in minimalist        higher than in
norms and leads to deposits that are far lower than the members' savings potential. Deposits         any other major
                                                                                                     region offering
form just 4.0% of the average SHG MFIs' portfolio, though (as indicated earlier) this excludes       microfinance.
the far larger amounts revolved internally by SHG members.2                                          Some 326 staff
                                                                                                     members per
                                                                                                     MFI serve over
3 Operating efficiency & portfolio quality                                                           230 borrowers
                                                                                                     each while the
Staff productivity in India is now higher than in any other major region offering microfinance.      leading MFIs
                                                                                                     average 275
Some 326 staff members per MFI serve over 230 borrowers each while the leading MFIs average          borrowers per
275 borrowers per member of staff. This results in some of the lowest servicing costs for MFIs       member of
                                                                                                     staff. This
anywhere in the world. Both Grameen and SHG MFIs record average servicing costs of the
                                                                                                     results in some
order of Rs400 ($10) per borrower, lower than the MIX median even for Bangladesh. As MFIs            of the lowest
have grown and staff productivity has increased over the years, servicing costs have come            servicing costs
                                                                                                     for MFIs
down even in nominal terms. With an inflation rate averaging 5% per annum in the mid-                anywhere in the
2000s, this has resulted in a decline of around 9% per annum in the cost of servicing borrowers.     world

Indian MFIs are now amongst the most efficient internationally. At 15.9% the average operating
expense ratio (Table 4.4) has not changed much since the 2005 Review as growth focussed
MFIs have accepted higher travel and other costs, while productivity gains have also been
neutralised by lower loan balances, hence smaller portfolios serviced per member of staff, in
real terms. OERs reported by Indian MFIs are, nevertheless, lower than those of MFIs in Bangladesh
and significantly lower than the medians for Asian and other MFIs worldwide.




                                                                                                 77
Table 4.4 Operating expense ratios of Indian MFIs
                     Model              Weighted Typical MFI     Operating Expense Ratio                     Total no.
                                       average (%)  (%)      <10% 10-15% 15-25%          >25%                 of MFIs

                     G                      16.7            16.4          4             8     6       3         21
                     IB                     20.5            24.5          2             1     4       1          8
                     SHG                    11.2            23.2          7             4     7       7         25
                     M-CRIL, 2007           15.9            20.7          13            13   17      11         54
                                2005        15.6            18.5          25            19   23      16         83
                                2003        20.5            36.5                        23   21      46         90
                     Top 10                 13.1            11.6          4             4     2       0         10
                     MIX*                   India       Bangladesh Nepal South Asia MIX global MIX Asia
                                            10.4            14.2        11.2        14.3     20.1   17.2
                    * Operating expense as a proportion of Gross Loan Portfolio (GLP)


  The effective      Analysis of operating expense ratios by size of MFI, its age, microfinance methodology and
  interest rate
                     loan size shows that it is the last factor that is the major determinant of operating efficiency.
    paid by the
average Indian       As the size of loans disbursed increases from Rs3,000 ($75) to Rs10,000 ($250), the operating
   microfinance      expense ratio declines from 25% down to an average of around 12% (Figure 4.3)
 borrower is no
more than 25%
            - not
   significantly                                    Figure 4.3 OER by loan size (Rs)
 different from
      the ~24%
usually charged
        even by
     commercial
       banks on
       consumer
         finance




                     The effective interest rate paid by the average Indian microfinance borrower is no more than
                     25% - not significantly different from the ~24% usually charged even by commercial banks on
                     consumer finance. By and large, new institutions have low yields and high OERs but, as
                     expansion takes place, and economies of scale set in, yields improve and OERs decline to
                     acceptable levels. There are significant economies of scale up to a portfolio size of Rs2.5
                     crores ($600,000) - Figure 4.4.




                78
CHAPTER 4
                                                                                           MFI Performance:
                                                                                           Efficiency with Growth




          Figure 4.4 Relationship of portfolio size with efficiency




Official action against MFIs in Andhra Pradesh and elsewhere has resulted in a significant Official action
deterioration in the credit culture, having an adverse effect on microfinance operations. against MFIs in
                                                                                                  Andhra Pradesh
Portfolio quality has deteriorated since the 2005 Review with the weighted average PAR60          and elsewhere
has declined from 4.7% in 2005 to 6.0% now. Particularly affected are the leading MFIs            has resulted in
                                                                                                  a significant
whose PAR has declined from 1.4% for the 2005 sample to 4.6% now. This is also much higher        deterioration in
than the MIX benchmarks for Asia. The implications of this for the long term performance of       the credit
the microfinance sector are yet to emerge.                                                        culture, having
                                                                                                  an adverse
                                                                                                  effect on
4 Portfolio financing                                                                             microfinance
                                                                                                  operations.
                                                                                                  Portfolio quality
The structural shift indicated by an increase in debt financing among Indian MFIs has continued   has
while net worth as a proportion of the total has been reduced as current surpluses and a very     deteriorated
                                                                                                  since the 2005
limited flow of grants have failed to keep pace with growth. Borrowings have reached three-
                                                                                                  Review with the
quarters of total liabilities on MFI balance sheets as funds have been readily available from     weighted
both private and public commercial banks (Figure 4.5). Even small institutions with relatively    average PAR60
                                                                                                  has declined
low exposure to financial markets have succeeded in sourcing half of their liabilities through    from 4.7% in
bank borrowings, bringing over 60% of MFIs under the 15% suggested capital adequacy ratio.        2005 to 6.0%
                                                                                                  now
          Figure 4.5 Sources of funds for microfinance operations




                                                                                              79
Until now, with substantial historical grant funding and more recent operating surpluses
                    accompanied by relatively small portfolios, the Indian microfinance sector has been well provided
                    for in terms of owned funds. Now, the growth aspirations of MFI managements, competition
                    and the relative paucity of grant funds, on the one hand, and the availability of liberal
                    commercial debt funds, on the other, have taken their toll. The aggregate figures suggest
                    that capital adequacy is now an issue as even the Top10 MFIs fail to register the 15% norm
                    suggested above, though it is not alarming yet (Table 4.5).

 When managed       The trend towards commercialization becomes even stronger in the context of off-balance
loans are added
                    sheet financing under the partnership model, which accounts for an additional 44% of the
      back to the
 balance sheets     overall portfolio in the sector. When managed loans are added back to the balance sheets of a
   of a subset of   subset of leading Indian MFIs, the leverage ratio jumps from 10.7 to 11.9, far exceeding the
  leading Indian
        MFIs, the   regional median of 5:1. While a limited amount of debt continues to be available at concessional
  leverage ratio    rates, much of it is contracted at commercial rates in the range of 10-14% per annum. With
      jumps from    such financing accounting for four-fifths of the portfolio of leading MFIs, the commercialization
  10.7 to 11.9,
   far exceeding    of the Indian sector far exceeds that of other important markets in the region, such as
     the regional   Bangladesh, where institutions source less than one-tenth of their portfolios from commercial
  median of 5:1
                    funds.

                                     Table 4.5 Capital adequacy ratios of Indian MFIs
                               Models                      Weighted CAR (%)                    Typical MFI (%)
                     Grameen                                       11.3                              13.6
                     IB                                            22.3                              15.6
                     SHG                                             8.4                             12.5
                                                                   12.7                              13.4
                     Top 10                                        11.1                                9.4
                     Debt-equity ratios
                     M-CRIL sample                                  7.2                              14.2
                     Top10                                          8.6                              10.5
                     MIX India median                                                                11.9

                    Indeed, Indian MFIs are increasingly turning to the banking sector as their access to grants
                    and customer deposits continues to diminish. The share of grants dropped from one third of
                    the balance sheet in 2003 to just 3% in 2006, barely covering cumulative losses among
                    smaller institutions. With the ability to raise equity capital limited to just a few legal entities,
                    reliance on net worth fell to 10%, less than one-third of that in 2003. Bank borrowings have
                    also had to fill in for customer deposits, which amounted to one-fourth of MFI resources in
                    2003 and are now under one-tenth of the balance sheet. Concerns over the legality of savings
                    mobilization combined with increasing transformation to NBFCs have phased savings out of
                    MFI balance sheets and mostly confined these to community-based institutions such as SHGs
                    and cooperatives.

                    Indian financing patterns, however, could look quite different in the next few years. Under
                    proposed legislation, societies, trusts and cooperatives will be able to offer thrift services.
                    While companies are excluded from this proposed regulatory regime, a number of these have

                80
CHAPTER 4
                                                                                              MFI Performance:
                                                                                              Efficiency with Growth




recently announced large investments by private equity funds. With the Top10 accounting
for two-thirds of the financing, debt may be ceding some of its share to equity capital.


5 Financial performance
The financial viability of microfinance institutions in India is under threat, despite improvements
in the yield gap. The 2.1% weighted return on assets of the 2005 sample has been reduced to
zero while typical MFI returns are -9.8%, well behind Bangladeshi institutions reporting to
the MIX, which lead the region in profitability. Low portfolio yields, combined with poor
portfolio quality and rising financial costs have reduced Indian MFI surpluses though
improvements in collection measures have boosted portfolio yields to 93% of the expected              The financial
figure, up from 85% in 2005 (Table 4.6). Yields, however, remain low, with 43% of Indian              viability of
                                                                                                      microfinance
MFIs earning less than 24% on their portfolios. In comparison with 36-50% real costs of bank          institutions in
loans and moneylender interest rates ranging from 36% to 120%, MFI average yields represent           India is under
                                                                                                      threat, despite
a substantial benefit for low income clients.
                                                                                                      improvements
                                                                                                      in the yield
Nonetheless, these are not sufficient to cover rising costs brought on by ambitious growth            gap. The 2.1%
plans, deteriorating portfolio quality and hardening of domestic interest rates on borrowings.        weighted return
                                                                                                      on assets of the
Benchmarks for profitable Indian MFIs indicate that they charge more sustainable rates than           2005 sample
their unprofitable peers and earn 24.8% on their portfolios as compared to 19.5%, but they            has been
also maintain tighter cost control. While both groups face similar financial costs, sustainable       reduced to zero
                                                                                                      while typical
institutions benefit from lower provisioning expenses because of their superior portfolio             MFI returns are
quality. Moreover, they benefit from economies of scale as the typical sustainable MFI manages        -9.8%, well
                                                                                                      behind
a much larger portfolio than an unsustainable institution. Indeed, the sample of 58 institutions      Bangladeshi
shows a concentration of portfolio and borrowers among institutions that are at or near               institutions
sustainability. As Table 4.7 shows, nearly 50% of borrowers are served by MFIs with operational       reporting to the
                                                                                                      MIX, which lead
self-sufficiency in excess of 90% . Since outreach has grown dramatically, the absolute               the region in
numbers of clients served by sustainable institutions has actually increased by 35% over the          profitability
past two years.

                      Table 4.6 Portfolio yield relative to APR
       Models                  Yield (%)                 APR (%)               Yield/APR (%)
Grameen                           27.6                     27.6                     100.2
Indl Banking                      26.1                     32.3                      80.7
SHG                               13.8                     16.9                      81.5
M-CRIL India                      24.2                     26.1                      92.8
Top 10                            23.5                     24.8                      95.0
M-CRIL 2005                       25.0                     29.3                      85.2
Top10, 2005                       23.9                     27.8                      86.0




                                                                                                  81
Table 4.7 Outreach of efficient microfinance institutions
             OSS (%)                            Number                       Proportion (%)
              >100                              1,696,447                          39.5
             90-100                              440,107                           10.3
              80-90                              824,990                           19.2
               <80                              1,330,527                          31.0
               Total                            4,292,071                           100


 Despite the sobering events of the past two years, the overall impression of an efficient MFI
 sector that is growing strongly remains unchanged. As the discussion in this chapter and
 that on social rating shows, it is apparent that while MFIs have learnt much in terms of
 operational efficiency a substantial effort is required in the areas of clarifying social objectives,
 poverty targeting, product development and client orientation. The challenge for MFIs over
 the next few years is to achieve growth with equity as well as efficiency.




 Endnotes

 1 Sanjay Sinha is Managing Director of M-CRIL

 2 Issues of deposit orientation of MFI models and their relationship with regulation and resource
     mobilisation are discussed in Section 4.




82
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                             Urban Microfinance




                                        CHAPTER 5


                 Urban Microfinance

The new urban microfinance                          1




There has been an upsurge of interest in urban microfinance with several recent start-ups in
the metros, promoted by professionals who have a proven track record of successful careers in
banking and other fields.2 Other start-ups are being promoted by microfinance professionals
who already have some experience in rural microfinance but feel challenged by the relatively
unfamiliar territory of large-scale urban microfinance.3 Both sets of entrants are part of what
have been referred to as a "generational change"4 in Indian microfinance.

A third set of entrants are many of the well-established, primarily rural MFIs expanding            There has been
                                                                                                    an upsurge of
increasingly into small towns and peri-urban areas as they grow.5 Fourth, an increasing number
                                                                                                    interest in
of NBFCs and banks already operating in the urban areas are experimenting with "downscaling"        urban
through smaller, individual, loan products.6 A possible fifth, although still very small category   microfinance
                                                                                                    with several
consists of the new urban MFIs being incubated by ACCESS Development Services in Kolkata.7          recent start-ups
Finally there is renewed interest in the pioneers of urban microfinance such as SEWA, WWF, and      in the metros,
                                                                                                    promoted by
SPMS, whose experience over the years is being reexamined by the new comers for the valuable
                                                                                                    professionals
lessons they offer.                                                                                 who have a
                                                                                                    proven track
Although the "new generation" urban MFIs exhibit considerable diversity, they are distinguished     record of
                                                                                                    successful
by the following broad features. First, in contrast to the pioneers they have much greater          careers in
ambitions in respect of scale. Several of them intend to grow rapidly to become national            banking and
institutions with branches in several metros and large cities as well as in the surrounding rural   other fields

hinterland.8 In keeping with this ambition, they intend to achieve sustainability as soon as
possible so as to be able to attract the huge volume of on-lending funds required, as well as
the investments with which to support them. They have been very successful in attracting
funds so far because of the backgrounds of their promoters.

They intend to cater primarily to the vast majority of urban residents who are still unserved by
the banks and depend largely on the informal sector for their financial needs. Reaching the
poorest of the poor is not a primary goal, at least initially. Phrases like sub-prime borrowers,
the missing middle, lower income groups are frequently used in descriptions of their target
clientele. Some of them are experimenting with new lending models more suited to urban
microfinance, and they intend to induct the latest offerings of technology, wherever cost
effective, to enhance scale and efficiency. They are cognizant of the need to offer a full set of
financial services including savings, insurance and remittances, over and above a range of

                                                                                                83
credit products to suit the greater heterogeneity of urban financial markets. However they
                   intend to meet non-financial needs such as health and vocational training through partnerships
                   with NGOs and other civil society organizations and socially minded corporations.

                   Some of them are treating their first couple of years as pilot projects, which they are using to
                   stabilize delivery technology and product design, and learn the lessons of large-scale urban
                   microfinance first hand. In this they are being assisted by at least two service providers who
                   also in a sense belong to this new generation, the Michael and Susan Dell Foundation, which
                   sees its mission in India to catalyze urban MFIs by providing grant support for capacity
                   building, and risk capital, and by ACCION, an international NGO with considerable experience
                   world wide in the introduction of individual lending and downscaling.

                   The third set of entrants, the Rural Converts, are mostly moving into urban microfinance from
                   the contiguous rural areas and are operating mostly in the smaller towns and peri-urban
                   areas.9 Initial and average loan size is higher than in their rural operations, and this is where
                   they are also introducing larger, individual loans to microentrepreneurs, both of which are
                   advantageous from the point of view of profitability.

                   The fourth set, the increasing number of existing NBFCs and banks getting interested in
                   downscaling, are an extremely heterogeneous bunch. Among the former are Satin Creditcare in
                   West Delhi which is best known for its system of doorstep daily collections, even though
                   average loans size is currently as high as Rs 27,000.

 Banks in India    Banks in India have been excluded from the small loans market partly by regulatory fiat. They
      have been    are not allowed to make loans of less than Rs 200,000 at a rate any higher than their PLR
  excluded from
the small loans    (their lending rate to prime customers) if they want the loans to count towards their priority
  market partly    sector targets. Despite this disincentive, Yes Bank has decided to get into the microfinance
   by regulatory
                   market by introducing a personal loan product, ranging in size from Rs 8000 to Rs 25,000
  fiat. They are
 not allowed to    repayable in 3 to 6 months, with technical assistance from ACCION. The area surrounding the
  make loans of    bank's headquarters in Worli has been divided into 8 zones not more than 45 minutes' walking
    less than Rs
  200,000 at a     distance away. Each has been placed under a Relationship Manager who identifies borrowers
rate any higher    and remains responsible for them, but with all cash transactions being handled out of an
 than their PLR
                   office at bank headquarters itself.10
 (their lending
  rate to prime
  customers) if    Indian Bank's Microsate branch in Chennai is unusual in being a bank branch in an urban area
 they want the     which only makes loans to SHGs.11 It is in effect doing SHG-bank linkage in an urban area.
 loans to count
  towards their    With the assistance of about 51 registered NGOs it is currently lending to about 4000 active
 priority sector   groups out of an estimated 14,000 spread over about 140 slums in Chennai. Average group
         targets   size is 17, and the main member activities are retailing, trading and handicrafts. Microsate
                   branch12 had a portfolio of Rs 7 crores in March 2007, which is expected to go up to about Rs
                   20 crores by March 2008. This is its third year, and it has become profitable. Indian Bank has
                   already set up another Microsate branch in Patna, and plans to open one in South Chennai,
                   apart from branches in several cities all over the country. The main challenge it will face will be
                   the availability of good NGOs with the capacity to form good SHGs. Tamil Nadu is unusual in
                   having a very strong women's development corporation with an important urban component
                   in its SHG programme, and with a policy to form SHGs only through NGOs (as distinct from the
                   government agencies commonly used in other states). It ensures quality control through a
                   system of accreditation of NGOs and provides training and other forms of assistance to them.

               84
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                               Urban Microfinance




Experience with SHGs in some other urban microfinance programmes has been mixed, as discussed
below. However, if the Microsate experience can be replicated it will be a significant
breakthrough.

The Pioneers have stayed relatively small. In contrast with the more minimalist, financial services
approach, of their successors, and in keeping with the more holistic view of the nature of
poverty and powerlessness they espouse, many of them they have placed equal emphasis on
organizational inputs and collective action in pursuit of working women's rights and other
social goals.13 This meant accepting a much lower rate of growth, although in response to
member needs SEWA Bank in particular (Box 5.6) has expanded much more rapidly in respect of
savings and insurance than on the credit side. Its experience in respect of savings and insurance
services in an urban context as well as on credit products such as housing loans and individual
loans generally, are of great interest. Sri Padmavathy Mahila Abyudaya Sangh (SPMS) is unusual
in several respects, which combine to make it unique. It may be the country's first SHG federation.
Not only is it one of the few federations located in an urban area, it relies only for technical and
strategic inputs on its promoters, and has become self-sufficient in respect of financial activities,
although it receives grants for a variety of economic development activities, including
participation in urban infrastructure activities such as housing, environmental sanitation and In our use of
even road building (DHAN Foundation 2005 and Box 3.3).                                                the term
                                                                                               financial
                                                                                               inclusion (or
The Context                                                                                    inclusion into
                                                                                               the formal and
                                                                                               semi-formal or
Urbanization and urban poverty                                                                 MFI sector)
                                                                                               there is a
Some of the salient facts on India's urbanization and urban poverty are as follows:14          danger of
                                                                                               forgetting that
                                                                                               the "excluded"
(i)   The rate of urbanization increased sharply in the 1990s to almost twice the rural are in fact
      population growth rate, and the share of the urban population, although still lower served by a
      than the global and Asian average, had grown to 31 percent by 2001 Much of the huge informal
                                                                                               financial sector.
      growth is being driven by migration from the rural areas.                                The challenge is
                                                                                               not to fill a
(ii) While urban poverty is declining in relative terms it is increasing in absolute terms. In supposed credit
                                                                                               vacuum, but to
      the three decades since 1970 the number of poor went up from 52 to 67 million.15
                                                                                               improve on the
      However in some cities like Delhi the poverty ratio was as low as 8 percent in 1999 terms of the
      (Mukherjee 2004).                                                                        informal sector


(iii)   India's metros and large towns have some of the most congested slums in the world and
        are "home" to some of the worst living conditions anywhere Thus the extent of "human
        poverty" and deprivation is much worse than the "income" poverty measured and reported
        in the statistics.

The urban informal financial sector
In our use of the term financial inclusion (or inclusion into the formal and semi-formal or MFI
sector) there is a danger of forgetting that the "excluded" are in fact served by a huge
informal financial sector. The challenge is not to fill a supposed credit vacuum, but to improve
on the terms of the informal sector. This will have two benefits -- the direct benefit to those
"included", and the indirect benefit to those left behind in the informal sector (likely the
great majority). The terms on which the latter receive financial services will improve because

                                                                                                   85
of the competition offered by MFIs, just as they have in pockets in the rural areas where MFIs
 have achieved significant penetration.

 There is a huge literature on the variety of informal sector lenders, and lending and savings
 devices and mechanisms, including moneylenders, pawnbrokers, chit funds, informal finance
 companies, employers, pygmy deposit collectors etc.16 In Kalisbasti, a squatter settlement in
 West Delhi, Ruthven (2001), mentions (i) interest-free loans from friends, neighbours and
 relatives17 (ii) wage advances, (iii) groceries on credit, (iv) goods on credit, (v) private loans
 taken on interest from ex-neighbours, relatives etc at rates lower than moneylenders, and (vi)
 loans from professional moneylenders'. It is important for MFIs to understand each of these
 sources, but particularly moneylenders, because they are the main competition, both with
 respect to serving the poor and the excluded non-poor. In Kalisbasti, of the various sources,
 moneylenders had the highest share of poor users, or 40 percent, as Box 5.1(excerpted from
 Ruthven 2001) describes. For households in a household monthly income bracket one-notch
 higher, who constitute Ujjivan's target group, they are ubiquitous, as described in Box 5.2
 (from Ujjivan 2006).


                          Box 5.1      The uses and abuses of moneylenders

     While 18% of respondents used (or admitted to using) professional moneylenders, close to
     half of these (40%) were categorized as poor. The operations and role of moneylenders in
     Kalibasti has been documents elsewhere (see Patole & Ruthven 2001). It is our observation
     that moneylenders hold a special place in the financial portfolio of poorer residents fro two
     main reason. Firstly, their convenience and reliability is unbeatable, an attribute particularly
     valuable for poor people who are short of time and money to negotiate deals and whose needs
     are most urgent. Secondly they are unique within the informal sector, in being commercial (or
     "professional") and incur no wider social obligations on the part of the borrower. In other
     words there is no dignity at stake in dealing with a professional moneylender- it is just a
     straight commercial deal. This makes them attractive to those who require discretion, who
     don't wish to strain social relations with financial concerns, or who simply don't have such
     relations to lean on. As one respondent put it, "When I go to the moneylender, it's between
     him and me. I give my relatives no reason to talk."

     While the users of professional moneylenders are a mixed group (mostly Muslims and OBCs), the
     circumstances in which people borrow fall broadly in to two types: (i) those facing income
     shortfalls for whom other borrowing options are limited or non existent (Box 9), and (ii) those
     managing a mixed credit portfolio, within which moneylenders have a niche of convenience and
     instant access ( Box 10). Both types frequently drag repayment, but those of the first type-
     unless their income increases- find it increasingly difficult to raise money as they are refused in
     turn by each moneylender who recognizes their cash-flow inadequate to repay.

                             Box 5.1.1 The uses and abuse of moneylenders

     Surender( 27) and Anita( 24, P) have been in Delhi for most of their lives. Surender is a painter, taking
     contracts through a local hardware store and has an erratic income due to the seasonal nature of his
     work. Anita stopped working recently following pregnancy. This is the couple's seventh year in Kalibasti
     and over the years they've become acquainted with several of the local moneylenders. Usually they go
     to those who take daily installments since this suits Surender's income pattern. A month ago they took
     one such loan of Rs 1500 from a Tamil moneylender and passed the money to a friend who had just


86
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                                  Urban Microfinance




given birth. Handling them Rs 1350, he informed them they'd need to pay Rs 35 for 50 days (a monthly
rate of about 50%). They agreed, as they had in the past. But when Surender's income dried up they
started facing repayment problems. Anita informed us she was planning a visit to a Rajasthani lender
well-known to her mother. Since he collects monthly rather than daily, his terms are more suited to the
couple at this time of year. She'll try for Rs 2000 at 3% per month. She'll repay the Tamil moneylender
with this loan and use the balance to pay the house rent which is already two month overdue.

                     Box 5.1.2 The USP of the professional moneylender

At first glance one would have thought Santosh (42) and Roshan Lal (45, B), would have no use for
moneylender and their high interest rates. They've both got permanent jobs which they can take
advances, only one son to look after, an array of friends to borrow from when the need arises, they
have a bank savings account and Roshan sits in a RoSCA at the office. Nonetheless when they heard
five years ago about a cheap deal going for a plot in Kalibasti they went straight to the moneylender
and borrowed Rs 5000 to make the offer. Over the next 4 months they repaid the loan at 5% per month.
It was-they say- the only way they could raise money quickly enough.

                                                                         Adapted from Ruthven 2001



                 Box 5.2 The ubiquity of moneylenders in Bangalore

The unorganized sector is dominated by a vast assortment of virtually nameless, faceless
financiers. They are present in market and non-market locations, and undertake their business
very quietly and unobtrusively. The relationship between moneylenders and borrowers is
symbiotic. With poor access to any formal funding, borrowers work to maintain a good
relationship with their only source of credit, i.e. the non formal individual moneylender.
Additionally, there is a sense of loyalty towards him as he is considered to be his saviour in
times of need. As for the moneylender, the borrower is his market. He services good borrowers
with relatively easier repayment terms.

Generally, the interest rates levied by moneylenders are higher than those charged in the
organised sector. Moneylenders charge between 2% and 10% per month on a loan amount.
                                                                                                          Why was urban
There are exceptions where the interest rates are lower or higher then these rates. In spite of           microfinance
the high interest rates that they charge, moneylenders are the most popular source of finance.            left unexplored
This is probably because they offer unsecured loan that are tailored to the income cycle of               territory for so
                                                                                                          long, despite
customers.                                                                                                the prospects of
                                                                                                          huge loan
                                                                            Based on Ujjivan 2006         demand, larger
                                                                                                          average loan
 Finally, it is worth reminding ourselves that the burden of exclusion falls most heavily on the          size and higher
                                                                                                          population
poor, because it is the poor who are most likely to be excluded also by moneylenders and other            density making
informal sector lenders, for essentially the same reasons. So at the bottom of the pyramid                for lower costs,
                                                                                                          the need to
there may indeed be a credit vacuum. Second, to the extent rural microfinance reduces rural-
                                                                                                          reach the
urban migration it reduces the inclusion task for urban microfinance. On the other hand, it               growing
could on balance fuel it by financing it.18                                                               numbers of the
                                                                                                          urban poor, and
                                                                                                          the example of
The particular challenges of urban informal finance                                                       Latin America
                                                                                                          where
                                                                                                          microfinance is
Why was urban microfinance left unexplored territory for so long, despite the prospects of                predominantly
huge loan demand, larger average loan size and higher population density making for lower                 urban?

                                                                                                      87
costs, the need to reach the growing numbers of the urban poor, and the example of Latin
                     America where microfinance is predominantly urban? Some of the reasons have to do with
                     institutional factors such as the lack of a structured programme similar to the SBLP promoted
                     by a single apex agency such as NABARD, which enjoyed the visibility the SBLP gave it. Similar
                     programmes in the urban areas such as the Jawahar Shahari Rozgar Yojana failed to attain
                     anywhere near the same prominence, although this was largely due to the same inherent
                     difficulties that beset urban MFIs discussed in this chapter.

                     As regards the MFI model, the inspiration and delivery technology were derived from the
                     Grameen Bank, which was almost exclusively rural, and whose model was proving as successful
                     in the densely populated parts of rural India as in Bangladesh. Why jeopardize high growth
                     and expend scarce managerial energy on venturing into unchartered territory, especially when
                     the standardization and borrower-time requirements of the group-lending model might prove a
                     handicap in the much more heterogeneous and time-constrained urban environment? Even
                     more frequently mentioned as a difficulty for group lending with its reliance on peer-pressure
                     and mutual trust based on long-standing neighbourhood and kinship ties, was the supposed
                     much greater mobility and lack of social cohesion, even atomization, of urban slum-dwellers.

                     Mobility and transience
        More of a    As urban microfinance expands, some of these constraints and apprehensions are beginning to
       problem in
                     come into clearer focus (although only just, we are looking at the tip of the iceberg in terms of
     these areas,
 Swadhaar finds,     what we need to learn through patient rigorous field work, an example of which is contained in
 is that as many     the boxes included here from Ruthven 2001). As with most generalizations, the validity of that
         as 30-35
    percent of its   relating to the obstacle posed by mobility and transience depends on which income segment
  borrowers have     and location one is looking at. It certainly seems to the case that mobility has proved less of a
        no formal
                     problem than was originally feared. Fairly typical is Veena Mankar's observation that many slum
  documentation
      to establish   dwellers have been living in the same location for a generation or more, and that even if they go
  either identity    home to their villages for a couple of months a year they come back to the same area because of
or address. More
    of a problem,    proximity to a known livelihood.19 More of a problem in these areas, Swadhaar finds, is that as
        also, than   many as 30-35 percent of its borrowers have no formal documentation to establish either
  mobility per se    identity or address. More of a problem, also, than mobility per se is what might be called
   is what might
         be called   "involuntary mobility", caused by the ongoing drive in Mumbai (and elsewhere) to demolish
     "involuntary    slums and relocate them elsewhere, which has affected 10 percent of her clients already.20
        mobility"
                     On the other hand, in her research in Kalibasti, an unauthorized squatter settlement in West
                     Delhi, Ruthven 2001 found that 16 percent of her sample had been resident for less than a
                     year, and 35 percent for two years (Box 5.3 from Ruthven 2001). There is no doubt that much
                     of the growth of India's urban slums is being fed by accelerating migration.21 However it is
                     not in-migration we are concerned with so much as the intention to stay, and here she
                     reminds us that a good proportion of recent arrivals are planning to move on within a year or
                     two (mostly back to their villages, in thier case).22 Aajivika in Delhi has been affected by
                     mobility not directly, but indirectly, in that it is located in a resettlement colony in Northwest
                     Delhi where more than ten thousand households have been located in the last five years. Aditi
                     Mehta (2007) talks of the "almost complete lack of mutual trust within the community" which
                     affected operations initially.




                 88
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                             Urban Microfinance




                            Box 5.3 Mobility in a Delhi slum

If we take the World Bank's global poverty line of US$1 (equivalent in Rupee purchasing power
parity) of income per day per family member, just under a third of our sample emerge as below
the poverty line. There is only a partial correspondence, however, between this group, ranked
by current income, and the "poor" group ranked by our wider range of criteria during wealth
ranking exercises. Current income after all is not able to reflect the changing dynamic of
livelihoods over time and the wider context of assets and security which people experience
(or not) independently of immediate income sources.

A large proportion of Kalibasti residents are on the move. Sixteen % of our sample had been in
Kalibasti for less than a year, 35% for two years or less. Clearly this challenges assumptions of
slums as inhabited by permanent squatters since a good proportion of those who come are
moving on within one or two years. Almost half of residents were experiencing a "dynamic
trajectory"- improving their circumstances quite rapidly, or conversely in the midst of hard
times or a crisis which sees them impoverished. Most of the others were facing some turbulence
and hotly engaged in avoiding economic decline, making themselves less vulnerable to shocks,
paying off past debts and securing higher and more regular income. A minority of respondents
(20%) could be seen as "cruising ", not moving in any direction having secured a comfortable
niche in Delhi and without much ambition…

…we can divide respondents into five broad categories in respect of their history and the
circumstances which led to their arrival in Kalibasti. This is important because-even after
several years in the colony- it informs their money management strategy. The table below
describes these five categories.

                     Reasons for respondents moving to Delhi (n =27)

Reason                                                                             Percentage
Gradual rural impoverishment: shrinking, unviable landholdings are not                     29
compensated by availability of alternative employment, over generations.

City hoppers hunt for opportunity: Business/self employed families                           29
from regional cities try their luck in the capital

Young members of secure rural families hunt for opportunity: unmarried male                  21
members of families with land ( especially from Western UP) take time out
before settling down to marriage and village responsibilities.

Refugees from a crisis in the village: the death of the mal bread winner, a severe           13
health problem or an accident forces people to the city where they seek work to
repay debts, rebuild assets or start a new life.

Long-term Delhi residents in financial crisis: Lower middle-class families                   17
downshift their lifestyle after being cheated, robbed or imprisoned

Total                                                                                      100

The table highlights the misconception that slum dwellers are necessarily impoverished economic
refuges from the country side permanently flowing to the city. Nearly half (44%) of our
respondents are from relatively secure backgrounds, already urbanized or with a strong asset
base in the village. Even among the balance, while most have come to Delhi in response to
economic hardship of some kind, it can not be assumed that most will stay. Many are using
city earning power to build a more viable life in the countryside.

                                                                       Based on Ruthven 2001

                                                                                                    89
The main    The main response so far to the problem of mobility in areas where it is acute is exclusion.
 response so far
                    Thus Arohan in Kolkata would like very much to serve the huge population of mostly day
 to the problem
  of mobility in    visitors who flood into the middle-class areas of South Kolkata from the rural hinterland as day
  areas where it    labourers and maids etc, but has for very understandable reasons been unable to do so.
      is acute is
        exclusion   Likewise with the large population of rickshaw drivers who park by the wayside to sleep at
                    night. If there is any successful experience of reaching Mumbai's pavement dwellers through
                    microfinanance on a significant scale, it has not yet been documented. Although Ujjivan
                    defines its target group as those with a household income of between Rs 2000 to Rs 8000 a
                    month, 98 percent of its clientele were above the Rs 3000 line in March 2007.23 Aditi Mehta
                    is explicit in recognizing that Aajivika's participation comes so far from the "economically
                    active poor, validating the opinion that microfinance may not be the most suitable instrument
                    to target the poorest households. In the urban context this leaves unanswered the question
                    of how the livelihoods of this segment might be addressed".24

                    In locations where they do operate, most urban MFIs do however appear to have found ways
                    of providing themselves with enough comfort to establish that the borrower has a fixed abode
                    locally, despite lack of formal documentation.25 Thus Swadhaar and others establish veracity of
                    information through cross checks with neighbours and using whatever documents are available,
                    even wedding photographs. While joint liability groups may not be able to ensure repayments
                    above a certain level of loan size (which most urban practitioners put at Rs 15.000 to Rs
                    20,000)26 they do serve as a screening mechanism in respect of residence. Another screening
                    mechanism, which has been used by Basix and others, is to require prospective borrowers to
                    save regularly for a period before becoming eligible for borrowing.27

                     A final point to be made is that even if a significant proportion of residents in a slum are
                    transient, MFIs would have to achieve a very high level of penetration before running out of
     In locations   prospective borrower from among permanent residents for group membership, especially for
  where they do     the smaller, JLG groups, as discussed below. The trick would seem to lie in achieving a high
   operate, most
   urban MFIs do    success rate in spotting them.
 however appear
   to have found    Urban heterogeniety
          ways of
        providing
themselves with     There are several cross-cutting ways in which to view urban heterogeneity. It can be viewed in
 enough comfort     terms of financial needs, or purposes for which money is raised, as in Box 5.4 excerpted from
     to establish
                    Ruthven 2001, describing "spending sets" in Kalibasti. It can also be viewed in relation to loan
         that the
  borrower has a    types designed to serve those needs, such as the informal sector business and personal loans
     fixed abode    taken by persons in the MHI class that constitutes Ujjivan's target group (as described Ujjivan
 locally, despite
   lack of formal
                    2006). Again it can be described in terms of occupational segments (an example of which, from
  documentation     Mumbai, is given below) or in terms of modes of employment (self versus wage employment).

                                           Box 5.4 Segmentation by loan purpose

                    What do Kalibasti residents need financial services for? The spending behavior of residents (
                    and the concomitant way in which they raise significant sums of money towards such expenses)
                    can be divided into six "spending sets" summarized below:

                    i.    Lifecycle costs: overwhelmingly towards the marriage of daughters

                    ii.   Income shortfalls: chronic or intermittent


                90
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                            Urban Microfinance




iii.   Dependents outside Delhi: relatives in the village but also children in school

iv.    Health crisis, chronic health problems and the stresses associated with these

v.     Investment: in fixed assets or a job opportunity, in Delhi or the village

vi.    House construction in Delhi or the village

The table below illustrates the purposes for which significant sums of money ("lump sums")
were raised (whether through savings, advances or loans) by residents in the months running
up to our survey. It shows the proportion of residents who had recently raised a lump sum for
each of the purposes described and - among these residents- how many were ranked as poor.

Use of lump sums among                      % of sample              Of which ranked
                                                                       as poor(%)

Kalibasti residents (%)

Lifecycle cost                                   39                         25

Income shortfalls in Delhi                       27                         57

Dependents outside Delhi*                        31                         25

Health & mental stress                           24                         58

Investment                                       24                          0

House construction                               24                         33

*This is not equivalent to all those remitting money to the village since it includes only those
who raised a significant sum for a trip or to send resources to the Village. Remittances have
been examined separately.

As we might expect, the poor face disproportionately high expenses for health as well as to
cover periodic or regular income deficits. No respondents ranked as poor had recently raised
lump sums for investment. On the other hand a proportionate number of this group was
making investments in houses, mostly in their home towns or village. This highlights the role ... quite apart
of urban livelihoods in making possible the acquisition of rural assets.                      from the much
                                                                                                   greater
                                                                      Based on Ruthven 2001 importance of
                                                                                                   wage
                                                                                                   employment in
                                                                                                   the urban areas,
To take the last of these dimensions first, quite apart from the much greater importance of
                                                                                                   self-employment
wage employment in the urban areas, self-employment itself, whether in manufacture or services,    itself, whether
is likely to exhibit a much greater diversity than in the rural areas where a much smaller group   in manufacture
                                                                                                   or services, is
of activities such as livestock and petty trading often account for the majority of loans. The     likely to exhibit
proportion of wage and self-employed among MFI borrowers is likely to vary according to            a much greater
income group targeted, the urban area concerned and MFI policy. As many as half of Ujjivan         diversity than
                                                                                                   in the rural
borrowers are wage-employed in occupations such as domestic help, garment factory workers,         areas where a
sweepers in the municipal corporation or are helpers in shops, schools and hospitals. Many of      much smaller
                                                                                                   group of
them however have secondary self-employment activities. The self-employed are flower or            activities such
vegetable vendors, or pushcart vendors of food and snacks, or run tea shops, or retail saris out   as livestock and
of their homes, etc. Piece-rated job-work, which accounts for 10 percent of customers is an        petty trading
                                                                                                   often account
intermediate form of employment, is common in agarbatti making and beedi rolling and tends         for the majority
to be the worst remunerated, absorbing the most recent arrivals. In the case of Swadhaar and       of loans

                                                                                               91
SWAWS, the proportion among borrowers is the reverse, largely for reasons of policy.28 But
                    clearly there is plenty of scope for lending to both sets of borrowers in India's metros. In
                    Mumbai one estimate places the number of workers in various occupational segments (offering
                    both self and wage employment) which engage a high proportion of women, as: 700,000
                    household workers, of which 95 percent are women (maids); 200,000 hawkers (25 percent
                    women); 100,000 each of sweepers and rag pickers (40 percent women and children); and
                    50,000 zari workers (35 percent women and children)29.

                    The numbers engaged in the more male dominated occupational segments such as taxi drivers,
                    auto drivers, loom workers, leather industry workers, and mathedi and hamali workers were
                    estimated in the same study.30 At least one urban MFI would like at some stage to lend to men
                    too. As with rural microfinance, and contrary to the enduring fiction that "95 percent" of
                    microfinance borrowers are women, a large share of the loans are used by men anyway, and not
                    just husbands (Chapter 6).

       Given the    Also, there is no clear-cut correspondence between mode of employment and use of loans. As
   shortage and     many as 30 percent of Swadhaar's borrowers running businesses borrow for non-business purposes.
     dilapidated
    condition of    Retirement of high-cost existing debt to moneylenders and others tends to one of the commonest
  housing in the    uses of the first and second loans for both sets of borrowers (as may be the case in the rural areas
urban areas, the
                    too). Given the shortage and dilapidated condition of housing in the urban areas, the demand
     demand for
housing loans is    for housing loans is extremely high, as is that for products designed to cater to life-cycle
extremely high,     events, education and health expenditures (given the high income elasticities of demand of all
   as is that for
        products    these services, and higher incomes in the urban areas). All this has implications for the range of
     designed to    products offered and their design, as well as for lending procedures.
   cater to life-
   cycle events,
  education and     Responses
           health
   expenditures
(given the high
                    Products
          income
  elasticities of   Several MFIs have conducted careful market research and are in the process of developing products
   demand of all    based on it. Ujjivan's research into the market for housing loans revealed the life-time progression
 these services,
      and higher    of the typical customer from renting to "leasing" (in which the tenant pays in lieu of rent a
 incomes in the     relatively large interest-free lump sum to the owner), to buying a house site, to building a house,
    urban areas)
                    to extending and repairing it. For good customers who have established a track-record Ujjivan has
                    started offering loans of up to Rs 30,000 for any of these purposes using a loan from HDFC which
                    should suffice for 1700 customers. (Box 5.5). It is looking also at educational loans required
                    specially at the beginning of the school year, and loans for higher education. These products are
                    in addition to Ujjivan's standard family-needs (or personal) loans, business loans, top-up loans,
                    emergency loans and festival loans. SWAWS and VWS also have educational loans.31 SEWA's products
                    have evolved over 30 years to result in the diversity described in Box 5.6.

                                Box 5.5 Ujjivan's approach to urban housing microfinance:
                                       helping customers climb the housing ladder

                    Driven by heavy migration into the city and a booming economy, Bangalore faces a critical
                    housing shortage, boosting the price of housing ever higher. For the urban poor, bearing the
                    burden of rising housing costs requires substantial financing. To date this has been supplied
                    by Bangalore's highly-developed yet costly informal financial sector, with little presence of


                92
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                             Urban Microfinance




urban MFIs. Ujjivan recognized the opportunity for affordable housing finance, and recently
began a pilot urban housing microfinance scheme.
The pilot process commenced with a study designed to provide an understanding of urban
housing needs. The study revealed three types of urban residents: renters, leasers and
homeowners, who each correspond to a progressive rung on what Ujjivan terms the "Housing
Ladder". The first rung is renting, which typically requires a monthly rent of Rs1000-2000 and
a refundable deposit of 10 times the monthly rent. The second rung is leasing, which typically
requires a lump sum between Rs 50,000-Rs.100,000 in lieu of a monthly rent for 3 to5 years.
Leases are desirable because the lump-sum is returned at the lease end, albeit without interest,
allowing customers to reinvest the amount in a larger lease, land site, or other purposes. The
third rung is owning a home, which typically occurs in three phases: buying a land site,
constructing a simple home, and later progressively improving the house.
To climb each rung, the urban poor are dependent on access to affordable financing. For
example, Sunita, an Ujjivan customer, is renting a house for Rs 2000 per month with a deposit
of Rs 20,000. She says, "I want a lease because they are better than renting because you do
not have to pay every month, and you can save your money. But I need Rs 30,000 more to
afford a lease in my area, and moneylenders are too expensive." The need for housing financing
was echoed by Uma, also an Ujjivan customer, who says "I own my house and I am very happy
because I can stay here forever now. But now I need money to build one more room because
my children are older now and we don't have enough space." The presence of renters and              The study
                                                                                                    revealed three
leasers in the urban housing landscape marks the key difference between urban and rural             types of urban
settings, as nearly 60% of Ujjivan's customers rent or lease while just 40% own, in contrast to     residents:
80 to 90 percent home ownership rates in rural areas.                                               renters, leasers
                                                                                                    and
The study also demolished several myths about urban housing microfinance. Myth 1: Housing           homeowners,
loans must be large with long tenors and are unsuitable for MFIs. The Housing Ladder reveals that   who each
                                                                                                    correspond to a
in fact the poor need loans as small as Rs 10,000 to reach subsequent rungs in the Housing          progressive rung
Ladder, for example a move from a Rs 50,000 to a Rs 60,000 lease. Smaller, incremental loans        on what Ujjivan
are actually better suited for both customers and MFIs, because they are more affordable for        terms the
                                                                                                    "Housing
customers, and offer lower risk and returning customers for MFIs. Myth 2: The urban poor are
                                                                                                    Ladder"
too mobile for MFIs to give loans to them. Despite this perception, urban families are highly
rooted to their communities and often live in the same area for generations. In fact, because
the pressure to move is often created by an inability to afford rising costs, microfinance may
have a stabilizing effect on the mobility of urban low-income families. Myth 3: The poor do not
have proper documentation for their homes. While the majority of renters and leasers do not
have documentation for current contracts, MFIs can to influence new documentation because
customers will be entering into new agreements with the loans they receive. MFIs can require
customers to submit proper documentation, putting pressure on them to demand documentation
from landlords. For home owners, the study found that over 90% of urban customers did have
legal land titles. Although MFIs must develop methodologies to screen for forged documents,
Ujjivan found that documentation is not in fact a major barrier.
Ujjivan's housing loans have attempted to address each rung in the Housing Ladder and are
currently being tested in a pilot phase. The products offered include rental deposit, lease
amounts and house improvement loans, ranging in size from Rs 10,000-30,000 with tenors of
up to 3 years. Original documentation is not required, and customers can avail of the loan
after completing one full year with an excellent repayment record, and with center and group
recommendation. Ujjivan plans to roll out the loans nationwide in 2008, and in the future will
offer value-added housing products, larger loan sizes and individual housing loans.
                                Anjali Banthia, Product Manager, Ujjivan Financial Services

                                                                                                93
Box 5.6      Individual loans and product diversification at SEWA Bank

 Recognizing that the diversity of occupational, economic and social backgrounds of SEWA
 Bank members, with their very different financial requirements, made group lending
 suboptimal in the urban context, SEWA was one of the first MFIs to take the more
 challenging path of individual lending. Starting in 1974 with a simple savings and a simple
 loan account SEWA Bank has evolved into a composite financial institution offering a
 variety of savings and recurring deposit accounts, fixed deposits and secured and
 unsecured loans. Unsecured loans have to be backed only by two guarantors, one of who
 can be a family member. About a fifth of its roughly 150,000 members are borrowers, of
 which three-fourths have unsecured loans of up to Rs 50,000 repayable in 35 months at an
 interest rate of 18 percent. Slightly better off clients with urgent cash requirements can
 avail of secured loans at 12 percent, backed by a personal asset, usually jewelry. In 1998
 the Bank introduced longer-term housing loans in partnership with HUDCO, linked to a
 requirement to save Rs 20,000 through a 5-year recurring deposit scheme for housing.
 Finally, in 2001, SEWA introduced daily collection loans to extend outreach to poorer
 clients with a daily income cycle such as vegetable and flower vendors. This product mimics
 the money-lender, although at a much lower rate of interest, through bank "sathis", a team
 of former client with good financial literacy skills, who work on a commission basis, and
 visit clients daily not only to collect daily loan repayments, but to offer also daily savings
 collection and other recurring deposit schemes.

 By introducing various specialized recurring deposit schemes each tailored to a specific
 life-cycle need (including, now, pensions for old-age) Sewa has greatly reduced the cost of
 predictable expenditures for life-cycle needs. For unexpected shocks (death, accidents,
 sickness) it has made insurance compulsory though its insurance wing VIMO SEWA. Based
 on close studies of its clients' needs, today SEWA offers more than 40 differentiated
 products. Jayshreeben Vyas describes the process "We looked at their life-cycle needs and
 have come up with various savings products to mirror those needs - various recurring
 accounts, savings for buying gold, for education, for marriage, for old age, etc. Similarly,
 we have developed a range of products within credit".

                                                     Based on Pasheva and Desai in CMF 2006



 Processes
 As regards processes, one response to urban mobility and heterogeneity has been to do away
 with center meetings altogether, and experiment with smaller sized JLGs, more suited to
 accommodating the diversity of occupations, loan sizes requirements and time availabilities.
 As Veena Mankar points out, a maid and a hawker are unlikely to be free at the same time to
 attend a group meeting (assuming they have any free time at all). Both Ujjivan and Swadhaar
 have introduced monthly instead of weekly repayments, given the particularly acute time
 pressures experienced by borrowers in metros (many of who have long commutes). Swadhaar
 even gives them the option to pay a little extra to have their repayments collected at the
 doorstep. Also, doing away with center meeting makes a virtue out of necessity, since sufficient
 space for a gathering (let alone for a branch office) is prohibitively expensive, if available at
 all, in many urban localities.


94
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                             Urban Microfinance




It will be interesting to see how these innovations work out. It should be noted though that The next logical
                                                                                                    step of course
not all urban MFIs are departing from the tried and tested. Arohan feels its present system is
                                                                                                    is to do away
well suited to its clients,32 while recognizing changes to it may be required for different         with JLGs
segments, when they are covered (monthly repayments, for instance, for the salaried for             altogether and
                                                                                                    introduce
personal loans).                                                                                    individual
                                                                                                    loans, which are
Individual loans                                                                                    already the
                                                                                                    norm in Latin
                                                                                                    America. The
The next logical step of course is to do away with JLGs altogether and introduce individual
                                                                                                    advantage of
loans, which are already the norm in Latin America. The advantage of individual loans is that       individual loans
they can be more easily tailored to the loan size, gestation period and other cash flow             is that they can
                                                                                                    be more easily
requirements of the specific activity chosen by each borrower. Individual loans are usually         tailored to the
made to borrowers who have established a track record through group borrowing and who               loan size,
                                                                                                    gestation
require larger loans. Their higher risk is usually addressed by security in some form and higher
                                                                                                    period and
interest on account of the risk premium. Many MFIs have in fact already been making individual      other cash flow
loans for housing purposes to senior group members, although, since funds for these usually         requirements of
                                                                                                    the specific
come from the housing financing institutions, their interest rates are lower and tenor longer.      activity chosen
What are more recent, are loans made to small entrepreneurs and traders referred to by names        by each
such microenterprise loans, etc.33 For most MFIs individual loans are still a small part of their   borrower

portfolio, except for SEWA Bank, the MFI with the longest experience in India (and perhaps
anywhere) of individual loans, as described in Box 5.6.

SHGs or JLGs?
As a delivery vehicle SHGs (instead of JLGs) would also be affected by the mobility and time-
scarcity related constraints of urban life, perhaps even more so, since SHGs have more members
than JLGs, which should make it even harder to find a time for meetings suitable for all
members, and increase the likelihood of at least one member moving out of the locality. On
the other hand, in theory at least, SHGs are better suited to handle urban heterogeneity since
they are expressly designed to accommodate different loan amounts, and like chit funds can
accomodate non-borrowing or net saver members who prefer to sit back and earn interest on           On the other
                                                                                                    hand, in theory
loans taken by others. Moreover, given adequate accounting skills they should be able to            at least, SHGs
accommodate heterogeneity in respect of variation in desired savings, both between members          are better
and over time. Despite this, their use is very much the exception, although Indian Bank's           suited to handle
                                                                                                    urban
Microsate branch, SPMS and Roshan Vikas (Box 3.5) rely on them exclusively, the last two as         heterogeneity
SHG federations.                                                                                    since they are
                                                                                                    expressly
                                                                                                    designed to
Janalakshmi in Bangalore also relied on them exclusively in its previous avatar as Sanghamitra's    accommodate
Urban Microfinance Programme, but is reported to be moving away from them. Ujjivan also             different loan
used them, outsourcing the task of forming them to existing NGOs, but like Janalakshmi has          amounts, and
                                                                                                    like chit funds
moved away from SHGs organized by others, to forming JLGs itself. In Ujjivan's case the             can accomodate
reasons had to do with lack of control over the quality of the groups formed, with some             non-borrowing
                                                                                                    or net saver
members frequently cornering all the funds, and instances of illegal commissions being charged
                                                                                                    members who
from the groups by middlemen masquerading as NGOs. It also felt the margin between what it          prefer to sit
paid the SHG and the rates paid by the ultimate borrower was unjustified. Finally, hoping to        back and earn
                                                                                                    interest on
graduate borrowers in the medium term to larger individual loans, it felt JLGs gave it a much       loans taken by
closer understanding of their credit and savings behaviour.34                                       others



                                                                                                95
Aajivika in Delhi actually initiated operations through NGOs who had an existing presence in
                     slum clusters in activities such as health, literacy and advocacy, but dropped this approach
                     since it found that partners relegated microfinance very low on their list of priorities, and the
                     groups formed were often short lived. It chose then to initiate direct operations in a huge
                     new resettlement colony, but found the level of trust insufficient to mobilize 15 member SHGs.
                     It settled finally on smaller groups of five clustered in centers of 8 along classic Grameen lines.

                     However, none of the problems encountered are inherent in the SHG channel, and warrant
                     further investigation. The experience is mixed, and as noted above there are several examples
                     of successful use of SHGs. For MFIs striving to attain rapid growth however, JLGs give it more
                     control over loan size and frequency, and this may be one of the decisive consideration in
                     favor of the latter in most cases.35


                     Some other challenges
                     Human resources
    While the MFI    While the MFI human resources challenge - not just training, but attracting and retaining
human resources      staff - has been engaging the attention of the MFI community generally in the last few years,
  challenge - not
    just training,   its severity in the urban areas has taken the new urban MFIs by surprise. Nearly all of them are
   but attracting    finding it difficult to recruit and retain staff in conditions of a tightening job market,
    and retaining
                     especially in cities like Bangalore where Ujjivan reports attrition rates of 20 to 30 percent a
staff - has been
     engaging the    year. The skills field workers acquire are turning out to be in high demand in other parts of the
attention of the     financial sector, and in marketing. Also, as Veena Mankar points out, many young entrants to
 MFI community
generally in the     the labour force find the multi-tasking nature of MFI field work too demanding, and prefer a
  last few years,    more uni-dimensional job (and one offering, preferably, a little more "glamour" or office
   its severity in
                     comfort). Finally, the relatively flat nature of the MFI pyramid doesn't help when it comes to
 the urban areas
    has taken the    promotion prospects. Clearly better pay and incentives will have to be part of the solution,
 new urban MFIs      but will raise costs. Another solution being tried out is recruiting staff in the rural areas and
       by surprise
                     providing them with accommodation.36

                     Borrower and external relations: "Money with respect"
                     Another aspect of urban operations MFIs are learning about is the much greater awareness of
                     urban borrowers on financial and other matters, stemming partly from higher literacy, but also
                     from the much closer presence of the formal sector.37 As one CEO points out "one significant
                     difference with rural operations is that you can't treat your customers as fools - you can't talk
       As one CEO    down to them". As another MFI leader put it "we impress on our staff that what we are offering
 points out "one
       significant   is not just money, but money with respect". Borrower sophistication may be particularly high in
  difference with    West Bengal because of greater political awareness.38 West Bengal MFIs have been particularly
 rural operations
                     conscious of the need to maintain good customer and external relations. They keep local ward-
is that you can't
        treat your   level politicians informed of their activities and plans, and invite them to preside over functions.
     customers as    VWS has followed a conscious policy of developing borrower rapport and community goodwill
 fools - you can't
     talk down to    through its diversity of microfinance plus activities, as well as schemes such as scholarships for
            them"    children of borrowers who top in their classes, grants to local youth clubs etc.39




                 96
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                              Urban Microfinance




Technology
The cost of space has already been mentioned, and is enhancing the interest in technological
solutions such as branchless banking. Ujjivan for instance is taking advantage of broadband
connectivity in urban areas by centralizing all data entry at the head office and having the
branches merely scan daily loan transaction data sheets and transmit them by email. (Alternatively,
since the branches are located in the same urban area, the sheets can be hand-carried). SEWA
and Swadhaar are using biometric smart cards to make it easier for their members to operate
savings accounts through ATMs, since they tend to forget their PINs. VWS has been given a
grant by SIDBI to introduce 5000 smart cards and hand-held machines in each of 2 branches.40

Competition
After what has been said earlier about the huge unsatisfied demand for credit in the urban            ... there is
                                                                                                      clearly a
areas it may seem surprising that excessive competition between MFIs even figures as an issue
                                                                                                      perception
is discussions of urban microfinance. However, there is clearly a perception among MFI leaders        among MFI
in several locations that competition could get out of hand and needs to be handled carefully.        leaders in
                                                                                                      several
Allegations relate to poaching of customers, even whole groups, as well as staff, with some           locations that
MFIs having acquired reputations for being particularly aggressive and even predatory. It is          competition
                                                                                                      could get out of
possible that some MFIs try to pre-empt others by planting the flag, so to speak, in new
                                                                                                      hand and needs
locations, by forming groups where the arrival of a rival is perceived to be imminent. It is          to be handled
possible also that there is a sort of herd mentality among MFIs as they follow others to new          carefully
areas that have been shown to be operable by the first mover. It is surprising again that of all
places, Kolkata, and the districts surrounding it, a huge urban and semi-urban conurbation
with a population of about 30 million living within a radius of 50 km from Kolkata and
accounting for about 40 percent of the population of West Bengal, should figure as a locus of
concern about excessive competition.41 Similar concerns are expressed in Bangalore and
Hyderabad42.

Until technological advances make unique identifiers and credit bureas economical, geographical
separation would seem offer one solution, but has not led to any explicit understandings
anywhere, on account of fears of "cartelization" restricting competition and leading to anti-
consumer behavior. However, even sharing of lists of borrowers is not practiced.


Conclusion
These are early days yet for urban microfinance. In the major metros it seems to be growing
relatively fast in Bangalore, Hyderabad and Kolkata, but more slowly in Mumbai and Delhi, for
reasons not entirely clear. Loan demand in Kolkata is particularly strong, and staff easier to
recruit because of higher unemployment among youth. Costs could also be lower. It will be
interesting to see how the early experiences and issues discussed in this chapter develop.




                                                                                                  97
Endnotes


 1 The task of writing this chapter was made considerably easier by two reports presented at last years'
     Microfinance India conference: CARE, MSDF and ICICI Bank, 2006, "A Promise to Pay the Bearer: An
     Exploration of the Potential for Urban Microfinance in India" and a companion volume of case
     studies, CMF 2006 "Reaching the Other 100 Million Poor in India". I am indebted also to a recent
     special issue of Microfinance Insights brought out quarterly by Intellecap, on "Reaching out to the
     Urban Poor" in March 2007, for a number of interesting articles some of them written by the
     promoters themselves.

 2 Examples are Janalakshmi and Ujjivan in Banglore, Swadhaar in Mumai, Mimo Finance in Dehradun
     and Aajivika in Delhi).

 3 Such as Arohan in Kolkata, and Sonata in Allahabad.

 4 The phrase is from CARE et al 2006, as are also the phrases "Rural Converts" and "Pioneers" used
     below. All the "new generation" MFIs mentioned so far have been started by professionals, although
     not all by former bankers. One of them has worked for the UN, and another is a serving civil servant.
     It is too early to say whether this could become a trend in the rural areas too, but a former NRI has
     started a rural MFI in northern Karnataka recently with a strong emphasis on livelihood promotion.

 5 Such as Spandana, SHARE, SKS, Bandhan, VWS, Basix, Grameen Koota, Maheseman, and SWAWS, the
     last of which is almost exclusively urban, with operations in Hyderabad's Old City.

 6 Examples are Satin Creditcare in Delhi, MAS Financial Services in Ahmedabad, and Yes Bank in
     Mumbai.

 7 ACCESS is the successor organization to the DFID-assisted CARE-CASHE project, which incubated about 30
     rural SHPIs in 3 states including West Bengal, using grants to build capacity and subsidize operational
     costs. In collaboration with SIDBI, ACCESS intends to incubate 8 nascent MFIs in the Kolkata municipal
     area, assisting them to develop systems and capacity through mentoring services provided by an Urban
     Microfinance Resource Centre. It intends to achieve a collective outreach of 40,000 borrowers and a
     portfolio of Rs 12 crores by the end of Year 1 (June 2008) going up to 1.32, 000 and Rs 120 crores by
     the end of Year 5. Loan funds will be provided by SIDBI, coupled with grants of up to 25 percent of the
     loan amounts for capacity building and overheads. The project aims to attain break-even for the MFIs by
     the end of the 3rd year. ACCESS has similar projects in the MP and Rajasthan, but which are rural.
     Kolkata was chosen because it is the city in India with the highest population density, containing about
     60 percent of the state's urban population, and because of the availability of suitable candidate nascent
     MFIs, and a history of operation in WB from CASHE days. It will be interesting to see how the incubation
     approach works out in comparison with the others described here.

 8 Thus Janalakshmi and Ujjivan both plan to grow to half a million clients within a few years. Ujjivan
     now has 3 branches each in Delhi and 5 in Kolkata apart from the 13 in Banglaore, and by March 2008
     expects to grow to 100,000 clients within just over two years.


98
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                                         Urban Microfinance




9 Data is lacking on the respective shares of their rural, peri-urban and urban operations, although in
   some cases the last two are relatively important, going up to half, reportedly, in the case of Spandana,
   which has been making daily collection loans in several urban areas for some time now. Basix started
   expressly urban operations through a small pilot project in Hyderabad in 2004.

10 Yes Bank hopes to reach about 2000 borrowers, mostly the self-employed in need of working capital
   loans, by March 2008, and is targeting about 150,000 in 5 years out of all its branches, with an
   average loan size of Rs 35,000. It does require security by hypothecating specific household goods like
   TV sets, which act as "reputational" collateral. The bank hopes to add new products soon, such as
   loans for the salaried, fixed asset loans and home improvement loans. It has been urging the RBI to
   treat a microfinance-only branch (which it is willing to open in Dharavi) as fulfilling the requirement
   to open one rural branch for every three urban branches. It would also like to receive a license to open
   a microfinance-only NBFC.

11 The lower cost of SHG loans ( as compared to individual loans) makes it possible for them to be
   extended at rates below the PLR.

12 The name Microsate comes from a plan to open mobile satellite branches, which was later dropped,
   although the name was retained. The branch is the subject of one of the case studies in CMF 2006.

13 Referring to the value placed by the Alliance in Mumbai (SPARC, NSDF and Mahila Milan), on savings,
   for the moral discipline and commitment to the collective that it inculcates, Ruthven 2001 points out
   that the "mixed and complex agendas of urban development organizations can impose transactions
   costs on clients in their attempt to access financial services; it can even contribute to the unreliability
   of a service if more political agendas start to dominate"

14 Several of the statistics in this section are taken from various articles in Intellecap 2007

15 Unlike urban poverty rural poverty is declining both in relative and absolute terms. However the
   number of rural poor is still three times higher than that of the urban poor.

16 See for instance Ghate 1992 and Rutherford and Arora 1997

17 Or what has been called "reciprocal credit" in Ghate 1992.

18 For many migrants, of course, this may turn out to be a good thing. Not all of them join the pool of
   the unemployed, although one theory holds this pool will always exist, and its size will depend on the
   probability of getting a job.

19 Veena Mankar and Lara Gidwani, 2007. This is clearly the case in the older, more settled, slums of
   which there may be a higher proportion in cities growing less rapidly.

20 Many of them have left without repaying. Similar drives appear to be fairly common in other metros
   too, as well as resettlement occasioned by the widening of roads and making space for higher income
   residential neighbourhoods, as in Delhi where Mukherjee describes the snapping of ties between job-
   work suppliers and workers resettled far away (coincidentally, in Holambi Kalan, the large new resettlement
   colony, where Aajivika also operates - see below). We are reminded, interestingly, from his study that
   mobility results also from re-shifting to the original or other neighbourhoods closer to work. (Mukheree,
   RK, 2004).



                                                                                                             99
21 Inter-state migration according to the 2001 census increased by 30 percent over the decade of the
      1990s.The largest in-migration states were Maharashtra (7.9 million) Delhi (5.6 million) and West
      Bengal (5.5 million) (Mukherjee, Piyasree, 2007). Half a million people are said to migrate into
      Mumbai every year, most of them swelling Mumbai's slum population which already accounts for 60
      percent of the total population of about 15 million. An estimate of the annual increment to Delhi's
      slums is 300,000 a year, or 3 percent of the city's population.

  22 She reminds us also that not all of them are poor. An estimate of mobility in the Mumbai occupational
      segments referred to below is that the average period for which an individual stays in the same house
      is 28 months.

  23 The urban poverty line for a household of five is currently Rs 2270 (Chapter 6). According to Ujjivan
      2006, the share of Rs 3000 to Rs 7000 segment was only two-thirds of the 47 percent of the city's
      population below this income class. Arohan appears to reach lower down the Kolkata income distribution,
      with 38 percent of its loans being directed to the 31 percent of borrowers in the two monthly per
      capita expenditure classes below the Rs 700 to Rs 900 class in which its average borrower falls (Arohan
      2007).

  24 Mehta 2007. This recognition is of course not new. It has long been arrived at with respect to rural
      microfinance, and there is no reason why urban practitioners should feel defensive about it. Microfinance
      is ill-suited to solving the problem of chronic income deficits. However it is also the case that there are
      many potential borrowers whose income deficits could be removed by credit, combined usually with
      other inputs. The challenge is to identify such persons and arrange for the provision of the other inputs
      by some other agency if necessary. There is also the question of the level of income at which such
      deficits turn from being usually temporary to becoming permanent. Defining the target group too
      conservatively finesses all these challenges. The method of exclusion used by one urban MFI is to set the
      monthly group savings requirement (referred to as a security deposit, which NBFCs are allowed to
      collect) high enough to be affordable only to the target group.

  25 Having a fixed abode is a much less stringent requirement than owning or renting a house. Indeed as the
      customer satisfaction survey conducted for Arohan (Arohan 2007) says, "in the slum areas there is rarely
      any rent being paid and the people dwelling there are staying since long and hence the accommodation
      pattern is taken as ownership." Those renting constitute 30 percent of the sample. In contrast among
      Ujjivan's members, as many as 40 percent own their accommodation, about 50 percent rent it, and 10
      percent "lease" it (as defined below). Overall, only 61 percent of the urban population own their dwelling
      units as against 93 percent in the rural areas, according to NSS 2001 data.

  26 They point out that while JLG members may be willing to pitch in for fellows when they are experiencing
      temporary cash flow problems, they tend to put their foot down after say three missed monthly
      installments. It is often forgotten that the quality of JLGs themselves varies. Arohan 2007 found that
      of JLG members, only 44 percent could identify all other JLG members by name and purpose of loan
      taken. Seventeen percent could not identify some other JLG members by name, and 33 percent could
      not identify the purpose of the loans taken by some JlG members. Six percent could not identify any
      member by name or loan purpose. The situation varied by branch.

  27 Aajivika tried this, but found that SHG members were unwilling to trust it with their savings unless
      deposited in their name in a bank.




100
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                                        Urban Microfinance




28 In Arohan's case the share of the self-employed is 55 percent. SEWA's very name indicates it is primarily
   for self-employed women.

29 Rag pickers and hawkers were found to have the lowest daily income (Rs 60 and Rs 80 respectively.

30 Interestingly, migrant construction workers were not included, perhaps because in Mumbai construction
   workers are not as visible, as they do not live in temporary colonies next to the building site like those
   in smaller or more spacious cities, but tend to disperse themselves among the neighbouring population.

31 Interestingly, both MFI's educational loans are repayable in 10 monthly installments. VWS' carry a
   lower rate than other loans.

32 As the customer satisfaction survey says "it is noted with pleasure that on the whole the customers are
   satisfied with loan tenure, its rate of interest, the EWI amount, other costs involved, repayment
   modalities and necessary formalities". The rate of interest is presently 30 percent but is planned to be
   reduced to 24 percent. However, 90 percent of customers wanted larger loans and 20 percent fortnightly
   or monthly instead of weekly repayments. Minimum loan size is presently Rs 5000. VWS has chosen the
   middle path and opted for fortnightly meetings and repayments, which gives field workers more time
   for group formation work.

33 Thus in late 2006, SWAWS started making individual loans of between Rs 20,000 to Rs 50,000 at 15
   percent flat, mostly for income generation activities. Loans are disbursed as demand drafts and security
   is taken in the form of post-dated cheques and sureties by guarantors. They still account only for about
   5 to 6 percent of the portfolio but are finding a ready market in new centres such as Coimbatore to which
   SWAWS is expanding. VWS has a similar product, which is appraised by the branch manger instead of
   field staff. Spandana and the other large MFIs have been making individual loans for some time. It
   would be instructive to compare the profitability of individual loans with group loans for a group of
   MFIs. Their unit administration costs should be lower given larger average loan size.

34 It did attempt a closer than arms-length association with SHGs by requiring its own field workers to
   participate in training, and ensuring that proper group records were maintained. Apart from hoping
   to ensure that credit-histories of group members were built up, this was also in keeping with the
   Grameen tradition of monitoring the use of loans in accordance with its stated purpose. By making
   personal loans Ujjivan and other MFIs have released borrowers from the pretense that the loan is being
   used for a "productive" purpose, but it does like to ensure that the loan is being used for the stated
   purpose, whatever that be.

35 See Box 5.5, Chapter 5,on Swayanshree, an SHG federation in Cuttack, which has recently started
   organizing JLGs in addition to its SHGs.

36 Thus Ujjivan has partitioned space off in branch offices for this purpose.

37 Reportedly, there are on an average two cooperative banks in every slum in Mumbai, and the number
   of credit societies operating in Mumbai is one hundred, including 10 in Dharavi (Caitlin, would be
   useful to give the reference here).

38 It will be interesting to see whether the greater sophistication of urban borrowers leads to greater
   transparency on matters such as the effective interest rate.

39 Thus VWS has an OPD centre in each branch with a doctor and generic drugs available at a 60 percent

                                                                                                            101
discount. Fees per visit are Rs 35 for borrowers and Rs 40 for members of the public. The scheme pays
      for itself at a break-even level of 50 patients a day. VWS also has a very popular compulsory health
      insurance scheme with an annual premium of Rs 300 for a family of up to 4 members that includes
      maternity, caesarian and fractures without the need for hospitalization. The scholarships of Rs 100 go
      to students who come first, second, or third in classes 7 to 10. VWS legal form as a S 25 company
      makes it easier to use surpluses for microfinance and charitable activities.

  40 The cards will be able to handle all of the several VWS products. Card holders who pay a one-time
      charge of Rs 50 will be entitled to borrow emergency loans or up to Rs 2000 repayable within 8 weeks.

  41 Especially in the North 24-Parganas just north of the Kolkata municipal area. Incumbent WB MFIs such
      as Bandhan, Village Welfare Society, and Arohan, and at least 4 SIDBI borrowers about to convert to
      NBFC status, have been joined recently by out-of-state MFIs SKS and Ujjivan. In addition, as mentioned
      above, ACCESS Development Services is in the process of incubating 8 MFIs in the inner Kolkata muncipality
      area. Bandhan with an outreach of 4.3 lakhs in January 2007 is by far the largest. Of its 300 odd
      branches 30 are urban of which 13 are in Kolkata proper. VWS had an outreach of 63,000 in March 2007
      with half its portfolio urban. Other MFIs with a presence in the greater Kolkata metropolitan area
      (including Kolkata municipality), are, in approximate order of size, Sahara Utsarg, Kalighat SDF,
      Rakapur SN, Ullon SSW, and HDC. Arohan has started operations in the inner Kolkata municipal area but
      has plans to expand outwards. The consumer satisfaction survey done for Arohan found that 15 to 20
      percent of its borrowers have borrowings from other individuals and institutions, formal and informal,
      including 7 percent from other MFIs. Arohan has a policy of lending to persons who have up to one loan
      from another MFI, but no more. However as Shubhankar Sengupta, the CEO points out, customers are
      not always candid about other loans. In the case of VWS the extent of overlapping was found to be about
      40 percent in one branch. Aiming to build up a presence so strong that it will dissuade competitors from
      entering, VWS has opted for an "intensive" strategy in a limited number of blocks (which could increase
      to 25 from the present 18, in four districts) by covering at least half the target group of poor households
      in each block (or about 10,000 borrowers in each block). On competition in West Bengal, see also the
      article by Chandra Shekhar Ghosh, the CEO of Bandhan (Ghosh 2007). Since Ghosh's article was written,
      WB MFIs have formed an association to coordinate their activities. Also, the DMs have been asked by the
      government to hold a coordination meeting every month.

  42 Janalakshmi and Ujjivan, both plan to grow to a size of about half a million in a few years, as we have
      seen, growing outwards from Bangalore city. Spandana and SKS have also commenced operations in
      the area. Spandana, SWAWS, Basix and Roshan Vikas all operate in Hyderabad. It is interesting that
      SWAWS gives as the reason for dropping Grameen Bank's well known 2:2:1 system, the need to become
      more accommodating with growing competition from Spandana.




102
CHAPTER 5
                                                                                           Urban Microfinance




References


Arohan, 2007, "A Survey and Critical Study on the Customer Satisfaction of the Customers of
Arohan), Report done by Friday Solutions, Kolkata, mimeo

CARE, MSDF and ICICI Bank, 2006, "A Promise to Pay the Bearer: An Exploration of the Potential
for Urban Microfiinance in India", report presented at Microfinance India Conference, October
29 and 30, New Delhi

Centre for Micro Finance (CMF), 2006, "Reaching the Other 100 Million Poor in India"
Microfinance India Conference, report presented at Microfinance India Conference, October
29 and 30, New Delhi

DHAN Foundation, 2005, "Impacting Urban Poverty Through Microfinance: The SPMS
Experience", DHAN Foundation, Madurai.

Ghate, Prabhu, 1992, "Informal Finance: Some Findings from Asia", OUP for ADB, Hong Kong

Ghosh, Chandra Shekhar, 2007, "Challenges of Scaling Up", in Intellecap 2007

Intellecap 2007, "Reaching out to the Poor", special issue of Microfinance Insights, Vol 2,
March, Mumbai

Mankar, Veena, and Lara Gidwani, 2007, "Metro Microfinance: Opportunities and Challenges in
Mumbai", in Intellecap 2007.

Mehta, Aditi, 2001, "Innovating Financial Services Delivery for the Urban Poor", in Intellecap,
2007

Mukherjee, Piyasree, 2007, "Access to Finance:The Barrier to Mobility" in Intellecap, 2007

Mukheree, RK, 2004, "Study of the Demand for Micro Financial Services and Livelihood Promotion
Services in Delhi", conducted for Indian Grameen Services, New Delhi, Mimeo

Pasheva, Vanya and Manasee Desai 2006, in CMF 2006.

Rutheford, Stuart, and Sukhwinder Arora, 1997, City Savers, "How the Poor, DFID, and its
Partners are Promoting Financial Services in Urban India (full reference?)

Ruthven, O, 2001, 'Money Mosaics: Financial Choice and Strategy in a West Delhi Squatter
Settlement", Paper No 32, Working Paper Series, Finance and Development Research Programme,
University of Manchester, also published in Journal of International Development

Also available on http://www.sed.manchester.ac.uk/idpm/publications/fd/fdwp32.pdf

Ujjivan, 2006. "A Study of Economically Active Poor Women in Bangalore -- 2005", Report
done for Ujjivan by Delphi Research Services, Bangalore
                                                                                              103
104
CHAPTER 6
                                                                                            Social performance in
                                                                                            Indian microfinance




                                       CHAPTER 6


 Social performance in Indian
         microfinance
                                                                    Frances Sinha1
For most microfinance institutions (MFIs) and those that work with MFIs (banks, investors,          In this chapter
                                                                                                    we present the
donors) microfinance is a social enterprise. As an enterprise, the organisation is a business
                                                                                                    new perspective
that aims to cover its costs and be financially sustainable. As a social enterprise, the business   on social
is a means to achieving social goals. Different organisations - or models of microfinance -         performance
                                                                                                    that is wider
may articulate some variation in their social goals or mission. Nevertheless, there is agreement    than impact,
that social goals in microfinance generally include serving poor people, serving people otherwise   but at the same
excluded from formal financial services, providing appropriate financial services, contributing     time practical.
                                                                                                    Through
to employment, contributing to positive change for clients and their households, contributing       defining
to poverty reduction and being socially responsible.                                                different
                                                                                                    dimensions of
                                                                                                    social
Financial sustainability is important. An MFI that can cover its costs - has good financial         performance, we
performance - can grow to serve more clients in more areas. The growth in microfinance in           are able to look
India - and elsewhere in the world - is most probably due in large part to mechanisms that are      at ways in
                                                                                                    which MFIs can
financially sustainable, or on track to being sustainable. We have the systems to track financial   themselves
sustainability, with definitions and indicators for reporting on financial performance. These       manage their
                                                                                                    social
are now almost routinely included in the annual reports of MFIs; over 35 MFIs in India report
                                                                                                    performance,
on them to the Microfinance Information eXchange (the MIX);2 and these are the indicators           and identify the
applied in credit ratings.                                                                          indicators that
                                                                                                    are relevant to
                                                                                                    social reporting
On the social side, the reporting is less widespread. We have relied on impact assessments to
provide the main evidence, with the focus on exploring the contribution of microfinance to
various aspects of change. Impact studies are of varying complexity and quality - and their
analysis is sometimes suspect and not readily understood. Though, overall, the evidence
tends to be positive, but nuanced.

In this chapter we present the new perspective on social performance that is wider than
impact, but at the same time practical. Through defining different dimensions of social
performance, we are able to look at ways in which MFIs can themselves manage their social
performance, and identify the indicators that are relevant to social reporting. These indicators
are currently being tested by M-CRIL in its pioneering initiative to develop social rating as a
complementary activity to credit rating - a new form of social performance assessment.

So far, M-CRIL has undertaken seven social ratings in India supported by Friends of Women's
World Banking and the Ford Foundation, and also nine poverty audits supported by SIDBI.
Some of the findings from these social assessments are summarised as part of this chapter. But
first, what do we mean by social performance?
                                                                                                105
Unpacking the concept of social performance
                     A number of international initiatives have come together as part of the Social Performance
                     Task Force3 to reach consensus on the following definition of social performance. Social
                     performance in microfinance is defined as "the translation of mission into practice in line
                     with accepted social goals": These social goals relate to
                            •        reaching poor or excluded clients
                            •        improving the quality and appropriateness of financial services
                            •        contributing to employment and enterprise growth
            Social
 performance is             •        improving the economic and social conditions of clients and their households
    not only the            •        and ensuring social responsibility to clients, to staff and to the communities in
 end result, but
       the entire                    which they work
       process of
 achieving that      Under this definition, impact, which refers to changes in the conditions of clients or the
 result. As such     community that can be attributed to the microfinance programme, is just one aspect of social
the focus shifts
  from trying to     performance. Social performance is not only the end result, but the entire process of achieving
    prove an end     that result. As such the focus shifts from trying to prove an end result to looking at the steps
         result to
                     to get there, and managing and reporting on those steps that are likely to lead to positive
  looking at the
    steps to get     social outcomes. Box 6.1 shows the different steps involved.
             there


                                            Box 6.1     Dimensions of Social Performance

                                                            INTENT AND DESIGN
                                                  What is the mission of the institution?
                                         Does it have clear social objectives based on its mission?
                                Do its objectives include formulation of principles of social responsibility?



                                                 INTERNAL SYSTEMS & OPERATIONS
                                   Are systems designed and in place to achieve those objectives?
                        Does the institution have information to track performance towards those objectives?



                                                                 OUTPUTS
                                    Who does the institution serve? Is it reaching intended clients?
                                                        Is it serving poor people?
                                    Are the financial services catering to their needs and capacities?



                                                            OUTCOMES
                         Have clients and their households experienced social and economic improvements?

                                                                     OR

                                                              IMPACT
                                    Can these improvements be attributed to institutional activities?

                                                                                   [C-GAP, 2007, and Sinha, Frances, 2006]


               106
CHAPTER 6
                                                                                              Social performance in
                                                                                              Indian microfinance




•   Social performance starts with analysis of the declared social objectives of institutions
    (intent and design).
    •    Does the institution have a social mission and, whatever the social missions may be,
         are social goals clearly defined and articulated to conform to the social mission?
•   Social performance includes assessment of internal systems and operations.
    •    Are systems and operations aligned to mission and achievement of social goals?
    •    Is progress towards these goals being tracked?
•   Social performance includes social responsibility:
    •    Does the institution have a policy on social responsibility - to clients, staff,
         community and the environment?
    •    Are there systems in place to ensure compliance?
•   Social performance is about outputs.
    •    Is the institution reaching large numbers of poor? excluded or marginal people? ...the basic
    •    Do products cater to the needs and capacities of intended clients?              principle of SPM
                                                                                                     is that social
•   Social performance is also about outcomes-are clients improving their social and economic        benefits are
    conditions, for themselves and for their families?                                               more likely to
•   And finally social performance is indeed about impact; exploring causality between               happen if an
                                                                                                     MFI deliberately
    programme participation and changes in the conditions of clients and their households.           manages the
                                                                                                     process towards
Towards social performance management by MFIs                                                        achieving them


Most MFIs have a social mission. Putting that mission into practice - doing so in a systematic
way - is what social performance management (SPM) is about. Social benefits may result from
microfinance interventions. But the basic principle of SPM is that social benefits are more
likely to happen if an MFI deliberately manages the process towards achieving them. As part
of routine financial performance management, an institution defines its organisational and
financial targets, and puts systems in place to build efficiency and portfolio quality with
regular monitoring, tracking and reporting on key indicators and ratios. A similar process can
contribute to social performance management, a process which involves clarifying social goals
and objectives, defining social responsibility principles, aligning strategies and systems to
achieve those goals, strengthening the information system to monitor and assess progress
and compliance, and using this information to improve performance.

The process of starting SPM involves a set of core performance questions:


    •    Are you clear about: what type of areas you aim to work in? who are your target
         clients? how do you define your target clients?
    •    Do you know whether you are reaching your target clients?
    •    Do you monitor and understand whether your services are appropriate to your target
         clients?
    •    Do you monitor how long clients stay with your programme?
    •    Do you monitor and understand why some clients leave or become inactive?
    •    Do you use this information to improve your services?
    •    Do you have clear policies and systems for social responsibility - especially to clients?
         And also social responsibility to staff, local communities and the environment?
    •    Can you improve the systems and processes through which you answer these
         questions?

                                                                                                 107
These questions look ambitious. They raise additional questions of definition, and tools - and
                     how to address them cost-effectively. For example, many MFIs mention the 'poor' as their
                     target group. How then to define 'poor', and measure poverty levels? Similarly, many clients
                     may be leaving, but how to track the drop-out rate? What are the key elements of social
                     responsibility relevant to MFIs?

                     These are areas that are now receiving technical attention. It took ten years (yes ten!) to
                     reach a level of consensus on financial indicators, definitions and reporting systems. We are
                     in the start-up phase for social reporting. And there is a lot of interesting work going on.
                     Some of it is happening here in India, and part of this new area of social assessment is M-
                     CRIL's pioneering of a methodology for social rating.


                     A new form of social assessment - social rating
These questions      The development of a social rating methodology has the potential to contribute to four
 look ambitious.     important goals in microfinance:
       They raise
       additional
     questions of         •     assist microfinance institutions to identify both whether they are achieving their
  definition, and               social mission and the institutional factors that may be facilitating or hindering
 tools - and how
                                achieving this target;
to address them
cost-effectively.         •     assist potential investors and donors in their review of microfinance institutions as
    For example,
       many MFIs
                                part of their monitoring and due diligence processes;
     mention the          •     increase the transparency of the microfinance field; and
   'poor' as their
    target group.         •     if adopted widely, establish social performance as equally important as financial
     How then to                sustainability in microfinance.
    define 'poor',
     and measure
  poverty levels?    A social rating aims to be a relatively quick, low cost assessment, similar to credit rating. As in
 Similarly, many     credit rating, the social rating uses information available with the MFI to the extent possible,
  clients may be     drawing on available documentation and data, and discussions with staff at all levels. It
     leaving, but
     how to track    covers both the process (intent, policies, design, systems) and part of the results (outreach
     the drop-out    and appropriate services) along the dimensions of social performance as outlined in Figure 1.
            rate?
                     A social rating is not an impact assessment. That is a more complex exercise. But if there is
                     information on impact - or outcomes, and the information is robust, then the social rating
                     can report on the impact findings.

                                              Fig 6.1 Assessing social performance




                              [------------------PROCESS-----------------]       [------------------RESULTS----

                                                                Social Rating
                                                                                                         [C-GAP,


                108
CHAPTER 6
                                                                                           Social performance in
                                                                                           Indian microfinance




How do we obtain information on the outputs, to understand: who the clients are? do
they match the MFI's target group? are the financial services appropriate? Most MFIs do
not have this information (some may, , if they are implementing social performance
management). So as to obtain direct client-level information about outreach to target
groups and feedback on services provided, M-CRIL includes as part of the social rating
exercise a small field survey, covering a sample of recent clients (to capture outreach
profile on entry) and FGDs with older clients (for market feedback on MFI services). The
field-work is undertaken in 3-5 clusters selected as representative of the MFI's current
operations. The social rating sample covers a minimum of 127 clients from an average of
four clusters. 127 is the minimum statistical level which gives a confidence level of 95%
and precision of +/-10%.4 A larger sample size might be preferred, and can be done, but
would take more time and cost more!

A social rating aims to cover all the dimensions up to outcomes/impact. In covering the           A social rating
                                                                                                  aims to cover all
steps of the process that lead to impact, the social rating can be seen as a good predictor of
                                                                                                  the dimensions
impact, an assessment of whether the MFI is on track to achieve its social goals. Or, in rating   up to outcomes/
terminology, it is an assessment of the risk of non-achievement - or mission drift.               impact. In
                                                                                                  covering the
                                                                                                  steps of the
Findings - social ratings and poverty audits                                                      process that
                                                                                                  lead to impact,
                                                                                                  the social rating
Key findings from the seven social ratings undertaken so far in India, with support from FWWB     can be seen as a
and the Ford Foundation, are summarised here, supplemented by additional information from         good predictor
                                                                                                  of impact, an
a number of poverty audits undertaken with support from SIDBI. The social rating exercise,
                                                                                                  assessment of
including the field work requires a team working up to 8-10 days with the MFI and in the          whether the MFI
field. The poverty audit was a quicker exercise, carried out over 3-5 days, with less detailed    is on track to
                                                                                                  achieve its
review of MFI systems, and client profiling based on FGDs with a smaller sample (therefore less   social goals. Or,
robust than those from the social ratings). The presentation broadly follows the dimensions of    in rating
social performance (as outlined in Figure 1), covering process (intent and design, systems)       terminology, it
                                                                                                  is an
and results (outputs - outreach and appropriate services).                                        assessment of
                                                                                                  the risk of non-
                                                                                                  achievement -
                                                                                                  or mission drift
Twelve MFIs
We have social performance data from twelve MFIs,                   MFIs covered:
eight from the south, four from the north. These         Social Rating      Poverty Audit
MFIs are quite representative of MFIs in the country:
                                                         South:
five follow the Grameen model, three the SHG model,
                                                          BWDA              ASA
three are Cooperatives (MACS) and one follows the
                                                          ASP               SKS
individual model. The data is mainly from 2006.
                                                          BASIX             PWMACS
The 12 MFIs together represent over 1 million             AMMACTS
microfinance clients.                                     SWAWS
                                                         North:
                                                          Cashpor           RGVN
                                                          Bandhan           NBJK




                                                                                              109
Institutional processes as part of social performance
                    Intent and Design

                    The mission statements of the twelve MFIs include reference to:

                         •    serving the poor and vulnerable (10 MFIs)
                         •    enhancing community capacities (4)
                         •    women's empowerment (4)
                         •    improved livelihoods (2)
                         •    poverty reduction (2)
                         •    quality services (2)

Accordingly, the    Whilst the overall orientation is usually clear, the meaning of key terms is not so clear and is not
   mission is no
    more than a
                    usually defined by the MFIs. For example, who is 'poor'?, in what way will community capacities be
       rhetorical   enhanced? what counts as women's 'empowerment'? what counts as poverty reduction? Accordingly,
   statement or     the mission is no more than a rhetorical statement or wish; it is not translated into social
 wish; it is not
 translated into    objectives that are the first step to putting mission into practice, objectives that are SMART
           social   (specific, measurable, adequate, relevant, time-bound) and strategic (what leads to what).
objectives that
    are the first
                    Out of twelve MFIs, three had clear definition of key terms (poor, vulnerable social groups,
step to putting
    mission into    improved livelihoods). One of the three had gone further to develop SMART social objectives.
        practice,
objectives that     Governance appeared fairly well balanced in terms of financial and social experience and
      are SMART
       (specific,   orientation, but reporting remains primarily financial - both within the organisation, and
     measurable,    externally, in for example annual reports.
      adequate,
 relevant, time-
                    Services and access
     bound) and
strategic (what
 leads to what)     The range of services include general/enterprise loans starting at Rs2-5,000, some larger
                    (individual) loans (Rs15,000-30,000) including in the MACS and SHG model MFIs. Along with
                    credit, loan insurance and savings (or security deposits) are compulsory in 8 of the 12 MFIs.
                    A few MFIs offer additional loans: an education loan of Rs1-10,000, emergency loan Rs500-
                    1,000, and offer insurance products (with linkages to formal sector insurance companies
                    mainly for life and health). A few also offer non-financial services, directly, or through linkages
                    to other providers - services such as agricultural/business development support, health and
                    education as part of community development, gender training, a school. Access to such
                    services is quite low, usually under 10%.


                                                     Additional MFI services
                              Services                 Number of MFIs providing             % clients accessing
                                                                                                 (prev yr)


                    Education loan                                  1                                 3%
                    Emergency loan                                  1                               <0.1%
                    Life/medical other insurance                    7                               <20%
                    Non-financial services                          5                             6% - 30%



               110
CHAPTER 6
                                                                                               Social performance in
                                                                                               Indian microfinance




Internal systems

The conceptual framework for social performance includes an analysis of operational systems
to see whether they support the mission - in particular, targeting strategy, staff training and
incentives, and systems for MIS, monitoring and reporting.

In terms of targeting, the main approach is area targeting. MFIs may select less developed
states and less developed regions within states, and slum or low income areas in cities. One
MFI also strategically targets poor clients and monitors poverty profile at entry. Another
targets SC/ST and backward castes. Some MFIs are beginning to cater to different market
segments (with Joint Liability Groups, often men, alongside SHGs, and at different income
levels), though without specifically planning for what proportion of their clients (or portfolio)
should be from different segments.

In relation to human resources - orientation and incentives - the mission and values are usually       In terms of
part of staff induction. But in practice, the main emphasis is on financial management and             targeting, the
                                                                                                       main approach
growth, as reflected in incentive systems that emphasis productivity (client numbers) and on-          is area
time repayment. Though one MFI includes an incentive linked to coverage of poorer clients.             targeting. MFIs
                                                                                                       may select less
In terms of monitoring and MIS, there is substantial scope for MFIs to strengthen their                developed
                                                                                                       states and less
routine data collection and analyzing portfolio information from a social perspective. Many            developed
have interesting information fields relevant to client profiling in their loan appraisal formats       regions within
                                                                                                       states, and
but this is not being completed systematically or used for tracking outreach or market segments        slum or low
(except by one MFI). Portfolio information can be analysed not only to track growth and                income areas in
arrears, but to track client retention over time, how many stay for how many loan cycles, what         cities. One MFI
                                                                                                       also
is the dropout rate, what differences are there for rural and urban clients, or for women and          strategically
men clients (if an MFI has both). A few MFIs have started applying or have commissioned                targets poor
                                                                                                       clients and
market research surveys, though most rely on informal feedback from staff.
                                                                                                       monitors
                                                                                                       poverty profile
Results - Outreach                                                                                     at entry

Areas

For information on outreach, we first look at areas of operation, including rural/urban distribution
and analysing the district (branch) distribution of clients with reference to development ranking
of districts in the country. Based on data from the 2001 Census, the 593 districts in the country
are divided into development quintiles based on literacy rates, as a proxy for development level.
Overall, in the sample, MFI outreach is proportionate (with 20% in the bottom district quintile,
41% in the lowest two district quintiles). The five-six MFIs with no clients in the lower district
quintiles are located in the southern states. The majority of MFIs have mainly rural clients.
Rural/urban classification is usually based on administrative definitions.

                MFI outreach - rural and less developed districts
% of clients:                            0          <20%        21-55%        >55%        Average

- in bottom district quintile            6            2            3            1           20%
- in two lowest district quintiles       5                         3            4           41%
- rural                                  1                         1            10          69%


                                                                                                    111
Beyond this broad (rural/urban) classification, it would be interesting to capture extent of
                     outreach in semi-urban/semi-rural areas. This would cover market town areas as a separate
                     category (from rural) - with different implications for livelihoods, appropriate products and
                     MFI costs of operations.

                     Reaching the unreached (financial inclusion)

                 Secondly we seek information to understand whether the MFI is serving the poor and excluded.
                 To obtain this information we undertake a small field survey of recent clients (noted above),
                 i.e. clients who have recently joined the MFI (within one year) so as to capture their profile
                 on entry (before the likelihood of change). The sample size averaged 152/social rating and
      To capture
   exclusion, we 48/poverty audit. The total sample for 12 MFIs is 1,306.
analyse whether
clients are from     To capture exclusion, we analyse whether clients are from vulnerable communities (such as SC/
       vulnerable
                     ST) or from households without alternative access to formal or semi-formal finance. From the
    communities
(such as SC/ST)      rating sample, we find that most MFIs have a proportion of SC/ST above the national average,
          or from    reflecting substantial outreach to these communities. Interestingly, though, we find that not
       households
          without    all client households have been excluded from formal financial services. On average 26% have
      alternative    a bank or post office savings account; 12% have had a bank loan in the previous three years.
access to formal
                     This compares with the 36% national figure. And 6% of client households have members in
  or semi-formal
   finance. From     another MFI, or an SHG (with this figure higher for southern MFIs.
       the rating
sample, we find                                     Reaching the unreached
 that most MFIs
           have a    % of recent client households              Range       Average       All India populationa
    proportion of
     SC/ST above     SC/ST                                   15% - 57%        33%                  25%
     the national
         average,    With savings in bank or post office     14% - 39%        26%                  36%
        reflecting
      substantial    With bank loan in previous 3 years       2% - 21%        12%
      outreach to
             these   With client in other MFI or SHG          2% - 13%         6%
    communities      a
                         Census of India, 2001


                     A key question is poverty outreach. As we have seen, all the MFIs have a mission to serve the
                     poor. How many clients are poor when they join? And how do we define poverty? A useful
                     benchmark is the poverty line, the $1/day at purchasing power parity (PPP) which, currently
                     at Rs17.5/day or Rs524/person/month is just above the Indian poverty line (Rs395/person/
                     month rural, Rs454 urban).5 The social rating questionnaire includes two pages to estimate
                     client household income in detail, from which the per capita per day figure can be calculated.
                     Alternatively, and more easily, a poverty score card has now been developed for India.6 We
                     have used both methods, to find poverty levels mostly at or less than the estimated poverty
                     rate in the country.

                     Outreach to those below $1/day varies substantially around the average, which at 30% is
                     slightly below the All India poverty incidence. Most of the MFIs rated are below the average.
                     One MFI with a strong strategic focus on poverty outreach has 68% of its clients below the
                     poverty line when they joined the programme.




                112
CHAPTER 6
                                                                                                  Social performance in
                                                                                                  Indian microfinance




 Serving the poor

 % of recent client households                Range        Average           All India populationa

 < $1/day at PPP                            13% - 68%           30%                  39%
 a
     NSSO, 2005


 These figures are pause for thought. Is this the depth of outreach intended for microfinance?
 By MFIs whose stated mission is to serve the poor and contribute to poverty reduction? Are
 there elements in their operations which need strategic review, so as to align with a deeper
 poverty focus?

 Microfinance and women

 The majority of MFI clients are women, with eight MFIs working only with women clients. The            Outreach to
 balance in staff is skewed to men, due partly to issues of field mobility, especially in the           those below
                                                                                                        $1/day varies
 northern states. Two MFIs have less than 10% staff who are women, including one in the south.          substantially
                                                                                                        around the
                          Women as clients and staff of MFIs                                            average, which
                                                                                                        at 30% is
                                 <50             51-99%                100%              Average        slightly below
                                                                                                        the All India
 % women clients                  1                   3                  8                  86%         poverty
                                                                                                        incidence. Most
 % women staff                   10                   2                                     32%         of the MFIs
                                                                                                        rated are below
                                                                                                        the average.
 Gender related indicators, beyond the number of women, relate to women's schooling at leat             One MFI with a
                                                                                                        strong strategic
 up to primary (which at 35% on average can affect awareness and understanding of MFI
                                                                                                        focus on
 information and services), whether the household is woman headed (which is an indicator of             poverty
 poverty especially if there are no adult male earners in the family), and women clients' involvement   outreach has
                                                                                                        68% of its
 in managing an enterprise for which they have taken a loan. On average, just over one in five          clients below
 women clients manage by themselves the enterprise for which they take credit, another 40%              the poverty line
 manage jointly with a husband or son, and a similar percentage pass the loan to a male                 when they
                                                                                                        joined the
 relative. This has implications for women's empowerment. In one MFI, working with urban                programme.
 women, women's independent enterprise activity was the highest (over 70%).                             These figures
                                                                                                        are pause for
                                                                                                        thought. Is this
                               Gender related indicators
                                                                                                        the depth of
                                                                                                        outreach
% of recent women clients                                             Range            Average
                                                                                                        intended for
                                                                                                        microfinance?
Have completed primary school or above                            14% - 63%                35%
Are women heads of households with no adult male earner           3% - 10%                 4%
Manage credit supported enterprise:
                                             Yes - by herself     12% -72%                 22%
                            Yes - jointly with husband/son        25% - 44%                40%
                   No - husband/son manages (loan pass)           3% - 45%                 38%




                                                                                                     113
Microfinance and employment (indirect outreach)

                      Additional profile information from the rating survey relates to employment or 'indirect' outreach.
                      The majority of enterprises supported by microfinance are usually family based micro-enterprises,
                      providing self-employment to family members. If hired labour is employed in an enterprise,
                      micro-credit can be seen to be supporting employment for others who are not direct MFI
                      clients - and may be of a lower income category. This is likely for larger micro-enterprises or
                 'small enterprises'. In five MFIs for which we have this information, an average 8% of enterprises
The findings are with credit have employed non-family labour, with an average employed of 2.4.
 that clients are
mostly aware of                          Employment in credit supported enterprises
     the notional
       interest on                                                                    Range [5 MFIs]         Average
         loans and
           interest   % supported enterprises with hired (non-family)                    3% - 11%               8%
    receivable on     employees
            savings
          deposits    Average number of hired employees in such enterprises               1.6 - 3.7             2.4
     (though in a
   couple of MFIs
     awareness is     Results - Appropriate Services
   60% or less).
      Few clients     The first set of questions under appropriate services, relates to client awareness of the financial
    (around half)
  on average are      products and terms of the MFI. This is a key element of social responsibility to clients,
     aware of the     reflecting effective communication and transparency. These questions are covered as part of
 details of costs
                      the rating survey, with reference to each MFI's specific services, and the responses are quantified.
     (interest on
 declining basis,     The findings are that clients are mostly aware of the notional interest on loans and interest
break-up of loan      receivable on savings deposits (though in a couple of MFIs awareness is 60% or less). Few
 fees), and loan
insurance (what       clients (around half) on average are aware of the details of costs (interest on declining basis,
      is covered)     break-up of loan fees), and loan insurance (what is covered).

                                             Client awareness of financial services
                      % who know                                                           Range             Average

                      Notional interest on credit and repayment instalments             60% - 98%              78%
                      Interest on savings deposits                                      55% - 91%              77%
                      More details of costs (EIR, declining interest, break-up of       31% - 90%              52%
                      loan fees)
                      Details of loan insurance                                         30% - 89%              49%




                114
CHAPTER 6
                                                                                          Social performance in
                                                                                          Indian microfinance




Client feedback is obtained through Focus Group Discussions with older clients. This provides
both positive feedback, and some suggestions to the MFI.


Examples of client feedback on MFI services
(from FGDs)
Clients like
    •    timely credit, without collateral
    •    savings - where available - no other option for saving small amounts
    •    discipline of weekly repayments (mainly non-farm enterprises, in market centres)
    •    convenient repayment in instalments
    •    grace period (1 MFI): 46 payments over one year
    •    lower interest rate than moneylenders

Clients would like
    •    loan products for other credit needs (education)
    •    larger loans, compare cost of dairy animal Rs7-15,000); also demand from better-off
         clients (around 10% of clients interviewed), urban clients
    •    Monthly loan instalments - rural
    •    Loan insurance to cover husband's death too (in case of women clients)
    •    Avoid high up-front security deposit.



A strong indicator of client satisfaction or appropriateness of services is the rate of exit, A strong
                                                                                                 indicator of
particularly dropout. Of course, some clients who leave may be 'fly-outs' who no longer need
                                                                                                 client
microfinance, or may be able to graduate to a formal service. But many who leave (as studies     satisfaction or
have shown) do so because the microfinance services do not match their requirements, for         appropriateness
                                                                                                 of services is
reasons of dissatisfaction, problems with repayment, other financial difficulties. The annual    the rate of exit,
dropout rate overall can be estimated from the loan portfolio, based on the number of clients    particularly
                                                                                                 dropout
at the end of the previous year, the number of new clients who joined during the year and the
total number of clients at the end of the year.7

The data shows higher rates of exit compared to figures from 2002-3 of around 4-6% (M-CRIL
data). Where MFIs are growing very fast, the large number of new clients in the year may mask
the rate of dropout (just as high disbursement of portfolio can mask the portfolio at risk).

                                        Client exit
                                                                 Range            Average

Dropout rate                                                   5% - 17%             11%


Additional analysis would ideally include dropout rate by time with the MFI (or by loan cycle)
and by other client characteristics (poverty, social group). In future, we aim too to track
client retention in terms of those who stay with the MFI for a certain period of time, say at
least three years, or five years - which may be the minimum time within which to achieve

                                                                                             115
change, or sustainable impact. Less than this is probably not long enough for substantial
                    change, at least in terms of poverty reduction (provided, that is, it is not the poorer clients
                    who have dropped out of the programme).


                    Future directions
       The social   The social rating tool has been under development. Its full form has now evolved in line with
 rating tool has    the understanding of what social performance is, and what are the key indicators of achieving
      been under
   development.     social performance. It therefore now includes, for example, more details of social responsibility:
Its full form has   whether MFIs are putting into practice key elements of the Code of Conduct towards clients,
 now evolved in
   line with the
                    recently framed by Sa-Dhan.
  understanding
  of what social    The selected findings presented here are an example of social performance assessment, related
 performance is,    to indicators that it is hoped MFIs will increasingly be able and willing to report on. And refer
   and what are
          the key   to as part of an internal system for social performance management.
    indicators of
achieving social    They are indicators that are covered as part of a social rating. This does not go as far as to try
     performance
                    to assess impact. But the social rating presents a range of information that is relevant to
                    achieving mission and contributing social value. It is therefore a good predictor of impact,
                    and an exercise which is faster and cheaper than impact assessment.




               116
CHAPTER 6
                                                                                                      Social performance in
                                                                                                      Indian microfinance




Endnotes


1 I would like to thank my colleagues in EDA and M-CRIL, past and present, who have worked on the
   social ratings and poverty audits that provide the material for this chapter. Particularly, Monika
   Agarwal, LB Prakash, Amit Brar, Komal P Rana, Nishant Tirath and Sudipto Saha.

2 The MIX Market is the global microfinance information marketplace, providing financial data and
   profiles on microfinance institutions and the microfinance sector on the Internet, at http://
   www.themix.org.

3 For more information, please visit http://www.microfinancegateway.org/resource_centers/
   socialperformance/

4 See EDA Technical note: Estimating Sample Size which explains the sampling formula. A larger sample
   of 340, or 510, would improve precision to +/- 5%.

5 Updated to 2006 based on relevant CPIs agricultural labourers and industrial manual labourers, from
   World Bank estimates of purchasing power parity for the international poverty line (SEEP, Sillers
   Donald 2006), and the Deaton adjusted national poverty line, (in Schreiner, 2007)

6 Schreiner, Mark, 2007. The scorecard has 10 relatively simple questions which can be easily answered/
   observed about a household without much calculation or judgement. The indicators are: number of
   children under 17 years, whether house is pucca, whether own a TV, electric fans, almirah, sewing
   machine, pressure pan, land, primary energy source for cooking, number of acres of land, principal
   income source for the household . The answers to these questions are scored for their 'poverty
   probability', with the scores derived from statistical regression of NSSO data. The scores can be linked
   to any poverty line. For India, they are linked to the international poverty lines - $1 and $2/day. The
   poverty score card thus provides a simple but statistically robust method for measuring poverty levels.

7 M-CRIL applies the following formula:

   (Number of clients at beginning of year + New clients during the year - Number of clients at end of
   year)/ (Number of clients at beginning of year + New clients during the year)

   A 'dropout' or client who exits is defined as: 'any client who has had not transaction with the MFI for
   the previous six months'. See M-CRIL Technical Note: Estimating Exit Rate




                                                                                                          117
References


  C-GAP, 2007, “Beyond Good Intentions: Measuring the Social Performance of Microfinance
  Institutions”, Focus Note Number 41, Washington DC

  Census of India, 2001, Population Tables, Government of India

  NSSO, 2005, National Sample Survey Organisation, Household Consumer Expenditure in India:
  NSS 59th Round, January-December 2003. Report No. 490, Ministry of Statistics and Programme
  Implementation, Government of India

  Schreiner, Mark, 2007, “Is one poverty score card enough for India?” Washington DC See
  http://www.microfinance.com/English/Papers/

  Sinha, Frances, 2006, “Social Rating and Social Performance Reporting in Microfinance: Towards
  a Common Framework”, SEEP Occasional Paper, Washington DC




118
CHAPTER 7
                                                                                            Micro Insurance




                                       CHAPTER 7


                      Micro Insurance
                                                                 Sai Gunaranjan1

The importance of micro insurance for the poor as a tool to
protect livelihoods
Financial inclusion of the poor by providing them with access to savings, credit and insurance In the absence
forms an integral part of the package of livelihood promotion services that the poor require. of proper risk
                                                                                                    hedging
While a diverse set of both formal and informal institutions have evolved to cater to the mechanisms like
savings and credit needs of the poor, there is still a huge gap with respect to insurance insurance, the
                                                                                                    poor stand to
services available for the poor. It is also well understood that the vulnerability to various risks
                                                                                                    loose their
is highest for the poor. In the absence of proper risk hedging mechanisms like insurance, the wages, borrow,
poor stand to loose their wages, borrow, liquidate their assets, migrate and face several other liquidate their
                                                                                                    assets, migrate
hardships, which in turn only traps them into a deeper and vicious cycle of poverty. With the       and face several
increasing prevalence of nuclear families, the informal support system of the joint family too      other hardships,
                                                                                                    which in turn
is unavailable for most people today. The penetration of the formal insurance sector is very
                                                                                                    only traps them
low today. Estimates put that less than 15% of the country's population is insured. The             into a deeper
challenge for providing a whole of range of insurance products to cover the risks related to        and vicious
                                                                                                    cycle of poverty
both lives and livelihood generating assets of the poor is huge. However, the current situation
is also seen as an opportunity by many players in the insurance industry, to expand and
deepen the insurance market in India. MFIs have made major strides to improve the access to
credit and savings for the poor. It is imperative for micro finance institutions to seize the
moment by actively providing micro insurance services for the poor and thereby contribute to
achieving comprehensive financial inclusion of the poor.

Issues related to the growth of micro insurance
The rapid growth of the micro-credit movement in terms of scale has tempted many to expect
a similar growth in micro-insurance. To the extent that micro insurance has grown today, a
large chunk of it comprises credit life insurance which is automatically bundled with micro-
credit. However providing insurance as a stand alone product for the poor has not been as
easy. The reason for this contrast is not difficult to ascertain. Micro credit is largely a pull
product (demand driven) whereas micro insurance or any insurance for that matter is a push
product which requires significant marketing and sales effort to enrol customers. This transition
from selling a pull product to a push product has not been easy for micro credit institutions.
To enable this transition, one needs to look at a whole range of issues including capacity
building of staff and incentive structures for the staff of micro credit institutions. However,
the growth issues of micro insurance are not limited to the distributions channels such as

                                                                                                119
MFIs alone; they encompass other stake holders like insurance companies and their ability to
                     provide suitable micro insurance products and service them.

                     Another issue which has to be addressed to promote micro insurance is the sustainability of
                     such programs. The micro credit movement has grown with a strong focus on sustainability of
                 the program to ensure scalability of the models. This has meant that institutions charged
                 interest rates that covered both the cost of capital and cost of operations. In the overall
                 analysis the interest rates charged by these institutions were viable for customers due to the
                 customisation of credit products and the hassle free lending procedures adopted. However
    the focus on the focus on sustainability of insurance products has not received as much attention as
  sustainability required by MFIs. This situation is partly due to the fact that the actuarial science involved
     of insurance
     products has    in pricing of insurance products may not be too well understood by MFIs. Therefore there is a
 not received as     temptation on their part to bargain for rock bottom premium rates from insurance companies,
 much attention
  as required by
                     without taking into consideration all the costs that may involved. This can seriously compromise
        MFIs. This   the sustainability and continuity of such products. Currently MFIs may not feel the pinch of
      situation is   such products as they do not underwrite the risk, and given the current market scenario where
    partly due to
   the fact that     several new insurers are trying to get a foothold in the market, there is always another insurer
    the actuarial    who may be willing to underwrite for a brief period such unsustainable products. The advantage
science involved
                     of meeting rural and social sector obligations in a quick manner with such under priced
     in pricing of
         insurance   products may more than offset the loss making micro risks that an insurer underwrites. The
    products may     answer to this problem is the need for MFIs to work towards building internal capacities to
 not be too well
   understood by     understand and provide sustainable micro insurance products, as they have done in the area
              MFIs   of micro credit.

                     Challenges to be overcome to achieve sustainable and scalable
                     micro-insurance models
                     Creating actuarial data for micro-insurance, rather than searching for actuarial
                     data to get micro insurance started

                     Most poor people have not had access to insurance in the past as in the present. This translates
                     into absence of data regarding frequencies of various risks faced by them. In the absence of
                     this data, insurance companies are often constrained in their ability to offer products, as the
                     availability of historical data is critical to the design of insurance products. This perpetuates
                     the problem of making insurance products available to the poor. To break the deadlock,
                     insurance companies should be willing to introduce products even in the absence of adequate
                     actuarial data. The incentives for doing this would be:




                            1.     It would help to build data on various risks for this segment of the market,
                                   which is huge. This data, and coupled with it the experience in administering
                                   micro insurance policies, would serve as an asset for the insurance companies in
                                   expand their penetration of the huge and untapped rural market.

                            2.     The marginal error in pricing micro insurance policies in the absence of historical
                                   data would not seriously affect the insurance companies as the financial value
                                   of risk in micro insurance policies is very marginal compared to the traditional


                120
CHAPTER 7
                                                                                              Micro Insurance




              high value insurance contracts underwritten by insurance companies. This
              marginal risk too can be mitigated by taking a conservative approach to pricing
              of the micro insurance policies in the inception years and then reviewing the
              price, based on actual claims experience in subsequent years.

       3.     Global reinsurers are also beginning to recognise the potential of micro insurance,
              in order to expand the overall insurance market size. Munich Re and Swiss Re are
              examples of Global reinsurers who have been actively studying and promoting
              micro insurance in the Indian insurance market. The willingness and the interest
              of these re-insurers provide an opportunity to local insurance companies to
              enter the micro insurance market, by ceding a portion of micro insurance risks
              to global reinsurers. The reinsurers would be in a better position to absorb the
              risks from micro insurance programs where the market experience is still in a
              very nascent stage.

      Box 7.1      Providing sustainable and competitive insurance products
                                 to rural customers
BASIX, a livelihood promotion institution set up in 1996, provides both financial and technical
assistance services to about half a million households spread over 8 states in India. In October
2002, it began its initiative to provide life insurance cover to customers who took micro
credit. BASIX took a group policy from AVIVA which covered its borrower for 1.5 times of the
loan amount taken by him or her during the loan tenor. In the absence of any past experience
of mortality for the customer profile served by BASIX, AVIVA priced the product conservatively
at Rs.8.61per thousand sum insured. By October of 2004, the experience of covering more
than 50,000 person years was completed. The positive performance of the product by this
stage allowed the insurance company to lower the premium rate to Rs.6.89 per thousand sum
insured. A year later in 2005, over 100,000 person years were covered cumulatively. The claims
experience gained till then allowed the insurance company to reduce the premium rate to
Rs.3.98 per thousand sum insured. Based on the actual performance of the product, BASIX
and AVIVA could reduce the premium rate by more than 50% in a three year period. This
further allowed BASIX to extend cover to the spouses of the borrowers, as the premium was
much more affordable now. This experience proves that a sustainable approach to pricing of
micro insurance, combined with proper administration of the products, allows the partners to
                                                                                                      A major
add value to the small premiums paid by its customers.                                                roadblock for
                                                                                                      rolling out
                                                                                                      insurance
Rationalising underwriting procedures for micro-insurance to make it accessible to                    products for the
target clients                                                                                        poor has been
                                                                                                      the gap
                                                                                                      between
A major roadblock for rolling out insurance products for the poor has been the gap between            expectations of
expectations of insurance companies about completing a certain kind of paperwork for issuing          insurance
insurance contracts, and what the poor can actually provide. The poor and especially those in         companies
                                                                                                      about
the rural areas are in a disadvantaged position in terms of their ability to access hospitals,        completing a
schools and various public utility service providers. The certificates issued by these institutions   certain kind of
                                                                                                      paperwork for
often serve as proofs for establishing identity and also age to be considered for an insurance
                                                                                                      issuing
contract. In such scenarios, as in the case of BASIX, the micro insurance service providers           insurance
have worked with the insurance companies to accept alternative age proofs like declaration of         contracts, and
                                                                                                      what the poor
age by community members like SHGs, or even declaration by the individual or the household            can actually
itself as sufficient for the purpose of extending insurance. This has helped in extending             provide

                                                                                                  121
insurance to individuals who would not have otherwise been insured due to non-availability
                      of formal certificates of age and residence.

                      In the area of health insurance, traditionally, insurance companies have required that a hospital
                      should have at least ten beds to allow policy holders to qualify for re-imbursement of expenses.
                      However, most hospitals in rural areas do not have this kind of infrastructure. Therefore to
                      allow customers to take treatment at rural hospitals, the policy conditions have been simplified
                      in health insurance policies so that customers can get admitted and treated at any registered
                      hospital, even if it does not have the mandatory ten bed infrastructure. This kind of flexibility
                      in re-looking at traditional procedures in administering insurance policies holds the key to
                      unlocking the availability and access of micro insurance to the poor.

                      Creating a conducive environment for the growth of micro insurance
 a large number       Several stages of innovation have yet to be undergone before micro insurance reaches the
of micro finance
                      position where micro-credit is today, in terms of productisation and operating systems. While
      institutions
         which are    micro credit is of interest today for many stakeholders ranging from private to public purpose
 registered as S      institutions, it should be remembered that the sector has reached its current stage over a
   25 companies
     or as NBFCs,     span of three decades. During this period, several grass root organisations have grappled with
   with outreach      a host issues to make micro credit work. These included addressing financial capital and grant
    to millions of    requirements for the sector, regulatory bottlenecks, and also product and operating system
rural household,
            are not   design and implementation. Each of these areas has gone through various phases of maturity
    recognised as     and iterations to enable the micro credit movement to reach the stage where it is. This long
 micro insurance
agents by micro
                      journey has to be kept in mind while work is being done to replicate the success of micro
         insurance    credit to micro insurance. While the journey of progress in micro insurance can be accelerated,
  regulation and      the issues cited need to be addressed and cannot be bypassed or overlooked. A unique
    are therefore
       constrained    challenge that the micro insurance movement has to confront is the rather complex task
  from using the      involved in designing and distributing a diverse range of insurance products where knowledge
          enabling
                      and technical expertise is required from several fields like health care systems, animal husbandry,
provisions made
      under these     enterprise valuation, agriculture etc. This calls for a more collaborative approach in actual
   regulations to     delivery of micro insurance products, where expertise from insurers, distributors, and service
     spread micro
  insurance on a      providers (e.g. health care) needs to be synchronised to achieve a seamless delivery of micro
        large scale   insurance products. The complexity involved in micro insurance is quite evident from the
                      relatively slow introduction and growth of micro insurance among practioners of micro credit.
                      There is certainly a strong case for greater investments into capacity building for potential
                      micro insurance distributors and collaborative partnerships for scaling up of micro insurance.

                      The growth in a nascent sector like micro insurance will also be strongly influenced by the
                      regulatory environment. A major impetus for the growth for micro insurance in India has come
                      from the rural and social sector obligations stipulated under the IRDA Act. This has ensured
                      that all insurance companies in India develop and distribute products for the rural and social
                      sector. Taking this effort forward, IRDA introduced the micro insurance regulations in December,
                      2005. These regulations aimed at making certain enabling provision to encourage both insurers
                      and micro insurance distributors to actively promote micro insurance. The regulation enable
                      SHGs, societies and co-operatives to function as micro insurance agents and carry out a lot
                      functions like premium collection, policy bond distribution, and claims administration. However,
                      a large number of micro finance institutions which are registered as S 25 companies or as
                      NBFCs, with outreach to millions of rural household, are not recognised as micro insurance

                122
CHAPTER 7
                                                                                              Micro Insurance




agents by micro insurance regulation and are therefore constrained from using the enabling
provisions made under these regulations to spread micro insurance on a large scale.

Livestock Insurance: insuring the wealth of rural India
After agriculture, it is livestock which is the most common source of income for rural households.
Very often it provides a supplementary source of income for rural households, helping them to
tide over loss of income from other sources. According to the 17th national livestock census
conducted in 2003, there were 284 million cattle in India. There was no growth in the cattle
population of the country between from 1997 (when the 16th livestock census was conducted)
to 2003. In the year 2002-03, according to Department of Animal Husbandry & Dairying,
Ministry of Agriculture, 18 million cattle were insured, which means that only 6% of the cattle
population was insured. Traditionally, livestock insurance has always been seen as an unattractive
portfolio for insurance companies due to its poor financial performance on account of the
behavioural risks associated with both customers and service providers. One of the requisites
for offering livestock insurance has been the need for getting a certificate from a veterinary
                                                                                                     if the death of
doctor. Many remote places still do not have the services of a veterinary doctor and to get this
                                                                                                     the cattle takes
only adds to the cost of obtaining livestock insurance. To overcome this difficulty, which           place when the
seriously compromises the ability to offer livestock insurance in rural areas, BASIX worked with     market value is
                                                                                                     at the low end
Royal Sundaram to enable the certification of livestock insured through its field staff who are      of the cycle,
adequately trained in assessing the economics of cattle rearing, and the insurable status of         then the farmer
cattle. While this arrangement greatly simplifies the ease of insuring animals, great care has       suffers
                                                                                                     considerable
also to be exercised by BASIX staff to ensure that proper controls are in place to ensure that       loss of future
no adverse selection of high risk animals happens. Also, in the event of a claim, if a death         value. Besides,
                                                                                                     it is also
certificate cannot be given by a doctor, an inspection and report from a field facilitator           difficult for the
approved by the insurance company is considered for settlement of claim. There are other key         farmer to come
issues which had to be addressed to make cattle insurance more attractive to rural customers:        to terms with
                                                                                                     the fact that
                                                                                                     while he has
Assessment of market value at the time of claim                                                      paid a premium
                                                                                                     for a certain
Traditionally cattle insurance policies are indemnity based contracts, i.e. the claim amount         sum insured, he
paid is based on the market value of the animal at the time of death of animal. If the value of      gets paid an
                                                                                                     amount less
the animal is greater than the sum insured only then is the sum insured paid. It is known that       than that
the market value of milching cattle follows an almost cyclical path based on the reproductive
stages that they go through. Thus if the death of the cattle takes place when the market value
is at the low end of the cycle, then the farmer suffers considerable loss of future value.
Besides, it is also difficult for the farmer to come to terms with the fact that while he has paid
a premium for a certain sum insured, he gets paid an amount less than that. In order to
overcome these situations, BASIX worked with Royal Sundaram to convert the policy to a full
benefit policy, i.e one where the claim paid is equal to the sum insured. To ensure that the
principle of indemnity is not compromised, the cattle were insured for about only 80% of the
animal value. This also ensured that there was an element of self insurance by the farmer,
which would translate into better care of the animal.

Reducing adverse selection

Avoiding adverse selection is a major challenge in livestock insurance. A field staff who is not
too technically trained in veterinary science cannot easily asses the exact health status of
cattle from mere visual observation. To overcome this challenge, most insurance policies have
                                                                                                 123
a window period of 10-15 days from the date of tagging after which the risk cover period
                    commences. To further minimise adverse selection, customers are also sometimes incentivised
                    to insure all the cattle in the household by providing a premium discount for insurance of
                    multiple animals.

                    Since most of the lending in micro finance is not necessarily targeted at a single economic
                 activity, most MFIs have not entered the space of insuring the livestock of their clients.
                 Among those MFIs which do lend to specific activities like purchase of livestock, combinations
                 of factors like (i) high premium rates (ranging from 3 to 8 percent of the insured value), (ii)
                 inordinate paper work (iii) a poor history of claims settlements and (iv) issues related to
                 adverse selection deter them from making livestock insurance compulsory for their clients.
 As the margins Only in specific locations where the above issues can be addressed do MFIs encourage their
    in pure risk customers to take livestock insurance on a voluntary basis. BASIX has cumulatively insured
 products (term
  insurance) are    over 40,000 livestock so far. In the recent two years, BASIX has also begun providing preventive
  thin compared     vet care services on a fee basis under its Business Development Services (BDS) program. It
       to savings
products for the
                    currently has close to 50,000 customers who are availing of these services. BASIX expects that
        insurance   the BDS services will result in reducing the risk and thereby reducing mortality of livestock
     companies,     owned by its customers. This would eventually translate into reduction of premium of premium
      innovative
approaches need     rates for livestock insurance, making it more attractive to enrol larger number of customers for
 to be taken to     livestock insurance.
      reduce the
     transaction
  costs involved    Life insurance
    in providing
 term insurance     Life insurance has perhaps had the longest innings in the domain of rural insurance, where it
                    is popularly associated with LIC. One of the consequences of this legacy is that insurance is
                    the rural areas is closely associated with savings, under which on maturity of the contract, the
                    customer gets back his premium back with some return on it. However, a high percentage of
                    lapsation of such policies has translated into erosion of the savings of the poor to the tune
                    of a few crores of rupees. Due to the seasonality and unpredictability their incomes, the poor
                    cannot often pay timely renewal premiums, resulting in policy lapsation. In spite of this past
                    experience, the focus on selling savings policies is perpetuated as the insurance agent stands
                    to earn a hefty commission on the first year's premium on such policies. However, what the
                    poor need most is risk protection, which is offered through pure-risk term policies. The lower
                    premium instalments of such policies also make the pure-risk term polices more affordable for
                    the poor.

                    As the margins in pure risk products (term insurance) are thin compared to savings products
                    for the insurance companies, innovative approaches need to be taken to reduce the transaction
                    costs involved in providing term insurance. One way to address this is to take the cue from
                    how micro credit has addressed the problem of transaction costs through the group approach.
                    Today all BASIX borrowers and also their spouses are covered under a group policy called Credit
                    Plus, a product from AVIVA. This group product covers each of the insured individuals to 1.5
                    times of the loan amount taken. This ensures that in an unfortunate event of the death of the
                    insured person, not only is the loan amount written off, but the dependent also gets some
                    additional financial support to cover immediate financial needs.

                    Another unique feature of the Credit Plus policy is that it provides borrowers with the
                    convenience of paying the insurance premium in small monthly instalments to the insurance

               124
CHAPTER 7
                                                                                              Micro Insurance




company along with their loan repayments. By the end of September 2007, BASIX had covered
0.5 million individuals under this policy. Cumulatively it has settled life insurance claims to
about 2000 families amounting to Rs 3 crores.

Under the IRDA act, all insurance companies are mandated to achieve a certain number of
policies in the rural and social sector. This combined with the new micro insurance regulations
are giving a new impetus to providing affordable term policies for the poor. Today, with 16 life
insurance companies operating, a reasonable number of term insurance products are available
in the market.

Health insurance
For many poor who do not have any significant assets, their body is their only asset. They            Given the
earn their livelihood, which often borders on subsistence, by engaging in both farm and non-          enormity of the
                                                                                                      challenge
farm labour. Health risks seriously affect such households, as they not only lack the financial       involved in
resources to pay for health care, but also stand to loose their only source of income from            providing health
                                                                                                      care financing
labour. However, the perils of ill health do not restrict its impact to the above category of         options, it is
people. It also has a serious impact on not-so-poor people, as health care costs are spiralling,      not surprising
and are unaffordable even by middle class income standards. This problem is further compounded        that the micro
                                                                                                      health insurance
by reduced public spending on health care, leaving most people to meet health care costs out          sector has seen
of pocket. Given the enormity of the challenge involved in providing health care financing            numerous
                                                                                                      initiatives,
options, it is not surprising that the micro health insurance sector has seen numerous initiatives,
                                                                                                      making it one
making it one of the most active and innovative fields in the domain of micro insurance.              of the most
There are a variety of models which are emerging in this sector, some which are underwritten          active and
                                                                                                      innovative
by insurance companies, some self managed within the community or an institution without              fields in the
a tie with an insurance company and some of which are hybrid of both formal and in-house              domain of micro
                                                                                                      insurance
insurance arrangements. A compilation of the various micro health insurance programs carried
out by ILO under its STEP program indicate that close to 9 million people are insured in about
90 micro health insurance programs in India. Of these, the two biggest schemes are (i)
Yashashwini which is managed by a trust with contributions from the state government and
users from cooperatives in Karnataka, currently covering over 2 million individuals. This makes
it one of the largest micro insurance programs in the world and interestingly the risks are not
underwritten by an insurer, and (ii) the Sampoorna Suraksha health insurance scheme introduced
by SKDRDP trust based at Dharmasthala in Karnataka. It covers today over 7 lakh individuals,
and the risk is currently underwritten by ICICI Lombard. The uniqueness of both these models
is that the health insurance program is independent of any micro credit program. It is a clear
indicator that the penetration of micro insurance on a large scale does not have to be entirely
dependent on the availability of the micro credit vehicle. While this may be the case, micro
finance institutions certainly possess the necessary outreach and experience in financial
services to give a major fillip to providing access to micro insurance for the poor. An increasing
number of micro finance institutions are introducing micro health insurance to their customers
along with life insurance cover. SEWA from Gujarat stands as an example for providing a whole
suite of financial services for its customers. Its customers today have access to savings, credit
and a whole suite of insurance products. Its composite insurance product offers risk cover for
life, health and household assets and SEWA currently covers close to 2 lakh individuals under
its health insurance policy.



                                                                                                  125
While there are several promising models of micro health insurance emerging, the problems of
                     adverse selection and moral hazard continue to challenge all players in their attempt to deliver
                     affordable, hassle free and sustainable health insurance products. While adverse selection can
                     be controlled by covering well defined groups, moral hazard (e.g. inflated billings) continue
                     to challenge insurance providers. This problem is further perpetuated by poorly defined and
                     poorly implemented protocols for health care management in India. There exist an ever growing
                     number of health care service providers in the market, mainly in the private sector, and
                     implementing standards of quality and health care procedures across so many providers remain
                     a challenge. While current health insurance providers continue to innovate around these
                     problems, the growth of health insurance will depend a lot on the proactive role played by
                     public institutions to establish standards and quality in health care systems in India.

                     Enterprise insurance
         The crop    A large percentage of rural customers are engaged in various forms of non-farm enterprises.
        insurance
                     These enterprises are often housed in kacha premises and face a high level of risk from elements
   schemes have
   also not been     like fire, floods, storms, etc. and from external impact damage. It is important to safeguard
    very popular     them against these risks. In recent years some of the private insurance companies have begun
with farmers as
        the claim    to offer insurance cover for such kacha enterprises where enterprise value may be as small as
      assessment     ten to twenty thousand rupees. The key to scale up outreach on micro enterprise insurance
   process is not
                     would be to have simplified products for valuation of such enterprises and simplified claims
             very
transparent and      procedures to survey and settle their claims.
claim payments
        are often    Managing agricultural risks
         delayed.
      Alternative
        models to    India has a large exposure to weather risks, where the majority of the population is dependent
    manage crop      on rainfed agriculture. In the past two decades, large scale attempts have been made to cover
   risks are now
 being explored
                     the risks of farmers through state sponsored crop insurance schemes, aimed at covering multiple
  to find a more     risks faced by the crops. These schemes have however imposed significant fiscal pressure on
      sustainable    the states even though they cover only about 10 percent of Indian farmers. This situation has
     approach to
        managing     arisen due to the adverse claims experience, where the claim payouts have been more than
      agricultural   four times of the premium collected. Besides a 50 premium subsidy offered by the government,
     risks. Index
                     all the excess claim payouts have been borne from state finances. The crop insurance schemes
  based weather
     insurance is    have also not been very popular with farmers as the claim assessment process is not very
   now emerging      transparent and claim payments are often delayed. Alternative models to manage crop risks are
 as a promising
      alternative    now being explored to find a more sustainable approach to managing agricultural risks. Index
                     based weather insurance is now emerging as a promising alternative.

                     A simple weather index insurance product would work in the following manner. In the event of
                     a shortfall of rain from a predetermined level (index) during a particular period of the crop
                     season, the farmer would be compensated based on a predetermined formula which takes into
                     account the probable loss incurred due to the extent of shortfall in rain. This allows for an
                     objective way to measure claims payable to the insured farmer. As the claim payout formula is
                     predetermined, it automatically leads to timely settlement of claims to farmers, allowing them
                     to reinvest in their next crop or to meet their immediate consumption needs. With the
                     availability of historical weather data, the pricing of the insurance product can be done on an
                     actuarial basis, leading to a more financially sustainable product. The availability of
                     international reinsurance for weather insurance helps to transfer the local weather risk to the

               126
CHAPTER 7
                                                                                              Micro Insurance




global weather risk market and thus provides for a the pooling of risks.

BASIX works with a large number of households whose livelihoods depend on agriculture,
without any assured source of irrigation. Between 2000 and 2002 BASIX undertook several
                                                                                                     for taking
research projects to provide cover for crop risks. These efforts culminated in a collaboration
                                                                                                     weather
with the Commodity Risk Management Group of the World Bank and ICICI Lombard, to launch              insurance to a
the first index based weather insurance in 2003 in Mababubnagar district of India covering           larger scale,
                                                                                                     there are
230 farmers in the first pilot program. In subsequent years the index based weather insurance        challenges to be
market in India has scaled up, covering more than 300,000 farmers. Today there are more              overcome. One
                                                                                                     of them is to
companies offering weather insurance in India, including the government owned Agriculture
                                                                                                     increase the
Insurance Company. However for taking weather insurance to a larger scale, there are challenges      density of
to be overcome. One of them is to increase the density of weather stations in big way, so that       weather
                                                                                                     stations in big
rainfall measured in a particular weather station is better correlated to the actual rainfall in a   way, so that
particular farm.                                                                                     rainfall
                                                                                                     measured in a
                                                                                                     particular
While weather insurance can protect farmers from significant deviations in weather performance,
                                                                                                     weather station
there is still a need and huge scope for providing risk minimisation and productivity                is better
enhancement services needed by farmers. These advisory services are needed to complement             correlated to
                                                                                                     the actual
the index insurance product. In the absence of these services, weather insurance would carry         rainfall in a
too much of the weight of farmer's expectations and prove to be an incomplete solution or            particular farm
promise to the farmers.

                         Box 7.2 SEWA and Rainfall Insurance

The Self Employed Womens' Association (SEWA) developed, in collaboration with ICICI Lombard,
an insurance product to insure against risks arising out of deficit and excess rainfall. While
the insurance product offered by ICICI/Lombard has gone through several cycles elsewhere in
India, the product requires customization to local agro-climatic settings. One challenge is
understanding the precise relationship between rainfall and rural income, particularly given
the paucity of data on rural income. A well-designed product should pay the poor precisely
when they need income the most. One goal of SEWA was to make the product accessible to
even its poorest members. As a result, the minimum unit size for purchase was quite low,
available to anyone whose income varies with the weather.

This project aims to (i) evaluate the potential of rainfall insurance to improve the livelihood
and sustainability of rural poor in Gujarat, India (ii) understand how behavioral biases and
risk aversion influence decision making at the household level, and (iii) evaluate the
effectiveness of different marketing and communication strategies in encouraging take up of
the product.

For the purposes of rolling out the insurance product, 100 villages have been identified that
are within 30 km of an IMD-recognized weather station in 3 districts - Ahmedabad, Anand and
Patan. Since SEWA will initially be able to offer weather insurance to only a limited number of
villages, 33 villages were selected at random, where insurance is offered. In the second year ,
it expanded to a group of 50 villages.

The baseline and the midline surveys have been completed in a little over 1500 households.
Based on the data and experiences from the first year, the insurance product and the marketing
strategy are being redesigned to serve the needs of the clients more effectively.



                                                                                                  127
Making micro insurance more affordable and accessible
                      The biggest constraint involved in the distribution of micro insurance is the disproportionate
                      cost of distribution and servicing, in comparison to the value of the premium and the sum
                      insured of these policies. One of the key learnings from the field of micro finance has been
                      that the poor can save and pay in frequent and small instalments. Most insurance policies
                      require premiums to be paid in annual instalments. This makes the premium instalments quite
                      unaffordable for the poor. The key to enhancing outreach of insurance for the poor would be
                      to make provision for collecting premium in more frequent and smaller instalments. However,
                      this benefit can be outweighed by the increase in transaction costs for collecting such small
                      premiums. A solution to this could be to bundle the premium collections with other forms of
                      financial transactions like savings and credit repayments.

        The key to    Another key to the success of micro insurance is simplicity in documentation. One of the
         enhancing    earliest products introduced by AVIVA for the rural sector goes by the name of "Jan Suraksha".
       outreach of
     insurance for    This is a pure term life insurance product with a sum insured limit of Rs.50,000. The proposal
  the poor would      form for this policy contained 4 pages. In collaboration with its micro insurance partners
       be to make
     provision for
                      AVIVA developed and recently introduced a new life term micro insurance product by the name
         collecting   "Gramin Suraksha" with similar policy limits. However the proposal form for this policy has
       premium in     been shortened to a single page. This ensures that minimal and relevant data is captured from
   more frequent
       and smaller    the customer and the scope for errors in documentation are minimised. It also reduces the
      instalments.    transaction costs involved in selling micro insurance policies.
    However, this
   benefit can be
                      The level of risks covered under micro insurance policies is often of a small value, in the range
  outweighed by
  the increase in     of Rs 5,000 to Rs 50 thousand rupees, as compared to regular insurance policies where the
       transaction    risk cover is often in excess of a lakh of rupees. Given the small value of insurance benefits
          costs for
  collecting such     that come with micro insurance products, it is important to ensure that the products have
small premiums.       minimal exclusions and fine print that is usually associated with insurance policies. This is
    A solution to
                      essential to ensure that the poor perceive the insurance products to be fair and to encourage
 this could be to
        bundle the    greater enrolment of customers under such products. Some of the micro health insurance
          premium     products currently being offered in the country cover both pre-existing diseases and maternity
 collections with
   other forms of     related treatments under such policies and some have demonstrated that they can be offered
          financial   on a financially sustainable basis.
      transactions
like savings and
             credit
                      The role of public institutions in developing micro insurance
       repayments
                      The government and its institutions wear several hats in the insurance industry. They together
                      perform several roles: that of a regulator, a development agency, an insurer, a re-insurer and an
                      insurer for the uninsured - in the form of various welfare and relief programs run by the
                      government. Some of these functions are also performed by several private and non profit
                      institutions. It is often a tough balancing act for the various public institutions to perform,
                      so that they function effectively in each of these roles, and also ensure that no one function
                      works at cross purpose with any other function. A case in point is that of the several insurance
                      schemes announced by both the central and state governments which aim to cover rural
                      clients or special categories of social sector clients, with a premium subsidy provided by the
                      government. Sometimes these schemes can crowd out the development of market based insurance
                      products for the poor, making the poor perpetual dependent on such schemes. In other cases
                      such schemes do not reach the targeted population. An example of a recent state government

                128
CHAPTER 7
                                                                                                Micro Insurance




sponsored scheme is the Mukhyomantri Jibon Jyoti Bima Achoni2 launched by the Assam state
government in July-2005, covering all the 30 million population in the state, where each                 A part of the
                                                                                                        subsidy should
individual is covered for hospitalisation expenses up to Rs.25,000 per annum. The state
                                                                                                        be apportioned
government paid a premium of Rs 250 million to ICICI Lombard General Insurance Company for              to programs for
this cover. Within one year of this policy, i.e. up to July 2006, about 4205 people (out of 30          improving
                                                                                                        awareness and
million!) are reported to have benefited from this policy with about Rs 90 million paid in              education about
claims.                                                                                                 the benefits of
                                                                                                        micro insurance
Such low utilisation of the benefits can be attributed to the low awareness of the policy               for the targeted
                                                                                                        population. The
among the insured population. The question that arises is the right manner in which the                 latter holds the
public subsidy should be targeted. There is certainly a case for subsidising the poorest of the         key to laying a
                                                                                                        strong
poor for their premiums. But the above example also indicates that unless investments are
                                                                                                        foundation to
made to educate the poor on the benefits of insurance, such subsidies do not really help the            scale up and
majority of the targeted population. A part of the subsidy should be apportioned to programs            develop a
                                                                                                        healthy micro
for improving awareness and education about the benefits of micro insurance for the targeted            insurance
population. The latter holds the key to laying a strong foundation to scale up and develop a            market in India
healthy micro insurance market in India.




Endnotes


1 Manager, Insurance Business, BASIX

2 See Central Bureau of Health Intelligence (CBHI), Ministry of Health and Family Welfare, Government
   of India

   http://www.cbhi-hsprod.nic.in/retopt2.asp?SD=21&SI=9&ROT=1




                                                                                                    129
130
CHAPTER 8
                                                                                          Microfinance and
                                                                                          Technology




                                       CHAPTER 8


 Microfinance and Technology
                         Prasanth V Regy and Vijay Mahajan1

1      Technology: the Key to Efficient Microfinance
1.1 Technology for MF: Why?
As one of the authors predicted in 1998, "the day we can marry the power of the microprocessor    As one of the
                                                                                                  authors
with the power of microfinance, we will have developed a terrific solution to provide
                                                                                                  predicted in
microfinance transactions to poor people in a low-cost, user-friendly way" (Mahajan 1998).        1998, "the day
The proper use of information and communication technologies can be very beneficial to            we can marry
                                                                                                  the power of
MFIs. A well-designed and well thought-out Management Information System (MIS) is essential       the
to achieve scale, improve efficiency, and reduce cost. By reducing manual work, it decreases      microprocessor
                                                                                                  with the power
the possibility of error and fraud. Such a system can serve as the backbone of the MFI's
                                                                                                  of microfinance,
processes. It can provide decision-making support to the management by facilitating the           we will have
analysis of data. It can also help the management monitor the activities of the MFI on a day-     developed a
                                                                                                  terrific solution
to-day basis. Further, such applications can help in managing complex products, allowing the      to provide
MFI to offer tailor-made products to its customers with marginal extra effort. They are also      microfinance
very useful for HR purposes, including recording employee information, and calculating salaries   transactions to
                                                                                                  poor people in a
and commissions.                                                                                  low-cost, user-
                                                                                                  friendly way"
MIS is not the only application of IT in microfinance. Another technology fast gaining
importance is that of various Point-of-Sale devices, which can make transactions faster and
safer. This chapter is an attempt to examine the use of various technology products and
channels in the delivery of microfinance in India.

Within microcredit, the key activities involved are registration, appraisal, disbursement,
repayment, and monitoring.

Registering a customer involves recording details about her name, age, and other personal
and household details. In addition, data about the livelihoods, education, and assets of the
household are also usually captured. This data can help in the assessment of the social and
economic impact of the activities of the MFI. Depending on the delivery model, we may also
need to record details about the group, centre, JLG, guarantor, etc.

During appraisal, information about the cash-flow of the activity, and of the household,
needs to be captured. Repayment is an activity that will happen over and over again, so it
should be quick and fraud-proof. The MIS should generate the demand statement and it
should also help in monitoring the portfolio by generating statements of PAR, NPA, etc.
                                                                                              131
The regulatory requirements for being able to provide microsavings services are much more
                       stringent than those for microcredit. In India, only banks and certain NBFCs are allowed to
                       accept savings. An effective Assets and Liability Management application will be useful in risk
                       monitoring. In contrast to microcredit, where most products involve regular transactions,
                       microsavings products would have to be flexible enough to accommodate irregular savings.

                       The information requirements for microinsurance are slightly different from that of microcredit.
                       MFIs selling microinsurance are retailers for insurance companies. This requires collaboration
                       between the MFI and the insurance company, and the MFI's MIS would need to be able to
                       output data in the format required by the insurance company. The amount of data to be
                       entered is also very high, since insurance is often offered for the whole family. Further, the
                       data accuracy needs to be higher as compared to microcredit.

                       1.2 The current usage of IT by MFIs
       When asked      A survey on the use of technology in DCCBs and MFIs in India was conducted recently by Saral
         about the
                       Services (Saral Services 2007). The results are quite interesting.
      factors that
    inhibited the
       adoption of     94% of the MFIs used software applications for internal accounting. 64% reported that they
 technology, the       used loan-tracking software, and only 30% used payroll software. 14% used PDA applications
 most commonly
cited constraint       to capture field transactions. In 64% of the cases, the head office of the MFI has a LAN. All
 was budgetary.        the MFIs had internet access in their HO and branches. It is also notable that the cellphone
            Lack of    network was accessible from almost all the MFI locations.
          adequate
         expertise,
      training and     When asked about the factors that inhibited the adoption of technology, the most commonly
     support were      cited constraint was budgetary. Lack of adequate expertise, training and support were
      contributing
                       contributing factors. Another issue was the lack of awareness about technology providers.
factors. Another
   issue was the       While irregular power supply is also a problem, it is one that could be rectified by using a UPS,
             lack of   which is again expensive.
         awareness
              about
        technology     2      MIS Solutions - A Survey
providers. While
 irregular power
 supply is also a      The microfinance software vertical has seen a lot of activity in the last year. Along with well-
   problem, it is      established MFIs offering software that they themselves use, a few new application developers
  one that could
                       have entered the arena. What follows is a review of some MIS applications, classified according
  be rectified by
     using a UPS,      to the various microfinance models. This is not a comprehensive list, but it will help to give
  which is again       us an overview of this sector.
         expensive

                       2.1        Software for SHGs
                       Since SHG-Bank Linkage is the predominant microfinance model in India, several applications
                       have been developed for it. Most of these applications are meant to help the promoting MFI
                       or NGO track all the financial transactions that happen at the SHG meetings.

                              •      McFinancier of Sharada Computer Services, Gurgaon: This is a software system
                                     solely targeted at SHGs. It can handle group-wise books, and provides all the
                                     required administration, tracking and accounting functionalities. It is used by
                                     PRADAN, Sarvodaya Nano Finance Ltd, etc.


                 132
CHAPTER 8
                                                                                             Microfinance and
                                                                                             Technology




       •      SafalFin of Safal Solutions Ltd, Hyderabad: SafalFin is an integrated solution for
              NGOs, which helps to track internal credit, deposit and insurance transactions
              of the members of SHGs promoted by the NGO/MFI. It keeps track of the day-to-
              day loan activities of these MFIs in addition to managing their Member, Staff,
              SHG, Accounts and other details.

       •      MTech developed a product named "SHG-MIS", which is meant to help the SHGs
              track their operations, and also to help the promoting organisation track the
              SHG performance. After every SHG meeting, the transaction sheets are sent to a
              centralised location, where it is entered into the MIS and the next demand
              sheet is printed and returned to the SHG. This product was jointly developed
              with Andhra Pradesh's Velugu, so that it could be used by all the Velugu groups.

       •      Mahila Sphurthi, developed by CoOptions: This software is intended to be an
              integrated information system to streamline SHG activities. This product also
              attempts to bridge the digital divide, by bringing relevant information to the
              villager about agri-inputs, market intelligence, sanitation and health, etc.

       •      Ekgaon's Mahakalasm MIS: This MIS will allow the promoting NGO/MFI to track
              the performance of its SHGs. Ekgaon has also designed a unique and accessible
              system of paper forms for data entry in the field.

An interesting innovation in this field has been PRADAN's Computer Munshi. Many SHGs remain  PRADAN
dependent on the promoting NGO for book-keeping. Even when they can maintain the daybooks    conceived the
                                                                                             idea of a
themselves, they are usually unable to produce the group financial statements. PRADAN conceived
                                                                                             community
the idea of a community based computer entrepreneur, the Computer Munshi (CM), who would     based computer
                                                                                             entrepreneur,
provide accounting services to the SHGs for a reasonable payment. He could offer his services
                                                                                             the Computer
to about 200 SHGs, resulting in viable employment. Most CMs supplement this income with Munshi (CM),
other activities, such as STD PCOs, internet and photocopying facilities.                    who would
                                                                                             provide
                                                                                             accounting
2.2 Software for the Grameen model                                                           services to the
                                                                                             SHGs for a
The Grameen model of microcredit, which originated with the Grameen Bank of Bangladesh, reasonable
                                                                                             payment. He
has been used heavily in India with significant improvements. One of the most commonly could offer his
used applications for monitoring Grameen-style microcredit, Portfolio Tracker, was developed services to
by Grameen Communications (GC) of Bangladesh, an IT service provider and a member of the about 200
                                                                                             SHGs, resulting
Grameen group of enterprises. Together with modules for performance monitoring and in viable
accounting, this application reduces paper work considerably and raises work efficiency. In employment
India, it is used by CASHPOR, SKS, and several other Grameen replicators.

2.3 Software implementing multiple methodologies
Various lending models have been tried out in the field of microcredit. Lending may be to
individuals or to small groups (SHGs, Grameen groups, and JLGs), and at the other end of the
spectrum, to Federations and MACTS. There are a variety of methods to calculate interest and
schedule payments. The organisations that offer multiple models and several kinds of products
need software that can handle the complexity.




                                                                                                133
2.3.1 FAMIS Plus

                    FAMIS is short for Financial Accounting and Management Information System. It was developed
                    by BASIX's software partner, Sathguru Management Consultants, based on BASIX's specifications.
                    It was designed to be a comprehensive solution for accounting and management information
                    needs. While it is no longer used within BASIX, it continues to serve more than 36 other MFIs
                    at 140 installations, to whom BASIX provides ongoing support.

                    FAMIS PLUS is a very mature application, satisfying the requirements of 36 MFIs throughout
                    India. It runs on Windows, and requires minimal maintenance and support. It is very rich in
                    features, being able to support credit, savings, and insurance. It has extremely rich reporting
                    features, which have enabled its users to track metrics that couldn't be tracked earlier, leading
                    to better recoveries. It is highly configurable software, easily adaptable to any terminology,
                    interest calculation method and lending/saving methodology.

         Delphix,   FAMIS' main negative has to do with the database it uses - FoxPro. This database is not as
 designed to be     robust as the other databases available, and is not perceived very favourably today.
       an MIS for
       livelihood
    finance, was    2.3.2 Delphix
  also developed
    by Sathguru,    Delphix, designed to be an MIS for livelihood finance, was also developed by Sathguru, based
        based on
          BASIX's
                    on BASIX's specifications. It drew heavily from BASIX's previous experience of creating FAMIS.
  specifications.   In particular, it is highly robust and customisable, and is based on the Oracle platform.
 It drew heavily
    from BASIX's    BASIX uses Delphix for all its lending operations, serving more than 200,000 customers in
         previous
   experience of    more than 60 units. New features are being added to Delphix, including savings, life insurance,
creating FAMIS.     and agricultural and business development services. It is a highly capable system, based on a
In particular, it
                    rugged and proven platform. Box 8.1 describes the evolution of MIS applications in BASIX.
is highly robust
              and
   customisable,    2.3.3 Micro Financier
and is based on
       the Oracle   Java Softech's Micro Financer is a flexible solution capable of supporting a variety of models,
         platform
                    including SHGs, Federations, Grameen, and individual loans. It also has a full-featured savings
                    module. It enables the capture of several kinds of socio-economic data, and it can generate
                    a variety of reports. It comes integrated with a financial accounting module.

                    Its clients in India include SERP, CARE, Gram Utthan, and several MACS and federations.

                    2.3.4 Banksoft

                    BankSoft is an integrated suite of applications for banking, created by Processware Systems,
                    Bangalore. It enables branch automation, head office consolidation, and inter-branch
                    reconciliation. A user-friendly software package, BankSoft provides integrity, flexibility and
                    security to the user.

                    BankSoft has been installed at more than 300 locations in Karnataka, Andhra Pradesh, and
                    Goa. It supports multiple delivery channels such as Internet, PDAs, Touch Screen Kiosks,
                    Mobile phones, and ATMs. It enables the bank to generate all the statutory reports required by
                    RBI. It was chosen by BASIX for use in the Krishna Bhima Samruddhi Local Area Bank (KBSLAB).
                    Responding to the requirements of KBSLAB, Processware added several features to Banksoft,
                    making it a suitable product for microbanking.
               134
CHAPTER 8
                                                                                             Microfinance and
                                                                                             Technology




                       Box 8.1      The evolution of MIS in BASIX

FAMIS was BASIX's first effort at a comprehensive solution to our accounting and management
information needs, and it served us from 1997 to 2005. It was first developed on a Visual
Basic/FoxPro/MS-DOS platform. After the release of the first version in 1997, several more
versions were released, each adding to functionality and robustness.

At that time, there was no other software on the market which had the functionality needed
by MFIs. Most MFIs used manually prepared charts to determine repayments. In the year 2000,
FAMIS was supplied to its first external user, ASSEFA. This version was named ASSEFAMIS, and
it was installed in ASSEFA offices in Maharashtra, Rajasthan, Madhya Pradesh, and Bihar. This
involved not just providing the software, but also setting up the requisite infrastructure,
including buying generators and UPS, as well as training the operators who would use it.

RGVN, who had centres in Orissa, Assam and Bihar, was next. They lent to groups as well as to       At that time,
other NGOs, and these two activities were very different in the software functionality that         there was no
                                                                                                    other software
they demanded. RGVN had a wider portfolio of products, including savings and grants, and            on the market
required many new reports as well. Our analysts spent a lot of time on the field understanding      which had the
their processes and requirements, and then we converted them into software specifications           functionality
                                                                                                    needed by MFIs.
that we passed on to the developer. This was our first experience in customising our software       Most MFIs used
for external users. RGVN installed FAMIS in 16 locations.                                           manually
                                                                                                    prepared charts
This was followed by a very large number of other MFIs. It may be noted that BASIX charged          to determine
these users only for training and customization. In each case, our analysts invested a lot of       repayments
time in understanding the requirements and tailoring FAMIS accordingly. As may be imagined,
every MFI had different lending methodologies and interest calculation methods. Other
requirements like savings and grants were also integrated into FAMIS. The complexity quickly
increased, till there were 10 different versions of FAMIS for 10 MFIs! This large number of
versions obviously created several problems for us, and so we decided to combine these
different versions into one. This unified version was called FAMIS PLUS. This is the only
version that is used today.

The main problem with FAMIS was the database that it used. While it works very well for small
MFIs, it could not keep up with the growth of BASIX. In the year 2000, inspired by the
information system employed by DID Canada, plans were laid for the creation of a new software,
Delphix. It drew heavily from our experience of creating FAMIS. It was based on the Oracle
platform, which, we expected, would be able to handle anything we could throw at it.

The design of the new system was done in the year 2000, and the development largely took
place in 2001. The development was done by the same company who developed FAMIS. In
2002, we pilot tested it in three units, entering data in Delphix in parallel to FAMIS. However,
there were several problems migrating data from FAMIS to Delphix. In addition, Delphix was
immature at that time. So there were several issues in the way of moving to Delphix completely.

The pilot testing continued in the year 2003 and 2004, with seven more units taking part in
the pilot. In 2004, all our software development efforts were focused at building features for
handling insurance in FAMIS, so Delphix development was stopped during that time. All this
while, the parallel entry into Delphix continued in the ten pilot units.

In 2004 September, the first round of systems auditing was done by our auditor, who identified
several issues with Delphix. These issues were fixed, and then another round of audit done. After
this round, in which only minor issues were reported, we inducted Delphix into all our units.


                                                                                                135
2.3.5 MIFOS

                      The Mifos Initiative was established by Grameen Foundation's Technology Center to address
                      the microfinance industry's information management challenge. The initiative aims to deliver
                      an open source information management system for the global microfinance industry via a
                      collaborative development and support community. The open source framework allows
                      microfinance institutions to select local developers to assist with the customization,
                      implementation and maintenance of their software. MIFOS is still under development and is
                      not currently recommended for use in a production environment.

                      2.4 Hosted Solutions
                      As internet connectivity improves, a different kind of application software is now possible -
                      one that is hosted by the solution provider on its own servers, rather than being installed
                      locally. The data is entered and accessed over the internet, through a browser. Installing and
                      upgrading software locally is replaced by a subscription-based model, in which data is stored
                      remotely. FINO and Salesforce.com are among the prominent players in this space.

          Software    This model has many advantages. Software development and its maintenance are not the core
    development
                      competencies of an MFI. Rather than spending money and resources on purchasing (or, worse,
            and its
    maintenance       developing), installing, configuring, maintaining, and upgrading application software and
are not the core      hardware, it may be more economical to just use a ready-made application hosted elsewhere
competencies of
  an MFI. Rather      and accessible through the browser. This will also lead to lower manpower requirements. The
  than spending       solution provider will take care of ensuring data protection and data redundancy, which are
       money and
                      requirements that are typically neglected by MFIs. Thus, such applications can deliver benefits
     resources on
 purchasing (or,      at reduced costs and risks.
            worse,
    developing),      There are disadvantages to this model as well, the first being that it requires internet
        installing,
     configuring,     connectivity. The internet is not available or is highly unreliable in large parts of our country.
    maintaining,      If only very limited functionality is required, it may still be possible to use a hosted solution
  and upgrading       with once a day connectivity. But for more complex usage, the information will be required to
       application
    software and      be cached locally and synchronised with the hosted server whenever possible. This may require
     hardware, it     local installation of caching software, which neutralises some of the advantages of such
    may be more
                      hosted solutions. Another problem is that of regular subscription payments. This payment is
   economical to
        just use a    typically based on the number of groups or customers handled by the application.
      ready-made
       application    There are also data-ownership issues: MFIs may not wish to part with their customer data to
            hosted
  elsewhere and       solution providers if they fear that the data may be shared with others. In addition, the fact
        accessible    that the data is stored by the solution provider may tie down the MFI if it later wishes to
      through the
                      migrate to a different solution.
           browser

                      2.4.1 FINO platform

                      FINO (Financial Information Network and Operations) Ltd. was set up by ICICI, which still
                      owns 20% of it. It provides a technology platform to MFIs to manage their data electronically.
                      It has been designed to support all the common lending methodologies.

                      This solution is based on a central Core Banking Solution (CBS), which will be the repository
                      of all the customer accounts. FINO is able to provide multiple levels of reports for MFIs that

                136
CHAPTER 8
                                                                                              Microfinance and
                                                                                              Technology




choose to be hosted on their platform. It also claims that it can even support MFIs who wish
to host their accounts themselves - the MFI can upload the data to it, and use the reporting
and analysing abilities of the platform. FINO also offers the ability to handle smartcards. FINO
is described further in Box 8.2

2.4.2 Salesforce.com

Salesforce.com is the leading provider of hosted enterprise applications internationally. In fact,
a large part of the credit for creating the hosted enterprise solutions space goes to them, due to
their pioneering work in web-based Customer Relationship Management applications. They are
in the process of developing a web-based tool for microfinance institutions. Being at an early
stage, they are looking for MFI partners who are willing to test their application.


                           Box 8.2      A hosted solution: FINO

Indian startup Financial Information, Network, and Operations Ltd (FINO) has recently become         While back end
the first company in the world to offer a complete end to end technology solution to                 data
                                                                                                     management
microfinance institutions. While back end data management software designed for microfinance         software
operations has been available on the market for years, FINO is the first to link a back end          designed for
software system with a front end based on biometric smartcards for customers, and field              microfinance
                                                                                                     operations has
devices for credit officers, to offer a complete, integrated solution.                               been available
                                                                                                     on the market
The basics of the FINO product are simple. FINO is targeted at Business Correspondents,              for years, FINO
governments, MFIs and in fact, at any organization that intends to reach the unbanked                is the first to
sector. Customers of the organization are given biometric enabled smartcards which store the         link a back end
                                                                                                     software
customers' fingerprints, account details, a unique identification number, and photo.                 system with a
Transactions are recorded using a field device equipped with a smartcard reader, fingerprint         front end based
reader, and small printer and then automatically uploaded from the field device to the back          on biometric
                                                                                                     smartcards for
end FINO software via a phone line. At the back end, all data is stored and maintained by FINO       customers, and
itself and accessed by the organization via web browsers. In addition to the full solution           field devices for
described above, FINO also allows organizations to purchase just the front or back end portions      credit officers,
                                                                                                     to offer a
of the system. (So far, several MFIs have opted to adopt the back end only.)                         complete,
                                                                                                     integrated
A key application of FINO would be to enable the Business Correspondent model. The BC model          solution
can work only if there is quick and accurate flow of information between the BC and the bank
(Section 6.2). The bank needs to be able to monitor and control the services offered by the BC
to the end customer. FINO provides offline-mode capability and detailed report-generation
systems, thus making it feasible and safe to adopt the BC model.

Another obvious application of the FINO product is to streamline the existing operations of
MFIs. By replacing rote paperwork with automatic data transfer, FINO allows MFIs to reduce
labour costs, lessen the chance of fraud, create reports more quickly, and gain better overall
insight into the performance of their portfolio. In addition to cutting costs, FINO also
benefits MFIs and their customers by allowing MFIs to offer new products such as remittances
and flexible savings accounts to their customers. Without the enhanced security, data
management capacity, and connection to the existing financial system which FINO allows,
these products would be nearly impossible for an MFI to offer.

The FINO product holds potential for increasing financial inclusion in India and elsewhere in
other ways as well. In addition to MFIs, banks may also use the FINO platform to directly


                                                                                                  137
engage in microfinance activities. Similarly, governments may use the FINO platform to deliver
  wages and other benefits to the public more efficiently and with less leakage. Finally, FINO
  may benefit the microfinance sector as a whole by serving as a platform for the development
  of a credit bureau for the sector. Because FINO collects the fingerprints of all customers it
  gives smartcards to, and stores this information in a central location, FINO could easily be
  used to track and share the credit histories of customers as they move from MFI to MFI. FINO
  has already begun work on a credit model to predict customer credit profile. A credit bureau
  would allow MFIs to cut down on the cost of screening clients, reduce overall defaults, and
  allow customers to more easily move from MFI to MFI, or to graduate from microfinance
  lending to bank lending. It can also enable the MFI to offer individual loan products instead
  of group-based products.

  Whether these potential benefits are realized depends greatly on how much FINO is able to
  bring down the costs of the system for the MFI as well as the amount of support commercial
  banks give FINO. Up until now, many MFIs have been reluctant to adopt the FINO system due
  to the high initial investment and yearly fees. For more MFIs to be convinced that adopting
  FINO is a smart move, these costs will have to be brought down. FINO could see easier
  acceptance in the Business Correspondent sector, since the initial investments would be
  borne/subsidized by banks.

  Despite a slow start, FINO is gaining steam. The company has signed up about 15 MFIs for its
  solution and a few of them have already gone live. It has carried out about 3 lakh enrolments,
  and has issued 1.5 lakh cards. The AP government is already using the FINO platform to deliver
  government benefits to recipients as a pilot, and it intends to replicate it in the entire state.
  In addition, Corporation Bank, ICICI, Indian Bank, and Union Bank of India have all made
  major investments in the company. Having these banks on board will do much to help ensure
  the success of the company. But FINO will need to sign up far more MFIs and gain the support
  of several more players, including governments. For FINO to be truly successful, it will also
  have to reduce costs by delivering multiple services through the same cards.



  3      Transaction Support Technologies
  In microfinance, transaction costs have traditionally been high. Innovations like the Grameen
  model, SHG, and JLG, made large-scale microfinance possible by bringing down this cost
  significantly. In this section, we examine how technology can be used to further bring down
  transaction costs.

         •      they should be easy to use, even by people unfamiliar with technology

         •      they should be able to handle even small ticket transactions in an economically
                feasible manner

         •      they should take minimal time and effort

         •      they should protect the interest of customers, and

         •      they should have the checks and balances necessary to avoid frauds.

  In practice, the transactions are usually captured manually in the field by an agent of the MFI,
  who gives the customer a receipt. This data is then fed into MIS loaded on a PC in the MFI
  branch office. The problem with this approach is the amount of time and effort this requires,

138
CHAPTER 8
                                                                                              Microfinance and
                                                                                              Technology




and the possibility of error and fraud. The information entered into the MIS is the same as the
information written down in the receipt - if this duplication of effort is avoided, then it can
lead not only to a savings in effort, but also to greater accuracy.

3.1 Hand-held devices
One way to avoid this error- and fraud-prone duplication is to use portable Point-of-Sale One way to
(POS) devices that can electronically capture transactions. BASIX has experimented with several avoid this error-
                                                                                                      and fraud-prone
hand-held devices, including Simputers, for this purpose, before settling on devices                  duplication is
manufactured by Edgar Interactive, Bangalore. When the field agent enters the transaction,            to use portable
                                                                                                      Point-of-Sale
the device records it and prints out a receipt for the client. When the agent comes back to the       (POS) devices
field office, he connects his HHD to the server, and the data is synchronised. Such devices are       that can
already being used in bus ticketing, electricity billing, etc.                                        electronically
                                                                                                      capture
                                                                                                      transactions
3.2 Rural ATMs
IIT Chennai, The Tenet group, and ICICI Bank have designed a secure, low cost, and low
maintenance ATM called the Gramateller. The idea behind this is to increase financial institutions'
outreach and penetration in rural areas.

The Gramateller can use existing connectivity in rural areas to enable a bank to extend its
services to the poor in an efficient and cost effective manner. It can use smartcards or
fingerprints for authentication. It also has a battery backup to deal with power outages.

3.3 Mobile phone based solutions
Cellular networks have recently become ubiquitous in India. It is estimated that there are
more than 180 million cellphone subscribers in India, and their numbers are fast increasing.
The cellphone combines processing power, storage, and wireless communication. Cellphones
are falling in price, while their memory and processor power have been increasing. Increasingly, Increasingly,
cameras and Near Field Communication (NFC) chips are built into them, as cellphone cameras and
                                                                                                      Near Field
manufacturers try to make them more and more useful in an effort to supplant the PC as the            Communication
primary personal computing device. Extrapolating these trends, it can be safely said that             (NFC) chips are
                                                                                                      built into them,
cellphones will play an important role in transaction capturing in microfinance.                      as cellphone
                                                                                                      manufacturers
3.3.1 A Little World                                                                                  try to make
                                                                                                      them more and
This company has come up with an initiative that envisages the mass deployment of multi-              more useful in
                                                                                                      an effort to
application smart cards through a network of service delivery points, with the POS device             supplant the PC
being a cellphone. It has the following components:                                                   as the primary
                                                                                                      personal
       •      Agent/employee with an NFC-enabled mobile phone                                         computing
                                                                                                      device.
       •      Customer with a NFC-enabled smart card                                                  Extrapolating
                                                                                                      these trends, it
       •      MFI/Bank                                                                                can be safely
                                                                                                      said that
       •      Centralised Card Management System.                                                     cellphones will
                                                                                                      play an
NFC is a short range (a few cm) wireless communication technology that works through magnetic         important role
                                                                                                      in transaction
induction. In ALW's model, the smart cards issued to customers have NFC-enabled chips on              capturing in
them, allowing them to transfer small amounts of data wirelessly and almost instantaneously.          microfinance

                                                                                                  139
The model is relatively low cost. A smart card is estimated to cost around Rs.100 and the
                    equipment with the agent (comprising a mobile phone, a finger print reader, and a printer, all
                    NFC-enabled) around Rs.20,000. The initial investment costs of the cards and the equipment
                    are high, so this system is best for MFIs that intend to become Business Correspondents (BC),
                    where the bank can bear the setup cost. Compared to the cost of establishing and operating
                    a physical bank branch in the rural area, this system would be extremely cost effective. The
                    operating costs of the model are expected to be minimal and can be easily absorbed by banks.

                    ALW has already deployed this technology in collaboration with banks in Pithoragarh in
                    Uttarakhand , Aizawl in Mizoram and Medak in AP. This technology is now being deployed with
                    IGS acting as the BC of Axis Bank in Delhi and in Muzaffarpur, Bihar, as described in Box 8.2.

                    3.3.2 Acceltree

                    The solution provided by Acceltree is a mobile phone based technology that provides a low cost
                    mechanism to computerize microfinance processes. Here, again, the mobile phone (or a wireless PDA)
                    itself operates as an on-line/off-line terminal. This device connects to a low cost central server.

                    Acceltree provides an easy to configure framework that enables quick deployment after
                    customising the application software to suit local business and government rules. The
                    application can be made available in local languages with little effort.

                    3.3.3 Ekgaon

                    Ekgaon has developed a mobile information services framework called CAM. This framework
                    comprises a cellphone application, paper forms with bar-codes that embed processing
                    instructions, and a server. This system offers the ability to have a hybrid system, combining
                    paper-based processes with automated systems, using bar-codes and image recognition through
                    cellphone cameras. The system also offers a voice-based menu, which will be helpful for illiterate
                    users. It can deal with situations where the cellular network is not available. Further, the
                    system is easily localisable. This system can be used by SHGs as well as by Business Correspondents.

                    4      Caveats
  Using multiple
     software to
  handle related
                    This section details some of the key aspects MFI managers should keep in mind as they
services results    implement a technology solution.
  in dissipation
of development
      energy and
                    4.1 Proper design and integration
      managerial
    attention. If   Often, when new features or services are being developed by an MFI, it may choose to prototype
   the different    it using a new application. But once the service becomes standard and mainstream, it is felt
     services are
     used by the    that it is too much bother to change the application, and so the MFI continues to use the
            same    prototype application for production purposes.
   customers, it
might be useful
                    Using multiple software to handle related services results in dissipation of development energy
 to build in the
 functionalities    and managerial attention. If the different services are used by the same customers, it might
required for the    be useful to build in the functionalities required for the different services into one program,
        different
   services into    or alternatively, to ensure that the different applications for the multiple services can talk to
    one program     each other. This is important in enabling us to have a unified view of the customer base.


               140
CHAPTER 8
                                                                                               Microfinance and
                                                                                               Technology




The operations staff has to be inducted into the application development project right from the
conceptualisation stage to ensure that the solution meets the requirements of the end users. They
play a vital role in the success of the project, and their feedback should always be taken into
account. This will help to ensure that the application is easy to use for those who actually use it.

4.2 Pilot testing
It is vital to test the software/hardware thoroughly in a few locations in the field before
deploying it company-wide. This will help the field staff to get used to the new way of doing
things, and also will catch issues before they become serious. In particular, it should be
recognized that software design is essentially iterative, and that the early versions will need
to be refined over a period of time before they can be used in a production environment.

4.3 Project management and documentation
Good project management is essential to the success of any project. The project should be
monitored by all the concerned parties, and the MFI should work closely with the IT partner to
resolve issues immediately. If a new product or process is being introduced, the development
of the software required should start well in advance. Otherwise, the unavailability of the
software may delay the new product.

In the IT industry, the employee turnover is generally very high. Hence, the application
development/deployment project should be process driven and not person driven.
Documentation can play a key role in ensuring this. If the required documentation is in place,
the maintenance of the application will become easy later. Proper documentation also helps
us evaluate whether we got what we asked for.

4.4 Security
It is generally seen that the security aspects of using technological solutions are often   It should be
                                                                                            noted that
overlooked. This is perhaps due to the assumption that most users, particularly field agents,
                                                                                            while
do not have the skills required to manipulate the software/hardware. It should be noted thattechnology can
while technology can help prevent frauds, it can also enable a skilled hacker to perpetrate help prevent
                                                                                            frauds, it can
frauds on a large scale. This can be avoided by a proper security architecture, including also enable a
appropriate access permissions, logging, regular backups, and encryption.                   skilled hacker
                                                                                            to perpetrate
                                                                                            frauds on a
5      A Guide to the Perplexed                                                             large scale. This
                                                                                            can be avoided
So, as the CEO or CTO of an MFI, how should you decide what solution to go for?             by a proper
                                                                                            security
                                                                                            architecture
The kind of MIS required will change according the size of the MFI. Even a small MFI would
need at least basic tools like a spreadsheet application or Access. As the size of the MFI
increases, the demands from the MIS increase as well, requiring more features, robust databases,
and easy to use user interfaces (Intellecap 2007). An MFI with a country-wide presence may
require a solution with a three-tier architecture, in which the data, business logic, and
presentation are split into distinct layers. This can web-enable the MIS and also provide the
extensibility required to be able to work with other applications and partners.

Thus, MFIs may need to migrate from one solution to another as they grow. Migration is

                                                                                                   141
usually a long and messy process, and it is best if planning is done in advance so as to avoid
                       it or, at least, to minimise the disruption caused by it.

                       A rough typology of the MIS features required by MFIs of various sizes is given below. These
                       numbers are indicative: an MFI with a very simple model might be able to serve millions of
                       customers with a very simple MIS, and another with more flexible and complex products may
                       need a more advanced solution from an early stage. Since the actual feature requirements will
                       vary according to factors such as the operational model of the MFI, and the number of
                       products it offers, these figures are order-of-magnitude estimates.

                       MFI Size (number of customers)                              MIS Features

                                      < 100                   Manual, paper-based system may be sufficient.
                                      < 10,000                Excel/Access based solution
                                     < 100,000                Robust Database with good consolidation and
   In general, for                                            reporting features
               small
organisations or                     >100,000                 Web-enabled and extensible, can work with other
    organisations                                             applications, enables high-level analysis
  using standard
     microfinance
 lending models,       Whether to purchase a ready-made product, to develop a new application altogether is another
   it is better to     key question. The answer to this question depends on several factors: the microfinance model
        source the
           software    followed by your organisation, the size of your organisation, the criticality of the software to
  externally, and      you, the quality of the external developer, and the comparative costs of development. Obviously,
have the vendor        this will vary from organisation to organisation, and even within an organisation, from service
 customise it to
     one's specific    to service.
    requirements.
          For large    In general, for small organisations or organisations using standard microfinance lending models,
   organisations,
     or where the
                       it is better to source the software externally, and have the vendor customise it to one's
     requirements      specific requirements. For large organisations, or where the requirements are specialised, it
 are specialised,      may be possible or necessary to develop a custom application. In this case, one should
         it may be
       possible or     carefully factor in the implications of developing in-house versus outsourcing the software
      necessary to     development to an application developer. Given the problems inherent in employing software
         develop a
                       engineers in-house, including their management, their high salaries and their high attrition,
             custom
       application     outsourcing to a technology partner may be the more attractive solution.

                       The selection of the technology partner plays a vital role in determining the success of the
                       project. The options that the partner can offer you are limited by his knowledge and experience.
                       Hence, we should carefully research his technological capabilities to ensure that he is
                       knowledgeable enough to be able to choose the best technology. We should also satisfy
                       ourselves that his project management capabilities are good enough that he will be able to
                       deliver the most cost-effective and robust solution, and support it over a long period.

                       The decision to go for a particular MIS or to develop a new one should be guided by a clear
                       idea of the costs and the benefits of that solution. The upfront price of the package may only
                       a very small part of the entire cost (Ivatury and Pasricha 2005). The larger chunk will be made
                       up of the costs of personnel, training, support and maintenance. One should also account for
                       the costs of the underlying operating system, database, hardware, and security costs.



                 142
CHAPTER 8
                                                                                             Microfinance and
                                                                                             Technology




As mentioned above, the particular technologies that are chosen will depend on the capabilities
of the technology partner. However, there are some aspects that the MFI should pay close
attention to:

       •      Robustness and suitability: We should ensure that the technology is well suited
              to the use it will be put to, and the scenarios it will be used in. Buying extremely
              expensive and unduly high-end hardware or software can be as bad as buying
              underpowered components.

       •      Cost: In general, open standards, whether in hardware or in software, are attractive
              because it leads to low prices. Also, in addition to the development or purchase
              costs, one should pay attention to the maintenance costs and any licensing or
              subscription costs of the operating system and database.

       •      Life: We should ensure that the software and hardware technologies we use do
              not become outdated too soon. A technology solution should be able to serve
              your needs at least 3-4 years into the future. Both hardware and software
              should be maintainable locally.

The technology platform is another issue. Most solutions seen so far run on Microsoft Windows. The field of
                                                                                               micro-finance is
This is primarily due to pervasiveness of that platform, and the large number of developers
                                                                                               becoming
familiar with it. There are a few solutions that run on free platforms like Linux. The advantages
                                                                                               mainstream,
                                                                                               and along with
of such a platform are that the costs are much lower, systems are generally more secure (free of
                                                                                               it, so is the
viruses, trojans, worms, etc), hardware requirements may be lighter, and one is free to upgradetechnology for
at one's convenience. A similar situation obtains for databases. While large organisations may this field
require expensive and high-end databases such as Oracle, SQL Server or DB2, it is usually seen
that most of the functionality exists in free/open source databases like MySQL and Postgres.
Grameen Foundation's MIFOS, and Ekgaon's various products are based on open-source
technologies. The vendors of most of the high-end databases now offer 'express' or 'lite'
versions of their products, which can be deployed in applications for free. Some of the high-
end features are disabled, but that is generally not a problem for MFIs.

The Microfinance Gateway and the MIX Market offer some online information about various
technologies, products and vendors.


6      The Way Ahead
6.1 New technologies
The field of micro-finance is becoming mainstream, and along with it, so is the technology for
this field. Several interesting players are just stepping in. With the advent of new players like
FINO, Grameen's MIFOS, Atyati's Ganaseva and Salesforce.com, and of new technologies like the
use of mobile phones, smart cards, and NFC, MFIs can look forward to having more and better
technology options at their disposal in the coming years.

Some of the technologies mentioned above, particularly smart cards and cell-phone based
readers, may be especially suited to banks providing savings services. Their costs are also
currently high enough that they can be afforded by banks only. This raises the question,
would banks take over microfinance, rendering MFIs superfluous?

                                                                                                 143
On the other hand, MFIs have several strengths of their own. They specialize in assessing and
                    originating micro-loans, in educating the customer, and in dealing with delinquencies. Even if
                    banks were to enter this field in a more direct manner, they would need to build up these
                    competencies. They might instead, prefer to continue to "outsource" these functions to MFIs.

                    6.2 Regulatory environment
                    One of the recent initiatives of the RBI has been the Business Facilitator and Business
                    Correspondent (BC) models (RBI 2006). The BC model is meant for the conduct of banking
                    business. Only NGOs/MFIs set up under Societies/Trusts acts, Societies registered under Mutually
                    Aided Cooperative Societies Acts or the Cooperative Societies Acts of States, section 25 companies,
                    and Post Offices may act as Business Correspondents2. The RBI has made it clear that the Bank is
                    responsible to the customer for the acts of the BC. Further, considering that the objective is to
                    extend banking services to the unbanked, the RBI has also allowed banks to rely upon certificates
                    of identification issued by the BC for the purpose of satisfying KYC norms.

                    BCs can perform a wide range of activities, including: assisting in the enrolment of new
                    customers, disbursal of small value credit, collection of small value deposits, recovery of
                    principal and collection of interest, receipt and delivery of payment instruments including
                    remittances, and the sale of third-party financial products. Thus, the BC model enables a
                    pooling of competencies between the bank, which can create financial products, but which
                    may not be able to deliver these products to all segments of the population, and the BC,
                    which does not have the ability to offer financial products, but which does have existing
                    infrastructure that can be used as a delivery channel to reach the financially excluded.

    The RBI has     The RBI has explicitly exhorted banks "to adopt technology-based solutions for managing the
       explicitly   risk, besides increasing the outreach in a cost effective manner." Using an IT solution is in any
exhorted banks
       "to adopt    case, almost a regulatory requirement, since transactions need to be reflected in the bank's
     technology-    books by the end of the day or the next working day. Within the guidelines issued by RBI, banks
based solutions
   for managing
                    and BCs have a fair amount of latitude in determining the payment systems to be used.
        the risk,
         besides    For example, IGS, a BASIX group company, has become a BC of Axis Bank. This project is being
 increasing the     operationalised first in Delhi and Muzaffarpur, Bihar, and it is particularly directed at migrants
   outreach in a
  cost effective    from Muzaffarpur working in Delhi who want to remit money back home to their families. To
        manner"     reduce the operational risk, customers are given smart cards which store their fingerprints.
                    Transactions are authorized and settled electronically, with the communications happening
                    through the mobile phone. Customer information is collected by IGS and passed on to the
                    bank. The bank opens a no-frills SB account for the customer. The information captured for
                    every customer, including his photograph and his fingerprints, is stored in the smart card
                    issued to him. He can withdraw and deposit money using this smart card at the terminal of the
                    IGS agent. Transactions are authenticated biometrically, using the stored fingerprints. A
                    printed receipt is provided to the customer for every transaction. The project is described in
                    more detail in Box 8.3.

                    It is interesting to note that nations such as Brazil, South Africa, and the Philippines are
                    ahead of India in using such technological and structural arrangements to promote financial
                    inclusion (CGAP 2006). In Brazil, a variety of retail agents are allowed to offer financial
                    services on behalf of banks, including post offices, lottery kiosks, and supermarkets. These


               144
CHAPTER 8
                                                                                                Microfinance and
                                                                                                Technology




"banking correspondents" have ensured that every single municipality in Brazil - 5800 of
them - have access to formal financial services. Similarly, in the Philippines, Globe Telecom
offers an e-money product tied to the mobile phone SIM card of the subscriber. While this is
meant to be used as a payments and remittance mechanism, many poor people also use it as a
savings account. In South Africa, mobile phone operators have tied up with banks to offer
cell-phone based bank accounts.

Today in India, technology makes it possible to have a one-man bank branch, at any place one           Today in India,
                                                                                                       technology
wishes. One individual, armed with a mobile phone, can do most of the cash-in cash-out functions       makes it
of a bank teller. While the BC model enables us to tap into this possibility, further changes in       possible to have
regulations will be required to make the BC model feasible on a large scale (Tankha 2006)              a one-man bank
                                                                                                       branch, at any
                                                                                                       place one
                 Box 8.3      TAFI: Putting mobile phone technology to                                 wishes. One
                                                                                                       individual,
                               work as a BC for remittances
                                                                                                       armed with a
                                                                                                       mobile phone,
BASIX, in collaboration with Axis Bank and A Little World (ALW), has launched an initiative in         can do most of
Delhi and Muzaffarpur, Bihar, called TAFI - Technology Assisted Financial Inclusion. This started      the cash-in
as a result of BASIX's efforts to provide financial access to migrant workers. Studies have            cash-out
                                                                                                       functions of a
found that rural people in Bihar have become highly mobile due to poor local employment                bank teller
prospects. The destination is often determined by social networks: people tend to go to
places where others from their village and caste have previously gone. Delhi is one of the
major destinations. Migrants remit a large part of their income, and these remittances greatly
improve the standard of living of their families. Many remittance mechanisms are used, including
money orders, private agents, and hand-carrying. Deshingkar3 (2006) quotes Rs 450 crore as
the amount of money sent through money orders to Bihar in 2005-06. Most of this would be
due to migrants. The amounts they hand-carry or send through private agents are each likely
to comparable to this amount.

Migrants find it very difficult to open bank accounts, and to save or borrow money from
formal sources. Money orders were also not preferred due to the cost (both official and unofficial),
unreliability and frequent delays. This forces them to rely on less-favoured unsafe/illegal
methods to send money back home, at a high cost. This issue could be easily solved if the
remitter and the payee each had access to a savings bank account. Also, such an account
could provide a proof of income and of credit-worthiness, allowing them to borrow from the
formal financial system. Hence, BASIX saw savings accounts as key to achieving financial
inclusion. We approached Axis Bank and ALW to be our partners. The plan was for IGS (a BASIX
group section 25 company) to become Axis Bank's Business Correspondent (BC), at Delhi and
at Muzaffarpur, using the technology provided by ALW. By using common delivery mechanisms
to provide the BC services and our other services, we hoped to keep the costs low.

We surveyed households in several areas in Muzaffarpur, and found that most households had
sent male family members to work outside the state, particularly to Kolkata and Delhi. In Delhi,
migrants from Muzaffarpur were concentrated in the slum area of Mandavali. From our survey in
Muzaffarpur, we were able to get the names and addresses of a large number of migrants in Delhi.
On an average, they send around Rs 1000-1500 per month back home. They commonly use
money orders, private agents, and sometimes, even bank drafts. We decided to offer our services
to the migrants in Mandavali and other slum dwellers. In Bihar, we decided to open our SPOTs
(Specified Point of Transaction) in Muzaffarpur town and in a few villages in the district.

We initially explored opening a joint account for the migrant in Delhi and his wife/relatives in

                                                                                                   145
But we soon      Bihar. But we soon learnt that they would prefer to avoid joint accounts - the migrants didn't
learnt that they     want their families in Bihar to have access to all their money! So we planned to open separate
 would prefer to
      avoid joint    no-frills savings accounts for the migrants and their families. Remittance would be just an
  accounts - the     account-to-account transfer. We needed a safe, secure and robust method for identifying and
 migrants didn't     authenticating customers, so we chose fingerprint-based authentication. After data is collected
       want their
      families in    and verified for each customer by IGS, Axis Bank vets it and opens a no-frills savings account
   Bihar to have     for him. A smartcard which stores his fingerprints, photo, and other details is issued to him.
    access to all
their money! So      Operating the account has been made as easy as possible. Each IGS agent has a kit: a mobile
  we planned to      phone, a fingerprint reader, and a printer. All these communicate with each other through the
  open separate
 no-frills savings   NFC chips built into them. To withdraw cash, the customer authenticates himself at the
accounts for the     fingerprint reader. When successfully authenticated, the reader authorizes a single transaction
    migrants and     on the card. Now, the agent presses his phone to the card. The phone reads the information
   their families
                     in the card, and displays a menu on its screen. The agent then chooses the appropriate menu
                     item and enters the amount the customer wishes to withdraw. The mobile phone checks the
                     customer's balance, and if there is enough money in the account, it informs the server about
                     the transaction, and gives the agent the go-ahead. The agent then pays the customer his
                     money. To print a receipt, the printer is brought in contact with the cellphone. The transaction
                     is committed only after the receipt is printed, ensuring safety. At the end of the day, an IGS
                     agent will visit the nearest Axis Bank branch to square the accounts.

                     For remittances, a customer (say, in Delhi) can register other customers (his wife in Bihar)
                     with us, as his payees. He can then transfer money from his account to theirs, and IGS shall
                     inform the recipient. The remittance fee is proposed to be just 0.5% of the amount. In the
                     initial stages of the project, the recipient shall have to come to the nearest SPOT to withdraw
                     the money. Later, our agents will travel through the villages, providing doorstep service to the
                     customers. The recipient will be paid within a day.

                     This technology is new to customers. To encourage them to use this mode of transaction, we
                     incentivise our agents by paying them a commission per transaction. However, this needs to
                     be carefully monitored, as it can be misused. The agents will be based at units situated close
                     to the customers. The project is still in its very early stages - at the time of writing, only a
                     month had passed since its inauguration. Within this short time, 1000 customers (both
                     migrants and non-migrant slum dwellers) had already enrolled. We hope to achieve break-even
                     in about 2 years.



                     6.3 Technology Fund
                     We already know that business process innovations backed by technology can make financial
                     services accessible to the poor. However, much work needs to be done to investigate the ways
                     to upscale these innovations to achieve complete financial inclusion. In his budget speech,
                     the Finance Minister has promised to create a Financial Inclusion Technology Fund, with the
                     objective: "to meet the costs of research and development, pilot testing and scaling up of
                     appropriate and cost-effective technologies for enhancing financial inclusion". This fund, if
                     properly utilised, will be of great help in promoting innovative ways of taking banking to the
                     unbanked. It can target projects that use technology to address financial exclusion by reducing
                     the transaction and monitoring costs, increasing the reach and scale of operations, and
                     preventing fraud. Some of the promising technologies it could support could be:

                146
CHAPTER 8
                                                                                                    Microfinance and
                                                                                                    Technology




       •       Technologies which use the increasing ubiquity of mobile phone networks and
               the internet for financial inclusion

       •       Methods to standardise and automate the calculation of customer credit risk to
               the extent possible

       •       Cheap, reliable and rugged ATMs

       •       Development of cheaper identification/authentication mechanisms

       •       Inexpensive smartcards and other secure ways of reducing - ideally eliminating
               - cash




Endnotes



1 Prashant Regy is Manager, Strategic Initiatives, BASIX and Vijay Mahajan is an electrical engineer, and
   Chairman, BASIX.

2 In the original circular (issued in January 2006), registered NBFCs not accepting public deposits were
   also allowed to become BCs, but in a subsequent circular, RBI adviced banks to avoid the use of NBFCs
   as BCs (with the exception of those NBFCs licenced under Section 25).

3 Deshingkar et al, 2006, "The Role of Migration and Remittances in Promoting Livelihoods in Bihar"




                                                                                                        147
References


  Saral Services, 2007, "Information and Communication Technology Survey of DCCBs and MFIs
  in India", Saral Services, Sheffield Hallam University, Oxford University, ODI, 2007

  Intellecap, 2006, "The Way Forward: Technology in Indian Microfinance", report for CARE
  India, Mumbai

  CGAP, 2005, Gautam Ivatury, and Nicole Pasricha, "Funding Microfinance Technology",
  Washinton DC

  Deshingkar et al, 2006, "The Role of Migration and Remittances in Promoting Livelihoods
  in Bihar"

  RBI, 2006, "Financial Inclusion by Extension of Banking Services", Mumbai

  CGAP 2006: Timothy R. Lyman, Gautam Ivatury, Stefan Staschen, "Use of Agents in Branchless
  Banking for the Poor", CGAP 2006

  Tankha, Ajay, 2006, "Challenges and potential for Indian banks to implement the Business
  Facilitator and Business Correspondent Models", NABARD and GTZ, 2006




148
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                             Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                             An Opportunity Being Lost?




                                        CHAPTER 9


          Regulation:
     The Microfinance Bill:
  An Opportunity Being Lost?
Finalization of the draft microfinance bill promised by the finance minister in his budget
speech of February 2005 has not only turned out to be a lengthy affair, as is common with
microfinance bills around the world, but the bill has undergone considerable modification
from the original version of the bill proposed by Sa-Dhan, the network of MFIs in India, after
extensive consultations within its membership. The fundamental changes in concept undergone The latest
                                                                                               version of the
by the bill in its various versions are described at greater length in Box 9.1.1 The bill was
                                                                                                     bill being
introduced in parliament as the Micro Financial Sector (Development and Regulation) Bill,            considered by
2007, on 20 March 2007, and was referred by the Lok Sabha to the Standing Committee of               the
                                                                                                     parliamentary
Finance, which was still considering it at the time this chapter went to the printers (at the        standing
end of September 2007). The chapter first describes the main objectives of the bill as it            committee on
                                                                                                     finance3,
presently stands. It then discusses the major issues arising out of it. It does so because
                                                                                                     applies only to
whatever the fate of the bill, the issues it raises will remain relevant to the sector for a long    three categories
time.2 Finally it draws attention to two regulatory steps the RBI could take immediately that        of not-for-profit
                                                                                                     MFIs: societies,
would have a much greater short-term impact on the sector than the bill itself, even if it gets      trusts and
passed in its present form.                                                                          cooperatives.
                                                                                                     These are
                                                                                                     collectively
The proposed microfinance bill                                                                       referred to in
                                                                                                     the bill as Micro
The latest version of the bill being considered by the parliamentary standing committee on           Finance
                                                                                                     Organizations
finance3, applies only to three categories of not-for-profit MFIs: societies, trusts and             (MFOs). It does
cooperatives. These are collectively referred to in the bill as Micro Finance Organizations          not cover the
                                                                                                     bulk of the
(MFOs). It does not cover the bulk of the sector in terms of share of borrowers and loans            sector in terms
outstanding, which is accounted for by MFIs registered as companies (for-profit NBFCs and            of share of
not-for-profit S 25 companies).4                                                                     borrowers and
                                                                                                     loans
                                                                                                     outstanding,
The bill contains both prudential and non-prudential provisions. The former seek to allow            which is
MFOs to offer what are referred to as "thrift" services, defined as savings collected through        accounted for
                                                                                                     by MFIs
groups,5 after obtaining a certificate of registration from the new regulator created by the bill,
                                                                                                     registered as
NABARD. NABARD may grant approval to an MFO to collect thrift if it has been in existence for        companies (for-
at least three years, has net owned funds of at least Rs 5 lakhs, and if NABARD is satisfied         profit NBFCs
                                                                                                     and not-for-
about the "general character" of the management of the MFO. Every MFO granted approval to            profit S 25
offer thrift services shall create a reserve fund out of transfers to the fund of not less than 15   companies)

                                                                                                 149
percent of its net profit or surplus every year, and will prepare financial statements by the end
                      of the year, in such form as may be specified, to be audited by an approved auditor.

                      Cooperatives are of course already empowered to offer much more than "thrift" to their members
                      as defined in the bill, since cooperative thrift or savings and credit societies offer their
                      members individual savings accounts as well as fixed deposits. It is widely accepted that as
                      mutual organizations prudential regulation of cooperatives can be much lighter than for
                      entities accepting non-member (or public) deposits. Now they find themselves being treated
                      on a par with societies and trusts. Sections of the cooperative movement feel understandably
                      aggrieved that they were not consulted during formulation of the bill,6 and feel threatened by
                      the uncertainties introduced by the arrival of the new regulator. A section of the cooperative
                      movement has opposed the bill vocally, as discussed below.

    While one of      While one of the main objectives of the bill is to allow NGO-MFIs to accept savings in the
         the main     limited form of group savings, the bill prescribes in addition the "duty" of the regulator to
    objectives of
    the bill is to    achieve the much broader non-prudential objective of promoting the "orderly growth of the
allow NGO-MFIs        micro financial sector so as to ensure greater transparency, effective management, good governance
        to accept
  savings in the
                      …" Among the measures suggested through which it may do so are (i) setting benchmarks
limited form of       and performance standards (ii) facilitating the development of credit ratings norms (iii)
 group savings,       specifying accounting and auditing standards (iv) facilitating institutional development
           the bill
    prescribes in     through training and capacity building (v) supporting sector related research (vi) documenting
    addition the      and disseminating information relating to fair practices (vii) laying down a code of conduct
   "duty" of the
                      and (viii) and promoting consumer education.
     regulator to
      achieve the
   much broader       The last three of these activities will support a third objective of the bill which is to create a
 non-prudential       consumer protection regime by enabling the regulator to appoint "as many Micro Finance
     objective of
  promoting the       Ombudsmen as it may deem fit" with powers to redress grievances by issuing directions to
"orderly growth       MFOs. A strict reading of the definition of MFO would seem to preclude the benefits of the
     of the micro
                      ombudspersons from applying to the clients of NBFCs and not-for-profitS 25 companies.
financial sector
so as to ensure
           greater    A fourth objective of the bill is to create a national data base "in the public domain" and
   transparency,      disseminate it through a "national dissemination network". To this end every MFO whether
         effective
   management,        providing thrift services or not will be required to file at the commencement of the act and at
             good     intervals thereafter, duly audited returns. While on the one hand no minimum size for the
governance …"         purpose of filing returns is laid down for the societies, trusts and cooperatives falling within
                      the purview of the bill, i.e. those offering "micro finance services",7 the bill on the other hand
                      provides no authority to seek returns from NBFCs. This is the case also for the first three of the
                      "orderly growth" activities listed above. With the exception of the training and research
                      activities, the orderly growth activities will apply only to MFOs. It is hard to see how therefore
                      the bill will succeed in promoting orderly growth for the sector as a whole, including equipping
                      it with a much needed data base.

                      Fifth, the bill provides for the setting up of a Micro Finance Development Council to advise the
                      regulator on the "formulation of policies, schemes, and other measures required in the interest
                      of orderly growth and development" of the sector. The Council shall consist of an experienced
                      "person of eminence" as chairman, 7 official members,8 and 6 non-official experts with experience
                      in rural banking and microfinance.



                150
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                             Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                             An Opportunity Being Lost?




Sixth, it provides for the continuation of the existing Micro Finance Development and Equity
Fund to receive grants from the government and donors, to make loans to MFOs, to invest in
their equity or quasi-equity, to make grants to them for capacity building, and to pay for the
various functions of the regulator enumerated above.

Finally, although this would be an effect rather than an explicit objective of the bill, it could   Finally,
                                                                                                    although this
be argued that by recognizing the legitimacy of their microfinance activities, the bill will
                                                                                                    would be an
enhance the legal status of NGO-MFIs, and will in effect protect them from arbitrary state          effect rather
government action. However it provides no protection against state moneylenders acts, or            than an explicit
                                                                                                    objective of the
even for that matter the central government's own Usurious Loans Act 1918, which is still on        bill, it could be
the statute books. S 21A of the Banking Regulation Act expressly exempts the rate of interest       argued that by
charged by banks from state moneylender acts, as well as from any other law related to              recognizing the
                                                                                                    legitimacy of
indebtedness in force in any state. There is no such provision in the present bill. In fact,        their
quite the opposite. S 36 says its provisions "shall be in addition to, and not in derogation of,    microfinance
                                                                                                    activities, the
the provisions of any other law for the time being in force".
                                                                                                    bill will enhance
                                                                                                    the legal status
Major issues                                                                                        of NGO-MFIs,
                                                                                                    and will in
                                                                                                    effect protect
The bill excludes the bulk of the sector                                                            them from
                                                                                                    arbitrary state
                                                                                                    government
One of the major omissions in the bill is that it excludes MFIs registered as NBFCs and S 25
                                                                                                    action. However
companies, which account for nearly all the large MFIs and the larger part of total microcredit     it provides no
in the country. Their number is steadily increasing as they are joined by more and more NGO-        protection
                                                                                                    against state
MFIs transforming themselves into companies in order to be able to attract equity investments       moneylenders
with which to leverage borrowed funds, and at the same time escape the vicissitudes of state        acts
government policy towards NGO-MFIs (NBFCs are regulated by the RBI).9 However, by including
only societies, trusts and cooperatives, the bills is proposing to cut out at one stroke 60
percent of the sector in terms of portfolio outstanding on March 2007, and 55 percent of the
total number of borrowers.10 It is doing so on the mistaken grounds that NBFCs are already
regulated by the RBI. They are -- RBI regulations recognize 10 categories of NBFCs including
loan, leasing, investment, and hire-purchase companies, and even a "residual" category of
NBFCs like Sahara and Prudential. But microfinance is not one of the recognized categories.
Nor have any of more than two dozen NBFCs conducting microcredit (defined in the bill as
loans smaller than Rs 50,000 for most purposes, and smaller than Rs 1.5 lakhs for housing)
managed to satisfy the stringent requirements that have been laid down by NBFC regulations
to become eligible to mobilize savings.

The irony is that not only can NBFC-MFIs not accept public deposits, but by virtue of being
excluded from the bill they will not be able to accept the savings of their own borrower-
members who will continue to have to rely on less convenient, riskier11 lower yielding, and
often socially less productive savings instruments (such as ornaments). There is understandable
reluctance to allow MFIs to mobilize public deposits, without putting in place the necessary
safequards, for sound prudential reasons. But the vast majority of MFI members are net borrowers
of the MFI at any one time.

They borrow to finance their larger investment requirements, but simultaneously save small
amounts regularly to finance their liquidity requirements, provide for emergencies, build up a
cushion to tide over the lean season when agricultural wage employment is scarce, and aggregate

                                                                                                151
savings into amounts large enough to make useful investments, repair the hut, send a daughter
                     to high school, or a son to the big city to look for work.

                     The argument adduced for keeping NBFCs outside the purview of the bill (the need to avoid
                     duality of regulation) is equally applicable to district, state and urban cooperative banks
                     which are governed by the Banking Regulation Act in respect of banking activities, while
                     conforming to the cooperative law in other respects. Like them, NBFCs would be governed by
                     the microfinance bill in respect of thrift activities, without any dilution of their capital,
                     reserve, or liquidity requirements as NBFCs, until they qualify under NBFC regulations to mobilize
                     not just thrift from members, but hopefully, also, public savings. It is true that dual regulation
                     of cooperative banks has not been a resounding success. However as Sinha points out (2007b)
                     UCBs are financed primarily by deposits, whereas MFIs, even after being allowed to accept
                     thrift, will always depend primarily on borrowings from the banks and the financial institutions,
                     and will be subject therefore to due diligence exercised by their lenders.12

      However as     In confusing the form of incorporation with the substantial nature of the institution, or form
    Sinha points
                     with function, the act will also deprive more than half of borrowers (the proportion is set to
   out (2007b)
        UCBs are     grow) from the protection of the ombudsman, and the sector as a whole from the benefits of
         financed    universal performance standards in respect of microfinance activities and a much needed data
     primarily by
        deposits,    base.
  whereas MFIs,
       even after    It allows NGO-MFIs to mobilize thrift: which is a small step forward
   being allowed
to accept thrift,
                     India's attitude to savings mobilization by non-banks has been more restrictive than elsewhere,
      will always
           depend    an attitude strengthened by periodic scams which affect the savings of the urban middle
     primarily on    classes and which therefore receive widespread publicity in the press. Most of the countries of
borrowings from
  the banks and      South Asia, which share the same legal heritage, now expressly allow savings in their microfinance
    the financial    legislation. Bangladesh, where conditions are closest to India, and where the MFI model
    institutions,
                     originated, has recently passed the Micro Credit Regulatory Authority (MCRA) Act 2006, which
      and will be
           subject   allows the MCRA to allow MFIs to offer savings withdrawable on demand. Sri Lanka also allows
therefore to due     NGO-MFIs to mobilize deposits once they have received the regulators permission.13 The
        diligence
    exercised by     provisions in the bill enabling savings, albeit in a limited form, are probably the single most
    their lenders    important contribution of the bill. However, ironically it is this aspect of the bill that has
                     been the most widely misunderstood by critics. These misunderstandings are dealt with
                     separately in Box 9.2.

                     There is also a widespread misconception that the poor are too poor to save, and that they
                     need credit, not savings facilities and services. On the contrary, savings is probably a more
                     widely felt need than credit, and takes place through a variety of savings mechanisms and
                     institutions in the informal sector, such as itinerant deposit collectors,14 small community
                     chit funds, informal credit unions (such as the bishis of Maharashta), investments in livestock
                     or ornaments (which can later be liquefied through the pawnbroker and moneylender), or by
                     lending to a friend in need so that the lender can borrow reciprocally when required.15 The
                     phenomenal growth of the SHG movement in which rural women meet with unfailing regularity
                     once a month to save small sums ranging from Rs 10 to 50, and the fact that poor urban slum
                     dwellers, far from earning interest on their savings, are willing to pay to have their deposits
                     collected at the doorstep and stored safely until they amount to a useful sum, and countless
                     other examples, attest to the importance of the almost universal need to save. Like the rest

                152
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                              Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                              An Opportunity Being Lost?




of us, the poor are looking for savings services which are convenient, safe, liquid, and can
preferably be used to leverage loans.

By allowing at least MFOs to meet this need, the draft microfinance bill takes a long overdue,    Because Indian
albeit small step forward.16 Quite apart from the benefits to MFO members, there will be benefits MFIs have had
                                                                                                  to rely
to the MFOs themselves - their cost of funds will come down, and their members' sense of          exclusively on
ownership in their MFO will increase, since a part of the loans they will be getting will be theirfunds borrowed
                                                                                                  from the banks,
own money coming back to them, giving them a further incentive to maintain high repayment         their financial
rates. Because Indian MFIs have had to rely exclusively on funds borrowed from the banks, expense ratios
their financial expense ratios (cost of funds as a proportion of total costs) are the highest in (cost of funds
                                                                                                  as a proportion
the world (see Chapter 4 of last year's report). In Bangladesh, on the other hand, interest rates of total costs)
are slightly lower than in India, because as much as a third of the funds base comes from are the highest
                                                                                                  in the world
member savings. Many Bangladeshi MFIs also pay a slightly higher rate to savers than the
banks, because of the cost efficiencies that ensue from economies of scope in being able to
use existing field staff, who have to meet borrowers once a week anyway to collect loan
repayment installments and disburse fresh loans. Grameen Bank mobilizes in fact more savings
than it disburses as credit (as does Bank Rakyat Indonesia, further examples of how savings
are as valued by poor clients as credit).

How can it be ensured that the vast majority of MFIs members remain net borrowers at any one
time? (i) First, by licensing MFIs to collect savings only after they have established a track
record as lenders. (ii) Second, once licensed, by limiting acceptance of savings only to their
borrowers and not the public. (iii) Third, by ensuring that not more than a small proportion
of the borrowers of the MFI are net savers at any one time, or in other words have more savings
deposited than loans outstanding.17 (iv) Fourth, by laying down a ceiling on the total savings
that can be mobilized as a proportion of the liquid assets of the MFI in the form of loans
outstanding at any one time, the savings/loans outstanding ratio could be set, say, at 50
percent, which would ensure that the MFI would also have to borrow to fund its loans and
thereby subject itself to the normal scrutiny that any lender such as bank or financial institution
would exercise (Sinha 2007b). (v) A further prudential measure would be to prescribe a liquidity
reserve, the size of which should depend on the liquidity of savings offered.18 While the bill
provides for the first two of these conditions, Section 10 (1) (e) enables the regulator to lay
down the remaining three or any other condition it deems appropriate.

… however, it remains a rather small step: compulsory versus
voluntary savings
While the proposal to allow thrift is welcome and long overdue, it is important to note it is
only the first small step forward in introducing savings. Quite apart from the fact that it only
applies to MFOs, thrift is defined in the bill as monies collected by a micro finance organization
only from "a group, or by a group from its members through the group mechanism…" What
this definition seems to have in mind is the kind of uniform, mandatory, monthly savings
service offered by SHGs in India, and by the smaller joint liability groups used by MFIs in
Bangladesh, the Philippines, and in more than 45 other countries which have MFIs based on
the Grameen Bank model.

While many savers welcome the discipline of compulsory savings, they tend to belong to the
better-off among the poor or to the "near-poor" above the poverty line. On the other hand

                                                                                                  153
many of the poorer members of SHGs (and most of the self-excluded non-members), who have
                     highly uncertain and variable incomes, would prefer to save small variable amounts, with variable
                     frequency (Rutherford 2005). Several surveys have found that the main reason for why only
                     half the members of SHGs are below the poverty line is the inability of BPL persons to commit
                     themselves to the required mandatory savings amounts and periodicities. Uniform mandatory
                     savings are also the most frequent reason cited by drop-outs for leaving SHGs.19

           Indeed,   A concomitant of mandatory savings products is their illiquidity. While illiquid savings protect
 recognizing the
                     the savings of the poor from daily demands, and are suited to accumulating lump-sums for
         liquidity
    preference of    expected purposes such as life-cycle events or school fees or adding a new room to the hut,
     the poor for    they are unsuited to coping with unexpected emergencies including sickness and disease, or
  many although
  not all savings    consumption smoothening in the lean season, or replacing a leaky roof in the middle of the
        purposes,    monsoons (CGAP 2005a). While the SHG movement provides for unexpected demands to some
 several MFIs in     extent, through small intra-group loans, and the MFI model does so through "emergency
Bangladesh, and
   indeed world-     loans", these are an imperfect substitute for being able to access ones own savings quickly in
wide, who have       an emergency.
    the requisite
      accounting
                     Indeed, recognizing the liquidity preference of the poor for many although not all savings
    systems, are
     moving to a     purposes, several MFIs in Bangladesh, and indeed world-wide, who have the requisite accounting
       system of     systems, are moving to a system of voluntary savings in which the saver has some choice over
        voluntary
       savings in    the timing and amount of savings and withdrawals. Some Bangladesh MFIs have introduced
which the saver      "open access" savings (in which savers have access to their savings whenever they like), and
has some choice
                     have found that the inflow of total savings far from declining has in fact increased,20 (See Box
over the timing
  and amount of      9.3 and Wright 2000).21 It is not being suggested that most small Indian NGO-MFIs have
     savings and     developed the requisite systems yet to be able to able to offer such a savings product,22 or
     withdrawals
                     that mandatory savings do not have their advantages for certain purposes.

                     However, provision should be made for the day when a larger number of NGO-MFIs have developed
                     the requisites systems and capacity to offer voluntary savings.23 Since voluntary savings are
                     more conveniently offered as individual savings (because voluntary savings amounts and
                     frequency will always vary from individual to individual), it would seem essential to allow the
                     regulator the option to approve individual, voluntary, savings products in appropriate cases
                     after due diligence by the regulator on a case by case basis.

                     In order to do so, the words "or by other means" need to be inserted after the words "group
                     mechanism" in the definition of thrift in clause 2 (l) of the Bill. Also, the exclusion in the
                     definition of thrift of current accounts and demand deposits needs to be removed. These
                     would be enabling provisions in the case of most MFOs for now, but a very useful one when the
                     time comes (given the difficulties of securing amendments to a legislative act in the future).

                     A third amendment required it to clearly exclude SHG federations from the definitions of groups.
                     The phrase in the definition of "group" "or a group called by any other name" has created
                     apprehensions to the contrary. The definition requires a group to provide micro finance services
                     to individual members of the group, which many federations do (see Chapter 3).24

                     Should cooperatives be covered by the Act?
                     Cooperatives are defined in the bill to include all cooperatives except cooperative banks and


                154
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                             Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                             An Opportunity Being Lost?




cooperatives "engaged in agricultural operations".25 India's has for a long time had a large
thrift cooperative movement which at one time was one of the strongest in the world.26 There
is no estimate at present of the number of thrift cooperatives, or even of those registered
under the new MACS acts (see below). At one time NABARD did publish data on cooperatives
on the basis of information received from state registrars but has for some years stopped
doing so.27 The responsibility for regulation and supervision of PACS is being transferred to
NABARD under the central government's Revival Package for the Rural Cooperative Thrift and
Credit System.28 With the present bill a similar responsibility is being conferred on NABARD for
thrift cooperatives.

The issue with respect to bringing thrift cooperatives under the bill is that cooperatives, as The
mutual organizations, are already allowed to accept savings from their members. Indeed the responsibility
                                                                                                     for regulation
term thrift has been in use by thousands of cooperatives in India for several decades now29          and supervision
and has been further popularized by the Cooperative Development Foundation, a well known             of PACS is being
                                                                                                     transferred to
civil society organization registered as an NGO in Andhra Pradesh, which spearheaded the             NABARD under
movement for cooperative reform, and lobbied with the AP legislature to enact the Mutually           the central
Aided Cooperative Societies Act or APMACS Act in 1995. This was followed by the enactment            government's
                                                                                                     Revival Package
of similar acts in 8 other states and a central multi-state act to provide for a new type of         for the Rural
"mutually aided" or "mutual benefit"30 cooperative which would be much truer to cooperative          Cooperative
                                                                                                     Thrift and
principles than traditional cooperatives under existing state acts, and enjoy much more
                                                                                                     Credit System.
autonomy and freedom from government interference of the kind that has led to the                    With the
deterioration of traditional cooperatives.31                                                         present bill a
                                                                                                     similar
                                                                                                     responsibility is
CDF has set up 450 "mutually aided", women's and men's thrift cooperatives under the new act         being conferred
in Warangal, and two neighbouring districts of AP, which exercise a powerful demonstration           on NABARD for
                                                                                                     thrift
effect on how savings and credit cooperatives should function. With meticulous accounts,
                                                                                                     cooperatives
good governance, compulsory monthly thrift ranging from Rs 20 to 50, and membership of
about 250 each, they have mobilized own funds or member savings in various forms to the
tune of Rs 46 crores (by March 2007), of which Rs 40 crores has been lent back to members.
CDF is strongly opposed to MACS being brought under the bill since they are already empowered
to mobilize thrift. It fought a long battle to rescue cooperatives from the ill advised attempt
over the years to assist cooperatives with subsidies so as to convert them into vehicles for
political patronage, and is understandably worried about coming under the oversight of an
organization it fears may not understand the MACS ethos. It is strongly opposed to MACS
being brought under the bill.

The bill does indeed empower the central government to exempt a particular class of microfinance
organization from any or all the provisions of the Act, and it will have to do so for SHGs of
which there were 2.86 million by March 2007, and which can not possibly be expected to
apply for registration to mobilize savings individually. However CDF and the MACS community
(including, reportedly, the AP government setting up SHG federations registered as MACS
under IKP) are understandably reluctant to depend on government to exempt them as a class
after the bill becomes law. As a vocal civil society organization CDF has experienced considerable
opposition from the state government on a host of issues in the past, an instance of which
was the AP government's action to foreclose the MACS option for dairy cooperatives, a matter
which CDF took to the AP High Court and had overturned. A more recent instance is the ban
the AP government has placed on further registration of thrift cooperatives as MACS. CDF is


                                                                                                 155
likely to lead the challenge to the bill on the grounds that as mutual organizations cooperatives
                     are already allowed to mobilize thrift under the principle of mutuality, and on other grounds.

                     The alternatives however are not clear. There has been little effective supervision of thrift
                     cooperatives by the state registrars of cooperative societies, even under the new acts. None
                     of the states with MACS acts have appointed a separate set of registrars at the state of district
                     level, who continue to exercise jurisdiction under both acts. Perhaps for reasons of lack of
                     proper orientation under the MACS acts the registrars have shown little inclination to discharge
                     the functions entrusted to them under the statute.32

                     Although prudential concerns are greatly softened by the member-owned nature of cooperatives,
                     they are not entirely eliminated. While it is unique among the nine MACS acts in this respect,
                     the AP MACS act allows societies to accept deposits even from non-members and many of them
                     do. Also, as the Union Task Force on Revival of Cooperative Credit Institutions points out,
                     most cooperative members restrict membership with full voting rights to borrowers. Depositors
                     are categorized as nominal members33 without full voting rights, or are not given any membership
                     status. Cooperative boards tend therefore to be dominated by borrowers. Thorat and Wright
                     have suggested that restrictions on loans to board members and strengthening the presence
                     of net savers on cooperative boards will lead to more effective pressure on cooperative
                     management to ensure prudent governance and protect the interest of savers (Thorat and
                     Wright 2006).

         Although    Effective supervision is important not only at the primary level but also at the secondary level.
        prudential   SHG federations registered as MACS have become important players in the sector in AP, where
     concerns are
greatly softened     the two tiers of SHG federations at the village and mandal level, as we have seen in Chapter 3,
 by the member-      have either already been, or are slated to be, registered as MACS. Orissa, where federations
owned nature of
    cooperatives,
                     have been formed in every panchayat of the state (but are not yet active) has also registered
     they are not    its federations under the Orissa Self Help Cooperatives Act, the equivalent of the MACS in the
          entirely   state. Other states may well adopt the MACS form of registration for their federations. At
      eliminated.
       While it is   present, according to one observer, the relationship of such federations with the MACS act
    unique among     ends as soon as they have been registered, and they simply exist in the books of the district
   the nine MACS
                     registrar.34
      acts in this
 respect, the AP
MACS act allows      The supervision of thousands of thrift cooperatives all over the country is going to be a huge
      societies to   task compared to the supervision of the much smaller number of societies and trusts providing
 accept deposits
  even from non-     microfinance services whose number is estimated at not more than a thousand. Rather than
     members and     seeking to supplant the registrars all over the country it might be more practicable (and
    many of them
                     certainly more in accordance of the spirit of cooperation) for the states to energize the state
                do
                     registrars and ensure they carry out their obligations under the old and new acts.

                     A third alternative is for MACS conducting microfinance to set up a system of self-regulation
                     a possible solution being studied by APMAS.35 At the very least a careful study of the situation
                     on the ground would seem desirable before rushing into a supervisory solution that might not
                     be practicable (apart from being possibly unconstitutional, unless the states sign on to it as
                     some of them have to the broader cooperative reform programme36). Also, as discussed below,
                     while NABARD does have a presence in the field, it is not clear whether it is willing to employ
                     the resources necessary to supplement it if required by the added workload. The decision
                     should hinge on which agency is likely to have greater commitment, resources and expertise.37

                156
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                              Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                              An Opportunity Being Lost?




As already noted, one of the purposes of the bill is to create a data base in the public domain
containing essential information such as the number and type of MFOs of different kinds, the
number of borrowers (and now savers), the quantum of lending and savings (or in other words
something as basic as the size of the sector), and a host of other variables the lack of which
is an important gap in the knowledge base essential for sound policy making for the sector.38
However, despite the reporting requirements in the MACS acts, data on MACS is as deficient as
it is on societies and trusts. It would seem advisable therefore to find a way of at least
including cooperatives in respect of the reporting requirements of the bill, and perhaps also
those relating to its consumer protection provisions, since not all cooperatives, whether
traditional or MACS, have as good and responsive a governance as those organized by CDF.39 At
the very least the actual position with respect to this and other issues needs to be examined
at the field level and discussed much more widely and openly than they have been so far.

Who should the regulator be?
The bill initially prepared by Sa-Dhan envisaged that the regulator would be the Micro Finance        The bill initially
                                                                                                      prepared by Sa-
Development Council itself, which would have body corporate status, and consist of a                  Dhan envisaged
chairperson, not more than five whole-time members, and not more than four part-time members.         that the
All the members were to be persons of experience in micro finance and related disciplines,            regulator would
                                                                                                      be the Micro
with not less than half representing the micro finance, NGO or the rural development sectors.         Finance
Members would hold office for up to five yeares. The Council would be much more than an               Development
                                                                                                      Council itself,
advisory body. Apart from all the powers of the regulator listed above, it would be the registering
                                                                                                      which would
authority for MFOs and MFIs as well as for the empanelment of rating agencies and chartered           have body
accountants.                                                                                          corporate
                                                                                                      status, and
                                                                                                      consist of a
Although it would have been the appointing authority of the Council, the government felt              chairperson, not
unable to cede regulatory authority to an independent professional authority and opted for            more than five
                                                                                                      whole-time
NABARD as the regulator in the version of the bill that was submitted to parliament. Considerable
                                                                                                      members, and
unease has been expressed in the sector at his choice, primarily on grounds of its conflict of        not more than
interest with NABARD's role as the promoter and champion of one particular model of                   four part-time
                                                                                                      members. All
microfinance, the SHG-bank linkage model. Other observers have identified the alleged source          the members
of conflict as coming from the opposite direction, from the fact that NABARD is an investor           were to be
in, and lender to, MFIs through the MFDEF. However this is an unlikely source of bias - the           persons of
                                                                                                      experience in
major criticism of the MFDEF is that it has been extremely slow so far in getting off the ground      micro finance
on account of excessive caution by NABARD on account of bureaucracy and lack of familiarity           and related
                                                                                                      disciplines,
with the MFI model. Besides the MFDEF board has non-official sector representatives on it.            with not less
                                                                                                      than half
What is surprising, however, is that after NABARD had been named the regulator in the pending         representing
bill, it announced that it was planning to float a huge retail MFI of its own called Nabard           the micro
                                                                                                      finance, NGO or
Financial Services, or NABFINS, as an NBFC. The proposal was reportedly motivated by a desire         the rural
to act as a role model to the sector.40 As has been pointed out NABFINSs would be more of a           development
                                                                                                      sectors
role model if it were to be set up in the one of the underserved parts of the country. Being a
majority owner of an MFI would be a clear conflict of interest for NABARD.

Some observers have argued that the regulator ought to be the RBI.41 The RBI of course
already regulates MFI-NBFCs, along with thousands of other NBFCs. Were it to create a separate
category of NBFCs with requirements more suited to microfinance, as recommended below,
their number is not likely to exceed more than a few dozen for at least some years, which is

                                                                                                  157
surely a manageable supervisory task. However, it would not seem feasible for the RBI to
                      supervise MFOs, even without coopearatives.

                      Sa-Dhan in its submission to the Standing Committee is reported to sought to have attempted
                      to partly retrieve the original concept of an independent authority by urging that 50 percent
                      of the members of the Council's proposed 14 members be selected from the microfinance
                      sector (instead of, as currently proposed, 7 from officialdom, 6 non-official experts and a
                      chairman) and also that the Council's decisions should be binding on the implementing
                      agencies under the act. It is unlikely that this good suggestion will be accepted.

                      What about supervision?
 "it is relatively    There has been virtually no discussion of what arrangements NABARD envisages to implement
          easy and    its regulatory responsibilities through supervision. As CGAP 2003 points out "it is relatively
   interesting to
              craft   easy and interesting to craft regulations, but harder and less attractive to do the concrete
regulations, but      practical planning for effective supervision…the result may be regulation that is not enforced,
  harder and less
attractive to do
                      which can be worse than no regulation at all". We have already touched on the problems of
      the concrete    regulating thousands of thrift cooperatives. To supervise societies and trusts, field supervisory
          practical   personnel will have to be trained in microfinance methods and operations, and special skills
       planning for
          effective   such as portfolio testing. NABARD does have a field presence in the districts but it may have
supervision…the       to supplement it, not just to carry out supervisory responsibilities but to assist the
    result may be
                      ombudspersons and participate in the data gathering effort. The extra costs will have to be
  regulation that
 is not enforced,     realistically estimated, and provided for.
     which can be
   worse than no      Consumer protection
     regulation at
               all"
                      Although the bill does not explicitly use the term consumer protection, and the final version
                      of the bill now merely enables the appointment of one or more ombudspersons rather than
                      make it mandatory, and that too only for NGO-MFIs, it specifies several of the important
                      features of a consumer protection regime by suggesting such measures as a code of conduct,
                      disseminating information on fair practices, and promoting consumer education. The last
                      three of these are also a fruitful area for collaboration between the regulator and the industry
                      through self-regulation.

                      Among the positive effects of the Krishna district episode in March 2006 (Chapter 4 of last
                      year's report) was the fact that many of its lessons for MFI practices were recognized and
                      codified in Sa-Dhan's interim code of conduct (Box 4.1 of last year's report). The interim code
                      emphasized among other things the need to (i) avoid over-financing of the same household
                      by different MFIs, (ii) make interest rates more transparent, (iii) ensure that staff do not use
                      abusive language or intimidation tactics while collecting repayments, (iv) ensure high standards
                      of corporate governance by including on MFI boards eminent independent board members,
                      and (v) stay in touch with government authorities, banks and the media on a regular basis.

                      The interim code was replaced with a statement of "core values and a voluntary mutual code of
                      conduct" released at Sa-Dhan's annual conference in January 2007. The first part of the
                      statement, relating to core values reiterated that MFI services will be delivered in an "ethical,
                      dignified, transparent, equitable and cost effective" manner. Clients should be educated about
                      the terms of loans offered to them, and a balance struck between respect for a client's dignity,
                      an understanding of her vulnerability, and a "reasonable pursuit" of loan recovery.
                158
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                              Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                              An Opportunity Being Lost?




The Code of Conduct itself is part II of the statement, parts of which are reproduced in Box
9.4. Part III of the statement provides for the setting up of an Ethics and Grievance Redressal
Committee to look into cases of non-compliance by member MFIs, leading to expulsion from
Sa-Dhan if warranted.

The existence of a code of conduct should make it unnecessary for the regulator to prepare its       Now that the
own, although it will have to adopt it formally (with modifications if need to be) so as to give     sector has
                                                                                                     experienced at
it legal sanction, and bring within its purview NGO-MFIs that are not members of Sa-Dhan. As         first hand how
discussed in last year's report, many difficult questions remain in translating the general          bad practice by
                                                                                                     some members
principles in the code of conduct into specifics, such as when exactly competition become            can undermine
unethical, or what constitutes over-lending, or above what level interest rates become               the reputation
"unreasonable". Individual grievances brought before the ombudsmen (if and when appointed)           of sector as a
                                                                                                     whole, members
will also serve to put flesh and bones on these principles, just as the decisions of the courts      of the
continue to add to the general law.                                                                  committee will
                                                                                                     hopefully be
                                                                                                     more likely than
A much broader role for self-regulation was envisaged as early as 1998, when a task force was
                                                                                                     before to
set up by the RBI under the chairmanship of NABARD. (Box 9.5). Although nothing came of              overcome any
the initiative, and there are no examples of comprehensive self-regulation being successful          natural
                                                                                                     reluctance they
anywhere in the world, consumer protection is one area where self-regulation has a major role        may feel about
to play (CGAP 2005b). Now that the sector has experienced at first hand how bad practice by          making adverse
                                                                                                     evaluative
some members can undermine the reputation of sector as a whole, members of the committee
                                                                                                     judgements
will hopefully be more likely than before to overcome any natural reluctance they may feel           about their
about making adverse evaluative judgements about their peers, which has been the Achilles            peers, which
                                                                                                     has been the
Heel of self-regulation in other areas. It is all the more important that they do so in view of      Achilles Heel of
the fact that the legal backing of the bill will be available, if at all, only for breaches of the   self-regulation
code by NGO-MFI members. The precipitating factor behind the chain of events set into                in other areas

motion by the Krishna district episode on the other hand were allegations of misconduct by
NBFC members. The advantage of the Sa-Dhan code is that it applies to all members.


Two other regulatory issues are as important as the
microfinance bill
There are two important areas of reform that would have a more immediate impact on financial
inclusion, at least in respect of credit services, than the bill as presently drafted, essential
though legislation is in the long run, if microfinance in India is to "enter the arena of
licensed, prudentially supervised financial intermediation" (CGAP 2003) as it has in most
other countries with microfinance acts. Both areas lie within the jurisdiction of the RBI. The
first is less intractable politically, and depends very much on the attitude and stance of the
RBI towards commercial microfinance through for-profit institutions such as NBFCs. The real
questions with respect to the first area therefore is RBI's vision of the role of microfinance in
India as discussed in Chapter 1.

If the RBI wanted to, it could easily create a new category of Microfinance NBFC more suited
to microfinance than that the RBI's present NBFC guidelines. If the microfinance bill is not
amended to include NBFCs, or enacted at all, the RBI could take the liberal view that thrift
contributions do not constitute public deposits,42 and allow these new MFI-NBFCs to mobilize
member-savings. After all, this is the implicit view taken by the bill with respect to NGO-MFI

                                                                                                 159
member-savings, and would be in keeping with the RBI's own bold view taken in the mid-90s
                     that SHG member savings do not constitute public savings because SHGs partake of the nature
                     of member-owned mutual institutions despite being purely informal. Without this interpretation
                     by the RBI at the time, the SHG bank linkage programme would never have happened. As
                     noted earlier, the regulatory task of supervising the relatively small number of new MFI-NBFCs
                     will remain manageable.43

                     The second area is more sensitive politically, and relates to the interest cap on loans below Rs 2
                     lakhs for commercial banks, which is fixed at the prime lending rate. This issue has been discussed
                     in detail elsewhere, including last year's report, and will not be expanded upon here, but it is
                     important to note that it relates to a restriction that is self-imposed by the RBI, although the
                     RBI would no doubt want to consult the government before removing it. The main effect of the
                     restriction is to deny credit to poor borrowers, and its removal is likely to see a significant
                     expansion of micro and small loans, whose share in total lending and number of accounts has
                     been steadily declining. It will be interesting to see whether the Committee on Financial Inclusion
                     will have the political will to include it in its reommendations.44

   So ambivalent     Because the cap applies to the business correspondent model too, it has effectively killed that
is the bill about    model on the lending side. As discussed in last year's report (Chapter 7A) the PLR does not
  savings that it
    does not use     allow enough headroom for the bank to compensate the correspondent for its loan initiation,
        the word     monitoring and collection services.
 "savings" once.
 Even "thrift" is
  not included in    Conclusion45
   the bill in the
    definition of
                     The bill makes a small beginning in introducing savings to less than half the sector, but in far
  "micro finance
        services"    too limited a form. Savings are defined much too narrowly as "thrift" or small compulsory
                     periodic savings. One does not have to agree with much of the microfinance literature which
                     argues that these contributions are not savings at all, but are viewed by most borrowers as
                     part of the cost of borrowing, which they passively accept as a condition of accessing loans
                     rather than value for their own sake. This does not seem to be generally true in India, where
                     savings have been the most successful part of the SHG programme (too successful it could be
                     argued, because productive opportunities to use the savings haven't kept pace with their
                     growth). But it is the case that the inflexibility of compulsory savings has kept the poorest
                     out of the programme, as many surveys show.

                     So ambivalent is the bill about savings that it does not use the word "savings" once. Even
                     "thrift" is not included in the bill in the definition of "micro finance services". It has even
                     been suggested that the primary motivation of the RBI, if not of the government, in promoting
                     the bill, is to address the concern expressed by some that the whole SHG programme is illegal
                     because it allegedly violates the Banking Regulation Act. This concern is unfounded, since
                     SHGs, although purely informal and unregistered, are mutual organizations. As noted above, it
                     was this bold view taken by the then RBI governor that allowed the banks to lend to SHGs and
                     give rise to the largest, and so far one of the most successful, microfinance programmes in the
                     world. The approach at present seems timid in comparision.

                     Second, by excluding companies, the bill not only denies a large part of the sector the direct
                     benefits of the bill (mobilization of member savings, and possibly consumer protection if the
                     regulator decides to provide it) it denies the sector as a whole the indirect sector-wide

                160
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                              Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                              An Opportunity Being Lost?




benefits. While some "orderly growth" activities could be taken care of by the RBI for NBFCs,
such as setting performance and accounting standards, it is unlikely to be able to set up a
consumer protection regime or build a data base, even for the MFI-NBFCs under its purview,46
for lack of supervisory resources.

The bill confers a modicum of legitimacy on the most vulnerable part of the sector, the NGO-
MFIs, but is careful not to step on the toes of the states by failing to assert that the principle
of cost-recovering interest rates takes precedence over caps on interest rates under state
moneylender acts, although this principle has recently been implicitly recognized by the
Technical Group to Review Legislations on Moneylending (RBI 2007).47 The group has
recommended that societies and trusts should be exempted from the purview of moneylender
acts, and that state governments in setting interest rate caps, should "look at the range of
interest rates being charged by micro finance entities".

The bill violates the spirit and intent of the new MACS acts in reducing the role of government Given these and
                                                                                                  other
in cooperation. It is true that the registrars under the new acts are not performing supervisory,
                                                                                                     limitations of
data gathering and consumer protection functions any better than the old ones, but will the          the bill, and the
new regulator be able to do a better job for thousands of thrift cooperatives all over the           fact that
                                                                                                     amendments to
country? In any case cooperation is a state subject, and the states will have to sign on,            an act once
unless the courts take the narrow view that accepting thrift even from one's own member-             passed are not
                                                                                                     easy to make,
borrowers constitutes "banking", which is a central subject.
                                                                                                     many observers
                                                                                                     feel it may be
The bill does not provide the sector with a form of registration uniquely suited to microfinance.    desirable for
It leaves NGO-MFIs with no alternative between remaining NGOs and having to raise enough             the sector to
                                                                                                     wait a little
capital to become NBFCs.48 Societies and trusts were not designed as vehicles for financial          longer till
operations, and although NGO-MFIs are non-profits, they have a hard time convincing the              further debate,
local income tax authorities that their surpluses are intended for expansion and leverage of         advocacy, and
                                                                                                     field studies,
borrowed funds. Yet Rs 2 crores is too much for many NGOs to raise, especially as an NGO is not      where
allowed to contribute its accumulated surpluses to the equity of a new NBFC for tax reasons.49       necessary, lead
                                                                                                     to a better
Rs 25 lakhs as the entry capital requirement for the special-window "MFIs" envisaged seemed          understanding
about right when the first version of the bill was formulated. However, it could be increased to     of microfinance
Rs 50 lakhs now. Special-window MFIs would constitute a valuable intermediate stage of               among policy
                                                                                                     makers, and
incorporation between remaining an NGO and becoming a full-fledged NBFC.                             indeed among
                                                                                                     many sector
Finally, as we have seen the nature and composition of the Microfinance Development Council          players
                                                                                                     themselves
leave much to be desired. Given these and other limitations of the bill, and the fact that
amendments to an act once passed are not easy to make, many observers feel it may be
desirable for the sector to wait a little longer till further debate, advocacy, and field studies,
where necessary, lead to a better understanding of microfinance among policy makers, and
indeed among many sector players themselves. They would argue that some of the benefits of
the bill can be partly provided through self-regulation, such as those relating to consumer
protection and the "orderly growth" activities, and that the costs of postponing enactment
of the bill are lower than enacting it without major amendments. The main cost would be the
loss of the limited go-ahead to "thrift" services, and of the modicum of legitimacy the bill
should impart to public and state level bureaucratic perceptions of microfinance.

It is not an easy choice, but at least it needs to be widely debated by the sector before the
parliamentary committee completes its work.

                                                                                                 161
Box 9.1     The microfinance bill: a case study in dilution

  The draft bill initially prepared by Sa-Dhan envisaged that the regulator would be an independent
  professional body appointed by the central government. It also proposed the creation of a
  two-tier structure for the sector, with two categories of microfinance service providers. Micro
  Finance Organizations (MFOs) would be allowed to mobilize savings only from members and be
  subjected to simple reporting requirements. Once they had a loan portfolio of more than Rs 1
  crore however, they would have to convert themselves into companies as "Micro Finance
  Institutions", but with a lower entry capital requirement than is required currently for NBFCs
  (Rs 25 lakhs instead of Rs 1 crore). This special window would have made it much easier for
  NGO-MFIs to transform to company status, which is more suited to microfinance operations as
  discussed earlier. Micro Finance Institutions, on the other hand, would be allowed to mobilize
  savings from the public subject to several conditions.

  However, after extensive inter-agency consultations led by the Ministry of Finance, the bill
  actually submitted to government in August 2006 for inter-ministerial discussion and Cabinet
  consideration took the form of an amendment to the NABARD Act which nominated NABARD as
  the regulator, giving the Council only an advisory role. In this modified version not only was
  the two-tier structure abandoned, NBFCs were dropped from the bill altogether. In the third
  and final version that was presented to parliament it became apparent that four further
  changes had taken place.50 The bill was no longer an amendment bill to an existing act (the
  NABARD) act, but a bill relating to a new act, and was renamed the Micro Finance Sector
  (Development and Regulation) Bill, 2007. The composition of the Council, which had already
  become merely advisory, was changed from being primarily non-official and professional, to
  predominantly official. Not-for-profit S 25 companies were dropped from the definition of
  MFOs, who were to consist now only of societies, trusts and cooperatives. Finally, the proposal
  to create an ombudsman went from being mandatory to merely enabling. Table 9.1 summarizes
  the major differences between the three versions, and Table 9.2 differences between MFOs and
  the new "MFIs" (the proposal to create which has now been dropped).




162
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                        Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                        An Opportunity Being Lost?




            Table 9.1 Successive versions of the microfinance bill
                 Original bill proposed    Modified bill            Current version
                 by Sa-Dhan in             circulated by Ministry   approved by Cabinet
                 consutation with          of Finance for inter-    and introduced in
                 members and key           agency discussion        parliament
                 government agencies
Name             Micro Finance             National Bank for        The Micro Financial
                 Development Council       Agriculture and Rural    Sector (Development
                 Act, 2005                 Development              and Regulation) Act,
                                           (Amendment) Bill,        2007 (Bill No. 41 of
                                           2006                     2007)
Scope            All existing categories   New category of "MFI"    Only NGO-MFIs
                 of MFIs, including a      dropped, but MFOs        registered as
                 new category of "MFI"     defined to include all   societies, trust and
                 registered as a           non-profits, including   cooperatives (i.e.
                 company with an           S 25 companies           excluding NBFCs an S
                 entry capital of Rs 25                             25 companies)
                 lakhs (see Table …
Structure        Two-tier, with MFOs       One tier, MFOs only,     One tier, MFOs only,
envisaged for    and "MFIs" (apart from    (apart from NBFCs,       (apart from NBFCs and
sector           NBFCs)                    who along with banks     S 25 companies, but
                                           are included in data     no provisions
                                           gathering                applicable to them)
                                           requirements)
Savings          "Thrift" for MFOs,        Only "thrift" for MFOs   Only "thrift" for MFOs
authorization    public savings for
                 special category
                 "MFIs"
Regulator        Microfinance              NABARD                   NABARD
                 Development Council
Micro Finance    Independent body of       Advisory body, but       Advisory, with
Development      experienced               with majority of         majority consisting of
Council          professionals with        members representing     officials representing
                 executive                 the sector               specified agencies ex-
                 responisbilities                                   officio
Ombudsman        Not specifically          MFDC required to set     MFDC "may" set up
                 provided, but MFDC to     up ombudsman             ombudsman
                 establish mechanism
                 for redressal of
                 greivances




                                                                                             163
Table 9.2 MFOs and "MFIs"

                 Original bill proposed by Sa-Dhan in           Modified bill circulated by
                 consutation with members and key               Ministry of Finance for inter-
                 government agencies                            agency discussion

                 MFO                  "MFI" (as defined in      MFO                    MFI (in
                                      bill with capital of Rs                          generic
                                      25 lakhs)                                        sense)
  Size-          Credit               Above the limits for      Since "MFIs"           NBFCs
  trigger for    outstanding not      an MFO must               dropped, none. Bill
  registration   to exceed Rs 1       incorporate an "MFI"      includes all non-
  as "MFI"       crore or 10 times    company if MFO is a       profit forms of
                 NOF, whichever is    society or trust (if      registration
                 less                 cooperative, must         including S 25
                                      comply with norms for     companies
                                      "MFIs")
  Capital        Must maintain a      NOF of not less than      NOF of at least Rs 5   As per
                 capital adequacy     Rs 25 lakhs, of which     lakhs and a capital    existing
                 ratio of 10          at least 10 percent       adequacy ratio of      NBFC
                 percent              promoters                 15 percent             regulations
                                      contribution (with
                                      provision for
                                      exemption for
                                      cooperatives) and CA
                                      ratio of 15 percent
  Type of        Only thrift from     Deposits from the         Only thrift from       As per
  savings        members              public                    members                existing
                                                                                       NBFC
                                                                                       regulations
  Limit on       Not more than Rs     No limit, but             No limit, but must     As per
  savings/       25 lakhs in          certificate of            have had surplus       existing
  eligibility    aggregate, and       registration as "MFI"     income in at least     NBFC
  conditions     Rs 5000 or such      to be granted only to     the year before        regulations
                 other amount         MFO with aggregate        applying for
                 specified by         thrift of not more        registration, and
                 Council per          than 4 times NOF, or      compliance with
                 individual           more than aggregate       rating norms
                                      loans outstanding,
                                      whichever is less
  Restricitons   Not be repayable     No restrictions           No restrictions        As per
  on thrift      in less than three                                                    existing
                 months                                                                NBFC
                                                                                       regulations
  Reserve        Must transfer not    Must transfer not less    Must transfer not      As per
  fund           less than 10         than 15 percent of        less than 15           existing
                 percent of           surplus to RF             percent of surplus     NBFC
                 surplus to RF                                  to RF                  regulations




164
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                             Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                             An Opportunity Being Lost?




                      Box 9.2 Misunderstandings about savings

The provisions in the bill enabling savings, albeit in a limited form, are probably the single
most important contribution of the bill. However, ironically it is this aspect of the bill that
has been the most widely misunderstood and attacked by critics, who have alleged that NGO-
MFIs must not be allowed to mobilize "public" savings. However this is not what is proposed.
The savings in question are the savings of borrower-members, the vast majority of whom are
net borrowers of the MFI at any one time. To argue, as some people do, that borrowers are not
"members" of the MFI in the same sense that members of mutual institutions are, depends on
whether one defines membership in a strictly technical sense or according to the substantive
nature of the bond it creates.

Under the Grameen Bank methodology, borrowers have to meet eligibility conditions, receive
week-long training, and pass a test before qualifying to receive their first loan. Thereafter
they are in contact with the MFI at least once a week, when the MFI field worker comes to
collect loan repayments, which is much more frequent than in mutual organizations. The peer
pressure to repay loans exercised through joint liability groups is often much stronger than in
the larger and far looser primary groups of mutual organizations. MFIs recognize and reward
long-standing "members" when graduating them to larger, housing, or other individual, loans.
The loyalty of members to their MFI is usually every bit as strong as in a mutual institution, in
which, as has been pointed out, the boundaries of membership can be porous, depending on
the nature of the "common bond" of the mutual institution. If the common bond is area-
based, or geographical, membership can be given to anyone in the area who wants to make a
deposit. In any case, in practice, as the 2005 Union Task Force on the Revival of Cooperative
Credit Credit Institutions points out, membership with full voting rights is usually given only
to borrowers, with depositors being categorized as nominal members without voting rights,
which is why borrowers rather than net savers tend to dominate cooperative boards, although
this is not the case with the new mutually-aided cooperative society acts passed in nine
states, and is an issue the ongoing cooperative reform is trying to set right.

Thus, if an MFI "flies by night" (the second misunderstanding) it will stand to lose much more
than it gains, since most members will owe the MFI much more than it owes them. Also, an MFI
can not "fly by night" because it is first and foremost a credit institution. Unlike an unlicensed
finance company, it needs dozens if not hundreds of field workers, who work out of branch
offices as it expands. These huge establishments and infrastructure requirements can not
disappear overnight. The MFI can of course collapse from incompetence or fraud, but if it
does so (and no recognized MFI out of the approximately 1000 societies, trusts etc estimated
to be conducting microfinance in India, is reported to have done so yet) it will again be
borrowers who will be the net gainers in a strict financial sense, provided the norms recommended
earlier are followed. The regulator is in any case required to assess the "general character" of
an MFI before approving it for thrift.

Last, and this is the third misunderstanding, the mere act of mobilizing savings, or financial
intermediation, does not constitute "banking" as has been widely alleged in the debate on the
bill. If it did, NBFCs approved to collect deposits would not remain non-banks, and every
cooperative credit society would be a bank. An essential element of banking, in the wider sense
understood by economists, is money and credit creation through the money and credit multipliers
of fractional reserve banking, which connects banks to the wider financial system in a systemic
way. This is not the case with small stand-alone financial institutions such as cooperatives and
MFIs. Even more important, they do not participate in the payments system by issuing cheques.

                                                                                                 165
Box 9.3     Grameen II and flexible, voluntary savings

  "Under Grameen II, each member opens a personal savings account, into which she may pay
  whatever she likes, subject to a weekly minimum that depends on the value of her loans from
  the bank, and withdraw whatever she likes whenever she likes, for any purpose, subject to
  being up-to-date in her loan repayments. Deposits are made at the weekly 'centre' meeting,
  but withdrawals are made at branch offices (normally within a half-hour's rickshaw trip or so).
  When she takes a loan, 2.5% of its value is deposited to this account (but may be withdrawn).
  Deposits earn interest at 8.5% pa: a higher rate than passbook savings in commercial banks…

  …Withdrawal symptoms: At first, many staff feared open withdrawals: they sincerely believed
  that members would quickly drain their accounts, leaving them with no reserves to fall back
  on, and Grameen with no implicit cash collateral for the loans. Then during 2003 some managers
  began to allow withdrawals for 'approved' uses, such as health emergences and marriage
  ceremonies, while denying them for making loan repayment installments. Finally in 2004 the
  product began to be administered as designed: HQ issued passbooks with the message that
  'you may withdraw cash from your personal savings at any time' printed on every page. Staff
  learned that open withdrawal wasn't the disaster they had feared. Members, finding withdrawals
  easier, began to use their accounts for the (often short-term) storage of larger sums, in
  addition to their small regular weekly deposits. The chart shows the growing number of
  withdrawals in our sample branches.51

  Balances: Average balances per member in personal savings accounts did not change much
  during this period (Note Q3 2002 to Q3 2004): in two of our branches it grew but fell in the
  third, and ranged between 500 and 800 taka ($8-13).Membership grew rapidly, pushing down
  average balances as new accounts opened, so it is clear that members did not choose to
  exhaust their accounts as withdrawals became freely available.

  Uses: Mrs NB, a member in sample branch S, is one of the Grameen clients whose financial
  behaviour we are tracking. In 2004 her personal savings account transactions amounted to
  $64 in 48 (mainly weekly) deposits and $60 in 5 withdrawals, leaving her with a year-end
  balance of just $9. She used the withdrawals for household consumption and health care, to
  lend to others, and to make repayment installments to Grameen and other MFIs. The personal
  savings account, for her, is becoming a convenient current account. Large flows of cash in
  and out of such accounts, resulting in small balances, is both common and rational among the
  poor, whose small and fragile incomes require them to resort to saving and borrowing to
  finance even small items of expenditure such as a visit to the doctor or the purchase of a new
  sari. This useful service did not exist in Grameen before Grameen II: but is now one of the
  bank's most popular products.

  Extracted from Member Savings by Stuart Rutherford, MicroSave Briefing Notes on Grameen
  II #2




166
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                            Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                            An Opportunity Being Lost?




                 Box 9.4   Sa-Dhan's Voluntary Mutual Code of Conduct

"To ensure that all our activities and dealings with clients are in compliance with the above
core values, we all agree to adopt the code of conduct as elaborated hereunder…:

2.1 We all agree to-

i)    Promote and strengthen the microfinance movement in the country by bringing the
      low-income clients to the mainstream financial sector.

ii)   Build progressive, sustainable and client-centric microfinance institutions in the country
      to provide integrated financial services to our clients.

iii) Promote cooperation and coordination among microfinance institutions and other
     agencies to achieve higher operating standards and avoid unethical competition in
     order to serve our clients better.

2.2 In order to achieve the aforesaid, we all agree to follow the following practices mentioned
    below:

2.2.1Integrity

We agree to-

i)    Act honestly, fairly and reasonably in conducting microfinance activities.

ii)   Conduct our microfinance activities by means of fair competition, not seeking competitive
      advantages through illegal or unethical microfinance practices. No officer, employee,
      agent or other person acting on our behalf shall take unfair advantage of anyone by
      manipulation, concealment, abuse of privileged information, misrepresentation of material
      facts or any other unfair practice.

iii) Prominently display the core values and code of conduct on the notice board of head
     office and all branches, and put systems in place to ensure compliance.

iv)   Ensure that our staff and any person acting for us or on our behalf, are trained or
      oriented to put these values into practice.

2.2.2 Transparency

We agree to-

i)    Disclose to clients all the terms and conditions of our financial services offered in the
      language understood by the client.

ii)   Disclose the source of funds, costs of funds and use of surpluses to provide truthful
      information to clients.

iii) Provide information to clients on the rate of interest levied on the loan, calculation of
     interest (monthly/quarterly/half-yearly), terms of repayment, and any other information
     related to interest rates and other charges

iv)   Provide information to clients on the rate of interest offered on the thrift services
      provided by us.

v)    Provide information to clients related to the premium and other fees being charged on
      insurance and pension services offered by us as intermediaries.

vi)   Provide periodical statements of our accounts to the clients.

                                                                                               167
2.2.3 Fair practices

  We are committed to follow fair practices built on dignity, respect, fair treatment, persuasion
  and courtesy to clients. We agree to-

  i)    Provide microfinance services to low income clients irrespective of gender, race, caste,
        religion or language.

  ii)   Ensure that the services are provided using the most efficient methods possible to
        enable access to financial services by low income households at reasonable cost.

  iii) Recognize our responsibility to provide financial services to clients based upon their
       needs and repayment capacity.

  iv)   Promise that, in case of loans to individual clients below Rs 25,000, the clients shall not
        be asked to hand over original land titles, house pattas, ration cards, etc as collateral
        security for loans except when obtaining copies of these for fulfilling "know your
        customers" norms of the RBI. Only in case of loan to individual clients of Rs 25,000/-
        and above can land titles, house pattas, vehicle RC books, etc. be taken as collateral
        security.

  v)    Interact with the clients in an acceptable language and dignified manner and spare no
        efforts in fostering clients' confidence and long-term relationship.

  vi)   Maintain decency and decorum during the visit to the clients' place for collection of
        dues.

  vii) Avoid inappropriate occasions such as bereavement in the family or such other calamitous
       occasions for making calls/visits to collect dues".

  Excerpted from the Statement of Core Values and a Voluntary Mutual Code of Conduct"
  released at Sa-Dhan's annual conference in January 2007




         Box 9.5     A bit of history: Self-regulation backed by legal sanctions

  In 1998, a task force was set up by the RBI under the chairmanship of NABARD, which proposed
  that all MFIs (including credit-only MFIs) register themselves with an Self Regulatory Organizations
  (SRO) (with recognition of the SROs to be conferred by the central bank). However MFIs were
  defined to include only entities with a recognized legal identity, so that CBOs not registered as
  societies or trusts would continue to operate informally and remain outside the purview of
  reporting and prudential controls below a certain size. The registration with the SRO would be
  provisional for the first three years, during which time the MFI would either attain the standards
  specified by the SRO, or have its registration cancelled. Societies and trusts would have to
  transform themselves into cooperatives or companies once the sum of their deposits and loans
  exceeded a certain level, tentatively proposed at Rs 25 lakhs. Prudential norms for all MFIs
  irrespective of size or form of organization were proposed as follows (i) a reserve requirement of
  at least 10 percent of deposits, to be deposited in a bank (ii) a provision equivalent to the
  entire principal outstanding and interest thereon for loans which were past due by 90 days at
  the end of the financial year (iii) interest recognition on an accrual basis to stop at that time,
  and (iii) limits on loan sizes to any one individual, group, or other MFI.


168
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                                Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                                An Opportunity Being Lost?




It was further envisaged that for a large country like India there could be different SROs recognized
by the central bank for different states, given the fact that there was as yet no single apex body
of MFIs for the country as a whole. State level Recognized SROs (RSROs) would also be able to
take advantage of local knowledge, and of proximity for purposes of on-site visits and inspections.
An RSROs would have to establish mandatory standards for its MFI members, which would have
to be approved by the central bank. The RSRO would require periodic returns from its members,
and would submit periodic summary returns to the central bank. The RSRO would suspend the
registration of an MFI which failed to submit returns or comply with prudential norms, and bar
it from carrying on further business. The central bank would have the right to derecognize an
RSRO if more than say one-fifth of its members were reported to be in non-compliance of
standards.

Clearly a great deal of further consensus building and preparatory work remained to be done
and the RBI never took a view on the task force recommendations. Given the uneven spread of
MFIs in India it might have been possible to start with one or more regions which had a
relatively high concentration of MFIs and a few that were role models, and then proceed
incrementally, developing and revising performance standards and prudential norms on the
basis of experience, identifying potential SRO members in other regions, and training them
and MFIs generally.

Thus the proposed regulatory framework recognized the advantages to MFIs of starting up as
societies and trusts, given the relative ease of registration under these forms of organization,
but required them to transform into cooperatives or non-profit companies or non-bank financial
companies above a certain level of total business. This was also the approach taken in the
initial bill prepared by Sa-Dhan with the difference that it gave NGO-MFIs the special-window
option of registering as an "MFI" which would be a company with an entry capital of Rs 25
operating in conformity with requirements custom-made to microfinance. Unfortunately this
concept was dropped.




                                                                                                    169
Endnotes


  1 For a detailed discussion of the "twists and turns" taken by the bill up to January 2007 see Sinha
      2007a. This is a good source on recent regulatory concerns generally. Other sources for background on
      regulatory issues in Indian microfinance are Radcliffe and Tripathi 2006 and Eschborn 2004. Small
      parts of this chapter are taken from two articles by the author, Ghate 2007a and Ghate 2007b.

  2 Another reason for doing so is that the State of the Sector report is intended to serve as a sort of
      "moving" reference document for posterity, through a series of annual snapshots. It is recognized
      though that this chapter may well be out of date soon after it appears. Apart from being amended the
      bill could expire unless reintroduced.

  3 Bill No.41 of 2007

  4 The title of the bill has therefore become a misnomer - it does not apply to the bulk of the sector.

  5 Thrift is defined as "any money collected (other than in the form of current account or demand
      deposit) by a micro finance organization from a group" and a "group" is defined to mean "any
      association of eligible clients formed either as self-help groups or joint liability groups or a group
      called by any other name for the purpose of providing thrift and micro finance services to individual
      members of such association" (italics added).

  6 The Ministry of Finance did not make copies of the bill available to sector participants other than to
      Sa-Dhan, and Sa-Dhan felt constrained not to share the bill with non members (members are almost
      entirely MFIs and a few service providers, which leaves out a large number of sector participants
      affected by the bill such as cooperatives, banks, equity investors, rating agencies, consultants, researchers,
      microfinance policy analyst, etc). A MoF spokesman said at the annual Sa-Dhan conference in January
      2007 that the bill had not been put onto the ministry's web-site in order to save time. During the whole
      process of discussion of the bill several versions of the bill were floating around simultaneously, making
      for much confusion. It was only when the bill reached parliament that copies of it became available.
      The Standing Committee on Finance has initiated a process of widespread consultation on the bill by
      inviting a cross section of sector participants and interested observers to send in their views and appear
      before it if required. Civil society organizations have been urging persons to send in their views to the
      committee.

  7 These are defined as credit, insurance, pension, and any other services that may be specified by the
      regulator. This leaves open the possibility of adding money transfer services. It is surprising that
      savings services are not mentioned, not even as "thrift".

  8 These are to be two officers nominated by the ministries of finance and rural development, two
      representing NABARD and one each nominated by the RBI, SIDBI and the National Housing Bank.

  9 The Indian microfinance sector has seen a steady migration of NGO-MFIs in the last few years from the
      society and trust form of registration to the company form of incorporation, most of them becoming
      NBFCs, but many of them preferring to retain their not-for-profit status as S 25 companies. The

170
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                                        Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                                        An Opportunity Being Lost?




   transformation is taking place worldwide, for several reasons. First, companies have to meet more
   stringent disclosure, transparency and audit requirements, more suited to financial operations, than
   those laid down for registered societies and trusts, which were designed for charitable, welfare or
   educational activities. Second, by providing for capital or equity in the form of shares, companies
   encourage a stronger sense of ownership on the part of promoters, leading usually to stronger governance
   and management. An NGO has no "owner" of the net owned funds built up out of grants and
   operational surpluses. This combination of advantages gives banks and financial institutions lending
   to MFIs the essential comfort without which the sector will never attract the funds to expand fast
   enough to make a rapid dent on poverty and challenge of financial inclusion. The steady stream of
   transformations has been assisted by the advent of private investors, both social and commercial, who
   are willing to provide transforming as well as start-up MFIs not just the Rs 2 crores required as entry
   level capital, but the much greater investments required to give them the capital adequacy to support
   the more than Rs 3000 crores of borrowing by MFIs that took place last year (see last year's report),
   and the projected rapid growth in the near future.

10 These figures are derived from Sa-Dhan's Quick Report 2007 (Sa-Dhan 2007) and represent the share of
   17 NBFCs and 13 S 25 companies out of a total 129 MFIs in the survey.

11 While a similar study does not exist for India, evidence exists for Uganda that of the formal, semi-
   formal (MFI) and informal sectors in Uganda, the last was the riskiest for savers (Wright and Mutesasira).

12 Nearly all large Indian MFIs have been rated not just once but several times in order to qualify for
   loans from SIDBI, which makes a satisfactory rating a condition for its lending, as do increasingly
   many of the banks.

13 According to World Bank 2007 "there is an increasing sense worldwide that NGOs mobilizing deposits
   from members need not be regulated like banks …"

14 See "City Savers" by Rutherford and Arora (1997) Savings safe-keepers are referred to as "moneyguards"
   in Africa. In India door step cumulative savings collectors have given rise to huge organizations like
   Peerless and Sahara.

15 See Ghate 1992 for a comprehensive review of different types of informal finance in India and 5 other
   Asian countries, Das-Gupta et al 1989 on urban informal finance in India, Bouman 1998 on the bishis
   of Maharasthra, and Rutherford and Arora 1997 on urban informal savings mechanisms in India.

16 Restrictions proposed in the initial version of the bill on maximum savings per member and the
   aggregate savings liability outstanding of the MFI as a ratio of net owned funds and total assets, and
   a liquidity reserve requirement, have been dropped, presumably because they are hard to monitor. The
   liquidity reserve would have been desirable since liquidity is a particularly highly valued attribute of
   savings among the poor, as discussed below.

17 For most MFIs, a small proportion of borrowers will be between loan cycles, and some others as they
   approach the end of the repayment cycle will temporarily have more savings to their credit than loans.
   A ceiling could be fixed for the proportion of net savers. Compliance could be monitored through
   periodic returns and occasional on-site checks where necessary. There are some MFIs in other countries,
   those offering "open access" savings (see below) such as BURO Tangail in Bangladesh, whose savings
   products are so popular that they have a fairly high proportion of net savers and indeed of pure savers
   at any one time. However these will be special cases for the foreseeable future, especially in India

                                                                                                            171
which is a late starter in offering savings services, and they can always be dealt with through special
      exemptions after due diligence on a case by case basis.

  18 Liquidity is an important attribute of savings for the reasons discussed below. The bill proposes that 15
      percent of profits be transferred to a reserve fund, but this is not quite the same thing as a reserve
      fund created out of savings, since profits and surpluses may not accrue for several years initially.
      Transfers to the fund should come from savings, not profits.

  19 These were some of the findings of EDA 2005, the first and most comprehensive impact evaluation so
      far of SIDBI's MFI partners (who conduct lending through SHGs as well as JLGs). The second
      evaluation of the SIDBI project which was undertaken by the Agriculture Finance Corporation, has yet
      to be released by SIDBI although it was completed in August 2006.

  20 Although initially there is a massive out-rush as clients "test" the system to see if they really will be
      permitted to withdraw their savings!

  21 Nearly all Bangladeshi MFIs offer a variety of savings opportunities to their borrowers apart from
      compulsory savings, as "special savings", contractual savings, time deposits and daily savings.

  22 These systems include (i) strong governance and management, (ii) high portfolio quality, (iii)
      liquidity management (asset and liability management) skills, (iv) good information systems, and (v)
      strong internal controls.

  23 Some of them have already done so. Although the largest MFIs are mostly companies, some of the
      largest are still societies and trusts and intend to stay that way, especially as the bill will deny them the
      opportunity to mobilize thrift if they transform. Also, there is a possibility that the bill may be
      amended to include NBFCs and S 25 companies, who do have such capacities. The attainment of
      profitability is a requirement that it often also suggested as a requirement for being allowed to
      mobilize voluntary savings.

  24 While there is agreement that federations should not usurp the function of the groups to make loans
      to their individual members, and should only make loans to their groups, some groups themselves want
      their federations to lend to individual members, usually by accessing loans from the banks, who feel
      more comfortable tracking loans in the name of individuals rather than groups (See Chapter 3).

  25 This had been taken to mean that it will not apply to PACS, although a large part of PACS lending is
      for non-crop rural activities, or in other words constitutes microcredit in the usual sense of credit for
      non-crop activities. Both cooperative banks (district and state level) as well as PACS are part of the
      ongoing cooperative reform project - see footnote 27).

  26 Speech by Thomas Carter of CLUSA at a conference of railway employees' thrift societies in Hyderabad
      on 6-7 February, 1986, who pointed out that it was from a trip to Bengal in the early 1900s that
      Edward Filene, the pioneer leader of thrift cooperatives in the US, drew his inspiration. (Circulated by
      CDF).

  27 Carter in his speech in 1986 (see previous footnote) said "I believe there are more than 23,000 thrift
      cooperatives in the country with close to 150 lakh members and savings of more than Rs 1,250 crores"

  28 The package is being supported by the World Bank's $600 million "Strengthening Rural Cooperatives"
      project and an ADB loan. According to a World Bank press note dated on the project "Twelve Indian

172
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                                         Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                                         An Opportunity Being Lost?




   states have signed up to the reform program. Potentially viable CCBs" (defined to include PACS, DCCBs
   and SCBs) " in those states will commit to a set of far-reaching legal, regulatory, governance and
   institutional reforms which will open the way to financial and operational restructuring. In the process
   the CCBs will be recapitalized with grants to wipe out the accumulated losses, the value of members'
   capital will be restored, and a minimum capital to risk weighted assets ratio (CRAR) of 7 percent will
   be achieved. The project will also provide technical assistance throughout the process to strengthen CCB
   governance, managerial and operational performance, and support computerization for enhanced
   efficiency and transparency. CCB members, particularly small and marginal farmers, will receive training
   in areas such as financial literacy, and a strong project focus on monitoring and evaluation systems
   will include monitoring by CCB members themselves.

29 See note by Shashi Rajagopalan, "The Bill Relating to Micro-Finance Organizations", circulated by CDF.
   As she points out the amount of thrift is agreed to by all members, is usually the same for all members
   in absolute terms, or, in the case employees savings and credit cooperatives, a fixed percentage of
   their pay.

30 Or "self reliant" or "self help" or "self supporting" or "autonomous" or "fraternal".

31 The MACS registrar has fewer powers than the registrar under the existing act in keeping with the lack
   of dependence of MACS on government. Indeed, MACS can not accept government equity.

32 According to a personal communication from Shri Rama Reddy, President, CDF "The Registrar under
   the Macs Act is entitled to receive annual financial statements from every macs cooperative within 30
   days from the holding of the annual general meeting; is empowered to get a special audit conducted
   at the cost of the macs cooperative; is empowered to conduct an enquiry into specific affairs of a macs
   cooperative; is empowered to convene a special general body meeting to explain to the members how
   their cooperative is being mismanaged; is empowered to request the Cooperative Tribunal to order the
   liquidation of a macs cooperative if that macs cooperative is not being run in accordance with the
   concept of cooperation and the provisions of the Macs Act".

33 Or "nominal members", "associate members", "B class members" etc.

34 According to Rama Reddy "Neither the SHG Federation, nor the promoting GO, nor the promoting NGO,
   nor the registering DCO is interested in the functioning of the village organisation as a Macs cooperative.
   They do not need any supervision and/or regulation since they themselves are part and parcel of the
   governmental organisations or of the non-governmental organisations. On the one hand, as a policy,
   the State Government is interested in getting village organisations registered as macs cooperatives and
   on the other hand, again as a matter of policy, the same government puts a ban on the registration
   of citizen-promoted genuine thrift cooperatives and dairy cooperatives under the Macs Act" (Personal
   communication).

35 Of the 129 MFIs covered by Sa-Dhan's Quick Report, 21 were MACS with 1.6 percent of the total number
   of borrowers, and 4 of them cooperatives with 3.9 percent. However as noted above there are thousands
   of thrift cooperatives in the country.

36 At least one state, AP, as noted above, is said to be opposed to it.

37 CGAP 2003 suggests a fourth alternative. It recommends that "financial cooperatives - at least large
   ones - should be prudentially supervised by a specialized financial authority, rather than by an agency
   that is responsible for all cooperatives".
                                                                                                             173
38 There is no firm estimate even of the population of MFOs in the country.

  39 According to one observer, "it is next to impossible to have a data base at state level itself, leave alone
      the national level. The long and tortuous experience of the RBI, up to 1982, and of NABARD since
      1982, in collecting, collating and publishing basic data relating to three-tier rural cooperative thrift
      and credit system (approximately 90,000 PACS, 375 DCCBs and 30 SCBs) should tell us that we are on
      very slippery ground as far as a data base is concerned. From 1966 to 1982, the RBI supervised and
      regulated DCCBs and SCBs and, since 1982, they are being supervised by the NABARD and regulated by
      the RBI"…"The RBI and NABARD published data over a long period… Most of it is guesstimates
      manufactured manually till computers arrived. After the arrival of computers, the projections based
      on already manufactured data are presented as hard, primary data." (Rama Reddy, comments on this
      chapter). However Misra 2007 observes that the MACS she studied do file audited annual returns to the
      registrar. She does not say whether they are scutinized.

  40 According to a report in the Hindu dated 3 July Nabfins would provide micro credit at "reasonable"
      rates with an authorised capital of Rs 100 crores. It would have an issue capital of Rs 20 crores and
      of which 51% would be subscribed to by Nabard and the rest by several banks and state governments.
      The MFI would start functioning in the two months by taking up a pilot project in Karnataka. In the
      second phase, it would be extended to Andhra Pradesh and Tamil Nadu and gradually other states. The
      Chairman of Nabard is reported to have pointed out that the the major defects of MFIs are lack of
      transparency in account disclosures, high transaction costs, high rates of interest and coercive collection
      practices. "We want to show that an MFI can function without any defects and deliver micro credit at
      affordable interest rates and without coercive collection practices. The interest rates would be affordable,
      as the idea was to reduce transaction costs", he added.

  41 See for instance Sanjay Sinha, 2007b. Sinha suggests that the RBI's refusal to engage with microfinance
      is influenced by the recent failures of urban cooperative banks for which the RBI was blamed. He points
      out that its fear is unfounded for the reasons discussed earlier and also because it sends out the
      message that the "the lowly world of the poor does not need its attention".

  42 "Banking" is defined in the Banking Regulation Act, 1949, as "the accepting, for the purpose of
      lending or investment, of deposits of money from the public, repayable on demand or otherwise, and
      withdrawable by cheque, draft, order, or otherwise".

  43 The RBI has often been urged, further, to reduce the entry capital requirement from Rs 2 crores at
      present to perhaps Rs 50 lakhs to speed up the process of transformation of NGO-MFIs to incorporation
      as NBFCs. The initial version of the bill, as we have seen, envisaged entry capital for the new-window
      "MFIs" it envisaged, as 25 lakhs, but that was two years ago, and most MFIs should not find it difficult
      to raise Rs 50 lakhs. However, the RBI takes the view that S 45-I A of the RBI Act 1934 does not give
      it the latitude to distinguish between the various categories of NBFC in this respect. It points out that
      it sought such powers through a draft Financial Companies Regulation Bill submitted to the previous
      parliament, but the bill could not be enacted before the NDA government fell. The RBI could also lay
      down higher provisioning requirements for Microfinance-NBFCs.

  44 The cap only applies to the commercial banks, and not to the RRBs or DCCBs, and only to priority sector
      loans, and not to personal loans. However, meeting priority sector targets is an important motivation
      for the commercial banks who accounted for 28 percent of all loans below Rs 25,000, with the RRBs
      accounting for another 9 percent, in March 2006 (Speech by Deputy Governor, RBI at Sa-Dhan Annual


174
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                                     Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                                     An Opportunity Being Lost?




   Meeting, Chennai, August 10, 2007, Usha Thorat 2007). Were the restriction removed, the number of
   commercial bank micro loans is likely to increase dramatically. See Sinha 2007a and 2007b. The RBI
   has taken a step to remove the cap recently by allowing the banks to issue General Purpose Credit Cards
   (GCCs) with limits up to Rs 25,000 and allowing 50 percent of the amounts utilized to be included in
   the priority sector. It is not known whether the scheme has taken off. , it is limposed

45 This recommendation in this section is based on the assumption that there will be no major amendments
   to the bill. It there are, the conclusion would have to be reviewed.

46 The RBI did come out in May 2006 after the Krishna district episode with guidelines for NBFCs to abide
   by a "fair practices" code, but it does not have a field presence in the districts in the way the
   ombudsman could.

47 Also known as the SC Gupta committee report on the proposal for the states to register moneylenders
   as accredited loan providers out of funds borrowed form the banks.

48 Non-profit S 25 company status requires no entry capital, and has provision for equity, but its
   prohibition of dividends makes it unattractive to investors and therefore lenders.

49 It is understood that that in its interim suggestions the Committee for Financial Inclusion (headed by
   former RBI governor, C Rangarajan) has proposed amendments to S 11(4) of the Income Tax Act so as
   to allow NGOs to invest in microfinance companies without prejudicing their tax status, S 2(15)
   specifying microfinance as a charitable activity, and some others relating to tax concessions to NBFCs.

50 It was only at this stage that copies of the bill became freely available to the wider microfinance
   community, as the Standing Committee on Finance began inviting the views and suggestions of experts
   and persons and groups who wanted to be heard….

51 Note: chart not included.




                                                                                                         175
References


  APMAS, 2005, "A Report on Spandana's Microfinance Activity", Mimeo, APMAS, Hyderabad.

  APMAS, 2006, "Voice of the People on the Lending Practices of Microfinance Institutions in
  Krishna District of Andhra Pradesh", Mimeo, APMAS, Hyderabad.

  Bouman, FJA, 1989, "Small, Short, and Unsecured: Informal Rural Finance in India, Oxford
  University Presss, New Delhi

  CGAP, 2003, "Microfinance Consensus Guidelines: Guiding Principles on Regulation and
  Supervision of Microfinance", Washington, DC

  CGAP, 2004, "Interest Rate Ceilings and Microfinance: The Story So Far", Occasional Paper,
  Washington DC.

  CGAP, 2005a, "Microfinance Consensus Guidelines: Developing Deposit Services for the Poor",
  Washington, DC

  CGAP 2005b, "Protecting Microfinance Borrowers", Focus Note No.27, Washington, DC

  Das-Gupta, Arindam, CPS Nayar, and Associates, 1989, "Urban Informal Credit Markets in India,
  Study prepared for ADB by NIPFP, New Delhi

  EDA Rural Systems, 2005, "The Maturing of Indian Microfinance: Findings of a microfinance
  assessment study (baseline) - implications for policy and practice, study done for SIDBI,
  Gurgaon.

  EDA Rural Systems and APMAS, 2006, "Self Help Groups in India: The Lights and Shades", for
  CRS, USAID, CARE and GTZ/NABARD, Microfinance India, New Delhi

  Eschborn 2004, "Emerging Scenarios for Microfinance Regulation in India: Some Observations
  from the Field", GTZ, Federal Ministry for International Cooperation, Germany

  Ghate, Prabhu, 1992, "Informal Finance: Some Findings from Asia", OUP Hong Kong, for ADB,
  Manila

  Ghate, Prabhu 2006, "Microfinance in India: A State of the Sector Report, 2006", Microfinance
  India, New Delhi, and "Indian Microfinance:The Challenges of Rapid Growth, Sage, New Delhi

  Ghate, Prabhu, 2007a, "Consumer Protection in Indian Microfinance: Lessons from Andhra
  Pradesh and the Microfinance Bill", Economic and Political Weekly, March 31, Mumbai.

  Ghate, Prabhu, 2007b, "Financial inclusion via exclusion?" Economic Times, July 19, New
  Delhi

  Misra, Rewa, 2007, "Case of SHGs and MACS - Does Federating Enable Remote Outreach?",
176
CHAPTER 9
                                                                                            Regulation: The Microfinance Bill:
                                                                                            An Opportunity Being Lost?




paper for the Comparative Study of Member-Owned Institutions Offering Financial Services in
Remote Rural Areas, Coady International Institute/Ford Foundation, Antigonish.

PRS Legislative Reseach, 2007, "Legislative Brief: The Micro Financial Sector (Development
and Regulation) Bill, 2007, Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi

Radcliffe, Daniel, and Rati Tripathi, 2006,"Sharpening the Debate: Accessing the Key Constraints
in Indian Micro Credit Regulation", Centre for Micro Finance, Chennai

Rutherford, Stuart and Sukhwinder Singh Arora, 1997, "City Savers: How the poor, the DFID
and its partners are promoting financial services in urban India", discussion paper prepared
for Urban Poverty Office, DFID, New Delhi

Rutherford, Stuart, 2005, "Why Do the Poor Need Savings Services? : What They Get and What
They Might Like", in Madeline Hirschland, editor, Savings Services for the Poor", Kumarian
Press, Bloomfield

Rutherford, Stuart, "Member Savings", MicroSave Briefing Notes on Grameen II # 2, MicroSave,
Kenya, Uganda and India

Sa-Dhan, 2007, "Quick Report, 2007: A Snapshot of MFIs in India, New Delhi

Sinha, Sanjay, 2007a, "Microfinance Regulation for Financial Inclusion: The Street Child Needs
Nurturing", essays on Regulaton and Supervison No.22, CGAP and IRIS Center, Washington,
DC, carried on www.cgap.org/regulation

Sinha, Sanjay, 2007b, "The financial exclusion bill", Economic Times, June 1, New Delhi

Sriram, MS, 2005, "Expanding Financial Services Access for the Poor: The Transformation of
Spandana", WP No 2005-04-03, IIMA, Ahmedabad.

Thorat, Usha, 2007, "Microfinance and financial inclusion", speech at Sa-Dhan function to
release "Quick Report, 2007", Chennai

Thorat, YSP and Wright, Graham, 2006 "Cooperatives - The Flawed Gem of Indian Rural Finance",
MicroSave Briefing Note No. 56, MicroSave, Kenya, Uganda and India Thorat

World Bank, 2007, "Microfinance in South Asia: Toward Financial Inclusion for the Poor",
Washington DC

Wright, Graham, 2000, "Microfinance Systems: Designing Quality Financial Services for the
Poor", University Press, Dhaka

Wright, Graham, and Leonard Mutesasira, "The Relative Risks to the Savings of Poor People",
MicroSave Briefing Note No. 6, MicroSave, Kenya, Uganda and India




                                                                                               177
178
APPENDIX TABLE




          Table A.1    Fact sheet on coverage and growth of Indian microfinance, 2006-07

    1   Total number of SHG members                                              26.3 million1
    2   Total number of MFI borrowers                                            10.5 million2
    3   Total number of microfinance borrowers                                   36.8 million
    4   Total number of poor SHG members                                         13. 4 million3
    5   Total number of poor MFI borrowers                                       3.2 million4
    6   Total number of poor microfinance borrowers                              16.4 million
    7   Growth of outreach of the SHG programme in 2006-07                       31 percent
    8   Growth of loans outstanding under the SHG programme in 2006-07           48 percent
    9   Growth of outreach of MFIs in 2006-07                                    42 percent5
    10 Growth of loans outstanding of MFIs in 2006-07                            76 percent6
    11 Average loans outstanding, SHG members                                    Rs 40007
    12 Average loans outstanding, MFI borrowers                                  Rs 34008


1
     2.94 SHGs ever linked (Table 2.1) out of which 71 percent estimated to be currently linked
    (Chapter 2) times an average of 14 members each, minus 10 percent estimated to have dropped
    out.

2
     Sa-Dhan estimate of 10.49 million members served by 184 Sa-Dhan member MFIs (Sa-Dhan's
    Quick Report 2007). It is assumed that an estimated 10 percent of MFI members belong to MFIs
    that are not Sa-Dhan members which offsets an assumed 10 percent of membership that is
    inactive, i.e not currently borrowing.

3
    26.3 times 0.51, the proportion of SHG members found to be poor by EDA and APMAS 2006
    (reference in Chapter 1)

4
    Thirty percent is the proportion of poor borrowers found by the second (or endline) evaluation
    of the longitudinal study of SIDBI partnered MFIs by the Agricultural Finance Corporation, as
    well as the finding from the social performance assessment of 12 MFIs reported in Chapter 6.

5
    This is the growth of outreach of 184 Sa-Dhan members as reported in Sa-Dhan 2007. The
    growth of outreach of the subset of 129 MFIs who responded to the survey reported in Sa-Dhan
    2007 was 60 percent.

6
     The total outstanding of the 129 MFIs referred to in the previous footnote, of Rs 3064 crores
    (Table A.2) represented an increase of 76 percent over the reported outstanding of Rs 1743
    crores in the previous year (Sa-Dhan 2007).

7
    Cumulative loans disbursed under the programme times 0.59 (ratio from Chapter 2) yields an
    estimate of loans outstanding in March 2007. This divided by 26.3 million (row 1) yields an
    estimate of about Rs 4000.

8
    Chapter 4.


                                                                                                     179
Table A.2 Imnformation on 129 MFIs covered in Sa-Dhan's Quick Report 2007

Sr No   Name of MFI                     Location                    Outreach    Gross loan portfolio
                                                                                (GLP) (Rs lakh)2
1       Share Microfin Ltd              Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh   1,083,035                 39,965
2       Spandana Sphoorthy              Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh     916,261                39,160
        Innovative Financial Services
        Limited (SPANDANA)
3       SKS Microfinance Pvt Ltd        Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh    603,033                 27,546
4       KAS Foundation                  Bhubaneswar,Orissa            588,960                12,098
5       Shree Kshetra Dharmasthala      Dharmasthala,Karnataka        463,765                 22,760
        Rural Development Projects
        (SKDRDP)
6       Bandhan Konnagar                Kolkata,West Bengal          433,324                 12,613
7       Bharat Integrated Social        Sambalpur,Orissa             364,325                   9,422
        Welfare Agency (BISWA)
8       Shri Mahila Sewa Sahakari       Ahmedabad,Gujrat              304,933                  3,030
        Bank Ltd (SEWA Bank)
9       BWDA Finance Ltd                Villupuram,Tamil Nadu        236,388                   7,209
10      Mahasemam                       Madurai,Tamil Nadu            221,613                  7,696
11      Semam Microfiinance             Chennai,Tamil Nadu            221,613                  5,877
        Investment Literacy and
        Education Ltd
12      CASHPOR Micro Credit            Varanasi,Uttar Pradesh       201,692                   2,601
13      BASIX                           Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh     198,282                 13,970
14      Activists for Social            Trichy,Tamil Nadu             196,224                  8,025
        Alternatives (ASA)
15      Evangelical Social Action       Thrissur,Kerala              178,143                   5,625
        Forum (ESAF)
16      Sarvodaya Nano Finance Ltd      Chennai,Tamil Nadu           126,211                   6,425
        (SNFL)
17      Kotalipara Development          Kolkata,West Bengal          115,035                   2,410
        Society (KDS)
18      GR Koota                        Bangalore,Karnataka          109,251                   4,598
19      Acts Mahila Mutually Aided      Chitoor,Andhra Pradesh         82,904                  4,572
        Cooperative Thrift Society
        (AMMACTS)
20      Sharadas Women's                Secunderabad,Andhra           79,626                   3,827
        Association for Weaker          Pradesh
        Section (SWAWS)
21      Bharatha Swamukti Samsthe       Bangalore,Karnataka           69,753                   3,887
        (BSS)
22      Sreema Mahila Samity            Nadiya,West Bengal            62,024                   1,635
23      Krishna Bhima Samruddhi         Mahaboobnagar,Andhra           61,078                  3,021
        Local Area Bank Ltd (KBSLAB)    Pradesh
24      Saadhana Microfin Society       Kurnool,Tamil Nadu            60,440                   3,007
25      Indian Association for          Coimbatore,Tamil Nadu          55,539                  1,740
        Savings and Credit (IASC)
26      Krushi                          KarimNagar,Andhra Pradesh     50,241                   3,054
27      SE Investments Ltd (SEIL)       Agra,Uttar Pradesh             45,924                 12,722
28      Rashtriya Seva Samiti (RASS)    Tirupati,Tamil Nadu            45,682                  1,388
29      Adhikar                         Bhubaneswar,Orissa             43,335                  1,209
30      Rashtriya Gramin Vikas Nidhi    Guahati,Assam                  42,507                  1,322
        (RGVN)
31      Pragathi Seva Samiti (PSS)      Warangal,Andhra Pradesh       38,812                   1,892
32      Village Welfare Society (VWS)   Kolkata,West Bengal            35,394                  1,525

            180
APPENDIX TABLE




Legal form          Delivery     Borrowings   Net owned    Interest    Operating cost    Category    Category
                    model3       (Rs lakh)    funds (Rs)   rate (%)4     ratio5 (%)     (outreach)    (GLP)

NBFC               GR, IL            36,985        3,735        22.0            10.8     Large       Large
NBFC               GR                27,513        3,460        17.9            16.6     Large       Large



NBFC               GR                25,797        7,131        26.1            27.1     Large       Large
Section 25 Company SHG, JLG          12,127          206        23.0             4.8     Large       Large
Trust              SHG               25,087          778        21.1             2.3     Large       Large



Society            IL                10,023        1,085        26.2            18.9     Large       Large
Society            SHG                8,046        1,376        20.0             0.2     Large       Large

Cooperative        IL                   175          652        17.0            12.0     Large       Large

NBFC               SHG, IL            6,966          513        15.5             0.1     Large       Large
Trust              GR                12,630            8        10.0            23.3     Large       Large
NBFC               GR                 2,987          620        19.0             5.6     Large       Large



Section 25 Company GR, JLG               10          567        26.0            27.3     Large       Large
NBFC               JLG               12,362        2,799        25.8            18.2     Large       Large
Trust              GR                 8,587            -        12.0            18.0     Large       Large

Society            GR                 4,446          126        15.0            13.0     Large       Large

NBFC               SHG                4,634        1,370        12.0            12.0     Large       Large

Society            IL                 2,586           66        15.0            10.0     Large       Large

Trust              GR                 4,715          490        23.2            15.0     Large       Large
MACs               GR                 3,944          683        23.6             8.9     Large       Large



Society            GR, JLG, IL        4,017          104        15.5            10.1     Large       Large



Trust              GR                 3,200          346        28.5            23.8     Large       Large

Society            SHG                1,563           84        18.5             7.0     Large       Medium
Local Area Bank    JLG, IL            4,228          589        19.0            18.0     Large       Large

Society            IL                 2,300          304        22.5            21.3     Large       Large
Section 25 Company SHG,IL             1,967          115        17.0            11.2     Large       Medium

Society            SHG/ JLG              33            -        16.5             3.0     Large       Large
NBFC               IL                13,540        2,769        27.0             7.0     Medium      Large
Society            SHG                1,123          247        15.0             4.0     Medium      Medium
Society            JLG & GR           1,425           43        25.8             5.3     Medium      Medium
Society            SHG, JLG           1,420           33        15.0             9.4     Medium      Medium

Society            SHG                1,615          346        14.0             2.9     Medium      Medium
Society            JLG,IL             1,425          271        22.2            18.6     Medium      Medium

                                                                                             181
Sr No   Name of MFI                      Location                   Outreach   Gross loan portfolio
                                                                               (GLP) (Rs lakh)2
33      Thirumalai Charity Trust (TCT)   Ranipet,Tamil Nadu           35,011                    418
34      Karimangalam Ontriya Pengal      Bangalore,Karnataka          32,247                  1,003
        Semipu Amaipu (SEARCH
        KOPSA)
35      Prochesta                        Guwahati,Assam              31,927                      44
36      Star Microfinance services       Kurnool,Andhra Pradesh       31,389                  1,264
        Society
37      Mari- Sangatitha Mahila          Warangal,Andhra Pradesh     30,084                     226
        Mutually Aided Cooperative
        Societies Federation Ltd
38      Nav Bharat Jagriti Kendra        Hajaribagh, Jharkhand       28,446                     436
        (NBJK)
39      Village Micro Credit Services    Kolkata,West Bengal         27,579                   1,136
        (VMCS)
40      Liberal Association For          Kolkata,West Bengal         27,332                     210
        Movement of People (LAMP)
41      Shalom Charitable Trust          Palakkad,Kerala             26,170                     852
42      Nanayasurabhi Development        Trichy,Tamil Nadu            26,046                    464
        Financial Services (NDFS0
43      Samuha                           Bangalore,Karnataka         22,980                     344
44      Welfare Services Ernakulam       Kochi,Kerala                 22,645                     33
45      Janodaya Public Trust (JPT)      Bangalore,Karnataka          22,500                    817
46      Ujjivan Financial Services Pvt   Bangalore,Karnataka          22,220                    843
        Ltd
47      Social Education and             Warangal,Andhra Pradesh     21,752                     308
        Vountary Action (SEVA)
48      Kalighat Society For             Kolkata,West Bengal         20,976                     375
        Development Facilitation
        (KSDF)
49      Agricultural Science             Gadag,Karnataka             20,598                     184
        Foundation
50      Disha Social Organization        Saharanpur,Uttar Pradesh    19,897                      14
51      Village Financial Servies Pvt    Kolkata,West Bengal          19,632                    539
        Ltd
52      Bandhan Financial Services       Kolkata,West Bengal         19,314                     459
        Pvt Ltd
53      Shramik Bharati                  Kanpur,Uttar Pradesh        18,629                     395
54      Cooperation Development          Puri,Orissa                  17,718                    603
        Council (CDC)
55      NIDAN                            Patna,Bihar                 17,562                     189
56      Watershed OrganiZation           Ahmednagar,Maharashtra       17,086                    363
        Trust(WOTR)
57      Swayamshree Micro Credit         Bhubaneswar,Orissa          15,868                     645
        Services (SMCS)
58      Community Development            Theni,Tamil Nadu            15,680                     675
        Centre (CDC)
59      Sanghamitra Rural Financial      Mysore,Karnataka            15,626                   3,272
        Services
60      Hope Foundation                  Palakkad,Kerala             15,366                     103
61      South Indian Federation of       Trivendram,Kerala            14,566                    672
        Fishermen Societies
62      Satin Credit Care Network Ltd    Delhi,Delhi                 14,372                   2,646


            182
APPENDIX TABLE




Legal form           Delivery     Borrowings       Net owned    Interest    Operating cost    Category    Category
                     model3       (Rs lakh)        funds (Rs)   rate (%)4     ratio5 (%)     (outreach)    (GLP)

Society            SHG                 1,533               21        24.0            13.0     Medium      Small
Section 25 Company SHG                 1,211              343        14.0            10.9     Medium      Medium



Society            SHG                    92               20        18.0             7.9     Medium      Small
Society            GR                  2,021              260        16.1            11.5     Medium      Medium

MACs               SHG                   302               74        18.0            23.0     Medium      Small



Society            SHG, JLG              177              371        24.0            11.0     Medium      Small

Section 25 Company JLG,IL              1,400               10        22.2             1.0     Medium      Medium

Society            SHG, JLG               76              117        24.8             9.8     Medium      Small

Trust              SHG                   931                -        27.0            16.0     Medium      Medium
Section 25 Company SHG                   525               15        18.0             4.0     Medium      Small

Society            SHG                   421                7        10.5             6.4     Medium      Small
Society            SHG                   280               80        12.8             5.9     Medium      Small
Trust              SHG,IL                809               34        27.0            15.3     Medium      Medium
NBFC               GR                    616              329        24.0            63.2     Medium      Medium

Trust              SHG                   939              106        21.0             6.0     Medium      Small

Society            SHG, JLG              374               47        12.5             3.8     Medium      Small



Society            SHG                   186               20        22.8             4.7     Medium      Small

Society            SHG                    50                2        24.0             7.5     Medium      Small
NBFC               JLG                   431              112        23.0            15.5     Medium      Medium

NBFC               IL                    306               67        26.2            17.2     Medium      Small

Society            SHG                         -          388        11.4             6.0     Medium      Small
Trust              JLG, IL & GR          743                1        25.0            13.2     Medium      Medium

Society            SHG                   295               31        19.0            20.0     Medium      Small
Society            SHG                         -          450        21.0            24.0     Medium      Medium

Section 25 Company SHG                   570               29        16.0             5.2     Medium      Medium

Trust              SHG                   673                -        18.0            15.0     Medium      Medium

Section 25 Company SHG                 2,708              561        14.0             4.0     Medium      Large

Trust              SHG                   128               15        20.9            21.0     Medium      Small
Society            IL                    225              245        12.0            12.6     Medium      Medium

NBFC               IL                    184              542        20.0            16.4     Medium      Large


                                                                                                  183
Sr No   Name of MFI                     Location                   Outreach   Gross loan portfolio
                                                                              (GLP) (Rs lakh)2
63      Guide                           Krishna,Andhra Pradesh       12,504                    333
64      Sonata Finance Pvt Ltd          Puri,Orissa                  11,393                    498
65      Sahabhagi Vikash Abhyan         Khurda,Orissa                11,176                    127
66      The Payakaraopta Women's        Vishakhapatnam,Andhra        10,650                    643
        Mutually Aided Cooperative      Pradesh
        Thrift and Credit Society Ltd
67      Bhoruka Charitable Trust        Churu,Rajasthan             10,252                      43
68      Arohan                          Kolkata,West Bengal          10,110                    299
69      Vedika Credit Capital Limited   Ranchi,Jharkhand              9,421                    997
70      Initiatives For Development     Bangalore,Karnataka           9,064                    181
        Foundation (IDF)
71      Hindustan Cooperative Credit    Mumbai,Maharashtra           8,061                   1,918
        Society Ltd
72      Ishara Foundation for           New Delhi,New Delhi          7,251                      58
        Finance and Rural
        Development
73      Institute of Integrated         Dekargaon,Assam              6,927                     239
        Resource Management (IIRM)
74      Support                         Hajaribag,Jharkhand          6,809                      27
75      Navachetana Foundation          Haveri,Karnataka              6,734                    418
76      Raghunath Pathagar (RNP)        Ganjam,Orissa                 6,540                    458
77      People's Action for             Trichy,Tamil Nadu             6,521                    277
        Transformation
78      Bal- Mahila Vikas Samiti        Madhya Pradesh               6,075                      21
79      Darabar Sahitya Sansad (DSS)    Khurda,Orissa                 5,889                     54
80      Ullon Social Welfare Society    South 24 Pgs,West Bengal      4,967                    108
81      Adarsa                          Sambalpur,Orissa              4,917                     37
82      Sarala Women Welfare Society    Howrah,West Bengal            4,826                    166
83      Community Services Trust        Salem,Tamil Nadu              4,386                    446
        (CST)
84      Pikepara Kamala Seva samity     24 Pgs,West Bengal           4,092                      55
85      Social Welfare Agency and       Kandhmal,Orissa               3,885                     16
        Training Institute (SWATI)
86      Arman Lease and Finance Ltd     Ahmedabad,Gujrat             3,770                   1,786
87      Guidance Society for Labour     Vellore,Tamil Nadu            3,626                     80
        Orphans and Women (GLOW)
88      Rajapur Seva Niketan (RSN)      Howrah,West Bengal           3,272                     150
89      Youth Voulunteers Union         Wangamataba,Manipur           3,114                    380
90      Sakhi Samudaya Kosh             Solapur,Maharashtra           3,072                    140
91      Ajiwika Society                 Deoghar,Jharkhand             2,515                    228
92      Mother Theresa Mahila MACCS     Krishna,Andhra Pradesh        2,501                     78
        Ltd
93      Society for Model, Gram Bikas   Kolkata,West Bengal          2,453                      73
        Kendra
94      Priyasakhi Mahila Sangh,        Indore,Madhya Pradesh        2,350                      53
        Indore
95      People's Action for National    Faizabad,Uttar Pradesh       2,324                     148
        Integration (PANI)
96      Jeevika Livelihoods Support     Jabalpur,Madhya Pradesh      2,100                      57
        OrganisationMax Wealth Trust


            184
APPENDIX TABLE




Legal form          Delivery      Borrowings       Net owned    Interest    Operating cost    Category    Category
                    model3        (Rs lakh)        funds (Rs)   rate (%)4     ratio5 (%)     (outreach)    (GLP)

Society            SHG                   222               12        18.5            19.0     Medium      Small
NBFC               GR                    602              150        36.0            42.7     Medium      Small
Society            SHG                    89               38        24.0             3.5     Medium      Small
MACs               JLG,IL                850               25        18.5             5.2     Medium      Medium



Trust              SHG                   105               15        22.8            20.0     Medium      Small
NBFC               JLG                   211              125        30.0            64.0     Medium      Small
NBFC               JLG,IL                713              885        24.0            16.0     Small       Medium
Trust              SHG                   168               18        17.5             7.9     Small       Small

Cooperative        JLG,IL              1,135              317        18.0             8.0     Small       Medium

Section 25 Company SHG                    58               15        27.0            21.9     Small       Small



Society            JLG                   333                -        15.0            18.5     Small       Small

Society            SHG, JLG               57                -        22.8             8.0     Small       Small
Society            GR                    430                -        27.9             6.8     Small       Small
Society            SHG, JLG              445               13        10.8             5.0     Small       Small
Trust              SHG                   235               20        28.0            23.5     Small       Small

Cooperative        SHG                    20                1        34.2            38.1     Small       Small
Society            SHG                    98                2        19.0            10.8     Small       Small
Society            SHG,IL                      -          199        24.0             7.8     Small       Small
Society            SHG                    76                -        24.0            19.2     Small       Small
Section 25 Company IL                    150               19        33.0             8.7     Small       Small
Trust              SHG                   502               21        22.8            40.0     Small       Small

Society            SHG                    13                -        24.0             8.0     Small       Small
Society            SHG, JLG, IL            3                -        18.0             5.0     Small       Small

NBFC               IL                    867              597        19.5            11.8     Small       Medium
Society            JLG                   100               19        22.8            16.5     Small       Small

Society            SHG, JLG              184               28        15.2             4.6     Small       Small
Society            SHG, JLG, IL           34              382        22.8            12.1     Small       Small
Section 25 Company SHG                   125               63        20.0            42.2     Small       Small
Section 25 Company SHG, JLG              148                9        18.0             6.0     Small       Small
MACs               SHG                    19               60         7.1            12.0     Small       Small

Society            GR                     27                3        35.8             2.9     Small       Small

Society            SHG                    34               11        21.8            24.4     Small       Small

Society            SHG                    45              103        22.8            10.0     Small       Small

Society            JLG, GR                56               11        38.0            45.0     Small       Small



                                                                                                  185
Sr No   Name of MFI                    Location                    Outreach   Gross loan portfolio
                                                                              (GLP) (Rs lakh)2
97      Mahila Kalyan Samiti Dhori,    Bokaro,Jharkhand               1,865                     25
        Bokaro
98      Manab Sewa Sangh (MSS)         Guwahati,Assam                1,750                       4
99      Hope Integrated Rural          Kurnool,Andhra Pradesh         1,710                      6
        Development Society
100     Max Wealth Trust               Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh     1,425                      61
101     Social Action for Rural        Sambalpur,Orissa               1,208                      6
        Community (SARC)
102     Swadhar Financcess             Mumbai,Maharashtra            1,125                      43
103     Ma tarani Prathamika Mahila    Nayagarh,Orissa                 982                      17
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd
104     CHINYARD                       Dharwad,Karnataka               918                      50
105     Society for Empowerment and    Hajaribag,Jharkhand             886                      23
        Women Advancement (SERV-
        SEVA)
106     GramIn Vikas Mandal            Beed, maharashtara              882                      37
107     Indian Institute for Rural     Jaipur,Rajasthan                773                      58
        Development (IIRD)
108     Nari Jagruti Prathamika        Cuttack,Orissa                  750                      24
        Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya
        Ltd
109     Sramajibi Bikas Prathamika     Khurda,Orissa                   740                      15
        Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya
        Ltd
110     Mahila Vikas Prathamika        Khurda,Orissa                   682                      17
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd
111     Mahalaxmi Prathamika Mahila    Nayagarh,Orissa                 598                      18
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd
112     Mimo Finance                   Dehradun,Uttaranchal            570                      30
113     Nava Jagriti                   Saran,Bihar                     512                      32
114     Upkar                          Nimapara,Orissa                 482                       3
115     PadmabatiPrathamika Mahila     Nayagarh,Orissa                 470                       9
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd
116     Ma Sakti Prathamika Mahila     Cuttack,Orissa                  435                       3
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd
117     Ma Adisakti Prathamika         Cuttack,Orissa                  310                       2
        Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya
        Ltd
118     Nari Bikas Prathamika Mahila   Bhubaneswar,Orissa              308                      11
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd
119     Devisakti Prathamika Mahila    Cuttack,Orissa                  219                       1
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd
120     Gram Swaraj Seva Trust         Wardha,Maharashtra              208                      12
121     Ma Matrusakti Prathamika       Cuttack,Orissa                  188                       1
        Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya
        Ltd
122     Khandual Prathamika Mahila     Cuttack,Orissa                  181                       2
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd
123     Khetrapal Prathamika Mahila    Khurda,Orissa                   148                       2
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd
124     Potolei Prathamika Mahila      Cuttack,Orissa                  143                       1
        Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd




            186
APPENDIX TABLE




Legal form          Delivery     Borrowings   Net owned    Interest    Operating cost    Category    Category
                    model3       (Rs lakh)    funds (Rs)   rate (%)4     ratio5 (%)     (outreach)    (GLP)

Society            JLG                   36           15        34.2            18.0     Small       Small


Society            SHG, JLG              60            2        18.0            12.0     Small       Small
Society            GR                    96            2        31.0            35.5     Small       Small


Trust              SHG                   68            -        23.5           115.5     Small       Small
Society            SHG                    1            1        25.0            42.7     Small       Small


Section 25 Company JLG                   25           20        35.8           203.0     Small       Small
MACs               SHG,IL                12           18        19.5            16.0     Small       Small


Trust              SHG/ JLG              50           12        12.5             7.7     Small       Small
Society            SHG                   18           12        22.8             1.8     Small       Small



Society            SHG                   37            -        34.2             3.1     Small       Small
Society            JLG                   50           50        25.7             7.0     Small       Small


MACs               IL                     9           24        21.3            13.5     Small       Small



MACs               IL                    12           20        18.7            12.7     Small       Small



Cooperative        SHG, JLG               9           11        24.0             8.0     Small       Small


MACs               SHG,IL                 8           20        16.1            11.6     Small       Small


NBFC               JLG,SHG, GR           20           30        32.3           100.0     Small       Small
Society            SHG                   32            -        18.0            16.0     Small       Small
Society            SHG,IL                 7            3        34.2             2.0     Small       Small
MACs               IL                     5            7        18.9            16.8     Small       Small


MACs               SHG,IL                 2            6        19.8            16.4     Small       Small


MACs               IL                     1            1        22.1            18.9     Small       Small



MACs               IL                     6           14        21.4            15.4     Small       Small


MACs               IL                     1            1        16.7            23.1     Small       Small


Society            SHG, JLG              NA           26        24.0            23.0     Small       Small
MACs               SHG,IL                 1            1        19.3            20.3     Small       Small



MACs               IL                     1            2        12.8            12.7     Small       Small


MACs               IL                     2            2        13.7            10.6     Small       Small


MACs               IL                     1            3        20.6            18.8     Small       Small




                                                                                             187
Sr No     Name of MFI                     Location                            Outreach         Gross loan portfolio
                                                                                                   (GLP) (Rs lakh)2
    125       Saktimayeeni Prathamika         Khurda,Orissa                            141                            2
              Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya
              Ltd
    126       Ma Jogamaya Prathamika          Cuttack,Orissa                           104                            1
              Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya
              Ltd
    127       Jhanshirani Prathamika          Khurda,Orissa                            102                            1
              Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya
              Ltd
    128       Swayamsakti Prathamika          Cuttack,Orissa                            69                            0
              Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya
              Ltd
    129       Nirantara Community Services    Bidar,Karnataka                           30                            2
    Total                                     Total                               8,231,026                    306,475



Notes:

1.       Self reported data as of 31 March 2007, taken from Sa-dhan’s Quick Report 2007: A Snapshot of
         Microfinance Institutions in India.

2.       Gross Loan Portfolio: = sum total of all the loans outstanding of the MFI. This includes portfolio on the
         balance sheet as well as off the balance sheet

3.       GR= Grameen, IL= Individual Loan,JLG = Joint Liability Groups (JLG). The JLG model refers to group
         lending models, which do not strictly follow the five member, up to eight group, center concept




                     Table A.3 Lending by selected apex financing Institutions and banks to MFIs

    Sr      Apex financing institution/Bank                    Partners                       Outstanding (Rs crores)

                                                 31-Mar-06            31-Mar-07      31-Mar-06              31-Mar-07
    1       SIDBI                                     NA                  100            329                    548
    2       FWWB                                      NA                  102             67                    104
    3       Maanaveeya Holdings                       NA                  24              NA                    50
    4       ICICI Bank                                100                 NA            2350                   1392
    5       HDFC Bank                                 NA                  66             250                    300
    6       ABN Amro Bank                             19                  27              87                    161
    7       Yes Bank                                  NA                   7              NA                    62
    8       Standard Chartered Bank                   12                  12              50                    38
    9       Other private sector banks                NA                  NA              NA                    554
    10      Public sector banks                       NA                  NA              NA                    195
                     1
    11      Others                                    NA                  NA              NA                    25

Notes:
1 Items no 1-8 are based on information provided by the apex financing institutions/banks.
2. Items no 9-11 are based on information compiled from the annual reports/annual financial statements of 48 MFIs.

1
    Grameen Trust, Grameen Foundation, Oikocredit, etc.

                     188
APPENDIX TABLE




 Legal form                 Delivery        Borrowings     Net owned       Interest        Operating cost     Category           Category
                            model3          (Rs lakh)      funds (Rs)      rate (%)4         ratio5 (%)      (outreach)           (GLP)

 MACs                     IL                          2             2              10.2              8.7      Small              Small


 MACs                     SHG,IL                     1              1              14.5             15.3      Small              Small



 MACs                     IL                         1              1               8.0             10.1      Small              Small



 MACs                     IL                         0              0               9.3             21.3      Small              Small



 Society                  GR                        10              -              29.0             27.5      Small              Small
                                               274,412         38,675




4.      The interest rate is the annual effective rate of interest charged by the MFI to its borrowers.

5.      Operating Cost Ratio is calculated by dividing the total operating costs (salaries, travel, depreciation and
        other administrative costs) by average loans outstanding.




                        Table A.4       Salient features of selected India-oriented equity investors

                          Bellwether            Lok Capital             Aavishkaar            Michael and             Unitus Equity Fund
                                                                        Goodwell India        Susan Dell
                                                                        Microfinance          Foundation
                                                                        Development
                                                                        Company
     Indian/Offshore      Indian                Offshore                Offshore              Offshore                Offshore
     Size at first        $22 million           Size at first           USD 8.4 Mn            A foundation            US$23.5m
     closing                                    closing $12                                   with an
                                                million                                       endowment of
                                                (expecting 2nd                                more than US $ 1
                                                close of greater                              billion, which
                                                than $15                                      also makes equity
                                                million)                                      investments
     Life of Fund         15 Years              10 years                10 years,             NA                      10 yrs
                                                                        extendable by 2
                                                                        years
     Main Investors       Individual &          IFC, KfW, CDC,          Institutional         NA                      Mix of social and
                          Institutional         FMO (In process         (Goodwell MDC,                                commercial
                          (Hivos Triodos,       of closing              IFC, FMO, DB)                                 investors
                          Gray Ghost and        investment from
                          FMO)                  ACCION)
     Investees so far     12 of which           2 of which both         One MFI – Equity      2 equity                2 equity
     (In India)           Equity (8),           are equity              investment            investments, 2
                          Convertible Debt                                                    grants of
                          (2) and debt (2).                                                   donated equity
                                                                                              to non profit
                                                                                              MFIs, 1
                                                                                              incubation grant


                                                                                                                     189
Bellwether           Lok Capital            Aavishkaar              Michael and Susan      Unitus Equity Fund
                                                                    Goodwell India          Dell Foundation
                                                                    Microfinance
                                                                    Development
                                                                    Company
  Investees so far      12 of which          2 of which both        One MFI – Equity        2 equity               2 equity
  (In India)            Equity (8),          are equity             investment              investments, 2
                        Convertible Debt                                                    grants of donated
                        (2) and debt (2).                                                   equity to non
                                                                                            profit MFIs, 1
                                                                                            incubation grant
  Pipeline              2 Existing MFIs      MFIs, spread across    3 existing entities,    3-4 additional MFIs    Expect 2-3
                        and 2 start-ups      10 states, half of     2 start ups             over the next year     additional equity
                                             which are start-up     franchisee                                     investments in
                                             or early-stage         companies                                      India by end of
                                             MFIs. Expecting to                                                    year
                                             close 2 further
                                             investments by
                                             end of 2007.
  Coverage Goals        By year 5, aims to   Targeting 12-15        The fund would        3-4 new MFIs every       8-10 leading MFIs
                        successfully         investments in         invest in established year                     worldwide with
                        transform 7 MFI's,   total, which will      MFIs, transforming                             the first fund
                        of which at least    be diversified         MFIs, to foster and
                        3 will be start      through                encourage the
                        ups. Expects 40      geographies,           spread of MF across
                        per cent of          growth stages and      the country, in small
                        investments to       product/market         start up entities as
                        be outside           specializations.       well in partnership
                        southern states,                            with Intellecash
                        and a rural urban                           franshisee program
                        balance.
  Arrangements for      Will access grants   TA Lok Foundation      Will channel TA to      As a Foundation,       Affiliate of Unitus
  TA                    for partners from    will have the          enable fulfilling its   can offer grant        through whom a
                        other sources        ability to finance     mandate of              finances               breadth of
                                             $2-3 million           spreading MF across                            capacity building,
                                             worth of TA            the country and                                capital advisory,
                                             services to            encouraging start                              functional
                                             investee MFIs.         up entities                                    solutions and
                                             Partnerships have                                                     network linkages
                                             been estabilished                                                     are offered. Unitus
                                             with both Indian                                                      currently has 16
                                             as well as                                                            MFI Partners
                                             international TA                                                      worldwide
                                             providers.                                                            (10 in India).
  Emphases &            Apart from social    Lok Capital is an      To maximize value       Focuses exclusively    Demonstrate that
  Special features      returns, investees   India-focused MF       through superior        on early-stage         industries which
                        must offer clear     fund. Apart from       risk – adjusted         urban microfinance     serve the poor in a
                        prospects of         social returns,        social and financial    institutions which     commercially
                        attractive returns   investees must offer   returns, by focusing    are (potentially)      sustainable
                        on equity.           clear prospects of     on scalability,         scalable and           manner, such as
                                             attractive returns     efficiency and          sustainable model.     microfinance, are
                                             on equity. Lok         leverage and by         Emphasis on            viable investment
                                             seeks longer term      applying a private      financial and social   vehicles.
                                             investment             equity approach         performance
                                             timelines of 5-7       within a mission        parameters. Also
                                             years, and looks to    driven setting. The     supports non-profit
                                             provide significant    geographic focus is     MFIs
                                             value-add services     India.
                                             to its investees.
                            Investees
Bellwether                 Satin Credit Care (Debt), Ujjivan Financial Services Pvt Ltd (Equity), Sharda's Women's association for
                           Weaker Sections (SWAWS) – Equity, MAS Financial Services (Debt), Sonata Finance Pvt Ltd (Equity),
                           Arohan Financial Services (Equity),Indur MACS Federation (Debt), BISWA Microfinance Services (Equity
                           and Debt), Janalakshmi Financial Services (Equity and Debt), Swayamshree Micro Credit Services (Debt
                           plus option), MIMO Finance (Equity and debt).
Lok Capital                Spandana Sphoorty Financial Services Ltd, Janalakshmi Financial Services (Equity)
Aavishkaar Goodwell        Share Microfin Limited
India Microfinance
Development Company
MSDF                       Janalakshmi Financial Services (Equity), Swadhaar Finaccess (Grant), Ujjivan Financial Services Pvt Ltd
                           (Equity), Nirmaan Bharati Arthik and Samajik Sansthan (Grant)
Unitus Equity Fund         Ujjivan Financial Services Pvt Ltd (Equity), SKS Microfinance Ltd (Equity).
Source: Self-reported

                190
APPENDIX TABLE



                                   Table A.5     Insurance coverage by selected MFIs

 Sr                       MFI                    Customers    Customers   Customers    Number      Number         No of
                                                  covered      covered     covered        of       of micro      weather
                                                 under life     under       under     livestock   enterprises   insurance
                                                 insurance      health     accident    insured     insured      customers
                                                              insurance   insurance
                                                                             only

 1     Bharat Integrated Social Welfare             58,743      153223      47386        237          3,862           -
       Agency (BISWA)
 2     KAS Foundation                                2,794                 190357      1,934         5,505            -
 3     Kotalipara Development Society (KDS)         25,000       5,000           -          -       25,000            -
 4     CASHPOR Micro Credit                         27,879            -          -          -              -          -
 5     Satin Credit Care Network Ltd                     -            -          -          -              -          -
 6     SE Investments Ltd (SEIL)                         -            -          -          -              -          -
 7     Activists for Social Alternatives (ASA)      49,623            -          -          -              -          -
 8     BASIX                                       372,344      356,545          -     10,098         1,263      10,711
 9     Evangelical Social Action Forum (ESAF)          287       13,510     68,521          -              -          -
 10    Krishna Bhima Samruddhi Local Area           17,892       17,892          -       953               -      1,005
       Bank Ltd (KBSLAB)
 11    Mahasemam Trust                            221,613       30,498           -          -              -          -
 12    Saadhana Microfin Society                   101,901            -          -          -              -          -
 13    Sarvodaya Nano Finance Ltd (SNFL)                 -            -          -          -              -          -
 14    Sharadas Women's Association for             48,154      48,154           -          -              -          -
       Weaker Section (SWAWS)
 15    Shree Kshetra Dharmasthala Rural                  -     721,203           -          -              -          -
       Development Projects (SKDRDP)
 16    SKS Microfinance Pvt Ltd                   603,933          990           -          -              -          -
 17    Spandana Sphoorthy Innovative             10,20,000            -          -          -              -          -
       Financial Services Limited (SPANDANA)
       Total                                     1,530,163    1,537,372    115,907     13,222       35,630       11,716


Source: Information provided by MFIs on the basis of a questionnaire.




                                                                                                     191
Table A.6      List of selected transformations
 SHARE, Andhra Pradesh transformed from a society to an NBFC - Share Microfin Limited
 Swayam Krishi Sangam (SKS), Andhra Pradesh transformed from a society to an NBFC - SKS Microfinance Pvt Ltd
 Spandana, Andhra Pradesh transformed from a society to an NBFC - Spandana Sphoorty Innovative Financial Services Limited
 Bullockcart Worker's Development Association (BWDA), Tamilnadu transformed from a society to an NBFC - BWDA Finance
 limited
 Cashpor, Uttar Pradesh transformed from a society to a Section 25 company - Cashpor Micro Credit (CMC)
 The Microfinance programme of Swayam Sikshan Prayog (SSP), Maharastra transformed from a Society to a Section 25 Company
 - SakhiSamudaya Kosh (SSK)
 The Microfinance Programme of NEEDS, Jharkhand has sformed in to a Section 25 Company - AJIWIKA
 Evangelical Social Action Forum (ESAF), Kerala is in the process of transforming from a society to an NBFC - ESAF Microfinance
 Limited.
 Konnagar Bandhan, West Bengal is in the process of transforming from a society to the NBFC - Bandhan Financial Services
 Limited.
 Village Welfare Society (VWS), West Bengal is in the process of transforming from a society to an NBFC - Village Financial
 Services Limited
 Shardas Women's Association for Weaker Sections (SWAWS), Andhra Pradesh is in the process of transforming in to an NBFC
 Mahasemam Trust, Tamilnadu is in the process of transforming its microfinance programme to an NBFC, Semam Microfinance
 Investment Literacy and Empowerment (SMILE)
 Microfinance programme of SHEPHERD, Tamilnadu has transformed in to a Section 25 Company - Nanyasurabhi Development
 Financial Services
 Microfinance programme of CYSD, Orissa has transformed in to a Section 25 Company - Swayanshree Microcredit Services.
 The microfinance programme of Gram Utthan, Orissa microfinance programme is in the process of transformation into a Section
 25 Company - Kalyani Microfinance Foundation
 The microfinance programme of BISWA, Orissa is in the process of transforming in to an NBFC - Credible Securities and Finance
 Private Ltd."
 The microfinance programme of ADHIKAR, Orissa has been transformed into a Section 25 Company - Sanchayika.
 Council of Professional Social Workers (CPSW), Orissa is in the process of transforming its microfinance programme in to a
 Section 25 Company - Amba Jibika.
 Organisation for Development Coordination (ODC), Orissa is also in the process of transforming into a Section 25 Company -
 Jana Jibika Foundation.


Notes:
This information has been compiled on the basis of interaction with various stakeholders. It is not a comprehensive list,
but may be of interest. For the purpose of this table, only transformation from a society/trust to a Section 25 Company or
an NBFC has been considered.




               192
Mf in inia 2007
Mf in inia 2007

More Related Content

PDF
Wrld bank remittance
PDF
Rekindling the Future - India Pakistan Economic Relations
PDF
62932
PDF
Banking industry
PDF
Banking on NMACS
PDF
Karvy Private Wealth - India Wealth Report
PDF
Publication ifc msme report
DOC
52652115 analysis-of-credit-default-of-j-k-bank
Wrld bank remittance
Rekindling the Future - India Pakistan Economic Relations
62932
Banking industry
Banking on NMACS
Karvy Private Wealth - India Wealth Report
Publication ifc msme report
52652115 analysis-of-credit-default-of-j-k-bank

What's hot (19)

DOC
37040899 icici-project
PDF
Morning note keynote 12
PDF
Icici bank event update - 18-05-10
PDF
Mergers&amp;Acquisition Report
DOCX
Analysis of Facebook’s Acquisition of Whatsapp
DOCX
Banking 2
PDF
54589226 kotak
PDF
Vc Circle The Deal Outlook 2009
PDF
Daily Newsletter: 19th July, 2011
PDF
Market23 (1)
DOC
Beacon insurance brokers pvt. ltd.
PDF
18 zijmr vol2_issue5_may 2012
PDF
Portfolio investment opportuities in india
PDF
A Study on Micro Credit in Eastern Uttar- Pradesh with Reference to Cashpor
PDF
17 june 2020
PPTX
Presentation for imt delhi v6 slide and linked share
PDF
28 document jkti ar 2009-10
DOCX
Corporate profile, history, etc
37040899 icici-project
Morning note keynote 12
Icici bank event update - 18-05-10
Mergers&amp;Acquisition Report
Analysis of Facebook’s Acquisition of Whatsapp
Banking 2
54589226 kotak
Vc Circle The Deal Outlook 2009
Daily Newsletter: 19th July, 2011
Market23 (1)
Beacon insurance brokers pvt. ltd.
18 zijmr vol2_issue5_may 2012
Portfolio investment opportuities in india
A Study on Micro Credit in Eastern Uttar- Pradesh with Reference to Cashpor
17 june 2020
Presentation for imt delhi v6 slide and linked share
28 document jkti ar 2009-10
Corporate profile, history, etc
Ad

Similar to Mf in inia 2007 (20)

DOC
A project report on study of banking products and investment behavior of cons...
PDF
State of-the-sector-report-2009
PDF
Malegam report-issues-microfinance-india
PDF
Mobile Banking for Equitable International Development
PPTX
Bbi ppt
DOC
A dissertation report on indian retail industry trends
DOC
Final Year Project Report Of Pgdm 6th Trimester
PDF
48947731 a-project-report-on-microfinance-in-india
PDF
Toc indian retail industry
PDF
THESIS-The Productive Efficiency of Banks in Developing Country With Special ...
PDF
India pefa20101
PDF
Analysis of the Efficiency of NBFCs
PDF
Maruti suzuki-balansheet-analysis
PPTX
Merger-Mahindra Bank & ING Vysya Bank
PDF
Microfinance policy
PDF
PROJECT ON LOAN APPROVAL
DOC
Bank islami final report edited
PDF
BHAFIN 1QFY18
PDF
Rbi securitisation guidelines may 2012 icra
PDF
Microfinance and SHGs at a glance
A project report on study of banking products and investment behavior of cons...
State of-the-sector-report-2009
Malegam report-issues-microfinance-india
Mobile Banking for Equitable International Development
Bbi ppt
A dissertation report on indian retail industry trends
Final Year Project Report Of Pgdm 6th Trimester
48947731 a-project-report-on-microfinance-in-india
Toc indian retail industry
THESIS-The Productive Efficiency of Banks in Developing Country With Special ...
India pefa20101
Analysis of the Efficiency of NBFCs
Maruti suzuki-balansheet-analysis
Merger-Mahindra Bank & ING Vysya Bank
Microfinance policy
PROJECT ON LOAN APPROVAL
Bank islami final report edited
BHAFIN 1QFY18
Rbi securitisation guidelines may 2012 icra
Microfinance and SHGs at a glance
Ad

More from Renu Lamba (20)

PPT
Five Generic Competitive Strategies wid eg.ppt
PPTX
OB Google case study- Organisational behaviour
PPTX
Challenges and Opportunities of organisational behaviour
PPT
Disrutive innovation TIM.ppt
PPTX
Authority Responsibility.pptx
PPTX
Performance counseling.pptx
PPTX
Approaches to Counseling.pptx
PPT
q1-a-lesson-on-carbon-footprint.ppt
PPTX
SWM SUSTAINABLE BUSINESS MODEL.pptx
PPT
store mgt n maintenance.ppt
PPT
women entrepreneurship ppt.ppt
PPT
Basics of logistics and supply chain.ppt
PPTX
components of social work profession.pptx
PPTX
DRA1.pptx
PPTX
BPR and Change Management1.pptx
PPTX
Process Mapping and Process Improvement 1111.pptx
PPT
facility layout.ppt
PPTX
bpr-examples from indian.pptx
PPTX
Predictive analytics.pptx
PDF
niti aayog1.pdf
Five Generic Competitive Strategies wid eg.ppt
OB Google case study- Organisational behaviour
Challenges and Opportunities of organisational behaviour
Disrutive innovation TIM.ppt
Authority Responsibility.pptx
Performance counseling.pptx
Approaches to Counseling.pptx
q1-a-lesson-on-carbon-footprint.ppt
SWM SUSTAINABLE BUSINESS MODEL.pptx
store mgt n maintenance.ppt
women entrepreneurship ppt.ppt
Basics of logistics and supply chain.ppt
components of social work profession.pptx
DRA1.pptx
BPR and Change Management1.pptx
Process Mapping and Process Improvement 1111.pptx
facility layout.ppt
bpr-examples from indian.pptx
Predictive analytics.pptx
niti aayog1.pdf

Recently uploaded (20)

PPTX
Research Writing in Bioiinformatics.pptx
PDF
3CMT J.AFABLE Flexible-Learning ENTREPRENEURIAL MANAGEMENT.pdf
PPTX
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
PDF
Best Accounting Outsourcing Companies in The USA
PPTX
PROFITS AND GAINS OF BUSINESS OR PROFESSION 2024.pptx
PDF
Fintech Regulatory Sandbox: Lessons Learned and Future Prospects
PPTX
RISK MANAGEMENT IN MEDICAL LABORATORIES 2.pptx
PPT
Relevant Information & Alternative Choice Decisions
PDF
Financial discipline for educational purpose
PDF
2018_Simulating Hedge Fund Strategies Generalising Fund Performance Presentat...
DOCX
ENHANCING THE DINING EXPERIENCE LESSONS FROM THAI TOWN MELBOURNE’S SERVICE EN...
PDF
In July, the Business Activity Recovery Index Worsened Again - IER Survey
PPTX
ANALYZE MARKET DEMAND, MARKET SUPPLY AND MARKET.pptx
PDF
Very useful ppt for your banking assignments BANKING.pptx.pdf
PPT
Managerial Accounting Chap 1. Guide to managerial accounting
PDF
01 KEY PROVISIONS on NGPA and PROFESSIONALIZATION.pdf
PPTX
Lesson Environment and Economic Growth.pptx
PDF
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
PDF
epic-retirement-criteria-for-funds (1).pdf
PPTX
balanced_and_unbalanced_growth_theory_ppt.pptx
Research Writing in Bioiinformatics.pptx
3CMT J.AFABLE Flexible-Learning ENTREPRENEURIAL MANAGEMENT.pdf
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
Best Accounting Outsourcing Companies in The USA
PROFITS AND GAINS OF BUSINESS OR PROFESSION 2024.pptx
Fintech Regulatory Sandbox: Lessons Learned and Future Prospects
RISK MANAGEMENT IN MEDICAL LABORATORIES 2.pptx
Relevant Information & Alternative Choice Decisions
Financial discipline for educational purpose
2018_Simulating Hedge Fund Strategies Generalising Fund Performance Presentat...
ENHANCING THE DINING EXPERIENCE LESSONS FROM THAI TOWN MELBOURNE’S SERVICE EN...
In July, the Business Activity Recovery Index Worsened Again - IER Survey
ANALYZE MARKET DEMAND, MARKET SUPPLY AND MARKET.pptx
Very useful ppt for your banking assignments BANKING.pptx.pdf
Managerial Accounting Chap 1. Guide to managerial accounting
01 KEY PROVISIONS on NGPA and PROFESSIONALIZATION.pdf
Lesson Environment and Economic Growth.pptx
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
epic-retirement-criteria-for-funds (1).pdf
balanced_and_unbalanced_growth_theory_ppt.pptx

Mf in inia 2007

  • 3. Microfinance in India A State of the Sector Report, 2007 By Prabhu Ghate Sai Gunaranjan Vijay Mahajan Prasanth Regy Frances Sinha Sanjay Sinha Microfinance India 28 Hauz Khas Village, New Delhi 110 016 This report represents the personal views of the chapter authors. It does not represent the views of Microfinance India, or of its sponsors, or of the Microfinance India Advisory Group. 1
  • 4. 2
  • 5. Contents Chapter Page No Foreword 5 Preface and Acknowledgments 6 Abbreviations 8 1 Overview 11 Prabhu Ghate 2 Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme 35 Prabhu Ghate 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? 49 Prabhu Ghate 4 MFI Performance: Efficiency with Growth 73 Sanjay Sinha 5 Urban Microfinance 83 Prabhu Ghate 6 Social Performance in Indian Microfinance 105 Frances Sinha 7 Micro Insurance 119 Sai Gunaranjan 8 Microfinance and Technology 131 Prasanth V Regy and Vijay Mahajan 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? 149 Prabhu Ghate List of Tables Page No Table 2.1 Growth trends in the SBLP 36 Table 2.2 Growth of linked SHGs in 13 Priority States 37 Table 2.3 Growth trends in the SBLP for 2006-07, by state 43 Table 2.4 Growth of linked SHGs in the regions 38 Table 2.5 Agency- wise number of SHGs financed 38 Table 4.1 Regional distribution of Indian MFIs rated by M-CRIL 74 Table 4.2 Distribution of sample Indian MFIs by microfinance model 75 Table 4.3 Distribution of sample MFIs by legal form 75 Table 4.4 Operating expense ratios of Indian MFIs 78 Table 4.5 Capital adequacy ratios of Indian MFIs 80 Table 4.6 Portfolio yield relative to APR 81 Table 4.7 Outreach of efficient microfinance institutions 82 Table 9.1 Successive versions of the microfinance bill 163 Table 9.2 MFOs and MFIs 164 3
  • 6. Appendix Tables Page No Table A.1 Fact Sheet on coverage and growth of India microfinance, 2006-07 179 Table A.2 Information on 129 MFIs covered in Sa-Dhan's Quick Report 2007 180 Table A.3 Lending by selected apex financing institutions and banks to MFIs 188 Table A.4 Salient features of India-oriented equity investors 189 Table A.5 Insurance coverage by selected MFIs 191 Table A.6 List of selected transformations 192 List of Boxes Page No Box 1.1 Cashpor: Stoppage of Partnership Funding 14 Box 1.2 The challenges of raising capital: Inside the entrepreneur’s mind 26 Box 3.1 “The SHG Revolution: What Next?” 50 Box 3.2 MYRADA’s Community Managed Resource Centres (CMRCs) 53 Box 3.3 DHAN Foundation federations: changing with the times 55 Box 3.4 Making non-financial federations viable: PRADAN’s experience 57 Box 3.5 Roshan Vikas: An urban SHG federation 62 Box 3.6 Swayanshree at the crossroads: To borrow or to facilitate direct linkages? 63 Box 5.1 The uses and abuses of moneylenders 86 Box 5.2 The ubiquity of moneylenders in Bangalore 87 Box 5.3 Mobility in a Delhi slum 89 Box 5.4 Segmentation by loan purpose 90 Box 5.5 Ujjivan’s approach to urban housing microfinance: helping customers climb the housing ladder 92 Box 5.6 Individual loans and product diversification at SEWA Bank 94 Box 6.1 Dimensions of social performance 106 Box 7.1 Providing sustainable and competitive insurance products to rural customers 121 Box 7.2 SEWA and rainfall insurance 127 Box 8.1 The evolution of MIS in Basix 135 Box 8.2 A hosted solution: FINO 137 Box 8.3 TAFI: Putting mobile phone technology to work as a BC for remittances 145 Box 9.1: The microfinance bill: a case study in dilution 162 Box 9.2 Misunderstandings about savings 165 Box 9.3 Grameen II and flexible, voluntary savings 166 Box 9.4 Sa-Dhan’s Voluntary Mutual Code of Conduct 167 Box 9.5 A bit of history: Self-regulation backed by legal sanctions 168 List of Figures Page No Figure 4.1 Membership of sample MFIs 76 Figure 4.2 Average savings per member by model 77 Figure 4.3 OER by loan size 78 Figure 4.4 Relationship of portfolio size with efficiency 79 Figure 4.5 Sources of funds for microfinance operations 79 Figure 6.1 Assessing social performance 108 4
  • 7. Foreword This is the second of a series of Annual Reports on the microfinance sector in India, prepared for presentation to the annual Microfinance India conference organized by ACCESS Development Services. The Microfinance India Conference, over the last four years, has become established as perhaps the most recognized sector event, and attracts large-scale interest from diverse stakeholders from the sector, and interested observers from within and outside the country, and has become known for insightful discussions and debates of key issues challenging the sector. This year's conference, the fourth in the series, is being held on October 9- 10. Among others, a specific significant contribution of Microfinance India, in addition to the conference, has been the publication of the State of the Sector Report annually released at the time of the Conference. Like last year, the State of the Sector Report contains two chapters on progress under each of the two main models of microfinance in India viz. linkage banking and MFIs. These two chapters are proposed to be carried every year and carry the most updated review of how the two models have progressed during the year. In addition, the Report includes five chapters on "new" topics and themes that could not be covered in the last State of the Sector Report, but continue to be of current and future significance to the Sector. These topics relate to SHG federations, evaluation of social performance, urban microfinance, developments in technology, and perspectives on regulatory issues, including the pending microfinance bill. A few topics such as developments in commercial bank lending to MFIs, equity investments, and issues relating to the mounting challenge of the growing need for quality human resource for the sector could not be covered again in this year's report for reasons of space, but are proposed to be taken up in subsequent years. In future years, we also hope to include themes, which have yet to be covered, such as livelihoods finance, financial inclusion, financial literacy, et al. The abundance of additional information collated by the author may necessitate a second edition of the report. In order to broad-base participation in preparation of the report and take fullest advantage of the rich expertise available in the sector, four of the chapters contained in this year's report have been contributed by well known sector experts. I am personally grateful to them for taking valuable time off from their other responsibilities. I acknowledge support extended for one of these chapters, that on the MFI model, by the MIX. All of them have been equally ambitious to continue to support this ACCESS - Microfinance initiative to make the State of the Sector Report as valuable to the sector as possible. To ensure widespread distribution of last year's State of the Sector Report, it has been brought out as book under the title of Microfinance in India: The Challenges of Rapid Growth. The book has been published by Sage Publications as a paperback so as to enhance affordability. I am also grateful to our sponsors Swiss Development Cooperation and Ford Foundation and the close association of both Adrian and Ajit at all stages of the Report's progress. And finally, I am immensely grateful to Prabhu, who, exhausted from the first effort, with some persuasion, agreed to author the 2007 report. I also would like to thank my team at ACCESS for the support provided to this effort. Most importantly, I am grateful to the sector at large for their very positive response to last year's report, which encouraged us to raise our ambition for the current year's report, and to persist with the idea of bringing it out annually. I hope the sector will find the State of the Sector Report 2007 equally valuable as last year and continue to support the effort through sharing information, contributing experiences from the field and bringing in their perspectives on the sector. Vipin Sharma CEO, ACCESS Development Services, New Delhi 5
  • 8. Preface and Acknowledgements Like last year's report on the state of the Indian microfinance sector, this year's seeks to document developments, clarify issues, publicize studies, stimulate research, identify policy choices, generate understanding, and enhance support for the sector. Given the increasing complexity and diversity of the sector, each annual edition of the report can try, but is unlikely to succeed, in being a comprehensive record of everything that happened during the year. In its choice of topics this year's report tries to complement last year's. Thus it covers five topics not covered last year, two of them contained in chapters by practitioners (those on technology and social performance) and three of them in chapters by the lead author (those on SHG federations, urban microfinance, and regulation). A third chapter on insurance is also by a practitioner. I am grateful to Vijay Mahajan, Sai Gunaranjan and Prasanth Regy for giving the report a more practical flavour by drawing on the experience of BASIX, an industry leader in the adoption (and adaptation) of both technology and micro insurance. Frances Sinha leads M-CRIL's pioneering efforts in introducing social performance assessment to India (and indeed to many other countries), and Sanjay Sinha is one of India's leading analysts of the MFI model through M-CRIL's rating work and the periodic M-CRIL Reviews. Many of the people whose help I gratefully acknowledged last year were generous again in sharing their time and understanding. I hope they will understand if I do not thank them individually again. Among those I had not managed to contact last year but were an invaluable source of information and guidance this year were Vikram Akula, Ramesh Arunachalam, Anjali Banthia, Mukti Bosco, Arabdha Das, T Dhanaraj, BR Diwakar, Malini Eden , Aloysius Fernandez, Suvarna Rani Gandham, Aseem Gandhi, Chandra Shekhar Ghosh, Samit Ghosh, Gita Goel, Marie- Luise Haberberger, Pradeep Jena, Mohd Ali Karim, KG Karmakar, Jugal Kataria, S. Kathiresan, Manish Khera, Sudha Kothari, Aparna Krishnan, Ajit Kumar Maity, Veena Mankar, Jan Meissner, Amulya Mohanty, Nayana Mohanty, R Murali, Ravi Narasimhan, Venky Natarajan, Anant Natu, Parashuram Nayak, LB Prakash, Vidya Ramachandran, RV Ramakrishna, S Ramamurthy, Abhijit Ray, Chinappa Reddy, Rama Reddy, Suma Reddy, Shubhankar Sengupta, HP Singh, Jaipal Singh, Usha Somasundaram, Girija Srinivasan, Mark Straub, Yusuke Taishi,Usha Thorat, and Srikrishna. My apologies to the many others who have been left out. My thanks to all of you. I would like to thank the following institutions for their support: Sa-Dhan for coming out in such timely fashion with this year's "Quick Report 2007: A Snapshot of MFIs in India" which forms the basis of an important table in the statistical appendix; the Center for Micro Finance, Chennai, for useful interactions over the year: and M2i through Deepak Alok and Avishek 6
  • 9. Sarcar, who helped put together the statistical appendix, brief though it is because of the paucity of time and the scattered nature of the data available. I would like to thank the sponsors for giving me this opportunity to immerse myself for another year in a sector peopled by so many creative and inspiring individuals. I am grateful also to Vipin Sharma of ACCESS India for his encouragement, and the freedom and flexibility he gave me while I tried to put together the various pieces of the complicated puzzle that is Indian microfinance; to his team consisting of Nishant Tirath and Yeshu Bansal and other colleagues for help provided; and to Malcolm Harper and Brij Mohan, two of our resource persons, for being on tap once again with a constant flow of good advice and stimulating comments. In order to establish continuity and avoid duplication, I refer back frequently to "last year's report", which is now conveniently available as a paperback. While I have attempted to consult as many sector participants as possible, I am conscious that a number of significant developments and materials relevant to the topics covered may have escaped my attention. I would request readers to bring them to my attention, as well as any other comments or corrections, so that they can be taken into account while preparing the report for final publication. I am sure the other chapter authors would also welcome feedback. The intention is to make these reports as collaborative an effort as possible. Needless to say, the views expressed in our respective chapters are entirely our own. Prabhu Ghate pghate1@gmail.com 7
  • 10. Abbreviations AIDS Acquired Immune Deficiency Syndrome ALW A Little World AMMACTS Acts Mahila Mutually Aided Cooperative Thrift Society AMUL Anand Milk-producers Union Limited AP Andhra Pradesh APMACS Andhra Pradesh Mutually Aided Cooperative Societies APMAS Andhra Pradesh Mahila Abhivruddhi Society APR Annualised Percentage Rate ASP Ankuram Sanghamam Poram ATM Automated Teller Machine AWA Assistant Anganwadi Worker AWW Anganwadi Worker BC Business Correspodent BDS Business Development service CASHE Credit and Savings for Household Enterprise CASHPOR Credit and Savings for the Hardcore Poor CBHI Central Bureau of Health Intelligence CBMFI Community Based MFI CBO Capacity Building Organisation CBS Core Banking Solution CDF Cooperative Development Foundation CGAP Consultative Group to Assist the Poor CIF Community Investment Funds CM Computer Munshi CMF Center for Microfinance CMRC Community Managed Resource Centres CRAR Capital to Risk Weighted Assets Ratio DCCB District Central Cooperative Bank DF DHAN Foundation DFID Department for International Development+B1 DRDA District Rural Development Authority DWCD Department of Women and Child Development EIR Effective Interest Rate EWI Equated Weekly Installment FAMIS Financial Accounting and Management Information System FGD Focussed Group Discussion FINO Financial Information Network & Operations Ltd FLDG First Loss Deficiency Guarantee FWWB Friends of Women’s World Banking 8
  • 11. GCC General Purpose Credit Cards GNI Gross National Income GRADES G stands for governance, R for resources, A for asset quality, D for design of systems, E for efficiency and profitability, and S for services to member SHGs and their performance. GTZ Deutsche Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit HDFC Housing Development Finance Corporation HIV Human Immunodeficiency Virus HO Head Office HR Human Resources HUDCO Housing Urban Development Corporation IB Individual Banking ICT Information Communication Technology IFAD International Fund for Agricultural Development IGS Indian Grameen Services IKP Indira Kranti Patham ILO International Labour Organisation IPO Initial Public Offering IRDA Insurance Regulatory and Development Authority IT Information Technology JLG Joint Liability Group KBSLAB Krishna Bhima Samruddhi Local Area Bank KDFS Kalanjiam Development and Financial Services KSDF Kalighat Society for Development Facilitation KVK Krishi Vigyan Kendras KYC Know Your Customer LAB Local Area Bank LAN Local Area Network LSS "Lights and Shades" Study MACS Mutually Aided Cooperative Society MBT Mutual Benefit Trust MCRA Micro Credit Regulatory Authority M-CRIL Micro-credit Ratings International Ltd MFDC Microfinance Development Council MFDEF Micro Finance Development and Equity Fund MFI Microfinance Institution MFO Microfinance Organisations MIFOS Microfinance Open Source MIS Management Information System MIX Microfinance Information Exchange MSDF Michael & Susan Dell Foundation NABARD National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development NABFINS Nabard Financial Services NBFC Non-Banking Financial Company NBJK Nav Bharat Jagriti Kendra NCAER National Council for Applied Economic Research (NCAER NDA National Democratic Alliance NDDB National Dairy Development Board NE North East NFC Near Field Communication NGO Non Governmental Organization NOF Net Owned Fund NPA Non Performing Assets 9
  • 12. NREGA National Rural Employment Guarantee Act NSSO National Sample Survey Organisation OER Operating Expense Ratio OSS Operating Self Sufficiency PACS Primary Agricultural Credit Societies PAR Portfolio At Risk PC Personal Computer PDA Personal Digital Assistant PHC Public Health Centre PLR Prime Lending Rate POS Point of Sale PPP Purchasing Power Parity PRADAN Professional Assistance for Development Action PSS Pragathi Sewa Samithi PWMACTS The Payakaraopta Women’s Mutually Aided Cooperative Thrift And Credit Society Ltd RBI Reserve Bank of India RGVN Rashtriya Grameen Vikas Nidhi RMK Rashtriya Mahila Kosh RRB Regional Rural Bank RSRO Recognised Self Regulatory Authority RV Roshan Vikas SBLP SHG Bank Linkage Program SC Scheduled Caste SCB State Cooperative Bank SEEP Small Enterprise Education and Promotion SERP The Society for Elimination of Rural Poverty SEWA Self-Employed Women's Association SGSY Swarna Jayanti Gram Swarozgar Yojna SHG Self Help Group SHPA Self Help Promotion Agency SHPI Self Help Promoting Institution SIDBI Small Industries Development Bank of India SIM Subscriber Identity Module SKDRDP Shri Kshetra Dhamrmasthala Rural Development Project SKS Swayam Krishi Sangam SNFL Sarvodaya Nano Finance Limited SPM Social Performance Management SPMS Sri Padmavathy Mahila Abyudaya Sangh SPOT Specified Point of Transaction SQL Structured Query Language SRO Self Regulatory Authority ST Scheduled Tribe STEP Strategies and Tools against social Exlusion and Poverty SWAWS Sharadas Women’s Association for Weaker Section TAFI Technology Assisted Financial Inclusion TNCDW Tamil Nadu Corporation for the Development of Women UCB Urban Cooperative Bank UNDP United Nations Development Program UPS Uninterruptible Power Supply USP Unique Selling Proposition VO Village Organization VWS Village Welfare Society NOTE: 1 CRORE = 10 MILLION, 1 LAKH = 10,000, US$1 = RS 40 APPROXIMATELY 10
  • 13. CHAPTER 1 Overview CHAPTER 1 Overview Growth of the sector continues to be rapid... The SHG-Bank Linkage Programme (SBLP) covered a further 9.6 million persons in 2006-07, over 90 percent of them women, and about them half of them poor (Fact Sheet, Table A.1). The total number of SHG members who have ever received credit through the programme has grown therefore to 41 million persons. Microfinance Institutions, (MFIs), the other model of microfinance in India, grew even more strongly, and added an estimated 3 million new borrowers to reach a total coverage of about 10.5 million borrowers. Both programmes taken together have therefore reached about 50 million households. Only 36.8 million of these are being currently being served, however. (Table A.1) However, not all microfinance borrowers are poor About half of SHG members, and only 30 percent of MFI members are estimated to be below the Indicate the poverty line.1 Thus about 22 percent of all poor households (about 75 million) are currently sector continues to receiving microfinance services, or at least microcredit. Given limitations in the data base make strong that continue to afflict the sector, these are only rough estimates, but they indicate the progress towards the sector continues to make strong progress towards the goal of extending financial inclusion to goal of the roughly fourth-fifths of the population who do not receive credit from the banks, although extending there is still a long way to go. Slower progress is being made in reaching out to poor households.2 financial inclusion to the roughly fourth- MFI borrowers receive larger first loans than SHG members, but since (i) the average duration fifths of the of MFI loans is shorter (generally one year instead of two), (ii) MFIs have been expanding population who do not receive rapidly, bringing down average MFI loan size (Chapter 4), and (iii) the size of repeat loans to credit from the SHGs has been growing even faster than first loans (Chapter 2), the difference in average loans banks, although outstanding per borrower in the two models no longer appears to be significant.3 there is still a long way to go. Slower progress The sector needs to pay more attention to depth of is being made in reaching out outreach and other quality issues to poor households Both models continue to do relatively well on loan repayment performance4 and on empowering women by improving their economic status in the household. The SHG model has the additional empowerment benefit of bringing almost a million SHG leaders into direct contact with the banks, and in a few states giving them an opportunity to represent their groups in SHGs federations at the village and higher levels. While SHG federations are still being formed in 11
  • 14. most states, in a few states such as AP they have started playing an increasingly active role in delivering economic and social services (Chapter 3). Last year's report made the point that now that the goal of making a significant dent on the challenge of financial inclusion seems attainable, the sector should pay more attention to quality issues. It expressed the concern that growth in the SBLP in particular was running ahead of the programme's capacity to ensure quality. The programme has decelerated only slightly this year in terms of new groups linked, and not at all in respect of loans disbursed (which now amount to a cumulative amount of Rs 18,000 crores (Chapter 2). Indeed the SBLP is now growing under its own momentum. There is of course a need to accelerate growth in the underserved states which are mostly in Although there the central and eastern regions, and slower growth in the programme as a whole will not in are some well known itself lead to higher quality in terms of depth of outreach (the proportion of SHG members exceptions, below the poverty line), or in book-keeping capacity, which is crucial for a whole range of including MFIs performance variables such as the drop-out rate, the equity of loan distribution within groups, who rely on methods such and indeed of the longevity of groups themselves. There have been no reported new approaches as an easy-to- by NGOs promoting SHGs, or by NABARD, in tackling the phenomenon of self-exclusion, by use housing index to target introducing lower and more flexible monthly savings requirements in keeping with the variable the poor, most and uncertain incomes of the poor. Assistance to promoting NGOs remains inadequate to MFIs, while enable them to provide training inputs for long enough to ensure group sustainability. Studies contributing to the financial show that groups promoted by field level government functionaries who are given targets in inclusion addition to their regular duties, tend to be the weakest, and receive the lowest hand-holding objective, are inputs after the groups have been formed. While progress is being made in expanding the making no special efforts programme in 13 priority states as discussed in Chapter 2, it is being achieved on the basis of to target the government-promoted groups, since these are the states where good NGOs tend be thinnest poor on the ground. It would enhance quality consciousness at all levels of the programme if NABARD could include in its annual report on the programme, information on the quality of groups. A grading system has already been prescribed for purposes of loan appraisal by the banks, but it is not being used in monitoring of the programme. Grading would of course have to be done on a sample basis given the immensity of the task of grading all groups. Increasing the depth of outreach is equally urgent for MFIs,5 although it could be argued that as the SHG programme expands to all parts of the country SHGs should attempt to meet the demand for household consumption and emergency loans and for relatively small investment loans for income generation activities, while allowing MFIs to cater to the market for larger loans, which is growing rapidly in the rural areas. The emergence of some such division of labour will help reduce MFI transactions costs and therefore interest charged to MFI borrowers. SHGs are designed to internalize these costs. Although they do so, they end up charging their borrowers about the same rates as MFIs, in order to build up group capital. The modal SHG charges 2 percent per month, or 24 percent per annum, as against average MFI rates for the country as a whole of 21 percent as self-reported by 129 MFIs in Sa-Dhan 2007, or about 25 percent according to a smaller M-CRIL sample (Chapter 4).6 However, until some such division of labour takes place it would be unfortunate if MFIs in their urge to expand and reduce unit costs increasingly neglect the poorest borrowers, as seems to be already happening. Although there are some well known exceptions, including MFIs who rely on methods such as an easy-to-use housing index to target the poor,7 most MFIs, while contributing to the financial inclusion objective, are making no special efforts to target the poor. For many of them, lending to the poorest borrowers is increasingly becoming 12
  • 15. CHAPTER 1 Overview a niche activity, assigned to special projects. Many of them are increasingly describing their target group in such terms as the "the sub-prime market", the "missing middle", "low income groups" etc.8 Depth of outreach is one of the social performance variables that the new social rating tools being developed in India and elsewhere seek to monitor (Chapter 6). Client satisfaction and client protection issues are other social performance quality variables that have come to the fore in India after last year's Krishna district episode (Chapter 4 of last year's report). The on-lending funds constraint makes a reappearance As last year's report points out, there was a time when MFI managers had to devote most of their time and energy to dealing with the uncertainty of where the next loan for on-lending funds was going to come from. However the rapid expansion of commercial bank lending to the sector from 2004 led to the happy situation in which this was no longer the case. MFI lending grew rapidly, both through the expansion of existing MFIs and the incubation of new ones, and the Indian microfinance sector became one the most highly leveraged in the world (Chapter 3, last year's report). However, developments during the year have made it more difficult to be as sanguine as before The partnership that the onlending funds constraint on continued growth of MFI's has for once and all been model in effect removed. The rapid expansion of lending to MFIs was due largely to the introduction by ICICI removed both Bank of its "partnership model", under which loans to borrowers remained on the books of the the equity and the on-lending bank, off the balance sheet of the MFI partner, which only undertook loan origination, monitoring funds and collection services for a fee. Thus the MFI performed the role of a social intermediary, while constraints at credit risk was borne largely by the bank, although the MFI had to share the risk of default up to one stroke... This major a specified level, by providing a "first loss guarantee". This greatly reduced the amount of equity innovation with which an MFI required to support its borrowings, and the partnership model in effect unfortunately came unstuck removed both the equity and the on-lending funds constraints at one stroke. during the year This major innovation unfortunately came unstuck during the year, initially due to the AP crisis in March 2006 and regulatory concerns about KYC (Know Your Customer) requirements, but thereafter because ICICI changed its own requirements under the partnership model, and indeed its whole vision of the nature of the relationship it wants to have with its partners. By March 2006, ICICI Bank's lending had grown to constitute about two-thirds of total lending to the sector, with about 60 percent of its lending coming under the partnership model.9 However, instead of increasing sharply again as in previous years, ICICI's lending has declined in 2006-07, and is likely to stay relatively low in the current year. One of the concerns raised by the AP crisis was the possibility of multiple borrowing by MFI customers from both the major MFIs in the district concerned, both of who were major partners of the bank under the partnership model. While there is no evidence that this led to over-lending as reflected in an inability to repay loans,10 ICICI was urged by the RBI to strengthen its KYC procedures now that the loans were on the bank's own books and not on those of the partner.11 It took some time for ICICI's partners to furnish the relevant information, during which time fresh lending under the partnership model was suspended. It was partly substituted by term loans, but not in sufficient amounts to alleviate the stress being experienced by partners who were now strapped for funds. While other banks increased their lending, it was mostly to 13
  • 16. existing partners, although some switching may have taken place. Box 1.1 describes the loan fund stringency caused to a major partner of the bank, an experience not untypical of that undergone by a number of former partners, especially the smaller ones.12 Box 1.1 Cashpor: Stoppage of Partnership Funding This was an unexpected and major challenge for the Company during the last Fiscal. Funds stopped flowing, suddenly and without notice, from our major off-balance sheet funder in early September. As about half (47%) of our total portfolio was under Partnership, and it amounted to Rs. 29.2 crore, danger signals started flashing. To make things worse, we could not get a clear explanation from the Bank, nor any indication as to when the funds would flow again. Normally under Partnership, our portfolio grows over-time according to demand from clients, as the funds are on tap. For efficient fund management the practice is to contra due repayments against new loan disbursement. If there are no longer any funds for new disbursement, however, due repayments still have to be made - taking funds out of circulation in the field. With the stoppage of funds, not only did we have to find new funds for new clients but also for subsequent loans of existing clients. Suddenly we needed about Rs.6 crore of new funds, every month! Fortunately we had been negotiating with two other banks to provide funding under Partnership, so as to diversify our sources of that important category of funding. They agreed to start funding under Partnership, and we transferred 4 of the 6 Districts funded under partnership to them. One of them got cold feet, however, at the last moment, as there were rumours circulating that the RBI was not happy with Partnership funding, and had directed the major bank involved to stop it. Similar rumours have continued to circulate and have even appeared in the press; but RBI has not issued any public clarification. Meanwhile, after a month and a half, our original Partner Bank, offered a term loan to replace its Partnership funding, which the Company accepted. Then in December, funds started flowing again under Partnership. Then, just as suddenly and without notice, the flow stopped again in early January. It had not resumed by end of the Fiscal; but the Bank has made an additional term loan available. Nevertheless, the irregularity and uncertainty over the flow of Partnership funds have caused considerable delay and confusion on the ground among clients and staff of the Company. The continuing failure of the Bank and RBI to inform the MFIs and the public as to the reasons for the stoppage and if and how the flow of funds could be resumed is creating uncertainty which is unhealthy for the financial system…Partnership funding was a break- through to reaching increasing numbers of BPL households with financial services. Its stoppage removes economic opportunity from them. Informally we have discovered that the proximate reason for the stoppages in Partnership funding last Fiscal was strict new guidelines that RBI insisted for it. It seems that the main Bank involved was slow to meet these requirements, did not inform its partner MFIs clearly about them and their deadlines, and finally was instructed by their own legal department that they were in violation and had to stop. We are now clear that Partnership funding can resume when RBI KYC (Know Your Client) requirements are fully-met and compliance is maintained, and when the banks involved receive day-end transaction information for clients under Partnership. KYC requirements are being fully complied with by CMC; and we will soon test the FINO technological solution for providing day-end transaction information to the banks. Partnership funding is expected to resume as the new technology spreads. It might be asked as to why the Company wishes to resume Partnership funding, when it and the main Bank involved have been unreliable? The answer is simple. Our overriding objective is increase in our outreach to BPL households. Partnership funding, as imperfect as it has been, enables us to expand that outreach twice as much as we could without it. Extract from "Highlights from the Chairman", in "CASHPOR Annual Report, 2006-07: Crossing Two Lac BPL Clients", CASHPOR, Varanasi, 2007 14
  • 17. CHAPTER 1 Overview And technology makes an entry During this period it seems ICICI's own thinking underwent a change as it gained a better understanding of the limitations of the MIS systems of most of its partners. Many MFIs are still putting in place computerized information systems that can track ever-larger number of transactions and branch accounts. MIS systems are the foundation of other technology applications, and are discussed in Chapter 8. It came around to the view that without major reliance on technology (and renewed inputs of capacity-building) most partners would not be available to furnish KYC (Know Your Customer) information in a timely fashion, and certainly not by the "end of day", as required under the guidelines of the business correspondent model (see below). However, there was an even more important reason for why ICICI Bank came to feel the need to reflect all transactions in its books on a real time basis, which had to do with the bank's own rethinking of its stance towards microfinance. The bank has always been interested in developing what it has called the "missing markets" of Many MFIs are complementary infrastructure, including shared borrower information systems. It is making a still putting in place major effort to introduce smart cards bearing unique ID numbers and biometric information computerized (finger prints) that will help identify customers, track service usage, and build up customer information systems that histories. In the longer term this will be an essential element in the creation of credit information can track ever- systems such as credit bureaus. The "front-end" technology will have to be supported however larger number by "back-end" "core banking" infrastructure consisting of "hosted" or centralized software, of transactions and branch which can be shared by several customers, and which can communicate with hand held devices accounts. MIS (or POS or "point of sale" terminals) in the field, which read and record transaction information systems are the foundation of on the customer's smart cards. If internet connectivity is available, the smart cards can be other used on a real time basis, enabling real-time sharing of credit information across the branch technology network. ICICI is supporting such a system through FINO, a company which seeks to provide applications a core banking solution, not just to MFIs but to other banks and financial institutions and even state governments (Chapter 8).13 Partnership loans are being extended only to existing or new partners who are willing to sign up for FINO, or any alternative core banking system.14 Only a small proportion of the bank's former 100 odd partners are reported to have joined so far.15 As we have seen, for those former partners who have decided not to join, lending flows have declined because term loans are not intended to fully substitute for the former level of partnership flows. While ICICI Bank continued to make term loans as an interim measure to alleviate distress, it has veered around to a strong preference for partnership lending supported by technology for the long-term advantage the combination of partnership lending and ICT holds out of being able to generate customer information, not just on credit, but also on savings, insurance, remittance and other transactions, built up through the use of smart cards. Smart cards are being issued through partners to all borrowers. ICICI has also launched pilots to collect savings through smart cards and point of sale devices through several partners around the country under the business correspondent scheme, and expects eventually to be able to make individual loans to the same customers on the basis of the customer information built up.16 Conversely it has lost interest in making term loans to MFIs conducting group lending along traditional minimalist lines. Given the radically changed perspective on the part of the major lender it is possible we are 15
  • 18. Given the likely to be in the midst of at least a temporary hiccup in the growth rate of lending under the radically MFI model, especially to medium sized and small MFIs, until other banks and bulk lenders such changed perspective on as SIDBI, FWWB, and others can step in to fill the breach.17 While banks other than ICICI have the part of the been increasing their lending quite sharply, they are doing so from a relatively small base.18 major lender it Independently of these developments, the World Bank is reported to be considering making a is possible we are likely to be loan to SIDBI which would enable SIDBI to further step up its lending, and make longer term in the midst of loans with the grace periods necessary to finance MFI deficits in the initial years. Demand for at least a temporary such loans is certainly likely to strengthen, especially on the part of smaller MFIs who may not hiccup in the be able to attract the equity investments which could temporarily alleviate credit stringency growth rate of for larger MFIs. A greater diversity of lenders will reduce unhealthy dependence on a single lending under the MFI model, large lender. Another possible source of funds are member savings which in Bangladesh especially to contribute about a third of the funding base, while lowering at the same time the average medium sized and small MFIs, cost of funds (Chapter 9). However this option is not proposed to be made available to the until other bulk of the sector consisting of NBFCs and S 25 companies by the emerging regulatory regime banks and bulk for the sector, as discussed below. lenders such as SIDBI, FWWB, and others can step in to fill Private equity also makes an entry, but what are the the breach implications? Two landmark private equity investments in Indian MFIs took place in the first part of the year; a $ 11.5 million investment in SKS, led by Sequoia Capital, at the end of March, followed soon after by a $25 million investment in SHARE, by Legatum Capital. Hyderabad-based SKS is the third largest MFI in India (Table A.2), and is growing perhaps the most rapidly, hoping to end the current financial year with an outreach of about 1.5 million borrowers in 11 states. Sequoia was joined by Unitus equity fund, which already has 2 equity investment partners in India and 8 other "capacity building" partners through an associated foundation with offices in Bangalore, as well as by Vinod Khosla and other investors. This infusion of fresh equity enabled SKS to leverage a Rs 180 crore financial arrangement with Citibank India to finance its expansion plans. Under the deal, Citibank will purchase loans originated by SKS under a limited guarantee provided by US-based Grameen Foundation, which also has an office in India.19 SHARE is India's largest MFI with over 1 million clients and has plans to grow to 6 million over the next five years. When lending under ICICI Bank's partnership model was suspended at the beginning of the year until partners could fulfill KYC requirements SHARE found itself strapped not just for lending funds, but short of the equity capital with which to borrow them as term loans from the banks. Legatum's investment gives it majority control of SHARE. It was accompanied by a $2 million investment by Aavishkaar Goodwell Microfinance Development Company, an Indo-Dutch joint venture,20 which becomes the fifth social venture capital company to have a presence in India (Table A.4, and Chapter 7B, last year's report). The size of these investments is unusual even by Latin American standards. One came just before, and the other just after Banco Compartamos, a Mexican bank specializing in microfinance, that had started life as an NGO, made an initial public offering of 30 percent of its stocks on Wall Street, in April. The success of the Compartamos floatation, and the size of the SKS and SHARE private placements occasioned considerable excitement world-wide. These were investments by mainstream commercial (as opposed to socially-motivated) investors, whose support would accelerate the mobilization of private capital for massive expansion of 16
  • 19. CHAPTER 1 Overview outreach. They were seen as heralding the beginning of large private placements in microfinance as "investors now have a clear line of sight towards an exit" (Satterthwaite 2007). However, the huge profits made by the shareholders of Compartamos also stirred world-wide debate about "whether this was what microfinance was all about". The IPO was oversubscribed 13 times and the share price surged by 22 percent on the first day of trading alone. Two- thirds of the shares were held by public-purpose institutions and a third were held by private individuals, including the co-founders of the NGO.21 The issues raised by Compartamos have been discussed comprehensively in a CGAP study. It points out the extremely high profitability of Banco (resulting in a return to equity of over 50 percent a year) was based on interest rates that were high even by Mexican standards (CGAP 2007). The study felt that that as long as Compartamos was an NGO, its strategy of funding growth on the basis of unusually high profits The study felt and retained earnings so as to expand coverage rapidly to new borrowers, was justified. But that that as long as once it commercialized in 2000,22 and private investors stood to benefit, it should have Compartamos funded further growth by tapping into the rapidly expanding flow of funds from socially- was an NGO, its strategy of minded investors and development-oriented lenders. This would have enabled it to decrease funding growth interest rates considerably. As the report says "it seems to us at CGAP that after 2000 there on the basis of was a direct conflict between the profits of private investors and the financial interest of unusually high profits and Compartamos borrowers. We don't think that Compartamos and its pro-bono majority retained shareholders gave enough weight to borrowers when setting its prices" earnings so as to expand coverage It pointed out further that the high IPO prices sets in place expectations and alters the rapidly to new ownership structure of Compartamos in such a way that will make it even harder for the borrowers, was company to balance social and commercial objectives in the future. The not-for-profit justified. But once it institutional shareholders are now in a minority by a tiny margin, although they can still commercialized exercise effective control if they vote together. However, the "…practical implication is that in 2000, and private new purchasers cannot realize a respectable return on their investment unless future profitability investors stood is considerably higher than it already was in 2006…new investors…will have little sympathy to benefit, it for interest rate policies that do not stretch profits to the maximum …" should have funded further growth by The report is candid enough to admit that "those of us who are involved in MFI transformations tapping into may need to be clearer about the inevitable governance consequences of those transformations… the rapidly since our founding in 1995, CGAP has been vocal about the need for interest rates that are high expanding flow of funds from enough to cover costs, but we have been less emphatic about the loss to clients when interest socially-minded rates are driven by inefficiency or exorbitant profits. We never made concrete predictions about investors and development- how quickly competition would fix these problems, but we were probably too optimistic on this oriented score. The Compartamos IPO gives all of us an opportunity to take another look at these questions." lenders Some of the issues raised in the Compartamos debate were reflected in India too, for example in the debate carried by Microfinance Insights, a quarterly publication by Intellecap, the microfinance consultingancy company, between the founders of SKS, SHARE and the Basix group of companies. The flavour of the debate is conveyed by extracts in Box 1.2. The key question is what is the impact of large commercial investments likely to be on the Indian microfinance sector and the borrower? India already has a group of microfinance venture capital funds driven by a mix of social and commercial objectives23 and they have been active during the year, investing both in "transformees" (see below) and start-ups. As a group, they have longer time horizons and probably lower-return expectations than the new private equity investors.24 However, they cannot hope to match the scale of investments required by the 17
  • 20. larger MFIs or the sector as a whole, especially after the sharp decline in the number of MFIs under the partnership model. The pressure to maximize returns by the new PE investors is unlikely to result in upward pressure on interest rates, as was the case with Compartamos, although it could dampen the decline of rates that should come with further growth. Public, political and regulator acceptability will not allow high rates in India. With this option cut off, the pressure to maximize returns is likely to take the form of the desire to reach massive scale. This portends well for financial inclusion, and for better regional balance of MFI lending, since the large MFIs are stepping out of their base in Andhra, but it does not portend as well for the quality of growth. The problems in AP in 2006 were caused by "the rush to grow". Moreover, since organic growth yields slower increases in scale than mergers and acquisitions, it is widely expected that the sector will witness mergers between MFIs.25 Further large investments by private equity are also expected, with the possibility of IPOs.26 The pressure to Recent developments on the equity front have been welcomed by most observers as the only maximize returns is likely means of meeting the huge equity requirements of a rapidly expanding, but increasingly to take the capital inadequate sector (Chapter 4). The Indian sector is now seen to be attracting the form of the whole spectrum of funding from purely commercial private equity at one end to grants at the desire to reach massive scale. other, although the latter are much less important than in other countries. It is too early to This portends say whether the concerns of the pessimists will materialize. There is little doubt that there is well for financial considerable interest among new investors in entering the sector, despite declining margins inclusion, and being squeezed by rising costs and limits to acceptable interest rate increases (Chapter 4).27 for better There is no dearth of potential investees either, as more and more non-profits are lining up to regional balance of MFI transform to NBFCs, a phenomenon driven primarily by capital adequacy concerns, but also by lending, since the enhanced sense of vulnerability induced by the AP crisis. The new bill which seeks to the large MFIs confer a modicum of legitimacy to non-profits does not seem to be stemming the flow of non- are stepping out of their profits voting with their feet. An active market has developed in NBFC licenses not being used base in Andhra, by the original owners which are being brought up for a premium by transforming NGOs.28 Thus but it does not portend as well the chain of consequences set in motion by the Andhra crisis is still playing itself out. By for the quality putting an end to partnership lending in the form we knew it, it has increased the demand for of growth term loans, which in turn have increased the demand for equity, and have led to a spate of transformations to NBFC status. The new microfinance bill is out of tune with these developments, as discussed next. The new microfinance bill takes a small but important step forward in allowing NGO-MFIs to mobilize savings, but limits savings to "thrift" The absence of savings in Indian microfinance has distinguished it till now from microfinance in most other countries, and has been likened to "walking on one leg" since without savings microfinance is not microfinance at all but microcredit. There is a widespread misconception that the poor are too poor to save, and that they need credit, not savings facilities. On the contrary, as Chapter 9 points out, savings is probably a more widely felt need than credit, and takes place through a variety of savings mechanisms and institutions in the informal sector.29 Like the rest of us, the poor are looking for savings services which are convenient, safe, liquid, and can preferably be used to leverage loans. 18
  • 21. CHAPTER 1 Overview By allowing at least what it call micro finance organizations (MFOs) to meet this need, the draft microfinance bill takes an important step forward. However, ironically, it is this aspect of the bill that has been the most widely misunderstood by critics. India's attitude to savings mobilization by non-banks has been more restrictive than elsewhere, an attitude influenced by exaggerated perceptions of fraud in the informal and cooperative sectors, and strengthened by periodic scams which affect the savings of the urban middle classes and which therefore receive widespread publicity in the press. Most of the countries of South Asia, which share the same legal heritage, now expressly allow savings to registered MFIs in their microfinance legislation. Bangladesh, where conditions are closest to India, and where the MFI model originated, has recently passed the Micro Credit Regulatory Authority (MCRA) Act 2006, which allows the MCRA to allow registered MFIs to offer savings withdrawable on demand. Unfortunately, the bill limits permissible savings to what it calls thrift, or the small, Indeed, recognizing the compulsory savings of uniform size for all members. While the proposal to allow thrift is liquidity welcome and long overdue, it is important to note it is only the first small step forward in preference of introducing savings. While many savers welcome the discipline of compulsory savings, the poor for many although they tend to belong to the better-off among the poor, or to the "near-poor" above the not all savings poverty line. On the other hand many of the poorer members of SHGs (and most of the purposes, several MFIs in self-excluded non-members), who have highly uncertain and variable incomes, would prefer Bangladesh, and to save small variable amounts, with variable frequency. Several surveys have found that the indeed world- main reason for why only half the members of SHGs are below the poverty line is the wide, who have the requisite inability of BPL persons to commit themselves to the required mandatory savings amounts accounting and periodicities. Uniform mandatory savings are also the most frequent reason cited by systems, are drop-outs for leaving SHGs. moving to a system of voluntary A concomitant of mandatory savings products is their illiquidity. While illiquid savings protect savings in the savings of the poor from daily demands, and are suited to accumulating lump-sums for which the saver has some choice expected purposes such as life-cycle events or school fees or adding a new room to the hut, over the timing they are unsuited to coping with unexpected emergencies including sickness and disease, or and amount of consumption smoothening in the lean season, or replacing a leaky roof in the middle of the savings and withdrawals monsoons. Indeed, recognizing the liquidity preference of the poor for many although not all savings purposes, several MFIs in Bangladesh, and indeed world-wide, who have the requisite accounting systems, are moving to a system of voluntary savings in which the saver has some choice over the timing and amount of savings and withdrawals. It is not being suggested that most small Indian NGO-MFIs have developed the requisite systems to be able to able to offer such a savings product yet, or that mandatory savings do not have their advantages for certain purposes. However, provision should be made for the day when a larger number of NGO-MFIs have developed the requisites systems and capacity to offer voluntary savings. Also, there is a possibility that the bill may be amended to include NBFCs and S 25 companies, who do have such capacities. Since voluntary savings are more conveniently offered as individual savings (because voluntary savings amounts and frequency will always vary from individual to individual), it would seem essential to allow the regulator the option to approve individual, voluntary, savings products in appropriate cases after due diligence by the regulator on a case by case basis. 19
  • 22. Moreover, the microfinance bill excludes the larger, and more rapidly growing part of the sector One of the major omissions in the bill is that it excludes MFIs registered as NBFCs and S 25 companies, which account for nearly all the large MFIs, and the larger part of total microcredit in the country. Their number is steadily increasing, as more and NGO-MFIs transform themselves into companies for the reasons discussed above. The argument usually adduced for keeping NBFCs outside the purview of the bill is that they are already regulated by the RBI. However, the argument applies equally to district, state and urban cooperative banks which are governed by the Banking Regulation Act in respect of banking activities, while conforming to the cooperative law in other respects. Like them, NBFCs would be governed by the microfinance bill in respect of thrift activities, without any dilution of their capital, reserve, or liquidity requirements as NBFCs. There is The irony is that not only can NBFC-MFIs not accept public deposits, by virtue of being understandable excluded from the bill they will not be able to accept the savings of their own borrower- reluctance to allow MFIs to members either,30 who will continue to have to rely on less convenient, riskier lower yielding, mobilize public and often socially less productive savings instruments (such as ornaments). There is deposits, without putting understandable reluctance to allow MFIs to mobilize public deposits, without putting in place in place the the necessary safequards, for sound prudential reasons. But the vast majority of MFI members necessary are net borrowers of the MFI at any one time. They borrow to finance their larger investment safequards, for sound requirements, but simultaneously save small amounts regularly to finance their liquidity prudential requirements, provide for emergencies, build up a cushion to tide over the lean season when reasons. But the vast agricultural wage employment is scarce, and aggregate savings into amounts large enough to majority of MFI make useful investments, repair the hut, send a daughter to high school, or a son to the big members are city to look for work. Since they are net borrowers, prudential concerns are much less pressing. net borrowers of the MFI at any one time So are we missing an important opportunity with the microfinance bill? In excluding NBFCs and S 25 companies, the act will also deprive more than half of borrowers from the protection of the ombudsman envisaged under the bill, and the sector as a whole from the benefits of universal performance standards in respect of microfinance activities, and a much needed data base. The bill confers a modicum of legitimacy on the most vulnerable part of the sector, the NGO-MFIs, but is careful not to step on the toes of the states by failing to assert that the principle of cost-recovering interest rates takes precedence over caps on interest rates under state moneylender acts. The bill violates the spirit and intent of the new MACS acts in reducing the role of government in cooperation. It is true that the registrars under the new acts are not performing supervisory, data gathering and consumer protection functions any better than the old ones, but will the new regulator be able to do a better job for thousands of thrift cooperatives all over the country? In any case cooperation is a state subject, and the states will have to sign on, unless the courts take the narrow view that accepting thrift even from one's own member- borrowers constitutes "banking", which is a central subject. The bill does not provide the sector with a form of registration uniquely suited to microfinance. 20
  • 23. CHAPTER 1 Overview It leaves NGO-MFIs with no alternative between remaining NGOs and having to raise enough the envisaged Microfinance capital to become NBFCs. Societies and trusts were not designed as vehicles for financial Development operations, and although NGO-MFIs are non-profits, they have a hard time convincing the Council will be a government local income tax authorities that their surpluses are intended for expansion and leverage of dominated body borrowed funds. "Special-window" MFIs, with lower entry capital but higher capital adequacy with a purely requirements, as a unique legal form under the act, would have constituted a valuable advisory role. Given the fact intermediate stage of incorporation between remaining an NGO and becoming a full-fledged that the NBFC. microfinance sector, like the IT sector, has Finally, as Chapter 9 points out, the envisaged Microfinance Development Council will be a grown so rapidly government dominated body with a purely advisory role. Given the fact that the microfinance and in many sector, like the IT sector, has grown so rapidly and in many ways creatively, precisely because ways creatively, precisely it was outside the government, one would have thought that sector representation on the because it was council would be higher, and that it would be given much greater autonomy. For all these outside the reasons, discussed at greater length in Chapter 9, the bill, as it presently stands, may be government, one would have missing an important opportunity. thought that sector Why has commercial microfinance been excluded from representation on the council the bill? Three alternatives views of the role of would be higher, and that it microfinance would be given much greater autonomy The exclusion of MFIs has brought into sharper focus three different visions of the role of the sector. The first accords an important place to financial intermediation as a means of offering savings as an essential financial service to the poor, since MFIs under the group lending model meet their borrowers once a week anyway, and therefore enjoy economies of scope in being able to collect savings cheaply and conveniently along with loan repayment installments. Most savers at any one time remain net borrowers of the MFI, which fund the bulk of their on- lending requirement initially from donors and apex financial institutions with access to soft funds, and then from more commercial sources. As NGO-MFIs strengthen their capacity and profitability and transform into for-profit entities they apply for licenses to mobilize the savings also of non-members, or the public. This is essentially the path along which microfinance has developed in most countries where the Grameen bank group lending model is dominant, as it is Asia and in countries in many other regions. In India, however, MFIs have not been allowed to mobilize savings even from their borrower members. They have had to rely exclusively on borrowings to fund their growth, acting as retailers of whole sale funds borrowed from the banks and financial institutions. They have been valued primarily as retailers of "last mile" services in delivering credit to borrowers the banks are not in a position to reach directly. The microfinance bill seeks to allow NGO-MFIs to conduct limited financial intermediation but only in the form of thrift or small, weekly, compulsory savings. By excluding NBFC and S 25 companies from the purview of the bill it denies this limited savings opportunity to their members, as well as cheaper funds to the MFIs themselves, which might enable them to reduce their interest rates. However there is a third view of the role of MFIs purely as facilitators of credit and other financial service,s and providers of credit-plus services. The partnership model as noted above has always envisaged the MFI as playing the role of a social intermediary, identifying and monitoring 21
  • 24. borrowers and servicing collections for a fee. The major lender to the sector seems to be veering round to the view that new developments in technology have strengthened the suitability of the model to the extent that in the long run it may be able to dispense with the services of MFIs altogether, relying instead on a range of business facilitators and correspondents such as internet kiosks, post offices, merchant vendors (when the guidelines allow it) or even trustworthy local individuals, to provide essential local knowledge and information on borrowers, and enable it, on the basis of credit histories on such borrowers built up through their savings and other behaviour, to eventually lend to them directly (just as MFIs do, with graduates of group lending). This third view, which might be called the facilitator or agent view, is also the view that the RBI seems to be veering around to. It was first articulated in the RBI's business facilitator and business correspondent circular of January 2006.31 The Deputy Governor of the RBI responsible for regulatory issues enunciated it most recently at a Sa-Dhan meeting when she envisaged financial inclusion depending not just on technology but also on the "credit plus services that community based organizations are able to provide because of enjoying the trust of local persons, having knowledge of the local community and being able to facilitate financial This third view, which might be literacy, credit counseling, and garner credit information…" (Thorat 2007). This view of the role of MFIs was expressed even more explicitly in a recent speech in which she said "… the called the facilitator or real value of NGOs and MFIs lies in their role as providing "credit plus" services and not just agent view, is also the viewfunctioning as an intermediary for onlending. Banks with their resources and scale have that the RBI greater cost advantages, but linking with local community based organizations and local seems to be veering around persons/entities would help them get over the information gap and access barriers" (Thorat to 2007). Efforts at extending financial inclusions by the banks in India have focused so far largely on savings products. The greatest progress had been made in opening "no-frills" zero-balance savings accounts which numbered 6 lakhs by March 2007. In mobilizing savings, banks have an advantage over MFIs in that the savings are insured. In her Sa-Dhan speech the Deputy Governor referred to another advantage bank savings have over MFI savings, that of "being able to obtain access to the national payments systems through bank accounts - or in countries where the regulatory system allows, through electronic accounts with such service providers facilitated by mobile phones. In South Africa and Brazil, for example, efforts at financial inclusion are targeted at enabling easier and low cost access to payments systems for money transfers, utility payments, and other daily transactions" (Thorat 2007). The financial inclusion movements seeks to remove the disadvantages the banks have traditionally suffered from in respect of access, and the liquidity of their savings for the poor.32 However until it succeeds in doing so, it is the regulatory prohibition that restricts MFIs in India to contributing to financial inclusion through the remaining three financial services - credit, insurance and money transfers. Credit, with the contraction of the partnership model, has reverted for the time being to being provided by MFIs almost entirely as intermediaries retailing funds wholesaled by the banks. Insurance services however are being provided mostly in an agency role (Chapter 7). The provision of remittance services has been rudimentary so far, but for regulatory reasons will also have to be provided in the agency role.33 An example of a pilot project being implemented by BASIX in partnership with Axisbank and the technology provider, A Little World, that provides a remittance service using mobile phones, is described in Box 8.3. 22
  • 25. CHAPTER 1 Overview MFIs have not succeeded (or shown much interest for that matter) in providing credit under the BC scheme because of the interest rate cap on small loans which has rendered the BC scheme dysfunctional as far as credit is concerned (Chapter 9)34 Even if there were no cap however, and even after the full development of the ICT applications discussed above, there is no presumption that the BC role is more suited to MFI credit than the financial intermediary or last-mile retailer role.35 MFIs will always have a comparative advantage over banks in being able to originate, monitor and collect micro loans. This advantage also derives form technology, but from a technology of a softer kind, the technology of group lending pioneered by the Grameen Bank. While group lending does have well known disadvantages, and while alternative channels to reach the borrower will and should develop, it is difficult to see how MFIs, with their field presence, will lose their comparative advantage in identifying creditworthy borrowers, providing them with hand-holding support, and dealing with delinquencies. This advantage can be put to use in any of the three roles, but MFIs have shown a distinct preference so far for the first two. This may be for non-financial reasons as much as financial.36 It is perhaps no MFIs will always coincidence that even in Brazil the services that are being provided by agents (including have a merchant outlets such as shops, who are not eligible under India's BC scheme) are mostly comparative advantage over remittances, bill payments, and savings services, but not credit. The stance the RBI appears banks in being to be developing on the other hand is that in the long run MFIs should function as banking able to originate, correspondents and agents for all services, including credit, although last mile retailing will monitor and continue to be allowed. It is this vision of the long run role of MFIs that appears to explain collect micro the exclusion of NBFCs MFIs from the microfinance bill, even more than concerns about dual loans regulation of microfinance NBFCs. Early experience with the new urban microfinance A major development during the last couple of years has been the upsurge of interest in urban microfinance (Chapter 5). The urban areas have remained virtually uncharted territory, except by a few prominent exceptions such as SEWA Bank, despite the prospects of (i) huge loan demand, (ii) larger average loan size and higher population density making for lower costs, (iii) the need to reach the growing numbers of the urban poor, and (iv) the example of Latin America where microfinance is predominantly urban. The rate of urbanization in India has increased sharply in the 1990s to almost twice the rural population growth rate, the difference being driven by migration from the rural areas.37 Moreover, while urban poverty is declining in relative terms, it is increasing in absolute terms.38 India's metros and large towns have some of the most congested slums in the world and are "home" to some of the worst living conditions anywhere.39 One of the main reasons why MFIs were reluctant to initiate operations in the urban areas was their apprehension that the Grameen-style group lending model, which was proving so successful in the rural areas, was too dependent on peer-pressure and mutual trust, based on long- standing neighbourhood and kinship ties, to be successful in the urban slums. Also the one- size-fits-all standardization (of loan size and duration) and the borrower- time requirements (attendance at weekly meetings) of the group-lending model might prove a handicap in the much more heterogenous and time-constrained environment of urban slum-dwellers. However mobility and transience have proved to be much less of a problem than was originally feared, and the new urban MFIs are finding that many slum dwellers have been living in the same location for a generation or more, and that even if they go home to their villages for a couple of months a year they come back to the same area because of proximity to a known livelihood. 23
  • 26. More of a problem it turns out is that as many as a third of borrowers have no formal documentation to establish either identity or address. More of a problem, also, than mobility per se, is what might be called "involuntary mobility", caused by the ongoing drive in many cities to demolish slums and relocate them elsewhere, and by the widening of roads, etc. Also, even in slums where a significant proportion of residents are transient, MFIs have to achieve a very high level of penetration before running out of prospective borrower from among permanent residents. The trick, they are learning, is a high success rate in spotting them. As with many other generalizations, the obstacle posed by mobility and transience depends on which income segment and location one is looking at. Many of the new urban MFIs intend to cater primarily to the vast majority of permanent urban residents who are still unserved by the banks, and depend largely on the informal sector for their financial needs. Reaching the transient poor is not a primary goal, at least initially. For example, while MFIs in Kolkata would like to serve the huge population of mostly day visitors who flood into the middle-class areas of South Kolkata from the rural hinterland as day labourers and maids etc, or rickshaw drivers who park by the wayside to sleep in their rickshaws at night, they are unlikely to be able to do so unless they extend their operations to the peripheral rural areas, as many of them are in fact doing. It is well It is well accepted that microfinance is best suited to reaching the economically active poor. It is accepted that ill-suited to solving the problem of chronic income deficits. However it is also the case that there microfinance is best suited to are many potential borrowers whose income deficits could be removed by credit if they were reaching the combined with other inputs.40 The challenge is to identify such persons, and arrange for the economically active poor. It provision of the other inputs by some other agency if necessary. While urban MFIs are cognizant of is ill-suited to the need to offer a full set of financial services including savings, insurance and remittances, they solving the intend to meet non-financial needs such as health and vocational training through partnerships problem of chronic income with NGOs, other civil society organizations, and socially minded corporations. deficits. However it is Some of the recent start-ups in the metros are promoted by professionals who have a proven also the case that there are track record of successful careers in banking and other fields. Their backgrounds have been many potential very successful in attracting lenders and investors. The new urban start-ups are growing borrowers whose particularly strongly in Bangalore and Kolkata, but are still nascent in Mumbai and Delhi. In income deficits could be locations such as Hyderabad and other towns across the country existing rural MFIs are removed by moving into contiguous urban and peri-urban areas. They are being joined by several NBFCs credit if they who have already been operating in the urban areas but are now experimenting with were combined with other "downscaling" to smaller loans. Banks in India have in effect been excluded from the small inputs loans market by regulatory fiat. They are not allowed to make loans of less than Rs 200,000 at a rate any higher than their PLR (their lending rate to prime customers) for the loans to qualify as priority sector loans. Despite this cap, Yes Bank is pioneering individual loans in urban microfinance. The Microsate branch of Indian Bank is successfully doing SHG-bank linkage in Chennai (Chapter 5). While the MFI human resources challenge - not just training, but attracting and retaining staff - has been engaging the attention of the MFI community generally in the last few years (Chapter 6 of last year's report), its severity in the urban areas has taken the new urban MFIs by surprise. Nearly all of them are finding it difficult to recruit and retain staff in conditions of a tightening job market, especially in cities like Bangalore where attrition rates are as high as 20 to 30 percent a year. The skills field workers acquire are turning out to be in high demand in other parts of the financial sector, and in marketing. 24
  • 27. CHAPTER 1 Overview The sector's infrastructure of support services is gradually strengthening Given its rate of growth, the human resource challenge remains the most important facing the sector. It has not been possible to include a chapter this year on developments in training and capacity building, but apart from the activities of the older, more established service providers, the year saw several new initiatives, such as Intellecap's Microfinance Franchise Package which seeks to incubate start-ups by providing training, manuals, and a complete business plan and financial model combined with operational exposure in group formation, lending processes, and branch and head office management at CASHPOR in Varanasi.41 With a view to channeling start-up and capacity building support to MFIs in underserved regions, MicroSave relocated itself in the North, with a view to creating a centre of excellence in microfinance at the IIM-Lucknow with links to SIDBI. In line with its plans to create a cadre of 50-60 "low cost-high capacity" consultants spread out across India, it continued to impart training in specialized areas such as loan portfolio audits, process mapping and new product development. Work on running training workshops, and developing action research partnerships and toolkits continued. The amount of timely information and analysis on the sector on the sector is increasing through publications such as Intellecap's quarterly Microfinance Insights which devotes each issue to a special topic, and online publications such as the monthly Microfinance Focus. Sa-Dhan achieved a major breakthrough by publishing “Quick Report 2007: A Snapshot of Microfinance Institutions in India”, within just over four months of the closing of the financial year. The report carries core data on the bulk of its membership. Although it based on self- reported data prepared without waiting for audited annual reports, the report greatly enhances the cause of transparency and timely public reporting. A few, but not enough, extremely educative MFI annual reports are also being prepared which A few, but not enough, convey more than just the numbers but deal with the nitty-girtty issues facing the sector.42 extremely The MIX continues to contribute to the cause of transparency by expanding its reporting on educative MFI the performance indicators of the larger Indian MFIs in collaboration with M-CRIL. One of the annual reports are also being most useful developments in the last year has been UNDP's email-based Solutions Exchange prepared which service which carries an active, high quality and widely-used exchange of views and information convey more on Indian microfinance. There is still a need however for greater timeliness and coverage in than just the numbers but the reports of some of the financial institutions, and for a timely annual statistical compendium, deal with the which perhaps the new regulator will bring out. There continues to be a dearth of good case nitty-girtty studies, and the research effort remains insufficient to the needs of the sector. Here too the issues facing the sector new regulator will hopefully make a difference. Finally, although it is not part of the infrastructure of support services, a new product introduced recently by MFIs deserves special mention, and that is participation in UTI's Retirement Benefit Pension Fund which accepts monthly contributions of as low as Rs 50 a month for individual retirement accounts. The fund is approved to invest up to 40 percent of collections in the Indian stock market. SEWA and SHEPHERD (in Trichy, Tamil Nadu) are the first two MFIs to have distributed participation to their members. Subscribers are not required to pay any initiation fees, and are sent monthly statements. Monthly pension payments start at the age of 58, and are paid into bank accounts. In the event of the death of a member accumulated contributions with interest are paid to a nominee. 25
  • 28. Box 1.2 The challenges of raising capital: Inside the entrepreneur's mind MICROFINANCE INSIGHTS: As the Share deal showed, microfinance is becoming more and more accepted by mainstream investors. Do you have any personal concerns about the pressure for financial performance and its possible impact on the social mission of MFIs? UDAIA KUMAR: Actually there is no conflict between both of them... what we are trying to do at Share is focus on the poorest of the poor, trying to help them come out of poverty. In the process, we run a viable program where we cover all costs, make reasonable profits, service all investors, and also pay the right price to banks we borrow money from. Everybody is in a win-win situation. If we are able to use this model, then we will be able to channel bigger money into the sector and we'll also be able to increase our scale. We will be able to get into the capital markets, offer IPOs and so on. I don't think anybody would have given us those 26 million dollars as a grant… VIKRAM AKULA: …I do not feel that the two interests are separate. In our case, we strive to be profitable and increase our investments because it enables us to reach out to more poor; we plough our profits into expansion efforts throughout India. Also, the majority share of SKS is held by members; thus, the interests of our investors and of our clients are aligned. As a response to the concerns that microfinance is not reaching the poorest of the poor, SKS has developed a pilot ultra poor program to target the needs of destitute populations, those too poor to qualify for traditional microfinance. VIJAY MAHAJAN: Yes, I am concerned about the impact of extreme profit seeking investors on the mission of MFIs. Such investors might say that reaching the poor is not their problem and that they are just investing in a company which is doing microcredit as a commercial service. To such investors I would say, please stay out of this field. The sector has not been built by commercial investors; it has been built by the sweat equity of development workers, by funding from public and philanthropic institutions and accumulation of capital of the poor themselves. Globally perhaps some 3 or 4 billion dollars have been spent to bring the field to where it has reached now. For extreme profit-seeking investors to now cherry pick that part of this field which gives a high return, without any care as to what it does to the poor, is not acceptable. If they still insist on coming in, as they are free to do, they will soon find a rise of popular revulsion against MFIs and political actions to curb interest rates, etc, which will not only kill the extreme profits, but also shut down other MFIs who are trying to be sustainable. Net result, the poor will be back to the clutches of moneylenders and government doles. MICROFINANCE INSIGHTS: If a decision to move towards commercial funding is taken, what are the key obstacles that MFIs face? How have these changed in recent years? UDAIA KUMAR: In our case, there are two parts to the fundraising effort: one is equity, the other is debt funds. The debt funds were quite difficult because of the limited capital and surplus we had...I never thought that we would require such huge investment because of the changes that took place in the banking sector: funding microfinance institutions, stopping partnership arrangements and so on. VIJAY MAHAJAN: The key obstacle that an MFI faces in raising commercial equity is what it does to the poor… For example, let us take the recent case of Compartamos …Its founders have personally become multimillionaires … Presumably, this will attract more capital, but on what terms to the ultimate users? Is this what we set up this sector for?...If this is microfinance, 26
  • 29. CHAPTER 1 Overview then I repudiate the field: I don't want to be part of this. In BASIX we don't want to deal with any investor who thinks this is what they are for in microfinance. Instead, we'll raise money from the community, as we did in our sister company Sarvodaya Nano Finance and from development finance institutions and from philanthropic foundations. MICROFINANCE INSIGHTS: What effect do you think the upcoming microfinance bill will have on the sector? Is there an actual need for stronger regulation? UDAIA KUMAR…The new bill will bring visibility and legitimacy to the sector and … support from the government as well as from the state governments…. VIJAY MAHAJAN: The upcoming bill is a mixed blessing. It is positive in as much as microfinance is being recognized for the first time, but on the down side, it does not extend its scope to NBFC MFIs, which are the main players in the sector…The problem is that if we leave it to complete self regulation, opportunism will take off. In Andhra Pradesh last year this led the government to shut down branches of two MFIs because these institutions were seen to be making excessive profits, charging high rates of interest. Those interest rates were right when they started because they were not breaking even. But when the institutions grew to scale, they did nothing to bring those interest rates down, they just kept raking in those profits until it became an issue. And so they got the treatment that they deserved. The question is: at what stage, do you really expect the regulator to be looking at your quarterly result, and thinking now you are making too much profit? There is a simple way to do it. Look at the Return on Assets. World over, we know that a healthy commercial bank makes ROA of 1.5% to 2.5%, at best. So why do we want a microfinance institution to make 20% ROA? I think we need a sectoral cap. I think something like 4% ROA after tax is the upper limit to ensure that we are providing enough incentive to investors. Even with a 1:5 leveraging, this would mean an ROE of 20%. Extracts from of an interview by Microfinance Insights with three leading Indian microfinance entrepreneurs: Udaia Kumar of Share Microfin, Vikram Akula of SKS and Vijay Mahajan of BASIX (Microfinance Insights, Volume 3, June 2007) 27
  • 30. Endnotes 1 Thirty percent is the estimate of the proportion of poor borrowers in MFIs in the second or endline survey in the seven year longitudinal study of SIDBI-partnered MFIs undertaken by EDA (baseline) and the Agricultural Finance Corporation, (endline, conducted in 2006, but not yet released) as well as the finding from the social performance assessment of 12 MFIs conducted by M-CRIL reported in Chapter 6. The proportion of poor SHG members was found in EDA and APMAS 2006 to be 51 percent. 2 For the assumptions see Table A.1. 3 Chapter 4 estimates that because of rapid expansion of outreach by MFIs, average loans outstanding of sample MFIs is only Rs 3400. The average size of the first loan received by SHGs members has gone up this year to Rs 3167 (Table 2.1, assuming 14 members per SHG). However, because the average size of repeat loans is even higher (Rs 5650, Table 2.1) and because the average tenor of SHG loans is generally two years, average loans outstanding may be about the same in the two models. Using the ratio reported in Chapter 2 of loans outstanding being 59% of cumulative bank loans disbursed, one derives a rough estimate of SHG loans outstanding per member of about Rs 4000 (Table A.1) 4 See however Chapter 4, which estimates that PARs have increased since the last M-CRIL Review, especially sharply for large MFIs, partly because of the deterioration of the credit culture that occurred after the AP crisis. Loan portfolio audits that have been conducted by MicroSave and others often reveal a less rosy picture than the financial statements claim. 5 Thirty percent is the estimate of the proportion of poor borrowers in MFIs in the second or endline survey in the seven year longitudinal study of SIDBI-partnered MFIs undertaken by EDA (baseline) and the Agricultural Finance Corporation, (endline, conducted in 2006, but not yet released) as well as the finding from the social performance assessment of 12 MFIs reported in Chapter 6. 6 The average interest rate of the 129 MFIs in the Sa-Dhan Quick Report was 21.I percent and came down for large MFIs in the sample to 19.7 percent from 20.8 percent last year. Not surprisingly it was the small MFIs that had the higher rates (22 percent) than the large and medium sized MFIs (both 19.7 percent). Chapter 4 reports higher rates of up to 25 percent, probably because it includes fees etc to the nominal rates to work out the effective interest rate. Although on average, the interest rates of Indian MFIs are slightly higher than that for other South Asian countries, the South Asian region has the lowest average rates of all regions in the world according to MIX data. 7 Thus CASHPOR restricts its lending to BPL families and identifies likely BPL families as those scoring less than 3 points i.e. those living in small houses with mud walls of less than 8 feet in height. These candidates then have to satisfy three further criteria (not less than half of household income from seasonal agricultural labour, no irrigated land, and no large farm animals or any other significant productive assets) 8 Bandhan and SKS are two MFIs that have special programmes for the poorest of the poor. Bandhan's Targeting the Hard Core project, based on the experience of BRAC in Bangladesh, focuses on skill training, asset creation through grants, hand-holding for 1.5 to 2 years to ensure productive utilization 28
  • 31. CHAPTER 1 Overview of the assets, and regular savings, before participants join the mainstream credit programme. SKS runs a similar programme for the "ultra-poor" through an associated NGO. 9 Chapter 7A, last year's report. 10 The issues involved are discussed in Chapter 4 of last year's report. 11 Although KYC norms were motivated internationally mostly by anti-money laundering and anti-terrorism concerns, the KYC guidelines issued by RBI make it clear that they are also designed to serve a risk management and transparency enhancing role. The RBI in November 2006 advised the banks that "they, as principal financiers of MFIs, needed to engage MFIs with regard to their systems, practices and lending policies with a view to ensuring better transparency and adherence to best practices (Usha Thorat 2007) 12 Some of them are reported to have suffered declines in their repayment rates, as borrowers were not assured of getting fresh loans on time, and consequents shrinkages in their portfolios. Despite this however, the sector as a whole has shown surprising resilience, with few reported cases of partners going under. 13 The AP government has distributed smart cards in Warangal district to receive NREGA and pension payments. 14 ICICI Bank is a partner in FINO. 15 Uptake has been slow for several reasons. One of them is the perception that FINO is expensive. Its charges are levied on a per transactions basis with no discount for higher usage, and larger MFIs are concerned that above a certain level of transactions, it would be cheaper for them to go it alone through their own stand-alone systems. Joining FINO or some other core banking solution would seem to be much more attractive for start-ups and small MFIs, and for MFIs functioning as business correspondents where the front-end and back-end are equally important (Chapter 8). Also, some partners are reported to be experiencing problems in customizing FINOs software to their unique requirements, especially as it was developed originally for banking operations. 16 It is also becoming more interested in supporting the livelihoods of its customers by tailoring loan products to the specific size, cash flow and other requirements of different activities and supporting enterprises that will buy their products. 17 SIDBI is expecting to double its portfolio to about Rs 1000 crores from Rs 548 crores in March 2007 (see Table A.3) New players such as Fullerton, a newly set up finance company could also add to loan supply in a few years. Fullerton has ambitious plans to set up rural branches all over the country and and get into both direct, and indirect microfinance through intermediaries. 18 Table A.3 contains data on the growth of lending by selected commercial banks, financial institutions, and other bulk lenders to MFIs in 2006-07. Several large loans have been made by banks other than ICICI in the current year, but these include relatively large loans to the newly capital rich MFIs which have received equity investments. One of them is a portfolio buyout of Rs 180 crores by Citibank (see below). Table A.3 is incomplete and contains fewer banks than Table 7.1 in last year's report, because banks are under no obligation to furnish information on their MFI lending, and several of them were unable or unwilling to do so. 29
  • 32. 19 While arrangements such as this are often referred to as securitizations, they are more correctly regarded as portfolio buyouts, with the purchaser of the loans having the option of securitizing them by pooling them with other assets, getting them rated, and selling them in the capital markets. See Chapter 7B of last year's report. 20 Legatum's financial advisor on the transactions was Intellecap, a microfinance consulting firm and social investment adviser, which is closely associated with Aavishkaar Goodwell. 21 The private shareholders received $150 million for an investment of $6 million, or a return of over 100 percent a year compounded over an eight year period. They received more than 12 times the book value of their shares, resulting in a valuation of Banco Compartamos of over $1.5 billion (CGAP 2007). 22 It first became a regulated finance company and then in 2006 a full-service bank) 23 See Chapter 7B of last year's report, and Table A.4. 24 The new investors in SKS seek, according to Satterthwaite 2007, to "cash out within 3-5 years", which if true is more aggressive than the stated time horizons of the India-dedicated funds. Dubai-based Legatum Capital has investments of over $1 billion in India's financial sector. Its President, Mark Stoleson is reported as saying "Legatum is a global investor that seems extraordinary opportunities without regard to sector or geography". However, the press note dated May 15, 2007 quotes him as also saying that "… we will seek to support SHARE in setting new standards for best practice and governance…" 25 Another reason to expect mergers is competition from the large MFIs expanding to other states. The borrowers and staff of the smaller existing MFIs may not be able to resist the attraction of switching to a larger, more rapidly expanding MFI. The only reported merger so far is that between Sonata (referred to in Chapter 5 as a new start-up partly urban MFI and a smaller MFI, also in UP, but this was reportedly at the behest of a social venture capital company). 26 It is possible also that some existing large MFIs may themselves be acquired by the large corporate houses that have recently made a foray into agri marketing as a means of financing their producers and suppliers. Yet another possible impact of fresh capital and borrowings may be to accelerate the trend towards increasing the share of the more profitable larger loans in the portfolios of the larger MFIs, and could lead even to their gradually exiting the sector as they move up-market, making room for the others. 27 Average return of assets in the M-CRIL sample has been reduced to zero. This is not to say some individual MFIs do not offer highly profitable prospects. SKS earned an ROA of 3.3 in 2006 and ROE of 23.9 28 The licenses of thousands of such non-functioning NBFCs are said to be for a sale, at a premium over their net worth given demand by transforming NGO-MFIs, but they still cost much less than raising Rs 2 crores to seek a new NBFC. The entry capital requirement was earlier Rs 25 lakhs. Besides, not all MFI applicants have succeeded in getting new NBFC licenses, of which only about 5 have been issued since around 2000. 29 Such as itinerant deposit collectors, small community chit funds, informal credit unions (such as the bishis of Maharashta), investments in livestock or ornaments (which can later be liquefied through the 30
  • 33. CHAPTER 1 Overview pawnbroker and moneylender), or through "reciprocal finance", that is, lending to a friend in need so that the lender can borrow reciprocally when required. The phenomenal growth of the SHG movement, in which rural women meet with unfailing regularity once a month to save small sums ranging from Rs 10 to 50, and the fact that poor urban slum dwellers, far from earning interest on their savings, are willing to pay to have their deposits collected at the doorstep and stored safely until they amount to a useful sum, and countless other examples, attest to the importance of the almost universal need to save. 30 Quite apart from benefits to members, the cost of funds MFIs will come down. Because Indian MFIs have had to rely exclusively on funds borrowed from the banks, their financial expense ratios (cost of funds as a proportion of total costs) are the highest in the world (see Chapter 4 of last year's report). In Bangladesh, on the other hand, interest rates are slightly lower than in India, because as much as a third of the funds base comes from member savings. Many Bangladeshi MFIs also pay a slightly higher rate to savers than the banks, because of the cost efficiencies that ensue from economies of scope in being able to use existing field staff, who have to meet borrowers once a week anyway to collect loan repayment installments and disburse fresh loans. Grameen Bank mobilizes in fact more savings than it disburses as credit (as does Bank Rakyat Indonesia, further examples of how savings are as valued by poor clients as credit). 31 For details and a discussion see Chapter 7A of last year's report. 32 Especially with the use of smart cards, as in the pilots referred to above, where the BC's field agent travels to the doorstep to collects savings and dispense withdrawals. The frequency of withdrawals, minimum accounts that can be deposited etc are still being worked out. 33 MFIs can not accept cash for remittances since these are treated as savings. In the UK, in order to encourage ease of entry and competition among money transfer operators so as to lower the costs of remittances, regulators allow an MTO to hold money for up to 3 days before it is treated as savings. Adhikar (see Chapter 5B of last year's report) is talking to banks to continue its operations as a BC. 34 There are no similar caps on the maximum rate that can be paid on savings or remittance services. 35 The one argument that can be made against the latter is that it represents an inefficient use of equity. 36 Perhaps MFIs value the autonomy and psychic satisfactions of being autonomous (the equivalent of "being one's own boss" in preferring self-employment to salaried employment) and do not want to be anyone's agent 37 The share of the urban population, although still lower than the global and Asian average, had grown to 31 percent by 2001. 38 In the three decades since 1970 the number of poor went up from 52 to 67 million. Rural poverty is declining both in relative and absolute terms. However the number of rural poor is still three times higher than that of the urban poor. 39 Thus the extent of "human poverty" and deprivation is much worse than the "income" poverty measured and reported in the statistics. In cities like Delhi the income poverty ratio is as low as low as 8.23 percent in 1999 40 It is important to be able to assess whether the deficit is merely temporary, or likely to remain 31
  • 34. permanent in the absence of the provision of other inputs. Defining the target group too conservatively finesses this challenges. 41 The package includes periodic visits and handholding for 9 months and assistance with the installation of a computerized MIS. Equity can be provided by sister company Aavishkaar Goodwell and loans by ICICI Bank which is expected to play the role of lead banker to the institutions.. Three start ups have signed on so far. Apart from an upfront fee, partners are charged a part of the margin between their borrowing and lending rates. 42 An example is CASHPOR's, from which Box 1.1 is excerpted, and which discusses the problem of the increasing frequency and size of frauds and steps being taken to combat it. Sa-Dhan should institute an annual award for the each of the three most informative annual reports and websites. 32
  • 35. CHAPTER 1 Overview References CGAP, 2007, "CGAP Reflections on the Compartamos Initial Public Offering: A Case Study on Microfinance Interest Rates and Profits, Focus Note No. 42, Washington DC EDA Rural Systems and APMAS, 2006, "Self Help Groups in India: A Study of the Lights and Shades" for CRS, USAID, CARE and GTZ/NABARD, Microfinance India, New Delhi Sa-Dhan, 2007, "Quick Report 2007: A Snapshot of Microfinance Institutions in India", New Delhi Satterthwaite, David, 2007, "MicroCapital Equity Report: 2007 Starts Strong" in Microfinance Insights, Vol. 3, June 2007, Intellecap, Mumbai Thorat, Usha, 2006, "Financial Inclusion for Sustainable Development : Role of IT and Intermediaries" speech, as circulated at the Annual Bankers' Conference 2006, November 4, Hyderabad. Thorat, Usha, 2007, "Microfinance and financial inclusion", speech at Sa-Dhan function to release "Quick Report, 2007", Chennai, August 10 World Bank, 2007, "Microfinance in South Asia: Toward Financial Inclusion for the Poor", Washington DC 33
  • 36. 34
  • 37. CHAPTER 2 Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme CHAPTER 2 Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme Growth continues to be rapid… A further 686,408 SHGs were linked during the year, bringing the cumulative number of SHGs that had ever been linked (provided with bank loans) to 2.92 million by March 2007 (Table 2.1). Assuming average group size of 14 members1 this translates into coverage during the year of another 9.6 million persons, over 90 percent of them women, and the total number of SHG members who have ever benefited from the programme to about 41 million. Since some households have more than one member in the programme, the number of families benefited is slightly smaller than these numbers imply.2 About half of them are below the poverty line. In addition to first loans to new SHGs, 457,410 SHGs received repeat loans. The number of new SHGs linked this year represents an increase of about 11 percent over those linked Reporting under the programme last year. This represents only a slight deceleration of the rate of growth of loans to new SHGs from 15 has until now percent last year. The increase in the number of repeat loans however, was exactly the same, at 33 been carried percent. Lending under the programme grew by Rs 6643 crores, or an increase of 48 percent over last out entirely in terms of year's new lending, which had grown by 50 percent over the previous year. The average size of first loans disbursements, made to new SHGs went up by 18 percent to about Rs 44,300 per group, or to an average of about Rs both annual and 3200 per member. The average size of repeat loans, on the other hand, grew by 25 percent to almost Rs cumulative, rather than 79,000 per group, or Rs 5650 per member.3 loans outstanding at We now have an estimate of the total size of the programme the end of year Reporting under the programme has until now been carried out entirely in terms of disbursements, both annual and cumulative, rather than loans outstanding at the end of year. The latter is a stock measure of size, as compared to a flow, and provides a better basis for comparison with the size of lending under the MFI model, or with bank lending to other categories of borrowers such as marginal farmers, since it standardizes for loan tenor.4 In an important study based on a survey of participating banks under the programme conducted by GTZ/NABARD in 2005 (Ramakrishna 2006), loans outstanding under the programme as of March 2005 were established for the first time as amounting to 59 percent of cumulative lending till that date. Moreover, of the SHGs that had been linked till that date, 71 percent had loans outstanding.5 These ratios had been the subject of conjecture until now. NABARD had been unable to report exposure (loans outstanding) figures under the programme because of the inability of the participating banks to furnish them in a timely fashion. 35
  • 38. Table 2.1 Growth trends in the SBLP 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 1 No. of new SHGs provided 263,825 461,478 717,360 1,079,091 1,618,456 2,238,565 2,924,973 with bank loans (cumulative) 1a Of which in Southern region 938,941 1,214,431 1,522,144 (cumulative) 1b Percent in Southern region 58 54 52 (percent) 2 No. of new SHGs financed 149,650 197,653 255,882 361,731 539,365 620,109 686,408 during the year 2a Of which in Southern region 275,490 307,713 2b Percent in Southern region 44 45 2c Rate of growth of loans to 32 29 41 49 15 11 new SHGs (percent) 3 No. of SHGs receiving repeat 21,630 41,413 102,391 171,669 258,092 344,502 457,410 loans 3a Rate of growth of repeat 91 147 68 50 33 33 loans 3b Proportion of repeat loans in 17 29 40 32 36 40 total loans 4 Bank loan disbursed 481 1,026 2,049 3,904 6,896 11,398 18,040 cumulative (Rs. crore) 4a Bank loan disbursed during NA 545 1,023 1,855 2,994 4,499 6,643 year (Rs crore) 4b Of which, disbursed to new 290 453 691 1,158 1,727 2,330 3,044 groups (Rs crore) 4c Of which, disbursed as repeat NA 92 332 698 1,268 2,169 3,599 loans (Rs crore) 4d Proportion of repeat loans in 17 33 38 42 48 54 total disbursed (percent) 5a Average loan sizes - New 19,379 22,919 27,005 32,013 32,019 37,574 44,343 5b Repeat 22,215 32,425 40,660 49,130 62,960 78,682 Source: NABARD annual reports and Table 2.3 The RBI has Fortunately, the RBI has now made it mandatory for all banks to report exposure and NPA now made it figures to it every six months, and the NABARD annual report on the programme should be in mandatory for all banks to a position to report at least the former for the year ending March 2008. Until then, these report exposure estimates are a great step forward in strengthening the statistical base of the programme (and and NPA figures to it every six are used in the Fact Sheet). months, and the NABARD …and of its savings outreach annual report on the programme The GTZ study also carried important new information of savings under the programme, which should be in a were reported by the survey participants as amounting to Rs 2391 crores as of March 2005. position to RRBs and cooperative banks have a higher share of total savings accounts and savings report at least the former for outstanding than of total loan accounts and loans outstanding. One would like to think this the year ending is because of greater ease of access to these institutions than to the commercial banks, but it March 2008 turns out that as with loans (discussed below, under Operations), savings performance is highly concentrated in a few institutions around the country, especially in the case of RRBs.6 36
  • 39. CHAPTER 2 Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme Since loans outstanding were Rs 4205 crores, the credit-deposit ratio was 1.76. In other words a little more than half of linkage loans are financed by the SHGs themselves. However, since 29 percent of SHGs are not currently linked, and the total savings figure includes their savings, the ratio would be higher for those SHGs that are linked. Rectifying regional skew The SBLP expanded by 37 percent in 13 priority states which account for 67 percent of the The two regions which have the rural poor (Table 2.2). These states were identified by NABARD in 2005 for special efforts and most catching location-specific strategies. Growth was particularly rapid in Maharashtra (Table 2.3) As a up to do are result, the western region experienced the fastest growth (63 percent) of all the regions, and the central and eastern its share in the total number of groups linked is now only 5 percentage points behind its regions, whose share of the total number of poor (Table 2.4). The two regions which have the most catching share of groups lag behind their up to do are the central and eastern regions, whose share of groups lag behind their share of share of the the poor by 21 and 11 percentage points respectively. Growth in the East was 33 percent, poor by 21 and about the same as overall national growth of 31 percent, and well below the previous year's 11 percentage points growth of 48 percent. Growth in the central region was only 24 percent. Table 2.2 Growth of linked SHG's in 13 Priority States State 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Percent growth Assam 3,477 10,706 31,234 56,449 81454 44 Bihar 8,161 16,246 28,015 46,221 72339 57 Chhatisgarh 6,763 9,796 18,569 31,291 41703 33 Gujarat 13,875 15,974 24,712 34,160 43572 28 Himachal Pradesh 8,875 13,228 17,798 22,920 27799 21 Jharkhand 7,765 12,647 21,531 30,819 37317 21 Maharashtra 28,065 38,535 71,146 131,470 225856 72 Madhya Pradesh 15,271 27,095 45,105 57,125 70912 24 Orissa 42,272 77,588 123,256 180,896 234451 30 Rajasthan 22,742 33,846 60,006 98,171 137837 40 Uttar Pradesh 53,696 79,210 119,648 161,911 198587 23 Uttaranchal 5,853 10,908 14,043 17,588 21527 22 West Bengal 32,647 51,685 92,698 136,251 181563 33 Total 249,462 397,464 667,761 1,005,272 1374917 37 Percent increase 59 68 51 37 Source: NABARD annual reports and Table 2.3 37
  • 40. Table 2.4 Growth of linked SHG's in the regions Region Mar-04 Mar-05 Mar-06 Percent Mar-07 Percent Share of Share of 2006 2007 population BPL population Northern 52,396 86018 133097 6 182018 6 13% 7% North 12278 34238 62517 3 91754 3 4% 3% Eastern Region Eastern 158237 265628 394351 18 525881 18 22% 29% Region Central 127009 197365 267915 12 332729 11 25% 32% Region Western 54815 96266 166254 7 270447 9 15% 14% Region Southern 674356 939941 1214431 54 1522144 52 21% 15% Region All India 1079091 1618456 2238565 100 2924973 100.00 100% 100% Source: Poverty Estimates for 2004-05, Press Information Bureau, Government of India, New Delhi, March, 2007 Despite relatively rapid growth in the priority states, the programme continues to remains heavily skewed in favour of the South. While the share of the South in linked groups came down marginally during the year (Table 2.1) lending in the South still accounted for 75 percent of total lending during the year, and an even higher share of repeat lending (88 percent), indicating both higher average initial loan size, and even higher average repeat loan size on account of the seniority of groups in the southern Region. In Andhra Pradesh, the number of new loans remained about the same but the number of repeat loans increased by 31 percent year. Given relatively high loan size in the state APs share of total and repeat lending during the year constituted as much as 42 and 65 percent respectively of that for the country as a whole. Operations Table 2.5 Agency-wise share of SHGs financed During 2005-06 During 2006-07 Agency SHGs Loans SHGs Loans No. % Amount % No. % Amount % CBs 344567 56 28284 63 406707 59 44101 66 RRBs 176178 28 12226 27 170783 25 17089 26 Co-operatives 99364 16 4481 10 108878 16 5242 8 Total 620,109 100 44,991 100 686368 100 66432 100 Source: NABARD annual reports Table 2.5 shows the respective share of commercial banks, RRBs and cooperatives in financing SHGs. The share of commercial banks has gone up in 2006-07, both in respect of number of loans and amounts disbursed, at the expense mostly of the of RRBs in respect of share of number of loans and of the cooperatives in respect of share of loans disbursed. In 2005-06,7 twenty-seven public sector banks accounted for 93 percent of commercial bank financing and 38
  • 41. CHAPTER 2 Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme 20 private banks for 7 percent. Among public sector banks, the SBI linked by far the highest number of SHGs during the year (142,034)8 followed by Indian Bank (30,632) and Canara Bank (18,445). We know from the GTZ/NABARD study that in March 2005 SBI accounted for 40 percent of all active clients (i.e. those in currently linked SHGs) and the top five lenders accounted for more than two-thirds of them.9 Similarly, 20 out of the total of 196 participating RRBs served 50 percent of active clients, and cooperative banks in three states (Tamil Nadu, Karnataka and West Bengal) accounted for 82 percent of those served by the cooperative banks.10 ICICI accounted for half the SHGs linked by the private banks. The share of the three models of linkage remained roughly the same, with Model II (SHGs formed by agencies other than banks, mainly NGOs, but also farmer clubs, and individual rural volunteers who are paid a fee) increasing its share from 74 to 75 percent of cumulative linkages at the expense of the share Model I, in which SHGs are formed by the banks themselves. In Model III, NGOs and SHG federations act as credit intermediaries, or in other words as MFIs, borrowing at their own risk to onlend to SHGs.11 An interesting addition to the intermediaries being used under Model III was made during An interesting addition to the the year through a pilot project in 5 districts of Tamil Nadu to lend through post offices. Post intermediaries offices have huge potential outreach, with about 155,000 branches, and have close local being used knowledge. They will borrow at 6 percent from NABARD and on-lend to SHGs at 9 percent. Like under Model III was made the banks, they will use NGOs to form and train groups, and the NGOs will be eligible for the during the year grants NABARD pays NGOs to defray their costs (but only partially)12. through a pilot project in 5 districts of SHG lifespans Tamil Nadu to lend through In perhaps the first rigorous academic study of an aspect of the SHG movement, using post offices. sophisticated econometric methods; Micro-finance Lifespans: A Study of Attrition and Exclusion Post offices have huge in Self-Help Groups in India by Jean-Marie Baland, Rohini Somanathan and Lore Vandewalle potential (Baland et al 2007), welcome confirmation was found for two of the "lights", or reassuring outreach, with about 155,000 findings, of the SHG "Lights and Shades"study (LSS) discussed at length in last year's report branches, and (EDA and APMAS 2006). These relate to the longevity groups and the drop-out rate. In a have close local sample of 1102 PRADAN promoted groups in three tribal districts of Orissa and Chattisgarh, knowledge only 10 percent of groups formed between 1998 and 2006 were found by the survey carried out in early 2007, to be no longer active. This is comparable with the estimated proportion of defunct and broken groups of 7 percent, in groups of average age of 6 years, in the much smaller 214-SHG, LSS sample taken across 4 states. The drop-out rate of individual members was found to be almost identical, at 14 percent.13 The study found that the factors behind group survival were different from those behind member longevity. The former was strongly associated with the presence of an educated member in the group, perhaps because this facilitates transactions, interaction with bank officials, and the accuracy of book-keeping. A second factor was the presence of other groups in the village. Since PRADAN organizes groups in the same village into clusters, this is the first empirical finding in support of the potential role of higher-level formations such as clusters of SHGs and their federations in enhancing SHG quality and sustainability. On the other hand, a third possible factor, social heterogeneity, measured by the number of different castes represented in the group, does not have systematic effects on group survival. 39
  • 42. However, the study found that social heterogeneity does increase the probability of individual member exit from the group (or of dropping out), presumably by increasing the probability of personal conflict with other members, which was the single most important reason for departures in Chattisgarh, and the second most important one in Orissa, where difficulties in meeting loan repayment and monthly savings obligations were twice as important. This last reason for member departures may also explain the finding of the study that tribal and SC women have shorter SHG lifespans than groups that lie higher in the social hierarchy. On the other hand higher levels of education, bigger landholdings and more relatives within the groups are associated with a lower probability of exit. The finding about land-holdings is interesting, because it is well-known that an important use of SHG loans is to finance crop inputs and the other recurrent costs of family agriculture. Since a large proportion of SHG members, both above the below the poverty line, are farmers' wives, the SHG programme, as it expands, is beginning to become increasingly important as a source of crop credit. It already supplies close to one-fifth of total agricultural lending by the banks to marginal farmers with less than 2.5 acres of land.14 Quality remains the major problem, and may be growing: a case study of the programme in a priority state The report finds Another important recent study, "Quality Issues of SHGs in Rajasthan", conducted recently by that the the Centre for Microfinance, Jaipur and APMAS, gives us a much more differentiated picture of "overall quality of groups is low the programme in a particular state than is usually possible in a multi-state study.15 It and there are provides a useful corrective to any complacency that might be engendered by the impressive startling inter- district and macro numbers for the country as a whole. It also serves as a useful reminder that while it is intra-promoter important for the programme to grow in the 13 priority states (Rajasthan is one of them) variations long-run growth will be much more rapid if it takes place on the basis of strong foundations. across the groups". The The report finds that the "overall quality of groups is low and there are startling inter-district proportion of A and intra-promoter variations across the groups". The proportion of A groups was 30 percent groups was 30 as against 66 percent found by APMAS 2005 in AP. percent as against 66 percent found The study was carried out in 5 districts based on a sample of 202 SHGs, a little more than half by APMAS 2005 of which were of less than 3 years old given the age of the programme in Rajasthan. However in AP a third were between 3 and 5 years old. Interestingly, the number of BPL members were almost exactly the same as the number of poor members as defined in LSS (49 percent as against 51 percent respectively). While the study agrees with other studies that SHGs have a significant impact on women's empowerment, a medium impact on household income, and that overdues and defaults on bank loans are not a serious problem, it found the dropout rate to be considerably higher (30 percent for groups older than 5 years, with a disproportionate share of them being BPL members). Regarding the quality of governance, at least a tenth of all groups had held no meetings at all during the year, and more than 20 percent has carried out all transactions outside the meetings. Savings per member were an average of Rs 40 a month, but two-thirds of the amount saved had accumulated as idle funds parked in the banks, instead of being lent out to members. The report is critical of the fact that these funds constituted 44 percent of bank loans outstanding to the groups, on which they were paying much higher interest than they received on their 40
  • 43. CHAPTER 2 Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme savings balances. It is not clear however what part of these funds belonged to groups with loans outstanding.16 The study observed several other symptoms of weak loan demand, such as the fact that only 59 percent of members borrowed, of which 14 percent were group leaders,17 and that 12 percent of the groups received first loans of less than Rs 5000.18 It also notes some extreme instances of the deleterious effects of targetitis, with cases in one district of small loans being forced on groups who were told to repay within two months. Although, on average, groups received 1.6 loans each, the average amount of loans received including repeat loans was only Rs 27,000.19 With two-thirds of sample groups organized by government functionaries, primarily anganwadi The study proposes that workers from the DWCD,20 which is also the nodal coordinating agency, as it is in many other monitoring of states, the Rajasthan programme is particularly vulnerable to the distortions introduced by the programme targets. The study proposes that monitoring of the programme should henceforth be in terms should henceforth be in of the respective numbers of A, B, and C grade groups, as well as in respect of repeat loans and terms of the size of loans, which is a useful suggestion for the programme at the national level too. It respective numbers of A, suggests that the 50 percent of groups in the B category need to brought up to the A B, and C grade category with extra inputs of training, hand-holding support, and exposure visits. The DCWD, groups, as well which receives inadequate funds as the main SHPI, needs to enhance its own capacity in order as in respect of repeat loans to accomplish this. and size of loans, which is The report makes the important point that although it is claimed that the programme has a useful achieved an important paradigm shift from a loan-centred to a savings- centred strategy, "the suggestion for the programme sample groups, by and large, are functioning around loans if not subsidies.21 Savings are at the national nominal at times."22 But because they are compulsory they exclude a large number of the poor, level too whose incomes fluctuate. Several other studies have shown that reluctance to commit themselves to fixed monthly savings in the face of uncertain and fluctuating incomes is the single most important reason for why only half the membership of the movement is poor, and for dropping out. The report recommends introducing therefore some flexibility in savings and repayments to overcome the effects, which are particularly strong in Rajasthan, both because of seasonality in agriculture,23 and of migration. Second, it proposes distribution of at least part of the accumulated corpus of groups from time to time as "dividends", both as an incentive to save, and so as to ensure that the accounting is timely and accurate enough to ensure allocability of the corpus between members. It recommends that at the very least, all groups prepare, discuss and approve the balance sheet of the group once a year, which is yet another reminder of the importance of good bookkeeping (and training for it) in the programme. All in all, the study provides a much more nuanced view of how the programme actually operates in one priority state, and draws attention to the urgency of tackling quality related issues if the programme is to grow sustainably. We need many more state level studies before deciding how representative the problems identified are, but anecdotal experience suggests they are widespread, and a "vision document" prepared by the Government of Orissa itself says the "mushrooming growth of groups in the state and lack of adequate monitoring has resulted in irregular savings, irregular meetings, improper book-keeping, lack of solidarity and peer pressure in the groups…"(Government of Orissa 2005).24 41
  • 44. As the Rajasthan study points out, the programme suffers from several "structural" constraints which are particularly acute in Rajasthan, with its low population density and widely dispersed habitats,25 high female illiteracy,26 cultural tradition of female seclusion,27 predominance of agriculture, and high incidence of migration.28 One suspects however that the most important factor explaining differences in programme quality across states is the quality of grass-roots governance in a state. It is important also that such studies be carried out by neutral observers such as state level resource agencies whose independence is not fettered by any assistance they may receive from the state government or interested donors. Since NABARD is likely to Statistics become the regulator under As noted earlier, the biggest gap in the statistical foundations of the programme, the lack of the new microfinance exposure (loans outstanding) data, is about to be filled. But the others identified in last bill pending in year's report remain: (i) the lack of disaggregated data on repeat loans (separating them into partliament, a second, third and subsequent loans) so that loan size progression can be observed, (ii) data major objective of which is to on savings balances and CD ratios (although we now have an estimate for March 2005), (iii) improve the reported data on institution-wise and state-wise NPAs under the programme, although, again, national data we do have one-time information on NPAs as of March 2005 from the GTZ report. A further base, it needs to set a good suggestion, as noted above, is a tabulation of the quality of the groups in terms of the mix of example by their A, B, and C grades. presenting timely and comprehensive Since NABARD is likely to become the regulator under the new microfinance bill pending in data on the partliament, a major objective of which is to improve the national data base, it needs to set programme a good example by presenting timely and comprehensive data on the programme under its under its own direct oversight own direct oversight. 42
  • 45. CHAPTER 2 Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme Table 2.3 Growth trends in the SBLP for 2006-07, by state S. Region/State Cumulative No. of new No. of Cumulative Cumulative Bank Loan Of Col.8, Cumulative No. of SHGs SHGs existing No. of SHGs bank loan during repeat bank bank loan No. provided provided SHGs provided upto 2006-07 loan to upto with bank with bank provided with bank 31 March existing 31 March loan upto loan during with repeat loan upto 2006 SHGs 2007 (7+8) 31 March 2006-07 bank loan 31 March 2006 during 2007 (3+4) (Rs million) (Rs million) (Rs million) (Rs million) 2006-07 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 A Northern Region 1 Himachal Pradesh 22,920 4,879 2,282 27,799 863.98 388.27 153.60 1,252.25 2 Rajasthan 98,171 39,666 3,692 137,837 2,447.94 1,447.40 191.53 3,895.34 3 Haryana 4,867 1,966 1,821 6,833 316.01 183.31 69.86 499.32 4 Punjab 4,561 1,893 517 6,454 238.86 117.74 29.24 356.60 5 Jammu & Kashmir 2,354 405 199 2,759 100.48 44.25 15.83 144.73 6 New Delhi 224 112 336 18.58 8.65 27.23 T O T A L (A) 133,097 48,921 8,511 182,018 3,985.85 2,189.62 460.05 6,175.47 B North Eastern Region 7 Assam 56,449 25,005 160 81,454 1,423.98 794.40 2.91 2,218.38 8 Meghalaya 735 476 0 1,211 16.19 17.40 0.00 33.59 9 Tripura 1,996 910 57 2,906 31.12 18.40 1.48 49.52 10 Sikkim 127 33 0 160 1.86 1.12 0.00 2.98 11 Manipur 1,468 1,215 0 2,683 71.85 40.80 0.00 112.65 12 Arunachal Pradesh 346 101 0 447 13.49 5.72 0.00 19.21 13 Nagaland 422 576 10 998 34.38 33.50 2.97 67.88 14 Mizoram 974 921 0 1,895 64.14 70.56 0.00 134.70 T O T A L (B) 62,517 29,237 227 91,754 1,657.01 981.89 7.36 2,638.90 C Eastern Region 15 Orissa 180,896 53,555 28,806 234,451 4,754.65 3,274.27 1,409.33 8,028.92 16 Bihar 46,221 26,118 1,306 72,339 1,052.19 960.28 211.15 2,012.47 17 Jharkhand 30,819 6,498 1,153 37,317 1,114.60 391.96 84.21 1,506.56 18 West Bengal 136,251 45,312 22,014 181,563 2,424.52 2,060.64 888.40 4,485.16 19 UT of A & N Islands 164 47 30 211 8.23 4.58 3.40 12.81 T O T A L (C) 394,351 131,530 53,309 525,881 9,354.19 6,691.72 2,596.50 16,045.91 D Central Region 20 Madhya Pradesh 57,125 13,787 1,726 70,912 1,666.86 499.23 65.12 2,166.09 21 Chhatisgarh 31,291 10,412 1,330 41,703 337.81 218.44 27.51 556.25 22 Uttar Pradesh 161,911 36,676 2,873 198,587 5,153.54 1,778.48 192.43 6,932.02 23 Uttarakhand 17,588 3,939 1,288 21,527 891.86 382.69 225.64 1,274.55 T O T A L (D) 267,915 64,814 7,217 332,729 8,050.07 2,878.84 510.69 10,928.91 E Western Region 24 Gujarat 34,160 9,412 64 43,572 1,244.51 885.46 4.69 2,129.97 25 Maharashtra 131,470 94,386 19,382 225,856 3,951.67 2,983.86 841.01 6,935.53 26 Goa 624 395 142 1,019 55.21 28.28 9.03 83.49 T O T A L (E) 166,254 104,193 19,588 270,447 5,251.39 3,897.60 854.72 9,148.99 F Southern Region 27 Andhra Pradesh 587,238 96,381 262,895 683,619 43,455.18 27,754.55 23,536.74 71,209.73 28 Karnataka 224,928 92,708 56,717 317,636 9,927.53 8,163.89 3,239.26 18,091.42 29 Kerala 86,988 30,925 13,559 117,913 4,821.48 2,889.40 1,067.68 7,710.88 30 Tamil Nadu 312,778 87,699 35,387 400,477 27,121.87 10,984.48 3,721.55 38,106.35 31 UT of Pondicherry 2,499 2,499 350.86 350.86 T O T A L (F) 1,214,431 307,713 368,558 1,522,144 85,676.92 49,792.32 31,565.24 135,469.24 GRAND TOTAL 2,238,565 686,408 457,410 2,924,973 113,975.43 66,431.99 35,994.56 180,407.42 Source: www.nabard.org 43
  • 46. Endnotes 1 This is the average size for the overall sample reported in the most recent large scale survey of SHGs, "Self Help Groups in India: A Study of the Lights and Shades" (EDA and APMAS 2006), discussed in last year's State of the Sector, and hereafter referred to as LSS. For a national average this is probably on the low side, given that the average age of the groups was 6 years, and the dropout rate 10 percent. In its annual reports on the programme NABARD uses a higher figure (15 in 2004-05 and 14.7 in 2005-06). 2 A recent estimate of the percentage of members who have at least one relative in the group is about 10 percent (Baland et al 07). If they had only one relative each, the number of families benefited would have to adjusted downwards by 5 percent. 3 The corresponding increases last year were 17 and 28 percent respectively. Data on repeat loans are for an unreported, and probably unknown, mix of second, third and further loans. 4 Thus two six monthly seasonal crop loans will show twice the disbursement level of a one-year loan of the same size. 5 Table 1 of Ramakrishna 2006. Responses were received from all the 27 public sector commercial banks participating in the programme, 192 out of the 196 RRBs, and 114 cooperative credit institutions from the five major states who hold 95 percent of the share of the cooperative banks in the SHG programme. 6 Thus in terms of savings outstanding, 10 percent of RRBs in the country account for 83 percent of total savings outstanding. The situation is better with the DCCBs where 20 percent of the institutions account for 45 percent of total savings outstanding. 7 NABARD's annual report on the SBLP, and hence the corresponding data for 2006-07, were not available at the time of writing this chapter in late September 2007. 8 The SBI has announced a goal of linking 1 million SHGs by March 2008. 9 These are the State Bank of India, Andhra Bank, State Bank of Hyderabad, Indian Overseas Bank and Indian Bank (Table 1 of Ramakrishna 2006). Most of AP's programme is served by the second two. 10 Tables 6 and 7 in Ramakrishna 2006. 11 The share of Model I declined from 20 to 17 percent, unlike last year when it increased, and that of Model III increased from 6 to 8 percent, after declining steadily for the last few years. 12 Thus the post offices under the pilot are in a sense being given special treatment since intermediaries under Model III are expected to defray the costs of group promotion through the margin. The most common estimate used for the actual cost of forming and "hand-holding" groups is Rs 10,000, incurred over the few years necessary, but NABARD treats the incentive as an add-on, meant to supplement grants from other sources. See last year's report for a fuller discussion. An increase in the 44
  • 47. CHAPTER 2 Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme incentive from Rs 3000 to Rs 4000 is reportedly under consideration (The incentive is already higher in the Northeast, where it is Rs 5,000 per SHG). 13 The rate in LSS was 10 percent, but some of the drop-outs among the 14 percent went on to join other groups. Overall, the study estimated that about 20 percent of SHG members who had joined a group had left the SHG network within the 8-year period. 14 A comparison of loans outstanding in 2003-04 against marginal farmers, shown in Table 59 of the RBI Handbook of Statistics on the Indian Economy (on short-term and long-term direct finance to farmers in various land-holding classes) with the amount of SHG loans outstanding in that year (estimated, as discussed above, by assuming it was 70 percent of cumulative lending in that year), shows that SHG lending constituted 18.5 percent of total lending to farmers. (It is assumed that the figures in Table 59 include SHG lending, which is classified as agricultural). 15 Although LSS provided extensive tabulation and analysis on state-wise performance in the four states it studied (AP, Karnataka, Orissa and Rajasthan) it looked at 214 SHGs in the four states as against the 202 in a single state in this study. The state that has been studied the most extensively is AP, largely because of the presence in that state of the first and largest SHG resource institution, APMAS. Last year's Report carries in Chapter 2 a section describing the findings of APMAS 2005, a comprehensive summary of several studies on SHGs in AP, conducted by APMAS since 2003. 16 To the extent they were, one reason could be mismanagement by group leaders, made possible by the fact that many members had no clear picture of "where the savings is, how it is being used and for what purpose…" Another reason could be the reported practice by the banks of impounding the savings of the group as collateral, against both the letter and spirit of the linkage programme. Impounding of part of the loan amount is also reported to have been in vogue, with no interest paid on the deducted amount. To the extent savings belonged to surplus groups with no bank loans outstanding, the "balancing" of funds between surplus and deficit groups is one of the functions proposed for federations performing financial intermediation, as discussed in Chapter 3. 17 In this sense loan distribution was less equitable than in LSS. On the other hand, need based borrowing is clearly preferable to loans being distributed between all group members equally, which is another symptom of weak loan demand (and in some cases also lack of trust within a group) and happened in the case of 13 percent of all loans, with another 16 percent being distributed on the basis of "need plus equal basis". 18 The banks lend at between 8 to 12 percent as in other parts of the country but onlending rates range from as low as 8 percent (the rate at which funds are borrowed) to 36 percent. The on-lending rate is the lowest in the district in which the leaders receive the highest proportion of loans. 19 Instances were noted of first loans of Rs 1000, a second loan of Rs 2000, and 3rd loans of Rs 5000. Evidence of the emergence of a significant loan absorption constraint has been found in many other studies. However the solution lies not within the SHG programme but enhancing the effectiveness of the general development programme in increasing the productive opportunities open to the poor. 20 These are the Anganwadi Worker (AWW) and Assistant Anganwadi Worker (AWA), who not only organized groups, but in most groups promoted by them also became the leaders of the groups, and sometimes of more than one group. The report notes that groups have failed to internalize the norms of the programme, and tend to be perpetually dependent on SHG staff for their day to day activities. Also, 45
  • 48. meeting dates, venues and timing tend to be fixed at the convenience of SHPI field staff and leaders. Thus group meetings are fixed in the afternoons, which is a convenient time for the AWW and field staff of NGOs, but not for members, who are free only by late evening. 21 The reference to subsidies is to the 10 SGSY groups. Apart from subsidies these groups had received average loans of Rs 300,000, which is ten times higher than the average received by the 151 groups linked under the regular programme. 51 groups in the sample of 202 groups had not yet been linked. 22 Although average savings were Rs 40 a month, about 50 percent of groups had saving of Rs 20 or less a month. 23 Over 85 percent of the female work force in employed in agriculture, either as cultivators or labourers. 24 Orissa along with Rajasthan is one of the 13 Priority States where the programme is growing relatively rapidly. With the assistance of CARE India, Orissa prepared a "vision" document released by the Chief Minister for Mission Shakti, which lays down the goal of forming 300,000 groups by the end of 2008, of which 80 percent would be credit linked, and would be of grade A. Repeat linkage would be ensured in the case of 50 percent of the groups and average lending per group would be Rs 40,000. Every revenue village in the state would have at least one SHG. Top priority would be given to the formation of cluster and block level federations in every panchayat and block respectively, as well as "activity based federations" and cooperatives (See Chapter 3). The government would facilitate the setting up of a Capacity Building Institute to meet the capacity building demands of stakeholders (Government of Orissa 2005). Unfortunately the Department of Women and Child Development does not publish statistics on progress towards these goals, although the target for credit linked groups is likely to be 90 percent reached as can be seen from Table 2.2. Also, 6065 panchayat level clusters and 208 block level federations had been formed by March 2007, a coverage of 95 percent of the goal, although mostly only on paper. According to NABARD statistics the proportion of repeat loans was only 12 percent by March 2007 (Table 2.3). Since a capacity building and resource institute for the programme has not been set up yet, no quality assessment study exists yet similar to the present one being discussed for Rajasthan, although a rating exercise was carried out in 2003 which found that the number of A, B, and C groups constituted 29, 14, and 57 percent of the total, respectively. 25 These partly explain relatively low average group size of 12 and irregularities in meetings and attendance. 26 At about 75 percent on of the lowest in the country. 27 Rajasthan is one of the most conservative states in the country, with high discrimination against women. A high proportion of members are elderly women who are subjected to less seclusion. 28 Migration is one of the most important livelihood strategies in the state. Those women who are left behind are unable to participate in meetings because of heavier workloads caused by the absence of the male family members. 46
  • 49. CHAPTER 2 Progress Under the SHG Bank Linkage Programme References Baland, Jean-Marie, Rohini Somanathan and Lore Vandewalle, 2007, "Micro-finance Lifespans: A Study of Attrition and Exlusion in Self-Help Groups in India, paper prepared for presentation at the Brookings-NCAER India Policy Forum 2007, July 17-18, New Delhi EDA Rural Systems and APMAS, 2006, "Self Help Groups in India: A Study of the Lights and Shades" for CRS, USAID, CARE and GTZ/NABARD, Microfinace India, New Delhi Government of Orissa, 2005, "Empowered Woman: A Vision Document for micro-Finance in Orissa", Women and Child Development Department, Bhubaneshwar Centre for Microfinance and APMAS, 2006, "Quality Issues of SHGs in Rajasthan", CMF, Jaipur Ramakrishna, RV, 2006, "Management Information System (MIS): SHG Bank Linkage Programme" mimeo, GTZ, New Delhi 47
  • 50. 48
  • 51. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers 1 or Nurturers? A few years ago a chapter such as this might have started with the question "are federations necessary", but today, whatever the answer to that question, federations seem to be a fait accompli, with a 2005 estimate of at least 66,000 in the country as a whole (Reddy et al 2007). This number has increased since then, propelled both by a variety of push factors, with donors, governments, and several banks supporting them for various reasons, as well as by the A number of state pull factor of the demand for credit that remains unsatisfied by the SBLP. Several multilateral governments, and bilateral donor-sponsored projects have included federations as an important component AP being the of their SHG-based livelihoods projects, primarily as a means of ensuring the long run most important of them, institutional sustainability of the SHG programme.2 More communitarian-minded donors, mainly accounting for international and local NGOs, have promoted federations for the stronger organized identity, almost half the and greater possibilities for collective action, they offer SHG women, much more than a single federations in the country SHG could ever do3. through the IKP programme, are A number of state governments, AP being the most important of them, accounting for almost attracted by federations as a half the federations in the country through the IKP programme, are attracted by federations convenient as a convenient means of offering a variety of economic and social services in the rural areas, means of as well as for their empowerment and potential political advantages. West Bengal for instance offering a variety of has a minister for SHGs, who is reported to oversee 13600 panchayat level federations and 350 economic and block level federations, and Kerala implements the Kudumbasree programme consisting of social services in the rural about 15,000 federations through local bodies.4 Banks are interested in the federations for areas, as well the economies of scale they promise, and SHGs are attracted by the greater sense of efficacy as for their they experience through belonging to a larger fraternity, referred to often as "being able to empowerment and potential walk into the Collector's office". Finally, in areas or pockets where credit demand is high, many political of them are impatient with the quantum and timeliness of credit available under the SBLP, advantages despite rapid expansion of the programme in recent years.5 While the estimate of 66,000 federations needs to be updated, it is important to note that the numbers come mostly from a few states in which government-sponsored programmes have set up federations in every panchayat or block. Except in AP and Kerala, many of these have yet to be registered, and the vast majority are still inactive. The number of federations set up by NGOs and NGO-networks is much smaller, and probably below 2 to 3 thousand.6 Even for them, details on distribution by level (whether cluster or higher), size, type, major programme under which promoted, etc. are lacking. The sheer heterogeneity of federations,7 the fact that many of them are still nascent and inchoate, and the dearth of case studies all complicate the effort of coming up with a satisfactory typology, a necessary step in building a meaningfully differentiated data base.8 49
  • 52. It is important to note also, that despite their obvious appeal, the "are they necessary" question is still being asked by the main actor in the SHG movement - NABARD - and by others who argue that in a situation of limited promotional resources (promoter capacity and the long-term commitment required) it is more efficient to devote these scarce resources to improving the quality of SHGs and therefore the flow of resources from the banks to SHGs directly, which after all is likely to remain by far the larger source of funds to SHGs than bulk funding through federations. Thus although many federations have already been formed, this argument goes, they are not entirely a "sunk cost" in the context of the further huge growth of the SBLP envisaged. The tentative The tentative hypothesis put forward in this chapter is that we should still be very interested in hypothesis put federations primarily as a cost-effective means (but not the only one) of enhancing the prospects forward in this chapter is that of sustainability of the SBLP and individual SHG quality.9 We need a greatly stepped up programme we should still of coordinated action research to fully investigate the potential of federations in this respect. be very interested in Moreover as discussed below, there appear to be situations where they are needed for their federations financial services too, as in bridge financing, as DHAN Foundation seems to have concluded, or primarily as a where federations have become so strong and efficient that lenders are genuinely persuaded cost-effective means (but not about the scale advantages of lending to them directly, adding a third channel to the two main the only one) of existing channels of microfinance in the country, or what have been called community based enhancing the prospects of MFIs (CBMFIs). Third, federations offer the prospect of very real empowerment benefits. Ultimately, sustainability and quite apart from their benefits as aggregators of services, it is these benefits, of experiencing of the SBLP and a sense of efficacy through advocacy and collective action, that drives SHGs and many promoters individual SHG quality to federate. It is this aspect of the SHG "revolution" that attracts many observers the most. As Jairam Ramesh points out, financial services are only part of the success story. "More fundamental has been voice, identity and empowerment" (Box 3.1) Box 3.1. "The SHG Revolution: What Next?" "Today, in some parts of the country, SHGs are taking on new roles and responsibilities that lie at the very core of livelihood security for the poor. Indeed, as institutions of social capital, they offer great potential…The SHG network in Andhra has gone beyond credit… First, it has taken up the marketing of commodities like maize, neem, soybean, coffee, lac and red gram. Last year, the value of procurement was in the region of Rs 130 crores. The big challenge here is to go beyond traditional marketing and get into value-addition in meaningful measure and develop linkages with exporters and processors directly. Second, it is being used to distribute old-age pensions-in 2006/07, over Rs 700 crores was distributed to around 3 million beneficiaries through the SHGs. Timely disbursement of pensions and disbursements without a "consideration" are the hallmark of SHG involvement. Third, the elements of a community-based food security system are being put in place. At the moment, it consists almost entirely of a rice credit line but the goal seems to be paddy purchase and milling by the SHG network at the village and mandal level itself. Fourth, dairy interventions have started with livestock being purchased through SHG-bank linkages and with the SHG network setting up bulk milk coolers and milk procurement centres. My own involvement has been to try and ensure that there are links established between the network of SHGs and the traditional NDDB procurement network… Dairying is very important as an income-augmenting occupation to crop agriculture. 50
  • 53. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? There is one more somewhat unusual intervention through the SHG network. This relates to non-pesticide management in agriculture, particularly cotton… Cotton lies at the heart of the suicide tragedies that have stalked the state over the past decade and so this particular initiative has great significance. So far, something like 2 lakh acres have been covered and by the end of the decade about 10% of the net sown area in the state will be covered. In my capacity as Minister of State of Commerce, I am particularly interested in exports of spices. Today, about 25% of the $ 600 million of spice exports is accounted for by chillies that are grown predominantly in Andhra Pradesh. We have discovered that chillies without pesticide residue command a premium in world markets. I will distinguish here between non- pesticide agriculture where fertilizers are still used and organic farming where yields may turn out to be lower but net returns to farmers could actually increase. NPM agriculture is, in my view, the first step to organic farming that has relevance in certain situations and niche regions. I want to mention another important initiative … About 2 million ha.of government land has been assigned to the landless poor in Andhra Pradesh over the past decades. But as is well known, the productivity of these assigned lands is very low-perhaps, that is why they were "assigned" in the first place. Against this background, the state government has launched a comprehensive land development project that takes up about 10% of this area to be brought under productive use in four years time. … it is critical to see SHGs not The Andhra SHG story has undoubtedly been government-driven. … What it shows is that as just networks for confidence- government can innovate, that government can demonstrate commitment and concern. building and Efficiency is not the monopoly of the private sector nor is sensitivity the preserve of civil empowerment society. Within the government system, there are people who are motivated and who, given but also as networks that political support, can and will deliver… must have access to new To be sure, over time the SHG network must become self-sustaining. Indeed, that is the true economic test of whether the government has succeeded or not. When will this happen? I have been opportunities asking this question of my colleagues in Andhra Pradesh and the answer they have come up is the following. A Mandal Samakhya will have the capacity to be on its own feet when it has a monthly net income of Rs 50,000. Today, while a detailed financial analysis is still being done, it appears that of the 1000 Mandal Samakhyas, perhaps just about 10-15% meet this criteria. Clearly, there is a long way to go yet. Further, even in these 100-odd Mandal Samakhyas, the bulk of the monthly income-around three-fourths-is really interest income. This proportion has to reduce. … it is critical to see SHGs not as just networks for confidence-building and empowerment but also as networks that must have access to new economic opportunities. One of the initiatives taken by the Ministry of Commerce in recent months is to link export promotion councils with SHGs so that the benefits of export expansion can accrue directly to the poor where they have skills. A beginning has been made in leather in Tamil Nadu and in shellac in Andhra Pradesh. The export promotion councils are working with SHGs to provide design and marketing assistance, while the SHGs are responsible for production. Another example is how the SHG-run lace export park in Narsapur in West Godavari district of Andhra Pradesh is being facilitated to establish global linkages. A recent breakthrough has been obtained with Ikea. …SHGs are not panaceas for every situation. In India, there have been many instances of innovative initiatives have been taken and pretty soon these initiatives degenerating into 51
  • 54. "solutions in search of problems" … Since the state administrative machinery has collapsed in so many areas, there is a temptation to give the SHG network an ever expanding role. … Proponents of SHGs have raised the possibility of SHGs managing PHCs, for instance. When there is a good thing going, exaggerated expectations can and do set in, especially when there is political mileage to be derived as well. Drawing a Lakshman Rekha around the SHG network so that it does not spread itself very thin is very essential. At the same time, I do recognize that there has to be some room for responding to new challenges. For instance, now that Andhra Pradesh has emerged as number 1 in HIV/AIDS prevalence in the country, public health planners should use the extensive SHG network for combating this scourge. I had alluded to MFIs earlier… I believe that both are have important roles to play. The separation of the social organization to be performed by the IKP and capital mobilization and disbursement to be performed by the MFIs is the starting point of a cooperative approach. In such an approach, the regulation of the industry will be driven by the market and community, rather than by legislation. The separation …the panchayat revolution … has swept India, thanks to the 73rd Amendment to the of the social Constitution. While much remains to be done, over 30 lakh elected representatives now all organization to be performed by over rural India with over 12 lakh of them being women is a visible manifestation of this the IKP and momentous change. capital mobilization …Simultaneously, there has been the SHG upsurge, an upsurge that is uniquely Indian. Over 3 and crore women are now linked to banks through over 22 lakh SHGs and as I have shown, financial disbursement to be performed by services is only a small part of their success story. More fundamental has been voice, identity the MFIs is the and empowerment. starting point of a cooperative …The relationship between SHG institutions and panchayat bodies needs greater approach attention…There is really no conflict between the two. SHG institutions can and must play a supporting role in social mobilization and in social audit, like, for instance, in the NREGA. ...Over time, as SHG members gain in voice and self-confidence, they can be expected to contest panchayat elections on their own. In the recent local body elections, about 9-10% of those elected to mandal and zilla panchayats were "SHG women", something that was unheard of before. …For inclusive growth which has become the mantra these days, India needs not just globalization as traditionally understood but actually glocalisation which ensures that economic growth is more broad-based, equitable and sustainable than it has been so far. Panchayats are institutions of representation. SHGs are institutions of participation. These are the twin pillars on which India's glocalisation strategy should rest." Excerpts from Silver Jubilee Lecture at the Society for the Promotion of Wastelands Development, New Delhi, May 5, 2007 by Jairam Ramesh, Minister of State for Commerce (with a shortened version in the Economic and Political Weekly, September 8-14, 2007). Non-financial support services to SHGs It is useful to discuss the experience with federations according to three broad sets of objectives they could serve. These are (i) non-financial support services designed to strengthen the quality of member SHGs (ii) financial services and (iii) non-credit related economic and social activities. 52
  • 55. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? Between the first two of these at any rate, most observers would regard the first as more important. While credit can be accessed through direct linkages, and that too relatively easily judging by the pace of expansion of SHG Bank Linkage Programme, studies show that the long-run health of SHGs and the very sustainability of the programme depends crucially on strengthening SHG capacity.10 Federations are an important means of doing so, although it is important to note that they are not the only ones. Other approaches are (i) institutions such as MYRADA's Community Managed Resource Centres (CMRCs) (Box 3.2) (ii) accounting system innovations such as Computer Munshi, (iii) greater capacity building of the capacity builders themselves, strengthening SHPAs to provide more effective and longer-term hand-holding of SHGs directly, financed if necessary by higher and longer-term promotional assistance from government, (iv) bank branches insisting of better account keeping and playing a stronger role in capacity building of linked SHGs, either directly or though outsourcing (as SBI is doing), (v) DRDAs and government programmes eschewing targets, and preferably direct group formation by government functionaries altogether, or at least improving their own capacity building efforts, and (vi) induction of technology11. Box 3.2 MYRADA's Community Managed Resource Centres (CMRCs) MYRADA had set up 89 CMRCs with 303 full-time workers by December 2006, each covering 100- 200 SHGs, watershed institutions and other CBOs, to provide training, support and information on a variety of government schemes, insurance and legal matters, and equipped with telephone and internet facilities to access information and download forms etc. The major activity is training (about 6000 trainings a year) not just on SHG related skills such as book keeping, but in other areas too such as awareness of health, veterinary care, disability, and legal issues. Eye, blood-donation, and animal health camps are also organized. All services are paid for. 15 CMRCs had reached self-sufficiency by Sept 2005, including payment for the services of the Manager and other staff, both full-time and community volunteers. CMRCs play a key role in MYRADA's withdrawal strategy after 6 to 8 years in an area. The centres are strictly speaking not representative organizations (and are unlike federations in this respect) but are run by management committees comprising representatives of member CBOs. MYRADA also has federations through which representatives to the CMRCs are chosen, but these are cluster level groups of only 10-15 SHGs, kept small so as to maximize participation, and are paid for by one-time admission fees and monthly membership fees from the SHGs. Unlike in many other parts of the country, the availability of local book-keepers does not seem to be a major issue in MYRADA's areas, and book keeping is handled by the SHGs themselves, with the assistance of training offered by the CMRCs. Facilitation in availing of linkage loans from the bank branches, and in getting loans from Sanghamitra, is offered by the CMRCs and not by the federations, whose task is essentially to offer audit services, review the functioning of member SHGs, resolve any conflicts, and organize trainings and exposure visits through the CMRC. Based on discussions with Al Fernandez, MYRADA However these approaches are not alternatives to federations,12 or to each other. The main non-financial services federations can provide to develop capacity are (i) training and hand- holding in book-keeping and accounting, (ii) direct provision of accounting services, (iii) ongoing quality monitoring, (iv) periodic grading or quality assessment and (v) annual 53
  • 56. auditing. Other non-financial services they can provide, although not directly related to capacity-building are (i) conflict resolution and problem solving within and between groups (ii) promoting new groups (iii) awareness building and advocacy of social issues and (iv) livelihood promotion activities if the funding is available. We need much more action research to get a feel for how federations can provide such services effectively and sustainably. APMAS's 2006 quality assessment report found the provision of services to be the weakest aspect of federation performance across the six indicators in GRADES.13 One of the best known cases of a federation providing non-financial services along with limited financial intermediation (but no bulk borrowing14 from external sources) is that of Sakhi Samiti in Alwar district, Rajasthan, which was promoted by PRADAN. After supporting it for about ten years PRADAN exited Sakhi Samiti six years ago. Since then Sakhi Samiti has been successfully providing book-keeping services to about 250 SHGs on its own, through a Anecdotal small staff of field workers at the federation level, and one munshi (accountant) based at each evidence of three clusters. Sakhi Samiti charges member SHGs 2 per Rs 1000 of cumulative group suggests that once savings a month, so that a typical group pays about Rs 200 a month. It also facilitates federations get linkages of new groups with the local banks, for which it charges half a percent of the loan into the amount. A third source of revenue is lending from an associated fund called Sakhi Suvidha, to business of accessing bulk which each group makes a one-time contribution or Rs 1000, and each group member Rs 50. funds, the Loans from the fund are meant to tide groups over periods when they are waiting for loans preoccupation from the banks, and the fund lends much less than the banks. It seems these sources of with sustainability income15 are insufficient to recover costs fully, which are met through cross-subsidization leads to a from other activities. It is not known how much higher fees, (and interest on Sakhi Suvidha neglect of non- financial loans, or its scale of operations) would have to be for Sakhi Samiti as a whole to achieve self- services sufficiency.16 A question that often arises is whether it helps to separate non-financial from financial service provision (i.e for federations to do one or the other) Anecdotal evidence suggests that once federations get into the business of accessing bulk funds, the preoccupation with sustainability leads to a neglect of non-financial services, given limitations on field worker time and managerial energy and attention-span. Also, it has been pointed out that the balance of power within federations tends to shift away from the primaries towards the higher tiers, with the former becoming more dependent on the latter, and the federation becoming less responsive to the primaries and their non-financial needs and interests. Shashi Rajgopalan in particular has in various writings described the dynamics involved.17 It could be argued, on the other hand, that a bulk funder would itself be expected to exercise pressure for maintaining group quality out of prudential self-interest. However there is little evidence to support this hypothesis One district level federation visited by the author that was borrowing from the banks to on-lend to its middle-tier secondaries, widely referred to as MACS in AP after their form of incorporation, relied for its high recoveries by the MACS from their groups more on the informal personal responsibility each MACS member took for the geographical set of SHGs she represented in the MACs, than on the inherent good quality of the groups. Moreover, the accounting assistance that the MACS level accountants provided to the groups was restricted to the loan ledgers relating to the MACS loan and not to the rest of the group's books. (The groups were free to borrow also from the large government-sponsored SHG federation programme, IKP, formerly called Velugu). In this respect, the federation was functioning more as an MFI than a federation set up to strengthen its primaries.18 Indeed 54
  • 57. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? APMAS 2006 and a number of other studies point out that recoveries within groups are much poorer than those from groups to the secondaries, so that each level is drawing at least temporarily on its own funds (savings deposits and accumulated surpluses from operations), a process which in the long run is not sustainable. It would be useful to gather empirical material on how real these concerns are, and the other dynamics involved. If the case studies were to show that the fee-for-service concept has not usually worked in If the case studies were to purely non-financial federations, then one argument against separating financial from non- show that the financial service provision is that the former might be able to pay for the latter. An example of fee-for-service a federation that has been successful in doing so is KVK sponsored by the DHAN Foundation. concept has not usually worked KVK is one of the few federations which have been studied carefully through a case-study in purely non- (Srinivasan 2005) KVK offered credit through bulk borrowing and on-lending services, apart financial federations, from providing non-financial services to its members, and the margin of 3 percent added on then one by both the apex level as well as the cluster level sufficed to pay not just for accounting argument assistance costs, but for total operating costs including all staff. From 2002-03, however, KVK against separating switched from financing support costs from lending margins to a system of sharing total costs financial from determined once a year (at the AGM) by all SHG members equally. The switch to this system non-financial was made to ensure greater accountability to the SHGs, and was in keeping with DHAN service provision is that Foundation's new policy of moving away from bulk borrowing for all its federations as discussed the former in Box 3.3. might be able to pay for the latter Box 3.3 DHAN Foundation federations: changing with the times DHAN Foundation's policy towards bulk borrowing by federations has evolved through several stages. In the first stage, as an increasing number of SHGs were formed under the Kalanjiam banking programme, the demand for linkage loans could not keep pace with supply from the SBLP, which was still gathering pace. In order to increase the quantum of credit available to SHGs, capture scale economies, and earn much needed revenue to support non-financial services to the clusters and groups through the spread, several federations initiated bulk borrowing from the banks and financial institutions. SPMS and KVK are prominent examples, the former being located, unusually, in an urban area (Tirupati). Cumulatively, 25 federations are reported to have mobilized 24 crores from this source, as against Rs 134 crores through linkage lending. (Vasimalai and Narender 2007). However, as it became apparent that building up truly member controlled federations with the specialized financial skills to manage bulk borrowing was going to take an unacceptably long time, the Kalanjium community banking programme decided to centralize bulk borrowing in a S 25 company, the Kalanjiam Development and Financial Services (KDFS), which was registered in 2001 and had borrowed Rs 14 crores from SIDBI, ABN-Amro and others by March 2004. (DHAN Foundation 2004). The company is owned by the federations but professionally managed by employees. Direct bulk borrowing by the federations was increasingly restricted thereafter to specialized purposes such as housing, where the lending institutions were themselves wholesale institutions without branches, such as HUDCO, HDFC, and NHB, and could not make small loans to individual SHGs. It is important to note that for the same capacity-related reasons affecting bulk borrowing (with a few prominent exceptions such as KVK and SPMS) KDFS decided to lend directly to the groups and not to the federations. According to the booklet "Catalysing Linkages:SHGs and Banks: the KDFS Experience 2001- 2004" (DHAN Foundation 2004), the demonstration effect of KDFS lending has been partly 55
  • 58. responsible for growth of direct linkage lending from the banks and the improvement in the overall proportion of groups linked (to 75 percent) and the leverage ratio, or loan amount to own savings, (to about 1:1) The booklet is very clear that "KDFS needs to maintain its role and identity as an enabler and for bridging the gap. It should guard against becoming another microfinance agency providing credit services." Of the 130 odd locations in which DF currently has operations, it has so far registered federations in about 80 (20 in AP, 10 in Karnataka, 2-3 in Orissa, 1 in MP and the rest in Tamil Nadu). Several of these are in urban areas such as Madurai, Vishakapatnam, and Salem. Federations are registered as societies and trusts so that SHGs can become primary members. Of the 80 federations only about 10 are currently involved in bulk borrowing, and that too at a reducing level. The primary mode of group financing is through direct linkages with the federation acting as facilitator for a fee (as in Karnataka where the SBI pays the federations 1 percent of the interest rate charged the groups). It has been Even SPMS, which is possibly the first SHG federation registered in the country, in 1992, as a pointed out society, and which relied primarily on bulk borrowing in the first few years after receiving that one factor driving loans from SIDBI, HUDCO and HDFC in the mid-1990s, has with the growth of the SBLP for the federations last few years been encouraging direct linkages. These increased rapidly after 2002 and finally towards overtook bulk borrowing in 2005. One of the major lenders was the Venkateshwara Grameen provision of financial Bank, with SHG lending accounting for 10 percent of its business. Unlike institutions in services is cities, those in towns can operated in the surrounding peri-urban areas with access to public precisely this sector branch banks. Apart from a major emphasis on housing, which it shares with urban scope for cross- subsidization, microfinance generally SPMS has like other DF federations branched increasingly into economic and if grant and social initiatives such as insurance, health programmes, slum improvement, reproductive funds were more and child heath and even consumer stores (DHAN Foundation 2005). This is in accordance readily available to with DF's philosophy of seeking to provide critical missing services, based on core competencies finance their at each level. non-financial services, Contrary to the hypothesis that bulk borrowing would increase self-sufficiency, federations federations that have not got into financing (as noted above, the majority now) are more often cost would more often resist the recovering than those which do bulk borrow. Roughly 35 to 40 of Dhan's 80 federations are temptation to reported to be fully cost recovering. get into bulk funding Based on discussion with K. Narender, DHAN Foundation It has been pointed out that one factor driving federations towards provision of financial services is precisely this scope for cross-subsidization, and if grant funds were more readily available to finance their non-financial services, federations would more often resist the temptation to get into bulk funding. Another issue that arises therefore is whether there is a case for greater use of grant money to enable federations to undertake non-financial services without getting into bulk funding.19 However too much should not be made of the cross-subsidization benefits of bulk financing. Data contained in comments on this chapter received from PRADAN (Box 3.4) show how viability might be achieved without bulk borrowing but with assistance from economic activities. Some federations such as Shramik Bharti in UP have actually got out of bulk borrowing because they felt they were was losing sight of their objectives as peoples organizations, and are now facilitating direct linkages through the local banks.20 Several 56
  • 59. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? SHPAs promoting federations at a recent Sa-Dhan consultation on federations said that revenues from fees manage to pay for a substantial part of expenditures on training, accounting assistance, auditing and other support services offered by their federations21. Box 3.4 Making non-financial federations viable: PRADAN's experience Federations are needed to provide support to SHGs in maintaining quality by providing appropriate services. Groups are complicated phenomena, however small they are. It is not wise to expect them to survive on their own without support from some mechanism external to the group. That is where the peerage created through clusters and the federation comes into play. But then, clusters and federations are also groups. So we have to create an integrated prototype, with SHGs, clusters and the federation as the different levels, and a set of community resource persons housed in it. It has to be a financially sustainable model, the revenue being generated by different services that the different levels provide. The clusters and federation also need to evolve as independent entities of their own, each Federations are with a clear vision and agenda of its own. This evolves over a period of time. The clusters are needed to provide support for peer monitoring and learning, collective action at the local level and sharing resources at to SHGs in the local level when needed, such as a cluster accountant. The federation provides identity to maintaining the women, plays the role of a people's organization dealing with poor peoples' agenda, and quality by providing provides a set of services relevant to the SHGs - hosting the Computer Munshi, the MIS appropriate system, as many livelihood support services as can be managed, and building solidarity and services. Groups empowerment. Clusters and federations have to be built around the skills and resources of the are complicated phenomena, SHG women and not on that of the NGO professional. however small they are. It is If there are 200 SHGs and 3000 members in a federation, the income and expenditure will look not wise to like this expect them to survive on their 12 staff @ Rs 1500 per month - 12 months 216000 own without Computer Munshi - 2000 pm 24000 support from some mechanism Federation manager - 2000 pm 24000 external to the Stationery - 2000 pm 24000 group Admin - rent electricity, computer Maintenance etc - Rs 3000 pm 36000 Local travel @ Rs 2000 pm (board meeting monthly) 24000 Contingencies 10000 TOTAL 358000 This works out to about Rs 120 per member per year, which is on the high side. Thus the federation will have to get into livelihood support activities such as collective purchase of inputs or collective marketing which can earn it a surplus of about Rs 50-60 thousand, and can help maintain the member contribution at about Rs 100/- per member per year. In Kesla last year the federation mobilized a surplus of Rs 70000/- by trading in agri inputs. So it is possible. We can further reduce the member contribution by mobilizing grant funds if available, or building up a corpus from start up grants. The services that the member gets are regular group monitoring support, in situ training, periodic audit, MIS, and problem solving support. In addition to the Rs 100 contribution made to the federation by each member, the group pays the group accountant Rs 30 to 50 every month for writing accounts, from their interest surplus. We need to do more action research on this before we surmise anything… What we need are inputs from the behavioural 57
  • 60. sciences. They are the ones to can tell us about groups, group dynamics, and institutions etc. Action research is required with inputs not just from bankers and economists, and NGO- wallahs, but from people who understand groups from the most basic psychological, human processes point of view. Institutions are after not about services but about people.. One of the reasons PRADAN is against financial services by federations is because it requires a lot of sophistication to run a MFI especially when volumes are large, and it has to be done by professionals which introduces its own kind of information asymmetry. When finances are made available though the SBLP it does not make the women dependent on the professionals. At the same time, the women have other kinds of skills - political skills, skills of mobilizing, human skills, leadership skills etc. That is what needs to be used and nurtured, we are unnecessarily burdening the women by making them run MFIs. I would even go so far as to say that even if financial and non-financial services are unviable or ineffective, the empowerment benefits still make federations worthwhile I think it is even possible to have a viable organization only involved in empowerment related issues The question is - will people pay for empowerment and dignity? Intuitively yes. If people are willing to give up lives for such issues, surely they would pay 100 rupees a year to have an organization of their own which gives them an enhanced sense of dignity! But how do we bring it to life? There might be need to really look around for examples- there is a need to document some best cases from across the country in understanding these issues. Today we are all talking with very inadequate understanding of what is happening At least I am. Comments received from D Narendranath, PRADAN Financial services Bulk funding Bulk funding (of Among financial services, the most important one is clearly bulk funding.22 Bulk funding (of a a truly truly commercial nature)23 is driven by the prospect of scale economies for the lender and commercial nature) is greater access to funds by the borrower. Private banks (such as ICICI, HDFC ABN-AMRO, UTI,), driven by the wholesale lenders (HUDCO, FWWB, SIDBI, NABARD), public commercial banks (SBI, Canara Bank, prospect of scale Bank of India, Indian Bank and Bank of Maharashtra), RRBs, and Basix (through both its NBFC economies for and LAB) are all current or erstwhile lenders.24 The most recent phase of bulk lending to the lender and federations took place by private banks to NGO-promoted federations, mostly in AP. Lending by greater access to funds by the the public commercial banks took place mostly in Tamil Nadu to DHAN Foundation promoted borrower federations when DHAN Foundation was actively encouraging its federations to borrow. It has since changed its policy as discussed below, and has set up a S 25 company to centralize bulk borrowing, but only to supplement direct linkages in a "bridge financing" role. This is because the SBLP is now judged to have reached the stage where the argument for bulk borrowing (credit stringency) is no longer valid. Several other NGOs have recently set up similar S 25 companies to play the same role. Finally, there has been some nascent RRB lending to Village Organizations, the second-level tier in the IKP programme in AP, propelled largely by moral suasion from the state government. A documented example of bulk borrowing is an ICICI loan for SHGs in 19 MACS organized by Pragati Seva Samiti, an MFI in Warangal district, AP (described in Harper and Kirsten 2006). The loans to the SHGs, while more expensive than the loans the SHGs received when sourced 58
  • 61. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? from the local RRB, were for a larger amount, and part of the difference in price was offset by lower borrower transactions costs.25 The case does not provide information on the relative importance of the bulk funder as a source of loans as against direct linkages, if any. Some federations discourage or even prohibit constituent groups from borrowing directly from the banks, which are usually cheaper despite higher transactions costs. What should the policy be here? Another issue is the distribution of functions between various levels. Although many federations have three levels, in some cases the apex or intermediate level performs only non-financial or economic and social activities services so that the intermediating tiers are in effect only two. The distribution of the total spread between the various levels depends largely on the distribution of functions, respective staff complements, and which level pays for them. Thus in MARI, also in Warangal district and also a former CASHE partner, the MACS managers are paid for by the apex level and are transferable.26 MARI borrows in bulk from ICICI, on behalf of a district level apex, Sangatitha. A UTI loan was In a sense, the real test (for borrowed by Sangatitha directly. Accessed funds are on-lent at 16 percent to the MACS which the economies of on-lend to the SHGs at 19 percent. Kakatia Grameen Bank has made housing loans to the MACS scale argument) directly. Total membership is expected to grow to about 50,000 borrowers by March 2008, is whether banks with rural branch with loans outstanding of Rs 35 to 40 crores. The MACS are graded monthly according to networks such as certain parameters, have all been rated by APMAS, are audited annually, and there is an SBI see it as cheaper to make incentive component to field and HO staff pay. The average operational self-sufficiency (OSS) bulk loans to of all the MACSs was 149 percent in August 2006, and that of the Sangatitha, the district level federations apex, 118 percent. An urgent need (in this as in other federations) is the induction of one or rather than conduct direct more professionals at the apex level, for which the federation will have to be willing to pay the linkages going market rate.27 MACS promoted by the AP NGO, GRAM, are reported to be even larger than MARI's. Indur MACS promoted by GRAM has received convertible debt from Bellwether, the social venture capital fund.28 A third AP federation, Ankuram Sanghamam Poram (ASP), which borrows from the commercial banks29 constitutes in a sense a unique model for federations in AP because it is a state level federation, and was not promoted by any particular NGO, but grew out of the Dalit movement30. ASP is the subject of a detailed case study full of insights into the relationship between the three levels by Rewa Misra, who refers to it as "a massive combination of a trade union movement, a Dalit movement, and an NGO" (Misra 2007). ASP now has about 150,000 members at the base level and has received considerable grant funding from donors in view of its uniqueness. The case shows that while ASP absorbed the initial risks and costs associated with outreach to remote areas and marginalized communities, it is facing competition from new entrants at the primary level, and further growth will have to depend less on member loyalty than the ability to deliver timely and adequate loans. The sample SHGs in the case now have a choice of borrowing not just from the banks and IKP's Village Organizations, but some of them even belong to more than one federation (other than IKP).31 Bulk funding as we have seen has come so far mostly from the private banks who in the absence of extensive rural branch networks have an incentive to lend to SHGs through federations in order to meet their priority sector targets. Indeed, banks like HDFC have also been lending to urban SHGs through their federations, such as Roshan Vikas (Box 3.5) for the same reason. Seven private banks currently have loans outstanding to the largest bulk borrowing federation in the country, Sarvodaya Nano Finance Corporation.32 In a sense, the real test (for the economies 59
  • 62. of scale argument) is whether banks with rural branch networks such as SBI see it as cheaper to make bulk loans to federations rather than conduct direct linkages, and whether scale economies will ever offset the perception of higher risk in making say one Rs 50 lakh loan rather than 50 Rs one lakh loans. This test has not really been met yet, although there continue to be cases of public sector banks lending to federations, such as the recent cash- credit loan extended by the Bank of Maharashtra to Chaitanya in Maharashtra. As noted earlier, there has also been sporadic RRB lending to VOs in AP, especially in Mahbubnagar district where a concerted effort was made in 2005 at the urging of the IKP programme, to lend to VOs in accordance with guidelines issued few years ago by the Hyderabad office of NABARD. It was reported at a recent workshop on financing federations in AP that about 150 VOs have been financed in the district by several banks to the extent of about Rs 10 crores. While the workshop favoured the concept of lending to VOs, bankers urged the need to proceed cautiously as several VOs had been defaulting for more than a year. Among the prior steps necessary was a clear strategy for training raters, bankers, SHPI staff and federation leaders especially in VO financial management. Insurance is less The dominant trend currently is for mostly public sector banks to lend to S 25 companies being extensive among set up by SHPIs such as MYRADA, DHAN Foundation and several others, which lend directly to SHG members than MFI SHGs rather than to their federations. The first of these was Sanghamitra Rural Financial members. If this Services incorporated by MYRADA in 1995 (see Fernandez 2007) followed by Kalanjiam is because Development and Financial Services (KDFS), which was registered by DHAN in 2001. More individual SHGs are too small to recently CYSD has promoted Swayanshree Micro Credit Services in Orissa, with loans outstanding access insurance, to SHGs of Rs 7.5 crores in July 2007, borrowings from SBI and HDFC, and quasi-equity from federations would seem to offer an Bellwether, and SEARCH has set up KOPSA in Tamil Nadu33. opportunity to rectify the It is important to note that DHAN Foundation's rationale for centralizing bulk borrowing and situation. on-lending into a community owned but professionally managed S 25 company, was that Insurance is one service where building up truly member controlled federations with the specialized financial skills to manage large bulk borrowing was turning out to much more difficult than was originally anticipated and government- sponsored was taking an unacceptably long time. For the same capacity-related reasons, KDFS decided to federation lend directly to the groups and not to the federations. DHAN Foundation is very clear that programs should "KDFS needs to maintain its role and identity as an enabler, and for bridging the gap (in have an advantage, since direct linkage loans). It should guard against becoming another microfinance agency providing they can credit services." (DHAN Foundation 2004). aggregate huge numbers An important issue for both types of federations (non-financial as well as financial) is how high are promotional costs, and who is to bear them? Promotional costs have been borne so far (and continue to be borne)34 largely by donors, including international NGOs with an ideological leaning towards federations. One of the few estimates we have for promotion cost per SHG is for the DHAN foundation in Srinivasan 2005 ($150 to $200) and Nair 2005 (also about $150).35 Insurance A second increasingly important financial service is insurance36 According to EDA's evaluation of 20 SIDBI MFIs (EDA 2005), insurance is less extensive among SHG members than MFI members. If this is because individual SHGs are too small to access insurance, federations would seem to offer an opportunity to rectify the situation. Insurance is one service where large government-sponsored federation programs should have an advantage, since they can 60
  • 63. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? aggregate huge numbers. IKP is reported to have 1.8 million of its members insured. Banks too can play a useful role. Some banks such as Andhra Bank is reported to insist that 15 percent of its linkage loans be used to avail of insurance.37 An area calling for field investigation is how extensive insurance is through federations, how it is organized, and how it could it be increased. It should be noted though that insurance can be provided just as well by non- financial federations. Rotating liquidity between groups A third financial service is the movement of surplus funds from surplus to deficit SHGs, or what To the extent the option of is commonly referred to by practitioners as the "balancing" role. This liquidity balancing role depositing seems to be fairly common. At least two promoters in the Sa-Dhan consultation, Roshan Vikas surplus funds in (Box 3.5) and Chaitanya said their federations "balance" funds, as does ASP.38 To the extent a higher tier increases choice, the option of depositing surplus funds in a higher tier increases choice, and SHGs and MACS and SHGs and remain free to deposit them in the banks instead, the balancing role could be extremely useful MACS remain in well managed federations. Idle funds with SHGs crop up as a concern in many APMAS free to deposit them in the studies, but they seem to be a problem at the federation level too. It would be useful to banks instead, investigate why this is, if they can be routed to deficit SHGs. the balancing role could be extremely useful Facilitating linkages in well managed federations While we have already counted this service as non-financial, it could be regarded as financial if it is backed by guarantees from the higher tier. Federations often render assistance to new groups by helping banks appraise loan applications, and setting up counters at a bank on a fixed day of the week to assist groups with repayments and new applications. Federations and SHPI staff seek to improve their leverage with banks by promising exclusive banking relationships with them, and making deposits of their own idle/surplus funds. Again, except for providing guarantees, all these services can be provided by non-financial federations too. Savings services These too need to be studied and described in greater detail. Many federations require SHGs to share their monthly savings with the higher tier compulsorily (an example being Swayanshree described in Box 3.6) and many offer voluntary savings too (for instance Roshan Vikas, described in Box 3.5)39 Security deposits or margin money payments are also often required to be placed in the higher level on receipt of a loan, as in the case of MARI above. On the face of it a federation should be able to offer a higher rate on savings than a bank if it is intermediating to deficit units at lower cost or higher interest than the banks. An issue here is how much incremental savings take place as a result of a federation's savings service and how much of it represents diversion from bank savings. Another issue (discussed below) is that of appropriate regulation and supervision to ensure the safety of savings. Finally, some federations are reported to be offering pensions, such as some of those promoted by DHAN Foundation, although for most others this would seem a bit a bit futuristic. 61
  • 64. Box 3.5 Roshan Vikas: An urban SHG federation Roshan Vikas is an urban cooperative SHG federation operating in Hyderabad's old city, with plans to expand into roughly a third of the city's 40-50 municipal wards by 2010. It started off as a two-tier structure (SHGs federated into a ward level MACS) in the late 1990s, with an emphasis on linking its SHGs to health and other government programmes, but as its groups started accumulating idle funds it commenced the activity of inter-lending, or "balancing" funds, by paying surplus groups 12 percent on their deposits and lending them to deficit groups at 18 percent, at a 5:1 ratio on their savings (only those deposited with the federation or on total savings?). There was also a requirement that the SHGs, whether surplus or not, would pool 25 percent of their savings in RV for lending to deficit groups. In 2006 Roshan Vikas (RV) decided to augment the supply of loans to its groups by linking them to the banks, starting with a 3 year term loan of Rs 2.5 crores from HDFC Bank. To prepare for the large planned expansion into a number of new wards, it also decided to decentralize to a three-tier structure, with ward-level federations, also registered as MACS, taking on the accounting functions handled till now by RV. The HDFC loan, at 8 percent, which can be used for IG purposes only, reaches the SHGs at 14 percent, with each of RV and the ward federations taking a margin of 3 percent. Although documentation is prepared by the federation, the loan documents are signed directly with the groups at a gearing of 6 to 8 times of the group's surpluses. The groups (who on-lend at 24 percent) decide on the allocation of loans among members. Only about a fifth of the total membership have taken bank or federation loans, the rest being happy to take positions as net savers (the savings requirement is Rs 30 a month). Maximum loan size is Rs 50,000. Each accountant employed at the ward level visits up to 35 group meetings a month to help with the book-keeping, and returns with an audit report showing the group's latest position at the next monthly meeting. Group share capital in the ward level MACS is Rs 100 per member, and membership fees Rs 10 per member. The system of banking a minimum of 25 percent of savings with the higher tiers continues, with three-quarters going to the ward MACS and one-quarter going to RV. Group surpluses above this can be parked with RV in savings accounts, fixed deposits or recurring deposits. To meet the heavy demand for funds, and to have the flexibility to introduce new products such as housing and gold loans, RV is negotiating with several private banks to lend to RV directly. As a prelude to housing loans, RV is planning to assist members in registering their homes, with the cost being recovered as a loan. RV is functioning as a truly representative structure, and at the bottom level the SHGs are genuine autonomous SHGs. The loan is a single loan to the group with the SHG deciding who the loan should be given to, for what purposes, on what terms and with what schedule of recovery (bank loans are typically recovered in less than 36 months and recycled). As in the rural areas though, an SHG federation is less likely to reach down to the poorest of the urban poor as compared to an MFI that can target the poor actively it wants to (SHGs are in theory at least self-selected). Members would seem to enjoy more empowerment than in urban MFIs using JLGs, however, through opportunities to participate in the federation structure. Based on discussion with Mohd Kareem, Roshan Vikas 62
  • 65. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? Box 3.6 Swayanshree at the crossroads: To borrow or to facilitate direct linkages? Swayanshree, a member owned and controlled but professionally managed urban federation serving the slums of Cuttack, has grown steadily over the last 12 years to attain its present size of almost 9000 members distributed over 670 SHGs and 80 JLGs. The primary groups are clustered into zonal bodies each of which elects a director to the governing body. On joining the federation an SHG pays Rs 100 per member as share capital, Rs 10 as membership fees and Rs 20 to go into a fund to provide legal services to members in cases of domestic violence, dowry deaths and other forms of gender discrimination. SHG members save an average of Rs 40 a month, Rs 30 of which goes to the federation to fund various loan products and Rs 10 of which remains in the SHG to fund emergency loans. Until 2006 the federation had idle funds, partly on account of grant funds received to subsidize operational funds from the CASHE project. But by 2007, with the general process of urban growth, the termination of CASHE, an increase in the maximum loans granted for various purposes and a decrease in the interest rate on loans from 24 to 18 percent, loan demand began to exceed the supply. In response to increasing loan demand from non-members Swayanshree also started organizing 5 member JLGs, whose members have to save only Rs 10 per month and can start borrowing immediately (although at a higher interest than older SHG members) without going through the mandatory 6 months savings requirement for SHGs. Swayanshree is faced with an important strategic decision. Should it meet growing loan demand by encouraging member SHGs to borrow from the banks, and facilitating the process by assisting in loan appraisal and monitoring for a fee, or should it start bulk borrowing on its own account to on-lend to member SHGs and JLGs. The banks have become much more interested in the last year or so in lending to urban SHGs (although not to JLGs). Thus SBI recently made loans to four SHGs, and like some other private banks HDFC Bank is willing to lend to them along the same lines it lends to Roshan Vikas in Hyderabad (see Box 3) HDFC is willing to share 3 percent with Swayanshree out of the 12 percent loans it proposes to charge SHGs. However it does want a letter of comfort from Swayanshree backing the loans. Swayanshree is inclined to prefer the alternative of borrowing itself from the banks and organizations like Swayanshree MCS, the S 25 company, since it stands to earn more from the intermediation margin (of about 6 percent) in on-lending to SHGs, and more in the case of JLGs. It will be interesting to see which way it goes, and why. Based on discussion with Nayana Mohanty, Swayanshree Social and economic activities A seemingly huge variety of social and economic activities and services are being undertaken by federations in AP, some of them described in Box 3.1, and increasingly in other states, and it would be useful to categorize them meaningfully and identify issues with respect to each of them that need to be looked into further. Among economic activities and services being undertaken by federations (some of them as agents, others on own behalf) are foodgrain procurement, marketing, input supply, ration shops, other retailing, food security activities such as grain banks, works under the watershed programme, preparing mid-day meals Second, potentially at least, federations provide a forum for viably aggregating business development services for livelihood promotion and microfinance plus activities (such as veterinary care, skills training, 63
  • 66. marketing support, milk chilling plants, design up-gradation in e.g. crafts activities, etc). Social services include distribution of pensions and payments under the rural employment guarantee scheme, running crèches, supervising the implementation of social programmes, participating in health education, sanitation, drinking water, nutrition and family planning activities and serving as a conduit for development information generally. A fourth set of activities relates to social causes and advocacy relating to domestic violence, alcoholism, child labour, gender sensitization etc. A fifth entails political participation and representation activities, both formally through the gram panchayat and higher level echelon elections, and informally by constituting a pro-poor pressure group for rights and entitlements. The processes The processes and dynamics through which "empowerment" accrues through participation in and dynamics these activities is still only hazily understood and needs to be researched further. However through which "empowerment" SHG federations constitute an important vehicle for promoting grass-roots democracy and accrues through participation, and for the women themselves a vehicle for experiencing and asserting a much participation in these activities stronger collective identity and solidarity. They have led to the emergence a new kind of elite is still only in rural Andhra Pradesh, who have been given an opportunity "to elect, be elected, make hazily policies and take decisions" (Misra 2007).40 A less benign political effect of federations is understood and needs to be that they have become a potential vote bloc and an attractive target of "capture" by political researched parties through inducements and subsidies, including credit subsidies as in AP's pavla vaddi further. However SHG federations scheme. It would be interesting to look at the effects these are having, quite apart from their constitute an cost.41 Thus there is anecdotal evidence that hitherto defunct groups of the non-poor are important getting revived in order to avail of the pavla vadi scheme.42 vehicle for promoting grass- roots democracy Another issue is the interplay between this third category of functions of federations (economic and and social activities) and the first two. It has been pointed out that they can pre-empt scarce participation, and for the managerial talent and energy to the detriment of the first two functions (the provision of women financial and non-financial services). Is this true, or do they more often enhance the skills themselves a and sense of ownership that strengthens those functions too, increasing credit absorption vehicle for experiencing and capacity and repayment discipline? Also, activities like bulk purchase have in cases contributed asserting a much revenue to pay for non-financial support services (an example of which is contained in stronger Box 3.4). On the other hand, unless all the groups in a federation participate in an economic collective identity and activity equally, losses can put non-participating (or reluctantly participating) groups at risk. solidarity A related issue is whether federations should first focus on achieving institutional and financial viability before branching into economic activities?43 Regulation and supervision SHG federations registered as MACS have become important players in the sector in AP, where the two tiers of SHG federations at the mandal and village level, have either already been, or are slated to be, registered as MACS (Chapter 9). In Orissa panchayat level federations are being registered under the The Orissa Self Help Cooperatives Act (the equivalent of the MACS act in the state).44 Tamil Nadu does not have a parallel cooperative law, where panchayat and block level federations are being registered as societies. The MACS Act was a major step towards building more member owned and accountable institutions. However, the new microfinance bill is proposing to supplant the registrars of cooperative societies, whether under the new or old acts, by a new regulator, NABARD, for the 64
  • 67. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? regulation of thrift services. There is some question whether federations (the two tiers above ... it will become all the the SHG level) fall within the purview of the bill. Chapter 9 argues that it would seem more more important practicable (and certainly more in accordance of the spirit of cooperation) for the bill to leave for the states to energize their out cooperatives altogether, whether thrift cooperatives at the primary level or their federations. state registrars, If the bill is amended accordingly, and even it is not, if it is clarified that federations do not and ensure they fall under its purview, it will become all the more important for the states to energize their carry out their supervisory state registrars, and ensure they carry out their supervisory obligations towards cooperative obligations thrift societies, whether primary or higher level, much more diligently. At present, according towards to one observer, the relationship of most federations with the MACS act ends as soon as they cooperative thrift societies, have been registered, and they simply exist in the books of the district registrar.45 whether primary or higher level, A second alternative is for MACS conducting microfinance to set up a system of self-regulation, much more diligently a possible solution being studied by APMAS, with the right to suspend, merge or close non- compliant federations to be vested in a state-level body. A third solution is much stronger self-supervision by federations themselves. However this requires a foundation of strong management and record keeping. Some of the difficulties that stand in the way of relying entirely on more effective self-supervision especially in large state-wide federations such as ASP are (i) the high cost of on-site supervision (ii) the lack of stringent standards (iii) relatively weak staff capacity (iv) the lack of regular rating and (v) good book-keeping. The difficulties may be a little less intractable for smaller federations, but are still formidable. A combination of all three alternatives (energizing the registrars, self-regulation by the microfinance MACS community, and stronger self-supervision) is likely to be required. Conclusion In stating a preference for the non-financial over the financial role of federations it is not the intention of this chapter to be prescriptive. Despite the expansion of the SBLP there may well be circumstances and areas where financial federations are called for, and not just because the SHG women themselves "want their own bank" as is often claimed by promoters. Such areas will generally have a higher demand for credit than the SBLP can satisfy, unlike areas where the carrying capacity of the community is low, as in tribal belts, dry and rain fed farming areas. They could also be areas where the demand for credit is high but branch branches are sparsely distributed, as in the northern hill states. Also, in using a three fold classification of functions for analytical reasons it is not being implied that federations must choose between one or the other. Thus non-financial support services aimed at enhancing SHG quality can, and usually are, combined with activities from the third category from very inception, such as addressing gender and other social issues, accessing and seeking convergence for members of ongoing government programmes, and perhaps providing what are referred to in the jargon as "business development services" or BDS. As Girija Srinivasan points out,46 federation building needs to be carefully sequenced, with each phase responding to a real need, and carefully monitored. The first stage is social mobilisation of groups, providing non financial services, and institutionalising the fee-for- services concept. After 3 or 4 years the federation could intensify the provision of BDS in order to improve credit absorption capacity, as well as introduce specialised bulk loans for housing, etc. which are not catered to by SBLP. Finally, after 5 or 6 years it could start 65
  • 68. Endnotes 1 The purpose of this chapter is to raise issues, stimulate discussion, and suggest further field work and case studies. Given limitations of space the issues discussed are mainly policy issues centering on the problem of financial sustainability, since there is some existing literature on institutional sustainability issues (governance, representative structure, systems, training, number of levels, the distribution of functions between levels etc) as well as what were referred to as "non-negotiables" at two workshops held in December 2002 and June 2003, based on an extensive Sa-Dhan study of 27 federations Examples of these are (i) promotion of federations should be process rather than blue-print oriented, (ii) it should be undertaken only after strong primaries are in place and (iii) should add value without competing with the primaries (Sa-Dhan 2004). The study categorized federations into four quadrants depending on the whether they were member of promoter controlled, and whether they offered only microfinance or microfinance "plus", that is, also social and livelihood interventions. The consensus was that federations with an internal locus of control and microfinance plus had the best chance of developing into true institutions of the poor. A financial analysis of 7 out of the 27 federations in the study by Ramesh Arunachalam found that from the point of view of financial sustainability however, federations with high member control but offering microfinance only had the highest sustainability (because they relied primarily on member savings, a low cost source capital, had lean organizational structures, good asset quality, and minimal idle cash). Unfortunately this was the last nationwide empirical study based on extensive field work. More recent documents include Sa-Dhan, 2004, and several APMAS's quality assessment reports, the latest being APMAS 2006. One of the best shorter studies on federations remains that Ajai Nair 2005 and for a highly readable account of the history and rationale of the federation movement in Tamil Nadu, full of practical programmatic detail, Gariyali 2007. I am grateful to CS Reddy, LB Prakash, Girija Srinivasan, and the participants at the Sa-Dhan consultation in Delhi on May 30, 2007 for useful discussions and comments. 2 Thus IFAD, UNDP and the World Bank have all promoted federations, as have bilateral donors such as DFID though the CASHE project. The World Bank is reported to be preparing further projects. containing federations for Bihar, Jharkhand and the Northeast. 3 Some donors and international NGOs with an interest in federations are NOVIB, HIVOS, Christian Aid, and CRS. 4 More than the programme in other states, Kudumashree emphasizes collective as well as individual activities, and convergence with government services. 5 These areas, ironically, tend to be those where the SBLP is longest established, since the demand for credit is probably correlated with the presence of good promoting NGOs, both of them being associated with the general state of development, and largely explaining the regional skew of the SBLP. 6 Some of the the leading NGO federation promoters have been PRADAN, DHAN Foundation, MYRADA, CDS, SEWA, PREM, Chaitanya, Gram Vikas, ASA, and YCO. 7 As a further example, the Tamil Nadu Corporation for the Development of Women (TNCDW) sponsors urban federations at the ward level, and AP is piloting them too (for an example see Box 5). 66
  • 69. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? 8 Thus, in AP most of the 29,000 federations (estimated at the time) belong to the World Bank-assisted IKP programme's three tier federation structure. Tamil Nadu's 14104 federations consist mostly of the 12527 panchayat level federations that were formed under the leadership of the TN Corportation for the Development of Women in accordance with orders issued by the state government in 2002. Till 2000 there were only 645 cluster level federations in Tamil Nadu that had been set up under an IFAD sponsored project (Gariyali 2007). Similarly, the 5429 federations reported from Orissa in the estimate consist of panchayat and block level federations set up under Mission Shakti. Their number has now gone up to 6278 (March 2007) or 95 percent of the total number of panchayats and blocks. As in Tamil Nadu, most of these have yet to be registered, and are still inactive. The numbers for two other states, Kerala and West Bengal have already been mentioned above. 9 There is consensus that the focus should be on the constituent SHGs, whose interests the federations should always serve rather than the other way round, although best practice towards the goal of federation systems being self-managed is still evolving. The situation is one of a thousand flowers blooming, which is what makes the field particularly fascinating, but also challenging to document and distill lessons from. 10 Many of these are discussed in the Chapter 2 of last year's report. APMAS 2005 finds a disquieting tendency for SHGs to deteriorate with age. Of concern is the apparent tendency of the doctor to succumb to the same desease - APMAS 2006 finds that federations too generally weaken with age. 11 Such as data transmission by mobile phones to a centralized MIS being developed by Ekgaon Technologies ( Chapter 8), etc. 12 Indeed CMRCs provide representation to federations in their area along with other CBOs, and the Computer Munshi system uses cluster level federations to discuss monthly trial balances of member groups (see Box 2.1 of last year's report). 13 G stands for governance, R for resources, A for asset quality, D for design of systems, E for efficiency and profitability, and S for services to member SHGs and their performance. Only 3.6 percent of the federations assessed were providing quality services overall, of which only 17 percent were providing quality support services as against 93 percent providing quality financial services (APMAS 2006). 14 We use the term bulk borrowing in this chapter to distinguish outside borrowing from collecting and lending out savings within the federation, although the latter term is usually used as a generic term that covers both. 15 A fourth source of income is Rs 500 charged numerous visitors from nearby Delhi! 16 Sakhi Suvidha is reported to be the most profitable of the four federations studied in Part I of CGAP 2007. 17 See Rajagopalan 2004, but she has written many other discussion papers available unfortunately only in mimeo form. 18 For semantic purposes, the distinction between an MFI lending through SHGs on one the one hand, and a federation accessing bulk funds on the other, would seem to lie in whether the institution has at least one layer of autonomous organizations above the SHG. If the institution accesses bulk funds to lend directly to SHGs it should be regarded as an MFI, but if it has autonomous secondaries even if they provide only support services or undertake social and economic activities, the institution should be 67
  • 70. regarded as a federation, even if loan funds flow directly from the apex to the SHGs as is sometimes the case. On this definition SNFL would be defined as a federation rather than an MFI. 19 Some questions of interest are how much grant money is already available under the major programmes (state womens' development corporations, DRDAs, Velugu, Swashakti, etc and how well is the money being used? NGO-promoted SHGs in AP used to pay for accounting services directly. Now that many of them have joined Velugu, and their accountants have become "government" employees, are the latter as conscientious? 20 It has paid off its former bulk lenders such as SIDBI, HUDCO and RMK (Rakesh Kumar Pandey at the Sa- Dhan consultation, see endnote 1). It is hopeful that its federations will be able to recover their accounting-support, auditing and account-book costs through fees, and is planning to introduce the Computer Munshi system, and get into livelihood support once the federations have been strengthened further. Many federations have scaled down the financial intermediation role. Other federations that are reported to have scaled down financial intermediation are those that have been promoted by SSP in Mahrashtra, and by CCD in Tamil Nadu. 21 PRADAN said that in Jharkhand, its federations manage to recover the entire cost (approximately Rs 75 per member a year) either through a once-a-year contribution per member or in installments over the year. Box 4 contains a slightly higher estimate. Participants pointed out however that grant money played a crucial role initially, although it was often inherited from previous programme activities, such as grants for revolving funds, watershed development and health. 22 We use the term bulk funding to distinguish it from the broader term financial intermediation because the latter includes borrowing from members. Bulk funding is of course indirectly intermediating the savings of savers in the formal sector. Of the 129 MFIs covered by Sa-Dhan's Quick Report, 21 were MACS with 1.6 percent of the total number of borrowers, and 4 of them cooperatives not registered as MACS (such as Sewa Bank), with 3.9 percent. In addition, many federations are registered as societies rather than cooperatives, such as those in Tamil Nadu. The Quick Report contains data on borrowings for each MFI. 23 Commercial, as opposed to donor funding of on-lending funds such as Velugu's Community Investment Fund, or CASHE's revolving fund, which has now been inherited by ACCESS to support their incubation of new MFIs. 24 However there is no estimate of total lending to federations. 25 In the case of direct linkages, all the SHG members had to travel to the Kakatiya Grameen Bank to collect their loans, costing them bus fares as well as lost wages. The Grameen Bank also conducted bulk lending to the groups, and the groups received these loans at 18 percent. The case does not include information on margins retained by the MACS and PSS, or say whether any deposits had to be made by the SHGs in the MACS and by the MACS in PSS to fund the deposit of 15 percent of the loan amount PSS had to make as an FLDG deposit with ICICI earning 5.5 percent interest. 26 The pros and cons of this arrangement - better control over possible malfeasance at the MACS level but less autonomy for the MAC - also need to be analyzed. 27 A topic that generates much heat in sector conclaves is the need to manage the relationship between professionals and the representative governance structure sensitively. The following comment received on this chapter is frequently heard. "Another very frustrating observation I have made during my field 68
  • 71. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? visits and interactions with promoting agencies' staff and federation leaders is that most of the time professionals who manage the entire show on behalf of federations are too intimidating, over-powering, and lack sensitivity and patience. They are unable to understand the limitations and unique strengths of these women. As a result, the vibrant leaders of federations are reduced to good accountants and obedient workers of promoting agencies. Given a choice, federation leaders would not like to go through that route …in most cases it is the promoting agencies' agenda that push federations into a provider role. Given a choice, women would like to keep out of this game. Federations might have proved their utility for the promoting agency, but we need to check whether the same applies when it comes to SHGs." The view taken here is that if the relationship is successfully managed (and it can be) a community based institution can be community or member owned without necessarily having to be entirely community managed. The best known example is AMUL, and among federations, SIFFS, a federation of fishermen's cooperatives, and SNFL, both in Tamil Nadu. 28 This is something of a first. An equity investment is ruled out however by the cooperative principle of one man one vote. 29 Currently, Syndicate Bank, ICICI,Canara Bank and the State Bank of Hyderabad. 30 Apart from NGO-promoted federations and ASP, the third federation model in AP is the ubiquitous IKP, which does not borrow from the banks but does on-lend Community Investment Funds (CIF) it has received from the World Bank. These funds are on-lent down the three tier structure with each tier earning a margin. Finally there is the well-known fourth model in AP of the two tier federations of thrift cooperatives, also in Warangal district, promoted by CDF (Chapter 9). This however is a special case since the primaries here are not SHGs but much larger thrift cooperatives or in effect credit unions, with credit activities funded almost entirely by savings and with little outside borrowing as a matter of philosophy. 31 ASP's operational sustainability is only 25 percent, partly because of the relatively large staff required to support state wide operations, and also because in keeping with its respect for the autonomy of each level, ASP's relationship with member MACS is loosely defined. Its strategic plan lays down that "the standardization of systems and procedures that are required for taking advantages of economies of scale will be realized through processes of consensus building" (Misra 2007). 32 SNFL is in a sense a unique case since it is an NBFC at the apex level which on-lends to federations registered as mutual benefit trusts at the secondary level. Although the CEO and two board members of each MBT are appointed by the apex, they otherwise enjoy substantial autonomy, and the apex itself is owned by the MBTs. Thus SNFL is professionally managed but community owned. It is the largest federation in India, with loans outstanding of Rs 64 crores in March 2007 and an outreach of 126,000 SHG members organized in 25140 SHGs belonging to 108 MBTs in six states. 33 KOPSA, in three districts of Tamil Nadu, borrows from SBI at 8 percent and on-lends at 12 percent, directly to SHG groups. It also has a loan from ING Vysya Bank. 34 For instance in the new World Bank IKP-type project in Bihar. 35 Presumably this includes the historical costs that were incurred on promoting the individual SHGs. Ultimately it is the total promotional cost at both levels that is relevant. Federations, once formed, offer the prospect of bringing down the average cost per SHG formed as they get into the business of promoting new SHGs themselves. 69
  • 72. 36 It is usually provided by the federation as an agent for an insurance company, but sometimes also through the in-house model, as with life and health insurance in DHAN, although DHAN kalanjiams are reported to be switching to the former model, at least for life insurance (Chapter 5A of last year's report). 37 The commission payment of 20 percent of the premium payable to the agent is an incentive to the banks. 38 However, it is only the apex that balances the surpluses of its MACS, since SHG prefer the safety of depositing their funds in the banks or leaving them idle. 39 The distinction between the liquidity balancing and savings services role can be thought of as the former applying only to group as opposed to individual savings, and being shorter term. 40 She points out also that new elites can fall into old habits, leading to issues of elite domination at the second tier, dominating the agenda at general assemblies, "deciding which entitlements and schemes to opt for, which members to pull up for non repayment and which loans to sanction without any form of active engagement even with the SHG leaders". 41 Assuming an interest subsidy of 9 percent (the bank rate minus the pavla vadi rate of 3 percent) on about Rs 3500 crores of loans outstanding in AP in March 2007 (or 60 percent of cumulative disbursements of Rs 5889 crores using the assumptions discussed in Chapter 2), the bill to the state government could come to Rs 300 crores at current levels of lending. 42 At the Microfinance India conference in October 2006, a Rajya Sabha member from Orissa credited the SHG programme for getting his party re-elected in the last elections. 43 Economic, because social activities do not preempt scarce skills to the same extent. 44 The Orissa act allows membership to the primaries or SHGs unlike the AP MACS Act which only allows membership to individuals or cooperatives, so that SHGs have to be represented by representatives acting formally in an individual capacity. This is the reason DHAN Foundation prefers to register federations as societies or trusts. 45 As Rama Reddy points out "Neither the SHG Federation, nor the promoting GO, nor the promoting NGO, nor the registering DCO is interested in the functioning of the village organisation as a Macs cooperative. They do not need any supervision and/or regulation since they themselves are part and parcel of the governmental organisations or of the non-governmental organisations. On the one hand, as a policy, the State Government is interested in getting village organisations registered as macs cooperatives and on the other hand, again as a matter of policy, the same government puts a ban on the registration of citizen-promoted genuine thrift cooperatives and dairy cooperatives under the Macs Act" (Personal communication). 46 This paragraph is based on comments received from Girija Srinivasan. 70
  • 73. CHAPTER 3 SHG Federations: Financiers or Nurturers? References APMAS, 2006, "Status of SHG Federations in Andhra Pradesh: Quality Assessment:2nd Report", Hyderabad Christen, Bob, and Guatam Ivatury, 2005, "A Systemic View of the SHG Bank-Linkage System: Four Sustainable Models" paper presented at World Bank conference in New Delhi, December CGAP, 2007, Sustainability of Self-Help Groups in India: Two Analyses" Occasional Paper, World Bank, DC Dhan Foundation, 2004, "Catalysing Linkages: SHGs and Banks: the KDFS Experience 2001- 2004". DHAN Foundation, 2005, "Impacting Urban Poverty Through Microfinance: The SPMS Experience", DHAN Foundation, Madurai. EDA Rural Systems, 2005, "The Maturing of Indian Microfinance", study done for SIDBI, Gurgaon Fernandez, Aloysius, 207, "A Microfinance Institution with a Difference", Economic and Political Weekly, March 31, Mumbai Gariyali, CK, 2007, "Climbing Higher: Federations of Women Self-Help Groups at the Panchayat Level", Vetri Publications, New Delhi Harper, Malcolm and Marie Kirsten 2006 "ICICI Bank and microfinance linkages in India", Small Enterprise Development, Volume 17, Number 1, March. Misra, Rewa, 2007, "Case of Mutually Aided Cooperative Societies, India: SHG federations as a model for remote outreach of financial services", study commissioned by Ford Foundation, Coady International Institute, Antigonish, NS Nair, Ajay, 2005, "Sustainability of Microfinance Self-Help Groups in India: Would Federating Help", Policy Working Research Paper 3516, South Asia Region, Finance and Private Sector Development Unit, World Bank, D.C. Rajagopalan, Shashi, 2004, "Do federations have a role in financial intermediation?", paper written for "Microfinance India 2008" conference, 24-26 February, New Delhi Ramesh, Jairam, 2007, "The SHG Revolution: What Next?, Silver Jubilee Lecture at the Society for the Promotion of Wastelands Development, New Delhi, May 5, Reddy, CS, N Tirupathaiah, and S Ramalakshmi, 2007, "Emerging SHG Federations and Challenges", International Conference on Andhra Pradesh Experience with Member-Based Organizations of the Poor, Mimeo, CESS, Hyderabad, June 5-6. Sa-Dhan, 2004, "SHG Federations in India: Emerging Structures and Practices" Srinivasan, R, 2005, "Canara Bank, Allanganallur branch, Madurai district, Tamil Nadu, India" in Harper and Arora, eds. "Small Customers, Big Markets:Commercial Banks in Microfinance", Practical Action Group, London. Vasimalai, MP, and K Narender, 2007, "Microfinance for Poverty Reduction: the Kalanjiam Way", Economic and Political Weekly, March 31, 2007. 71
  • 74. 72
  • 75. CHAPTER 4 MFI Performance: Efficiency with Growth CHAPTER 4 MFI Performance: Efficiency with Growth Sanjay Sinha1 Overview The past two years have seen a series of critical developments in the Indian MFI sector. These The past two are both positive and negative. On the positive side, MFIs have started to leverage their new years have seen a series of found management expertise to achieve scale and to spread their operations well beyond their critical traditional operational areas. Thus, rating data from a large sample of the leading MFIs shows developments in the Indian MFI that these have recorded high growth rates of the order of 80% per annum in terms of sector. These numbers of borrowers and around 40% per annum in terms of portfolio reaching from 300,000 are both to one million clients each. Also positive is that a significant part of that expansion has been positive and negative. On either to less developed areas of the country - Orissa, Jharkhand, Rajasthan, Madhya Pradesh, the positive Tripura, Assam - or to areas such as Maharashtra that also have substantial numbers of low side, MFIs have started to income families in some regions even if their overall development indicators are not as low as leverage their those for the other states. new found management On the negative side, MFIs have been under attack from politicians and bureaucrats in some expertise to achieve scale of their traditional operational areas in Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka (with questions even and to spread being asked in Orissa). Their loan recovery practices have been questioned and their interest their operations well beyond rates described as exorbitant. The related publicity has vitiated the credit culture in the their traditional traditional microfinance states forcing a lowering of interest rates and increasing the necessary operational level of loan loss reserves and provisioning. Operationally, the increase in costs has been areas compounded by the spread of the operations of individual MFIs simultaneously (and inorganically) to a number of non-traditional states. This has put pressure on operating efficiency and resulted in slowing the trend to lowering unit costs. The growth of the microfinance sector has been fuelled by continuing interest from banks in increasing their exposure to microfinance resulting in a highly leveraged industry with capital adequacy ratios down below 10% and debt-to-equity ratios of the order of 11:1. Given the pressure on margins (which has already reduced the collective return on assets of the sector to negligible, if still positive, levels) it is unclear for how long such high leverage ratios can be sustained. The increased coverage of clients made possible by the high growth rates of Indian MFIs is laudable. Even as it increases outreach, the industry continues to be amongst the most 73
  • 76. efficient in the world. But, high growth brings with it possible dangers of mission drift as many MFIs emphasise commercial behaviour and may not strategically balance this with their original social mission, or with social values expected in microfinance. As the discussion in this chapter and that on social rating shows, it is apparent that while MFIs have learnt much in terms of operational efficiency a substantial effort is required in the areas of clarifying social objectives, poverty targeting, product development and client orientation. The challenge for MFIs over the next few years is to achieve growth with equity as well as efficiency. This chapter presents a summary analysis of the information obtained by M-CRIL during its ratings of 58 Indian MFIs over the 18 month period January 2006 to June 2007. The overview of the performance of Indian MFIs emerging from this analysis is placed in perspective by a comparison with the benchmarks emerging from the database of the MIX's latest set of 37 reporting MFIs (for March 2007). The India Microfinance Review, published separately by M-CRIL and the MIX, presents the detailed analysis. 1 Characteristics of MFIs covered by this analysis By and large, Regionally, this analysis provides a comprehensive picture of microfinance in India. The however, Indian MFIs have been samples used contain a large number of MFIs from South India. innovating, experimenting This is de facto recognition of the fact that South India MFIs provide a substantial portion of with and client coverage in Indian microfinance. Table 4.1 presents a broad regional analysis of the growing out of the samples. conventional mould of SHG and Grameen Table 4.1 Regional distribution of Indian MFIs rated by M-CRIL operations, to cater to the Regions M-CRIL MFIs Update MIX dataset needs of their sample markets more Rated Sample % of sample 2005-06 2006-07 effectively South 27 24 24 18 (62%) 28 24 (64.9%) East & NE 24 20 20 8 (28%) 8 10 (27.0%) West 10 6 6 1 (3%) 0 1 (2.7%) North 11 8 8 2 (7%) 2 2 (5.4%) India 72 58 58 29 (100%) 38 37 (100.0%) There are many SHG-based microfinance programmes but, in recent years, most of the new MFIs have been established using the Grameen model. There has been a tendency for MFIs increasingly to adopt the Grameen model since this is seen by many as a means of accelerating their growth and progress towards sustainability. By and large, however, Indian MFIs have been innovating, experimenting with and growing out of the conventional mould of SHG and Grameen operations, to cater to the needs of their markets more effectively. The distribution of sample Indian MFIs based on microfinance models is shown in Table 4.2. This distribution is a broad reflection of the pattern of microfinance undertaken through microfinance institutions (as opposed to the SHG-bank linkage programme) in India. 74
  • 77. CHAPTER 4 MFI Performance: Efficiency with Growth Table 4.2 Distribution of sample Indian MFIs by microfinance model Models M-CRIL Sample MIX dataset 2005 2007 Top 10 Updates 2005-06 2006-07 G 19 23 7 16 19 21 IB 15 8 1 6 14 15 SHG 50 27 2 10 25 21 Total MFIs 84 58 10 32 38 37 Though there is a trend, India-wide, towards for-profit and formal registration of MFIs as finance companies, not-for-profit institutions continue to dominate by numbers of organisations in the provision of microfinance services. Table 4.3 shows the distribution of sample MFIs across legal forms. The 15 for-profit companies in the M-CRIL sample of 58 includes 5 institutions that were still registered as not-for-profit institutions (when rated) but are either in the process of transforming or have already transformed to companies (at the time of writing). Of the 10 best institutions selected for the purpose of comparison with the overall sample, There are relatively few just two in this group have been replaced since the last review. However, while earlier six of MFIs in the the 10 were non-bank finance companies (NBFCs), all but one of the Top 10 MFIs in India is West. Grameen now legally registered as such. MFIs with over 130,000 clients each are the largest in the Table 4.3 Distribution of sample MFIs by legal form country and Form of registration M-CRIL Top 10 MIX, 2006 together serve over 50% of Not-for-profit the total number of societies & trusts 34 1 22 clients covered Cooperatives 4 1 Section 25 companies 5 2 Non-bank finance companies/bank 15 9 12 Total MFIs 58 10 37 2 Client outreach & services The microfinance outreach of sample MFIs amounts to some 5.6 million clients (M-CRIL, September 2006) to 6.6 million clients (for the MIX dataset, March 2007). Around three- quarters of these are based in South India and another 20% in the East. Most of the remainder are in North India. There are relatively few MFIs in the West. Grameen MFIs with over 130,000 clients each are the largest in the country and together serve over 50% of the total number of clients covered. Though extensive government support for SHG programmes has resulted in the establishment of a large number of MFIs using the SHG methodology, these are around half the size of Grameen MFIs and, as a result, provide outreach to only about one-third of the total number of clients covered (Figure 4.1). From the perspective of the legal framework, the proposed new microfinance law does not cover nearly 80% of these clients since 73% are 75
  • 78. served by NBFCs (or MFIs on the verge of transformation to NBFCs) and another 6% by Section 25 (not-for-proft) companies. Such institutions fall outside the ambit of the proposed law. Figure 4.1 Membership of sample MFIs (a)…by microfinance methodology (b) …by legal form Indian MFIs have minuscule outstandings Rs3,400 ($82) compared to the international average Rs19,200 ($468) and has not grown over the past couple of years. The Grameen clients have the smallest loan balances Rs2,700 ($65). This has happened despite a high growth rate of MFI portfolios (40%) because client outreach has expanded even faster (84%). Large numbers of new MFI clients inevitably means small loan sizes. At an average loan balance that is just 9.9% of GNI per capita, depth of outreach is apparently substantial. However, field experience shows that significant numbers of not-so-poor women join microfinance groups - often for social reasons - so the loan balance-GNI ratio is not a good indicator of poverty outreach (at least for India). A highly restrictive legal framework for deposit taking has severely constrained the offering of thrift services so client savings form just 8.1% of outstanding loan balances. As Figure 4.2 indicates, all the methodologies have low average savings per member except for the individual banking model. Each of the bars reflects the nature of the methodologies and the legal framework in which the organisations operate. 76
  • 79. CHAPTER 4 MFI Performance: Efficiency with Growth Figure 4.2 Average savings per member by model, Rupees SHG programmes, usually have voluntary deposit schemes in which the members themselves Staff determine the amount of the recurring savings deposit. Since disposition of this amount is productivity in India is now determined by the group rather than by the individual saver, this often results in minimalist higher than in norms and leads to deposits that are far lower than the members' savings potential. Deposits any other major region offering form just 4.0% of the average SHG MFIs' portfolio, though (as indicated earlier) this excludes microfinance. the far larger amounts revolved internally by SHG members.2 Some 326 staff members per MFI serve over 3 Operating efficiency & portfolio quality 230 borrowers each while the Staff productivity in India is now higher than in any other major region offering microfinance. leading MFIs average 275 Some 326 staff members per MFI serve over 230 borrowers each while the leading MFIs average borrowers per 275 borrowers per member of staff. This results in some of the lowest servicing costs for MFIs member of staff. This anywhere in the world. Both Grameen and SHG MFIs record average servicing costs of the results in some order of Rs400 ($10) per borrower, lower than the MIX median even for Bangladesh. As MFIs of the lowest have grown and staff productivity has increased over the years, servicing costs have come servicing costs for MFIs down even in nominal terms. With an inflation rate averaging 5% per annum in the mid- anywhere in the 2000s, this has resulted in a decline of around 9% per annum in the cost of servicing borrowers. world Indian MFIs are now amongst the most efficient internationally. At 15.9% the average operating expense ratio (Table 4.4) has not changed much since the 2005 Review as growth focussed MFIs have accepted higher travel and other costs, while productivity gains have also been neutralised by lower loan balances, hence smaller portfolios serviced per member of staff, in real terms. OERs reported by Indian MFIs are, nevertheless, lower than those of MFIs in Bangladesh and significantly lower than the medians for Asian and other MFIs worldwide. 77
  • 80. Table 4.4 Operating expense ratios of Indian MFIs Model Weighted Typical MFI Operating Expense Ratio Total no. average (%) (%) <10% 10-15% 15-25% >25% of MFIs G 16.7 16.4 4 8 6 3 21 IB 20.5 24.5 2 1 4 1 8 SHG 11.2 23.2 7 4 7 7 25 M-CRIL, 2007 15.9 20.7 13 13 17 11 54 2005 15.6 18.5 25 19 23 16 83 2003 20.5 36.5 23 21 46 90 Top 10 13.1 11.6 4 4 2 0 10 MIX* India Bangladesh Nepal South Asia MIX global MIX Asia 10.4 14.2 11.2 14.3 20.1 17.2 * Operating expense as a proportion of Gross Loan Portfolio (GLP) The effective Analysis of operating expense ratios by size of MFI, its age, microfinance methodology and interest rate loan size shows that it is the last factor that is the major determinant of operating efficiency. paid by the average Indian As the size of loans disbursed increases from Rs3,000 ($75) to Rs10,000 ($250), the operating microfinance expense ratio declines from 25% down to an average of around 12% (Figure 4.3) borrower is no more than 25% - not significantly Figure 4.3 OER by loan size (Rs) different from the ~24% usually charged even by commercial banks on consumer finance The effective interest rate paid by the average Indian microfinance borrower is no more than 25% - not significantly different from the ~24% usually charged even by commercial banks on consumer finance. By and large, new institutions have low yields and high OERs but, as expansion takes place, and economies of scale set in, yields improve and OERs decline to acceptable levels. There are significant economies of scale up to a portfolio size of Rs2.5 crores ($600,000) - Figure 4.4. 78
  • 81. CHAPTER 4 MFI Performance: Efficiency with Growth Figure 4.4 Relationship of portfolio size with efficiency Official action against MFIs in Andhra Pradesh and elsewhere has resulted in a significant Official action deterioration in the credit culture, having an adverse effect on microfinance operations. against MFIs in Andhra Pradesh Portfolio quality has deteriorated since the 2005 Review with the weighted average PAR60 and elsewhere has declined from 4.7% in 2005 to 6.0% now. Particularly affected are the leading MFIs has resulted in a significant whose PAR has declined from 1.4% for the 2005 sample to 4.6% now. This is also much higher deterioration in than the MIX benchmarks for Asia. The implications of this for the long term performance of the credit the microfinance sector are yet to emerge. culture, having an adverse effect on 4 Portfolio financing microfinance operations. Portfolio quality The structural shift indicated by an increase in debt financing among Indian MFIs has continued has while net worth as a proportion of the total has been reduced as current surpluses and a very deteriorated since the 2005 limited flow of grants have failed to keep pace with growth. Borrowings have reached three- Review with the quarters of total liabilities on MFI balance sheets as funds have been readily available from weighted both private and public commercial banks (Figure 4.5). Even small institutions with relatively average PAR60 has declined low exposure to financial markets have succeeded in sourcing half of their liabilities through from 4.7% in bank borrowings, bringing over 60% of MFIs under the 15% suggested capital adequacy ratio. 2005 to 6.0% now Figure 4.5 Sources of funds for microfinance operations 79
  • 82. Until now, with substantial historical grant funding and more recent operating surpluses accompanied by relatively small portfolios, the Indian microfinance sector has been well provided for in terms of owned funds. Now, the growth aspirations of MFI managements, competition and the relative paucity of grant funds, on the one hand, and the availability of liberal commercial debt funds, on the other, have taken their toll. The aggregate figures suggest that capital adequacy is now an issue as even the Top10 MFIs fail to register the 15% norm suggested above, though it is not alarming yet (Table 4.5). When managed The trend towards commercialization becomes even stronger in the context of off-balance loans are added sheet financing under the partnership model, which accounts for an additional 44% of the back to the balance sheets overall portfolio in the sector. When managed loans are added back to the balance sheets of a of a subset of subset of leading Indian MFIs, the leverage ratio jumps from 10.7 to 11.9, far exceeding the leading Indian MFIs, the regional median of 5:1. While a limited amount of debt continues to be available at concessional leverage ratio rates, much of it is contracted at commercial rates in the range of 10-14% per annum. With jumps from such financing accounting for four-fifths of the portfolio of leading MFIs, the commercialization 10.7 to 11.9, far exceeding of the Indian sector far exceeds that of other important markets in the region, such as the regional Bangladesh, where institutions source less than one-tenth of their portfolios from commercial median of 5:1 funds. Table 4.5 Capital adequacy ratios of Indian MFIs Models Weighted CAR (%) Typical MFI (%) Grameen 11.3 13.6 IB 22.3 15.6 SHG 8.4 12.5 12.7 13.4 Top 10 11.1 9.4 Debt-equity ratios M-CRIL sample 7.2 14.2 Top10 8.6 10.5 MIX India median 11.9 Indeed, Indian MFIs are increasingly turning to the banking sector as their access to grants and customer deposits continues to diminish. The share of grants dropped from one third of the balance sheet in 2003 to just 3% in 2006, barely covering cumulative losses among smaller institutions. With the ability to raise equity capital limited to just a few legal entities, reliance on net worth fell to 10%, less than one-third of that in 2003. Bank borrowings have also had to fill in for customer deposits, which amounted to one-fourth of MFI resources in 2003 and are now under one-tenth of the balance sheet. Concerns over the legality of savings mobilization combined with increasing transformation to NBFCs have phased savings out of MFI balance sheets and mostly confined these to community-based institutions such as SHGs and cooperatives. Indian financing patterns, however, could look quite different in the next few years. Under proposed legislation, societies, trusts and cooperatives will be able to offer thrift services. While companies are excluded from this proposed regulatory regime, a number of these have 80
  • 83. CHAPTER 4 MFI Performance: Efficiency with Growth recently announced large investments by private equity funds. With the Top10 accounting for two-thirds of the financing, debt may be ceding some of its share to equity capital. 5 Financial performance The financial viability of microfinance institutions in India is under threat, despite improvements in the yield gap. The 2.1% weighted return on assets of the 2005 sample has been reduced to zero while typical MFI returns are -9.8%, well behind Bangladeshi institutions reporting to the MIX, which lead the region in profitability. Low portfolio yields, combined with poor portfolio quality and rising financial costs have reduced Indian MFI surpluses though improvements in collection measures have boosted portfolio yields to 93% of the expected The financial figure, up from 85% in 2005 (Table 4.6). Yields, however, remain low, with 43% of Indian viability of microfinance MFIs earning less than 24% on their portfolios. In comparison with 36-50% real costs of bank institutions in loans and moneylender interest rates ranging from 36% to 120%, MFI average yields represent India is under threat, despite a substantial benefit for low income clients. improvements in the yield Nonetheless, these are not sufficient to cover rising costs brought on by ambitious growth gap. The 2.1% plans, deteriorating portfolio quality and hardening of domestic interest rates on borrowings. weighted return on assets of the Benchmarks for profitable Indian MFIs indicate that they charge more sustainable rates than 2005 sample their unprofitable peers and earn 24.8% on their portfolios as compared to 19.5%, but they has been also maintain tighter cost control. While both groups face similar financial costs, sustainable reduced to zero while typical institutions benefit from lower provisioning expenses because of their superior portfolio MFI returns are quality. Moreover, they benefit from economies of scale as the typical sustainable MFI manages -9.8%, well behind a much larger portfolio than an unsustainable institution. Indeed, the sample of 58 institutions Bangladeshi shows a concentration of portfolio and borrowers among institutions that are at or near institutions sustainability. As Table 4.7 shows, nearly 50% of borrowers are served by MFIs with operational reporting to the MIX, which lead self-sufficiency in excess of 90% . Since outreach has grown dramatically, the absolute the region in numbers of clients served by sustainable institutions has actually increased by 35% over the profitability past two years. Table 4.6 Portfolio yield relative to APR Models Yield (%) APR (%) Yield/APR (%) Grameen 27.6 27.6 100.2 Indl Banking 26.1 32.3 80.7 SHG 13.8 16.9 81.5 M-CRIL India 24.2 26.1 92.8 Top 10 23.5 24.8 95.0 M-CRIL 2005 25.0 29.3 85.2 Top10, 2005 23.9 27.8 86.0 81
  • 84. Table 4.7 Outreach of efficient microfinance institutions OSS (%) Number Proportion (%) >100 1,696,447 39.5 90-100 440,107 10.3 80-90 824,990 19.2 <80 1,330,527 31.0 Total 4,292,071 100 Despite the sobering events of the past two years, the overall impression of an efficient MFI sector that is growing strongly remains unchanged. As the discussion in this chapter and that on social rating shows, it is apparent that while MFIs have learnt much in terms of operational efficiency a substantial effort is required in the areas of clarifying social objectives, poverty targeting, product development and client orientation. The challenge for MFIs over the next few years is to achieve growth with equity as well as efficiency. Endnotes 1 Sanjay Sinha is Managing Director of M-CRIL 2 Issues of deposit orientation of MFI models and their relationship with regulation and resource mobilisation are discussed in Section 4. 82
  • 85. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance The new urban microfinance 1 There has been an upsurge of interest in urban microfinance with several recent start-ups in the metros, promoted by professionals who have a proven track record of successful careers in banking and other fields.2 Other start-ups are being promoted by microfinance professionals who already have some experience in rural microfinance but feel challenged by the relatively unfamiliar territory of large-scale urban microfinance.3 Both sets of entrants are part of what have been referred to as a "generational change"4 in Indian microfinance. A third set of entrants are many of the well-established, primarily rural MFIs expanding There has been an upsurge of increasingly into small towns and peri-urban areas as they grow.5 Fourth, an increasing number interest in of NBFCs and banks already operating in the urban areas are experimenting with "downscaling" urban through smaller, individual, loan products.6 A possible fifth, although still very small category microfinance with several consists of the new urban MFIs being incubated by ACCESS Development Services in Kolkata.7 recent start-ups Finally there is renewed interest in the pioneers of urban microfinance such as SEWA, WWF, and in the metros, promoted by SPMS, whose experience over the years is being reexamined by the new comers for the valuable professionals lessons they offer. who have a proven track Although the "new generation" urban MFIs exhibit considerable diversity, they are distinguished record of successful by the following broad features. First, in contrast to the pioneers they have much greater careers in ambitions in respect of scale. Several of them intend to grow rapidly to become national banking and institutions with branches in several metros and large cities as well as in the surrounding rural other fields hinterland.8 In keeping with this ambition, they intend to achieve sustainability as soon as possible so as to be able to attract the huge volume of on-lending funds required, as well as the investments with which to support them. They have been very successful in attracting funds so far because of the backgrounds of their promoters. They intend to cater primarily to the vast majority of urban residents who are still unserved by the banks and depend largely on the informal sector for their financial needs. Reaching the poorest of the poor is not a primary goal, at least initially. Phrases like sub-prime borrowers, the missing middle, lower income groups are frequently used in descriptions of their target clientele. Some of them are experimenting with new lending models more suited to urban microfinance, and they intend to induct the latest offerings of technology, wherever cost effective, to enhance scale and efficiency. They are cognizant of the need to offer a full set of financial services including savings, insurance and remittances, over and above a range of 83
  • 86. credit products to suit the greater heterogeneity of urban financial markets. However they intend to meet non-financial needs such as health and vocational training through partnerships with NGOs and other civil society organizations and socially minded corporations. Some of them are treating their first couple of years as pilot projects, which they are using to stabilize delivery technology and product design, and learn the lessons of large-scale urban microfinance first hand. In this they are being assisted by at least two service providers who also in a sense belong to this new generation, the Michael and Susan Dell Foundation, which sees its mission in India to catalyze urban MFIs by providing grant support for capacity building, and risk capital, and by ACCION, an international NGO with considerable experience world wide in the introduction of individual lending and downscaling. The third set of entrants, the Rural Converts, are mostly moving into urban microfinance from the contiguous rural areas and are operating mostly in the smaller towns and peri-urban areas.9 Initial and average loan size is higher than in their rural operations, and this is where they are also introducing larger, individual loans to microentrepreneurs, both of which are advantageous from the point of view of profitability. The fourth set, the increasing number of existing NBFCs and banks getting interested in downscaling, are an extremely heterogeneous bunch. Among the former are Satin Creditcare in West Delhi which is best known for its system of doorstep daily collections, even though average loans size is currently as high as Rs 27,000. Banks in India Banks in India have been excluded from the small loans market partly by regulatory fiat. They have been are not allowed to make loans of less than Rs 200,000 at a rate any higher than their PLR excluded from the small loans (their lending rate to prime customers) if they want the loans to count towards their priority market partly sector targets. Despite this disincentive, Yes Bank has decided to get into the microfinance by regulatory market by introducing a personal loan product, ranging in size from Rs 8000 to Rs 25,000 fiat. They are not allowed to repayable in 3 to 6 months, with technical assistance from ACCION. The area surrounding the make loans of bank's headquarters in Worli has been divided into 8 zones not more than 45 minutes' walking less than Rs 200,000 at a distance away. Each has been placed under a Relationship Manager who identifies borrowers rate any higher and remains responsible for them, but with all cash transactions being handled out of an than their PLR office at bank headquarters itself.10 (their lending rate to prime customers) if Indian Bank's Microsate branch in Chennai is unusual in being a bank branch in an urban area they want the which only makes loans to SHGs.11 It is in effect doing SHG-bank linkage in an urban area. loans to count towards their With the assistance of about 51 registered NGOs it is currently lending to about 4000 active priority sector groups out of an estimated 14,000 spread over about 140 slums in Chennai. Average group targets size is 17, and the main member activities are retailing, trading and handicrafts. Microsate branch12 had a portfolio of Rs 7 crores in March 2007, which is expected to go up to about Rs 20 crores by March 2008. This is its third year, and it has become profitable. Indian Bank has already set up another Microsate branch in Patna, and plans to open one in South Chennai, apart from branches in several cities all over the country. The main challenge it will face will be the availability of good NGOs with the capacity to form good SHGs. Tamil Nadu is unusual in having a very strong women's development corporation with an important urban component in its SHG programme, and with a policy to form SHGs only through NGOs (as distinct from the government agencies commonly used in other states). It ensures quality control through a system of accreditation of NGOs and provides training and other forms of assistance to them. 84
  • 87. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance Experience with SHGs in some other urban microfinance programmes has been mixed, as discussed below. However, if the Microsate experience can be replicated it will be a significant breakthrough. The Pioneers have stayed relatively small. In contrast with the more minimalist, financial services approach, of their successors, and in keeping with the more holistic view of the nature of poverty and powerlessness they espouse, many of them they have placed equal emphasis on organizational inputs and collective action in pursuit of working women's rights and other social goals.13 This meant accepting a much lower rate of growth, although in response to member needs SEWA Bank in particular (Box 5.6) has expanded much more rapidly in respect of savings and insurance than on the credit side. Its experience in respect of savings and insurance services in an urban context as well as on credit products such as housing loans and individual loans generally, are of great interest. Sri Padmavathy Mahila Abyudaya Sangh (SPMS) is unusual in several respects, which combine to make it unique. It may be the country's first SHG federation. Not only is it one of the few federations located in an urban area, it relies only for technical and strategic inputs on its promoters, and has become self-sufficient in respect of financial activities, although it receives grants for a variety of economic development activities, including participation in urban infrastructure activities such as housing, environmental sanitation and In our use of even road building (DHAN Foundation 2005 and Box 3.3). the term financial inclusion (or The Context inclusion into the formal and semi-formal or Urbanization and urban poverty MFI sector) there is a Some of the salient facts on India's urbanization and urban poverty are as follows:14 danger of forgetting that the "excluded" (i) The rate of urbanization increased sharply in the 1990s to almost twice the rural are in fact population growth rate, and the share of the urban population, although still lower served by a than the global and Asian average, had grown to 31 percent by 2001 Much of the huge informal financial sector. growth is being driven by migration from the rural areas. The challenge is not to fill a (ii) While urban poverty is declining in relative terms it is increasing in absolute terms. In supposed credit vacuum, but to the three decades since 1970 the number of poor went up from 52 to 67 million.15 improve on the However in some cities like Delhi the poverty ratio was as low as 8 percent in 1999 terms of the (Mukherjee 2004). informal sector (iii) India's metros and large towns have some of the most congested slums in the world and are "home" to some of the worst living conditions anywhere Thus the extent of "human poverty" and deprivation is much worse than the "income" poverty measured and reported in the statistics. The urban informal financial sector In our use of the term financial inclusion (or inclusion into the formal and semi-formal or MFI sector) there is a danger of forgetting that the "excluded" are in fact served by a huge informal financial sector. The challenge is not to fill a supposed credit vacuum, but to improve on the terms of the informal sector. This will have two benefits -- the direct benefit to those "included", and the indirect benefit to those left behind in the informal sector (likely the great majority). The terms on which the latter receive financial services will improve because 85
  • 88. of the competition offered by MFIs, just as they have in pockets in the rural areas where MFIs have achieved significant penetration. There is a huge literature on the variety of informal sector lenders, and lending and savings devices and mechanisms, including moneylenders, pawnbrokers, chit funds, informal finance companies, employers, pygmy deposit collectors etc.16 In Kalisbasti, a squatter settlement in West Delhi, Ruthven (2001), mentions (i) interest-free loans from friends, neighbours and relatives17 (ii) wage advances, (iii) groceries on credit, (iv) goods on credit, (v) private loans taken on interest from ex-neighbours, relatives etc at rates lower than moneylenders, and (vi) loans from professional moneylenders'. It is important for MFIs to understand each of these sources, but particularly moneylenders, because they are the main competition, both with respect to serving the poor and the excluded non-poor. In Kalisbasti, of the various sources, moneylenders had the highest share of poor users, or 40 percent, as Box 5.1(excerpted from Ruthven 2001) describes. For households in a household monthly income bracket one-notch higher, who constitute Ujjivan's target group, they are ubiquitous, as described in Box 5.2 (from Ujjivan 2006). Box 5.1 The uses and abuses of moneylenders While 18% of respondents used (or admitted to using) professional moneylenders, close to half of these (40%) were categorized as poor. The operations and role of moneylenders in Kalibasti has been documents elsewhere (see Patole & Ruthven 2001). It is our observation that moneylenders hold a special place in the financial portfolio of poorer residents fro two main reason. Firstly, their convenience and reliability is unbeatable, an attribute particularly valuable for poor people who are short of time and money to negotiate deals and whose needs are most urgent. Secondly they are unique within the informal sector, in being commercial (or "professional") and incur no wider social obligations on the part of the borrower. In other words there is no dignity at stake in dealing with a professional moneylender- it is just a straight commercial deal. This makes them attractive to those who require discretion, who don't wish to strain social relations with financial concerns, or who simply don't have such relations to lean on. As one respondent put it, "When I go to the moneylender, it's between him and me. I give my relatives no reason to talk." While the users of professional moneylenders are a mixed group (mostly Muslims and OBCs), the circumstances in which people borrow fall broadly in to two types: (i) those facing income shortfalls for whom other borrowing options are limited or non existent (Box 9), and (ii) those managing a mixed credit portfolio, within which moneylenders have a niche of convenience and instant access ( Box 10). Both types frequently drag repayment, but those of the first type- unless their income increases- find it increasingly difficult to raise money as they are refused in turn by each moneylender who recognizes their cash-flow inadequate to repay. Box 5.1.1 The uses and abuse of moneylenders Surender( 27) and Anita( 24, P) have been in Delhi for most of their lives. Surender is a painter, taking contracts through a local hardware store and has an erratic income due to the seasonal nature of his work. Anita stopped working recently following pregnancy. This is the couple's seventh year in Kalibasti and over the years they've become acquainted with several of the local moneylenders. Usually they go to those who take daily installments since this suits Surender's income pattern. A month ago they took one such loan of Rs 1500 from a Tamil moneylender and passed the money to a friend who had just 86
  • 89. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance given birth. Handling them Rs 1350, he informed them they'd need to pay Rs 35 for 50 days (a monthly rate of about 50%). They agreed, as they had in the past. But when Surender's income dried up they started facing repayment problems. Anita informed us she was planning a visit to a Rajasthani lender well-known to her mother. Since he collects monthly rather than daily, his terms are more suited to the couple at this time of year. She'll try for Rs 2000 at 3% per month. She'll repay the Tamil moneylender with this loan and use the balance to pay the house rent which is already two month overdue. Box 5.1.2 The USP of the professional moneylender At first glance one would have thought Santosh (42) and Roshan Lal (45, B), would have no use for moneylender and their high interest rates. They've both got permanent jobs which they can take advances, only one son to look after, an array of friends to borrow from when the need arises, they have a bank savings account and Roshan sits in a RoSCA at the office. Nonetheless when they heard five years ago about a cheap deal going for a plot in Kalibasti they went straight to the moneylender and borrowed Rs 5000 to make the offer. Over the next 4 months they repaid the loan at 5% per month. It was-they say- the only way they could raise money quickly enough. Adapted from Ruthven 2001 Box 5.2 The ubiquity of moneylenders in Bangalore The unorganized sector is dominated by a vast assortment of virtually nameless, faceless financiers. They are present in market and non-market locations, and undertake their business very quietly and unobtrusively. The relationship between moneylenders and borrowers is symbiotic. With poor access to any formal funding, borrowers work to maintain a good relationship with their only source of credit, i.e. the non formal individual moneylender. Additionally, there is a sense of loyalty towards him as he is considered to be his saviour in times of need. As for the moneylender, the borrower is his market. He services good borrowers with relatively easier repayment terms. Generally, the interest rates levied by moneylenders are higher than those charged in the organised sector. Moneylenders charge between 2% and 10% per month on a loan amount. Why was urban There are exceptions where the interest rates are lower or higher then these rates. In spite of microfinance the high interest rates that they charge, moneylenders are the most popular source of finance. left unexplored This is probably because they offer unsecured loan that are tailored to the income cycle of territory for so long, despite customers. the prospects of huge loan Based on Ujjivan 2006 demand, larger average loan Finally, it is worth reminding ourselves that the burden of exclusion falls most heavily on the size and higher population poor, because it is the poor who are most likely to be excluded also by moneylenders and other density making informal sector lenders, for essentially the same reasons. So at the bottom of the pyramid for lower costs, the need to there may indeed be a credit vacuum. Second, to the extent rural microfinance reduces rural- reach the urban migration it reduces the inclusion task for urban microfinance. On the other hand, it growing could on balance fuel it by financing it.18 numbers of the urban poor, and the example of The particular challenges of urban informal finance Latin America where microfinance is Why was urban microfinance left unexplored territory for so long, despite the prospects of predominantly huge loan demand, larger average loan size and higher population density making for lower urban? 87
  • 90. costs, the need to reach the growing numbers of the urban poor, and the example of Latin America where microfinance is predominantly urban? Some of the reasons have to do with institutional factors such as the lack of a structured programme similar to the SBLP promoted by a single apex agency such as NABARD, which enjoyed the visibility the SBLP gave it. Similar programmes in the urban areas such as the Jawahar Shahari Rozgar Yojana failed to attain anywhere near the same prominence, although this was largely due to the same inherent difficulties that beset urban MFIs discussed in this chapter. As regards the MFI model, the inspiration and delivery technology were derived from the Grameen Bank, which was almost exclusively rural, and whose model was proving as successful in the densely populated parts of rural India as in Bangladesh. Why jeopardize high growth and expend scarce managerial energy on venturing into unchartered territory, especially when the standardization and borrower-time requirements of the group-lending model might prove a handicap in the much more heterogeneous and time-constrained urban environment? Even more frequently mentioned as a difficulty for group lending with its reliance on peer-pressure and mutual trust based on long-standing neighbourhood and kinship ties, was the supposed much greater mobility and lack of social cohesion, even atomization, of urban slum-dwellers. Mobility and transience More of a As urban microfinance expands, some of these constraints and apprehensions are beginning to problem in come into clearer focus (although only just, we are looking at the tip of the iceberg in terms of these areas, Swadhaar finds, what we need to learn through patient rigorous field work, an example of which is contained in is that as many the boxes included here from Ruthven 2001). As with most generalizations, the validity of that as 30-35 percent of its relating to the obstacle posed by mobility and transience depends on which income segment borrowers have and location one is looking at. It certainly seems to the case that mobility has proved less of a no formal problem than was originally feared. Fairly typical is Veena Mankar's observation that many slum documentation to establish dwellers have been living in the same location for a generation or more, and that even if they go either identity home to their villages for a couple of months a year they come back to the same area because of or address. More of a problem, proximity to a known livelihood.19 More of a problem in these areas, Swadhaar finds, is that as also, than many as 30-35 percent of its borrowers have no formal documentation to establish either mobility per se identity or address. More of a problem, also, than mobility per se is what might be called is what might be called "involuntary mobility", caused by the ongoing drive in Mumbai (and elsewhere) to demolish "involuntary slums and relocate them elsewhere, which has affected 10 percent of her clients already.20 mobility" On the other hand, in her research in Kalibasti, an unauthorized squatter settlement in West Delhi, Ruthven 2001 found that 16 percent of her sample had been resident for less than a year, and 35 percent for two years (Box 5.3 from Ruthven 2001). There is no doubt that much of the growth of India's urban slums is being fed by accelerating migration.21 However it is not in-migration we are concerned with so much as the intention to stay, and here she reminds us that a good proportion of recent arrivals are planning to move on within a year or two (mostly back to their villages, in thier case).22 Aajivika in Delhi has been affected by mobility not directly, but indirectly, in that it is located in a resettlement colony in Northwest Delhi where more than ten thousand households have been located in the last five years. Aditi Mehta (2007) talks of the "almost complete lack of mutual trust within the community" which affected operations initially. 88
  • 91. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance Box 5.3 Mobility in a Delhi slum If we take the World Bank's global poverty line of US$1 (equivalent in Rupee purchasing power parity) of income per day per family member, just under a third of our sample emerge as below the poverty line. There is only a partial correspondence, however, between this group, ranked by current income, and the "poor" group ranked by our wider range of criteria during wealth ranking exercises. Current income after all is not able to reflect the changing dynamic of livelihoods over time and the wider context of assets and security which people experience (or not) independently of immediate income sources. A large proportion of Kalibasti residents are on the move. Sixteen % of our sample had been in Kalibasti for less than a year, 35% for two years or less. Clearly this challenges assumptions of slums as inhabited by permanent squatters since a good proportion of those who come are moving on within one or two years. Almost half of residents were experiencing a "dynamic trajectory"- improving their circumstances quite rapidly, or conversely in the midst of hard times or a crisis which sees them impoverished. Most of the others were facing some turbulence and hotly engaged in avoiding economic decline, making themselves less vulnerable to shocks, paying off past debts and securing higher and more regular income. A minority of respondents (20%) could be seen as "cruising ", not moving in any direction having secured a comfortable niche in Delhi and without much ambition… …we can divide respondents into five broad categories in respect of their history and the circumstances which led to their arrival in Kalibasti. This is important because-even after several years in the colony- it informs their money management strategy. The table below describes these five categories. Reasons for respondents moving to Delhi (n =27) Reason Percentage Gradual rural impoverishment: shrinking, unviable landholdings are not 29 compensated by availability of alternative employment, over generations. City hoppers hunt for opportunity: Business/self employed families 29 from regional cities try their luck in the capital Young members of secure rural families hunt for opportunity: unmarried male 21 members of families with land ( especially from Western UP) take time out before settling down to marriage and village responsibilities. Refugees from a crisis in the village: the death of the mal bread winner, a severe 13 health problem or an accident forces people to the city where they seek work to repay debts, rebuild assets or start a new life. Long-term Delhi residents in financial crisis: Lower middle-class families 17 downshift their lifestyle after being cheated, robbed or imprisoned Total 100 The table highlights the misconception that slum dwellers are necessarily impoverished economic refuges from the country side permanently flowing to the city. Nearly half (44%) of our respondents are from relatively secure backgrounds, already urbanized or with a strong asset base in the village. Even among the balance, while most have come to Delhi in response to economic hardship of some kind, it can not be assumed that most will stay. Many are using city earning power to build a more viable life in the countryside. Based on Ruthven 2001 89
  • 92. The main The main response so far to the problem of mobility in areas where it is acute is exclusion. response so far Thus Arohan in Kolkata would like very much to serve the huge population of mostly day to the problem of mobility in visitors who flood into the middle-class areas of South Kolkata from the rural hinterland as day areas where it labourers and maids etc, but has for very understandable reasons been unable to do so. is acute is exclusion Likewise with the large population of rickshaw drivers who park by the wayside to sleep at night. If there is any successful experience of reaching Mumbai's pavement dwellers through microfinanance on a significant scale, it has not yet been documented. Although Ujjivan defines its target group as those with a household income of between Rs 2000 to Rs 8000 a month, 98 percent of its clientele were above the Rs 3000 line in March 2007.23 Aditi Mehta is explicit in recognizing that Aajivika's participation comes so far from the "economically active poor, validating the opinion that microfinance may not be the most suitable instrument to target the poorest households. In the urban context this leaves unanswered the question of how the livelihoods of this segment might be addressed".24 In locations where they do operate, most urban MFIs do however appear to have found ways of providing themselves with enough comfort to establish that the borrower has a fixed abode locally, despite lack of formal documentation.25 Thus Swadhaar and others establish veracity of information through cross checks with neighbours and using whatever documents are available, even wedding photographs. While joint liability groups may not be able to ensure repayments above a certain level of loan size (which most urban practitioners put at Rs 15.000 to Rs 20,000)26 they do serve as a screening mechanism in respect of residence. Another screening mechanism, which has been used by Basix and others, is to require prospective borrowers to save regularly for a period before becoming eligible for borrowing.27 A final point to be made is that even if a significant proportion of residents in a slum are transient, MFIs would have to achieve a very high level of penetration before running out of In locations prospective borrower from among permanent residents for group membership, especially for where they do the smaller, JLG groups, as discussed below. The trick would seem to lie in achieving a high operate, most urban MFIs do success rate in spotting them. however appear to have found Urban heterogeniety ways of providing themselves with There are several cross-cutting ways in which to view urban heterogeneity. It can be viewed in enough comfort terms of financial needs, or purposes for which money is raised, as in Box 5.4 excerpted from to establish Ruthven 2001, describing "spending sets" in Kalibasti. It can also be viewed in relation to loan that the borrower has a types designed to serve those needs, such as the informal sector business and personal loans fixed abode taken by persons in the MHI class that constitutes Ujjivan's target group (as described Ujjivan locally, despite lack of formal 2006). Again it can be described in terms of occupational segments (an example of which, from documentation Mumbai, is given below) or in terms of modes of employment (self versus wage employment). Box 5.4 Segmentation by loan purpose What do Kalibasti residents need financial services for? The spending behavior of residents ( and the concomitant way in which they raise significant sums of money towards such expenses) can be divided into six "spending sets" summarized below: i. Lifecycle costs: overwhelmingly towards the marriage of daughters ii. Income shortfalls: chronic or intermittent 90
  • 93. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance iii. Dependents outside Delhi: relatives in the village but also children in school iv. Health crisis, chronic health problems and the stresses associated with these v. Investment: in fixed assets or a job opportunity, in Delhi or the village vi. House construction in Delhi or the village The table below illustrates the purposes for which significant sums of money ("lump sums") were raised (whether through savings, advances or loans) by residents in the months running up to our survey. It shows the proportion of residents who had recently raised a lump sum for each of the purposes described and - among these residents- how many were ranked as poor. Use of lump sums among % of sample Of which ranked as poor(%) Kalibasti residents (%) Lifecycle cost 39 25 Income shortfalls in Delhi 27 57 Dependents outside Delhi* 31 25 Health & mental stress 24 58 Investment 24 0 House construction 24 33 *This is not equivalent to all those remitting money to the village since it includes only those who raised a significant sum for a trip or to send resources to the Village. Remittances have been examined separately. As we might expect, the poor face disproportionately high expenses for health as well as to cover periodic or regular income deficits. No respondents ranked as poor had recently raised lump sums for investment. On the other hand a proportionate number of this group was making investments in houses, mostly in their home towns or village. This highlights the role ... quite apart of urban livelihoods in making possible the acquisition of rural assets. from the much greater Based on Ruthven 2001 importance of wage employment in the urban areas, To take the last of these dimensions first, quite apart from the much greater importance of self-employment wage employment in the urban areas, self-employment itself, whether in manufacture or services, itself, whether is likely to exhibit a much greater diversity than in the rural areas where a much smaller group in manufacture or services, is of activities such as livestock and petty trading often account for the majority of loans. The likely to exhibit proportion of wage and self-employed among MFI borrowers is likely to vary according to a much greater income group targeted, the urban area concerned and MFI policy. As many as half of Ujjivan diversity than in the rural borrowers are wage-employed in occupations such as domestic help, garment factory workers, areas where a sweepers in the municipal corporation or are helpers in shops, schools and hospitals. Many of much smaller group of them however have secondary self-employment activities. The self-employed are flower or activities such vegetable vendors, or pushcart vendors of food and snacks, or run tea shops, or retail saris out as livestock and of their homes, etc. Piece-rated job-work, which accounts for 10 percent of customers is an petty trading often account intermediate form of employment, is common in agarbatti making and beedi rolling and tends for the majority to be the worst remunerated, absorbing the most recent arrivals. In the case of Swadhaar and of loans 91
  • 94. SWAWS, the proportion among borrowers is the reverse, largely for reasons of policy.28 But clearly there is plenty of scope for lending to both sets of borrowers in India's metros. In Mumbai one estimate places the number of workers in various occupational segments (offering both self and wage employment) which engage a high proportion of women, as: 700,000 household workers, of which 95 percent are women (maids); 200,000 hawkers (25 percent women); 100,000 each of sweepers and rag pickers (40 percent women and children); and 50,000 zari workers (35 percent women and children)29. The numbers engaged in the more male dominated occupational segments such as taxi drivers, auto drivers, loom workers, leather industry workers, and mathedi and hamali workers were estimated in the same study.30 At least one urban MFI would like at some stage to lend to men too. As with rural microfinance, and contrary to the enduring fiction that "95 percent" of microfinance borrowers are women, a large share of the loans are used by men anyway, and not just husbands (Chapter 6). Given the Also, there is no clear-cut correspondence between mode of employment and use of loans. As shortage and many as 30 percent of Swadhaar's borrowers running businesses borrow for non-business purposes. dilapidated condition of Retirement of high-cost existing debt to moneylenders and others tends to one of the commonest housing in the uses of the first and second loans for both sets of borrowers (as may be the case in the rural areas urban areas, the too). Given the shortage and dilapidated condition of housing in the urban areas, the demand demand for housing loans is for housing loans is extremely high, as is that for products designed to cater to life-cycle extremely high, events, education and health expenditures (given the high income elasticities of demand of all as is that for products these services, and higher incomes in the urban areas). All this has implications for the range of designed to products offered and their design, as well as for lending procedures. cater to life- cycle events, education and Responses health expenditures (given the high Products income elasticities of Several MFIs have conducted careful market research and are in the process of developing products demand of all based on it. Ujjivan's research into the market for housing loans revealed the life-time progression these services, and higher of the typical customer from renting to "leasing" (in which the tenant pays in lieu of rent a incomes in the relatively large interest-free lump sum to the owner), to buying a house site, to building a house, urban areas) to extending and repairing it. For good customers who have established a track-record Ujjivan has started offering loans of up to Rs 30,000 for any of these purposes using a loan from HDFC which should suffice for 1700 customers. (Box 5.5). It is looking also at educational loans required specially at the beginning of the school year, and loans for higher education. These products are in addition to Ujjivan's standard family-needs (or personal) loans, business loans, top-up loans, emergency loans and festival loans. SWAWS and VWS also have educational loans.31 SEWA's products have evolved over 30 years to result in the diversity described in Box 5.6. Box 5.5 Ujjivan's approach to urban housing microfinance: helping customers climb the housing ladder Driven by heavy migration into the city and a booming economy, Bangalore faces a critical housing shortage, boosting the price of housing ever higher. For the urban poor, bearing the burden of rising housing costs requires substantial financing. To date this has been supplied by Bangalore's highly-developed yet costly informal financial sector, with little presence of 92
  • 95. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance urban MFIs. Ujjivan recognized the opportunity for affordable housing finance, and recently began a pilot urban housing microfinance scheme. The pilot process commenced with a study designed to provide an understanding of urban housing needs. The study revealed three types of urban residents: renters, leasers and homeowners, who each correspond to a progressive rung on what Ujjivan terms the "Housing Ladder". The first rung is renting, which typically requires a monthly rent of Rs1000-2000 and a refundable deposit of 10 times the monthly rent. The second rung is leasing, which typically requires a lump sum between Rs 50,000-Rs.100,000 in lieu of a monthly rent for 3 to5 years. Leases are desirable because the lump-sum is returned at the lease end, albeit without interest, allowing customers to reinvest the amount in a larger lease, land site, or other purposes. The third rung is owning a home, which typically occurs in three phases: buying a land site, constructing a simple home, and later progressively improving the house. To climb each rung, the urban poor are dependent on access to affordable financing. For example, Sunita, an Ujjivan customer, is renting a house for Rs 2000 per month with a deposit of Rs 20,000. She says, "I want a lease because they are better than renting because you do not have to pay every month, and you can save your money. But I need Rs 30,000 more to afford a lease in my area, and moneylenders are too expensive." The need for housing financing was echoed by Uma, also an Ujjivan customer, who says "I own my house and I am very happy because I can stay here forever now. But now I need money to build one more room because my children are older now and we don't have enough space." The presence of renters and The study revealed three leasers in the urban housing landscape marks the key difference between urban and rural types of urban settings, as nearly 60% of Ujjivan's customers rent or lease while just 40% own, in contrast to residents: 80 to 90 percent home ownership rates in rural areas. renters, leasers and The study also demolished several myths about urban housing microfinance. Myth 1: Housing homeowners, loans must be large with long tenors and are unsuitable for MFIs. The Housing Ladder reveals that who each correspond to a in fact the poor need loans as small as Rs 10,000 to reach subsequent rungs in the Housing progressive rung Ladder, for example a move from a Rs 50,000 to a Rs 60,000 lease. Smaller, incremental loans on what Ujjivan are actually better suited for both customers and MFIs, because they are more affordable for terms the "Housing customers, and offer lower risk and returning customers for MFIs. Myth 2: The urban poor are Ladder" too mobile for MFIs to give loans to them. Despite this perception, urban families are highly rooted to their communities and often live in the same area for generations. In fact, because the pressure to move is often created by an inability to afford rising costs, microfinance may have a stabilizing effect on the mobility of urban low-income families. Myth 3: The poor do not have proper documentation for their homes. While the majority of renters and leasers do not have documentation for current contracts, MFIs can to influence new documentation because customers will be entering into new agreements with the loans they receive. MFIs can require customers to submit proper documentation, putting pressure on them to demand documentation from landlords. For home owners, the study found that over 90% of urban customers did have legal land titles. Although MFIs must develop methodologies to screen for forged documents, Ujjivan found that documentation is not in fact a major barrier. Ujjivan's housing loans have attempted to address each rung in the Housing Ladder and are currently being tested in a pilot phase. The products offered include rental deposit, lease amounts and house improvement loans, ranging in size from Rs 10,000-30,000 with tenors of up to 3 years. Original documentation is not required, and customers can avail of the loan after completing one full year with an excellent repayment record, and with center and group recommendation. Ujjivan plans to roll out the loans nationwide in 2008, and in the future will offer value-added housing products, larger loan sizes and individual housing loans. Anjali Banthia, Product Manager, Ujjivan Financial Services 93
  • 96. Box 5.6 Individual loans and product diversification at SEWA Bank Recognizing that the diversity of occupational, economic and social backgrounds of SEWA Bank members, with their very different financial requirements, made group lending suboptimal in the urban context, SEWA was one of the first MFIs to take the more challenging path of individual lending. Starting in 1974 with a simple savings and a simple loan account SEWA Bank has evolved into a composite financial institution offering a variety of savings and recurring deposit accounts, fixed deposits and secured and unsecured loans. Unsecured loans have to be backed only by two guarantors, one of who can be a family member. About a fifth of its roughly 150,000 members are borrowers, of which three-fourths have unsecured loans of up to Rs 50,000 repayable in 35 months at an interest rate of 18 percent. Slightly better off clients with urgent cash requirements can avail of secured loans at 12 percent, backed by a personal asset, usually jewelry. In 1998 the Bank introduced longer-term housing loans in partnership with HUDCO, linked to a requirement to save Rs 20,000 through a 5-year recurring deposit scheme for housing. Finally, in 2001, SEWA introduced daily collection loans to extend outreach to poorer clients with a daily income cycle such as vegetable and flower vendors. This product mimics the money-lender, although at a much lower rate of interest, through bank "sathis", a team of former client with good financial literacy skills, who work on a commission basis, and visit clients daily not only to collect daily loan repayments, but to offer also daily savings collection and other recurring deposit schemes. By introducing various specialized recurring deposit schemes each tailored to a specific life-cycle need (including, now, pensions for old-age) Sewa has greatly reduced the cost of predictable expenditures for life-cycle needs. For unexpected shocks (death, accidents, sickness) it has made insurance compulsory though its insurance wing VIMO SEWA. Based on close studies of its clients' needs, today SEWA offers more than 40 differentiated products. Jayshreeben Vyas describes the process "We looked at their life-cycle needs and have come up with various savings products to mirror those needs - various recurring accounts, savings for buying gold, for education, for marriage, for old age, etc. Similarly, we have developed a range of products within credit". Based on Pasheva and Desai in CMF 2006 Processes As regards processes, one response to urban mobility and heterogeneity has been to do away with center meetings altogether, and experiment with smaller sized JLGs, more suited to accommodating the diversity of occupations, loan sizes requirements and time availabilities. As Veena Mankar points out, a maid and a hawker are unlikely to be free at the same time to attend a group meeting (assuming they have any free time at all). Both Ujjivan and Swadhaar have introduced monthly instead of weekly repayments, given the particularly acute time pressures experienced by borrowers in metros (many of who have long commutes). Swadhaar even gives them the option to pay a little extra to have their repayments collected at the doorstep. Also, doing away with center meeting makes a virtue out of necessity, since sufficient space for a gathering (let alone for a branch office) is prohibitively expensive, if available at all, in many urban localities. 94
  • 97. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance It will be interesting to see how these innovations work out. It should be noted though that The next logical step of course not all urban MFIs are departing from the tried and tested. Arohan feels its present system is is to do away well suited to its clients,32 while recognizing changes to it may be required for different with JLGs segments, when they are covered (monthly repayments, for instance, for the salaried for altogether and introduce personal loans). individual loans, which are Individual loans already the norm in Latin America. The The next logical step of course is to do away with JLGs altogether and introduce individual advantage of loans, which are already the norm in Latin America. The advantage of individual loans is that individual loans they can be more easily tailored to the loan size, gestation period and other cash flow is that they can be more easily requirements of the specific activity chosen by each borrower. Individual loans are usually tailored to the made to borrowers who have established a track record through group borrowing and who loan size, gestation require larger loans. Their higher risk is usually addressed by security in some form and higher period and interest on account of the risk premium. Many MFIs have in fact already been making individual other cash flow loans for housing purposes to senior group members, although, since funds for these usually requirements of the specific come from the housing financing institutions, their interest rates are lower and tenor longer. activity chosen What are more recent, are loans made to small entrepreneurs and traders referred to by names by each such microenterprise loans, etc.33 For most MFIs individual loans are still a small part of their borrower portfolio, except for SEWA Bank, the MFI with the longest experience in India (and perhaps anywhere) of individual loans, as described in Box 5.6. SHGs or JLGs? As a delivery vehicle SHGs (instead of JLGs) would also be affected by the mobility and time- scarcity related constraints of urban life, perhaps even more so, since SHGs have more members than JLGs, which should make it even harder to find a time for meetings suitable for all members, and increase the likelihood of at least one member moving out of the locality. On the other hand, in theory at least, SHGs are better suited to handle urban heterogeneity since they are expressly designed to accommodate different loan amounts, and like chit funds can accomodate non-borrowing or net saver members who prefer to sit back and earn interest on On the other hand, in theory loans taken by others. Moreover, given adequate accounting skills they should be able to at least, SHGs accommodate heterogeneity in respect of variation in desired savings, both between members are better and over time. Despite this, their use is very much the exception, although Indian Bank's suited to handle urban Microsate branch, SPMS and Roshan Vikas (Box 3.5) rely on them exclusively, the last two as heterogeneity SHG federations. since they are expressly designed to Janalakshmi in Bangalore also relied on them exclusively in its previous avatar as Sanghamitra's accommodate Urban Microfinance Programme, but is reported to be moving away from them. Ujjivan also different loan used them, outsourcing the task of forming them to existing NGOs, but like Janalakshmi has amounts, and like chit funds moved away from SHGs organized by others, to forming JLGs itself. In Ujjivan's case the can accomodate reasons had to do with lack of control over the quality of the groups formed, with some non-borrowing or net saver members frequently cornering all the funds, and instances of illegal commissions being charged members who from the groups by middlemen masquerading as NGOs. It also felt the margin between what it prefer to sit paid the SHG and the rates paid by the ultimate borrower was unjustified. Finally, hoping to back and earn interest on graduate borrowers in the medium term to larger individual loans, it felt JLGs gave it a much loans taken by closer understanding of their credit and savings behaviour.34 others 95
  • 98. Aajivika in Delhi actually initiated operations through NGOs who had an existing presence in slum clusters in activities such as health, literacy and advocacy, but dropped this approach since it found that partners relegated microfinance very low on their list of priorities, and the groups formed were often short lived. It chose then to initiate direct operations in a huge new resettlement colony, but found the level of trust insufficient to mobilize 15 member SHGs. It settled finally on smaller groups of five clustered in centers of 8 along classic Grameen lines. However, none of the problems encountered are inherent in the SHG channel, and warrant further investigation. The experience is mixed, and as noted above there are several examples of successful use of SHGs. For MFIs striving to attain rapid growth however, JLGs give it more control over loan size and frequency, and this may be one of the decisive consideration in favor of the latter in most cases.35 Some other challenges Human resources While the MFI While the MFI human resources challenge - not just training, but attracting and retaining human resources staff - has been engaging the attention of the MFI community generally in the last few years, challenge - not just training, its severity in the urban areas has taken the new urban MFIs by surprise. Nearly all of them are but attracting finding it difficult to recruit and retain staff in conditions of a tightening job market, and retaining especially in cities like Bangalore where Ujjivan reports attrition rates of 20 to 30 percent a staff - has been engaging the year. The skills field workers acquire are turning out to be in high demand in other parts of the attention of the financial sector, and in marketing. Also, as Veena Mankar points out, many young entrants to MFI community generally in the the labour force find the multi-tasking nature of MFI field work too demanding, and prefer a last few years, more uni-dimensional job (and one offering, preferably, a little more "glamour" or office its severity in comfort). Finally, the relatively flat nature of the MFI pyramid doesn't help when it comes to the urban areas has taken the promotion prospects. Clearly better pay and incentives will have to be part of the solution, new urban MFIs but will raise costs. Another solution being tried out is recruiting staff in the rural areas and by surprise providing them with accommodation.36 Borrower and external relations: "Money with respect" Another aspect of urban operations MFIs are learning about is the much greater awareness of urban borrowers on financial and other matters, stemming partly from higher literacy, but also from the much closer presence of the formal sector.37 As one CEO points out "one significant difference with rural operations is that you can't treat your customers as fools - you can't talk As one CEO down to them". As another MFI leader put it "we impress on our staff that what we are offering points out "one significant is not just money, but money with respect". Borrower sophistication may be particularly high in difference with West Bengal because of greater political awareness.38 West Bengal MFIs have been particularly rural operations conscious of the need to maintain good customer and external relations. They keep local ward- is that you can't treat your level politicians informed of their activities and plans, and invite them to preside over functions. customers as VWS has followed a conscious policy of developing borrower rapport and community goodwill fools - you can't talk down to through its diversity of microfinance plus activities, as well as schemes such as scholarships for them" children of borrowers who top in their classes, grants to local youth clubs etc.39 96
  • 99. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance Technology The cost of space has already been mentioned, and is enhancing the interest in technological solutions such as branchless banking. Ujjivan for instance is taking advantage of broadband connectivity in urban areas by centralizing all data entry at the head office and having the branches merely scan daily loan transaction data sheets and transmit them by email. (Alternatively, since the branches are located in the same urban area, the sheets can be hand-carried). SEWA and Swadhaar are using biometric smart cards to make it easier for their members to operate savings accounts through ATMs, since they tend to forget their PINs. VWS has been given a grant by SIDBI to introduce 5000 smart cards and hand-held machines in each of 2 branches.40 Competition After what has been said earlier about the huge unsatisfied demand for credit in the urban ... there is clearly a areas it may seem surprising that excessive competition between MFIs even figures as an issue perception is discussions of urban microfinance. However, there is clearly a perception among MFI leaders among MFI in several locations that competition could get out of hand and needs to be handled carefully. leaders in several Allegations relate to poaching of customers, even whole groups, as well as staff, with some locations that MFIs having acquired reputations for being particularly aggressive and even predatory. It is competition could get out of possible that some MFIs try to pre-empt others by planting the flag, so to speak, in new hand and needs locations, by forming groups where the arrival of a rival is perceived to be imminent. It is to be handled possible also that there is a sort of herd mentality among MFIs as they follow others to new carefully areas that have been shown to be operable by the first mover. It is surprising again that of all places, Kolkata, and the districts surrounding it, a huge urban and semi-urban conurbation with a population of about 30 million living within a radius of 50 km from Kolkata and accounting for about 40 percent of the population of West Bengal, should figure as a locus of concern about excessive competition.41 Similar concerns are expressed in Bangalore and Hyderabad42. Until technological advances make unique identifiers and credit bureas economical, geographical separation would seem offer one solution, but has not led to any explicit understandings anywhere, on account of fears of "cartelization" restricting competition and leading to anti- consumer behavior. However, even sharing of lists of borrowers is not practiced. Conclusion These are early days yet for urban microfinance. In the major metros it seems to be growing relatively fast in Bangalore, Hyderabad and Kolkata, but more slowly in Mumbai and Delhi, for reasons not entirely clear. Loan demand in Kolkata is particularly strong, and staff easier to recruit because of higher unemployment among youth. Costs could also be lower. It will be interesting to see how the early experiences and issues discussed in this chapter develop. 97
  • 100. Endnotes 1 The task of writing this chapter was made considerably easier by two reports presented at last years' Microfinance India conference: CARE, MSDF and ICICI Bank, 2006, "A Promise to Pay the Bearer: An Exploration of the Potential for Urban Microfinance in India" and a companion volume of case studies, CMF 2006 "Reaching the Other 100 Million Poor in India". I am indebted also to a recent special issue of Microfinance Insights brought out quarterly by Intellecap, on "Reaching out to the Urban Poor" in March 2007, for a number of interesting articles some of them written by the promoters themselves. 2 Examples are Janalakshmi and Ujjivan in Banglore, Swadhaar in Mumai, Mimo Finance in Dehradun and Aajivika in Delhi). 3 Such as Arohan in Kolkata, and Sonata in Allahabad. 4 The phrase is from CARE et al 2006, as are also the phrases "Rural Converts" and "Pioneers" used below. All the "new generation" MFIs mentioned so far have been started by professionals, although not all by former bankers. One of them has worked for the UN, and another is a serving civil servant. It is too early to say whether this could become a trend in the rural areas too, but a former NRI has started a rural MFI in northern Karnataka recently with a strong emphasis on livelihood promotion. 5 Such as Spandana, SHARE, SKS, Bandhan, VWS, Basix, Grameen Koota, Maheseman, and SWAWS, the last of which is almost exclusively urban, with operations in Hyderabad's Old City. 6 Examples are Satin Creditcare in Delhi, MAS Financial Services in Ahmedabad, and Yes Bank in Mumbai. 7 ACCESS is the successor organization to the DFID-assisted CARE-CASHE project, which incubated about 30 rural SHPIs in 3 states including West Bengal, using grants to build capacity and subsidize operational costs. In collaboration with SIDBI, ACCESS intends to incubate 8 nascent MFIs in the Kolkata municipal area, assisting them to develop systems and capacity through mentoring services provided by an Urban Microfinance Resource Centre. It intends to achieve a collective outreach of 40,000 borrowers and a portfolio of Rs 12 crores by the end of Year 1 (June 2008) going up to 1.32, 000 and Rs 120 crores by the end of Year 5. Loan funds will be provided by SIDBI, coupled with grants of up to 25 percent of the loan amounts for capacity building and overheads. The project aims to attain break-even for the MFIs by the end of the 3rd year. ACCESS has similar projects in the MP and Rajasthan, but which are rural. Kolkata was chosen because it is the city in India with the highest population density, containing about 60 percent of the state's urban population, and because of the availability of suitable candidate nascent MFIs, and a history of operation in WB from CASHE days. It will be interesting to see how the incubation approach works out in comparison with the others described here. 8 Thus Janalakshmi and Ujjivan both plan to grow to half a million clients within a few years. Ujjivan now has 3 branches each in Delhi and 5 in Kolkata apart from the 13 in Banglaore, and by March 2008 expects to grow to 100,000 clients within just over two years. 98
  • 101. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance 9 Data is lacking on the respective shares of their rural, peri-urban and urban operations, although in some cases the last two are relatively important, going up to half, reportedly, in the case of Spandana, which has been making daily collection loans in several urban areas for some time now. Basix started expressly urban operations through a small pilot project in Hyderabad in 2004. 10 Yes Bank hopes to reach about 2000 borrowers, mostly the self-employed in need of working capital loans, by March 2008, and is targeting about 150,000 in 5 years out of all its branches, with an average loan size of Rs 35,000. It does require security by hypothecating specific household goods like TV sets, which act as "reputational" collateral. The bank hopes to add new products soon, such as loans for the salaried, fixed asset loans and home improvement loans. It has been urging the RBI to treat a microfinance-only branch (which it is willing to open in Dharavi) as fulfilling the requirement to open one rural branch for every three urban branches. It would also like to receive a license to open a microfinance-only NBFC. 11 The lower cost of SHG loans ( as compared to individual loans) makes it possible for them to be extended at rates below the PLR. 12 The name Microsate comes from a plan to open mobile satellite branches, which was later dropped, although the name was retained. The branch is the subject of one of the case studies in CMF 2006. 13 Referring to the value placed by the Alliance in Mumbai (SPARC, NSDF and Mahila Milan), on savings, for the moral discipline and commitment to the collective that it inculcates, Ruthven 2001 points out that the "mixed and complex agendas of urban development organizations can impose transactions costs on clients in their attempt to access financial services; it can even contribute to the unreliability of a service if more political agendas start to dominate" 14 Several of the statistics in this section are taken from various articles in Intellecap 2007 15 Unlike urban poverty rural poverty is declining both in relative and absolute terms. However the number of rural poor is still three times higher than that of the urban poor. 16 See for instance Ghate 1992 and Rutherford and Arora 1997 17 Or what has been called "reciprocal credit" in Ghate 1992. 18 For many migrants, of course, this may turn out to be a good thing. Not all of them join the pool of the unemployed, although one theory holds this pool will always exist, and its size will depend on the probability of getting a job. 19 Veena Mankar and Lara Gidwani, 2007. This is clearly the case in the older, more settled, slums of which there may be a higher proportion in cities growing less rapidly. 20 Many of them have left without repaying. Similar drives appear to be fairly common in other metros too, as well as resettlement occasioned by the widening of roads and making space for higher income residential neighbourhoods, as in Delhi where Mukherjee describes the snapping of ties between job- work suppliers and workers resettled far away (coincidentally, in Holambi Kalan, the large new resettlement colony, where Aajivika also operates - see below). We are reminded, interestingly, from his study that mobility results also from re-shifting to the original or other neighbourhoods closer to work. (Mukheree, RK, 2004). 99
  • 102. 21 Inter-state migration according to the 2001 census increased by 30 percent over the decade of the 1990s.The largest in-migration states were Maharashtra (7.9 million) Delhi (5.6 million) and West Bengal (5.5 million) (Mukherjee, Piyasree, 2007). Half a million people are said to migrate into Mumbai every year, most of them swelling Mumbai's slum population which already accounts for 60 percent of the total population of about 15 million. An estimate of the annual increment to Delhi's slums is 300,000 a year, or 3 percent of the city's population. 22 She reminds us also that not all of them are poor. An estimate of mobility in the Mumbai occupational segments referred to below is that the average period for which an individual stays in the same house is 28 months. 23 The urban poverty line for a household of five is currently Rs 2270 (Chapter 6). According to Ujjivan 2006, the share of Rs 3000 to Rs 7000 segment was only two-thirds of the 47 percent of the city's population below this income class. Arohan appears to reach lower down the Kolkata income distribution, with 38 percent of its loans being directed to the 31 percent of borrowers in the two monthly per capita expenditure classes below the Rs 700 to Rs 900 class in which its average borrower falls (Arohan 2007). 24 Mehta 2007. This recognition is of course not new. It has long been arrived at with respect to rural microfinance, and there is no reason why urban practitioners should feel defensive about it. Microfinance is ill-suited to solving the problem of chronic income deficits. However it is also the case that there are many potential borrowers whose income deficits could be removed by credit, combined usually with other inputs. The challenge is to identify such persons and arrange for the provision of the other inputs by some other agency if necessary. There is also the question of the level of income at which such deficits turn from being usually temporary to becoming permanent. Defining the target group too conservatively finesses all these challenges. The method of exclusion used by one urban MFI is to set the monthly group savings requirement (referred to as a security deposit, which NBFCs are allowed to collect) high enough to be affordable only to the target group. 25 Having a fixed abode is a much less stringent requirement than owning or renting a house. Indeed as the customer satisfaction survey conducted for Arohan (Arohan 2007) says, "in the slum areas there is rarely any rent being paid and the people dwelling there are staying since long and hence the accommodation pattern is taken as ownership." Those renting constitute 30 percent of the sample. In contrast among Ujjivan's members, as many as 40 percent own their accommodation, about 50 percent rent it, and 10 percent "lease" it (as defined below). Overall, only 61 percent of the urban population own their dwelling units as against 93 percent in the rural areas, according to NSS 2001 data. 26 They point out that while JLG members may be willing to pitch in for fellows when they are experiencing temporary cash flow problems, they tend to put their foot down after say three missed monthly installments. It is often forgotten that the quality of JLGs themselves varies. Arohan 2007 found that of JLG members, only 44 percent could identify all other JLG members by name and purpose of loan taken. Seventeen percent could not identify some other JLG members by name, and 33 percent could not identify the purpose of the loans taken by some JlG members. Six percent could not identify any member by name or loan purpose. The situation varied by branch. 27 Aajivika tried this, but found that SHG members were unwilling to trust it with their savings unless deposited in their name in a bank. 100
  • 103. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance 28 In Arohan's case the share of the self-employed is 55 percent. SEWA's very name indicates it is primarily for self-employed women. 29 Rag pickers and hawkers were found to have the lowest daily income (Rs 60 and Rs 80 respectively. 30 Interestingly, migrant construction workers were not included, perhaps because in Mumbai construction workers are not as visible, as they do not live in temporary colonies next to the building site like those in smaller or more spacious cities, but tend to disperse themselves among the neighbouring population. 31 Interestingly, both MFI's educational loans are repayable in 10 monthly installments. VWS' carry a lower rate than other loans. 32 As the customer satisfaction survey says "it is noted with pleasure that on the whole the customers are satisfied with loan tenure, its rate of interest, the EWI amount, other costs involved, repayment modalities and necessary formalities". The rate of interest is presently 30 percent but is planned to be reduced to 24 percent. However, 90 percent of customers wanted larger loans and 20 percent fortnightly or monthly instead of weekly repayments. Minimum loan size is presently Rs 5000. VWS has chosen the middle path and opted for fortnightly meetings and repayments, which gives field workers more time for group formation work. 33 Thus in late 2006, SWAWS started making individual loans of between Rs 20,000 to Rs 50,000 at 15 percent flat, mostly for income generation activities. Loans are disbursed as demand drafts and security is taken in the form of post-dated cheques and sureties by guarantors. They still account only for about 5 to 6 percent of the portfolio but are finding a ready market in new centres such as Coimbatore to which SWAWS is expanding. VWS has a similar product, which is appraised by the branch manger instead of field staff. Spandana and the other large MFIs have been making individual loans for some time. It would be instructive to compare the profitability of individual loans with group loans for a group of MFIs. Their unit administration costs should be lower given larger average loan size. 34 It did attempt a closer than arms-length association with SHGs by requiring its own field workers to participate in training, and ensuring that proper group records were maintained. Apart from hoping to ensure that credit-histories of group members were built up, this was also in keeping with the Grameen tradition of monitoring the use of loans in accordance with its stated purpose. By making personal loans Ujjivan and other MFIs have released borrowers from the pretense that the loan is being used for a "productive" purpose, but it does like to ensure that the loan is being used for the stated purpose, whatever that be. 35 See Box 5.5, Chapter 5,on Swayanshree, an SHG federation in Cuttack, which has recently started organizing JLGs in addition to its SHGs. 36 Thus Ujjivan has partitioned space off in branch offices for this purpose. 37 Reportedly, there are on an average two cooperative banks in every slum in Mumbai, and the number of credit societies operating in Mumbai is one hundred, including 10 in Dharavi (Caitlin, would be useful to give the reference here). 38 It will be interesting to see whether the greater sophistication of urban borrowers leads to greater transparency on matters such as the effective interest rate. 39 Thus VWS has an OPD centre in each branch with a doctor and generic drugs available at a 60 percent 101
  • 104. discount. Fees per visit are Rs 35 for borrowers and Rs 40 for members of the public. The scheme pays for itself at a break-even level of 50 patients a day. VWS also has a very popular compulsory health insurance scheme with an annual premium of Rs 300 for a family of up to 4 members that includes maternity, caesarian and fractures without the need for hospitalization. The scholarships of Rs 100 go to students who come first, second, or third in classes 7 to 10. VWS legal form as a S 25 company makes it easier to use surpluses for microfinance and charitable activities. 40 The cards will be able to handle all of the several VWS products. Card holders who pay a one-time charge of Rs 50 will be entitled to borrow emergency loans or up to Rs 2000 repayable within 8 weeks. 41 Especially in the North 24-Parganas just north of the Kolkata municipal area. Incumbent WB MFIs such as Bandhan, Village Welfare Society, and Arohan, and at least 4 SIDBI borrowers about to convert to NBFC status, have been joined recently by out-of-state MFIs SKS and Ujjivan. In addition, as mentioned above, ACCESS Development Services is in the process of incubating 8 MFIs in the inner Kolkata muncipality area. Bandhan with an outreach of 4.3 lakhs in January 2007 is by far the largest. Of its 300 odd branches 30 are urban of which 13 are in Kolkata proper. VWS had an outreach of 63,000 in March 2007 with half its portfolio urban. Other MFIs with a presence in the greater Kolkata metropolitan area (including Kolkata municipality), are, in approximate order of size, Sahara Utsarg, Kalighat SDF, Rakapur SN, Ullon SSW, and HDC. Arohan has started operations in the inner Kolkata municipal area but has plans to expand outwards. The consumer satisfaction survey done for Arohan found that 15 to 20 percent of its borrowers have borrowings from other individuals and institutions, formal and informal, including 7 percent from other MFIs. Arohan has a policy of lending to persons who have up to one loan from another MFI, but no more. However as Shubhankar Sengupta, the CEO points out, customers are not always candid about other loans. In the case of VWS the extent of overlapping was found to be about 40 percent in one branch. Aiming to build up a presence so strong that it will dissuade competitors from entering, VWS has opted for an "intensive" strategy in a limited number of blocks (which could increase to 25 from the present 18, in four districts) by covering at least half the target group of poor households in each block (or about 10,000 borrowers in each block). On competition in West Bengal, see also the article by Chandra Shekhar Ghosh, the CEO of Bandhan (Ghosh 2007). Since Ghosh's article was written, WB MFIs have formed an association to coordinate their activities. Also, the DMs have been asked by the government to hold a coordination meeting every month. 42 Janalakshmi and Ujjivan, both plan to grow to a size of about half a million in a few years, as we have seen, growing outwards from Bangalore city. Spandana and SKS have also commenced operations in the area. Spandana, SWAWS, Basix and Roshan Vikas all operate in Hyderabad. It is interesting that SWAWS gives as the reason for dropping Grameen Bank's well known 2:2:1 system, the need to become more accommodating with growing competition from Spandana. 102
  • 105. CHAPTER 5 Urban Microfinance References Arohan, 2007, "A Survey and Critical Study on the Customer Satisfaction of the Customers of Arohan), Report done by Friday Solutions, Kolkata, mimeo CARE, MSDF and ICICI Bank, 2006, "A Promise to Pay the Bearer: An Exploration of the Potential for Urban Microfiinance in India", report presented at Microfinance India Conference, October 29 and 30, New Delhi Centre for Micro Finance (CMF), 2006, "Reaching the Other 100 Million Poor in India" Microfinance India Conference, report presented at Microfinance India Conference, October 29 and 30, New Delhi DHAN Foundation, 2005, "Impacting Urban Poverty Through Microfinance: The SPMS Experience", DHAN Foundation, Madurai. Ghate, Prabhu, 1992, "Informal Finance: Some Findings from Asia", OUP for ADB, Hong Kong Ghosh, Chandra Shekhar, 2007, "Challenges of Scaling Up", in Intellecap 2007 Intellecap 2007, "Reaching out to the Poor", special issue of Microfinance Insights, Vol 2, March, Mumbai Mankar, Veena, and Lara Gidwani, 2007, "Metro Microfinance: Opportunities and Challenges in Mumbai", in Intellecap 2007. Mehta, Aditi, 2001, "Innovating Financial Services Delivery for the Urban Poor", in Intellecap, 2007 Mukherjee, Piyasree, 2007, "Access to Finance:The Barrier to Mobility" in Intellecap, 2007 Mukheree, RK, 2004, "Study of the Demand for Micro Financial Services and Livelihood Promotion Services in Delhi", conducted for Indian Grameen Services, New Delhi, Mimeo Pasheva, Vanya and Manasee Desai 2006, in CMF 2006. Rutheford, Stuart, and Sukhwinder Arora, 1997, City Savers, "How the Poor, DFID, and its Partners are Promoting Financial Services in Urban India (full reference?) Ruthven, O, 2001, 'Money Mosaics: Financial Choice and Strategy in a West Delhi Squatter Settlement", Paper No 32, Working Paper Series, Finance and Development Research Programme, University of Manchester, also published in Journal of International Development Also available on http://www.sed.manchester.ac.uk/idpm/publications/fd/fdwp32.pdf Ujjivan, 2006. "A Study of Economically Active Poor Women in Bangalore -- 2005", Report done for Ujjivan by Delphi Research Services, Bangalore 103
  • 106. 104
  • 107. CHAPTER 6 Social performance in Indian microfinance CHAPTER 6 Social performance in Indian microfinance Frances Sinha1 For most microfinance institutions (MFIs) and those that work with MFIs (banks, investors, In this chapter we present the donors) microfinance is a social enterprise. As an enterprise, the organisation is a business new perspective that aims to cover its costs and be financially sustainable. As a social enterprise, the business on social is a means to achieving social goals. Different organisations - or models of microfinance - performance that is wider may articulate some variation in their social goals or mission. Nevertheless, there is agreement than impact, that social goals in microfinance generally include serving poor people, serving people otherwise but at the same excluded from formal financial services, providing appropriate financial services, contributing time practical. Through to employment, contributing to positive change for clients and their households, contributing defining to poverty reduction and being socially responsible. different dimensions of social Financial sustainability is important. An MFI that can cover its costs - has good financial performance, we performance - can grow to serve more clients in more areas. The growth in microfinance in are able to look India - and elsewhere in the world - is most probably due in large part to mechanisms that are at ways in which MFIs can financially sustainable, or on track to being sustainable. We have the systems to track financial themselves sustainability, with definitions and indicators for reporting on financial performance. These manage their social are now almost routinely included in the annual reports of MFIs; over 35 MFIs in India report performance, on them to the Microfinance Information eXchange (the MIX);2 and these are the indicators and identify the applied in credit ratings. indicators that are relevant to social reporting On the social side, the reporting is less widespread. We have relied on impact assessments to provide the main evidence, with the focus on exploring the contribution of microfinance to various aspects of change. Impact studies are of varying complexity and quality - and their analysis is sometimes suspect and not readily understood. Though, overall, the evidence tends to be positive, but nuanced. In this chapter we present the new perspective on social performance that is wider than impact, but at the same time practical. Through defining different dimensions of social performance, we are able to look at ways in which MFIs can themselves manage their social performance, and identify the indicators that are relevant to social reporting. These indicators are currently being tested by M-CRIL in its pioneering initiative to develop social rating as a complementary activity to credit rating - a new form of social performance assessment. So far, M-CRIL has undertaken seven social ratings in India supported by Friends of Women's World Banking and the Ford Foundation, and also nine poverty audits supported by SIDBI. Some of the findings from these social assessments are summarised as part of this chapter. But first, what do we mean by social performance? 105
  • 108. Unpacking the concept of social performance A number of international initiatives have come together as part of the Social Performance Task Force3 to reach consensus on the following definition of social performance. Social performance in microfinance is defined as "the translation of mission into practice in line with accepted social goals": These social goals relate to • reaching poor or excluded clients • improving the quality and appropriateness of financial services • contributing to employment and enterprise growth Social performance is • improving the economic and social conditions of clients and their households not only the • and ensuring social responsibility to clients, to staff and to the communities in end result, but the entire which they work process of achieving that Under this definition, impact, which refers to changes in the conditions of clients or the result. As such community that can be attributed to the microfinance programme, is just one aspect of social the focus shifts from trying to performance. Social performance is not only the end result, but the entire process of achieving prove an end that result. As such the focus shifts from trying to prove an end result to looking at the steps result to to get there, and managing and reporting on those steps that are likely to lead to positive looking at the steps to get social outcomes. Box 6.1 shows the different steps involved. there Box 6.1 Dimensions of Social Performance INTENT AND DESIGN What is the mission of the institution? Does it have clear social objectives based on its mission? Do its objectives include formulation of principles of social responsibility? INTERNAL SYSTEMS & OPERATIONS Are systems designed and in place to achieve those objectives? Does the institution have information to track performance towards those objectives? OUTPUTS Who does the institution serve? Is it reaching intended clients? Is it serving poor people? Are the financial services catering to their needs and capacities? OUTCOMES Have clients and their households experienced social and economic improvements? OR IMPACT Can these improvements be attributed to institutional activities? [C-GAP, 2007, and Sinha, Frances, 2006] 106
  • 109. CHAPTER 6 Social performance in Indian microfinance • Social performance starts with analysis of the declared social objectives of institutions (intent and design). • Does the institution have a social mission and, whatever the social missions may be, are social goals clearly defined and articulated to conform to the social mission? • Social performance includes assessment of internal systems and operations. • Are systems and operations aligned to mission and achievement of social goals? • Is progress towards these goals being tracked? • Social performance includes social responsibility: • Does the institution have a policy on social responsibility - to clients, staff, community and the environment? • Are there systems in place to ensure compliance? • Social performance is about outputs. • Is the institution reaching large numbers of poor? excluded or marginal people? ...the basic • Do products cater to the needs and capacities of intended clients? principle of SPM is that social • Social performance is also about outcomes-are clients improving their social and economic benefits are conditions, for themselves and for their families? more likely to • And finally social performance is indeed about impact; exploring causality between happen if an MFI deliberately programme participation and changes in the conditions of clients and their households. manages the process towards Towards social performance management by MFIs achieving them Most MFIs have a social mission. Putting that mission into practice - doing so in a systematic way - is what social performance management (SPM) is about. Social benefits may result from microfinance interventions. But the basic principle of SPM is that social benefits are more likely to happen if an MFI deliberately manages the process towards achieving them. As part of routine financial performance management, an institution defines its organisational and financial targets, and puts systems in place to build efficiency and portfolio quality with regular monitoring, tracking and reporting on key indicators and ratios. A similar process can contribute to social performance management, a process which involves clarifying social goals and objectives, defining social responsibility principles, aligning strategies and systems to achieve those goals, strengthening the information system to monitor and assess progress and compliance, and using this information to improve performance. The process of starting SPM involves a set of core performance questions: • Are you clear about: what type of areas you aim to work in? who are your target clients? how do you define your target clients? • Do you know whether you are reaching your target clients? • Do you monitor and understand whether your services are appropriate to your target clients? • Do you monitor how long clients stay with your programme? • Do you monitor and understand why some clients leave or become inactive? • Do you use this information to improve your services? • Do you have clear policies and systems for social responsibility - especially to clients? And also social responsibility to staff, local communities and the environment? • Can you improve the systems and processes through which you answer these questions? 107
  • 110. These questions look ambitious. They raise additional questions of definition, and tools - and how to address them cost-effectively. For example, many MFIs mention the 'poor' as their target group. How then to define 'poor', and measure poverty levels? Similarly, many clients may be leaving, but how to track the drop-out rate? What are the key elements of social responsibility relevant to MFIs? These are areas that are now receiving technical attention. It took ten years (yes ten!) to reach a level of consensus on financial indicators, definitions and reporting systems. We are in the start-up phase for social reporting. And there is a lot of interesting work going on. Some of it is happening here in India, and part of this new area of social assessment is M- CRIL's pioneering of a methodology for social rating. A new form of social assessment - social rating These questions The development of a social rating methodology has the potential to contribute to four look ambitious. important goals in microfinance: They raise additional questions of • assist microfinance institutions to identify both whether they are achieving their definition, and social mission and the institutional factors that may be facilitating or hindering tools - and how achieving this target; to address them cost-effectively. • assist potential investors and donors in their review of microfinance institutions as For example, many MFIs part of their monitoring and due diligence processes; mention the • increase the transparency of the microfinance field; and 'poor' as their target group. • if adopted widely, establish social performance as equally important as financial How then to sustainability in microfinance. define 'poor', and measure poverty levels? A social rating aims to be a relatively quick, low cost assessment, similar to credit rating. As in Similarly, many credit rating, the social rating uses information available with the MFI to the extent possible, clients may be drawing on available documentation and data, and discussions with staff at all levels. It leaving, but how to track covers both the process (intent, policies, design, systems) and part of the results (outreach the drop-out and appropriate services) along the dimensions of social performance as outlined in Figure 1. rate? A social rating is not an impact assessment. That is a more complex exercise. But if there is information on impact - or outcomes, and the information is robust, then the social rating can report on the impact findings. Fig 6.1 Assessing social performance [------------------PROCESS-----------------] [------------------RESULTS---- Social Rating [C-GAP, 108
  • 111. CHAPTER 6 Social performance in Indian microfinance How do we obtain information on the outputs, to understand: who the clients are? do they match the MFI's target group? are the financial services appropriate? Most MFIs do not have this information (some may, , if they are implementing social performance management). So as to obtain direct client-level information about outreach to target groups and feedback on services provided, M-CRIL includes as part of the social rating exercise a small field survey, covering a sample of recent clients (to capture outreach profile on entry) and FGDs with older clients (for market feedback on MFI services). The field-work is undertaken in 3-5 clusters selected as representative of the MFI's current operations. The social rating sample covers a minimum of 127 clients from an average of four clusters. 127 is the minimum statistical level which gives a confidence level of 95% and precision of +/-10%.4 A larger sample size might be preferred, and can be done, but would take more time and cost more! A social rating aims to cover all the dimensions up to outcomes/impact. In covering the A social rating aims to cover all steps of the process that lead to impact, the social rating can be seen as a good predictor of the dimensions impact, an assessment of whether the MFI is on track to achieve its social goals. Or, in rating up to outcomes/ terminology, it is an assessment of the risk of non-achievement - or mission drift. impact. In covering the steps of the Findings - social ratings and poverty audits process that lead to impact, the social rating Key findings from the seven social ratings undertaken so far in India, with support from FWWB can be seen as a and the Ford Foundation, are summarised here, supplemented by additional information from good predictor of impact, an a number of poverty audits undertaken with support from SIDBI. The social rating exercise, assessment of including the field work requires a team working up to 8-10 days with the MFI and in the whether the MFI field. The poverty audit was a quicker exercise, carried out over 3-5 days, with less detailed is on track to achieve its review of MFI systems, and client profiling based on FGDs with a smaller sample (therefore less social goals. Or, robust than those from the social ratings). The presentation broadly follows the dimensions of in rating social performance (as outlined in Figure 1), covering process (intent and design, systems) terminology, it is an and results (outputs - outreach and appropriate services). assessment of the risk of non- achievement - or mission drift Twelve MFIs We have social performance data from twelve MFIs, MFIs covered: eight from the south, four from the north. These Social Rating Poverty Audit MFIs are quite representative of MFIs in the country: South: five follow the Grameen model, three the SHG model, BWDA ASA three are Cooperatives (MACS) and one follows the ASP SKS individual model. The data is mainly from 2006. BASIX PWMACS The 12 MFIs together represent over 1 million AMMACTS microfinance clients. SWAWS North: Cashpor RGVN Bandhan NBJK 109
  • 112. Institutional processes as part of social performance Intent and Design The mission statements of the twelve MFIs include reference to: • serving the poor and vulnerable (10 MFIs) • enhancing community capacities (4) • women's empowerment (4) • improved livelihoods (2) • poverty reduction (2) • quality services (2) Accordingly, the Whilst the overall orientation is usually clear, the meaning of key terms is not so clear and is not mission is no more than a usually defined by the MFIs. For example, who is 'poor'?, in what way will community capacities be rhetorical enhanced? what counts as women's 'empowerment'? what counts as poverty reduction? Accordingly, statement or the mission is no more than a rhetorical statement or wish; it is not translated into social wish; it is not translated into objectives that are the first step to putting mission into practice, objectives that are SMART social (specific, measurable, adequate, relevant, time-bound) and strategic (what leads to what). objectives that are the first Out of twelve MFIs, three had clear definition of key terms (poor, vulnerable social groups, step to putting mission into improved livelihoods). One of the three had gone further to develop SMART social objectives. practice, objectives that Governance appeared fairly well balanced in terms of financial and social experience and are SMART (specific, orientation, but reporting remains primarily financial - both within the organisation, and measurable, externally, in for example annual reports. adequate, relevant, time- Services and access bound) and strategic (what leads to what) The range of services include general/enterprise loans starting at Rs2-5,000, some larger (individual) loans (Rs15,000-30,000) including in the MACS and SHG model MFIs. Along with credit, loan insurance and savings (or security deposits) are compulsory in 8 of the 12 MFIs. A few MFIs offer additional loans: an education loan of Rs1-10,000, emergency loan Rs500- 1,000, and offer insurance products (with linkages to formal sector insurance companies mainly for life and health). A few also offer non-financial services, directly, or through linkages to other providers - services such as agricultural/business development support, health and education as part of community development, gender training, a school. Access to such services is quite low, usually under 10%. Additional MFI services Services Number of MFIs providing % clients accessing (prev yr) Education loan 1 3% Emergency loan 1 <0.1% Life/medical other insurance 7 <20% Non-financial services 5 6% - 30% 110
  • 113. CHAPTER 6 Social performance in Indian microfinance Internal systems The conceptual framework for social performance includes an analysis of operational systems to see whether they support the mission - in particular, targeting strategy, staff training and incentives, and systems for MIS, monitoring and reporting. In terms of targeting, the main approach is area targeting. MFIs may select less developed states and less developed regions within states, and slum or low income areas in cities. One MFI also strategically targets poor clients and monitors poverty profile at entry. Another targets SC/ST and backward castes. Some MFIs are beginning to cater to different market segments (with Joint Liability Groups, often men, alongside SHGs, and at different income levels), though without specifically planning for what proportion of their clients (or portfolio) should be from different segments. In relation to human resources - orientation and incentives - the mission and values are usually In terms of part of staff induction. But in practice, the main emphasis is on financial management and targeting, the main approach growth, as reflected in incentive systems that emphasis productivity (client numbers) and on- is area time repayment. Though one MFI includes an incentive linked to coverage of poorer clients. targeting. MFIs may select less In terms of monitoring and MIS, there is substantial scope for MFIs to strengthen their developed states and less routine data collection and analyzing portfolio information from a social perspective. Many developed have interesting information fields relevant to client profiling in their loan appraisal formats regions within states, and but this is not being completed systematically or used for tracking outreach or market segments slum or low (except by one MFI). Portfolio information can be analysed not only to track growth and income areas in arrears, but to track client retention over time, how many stay for how many loan cycles, what cities. One MFI also is the dropout rate, what differences are there for rural and urban clients, or for women and strategically men clients (if an MFI has both). A few MFIs have started applying or have commissioned targets poor clients and market research surveys, though most rely on informal feedback from staff. monitors poverty profile Results - Outreach at entry Areas For information on outreach, we first look at areas of operation, including rural/urban distribution and analysing the district (branch) distribution of clients with reference to development ranking of districts in the country. Based on data from the 2001 Census, the 593 districts in the country are divided into development quintiles based on literacy rates, as a proxy for development level. Overall, in the sample, MFI outreach is proportionate (with 20% in the bottom district quintile, 41% in the lowest two district quintiles). The five-six MFIs with no clients in the lower district quintiles are located in the southern states. The majority of MFIs have mainly rural clients. Rural/urban classification is usually based on administrative definitions. MFI outreach - rural and less developed districts % of clients: 0 <20% 21-55% >55% Average - in bottom district quintile 6 2 3 1 20% - in two lowest district quintiles 5 3 4 41% - rural 1 1 10 69% 111
  • 114. Beyond this broad (rural/urban) classification, it would be interesting to capture extent of outreach in semi-urban/semi-rural areas. This would cover market town areas as a separate category (from rural) - with different implications for livelihoods, appropriate products and MFI costs of operations. Reaching the unreached (financial inclusion) Secondly we seek information to understand whether the MFI is serving the poor and excluded. To obtain this information we undertake a small field survey of recent clients (noted above), i.e. clients who have recently joined the MFI (within one year) so as to capture their profile on entry (before the likelihood of change). The sample size averaged 152/social rating and To capture exclusion, we 48/poverty audit. The total sample for 12 MFIs is 1,306. analyse whether clients are from To capture exclusion, we analyse whether clients are from vulnerable communities (such as SC/ vulnerable ST) or from households without alternative access to formal or semi-formal finance. From the communities (such as SC/ST) rating sample, we find that most MFIs have a proportion of SC/ST above the national average, or from reflecting substantial outreach to these communities. Interestingly, though, we find that not households without all client households have been excluded from formal financial services. On average 26% have alternative a bank or post office savings account; 12% have had a bank loan in the previous three years. access to formal This compares with the 36% national figure. And 6% of client households have members in or semi-formal finance. From another MFI, or an SHG (with this figure higher for southern MFIs. the rating sample, we find Reaching the unreached that most MFIs have a % of recent client households Range Average All India populationa proportion of SC/ST above SC/ST 15% - 57% 33% 25% the national average, With savings in bank or post office 14% - 39% 26% 36% reflecting substantial With bank loan in previous 3 years 2% - 21% 12% outreach to these With client in other MFI or SHG 2% - 13% 6% communities a Census of India, 2001 A key question is poverty outreach. As we have seen, all the MFIs have a mission to serve the poor. How many clients are poor when they join? And how do we define poverty? A useful benchmark is the poverty line, the $1/day at purchasing power parity (PPP) which, currently at Rs17.5/day or Rs524/person/month is just above the Indian poverty line (Rs395/person/ month rural, Rs454 urban).5 The social rating questionnaire includes two pages to estimate client household income in detail, from which the per capita per day figure can be calculated. Alternatively, and more easily, a poverty score card has now been developed for India.6 We have used both methods, to find poverty levels mostly at or less than the estimated poverty rate in the country. Outreach to those below $1/day varies substantially around the average, which at 30% is slightly below the All India poverty incidence. Most of the MFIs rated are below the average. One MFI with a strong strategic focus on poverty outreach has 68% of its clients below the poverty line when they joined the programme. 112
  • 115. CHAPTER 6 Social performance in Indian microfinance Serving the poor % of recent client households Range Average All India populationa < $1/day at PPP 13% - 68% 30% 39% a NSSO, 2005 These figures are pause for thought. Is this the depth of outreach intended for microfinance? By MFIs whose stated mission is to serve the poor and contribute to poverty reduction? Are there elements in their operations which need strategic review, so as to align with a deeper poverty focus? Microfinance and women The majority of MFI clients are women, with eight MFIs working only with women clients. The Outreach to balance in staff is skewed to men, due partly to issues of field mobility, especially in the those below $1/day varies northern states. Two MFIs have less than 10% staff who are women, including one in the south. substantially around the Women as clients and staff of MFIs average, which at 30% is <50 51-99% 100% Average slightly below the All India % women clients 1 3 8 86% poverty incidence. Most % women staff 10 2 32% of the MFIs rated are below the average. Gender related indicators, beyond the number of women, relate to women's schooling at leat One MFI with a strong strategic up to primary (which at 35% on average can affect awareness and understanding of MFI focus on information and services), whether the household is woman headed (which is an indicator of poverty poverty especially if there are no adult male earners in the family), and women clients' involvement outreach has 68% of its in managing an enterprise for which they have taken a loan. On average, just over one in five clients below women clients manage by themselves the enterprise for which they take credit, another 40% the poverty line manage jointly with a husband or son, and a similar percentage pass the loan to a male when they joined the relative. This has implications for women's empowerment. In one MFI, working with urban programme. women, women's independent enterprise activity was the highest (over 70%). These figures are pause for thought. Is this Gender related indicators the depth of outreach % of recent women clients Range Average intended for microfinance? Have completed primary school or above 14% - 63% 35% Are women heads of households with no adult male earner 3% - 10% 4% Manage credit supported enterprise: Yes - by herself 12% -72% 22% Yes - jointly with husband/son 25% - 44% 40% No - husband/son manages (loan pass) 3% - 45% 38% 113
  • 116. Microfinance and employment (indirect outreach) Additional profile information from the rating survey relates to employment or 'indirect' outreach. The majority of enterprises supported by microfinance are usually family based micro-enterprises, providing self-employment to family members. If hired labour is employed in an enterprise, micro-credit can be seen to be supporting employment for others who are not direct MFI clients - and may be of a lower income category. This is likely for larger micro-enterprises or 'small enterprises'. In five MFIs for which we have this information, an average 8% of enterprises The findings are with credit have employed non-family labour, with an average employed of 2.4. that clients are mostly aware of Employment in credit supported enterprises the notional interest on Range [5 MFIs] Average loans and interest % supported enterprises with hired (non-family) 3% - 11% 8% receivable on employees savings deposits Average number of hired employees in such enterprises 1.6 - 3.7 2.4 (though in a couple of MFIs awareness is Results - Appropriate Services 60% or less). Few clients The first set of questions under appropriate services, relates to client awareness of the financial (around half) on average are products and terms of the MFI. This is a key element of social responsibility to clients, aware of the reflecting effective communication and transparency. These questions are covered as part of details of costs the rating survey, with reference to each MFI's specific services, and the responses are quantified. (interest on declining basis, The findings are that clients are mostly aware of the notional interest on loans and interest break-up of loan receivable on savings deposits (though in a couple of MFIs awareness is 60% or less). Few fees), and loan insurance (what clients (around half) on average are aware of the details of costs (interest on declining basis, is covered) break-up of loan fees), and loan insurance (what is covered). Client awareness of financial services % who know Range Average Notional interest on credit and repayment instalments 60% - 98% 78% Interest on savings deposits 55% - 91% 77% More details of costs (EIR, declining interest, break-up of 31% - 90% 52% loan fees) Details of loan insurance 30% - 89% 49% 114
  • 117. CHAPTER 6 Social performance in Indian microfinance Client feedback is obtained through Focus Group Discussions with older clients. This provides both positive feedback, and some suggestions to the MFI. Examples of client feedback on MFI services (from FGDs) Clients like • timely credit, without collateral • savings - where available - no other option for saving small amounts • discipline of weekly repayments (mainly non-farm enterprises, in market centres) • convenient repayment in instalments • grace period (1 MFI): 46 payments over one year • lower interest rate than moneylenders Clients would like • loan products for other credit needs (education) • larger loans, compare cost of dairy animal Rs7-15,000); also demand from better-off clients (around 10% of clients interviewed), urban clients • Monthly loan instalments - rural • Loan insurance to cover husband's death too (in case of women clients) • Avoid high up-front security deposit. A strong indicator of client satisfaction or appropriateness of services is the rate of exit, A strong indicator of particularly dropout. Of course, some clients who leave may be 'fly-outs' who no longer need client microfinance, or may be able to graduate to a formal service. But many who leave (as studies satisfaction or have shown) do so because the microfinance services do not match their requirements, for appropriateness of services is reasons of dissatisfaction, problems with repayment, other financial difficulties. The annual the rate of exit, dropout rate overall can be estimated from the loan portfolio, based on the number of clients particularly dropout at the end of the previous year, the number of new clients who joined during the year and the total number of clients at the end of the year.7 The data shows higher rates of exit compared to figures from 2002-3 of around 4-6% (M-CRIL data). Where MFIs are growing very fast, the large number of new clients in the year may mask the rate of dropout (just as high disbursement of portfolio can mask the portfolio at risk). Client exit Range Average Dropout rate 5% - 17% 11% Additional analysis would ideally include dropout rate by time with the MFI (or by loan cycle) and by other client characteristics (poverty, social group). In future, we aim too to track client retention in terms of those who stay with the MFI for a certain period of time, say at least three years, or five years - which may be the minimum time within which to achieve 115
  • 118. change, or sustainable impact. Less than this is probably not long enough for substantial change, at least in terms of poverty reduction (provided, that is, it is not the poorer clients who have dropped out of the programme). Future directions The social The social rating tool has been under development. Its full form has now evolved in line with rating tool has the understanding of what social performance is, and what are the key indicators of achieving been under development. social performance. It therefore now includes, for example, more details of social responsibility: Its full form has whether MFIs are putting into practice key elements of the Code of Conduct towards clients, now evolved in line with the recently framed by Sa-Dhan. understanding of what social The selected findings presented here are an example of social performance assessment, related performance is, to indicators that it is hoped MFIs will increasingly be able and willing to report on. And refer and what are the key to as part of an internal system for social performance management. indicators of achieving social They are indicators that are covered as part of a social rating. This does not go as far as to try performance to assess impact. But the social rating presents a range of information that is relevant to achieving mission and contributing social value. It is therefore a good predictor of impact, and an exercise which is faster and cheaper than impact assessment. 116
  • 119. CHAPTER 6 Social performance in Indian microfinance Endnotes 1 I would like to thank my colleagues in EDA and M-CRIL, past and present, who have worked on the social ratings and poverty audits that provide the material for this chapter. Particularly, Monika Agarwal, LB Prakash, Amit Brar, Komal P Rana, Nishant Tirath and Sudipto Saha. 2 The MIX Market is the global microfinance information marketplace, providing financial data and profiles on microfinance institutions and the microfinance sector on the Internet, at http:// www.themix.org. 3 For more information, please visit http://www.microfinancegateway.org/resource_centers/ socialperformance/ 4 See EDA Technical note: Estimating Sample Size which explains the sampling formula. A larger sample of 340, or 510, would improve precision to +/- 5%. 5 Updated to 2006 based on relevant CPIs agricultural labourers and industrial manual labourers, from World Bank estimates of purchasing power parity for the international poverty line (SEEP, Sillers Donald 2006), and the Deaton adjusted national poverty line, (in Schreiner, 2007) 6 Schreiner, Mark, 2007. The scorecard has 10 relatively simple questions which can be easily answered/ observed about a household without much calculation or judgement. The indicators are: number of children under 17 years, whether house is pucca, whether own a TV, electric fans, almirah, sewing machine, pressure pan, land, primary energy source for cooking, number of acres of land, principal income source for the household . The answers to these questions are scored for their 'poverty probability', with the scores derived from statistical regression of NSSO data. The scores can be linked to any poverty line. For India, they are linked to the international poverty lines - $1 and $2/day. The poverty score card thus provides a simple but statistically robust method for measuring poverty levels. 7 M-CRIL applies the following formula: (Number of clients at beginning of year + New clients during the year - Number of clients at end of year)/ (Number of clients at beginning of year + New clients during the year) A 'dropout' or client who exits is defined as: 'any client who has had not transaction with the MFI for the previous six months'. See M-CRIL Technical Note: Estimating Exit Rate 117
  • 120. References C-GAP, 2007, “Beyond Good Intentions: Measuring the Social Performance of Microfinance Institutions”, Focus Note Number 41, Washington DC Census of India, 2001, Population Tables, Government of India NSSO, 2005, National Sample Survey Organisation, Household Consumer Expenditure in India: NSS 59th Round, January-December 2003. Report No. 490, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation, Government of India Schreiner, Mark, 2007, “Is one poverty score card enough for India?” Washington DC See http://www.microfinance.com/English/Papers/ Sinha, Frances, 2006, “Social Rating and Social Performance Reporting in Microfinance: Towards a Common Framework”, SEEP Occasional Paper, Washington DC 118
  • 121. CHAPTER 7 Micro Insurance CHAPTER 7 Micro Insurance Sai Gunaranjan1 The importance of micro insurance for the poor as a tool to protect livelihoods Financial inclusion of the poor by providing them with access to savings, credit and insurance In the absence forms an integral part of the package of livelihood promotion services that the poor require. of proper risk hedging While a diverse set of both formal and informal institutions have evolved to cater to the mechanisms like savings and credit needs of the poor, there is still a huge gap with respect to insurance insurance, the poor stand to services available for the poor. It is also well understood that the vulnerability to various risks loose their is highest for the poor. In the absence of proper risk hedging mechanisms like insurance, the wages, borrow, poor stand to loose their wages, borrow, liquidate their assets, migrate and face several other liquidate their assets, migrate hardships, which in turn only traps them into a deeper and vicious cycle of poverty. With the and face several increasing prevalence of nuclear families, the informal support system of the joint family too other hardships, which in turn is unavailable for most people today. The penetration of the formal insurance sector is very only traps them low today. Estimates put that less than 15% of the country's population is insured. The into a deeper challenge for providing a whole of range of insurance products to cover the risks related to and vicious cycle of poverty both lives and livelihood generating assets of the poor is huge. However, the current situation is also seen as an opportunity by many players in the insurance industry, to expand and deepen the insurance market in India. MFIs have made major strides to improve the access to credit and savings for the poor. It is imperative for micro finance institutions to seize the moment by actively providing micro insurance services for the poor and thereby contribute to achieving comprehensive financial inclusion of the poor. Issues related to the growth of micro insurance The rapid growth of the micro-credit movement in terms of scale has tempted many to expect a similar growth in micro-insurance. To the extent that micro insurance has grown today, a large chunk of it comprises credit life insurance which is automatically bundled with micro- credit. However providing insurance as a stand alone product for the poor has not been as easy. The reason for this contrast is not difficult to ascertain. Micro credit is largely a pull product (demand driven) whereas micro insurance or any insurance for that matter is a push product which requires significant marketing and sales effort to enrol customers. This transition from selling a pull product to a push product has not been easy for micro credit institutions. To enable this transition, one needs to look at a whole range of issues including capacity building of staff and incentive structures for the staff of micro credit institutions. However, the growth issues of micro insurance are not limited to the distributions channels such as 119
  • 122. MFIs alone; they encompass other stake holders like insurance companies and their ability to provide suitable micro insurance products and service them. Another issue which has to be addressed to promote micro insurance is the sustainability of such programs. The micro credit movement has grown with a strong focus on sustainability of the program to ensure scalability of the models. This has meant that institutions charged interest rates that covered both the cost of capital and cost of operations. In the overall analysis the interest rates charged by these institutions were viable for customers due to the customisation of credit products and the hassle free lending procedures adopted. However the focus on the focus on sustainability of insurance products has not received as much attention as sustainability required by MFIs. This situation is partly due to the fact that the actuarial science involved of insurance products has in pricing of insurance products may not be too well understood by MFIs. Therefore there is a not received as temptation on their part to bargain for rock bottom premium rates from insurance companies, much attention as required by without taking into consideration all the costs that may involved. This can seriously compromise MFIs. This the sustainability and continuity of such products. Currently MFIs may not feel the pinch of situation is such products as they do not underwrite the risk, and given the current market scenario where partly due to the fact that several new insurers are trying to get a foothold in the market, there is always another insurer the actuarial who may be willing to underwrite for a brief period such unsustainable products. The advantage science involved of meeting rural and social sector obligations in a quick manner with such under priced in pricing of insurance products may more than offset the loss making micro risks that an insurer underwrites. The products may answer to this problem is the need for MFIs to work towards building internal capacities to not be too well understood by understand and provide sustainable micro insurance products, as they have done in the area MFIs of micro credit. Challenges to be overcome to achieve sustainable and scalable micro-insurance models Creating actuarial data for micro-insurance, rather than searching for actuarial data to get micro insurance started Most poor people have not had access to insurance in the past as in the present. This translates into absence of data regarding frequencies of various risks faced by them. In the absence of this data, insurance companies are often constrained in their ability to offer products, as the availability of historical data is critical to the design of insurance products. This perpetuates the problem of making insurance products available to the poor. To break the deadlock, insurance companies should be willing to introduce products even in the absence of adequate actuarial data. The incentives for doing this would be: 1. It would help to build data on various risks for this segment of the market, which is huge. This data, and coupled with it the experience in administering micro insurance policies, would serve as an asset for the insurance companies in expand their penetration of the huge and untapped rural market. 2. The marginal error in pricing micro insurance policies in the absence of historical data would not seriously affect the insurance companies as the financial value of risk in micro insurance policies is very marginal compared to the traditional 120
  • 123. CHAPTER 7 Micro Insurance high value insurance contracts underwritten by insurance companies. This marginal risk too can be mitigated by taking a conservative approach to pricing of the micro insurance policies in the inception years and then reviewing the price, based on actual claims experience in subsequent years. 3. Global reinsurers are also beginning to recognise the potential of micro insurance, in order to expand the overall insurance market size. Munich Re and Swiss Re are examples of Global reinsurers who have been actively studying and promoting micro insurance in the Indian insurance market. The willingness and the interest of these re-insurers provide an opportunity to local insurance companies to enter the micro insurance market, by ceding a portion of micro insurance risks to global reinsurers. The reinsurers would be in a better position to absorb the risks from micro insurance programs where the market experience is still in a very nascent stage. Box 7.1 Providing sustainable and competitive insurance products to rural customers BASIX, a livelihood promotion institution set up in 1996, provides both financial and technical assistance services to about half a million households spread over 8 states in India. In October 2002, it began its initiative to provide life insurance cover to customers who took micro credit. BASIX took a group policy from AVIVA which covered its borrower for 1.5 times of the loan amount taken by him or her during the loan tenor. In the absence of any past experience of mortality for the customer profile served by BASIX, AVIVA priced the product conservatively at Rs.8.61per thousand sum insured. By October of 2004, the experience of covering more than 50,000 person years was completed. The positive performance of the product by this stage allowed the insurance company to lower the premium rate to Rs.6.89 per thousand sum insured. A year later in 2005, over 100,000 person years were covered cumulatively. The claims experience gained till then allowed the insurance company to reduce the premium rate to Rs.3.98 per thousand sum insured. Based on the actual performance of the product, BASIX and AVIVA could reduce the premium rate by more than 50% in a three year period. This further allowed BASIX to extend cover to the spouses of the borrowers, as the premium was much more affordable now. This experience proves that a sustainable approach to pricing of micro insurance, combined with proper administration of the products, allows the partners to A major add value to the small premiums paid by its customers. roadblock for rolling out insurance Rationalising underwriting procedures for micro-insurance to make it accessible to products for the target clients poor has been the gap between A major roadblock for rolling out insurance products for the poor has been the gap between expectations of expectations of insurance companies about completing a certain kind of paperwork for issuing insurance insurance contracts, and what the poor can actually provide. The poor and especially those in companies about the rural areas are in a disadvantaged position in terms of their ability to access hospitals, completing a schools and various public utility service providers. The certificates issued by these institutions certain kind of paperwork for often serve as proofs for establishing identity and also age to be considered for an insurance issuing contract. In such scenarios, as in the case of BASIX, the micro insurance service providers insurance have worked with the insurance companies to accept alternative age proofs like declaration of contracts, and what the poor age by community members like SHGs, or even declaration by the individual or the household can actually itself as sufficient for the purpose of extending insurance. This has helped in extending provide 121
  • 124. insurance to individuals who would not have otherwise been insured due to non-availability of formal certificates of age and residence. In the area of health insurance, traditionally, insurance companies have required that a hospital should have at least ten beds to allow policy holders to qualify for re-imbursement of expenses. However, most hospitals in rural areas do not have this kind of infrastructure. Therefore to allow customers to take treatment at rural hospitals, the policy conditions have been simplified in health insurance policies so that customers can get admitted and treated at any registered hospital, even if it does not have the mandatory ten bed infrastructure. This kind of flexibility in re-looking at traditional procedures in administering insurance policies holds the key to unlocking the availability and access of micro insurance to the poor. Creating a conducive environment for the growth of micro insurance a large number Several stages of innovation have yet to be undergone before micro insurance reaches the of micro finance position where micro-credit is today, in terms of productisation and operating systems. While institutions which are micro credit is of interest today for many stakeholders ranging from private to public purpose registered as S institutions, it should be remembered that the sector has reached its current stage over a 25 companies or as NBFCs, span of three decades. During this period, several grass root organisations have grappled with with outreach a host issues to make micro credit work. These included addressing financial capital and grant to millions of requirements for the sector, regulatory bottlenecks, and also product and operating system rural household, are not design and implementation. Each of these areas has gone through various phases of maturity recognised as and iterations to enable the micro credit movement to reach the stage where it is. This long micro insurance agents by micro journey has to be kept in mind while work is being done to replicate the success of micro insurance credit to micro insurance. While the journey of progress in micro insurance can be accelerated, regulation and the issues cited need to be addressed and cannot be bypassed or overlooked. A unique are therefore constrained challenge that the micro insurance movement has to confront is the rather complex task from using the involved in designing and distributing a diverse range of insurance products where knowledge enabling and technical expertise is required from several fields like health care systems, animal husbandry, provisions made under these enterprise valuation, agriculture etc. This calls for a more collaborative approach in actual regulations to delivery of micro insurance products, where expertise from insurers, distributors, and service spread micro insurance on a providers (e.g. health care) needs to be synchronised to achieve a seamless delivery of micro large scale insurance products. The complexity involved in micro insurance is quite evident from the relatively slow introduction and growth of micro insurance among practioners of micro credit. There is certainly a strong case for greater investments into capacity building for potential micro insurance distributors and collaborative partnerships for scaling up of micro insurance. The growth in a nascent sector like micro insurance will also be strongly influenced by the regulatory environment. A major impetus for the growth for micro insurance in India has come from the rural and social sector obligations stipulated under the IRDA Act. This has ensured that all insurance companies in India develop and distribute products for the rural and social sector. Taking this effort forward, IRDA introduced the micro insurance regulations in December, 2005. These regulations aimed at making certain enabling provision to encourage both insurers and micro insurance distributors to actively promote micro insurance. The regulation enable SHGs, societies and co-operatives to function as micro insurance agents and carry out a lot functions like premium collection, policy bond distribution, and claims administration. However, a large number of micro finance institutions which are registered as S 25 companies or as NBFCs, with outreach to millions of rural household, are not recognised as micro insurance 122
  • 125. CHAPTER 7 Micro Insurance agents by micro insurance regulation and are therefore constrained from using the enabling provisions made under these regulations to spread micro insurance on a large scale. Livestock Insurance: insuring the wealth of rural India After agriculture, it is livestock which is the most common source of income for rural households. Very often it provides a supplementary source of income for rural households, helping them to tide over loss of income from other sources. According to the 17th national livestock census conducted in 2003, there were 284 million cattle in India. There was no growth in the cattle population of the country between from 1997 (when the 16th livestock census was conducted) to 2003. In the year 2002-03, according to Department of Animal Husbandry & Dairying, Ministry of Agriculture, 18 million cattle were insured, which means that only 6% of the cattle population was insured. Traditionally, livestock insurance has always been seen as an unattractive portfolio for insurance companies due to its poor financial performance on account of the behavioural risks associated with both customers and service providers. One of the requisites for offering livestock insurance has been the need for getting a certificate from a veterinary if the death of doctor. Many remote places still do not have the services of a veterinary doctor and to get this the cattle takes only adds to the cost of obtaining livestock insurance. To overcome this difficulty, which place when the seriously compromises the ability to offer livestock insurance in rural areas, BASIX worked with market value is at the low end Royal Sundaram to enable the certification of livestock insured through its field staff who are of the cycle, adequately trained in assessing the economics of cattle rearing, and the insurable status of then the farmer cattle. While this arrangement greatly simplifies the ease of insuring animals, great care has suffers considerable also to be exercised by BASIX staff to ensure that proper controls are in place to ensure that loss of future no adverse selection of high risk animals happens. Also, in the event of a claim, if a death value. Besides, it is also certificate cannot be given by a doctor, an inspection and report from a field facilitator difficult for the approved by the insurance company is considered for settlement of claim. There are other key farmer to come issues which had to be addressed to make cattle insurance more attractive to rural customers: to terms with the fact that while he has Assessment of market value at the time of claim paid a premium for a certain Traditionally cattle insurance policies are indemnity based contracts, i.e. the claim amount sum insured, he paid is based on the market value of the animal at the time of death of animal. If the value of gets paid an amount less the animal is greater than the sum insured only then is the sum insured paid. It is known that than that the market value of milching cattle follows an almost cyclical path based on the reproductive stages that they go through. Thus if the death of the cattle takes place when the market value is at the low end of the cycle, then the farmer suffers considerable loss of future value. Besides, it is also difficult for the farmer to come to terms with the fact that while he has paid a premium for a certain sum insured, he gets paid an amount less than that. In order to overcome these situations, BASIX worked with Royal Sundaram to convert the policy to a full benefit policy, i.e one where the claim paid is equal to the sum insured. To ensure that the principle of indemnity is not compromised, the cattle were insured for about only 80% of the animal value. This also ensured that there was an element of self insurance by the farmer, which would translate into better care of the animal. Reducing adverse selection Avoiding adverse selection is a major challenge in livestock insurance. A field staff who is not too technically trained in veterinary science cannot easily asses the exact health status of cattle from mere visual observation. To overcome this challenge, most insurance policies have 123
  • 126. a window period of 10-15 days from the date of tagging after which the risk cover period commences. To further minimise adverse selection, customers are also sometimes incentivised to insure all the cattle in the household by providing a premium discount for insurance of multiple animals. Since most of the lending in micro finance is not necessarily targeted at a single economic activity, most MFIs have not entered the space of insuring the livestock of their clients. Among those MFIs which do lend to specific activities like purchase of livestock, combinations of factors like (i) high premium rates (ranging from 3 to 8 percent of the insured value), (ii) inordinate paper work (iii) a poor history of claims settlements and (iv) issues related to adverse selection deter them from making livestock insurance compulsory for their clients. As the margins Only in specific locations where the above issues can be addressed do MFIs encourage their in pure risk customers to take livestock insurance on a voluntary basis. BASIX has cumulatively insured products (term insurance) are over 40,000 livestock so far. In the recent two years, BASIX has also begun providing preventive thin compared vet care services on a fee basis under its Business Development Services (BDS) program. It to savings products for the currently has close to 50,000 customers who are availing of these services. BASIX expects that insurance the BDS services will result in reducing the risk and thereby reducing mortality of livestock companies, owned by its customers. This would eventually translate into reduction of premium of premium innovative approaches need rates for livestock insurance, making it more attractive to enrol larger number of customers for to be taken to livestock insurance. reduce the transaction costs involved Life insurance in providing term insurance Life insurance has perhaps had the longest innings in the domain of rural insurance, where it is popularly associated with LIC. One of the consequences of this legacy is that insurance is the rural areas is closely associated with savings, under which on maturity of the contract, the customer gets back his premium back with some return on it. However, a high percentage of lapsation of such policies has translated into erosion of the savings of the poor to the tune of a few crores of rupees. Due to the seasonality and unpredictability their incomes, the poor cannot often pay timely renewal premiums, resulting in policy lapsation. In spite of this past experience, the focus on selling savings policies is perpetuated as the insurance agent stands to earn a hefty commission on the first year's premium on such policies. However, what the poor need most is risk protection, which is offered through pure-risk term policies. The lower premium instalments of such policies also make the pure-risk term polices more affordable for the poor. As the margins in pure risk products (term insurance) are thin compared to savings products for the insurance companies, innovative approaches need to be taken to reduce the transaction costs involved in providing term insurance. One way to address this is to take the cue from how micro credit has addressed the problem of transaction costs through the group approach. Today all BASIX borrowers and also their spouses are covered under a group policy called Credit Plus, a product from AVIVA. This group product covers each of the insured individuals to 1.5 times of the loan amount taken. This ensures that in an unfortunate event of the death of the insured person, not only is the loan amount written off, but the dependent also gets some additional financial support to cover immediate financial needs. Another unique feature of the Credit Plus policy is that it provides borrowers with the convenience of paying the insurance premium in small monthly instalments to the insurance 124
  • 127. CHAPTER 7 Micro Insurance company along with their loan repayments. By the end of September 2007, BASIX had covered 0.5 million individuals under this policy. Cumulatively it has settled life insurance claims to about 2000 families amounting to Rs 3 crores. Under the IRDA act, all insurance companies are mandated to achieve a certain number of policies in the rural and social sector. This combined with the new micro insurance regulations are giving a new impetus to providing affordable term policies for the poor. Today, with 16 life insurance companies operating, a reasonable number of term insurance products are available in the market. Health insurance For many poor who do not have any significant assets, their body is their only asset. They Given the earn their livelihood, which often borders on subsistence, by engaging in both farm and non- enormity of the challenge farm labour. Health risks seriously affect such households, as they not only lack the financial involved in resources to pay for health care, but also stand to loose their only source of income from providing health care financing labour. However, the perils of ill health do not restrict its impact to the above category of options, it is people. It also has a serious impact on not-so-poor people, as health care costs are spiralling, not surprising and are unaffordable even by middle class income standards. This problem is further compounded that the micro health insurance by reduced public spending on health care, leaving most people to meet health care costs out sector has seen of pocket. Given the enormity of the challenge involved in providing health care financing numerous initiatives, options, it is not surprising that the micro health insurance sector has seen numerous initiatives, making it one making it one of the most active and innovative fields in the domain of micro insurance. of the most There are a variety of models which are emerging in this sector, some which are underwritten active and innovative by insurance companies, some self managed within the community or an institution without fields in the a tie with an insurance company and some of which are hybrid of both formal and in-house domain of micro insurance insurance arrangements. A compilation of the various micro health insurance programs carried out by ILO under its STEP program indicate that close to 9 million people are insured in about 90 micro health insurance programs in India. Of these, the two biggest schemes are (i) Yashashwini which is managed by a trust with contributions from the state government and users from cooperatives in Karnataka, currently covering over 2 million individuals. This makes it one of the largest micro insurance programs in the world and interestingly the risks are not underwritten by an insurer, and (ii) the Sampoorna Suraksha health insurance scheme introduced by SKDRDP trust based at Dharmasthala in Karnataka. It covers today over 7 lakh individuals, and the risk is currently underwritten by ICICI Lombard. The uniqueness of both these models is that the health insurance program is independent of any micro credit program. It is a clear indicator that the penetration of micro insurance on a large scale does not have to be entirely dependent on the availability of the micro credit vehicle. While this may be the case, micro finance institutions certainly possess the necessary outreach and experience in financial services to give a major fillip to providing access to micro insurance for the poor. An increasing number of micro finance institutions are introducing micro health insurance to their customers along with life insurance cover. SEWA from Gujarat stands as an example for providing a whole suite of financial services for its customers. Its customers today have access to savings, credit and a whole suite of insurance products. Its composite insurance product offers risk cover for life, health and household assets and SEWA currently covers close to 2 lakh individuals under its health insurance policy. 125
  • 128. While there are several promising models of micro health insurance emerging, the problems of adverse selection and moral hazard continue to challenge all players in their attempt to deliver affordable, hassle free and sustainable health insurance products. While adverse selection can be controlled by covering well defined groups, moral hazard (e.g. inflated billings) continue to challenge insurance providers. This problem is further perpetuated by poorly defined and poorly implemented protocols for health care management in India. There exist an ever growing number of health care service providers in the market, mainly in the private sector, and implementing standards of quality and health care procedures across so many providers remain a challenge. While current health insurance providers continue to innovate around these problems, the growth of health insurance will depend a lot on the proactive role played by public institutions to establish standards and quality in health care systems in India. Enterprise insurance The crop A large percentage of rural customers are engaged in various forms of non-farm enterprises. insurance These enterprises are often housed in kacha premises and face a high level of risk from elements schemes have also not been like fire, floods, storms, etc. and from external impact damage. It is important to safeguard very popular them against these risks. In recent years some of the private insurance companies have begun with farmers as the claim to offer insurance cover for such kacha enterprises where enterprise value may be as small as assessment ten to twenty thousand rupees. The key to scale up outreach on micro enterprise insurance process is not would be to have simplified products for valuation of such enterprises and simplified claims very transparent and procedures to survey and settle their claims. claim payments are often Managing agricultural risks delayed. Alternative models to India has a large exposure to weather risks, where the majority of the population is dependent manage crop on rainfed agriculture. In the past two decades, large scale attempts have been made to cover risks are now being explored the risks of farmers through state sponsored crop insurance schemes, aimed at covering multiple to find a more risks faced by the crops. These schemes have however imposed significant fiscal pressure on sustainable the states even though they cover only about 10 percent of Indian farmers. This situation has approach to managing arisen due to the adverse claims experience, where the claim payouts have been more than agricultural four times of the premium collected. Besides a 50 premium subsidy offered by the government, risks. Index all the excess claim payouts have been borne from state finances. The crop insurance schemes based weather insurance is have also not been very popular with farmers as the claim assessment process is not very now emerging transparent and claim payments are often delayed. Alternative models to manage crop risks are as a promising alternative now being explored to find a more sustainable approach to managing agricultural risks. Index based weather insurance is now emerging as a promising alternative. A simple weather index insurance product would work in the following manner. In the event of a shortfall of rain from a predetermined level (index) during a particular period of the crop season, the farmer would be compensated based on a predetermined formula which takes into account the probable loss incurred due to the extent of shortfall in rain. This allows for an objective way to measure claims payable to the insured farmer. As the claim payout formula is predetermined, it automatically leads to timely settlement of claims to farmers, allowing them to reinvest in their next crop or to meet their immediate consumption needs. With the availability of historical weather data, the pricing of the insurance product can be done on an actuarial basis, leading to a more financially sustainable product. The availability of international reinsurance for weather insurance helps to transfer the local weather risk to the 126
  • 129. CHAPTER 7 Micro Insurance global weather risk market and thus provides for a the pooling of risks. BASIX works with a large number of households whose livelihoods depend on agriculture, without any assured source of irrigation. Between 2000 and 2002 BASIX undertook several for taking research projects to provide cover for crop risks. These efforts culminated in a collaboration weather with the Commodity Risk Management Group of the World Bank and ICICI Lombard, to launch insurance to a the first index based weather insurance in 2003 in Mababubnagar district of India covering larger scale, there are 230 farmers in the first pilot program. In subsequent years the index based weather insurance challenges to be market in India has scaled up, covering more than 300,000 farmers. Today there are more overcome. One of them is to companies offering weather insurance in India, including the government owned Agriculture increase the Insurance Company. However for taking weather insurance to a larger scale, there are challenges density of to be overcome. One of them is to increase the density of weather stations in big way, so that weather stations in big rainfall measured in a particular weather station is better correlated to the actual rainfall in a way, so that particular farm. rainfall measured in a particular While weather insurance can protect farmers from significant deviations in weather performance, weather station there is still a need and huge scope for providing risk minimisation and productivity is better enhancement services needed by farmers. These advisory services are needed to complement correlated to the actual the index insurance product. In the absence of these services, weather insurance would carry rainfall in a too much of the weight of farmer's expectations and prove to be an incomplete solution or particular farm promise to the farmers. Box 7.2 SEWA and Rainfall Insurance The Self Employed Womens' Association (SEWA) developed, in collaboration with ICICI Lombard, an insurance product to insure against risks arising out of deficit and excess rainfall. While the insurance product offered by ICICI/Lombard has gone through several cycles elsewhere in India, the product requires customization to local agro-climatic settings. One challenge is understanding the precise relationship between rainfall and rural income, particularly given the paucity of data on rural income. A well-designed product should pay the poor precisely when they need income the most. One goal of SEWA was to make the product accessible to even its poorest members. As a result, the minimum unit size for purchase was quite low, available to anyone whose income varies with the weather. This project aims to (i) evaluate the potential of rainfall insurance to improve the livelihood and sustainability of rural poor in Gujarat, India (ii) understand how behavioral biases and risk aversion influence decision making at the household level, and (iii) evaluate the effectiveness of different marketing and communication strategies in encouraging take up of the product. For the purposes of rolling out the insurance product, 100 villages have been identified that are within 30 km of an IMD-recognized weather station in 3 districts - Ahmedabad, Anand and Patan. Since SEWA will initially be able to offer weather insurance to only a limited number of villages, 33 villages were selected at random, where insurance is offered. In the second year , it expanded to a group of 50 villages. The baseline and the midline surveys have been completed in a little over 1500 households. Based on the data and experiences from the first year, the insurance product and the marketing strategy are being redesigned to serve the needs of the clients more effectively. 127
  • 130. Making micro insurance more affordable and accessible The biggest constraint involved in the distribution of micro insurance is the disproportionate cost of distribution and servicing, in comparison to the value of the premium and the sum insured of these policies. One of the key learnings from the field of micro finance has been that the poor can save and pay in frequent and small instalments. Most insurance policies require premiums to be paid in annual instalments. This makes the premium instalments quite unaffordable for the poor. The key to enhancing outreach of insurance for the poor would be to make provision for collecting premium in more frequent and smaller instalments. However, this benefit can be outweighed by the increase in transaction costs for collecting such small premiums. A solution to this could be to bundle the premium collections with other forms of financial transactions like savings and credit repayments. The key to Another key to the success of micro insurance is simplicity in documentation. One of the enhancing earliest products introduced by AVIVA for the rural sector goes by the name of "Jan Suraksha". outreach of insurance for This is a pure term life insurance product with a sum insured limit of Rs.50,000. The proposal the poor would form for this policy contained 4 pages. In collaboration with its micro insurance partners be to make provision for AVIVA developed and recently introduced a new life term micro insurance product by the name collecting "Gramin Suraksha" with similar policy limits. However the proposal form for this policy has premium in been shortened to a single page. This ensures that minimal and relevant data is captured from more frequent and smaller the customer and the scope for errors in documentation are minimised. It also reduces the instalments. transaction costs involved in selling micro insurance policies. However, this benefit can be The level of risks covered under micro insurance policies is often of a small value, in the range outweighed by the increase in of Rs 5,000 to Rs 50 thousand rupees, as compared to regular insurance policies where the transaction risk cover is often in excess of a lakh of rupees. Given the small value of insurance benefits costs for collecting such that come with micro insurance products, it is important to ensure that the products have small premiums. minimal exclusions and fine print that is usually associated with insurance policies. This is A solution to essential to ensure that the poor perceive the insurance products to be fair and to encourage this could be to bundle the greater enrolment of customers under such products. Some of the micro health insurance premium products currently being offered in the country cover both pre-existing diseases and maternity collections with other forms of related treatments under such policies and some have demonstrated that they can be offered financial on a financially sustainable basis. transactions like savings and credit The role of public institutions in developing micro insurance repayments The government and its institutions wear several hats in the insurance industry. They together perform several roles: that of a regulator, a development agency, an insurer, a re-insurer and an insurer for the uninsured - in the form of various welfare and relief programs run by the government. Some of these functions are also performed by several private and non profit institutions. It is often a tough balancing act for the various public institutions to perform, so that they function effectively in each of these roles, and also ensure that no one function works at cross purpose with any other function. A case in point is that of the several insurance schemes announced by both the central and state governments which aim to cover rural clients or special categories of social sector clients, with a premium subsidy provided by the government. Sometimes these schemes can crowd out the development of market based insurance products for the poor, making the poor perpetual dependent on such schemes. In other cases such schemes do not reach the targeted population. An example of a recent state government 128
  • 131. CHAPTER 7 Micro Insurance sponsored scheme is the Mukhyomantri Jibon Jyoti Bima Achoni2 launched by the Assam state government in July-2005, covering all the 30 million population in the state, where each A part of the subsidy should individual is covered for hospitalisation expenses up to Rs.25,000 per annum. The state be apportioned government paid a premium of Rs 250 million to ICICI Lombard General Insurance Company for to programs for this cover. Within one year of this policy, i.e. up to July 2006, about 4205 people (out of 30 improving awareness and million!) are reported to have benefited from this policy with about Rs 90 million paid in education about claims. the benefits of micro insurance Such low utilisation of the benefits can be attributed to the low awareness of the policy for the targeted population. The among the insured population. The question that arises is the right manner in which the latter holds the public subsidy should be targeted. There is certainly a case for subsidising the poorest of the key to laying a strong poor for their premiums. But the above example also indicates that unless investments are foundation to made to educate the poor on the benefits of insurance, such subsidies do not really help the scale up and majority of the targeted population. A part of the subsidy should be apportioned to programs develop a healthy micro for improving awareness and education about the benefits of micro insurance for the targeted insurance population. The latter holds the key to laying a strong foundation to scale up and develop a market in India healthy micro insurance market in India. Endnotes 1 Manager, Insurance Business, BASIX 2 See Central Bureau of Health Intelligence (CBHI), Ministry of Health and Family Welfare, Government of India http://www.cbhi-hsprod.nic.in/retopt2.asp?SD=21&SI=9&ROT=1 129
  • 132. 130
  • 133. CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology Prasanth V Regy and Vijay Mahajan1 1 Technology: the Key to Efficient Microfinance 1.1 Technology for MF: Why? As one of the authors predicted in 1998, "the day we can marry the power of the microprocessor As one of the authors with the power of microfinance, we will have developed a terrific solution to provide predicted in microfinance transactions to poor people in a low-cost, user-friendly way" (Mahajan 1998). 1998, "the day The proper use of information and communication technologies can be very beneficial to we can marry the power of MFIs. A well-designed and well thought-out Management Information System (MIS) is essential the to achieve scale, improve efficiency, and reduce cost. By reducing manual work, it decreases microprocessor with the power the possibility of error and fraud. Such a system can serve as the backbone of the MFI's of microfinance, processes. It can provide decision-making support to the management by facilitating the we will have analysis of data. It can also help the management monitor the activities of the MFI on a day- developed a terrific solution to-day basis. Further, such applications can help in managing complex products, allowing the to provide MFI to offer tailor-made products to its customers with marginal extra effort. They are also microfinance very useful for HR purposes, including recording employee information, and calculating salaries transactions to poor people in a and commissions. low-cost, user- friendly way" MIS is not the only application of IT in microfinance. Another technology fast gaining importance is that of various Point-of-Sale devices, which can make transactions faster and safer. This chapter is an attempt to examine the use of various technology products and channels in the delivery of microfinance in India. Within microcredit, the key activities involved are registration, appraisal, disbursement, repayment, and monitoring. Registering a customer involves recording details about her name, age, and other personal and household details. In addition, data about the livelihoods, education, and assets of the household are also usually captured. This data can help in the assessment of the social and economic impact of the activities of the MFI. Depending on the delivery model, we may also need to record details about the group, centre, JLG, guarantor, etc. During appraisal, information about the cash-flow of the activity, and of the household, needs to be captured. Repayment is an activity that will happen over and over again, so it should be quick and fraud-proof. The MIS should generate the demand statement and it should also help in monitoring the portfolio by generating statements of PAR, NPA, etc. 131
  • 134. The regulatory requirements for being able to provide microsavings services are much more stringent than those for microcredit. In India, only banks and certain NBFCs are allowed to accept savings. An effective Assets and Liability Management application will be useful in risk monitoring. In contrast to microcredit, where most products involve regular transactions, microsavings products would have to be flexible enough to accommodate irregular savings. The information requirements for microinsurance are slightly different from that of microcredit. MFIs selling microinsurance are retailers for insurance companies. This requires collaboration between the MFI and the insurance company, and the MFI's MIS would need to be able to output data in the format required by the insurance company. The amount of data to be entered is also very high, since insurance is often offered for the whole family. Further, the data accuracy needs to be higher as compared to microcredit. 1.2 The current usage of IT by MFIs When asked A survey on the use of technology in DCCBs and MFIs in India was conducted recently by Saral about the Services (Saral Services 2007). The results are quite interesting. factors that inhibited the adoption of 94% of the MFIs used software applications for internal accounting. 64% reported that they technology, the used loan-tracking software, and only 30% used payroll software. 14% used PDA applications most commonly cited constraint to capture field transactions. In 64% of the cases, the head office of the MFI has a LAN. All was budgetary. the MFIs had internet access in their HO and branches. It is also notable that the cellphone Lack of network was accessible from almost all the MFI locations. adequate expertise, training and When asked about the factors that inhibited the adoption of technology, the most commonly support were cited constraint was budgetary. Lack of adequate expertise, training and support were contributing contributing factors. Another issue was the lack of awareness about technology providers. factors. Another issue was the While irregular power supply is also a problem, it is one that could be rectified by using a UPS, lack of which is again expensive. awareness about technology 2 MIS Solutions - A Survey providers. While irregular power supply is also a The microfinance software vertical has seen a lot of activity in the last year. Along with well- problem, it is established MFIs offering software that they themselves use, a few new application developers one that could have entered the arena. What follows is a review of some MIS applications, classified according be rectified by using a UPS, to the various microfinance models. This is not a comprehensive list, but it will help to give which is again us an overview of this sector. expensive 2.1 Software for SHGs Since SHG-Bank Linkage is the predominant microfinance model in India, several applications have been developed for it. Most of these applications are meant to help the promoting MFI or NGO track all the financial transactions that happen at the SHG meetings. • McFinancier of Sharada Computer Services, Gurgaon: This is a software system solely targeted at SHGs. It can handle group-wise books, and provides all the required administration, tracking and accounting functionalities. It is used by PRADAN, Sarvodaya Nano Finance Ltd, etc. 132
  • 135. CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology • SafalFin of Safal Solutions Ltd, Hyderabad: SafalFin is an integrated solution for NGOs, which helps to track internal credit, deposit and insurance transactions of the members of SHGs promoted by the NGO/MFI. It keeps track of the day-to- day loan activities of these MFIs in addition to managing their Member, Staff, SHG, Accounts and other details. • MTech developed a product named "SHG-MIS", which is meant to help the SHGs track their operations, and also to help the promoting organisation track the SHG performance. After every SHG meeting, the transaction sheets are sent to a centralised location, where it is entered into the MIS and the next demand sheet is printed and returned to the SHG. This product was jointly developed with Andhra Pradesh's Velugu, so that it could be used by all the Velugu groups. • Mahila Sphurthi, developed by CoOptions: This software is intended to be an integrated information system to streamline SHG activities. This product also attempts to bridge the digital divide, by bringing relevant information to the villager about agri-inputs, market intelligence, sanitation and health, etc. • Ekgaon's Mahakalasm MIS: This MIS will allow the promoting NGO/MFI to track the performance of its SHGs. Ekgaon has also designed a unique and accessible system of paper forms for data entry in the field. An interesting innovation in this field has been PRADAN's Computer Munshi. Many SHGs remain PRADAN dependent on the promoting NGO for book-keeping. Even when they can maintain the daybooks conceived the idea of a themselves, they are usually unable to produce the group financial statements. PRADAN conceived community the idea of a community based computer entrepreneur, the Computer Munshi (CM), who would based computer entrepreneur, provide accounting services to the SHGs for a reasonable payment. He could offer his services the Computer to about 200 SHGs, resulting in viable employment. Most CMs supplement this income with Munshi (CM), other activities, such as STD PCOs, internet and photocopying facilities. who would provide accounting 2.2 Software for the Grameen model services to the SHGs for a The Grameen model of microcredit, which originated with the Grameen Bank of Bangladesh, reasonable payment. He has been used heavily in India with significant improvements. One of the most commonly could offer his used applications for monitoring Grameen-style microcredit, Portfolio Tracker, was developed services to by Grameen Communications (GC) of Bangladesh, an IT service provider and a member of the about 200 SHGs, resulting Grameen group of enterprises. Together with modules for performance monitoring and in viable accounting, this application reduces paper work considerably and raises work efficiency. In employment India, it is used by CASHPOR, SKS, and several other Grameen replicators. 2.3 Software implementing multiple methodologies Various lending models have been tried out in the field of microcredit. Lending may be to individuals or to small groups (SHGs, Grameen groups, and JLGs), and at the other end of the spectrum, to Federations and MACTS. There are a variety of methods to calculate interest and schedule payments. The organisations that offer multiple models and several kinds of products need software that can handle the complexity. 133
  • 136. 2.3.1 FAMIS Plus FAMIS is short for Financial Accounting and Management Information System. It was developed by BASIX's software partner, Sathguru Management Consultants, based on BASIX's specifications. It was designed to be a comprehensive solution for accounting and management information needs. While it is no longer used within BASIX, it continues to serve more than 36 other MFIs at 140 installations, to whom BASIX provides ongoing support. FAMIS PLUS is a very mature application, satisfying the requirements of 36 MFIs throughout India. It runs on Windows, and requires minimal maintenance and support. It is very rich in features, being able to support credit, savings, and insurance. It has extremely rich reporting features, which have enabled its users to track metrics that couldn't be tracked earlier, leading to better recoveries. It is highly configurable software, easily adaptable to any terminology, interest calculation method and lending/saving methodology. Delphix, FAMIS' main negative has to do with the database it uses - FoxPro. This database is not as designed to be robust as the other databases available, and is not perceived very favourably today. an MIS for livelihood finance, was 2.3.2 Delphix also developed by Sathguru, Delphix, designed to be an MIS for livelihood finance, was also developed by Sathguru, based based on BASIX's on BASIX's specifications. It drew heavily from BASIX's previous experience of creating FAMIS. specifications. In particular, it is highly robust and customisable, and is based on the Oracle platform. It drew heavily from BASIX's BASIX uses Delphix for all its lending operations, serving more than 200,000 customers in previous experience of more than 60 units. New features are being added to Delphix, including savings, life insurance, creating FAMIS. and agricultural and business development services. It is a highly capable system, based on a In particular, it rugged and proven platform. Box 8.1 describes the evolution of MIS applications in BASIX. is highly robust and customisable, 2.3.3 Micro Financier and is based on the Oracle Java Softech's Micro Financer is a flexible solution capable of supporting a variety of models, platform including SHGs, Federations, Grameen, and individual loans. It also has a full-featured savings module. It enables the capture of several kinds of socio-economic data, and it can generate a variety of reports. It comes integrated with a financial accounting module. Its clients in India include SERP, CARE, Gram Utthan, and several MACS and federations. 2.3.4 Banksoft BankSoft is an integrated suite of applications for banking, created by Processware Systems, Bangalore. It enables branch automation, head office consolidation, and inter-branch reconciliation. A user-friendly software package, BankSoft provides integrity, flexibility and security to the user. BankSoft has been installed at more than 300 locations in Karnataka, Andhra Pradesh, and Goa. It supports multiple delivery channels such as Internet, PDAs, Touch Screen Kiosks, Mobile phones, and ATMs. It enables the bank to generate all the statutory reports required by RBI. It was chosen by BASIX for use in the Krishna Bhima Samruddhi Local Area Bank (KBSLAB). Responding to the requirements of KBSLAB, Processware added several features to Banksoft, making it a suitable product for microbanking. 134
  • 137. CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology Box 8.1 The evolution of MIS in BASIX FAMIS was BASIX's first effort at a comprehensive solution to our accounting and management information needs, and it served us from 1997 to 2005. It was first developed on a Visual Basic/FoxPro/MS-DOS platform. After the release of the first version in 1997, several more versions were released, each adding to functionality and robustness. At that time, there was no other software on the market which had the functionality needed by MFIs. Most MFIs used manually prepared charts to determine repayments. In the year 2000, FAMIS was supplied to its first external user, ASSEFA. This version was named ASSEFAMIS, and it was installed in ASSEFA offices in Maharashtra, Rajasthan, Madhya Pradesh, and Bihar. This involved not just providing the software, but also setting up the requisite infrastructure, including buying generators and UPS, as well as training the operators who would use it. RGVN, who had centres in Orissa, Assam and Bihar, was next. They lent to groups as well as to At that time, other NGOs, and these two activities were very different in the software functionality that there was no other software they demanded. RGVN had a wider portfolio of products, including savings and grants, and on the market required many new reports as well. Our analysts spent a lot of time on the field understanding which had the their processes and requirements, and then we converted them into software specifications functionality needed by MFIs. that we passed on to the developer. This was our first experience in customising our software Most MFIs used for external users. RGVN installed FAMIS in 16 locations. manually prepared charts This was followed by a very large number of other MFIs. It may be noted that BASIX charged to determine these users only for training and customization. In each case, our analysts invested a lot of repayments time in understanding the requirements and tailoring FAMIS accordingly. As may be imagined, every MFI had different lending methodologies and interest calculation methods. Other requirements like savings and grants were also integrated into FAMIS. The complexity quickly increased, till there were 10 different versions of FAMIS for 10 MFIs! This large number of versions obviously created several problems for us, and so we decided to combine these different versions into one. This unified version was called FAMIS PLUS. This is the only version that is used today. The main problem with FAMIS was the database that it used. While it works very well for small MFIs, it could not keep up with the growth of BASIX. In the year 2000, inspired by the information system employed by DID Canada, plans were laid for the creation of a new software, Delphix. It drew heavily from our experience of creating FAMIS. It was based on the Oracle platform, which, we expected, would be able to handle anything we could throw at it. The design of the new system was done in the year 2000, and the development largely took place in 2001. The development was done by the same company who developed FAMIS. In 2002, we pilot tested it in three units, entering data in Delphix in parallel to FAMIS. However, there were several problems migrating data from FAMIS to Delphix. In addition, Delphix was immature at that time. So there were several issues in the way of moving to Delphix completely. The pilot testing continued in the year 2003 and 2004, with seven more units taking part in the pilot. In 2004, all our software development efforts were focused at building features for handling insurance in FAMIS, so Delphix development was stopped during that time. All this while, the parallel entry into Delphix continued in the ten pilot units. In 2004 September, the first round of systems auditing was done by our auditor, who identified several issues with Delphix. These issues were fixed, and then another round of audit done. After this round, in which only minor issues were reported, we inducted Delphix into all our units. 135
  • 138. 2.3.5 MIFOS The Mifos Initiative was established by Grameen Foundation's Technology Center to address the microfinance industry's information management challenge. The initiative aims to deliver an open source information management system for the global microfinance industry via a collaborative development and support community. The open source framework allows microfinance institutions to select local developers to assist with the customization, implementation and maintenance of their software. MIFOS is still under development and is not currently recommended for use in a production environment. 2.4 Hosted Solutions As internet connectivity improves, a different kind of application software is now possible - one that is hosted by the solution provider on its own servers, rather than being installed locally. The data is entered and accessed over the internet, through a browser. Installing and upgrading software locally is replaced by a subscription-based model, in which data is stored remotely. FINO and Salesforce.com are among the prominent players in this space. Software This model has many advantages. Software development and its maintenance are not the core development competencies of an MFI. Rather than spending money and resources on purchasing (or, worse, and its maintenance developing), installing, configuring, maintaining, and upgrading application software and are not the core hardware, it may be more economical to just use a ready-made application hosted elsewhere competencies of an MFI. Rather and accessible through the browser. This will also lead to lower manpower requirements. The than spending solution provider will take care of ensuring data protection and data redundancy, which are money and requirements that are typically neglected by MFIs. Thus, such applications can deliver benefits resources on purchasing (or, at reduced costs and risks. worse, developing), There are disadvantages to this model as well, the first being that it requires internet installing, configuring, connectivity. The internet is not available or is highly unreliable in large parts of our country. maintaining, If only very limited functionality is required, it may still be possible to use a hosted solution and upgrading with once a day connectivity. But for more complex usage, the information will be required to application software and be cached locally and synchronised with the hosted server whenever possible. This may require hardware, it local installation of caching software, which neutralises some of the advantages of such may be more hosted solutions. Another problem is that of regular subscription payments. This payment is economical to just use a typically based on the number of groups or customers handled by the application. ready-made application There are also data-ownership issues: MFIs may not wish to part with their customer data to hosted elsewhere and solution providers if they fear that the data may be shared with others. In addition, the fact accessible that the data is stored by the solution provider may tie down the MFI if it later wishes to through the migrate to a different solution. browser 2.4.1 FINO platform FINO (Financial Information Network and Operations) Ltd. was set up by ICICI, which still owns 20% of it. It provides a technology platform to MFIs to manage their data electronically. It has been designed to support all the common lending methodologies. This solution is based on a central Core Banking Solution (CBS), which will be the repository of all the customer accounts. FINO is able to provide multiple levels of reports for MFIs that 136
  • 139. CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology choose to be hosted on their platform. It also claims that it can even support MFIs who wish to host their accounts themselves - the MFI can upload the data to it, and use the reporting and analysing abilities of the platform. FINO also offers the ability to handle smartcards. FINO is described further in Box 8.2 2.4.2 Salesforce.com Salesforce.com is the leading provider of hosted enterprise applications internationally. In fact, a large part of the credit for creating the hosted enterprise solutions space goes to them, due to their pioneering work in web-based Customer Relationship Management applications. They are in the process of developing a web-based tool for microfinance institutions. Being at an early stage, they are looking for MFI partners who are willing to test their application. Box 8.2 A hosted solution: FINO Indian startup Financial Information, Network, and Operations Ltd (FINO) has recently become While back end the first company in the world to offer a complete end to end technology solution to data management microfinance institutions. While back end data management software designed for microfinance software operations has been available on the market for years, FINO is the first to link a back end designed for software system with a front end based on biometric smartcards for customers, and field microfinance operations has devices for credit officers, to offer a complete, integrated solution. been available on the market The basics of the FINO product are simple. FINO is targeted at Business Correspondents, for years, FINO governments, MFIs and in fact, at any organization that intends to reach the unbanked is the first to sector. Customers of the organization are given biometric enabled smartcards which store the link a back end software customers' fingerprints, account details, a unique identification number, and photo. system with a Transactions are recorded using a field device equipped with a smartcard reader, fingerprint front end based reader, and small printer and then automatically uploaded from the field device to the back on biometric smartcards for end FINO software via a phone line. At the back end, all data is stored and maintained by FINO customers, and itself and accessed by the organization via web browsers. In addition to the full solution field devices for described above, FINO also allows organizations to purchase just the front or back end portions credit officers, to offer a of the system. (So far, several MFIs have opted to adopt the back end only.) complete, integrated A key application of FINO would be to enable the Business Correspondent model. The BC model solution can work only if there is quick and accurate flow of information between the BC and the bank (Section 6.2). The bank needs to be able to monitor and control the services offered by the BC to the end customer. FINO provides offline-mode capability and detailed report-generation systems, thus making it feasible and safe to adopt the BC model. Another obvious application of the FINO product is to streamline the existing operations of MFIs. By replacing rote paperwork with automatic data transfer, FINO allows MFIs to reduce labour costs, lessen the chance of fraud, create reports more quickly, and gain better overall insight into the performance of their portfolio. In addition to cutting costs, FINO also benefits MFIs and their customers by allowing MFIs to offer new products such as remittances and flexible savings accounts to their customers. Without the enhanced security, data management capacity, and connection to the existing financial system which FINO allows, these products would be nearly impossible for an MFI to offer. The FINO product holds potential for increasing financial inclusion in India and elsewhere in other ways as well. In addition to MFIs, banks may also use the FINO platform to directly 137
  • 140. engage in microfinance activities. Similarly, governments may use the FINO platform to deliver wages and other benefits to the public more efficiently and with less leakage. Finally, FINO may benefit the microfinance sector as a whole by serving as a platform for the development of a credit bureau for the sector. Because FINO collects the fingerprints of all customers it gives smartcards to, and stores this information in a central location, FINO could easily be used to track and share the credit histories of customers as they move from MFI to MFI. FINO has already begun work on a credit model to predict customer credit profile. A credit bureau would allow MFIs to cut down on the cost of screening clients, reduce overall defaults, and allow customers to more easily move from MFI to MFI, or to graduate from microfinance lending to bank lending. It can also enable the MFI to offer individual loan products instead of group-based products. Whether these potential benefits are realized depends greatly on how much FINO is able to bring down the costs of the system for the MFI as well as the amount of support commercial banks give FINO. Up until now, many MFIs have been reluctant to adopt the FINO system due to the high initial investment and yearly fees. For more MFIs to be convinced that adopting FINO is a smart move, these costs will have to be brought down. FINO could see easier acceptance in the Business Correspondent sector, since the initial investments would be borne/subsidized by banks. Despite a slow start, FINO is gaining steam. The company has signed up about 15 MFIs for its solution and a few of them have already gone live. It has carried out about 3 lakh enrolments, and has issued 1.5 lakh cards. The AP government is already using the FINO platform to deliver government benefits to recipients as a pilot, and it intends to replicate it in the entire state. In addition, Corporation Bank, ICICI, Indian Bank, and Union Bank of India have all made major investments in the company. Having these banks on board will do much to help ensure the success of the company. But FINO will need to sign up far more MFIs and gain the support of several more players, including governments. For FINO to be truly successful, it will also have to reduce costs by delivering multiple services through the same cards. 3 Transaction Support Technologies In microfinance, transaction costs have traditionally been high. Innovations like the Grameen model, SHG, and JLG, made large-scale microfinance possible by bringing down this cost significantly. In this section, we examine how technology can be used to further bring down transaction costs. • they should be easy to use, even by people unfamiliar with technology • they should be able to handle even small ticket transactions in an economically feasible manner • they should take minimal time and effort • they should protect the interest of customers, and • they should have the checks and balances necessary to avoid frauds. In practice, the transactions are usually captured manually in the field by an agent of the MFI, who gives the customer a receipt. This data is then fed into MIS loaded on a PC in the MFI branch office. The problem with this approach is the amount of time and effort this requires, 138
  • 141. CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology and the possibility of error and fraud. The information entered into the MIS is the same as the information written down in the receipt - if this duplication of effort is avoided, then it can lead not only to a savings in effort, but also to greater accuracy. 3.1 Hand-held devices One way to avoid this error- and fraud-prone duplication is to use portable Point-of-Sale One way to (POS) devices that can electronically capture transactions. BASIX has experimented with several avoid this error- and fraud-prone hand-held devices, including Simputers, for this purpose, before settling on devices duplication is manufactured by Edgar Interactive, Bangalore. When the field agent enters the transaction, to use portable Point-of-Sale the device records it and prints out a receipt for the client. When the agent comes back to the (POS) devices field office, he connects his HHD to the server, and the data is synchronised. Such devices are that can already being used in bus ticketing, electricity billing, etc. electronically capture transactions 3.2 Rural ATMs IIT Chennai, The Tenet group, and ICICI Bank have designed a secure, low cost, and low maintenance ATM called the Gramateller. The idea behind this is to increase financial institutions' outreach and penetration in rural areas. The Gramateller can use existing connectivity in rural areas to enable a bank to extend its services to the poor in an efficient and cost effective manner. It can use smartcards or fingerprints for authentication. It also has a battery backup to deal with power outages. 3.3 Mobile phone based solutions Cellular networks have recently become ubiquitous in India. It is estimated that there are more than 180 million cellphone subscribers in India, and their numbers are fast increasing. The cellphone combines processing power, storage, and wireless communication. Cellphones are falling in price, while their memory and processor power have been increasing. Increasingly, Increasingly, cameras and Near Field Communication (NFC) chips are built into them, as cellphone cameras and Near Field manufacturers try to make them more and more useful in an effort to supplant the PC as the Communication primary personal computing device. Extrapolating these trends, it can be safely said that (NFC) chips are built into them, cellphones will play an important role in transaction capturing in microfinance. as cellphone manufacturers 3.3.1 A Little World try to make them more and This company has come up with an initiative that envisages the mass deployment of multi- more useful in an effort to application smart cards through a network of service delivery points, with the POS device supplant the PC being a cellphone. It has the following components: as the primary personal • Agent/employee with an NFC-enabled mobile phone computing device. • Customer with a NFC-enabled smart card Extrapolating these trends, it • MFI/Bank can be safely said that • Centralised Card Management System. cellphones will play an NFC is a short range (a few cm) wireless communication technology that works through magnetic important role in transaction induction. In ALW's model, the smart cards issued to customers have NFC-enabled chips on capturing in them, allowing them to transfer small amounts of data wirelessly and almost instantaneously. microfinance 139
  • 142. The model is relatively low cost. A smart card is estimated to cost around Rs.100 and the equipment with the agent (comprising a mobile phone, a finger print reader, and a printer, all NFC-enabled) around Rs.20,000. The initial investment costs of the cards and the equipment are high, so this system is best for MFIs that intend to become Business Correspondents (BC), where the bank can bear the setup cost. Compared to the cost of establishing and operating a physical bank branch in the rural area, this system would be extremely cost effective. The operating costs of the model are expected to be minimal and can be easily absorbed by banks. ALW has already deployed this technology in collaboration with banks in Pithoragarh in Uttarakhand , Aizawl in Mizoram and Medak in AP. This technology is now being deployed with IGS acting as the BC of Axis Bank in Delhi and in Muzaffarpur, Bihar, as described in Box 8.2. 3.3.2 Acceltree The solution provided by Acceltree is a mobile phone based technology that provides a low cost mechanism to computerize microfinance processes. Here, again, the mobile phone (or a wireless PDA) itself operates as an on-line/off-line terminal. This device connects to a low cost central server. Acceltree provides an easy to configure framework that enables quick deployment after customising the application software to suit local business and government rules. The application can be made available in local languages with little effort. 3.3.3 Ekgaon Ekgaon has developed a mobile information services framework called CAM. This framework comprises a cellphone application, paper forms with bar-codes that embed processing instructions, and a server. This system offers the ability to have a hybrid system, combining paper-based processes with automated systems, using bar-codes and image recognition through cellphone cameras. The system also offers a voice-based menu, which will be helpful for illiterate users. It can deal with situations where the cellular network is not available. Further, the system is easily localisable. This system can be used by SHGs as well as by Business Correspondents. 4 Caveats Using multiple software to handle related This section details some of the key aspects MFI managers should keep in mind as they services results implement a technology solution. in dissipation of development energy and 4.1 Proper design and integration managerial attention. If Often, when new features or services are being developed by an MFI, it may choose to prototype the different it using a new application. But once the service becomes standard and mainstream, it is felt services are used by the that it is too much bother to change the application, and so the MFI continues to use the same prototype application for production purposes. customers, it might be useful Using multiple software to handle related services results in dissipation of development energy to build in the functionalities and managerial attention. If the different services are used by the same customers, it might required for the be useful to build in the functionalities required for the different services into one program, different services into or alternatively, to ensure that the different applications for the multiple services can talk to one program each other. This is important in enabling us to have a unified view of the customer base. 140
  • 143. CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology The operations staff has to be inducted into the application development project right from the conceptualisation stage to ensure that the solution meets the requirements of the end users. They play a vital role in the success of the project, and their feedback should always be taken into account. This will help to ensure that the application is easy to use for those who actually use it. 4.2 Pilot testing It is vital to test the software/hardware thoroughly in a few locations in the field before deploying it company-wide. This will help the field staff to get used to the new way of doing things, and also will catch issues before they become serious. In particular, it should be recognized that software design is essentially iterative, and that the early versions will need to be refined over a period of time before they can be used in a production environment. 4.3 Project management and documentation Good project management is essential to the success of any project. The project should be monitored by all the concerned parties, and the MFI should work closely with the IT partner to resolve issues immediately. If a new product or process is being introduced, the development of the software required should start well in advance. Otherwise, the unavailability of the software may delay the new product. In the IT industry, the employee turnover is generally very high. Hence, the application development/deployment project should be process driven and not person driven. Documentation can play a key role in ensuring this. If the required documentation is in place, the maintenance of the application will become easy later. Proper documentation also helps us evaluate whether we got what we asked for. 4.4 Security It is generally seen that the security aspects of using technological solutions are often It should be noted that overlooked. This is perhaps due to the assumption that most users, particularly field agents, while do not have the skills required to manipulate the software/hardware. It should be noted thattechnology can while technology can help prevent frauds, it can also enable a skilled hacker to perpetrate help prevent frauds, it can frauds on a large scale. This can be avoided by a proper security architecture, including also enable a appropriate access permissions, logging, regular backups, and encryption. skilled hacker to perpetrate frauds on a 5 A Guide to the Perplexed large scale. This can be avoided So, as the CEO or CTO of an MFI, how should you decide what solution to go for? by a proper security architecture The kind of MIS required will change according the size of the MFI. Even a small MFI would need at least basic tools like a spreadsheet application or Access. As the size of the MFI increases, the demands from the MIS increase as well, requiring more features, robust databases, and easy to use user interfaces (Intellecap 2007). An MFI with a country-wide presence may require a solution with a three-tier architecture, in which the data, business logic, and presentation are split into distinct layers. This can web-enable the MIS and also provide the extensibility required to be able to work with other applications and partners. Thus, MFIs may need to migrate from one solution to another as they grow. Migration is 141
  • 144. usually a long and messy process, and it is best if planning is done in advance so as to avoid it or, at least, to minimise the disruption caused by it. A rough typology of the MIS features required by MFIs of various sizes is given below. These numbers are indicative: an MFI with a very simple model might be able to serve millions of customers with a very simple MIS, and another with more flexible and complex products may need a more advanced solution from an early stage. Since the actual feature requirements will vary according to factors such as the operational model of the MFI, and the number of products it offers, these figures are order-of-magnitude estimates. MFI Size (number of customers) MIS Features < 100 Manual, paper-based system may be sufficient. < 10,000 Excel/Access based solution < 100,000 Robust Database with good consolidation and In general, for reporting features small organisations or >100,000 Web-enabled and extensible, can work with other organisations applications, enables high-level analysis using standard microfinance lending models, Whether to purchase a ready-made product, to develop a new application altogether is another it is better to key question. The answer to this question depends on several factors: the microfinance model source the software followed by your organisation, the size of your organisation, the criticality of the software to externally, and you, the quality of the external developer, and the comparative costs of development. Obviously, have the vendor this will vary from organisation to organisation, and even within an organisation, from service customise it to one's specific to service. requirements. For large In general, for small organisations or organisations using standard microfinance lending models, organisations, or where the it is better to source the software externally, and have the vendor customise it to one's requirements specific requirements. For large organisations, or where the requirements are specialised, it are specialised, may be possible or necessary to develop a custom application. In this case, one should it may be possible or carefully factor in the implications of developing in-house versus outsourcing the software necessary to development to an application developer. Given the problems inherent in employing software develop a engineers in-house, including their management, their high salaries and their high attrition, custom application outsourcing to a technology partner may be the more attractive solution. The selection of the technology partner plays a vital role in determining the success of the project. The options that the partner can offer you are limited by his knowledge and experience. Hence, we should carefully research his technological capabilities to ensure that he is knowledgeable enough to be able to choose the best technology. We should also satisfy ourselves that his project management capabilities are good enough that he will be able to deliver the most cost-effective and robust solution, and support it over a long period. The decision to go for a particular MIS or to develop a new one should be guided by a clear idea of the costs and the benefits of that solution. The upfront price of the package may only a very small part of the entire cost (Ivatury and Pasricha 2005). The larger chunk will be made up of the costs of personnel, training, support and maintenance. One should also account for the costs of the underlying operating system, database, hardware, and security costs. 142
  • 145. CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology As mentioned above, the particular technologies that are chosen will depend on the capabilities of the technology partner. However, there are some aspects that the MFI should pay close attention to: • Robustness and suitability: We should ensure that the technology is well suited to the use it will be put to, and the scenarios it will be used in. Buying extremely expensive and unduly high-end hardware or software can be as bad as buying underpowered components. • Cost: In general, open standards, whether in hardware or in software, are attractive because it leads to low prices. Also, in addition to the development or purchase costs, one should pay attention to the maintenance costs and any licensing or subscription costs of the operating system and database. • Life: We should ensure that the software and hardware technologies we use do not become outdated too soon. A technology solution should be able to serve your needs at least 3-4 years into the future. Both hardware and software should be maintainable locally. The technology platform is another issue. Most solutions seen so far run on Microsoft Windows. The field of micro-finance is This is primarily due to pervasiveness of that platform, and the large number of developers becoming familiar with it. There are a few solutions that run on free platforms like Linux. The advantages mainstream, and along with of such a platform are that the costs are much lower, systems are generally more secure (free of it, so is the viruses, trojans, worms, etc), hardware requirements may be lighter, and one is free to upgradetechnology for at one's convenience. A similar situation obtains for databases. While large organisations may this field require expensive and high-end databases such as Oracle, SQL Server or DB2, it is usually seen that most of the functionality exists in free/open source databases like MySQL and Postgres. Grameen Foundation's MIFOS, and Ekgaon's various products are based on open-source technologies. The vendors of most of the high-end databases now offer 'express' or 'lite' versions of their products, which can be deployed in applications for free. Some of the high- end features are disabled, but that is generally not a problem for MFIs. The Microfinance Gateway and the MIX Market offer some online information about various technologies, products and vendors. 6 The Way Ahead 6.1 New technologies The field of micro-finance is becoming mainstream, and along with it, so is the technology for this field. Several interesting players are just stepping in. With the advent of new players like FINO, Grameen's MIFOS, Atyati's Ganaseva and Salesforce.com, and of new technologies like the use of mobile phones, smart cards, and NFC, MFIs can look forward to having more and better technology options at their disposal in the coming years. Some of the technologies mentioned above, particularly smart cards and cell-phone based readers, may be especially suited to banks providing savings services. Their costs are also currently high enough that they can be afforded by banks only. This raises the question, would banks take over microfinance, rendering MFIs superfluous? 143
  • 146. On the other hand, MFIs have several strengths of their own. They specialize in assessing and originating micro-loans, in educating the customer, and in dealing with delinquencies. Even if banks were to enter this field in a more direct manner, they would need to build up these competencies. They might instead, prefer to continue to "outsource" these functions to MFIs. 6.2 Regulatory environment One of the recent initiatives of the RBI has been the Business Facilitator and Business Correspondent (BC) models (RBI 2006). The BC model is meant for the conduct of banking business. Only NGOs/MFIs set up under Societies/Trusts acts, Societies registered under Mutually Aided Cooperative Societies Acts or the Cooperative Societies Acts of States, section 25 companies, and Post Offices may act as Business Correspondents2. The RBI has made it clear that the Bank is responsible to the customer for the acts of the BC. Further, considering that the objective is to extend banking services to the unbanked, the RBI has also allowed banks to rely upon certificates of identification issued by the BC for the purpose of satisfying KYC norms. BCs can perform a wide range of activities, including: assisting in the enrolment of new customers, disbursal of small value credit, collection of small value deposits, recovery of principal and collection of interest, receipt and delivery of payment instruments including remittances, and the sale of third-party financial products. Thus, the BC model enables a pooling of competencies between the bank, which can create financial products, but which may not be able to deliver these products to all segments of the population, and the BC, which does not have the ability to offer financial products, but which does have existing infrastructure that can be used as a delivery channel to reach the financially excluded. The RBI has The RBI has explicitly exhorted banks "to adopt technology-based solutions for managing the explicitly risk, besides increasing the outreach in a cost effective manner." Using an IT solution is in any exhorted banks "to adopt case, almost a regulatory requirement, since transactions need to be reflected in the bank's technology- books by the end of the day or the next working day. Within the guidelines issued by RBI, banks based solutions for managing and BCs have a fair amount of latitude in determining the payment systems to be used. the risk, besides For example, IGS, a BASIX group company, has become a BC of Axis Bank. This project is being increasing the operationalised first in Delhi and Muzaffarpur, Bihar, and it is particularly directed at migrants outreach in a cost effective from Muzaffarpur working in Delhi who want to remit money back home to their families. To manner" reduce the operational risk, customers are given smart cards which store their fingerprints. Transactions are authorized and settled electronically, with the communications happening through the mobile phone. Customer information is collected by IGS and passed on to the bank. The bank opens a no-frills SB account for the customer. The information captured for every customer, including his photograph and his fingerprints, is stored in the smart card issued to him. He can withdraw and deposit money using this smart card at the terminal of the IGS agent. Transactions are authenticated biometrically, using the stored fingerprints. A printed receipt is provided to the customer for every transaction. The project is described in more detail in Box 8.3. It is interesting to note that nations such as Brazil, South Africa, and the Philippines are ahead of India in using such technological and structural arrangements to promote financial inclusion (CGAP 2006). In Brazil, a variety of retail agents are allowed to offer financial services on behalf of banks, including post offices, lottery kiosks, and supermarkets. These 144
  • 147. CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology "banking correspondents" have ensured that every single municipality in Brazil - 5800 of them - have access to formal financial services. Similarly, in the Philippines, Globe Telecom offers an e-money product tied to the mobile phone SIM card of the subscriber. While this is meant to be used as a payments and remittance mechanism, many poor people also use it as a savings account. In South Africa, mobile phone operators have tied up with banks to offer cell-phone based bank accounts. Today in India, technology makes it possible to have a one-man bank branch, at any place one Today in India, technology wishes. One individual, armed with a mobile phone, can do most of the cash-in cash-out functions makes it of a bank teller. While the BC model enables us to tap into this possibility, further changes in possible to have regulations will be required to make the BC model feasible on a large scale (Tankha 2006) a one-man bank branch, at any place one Box 8.3 TAFI: Putting mobile phone technology to wishes. One individual, work as a BC for remittances armed with a mobile phone, BASIX, in collaboration with Axis Bank and A Little World (ALW), has launched an initiative in can do most of Delhi and Muzaffarpur, Bihar, called TAFI - Technology Assisted Financial Inclusion. This started the cash-in as a result of BASIX's efforts to provide financial access to migrant workers. Studies have cash-out functions of a found that rural people in Bihar have become highly mobile due to poor local employment bank teller prospects. The destination is often determined by social networks: people tend to go to places where others from their village and caste have previously gone. Delhi is one of the major destinations. Migrants remit a large part of their income, and these remittances greatly improve the standard of living of their families. Many remittance mechanisms are used, including money orders, private agents, and hand-carrying. Deshingkar3 (2006) quotes Rs 450 crore as the amount of money sent through money orders to Bihar in 2005-06. Most of this would be due to migrants. The amounts they hand-carry or send through private agents are each likely to comparable to this amount. Migrants find it very difficult to open bank accounts, and to save or borrow money from formal sources. Money orders were also not preferred due to the cost (both official and unofficial), unreliability and frequent delays. This forces them to rely on less-favoured unsafe/illegal methods to send money back home, at a high cost. This issue could be easily solved if the remitter and the payee each had access to a savings bank account. Also, such an account could provide a proof of income and of credit-worthiness, allowing them to borrow from the formal financial system. Hence, BASIX saw savings accounts as key to achieving financial inclusion. We approached Axis Bank and ALW to be our partners. The plan was for IGS (a BASIX group section 25 company) to become Axis Bank's Business Correspondent (BC), at Delhi and at Muzaffarpur, using the technology provided by ALW. By using common delivery mechanisms to provide the BC services and our other services, we hoped to keep the costs low. We surveyed households in several areas in Muzaffarpur, and found that most households had sent male family members to work outside the state, particularly to Kolkata and Delhi. In Delhi, migrants from Muzaffarpur were concentrated in the slum area of Mandavali. From our survey in Muzaffarpur, we were able to get the names and addresses of a large number of migrants in Delhi. On an average, they send around Rs 1000-1500 per month back home. They commonly use money orders, private agents, and sometimes, even bank drafts. We decided to offer our services to the migrants in Mandavali and other slum dwellers. In Bihar, we decided to open our SPOTs (Specified Point of Transaction) in Muzaffarpur town and in a few villages in the district. We initially explored opening a joint account for the migrant in Delhi and his wife/relatives in 145
  • 148. But we soon Bihar. But we soon learnt that they would prefer to avoid joint accounts - the migrants didn't learnt that they want their families in Bihar to have access to all their money! So we planned to open separate would prefer to avoid joint no-frills savings accounts for the migrants and their families. Remittance would be just an accounts - the account-to-account transfer. We needed a safe, secure and robust method for identifying and migrants didn't authenticating customers, so we chose fingerprint-based authentication. After data is collected want their families in and verified for each customer by IGS, Axis Bank vets it and opens a no-frills savings account Bihar to have for him. A smartcard which stores his fingerprints, photo, and other details is issued to him. access to all their money! So Operating the account has been made as easy as possible. Each IGS agent has a kit: a mobile we planned to phone, a fingerprint reader, and a printer. All these communicate with each other through the open separate no-frills savings NFC chips built into them. To withdraw cash, the customer authenticates himself at the accounts for the fingerprint reader. When successfully authenticated, the reader authorizes a single transaction migrants and on the card. Now, the agent presses his phone to the card. The phone reads the information their families in the card, and displays a menu on its screen. The agent then chooses the appropriate menu item and enters the amount the customer wishes to withdraw. The mobile phone checks the customer's balance, and if there is enough money in the account, it informs the server about the transaction, and gives the agent the go-ahead. The agent then pays the customer his money. To print a receipt, the printer is brought in contact with the cellphone. The transaction is committed only after the receipt is printed, ensuring safety. At the end of the day, an IGS agent will visit the nearest Axis Bank branch to square the accounts. For remittances, a customer (say, in Delhi) can register other customers (his wife in Bihar) with us, as his payees. He can then transfer money from his account to theirs, and IGS shall inform the recipient. The remittance fee is proposed to be just 0.5% of the amount. In the initial stages of the project, the recipient shall have to come to the nearest SPOT to withdraw the money. Later, our agents will travel through the villages, providing doorstep service to the customers. The recipient will be paid within a day. This technology is new to customers. To encourage them to use this mode of transaction, we incentivise our agents by paying them a commission per transaction. However, this needs to be carefully monitored, as it can be misused. The agents will be based at units situated close to the customers. The project is still in its very early stages - at the time of writing, only a month had passed since its inauguration. Within this short time, 1000 customers (both migrants and non-migrant slum dwellers) had already enrolled. We hope to achieve break-even in about 2 years. 6.3 Technology Fund We already know that business process innovations backed by technology can make financial services accessible to the poor. However, much work needs to be done to investigate the ways to upscale these innovations to achieve complete financial inclusion. In his budget speech, the Finance Minister has promised to create a Financial Inclusion Technology Fund, with the objective: "to meet the costs of research and development, pilot testing and scaling up of appropriate and cost-effective technologies for enhancing financial inclusion". This fund, if properly utilised, will be of great help in promoting innovative ways of taking banking to the unbanked. It can target projects that use technology to address financial exclusion by reducing the transaction and monitoring costs, increasing the reach and scale of operations, and preventing fraud. Some of the promising technologies it could support could be: 146
  • 149. CHAPTER 8 Microfinance and Technology • Technologies which use the increasing ubiquity of mobile phone networks and the internet for financial inclusion • Methods to standardise and automate the calculation of customer credit risk to the extent possible • Cheap, reliable and rugged ATMs • Development of cheaper identification/authentication mechanisms • Inexpensive smartcards and other secure ways of reducing - ideally eliminating - cash Endnotes 1 Prashant Regy is Manager, Strategic Initiatives, BASIX and Vijay Mahajan is an electrical engineer, and Chairman, BASIX. 2 In the original circular (issued in January 2006), registered NBFCs not accepting public deposits were also allowed to become BCs, but in a subsequent circular, RBI adviced banks to avoid the use of NBFCs as BCs (with the exception of those NBFCs licenced under Section 25). 3 Deshingkar et al, 2006, "The Role of Migration and Remittances in Promoting Livelihoods in Bihar" 147
  • 150. References Saral Services, 2007, "Information and Communication Technology Survey of DCCBs and MFIs in India", Saral Services, Sheffield Hallam University, Oxford University, ODI, 2007 Intellecap, 2006, "The Way Forward: Technology in Indian Microfinance", report for CARE India, Mumbai CGAP, 2005, Gautam Ivatury, and Nicole Pasricha, "Funding Microfinance Technology", Washinton DC Deshingkar et al, 2006, "The Role of Migration and Remittances in Promoting Livelihoods in Bihar" RBI, 2006, "Financial Inclusion by Extension of Banking Services", Mumbai CGAP 2006: Timothy R. Lyman, Gautam Ivatury, Stefan Staschen, "Use of Agents in Branchless Banking for the Poor", CGAP 2006 Tankha, Ajay, 2006, "Challenges and potential for Indian banks to implement the Business Facilitator and Business Correspondent Models", NABARD and GTZ, 2006 148
  • 151. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? Finalization of the draft microfinance bill promised by the finance minister in his budget speech of February 2005 has not only turned out to be a lengthy affair, as is common with microfinance bills around the world, but the bill has undergone considerable modification from the original version of the bill proposed by Sa-Dhan, the network of MFIs in India, after extensive consultations within its membership. The fundamental changes in concept undergone The latest version of the by the bill in its various versions are described at greater length in Box 9.1.1 The bill was bill being introduced in parliament as the Micro Financial Sector (Development and Regulation) Bill, considered by 2007, on 20 March 2007, and was referred by the Lok Sabha to the Standing Committee of the parliamentary Finance, which was still considering it at the time this chapter went to the printers (at the standing end of September 2007). The chapter first describes the main objectives of the bill as it committee on finance3, presently stands. It then discusses the major issues arising out of it. It does so because applies only to whatever the fate of the bill, the issues it raises will remain relevant to the sector for a long three categories time.2 Finally it draws attention to two regulatory steps the RBI could take immediately that of not-for-profit MFIs: societies, would have a much greater short-term impact on the sector than the bill itself, even if it gets trusts and passed in its present form. cooperatives. These are collectively The proposed microfinance bill referred to in the bill as Micro The latest version of the bill being considered by the parliamentary standing committee on Finance Organizations finance3, applies only to three categories of not-for-profit MFIs: societies, trusts and (MFOs). It does cooperatives. These are collectively referred to in the bill as Micro Finance Organizations not cover the bulk of the (MFOs). It does not cover the bulk of the sector in terms of share of borrowers and loans sector in terms outstanding, which is accounted for by MFIs registered as companies (for-profit NBFCs and of share of not-for-profit S 25 companies).4 borrowers and loans outstanding, The bill contains both prudential and non-prudential provisions. The former seek to allow which is MFOs to offer what are referred to as "thrift" services, defined as savings collected through accounted for by MFIs groups,5 after obtaining a certificate of registration from the new regulator created by the bill, registered as NABARD. NABARD may grant approval to an MFO to collect thrift if it has been in existence for companies (for- at least three years, has net owned funds of at least Rs 5 lakhs, and if NABARD is satisfied profit NBFCs and not-for- about the "general character" of the management of the MFO. Every MFO granted approval to profit S 25 offer thrift services shall create a reserve fund out of transfers to the fund of not less than 15 companies) 149
  • 152. percent of its net profit or surplus every year, and will prepare financial statements by the end of the year, in such form as may be specified, to be audited by an approved auditor. Cooperatives are of course already empowered to offer much more than "thrift" to their members as defined in the bill, since cooperative thrift or savings and credit societies offer their members individual savings accounts as well as fixed deposits. It is widely accepted that as mutual organizations prudential regulation of cooperatives can be much lighter than for entities accepting non-member (or public) deposits. Now they find themselves being treated on a par with societies and trusts. Sections of the cooperative movement feel understandably aggrieved that they were not consulted during formulation of the bill,6 and feel threatened by the uncertainties introduced by the arrival of the new regulator. A section of the cooperative movement has opposed the bill vocally, as discussed below. While one of While one of the main objectives of the bill is to allow NGO-MFIs to accept savings in the the main limited form of group savings, the bill prescribes in addition the "duty" of the regulator to objectives of the bill is to achieve the much broader non-prudential objective of promoting the "orderly growth of the allow NGO-MFIs micro financial sector so as to ensure greater transparency, effective management, good governance to accept savings in the …" Among the measures suggested through which it may do so are (i) setting benchmarks limited form of and performance standards (ii) facilitating the development of credit ratings norms (iii) group savings, specifying accounting and auditing standards (iv) facilitating institutional development the bill prescribes in through training and capacity building (v) supporting sector related research (vi) documenting addition the and disseminating information relating to fair practices (vii) laying down a code of conduct "duty" of the and (viii) and promoting consumer education. regulator to achieve the much broader The last three of these activities will support a third objective of the bill which is to create a non-prudential consumer protection regime by enabling the regulator to appoint "as many Micro Finance objective of promoting the Ombudsmen as it may deem fit" with powers to redress grievances by issuing directions to "orderly growth MFOs. A strict reading of the definition of MFO would seem to preclude the benefits of the of the micro ombudspersons from applying to the clients of NBFCs and not-for-profitS 25 companies. financial sector so as to ensure greater A fourth objective of the bill is to create a national data base "in the public domain" and transparency, disseminate it through a "national dissemination network". To this end every MFO whether effective management, providing thrift services or not will be required to file at the commencement of the act and at good intervals thereafter, duly audited returns. While on the one hand no minimum size for the governance …" purpose of filing returns is laid down for the societies, trusts and cooperatives falling within the purview of the bill, i.e. those offering "micro finance services",7 the bill on the other hand provides no authority to seek returns from NBFCs. This is the case also for the first three of the "orderly growth" activities listed above. With the exception of the training and research activities, the orderly growth activities will apply only to MFOs. It is hard to see how therefore the bill will succeed in promoting orderly growth for the sector as a whole, including equipping it with a much needed data base. Fifth, the bill provides for the setting up of a Micro Finance Development Council to advise the regulator on the "formulation of policies, schemes, and other measures required in the interest of orderly growth and development" of the sector. The Council shall consist of an experienced "person of eminence" as chairman, 7 official members,8 and 6 non-official experts with experience in rural banking and microfinance. 150
  • 153. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? Sixth, it provides for the continuation of the existing Micro Finance Development and Equity Fund to receive grants from the government and donors, to make loans to MFOs, to invest in their equity or quasi-equity, to make grants to them for capacity building, and to pay for the various functions of the regulator enumerated above. Finally, although this would be an effect rather than an explicit objective of the bill, it could Finally, although this be argued that by recognizing the legitimacy of their microfinance activities, the bill will would be an enhance the legal status of NGO-MFIs, and will in effect protect them from arbitrary state effect rather government action. However it provides no protection against state moneylenders acts, or than an explicit objective of the even for that matter the central government's own Usurious Loans Act 1918, which is still on bill, it could be the statute books. S 21A of the Banking Regulation Act expressly exempts the rate of interest argued that by charged by banks from state moneylender acts, as well as from any other law related to recognizing the legitimacy of indebtedness in force in any state. There is no such provision in the present bill. In fact, their quite the opposite. S 36 says its provisions "shall be in addition to, and not in derogation of, microfinance activities, the the provisions of any other law for the time being in force". bill will enhance the legal status Major issues of NGO-MFIs, and will in effect protect The bill excludes the bulk of the sector them from arbitrary state government One of the major omissions in the bill is that it excludes MFIs registered as NBFCs and S 25 action. However companies, which account for nearly all the large MFIs and the larger part of total microcredit it provides no in the country. Their number is steadily increasing as they are joined by more and more NGO- protection against state MFIs transforming themselves into companies in order to be able to attract equity investments moneylenders with which to leverage borrowed funds, and at the same time escape the vicissitudes of state acts government policy towards NGO-MFIs (NBFCs are regulated by the RBI).9 However, by including only societies, trusts and cooperatives, the bills is proposing to cut out at one stroke 60 percent of the sector in terms of portfolio outstanding on March 2007, and 55 percent of the total number of borrowers.10 It is doing so on the mistaken grounds that NBFCs are already regulated by the RBI. They are -- RBI regulations recognize 10 categories of NBFCs including loan, leasing, investment, and hire-purchase companies, and even a "residual" category of NBFCs like Sahara and Prudential. But microfinance is not one of the recognized categories. Nor have any of more than two dozen NBFCs conducting microcredit (defined in the bill as loans smaller than Rs 50,000 for most purposes, and smaller than Rs 1.5 lakhs for housing) managed to satisfy the stringent requirements that have been laid down by NBFC regulations to become eligible to mobilize savings. The irony is that not only can NBFC-MFIs not accept public deposits, but by virtue of being excluded from the bill they will not be able to accept the savings of their own borrower- members who will continue to have to rely on less convenient, riskier11 lower yielding, and often socially less productive savings instruments (such as ornaments). There is understandable reluctance to allow MFIs to mobilize public deposits, without putting in place the necessary safequards, for sound prudential reasons. But the vast majority of MFI members are net borrowers of the MFI at any one time. They borrow to finance their larger investment requirements, but simultaneously save small amounts regularly to finance their liquidity requirements, provide for emergencies, build up a cushion to tide over the lean season when agricultural wage employment is scarce, and aggregate 151
  • 154. savings into amounts large enough to make useful investments, repair the hut, send a daughter to high school, or a son to the big city to look for work. The argument adduced for keeping NBFCs outside the purview of the bill (the need to avoid duality of regulation) is equally applicable to district, state and urban cooperative banks which are governed by the Banking Regulation Act in respect of banking activities, while conforming to the cooperative law in other respects. Like them, NBFCs would be governed by the microfinance bill in respect of thrift activities, without any dilution of their capital, reserve, or liquidity requirements as NBFCs, until they qualify under NBFC regulations to mobilize not just thrift from members, but hopefully, also, public savings. It is true that dual regulation of cooperative banks has not been a resounding success. However as Sinha points out (2007b) UCBs are financed primarily by deposits, whereas MFIs, even after being allowed to accept thrift, will always depend primarily on borrowings from the banks and the financial institutions, and will be subject therefore to due diligence exercised by their lenders.12 However as In confusing the form of incorporation with the substantial nature of the institution, or form Sinha points with function, the act will also deprive more than half of borrowers (the proportion is set to out (2007b) UCBs are grow) from the protection of the ombudsman, and the sector as a whole from the benefits of financed universal performance standards in respect of microfinance activities and a much needed data primarily by deposits, base. whereas MFIs, even after It allows NGO-MFIs to mobilize thrift: which is a small step forward being allowed to accept thrift, India's attitude to savings mobilization by non-banks has been more restrictive than elsewhere, will always depend an attitude strengthened by periodic scams which affect the savings of the urban middle primarily on classes and which therefore receive widespread publicity in the press. Most of the countries of borrowings from the banks and South Asia, which share the same legal heritage, now expressly allow savings in their microfinance the financial legislation. Bangladesh, where conditions are closest to India, and where the MFI model institutions, originated, has recently passed the Micro Credit Regulatory Authority (MCRA) Act 2006, which and will be subject allows the MCRA to allow MFIs to offer savings withdrawable on demand. Sri Lanka also allows therefore to due NGO-MFIs to mobilize deposits once they have received the regulators permission.13 The diligence exercised by provisions in the bill enabling savings, albeit in a limited form, are probably the single most their lenders important contribution of the bill. However, ironically it is this aspect of the bill that has been the most widely misunderstood by critics. These misunderstandings are dealt with separately in Box 9.2. There is also a widespread misconception that the poor are too poor to save, and that they need credit, not savings facilities and services. On the contrary, savings is probably a more widely felt need than credit, and takes place through a variety of savings mechanisms and institutions in the informal sector, such as itinerant deposit collectors,14 small community chit funds, informal credit unions (such as the bishis of Maharashta), investments in livestock or ornaments (which can later be liquefied through the pawnbroker and moneylender), or by lending to a friend in need so that the lender can borrow reciprocally when required.15 The phenomenal growth of the SHG movement in which rural women meet with unfailing regularity once a month to save small sums ranging from Rs 10 to 50, and the fact that poor urban slum dwellers, far from earning interest on their savings, are willing to pay to have their deposits collected at the doorstep and stored safely until they amount to a useful sum, and countless other examples, attest to the importance of the almost universal need to save. Like the rest 152
  • 155. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? of us, the poor are looking for savings services which are convenient, safe, liquid, and can preferably be used to leverage loans. By allowing at least MFOs to meet this need, the draft microfinance bill takes a long overdue, Because Indian albeit small step forward.16 Quite apart from the benefits to MFO members, there will be benefits MFIs have had to rely to the MFOs themselves - their cost of funds will come down, and their members' sense of exclusively on ownership in their MFO will increase, since a part of the loans they will be getting will be theirfunds borrowed from the banks, own money coming back to them, giving them a further incentive to maintain high repayment their financial rates. Because Indian MFIs have had to rely exclusively on funds borrowed from the banks, expense ratios their financial expense ratios (cost of funds as a proportion of total costs) are the highest in (cost of funds as a proportion the world (see Chapter 4 of last year's report). In Bangladesh, on the other hand, interest rates of total costs) are slightly lower than in India, because as much as a third of the funds base comes from are the highest in the world member savings. Many Bangladeshi MFIs also pay a slightly higher rate to savers than the banks, because of the cost efficiencies that ensue from economies of scope in being able to use existing field staff, who have to meet borrowers once a week anyway to collect loan repayment installments and disburse fresh loans. Grameen Bank mobilizes in fact more savings than it disburses as credit (as does Bank Rakyat Indonesia, further examples of how savings are as valued by poor clients as credit). How can it be ensured that the vast majority of MFIs members remain net borrowers at any one time? (i) First, by licensing MFIs to collect savings only after they have established a track record as lenders. (ii) Second, once licensed, by limiting acceptance of savings only to their borrowers and not the public. (iii) Third, by ensuring that not more than a small proportion of the borrowers of the MFI are net savers at any one time, or in other words have more savings deposited than loans outstanding.17 (iv) Fourth, by laying down a ceiling on the total savings that can be mobilized as a proportion of the liquid assets of the MFI in the form of loans outstanding at any one time, the savings/loans outstanding ratio could be set, say, at 50 percent, which would ensure that the MFI would also have to borrow to fund its loans and thereby subject itself to the normal scrutiny that any lender such as bank or financial institution would exercise (Sinha 2007b). (v) A further prudential measure would be to prescribe a liquidity reserve, the size of which should depend on the liquidity of savings offered.18 While the bill provides for the first two of these conditions, Section 10 (1) (e) enables the regulator to lay down the remaining three or any other condition it deems appropriate. … however, it remains a rather small step: compulsory versus voluntary savings While the proposal to allow thrift is welcome and long overdue, it is important to note it is only the first small step forward in introducing savings. Quite apart from the fact that it only applies to MFOs, thrift is defined in the bill as monies collected by a micro finance organization only from "a group, or by a group from its members through the group mechanism…" What this definition seems to have in mind is the kind of uniform, mandatory, monthly savings service offered by SHGs in India, and by the smaller joint liability groups used by MFIs in Bangladesh, the Philippines, and in more than 45 other countries which have MFIs based on the Grameen Bank model. While many savers welcome the discipline of compulsory savings, they tend to belong to the better-off among the poor or to the "near-poor" above the poverty line. On the other hand 153
  • 156. many of the poorer members of SHGs (and most of the self-excluded non-members), who have highly uncertain and variable incomes, would prefer to save small variable amounts, with variable frequency (Rutherford 2005). Several surveys have found that the main reason for why only half the members of SHGs are below the poverty line is the inability of BPL persons to commit themselves to the required mandatory savings amounts and periodicities. Uniform mandatory savings are also the most frequent reason cited by drop-outs for leaving SHGs.19 Indeed, A concomitant of mandatory savings products is their illiquidity. While illiquid savings protect recognizing the the savings of the poor from daily demands, and are suited to accumulating lump-sums for liquidity preference of expected purposes such as life-cycle events or school fees or adding a new room to the hut, the poor for they are unsuited to coping with unexpected emergencies including sickness and disease, or many although not all savings consumption smoothening in the lean season, or replacing a leaky roof in the middle of the purposes, monsoons (CGAP 2005a). While the SHG movement provides for unexpected demands to some several MFIs in extent, through small intra-group loans, and the MFI model does so through "emergency Bangladesh, and indeed world- loans", these are an imperfect substitute for being able to access ones own savings quickly in wide, who have an emergency. the requisite accounting Indeed, recognizing the liquidity preference of the poor for many although not all savings systems, are moving to a purposes, several MFIs in Bangladesh, and indeed world-wide, who have the requisite accounting system of systems, are moving to a system of voluntary savings in which the saver has some choice over voluntary savings in the timing and amount of savings and withdrawals. Some Bangladesh MFIs have introduced which the saver "open access" savings (in which savers have access to their savings whenever they like), and has some choice have found that the inflow of total savings far from declining has in fact increased,20 (See Box over the timing and amount of 9.3 and Wright 2000).21 It is not being suggested that most small Indian NGO-MFIs have savings and developed the requisite systems yet to be able to able to offer such a savings product,22 or withdrawals that mandatory savings do not have their advantages for certain purposes. However, provision should be made for the day when a larger number of NGO-MFIs have developed the requisites systems and capacity to offer voluntary savings.23 Since voluntary savings are more conveniently offered as individual savings (because voluntary savings amounts and frequency will always vary from individual to individual), it would seem essential to allow the regulator the option to approve individual, voluntary, savings products in appropriate cases after due diligence by the regulator on a case by case basis. In order to do so, the words "or by other means" need to be inserted after the words "group mechanism" in the definition of thrift in clause 2 (l) of the Bill. Also, the exclusion in the definition of thrift of current accounts and demand deposits needs to be removed. These would be enabling provisions in the case of most MFOs for now, but a very useful one when the time comes (given the difficulties of securing amendments to a legislative act in the future). A third amendment required it to clearly exclude SHG federations from the definitions of groups. The phrase in the definition of "group" "or a group called by any other name" has created apprehensions to the contrary. The definition requires a group to provide micro finance services to individual members of the group, which many federations do (see Chapter 3).24 Should cooperatives be covered by the Act? Cooperatives are defined in the bill to include all cooperatives except cooperative banks and 154
  • 157. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? cooperatives "engaged in agricultural operations".25 India's has for a long time had a large thrift cooperative movement which at one time was one of the strongest in the world.26 There is no estimate at present of the number of thrift cooperatives, or even of those registered under the new MACS acts (see below). At one time NABARD did publish data on cooperatives on the basis of information received from state registrars but has for some years stopped doing so.27 The responsibility for regulation and supervision of PACS is being transferred to NABARD under the central government's Revival Package for the Rural Cooperative Thrift and Credit System.28 With the present bill a similar responsibility is being conferred on NABARD for thrift cooperatives. The issue with respect to bringing thrift cooperatives under the bill is that cooperatives, as The mutual organizations, are already allowed to accept savings from their members. Indeed the responsibility for regulation term thrift has been in use by thousands of cooperatives in India for several decades now29 and supervision and has been further popularized by the Cooperative Development Foundation, a well known of PACS is being transferred to civil society organization registered as an NGO in Andhra Pradesh, which spearheaded the NABARD under movement for cooperative reform, and lobbied with the AP legislature to enact the Mutually the central Aided Cooperative Societies Act or APMACS Act in 1995. This was followed by the enactment government's Revival Package of similar acts in 8 other states and a central multi-state act to provide for a new type of for the Rural "mutually aided" or "mutual benefit"30 cooperative which would be much truer to cooperative Cooperative Thrift and principles than traditional cooperatives under existing state acts, and enjoy much more Credit System. autonomy and freedom from government interference of the kind that has led to the With the deterioration of traditional cooperatives.31 present bill a similar responsibility is CDF has set up 450 "mutually aided", women's and men's thrift cooperatives under the new act being conferred in Warangal, and two neighbouring districts of AP, which exercise a powerful demonstration on NABARD for thrift effect on how savings and credit cooperatives should function. With meticulous accounts, cooperatives good governance, compulsory monthly thrift ranging from Rs 20 to 50, and membership of about 250 each, they have mobilized own funds or member savings in various forms to the tune of Rs 46 crores (by March 2007), of which Rs 40 crores has been lent back to members. CDF is strongly opposed to MACS being brought under the bill since they are already empowered to mobilize thrift. It fought a long battle to rescue cooperatives from the ill advised attempt over the years to assist cooperatives with subsidies so as to convert them into vehicles for political patronage, and is understandably worried about coming under the oversight of an organization it fears may not understand the MACS ethos. It is strongly opposed to MACS being brought under the bill. The bill does indeed empower the central government to exempt a particular class of microfinance organization from any or all the provisions of the Act, and it will have to do so for SHGs of which there were 2.86 million by March 2007, and which can not possibly be expected to apply for registration to mobilize savings individually. However CDF and the MACS community (including, reportedly, the AP government setting up SHG federations registered as MACS under IKP) are understandably reluctant to depend on government to exempt them as a class after the bill becomes law. As a vocal civil society organization CDF has experienced considerable opposition from the state government on a host of issues in the past, an instance of which was the AP government's action to foreclose the MACS option for dairy cooperatives, a matter which CDF took to the AP High Court and had overturned. A more recent instance is the ban the AP government has placed on further registration of thrift cooperatives as MACS. CDF is 155
  • 158. likely to lead the challenge to the bill on the grounds that as mutual organizations cooperatives are already allowed to mobilize thrift under the principle of mutuality, and on other grounds. The alternatives however are not clear. There has been little effective supervision of thrift cooperatives by the state registrars of cooperative societies, even under the new acts. None of the states with MACS acts have appointed a separate set of registrars at the state of district level, who continue to exercise jurisdiction under both acts. Perhaps for reasons of lack of proper orientation under the MACS acts the registrars have shown little inclination to discharge the functions entrusted to them under the statute.32 Although prudential concerns are greatly softened by the member-owned nature of cooperatives, they are not entirely eliminated. While it is unique among the nine MACS acts in this respect, the AP MACS act allows societies to accept deposits even from non-members and many of them do. Also, as the Union Task Force on Revival of Cooperative Credit Institutions points out, most cooperative members restrict membership with full voting rights to borrowers. Depositors are categorized as nominal members33 without full voting rights, or are not given any membership status. Cooperative boards tend therefore to be dominated by borrowers. Thorat and Wright have suggested that restrictions on loans to board members and strengthening the presence of net savers on cooperative boards will lead to more effective pressure on cooperative management to ensure prudent governance and protect the interest of savers (Thorat and Wright 2006). Although Effective supervision is important not only at the primary level but also at the secondary level. prudential SHG federations registered as MACS have become important players in the sector in AP, where concerns are greatly softened the two tiers of SHG federations at the village and mandal level, as we have seen in Chapter 3, by the member- have either already been, or are slated to be, registered as MACS. Orissa, where federations owned nature of cooperatives, have been formed in every panchayat of the state (but are not yet active) has also registered they are not its federations under the Orissa Self Help Cooperatives Act, the equivalent of the MACS in the entirely state. Other states may well adopt the MACS form of registration for their federations. At eliminated. While it is present, according to one observer, the relationship of such federations with the MACS act unique among ends as soon as they have been registered, and they simply exist in the books of the district the nine MACS registrar.34 acts in this respect, the AP MACS act allows The supervision of thousands of thrift cooperatives all over the country is going to be a huge societies to task compared to the supervision of the much smaller number of societies and trusts providing accept deposits even from non- microfinance services whose number is estimated at not more than a thousand. Rather than members and seeking to supplant the registrars all over the country it might be more practicable (and many of them certainly more in accordance of the spirit of cooperation) for the states to energize the state do registrars and ensure they carry out their obligations under the old and new acts. A third alternative is for MACS conducting microfinance to set up a system of self-regulation a possible solution being studied by APMAS.35 At the very least a careful study of the situation on the ground would seem desirable before rushing into a supervisory solution that might not be practicable (apart from being possibly unconstitutional, unless the states sign on to it as some of them have to the broader cooperative reform programme36). Also, as discussed below, while NABARD does have a presence in the field, it is not clear whether it is willing to employ the resources necessary to supplement it if required by the added workload. The decision should hinge on which agency is likely to have greater commitment, resources and expertise.37 156
  • 159. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? As already noted, one of the purposes of the bill is to create a data base in the public domain containing essential information such as the number and type of MFOs of different kinds, the number of borrowers (and now savers), the quantum of lending and savings (or in other words something as basic as the size of the sector), and a host of other variables the lack of which is an important gap in the knowledge base essential for sound policy making for the sector.38 However, despite the reporting requirements in the MACS acts, data on MACS is as deficient as it is on societies and trusts. It would seem advisable therefore to find a way of at least including cooperatives in respect of the reporting requirements of the bill, and perhaps also those relating to its consumer protection provisions, since not all cooperatives, whether traditional or MACS, have as good and responsive a governance as those organized by CDF.39 At the very least the actual position with respect to this and other issues needs to be examined at the field level and discussed much more widely and openly than they have been so far. Who should the regulator be? The bill initially prepared by Sa-Dhan envisaged that the regulator would be the Micro Finance The bill initially prepared by Sa- Development Council itself, which would have body corporate status, and consist of a Dhan envisaged chairperson, not more than five whole-time members, and not more than four part-time members. that the All the members were to be persons of experience in micro finance and related disciplines, regulator would be the Micro with not less than half representing the micro finance, NGO or the rural development sectors. Finance Members would hold office for up to five yeares. The Council would be much more than an Development Council itself, advisory body. Apart from all the powers of the regulator listed above, it would be the registering which would authority for MFOs and MFIs as well as for the empanelment of rating agencies and chartered have body accountants. corporate status, and consist of a Although it would have been the appointing authority of the Council, the government felt chairperson, not unable to cede regulatory authority to an independent professional authority and opted for more than five whole-time NABARD as the regulator in the version of the bill that was submitted to parliament. Considerable members, and unease has been expressed in the sector at his choice, primarily on grounds of its conflict of not more than interest with NABARD's role as the promoter and champion of one particular model of four part-time members. All microfinance, the SHG-bank linkage model. Other observers have identified the alleged source the members of conflict as coming from the opposite direction, from the fact that NABARD is an investor were to be in, and lender to, MFIs through the MFDEF. However this is an unlikely source of bias - the persons of experience in major criticism of the MFDEF is that it has been extremely slow so far in getting off the ground micro finance on account of excessive caution by NABARD on account of bureaucracy and lack of familiarity and related disciplines, with the MFI model. Besides the MFDEF board has non-official sector representatives on it. with not less than half What is surprising, however, is that after NABARD had been named the regulator in the pending representing bill, it announced that it was planning to float a huge retail MFI of its own called Nabard the micro finance, NGO or Financial Services, or NABFINS, as an NBFC. The proposal was reportedly motivated by a desire the rural to act as a role model to the sector.40 As has been pointed out NABFINSs would be more of a development sectors role model if it were to be set up in the one of the underserved parts of the country. Being a majority owner of an MFI would be a clear conflict of interest for NABARD. Some observers have argued that the regulator ought to be the RBI.41 The RBI of course already regulates MFI-NBFCs, along with thousands of other NBFCs. Were it to create a separate category of NBFCs with requirements more suited to microfinance, as recommended below, their number is not likely to exceed more than a few dozen for at least some years, which is 157
  • 160. surely a manageable supervisory task. However, it would not seem feasible for the RBI to supervise MFOs, even without coopearatives. Sa-Dhan in its submission to the Standing Committee is reported to sought to have attempted to partly retrieve the original concept of an independent authority by urging that 50 percent of the members of the Council's proposed 14 members be selected from the microfinance sector (instead of, as currently proposed, 7 from officialdom, 6 non-official experts and a chairman) and also that the Council's decisions should be binding on the implementing agencies under the act. It is unlikely that this good suggestion will be accepted. What about supervision? "it is relatively There has been virtually no discussion of what arrangements NABARD envisages to implement easy and its regulatory responsibilities through supervision. As CGAP 2003 points out "it is relatively interesting to craft easy and interesting to craft regulations, but harder and less attractive to do the concrete regulations, but practical planning for effective supervision…the result may be regulation that is not enforced, harder and less attractive to do which can be worse than no regulation at all". We have already touched on the problems of the concrete regulating thousands of thrift cooperatives. To supervise societies and trusts, field supervisory practical personnel will have to be trained in microfinance methods and operations, and special skills planning for effective such as portfolio testing. NABARD does have a field presence in the districts but it may have supervision…the to supplement it, not just to carry out supervisory responsibilities but to assist the result may be ombudspersons and participate in the data gathering effort. The extra costs will have to be regulation that is not enforced, realistically estimated, and provided for. which can be worse than no Consumer protection regulation at all" Although the bill does not explicitly use the term consumer protection, and the final version of the bill now merely enables the appointment of one or more ombudspersons rather than make it mandatory, and that too only for NGO-MFIs, it specifies several of the important features of a consumer protection regime by suggesting such measures as a code of conduct, disseminating information on fair practices, and promoting consumer education. The last three of these are also a fruitful area for collaboration between the regulator and the industry through self-regulation. Among the positive effects of the Krishna district episode in March 2006 (Chapter 4 of last year's report) was the fact that many of its lessons for MFI practices were recognized and codified in Sa-Dhan's interim code of conduct (Box 4.1 of last year's report). The interim code emphasized among other things the need to (i) avoid over-financing of the same household by different MFIs, (ii) make interest rates more transparent, (iii) ensure that staff do not use abusive language or intimidation tactics while collecting repayments, (iv) ensure high standards of corporate governance by including on MFI boards eminent independent board members, and (v) stay in touch with government authorities, banks and the media on a regular basis. The interim code was replaced with a statement of "core values and a voluntary mutual code of conduct" released at Sa-Dhan's annual conference in January 2007. The first part of the statement, relating to core values reiterated that MFI services will be delivered in an "ethical, dignified, transparent, equitable and cost effective" manner. Clients should be educated about the terms of loans offered to them, and a balance struck between respect for a client's dignity, an understanding of her vulnerability, and a "reasonable pursuit" of loan recovery. 158
  • 161. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? The Code of Conduct itself is part II of the statement, parts of which are reproduced in Box 9.4. Part III of the statement provides for the setting up of an Ethics and Grievance Redressal Committee to look into cases of non-compliance by member MFIs, leading to expulsion from Sa-Dhan if warranted. The existence of a code of conduct should make it unnecessary for the regulator to prepare its Now that the own, although it will have to adopt it formally (with modifications if need to be) so as to give sector has experienced at it legal sanction, and bring within its purview NGO-MFIs that are not members of Sa-Dhan. As first hand how discussed in last year's report, many difficult questions remain in translating the general bad practice by some members principles in the code of conduct into specifics, such as when exactly competition become can undermine unethical, or what constitutes over-lending, or above what level interest rates become the reputation "unreasonable". Individual grievances brought before the ombudsmen (if and when appointed) of sector as a whole, members will also serve to put flesh and bones on these principles, just as the decisions of the courts of the continue to add to the general law. committee will hopefully be more likely than A much broader role for self-regulation was envisaged as early as 1998, when a task force was before to set up by the RBI under the chairmanship of NABARD. (Box 9.5). Although nothing came of overcome any the initiative, and there are no examples of comprehensive self-regulation being successful natural reluctance they anywhere in the world, consumer protection is one area where self-regulation has a major role may feel about to play (CGAP 2005b). Now that the sector has experienced at first hand how bad practice by making adverse evaluative some members can undermine the reputation of sector as a whole, members of the committee judgements will hopefully be more likely than before to overcome any natural reluctance they may feel about their about making adverse evaluative judgements about their peers, which has been the Achilles peers, which has been the Heel of self-regulation in other areas. It is all the more important that they do so in view of Achilles Heel of the fact that the legal backing of the bill will be available, if at all, only for breaches of the self-regulation code by NGO-MFI members. The precipitating factor behind the chain of events set into in other areas motion by the Krishna district episode on the other hand were allegations of misconduct by NBFC members. The advantage of the Sa-Dhan code is that it applies to all members. Two other regulatory issues are as important as the microfinance bill There are two important areas of reform that would have a more immediate impact on financial inclusion, at least in respect of credit services, than the bill as presently drafted, essential though legislation is in the long run, if microfinance in India is to "enter the arena of licensed, prudentially supervised financial intermediation" (CGAP 2003) as it has in most other countries with microfinance acts. Both areas lie within the jurisdiction of the RBI. The first is less intractable politically, and depends very much on the attitude and stance of the RBI towards commercial microfinance through for-profit institutions such as NBFCs. The real questions with respect to the first area therefore is RBI's vision of the role of microfinance in India as discussed in Chapter 1. If the RBI wanted to, it could easily create a new category of Microfinance NBFC more suited to microfinance than that the RBI's present NBFC guidelines. If the microfinance bill is not amended to include NBFCs, or enacted at all, the RBI could take the liberal view that thrift contributions do not constitute public deposits,42 and allow these new MFI-NBFCs to mobilize member-savings. After all, this is the implicit view taken by the bill with respect to NGO-MFI 159
  • 162. member-savings, and would be in keeping with the RBI's own bold view taken in the mid-90s that SHG member savings do not constitute public savings because SHGs partake of the nature of member-owned mutual institutions despite being purely informal. Without this interpretation by the RBI at the time, the SHG bank linkage programme would never have happened. As noted earlier, the regulatory task of supervising the relatively small number of new MFI-NBFCs will remain manageable.43 The second area is more sensitive politically, and relates to the interest cap on loans below Rs 2 lakhs for commercial banks, which is fixed at the prime lending rate. This issue has been discussed in detail elsewhere, including last year's report, and will not be expanded upon here, but it is important to note that it relates to a restriction that is self-imposed by the RBI, although the RBI would no doubt want to consult the government before removing it. The main effect of the restriction is to deny credit to poor borrowers, and its removal is likely to see a significant expansion of micro and small loans, whose share in total lending and number of accounts has been steadily declining. It will be interesting to see whether the Committee on Financial Inclusion will have the political will to include it in its reommendations.44 So ambivalent Because the cap applies to the business correspondent model too, it has effectively killed that is the bill about model on the lending side. As discussed in last year's report (Chapter 7A) the PLR does not savings that it does not use allow enough headroom for the bank to compensate the correspondent for its loan initiation, the word monitoring and collection services. "savings" once. Even "thrift" is not included in Conclusion45 the bill in the definition of The bill makes a small beginning in introducing savings to less than half the sector, but in far "micro finance services" too limited a form. Savings are defined much too narrowly as "thrift" or small compulsory periodic savings. One does not have to agree with much of the microfinance literature which argues that these contributions are not savings at all, but are viewed by most borrowers as part of the cost of borrowing, which they passively accept as a condition of accessing loans rather than value for their own sake. This does not seem to be generally true in India, where savings have been the most successful part of the SHG programme (too successful it could be argued, because productive opportunities to use the savings haven't kept pace with their growth). But it is the case that the inflexibility of compulsory savings has kept the poorest out of the programme, as many surveys show. So ambivalent is the bill about savings that it does not use the word "savings" once. Even "thrift" is not included in the bill in the definition of "micro finance services". It has even been suggested that the primary motivation of the RBI, if not of the government, in promoting the bill, is to address the concern expressed by some that the whole SHG programme is illegal because it allegedly violates the Banking Regulation Act. This concern is unfounded, since SHGs, although purely informal and unregistered, are mutual organizations. As noted above, it was this bold view taken by the then RBI governor that allowed the banks to lend to SHGs and give rise to the largest, and so far one of the most successful, microfinance programmes in the world. The approach at present seems timid in comparision. Second, by excluding companies, the bill not only denies a large part of the sector the direct benefits of the bill (mobilization of member savings, and possibly consumer protection if the regulator decides to provide it) it denies the sector as a whole the indirect sector-wide 160
  • 163. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? benefits. While some "orderly growth" activities could be taken care of by the RBI for NBFCs, such as setting performance and accounting standards, it is unlikely to be able to set up a consumer protection regime or build a data base, even for the MFI-NBFCs under its purview,46 for lack of supervisory resources. The bill confers a modicum of legitimacy on the most vulnerable part of the sector, the NGO- MFIs, but is careful not to step on the toes of the states by failing to assert that the principle of cost-recovering interest rates takes precedence over caps on interest rates under state moneylender acts, although this principle has recently been implicitly recognized by the Technical Group to Review Legislations on Moneylending (RBI 2007).47 The group has recommended that societies and trusts should be exempted from the purview of moneylender acts, and that state governments in setting interest rate caps, should "look at the range of interest rates being charged by micro finance entities". The bill violates the spirit and intent of the new MACS acts in reducing the role of government Given these and other in cooperation. It is true that the registrars under the new acts are not performing supervisory, limitations of data gathering and consumer protection functions any better than the old ones, but will the the bill, and the new regulator be able to do a better job for thousands of thrift cooperatives all over the fact that amendments to country? In any case cooperation is a state subject, and the states will have to sign on, an act once unless the courts take the narrow view that accepting thrift even from one's own member- passed are not easy to make, borrowers constitutes "banking", which is a central subject. many observers feel it may be The bill does not provide the sector with a form of registration uniquely suited to microfinance. desirable for It leaves NGO-MFIs with no alternative between remaining NGOs and having to raise enough the sector to wait a little capital to become NBFCs.48 Societies and trusts were not designed as vehicles for financial longer till operations, and although NGO-MFIs are non-profits, they have a hard time convincing the further debate, local income tax authorities that their surpluses are intended for expansion and leverage of advocacy, and field studies, borrowed funds. Yet Rs 2 crores is too much for many NGOs to raise, especially as an NGO is not where allowed to contribute its accumulated surpluses to the equity of a new NBFC for tax reasons.49 necessary, lead to a better Rs 25 lakhs as the entry capital requirement for the special-window "MFIs" envisaged seemed understanding about right when the first version of the bill was formulated. However, it could be increased to of microfinance Rs 50 lakhs now. Special-window MFIs would constitute a valuable intermediate stage of among policy makers, and incorporation between remaining an NGO and becoming a full-fledged NBFC. indeed among many sector Finally, as we have seen the nature and composition of the Microfinance Development Council players themselves leave much to be desired. Given these and other limitations of the bill, and the fact that amendments to an act once passed are not easy to make, many observers feel it may be desirable for the sector to wait a little longer till further debate, advocacy, and field studies, where necessary, lead to a better understanding of microfinance among policy makers, and indeed among many sector players themselves. They would argue that some of the benefits of the bill can be partly provided through self-regulation, such as those relating to consumer protection and the "orderly growth" activities, and that the costs of postponing enactment of the bill are lower than enacting it without major amendments. The main cost would be the loss of the limited go-ahead to "thrift" services, and of the modicum of legitimacy the bill should impart to public and state level bureaucratic perceptions of microfinance. It is not an easy choice, but at least it needs to be widely debated by the sector before the parliamentary committee completes its work. 161
  • 164. Box 9.1 The microfinance bill: a case study in dilution The draft bill initially prepared by Sa-Dhan envisaged that the regulator would be an independent professional body appointed by the central government. It also proposed the creation of a two-tier structure for the sector, with two categories of microfinance service providers. Micro Finance Organizations (MFOs) would be allowed to mobilize savings only from members and be subjected to simple reporting requirements. Once they had a loan portfolio of more than Rs 1 crore however, they would have to convert themselves into companies as "Micro Finance Institutions", but with a lower entry capital requirement than is required currently for NBFCs (Rs 25 lakhs instead of Rs 1 crore). This special window would have made it much easier for NGO-MFIs to transform to company status, which is more suited to microfinance operations as discussed earlier. Micro Finance Institutions, on the other hand, would be allowed to mobilize savings from the public subject to several conditions. However, after extensive inter-agency consultations led by the Ministry of Finance, the bill actually submitted to government in August 2006 for inter-ministerial discussion and Cabinet consideration took the form of an amendment to the NABARD Act which nominated NABARD as the regulator, giving the Council only an advisory role. In this modified version not only was the two-tier structure abandoned, NBFCs were dropped from the bill altogether. In the third and final version that was presented to parliament it became apparent that four further changes had taken place.50 The bill was no longer an amendment bill to an existing act (the NABARD) act, but a bill relating to a new act, and was renamed the Micro Finance Sector (Development and Regulation) Bill, 2007. The composition of the Council, which had already become merely advisory, was changed from being primarily non-official and professional, to predominantly official. Not-for-profit S 25 companies were dropped from the definition of MFOs, who were to consist now only of societies, trusts and cooperatives. Finally, the proposal to create an ombudsman went from being mandatory to merely enabling. Table 9.1 summarizes the major differences between the three versions, and Table 9.2 differences between MFOs and the new "MFIs" (the proposal to create which has now been dropped). 162
  • 165. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? Table 9.1 Successive versions of the microfinance bill Original bill proposed Modified bill Current version by Sa-Dhan in circulated by Ministry approved by Cabinet consutation with of Finance for inter- and introduced in members and key agency discussion parliament government agencies Name Micro Finance National Bank for The Micro Financial Development Council Agriculture and Rural Sector (Development Act, 2005 Development and Regulation) Act, (Amendment) Bill, 2007 (Bill No. 41 of 2006 2007) Scope All existing categories New category of "MFI" Only NGO-MFIs of MFIs, including a dropped, but MFOs registered as new category of "MFI" defined to include all societies, trust and registered as a non-profits, including cooperatives (i.e. company with an S 25 companies excluding NBFCs an S entry capital of Rs 25 25 companies) lakhs (see Table … Structure Two-tier, with MFOs One tier, MFOs only, One tier, MFOs only, envisaged for and "MFIs" (apart from (apart from NBFCs, (apart from NBFCs and sector NBFCs) who along with banks S 25 companies, but are included in data no provisions gathering applicable to them) requirements) Savings "Thrift" for MFOs, Only "thrift" for MFOs Only "thrift" for MFOs authorization public savings for special category "MFIs" Regulator Microfinance NABARD NABARD Development Council Micro Finance Independent body of Advisory body, but Advisory, with Development experienced with majority of majority consisting of Council professionals with members representing officials representing executive the sector specified agencies ex- responisbilities officio Ombudsman Not specifically MFDC required to set MFDC "may" set up provided, but MFDC to up ombudsman ombudsman establish mechanism for redressal of greivances 163
  • 166. Table 9.2 MFOs and "MFIs" Original bill proposed by Sa-Dhan in Modified bill circulated by consutation with members and key Ministry of Finance for inter- government agencies agency discussion MFO "MFI" (as defined in MFO MFI (in bill with capital of Rs generic 25 lakhs) sense) Size- Credit Above the limits for Since "MFIs" NBFCs trigger for outstanding not an MFO must dropped, none. Bill registration to exceed Rs 1 incorporate an "MFI" includes all non- as "MFI" crore or 10 times company if MFO is a profit forms of NOF, whichever is society or trust (if registration less cooperative, must including S 25 comply with norms for companies "MFIs") Capital Must maintain a NOF of not less than NOF of at least Rs 5 As per capital adequacy Rs 25 lakhs, of which lakhs and a capital existing ratio of 10 at least 10 percent adequacy ratio of NBFC percent promoters 15 percent regulations contribution (with provision for exemption for cooperatives) and CA ratio of 15 percent Type of Only thrift from Deposits from the Only thrift from As per savings members public members existing NBFC regulations Limit on Not more than Rs No limit, but No limit, but must As per savings/ 25 lakhs in certificate of have had surplus existing eligibility aggregate, and registration as "MFI" income in at least NBFC conditions Rs 5000 or such to be granted only to the year before regulations other amount MFO with aggregate applying for specified by thrift of not more registration, and Council per than 4 times NOF, or compliance with individual more than aggregate rating norms loans outstanding, whichever is less Restricitons Not be repayable No restrictions No restrictions As per on thrift in less than three existing months NBFC regulations Reserve Must transfer not Must transfer not less Must transfer not As per fund less than 10 than 15 percent of less than 15 existing percent of surplus to RF percent of surplus NBFC surplus to RF to RF regulations 164
  • 167. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? Box 9.2 Misunderstandings about savings The provisions in the bill enabling savings, albeit in a limited form, are probably the single most important contribution of the bill. However, ironically it is this aspect of the bill that has been the most widely misunderstood and attacked by critics, who have alleged that NGO- MFIs must not be allowed to mobilize "public" savings. However this is not what is proposed. The savings in question are the savings of borrower-members, the vast majority of whom are net borrowers of the MFI at any one time. To argue, as some people do, that borrowers are not "members" of the MFI in the same sense that members of mutual institutions are, depends on whether one defines membership in a strictly technical sense or according to the substantive nature of the bond it creates. Under the Grameen Bank methodology, borrowers have to meet eligibility conditions, receive week-long training, and pass a test before qualifying to receive their first loan. Thereafter they are in contact with the MFI at least once a week, when the MFI field worker comes to collect loan repayments, which is much more frequent than in mutual organizations. The peer pressure to repay loans exercised through joint liability groups is often much stronger than in the larger and far looser primary groups of mutual organizations. MFIs recognize and reward long-standing "members" when graduating them to larger, housing, or other individual, loans. The loyalty of members to their MFI is usually every bit as strong as in a mutual institution, in which, as has been pointed out, the boundaries of membership can be porous, depending on the nature of the "common bond" of the mutual institution. If the common bond is area- based, or geographical, membership can be given to anyone in the area who wants to make a deposit. In any case, in practice, as the 2005 Union Task Force on the Revival of Cooperative Credit Credit Institutions points out, membership with full voting rights is usually given only to borrowers, with depositors being categorized as nominal members without voting rights, which is why borrowers rather than net savers tend to dominate cooperative boards, although this is not the case with the new mutually-aided cooperative society acts passed in nine states, and is an issue the ongoing cooperative reform is trying to set right. Thus, if an MFI "flies by night" (the second misunderstanding) it will stand to lose much more than it gains, since most members will owe the MFI much more than it owes them. Also, an MFI can not "fly by night" because it is first and foremost a credit institution. Unlike an unlicensed finance company, it needs dozens if not hundreds of field workers, who work out of branch offices as it expands. These huge establishments and infrastructure requirements can not disappear overnight. The MFI can of course collapse from incompetence or fraud, but if it does so (and no recognized MFI out of the approximately 1000 societies, trusts etc estimated to be conducting microfinance in India, is reported to have done so yet) it will again be borrowers who will be the net gainers in a strict financial sense, provided the norms recommended earlier are followed. The regulator is in any case required to assess the "general character" of an MFI before approving it for thrift. Last, and this is the third misunderstanding, the mere act of mobilizing savings, or financial intermediation, does not constitute "banking" as has been widely alleged in the debate on the bill. If it did, NBFCs approved to collect deposits would not remain non-banks, and every cooperative credit society would be a bank. An essential element of banking, in the wider sense understood by economists, is money and credit creation through the money and credit multipliers of fractional reserve banking, which connects banks to the wider financial system in a systemic way. This is not the case with small stand-alone financial institutions such as cooperatives and MFIs. Even more important, they do not participate in the payments system by issuing cheques. 165
  • 168. Box 9.3 Grameen II and flexible, voluntary savings "Under Grameen II, each member opens a personal savings account, into which she may pay whatever she likes, subject to a weekly minimum that depends on the value of her loans from the bank, and withdraw whatever she likes whenever she likes, for any purpose, subject to being up-to-date in her loan repayments. Deposits are made at the weekly 'centre' meeting, but withdrawals are made at branch offices (normally within a half-hour's rickshaw trip or so). When she takes a loan, 2.5% of its value is deposited to this account (but may be withdrawn). Deposits earn interest at 8.5% pa: a higher rate than passbook savings in commercial banks… …Withdrawal symptoms: At first, many staff feared open withdrawals: they sincerely believed that members would quickly drain their accounts, leaving them with no reserves to fall back on, and Grameen with no implicit cash collateral for the loans. Then during 2003 some managers began to allow withdrawals for 'approved' uses, such as health emergences and marriage ceremonies, while denying them for making loan repayment installments. Finally in 2004 the product began to be administered as designed: HQ issued passbooks with the message that 'you may withdraw cash from your personal savings at any time' printed on every page. Staff learned that open withdrawal wasn't the disaster they had feared. Members, finding withdrawals easier, began to use their accounts for the (often short-term) storage of larger sums, in addition to their small regular weekly deposits. The chart shows the growing number of withdrawals in our sample branches.51 Balances: Average balances per member in personal savings accounts did not change much during this period (Note Q3 2002 to Q3 2004): in two of our branches it grew but fell in the third, and ranged between 500 and 800 taka ($8-13).Membership grew rapidly, pushing down average balances as new accounts opened, so it is clear that members did not choose to exhaust their accounts as withdrawals became freely available. Uses: Mrs NB, a member in sample branch S, is one of the Grameen clients whose financial behaviour we are tracking. In 2004 her personal savings account transactions amounted to $64 in 48 (mainly weekly) deposits and $60 in 5 withdrawals, leaving her with a year-end balance of just $9. She used the withdrawals for household consumption and health care, to lend to others, and to make repayment installments to Grameen and other MFIs. The personal savings account, for her, is becoming a convenient current account. Large flows of cash in and out of such accounts, resulting in small balances, is both common and rational among the poor, whose small and fragile incomes require them to resort to saving and borrowing to finance even small items of expenditure such as a visit to the doctor or the purchase of a new sari. This useful service did not exist in Grameen before Grameen II: but is now one of the bank's most popular products. Extracted from Member Savings by Stuart Rutherford, MicroSave Briefing Notes on Grameen II #2 166
  • 169. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? Box 9.4 Sa-Dhan's Voluntary Mutual Code of Conduct "To ensure that all our activities and dealings with clients are in compliance with the above core values, we all agree to adopt the code of conduct as elaborated hereunder…: 2.1 We all agree to- i) Promote and strengthen the microfinance movement in the country by bringing the low-income clients to the mainstream financial sector. ii) Build progressive, sustainable and client-centric microfinance institutions in the country to provide integrated financial services to our clients. iii) Promote cooperation and coordination among microfinance institutions and other agencies to achieve higher operating standards and avoid unethical competition in order to serve our clients better. 2.2 In order to achieve the aforesaid, we all agree to follow the following practices mentioned below: 2.2.1Integrity We agree to- i) Act honestly, fairly and reasonably in conducting microfinance activities. ii) Conduct our microfinance activities by means of fair competition, not seeking competitive advantages through illegal or unethical microfinance practices. No officer, employee, agent or other person acting on our behalf shall take unfair advantage of anyone by manipulation, concealment, abuse of privileged information, misrepresentation of material facts or any other unfair practice. iii) Prominently display the core values and code of conduct on the notice board of head office and all branches, and put systems in place to ensure compliance. iv) Ensure that our staff and any person acting for us or on our behalf, are trained or oriented to put these values into practice. 2.2.2 Transparency We agree to- i) Disclose to clients all the terms and conditions of our financial services offered in the language understood by the client. ii) Disclose the source of funds, costs of funds and use of surpluses to provide truthful information to clients. iii) Provide information to clients on the rate of interest levied on the loan, calculation of interest (monthly/quarterly/half-yearly), terms of repayment, and any other information related to interest rates and other charges iv) Provide information to clients on the rate of interest offered on the thrift services provided by us. v) Provide information to clients related to the premium and other fees being charged on insurance and pension services offered by us as intermediaries. vi) Provide periodical statements of our accounts to the clients. 167
  • 170. 2.2.3 Fair practices We are committed to follow fair practices built on dignity, respect, fair treatment, persuasion and courtesy to clients. We agree to- i) Provide microfinance services to low income clients irrespective of gender, race, caste, religion or language. ii) Ensure that the services are provided using the most efficient methods possible to enable access to financial services by low income households at reasonable cost. iii) Recognize our responsibility to provide financial services to clients based upon their needs and repayment capacity. iv) Promise that, in case of loans to individual clients below Rs 25,000, the clients shall not be asked to hand over original land titles, house pattas, ration cards, etc as collateral security for loans except when obtaining copies of these for fulfilling "know your customers" norms of the RBI. Only in case of loan to individual clients of Rs 25,000/- and above can land titles, house pattas, vehicle RC books, etc. be taken as collateral security. v) Interact with the clients in an acceptable language and dignified manner and spare no efforts in fostering clients' confidence and long-term relationship. vi) Maintain decency and decorum during the visit to the clients' place for collection of dues. vii) Avoid inappropriate occasions such as bereavement in the family or such other calamitous occasions for making calls/visits to collect dues". Excerpted from the Statement of Core Values and a Voluntary Mutual Code of Conduct" released at Sa-Dhan's annual conference in January 2007 Box 9.5 A bit of history: Self-regulation backed by legal sanctions In 1998, a task force was set up by the RBI under the chairmanship of NABARD, which proposed that all MFIs (including credit-only MFIs) register themselves with an Self Regulatory Organizations (SRO) (with recognition of the SROs to be conferred by the central bank). However MFIs were defined to include only entities with a recognized legal identity, so that CBOs not registered as societies or trusts would continue to operate informally and remain outside the purview of reporting and prudential controls below a certain size. The registration with the SRO would be provisional for the first three years, during which time the MFI would either attain the standards specified by the SRO, or have its registration cancelled. Societies and trusts would have to transform themselves into cooperatives or companies once the sum of their deposits and loans exceeded a certain level, tentatively proposed at Rs 25 lakhs. Prudential norms for all MFIs irrespective of size or form of organization were proposed as follows (i) a reserve requirement of at least 10 percent of deposits, to be deposited in a bank (ii) a provision equivalent to the entire principal outstanding and interest thereon for loans which were past due by 90 days at the end of the financial year (iii) interest recognition on an accrual basis to stop at that time, and (iii) limits on loan sizes to any one individual, group, or other MFI. 168
  • 171. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? It was further envisaged that for a large country like India there could be different SROs recognized by the central bank for different states, given the fact that there was as yet no single apex body of MFIs for the country as a whole. State level Recognized SROs (RSROs) would also be able to take advantage of local knowledge, and of proximity for purposes of on-site visits and inspections. An RSROs would have to establish mandatory standards for its MFI members, which would have to be approved by the central bank. The RSRO would require periodic returns from its members, and would submit periodic summary returns to the central bank. The RSRO would suspend the registration of an MFI which failed to submit returns or comply with prudential norms, and bar it from carrying on further business. The central bank would have the right to derecognize an RSRO if more than say one-fifth of its members were reported to be in non-compliance of standards. Clearly a great deal of further consensus building and preparatory work remained to be done and the RBI never took a view on the task force recommendations. Given the uneven spread of MFIs in India it might have been possible to start with one or more regions which had a relatively high concentration of MFIs and a few that were role models, and then proceed incrementally, developing and revising performance standards and prudential norms on the basis of experience, identifying potential SRO members in other regions, and training them and MFIs generally. Thus the proposed regulatory framework recognized the advantages to MFIs of starting up as societies and trusts, given the relative ease of registration under these forms of organization, but required them to transform into cooperatives or non-profit companies or non-bank financial companies above a certain level of total business. This was also the approach taken in the initial bill prepared by Sa-Dhan with the difference that it gave NGO-MFIs the special-window option of registering as an "MFI" which would be a company with an entry capital of Rs 25 operating in conformity with requirements custom-made to microfinance. Unfortunately this concept was dropped. 169
  • 172. Endnotes 1 For a detailed discussion of the "twists and turns" taken by the bill up to January 2007 see Sinha 2007a. This is a good source on recent regulatory concerns generally. Other sources for background on regulatory issues in Indian microfinance are Radcliffe and Tripathi 2006 and Eschborn 2004. Small parts of this chapter are taken from two articles by the author, Ghate 2007a and Ghate 2007b. 2 Another reason for doing so is that the State of the Sector report is intended to serve as a sort of "moving" reference document for posterity, through a series of annual snapshots. It is recognized though that this chapter may well be out of date soon after it appears. Apart from being amended the bill could expire unless reintroduced. 3 Bill No.41 of 2007 4 The title of the bill has therefore become a misnomer - it does not apply to the bulk of the sector. 5 Thrift is defined as "any money collected (other than in the form of current account or demand deposit) by a micro finance organization from a group" and a "group" is defined to mean "any association of eligible clients formed either as self-help groups or joint liability groups or a group called by any other name for the purpose of providing thrift and micro finance services to individual members of such association" (italics added). 6 The Ministry of Finance did not make copies of the bill available to sector participants other than to Sa-Dhan, and Sa-Dhan felt constrained not to share the bill with non members (members are almost entirely MFIs and a few service providers, which leaves out a large number of sector participants affected by the bill such as cooperatives, banks, equity investors, rating agencies, consultants, researchers, microfinance policy analyst, etc). A MoF spokesman said at the annual Sa-Dhan conference in January 2007 that the bill had not been put onto the ministry's web-site in order to save time. During the whole process of discussion of the bill several versions of the bill were floating around simultaneously, making for much confusion. It was only when the bill reached parliament that copies of it became available. The Standing Committee on Finance has initiated a process of widespread consultation on the bill by inviting a cross section of sector participants and interested observers to send in their views and appear before it if required. Civil society organizations have been urging persons to send in their views to the committee. 7 These are defined as credit, insurance, pension, and any other services that may be specified by the regulator. This leaves open the possibility of adding money transfer services. It is surprising that savings services are not mentioned, not even as "thrift". 8 These are to be two officers nominated by the ministries of finance and rural development, two representing NABARD and one each nominated by the RBI, SIDBI and the National Housing Bank. 9 The Indian microfinance sector has seen a steady migration of NGO-MFIs in the last few years from the society and trust form of registration to the company form of incorporation, most of them becoming NBFCs, but many of them preferring to retain their not-for-profit status as S 25 companies. The 170
  • 173. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? transformation is taking place worldwide, for several reasons. First, companies have to meet more stringent disclosure, transparency and audit requirements, more suited to financial operations, than those laid down for registered societies and trusts, which were designed for charitable, welfare or educational activities. Second, by providing for capital or equity in the form of shares, companies encourage a stronger sense of ownership on the part of promoters, leading usually to stronger governance and management. An NGO has no "owner" of the net owned funds built up out of grants and operational surpluses. This combination of advantages gives banks and financial institutions lending to MFIs the essential comfort without which the sector will never attract the funds to expand fast enough to make a rapid dent on poverty and challenge of financial inclusion. The steady stream of transformations has been assisted by the advent of private investors, both social and commercial, who are willing to provide transforming as well as start-up MFIs not just the Rs 2 crores required as entry level capital, but the much greater investments required to give them the capital adequacy to support the more than Rs 3000 crores of borrowing by MFIs that took place last year (see last year's report), and the projected rapid growth in the near future. 10 These figures are derived from Sa-Dhan's Quick Report 2007 (Sa-Dhan 2007) and represent the share of 17 NBFCs and 13 S 25 companies out of a total 129 MFIs in the survey. 11 While a similar study does not exist for India, evidence exists for Uganda that of the formal, semi- formal (MFI) and informal sectors in Uganda, the last was the riskiest for savers (Wright and Mutesasira). 12 Nearly all large Indian MFIs have been rated not just once but several times in order to qualify for loans from SIDBI, which makes a satisfactory rating a condition for its lending, as do increasingly many of the banks. 13 According to World Bank 2007 "there is an increasing sense worldwide that NGOs mobilizing deposits from members need not be regulated like banks …" 14 See "City Savers" by Rutherford and Arora (1997) Savings safe-keepers are referred to as "moneyguards" in Africa. In India door step cumulative savings collectors have given rise to huge organizations like Peerless and Sahara. 15 See Ghate 1992 for a comprehensive review of different types of informal finance in India and 5 other Asian countries, Das-Gupta et al 1989 on urban informal finance in India, Bouman 1998 on the bishis of Maharasthra, and Rutherford and Arora 1997 on urban informal savings mechanisms in India. 16 Restrictions proposed in the initial version of the bill on maximum savings per member and the aggregate savings liability outstanding of the MFI as a ratio of net owned funds and total assets, and a liquidity reserve requirement, have been dropped, presumably because they are hard to monitor. The liquidity reserve would have been desirable since liquidity is a particularly highly valued attribute of savings among the poor, as discussed below. 17 For most MFIs, a small proportion of borrowers will be between loan cycles, and some others as they approach the end of the repayment cycle will temporarily have more savings to their credit than loans. A ceiling could be fixed for the proportion of net savers. Compliance could be monitored through periodic returns and occasional on-site checks where necessary. There are some MFIs in other countries, those offering "open access" savings (see below) such as BURO Tangail in Bangladesh, whose savings products are so popular that they have a fairly high proportion of net savers and indeed of pure savers at any one time. However these will be special cases for the foreseeable future, especially in India 171
  • 174. which is a late starter in offering savings services, and they can always be dealt with through special exemptions after due diligence on a case by case basis. 18 Liquidity is an important attribute of savings for the reasons discussed below. The bill proposes that 15 percent of profits be transferred to a reserve fund, but this is not quite the same thing as a reserve fund created out of savings, since profits and surpluses may not accrue for several years initially. Transfers to the fund should come from savings, not profits. 19 These were some of the findings of EDA 2005, the first and most comprehensive impact evaluation so far of SIDBI's MFI partners (who conduct lending through SHGs as well as JLGs). The second evaluation of the SIDBI project which was undertaken by the Agriculture Finance Corporation, has yet to be released by SIDBI although it was completed in August 2006. 20 Although initially there is a massive out-rush as clients "test" the system to see if they really will be permitted to withdraw their savings! 21 Nearly all Bangladeshi MFIs offer a variety of savings opportunities to their borrowers apart from compulsory savings, as "special savings", contractual savings, time deposits and daily savings. 22 These systems include (i) strong governance and management, (ii) high portfolio quality, (iii) liquidity management (asset and liability management) skills, (iv) good information systems, and (v) strong internal controls. 23 Some of them have already done so. Although the largest MFIs are mostly companies, some of the largest are still societies and trusts and intend to stay that way, especially as the bill will deny them the opportunity to mobilize thrift if they transform. Also, there is a possibility that the bill may be amended to include NBFCs and S 25 companies, who do have such capacities. The attainment of profitability is a requirement that it often also suggested as a requirement for being allowed to mobilize voluntary savings. 24 While there is agreement that federations should not usurp the function of the groups to make loans to their individual members, and should only make loans to their groups, some groups themselves want their federations to lend to individual members, usually by accessing loans from the banks, who feel more comfortable tracking loans in the name of individuals rather than groups (See Chapter 3). 25 This had been taken to mean that it will not apply to PACS, although a large part of PACS lending is for non-crop rural activities, or in other words constitutes microcredit in the usual sense of credit for non-crop activities. Both cooperative banks (district and state level) as well as PACS are part of the ongoing cooperative reform project - see footnote 27). 26 Speech by Thomas Carter of CLUSA at a conference of railway employees' thrift societies in Hyderabad on 6-7 February, 1986, who pointed out that it was from a trip to Bengal in the early 1900s that Edward Filene, the pioneer leader of thrift cooperatives in the US, drew his inspiration. (Circulated by CDF). 27 Carter in his speech in 1986 (see previous footnote) said "I believe there are more than 23,000 thrift cooperatives in the country with close to 150 lakh members and savings of more than Rs 1,250 crores" 28 The package is being supported by the World Bank's $600 million "Strengthening Rural Cooperatives" project and an ADB loan. According to a World Bank press note dated on the project "Twelve Indian 172
  • 175. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? states have signed up to the reform program. Potentially viable CCBs" (defined to include PACS, DCCBs and SCBs) " in those states will commit to a set of far-reaching legal, regulatory, governance and institutional reforms which will open the way to financial and operational restructuring. In the process the CCBs will be recapitalized with grants to wipe out the accumulated losses, the value of members' capital will be restored, and a minimum capital to risk weighted assets ratio (CRAR) of 7 percent will be achieved. The project will also provide technical assistance throughout the process to strengthen CCB governance, managerial and operational performance, and support computerization for enhanced efficiency and transparency. CCB members, particularly small and marginal farmers, will receive training in areas such as financial literacy, and a strong project focus on monitoring and evaluation systems will include monitoring by CCB members themselves. 29 See note by Shashi Rajagopalan, "The Bill Relating to Micro-Finance Organizations", circulated by CDF. As she points out the amount of thrift is agreed to by all members, is usually the same for all members in absolute terms, or, in the case employees savings and credit cooperatives, a fixed percentage of their pay. 30 Or "self reliant" or "self help" or "self supporting" or "autonomous" or "fraternal". 31 The MACS registrar has fewer powers than the registrar under the existing act in keeping with the lack of dependence of MACS on government. Indeed, MACS can not accept government equity. 32 According to a personal communication from Shri Rama Reddy, President, CDF "The Registrar under the Macs Act is entitled to receive annual financial statements from every macs cooperative within 30 days from the holding of the annual general meeting; is empowered to get a special audit conducted at the cost of the macs cooperative; is empowered to conduct an enquiry into specific affairs of a macs cooperative; is empowered to convene a special general body meeting to explain to the members how their cooperative is being mismanaged; is empowered to request the Cooperative Tribunal to order the liquidation of a macs cooperative if that macs cooperative is not being run in accordance with the concept of cooperation and the provisions of the Macs Act". 33 Or "nominal members", "associate members", "B class members" etc. 34 According to Rama Reddy "Neither the SHG Federation, nor the promoting GO, nor the promoting NGO, nor the registering DCO is interested in the functioning of the village organisation as a Macs cooperative. They do not need any supervision and/or regulation since they themselves are part and parcel of the governmental organisations or of the non-governmental organisations. On the one hand, as a policy, the State Government is interested in getting village organisations registered as macs cooperatives and on the other hand, again as a matter of policy, the same government puts a ban on the registration of citizen-promoted genuine thrift cooperatives and dairy cooperatives under the Macs Act" (Personal communication). 35 Of the 129 MFIs covered by Sa-Dhan's Quick Report, 21 were MACS with 1.6 percent of the total number of borrowers, and 4 of them cooperatives with 3.9 percent. However as noted above there are thousands of thrift cooperatives in the country. 36 At least one state, AP, as noted above, is said to be opposed to it. 37 CGAP 2003 suggests a fourth alternative. It recommends that "financial cooperatives - at least large ones - should be prudentially supervised by a specialized financial authority, rather than by an agency that is responsible for all cooperatives". 173
  • 176. 38 There is no firm estimate even of the population of MFOs in the country. 39 According to one observer, "it is next to impossible to have a data base at state level itself, leave alone the national level. The long and tortuous experience of the RBI, up to 1982, and of NABARD since 1982, in collecting, collating and publishing basic data relating to three-tier rural cooperative thrift and credit system (approximately 90,000 PACS, 375 DCCBs and 30 SCBs) should tell us that we are on very slippery ground as far as a data base is concerned. From 1966 to 1982, the RBI supervised and regulated DCCBs and SCBs and, since 1982, they are being supervised by the NABARD and regulated by the RBI"…"The RBI and NABARD published data over a long period… Most of it is guesstimates manufactured manually till computers arrived. After the arrival of computers, the projections based on already manufactured data are presented as hard, primary data." (Rama Reddy, comments on this chapter). However Misra 2007 observes that the MACS she studied do file audited annual returns to the registrar. She does not say whether they are scutinized. 40 According to a report in the Hindu dated 3 July Nabfins would provide micro credit at "reasonable" rates with an authorised capital of Rs 100 crores. It would have an issue capital of Rs 20 crores and of which 51% would be subscribed to by Nabard and the rest by several banks and state governments. The MFI would start functioning in the two months by taking up a pilot project in Karnataka. In the second phase, it would be extended to Andhra Pradesh and Tamil Nadu and gradually other states. The Chairman of Nabard is reported to have pointed out that the the major defects of MFIs are lack of transparency in account disclosures, high transaction costs, high rates of interest and coercive collection practices. "We want to show that an MFI can function without any defects and deliver micro credit at affordable interest rates and without coercive collection practices. The interest rates would be affordable, as the idea was to reduce transaction costs", he added. 41 See for instance Sanjay Sinha, 2007b. Sinha suggests that the RBI's refusal to engage with microfinance is influenced by the recent failures of urban cooperative banks for which the RBI was blamed. He points out that its fear is unfounded for the reasons discussed earlier and also because it sends out the message that the "the lowly world of the poor does not need its attention". 42 "Banking" is defined in the Banking Regulation Act, 1949, as "the accepting, for the purpose of lending or investment, of deposits of money from the public, repayable on demand or otherwise, and withdrawable by cheque, draft, order, or otherwise". 43 The RBI has often been urged, further, to reduce the entry capital requirement from Rs 2 crores at present to perhaps Rs 50 lakhs to speed up the process of transformation of NGO-MFIs to incorporation as NBFCs. The initial version of the bill, as we have seen, envisaged entry capital for the new-window "MFIs" it envisaged, as 25 lakhs, but that was two years ago, and most MFIs should not find it difficult to raise Rs 50 lakhs. However, the RBI takes the view that S 45-I A of the RBI Act 1934 does not give it the latitude to distinguish between the various categories of NBFC in this respect. It points out that it sought such powers through a draft Financial Companies Regulation Bill submitted to the previous parliament, but the bill could not be enacted before the NDA government fell. The RBI could also lay down higher provisioning requirements for Microfinance-NBFCs. 44 The cap only applies to the commercial banks, and not to the RRBs or DCCBs, and only to priority sector loans, and not to personal loans. However, meeting priority sector targets is an important motivation for the commercial banks who accounted for 28 percent of all loans below Rs 25,000, with the RRBs accounting for another 9 percent, in March 2006 (Speech by Deputy Governor, RBI at Sa-Dhan Annual 174
  • 177. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? Meeting, Chennai, August 10, 2007, Usha Thorat 2007). Were the restriction removed, the number of commercial bank micro loans is likely to increase dramatically. See Sinha 2007a and 2007b. The RBI has taken a step to remove the cap recently by allowing the banks to issue General Purpose Credit Cards (GCCs) with limits up to Rs 25,000 and allowing 50 percent of the amounts utilized to be included in the priority sector. It is not known whether the scheme has taken off. , it is limposed 45 This recommendation in this section is based on the assumption that there will be no major amendments to the bill. It there are, the conclusion would have to be reviewed. 46 The RBI did come out in May 2006 after the Krishna district episode with guidelines for NBFCs to abide by a "fair practices" code, but it does not have a field presence in the districts in the way the ombudsman could. 47 Also known as the SC Gupta committee report on the proposal for the states to register moneylenders as accredited loan providers out of funds borrowed form the banks. 48 Non-profit S 25 company status requires no entry capital, and has provision for equity, but its prohibition of dividends makes it unattractive to investors and therefore lenders. 49 It is understood that that in its interim suggestions the Committee for Financial Inclusion (headed by former RBI governor, C Rangarajan) has proposed amendments to S 11(4) of the Income Tax Act so as to allow NGOs to invest in microfinance companies without prejudicing their tax status, S 2(15) specifying microfinance as a charitable activity, and some others relating to tax concessions to NBFCs. 50 It was only at this stage that copies of the bill became freely available to the wider microfinance community, as the Standing Committee on Finance began inviting the views and suggestions of experts and persons and groups who wanted to be heard…. 51 Note: chart not included. 175
  • 178. References APMAS, 2005, "A Report on Spandana's Microfinance Activity", Mimeo, APMAS, Hyderabad. APMAS, 2006, "Voice of the People on the Lending Practices of Microfinance Institutions in Krishna District of Andhra Pradesh", Mimeo, APMAS, Hyderabad. Bouman, FJA, 1989, "Small, Short, and Unsecured: Informal Rural Finance in India, Oxford University Presss, New Delhi CGAP, 2003, "Microfinance Consensus Guidelines: Guiding Principles on Regulation and Supervision of Microfinance", Washington, DC CGAP, 2004, "Interest Rate Ceilings and Microfinance: The Story So Far", Occasional Paper, Washington DC. CGAP, 2005a, "Microfinance Consensus Guidelines: Developing Deposit Services for the Poor", Washington, DC CGAP 2005b, "Protecting Microfinance Borrowers", Focus Note No.27, Washington, DC Das-Gupta, Arindam, CPS Nayar, and Associates, 1989, "Urban Informal Credit Markets in India, Study prepared for ADB by NIPFP, New Delhi EDA Rural Systems, 2005, "The Maturing of Indian Microfinance: Findings of a microfinance assessment study (baseline) - implications for policy and practice, study done for SIDBI, Gurgaon. EDA Rural Systems and APMAS, 2006, "Self Help Groups in India: The Lights and Shades", for CRS, USAID, CARE and GTZ/NABARD, Microfinance India, New Delhi Eschborn 2004, "Emerging Scenarios for Microfinance Regulation in India: Some Observations from the Field", GTZ, Federal Ministry for International Cooperation, Germany Ghate, Prabhu, 1992, "Informal Finance: Some Findings from Asia", OUP Hong Kong, for ADB, Manila Ghate, Prabhu 2006, "Microfinance in India: A State of the Sector Report, 2006", Microfinance India, New Delhi, and "Indian Microfinance:The Challenges of Rapid Growth, Sage, New Delhi Ghate, Prabhu, 2007a, "Consumer Protection in Indian Microfinance: Lessons from Andhra Pradesh and the Microfinance Bill", Economic and Political Weekly, March 31, Mumbai. Ghate, Prabhu, 2007b, "Financial inclusion via exclusion?" Economic Times, July 19, New Delhi Misra, Rewa, 2007, "Case of SHGs and MACS - Does Federating Enable Remote Outreach?", 176
  • 179. CHAPTER 9 Regulation: The Microfinance Bill: An Opportunity Being Lost? paper for the Comparative Study of Member-Owned Institutions Offering Financial Services in Remote Rural Areas, Coady International Institute/Ford Foundation, Antigonish. PRS Legislative Reseach, 2007, "Legislative Brief: The Micro Financial Sector (Development and Regulation) Bill, 2007, Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi Radcliffe, Daniel, and Rati Tripathi, 2006,"Sharpening the Debate: Accessing the Key Constraints in Indian Micro Credit Regulation", Centre for Micro Finance, Chennai Rutherford, Stuart and Sukhwinder Singh Arora, 1997, "City Savers: How the poor, the DFID and its partners are promoting financial services in urban India", discussion paper prepared for Urban Poverty Office, DFID, New Delhi Rutherford, Stuart, 2005, "Why Do the Poor Need Savings Services? : What They Get and What They Might Like", in Madeline Hirschland, editor, Savings Services for the Poor", Kumarian Press, Bloomfield Rutherford, Stuart, "Member Savings", MicroSave Briefing Notes on Grameen II # 2, MicroSave, Kenya, Uganda and India Sa-Dhan, 2007, "Quick Report, 2007: A Snapshot of MFIs in India, New Delhi Sinha, Sanjay, 2007a, "Microfinance Regulation for Financial Inclusion: The Street Child Needs Nurturing", essays on Regulaton and Supervison No.22, CGAP and IRIS Center, Washington, DC, carried on www.cgap.org/regulation Sinha, Sanjay, 2007b, "The financial exclusion bill", Economic Times, June 1, New Delhi Sriram, MS, 2005, "Expanding Financial Services Access for the Poor: The Transformation of Spandana", WP No 2005-04-03, IIMA, Ahmedabad. Thorat, Usha, 2007, "Microfinance and financial inclusion", speech at Sa-Dhan function to release "Quick Report, 2007", Chennai Thorat, YSP and Wright, Graham, 2006 "Cooperatives - The Flawed Gem of Indian Rural Finance", MicroSave Briefing Note No. 56, MicroSave, Kenya, Uganda and India Thorat World Bank, 2007, "Microfinance in South Asia: Toward Financial Inclusion for the Poor", Washington DC Wright, Graham, 2000, "Microfinance Systems: Designing Quality Financial Services for the Poor", University Press, Dhaka Wright, Graham, and Leonard Mutesasira, "The Relative Risks to the Savings of Poor People", MicroSave Briefing Note No. 6, MicroSave, Kenya, Uganda and India 177
  • 180. 178
  • 181. APPENDIX TABLE Table A.1 Fact sheet on coverage and growth of Indian microfinance, 2006-07 1 Total number of SHG members 26.3 million1 2 Total number of MFI borrowers 10.5 million2 3 Total number of microfinance borrowers 36.8 million 4 Total number of poor SHG members 13. 4 million3 5 Total number of poor MFI borrowers 3.2 million4 6 Total number of poor microfinance borrowers 16.4 million 7 Growth of outreach of the SHG programme in 2006-07 31 percent 8 Growth of loans outstanding under the SHG programme in 2006-07 48 percent 9 Growth of outreach of MFIs in 2006-07 42 percent5 10 Growth of loans outstanding of MFIs in 2006-07 76 percent6 11 Average loans outstanding, SHG members Rs 40007 12 Average loans outstanding, MFI borrowers Rs 34008 1 2.94 SHGs ever linked (Table 2.1) out of which 71 percent estimated to be currently linked (Chapter 2) times an average of 14 members each, minus 10 percent estimated to have dropped out. 2 Sa-Dhan estimate of 10.49 million members served by 184 Sa-Dhan member MFIs (Sa-Dhan's Quick Report 2007). It is assumed that an estimated 10 percent of MFI members belong to MFIs that are not Sa-Dhan members which offsets an assumed 10 percent of membership that is inactive, i.e not currently borrowing. 3 26.3 times 0.51, the proportion of SHG members found to be poor by EDA and APMAS 2006 (reference in Chapter 1) 4 Thirty percent is the proportion of poor borrowers found by the second (or endline) evaluation of the longitudinal study of SIDBI partnered MFIs by the Agricultural Finance Corporation, as well as the finding from the social performance assessment of 12 MFIs reported in Chapter 6. 5 This is the growth of outreach of 184 Sa-Dhan members as reported in Sa-Dhan 2007. The growth of outreach of the subset of 129 MFIs who responded to the survey reported in Sa-Dhan 2007 was 60 percent. 6 The total outstanding of the 129 MFIs referred to in the previous footnote, of Rs 3064 crores (Table A.2) represented an increase of 76 percent over the reported outstanding of Rs 1743 crores in the previous year (Sa-Dhan 2007). 7 Cumulative loans disbursed under the programme times 0.59 (ratio from Chapter 2) yields an estimate of loans outstanding in March 2007. This divided by 26.3 million (row 1) yields an estimate of about Rs 4000. 8 Chapter 4. 179
  • 182. Table A.2 Imnformation on 129 MFIs covered in Sa-Dhan's Quick Report 2007 Sr No Name of MFI Location Outreach Gross loan portfolio (GLP) (Rs lakh)2 1 Share Microfin Ltd Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh 1,083,035 39,965 2 Spandana Sphoorthy Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh 916,261 39,160 Innovative Financial Services Limited (SPANDANA) 3 SKS Microfinance Pvt Ltd Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh 603,033 27,546 4 KAS Foundation Bhubaneswar,Orissa 588,960 12,098 5 Shree Kshetra Dharmasthala Dharmasthala,Karnataka 463,765 22,760 Rural Development Projects (SKDRDP) 6 Bandhan Konnagar Kolkata,West Bengal 433,324 12,613 7 Bharat Integrated Social Sambalpur,Orissa 364,325 9,422 Welfare Agency (BISWA) 8 Shri Mahila Sewa Sahakari Ahmedabad,Gujrat 304,933 3,030 Bank Ltd (SEWA Bank) 9 BWDA Finance Ltd Villupuram,Tamil Nadu 236,388 7,209 10 Mahasemam Madurai,Tamil Nadu 221,613 7,696 11 Semam Microfiinance Chennai,Tamil Nadu 221,613 5,877 Investment Literacy and Education Ltd 12 CASHPOR Micro Credit Varanasi,Uttar Pradesh 201,692 2,601 13 BASIX Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh 198,282 13,970 14 Activists for Social Trichy,Tamil Nadu 196,224 8,025 Alternatives (ASA) 15 Evangelical Social Action Thrissur,Kerala 178,143 5,625 Forum (ESAF) 16 Sarvodaya Nano Finance Ltd Chennai,Tamil Nadu 126,211 6,425 (SNFL) 17 Kotalipara Development Kolkata,West Bengal 115,035 2,410 Society (KDS) 18 GR Koota Bangalore,Karnataka 109,251 4,598 19 Acts Mahila Mutually Aided Chitoor,Andhra Pradesh 82,904 4,572 Cooperative Thrift Society (AMMACTS) 20 Sharadas Women's Secunderabad,Andhra 79,626 3,827 Association for Weaker Pradesh Section (SWAWS) 21 Bharatha Swamukti Samsthe Bangalore,Karnataka 69,753 3,887 (BSS) 22 Sreema Mahila Samity Nadiya,West Bengal 62,024 1,635 23 Krishna Bhima Samruddhi Mahaboobnagar,Andhra 61,078 3,021 Local Area Bank Ltd (KBSLAB) Pradesh 24 Saadhana Microfin Society Kurnool,Tamil Nadu 60,440 3,007 25 Indian Association for Coimbatore,Tamil Nadu 55,539 1,740 Savings and Credit (IASC) 26 Krushi KarimNagar,Andhra Pradesh 50,241 3,054 27 SE Investments Ltd (SEIL) Agra,Uttar Pradesh 45,924 12,722 28 Rashtriya Seva Samiti (RASS) Tirupati,Tamil Nadu 45,682 1,388 29 Adhikar Bhubaneswar,Orissa 43,335 1,209 30 Rashtriya Gramin Vikas Nidhi Guahati,Assam 42,507 1,322 (RGVN) 31 Pragathi Seva Samiti (PSS) Warangal,Andhra Pradesh 38,812 1,892 32 Village Welfare Society (VWS) Kolkata,West Bengal 35,394 1,525 180
  • 183. APPENDIX TABLE Legal form Delivery Borrowings Net owned Interest Operating cost Category Category model3 (Rs lakh) funds (Rs) rate (%)4 ratio5 (%) (outreach) (GLP) NBFC GR, IL 36,985 3,735 22.0 10.8 Large Large NBFC GR 27,513 3,460 17.9 16.6 Large Large NBFC GR 25,797 7,131 26.1 27.1 Large Large Section 25 Company SHG, JLG 12,127 206 23.0 4.8 Large Large Trust SHG 25,087 778 21.1 2.3 Large Large Society IL 10,023 1,085 26.2 18.9 Large Large Society SHG 8,046 1,376 20.0 0.2 Large Large Cooperative IL 175 652 17.0 12.0 Large Large NBFC SHG, IL 6,966 513 15.5 0.1 Large Large Trust GR 12,630 8 10.0 23.3 Large Large NBFC GR 2,987 620 19.0 5.6 Large Large Section 25 Company GR, JLG 10 567 26.0 27.3 Large Large NBFC JLG 12,362 2,799 25.8 18.2 Large Large Trust GR 8,587 - 12.0 18.0 Large Large Society GR 4,446 126 15.0 13.0 Large Large NBFC SHG 4,634 1,370 12.0 12.0 Large Large Society IL 2,586 66 15.0 10.0 Large Large Trust GR 4,715 490 23.2 15.0 Large Large MACs GR 3,944 683 23.6 8.9 Large Large Society GR, JLG, IL 4,017 104 15.5 10.1 Large Large Trust GR 3,200 346 28.5 23.8 Large Large Society SHG 1,563 84 18.5 7.0 Large Medium Local Area Bank JLG, IL 4,228 589 19.0 18.0 Large Large Society IL 2,300 304 22.5 21.3 Large Large Section 25 Company SHG,IL 1,967 115 17.0 11.2 Large Medium Society SHG/ JLG 33 - 16.5 3.0 Large Large NBFC IL 13,540 2,769 27.0 7.0 Medium Large Society SHG 1,123 247 15.0 4.0 Medium Medium Society JLG & GR 1,425 43 25.8 5.3 Medium Medium Society SHG, JLG 1,420 33 15.0 9.4 Medium Medium Society SHG 1,615 346 14.0 2.9 Medium Medium Society JLG,IL 1,425 271 22.2 18.6 Medium Medium 181
  • 184. Sr No Name of MFI Location Outreach Gross loan portfolio (GLP) (Rs lakh)2 33 Thirumalai Charity Trust (TCT) Ranipet,Tamil Nadu 35,011 418 34 Karimangalam Ontriya Pengal Bangalore,Karnataka 32,247 1,003 Semipu Amaipu (SEARCH KOPSA) 35 Prochesta Guwahati,Assam 31,927 44 36 Star Microfinance services Kurnool,Andhra Pradesh 31,389 1,264 Society 37 Mari- Sangatitha Mahila Warangal,Andhra Pradesh 30,084 226 Mutually Aided Cooperative Societies Federation Ltd 38 Nav Bharat Jagriti Kendra Hajaribagh, Jharkhand 28,446 436 (NBJK) 39 Village Micro Credit Services Kolkata,West Bengal 27,579 1,136 (VMCS) 40 Liberal Association For Kolkata,West Bengal 27,332 210 Movement of People (LAMP) 41 Shalom Charitable Trust Palakkad,Kerala 26,170 852 42 Nanayasurabhi Development Trichy,Tamil Nadu 26,046 464 Financial Services (NDFS0 43 Samuha Bangalore,Karnataka 22,980 344 44 Welfare Services Ernakulam Kochi,Kerala 22,645 33 45 Janodaya Public Trust (JPT) Bangalore,Karnataka 22,500 817 46 Ujjivan Financial Services Pvt Bangalore,Karnataka 22,220 843 Ltd 47 Social Education and Warangal,Andhra Pradesh 21,752 308 Vountary Action (SEVA) 48 Kalighat Society For Kolkata,West Bengal 20,976 375 Development Facilitation (KSDF) 49 Agricultural Science Gadag,Karnataka 20,598 184 Foundation 50 Disha Social Organization Saharanpur,Uttar Pradesh 19,897 14 51 Village Financial Servies Pvt Kolkata,West Bengal 19,632 539 Ltd 52 Bandhan Financial Services Kolkata,West Bengal 19,314 459 Pvt Ltd 53 Shramik Bharati Kanpur,Uttar Pradesh 18,629 395 54 Cooperation Development Puri,Orissa 17,718 603 Council (CDC) 55 NIDAN Patna,Bihar 17,562 189 56 Watershed OrganiZation Ahmednagar,Maharashtra 17,086 363 Trust(WOTR) 57 Swayamshree Micro Credit Bhubaneswar,Orissa 15,868 645 Services (SMCS) 58 Community Development Theni,Tamil Nadu 15,680 675 Centre (CDC) 59 Sanghamitra Rural Financial Mysore,Karnataka 15,626 3,272 Services 60 Hope Foundation Palakkad,Kerala 15,366 103 61 South Indian Federation of Trivendram,Kerala 14,566 672 Fishermen Societies 62 Satin Credit Care Network Ltd Delhi,Delhi 14,372 2,646 182
  • 185. APPENDIX TABLE Legal form Delivery Borrowings Net owned Interest Operating cost Category Category model3 (Rs lakh) funds (Rs) rate (%)4 ratio5 (%) (outreach) (GLP) Society SHG 1,533 21 24.0 13.0 Medium Small Section 25 Company SHG 1,211 343 14.0 10.9 Medium Medium Society SHG 92 20 18.0 7.9 Medium Small Society GR 2,021 260 16.1 11.5 Medium Medium MACs SHG 302 74 18.0 23.0 Medium Small Society SHG, JLG 177 371 24.0 11.0 Medium Small Section 25 Company JLG,IL 1,400 10 22.2 1.0 Medium Medium Society SHG, JLG 76 117 24.8 9.8 Medium Small Trust SHG 931 - 27.0 16.0 Medium Medium Section 25 Company SHG 525 15 18.0 4.0 Medium Small Society SHG 421 7 10.5 6.4 Medium Small Society SHG 280 80 12.8 5.9 Medium Small Trust SHG,IL 809 34 27.0 15.3 Medium Medium NBFC GR 616 329 24.0 63.2 Medium Medium Trust SHG 939 106 21.0 6.0 Medium Small Society SHG, JLG 374 47 12.5 3.8 Medium Small Society SHG 186 20 22.8 4.7 Medium Small Society SHG 50 2 24.0 7.5 Medium Small NBFC JLG 431 112 23.0 15.5 Medium Medium NBFC IL 306 67 26.2 17.2 Medium Small Society SHG - 388 11.4 6.0 Medium Small Trust JLG, IL & GR 743 1 25.0 13.2 Medium Medium Society SHG 295 31 19.0 20.0 Medium Small Society SHG - 450 21.0 24.0 Medium Medium Section 25 Company SHG 570 29 16.0 5.2 Medium Medium Trust SHG 673 - 18.0 15.0 Medium Medium Section 25 Company SHG 2,708 561 14.0 4.0 Medium Large Trust SHG 128 15 20.9 21.0 Medium Small Society IL 225 245 12.0 12.6 Medium Medium NBFC IL 184 542 20.0 16.4 Medium Large 183
  • 186. Sr No Name of MFI Location Outreach Gross loan portfolio (GLP) (Rs lakh)2 63 Guide Krishna,Andhra Pradesh 12,504 333 64 Sonata Finance Pvt Ltd Puri,Orissa 11,393 498 65 Sahabhagi Vikash Abhyan Khurda,Orissa 11,176 127 66 The Payakaraopta Women's Vishakhapatnam,Andhra 10,650 643 Mutually Aided Cooperative Pradesh Thrift and Credit Society Ltd 67 Bhoruka Charitable Trust Churu,Rajasthan 10,252 43 68 Arohan Kolkata,West Bengal 10,110 299 69 Vedika Credit Capital Limited Ranchi,Jharkhand 9,421 997 70 Initiatives For Development Bangalore,Karnataka 9,064 181 Foundation (IDF) 71 Hindustan Cooperative Credit Mumbai,Maharashtra 8,061 1,918 Society Ltd 72 Ishara Foundation for New Delhi,New Delhi 7,251 58 Finance and Rural Development 73 Institute of Integrated Dekargaon,Assam 6,927 239 Resource Management (IIRM) 74 Support Hajaribag,Jharkhand 6,809 27 75 Navachetana Foundation Haveri,Karnataka 6,734 418 76 Raghunath Pathagar (RNP) Ganjam,Orissa 6,540 458 77 People's Action for Trichy,Tamil Nadu 6,521 277 Transformation 78 Bal- Mahila Vikas Samiti Madhya Pradesh 6,075 21 79 Darabar Sahitya Sansad (DSS) Khurda,Orissa 5,889 54 80 Ullon Social Welfare Society South 24 Pgs,West Bengal 4,967 108 81 Adarsa Sambalpur,Orissa 4,917 37 82 Sarala Women Welfare Society Howrah,West Bengal 4,826 166 83 Community Services Trust Salem,Tamil Nadu 4,386 446 (CST) 84 Pikepara Kamala Seva samity 24 Pgs,West Bengal 4,092 55 85 Social Welfare Agency and Kandhmal,Orissa 3,885 16 Training Institute (SWATI) 86 Arman Lease and Finance Ltd Ahmedabad,Gujrat 3,770 1,786 87 Guidance Society for Labour Vellore,Tamil Nadu 3,626 80 Orphans and Women (GLOW) 88 Rajapur Seva Niketan (RSN) Howrah,West Bengal 3,272 150 89 Youth Voulunteers Union Wangamataba,Manipur 3,114 380 90 Sakhi Samudaya Kosh Solapur,Maharashtra 3,072 140 91 Ajiwika Society Deoghar,Jharkhand 2,515 228 92 Mother Theresa Mahila MACCS Krishna,Andhra Pradesh 2,501 78 Ltd 93 Society for Model, Gram Bikas Kolkata,West Bengal 2,453 73 Kendra 94 Priyasakhi Mahila Sangh, Indore,Madhya Pradesh 2,350 53 Indore 95 People's Action for National Faizabad,Uttar Pradesh 2,324 148 Integration (PANI) 96 Jeevika Livelihoods Support Jabalpur,Madhya Pradesh 2,100 57 OrganisationMax Wealth Trust 184
  • 187. APPENDIX TABLE Legal form Delivery Borrowings Net owned Interest Operating cost Category Category model3 (Rs lakh) funds (Rs) rate (%)4 ratio5 (%) (outreach) (GLP) Society SHG 222 12 18.5 19.0 Medium Small NBFC GR 602 150 36.0 42.7 Medium Small Society SHG 89 38 24.0 3.5 Medium Small MACs JLG,IL 850 25 18.5 5.2 Medium Medium Trust SHG 105 15 22.8 20.0 Medium Small NBFC JLG 211 125 30.0 64.0 Medium Small NBFC JLG,IL 713 885 24.0 16.0 Small Medium Trust SHG 168 18 17.5 7.9 Small Small Cooperative JLG,IL 1,135 317 18.0 8.0 Small Medium Section 25 Company SHG 58 15 27.0 21.9 Small Small Society JLG 333 - 15.0 18.5 Small Small Society SHG, JLG 57 - 22.8 8.0 Small Small Society GR 430 - 27.9 6.8 Small Small Society SHG, JLG 445 13 10.8 5.0 Small Small Trust SHG 235 20 28.0 23.5 Small Small Cooperative SHG 20 1 34.2 38.1 Small Small Society SHG 98 2 19.0 10.8 Small Small Society SHG,IL - 199 24.0 7.8 Small Small Society SHG 76 - 24.0 19.2 Small Small Section 25 Company IL 150 19 33.0 8.7 Small Small Trust SHG 502 21 22.8 40.0 Small Small Society SHG 13 - 24.0 8.0 Small Small Society SHG, JLG, IL 3 - 18.0 5.0 Small Small NBFC IL 867 597 19.5 11.8 Small Medium Society JLG 100 19 22.8 16.5 Small Small Society SHG, JLG 184 28 15.2 4.6 Small Small Society SHG, JLG, IL 34 382 22.8 12.1 Small Small Section 25 Company SHG 125 63 20.0 42.2 Small Small Section 25 Company SHG, JLG 148 9 18.0 6.0 Small Small MACs SHG 19 60 7.1 12.0 Small Small Society GR 27 3 35.8 2.9 Small Small Society SHG 34 11 21.8 24.4 Small Small Society SHG 45 103 22.8 10.0 Small Small Society JLG, GR 56 11 38.0 45.0 Small Small 185
  • 188. Sr No Name of MFI Location Outreach Gross loan portfolio (GLP) (Rs lakh)2 97 Mahila Kalyan Samiti Dhori, Bokaro,Jharkhand 1,865 25 Bokaro 98 Manab Sewa Sangh (MSS) Guwahati,Assam 1,750 4 99 Hope Integrated Rural Kurnool,Andhra Pradesh 1,710 6 Development Society 100 Max Wealth Trust Hyaderabad,Andhra Pradesh 1,425 61 101 Social Action for Rural Sambalpur,Orissa 1,208 6 Community (SARC) 102 Swadhar Financcess Mumbai,Maharashtra 1,125 43 103 Ma tarani Prathamika Mahila Nayagarh,Orissa 982 17 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 104 CHINYARD Dharwad,Karnataka 918 50 105 Society for Empowerment and Hajaribag,Jharkhand 886 23 Women Advancement (SERV- SEVA) 106 GramIn Vikas Mandal Beed, maharashtara 882 37 107 Indian Institute for Rural Jaipur,Rajasthan 773 58 Development (IIRD) 108 Nari Jagruti Prathamika Cuttack,Orissa 750 24 Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 109 Sramajibi Bikas Prathamika Khurda,Orissa 740 15 Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 110 Mahila Vikas Prathamika Khurda,Orissa 682 17 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 111 Mahalaxmi Prathamika Mahila Nayagarh,Orissa 598 18 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 112 Mimo Finance Dehradun,Uttaranchal 570 30 113 Nava Jagriti Saran,Bihar 512 32 114 Upkar Nimapara,Orissa 482 3 115 PadmabatiPrathamika Mahila Nayagarh,Orissa 470 9 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 116 Ma Sakti Prathamika Mahila Cuttack,Orissa 435 3 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 117 Ma Adisakti Prathamika Cuttack,Orissa 310 2 Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 118 Nari Bikas Prathamika Mahila Bhubaneswar,Orissa 308 11 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 119 Devisakti Prathamika Mahila Cuttack,Orissa 219 1 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 120 Gram Swaraj Seva Trust Wardha,Maharashtra 208 12 121 Ma Matrusakti Prathamika Cuttack,Orissa 188 1 Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 122 Khandual Prathamika Mahila Cuttack,Orissa 181 2 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 123 Khetrapal Prathamika Mahila Khurda,Orissa 148 2 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 124 Potolei Prathamika Mahila Cuttack,Orissa 143 1 Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 186
  • 189. APPENDIX TABLE Legal form Delivery Borrowings Net owned Interest Operating cost Category Category model3 (Rs lakh) funds (Rs) rate (%)4 ratio5 (%) (outreach) (GLP) Society JLG 36 15 34.2 18.0 Small Small Society SHG, JLG 60 2 18.0 12.0 Small Small Society GR 96 2 31.0 35.5 Small Small Trust SHG 68 - 23.5 115.5 Small Small Society SHG 1 1 25.0 42.7 Small Small Section 25 Company JLG 25 20 35.8 203.0 Small Small MACs SHG,IL 12 18 19.5 16.0 Small Small Trust SHG/ JLG 50 12 12.5 7.7 Small Small Society SHG 18 12 22.8 1.8 Small Small Society SHG 37 - 34.2 3.1 Small Small Society JLG 50 50 25.7 7.0 Small Small MACs IL 9 24 21.3 13.5 Small Small MACs IL 12 20 18.7 12.7 Small Small Cooperative SHG, JLG 9 11 24.0 8.0 Small Small MACs SHG,IL 8 20 16.1 11.6 Small Small NBFC JLG,SHG, GR 20 30 32.3 100.0 Small Small Society SHG 32 - 18.0 16.0 Small Small Society SHG,IL 7 3 34.2 2.0 Small Small MACs IL 5 7 18.9 16.8 Small Small MACs SHG,IL 2 6 19.8 16.4 Small Small MACs IL 1 1 22.1 18.9 Small Small MACs IL 6 14 21.4 15.4 Small Small MACs IL 1 1 16.7 23.1 Small Small Society SHG, JLG NA 26 24.0 23.0 Small Small MACs SHG,IL 1 1 19.3 20.3 Small Small MACs IL 1 2 12.8 12.7 Small Small MACs IL 2 2 13.7 10.6 Small Small MACs IL 1 3 20.6 18.8 Small Small 187
  • 190. Sr No Name of MFI Location Outreach Gross loan portfolio (GLP) (Rs lakh)2 125 Saktimayeeni Prathamika Khurda,Orissa 141 2 Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 126 Ma Jogamaya Prathamika Cuttack,Orissa 104 1 Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 127 Jhanshirani Prathamika Khurda,Orissa 102 1 Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 128 Swayamsakti Prathamika Cuttack,Orissa 69 0 Mahila Sanchaya Samabaya Ltd 129 Nirantara Community Services Bidar,Karnataka 30 2 Total Total 8,231,026 306,475 Notes: 1. Self reported data as of 31 March 2007, taken from Sa-dhan’s Quick Report 2007: A Snapshot of Microfinance Institutions in India. 2. Gross Loan Portfolio: = sum total of all the loans outstanding of the MFI. This includes portfolio on the balance sheet as well as off the balance sheet 3. GR= Grameen, IL= Individual Loan,JLG = Joint Liability Groups (JLG). The JLG model refers to group lending models, which do not strictly follow the five member, up to eight group, center concept Table A.3 Lending by selected apex financing Institutions and banks to MFIs Sr Apex financing institution/Bank Partners Outstanding (Rs crores) 31-Mar-06 31-Mar-07 31-Mar-06 31-Mar-07 1 SIDBI NA 100 329 548 2 FWWB NA 102 67 104 3 Maanaveeya Holdings NA 24 NA 50 4 ICICI Bank 100 NA 2350 1392 5 HDFC Bank NA 66 250 300 6 ABN Amro Bank 19 27 87 161 7 Yes Bank NA 7 NA 62 8 Standard Chartered Bank 12 12 50 38 9 Other private sector banks NA NA NA 554 10 Public sector banks NA NA NA 195 1 11 Others NA NA NA 25 Notes: 1 Items no 1-8 are based on information provided by the apex financing institutions/banks. 2. Items no 9-11 are based on information compiled from the annual reports/annual financial statements of 48 MFIs. 1 Grameen Trust, Grameen Foundation, Oikocredit, etc. 188
  • 191. APPENDIX TABLE Legal form Delivery Borrowings Net owned Interest Operating cost Category Category model3 (Rs lakh) funds (Rs) rate (%)4 ratio5 (%) (outreach) (GLP) MACs IL 2 2 10.2 8.7 Small Small MACs SHG,IL 1 1 14.5 15.3 Small Small MACs IL 1 1 8.0 10.1 Small Small MACs IL 0 0 9.3 21.3 Small Small Society GR 10 - 29.0 27.5 Small Small 274,412 38,675 4. The interest rate is the annual effective rate of interest charged by the MFI to its borrowers. 5. Operating Cost Ratio is calculated by dividing the total operating costs (salaries, travel, depreciation and other administrative costs) by average loans outstanding. Table A.4 Salient features of selected India-oriented equity investors Bellwether Lok Capital Aavishkaar Michael and Unitus Equity Fund Goodwell India Susan Dell Microfinance Foundation Development Company Indian/Offshore Indian Offshore Offshore Offshore Offshore Size at first $22 million Size at first USD 8.4 Mn A foundation US$23.5m closing closing $12 with an million endowment of (expecting 2nd more than US $ 1 close of greater billion, which than $15 also makes equity million) investments Life of Fund 15 Years 10 years 10 years, NA 10 yrs extendable by 2 years Main Investors Individual & IFC, KfW, CDC, Institutional NA Mix of social and Institutional FMO (In process (Goodwell MDC, commercial (Hivos Triodos, of closing IFC, FMO, DB) investors Gray Ghost and investment from FMO) ACCION) Investees so far 12 of which 2 of which both One MFI – Equity 2 equity 2 equity (In India) Equity (8), are equity investment investments, 2 Convertible Debt grants of (2) and debt (2). donated equity to non profit MFIs, 1 incubation grant 189
  • 192. Bellwether Lok Capital Aavishkaar Michael and Susan Unitus Equity Fund Goodwell India Dell Foundation Microfinance Development Company Investees so far 12 of which 2 of which both One MFI – Equity 2 equity 2 equity (In India) Equity (8), are equity investment investments, 2 Convertible Debt grants of donated (2) and debt (2). equity to non profit MFIs, 1 incubation grant Pipeline 2 Existing MFIs MFIs, spread across 3 existing entities, 3-4 additional MFIs Expect 2-3 and 2 start-ups 10 states, half of 2 start ups over the next year additional equity which are start-up franchisee investments in or early-stage companies India by end of MFIs. Expecting to year close 2 further investments by end of 2007. Coverage Goals By year 5, aims to Targeting 12-15 The fund would 3-4 new MFIs every 8-10 leading MFIs successfully investments in invest in established year worldwide with transform 7 MFI's, total, which will MFIs, transforming the first fund of which at least be diversified MFIs, to foster and 3 will be start through encourage the ups. Expects 40 geographies, spread of MF across per cent of growth stages and the country, in small investments to product/market start up entities as be outside specializations. well in partnership southern states, with Intellecash and a rural urban franshisee program balance. Arrangements for Will access grants TA Lok Foundation Will channel TA to As a Foundation, Affiliate of Unitus TA for partners from will have the enable fulfilling its can offer grant through whom a other sources ability to finance mandate of finances breadth of $2-3 million spreading MF across capacity building, worth of TA the country and capital advisory, services to encouraging start functional investee MFIs. up entities solutions and Partnerships have network linkages been estabilished are offered. Unitus with both Indian currently has 16 as well as MFI Partners international TA worldwide providers. (10 in India). Emphases & Apart from social Lok Capital is an To maximize value Focuses exclusively Demonstrate that Special features returns, investees India-focused MF through superior on early-stage industries which must offer clear fund. Apart from risk – adjusted urban microfinance serve the poor in a prospects of social returns, social and financial institutions which commercially attractive returns investees must offer returns, by focusing are (potentially) sustainable on equity. clear prospects of on scalability, scalable and manner, such as attractive returns efficiency and sustainable model. microfinance, are on equity. Lok leverage and by Emphasis on viable investment seeks longer term applying a private financial and social vehicles. investment equity approach performance timelines of 5-7 within a mission parameters. Also years, and looks to driven setting. The supports non-profit provide significant geographic focus is MFIs value-add services India. to its investees. Investees Bellwether Satin Credit Care (Debt), Ujjivan Financial Services Pvt Ltd (Equity), Sharda's Women's association for Weaker Sections (SWAWS) – Equity, MAS Financial Services (Debt), Sonata Finance Pvt Ltd (Equity), Arohan Financial Services (Equity),Indur MACS Federation (Debt), BISWA Microfinance Services (Equity and Debt), Janalakshmi Financial Services (Equity and Debt), Swayamshree Micro Credit Services (Debt plus option), MIMO Finance (Equity and debt). Lok Capital Spandana Sphoorty Financial Services Ltd, Janalakshmi Financial Services (Equity) Aavishkaar Goodwell Share Microfin Limited India Microfinance Development Company MSDF Janalakshmi Financial Services (Equity), Swadhaar Finaccess (Grant), Ujjivan Financial Services Pvt Ltd (Equity), Nirmaan Bharati Arthik and Samajik Sansthan (Grant) Unitus Equity Fund Ujjivan Financial Services Pvt Ltd (Equity), SKS Microfinance Ltd (Equity). Source: Self-reported 190
  • 193. APPENDIX TABLE Table A.5 Insurance coverage by selected MFIs Sr MFI Customers Customers Customers Number Number No of covered covered covered of of micro weather under life under under livestock enterprises insurance insurance health accident insured insured customers insurance insurance only 1 Bharat Integrated Social Welfare 58,743 153223 47386 237 3,862 - Agency (BISWA) 2 KAS Foundation 2,794 190357 1,934 5,505 - 3 Kotalipara Development Society (KDS) 25,000 5,000 - - 25,000 - 4 CASHPOR Micro Credit 27,879 - - - - - 5 Satin Credit Care Network Ltd - - - - - - 6 SE Investments Ltd (SEIL) - - - - - - 7 Activists for Social Alternatives (ASA) 49,623 - - - - - 8 BASIX 372,344 356,545 - 10,098 1,263 10,711 9 Evangelical Social Action Forum (ESAF) 287 13,510 68,521 - - - 10 Krishna Bhima Samruddhi Local Area 17,892 17,892 - 953 - 1,005 Bank Ltd (KBSLAB) 11 Mahasemam Trust 221,613 30,498 - - - - 12 Saadhana Microfin Society 101,901 - - - - - 13 Sarvodaya Nano Finance Ltd (SNFL) - - - - - - 14 Sharadas Women's Association for 48,154 48,154 - - - - Weaker Section (SWAWS) 15 Shree Kshetra Dharmasthala Rural - 721,203 - - - - Development Projects (SKDRDP) 16 SKS Microfinance Pvt Ltd 603,933 990 - - - - 17 Spandana Sphoorthy Innovative 10,20,000 - - - - - Financial Services Limited (SPANDANA) Total 1,530,163 1,537,372 115,907 13,222 35,630 11,716 Source: Information provided by MFIs on the basis of a questionnaire. 191
  • 194. Table A.6 List of selected transformations SHARE, Andhra Pradesh transformed from a society to an NBFC - Share Microfin Limited Swayam Krishi Sangam (SKS), Andhra Pradesh transformed from a society to an NBFC - SKS Microfinance Pvt Ltd Spandana, Andhra Pradesh transformed from a society to an NBFC - Spandana Sphoorty Innovative Financial Services Limited Bullockcart Worker's Development Association (BWDA), Tamilnadu transformed from a society to an NBFC - BWDA Finance limited Cashpor, Uttar Pradesh transformed from a society to a Section 25 company - Cashpor Micro Credit (CMC) The Microfinance programme of Swayam Sikshan Prayog (SSP), Maharastra transformed from a Society to a Section 25 Company - SakhiSamudaya Kosh (SSK) The Microfinance Programme of NEEDS, Jharkhand has sformed in to a Section 25 Company - AJIWIKA Evangelical Social Action Forum (ESAF), Kerala is in the process of transforming from a society to an NBFC - ESAF Microfinance Limited. Konnagar Bandhan, West Bengal is in the process of transforming from a society to the NBFC - Bandhan Financial Services Limited. Village Welfare Society (VWS), West Bengal is in the process of transforming from a society to an NBFC - Village Financial Services Limited Shardas Women's Association for Weaker Sections (SWAWS), Andhra Pradesh is in the process of transforming in to an NBFC Mahasemam Trust, Tamilnadu is in the process of transforming its microfinance programme to an NBFC, Semam Microfinance Investment Literacy and Empowerment (SMILE) Microfinance programme of SHEPHERD, Tamilnadu has transformed in to a Section 25 Company - Nanyasurabhi Development Financial Services Microfinance programme of CYSD, Orissa has transformed in to a Section 25 Company - Swayanshree Microcredit Services. The microfinance programme of Gram Utthan, Orissa microfinance programme is in the process of transformation into a Section 25 Company - Kalyani Microfinance Foundation The microfinance programme of BISWA, Orissa is in the process of transforming in to an NBFC - Credible Securities and Finance Private Ltd." The microfinance programme of ADHIKAR, Orissa has been transformed into a Section 25 Company - Sanchayika. Council of Professional Social Workers (CPSW), Orissa is in the process of transforming its microfinance programme in to a Section 25 Company - Amba Jibika. Organisation for Development Coordination (ODC), Orissa is also in the process of transforming into a Section 25 Company - Jana Jibika Foundation. Notes: This information has been compiled on the basis of interaction with various stakeholders. It is not a comprehensive list, but may be of interest. For the purpose of this table, only transformation from a society/trust to a Section 25 Company or an NBFC has been considered. 192