P i o t r Ko z a r z e w s k i 
R i c h a r d Wo o d w a r d 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part I): 
Evolution of Ownership Structure 
and Company Performance in Firms 
Privatized by Employee Buyouts 
W a r s a w , 22 0 0 1 
No . 44 7
This research was undertaken with support from 
the European Union's Phare ACE Programme 1997, 
project P97-8201R „Secondary Privatization: The Evolution 
of Ownership Structure of Privatized Companies“, 
co-ordinated by Professor Barbara B³aszczyk, 
CASE Foundation, Warsaw. The content of the publication 
is the sole responsibility of the authors and it in no way 
represenets the views of the Commission or its services. 
Key words: privatization, secondary transactions, 
corporate governance, transition economies, 
Czech Republic, Slovenia, Poland. 
DTP: CeDeWu Sp. z o.o. 
Graphic Design – Agnieszka Natalia Bury 
Editing – Julia Iwiñska, Richard Woodward 
Warsaw 2001 
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be 
reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any 
form or by any means, without prior permission in writing 
from the European Commission. 
ISSN 1506-1647 ISBN 83-7178-277-2 
Publisher: 
CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research 
ul. Sienkiewicza 12, 00-944 Warsaw, Poland 
e-mail: case@case.com.pl 
http://www.case.com.pl
3 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Contents 
Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5 
1. Introduction: The Role of Employee Buyouts in the Polish Privatization Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . .7 
2. The Evolution of Ownership Structures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .9 
2.1. Companies Dominated by Top Management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .14 
2.2. Companies with Strategic Investors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .15 
3. Factors in the Post-Privatization Evolution of Ownership Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .17 
3.1. Motivations for Choice of the EBO Privatization Method and Subsequent Changes 
in Ownership Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .17 
3.2. Initial Ownership Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .18 
3.3. Sector, Company Size, and Unionization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .18 
3.4. Profitability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .21 
3.5. Methods for Ownership Transformation: Share Sales and New Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .22 
3.6. Top Management Domination . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .23 
3.7. Companies with Strategic Investors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .23 
4. The Economic Performance of Employee-Leased Companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .25 
4.1. Profitability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .25 
4.2. Investment Activity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .25 
4.3. Restructuring and Adjustment Activity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .28 
5. The Relationship between Ownership Structure and Productivity: Evidence 
from the Early 1990s . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31 
5.1. Productivity Analysis: Estimating Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31 
5.2. Productivity Analysis: The Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31 
6. Corporate Governance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .33 
6.1. Formation of Corporate Governance Bodies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .33 
6.2. The Decision-Making Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .36 
7. Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .40 
Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .42 
Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .43 
CASE Reports No. 47
Piotr Kozarzewski 
Piotr Kozarzewski has worked for the CASE Foundation since 1992. He obtained a PhD in political science in 1999 from 
the Institute for Political Studies of the Polish Academy of Sciences. He has participated in numerous research and adviso-ry 
projects focusing on the systemic transformation of post-communist countries and especially on ownership transforma-tion, 
in Poland and various post-Soviet countries (including Kyrgyzstan, Kazkhstan, Bulgaria and Belarus). His chief research 
interest to date has been in the area of employee ownership, and he is the author of numerous publications on the subject 
of employee-owned companies in Poland. Piotr Kozarzewski also works for the Institute of Political Studies of the Polish 
Academy of Sciences, where he is involved in a study of the effects of privatisation of the Polish enterprises. 
Richard Woodward 
Richard Woodward has collaborated with the CASE Foundation since 1994. He graduated from the Pennsylvania State 
University (economics) and received his PhD at the Department of Sociology and Economy of £ódŸ University (2000). He 
has participated in numerous research projects on the privatisation and restructuring of state enterprises in Poland and 
other post-communist countries, with a special focus on employee ownership issues. He also supervised the work of the 
Polish researchers participating in an UNDP programme focused on the decentralisation of the public administration 
(1997–1999) and a team conducting research on the institutional framework supporting small and medium-sized enter-prises 
(1997–1999). 
4 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
CASE Reports No. 47
5 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
This volume contains the output of country research 
undertaken in Poland by Piotr Kozarzewski and Richard 
Woodward under the international comparative project 
"Secondary Privatization: the Evolution of Ownership Struc-tures 
of Privatized Enterprises". The project was supported 
by the European Union's Phare ACE* Programme 1997 
(project P97-8201 R) and was coordinated by Barbara 
B³aszczyk from the Center for Social and Economic 
Research (CASE) in Warsaw, Poland. 
The support of the ACE Programme made it possible to 
organize the cooperation of an international group of schol-ars 
(from the Czech Republic, France, Poland, Slovenia and 
the U.K.). The entire project was devoted to the investiga-tion 
of secondary ownership changes in enterprises priva-tized 
in special privatization schemes (i.e., mass privatization 
schemes and MEBOs**) in three Central European countries 
– the Czech Republic, Poland and Slovenia. Through a com-bination 
of different research methods, such as secondary 
analysis of previous research, analysis of legal and other reg-ulatory 
instruments, original field research, statistical data 
CASE Reports No. 47 
base research and econometric analysis of individual enter-prise 
data, the project aimed to investigate the scope, pace 
and trends in secondary ownership changes, the factors and 
barriers affecting them and the degree of ownership con-centration 
resulting from them. 
The authors begin with a general discussion of MEBOs in 
Poland and go on to analyze ownership changes in a sample 
of such companies. First, they present the initial ownership 
structures created at the time of privatization and the evo-lution 
of those structures through 1999, and then go on to 
analyze the factors behind these changes and the relation-ships 
between the evolution of ownership structures on the 
one hand and economic performance and corporate gover-nance 
on the other. 
We hope that the results of this research will be of great 
interest for everyone interested in the little-researched 
question of what has happened to companies after privati-zation 
in transition countries. 
Barbara B³aszczyk 
Preface 
* "Action for Cooperation in the Field of Economics". 
** Management-Employee Buyouts.
6 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
CASE Reports No. 47
7 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
1. Introduction: The Role of Employee Buyouts in the Polish 
Privatization Process1 
In the Polish literature and legislation relating to privati-zation, 
two general types of privatization of state enterpris-es 
are generally distinguished. The first, privatization by 
commercial methods such as trade sales and initial public 
offerings, is currently referred to as indirect privatization 
(previously as capital privatization). The second, with which 
we will be concerned in this paper, is currently referred to 
as direct privatization (previously, as liquidation privatiza-tion2). 
In direct privatization, the state enterprise is dis-solved 
and its assets transferred (by one of three methods) 
to the private sector. The three methods of direct privati-zation 
are leasing of assets, sale of assets, and inkind contri-bution 
of assets to a company. Leasing decidedly dominates 
as the preferred form of direct privatization, and it is leased 
firms that we are concerned with in this paper, as the vast 
majority of employee buyouts in the Polish privatization 
process have been generated via the leasing variant of direct 
privatization3. In fact, since these employee buyouts only 
become real buyouts after several years of leasing, in the 
remainder of this paper we will refer to the companies in 
question not as employee buyouts, but rather as employee-leased 
companies. 
In the leasing variant of direct privatization, at least 50 
percent of the employees of the state enterprise being liq-uidated 
must form a company to lease the assets of the 
CASE Reports No. 47 
enterprise. Moreover, no corporate investors or foreigners 
were allowed to participate in the absence of special per-mission 
from the privatization ministry4. For this reason 
such companies are commonly referred to in Poland as 
"employee-owned companies" (spó³ki pracownicze). By 31 
December, 1998, 2966 state enterprises had completed 
either privatization or "Article 19 liquidation" (see the first 
footnote), with 240 indirect privatizations, 512 firms trans-ferred 
to the National Investment Funds, 1515 direct priva-tizations 
and 699 Article 19 liquidations. At this point, there-fore, 
51.1 percent of all privatizations were direct privatiza-tions. 
Since about 66 percent of the direct privatizations 
were leasing cases5, by the end of 1998 lease-leveraged 
employee buyout represented about one third of the complet-ed 
privatizations carried out under the supervision of the priva-tization 
ministry6, thus constituting the single most frequent-ly 
used method (in terms of the numbers of enterprises pri-vatized. 
It is important to note that this privatization 
method was intended by Polish legislators to be applied in 
the case of small and medium-sized enterprises, and for the 
most part this has been the case in practice. Most of the 
firms in this category are small- to medium-sized firms, usu-ally 
with less than 500 employees. As of 1998, 78.2 percent 
of leased companies had up to 250 employees, 19.7 percent 
had 251–1000 employees, and 2.1 percent had over 10007. 
1 This research was undertaken with support from the European Union's Phare ACE Program 1997, project P97-8201 R "Secondary Privatisation: 
The Evolution of Ownership Structure of Privatised Companies", coordinated by Professor Barbara Blaszczyk, CASE Foundation, Warsaw. The content 
of the publication is the sole responsibility of the authors and in no way represents the views of the Commission or its services. We would also like to 
thank Professor Maria Jarosz of the Polish Academy of Sciences for kindly allowing us to utilize the data bases created in research projects conducted 
under her direction. 
2 This is not to be confused with liquidation based on Article 19 of the 1981 Law on State Enterprises. Article 19 liquidation is applied to an insol-vent 
state enterprise, entailing its dissolution and the sale of its assets, and means the end of the enterprise as an economic unit, in contrast to direct 
privatization, in which the economic activity of the state enterprise is continued. 
3 Since 1995, we can also refer to the National Investment Fund program as a third type of privatization – Poland's version of voucher privatiza-tion. 
Reference is also often made to "small privatization." No separate law governed this process, which generally affected very small businesses in the 
areas of retail trade and consumer services (grocers' shops, restaurants, barber shops, etc.) and was largely carried out by local governments without 
supervision by the privatization ministry. 
4 The new privatization act of 30 August, 1996, requires that – unless a special exemption is granted – at least 20% of the shares of companies pri-vatized 
by leasing be held by outsiders. 
5 See Central Statistical Office (1999), 31, Kozarzewski et al. (2000), 32–33. 
6 If one considers employment, direct privatization does not outweigh capital privatization so strongly, as total employment in firms privatized by 
these two methods was – at least until recently – much closer to being equal. See Central Statistical Office (1995), 62–3. 
7 See Kozarzewski et al. (2000), 50.
8 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
Year privatized Number % 
1990 3 2.7 
1991 41 36.9 
1992 23 20.7 
1993 14 12.6 
1994 13 11.7 
1995 8 7.2 
1996 8 7.2 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Several preferential conditions facilitate this form of pri-vatization. 
First, the 1990 Law on Privatization essentially 
gave insiders precedence in privatizing their enterprises. 
Second, preferential interest rates are applied for the lease 
payments. The interest payment (referred to in Polish regu-lations 
as the "additional payment" [op³ata dodatkowa]) was 
originally set by the Finance Ministry at 75 percent of the 
central bank refinancing rate. (Moreover, the interest pay-ments 
could, to some extent, be postponed during the first 
two years of the leasing period.) Finally, the corporate 
income tax law allowed the firms to include the interest 
portion of the lease payments as costs in their accounts, 
thus reducing their tax liability. Later, it was determined that 
if the central bank refinance rate were to exceed 40 per-cent, 
the interest rate would be set at 30 percent (75 per-cent 
of 40 percent)8. In 1993, the interest rate was lowered 
again, to 50 percent of the refinance rate9. At the same time, 
further favorable conditions were created in order to stim-ulate 
investment in the employee-leased companies; these 
provisions, as well as the difficulties which leased firms con-tinue 
to face in spite of these measures, will be discussed 
below. The new privatization act of 30 August, 1996, once 
again liberalized leasing conditions somewhat. 
The data about employee-leased companies used in this 
paper were gathered directly in the companies during 
research conducted by the interdisciplinary team headed by 
Professor Maria Jarosz of the Polish Academy of Sciences: a 
three-year study (1993–1995) devoted to employee privati-zation 
(with a sample of 200 companies) and a four-year 
study (1997–2000) devoted to direct privatization (the sam-ple 
for this study included about 160 employee-leased com-panies) 
10. 
The samples were representative with respect to sector 
(manufacturing, construction, services, trade), size (mea-sured 
by number of employees) and region. Data were col-lected 
using two methods: interviews with the main actors 
in the companies and collection of hard data by question-naire 
(these included data from the balance sheets and finan-cial 
statements, as well as information on ownership and 
corporate governance issues, employment, restructuring, 
investments, etc.). Most financial and ownership data were 
collected for several periods of time: immediately following 
privatization, year-end, and at the time of the research (usu-ally 
the middle of a given year). Thus, we use two separate 
databases, each for three subsequent semi-panel polls: 
1993–1996 (polls in 1993, 1994, and 1995) and 1997–2000 
(polls in 1997, 1998, and 1999), which we refer to as Data-base 
1 and Database 2, respectively. 
The sample for Database 2, drawn on most frequently in 
this paper, consists of 110 firms privatized between 1990 
and 199611. 
This constitutes 12.9% of the total number of compa-nies 
privatized by the leasing method through the end of 
1996. 
For the purposes of the paper, all source data were 
processed. Where we considered this useful, we also used 
data from the earlier study as an additional source of infor-mation. 
Some findings of other members of Maria Jarosz's 
team are also referred to12. In discussing certain correla-tions, 
we refer to various variables referring to ownership 
structures using abbreviated labels. An explanation of these 
labels and the variables, as well as tables containing the cor-relations 
themselves, are found in the appendix13. 
Table 1. Number of firms privatized, by year (%) 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
8 Zarz¹dzenie Ministra Finansów z dnia 7 maja 1991 r. 
9 Zarz¹dzenie Ministra Finansów z dnia 13 maja 1993 r. (Monitor Polski 1993 nr 26, poz. 274). 
10 For detailed discussions of the results of these studies, see Jarosz (ed.), 1994, 1995, 1996, 1999, 2000. 
11 The moment of privatization is identified with the year in which the company was registered; we include among the firms privatized in 1990 one 
which was actually registered in 1989, since the Polish privatization law was not adopted until 1990. 
12 Most importantly, Gardawski (2000) and Kozarzewski (1999). 
13 The analysis presented here is indicative of linear correlations only. No tests have been made for non-linear relationships.
9 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
2. The Evolution of Ownership Structures 
From the very beginning, employee leasing has been the 
most "employee-oriented" privatization path, in terms of 
ownership structure. Immediately following privatization, 
insiders possessed, on the average, 92 percent of the shares 
in the sample of employee-leased companies, and in 95 per-cent 
of those companies, insiders owned over 50 percent of 
the shares14. 
In employee-leased companies, the share of non-man-agerial 
employees in ownership has steadily decreased, from 
58.7 percent immediately after privatization to 31.5 percent 
in 1999. It is worth noting, however, that despite wide-spread 
selling of their shares by non-managerial employees, 
by 1999 only in 6 percent of firms had this group of owners 
vanished completely. In most companies, non-managerial 
employees retained at least minor blocks of shares. Very 
often those blocks were very small: in 17 percent of the 
firms they did not exceed 10 percent, and in almost half of 
the companies (43 percent) non-managerial employees did 
Table 2. Ownership structure in the average employee-leased company immediately after privatization (%) 
CASE Reports No. 47 
not have blocking capabilities at shareholders' meetings (at 
least 25 percent of the votes). Because of the dispersed 
character of these blocks of shares, in practice the voting 
capacity of non-managerial employees is even weaker than 
these numbers indicate. If we assume that this group would 
need at least 50 percent of the shares in order to block cer-tain 
decisions at a shareholders' meeting, then it is clear that 
in at least 76 percent of the companies under review, non-managerial 
employees lack decisive influence on the deci-sion- 
making process as owners15. 
While non-managerial employees were losing their 
shares, the number of shares in the hands of outsiders 
increased fivefold (from 7.6 percent to 38.5 percent). 
Almost all of them are domestic investors; only three firms 
have foreign investors (in two cases, strategic investors). A 
large portion of the outsider shares represent concentrated 
holdings: 44.4 percent of the outsider shares were held by 
owners whom respondents referred to as strategic 
14 Where weighted, average ownership structure figures are weighted by end-of-year employment for the year preceding the given ownership 
structure observation. 
15 Of course, they can influence decision-making in other ways, for example, through trade unions, workers' protests, etc. However, analysis shows 
that the situation in almost all employee-leased companies is largely free of conflicts, with trade unions passive and even – in many companies – ceas-ing 
to exist. 
Shareholder groups Simple average 
(%) 
Weighted 
average (%) 
Outsiders 8.0 7.6 
Managers 41.0 33.7 
Non-managerial employees 51.0 58.7 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 3. Percentage of employee-leased companies dominated by various owner groups immediately following privatization 
Biggest shareholder group Simple average 
(%) 
Weighted 
average (%) 
Strategic outside investors 8.9 4.9 
Managers 32.7 37.3 
Non-managerial employees 50.5 57.8 
a Domination by one of four main shareholder groups (strategic investors, other outside investors, managers, and non-managerial employees) is defined 
by the group with the largest holdings. 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
10 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
CASE Reports No. 47 
investors. There is also a large group of private firms and 
entrepreneurs (18.7 percent). 
However, the second largest group of outsider owners 
consists of unidentified "others" (34 percent of outsider 
shares). One might hypothesize that this group consists 
mostly of former employees of the companies who lost 
their jobs due to layoffs, retired, or left for other reasons. 
Respondents were not asked in the survey to identify 
whether these "others" were in fact former employees, so 
we can only test this hypothesis indirectly. Initial calculations 
have not yielded clear results. There is negative correlation 
between growth in the shares of this group between the 
time of privatization and mid-1997 (GROO) and the change 
in the shares of non-managerial workers (GRWOR) – that is, 
the more the share of the workers fell, the more share of 
"other" outsiders grew – and there is a positive correlation 
between the change in employment from the time of priva-tization 
to mid-1997 (P.C. CH) and GRWOR (so that, for 
example, the more employment fell, the more the share of 
workers fell). However, there is no direct correlation 
between GROO and P.C. CH – between the drop in 
employment and the growth in the "other" outsiders' share. 
One might hypothesize that in cases in which employment 
drops were particularly drastic, these drops reflected a dra-matic 
worsening of the companies' economic prospects and 
workers sold their shares (e.g., to management) in a des-perate 
attempt to minimize their losses, in which case there 
would be a negative correlation between GROO and P.C. 
CH up to a certain threshold of employment reduction, 
beyond which this correlation would disappear and be 
replaced by a negative correlation between P.C. CH and the 
growth in the share of Executive Board members 
(GRMAN). And in fact, where employment reductions were 
over 50%, there is a negative correlation between GRMAN 
and P.C. CH. However, for other firms we observe no cor-relation 
between GROO and P.C. CH. It is, however, quite 
certain that we are not dealing with small portfolio investors 
here, because of the generally small size of the companies 
under review and the fact that less than two percent of 
them are listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange. 
Tables 4 and 5 show how the detailed ownership struc-ture 
of employee-leased companies evolved over the 
course of time. 
Interestingly, by comparing simple with weighted aver-ages, 
we see that at the time of privatization, the role of 
strategic investors is lower, and that of non-managerial 
employees greater, in the case of weighted averages. This 
means that strategic owners were generally involved in the 
privatization of smaller than average companies, while the 
percentage of shares belonging to non-managerial employ-ees 
at the time of privatization was generally higher in larg-er 
firms. By 1999 the situation has changed: while strategic 
Table 4. Ownership structure of employee-leased companies (weighted averages; %)16 
Shareholders 
Immediately 
after 
privatization 
1997 1998 1999 
Outsiders 
1. Strategic investors (domestic and foreign) 1.4 9.1 15.2 17.1 
2. Other domestic outside investors 
a. private firms – 0.6 1.5 2.1 
b. commercialized firms – 0.4 0.4 0.0 
c. private banks – – – – 
d. state-owned banks – – – – 
e. private businessmen 4.2 4.3 5.1 6.4 
f. others 2.0 7.0 9.2 12.9 
3. Other foreign investors – 0.1 0.1 0.0 
Insiders 
4. Supervisory board members employed in the 
company* 
9.4 10.6 6.1 3.9 
5. Executive board members 8.7 13.4 15.1 14.2 
6. Other managers 15.7 13.7 15.4 11.1 
7. Non-managerial employees 58.7 41.0 31.8 31.5 
TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 
* Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
16 In this and other tables "0" or "0.0" means that the frequency of occurrence of the given category is less than 0.5 or 0.05 respectively; a hyphen 
means that the category is absent, and "x" means lack of data.
11 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 5. Ownership structure of employee-leased companies (simple averages; %) 
investor presence tended to be noted in smaller firms at the 
time of privatization, in 1999 they tended to be present in 
larger firms. Executive board members' shares are consis-tently 
smaller when averages are weighted, meaning that 
they tend to dominate in smaller firms. As mentioned 
above, the higher non-managerial employee holdings in the 
weighted averages at the time of privatization indicate that 
at that time the largest group of employees exercised the 
strongest ownership domination in the largest firms. By the 
late 1990s, however, this difference has disappeared, indi-cating 
that the holdings of this group are now relatively 
equal with respect to the size of the firm. 
We will analyze the structure of employee-leased com-panies 
along two axes: concentrated versus dispersed own-ership, 
and insider versus outsider ownership. A combina-tion 
of these two axes gives us four main groups of 
investors: (1) outsiders with small holdings, (2) strategic 
outside investors, (3) insider shareholders with large hold-ings 
(members of managing and supervisory bodies), (4) 
insiders with small holdings (generally, non-managerial 
employees). Table 6 illustrates the dynamics of ownership 
structures with respect to these four groups. 
We see that more and more shares are in the hands of 
both outsider groups, while fewer and fewer shares are 
held by non-managerial employees (although in 1999 the 
employee shareholdings seem to stabilize). The position of 
managerial staff is more stabilized, although recently they 
have also begun to lose ground. Although it is not evident 
from Table 6, earlier studies show that in the first half of the 
1990s managers were actively buying shares from non-man-agerial 
employees and increasing their holdings17. 
Moreover, managers are a far from monolithic group, 
consisting of three main subgroups: executive board mem-bers, 
supervisory board members employed in the compa-nies, 
and lower level managers. Through 1997, executive 
and supervisory board members were actively increasing 
17 For more, see Gardawski (1996), 96–98, and Kozarzewski (1999), 78–82. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Shareholders 
Immediately 
after 
privatization 
1997 1998 1999 
Outsiders 
1. Strategic investors (domestic and foreign) 3.3 7.1 9.4 11.0 
2. Other domestic outside investors 
a. private firms – 0.6 2.1 2.7 
b. commercialized firms – 0.4 0.2 0.0 
c. private banks – – – – 
d. sta te-owned banks – – – – 
e. private businessmen 2.5 2.3 2.0 4.5 
f. others 2.2 6.4 8.5 12.2 
3. Other foreign investors – 0.2 0.7 0.6 
Insiders 
4. Supervisory board members employed in the company* 11.5 12.0 8.1 6.4 
5. Executive board members 16.0 18.8 18.9 19.3 
6. Other managers 13.5 11.9 14.5 11.0 
7. Non-managerial employees 51.0 40.3 36.2 32.3 
TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 
* Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 6. Ownership structure dynamics in employee-leased companies, by major shareholder groups (weighted averages; %) 
Shareholder groups 
Immediately 
after 
privatization 
1997 1998 1999 
Strategic outside investor 1.4 9.1 15.2 17.1 
Other outsider investors 6.2 12.3 16.3 22.0 
Managers 33.7 37.6 36.7 29.4 
Non-managerial employees 58.7 41.0 31.8 31.5 
TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
12 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
Table 7. Blocks of shares held by executive and supervisory board members (%) 
their shares in the companies (Table 7). Later the situation 
among executive board members stabilized, but the share 
of the supervisory board members began to decrease rapid-ly. 
This is probably not due to their selling of shares, but 
rather to the rotation in supervisory board membership, 
which is much higher than in the executive boards. As a rule, 
former supervisory board members still have managerial 
posts, and for this reason the total share of management 
remains relatively stable. 
The lower part of Table 7 shows that in order to effec-tively 
exercise their voting rights, members of both boards 
in question have to cooperate: thus, for example, in 1999 
acting together they can control almost three times more 
companies than if they act separately. The Jarosz group's 
research confirms the large extent of synergy between 
executive and supervisory boards, with the dominant posi-tion 
of the executive board in the decision-making system, 
in employee-leased companies18. 
The data presented here fail to confirm earlier predictions 
that the ownership structure of employee-leased companies 
would tend towards steadily increasing management domina-tion19, 
since in most companies the position of elites has sta-bilized. 
However, two trends are confirmed: the decrease in 
the shares of non-managerial employees and the increase of 
those of outsider investors, both strategic and non-strategic. 
Another earlier prediction concerned the appearance of 
manager-outsider ownership coalitions20. The fact that in 57 
percent of employee-leased companies, more than 50 percent 
of the shares belong to managers and outsiders together, could 
be seen as supporting this view. On the other hand, only 9 per-cent 
of the companies have both an outside investor and an 
inside investor possessing at least 10 percent of shares. 
In the remainder of this section, we will concentrate on 
changes in ownership structures in terms of shareholding by 
three groups of shareholders – strategic investors, top man-agement 
(i.e., Executive Board members), and non-manageri-al 
employees – considering each group to have attained a dom-inant 
block of shares when it exceeds 20%. First, in Table 8, we 
look at how many firms had domination by each group at the 
time of privatization and in 1997, 1998 and 1999, and then, in 
CASE Reports No. 47 
18 See Kozarzewski (2000a, 2000b). 
19 See Gardawski (1995); Kozarzewski (1999). 
20 See Gardawski (2000). 
Immediately 
after 
privatization 
1997 1998 1999 
Average block of shares: 
– executive board 8.7 13.4 15.2 14.2 
– supervisory board 9.4 10.6 6.1 3.9 
TOTAL 18.1 24.0 21.3 18.1 
Percent of companies with ownership dominance of: 
– executive board 7 8 8 8 
– supervisory board 3 6 2 1 
– both boards together 25 23 29 25 
Source: own calculations using Database 1 and Database 2. 
Table 8. Number of firms in which the given ownership groups had shares of at least 20% 
At time of 
privatization 
1997 1998 1999 
No data 8 9 13 14 
Strategic investor (SI) 4 8 10 12 
Executive board members (Managers) 5 10 10 8 
Non-managerial employees 69 50 42 36 
All three 1 1 0 2 
SI and managers 0 0 1 0 
Managers and employees 17 20 20 24 
SI and employees 1 5 4 3 
None 5 7 10 11 
Total 110 110 110 110 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
13 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 9. Transformation matrix 
Table 9, we present a transformation matrix. The latter shows 
the transformation trajectory of firms grouped with respect to 
dominant shareholders at the time of privatization: in the 
rightmost column, we see the number of firms in each group 
at the time of privatization, and looking leftward, we see 
where the firms in these groups ended up in 1997. The diag-onal, 
in which the numbers are printed in boldface, shows 
firms that remained in the same group in which they started. 
Again, all this confirms that in general non-managerial 
employees are slowly losing ground, while top management 
and strategic investors tend to consolidate and increase 
their holdings. We obtain an even sharper picture of the 
concentration that is going on if we look at the average 
shares of the single largest shareholder. 
In Table 10 we see that in the average company, the sin-gle 
largest shareholder held over one quarter of all the com-pany's 
shares by 1998. This indicates a large degree of con-centration 
on the average. 
Analysis of simple correlations between various owner-ship 
variables bears out the foregoing observations. The 
variables analyzed (presented in detail in the appendix) 
include the following: the percentage of shares held by 
strategic investors (SI), by Executive Board members 
(MAN), and by non-managerial employees (WOR), the per-centage 
of the work force holding shares (OWN), dummy 
variables for the degree of equality of shareholding (EQ1, 
EQ2, EQ3, and EQ4, in ascending order of equality). 
Relationships between various ownership variables tend to 
be pretty much as one would expect. Thus, for example, the 
size and growth of the shares of strategic investors and Execu-tive 
Board members on the one hand and the size and growth 
of non-managerial employees' shares on the other. There is a 
positive correlation between WOR and EQ3, which is logical 
given that EQ3 is a dummy representing a relatively high 
degree of equality and WOR the percentage of company's 
shares held by non-managerial employees (discrepancies 
between these two measures can arise in cases in which a large 
number of employees have been laid off or left the firm for 
other reasons but kept their shares). There is a correlation 
between equality and the percentage of the work force hold-ing 
shares (OWN), as evidenced in the negative correlations 
between EQ1 and OWN. Similarly, there is a positive relation-ship 
between equality and the percentage of shares held by 
non-managerial employees (WOR), as EQ3 is positively corre-lated 
with WOR and EQ1 negatively correlated with WOR for 
all three observations. Conversely, there is a positive correla-tion 
between MAN and EQ1. Generally, the size and growth 
of the shares of strategic investors and top management are 
positively correlated with the percentage of company shares 
held by the single largest shareholder (BIG). Again, as we 
would expect, we observe a positive correlation between the 
growth of non-managerial employees' shares (GRWOR) and 
the year of privatization (YR1) and a negative correlation 
between YR1 and the growth of strategic investors' shares 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Had over 20% in 1997 
Had over 20% at 
time of privatization 
No 
data 
SI M Wor SMW SM MW SW None Total at 
time of 
priv. 
No data 5 0 0 1 0 0 2 0 0 8 
Strategic investor 
0 3 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 4 
(S) 
Exec. Bd. memb. 
(M) 
0 0 4 0 0 0 1 0 0 5 
Non-mg. workers 
(W) 
3 4 2 48 0 0 5 3 4 69 
All three 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 
S & M 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 
M & W 0 0 4 1 0 0 12 0 0 17 
S & W 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 
None 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 5 
Total 9 8 10 50 1 0 20 5 7 110 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 10. Holdings of the single largest shareholder (weighted averages) 
N Minimum Maximum Mean Standard Deviation 
1997 88 0.1 86.3 22.896 20.592 
1998 93 0.3 100.0 27.652 26.075 
1999 108 2.0 100.0 27.364 25.507 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
14 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
time of privatization 1997 1998 1999 
Strategic vestor in 0.00 0.29 -1.09 
State Treasury -- - 5.32 
Individual entrepreneurs 1.23 0.77 0.56 0.74 
Other outside investors 1.49 1.03 2.49 3.51 
Supervisory Board members* 5.95 11.37 5.92 3.15 
Executive Board members 32.23 38.33 44.00 39.71 
Other managerial employees 20.47 19.29 20.37 11.12 
non-managerial employees 38.64 28.92 26.66 35.36 
* Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
(GRSI). This means that the earlier the firm was privatized, the 
more the worker share has fallen and the more the strategic 
investor share has grown. 
We now turn to a more detailed analysis of the evolution 
of ownership structures in two groups of companies: those 
with large ownership shares of top management (i.e., Exec-utive 
Board members) and those with strategic investors. 
2.1. Companies Dominated by Top 
Management 
Holdings of top management – i.e., Executive Board 
members – were over 20% in 23 firms, or less than a quar-ter 
of sample, at the time of privatization, in 31 (almost a 
third) in 1997 and 1998, and 34 in 1999. 
A comparison with the sample as a whole (see Table 1) is 
not particularly enlightening. While among the firms dominated 
by top management a higher percentage was privatized in 1991, 
a higher percentage was also privatized in 1995 and 1996. 
Next, we look at the average ownership structure in 
these firms, comparing those which already had top man-agement 
domination at the time of privatization with the 
larger group of those that had such domination in mid-1997. 
Both groups look very similar; in particular, in both we 
observe a decline in top management holdings from 1998 to 
1999. The most significant difference between the two 
groups appears to be the smaller average share held by top 
management in the larger group, where top management 
had not been in a dominant position from the very begin-ning. 
This is quite clearly an indication of inertia. 
Next, we compare firms in which top management gained 
control between the time of privatization and mid-1997 with 
those in which it neither had such control at the outset nor 
gained it later. We do this by looking at the initial ownership 
structure of the five firms in which top management held less 
than 20% at the time of privatization but at least 20% in 1997, 
comparing it with that of the 68 firms in which top manage-ment 
held less than 20% as of mid-1997 and for which we 
have the appropriate data. 
Table 11. Firms with top management domination in 1999, by 
year of privatization 
Number Percent 
1990 1 2.9 
1991 16 47.1 
1992 3 8.8 
1993 4 11.8 
1994 3 8.8 
1995 3 8.8 
1996 4 11.8 
Total 31 100.0 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 12. Firms with top management shares > 20% at time of privatization (weighted averages) 
Table 13. Firms with top management shares > 20% in mid-1997 (weighted averages) 
time of privatization 1997 1998 1999 
strategic investor 0.00 0.19 3.06 4.50 
private firms -- - 0.91 
state-owned companies - - 0.43 - 
State Treasury -- - 3.16 
individual entrepreneurs 0.81 0.51 0.35 0.44 
other outside investors 1.06 5.85 6.01 7.29 
Supervisory Board members* 6.51 10.06 6.34 4.15 
Executive Board members 24.64 34.53 37.53 34.09 
other managerial employees 20.54 18.00 21.13 15.85 
non-managerial employees 46.44 30.87 25.16 29.61 
* Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
15 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 14. Firms in which top management gained domination: Initial ownership structure 
Minimum Maximum Mean Standard 
strategic investor 0 0 0.00 0.00 
individual entrepreneurs 0 0 0.00 0.00 
other outside investors 0 1 0.27 0.44 
Supervisory Board members 0 22 8.50 8.69 
Executive Board members 4 17 8.75 4.97 
other managerial employees 7 31 19.41 8.72 
non-managerial employees 49 74 63.08 10.15 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 15. Firms in which top management does not dominate: Initial ownership structure 
Minimum Maximum Mean Standard 
strategic investor 0 66 1.78 9.72 
individual entrepreneurs 0 80 5.32 12.60 
other outside investors 0 20 1.65 4.19 
Supervisory Board members 0 54 10.02 12.40 
Executive Board members 0 18 6.20 4.69 
other managerial employees 0 42 13.09 9.24 
non-managerial employees 0 93 61.95 25.90 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Examination of the two above tables shows that there is 
very little difference between the two groups with respect to 
their average initial ownership structure. The most significant 
difference seems to be that in the group in which top man-agement 
later attained domination, lower levels of manage-ment 
had larger holdings than in those firms in which top man-agement 
had not gained a share of over 20% by mid-1997. 
2.2. Companies with Strategic Investors 
As of mid-1997, 13 companies had such investors; 17 
companies had them in mid-1998. No new strategic 
investors appeared in 1999. 
Comparing with the privatization dates of firms in the 
sample as a whole, it seems that companies privatized ear-lier 
may have a slight advantage in finding strategic outside 
investors (over 70% of them were privatized before 1993, 
whereas slightly over 60% of the sample as a whole was pri-vatized 
in that time). 
Foreign investors were present in only two firms in the 
sample by mid-1998 (one of which had gained its foreign 
investor in the year since the previous survey, in 1997). Both 
companies were privatized in 1991. 
As in the case of firms dominated by top management, 
we look at the average ownership structure in these firms, 
comparing those which already had strategic investors at 
the time of privatization with the larger group of those that 
had them in mid-1997. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Deviation 
Deviation 
For the last group (of which only five firms provided data 
on their ownership structure), the absence of data from 
even a single firm in one year can create large fluctuations in 
the mean values (and in fact we observe such fluctuations), 
so we should exercise great caution in interpreting the pat-terns 
in the Table 18. 
Next, we compare the initial ownership structure of the 
eight firms that had no strategic investors at the time of pri-vatization 
but found them by mid-1997 with that of the 84 
firms that had no strategic investor as of mid-1997 and for 
which we have the appropriate data. 
It is interesting to note that in companies that found strate-gic 
investors after privatization, top management owned 
much fewer shares at the time of privatization than in the case 
of those that did not find strategic investors later. This is borne 
out by analysis of correlations between various ownership 
variables, which shows, for example, negative correlations 
between the shares of strategic investors (SI) and those of 
Executive Board members (MAN) in 1997 and 1999. 
Table 16. Number of companies with strategic investors in 1998, 
by year of privatization 
Number Percent 
1990 1 5.9 
1991 9 52.9 
1992 2 11.8 
1993 2 11.8 
1994 1 5.9 
1996 2 11.8 
Total 17 100.0 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
16 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Table 17. Firms with strategic investors in mid-1997: ownership structure (weighted averages) 
time of 
privatization 
1997 1998 1999 
strategic investor 6.37 44.31 55.612 56.34 
private rms fi -- 0.686 3.19 
state-owned companies - - 0.954 - 
individual entrepreneurs 0.38 0.20 2.321 - 
other utside nvestorso i -8.43 8.640 14.23 
Supervisory Board members* 5.71 7.72 0.798 0.69 
Executive Board members 3.39 4.82 2.141 5.35 
other managerial employees 20.37 11.58 6.190 3.48 
non-managerial employees 63.77 22.93 22.659 16.23 
* Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 18. Firms with strategic investors at time of privatization: ownership structure (weighted averages) 
time of 
privatization 
1997 1998 1999 
strategic investor 53.28 38.57 55.079 55.40 
private firms -- - 10.67 
individual trepreneurs en 2.86 1.16 -- 
other utside vestorso in -7.49 25.704 10.05 
Supervisory Board members* 7.56 28.35 0.227 1.32 
Executive Board members 3.50 2.83 -11. 67 
other managerial employees 26.30 10.97 1.716 1.73 
non-managerial employees 6.51 10.63 17.274 6.24 
* Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 19. Firms that gained strategic investors: initial ownership structure (weighted averages) 
Minimum Maximum Mean Standard 
Deviation 
strategic investor 0 0 0.00 0.00 
individual entrepreneurs 0 0 0.00 0.00 
other outside investors 0 15 4.34 6.44 
Supervisory Board members 1 69 10.47 19.03 
Executive Board members 2 15 4.91 3.39 
other managerial employees 0 41 21.65 13.23 
non-managerial employees 10 88 58.63 26.30 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 20. Firms without strategic investors: initial ownership structure (weighted averages) 
Minimum Maximum Mean Standard 
Deviation 
strategic investor 0 0 0.00 0.00 
individual entrepreneurs 0 80 5.39 12.98 
other outside investors 0 30 1.56 4.68 
Supervisory Board members 0 54 10.72 12.98 
Executive Board members 0 100 11.85 12.61 
other managerial employees 0 37 13.67 9.93 
non-managerial employees 0 99 56.81 25.56 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
17 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
3. Factors in the Post-Privatization Evolution of Ownership 
Structure 
3.1. Motivations for Choice of the EBO 
Privatization Method and Subsequent 
Changes in Ownership Structure 
Employee privatization is a privatization method used 
only when it is chosen by insider actors. What are those 
actors' goals in employing this method of privatization in the 
enterprises where they work? Members of company elites 
were asked about this issue in interviews carried out by the 
Jarosz research team. 
In their responses, managers of the companies declared 
purely material goals aimed at the survival of their enterpris-es. 
Contrary to what might have been expected, such issues 
as independence of the firm, propertization and mobilization 
of employees, etc., were mentioned very rarely. But even if 
the main actors in state-owned enterprises were not advo-cates 
of employee ownership, the employee leasing path was 
attractive for them because, on the one hand, it was a rela-tively 
easy privatization method (especially for small and 
medium-sized enterprises), and on the other hand, it elimi-nated 
the threat posed by outsiders, thus minimizing the 
impact of privatization on existing interests and power struc-tures. 
This path was also attractive for non-managerial 
employees because it gave them a chance to acquire a title to 
part of the enterprise's property and opened up the prospect 
of material profits from dividends and capital gains. 
It took some time, however, for managers to become 
aware of the links between share ownership and authority 
in a capitalist system. Once this became clear to them, they 
began to concentrate shares in their hands more actively. By 
the mid-1990s, this process of "economization of mentality" 
was more or less complete. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
In addition to the incentive for management to acquire 
shares in order to consolidate its power, there are various 
factors that can contribute, alternatively, to the perpetua-tion 
of the initial (rather dispersed) ownership structure or 
to particular types of changes, while others can have 
ambivalent impacts on ownership changes. One variable we 
will look at as having a possible effect on both ownership 
changes and other types of activity in the firm is unioniza-tion. 
This is due to the fact that unionization can be seen as 
a measure of employee power which may compound the 
effects of the power that employees exercise as owners in 
the companies of this sample. As we see from table 21, a 
large number of the companies – almost half – lack unions 
altogether. 
In Table 22, we categorize a number of psychological 
and behavioral factors, as well as factors related to the legal 
environment, with respect to their impact on the evolution 
of the ownership structures of employee-leased companies. 
We believe that the patterns of ownership structure evolu-tion 
observed in employee-leased companies are to a large 
extent determined by those factors. 
Nevertheless, the analyzed group of companies is 
quite heterogeneous. It varies with respect to size, sec-toral 
affiliation, financial condition and many other specif-ic 
factors. In Sections 3.2 to 3.4, therefore, we analyze 
the impact of those factors, as well as unionization, to find 
reasons for particular deviations from the most common 
pattern of evolution (presented at the beginning of the 
previous section). In Section 3.5 we look at methods for 
ownership transformations (including trade in shares and 
issues of new shares), and in Sections 3.6 and 3.7 we 
attempt to investigate the factors behind transitions to 
management domination and strategic owner presence in 
particular. 
Table 21. Firms with no unions, by year 
Number Percent N 
At time of privatization 24 30.8 78 
1997 21 26.9 78 
1998 47 43.5 108 
1999 24 38.7 62 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
18 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
Table 22. Chief factors behind perpetuation and change of the initial ownership structure of employee-leased companies 
3.2. Initial Ownership Structure 
We begin our analysis with an investigation of the ques-tion 
of path dependency: how does the initial ownership 
structure at the moment of privatization (in terms of domi-nance 
of a certain group of owners) influence the further 
evolution of ownership structures? Our analysis began with 
a presentation of the transition matrix in Table 9, which 
showed that outside strategic investors and top manage-ment 
are steadily gaining ground (although the position of 
the latter seems to have stabilized and may even be begin-ning 
to decline), and non-managerial employees are steadily 
losing it. In Table 23, we take a closer look at the evolution 
of the ownership structure in the companies, grouping them 
with respect to the type of owner dominant at the time of 
privatization. 
Companies with a concentrated insider pattern of initial 
ownership also seem to tend towards the average owner-ship 
structure for the whole sample, although in manager-dominated 
companies the share of managers fell more 
rapidly than elsewhere in the period 1997–1999. Interest-ingly, 
it is in these companies that outside strategic investors 
had the least opportunities to acquire shares. 
The direction of some processes in these two groups of 
companies differs from that in the group of initial strategic 
investors' dominance, where insider shareholders have 
practically disappeared and almost two thirds of the shares 
are now concentrated in the strategic investor's hands. 
Changes in the shares of managers and outside investors 
have, as experience shows, two opposite vectors: on one 
hand, recently more and more strategic outsiders, especially 
in small firms, have become strategic insiders by acquiring 
top managerial posts in the companies. This can be seen 
when analyzing the unweighted ownership structure data: 
comparing to the previous year, in 1999 the unweighted 
share of strategic investors fell almost two times from 63.4 
to 38.1 percent. On the other hand, newly nominated mem-bers 
of the Executive Board are often formally not emp-loyees 
of the companies for taxation reasons. In initially out-sider- 
dominated companies, managers could attempt to buy 
shares from strategic outsiders in order to regain control, 
while some strategic outsider investors could have become 
disillusioned with the companies and begun to sell their 
shares. Finally, changes in proportions between managers 
and non-managerial employees could be caused by – among 
other things – rotation of managerial posts among insiders. 
3.3. Sector, Company Size, 
and Unionization 
The next table shows the trends in ownership changes 
by sector. We see that construction companies are the most 
"outsiderized" in the whole sample, while in services firms 
were not able to find a strategic external investor. In manu-facturing 
and trade we see some increase in outsider share- 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Factors Perpetuation Change 
Mentality and behavior 
“Legacy” of state-owned 
enterprise 
- organizational structure 
- structures of power and influence 
- old mentality of insiders 
Changes in the 
position of various 
insider groups 
- fear of outsiders - property factor: ownership = power 
- reconfiguration of functions and tasks 
- insiders have to adapt to new conditions 
- perception of outsiders as representing an 
opportunity for new investments, 
management techniques, etc. 
Legal environment 
Privatization law - employee leasing is insider-dominated 
- corporate partners and foreigners barred 
from participation in privatization 
- lower leasing fees (since 1997) 
- faster transfer of title to assets to 
employee-leased company (since 1997) 
- outsiders should hold at least 20 percent of 
shares (since 1997) 
- faster transfer of title to assets to 
employee-leased company (since 1997) 
Commercial Code - companies’ charters can contain 
restrictions on circulation of shares 
- new organizational structure 
- system of property rights 
- mechanisms of raising capital, share issues 
and share trading
19 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 23. Evolution of ownership structure, by initial ownership structure of the companies (weighted averages; %) 
holdings, especially non-strategic, but still the biggest share 
of property remains in the hands of insiders. 
Company size is often regarded as very strong factor deter-mining 
various characteristics of enterprise behavior. We there-fore 
looked at the relationship between the degree of concen-tration 
and firm size (measured by employment). The only con-sistent 
correlation is the positive one between EQ3 and size at 
the time of privatization and in 1997, which is easily explained: 
Given low levels of personal savings at the beginning of the 
CASE Reports No. 47 
transformation, it was more difficult for an individual or small 
group of individuals to buy a large block of shares in a large com-pany 
than in a small firm. It is also clear (see Section 4.3) that 
management ownership on the average appears in relatively 
small companies, while strategic investors appear in companies 
whose average employment is above the sample average. 
Is there a relationship between the direction of owner-ship 
structure changes and size? In table 25, we show the 
ownership structure evolution in three groups of companies 
Strategic investor Other 
outsiders Managers Non-managerial 
employees 
Initial strategic investors’ dominance 
Initial 53.3 2.9 37.4 6.5 
1997 33.8 9.9 47.2 9.1 
1998 48.9 33.9 0.3 16.9 
1999 70.6 16.8 3.4 5.6 
Initial managerial dominance 
Initial 0.0 13.4 59.2 27.4 
1997 1.9 14.5 65.4 18.2 
1998 0.1 25.3 51.3 23.3 
1999 3.6 26.0 45.5 25.0 
Initial non-managerial employee dominance 
Initial 0.0 3.9 25.4 70.7 
1997 7.0 12.4 28.1 52.6 
1998 16.2 12.0 32.7 39.1 
1999 12.8 21.0 27.3 38.9 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 24. Evolution of ownership structure, by branch (weighted averages; %) 
Strategic investor Other outsiders Managers Non-managerial 
employees 
Manufacturing 
Initial 0.7 9.5 33.0 56.9 
1997 1.8 12.4 39.2 46.6 
1998 4.5 21.3 38.3 35.9 
1999 7.5 25.6 31.5 35.4 
Construction 
Initial 2.8 4.9 31.7 60.7 
1997 23.3 17.5 31.5 27.8 
1998 28.6 17.6 24.2 29.6 
1999 32.4 21.1 22.0 24.0 
Trade 
Initial 1.3 1.8 46.0 51.0 
1997 0.1 9.9 57.2 31.9 
1998 7.0 12.4 53.6 27.0 
1999 8.1 22.8 44.2 24.9 
Services 
Initial 0.0 1.7 29.3 69.1 
1997 0.0 11.8 28.1 60.1 
1998 0.0 10.6 42.9 46.5 
1999 0.0 16.1 33.3 50.6 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
20 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
Table 25. Evolution of ownership structure, by size of companies (%) 
Strategic investor Other outsiders Managers Non-managerial 
– small, medium-sized, and large21. As it turns out, the dif-ferences 
between the first two groups are not very great. In 
small and medium-sized companies, we observe an extend-ed 
period of accelerated propertization of managers in 
1997–1998. Large companies seem to have undergone a 
more dynamic evolution, with a much larger share going to 
strategic investors, and the managerial share falling in 
1997–1998. 
It is very hard to explain differences in ownership 
changes with respect to sector and size, although these vari-ables 
undoubtedly affect the processes observed. In the 
course of the study conducted by the Jarosz team, a hypoth-esis 
was formulated that different patterns of ownership 
transformations are determined primarily by sector and 
number of employees. The hypothesized relationships are 
illustrated in Table 2622. The author of this hypothesis, 
Juliusz Gardawski, assumes that "there is a certain optimum 
ownership structure for small and medium-sized firms 
established as a result of privatization of state-owned enter-prises" 
23 and that this optimal structure is determined pri-marily 
by social relationships within the firm24. 
In Table 27, we present an analysis of ownership changes 
with respect to sector and size. This table shows that the 
situation is far more complex and not always consistent with 
the relationships hypothesized by Gardawski. Our results 
are different for all of manufacturing and for most construc-tion 
and trade firms. Additionally, it must be noted that sev-eral 
subgroups are too small to be representative; some are 
21 We define small companies as having up to 100 employees, medium-sized companies as having 101–200 employees, and large companies as 
CASE Reports No. 47 
having more than 200 employees. 
22 Gardawski (2000), 163. 
23 Ibid., 158. Here Gardawski assumes that almost all directly privatized companies are small or medium-sized. 
24 Ibid, 151–158. 
employees 
Small 
Initial 2.7 5.6 36.6 55.2 
1997 2.1 5.7 40.8 51.4 
1998 2.6 9.3 45.1 43.0 
1999 4.7 10.8 40.1 44.4 
Medium-sized 
Initial 1.8 6.4 38.4 53.4 
1997 2.0 13.9 45.1 39.0 
1998 2.4 10.0 46.8 40.8 
1999 4.4 19.3 40.6 35.7 
Large 
Initial 1.2 6.1 32.6 60.1 
1997 7.7 13.4 36.6 42.1 
1998 15.7 20.0 33.0 31.3 
1999 17.6 24.7 27.3 30.2 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 26. Ownership patterns in employee-leased companies in 1999 (Juliusz Gardawski) 
Sector Size of employment Form of ownership 
Manufacturing 
Small 
Medium-sized 
Large 
Investor companiesa 
Manager companies 
Manager-investor companies 
Construction 
Small 
Medium-sized 
Large 
Manager-employee companies 
Trade 
Small 
Medium-sized 
Large 
Manager companies 
Manager-investor companies 
Investor companies 
a By "investors" we understand external investors (outsiders). 
Source: Gardawski (2000), 163.
21 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 27. Ownership structure in employee-leased companies, by sector and number of employees, in 1999 (%) 
Number of employees Strategic investor Other outsiders Managers 
made up of only a single firm. In fact, only two groups of 
companies bear out Gardawski's hypothesis: small con-struction 
and medium-sized trade firms. 
Moreover, there is significant correlation between size 
and sector themselves. By the end of 1998, the average 
company in manufacturing employed 337 persons, in con-struction 
194, in trade 157, and in services 101 persons (the 
average for the whole sample was 203 persons). 
Finally, unionization is negatively correlated with the top 
management share at the time of privatization and in mid- 
1997, and negatively correlated with the non-managerial 
employee share in 1999. It is, however, not clear whether 
employee power resulting from unionization directly pre-vents 
management from accumulating employee shares, or 
whether the ownership effect is not due indirectly to union 
power, by virtue of unions' preventing layoffs (unionization 
is also negatively correlated with employment changes 
between the time of privatization and the end of 1996), and 
thus preventing worker shareholders from becoming out-sider 
shareholders. Interestingly, unionization is not corre-lated 
with TRSI, indicating that unions do not constitute a 
barrier to the entry of strategic investors. 
3.4. Profitability 
There are also strong correlations between size and 
sector on one hand and the financial situation in the com-panies 
on the other, reflecting the external conditions in 
which companies in various groups were operating. The 
simplest and most rigorous measure of financial perfor-mance 
is net profit (after payment of all liabilities except 
leasing obligations). If we divide the companies into two 
groups, those with net profits and those with net losses, 
we see that by the end of 1998, the best situation was 
found in services, where there were no loss-making com-panies 
at all. In construction, 12 percent of the firms had 
losses, in trade – 27 percent, and in manufacturing – 31 
percent. Bigger companies more often had losses than the 
smaller ones: among large firms 23 percent were loss-making, 
medium-sized – 17 percent, and among small 
firms – 15 percent. These figures confirm the existence of 
cross-correlations between the three variables (size, sec-tor, 
and financial performance). 
Table 28 shows the evolution of ownership structures 
in companies grouped according to net profits or losses in 
1993. This year was chosen as a starting point for com-parison 
because it is the earliest year for which econom-ic 
data in Database 2 is available. Selection of the earliest 
possible data allows us to minimize the impact of subse-quent 
ownership changes on the financial situation of the 
firms. 
In this table we see that initially in loss-bearing compa-nies 
there were no outside investors at all, although these 
companies were undoubtedly in great need of financial 
resources; outsiders were probably not interested in 
acquiring such enterprises. In 1997–1998, 7 to 9 percent of 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Non-managerial 
employees 
Industry 
Up to 100 employees – 4.3 57.7 38.0 
101-200 employees 21.4 38.6 27.1 12.9 
More than 200 
6.6 25.9 29.8 37.7 
employees 
Construction 
Up to 100 employees 10.1 15.2 28.3 46.4 
101-200 employees 27.6 3.1 44.9 24.4 
More than 200 
38.4 27.2 14.5 19.1 
employees 
Trade 
Up to 100 employees 7.8 20.9 36.5 34.9 
101-200 employees 15.5 31.4 35.8 17.3 
More than 200 
– 13.9 56.2 29.9 
employees 
Services 
Up to 100 employees – 23.8 26.6 49.6 
101-200 employees – 15.1 28.3 56.6 
More than 200 
– 13.0 41.2 45.8 
employees 
Two biggest shareholder groups in each category of companies are marked bold-italic. 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
22 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
Table 28. Evolution of ownership structure, by net loss vs. net profit (weightted averages; %) 
Strategic 
Investor 
these companies already had strategic investors, and by 
1999 as many as 50 percent did – mostly at the cost of man-agers 
which were selling their shares. The very quick 
growth of the share of non-strategic outsiders before 1999 
is most likely due to large-scale layoffs in those companies. 
At the same time, the shares of managers and non-manage-rial 
employees decreased very significantly: by 1999, the for-mer 
group lost almost two thirds of their initial amount of 
shares, and the latter group lost more than two thirds of ini-tially 
possessed shares. 
In the group of profitable companies, slow growth of 
shares of outside strategic investors is striking. It seems that 
the need for such investors is usually only felt when the sit-uation 
in the company is very poor. 
We conclude, therefore, that the most powerful factor 
determining the dynamics of ownership changes in the 
companies is their economic condition. When a company 
is doing well, the internal relations in the company are sta-ble, 
and none of the main actors has an incentive to 
undermine this stability. When a company encounters 
severe economic problems, the actors begin to look 
around for solutions. The most obvious one is to find an 
external investor who brings an injection of fresh capital. 
When major inside shareholders and stakeholders have to 
choose between survival of the company and preservation 
of their shares, they tend to choose survival, at the same 
time trying to keep some shares for themselves. In such 
conditions, moreover, non-managerial employees lose 
every possible motivation for them to hold on to their 
shares: the shares never allowed them to participate in 
management, and now they don't even bring dividends. In 
earlier studies, a strong positive correlation was discov-ered 
between lack of dividends and selling of shares by 
non-managerial employees25. 
3.5. Methods for Ownership 
Transformation: Share Sales and New 
Issues 
In most cases trade in shares was not a completely spon-taneous 
process. The main actors behind the privatization of 
the companies took care to minimize the risk of unwanted 
changes in the ownership structure in their firms. The char-ters 
of the great majority of companies (87 percent) con-tained 
restrictions on such trade. They were aimed at three 
main goals: (1) not to allow shares to "leak" outside the firm; 
(2) to facilitate ownership concentration in the hands of 
management elites, and (3) to prevent the emergence of 
new large shareholders within the firm who could under-mine 
the position of governing groups. Several methods 
were used to this end: right of first refusal by current own-ers; 
requiring share owners selling their shares to receive 
prior permission at the shareholders' meeting, or from the 
supervisory board (sometimes even the executive board); 
prohibition of share sales to outsiders, etc. Nevertheless, 
the processes of ownership redistribution often proved to 
be stronger than the restrictions, even in the companies 
where all trade in shares had been prohibited. Those 
restrictions only delayed changes (especially sales of shares 
to outsiders), but could not stop them completely26. 
Post-privatization ownership transformations, more-over, 
were achieved not only by trade in existing shares but 
also by issues of new ones. Nineteen firms had carried out 
new share issues by mid-1997. Of these, 11 were closed 
and 3 were public (we have no information on the charac-ter 
of five of the new issues). Of the 11 closed issues, recip-ients 
of new shares in all eight firms that we have informa-tion 
about were limited to persons already holding shares. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
25 See Kozarzewski (1999), 85–86. 
26 For more, see ibid., 87. 
Other 
outsiders Managers Non-managerial 
employees 
Net losses in 1993 
Initial – – 49.9 50.1 
1997 7.4 8.1 55.9 28.6 
1998 9.0 24.6 50.8 15.6 
1999 50.0 17.0 17.9 15.1 
Net profit in 1993 
Initial 0.2 5.8 31.0 63.0 
1997 5.8 13.2 35.2 45.9 
1998 13.9 16.8 34.1 35.2 
1999 11.8 22.9 31.7 33.6 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
23 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 29. Management-owned companies and entire sample, by population of headquarter location 
Most frequently, new share issues serve to promote con-centration 
of shares (especially in the hands of management 
and strategic investors), as evidenced by the positive corre-lations 
between new issues (the dummy variable NEW) and 
variables such as TRCON, TRSI, GRSI, and TRM. Correla-tion 
analysis also shows a positive correlation between new 
issues and company size, a negative correlation between 
new issues and the size of top management's share at the 
time of privatization, a negative correlation between NEW 
and YR1 (meaning that the earlier the privatization took 
place, the greater the likelihood that a new issue has 
occurred in the meantime), and a positive correlation 
between new issues and a transition to domination by a 
strategic investor (the dummy variable TRSI). 
Looking more closely at the latter relationship, we see 
that of the 13 companies with strategic investors as of mid- 
1997, six had carried out new issues, and seven had not. We 
have information on the character of four of them, and all 
four were closed. Of the three firms that declared having 
had a public listing, none had a strategic investor. It appears, 
therefore, that strategic investors appear in employee-owned 
companies through new share issues as often as 
through buying out the employee shareholders, and that 
employee-owned companies listing publicly are not looking 
for, and/or not finding, strategic investors. 
3.6. Top Management Domination 
Geography does not appear to be a factor in the transi-tion 
to management domination. If we look at the size of 
the cities in which the companies in which Executive Board 
members held at least 20% of the shares in 1997 are head-quartered, 
we see that there seems to be virtually no dif-ference 
between the firms dominated by management and 
the sample as a whole. 
With respect to branch, the only apparently significant 
difference between the firms dominated by management 
and the sample as a whole is the larger number of trade 
companies and smaller number of construction companies 
among the former. 
In almost all of the firms in which top management held 
a share of over 20% in mid-1997, respondents said that the 
firm was operating on a competitive market (24 such 
responses). Only one respondent claimed to be a monopo-list, 
and four claimed to be oligopolists. 
In conclusion, management ownership does not seem to 
be related to geographic factors or such economic factors 
as branch or market share. As we shall see, the situation 
with respect to companies in which strategic investors have 
appeared is somewhat different. 
3.7. Companies with Strategic Investors 
As in the case of management-owned companies, loca-tion 
seems to constitute no special advantage in finding an 
investor (Table 31). 
By contrast, as we see in table 32, there are significant 
differences between companies with strategic investors and 
the sample as a whole with respect to branch. Manufactur- 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Management-owned companies Whole sample 
POP1 3 (9.7%) 9 (8.3%) 
POP2 5 (16.1%) 16 (14.7%) 
POP3 11 (35.5%) 28 (25.7%) 
POP4 3 (9.7%) 23 (21.1%) 
POP5 9 (29.0%) 33 (30.3%) 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 30. Management-owned companies and entire sample, by branch 
Management-owned companies Whole sample 
Number Percent Number Percent 
Food processing 1 3.2 8 7.3 
Other manufacturing 7 22.6 21 19.0 
Construction 5 16.1 33 30.0 
Transport 1 3.2 3 2.7 
Trade 12 38.7 26 23.6 
Services 2 6.5 8 7.3 
Consulting and design 3 9.7 11 10.0 
Total 31 110 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
24 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
Companies with strategic investors Whole sample 
POP1 2 (11.8%) 9 (8.3%) 
POP2 2 (11.8%) 16 (14.7%) 
POP3 3 (17.6%) 28 (25.7%) 
POP4 5 (29.4%) 23 (21.1%) 
POP5 5 (29.4%) 33 (30.3%) 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Companies with strategic investors Whole sample 
Number Percent Number Percent 
Food processing 3 17.6 8 7.3 
Other manufacturing 4 23.5 21 19.0 
Construction 7 41.2 33 30.0 
Transport -- 3 2.7 
Trade 3 17.6 26 23.6 
Services -- 8 7.3 
Consulting nd esign a d -- 11 10.0 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Table 31. Companies with strategic owners and entire sample, by population of headquarter location 
Table 32. Companies with strategic owners and entire sample, by branch 
ing and construction are more strongly represented among 
the group with strategic investors than in the sample as a 
whole. Trade is represented more weakly, and services are 
not represented at all. 
Market share does not seem to differentiate companies 
with strategic investors from those dominated by Executive 
Board members. Of the 13 companies with strategic 
investors as of mid-1997, one claimed to be a monopolist, 
three claimed to be oligopolists, and nine said they were 
operating on highly competitive markets. Correlation analy-sis 
yields no evidence of a relationship between market 
share and the presence of strategic investors. 
There appears to be evidence that size (employment) is 
a factor in attracting strategic investors (positive correla-tions 
between TRSI and end-of-year employment in 1996 
and 1998), but there is also evidence that strategic investors 
have a positive effect on employment (no correlation 
between 1996 end-of-year employment and SI, but a posi-tive 
correlation between end-of-year employment in 1998 
and SI; also, a positive correlation between SI at the time of 
privatization and employment changes between the year 
before privatization and the end of 1996). The direction of 
causality therefore seems very difficult to ascertain, and we 
cannot say whether larger companies attract investors, or 
whether investors increase employment (or both). 
Respondents from companies with strategic investors 
were asked whether they had had trade relationships with 
the strategic investor previous to the latter's acquisition of 
shares. Of the 17 firms, we obtained no answer to this 
question from nine, and the remaining eight were evenly 
divided between those that had and those that had not 
maintained such contacts prior to the investor's acquisition. 
These data are clearly insufficient to allow us to draw any 
conclusions.
25 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
4. The Economic Performance of Employee-Leased 
Companies 
In this section we will review both previous studies of 
employee-leased companies in Poland and our own 
research results in order to evaluate the economic perfor-mance 
of the companies and assess, at least tentatively, the 
relationships between this performance and various factors, 
including ownership structure and ownership changes. 
4.1. Profitability 
The financial results of employee-owned companies seem 
to be generally fairly sound in spite of the burden of lease pay-ments 
and the restructuring needs facing all firms emerging 
from Poland's former state-owned sector. The data in Table 
33 allow one to compare the financial situation in employee-owned 
companies and state enterprises preparing for privati-zation 
by the leasing method with that in companies that have 
undergone capital privatization and companies participating in 
the National Investment Fund program. 
These data show that profitability indices for the average 
Polish employee-leased company have been close to – and 
Table 33. Gross profitability (ratio of gross profit or loss to total revenues) 
Employee-leased companies 6.4 6.3 6.0 4.9 4.5 
State enterprises currently 
undergoing direct privatization 3.1 0.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 
Capital-privatized companies 4.9 6.5 4.4 6.3 4.9 
Companies designated for 
participation in NIF program 4.2 2.5 0.23 1.6 -0.5 
Source: Kozarzewski et al. (2000), 49. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
sometimes even better than – the average indices for firms 
privatized by the capital method. In addition, they are much 
higher than those of state enterprises and firms participating 
in the NIF program27. 
It is, however, worth noting that this profitability index 
has been consistently falling from year to year, and that prof-itability 
was best for those types of enterprises which were 
least typical among the group of employee-leased compa-nies; 
i.e., among large industrial enterprises employing over 
300 persons28. 
4.2. Investment Activity 
High interest rates and considerable imperfections in the 
Polish banking sector rendered access to funds for the 
financing of investments difficult for practically all Polish 
enterprises, and especially small businesses, throughout the 
first half of the 1990s29. During this period, it was often 
claimed that leased companies in Poland were characterized 
by exceptionally low levels of investment activity. One group 
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 
27 See Ministry of Ownership Transformation (1995), 3. The vast difference between reported financial results for firms preparing for liquidation 
privatization and those preparing for capital privatization may reflect the use of "creative accounting" due to the different incentives facing the two types 
of firms: while the managers of the former type of firms are, for the most part, preparing to purchase the firm themselves, they have an incentive to 
underreport the financial results and value of the assets of the firm with a view toward negotiating as low a price as possible with the Ministry of Own-ership 
Transformation; the managers of firms being prepared for capital privatization, however, are looking for outsiders to purchase the firm and there-fore 
wish to make the firm as attractive as possible. 
28 See Pietrewicz (1995), 54. 
29 See "Eyeing up the risk".
26 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
of researchers found a tendency to low investment and 
decapitalization in employee-owned companies compared 
with the national economy as a whole30. 
However, as their name implies, leased companies must 
make regular – and sometimes very burdensome – lease 
payments, to which a large portion of profits must be dedi-cated, 
thus limiting the possibilities for using retained earn-ings 
to finance investment; additionally, these firms have 
exceptional difficulty (in comparison with other privately-owned 
firms) in obtaining bank credits, since (at least in the 
early phase of their operation) they do not own, but only 
lease, their physical capital and thus possess inadequate col-lateral31. 
Some of the consequences of the debt burden 
incurred as a result of the leasing construction of most 
employee-leased companies are investigated in the Jarosz 
group's research, which includes analysis of the liquidity 
indices for their sample of firms in comparison with nation-al 
averages. The current ratio (i.e., the ratio of current 
assets to current liabilities) was, on the average, not parti-cularly 
good, but better than the national average in 1993; in 
addition, the national average was falling at that time, while 
the index for the sample of leased companies was rising. (It 
should, however, be noted that the average current ratio in 
employee-leased companies in the trade and services sec-tors 
was much lower than the sample average; the index for 
these firms was on the threshold of becoming threateningly 
low and was, moreover, below the national average.) The 
same situation was observed with regard to the quick ratio 
(i.e., the ratio of current assets minus average reserves to 
current liabilities). Similarly, the ratio of long-term debt to 
equity was found to be quite high, averaging 2.47 for the 
entire sample for 1993 (7.52 in firms employing 100 persons 
or fewer)32. 
Various governments have made some attempts to alle-viate 
this problem. The reductions of the interest rate paid 
on the leases have been discussed above (in Section 1). In 
addition, a measure to stimulate investment was included in 
the 1993 regulatory changes. According to these provisions, 
a leased company can apply to its founding organ for a 
reduction of the interest payments owed by the company as 
a result of postponements during the first two years of the 
leasing period if its investment expenditures out of profits 
amount to at least 50 percent of its net profit. The new pri-vatization 
act of 30 August, 1996, also included a provision 
intended to enhance the creditworthiness of employee-leased 
firms when applying for bank loans. According to 
Article 52, the title to the assets being leased may be trans-ferred 
to the leased firm after it has paid only one third of 
the obligations resulting from the leasing contract if two 
years have passed since the signing of the leasing contract; 
this term may even be shortened to one year if the firm has 
paid at least one half of those obligations. 
In addition to the difficulties arising from the lack of col-lateral, 
it is worth noting that the leasing method of privati-zation 
is explicitly intended for firms which are considered 
to require little investment33. 
Bearing all of the foregoing in mind, it is difficult to con-duct 
research on, or make conclusive statements about the 
level of investment in leased companies – or, for that mat-ter, 
any Polish companies (except in the case of foreign-owned 
companies where the level of investment is general-ly 
so high in comparison with other privatized companies 
that it cannot fail to escape notice) – due to the fact that reg-ulation 
of depreciation allowances (not reformed until the 
passage of the 1999 corporate income tax act) made it 
unprofitable for companies to show investment expendi-tures 
as such on their income statements (tax liabilities were 
decreased by including such expenditures on the cost side 
instead). However, already in the early 1990s there was 
some evidence that an "elite" of leased companies was 
investing on a scale comparable with that observed in enter-prises 
privatized by the capital method but without foreign 
investors34. Moreover, anecdotal evidence indicates that as 
more and more employee-owned companies pay off their 
Table 34. Average value of investment projects, per employee (in PLN) 
30 See Pietrewicz (1995), 39–40. 
31 See Jarosz (ed.) (1995), 16. 
32 See Pietrewicz (1995), 43–48. 
33 See Supreme Control Chamber (1993), 9, Uchwa³a Sejmu Rzeczypospolitej Polskiej z dnia 12 lutego 1993 r. w sprawie podstawowych kierun-ków 
prywatyzacji w 1993 r., and Kierunki prywatyzacji maj¹tku pañstwowego w 1995 r. 
34 See Szomburg et al. (1994), 39, 54. Investment spending in capital-privatized firms with foreign investors was vastly greater than that in capital-privatized 
CASE Reports No. 47 
firms without foreign investors. 
Mean Minimum Maximum Standard 
Deviation 
N 
Sum 1992-1997 6.43 0.00 128.62 13.4625 110 
1998 4.66 0.00 128.44 13.6108 106 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
27 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 35. Number of firms that obtained investment credit 
leases, acquiring legal titles to the property which they had 
been leased and thereby gaining the ability to secure loans 
with collateral, their access to commercial credit has grown 
considerably, thus considerably increasing the level of 
investment. 
We try to investigate some of these questions using the 
data in Database 2. 
Table 34 provides evidence that a considerable acce-leration 
of investment had oc-curred by the late 1990s. 
The mean investment project underway in 1998 had a 
per-employee value of about two thirds the per-employ-ee 
value for all such projects in the years 1992–1996. 
Table 35 shows a similar trend with respect to the num-ber 
of firms in the sample that had obtained credit. 
Of 108 firms that answered the appropriate question, 
26 firms had paid off their leases by mid-1998 (24.1% of 
valid responses). Did this increase their access to credit? 
Perhaps too little time has elapsed since the payoff of the 
leases for statistical relationships to emerge from the 
data. At any rate, there is no correlation between the fact 
that a company has paid off its lease on the one hand and 
either 1998 per-employee investment spending or financ-ing 
of such investment by credit on the other. 
The question of dividend payments is a difficult one. On 
one hand, the failure to make dividend payments may repre-sent 
an abuse of shareholder rights by management (via use of 
"creative accounting" to "artificially" increase the level of costs, 
thus reducing profits and thereby tax liability and the pool of 
funds to which shareholders could exercise a claim). On the 
other hand, the opportunity cost of dividend payments is 
decreased funds available for investment, and therefore 
"asceticism" in the area of dividend payments may represent a 
pro-investment orientation of the shareholders and a consen-sus 
on their part to favor investment over the immediate grat-ification 
of dividends. As table 37 indicates, such asceticism is 
widespread among employee-owned companies. 
However, the data yield no statistical evidence that this 
asceticism leads to greater investment. There is no correla-tion 
between the dividend payments in either 1998 or 1999 
and per-employee investment spending in 1998, and there 
is actually a positive correlation between 1995 and 1996 
dividends and 1996 investment spending. (Similarly, there is 
a positive correlation in 1999 between the dummy indicat-ing 
whether a dividend was paid and the variable measuring 
expansion into new markets.) 
Does ownership make a difference with regard to the pay-ment 
of dividends (i.e., do different types of owners have dif-ferent 
preferences with regard to tradeoff between invest-ment 
and immediate gratification in the form of dividends)? 
There is a negative correlation between the dummy indicating 
whether a dividend was paid in 1997 on the one hand and the 
share belonging to non-managerial employees at the time of 
privatization and in 1997, and a positive correlation between 
the 1997 dividend dummy and the 1997 shares of strategic 
investors. On the other hand, there is negative correlation 
between the ratio of the dividend payment to the net profit 
Table 37. Number of firms that made, and did not make, dividend payments, 1997–1998 
Not paid 55 50.0 57 52.8 74 67.3 
Paid 55 50.0 51 47.2 36 32.7 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Number Percent N 
1992-1996 31 33.3 93 
1998 21 24.4 86 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 36. Average investment spending, 1993–1996 (in millions of pre-1995 zlotys) 35 
Mean Minimum Maximum Standard 
Deviation 
N 
1993 303.51 0 5200 864.87 70 
1994 476.91 0 10840 1517.96 88 
1995 379.72 0 10989 1227.71 110 
1996 601.74 0 17874 2253.85 110 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
1997 1998 1999 
Number Percent Number Percent Number Percent 
35 This table is based on figures from the companies' income statements for the relevant years. Unfortunately, for the years 1997 and 1998, we do 
not have such figures, but rather the total value of current investment projects.
28 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
and the strategic investor share, and a positive correlation 
between this ratio and the worker share. We can therefore 
conclude that in 1997 companies dominated by workers were 
less likely to pay dividends than those dominated by strategic 
investors, but if they did pay them, they tended to pay out a 
higher percentage of the profits in the form of dividends. In 
contrast, there is a positive correlation between the dividend 
dummy for 1999 and both the percentage of the workforce 
owning shares (OWN) and the percentage of the workforce 
belonging to a trade union (UNI) in 1999. So overall, these 
relations are rather ambiguous. 
Less ambiguous, and very surprising, is the complete 
absence of any correlation between various measures of 
strategic investor shares and their growth on the one 
hand and investment variables or paying off the lease on 
the other. In other words, there is no statistical evidence 
that the presence of a strategic investor actually leads to 
more investment! In contrast, for 1999 (but not for 1997), 
there is a positive correlation between concentration in 
the hands of management (TRM, but not GRMAN) and 
investment spending. Interestingly, per-employee invest-ment 
spending for the period 1992–1996 is positively cor-related 
with EQ336 – the least concentrated ownership 
structure – whereas in 1999 it is negatively correlated 
with OWN. Evidence concerning the relationship 
between the degree of non-managerial employees' partic-ipation 
in ownership and investment is therefore rather 
ambiguous. 
There is consistently a positive correlation between the 
value of investment projects and the use of credit as a means 
of financing them, which would tend to support the claims 
that lack of access to credit is one of the main explanatory 
factors for the low rate of investment in employee-owned 
companies in Poland. Interestingly, use of credit is not cor-related 
with size. In 1999, it was negatively correlated with 
the number of layoffs between the year of privatization and 
the end of 1996 (positive correlation with P.C. CH)37, and 
positively correlated with the acquisition by Executive 
Board members of ownership shares exceeding 20% during 
the same period (TRM). 
Finally, investment spending in 1992–1996 and in 1996 
was positively correlated with the size of the firm (employ-ment), 
and investment spending in the period 1992–1996 
was positively correlated with the dummy indicating 
whether a new share issue had occurred during the same 
period (NEW). 
Summarizing the results of this analysis, we conclude 
that size and access to credit do seem to be key variables in 
the determination of the level of investment spending, but 
neither the propensity to pay dividends nor the ownership 
structure seem to be related in any consistent and significant 
way to investment activity. 
4.3. Restructuring and Adjustment 
Activity 
Restructuring and adjustment activity in employee-leased 
firms tended in the first half of the 1990s to be con-centrated 
in increased promotional activity and adjustments 
of a simple, costreducing nature (e.g., employment reduc-tions), 
involving little in the way of introduction of new 
products or significant improvement in the level of technol-ogy38. 
Later, however, an increase in investments of an inno-vative 
nature was found39. 
Employee-owned companies have shown a great deal 
of elasticity in their employment policies, often engaging 
in significant layoffs (in firms that are on the average rela-tively 
small to begin with). Overall, employment in the 
sample consistently fell from year to year, as the table 
below shows. On the average, employment fell between 
Table 38. Average end-of-year employment, by year 
Mean Minimum Maximum Standard 
36 It is also positively correlated with the size of the workforce and the oligopoly dummy. 
37 It is also negatively correlated with the growth in the ownership share of "other" outsiders (GROO), which may further suggest a positive rela-tionship 
CASE Reports No. 47 
between the growth of their share and the number of layoffs (see the discussion in Section 2). 
38 See Pietrewicz (1995), 51–52. 
39 See Krajewski (1998), 108–109, Krajewski (2000), 123–124. 
Deviation 
N 
1992 262.14 6 1749 294.72 76 
1993 226.58 6 1882 275.65 90 
1994 219.74 5 2002 276.77 99 
1995 211.97 3 1942 268.69 104 
1996 206.50 3 1919 262.79 110 
1997 201.32 3 1713 246.79 106 
1998 192.37 2 1693 240.90 110 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
Table 39. Average end-of-year employment in companies owned by top management and strategic investors, by year 
Companies with top management domination Companies with strategic investors 
N Mean Minimum Maximum Mean Minimum Maximum N 
1992 22 184.32 6 723 374.46 21 990 13 
1993 28 163.54 6 643 362.00 21 964 12 
1994 30 151.07 5 606 342.80 21 864 15 
1995 33 144.48 3 624 323.00 21 821 16 
1996 34 151.06 3 629 299.29 31 751 17 
1997 33 158.12 3 638 296.82 34 805 17 
1998 34 139.06 2 627 281.59 34 778 17 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 40. Positive responses to new market expansion question, 1997–1999 
Number of positive responses Number of firms % 
0 42 38.5 
1 31 28.4 
2 25 22.9 
3 11 10.1 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 41. Positive responses to new market expansion question, 1997–1999 
40 In 1997 they were asked if they had acquired them since privatization; in 1998 and 1999 they were asked if they had acquired them in the pre-vious 
year. 
29 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
the end of the year prior to privatization and the end of 
1996 by 13.3%. 
It should be noted that the maximum values are outliers, 
as in 1997 only two companies in the sample had employ-ment 
of over 1000. 
As noted in Section 3.4, unionization is negatively corre-lated 
with employment changes between the time of priva-tization 
and the end of 1996, providing some evidence that 
unions were effective in preventing layoffs, at least early on. 
Later the situation seems to change: while 1997 unioniza-tion 
is positively correlated with employment in the year 
before privatization and at the end of 1996, unionization in 
1999 is not correlated with employment at the end of 1998. 
A comparison of tables 38 and 39 shows that average 
employment in the companies that have attracted strategic 
investors is consistently higher than the sample average, 
while average employment in those owned by top manage-ment 
is consistently below average. These companies are 
similar to the others in the sample, however, in that they 
also consistently reduced employment throughout the ana-lyzed 
period. Moreover, there appears to be no significant 
difference in the rate at which employment was reduced 
over the course of the entire period. 
Two measures of adjustment and restructuring activity 
that we expected to be particularly telling are measures of 
employment in marketing and expansion into new markets. 
Sixty-three firms (57.3% of the sample) had marketing units 
as of mid-1999. The average employment in these units was 
2.12 persons. The existence of a marketing unit and the size 
of that unit were both positively correlated with employ-ment 
at the end of 1998. These variables were not, howev-er, 
correlated with any ownership variables, with invest-ment 
indicators, or with expansion into new markets. 
With respect to new markets, the respondents were 
asked on three occasions whether they had acquired new 
markets40. A majority had (table 40), and almost half of the 
firms that had not acquired new markets were in trade, as 
table 41 shows. 
One was a monopolist, two were oligopolists, and 35 
were in competitive markets. However, as in the case of 
marketing activity, expansion into new markets has little 
correlation with other variables, and the few correlations 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Frequency Percent 
Food processing 2 4.8 
Other manufacturing 5 11.9 
Construction 8 19.0 
Trade 19 45.2 
Services 8 19.0 
Total 42 100.0 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
30 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
which do exist (with EQ2 and OWN) do not seem to admit 
of any explanation. 
Finally, we looked at the question whether concentrated 
ownership had affected ISO quality certification (Table 42). 
In terms of actual certification, there is virtually no dif-ference 
between the percentages of certified firms in the 
three groups; however, a significantly lower proportion of 
firms with strategic investors have no ISO certificate and do 
not plan to obtain one than in the other two groups. More-over, 
a much higher percentage of firms with strategic 
investors is in the process of certification. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Table 42. ISO quality certification by ownership group, 1998 
Top management 
domination 
Strategic investor Whole sample 
Number Percent Number Percent Number Percent 
No data -- 1 5.9 2 1.9 
Certified 4 12.9 2 11.8 13 12.0 
In process of 
certification 
2 6.5 4 23.5 11 10.2 
Intends to obtain 
certificate 
3 9.7 4 23.5 16 14.8 
Not certified and not 
planning certification 
22 71.0 6 35.3 66 61.1 
Total 31 100.0 17 100.0 108 100.0 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
31 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
5. The Relationship between Ownership Structure 
and Productivity: Evidence from the Early 1990s 
In this section we present the results of econometric 
analysis of the relationship between the ownership struc-ture 
of employee-leased companies and productivity41. In 
particular, we would like to know whether the extent of 
participation of non-managerial employees is related to 
enterprise performance. The sample is very well suited to 
such an analysis due to its great diversity with respect to the 
extent of employee participation in share ownership, with 
firms ranging from virtually no employee ownership to 
complete employee ownership. The analysis was carried 
out using data from Database 1. 
5.1. Productivity Analysis: Estimating 
Framework 
We analyze productivity here using an augmented pro-duction 
function framework that has been used in several 
earlier studies analyzing the relation between employee 
participation and productivity42. Ideally43, the logarithmized 
production function estimated is a Cobb-Douglas function: 
lnV lnK lnL Z X it it it it it it = α +α +α +α +α +μ 0 1 2 3 4 
where V denotes value added, K and L represent capital and 
labor inputs, respectively, X is a vector of industry and 
enterprise-specific variables such as dummies for the year 
of production and the branch in which the enterprise oper-ates, 
Z is a vector of participatory variables, firms are 
denoted by the subscript i, the time period in years by t, and 
the residual by μ. 
We estimate the models using Ordinary Least Squares 
(OLS) techniques. Ordinarily, the endogeneity of the inde-pendent 
variables would rule out use of the OLS method. 
However, researchers studying the relation between 
employee participation and productivity use this technique 
due to the fact that it is more robust against specification 
errors than simultaneous equations methods44. 
5.2. Productivity Analysis: The Results 
For this analysis, a fairly large portion of the sample was 
eliminated. This was due to the fact that various branches of 
manufacturing were represented by too small a number of 
firms. Thus, we were left only with firms in construction, 
trade, and services. The results of the OLS estimations are 
reported in Table 43. 
Before discussing these results, some remarks on the 
quality of the data and its implications for our analysis are in 
order. Unfortunately, no measure of capital costs (e.g., 
depreciation) is included in the data. For this reason, con-struction 
of a value added variable was impossible. More-over, 
in a number of studies of labor productivity in trans-forming 
economies, researchers have used sales revenues 
rather than value added in constructing measures of pro-ductivity45. 
This is most likely due to the fact that the manip-ulation 
of profits in post-Communist economies is endemic 
for a number of reasons. Two reasons are: first, the fact that 
an increase in the enterprise's profits entails a proportional 
increase in its tax liability, and second, the fact that some 
portion of profits is often distributed to shareholders in the 
form of dividends. In order to avoid such "losses" to the 
state treasury and shareholders and retain as much money 
in the firm as possible, managers manipulate their accounts. 
These manipulations occur on the cost side (for instance, by 
including some part of investment costs in production 
costs). 
41 A full discussion of this analysis is found in Woodward (1999). An earlier version was published in Woodward (1998). 
42 See Estrin et al. (1987), Conte and Svejnar (1988), and Jones (1993). 
43 Departures from the ideal are discussed in Section 5.2. 
44 In fact, the use of OLS to estimate production functions is generally accepted as appropriate. See Zellner et al. (1966). 
45 See, for example, Brada and Singh (1995), Grosfeld and Nivet (1998). 
CASE Reports No. 47
32 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
Table 43. OLS estimates of productivity effects (using sales revenues instead of value added) 
Variable Construction Trade Non-material services 
lnL 0.981263* 
For this reason, we performed regressions using the nat-ural 
logarithm of sales revenues instead of that of value 
added. With respect to non-participatory variables, we 
observe the following. Population coefficients appear only 
for one sector. We see that here, large population positive-ly 
affects sales, and smaller population negatively affects 
sales. Amortization is significant in only one sector, but its 
coefficient has a negative sign, as one would expect. 
Turning to the ownership variables which are our chief 
interest here, we note, first, that a number of them do not 
appear in the estimations at all, including EQ2 and OWN. 
A coefficient for variable WOR – i.e., the percentage of 
shares held by non-managerial employees – appears in two 
sectors; it is negative, but insignificant, in both. A high 
degree of concentration (EQ1) has a negative relationship 
with productivity in four sectors (significant in two). The 
coefficient for unionization is positive and significant, but 
very small. In one case EQ3 appears, with a coefficient 
which is negative and significant. This result is the only one 
which can be interpreted as evidence of a negative rela-tionship 
between (a relatively) egalitarian ownership struc-ture 
and productivity. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
(10.10735) 
0.429334* 
(3.07973) 
0.62137* 
(5.40815) 
lnK 0.151614* 
(2.38320) 
0.350398* 
(3.20938) 
0.20496* 
(3.47193) 
YEAR 0.208879* 
(2.48804) 
POP2 -1.35048* 
(-3.97939) 
POP5 0.90459* 
(6.02102) 
AMORT -0.02946* 
(-5.76673) 
EQ1 -0.367536* 
(-2.34528) 
-.410853* 
(-2.70768) 
EQ3 -0.495985* 
(-3.09907) 
WOR -0.003266 
(-1.11267) 
-0.00517 
(-1.77634) 
UNI 0.006062* 
(2.53779) 
n 86 52 40 
adjusted R2 .81642831 .78083193 .84440984 
Asterisks indicate coefficients which are statistically significant at the 95 percent confidence level. 
Figures in parentheses are t-statistics. 
Source: Own calculations using Database 1.
33 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
6. Corporate Governance 
6.1. Formation of Corporate Governance 
Bodies 
Privatization, as one of the pillars of the construction of 
the new economic and social relations in Poland's market 
economy, is effective only if it spurs innovation in the man-agement 
of enterprises. Privatization cannot, therefore, be 
seen as a simple matter of transferring shares to private 
hands; rather it involves a play of interests regulated by the 
Commercial Code and business practice: the interests of 
the new owners, in whose hands the chief decision-making 
powers are vested, and those of various stakeholders. 
Mechanisms are set in motion serving to harmonize the 
interests of these main groups. The ownership and stake-holder 
configurations emerging in the context of privatiza-tion 
play a decisive role in determining the firm's fate46, 
shaping authority structures that, in turn, direct the com-panies' 
post-privatization development and orientation. 
Thus, the reorganization of ownership is accompanied by a 
reorganization of management and control structures; the 
question is, how deep and effective is this latter process? 
Of course, this process represents a very complicated 
task. In the most highly developed market economies, corpo-rate 
organizational structures were formed in a longlasting, 
largely spontaneous, process. The organizational structure, 
tasks and functions of management and control bodies were 
subject to permanent evolution directed at ensuring the best 
possible defense of owners' interests. Legislative codification 
of these structures and functions represents a sort of consen-sus 
regarding "best practices" which had already emerged. In 
the post-Communist countries, by contrast, these structures 
were formalized by legislative means, overnight as it were, 
without a preceding phase of spontaneous evolution. 
In contrast to many post-Communist countries, Poland 
inherited, at the outset of its transition, a continental European 
(three-tier) model of corporate governance laid out in its Com-mercial 
Code, dating from the 1930s, which had never been 
suspended by the Communist authorities. However, the leg-islative 
circumstances are of secondary concern to us here. 
More important for our purposes is the mechanism for super-vision 
of the company's executive bodies implied in adoption of 
the continental model. This is particularly important in Poland, 
as the influence of various forms of so-called external control 
(e.g., product and financial markets) is in many cases still not 
fully effective. In such conditions, the efficient functioning of so-called 
internal supervision assumes fundamental importance. 
The basic task of the new body introduced into Polish 
enterprises as a result of ownership transformation – the 
supervisory board – consists in supervision of the compa-ny's 
operations on behalf of – and in the interests of – its 
owners. Lately, more and more frequently opinions are 
expressed that the supervisory board should not confine 
itself to representing exclusively the interests of the own-ers, 
but rather become a platform for coordinating the 
manifold interests in which the company is involved; i.e., to 
be a stakeholder forum. Without entering into a discussion 
on whether, in Polish conditions, the supervisory board 
should shoulder this additional responsibility, we will 
attempt to determine the extent to which such a function 
has been assumed by the supervisory boards in the com-panies 
under review. The formation and definition of the 
supervisory board's goals and functions, of its place among 
other organs of the company, is extremely complicated in 
Poland, where this body faces the brand new task of per-forming 
supervisory functions in the name of the share 
owners, a concern which did not exist in the state-owned 
enterprise. 
The supreme element of the executive line of authority 
– the executive board – has a very wide range of powers 
and is limited only insofar as certain powers are reserved 
for the owners themselves, acting through the sharehold-ers' 
meeting. 
Shareholders' Meeting 
The impact of ownership changes on the composition 
of the general assembly of shareholders is obvious. Partici- 
46 See Frydman and Rapaczynski (1994). 
CASE Reports No. 47
34 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
25% 
33% 19% 
20% 24% 
16% 
80 
70 
60 
50 
40 
30 
20 
10 
pation in shareholders' meetings and the degree of influ-ence 
on decision making at those meetings are strictly 
dependent on the size of one's share in the company's share 
capital. Therefore, the constellation of interests and power 
within this body is implied in the analysis of the ownership 
structure of employee-leased companies. In this section we 
will attempt to describe the general assembly's place with-in 
the authority structure of the firm with respect to other 
organs and interest groups. 
Supervisory Board 
The supervisory board is appointed by the sharehold-ers. 
It is (at least in theory) a supervisory and not a man-agement 
body, despite the fact that, in the nature of things, 
it cannot be excluded from participation in the firm's influ-ence 
structure. 
Based on responses to the Jarosz team's survey, we can 
confirm that a large majority of companies aspire to create, 
at least formally, a corporate governance body with the full 
range of responsibilities, implying that their owners are 
aware of the advantages of separating the ownership and 
control functions. Supervisory boards (which are required 
in companies exceeding certain size limits) exist in 86 per-cent 
of all the companies under review. This conclusion is 
supported by the fact that the minority of companies that 
have dispensed with a supervisory organ are mostly limited 
to the very smallest ones (in terms of employment, charter 
capital and number of owners). 
One of the most important traits of the personal com-position 
of the supervisory boards under review is the very 
high participation of insiders (most notably managerial 
employees). Interestingly, after a drop in their participation 
to 19 percent in 1998 from 33 percent in 1997, we wit-nessed 
an increase to 25 percent in 1999. On the other 
hand, the percentage of board members employed in the 
firm in non-managerial posts has grown steadily over this 
three-year period (16 percent, 20 percent and 24 percent, 
respectively). As a result, in 1999, the overall share of insid-ers 
in the membership of supervisory boards returned to 
the 1997 level (i.e., 49 percent). Among the outsiders, 
managers from other firms continue to make up the largest 
category (22 percent in 1997, 27 percent in 1998, and 24 
percent in 1999), of which three fourths are managers from 
private companies (Figure 1). 
The column "Total" in Table 44 contains detailed data 
on the personal composition of supervisory boards in the 
companies under review in 1999. In comparison with ear-lier 
years, it seems to have remained very stable. There 
are still very few experts from various fields of knowledge 
potentially useful to this body's work: the joint share of 
bankers, consultants, scientific and technological experts 
and professionals amounted to 9 percent in 1997 and 7 
percent in 1999. Thus, in practice, little use is made of one 
of the basic instruments for equipping the supervisory 
boards with the capacity for exercising expert control on 
behalf of the owners. 
We see that the composition of supervisory boards con-tinues 
to be dependent primarily on the ownership struc-ture: 
outsider dominance in the ownership structure is 
accompanied by outsider dominance in supervisory board 
membership. The most "outsiderized" supervisory boards 
are in the companies dominated by an outside strategic 
investor (79 percent of board members in such cases do 
not work in the company). The same applies to the domi-nance 
of managerial and non-managerial employees. Lack 
of dominance of any of the insider groups is correlated with 
managerial dominance of the supervisory board. We 
observe a larger than average share of private managers 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Figure 1. Basic groups of supervisory board members (% of total number of members) 
22% 27% 24% 
0 
1997 1998 1999 
Insiders – managers 
Insiders – non managers 
Outsiders – managers 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
35 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 44. Composition of the supervisory board in 1999, by categories of ownership dominance (%) 
and consultants in the supervisory boards of companies 
dominated by strategic outside investors, which should give 
these boards superior capacity to carry out their supervi-sory 
function competently. 
This aggregate picture of the composition of superviso-ry 
boards fails to convey the diversity of combinations of 
forces and interests found in different boards. The repre-sentation 
of different groups (most importantly insiders 
and outsiders) varies widely across companies. In 1999, in 
more than half (51 percent) of the boards under review, 
the majority was made up of people who were not 
employees of the given firm, and in 20 percent the boards 
were made up exclusively of outsiders. In 47 percent of the 
supervisory boards insiders dominated, and in 28 percent 
there was not a single person from outside the firm. When 
viewed over a longer period of time, the evolution of the 
composition of the supervisory boards has not been unidi-rectional. 
Contrary to what one might expect in view of 
the process of ownership "outsiderization", the position of 
insiders measured by numerical dominance in the compo-sition 
of different boards was markedly strengthened in 
1998–1999. At the same time, polarization into purely 
"insider" and purely "outsider" boards was accentuated. 
A closer look at the problem reveals that this seeming 
paradox actually constitutes a continuation of earlier con-centrated 
trends: in companies belonging to the employ-ees, 
institutional control is increasingly concentrated in the 
hands of insiders, while in the "outsider" companies their 
employees are more and more often allowed to participate 
in the organs of corporate governance. 
This can be seen as evidence that the corporate gover-nance 
system in Polish companies is gradually nearing the 
continental model. Moreover, this process has entered a 
new phase in which this adjustment does not stem primar- 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Ownership structure of the company; dominance of: 
Post occupied outside 
the supervisory board 
TOTAL Strategic 
outsiders 
Other 
outsiders 
Managers 
Non-managerial 
employees 
Without 
dominant 
group 
At the firm under review 
Managerial post 25 14 12 25 38 37 
Specialist 12 4 14 20 16 11 
Trade union activist 1 2 – – 2 2 
Non-managerial post 11 1 9 8 24 13 
Outside the firm under review 
Managerial post in state-owned 
enterprise 5 – 8 6 4 4 
Managerial post in private sector 19 37 20 13 3 13 
Bank employee 3 3 1 1 1 3 
Employee of state administration 3 4 3 – 2 1 
Employee of local administration 1 – – 2 – – 
Scientist 3 3 1 4 2 3 
Employee of consulting firm 1 6 – 1 – – 
Private businessman 8 10 25 8 1 6 
Pensioner 6 10 4 12 4 8 
Other 2 6 1 – 1 1 
Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 
Source: own calculations using Database 2. 
Table 45. Supervisory board composition in 1997–1999, by ownership structure (%) 
Ownership structure in the company 
Without strategic 
investor 
With a strategic 
investor 
Dominant insider 
ownership 
Dominant outsider 
ownership 
Supervisory board 
composition 
1997 1998 1999 1997 1998 1999 1997 1998 1999 1997 1998 1999 
Only outsiders 19 12 12 54 41 46 17 10 10 54 37 37 
Dominance of outsiders 16 29 29 23 50 38 16 29 27 21 49 40 
Mixed composition 11 6 2 13 – 3 13 5 1 9 2 4 
Dominance of insiders 28 25 21 5 9 10 28 26 22 9 8 13 
Only insiders 26 28 36 5 – 3 26 30 40 7 4 6 
Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
36 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
Table 46. The body that appoints the executive board, by ownership structure type (%) 
The executive board is appointed by: 
Dominant owner group 
shareholders' meeting supervisory board 
ily from legal requirements, but rather from the needs of 
the agents involved in the functioning of the companies. 
When we look at the evolution of supervisory board 
composition from the point of view of the occupations of 
their members (e.g., the increasing percentage of members 
with specialist and non-managerial positions), we see evi-dence 
of increasing representation of stakeholders on this 
body, which is consistent with the above-mentioned conti-nental 
model. While the external investor does not risk loss 
of control over the board (an overwhelming majority of 
incumbent and newly appointed supervisory board presi-dents 
are outsiders), naming a person from the company to 
the supervisory board contributes to ease tensions or con-flicts 
between employees and the owners and to create at 
least an illusion of employee representation. Presumably 
this is also due to the owners' realization that insiders have 
better access to certain information about what is going on 
in the firm than those observing it from outside. 
Executive Board 
The executive board can be appointed in different ways, 
depending on stipulations of the company's charter. In 
1999, in 69 percent of the companies under review, the 
executive board was appointed and dismissed not directly 
by the owners, but by the supervisory board (in 1998 this 
was the case in 60 percent of the companies). Appointment 
of the executive board by the supervisory board is most 
frequent in the companies not dominated by any particular 
group of owners, and secondly in companies with a strate-gic 
outside investor. The opposite pole is made up of firms 
characterized by "insider" ownership structures, where the 
executive board is relatively most frequently appointed 
directly by the owners (Table 46). Interestingly, superviso-ry 
boards appointed executive boards more often in 1999 
than in 1998, especially in the groups of companies where 
earlier they had performed this function most infrequently. 
Research shows that the boards' behavior depends 
largely on what positions their members occupied previ-ously, 
in particular on the nature of their involvement in the 
governance system of the transformed state-owned enter-prise. 
From this point of view, the majority of companies in 
our sample constitute examples of the reproduction of 
managerial elites47: as many as 79 percent of the current 
executive board members worked at the given firm before 
its privatization, and 74 percent occupied managerial posi-tions. 
The membership of the executive boards is dominated 
by former state enterprise managers (former state enter-prise 
directors and deputy directors together make up 55 
percent). Those coming to the companies' executive 
boards from outside are primarily managers and owners 
from the private sector – private businessmen or managers 
of private firms (together 14 percent). On the other hand, 
there are very few former managers of other state-owned 
enterprises or persons previously occupying non-manager-ial 
positions. 
Table 47 adds the ownership dimension to this analysis. 
There are few surprises here: the reproduction of elites is 
more frequently halted in firms in which over 50 percent of 
the shares are in the hands of outsiders than in the "insider" 
firms, especially those in which the majority of shares 
belong to non-managerial employees. Certain exceptions 
to this rule are firms with ownership dominance of the 
managerial staff, among which we see a surprising percent-age 
(14 percent) of private businessmen from other firms. 
6.2. The Decision-Making Process 
The role of supervisory boards 
The main factor defining the place and role of the super-visory 
board in the governance system of the companies in 
question is the range of powers with which it is vested and 
which are exercised by it in practice. Polish law sets the 
general framework in the Commercial Code, which pro-vides 
only for the following basic, minimum range of the 
supervisory board's responsibilities: 
– review of the company's balance sheet and profit and 
loss statement; 
– review of reports of the executive board; 
CASE Reports No. 47 
47 On the reproduction versus replacement of elites see Wasilewski and Wnuk-Lipinski (1995), 669 
Total 
Dominance of strategic outsider 25 75 100 
Dominance of other outsiders 36 64 100 
Dominance of managers 35 65 100 
Dominance of non-managerial employees 40 60 100 
Lack of dominant group 17 83 100 
TOTAL 31 69 100 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
37 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 47. Former posts of executive board members, by the companies' ownership structures (percent) 
– review of the executive board's proposals regarding 
the distribution of profits and coverage of losses; 
– reporting the results of the above reviews at the share-holders' 
meeting; 
– suspending, for important reasons, the executive board 
or individual members of the board in the perfor-mance 
of their functions; 
– delegating supervisory board members to temporary 
performance of functions of the suspended executive 
board members; 
– when necessary, taking steps towards supplementing 
the membership of the executive board. 
The Commercial Code allows for widening the range 
of the supervisory board's responsibilities through appro-priate 
provisions of the company's charter. In all the com-panies 
under review, the formal powers of the executive 
board were extended in comparison with the minimum 
provided for by Polish law. The extensions mostly regard 
approval of decisions made by other statutory bodies of 
the company, more rarely to making "own" binding deci-sions. 
Directions in which the rights of the supervisory 
boards have been extended can be divided into six cate-gories: 
1. Decisions on broadly understood organizational mat-ters 
(found in 99 percent of the companies where 
supervisory boards had been created): appointing 
executive board members, setting the company's 
wage scale, monitoring the execution of resolutions 
made by the executive board or shareholders' meet-ing. 
2. Decisions on financial matters (84 percent): approval 
of profit distribution, giving consent to contracting 
large financial liabilities. 
3. Decisions on economic and production-related mat-ters, 
i.e. the company's development and production 
plans, quality control, etc. (74 percent). 
4. Disposing of the firm's capital and the firm itself as a 
corporate entity, i.e. decisions on changes in the 
shareholders' agreement and the company's line of 
activity, size of the company's capital, operations on 
shares, change in the ownership structure, etc. (88 
percent). 
5. Giving consent to changes in the company's assets: 
acquisition or sale of real estate, putting assets to 
lease, investment purchases, etc. (73 percent). 
6. Powers conventionally defined as "social": monitoring 
compliance with occupational safety regulations and 
safeguarding the interests of employees (21 percent of 
the companies). 
The supervisory boards did not use all the powers they 
were given, at least during 1998–1999. The use of these 
powers depends not only on the character of the board, 
but also on the company's need for such actions. For 
example, it can be assumed that all supervisory boards are 
active in reviewing financial documents, statements, etc., 
while, as a rule, their participation in appointing and dis-missing 
the executive board, approving large transactions, 
etc., occurs much more rarely, simply because these 
actions are much less frequent. 
Table 48 shows which powers were actually exercised 
by the supervisory boards in 1998–1999. Only 9 percent of 
the boards under review confined their activity to the min- 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Dominant ownership categories 
Former positions of executive 
board members 
TOTAL 
outsiders managers 
non-managerial 
employees 
without 
dominant 
group 
Worked at the firm before 
privatization 
79 68 81 96 86 
Of which, in the position of: 
Director 26 25 24 31 29 
Deputy director, chief accountant 29 25 34 41 27 
Other managerial post 19 16 19 20 23 
Non-managerial post 5 2 4 4 7 
Did not work at the firm before 
privatization, but: 21 32 19 4 14 
In managerial position in a state-owned 
enterprise 2 5 – 2 – 
In managerial position in a private 
firm 8 17 4 2 4 
As employee of a public institution 1 – 1 – 2 
As employee of a consulting firm 1 2 – – – 
As private businessman 6 5 14 – 4 
Other positions 2 3 – – 4 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
38 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
imum outlined by the Commercial Code. The most fre-quently 
used additional powers were those of an organiza-tional 
nature (81 percent of the supervisory boards under 
review), followed by powers to dispose of the capital and 
the firm (62 percent), economic and production-related 
powers (60 percent), control over the firm's assets (49 per-cent), 
and powers in the financial sphere (44 percent). The 
list ends with supervisory boards that have made use of the 
powers defined as social (14 percent). 
This table points to certain trends. Confinement of 
activities to the statutory minimum of responsibilities is 
most frequent in supervisory boards that are composed 
exclusively of insiders, and in companies with ownership 
dominance of the managerial staff. The supervisory boards' 
powers in the organizational sphere are most frequently 
exercised where the board's composition is mixed, in loss-making 
companies, and in companies without a dominant 
owners' group. Financial powers are exercised most fre-quently 
in the companies in which more than 50 percent of 
the shares belong to the managerial staff and in loss-making 
companies. Economic and production-related powers are 
most characteristic of supervisory boards in loss-making 
companies and companies with a strategic investor. Dispos-ing 
of the capital and the firm is most typical of supervisory 
boards in firms without any dominant owner category, 
boards with mixed membership and boards of loss-making 
companies. Exercise of the right of control over the assets 
and of powers in the social sphere is most frequently 
observed in companies with employee ownership domi-nance 
and in loss-makers. 
To sum up, we can say that extension of the supervi-sory 
boards' activities is observed most frequently in com-panies 
in economic distress. Interrelationships between 
the ownership structure and the extension of the supervi-sory 
boards' powers are of a more complex nature. The 
most striking relationships seem to be the following: lack 
of any dominant owners' group is linked to extension of 
the supervisory boards' activities to the organizational 
sphere and to the control over the capital and the firm; 
dominance of employee ownership is linked to the board's 
"social" activity and control over the firm's assets, and 
dominance of the managerial staff in the ownership struc-ture 
is, in general, not accompanied by any extension of 
the supervisory board's powers, except to the area of 
finance. Thus, different configurations of the insider-dom-inated 
ownership structure go hand in hand with different 
patterns of extension of the supervisory board's range of 
powers. Lack of dominance of any group is often accom-panied 
by the assumption of other organs' and services' 
functions by the supervisory boards; dominance of 
employee ownership dictates special attention to matters 
that are important for the employees, i.e. to social prob-lems, 
and dominance of the managerial staff in the 
ownership structure tends to be accompanied by limita- 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Table 48. Percentage of supervisory boards exercising given powers in 1998–1999 
Kind of powers 
Characteristics of firm 
Only 
those 
provided 
for in the 
Commer-cial 
Code 
Organiza-tional 
Financial 
Economic 
and 
produc-tion-related 
Disposing 
over the 
capital and 
the firm 
Control 
over the 
assets 
Social 
Total 9 81 44 60 62 49 14 
Dominating ownership group 
Outsiders 8 85 40 66 64 57 8 
Managers 14 72 62 59 62 38 17 
Non- anageriaml employees 5 75 45 65 50 60 25 
Lack of predominant group – 95 29 62 86 38 14 
Presence of strategic investor 
Is not present 7 81 47 58 65 45 14 
Is present 8 84 37 76 66 61 13 
Type of supervisory board 
composition 
Only outsiders 7 86 54 75 57 61 11 
Predominance of outsiders 9 84 43 64 59 36 7 
Dominance of insiders 4 89 52 63 63 48 11 
Only insiders 13 70 38 45 68 55 23 
Profit criterion 
There is no profit 11 89 48 78 70 63 30 
There is profit 9 79 43 56 60 46 10 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
39 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Table 49. Average influence of different actors on decision making processes in the company, in the opinion of company presidents 
(1 – the weakest influence, 5 – the strongest influence) 
tion of the supervisory board's powers to certain strictly 
defined areas. 
The hierarchy of decision-makers 
The strong, stable ownership position of the executive 
board members and the inertia in the composition of 
executive boards constitute evidence of continuity of the 
governance structures in the periods before and after pri-vatization. 
We would therefore expect that in most cases it 
is the executive board that has the greatest influence on 
decision making processes, not only in day-to-day manage-ment 
matters but also with respect to strategic problems. 
This was verified in company presidents' responses to 
questions concerning the relative role of various groups in 
decision-making processes. 
The important role of company presidents is stressed 
more frequently than average in companies with owner-ship 
dominance of non-strategic outsiders and managerial 
staff; whereas that of the executive board as a whole is 
more frequently stressed in firms with dominance of 
employee ownership. The biggest shareholders have 
strongest influence in the "outsider" and manager-con-trolled 
companies, and the weakest where there are few 
such shareholders; i.e., in firms with dominant employee 
ownership. The general assembly of shareholders, in turn, 
is relatively strongest where the ownership dominance of 
managers, employees, or non-strategic outsiders has 
evolved. The influence of the supervisory board is at its 
strongest where there is ownership dominance of external 
investors, and weakest in the manager-owned companies. 
Trade unions are also at their weakest in the latter group 
and strongest in strategic outsider-controlled firms and in 
companies with dominance of non-managerial employee 
ownership. The role of non-managerial employees is per-ceived 
as relatively strongest (but still at the lower end of 
hierarchy) in companies controlled by non-managerial 
employees and weakest in firms with strategic outsider 
investors (Table 49). 
The owners most frequently act as decision makers 
where ownership is concentrated in the hands of a strate-gic 
outside investor. The role of owners in decision-making 
also grows in loss-making companies (at the expense of the 
powers of the executive and supervisory boards). 
The small role of owners is striking. Only 10 percent of 
company presidents mentioned them among the decision 
makers at all, and a mere 3 percent named them as the sole 
center of strategic decision-making. Accordingly, the per-ception 
of the relative importance of the general assembly 
of shareholders is often very low too. Almost half (45 per-cent) 
of the company presidents, when asked directly, 
described the role of this body as purely formal. There is 
no doubt that among company presidents there is a certain 
skewing in the perception of the power distribution within 
the companies. They perceive this question from the 
standpoint of their own position, tasks and responsibilities. 
Since the executive board's basic task is keeping the com-pany 
in operation, for them, the most important people are 
those who are directly involved in carrying out this task. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Dominating ownership group category 
Agent strategic 
outsiders 
other 
outsiders 
managers 
non-managerial 
employees 
without 
dominant 
category 
Total 
Executive board president 4.50 4.73 4.63 4.52 4.45 4.57 
Executive board as a whole 4.42 4.54 4.58 4.68 4.40 4.52 
Supervisory board 3.58 3.71 3.22 3.42 3.38 3.54 
General assembly of 
3.42 3.87 3.88 3.86 3.05 3.62 
shareholders 
The biggest shareholders 4.00 4.00 4.00 3.05 3.50 3.80 
Trade unions 2.38 2.00 1.80 2.17 2.09 2.07 
Non-managerial employees 2.17 2.40 2.27 2.70 2.29 2.32 
Source: own calculations using Database 2.
40 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
The ownership structure of Polish employee-leased 
companies, especially immediately after privatization, was 
characterized by large holdings of dispersed insider owners. 
Subsequently, the shares of non-managerial employees 
gradually decline, while those of outsiders grow. Concentra-tion 
of shares in the hands of managers can be seen from the 
very moment of privatization. Later, however, managerial 
holdings stabilize and even decrease somewhat in favor of 
outsiders. 
The sample of employee-leased companies is gradually 
becoming more and more heterogeneous. We observe 
three chief directions of ownership structure changes: 
– perpetuation of a dispersed shareholding structure, 
with dominance of insiders (an approximation of an 
egalitarian, worker cooperative ownership struc-ture); 
– consolidation of ownership in the hands of insider 
elites; 
– concentration of ownership in the hands of outside 
investors. 
In general, however, change is incremental. Radical 
changes in the ownership structure are rare, and owner-ship 
structure seems to be fairly inert. It would, never-theless, 
be wrong to conclude that significant change is 
not possible when it is in the interests of the incumbents, 
as new strategic investors had appeared in about 10 per-cent 
of the sample by 1998. (It is, however, worth noting 
that there is a negative relationship between the size of 
top management's share and the appearance of strategic 
investors; it appears that once managers have decisive 
control over the ownership structure of a company, they 
are reluctant to relinquish it.) 
A number of factors which influence the direction and 
the dynamics of ownership changes, among others sector 
affiliation, company size, initial ownership structure, etc., 
but the most important is the economic condition of the 
company, which, when it is poor, favors concentration and 
"outsiderization" of ownership (as well as changes in corpo-rate 
governance). Management ownership on the average 
appears in relatively small companies, while strategic 
investors appear in companies whose average employment 
is above the sample average. This is probably due to the fact 
that, given low levels of personal savings at the beginning of 
the transformation, it was more difficult for an individual or 
small group of individuals to buy a large block of shares in a 
large company than in a small firm. 
Post-privatization ownership transformations were 
achieved not only by trade in existing shares but also by 
issues of new ones. Nineteen firms had carried out new 
share issues by mid-1997. Most frequently, new share 
issues serve to promote concentration of shares (espe-cially 
in the hands of management and strategic 
investors). 
Access to credit and company size seem to be the 
most significant determinants of investment spending. 
Very surprisingly, the presence of strategic investors 
seems to be unrelated to investment spending. Many 
firms in the sample refrain from making dividend pay-ments, 
but there is no indication that this leads to 
increased investment and may simply be a result of ab-uses 
by management. There is some evidence that con-centration 
of shares in the hands of management is posi-tively 
related to investment, while the evidence concern-ing 
the relationship between the share of non-managerial 
employees and investment is ambiguous. There appears 
to be no relationship between ownership structure and 
marketing activity or expansion into new markets (the 
former is most strongly related to company size, and the 
latter to the branch in which the company is operating). 
However, companies with strategic investors do much 
better than others in the area of ISO quality certification. 
There is (very) slight evidence that the extent of non-managerial 
employees' share in the ownership of the firm 
had a negative effect on economic performance in the 
early 1990s. In particular, there is a case – albeit a weak 
one – to be made for the claim that companies whose 
employees constitute the dominant owners follow a poli-cy 
favoring consumption (wages, dividends and the like) 
over investment and development. However, the situa-tion 
in the companies is likely to be differentiated, with 
the character of relationships between ownership struc-ture 
and economic decision-making dependent on many 
CASE Reports No. 47 
7. Conclusions
48 We must remember that each firm in fact constitutes a complex social organism, and the number of groupings and factions is probably propor-tional 
to the number of employees. For a clear and comprehensive picture of the decision-making process in such firms, we probably need an indepth 
sociological analysis which would reveal the differences among such groups as current and former employees, new and old employees, white-collar and 
blue-collar employees, employees of various departments and divisions, etc. 
41 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
factors which we were unable to analyze here48. An 
example of such differences is found in the opinion 
encountered by one of the authors of this paper in case 
studies of Polish employee-owned companies, according 
to which the most consumption-oriented attitudes are 
exhibited by former employees. One of the company 
presidents expressing this opinion about former emp-loyees 
also said that he regretted the fact that new 
employees were unable to acquire shares in the company, 
since such employees (young, well-educated persons 
hired in the 1990s) are often the most valuable in the 
firm49. From this point of view, it is possible that emp-loyee- 
owned companies in Poland could gain certain 
advantages from the creation of trust funds which would 
hold employee shares on behalf of the employees, issuing 
shares to new employees and purchasing them from 
those that leave the company. Such a mechanism might 
resemble, for example, the Employee Stock Ownership 
Plans of the United States50. 
Turning to issues of corporate governance, we conclude 
with a brief look at executive boards and supervisory 
boards. 
The membership of the executive boards is dominated 
by persons who had managed the companies before priva-tization, 
when they were still state enterprises. The repro-duction 
of elites is more frequently halted in firms in which 
over 50 percent of the shares are in the hands of outsiders 
than in the "insider" firms, especially those in which the 
majority of shares belong to non-managerial employees. 
When viewed over a longer period of time, the evolu-tion 
of the composition of the supervisory boards has not 
been unidirectional. Contrary to what one might expect in 
view of the process of ownership "outsiderization", the 
position of insiders measured by numerical dominance in 
the composition of different boards was markedly strength-ened 
in 1998–1999. in companies belonging to the employ-ees, 
institutional control is increasingly concentration of in 
the hands of insiders, while in the "outsider" companies 
their employees are more and more often allowed to par-ticipate 
in the organs of corporate governance. Moreover, 
when we look at the evolution of supervisory board com-position 
from the point of view of the occupations of their 
members (e.g., the increasing percentage of members with 
specialist and non-managerial positions), we see evidence of 
increasing representation of stakeholders on this body. 
At the same time, polarization into purely "insider" and 
purely "outsider" boards was accentuated. 
The supervisory boards did not use all the powers they 
were given, at least during 1998–1999. The use of these 
powers depends not only on the character of the board, but 
also on the company's need for such actions. For example, 
it can be assumed that all supervisory boards are active in 
reviewing financial documents, statements, etc., while, as a 
rule, their participation in appointing and dismissing the 
executive board, approving large transactions, etc., occurs 
much more rarely, simply because these actions are much 
less frequent. 
Extension of the supervisory boards' activities is 
observed most frequently in companies in economic dis-tress. 
Interrelationships between the ownership structure 
and the extension of the supervisory boards' powers are of 
a more complex nature. The most striking relationships 
seem to be the following: lack of any dominant owners' 
group is linked to extension of the supervisory boards' activ-ities 
to the organizational sphere and to the control over the 
capital and the firm; dominance of employee ownership is 
linked to the board's "social" activity and control over the 
firm's assets, and dominance of the managerial staff in the 
ownership structure is, in general, not accompanied by any 
extension of the supervisory board's powers, except to the 
area of finance. Thus, different configurations of the insider-dominated 
ownership structure go hand in hand with dif-ferent 
patterns of extension of the supervisory board's 
range of powers. Lack of dominance of any group is often 
accompanied by the assumption of other organs' and ser-vices' 
functions by the supervisory boards; dominance of 
employee ownership dictates special attention to matters 
that are important for the employees, i.e. to social prob-lems, 
and dominance of the managerial staff in the owner-ship 
structure tends to be accompanied by limitation of the 
supervisory board's powers to certain strictly defined areas. 
Generally speaking, the small role of owners in the deci-sion- 
making process is striking. The owners most frequent-ly 
act as decision makers where ownership is concentrated 
in the hands of a strategic outside investor. The role of own-ers 
in decision-making also grows in loss-making companies 
(at the expense of the powers of the executive and super-visory 
boards). 
49 See Woodward (1999). 
50 For more on the subject of ESOPs, see Blasi (1988). 
CASE Reports No. 47
42 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
Appendix 
Definitions of variables and correlations 
Definitions of variables 
L employment (end of year) 
P.C. CH percentage change in employment between the end 
of the year prior to privatization and the end of 1996 
MAN percentage of the company's shares held by members 
of the Executive Board (at time of privatization, and 
in mid-1997, 1998, and 1999) 
SI percentage of the company's shares held by the 
strategic investor (at time of privatization, and in mid- 
1997, 1998, and 1999) 
WOR percentage of the company's shares held by non-managerial 
employees (at time of privatization, and in 
mid-1997, 1998, and 1999; in section 5, in mid-1992, 
1993, and 1994) 
GRMAN difference between percentage of the company's 
shares held by Executive Board members in mid- 
1997 and at time of privatization 
GRSI difference between percentage of the company's 
shares held by strategic investor in mid-1997 and at 
time of privatization 
GRWORdifference between percentage of the company's 
shares held by non-managerial employees in mid- 
1997 and at time of privatization 
TRCONdummy indicating whether neither Executive Board 
members nor a strategic investor had a share of more 
than 20% at time of privatization and one or both of 
these types of owners had over 20% in mid-1997 
TRSI dummy indicating whether strategic investor had a 
share of less than 20% at time of privatization and 
over 20% in mid-1997 
TRM dummy indicating whether Executive Board mem-bers 
had a share of less than 20% at time of privati-zation 
and over 20% in mid-1997 
BIG percentage of the company's shares held by the single 
largest shareholder (in mid-1997, 1998, and 1999) 
OWN percentage of the work force that holds shares (at 
time of privatization, and in mid-1997, 1998, and 
1999; in section 5, in mid-1992, 1993, and 1994) 
UNI percentage of the work force that belongs to a trade 
union (at time of privatization, and in mid-1997, 1998, 
and 1999; in section 5, in mid-1992, 1993, and 1994) 
DIV two variables: absolute value of the dividend payment 
in PLN, or dummy variable for payment of dividend 
(1: dividend was paid; 0: dividend was not paid) 
DIVS ratio of dividend to the face value of one share 
DIVP ratio of dividend to net profit 
LEA dummy for whether the lease had been paid off (mid- 
1999) 
NMKT number of positive responses to question whether 
new markets had been found (range: 0 to 3) 
MK DUM dummy for whether the firm has a marketing divi-sion 
MK EMPemployment in the marketing division 
Dummies for the degree of equality 
of shareholding: 
EQ1 at least one shareholder holds at least 10 percent of 
all shares (high concentration) 
EQ2 at least one person holds 5–10 percent of all shares 
(medium concentration) 
EQ3 at least one person holds 1–5 percent of all shares 
(relative equality) 
Dummies for the population of the city or town in 
which the company is located: 
POP1 less than 20,000 
POP2 21,000–50,000 
POP3 51,000–200,000 
POP4 201,000–500,000 
POP5 over 500,000 
Dummies concerning new issues: 
NEW a new share issue was held 
CLO the new share issue was a closed (i.e., not public) 
subscription 
Dummies for market share of the firm: 
MON the company is a monopolist 
OLI the company is an oligopolist 
COM the company operates in a competitive market 
Investment variables: 
INV annual investment spending (1996) 
PC value of current investment projects, per employee 
(total from 1992 through 1996, and 1998) 
INCR dummy for whether investment was financed by 
obtainment of credit 
Variables used only in Section 5: 
K = value of fixed assets, in millions of pre-1995 zlotys 
(as of June 199351, end of 1993, end of 1994) 
YEAR = dummy for year of production (1992=0, 1993=1, 
1994=2) 
AMORT= amortization of fixed assets at the time of privati-zation 
(as a proxy for the firm's age) 
51 End-of-year fixed assets data for 1992 were unfortunately not available. Given the choice between using fixed assets for the ti me of privatization 
(in 1990 or 1991) and in June 1993 as an approximation for the 1992 capital stock, the latter measure seemed much better, given that a great deal of 
property was frequently sold or leased by the companies within the initial period following privatization. 
CASE Reports No. 47
43 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
Bibliography 
Blasi, Joseph R. (1988), Employee Ownership: Revolution 
or Ripoff? Grand Rapids, Michigan. 
Brada, J.C. Singh, I. (1995), Industrial Transformation and 
Labor Productivity in Central and Eastern Europe. IN: 
Quaisser, W. Woodward, R. and B³aszczyk, B. (eds.) Privati-zation 
in Poland and East Germany: A Comparison. Munich, 
Osteuropa-Institut. 
Central Statistical Office (G³ówny Urz¹d Statystyczny). 
(1995), Prywatyzacja przedsiêbiorstw pañstwowych wg. stanu 
na 31.12.1994 r. (Privatization of state enterprises as of 31 
December, 1994). Warsaw. 
Central Statistical Office (G³ówny Urz¹d Centralny). 
(1999) Prywatyzacja przedsiêbiorstw pañstwowych w 1998 r. 
(Privatization of state enterprises as of 31 December, 1994). 
Warsaw. 
Conte, M.A. Svejnar, J. (1988) Productivity Effects of 
Worker Participation in Management, Profit-Sharing, Work-er 
Ownership of Assets and Unionization in U.S. Firms. 
International Journal of Industrial Organization, 6. 
Estrin, S. Jones, D.C. and Svejnar, J. (1987) The Produc-tivity 
Effects of Worker Participation: Producer Coopera-tives 
in Western Economies. Journal of Comparative Econom-ics, 
11 March. 
Eyeing up the risk (1995) Business Central Europe, 3 (25) 
October. 
Frydman, R. and Rapaczynski, A. (1994) Privatization in 
Eastern Europe: Is the State Withering Away? Budapest, CEU 
Press. 
Gardawski, J. (1995) Trends in the Ownership and 
Authority Structure of Employee-Owned Companies. IN: 
Jarosz, M. ed. Management Employee Buy-Outs in Poland, 
Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Gardawski, J. (1996) Toward Management-Employee 
Ownership. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Polish Employee-Owned Com-panies 
in 1995, Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Gardawski, J. (2000) Forming of Owner Groups in Pri-vatized 
Enterprises. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Ten Years of Direct Pri-vatization, 
Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Grosfeld, I. Nivet, J.F. (1998) Insider Power and Wage Set-ting 
in Transition: Evidence from a Panel of Large Polish Firms, 
1988–1994. Paper prepared for the European Economic 
Association Congress, 2–5 September, Berlin. 
Jarosz, M. ed. (1994) Employee-Owned Companies in 
Poland. Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Jarosz, M. ed. (1995) Management Employee Buy-outs in 
Poland. Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Jarosz, M. ed. (1996) Polish Employee-Owned Companies 
in 1995. Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Jarosz, M. ed. (1999) Direct Privatization. Investors. Man-agers. 
Employees. Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Jarosz, M. ed. (2000) Ten Years of Direct Privatization. 
Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Jones, D.C. (1993) The Productivity Effects of Employee 
Ownership Within Command Economies: Evidence from 
Poland. Managerial and Decision Economics, 14. 
Kierunki prywatyzacji maj¹tku pañstwowego w 1995r. 
(Directions of privatization of state property in 1995). Dzien-nik 
Ustaw 1995 nr 27, poz. 142. 
Kozarzewski, P. (1999) Elity kierownicze spó³ek pracow-niczych: 
w³asnooeæ – zarz¹dzanie – oewiadomooeæ (Elites of 
Employee-Owned Companies: Ownership – Management – 
Mentality). Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Kozarzewski, P. (2000a) Authority Structures in the 
Companies. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Ten Years of Direct Privatiza-tion. 
Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Kozarzewski, P. (2000b) Owner Control. IN: Jarosz, M. 
ed. Ten Years of Direct Privatization. Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Kozarzewski, P. Krajewski, S. and Majak, R. (2000) Own-ership 
Transformations in 1990–1998 in the Light of Law and 
Statistical Data. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Ten Years of Direct Privati-zation. 
Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Krajewski, S. (1998) Efekty ekonomiczne prywatyzacji 
bezpooeredniej (Economic effects of Direct Privatization). 
IN: Jarosz, M.ed. Prywatyzacja bezpooerednia: Inwestorzy, 
Mened¿erowie, Pracownicy (Direct Privatization. Investors. 
Managers. Employees), Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Krajewski, S. (2000) Economic effects of direct privati-zation. 
IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Ten Years of Direct Privatization, 
Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Ministry of Ownership Transformation (Ministerstwo 
Przekszta³ceñ W³asnooeciowych – Departament Delegatur i 
Analiz Prywatyzacji) (1995) Informacja o procesie prywatyza-cji 
przedsiêbiorstw pañstwowych – do dnia 31.12.1994 r. 
(Information on the process of privatization of state enterpris-es 
through 31 December, 1994), 21 January, Warsaw. 
Pietrewicz, J. (1995) Direction of Transformation of 
Employee-Owned Companies. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Manage-ment 
Employee Buy-outs in Poland,Warsaw, ISP PAN. 
Supreme Control Chamber (Najwy¿sza Izba Kontroli – 
Zespó³ Przekszta³ceñ W³asnooeciowych). (1993) Informacja o 
wynikach kontroli prywatyzacji przedsiêbiorstw pañstwowych w 
drodze likwidacji przez oddanie przedsiêbiorstwa lub jego czêoe-ci 
do odp³atnego korzystania (Results of investigation of privati-zation 
of state enterprises by the method of enterprise liquida-tion 
and asset leasing). December, Warsaw. 
Szomburg, J. D¹browski, J.M. and Kamiñski, T. (1994) 
Monitoring przedsiêbiorstw sprywatyzowanych (Review of pri-vatized 
enterprises). Gdañsk Institute for Market Economics, 
Gdañsk.
44 
P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 
CASE Reports No. 47 
Uchwa³a Sejmu Rzeczypospolitej Polskiej z dnia 12 lutego 
1993 r. w sprawie podstawowych kierunków prywatyzacji w 
1993 r. (Resolution dated 12 February, 1993, of the Polish par-liament 
concerning the directions of privatization in 1993). 
Monitor Polski 1993 nr 9, poz. 64. 
Wasilewski, J. Wnuk-Lipinski, E. (1995) Winding Road 
from the Communist to the Post-Solidarity Elite. Theory and 
Society, No. 24. 
Woodward, R. (1998) Various Forms of Employee Par-ticipation 
in Polish Employee-Owned Companies. IN: 
Jones, D.C. and others. eds. Advances in the Economic Analy-sis 
of Participatory and Labor-Managed Firms, 6, London, JAI 
Press Inc. 
Woodward, R. (1999) Employee Involvement in Emp-loyee- 
Owned Companies in Poland. Unpublished doctoral dis-sertation, 
University of £ódŸ. 
Zarz¹dzenie Ministra Finansów z dnia 7 maja 1991 r. 
(Instruction of the Minister of Finance, 7 May, 1991). Monitor 
Polski 1991 nr 18, poz. 123. 
Zarz¹dzenie Ministra Finansów z dnia 13 maja 1993 r. 
(Instruction of the Minister of Finance, 13 May, 1993). Moni-tor 
Polski 1993 nr 26, poz. 274. 
Zellner, A. Kmenta, J. and Dreze, J. (1966) Specification 
and Estimation of Cobb-Douglas Production Function Mod-els. 
Econometrica, October.
45 
Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 
26 M. D¹browski: Macroeconomic and Fiscal Challenges Facing Central European Countries during the EU 
Accession Process 
27 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ B. B³aszczyk i A. Cylwika: Charakterystyka wybranych sektorów infrastrukturalnych 
i wra¿liwych w gospodarce polskiej oraz mo¿liwooeci ich prywatyzacji 
28 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ B. Liberdy: Determinanty oszczêdzania w Polsce 
29 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ J.Kochanowicza: Ekonomia polityczna konsolidacji reform 
30 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ B. B³aszczyk, E. Balcerowicz: Uwarunkowania wzrostu sektora prywatnego w Polsce 
32 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ A. Wojtyny: Alternatywne strategie dezinflacji 
33 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ A. Wojtyny: Wspieranie wzrostu gospodarczego poprzez konsolidacjê reform 
34 J. Pankow, L. Dimitrov, P. Kozarzewski: Effects of Privatization of Industrial Enterprises in Bulgaria. Report on 
Empirical Research 
35 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ S. Golinowskiej: Edukacja i rynek pracy 
36 S. Golinowska, P. Kurowski (eds.): Rational Pension Supevision, First Experiences of Central and Eastern European 
States in Comparison with other Countries 
37 J. Pañków (ed.): Fiscal Effects from Privatization: Case of Bulgaria and Poland 
38 G. Ganev, M. Jarociñski, R. Lubenova, P. WoŸniak: Credibility of the Exchange Rate Policy in Transition Countries 
39 M. D¹browski (ed.): The Episodes of Currency Crises in Latin American and Asian Economies 
40 M. D¹browski (ed.): The Episodes of Currency Crises in the European Transition Economies 
41 M. D¹browski (ed.): Currency Crises in Emerging Markets – Selected Comparative Studies 
42 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ J. Cukrowskiego: Renta emisyjna jako Ÿród³o finansowania bud¿etu pañstwa 
43 P. Bujak, M. Jarmu¿ek, S. Kordel, W. Nawrot, J. OEmietaniak: OEredniookresowa projekcja dzia³alnooeci inwestycyjnej 
Otwartych Funduszy Emerytalnych na regulowanym rynku gie³dowym akcji 
44 E. Balcerowicz, A. Bratkowski: Restructuring and Development of the Banking Sector in Poland. Lessons to be 
Learnt by Less Advanced Transition Countries 
^ 
45 E. Kocenda: Secondary Privatization in the Czech Republic: Changes in Ownership and Enterprise Performance 
in Voucher- Privatized Firms 
46 M. Simoneti, A. Böhm, M. Rems, M. Rojec, J.P. Damijan, B. Majcen: Secondary Privatization in Slovenia: Evolution of 
Ownership Structure and Company Performance Following Mass Privatization

More Related Content

PDF
CASE Network Report 45 - Secondary Privatization in the Czech Republic: Chang...
PDF
CASE Network Report 59 - Understanding Reform: The Case of Poland
PDF
CASE Network Report 49 - The Evolution of Ownership Structure in Firms Privat...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 264 - Corporate Governance and Ownership St...
PDF
CASE Network Report 48 - Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part II): Evoluti...
PDF
Cluster and Workforce Development
PDF
Master Degree Capstone
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 325 - Privatization and Corporate Governanc...
CASE Network Report 45 - Secondary Privatization in the Czech Republic: Chang...
CASE Network Report 59 - Understanding Reform: The Case of Poland
CASE Network Report 49 - The Evolution of Ownership Structure in Firms Privat...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 264 - Corporate Governance and Ownership St...
CASE Network Report 48 - Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part II): Evoluti...
Cluster and Workforce Development
Master Degree Capstone
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 325 - Privatization and Corporate Governanc...

What's hot (9)

PDF
Ownership structure financial structure and r&d investment evid
PDF
Kasap_Haciibrahim_0524792_Management
PDF
Control and Power within Sino-Dutch Joint Ventures
PDF
Developing the global_guide_to_what_counts_webpdf
PDF
Subnational Full Toolkit
PDF
SMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RP
PDF
LED in post crises situation operations guide
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 271 - Enterprise Performance and Ownership ...
PDF
The Business Model Design of Social Enterprise
Ownership structure financial structure and r&d investment evid
Kasap_Haciibrahim_0524792_Management
Control and Power within Sino-Dutch Joint Ventures
Developing the global_guide_to_what_counts_webpdf
Subnational Full Toolkit
SMEDSEP Business Reg Licensing in RP
LED in post crises situation operations guide
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 271 - Enterprise Performance and Ownership ...
The Business Model Design of Social Enterprise
Ad

Similar to CASE Network Report 47 - Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part I): Evolution of Ownership Structure and Company Performance in Firms Privatized by Employee Buyouts (20)

PDF
CASE Network Report 46 - Secondary Privatization in Slovenia: Evolution of Ow...
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 263 - Corporate Governance and Secondary Pr...
PDF
Change in Economic Policy Paradigm: Privatization and State Capture in Poland
PDF
CASE Network Report 37 - Fiscal Effects from Privatization: Case of Bulgaria ...
PDF
The impact of privatisation on the performance of firms in egypt
DOCX
What is privatization doc 22.docx
PDF
Download Full The Political Economy of Privatization in Rich Democracies 1st ...
PDF
Budgetary tension and privatization The effects on firm performance
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 323 - Growth and Performance Factors in Pol...
PDF
Privatization in jordan, a critical assessment
PDF
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 347 - Corporate Governance Formation in Pol...
PDF
Doing business in Poland 2015
PDF
Doing business in Poland (May 2016)
PDF
Privatization Performance over Transition
PDF
CASE Network Report 44 - Restructuring and Development of the Banking Sector ...
PDF
CASE Network Reports 55 - The Sources of Economic Growth in Ukraine after 199...
PDF
ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES OF PRIVATISATION IN INDIA
PDF
Dancing with the devil : the political economy of privatization in China 1st ...
PDF
CASE Network Reports 62 - Competitiveness of the Polish Manufacturing Sector:...
CASE Network Report 46 - Secondary Privatization in Slovenia: Evolution of Ow...
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 263 - Corporate Governance and Secondary Pr...
Change in Economic Policy Paradigm: Privatization and State Capture in Poland
CASE Network Report 37 - Fiscal Effects from Privatization: Case of Bulgaria ...
The impact of privatisation on the performance of firms in egypt
What is privatization doc 22.docx
Download Full The Political Economy of Privatization in Rich Democracies 1st ...
Budgetary tension and privatization The effects on firm performance
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 323 - Growth and Performance Factors in Pol...
Privatization in jordan, a critical assessment
CASE Network Studies and Analyses 347 - Corporate Governance Formation in Pol...
Doing business in Poland 2015
Doing business in Poland (May 2016)
Privatization Performance over Transition
CASE Network Report 44 - Restructuring and Development of the Banking Sector ...
CASE Network Reports 55 - The Sources of Economic Growth in Ukraine after 199...
ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES OF PRIVATISATION IN INDIA
Dancing with the devil : the political economy of privatization in China 1st ...
CASE Network Reports 62 - Competitiveness of the Polish Manufacturing Sector:...
Ad

More from CASE Center for Social and Economic Research (20)

PDF
In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...
PDF
Praca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencje
PDF
The retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economy
PDF
Problems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economy
PDF
Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...
PDF
Informal employment and wages in Poland
PDF
The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...
PDF
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final Report
PDF
Increasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to Go
PDF
Is the economy doomed to a long recession?
PDF
mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...
PDF
Nasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii Europejskiej
PDF
Our Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European Union
PDF
The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....
PDF
The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...
PDF
30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus
PDF
Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?
PDF
Estonian corporate tax: Lessons for Poland
PDF
Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...
PDF
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final Report
In search of new opportunities. Circular migration between Belarus and Poland...
Praca nierejestrowana. Przyczyny i konsekwencje
The retirement age and the pension system, the labor market and the economy
Problems at Poland’s banks are threatening the economy
Thinking Beyond the Pandemic: Monetary Policy Challenges in the Medium- to Lo...
Informal employment and wages in Poland
The Rule of Law and its Social Reception as Determinants of Economic Developm...
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2020 Final Report
Increasing the International Role of the Euro: A Long Way to Go
Is the economy doomed to a long recession?
mBank-CASE Seminar Proceedings No. 162 "The European Union: State of play and...
Nasza Europa: 15 lat Polski w Unii Europejskiej
Our Europe: 15 Years of Poland in the European Union
The Story of the Open Pension Funds and the Employee Capital Plans in Poland....
The evolution of Belarusian public sector: From command economy to state capi...
30 Years of Economic Transformation in CEE: Key Five Lessons For Belarus
Does Low Inflation Pose a Risk to Economic Growth and Central Banks Reputation?
Estonian corporate tax: Lessons for Poland
Turning away from globalization? Trade wars and the rules of competition in g...
Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2019 Final Report

Recently uploaded (20)

DOCX
Final. 150 minutes exercise agrumentative Essay
PDF
Chapterrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrr 2_AP.pdf
PPTX
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
PDF
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
PPTX
Corporate Governance and Financial Decision-Making in Consumer Goods.pptx
PPTX
RISK MANAGEMENT IN MEDICAL LABORATORIES 2.pptx
PPTX
INDIAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM (Financial institutions, Financial Markets & Services)
PPTX
Integrated Digital Marketing and Supply Chain Model for.pptx
PPTX
Machine Learning (ML) is a branch of Artificial Intelligence (AI)
PDF
3CMT J.AFABLE Flexible-Learning ENTREPRENEURIAL MANAGEMENT.pdf
PDF
Fintech Regulatory Sandbox: Lessons Learned and Future Prospects
PPTX
Lecture on Perfect Competition of the course introduction to microeconomics
PPT
CompanionAsset_9780128146378_Chapter04.ppt
PDF
2018_Simulating Hedge Fund Strategies Generalising Fund Performance Presentat...
PPTX
Rise of Globalization...................
PPTX
Lesson Environment and Economic Growth.pptx
PPTX
PROFITS AND GAINS OF BUSINESS OR PROFESSION 2024.pptx
PDF
2012_The dark side of valuation a jedi guide to valuing difficult to value co...
PDF
MPEDA Export License Apply Online for Seafood Export License in India.pdf
PDF
Call cute girls 😀 Delhi, call now pls cute girls delhi call🔙
Final. 150 minutes exercise agrumentative Essay
Chapterrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrrr 2_AP.pdf
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
Management Accounting Information for Decision-Making and Strategy Execution ...
Corporate Governance and Financial Decision-Making in Consumer Goods.pptx
RISK MANAGEMENT IN MEDICAL LABORATORIES 2.pptx
INDIAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM (Financial institutions, Financial Markets & Services)
Integrated Digital Marketing and Supply Chain Model for.pptx
Machine Learning (ML) is a branch of Artificial Intelligence (AI)
3CMT J.AFABLE Flexible-Learning ENTREPRENEURIAL MANAGEMENT.pdf
Fintech Regulatory Sandbox: Lessons Learned and Future Prospects
Lecture on Perfect Competition of the course introduction to microeconomics
CompanionAsset_9780128146378_Chapter04.ppt
2018_Simulating Hedge Fund Strategies Generalising Fund Performance Presentat...
Rise of Globalization...................
Lesson Environment and Economic Growth.pptx
PROFITS AND GAINS OF BUSINESS OR PROFESSION 2024.pptx
2012_The dark side of valuation a jedi guide to valuing difficult to value co...
MPEDA Export License Apply Online for Seafood Export License in India.pdf
Call cute girls 😀 Delhi, call now pls cute girls delhi call🔙

CASE Network Report 47 - Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part I): Evolution of Ownership Structure and Company Performance in Firms Privatized by Employee Buyouts

  • 1. P i o t r Ko z a r z e w s k i R i c h a r d Wo o d w a r d Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part I): Evolution of Ownership Structure and Company Performance in Firms Privatized by Employee Buyouts W a r s a w , 22 0 0 1 No . 44 7
  • 2. This research was undertaken with support from the European Union's Phare ACE Programme 1997, project P97-8201R „Secondary Privatization: The Evolution of Ownership Structure of Privatized Companies“, co-ordinated by Professor Barbara B³aszczyk, CASE Foundation, Warsaw. The content of the publication is the sole responsibility of the authors and it in no way represenets the views of the Commission or its services. Key words: privatization, secondary transactions, corporate governance, transition economies, Czech Republic, Slovenia, Poland. DTP: CeDeWu Sp. z o.o. Graphic Design – Agnieszka Natalia Bury Editing – Julia Iwiñska, Richard Woodward Warsaw 2001 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, without prior permission in writing from the European Commission. ISSN 1506-1647 ISBN 83-7178-277-2 Publisher: CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research ul. Sienkiewicza 12, 00-944 Warsaw, Poland e-mail: case@case.com.pl http://www.case.com.pl
  • 3. 3 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Contents Preface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5 1. Introduction: The Role of Employee Buyouts in the Polish Privatization Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . .7 2. The Evolution of Ownership Structures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .9 2.1. Companies Dominated by Top Management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .14 2.2. Companies with Strategic Investors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .15 3. Factors in the Post-Privatization Evolution of Ownership Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .17 3.1. Motivations for Choice of the EBO Privatization Method and Subsequent Changes in Ownership Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .17 3.2. Initial Ownership Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .18 3.3. Sector, Company Size, and Unionization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .18 3.4. Profitability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .21 3.5. Methods for Ownership Transformation: Share Sales and New Issues . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .22 3.6. Top Management Domination . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .23 3.7. Companies with Strategic Investors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .23 4. The Economic Performance of Employee-Leased Companies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .25 4.1. Profitability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .25 4.2. Investment Activity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .25 4.3. Restructuring and Adjustment Activity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .28 5. The Relationship between Ownership Structure and Productivity: Evidence from the Early 1990s . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31 5.1. Productivity Analysis: Estimating Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31 5.2. Productivity Analysis: The Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .31 6. Corporate Governance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .33 6.1. Formation of Corporate Governance Bodies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .33 6.2. The Decision-Making Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .36 7. Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .40 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .42 Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .43 CASE Reports No. 47
  • 4. Piotr Kozarzewski Piotr Kozarzewski has worked for the CASE Foundation since 1992. He obtained a PhD in political science in 1999 from the Institute for Political Studies of the Polish Academy of Sciences. He has participated in numerous research and adviso-ry projects focusing on the systemic transformation of post-communist countries and especially on ownership transforma-tion, in Poland and various post-Soviet countries (including Kyrgyzstan, Kazkhstan, Bulgaria and Belarus). His chief research interest to date has been in the area of employee ownership, and he is the author of numerous publications on the subject of employee-owned companies in Poland. Piotr Kozarzewski also works for the Institute of Political Studies of the Polish Academy of Sciences, where he is involved in a study of the effects of privatisation of the Polish enterprises. Richard Woodward Richard Woodward has collaborated with the CASE Foundation since 1994. He graduated from the Pennsylvania State University (economics) and received his PhD at the Department of Sociology and Economy of £ódŸ University (2000). He has participated in numerous research projects on the privatisation and restructuring of state enterprises in Poland and other post-communist countries, with a special focus on employee ownership issues. He also supervised the work of the Polish researchers participating in an UNDP programme focused on the decentralisation of the public administration (1997–1999) and a team conducting research on the institutional framework supporting small and medium-sized enter-prises (1997–1999). 4 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward CASE Reports No. 47
  • 5. 5 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... This volume contains the output of country research undertaken in Poland by Piotr Kozarzewski and Richard Woodward under the international comparative project "Secondary Privatization: the Evolution of Ownership Struc-tures of Privatized Enterprises". The project was supported by the European Union's Phare ACE* Programme 1997 (project P97-8201 R) and was coordinated by Barbara B³aszczyk from the Center for Social and Economic Research (CASE) in Warsaw, Poland. The support of the ACE Programme made it possible to organize the cooperation of an international group of schol-ars (from the Czech Republic, France, Poland, Slovenia and the U.K.). The entire project was devoted to the investiga-tion of secondary ownership changes in enterprises priva-tized in special privatization schemes (i.e., mass privatization schemes and MEBOs**) in three Central European countries – the Czech Republic, Poland and Slovenia. Through a com-bination of different research methods, such as secondary analysis of previous research, analysis of legal and other reg-ulatory instruments, original field research, statistical data CASE Reports No. 47 base research and econometric analysis of individual enter-prise data, the project aimed to investigate the scope, pace and trends in secondary ownership changes, the factors and barriers affecting them and the degree of ownership con-centration resulting from them. The authors begin with a general discussion of MEBOs in Poland and go on to analyze ownership changes in a sample of such companies. First, they present the initial ownership structures created at the time of privatization and the evo-lution of those structures through 1999, and then go on to analyze the factors behind these changes and the relation-ships between the evolution of ownership structures on the one hand and economic performance and corporate gover-nance on the other. We hope that the results of this research will be of great interest for everyone interested in the little-researched question of what has happened to companies after privati-zation in transition countries. Barbara B³aszczyk Preface * "Action for Cooperation in the Field of Economics". ** Management-Employee Buyouts.
  • 6. 6 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward CASE Reports No. 47
  • 7. 7 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 1. Introduction: The Role of Employee Buyouts in the Polish Privatization Process1 In the Polish literature and legislation relating to privati-zation, two general types of privatization of state enterpris-es are generally distinguished. The first, privatization by commercial methods such as trade sales and initial public offerings, is currently referred to as indirect privatization (previously as capital privatization). The second, with which we will be concerned in this paper, is currently referred to as direct privatization (previously, as liquidation privatiza-tion2). In direct privatization, the state enterprise is dis-solved and its assets transferred (by one of three methods) to the private sector. The three methods of direct privati-zation are leasing of assets, sale of assets, and inkind contri-bution of assets to a company. Leasing decidedly dominates as the preferred form of direct privatization, and it is leased firms that we are concerned with in this paper, as the vast majority of employee buyouts in the Polish privatization process have been generated via the leasing variant of direct privatization3. In fact, since these employee buyouts only become real buyouts after several years of leasing, in the remainder of this paper we will refer to the companies in question not as employee buyouts, but rather as employee-leased companies. In the leasing variant of direct privatization, at least 50 percent of the employees of the state enterprise being liq-uidated must form a company to lease the assets of the CASE Reports No. 47 enterprise. Moreover, no corporate investors or foreigners were allowed to participate in the absence of special per-mission from the privatization ministry4. For this reason such companies are commonly referred to in Poland as "employee-owned companies" (spó³ki pracownicze). By 31 December, 1998, 2966 state enterprises had completed either privatization or "Article 19 liquidation" (see the first footnote), with 240 indirect privatizations, 512 firms trans-ferred to the National Investment Funds, 1515 direct priva-tizations and 699 Article 19 liquidations. At this point, there-fore, 51.1 percent of all privatizations were direct privatiza-tions. Since about 66 percent of the direct privatizations were leasing cases5, by the end of 1998 lease-leveraged employee buyout represented about one third of the complet-ed privatizations carried out under the supervision of the priva-tization ministry6, thus constituting the single most frequent-ly used method (in terms of the numbers of enterprises pri-vatized. It is important to note that this privatization method was intended by Polish legislators to be applied in the case of small and medium-sized enterprises, and for the most part this has been the case in practice. Most of the firms in this category are small- to medium-sized firms, usu-ally with less than 500 employees. As of 1998, 78.2 percent of leased companies had up to 250 employees, 19.7 percent had 251–1000 employees, and 2.1 percent had over 10007. 1 This research was undertaken with support from the European Union's Phare ACE Program 1997, project P97-8201 R "Secondary Privatisation: The Evolution of Ownership Structure of Privatised Companies", coordinated by Professor Barbara Blaszczyk, CASE Foundation, Warsaw. The content of the publication is the sole responsibility of the authors and in no way represents the views of the Commission or its services. We would also like to thank Professor Maria Jarosz of the Polish Academy of Sciences for kindly allowing us to utilize the data bases created in research projects conducted under her direction. 2 This is not to be confused with liquidation based on Article 19 of the 1981 Law on State Enterprises. Article 19 liquidation is applied to an insol-vent state enterprise, entailing its dissolution and the sale of its assets, and means the end of the enterprise as an economic unit, in contrast to direct privatization, in which the economic activity of the state enterprise is continued. 3 Since 1995, we can also refer to the National Investment Fund program as a third type of privatization – Poland's version of voucher privatiza-tion. Reference is also often made to "small privatization." No separate law governed this process, which generally affected very small businesses in the areas of retail trade and consumer services (grocers' shops, restaurants, barber shops, etc.) and was largely carried out by local governments without supervision by the privatization ministry. 4 The new privatization act of 30 August, 1996, requires that – unless a special exemption is granted – at least 20% of the shares of companies pri-vatized by leasing be held by outsiders. 5 See Central Statistical Office (1999), 31, Kozarzewski et al. (2000), 32–33. 6 If one considers employment, direct privatization does not outweigh capital privatization so strongly, as total employment in firms privatized by these two methods was – at least until recently – much closer to being equal. See Central Statistical Office (1995), 62–3. 7 See Kozarzewski et al. (2000), 50.
  • 8. 8 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward Year privatized Number % 1990 3 2.7 1991 41 36.9 1992 23 20.7 1993 14 12.6 1994 13 11.7 1995 8 7.2 1996 8 7.2 CASE Reports No. 47 Several preferential conditions facilitate this form of pri-vatization. First, the 1990 Law on Privatization essentially gave insiders precedence in privatizing their enterprises. Second, preferential interest rates are applied for the lease payments. The interest payment (referred to in Polish regu-lations as the "additional payment" [op³ata dodatkowa]) was originally set by the Finance Ministry at 75 percent of the central bank refinancing rate. (Moreover, the interest pay-ments could, to some extent, be postponed during the first two years of the leasing period.) Finally, the corporate income tax law allowed the firms to include the interest portion of the lease payments as costs in their accounts, thus reducing their tax liability. Later, it was determined that if the central bank refinance rate were to exceed 40 per-cent, the interest rate would be set at 30 percent (75 per-cent of 40 percent)8. In 1993, the interest rate was lowered again, to 50 percent of the refinance rate9. At the same time, further favorable conditions were created in order to stim-ulate investment in the employee-leased companies; these provisions, as well as the difficulties which leased firms con-tinue to face in spite of these measures, will be discussed below. The new privatization act of 30 August, 1996, once again liberalized leasing conditions somewhat. The data about employee-leased companies used in this paper were gathered directly in the companies during research conducted by the interdisciplinary team headed by Professor Maria Jarosz of the Polish Academy of Sciences: a three-year study (1993–1995) devoted to employee privati-zation (with a sample of 200 companies) and a four-year study (1997–2000) devoted to direct privatization (the sam-ple for this study included about 160 employee-leased com-panies) 10. The samples were representative with respect to sector (manufacturing, construction, services, trade), size (mea-sured by number of employees) and region. Data were col-lected using two methods: interviews with the main actors in the companies and collection of hard data by question-naire (these included data from the balance sheets and finan-cial statements, as well as information on ownership and corporate governance issues, employment, restructuring, investments, etc.). Most financial and ownership data were collected for several periods of time: immediately following privatization, year-end, and at the time of the research (usu-ally the middle of a given year). Thus, we use two separate databases, each for three subsequent semi-panel polls: 1993–1996 (polls in 1993, 1994, and 1995) and 1997–2000 (polls in 1997, 1998, and 1999), which we refer to as Data-base 1 and Database 2, respectively. The sample for Database 2, drawn on most frequently in this paper, consists of 110 firms privatized between 1990 and 199611. This constitutes 12.9% of the total number of compa-nies privatized by the leasing method through the end of 1996. For the purposes of the paper, all source data were processed. Where we considered this useful, we also used data from the earlier study as an additional source of infor-mation. Some findings of other members of Maria Jarosz's team are also referred to12. In discussing certain correla-tions, we refer to various variables referring to ownership structures using abbreviated labels. An explanation of these labels and the variables, as well as tables containing the cor-relations themselves, are found in the appendix13. Table 1. Number of firms privatized, by year (%) Source: own calculations using Database 2. 8 Zarz¹dzenie Ministra Finansów z dnia 7 maja 1991 r. 9 Zarz¹dzenie Ministra Finansów z dnia 13 maja 1993 r. (Monitor Polski 1993 nr 26, poz. 274). 10 For detailed discussions of the results of these studies, see Jarosz (ed.), 1994, 1995, 1996, 1999, 2000. 11 The moment of privatization is identified with the year in which the company was registered; we include among the firms privatized in 1990 one which was actually registered in 1989, since the Polish privatization law was not adopted until 1990. 12 Most importantly, Gardawski (2000) and Kozarzewski (1999). 13 The analysis presented here is indicative of linear correlations only. No tests have been made for non-linear relationships.
  • 9. 9 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 2. The Evolution of Ownership Structures From the very beginning, employee leasing has been the most "employee-oriented" privatization path, in terms of ownership structure. Immediately following privatization, insiders possessed, on the average, 92 percent of the shares in the sample of employee-leased companies, and in 95 per-cent of those companies, insiders owned over 50 percent of the shares14. In employee-leased companies, the share of non-man-agerial employees in ownership has steadily decreased, from 58.7 percent immediately after privatization to 31.5 percent in 1999. It is worth noting, however, that despite wide-spread selling of their shares by non-managerial employees, by 1999 only in 6 percent of firms had this group of owners vanished completely. In most companies, non-managerial employees retained at least minor blocks of shares. Very often those blocks were very small: in 17 percent of the firms they did not exceed 10 percent, and in almost half of the companies (43 percent) non-managerial employees did Table 2. Ownership structure in the average employee-leased company immediately after privatization (%) CASE Reports No. 47 not have blocking capabilities at shareholders' meetings (at least 25 percent of the votes). Because of the dispersed character of these blocks of shares, in practice the voting capacity of non-managerial employees is even weaker than these numbers indicate. If we assume that this group would need at least 50 percent of the shares in order to block cer-tain decisions at a shareholders' meeting, then it is clear that in at least 76 percent of the companies under review, non-managerial employees lack decisive influence on the deci-sion- making process as owners15. While non-managerial employees were losing their shares, the number of shares in the hands of outsiders increased fivefold (from 7.6 percent to 38.5 percent). Almost all of them are domestic investors; only three firms have foreign investors (in two cases, strategic investors). A large portion of the outsider shares represent concentrated holdings: 44.4 percent of the outsider shares were held by owners whom respondents referred to as strategic 14 Where weighted, average ownership structure figures are weighted by end-of-year employment for the year preceding the given ownership structure observation. 15 Of course, they can influence decision-making in other ways, for example, through trade unions, workers' protests, etc. However, analysis shows that the situation in almost all employee-leased companies is largely free of conflicts, with trade unions passive and even – in many companies – ceas-ing to exist. Shareholder groups Simple average (%) Weighted average (%) Outsiders 8.0 7.6 Managers 41.0 33.7 Non-managerial employees 51.0 58.7 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 3. Percentage of employee-leased companies dominated by various owner groups immediately following privatization Biggest shareholder group Simple average (%) Weighted average (%) Strategic outside investors 8.9 4.9 Managers 32.7 37.3 Non-managerial employees 50.5 57.8 a Domination by one of four main shareholder groups (strategic investors, other outside investors, managers, and non-managerial employees) is defined by the group with the largest holdings. Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 10. 10 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward CASE Reports No. 47 investors. There is also a large group of private firms and entrepreneurs (18.7 percent). However, the second largest group of outsider owners consists of unidentified "others" (34 percent of outsider shares). One might hypothesize that this group consists mostly of former employees of the companies who lost their jobs due to layoffs, retired, or left for other reasons. Respondents were not asked in the survey to identify whether these "others" were in fact former employees, so we can only test this hypothesis indirectly. Initial calculations have not yielded clear results. There is negative correlation between growth in the shares of this group between the time of privatization and mid-1997 (GROO) and the change in the shares of non-managerial workers (GRWOR) – that is, the more the share of the workers fell, the more share of "other" outsiders grew – and there is a positive correlation between the change in employment from the time of priva-tization to mid-1997 (P.C. CH) and GRWOR (so that, for example, the more employment fell, the more the share of workers fell). However, there is no direct correlation between GROO and P.C. CH – between the drop in employment and the growth in the "other" outsiders' share. One might hypothesize that in cases in which employment drops were particularly drastic, these drops reflected a dra-matic worsening of the companies' economic prospects and workers sold their shares (e.g., to management) in a des-perate attempt to minimize their losses, in which case there would be a negative correlation between GROO and P.C. CH up to a certain threshold of employment reduction, beyond which this correlation would disappear and be replaced by a negative correlation between P.C. CH and the growth in the share of Executive Board members (GRMAN). And in fact, where employment reductions were over 50%, there is a negative correlation between GRMAN and P.C. CH. However, for other firms we observe no cor-relation between GROO and P.C. CH. It is, however, quite certain that we are not dealing with small portfolio investors here, because of the generally small size of the companies under review and the fact that less than two percent of them are listed on the Warsaw Stock Exchange. Tables 4 and 5 show how the detailed ownership struc-ture of employee-leased companies evolved over the course of time. Interestingly, by comparing simple with weighted aver-ages, we see that at the time of privatization, the role of strategic investors is lower, and that of non-managerial employees greater, in the case of weighted averages. This means that strategic owners were generally involved in the privatization of smaller than average companies, while the percentage of shares belonging to non-managerial employ-ees at the time of privatization was generally higher in larg-er firms. By 1999 the situation has changed: while strategic Table 4. Ownership structure of employee-leased companies (weighted averages; %)16 Shareholders Immediately after privatization 1997 1998 1999 Outsiders 1. Strategic investors (domestic and foreign) 1.4 9.1 15.2 17.1 2. Other domestic outside investors a. private firms – 0.6 1.5 2.1 b. commercialized firms – 0.4 0.4 0.0 c. private banks – – – – d. state-owned banks – – – – e. private businessmen 4.2 4.3 5.1 6.4 f. others 2.0 7.0 9.2 12.9 3. Other foreign investors – 0.1 0.1 0.0 Insiders 4. Supervisory board members employed in the company* 9.4 10.6 6.1 3.9 5. Executive board members 8.7 13.4 15.1 14.2 6. Other managers 15.7 13.7 15.4 11.1 7. Non-managerial employees 58.7 41.0 31.8 31.5 TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 * Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. Source: own calculations using Database 2. 16 In this and other tables "0" or "0.0" means that the frequency of occurrence of the given category is less than 0.5 or 0.05 respectively; a hyphen means that the category is absent, and "x" means lack of data.
  • 11. 11 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 5. Ownership structure of employee-leased companies (simple averages; %) investor presence tended to be noted in smaller firms at the time of privatization, in 1999 they tended to be present in larger firms. Executive board members' shares are consis-tently smaller when averages are weighted, meaning that they tend to dominate in smaller firms. As mentioned above, the higher non-managerial employee holdings in the weighted averages at the time of privatization indicate that at that time the largest group of employees exercised the strongest ownership domination in the largest firms. By the late 1990s, however, this difference has disappeared, indi-cating that the holdings of this group are now relatively equal with respect to the size of the firm. We will analyze the structure of employee-leased com-panies along two axes: concentrated versus dispersed own-ership, and insider versus outsider ownership. A combina-tion of these two axes gives us four main groups of investors: (1) outsiders with small holdings, (2) strategic outside investors, (3) insider shareholders with large hold-ings (members of managing and supervisory bodies), (4) insiders with small holdings (generally, non-managerial employees). Table 6 illustrates the dynamics of ownership structures with respect to these four groups. We see that more and more shares are in the hands of both outsider groups, while fewer and fewer shares are held by non-managerial employees (although in 1999 the employee shareholdings seem to stabilize). The position of managerial staff is more stabilized, although recently they have also begun to lose ground. Although it is not evident from Table 6, earlier studies show that in the first half of the 1990s managers were actively buying shares from non-man-agerial employees and increasing their holdings17. Moreover, managers are a far from monolithic group, consisting of three main subgroups: executive board mem-bers, supervisory board members employed in the compa-nies, and lower level managers. Through 1997, executive and supervisory board members were actively increasing 17 For more, see Gardawski (1996), 96–98, and Kozarzewski (1999), 78–82. CASE Reports No. 47 Shareholders Immediately after privatization 1997 1998 1999 Outsiders 1. Strategic investors (domestic and foreign) 3.3 7.1 9.4 11.0 2. Other domestic outside investors a. private firms – 0.6 2.1 2.7 b. commercialized firms – 0.4 0.2 0.0 c. private banks – – – – d. sta te-owned banks – – – – e. private businessmen 2.5 2.3 2.0 4.5 f. others 2.2 6.4 8.5 12.2 3. Other foreign investors – 0.2 0.7 0.6 Insiders 4. Supervisory board members employed in the company* 11.5 12.0 8.1 6.4 5. Executive board members 16.0 18.8 18.9 19.3 6. Other managers 13.5 11.9 14.5 11.0 7. Non-managerial employees 51.0 40.3 36.2 32.3 TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 * Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 6. Ownership structure dynamics in employee-leased companies, by major shareholder groups (weighted averages; %) Shareholder groups Immediately after privatization 1997 1998 1999 Strategic outside investor 1.4 9.1 15.2 17.1 Other outsider investors 6.2 12.3 16.3 22.0 Managers 33.7 37.6 36.7 29.4 Non-managerial employees 58.7 41.0 31.8 31.5 TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 12. 12 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward Table 7. Blocks of shares held by executive and supervisory board members (%) their shares in the companies (Table 7). Later the situation among executive board members stabilized, but the share of the supervisory board members began to decrease rapid-ly. This is probably not due to their selling of shares, but rather to the rotation in supervisory board membership, which is much higher than in the executive boards. As a rule, former supervisory board members still have managerial posts, and for this reason the total share of management remains relatively stable. The lower part of Table 7 shows that in order to effec-tively exercise their voting rights, members of both boards in question have to cooperate: thus, for example, in 1999 acting together they can control almost three times more companies than if they act separately. The Jarosz group's research confirms the large extent of synergy between executive and supervisory boards, with the dominant posi-tion of the executive board in the decision-making system, in employee-leased companies18. The data presented here fail to confirm earlier predictions that the ownership structure of employee-leased companies would tend towards steadily increasing management domina-tion19, since in most companies the position of elites has sta-bilized. However, two trends are confirmed: the decrease in the shares of non-managerial employees and the increase of those of outsider investors, both strategic and non-strategic. Another earlier prediction concerned the appearance of manager-outsider ownership coalitions20. The fact that in 57 percent of employee-leased companies, more than 50 percent of the shares belong to managers and outsiders together, could be seen as supporting this view. On the other hand, only 9 per-cent of the companies have both an outside investor and an inside investor possessing at least 10 percent of shares. In the remainder of this section, we will concentrate on changes in ownership structures in terms of shareholding by three groups of shareholders – strategic investors, top man-agement (i.e., Executive Board members), and non-manageri-al employees – considering each group to have attained a dom-inant block of shares when it exceeds 20%. First, in Table 8, we look at how many firms had domination by each group at the time of privatization and in 1997, 1998 and 1999, and then, in CASE Reports No. 47 18 See Kozarzewski (2000a, 2000b). 19 See Gardawski (1995); Kozarzewski (1999). 20 See Gardawski (2000). Immediately after privatization 1997 1998 1999 Average block of shares: – executive board 8.7 13.4 15.2 14.2 – supervisory board 9.4 10.6 6.1 3.9 TOTAL 18.1 24.0 21.3 18.1 Percent of companies with ownership dominance of: – executive board 7 8 8 8 – supervisory board 3 6 2 1 – both boards together 25 23 29 25 Source: own calculations using Database 1 and Database 2. Table 8. Number of firms in which the given ownership groups had shares of at least 20% At time of privatization 1997 1998 1999 No data 8 9 13 14 Strategic investor (SI) 4 8 10 12 Executive board members (Managers) 5 10 10 8 Non-managerial employees 69 50 42 36 All three 1 1 0 2 SI and managers 0 0 1 0 Managers and employees 17 20 20 24 SI and employees 1 5 4 3 None 5 7 10 11 Total 110 110 110 110 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 13. 13 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 9. Transformation matrix Table 9, we present a transformation matrix. The latter shows the transformation trajectory of firms grouped with respect to dominant shareholders at the time of privatization: in the rightmost column, we see the number of firms in each group at the time of privatization, and looking leftward, we see where the firms in these groups ended up in 1997. The diag-onal, in which the numbers are printed in boldface, shows firms that remained in the same group in which they started. Again, all this confirms that in general non-managerial employees are slowly losing ground, while top management and strategic investors tend to consolidate and increase their holdings. We obtain an even sharper picture of the concentration that is going on if we look at the average shares of the single largest shareholder. In Table 10 we see that in the average company, the sin-gle largest shareholder held over one quarter of all the com-pany's shares by 1998. This indicates a large degree of con-centration on the average. Analysis of simple correlations between various owner-ship variables bears out the foregoing observations. The variables analyzed (presented in detail in the appendix) include the following: the percentage of shares held by strategic investors (SI), by Executive Board members (MAN), and by non-managerial employees (WOR), the per-centage of the work force holding shares (OWN), dummy variables for the degree of equality of shareholding (EQ1, EQ2, EQ3, and EQ4, in ascending order of equality). Relationships between various ownership variables tend to be pretty much as one would expect. Thus, for example, the size and growth of the shares of strategic investors and Execu-tive Board members on the one hand and the size and growth of non-managerial employees' shares on the other. There is a positive correlation between WOR and EQ3, which is logical given that EQ3 is a dummy representing a relatively high degree of equality and WOR the percentage of company's shares held by non-managerial employees (discrepancies between these two measures can arise in cases in which a large number of employees have been laid off or left the firm for other reasons but kept their shares). There is a correlation between equality and the percentage of the work force hold-ing shares (OWN), as evidenced in the negative correlations between EQ1 and OWN. Similarly, there is a positive relation-ship between equality and the percentage of shares held by non-managerial employees (WOR), as EQ3 is positively corre-lated with WOR and EQ1 negatively correlated with WOR for all three observations. Conversely, there is a positive correla-tion between MAN and EQ1. Generally, the size and growth of the shares of strategic investors and top management are positively correlated with the percentage of company shares held by the single largest shareholder (BIG). Again, as we would expect, we observe a positive correlation between the growth of non-managerial employees' shares (GRWOR) and the year of privatization (YR1) and a negative correlation between YR1 and the growth of strategic investors' shares CASE Reports No. 47 Had over 20% in 1997 Had over 20% at time of privatization No data SI M Wor SMW SM MW SW None Total at time of priv. No data 5 0 0 1 0 0 2 0 0 8 Strategic investor 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 4 (S) Exec. Bd. memb. (M) 0 0 4 0 0 0 1 0 0 5 Non-mg. workers (W) 3 4 2 48 0 0 5 3 4 69 All three 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 S & M 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 M & W 0 0 4 1 0 0 12 0 0 17 S & W 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 None 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 5 Total 9 8 10 50 1 0 20 5 7 110 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 10. Holdings of the single largest shareholder (weighted averages) N Minimum Maximum Mean Standard Deviation 1997 88 0.1 86.3 22.896 20.592 1998 93 0.3 100.0 27.652 26.075 1999 108 2.0 100.0 27.364 25.507 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 14. 14 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward time of privatization 1997 1998 1999 Strategic vestor in 0.00 0.29 -1.09 State Treasury -- - 5.32 Individual entrepreneurs 1.23 0.77 0.56 0.74 Other outside investors 1.49 1.03 2.49 3.51 Supervisory Board members* 5.95 11.37 5.92 3.15 Executive Board members 32.23 38.33 44.00 39.71 Other managerial employees 20.47 19.29 20.37 11.12 non-managerial employees 38.64 28.92 26.66 35.36 * Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. Source: own calculations using Database 2. CASE Reports No. 47 (GRSI). This means that the earlier the firm was privatized, the more the worker share has fallen and the more the strategic investor share has grown. We now turn to a more detailed analysis of the evolution of ownership structures in two groups of companies: those with large ownership shares of top management (i.e., Exec-utive Board members) and those with strategic investors. 2.1. Companies Dominated by Top Management Holdings of top management – i.e., Executive Board members – were over 20% in 23 firms, or less than a quar-ter of sample, at the time of privatization, in 31 (almost a third) in 1997 and 1998, and 34 in 1999. A comparison with the sample as a whole (see Table 1) is not particularly enlightening. While among the firms dominated by top management a higher percentage was privatized in 1991, a higher percentage was also privatized in 1995 and 1996. Next, we look at the average ownership structure in these firms, comparing those which already had top man-agement domination at the time of privatization with the larger group of those that had such domination in mid-1997. Both groups look very similar; in particular, in both we observe a decline in top management holdings from 1998 to 1999. The most significant difference between the two groups appears to be the smaller average share held by top management in the larger group, where top management had not been in a dominant position from the very begin-ning. This is quite clearly an indication of inertia. Next, we compare firms in which top management gained control between the time of privatization and mid-1997 with those in which it neither had such control at the outset nor gained it later. We do this by looking at the initial ownership structure of the five firms in which top management held less than 20% at the time of privatization but at least 20% in 1997, comparing it with that of the 68 firms in which top manage-ment held less than 20% as of mid-1997 and for which we have the appropriate data. Table 11. Firms with top management domination in 1999, by year of privatization Number Percent 1990 1 2.9 1991 16 47.1 1992 3 8.8 1993 4 11.8 1994 3 8.8 1995 3 8.8 1996 4 11.8 Total 31 100.0 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 12. Firms with top management shares > 20% at time of privatization (weighted averages) Table 13. Firms with top management shares > 20% in mid-1997 (weighted averages) time of privatization 1997 1998 1999 strategic investor 0.00 0.19 3.06 4.50 private firms -- - 0.91 state-owned companies - - 0.43 - State Treasury -- - 3.16 individual entrepreneurs 0.81 0.51 0.35 0.44 other outside investors 1.06 5.85 6.01 7.29 Supervisory Board members* 6.51 10.06 6.34 4.15 Executive Board members 24.64 34.53 37.53 34.09 other managerial employees 20.54 18.00 21.13 15.85 non-managerial employees 46.44 30.87 25.16 29.61 * Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 15. 15 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 14. Firms in which top management gained domination: Initial ownership structure Minimum Maximum Mean Standard strategic investor 0 0 0.00 0.00 individual entrepreneurs 0 0 0.00 0.00 other outside investors 0 1 0.27 0.44 Supervisory Board members 0 22 8.50 8.69 Executive Board members 4 17 8.75 4.97 other managerial employees 7 31 19.41 8.72 non-managerial employees 49 74 63.08 10.15 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 15. Firms in which top management does not dominate: Initial ownership structure Minimum Maximum Mean Standard strategic investor 0 66 1.78 9.72 individual entrepreneurs 0 80 5.32 12.60 other outside investors 0 20 1.65 4.19 Supervisory Board members 0 54 10.02 12.40 Executive Board members 0 18 6.20 4.69 other managerial employees 0 42 13.09 9.24 non-managerial employees 0 93 61.95 25.90 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Examination of the two above tables shows that there is very little difference between the two groups with respect to their average initial ownership structure. The most significant difference seems to be that in the group in which top man-agement later attained domination, lower levels of manage-ment had larger holdings than in those firms in which top man-agement had not gained a share of over 20% by mid-1997. 2.2. Companies with Strategic Investors As of mid-1997, 13 companies had such investors; 17 companies had them in mid-1998. No new strategic investors appeared in 1999. Comparing with the privatization dates of firms in the sample as a whole, it seems that companies privatized ear-lier may have a slight advantage in finding strategic outside investors (over 70% of them were privatized before 1993, whereas slightly over 60% of the sample as a whole was pri-vatized in that time). Foreign investors were present in only two firms in the sample by mid-1998 (one of which had gained its foreign investor in the year since the previous survey, in 1997). Both companies were privatized in 1991. As in the case of firms dominated by top management, we look at the average ownership structure in these firms, comparing those which already had strategic investors at the time of privatization with the larger group of those that had them in mid-1997. CASE Reports No. 47 Deviation Deviation For the last group (of which only five firms provided data on their ownership structure), the absence of data from even a single firm in one year can create large fluctuations in the mean values (and in fact we observe such fluctuations), so we should exercise great caution in interpreting the pat-terns in the Table 18. Next, we compare the initial ownership structure of the eight firms that had no strategic investors at the time of pri-vatization but found them by mid-1997 with that of the 84 firms that had no strategic investor as of mid-1997 and for which we have the appropriate data. It is interesting to note that in companies that found strate-gic investors after privatization, top management owned much fewer shares at the time of privatization than in the case of those that did not find strategic investors later. This is borne out by analysis of correlations between various ownership variables, which shows, for example, negative correlations between the shares of strategic investors (SI) and those of Executive Board members (MAN) in 1997 and 1999. Table 16. Number of companies with strategic investors in 1998, by year of privatization Number Percent 1990 1 5.9 1991 9 52.9 1992 2 11.8 1993 2 11.8 1994 1 5.9 1996 2 11.8 Total 17 100.0 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 16. 16 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward CASE Reports No. 47 Table 17. Firms with strategic investors in mid-1997: ownership structure (weighted averages) time of privatization 1997 1998 1999 strategic investor 6.37 44.31 55.612 56.34 private rms fi -- 0.686 3.19 state-owned companies - - 0.954 - individual entrepreneurs 0.38 0.20 2.321 - other utside nvestorso i -8.43 8.640 14.23 Supervisory Board members* 5.71 7.72 0.798 0.69 Executive Board members 3.39 4.82 2.141 5.35 other managerial employees 20.37 11.58 6.190 3.48 non-managerial employees 63.77 22.93 22.659 16.23 * Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 18. Firms with strategic investors at time of privatization: ownership structure (weighted averages) time of privatization 1997 1998 1999 strategic investor 53.28 38.57 55.079 55.40 private firms -- - 10.67 individual trepreneurs en 2.86 1.16 -- other utside vestorso in -7.49 25.704 10.05 Supervisory Board members* 7.56 28.35 0.227 1.32 Executive Board members 3.50 2.83 -11. 67 other managerial employees 26.30 10.97 1.716 1.73 non-managerial employees 6.51 10.63 17.274 6.24 * Note: Supervisory Board members in 1999 are only those who were also employees; prior to 1999 there was no such restriction in this definition. Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 19. Firms that gained strategic investors: initial ownership structure (weighted averages) Minimum Maximum Mean Standard Deviation strategic investor 0 0 0.00 0.00 individual entrepreneurs 0 0 0.00 0.00 other outside investors 0 15 4.34 6.44 Supervisory Board members 1 69 10.47 19.03 Executive Board members 2 15 4.91 3.39 other managerial employees 0 41 21.65 13.23 non-managerial employees 10 88 58.63 26.30 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 20. Firms without strategic investors: initial ownership structure (weighted averages) Minimum Maximum Mean Standard Deviation strategic investor 0 0 0.00 0.00 individual entrepreneurs 0 80 5.39 12.98 other outside investors 0 30 1.56 4.68 Supervisory Board members 0 54 10.72 12.98 Executive Board members 0 100 11.85 12.61 other managerial employees 0 37 13.67 9.93 non-managerial employees 0 99 56.81 25.56 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 17. 17 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 3. Factors in the Post-Privatization Evolution of Ownership Structure 3.1. Motivations for Choice of the EBO Privatization Method and Subsequent Changes in Ownership Structure Employee privatization is a privatization method used only when it is chosen by insider actors. What are those actors' goals in employing this method of privatization in the enterprises where they work? Members of company elites were asked about this issue in interviews carried out by the Jarosz research team. In their responses, managers of the companies declared purely material goals aimed at the survival of their enterpris-es. Contrary to what might have been expected, such issues as independence of the firm, propertization and mobilization of employees, etc., were mentioned very rarely. But even if the main actors in state-owned enterprises were not advo-cates of employee ownership, the employee leasing path was attractive for them because, on the one hand, it was a rela-tively easy privatization method (especially for small and medium-sized enterprises), and on the other hand, it elimi-nated the threat posed by outsiders, thus minimizing the impact of privatization on existing interests and power struc-tures. This path was also attractive for non-managerial employees because it gave them a chance to acquire a title to part of the enterprise's property and opened up the prospect of material profits from dividends and capital gains. It took some time, however, for managers to become aware of the links between share ownership and authority in a capitalist system. Once this became clear to them, they began to concentrate shares in their hands more actively. By the mid-1990s, this process of "economization of mentality" was more or less complete. CASE Reports No. 47 In addition to the incentive for management to acquire shares in order to consolidate its power, there are various factors that can contribute, alternatively, to the perpetua-tion of the initial (rather dispersed) ownership structure or to particular types of changes, while others can have ambivalent impacts on ownership changes. One variable we will look at as having a possible effect on both ownership changes and other types of activity in the firm is unioniza-tion. This is due to the fact that unionization can be seen as a measure of employee power which may compound the effects of the power that employees exercise as owners in the companies of this sample. As we see from table 21, a large number of the companies – almost half – lack unions altogether. In Table 22, we categorize a number of psychological and behavioral factors, as well as factors related to the legal environment, with respect to their impact on the evolution of the ownership structures of employee-leased companies. We believe that the patterns of ownership structure evolu-tion observed in employee-leased companies are to a large extent determined by those factors. Nevertheless, the analyzed group of companies is quite heterogeneous. It varies with respect to size, sec-toral affiliation, financial condition and many other specif-ic factors. In Sections 3.2 to 3.4, therefore, we analyze the impact of those factors, as well as unionization, to find reasons for particular deviations from the most common pattern of evolution (presented at the beginning of the previous section). In Section 3.5 we look at methods for ownership transformations (including trade in shares and issues of new shares), and in Sections 3.6 and 3.7 we attempt to investigate the factors behind transitions to management domination and strategic owner presence in particular. Table 21. Firms with no unions, by year Number Percent N At time of privatization 24 30.8 78 1997 21 26.9 78 1998 47 43.5 108 1999 24 38.7 62 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 18. 18 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward Table 22. Chief factors behind perpetuation and change of the initial ownership structure of employee-leased companies 3.2. Initial Ownership Structure We begin our analysis with an investigation of the ques-tion of path dependency: how does the initial ownership structure at the moment of privatization (in terms of domi-nance of a certain group of owners) influence the further evolution of ownership structures? Our analysis began with a presentation of the transition matrix in Table 9, which showed that outside strategic investors and top manage-ment are steadily gaining ground (although the position of the latter seems to have stabilized and may even be begin-ning to decline), and non-managerial employees are steadily losing it. In Table 23, we take a closer look at the evolution of the ownership structure in the companies, grouping them with respect to the type of owner dominant at the time of privatization. Companies with a concentrated insider pattern of initial ownership also seem to tend towards the average owner-ship structure for the whole sample, although in manager-dominated companies the share of managers fell more rapidly than elsewhere in the period 1997–1999. Interest-ingly, it is in these companies that outside strategic investors had the least opportunities to acquire shares. The direction of some processes in these two groups of companies differs from that in the group of initial strategic investors' dominance, where insider shareholders have practically disappeared and almost two thirds of the shares are now concentrated in the strategic investor's hands. Changes in the shares of managers and outside investors have, as experience shows, two opposite vectors: on one hand, recently more and more strategic outsiders, especially in small firms, have become strategic insiders by acquiring top managerial posts in the companies. This can be seen when analyzing the unweighted ownership structure data: comparing to the previous year, in 1999 the unweighted share of strategic investors fell almost two times from 63.4 to 38.1 percent. On the other hand, newly nominated mem-bers of the Executive Board are often formally not emp-loyees of the companies for taxation reasons. In initially out-sider- dominated companies, managers could attempt to buy shares from strategic outsiders in order to regain control, while some strategic outsider investors could have become disillusioned with the companies and begun to sell their shares. Finally, changes in proportions between managers and non-managerial employees could be caused by – among other things – rotation of managerial posts among insiders. 3.3. Sector, Company Size, and Unionization The next table shows the trends in ownership changes by sector. We see that construction companies are the most "outsiderized" in the whole sample, while in services firms were not able to find a strategic external investor. In manu-facturing and trade we see some increase in outsider share- CASE Reports No. 47 Factors Perpetuation Change Mentality and behavior “Legacy” of state-owned enterprise - organizational structure - structures of power and influence - old mentality of insiders Changes in the position of various insider groups - fear of outsiders - property factor: ownership = power - reconfiguration of functions and tasks - insiders have to adapt to new conditions - perception of outsiders as representing an opportunity for new investments, management techniques, etc. Legal environment Privatization law - employee leasing is insider-dominated - corporate partners and foreigners barred from participation in privatization - lower leasing fees (since 1997) - faster transfer of title to assets to employee-leased company (since 1997) - outsiders should hold at least 20 percent of shares (since 1997) - faster transfer of title to assets to employee-leased company (since 1997) Commercial Code - companies’ charters can contain restrictions on circulation of shares - new organizational structure - system of property rights - mechanisms of raising capital, share issues and share trading
  • 19. 19 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 23. Evolution of ownership structure, by initial ownership structure of the companies (weighted averages; %) holdings, especially non-strategic, but still the biggest share of property remains in the hands of insiders. Company size is often regarded as very strong factor deter-mining various characteristics of enterprise behavior. We there-fore looked at the relationship between the degree of concen-tration and firm size (measured by employment). The only con-sistent correlation is the positive one between EQ3 and size at the time of privatization and in 1997, which is easily explained: Given low levels of personal savings at the beginning of the CASE Reports No. 47 transformation, it was more difficult for an individual or small group of individuals to buy a large block of shares in a large com-pany than in a small firm. It is also clear (see Section 4.3) that management ownership on the average appears in relatively small companies, while strategic investors appear in companies whose average employment is above the sample average. Is there a relationship between the direction of owner-ship structure changes and size? In table 25, we show the ownership structure evolution in three groups of companies Strategic investor Other outsiders Managers Non-managerial employees Initial strategic investors’ dominance Initial 53.3 2.9 37.4 6.5 1997 33.8 9.9 47.2 9.1 1998 48.9 33.9 0.3 16.9 1999 70.6 16.8 3.4 5.6 Initial managerial dominance Initial 0.0 13.4 59.2 27.4 1997 1.9 14.5 65.4 18.2 1998 0.1 25.3 51.3 23.3 1999 3.6 26.0 45.5 25.0 Initial non-managerial employee dominance Initial 0.0 3.9 25.4 70.7 1997 7.0 12.4 28.1 52.6 1998 16.2 12.0 32.7 39.1 1999 12.8 21.0 27.3 38.9 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 24. Evolution of ownership structure, by branch (weighted averages; %) Strategic investor Other outsiders Managers Non-managerial employees Manufacturing Initial 0.7 9.5 33.0 56.9 1997 1.8 12.4 39.2 46.6 1998 4.5 21.3 38.3 35.9 1999 7.5 25.6 31.5 35.4 Construction Initial 2.8 4.9 31.7 60.7 1997 23.3 17.5 31.5 27.8 1998 28.6 17.6 24.2 29.6 1999 32.4 21.1 22.0 24.0 Trade Initial 1.3 1.8 46.0 51.0 1997 0.1 9.9 57.2 31.9 1998 7.0 12.4 53.6 27.0 1999 8.1 22.8 44.2 24.9 Services Initial 0.0 1.7 29.3 69.1 1997 0.0 11.8 28.1 60.1 1998 0.0 10.6 42.9 46.5 1999 0.0 16.1 33.3 50.6 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 20. 20 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward Table 25. Evolution of ownership structure, by size of companies (%) Strategic investor Other outsiders Managers Non-managerial – small, medium-sized, and large21. As it turns out, the dif-ferences between the first two groups are not very great. In small and medium-sized companies, we observe an extend-ed period of accelerated propertization of managers in 1997–1998. Large companies seem to have undergone a more dynamic evolution, with a much larger share going to strategic investors, and the managerial share falling in 1997–1998. It is very hard to explain differences in ownership changes with respect to sector and size, although these vari-ables undoubtedly affect the processes observed. In the course of the study conducted by the Jarosz team, a hypoth-esis was formulated that different patterns of ownership transformations are determined primarily by sector and number of employees. The hypothesized relationships are illustrated in Table 2622. The author of this hypothesis, Juliusz Gardawski, assumes that "there is a certain optimum ownership structure for small and medium-sized firms established as a result of privatization of state-owned enter-prises" 23 and that this optimal structure is determined pri-marily by social relationships within the firm24. In Table 27, we present an analysis of ownership changes with respect to sector and size. This table shows that the situation is far more complex and not always consistent with the relationships hypothesized by Gardawski. Our results are different for all of manufacturing and for most construc-tion and trade firms. Additionally, it must be noted that sev-eral subgroups are too small to be representative; some are 21 We define small companies as having up to 100 employees, medium-sized companies as having 101–200 employees, and large companies as CASE Reports No. 47 having more than 200 employees. 22 Gardawski (2000), 163. 23 Ibid., 158. Here Gardawski assumes that almost all directly privatized companies are small or medium-sized. 24 Ibid, 151–158. employees Small Initial 2.7 5.6 36.6 55.2 1997 2.1 5.7 40.8 51.4 1998 2.6 9.3 45.1 43.0 1999 4.7 10.8 40.1 44.4 Medium-sized Initial 1.8 6.4 38.4 53.4 1997 2.0 13.9 45.1 39.0 1998 2.4 10.0 46.8 40.8 1999 4.4 19.3 40.6 35.7 Large Initial 1.2 6.1 32.6 60.1 1997 7.7 13.4 36.6 42.1 1998 15.7 20.0 33.0 31.3 1999 17.6 24.7 27.3 30.2 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 26. Ownership patterns in employee-leased companies in 1999 (Juliusz Gardawski) Sector Size of employment Form of ownership Manufacturing Small Medium-sized Large Investor companiesa Manager companies Manager-investor companies Construction Small Medium-sized Large Manager-employee companies Trade Small Medium-sized Large Manager companies Manager-investor companies Investor companies a By "investors" we understand external investors (outsiders). Source: Gardawski (2000), 163.
  • 21. 21 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 27. Ownership structure in employee-leased companies, by sector and number of employees, in 1999 (%) Number of employees Strategic investor Other outsiders Managers made up of only a single firm. In fact, only two groups of companies bear out Gardawski's hypothesis: small con-struction and medium-sized trade firms. Moreover, there is significant correlation between size and sector themselves. By the end of 1998, the average company in manufacturing employed 337 persons, in con-struction 194, in trade 157, and in services 101 persons (the average for the whole sample was 203 persons). Finally, unionization is negatively correlated with the top management share at the time of privatization and in mid- 1997, and negatively correlated with the non-managerial employee share in 1999. It is, however, not clear whether employee power resulting from unionization directly pre-vents management from accumulating employee shares, or whether the ownership effect is not due indirectly to union power, by virtue of unions' preventing layoffs (unionization is also negatively correlated with employment changes between the time of privatization and the end of 1996), and thus preventing worker shareholders from becoming out-sider shareholders. Interestingly, unionization is not corre-lated with TRSI, indicating that unions do not constitute a barrier to the entry of strategic investors. 3.4. Profitability There are also strong correlations between size and sector on one hand and the financial situation in the com-panies on the other, reflecting the external conditions in which companies in various groups were operating. The simplest and most rigorous measure of financial perfor-mance is net profit (after payment of all liabilities except leasing obligations). If we divide the companies into two groups, those with net profits and those with net losses, we see that by the end of 1998, the best situation was found in services, where there were no loss-making com-panies at all. In construction, 12 percent of the firms had losses, in trade – 27 percent, and in manufacturing – 31 percent. Bigger companies more often had losses than the smaller ones: among large firms 23 percent were loss-making, medium-sized – 17 percent, and among small firms – 15 percent. These figures confirm the existence of cross-correlations between the three variables (size, sec-tor, and financial performance). Table 28 shows the evolution of ownership structures in companies grouped according to net profits or losses in 1993. This year was chosen as a starting point for com-parison because it is the earliest year for which econom-ic data in Database 2 is available. Selection of the earliest possible data allows us to minimize the impact of subse-quent ownership changes on the financial situation of the firms. In this table we see that initially in loss-bearing compa-nies there were no outside investors at all, although these companies were undoubtedly in great need of financial resources; outsiders were probably not interested in acquiring such enterprises. In 1997–1998, 7 to 9 percent of CASE Reports No. 47 Non-managerial employees Industry Up to 100 employees – 4.3 57.7 38.0 101-200 employees 21.4 38.6 27.1 12.9 More than 200 6.6 25.9 29.8 37.7 employees Construction Up to 100 employees 10.1 15.2 28.3 46.4 101-200 employees 27.6 3.1 44.9 24.4 More than 200 38.4 27.2 14.5 19.1 employees Trade Up to 100 employees 7.8 20.9 36.5 34.9 101-200 employees 15.5 31.4 35.8 17.3 More than 200 – 13.9 56.2 29.9 employees Services Up to 100 employees – 23.8 26.6 49.6 101-200 employees – 15.1 28.3 56.6 More than 200 – 13.0 41.2 45.8 employees Two biggest shareholder groups in each category of companies are marked bold-italic. Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 22. 22 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward Table 28. Evolution of ownership structure, by net loss vs. net profit (weightted averages; %) Strategic Investor these companies already had strategic investors, and by 1999 as many as 50 percent did – mostly at the cost of man-agers which were selling their shares. The very quick growth of the share of non-strategic outsiders before 1999 is most likely due to large-scale layoffs in those companies. At the same time, the shares of managers and non-manage-rial employees decreased very significantly: by 1999, the for-mer group lost almost two thirds of their initial amount of shares, and the latter group lost more than two thirds of ini-tially possessed shares. In the group of profitable companies, slow growth of shares of outside strategic investors is striking. It seems that the need for such investors is usually only felt when the sit-uation in the company is very poor. We conclude, therefore, that the most powerful factor determining the dynamics of ownership changes in the companies is their economic condition. When a company is doing well, the internal relations in the company are sta-ble, and none of the main actors has an incentive to undermine this stability. When a company encounters severe economic problems, the actors begin to look around for solutions. The most obvious one is to find an external investor who brings an injection of fresh capital. When major inside shareholders and stakeholders have to choose between survival of the company and preservation of their shares, they tend to choose survival, at the same time trying to keep some shares for themselves. In such conditions, moreover, non-managerial employees lose every possible motivation for them to hold on to their shares: the shares never allowed them to participate in management, and now they don't even bring dividends. In earlier studies, a strong positive correlation was discov-ered between lack of dividends and selling of shares by non-managerial employees25. 3.5. Methods for Ownership Transformation: Share Sales and New Issues In most cases trade in shares was not a completely spon-taneous process. The main actors behind the privatization of the companies took care to minimize the risk of unwanted changes in the ownership structure in their firms. The char-ters of the great majority of companies (87 percent) con-tained restrictions on such trade. They were aimed at three main goals: (1) not to allow shares to "leak" outside the firm; (2) to facilitate ownership concentration in the hands of management elites, and (3) to prevent the emergence of new large shareholders within the firm who could under-mine the position of governing groups. Several methods were used to this end: right of first refusal by current own-ers; requiring share owners selling their shares to receive prior permission at the shareholders' meeting, or from the supervisory board (sometimes even the executive board); prohibition of share sales to outsiders, etc. Nevertheless, the processes of ownership redistribution often proved to be stronger than the restrictions, even in the companies where all trade in shares had been prohibited. Those restrictions only delayed changes (especially sales of shares to outsiders), but could not stop them completely26. Post-privatization ownership transformations, more-over, were achieved not only by trade in existing shares but also by issues of new ones. Nineteen firms had carried out new share issues by mid-1997. Of these, 11 were closed and 3 were public (we have no information on the charac-ter of five of the new issues). Of the 11 closed issues, recip-ients of new shares in all eight firms that we have informa-tion about were limited to persons already holding shares. CASE Reports No. 47 25 See Kozarzewski (1999), 85–86. 26 For more, see ibid., 87. Other outsiders Managers Non-managerial employees Net losses in 1993 Initial – – 49.9 50.1 1997 7.4 8.1 55.9 28.6 1998 9.0 24.6 50.8 15.6 1999 50.0 17.0 17.9 15.1 Net profit in 1993 Initial 0.2 5.8 31.0 63.0 1997 5.8 13.2 35.2 45.9 1998 13.9 16.8 34.1 35.2 1999 11.8 22.9 31.7 33.6 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 23. 23 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 29. Management-owned companies and entire sample, by population of headquarter location Most frequently, new share issues serve to promote con-centration of shares (especially in the hands of management and strategic investors), as evidenced by the positive corre-lations between new issues (the dummy variable NEW) and variables such as TRCON, TRSI, GRSI, and TRM. Correla-tion analysis also shows a positive correlation between new issues and company size, a negative correlation between new issues and the size of top management's share at the time of privatization, a negative correlation between NEW and YR1 (meaning that the earlier the privatization took place, the greater the likelihood that a new issue has occurred in the meantime), and a positive correlation between new issues and a transition to domination by a strategic investor (the dummy variable TRSI). Looking more closely at the latter relationship, we see that of the 13 companies with strategic investors as of mid- 1997, six had carried out new issues, and seven had not. We have information on the character of four of them, and all four were closed. Of the three firms that declared having had a public listing, none had a strategic investor. It appears, therefore, that strategic investors appear in employee-owned companies through new share issues as often as through buying out the employee shareholders, and that employee-owned companies listing publicly are not looking for, and/or not finding, strategic investors. 3.6. Top Management Domination Geography does not appear to be a factor in the transi-tion to management domination. If we look at the size of the cities in which the companies in which Executive Board members held at least 20% of the shares in 1997 are head-quartered, we see that there seems to be virtually no dif-ference between the firms dominated by management and the sample as a whole. With respect to branch, the only apparently significant difference between the firms dominated by management and the sample as a whole is the larger number of trade companies and smaller number of construction companies among the former. In almost all of the firms in which top management held a share of over 20% in mid-1997, respondents said that the firm was operating on a competitive market (24 such responses). Only one respondent claimed to be a monopo-list, and four claimed to be oligopolists. In conclusion, management ownership does not seem to be related to geographic factors or such economic factors as branch or market share. As we shall see, the situation with respect to companies in which strategic investors have appeared is somewhat different. 3.7. Companies with Strategic Investors As in the case of management-owned companies, loca-tion seems to constitute no special advantage in finding an investor (Table 31). By contrast, as we see in table 32, there are significant differences between companies with strategic investors and the sample as a whole with respect to branch. Manufactur- CASE Reports No. 47 Management-owned companies Whole sample POP1 3 (9.7%) 9 (8.3%) POP2 5 (16.1%) 16 (14.7%) POP3 11 (35.5%) 28 (25.7%) POP4 3 (9.7%) 23 (21.1%) POP5 9 (29.0%) 33 (30.3%) Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 30. Management-owned companies and entire sample, by branch Management-owned companies Whole sample Number Percent Number Percent Food processing 1 3.2 8 7.3 Other manufacturing 7 22.6 21 19.0 Construction 5 16.1 33 30.0 Transport 1 3.2 3 2.7 Trade 12 38.7 26 23.6 Services 2 6.5 8 7.3 Consulting and design 3 9.7 11 10.0 Total 31 110 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 24. 24 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward Companies with strategic investors Whole sample POP1 2 (11.8%) 9 (8.3%) POP2 2 (11.8%) 16 (14.7%) POP3 3 (17.6%) 28 (25.7%) POP4 5 (29.4%) 23 (21.1%) POP5 5 (29.4%) 33 (30.3%) Source: own calculations using Database 2. Companies with strategic investors Whole sample Number Percent Number Percent Food processing 3 17.6 8 7.3 Other manufacturing 4 23.5 21 19.0 Construction 7 41.2 33 30.0 Transport -- 3 2.7 Trade 3 17.6 26 23.6 Services -- 8 7.3 Consulting nd esign a d -- 11 10.0 Source: own calculations using Database 2. CASE Reports No. 47 Table 31. Companies with strategic owners and entire sample, by population of headquarter location Table 32. Companies with strategic owners and entire sample, by branch ing and construction are more strongly represented among the group with strategic investors than in the sample as a whole. Trade is represented more weakly, and services are not represented at all. Market share does not seem to differentiate companies with strategic investors from those dominated by Executive Board members. Of the 13 companies with strategic investors as of mid-1997, one claimed to be a monopolist, three claimed to be oligopolists, and nine said they were operating on highly competitive markets. Correlation analy-sis yields no evidence of a relationship between market share and the presence of strategic investors. There appears to be evidence that size (employment) is a factor in attracting strategic investors (positive correla-tions between TRSI and end-of-year employment in 1996 and 1998), but there is also evidence that strategic investors have a positive effect on employment (no correlation between 1996 end-of-year employment and SI, but a posi-tive correlation between end-of-year employment in 1998 and SI; also, a positive correlation between SI at the time of privatization and employment changes between the year before privatization and the end of 1996). The direction of causality therefore seems very difficult to ascertain, and we cannot say whether larger companies attract investors, or whether investors increase employment (or both). Respondents from companies with strategic investors were asked whether they had had trade relationships with the strategic investor previous to the latter's acquisition of shares. Of the 17 firms, we obtained no answer to this question from nine, and the remaining eight were evenly divided between those that had and those that had not maintained such contacts prior to the investor's acquisition. These data are clearly insufficient to allow us to draw any conclusions.
  • 25. 25 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 4. The Economic Performance of Employee-Leased Companies In this section we will review both previous studies of employee-leased companies in Poland and our own research results in order to evaluate the economic perfor-mance of the companies and assess, at least tentatively, the relationships between this performance and various factors, including ownership structure and ownership changes. 4.1. Profitability The financial results of employee-owned companies seem to be generally fairly sound in spite of the burden of lease pay-ments and the restructuring needs facing all firms emerging from Poland's former state-owned sector. The data in Table 33 allow one to compare the financial situation in employee-owned companies and state enterprises preparing for privati-zation by the leasing method with that in companies that have undergone capital privatization and companies participating in the National Investment Fund program. These data show that profitability indices for the average Polish employee-leased company have been close to – and Table 33. Gross profitability (ratio of gross profit or loss to total revenues) Employee-leased companies 6.4 6.3 6.0 4.9 4.5 State enterprises currently undergoing direct privatization 3.1 0.3 1.6 1.0 0.5 Capital-privatized companies 4.9 6.5 4.4 6.3 4.9 Companies designated for participation in NIF program 4.2 2.5 0.23 1.6 -0.5 Source: Kozarzewski et al. (2000), 49. CASE Reports No. 47 sometimes even better than – the average indices for firms privatized by the capital method. In addition, they are much higher than those of state enterprises and firms participating in the NIF program27. It is, however, worth noting that this profitability index has been consistently falling from year to year, and that prof-itability was best for those types of enterprises which were least typical among the group of employee-leased compa-nies; i.e., among large industrial enterprises employing over 300 persons28. 4.2. Investment Activity High interest rates and considerable imperfections in the Polish banking sector rendered access to funds for the financing of investments difficult for practically all Polish enterprises, and especially small businesses, throughout the first half of the 1990s29. During this period, it was often claimed that leased companies in Poland were characterized by exceptionally low levels of investment activity. One group 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 27 See Ministry of Ownership Transformation (1995), 3. The vast difference between reported financial results for firms preparing for liquidation privatization and those preparing for capital privatization may reflect the use of "creative accounting" due to the different incentives facing the two types of firms: while the managers of the former type of firms are, for the most part, preparing to purchase the firm themselves, they have an incentive to underreport the financial results and value of the assets of the firm with a view toward negotiating as low a price as possible with the Ministry of Own-ership Transformation; the managers of firms being prepared for capital privatization, however, are looking for outsiders to purchase the firm and there-fore wish to make the firm as attractive as possible. 28 See Pietrewicz (1995), 54. 29 See "Eyeing up the risk".
  • 26. 26 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward of researchers found a tendency to low investment and decapitalization in employee-owned companies compared with the national economy as a whole30. However, as their name implies, leased companies must make regular – and sometimes very burdensome – lease payments, to which a large portion of profits must be dedi-cated, thus limiting the possibilities for using retained earn-ings to finance investment; additionally, these firms have exceptional difficulty (in comparison with other privately-owned firms) in obtaining bank credits, since (at least in the early phase of their operation) they do not own, but only lease, their physical capital and thus possess inadequate col-lateral31. Some of the consequences of the debt burden incurred as a result of the leasing construction of most employee-leased companies are investigated in the Jarosz group's research, which includes analysis of the liquidity indices for their sample of firms in comparison with nation-al averages. The current ratio (i.e., the ratio of current assets to current liabilities) was, on the average, not parti-cularly good, but better than the national average in 1993; in addition, the national average was falling at that time, while the index for the sample of leased companies was rising. (It should, however, be noted that the average current ratio in employee-leased companies in the trade and services sec-tors was much lower than the sample average; the index for these firms was on the threshold of becoming threateningly low and was, moreover, below the national average.) The same situation was observed with regard to the quick ratio (i.e., the ratio of current assets minus average reserves to current liabilities). Similarly, the ratio of long-term debt to equity was found to be quite high, averaging 2.47 for the entire sample for 1993 (7.52 in firms employing 100 persons or fewer)32. Various governments have made some attempts to alle-viate this problem. The reductions of the interest rate paid on the leases have been discussed above (in Section 1). In addition, a measure to stimulate investment was included in the 1993 regulatory changes. According to these provisions, a leased company can apply to its founding organ for a reduction of the interest payments owed by the company as a result of postponements during the first two years of the leasing period if its investment expenditures out of profits amount to at least 50 percent of its net profit. The new pri-vatization act of 30 August, 1996, also included a provision intended to enhance the creditworthiness of employee-leased firms when applying for bank loans. According to Article 52, the title to the assets being leased may be trans-ferred to the leased firm after it has paid only one third of the obligations resulting from the leasing contract if two years have passed since the signing of the leasing contract; this term may even be shortened to one year if the firm has paid at least one half of those obligations. In addition to the difficulties arising from the lack of col-lateral, it is worth noting that the leasing method of privati-zation is explicitly intended for firms which are considered to require little investment33. Bearing all of the foregoing in mind, it is difficult to con-duct research on, or make conclusive statements about the level of investment in leased companies – or, for that mat-ter, any Polish companies (except in the case of foreign-owned companies where the level of investment is general-ly so high in comparison with other privatized companies that it cannot fail to escape notice) – due to the fact that reg-ulation of depreciation allowances (not reformed until the passage of the 1999 corporate income tax act) made it unprofitable for companies to show investment expendi-tures as such on their income statements (tax liabilities were decreased by including such expenditures on the cost side instead). However, already in the early 1990s there was some evidence that an "elite" of leased companies was investing on a scale comparable with that observed in enter-prises privatized by the capital method but without foreign investors34. Moreover, anecdotal evidence indicates that as more and more employee-owned companies pay off their Table 34. Average value of investment projects, per employee (in PLN) 30 See Pietrewicz (1995), 39–40. 31 See Jarosz (ed.) (1995), 16. 32 See Pietrewicz (1995), 43–48. 33 See Supreme Control Chamber (1993), 9, Uchwa³a Sejmu Rzeczypospolitej Polskiej z dnia 12 lutego 1993 r. w sprawie podstawowych kierun-ków prywatyzacji w 1993 r., and Kierunki prywatyzacji maj¹tku pañstwowego w 1995 r. 34 See Szomburg et al. (1994), 39, 54. Investment spending in capital-privatized firms with foreign investors was vastly greater than that in capital-privatized CASE Reports No. 47 firms without foreign investors. Mean Minimum Maximum Standard Deviation N Sum 1992-1997 6.43 0.00 128.62 13.4625 110 1998 4.66 0.00 128.44 13.6108 106 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 27. 27 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 35. Number of firms that obtained investment credit leases, acquiring legal titles to the property which they had been leased and thereby gaining the ability to secure loans with collateral, their access to commercial credit has grown considerably, thus considerably increasing the level of investment. We try to investigate some of these questions using the data in Database 2. Table 34 provides evidence that a considerable acce-leration of investment had oc-curred by the late 1990s. The mean investment project underway in 1998 had a per-employee value of about two thirds the per-employ-ee value for all such projects in the years 1992–1996. Table 35 shows a similar trend with respect to the num-ber of firms in the sample that had obtained credit. Of 108 firms that answered the appropriate question, 26 firms had paid off their leases by mid-1998 (24.1% of valid responses). Did this increase their access to credit? Perhaps too little time has elapsed since the payoff of the leases for statistical relationships to emerge from the data. At any rate, there is no correlation between the fact that a company has paid off its lease on the one hand and either 1998 per-employee investment spending or financ-ing of such investment by credit on the other. The question of dividend payments is a difficult one. On one hand, the failure to make dividend payments may repre-sent an abuse of shareholder rights by management (via use of "creative accounting" to "artificially" increase the level of costs, thus reducing profits and thereby tax liability and the pool of funds to which shareholders could exercise a claim). On the other hand, the opportunity cost of dividend payments is decreased funds available for investment, and therefore "asceticism" in the area of dividend payments may represent a pro-investment orientation of the shareholders and a consen-sus on their part to favor investment over the immediate grat-ification of dividends. As table 37 indicates, such asceticism is widespread among employee-owned companies. However, the data yield no statistical evidence that this asceticism leads to greater investment. There is no correla-tion between the dividend payments in either 1998 or 1999 and per-employee investment spending in 1998, and there is actually a positive correlation between 1995 and 1996 dividends and 1996 investment spending. (Similarly, there is a positive correlation in 1999 between the dummy indicat-ing whether a dividend was paid and the variable measuring expansion into new markets.) Does ownership make a difference with regard to the pay-ment of dividends (i.e., do different types of owners have dif-ferent preferences with regard to tradeoff between invest-ment and immediate gratification in the form of dividends)? There is a negative correlation between the dummy indicating whether a dividend was paid in 1997 on the one hand and the share belonging to non-managerial employees at the time of privatization and in 1997, and a positive correlation between the 1997 dividend dummy and the 1997 shares of strategic investors. On the other hand, there is negative correlation between the ratio of the dividend payment to the net profit Table 37. Number of firms that made, and did not make, dividend payments, 1997–1998 Not paid 55 50.0 57 52.8 74 67.3 Paid 55 50.0 51 47.2 36 32.7 Source: own calculations using Database 2. CASE Reports No. 47 Number Percent N 1992-1996 31 33.3 93 1998 21 24.4 86 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 36. Average investment spending, 1993–1996 (in millions of pre-1995 zlotys) 35 Mean Minimum Maximum Standard Deviation N 1993 303.51 0 5200 864.87 70 1994 476.91 0 10840 1517.96 88 1995 379.72 0 10989 1227.71 110 1996 601.74 0 17874 2253.85 110 Source: own calculations using Database 2. 1997 1998 1999 Number Percent Number Percent Number Percent 35 This table is based on figures from the companies' income statements for the relevant years. Unfortunately, for the years 1997 and 1998, we do not have such figures, but rather the total value of current investment projects.
  • 28. 28 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward and the strategic investor share, and a positive correlation between this ratio and the worker share. We can therefore conclude that in 1997 companies dominated by workers were less likely to pay dividends than those dominated by strategic investors, but if they did pay them, they tended to pay out a higher percentage of the profits in the form of dividends. In contrast, there is a positive correlation between the dividend dummy for 1999 and both the percentage of the workforce owning shares (OWN) and the percentage of the workforce belonging to a trade union (UNI) in 1999. So overall, these relations are rather ambiguous. Less ambiguous, and very surprising, is the complete absence of any correlation between various measures of strategic investor shares and their growth on the one hand and investment variables or paying off the lease on the other. In other words, there is no statistical evidence that the presence of a strategic investor actually leads to more investment! In contrast, for 1999 (but not for 1997), there is a positive correlation between concentration in the hands of management (TRM, but not GRMAN) and investment spending. Interestingly, per-employee invest-ment spending for the period 1992–1996 is positively cor-related with EQ336 – the least concentrated ownership structure – whereas in 1999 it is negatively correlated with OWN. Evidence concerning the relationship between the degree of non-managerial employees' partic-ipation in ownership and investment is therefore rather ambiguous. There is consistently a positive correlation between the value of investment projects and the use of credit as a means of financing them, which would tend to support the claims that lack of access to credit is one of the main explanatory factors for the low rate of investment in employee-owned companies in Poland. Interestingly, use of credit is not cor-related with size. In 1999, it was negatively correlated with the number of layoffs between the year of privatization and the end of 1996 (positive correlation with P.C. CH)37, and positively correlated with the acquisition by Executive Board members of ownership shares exceeding 20% during the same period (TRM). Finally, investment spending in 1992–1996 and in 1996 was positively correlated with the size of the firm (employ-ment), and investment spending in the period 1992–1996 was positively correlated with the dummy indicating whether a new share issue had occurred during the same period (NEW). Summarizing the results of this analysis, we conclude that size and access to credit do seem to be key variables in the determination of the level of investment spending, but neither the propensity to pay dividends nor the ownership structure seem to be related in any consistent and significant way to investment activity. 4.3. Restructuring and Adjustment Activity Restructuring and adjustment activity in employee-leased firms tended in the first half of the 1990s to be con-centrated in increased promotional activity and adjustments of a simple, costreducing nature (e.g., employment reduc-tions), involving little in the way of introduction of new products or significant improvement in the level of technol-ogy38. Later, however, an increase in investments of an inno-vative nature was found39. Employee-owned companies have shown a great deal of elasticity in their employment policies, often engaging in significant layoffs (in firms that are on the average rela-tively small to begin with). Overall, employment in the sample consistently fell from year to year, as the table below shows. On the average, employment fell between Table 38. Average end-of-year employment, by year Mean Minimum Maximum Standard 36 It is also positively correlated with the size of the workforce and the oligopoly dummy. 37 It is also negatively correlated with the growth in the ownership share of "other" outsiders (GROO), which may further suggest a positive rela-tionship CASE Reports No. 47 between the growth of their share and the number of layoffs (see the discussion in Section 2). 38 See Pietrewicz (1995), 51–52. 39 See Krajewski (1998), 108–109, Krajewski (2000), 123–124. Deviation N 1992 262.14 6 1749 294.72 76 1993 226.58 6 1882 275.65 90 1994 219.74 5 2002 276.77 99 1995 211.97 3 1942 268.69 104 1996 206.50 3 1919 262.79 110 1997 201.32 3 1713 246.79 106 1998 192.37 2 1693 240.90 110 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 29. Table 39. Average end-of-year employment in companies owned by top management and strategic investors, by year Companies with top management domination Companies with strategic investors N Mean Minimum Maximum Mean Minimum Maximum N 1992 22 184.32 6 723 374.46 21 990 13 1993 28 163.54 6 643 362.00 21 964 12 1994 30 151.07 5 606 342.80 21 864 15 1995 33 144.48 3 624 323.00 21 821 16 1996 34 151.06 3 629 299.29 31 751 17 1997 33 158.12 3 638 296.82 34 805 17 1998 34 139.06 2 627 281.59 34 778 17 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 40. Positive responses to new market expansion question, 1997–1999 Number of positive responses Number of firms % 0 42 38.5 1 31 28.4 2 25 22.9 3 11 10.1 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 41. Positive responses to new market expansion question, 1997–1999 40 In 1997 they were asked if they had acquired them since privatization; in 1998 and 1999 they were asked if they had acquired them in the pre-vious year. 29 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... the end of the year prior to privatization and the end of 1996 by 13.3%. It should be noted that the maximum values are outliers, as in 1997 only two companies in the sample had employ-ment of over 1000. As noted in Section 3.4, unionization is negatively corre-lated with employment changes between the time of priva-tization and the end of 1996, providing some evidence that unions were effective in preventing layoffs, at least early on. Later the situation seems to change: while 1997 unioniza-tion is positively correlated with employment in the year before privatization and at the end of 1996, unionization in 1999 is not correlated with employment at the end of 1998. A comparison of tables 38 and 39 shows that average employment in the companies that have attracted strategic investors is consistently higher than the sample average, while average employment in those owned by top manage-ment is consistently below average. These companies are similar to the others in the sample, however, in that they also consistently reduced employment throughout the ana-lyzed period. Moreover, there appears to be no significant difference in the rate at which employment was reduced over the course of the entire period. Two measures of adjustment and restructuring activity that we expected to be particularly telling are measures of employment in marketing and expansion into new markets. Sixty-three firms (57.3% of the sample) had marketing units as of mid-1999. The average employment in these units was 2.12 persons. The existence of a marketing unit and the size of that unit were both positively correlated with employ-ment at the end of 1998. These variables were not, howev-er, correlated with any ownership variables, with invest-ment indicators, or with expansion into new markets. With respect to new markets, the respondents were asked on three occasions whether they had acquired new markets40. A majority had (table 40), and almost half of the firms that had not acquired new markets were in trade, as table 41 shows. One was a monopolist, two were oligopolists, and 35 were in competitive markets. However, as in the case of marketing activity, expansion into new markets has little correlation with other variables, and the few correlations CASE Reports No. 47 Frequency Percent Food processing 2 4.8 Other manufacturing 5 11.9 Construction 8 19.0 Trade 19 45.2 Services 8 19.0 Total 42 100.0 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 30. 30 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward which do exist (with EQ2 and OWN) do not seem to admit of any explanation. Finally, we looked at the question whether concentrated ownership had affected ISO quality certification (Table 42). In terms of actual certification, there is virtually no dif-ference between the percentages of certified firms in the three groups; however, a significantly lower proportion of firms with strategic investors have no ISO certificate and do not plan to obtain one than in the other two groups. More-over, a much higher percentage of firms with strategic investors is in the process of certification. CASE Reports No. 47 Table 42. ISO quality certification by ownership group, 1998 Top management domination Strategic investor Whole sample Number Percent Number Percent Number Percent No data -- 1 5.9 2 1.9 Certified 4 12.9 2 11.8 13 12.0 In process of certification 2 6.5 4 23.5 11 10.2 Intends to obtain certificate 3 9.7 4 23.5 16 14.8 Not certified and not planning certification 22 71.0 6 35.3 66 61.1 Total 31 100.0 17 100.0 108 100.0 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 31. 31 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 5. The Relationship between Ownership Structure and Productivity: Evidence from the Early 1990s In this section we present the results of econometric analysis of the relationship between the ownership struc-ture of employee-leased companies and productivity41. In particular, we would like to know whether the extent of participation of non-managerial employees is related to enterprise performance. The sample is very well suited to such an analysis due to its great diversity with respect to the extent of employee participation in share ownership, with firms ranging from virtually no employee ownership to complete employee ownership. The analysis was carried out using data from Database 1. 5.1. Productivity Analysis: Estimating Framework We analyze productivity here using an augmented pro-duction function framework that has been used in several earlier studies analyzing the relation between employee participation and productivity42. Ideally43, the logarithmized production function estimated is a Cobb-Douglas function: lnV lnK lnL Z X it it it it it it = α +α +α +α +α +μ 0 1 2 3 4 where V denotes value added, K and L represent capital and labor inputs, respectively, X is a vector of industry and enterprise-specific variables such as dummies for the year of production and the branch in which the enterprise oper-ates, Z is a vector of participatory variables, firms are denoted by the subscript i, the time period in years by t, and the residual by μ. We estimate the models using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) techniques. Ordinarily, the endogeneity of the inde-pendent variables would rule out use of the OLS method. However, researchers studying the relation between employee participation and productivity use this technique due to the fact that it is more robust against specification errors than simultaneous equations methods44. 5.2. Productivity Analysis: The Results For this analysis, a fairly large portion of the sample was eliminated. This was due to the fact that various branches of manufacturing were represented by too small a number of firms. Thus, we were left only with firms in construction, trade, and services. The results of the OLS estimations are reported in Table 43. Before discussing these results, some remarks on the quality of the data and its implications for our analysis are in order. Unfortunately, no measure of capital costs (e.g., depreciation) is included in the data. For this reason, con-struction of a value added variable was impossible. More-over, in a number of studies of labor productivity in trans-forming economies, researchers have used sales revenues rather than value added in constructing measures of pro-ductivity45. This is most likely due to the fact that the manip-ulation of profits in post-Communist economies is endemic for a number of reasons. Two reasons are: first, the fact that an increase in the enterprise's profits entails a proportional increase in its tax liability, and second, the fact that some portion of profits is often distributed to shareholders in the form of dividends. In order to avoid such "losses" to the state treasury and shareholders and retain as much money in the firm as possible, managers manipulate their accounts. These manipulations occur on the cost side (for instance, by including some part of investment costs in production costs). 41 A full discussion of this analysis is found in Woodward (1999). An earlier version was published in Woodward (1998). 42 See Estrin et al. (1987), Conte and Svejnar (1988), and Jones (1993). 43 Departures from the ideal are discussed in Section 5.2. 44 In fact, the use of OLS to estimate production functions is generally accepted as appropriate. See Zellner et al. (1966). 45 See, for example, Brada and Singh (1995), Grosfeld and Nivet (1998). CASE Reports No. 47
  • 32. 32 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward Table 43. OLS estimates of productivity effects (using sales revenues instead of value added) Variable Construction Trade Non-material services lnL 0.981263* For this reason, we performed regressions using the nat-ural logarithm of sales revenues instead of that of value added. With respect to non-participatory variables, we observe the following. Population coefficients appear only for one sector. We see that here, large population positive-ly affects sales, and smaller population negatively affects sales. Amortization is significant in only one sector, but its coefficient has a negative sign, as one would expect. Turning to the ownership variables which are our chief interest here, we note, first, that a number of them do not appear in the estimations at all, including EQ2 and OWN. A coefficient for variable WOR – i.e., the percentage of shares held by non-managerial employees – appears in two sectors; it is negative, but insignificant, in both. A high degree of concentration (EQ1) has a negative relationship with productivity in four sectors (significant in two). The coefficient for unionization is positive and significant, but very small. In one case EQ3 appears, with a coefficient which is negative and significant. This result is the only one which can be interpreted as evidence of a negative rela-tionship between (a relatively) egalitarian ownership struc-ture and productivity. CASE Reports No. 47 (10.10735) 0.429334* (3.07973) 0.62137* (5.40815) lnK 0.151614* (2.38320) 0.350398* (3.20938) 0.20496* (3.47193) YEAR 0.208879* (2.48804) POP2 -1.35048* (-3.97939) POP5 0.90459* (6.02102) AMORT -0.02946* (-5.76673) EQ1 -0.367536* (-2.34528) -.410853* (-2.70768) EQ3 -0.495985* (-3.09907) WOR -0.003266 (-1.11267) -0.00517 (-1.77634) UNI 0.006062* (2.53779) n 86 52 40 adjusted R2 .81642831 .78083193 .84440984 Asterisks indicate coefficients which are statistically significant at the 95 percent confidence level. Figures in parentheses are t-statistics. Source: Own calculations using Database 1.
  • 33. 33 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 6. Corporate Governance 6.1. Formation of Corporate Governance Bodies Privatization, as one of the pillars of the construction of the new economic and social relations in Poland's market economy, is effective only if it spurs innovation in the man-agement of enterprises. Privatization cannot, therefore, be seen as a simple matter of transferring shares to private hands; rather it involves a play of interests regulated by the Commercial Code and business practice: the interests of the new owners, in whose hands the chief decision-making powers are vested, and those of various stakeholders. Mechanisms are set in motion serving to harmonize the interests of these main groups. The ownership and stake-holder configurations emerging in the context of privatiza-tion play a decisive role in determining the firm's fate46, shaping authority structures that, in turn, direct the com-panies' post-privatization development and orientation. Thus, the reorganization of ownership is accompanied by a reorganization of management and control structures; the question is, how deep and effective is this latter process? Of course, this process represents a very complicated task. In the most highly developed market economies, corpo-rate organizational structures were formed in a longlasting, largely spontaneous, process. The organizational structure, tasks and functions of management and control bodies were subject to permanent evolution directed at ensuring the best possible defense of owners' interests. Legislative codification of these structures and functions represents a sort of consen-sus regarding "best practices" which had already emerged. In the post-Communist countries, by contrast, these structures were formalized by legislative means, overnight as it were, without a preceding phase of spontaneous evolution. In contrast to many post-Communist countries, Poland inherited, at the outset of its transition, a continental European (three-tier) model of corporate governance laid out in its Com-mercial Code, dating from the 1930s, which had never been suspended by the Communist authorities. However, the leg-islative circumstances are of secondary concern to us here. More important for our purposes is the mechanism for super-vision of the company's executive bodies implied in adoption of the continental model. This is particularly important in Poland, as the influence of various forms of so-called external control (e.g., product and financial markets) is in many cases still not fully effective. In such conditions, the efficient functioning of so-called internal supervision assumes fundamental importance. The basic task of the new body introduced into Polish enterprises as a result of ownership transformation – the supervisory board – consists in supervision of the compa-ny's operations on behalf of – and in the interests of – its owners. Lately, more and more frequently opinions are expressed that the supervisory board should not confine itself to representing exclusively the interests of the own-ers, but rather become a platform for coordinating the manifold interests in which the company is involved; i.e., to be a stakeholder forum. Without entering into a discussion on whether, in Polish conditions, the supervisory board should shoulder this additional responsibility, we will attempt to determine the extent to which such a function has been assumed by the supervisory boards in the com-panies under review. The formation and definition of the supervisory board's goals and functions, of its place among other organs of the company, is extremely complicated in Poland, where this body faces the brand new task of per-forming supervisory functions in the name of the share owners, a concern which did not exist in the state-owned enterprise. The supreme element of the executive line of authority – the executive board – has a very wide range of powers and is limited only insofar as certain powers are reserved for the owners themselves, acting through the sharehold-ers' meeting. Shareholders' Meeting The impact of ownership changes on the composition of the general assembly of shareholders is obvious. Partici- 46 See Frydman and Rapaczynski (1994). CASE Reports No. 47
  • 34. 34 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward 25% 33% 19% 20% 24% 16% 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 pation in shareholders' meetings and the degree of influ-ence on decision making at those meetings are strictly dependent on the size of one's share in the company's share capital. Therefore, the constellation of interests and power within this body is implied in the analysis of the ownership structure of employee-leased companies. In this section we will attempt to describe the general assembly's place with-in the authority structure of the firm with respect to other organs and interest groups. Supervisory Board The supervisory board is appointed by the sharehold-ers. It is (at least in theory) a supervisory and not a man-agement body, despite the fact that, in the nature of things, it cannot be excluded from participation in the firm's influ-ence structure. Based on responses to the Jarosz team's survey, we can confirm that a large majority of companies aspire to create, at least formally, a corporate governance body with the full range of responsibilities, implying that their owners are aware of the advantages of separating the ownership and control functions. Supervisory boards (which are required in companies exceeding certain size limits) exist in 86 per-cent of all the companies under review. This conclusion is supported by the fact that the minority of companies that have dispensed with a supervisory organ are mostly limited to the very smallest ones (in terms of employment, charter capital and number of owners). One of the most important traits of the personal com-position of the supervisory boards under review is the very high participation of insiders (most notably managerial employees). Interestingly, after a drop in their participation to 19 percent in 1998 from 33 percent in 1997, we wit-nessed an increase to 25 percent in 1999. On the other hand, the percentage of board members employed in the firm in non-managerial posts has grown steadily over this three-year period (16 percent, 20 percent and 24 percent, respectively). As a result, in 1999, the overall share of insid-ers in the membership of supervisory boards returned to the 1997 level (i.e., 49 percent). Among the outsiders, managers from other firms continue to make up the largest category (22 percent in 1997, 27 percent in 1998, and 24 percent in 1999), of which three fourths are managers from private companies (Figure 1). The column "Total" in Table 44 contains detailed data on the personal composition of supervisory boards in the companies under review in 1999. In comparison with ear-lier years, it seems to have remained very stable. There are still very few experts from various fields of knowledge potentially useful to this body's work: the joint share of bankers, consultants, scientific and technological experts and professionals amounted to 9 percent in 1997 and 7 percent in 1999. Thus, in practice, little use is made of one of the basic instruments for equipping the supervisory boards with the capacity for exercising expert control on behalf of the owners. We see that the composition of supervisory boards con-tinues to be dependent primarily on the ownership struc-ture: outsider dominance in the ownership structure is accompanied by outsider dominance in supervisory board membership. The most "outsiderized" supervisory boards are in the companies dominated by an outside strategic investor (79 percent of board members in such cases do not work in the company). The same applies to the domi-nance of managerial and non-managerial employees. Lack of dominance of any of the insider groups is correlated with managerial dominance of the supervisory board. We observe a larger than average share of private managers CASE Reports No. 47 Figure 1. Basic groups of supervisory board members (% of total number of members) 22% 27% 24% 0 1997 1998 1999 Insiders – managers Insiders – non managers Outsiders – managers Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 35. 35 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 44. Composition of the supervisory board in 1999, by categories of ownership dominance (%) and consultants in the supervisory boards of companies dominated by strategic outside investors, which should give these boards superior capacity to carry out their supervi-sory function competently. This aggregate picture of the composition of superviso-ry boards fails to convey the diversity of combinations of forces and interests found in different boards. The repre-sentation of different groups (most importantly insiders and outsiders) varies widely across companies. In 1999, in more than half (51 percent) of the boards under review, the majority was made up of people who were not employees of the given firm, and in 20 percent the boards were made up exclusively of outsiders. In 47 percent of the supervisory boards insiders dominated, and in 28 percent there was not a single person from outside the firm. When viewed over a longer period of time, the evolution of the composition of the supervisory boards has not been unidi-rectional. Contrary to what one might expect in view of the process of ownership "outsiderization", the position of insiders measured by numerical dominance in the compo-sition of different boards was markedly strengthened in 1998–1999. At the same time, polarization into purely "insider" and purely "outsider" boards was accentuated. A closer look at the problem reveals that this seeming paradox actually constitutes a continuation of earlier con-centrated trends: in companies belonging to the employ-ees, institutional control is increasingly concentrated in the hands of insiders, while in the "outsider" companies their employees are more and more often allowed to participate in the organs of corporate governance. This can be seen as evidence that the corporate gover-nance system in Polish companies is gradually nearing the continental model. Moreover, this process has entered a new phase in which this adjustment does not stem primar- CASE Reports No. 47 Ownership structure of the company; dominance of: Post occupied outside the supervisory board TOTAL Strategic outsiders Other outsiders Managers Non-managerial employees Without dominant group At the firm under review Managerial post 25 14 12 25 38 37 Specialist 12 4 14 20 16 11 Trade union activist 1 2 – – 2 2 Non-managerial post 11 1 9 8 24 13 Outside the firm under review Managerial post in state-owned enterprise 5 – 8 6 4 4 Managerial post in private sector 19 37 20 13 3 13 Bank employee 3 3 1 1 1 3 Employee of state administration 3 4 3 – 2 1 Employee of local administration 1 – – 2 – – Scientist 3 3 1 4 2 3 Employee of consulting firm 1 6 – 1 – – Private businessman 8 10 25 8 1 6 Pensioner 6 10 4 12 4 8 Other 2 6 1 – 1 1 Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 Source: own calculations using Database 2. Table 45. Supervisory board composition in 1997–1999, by ownership structure (%) Ownership structure in the company Without strategic investor With a strategic investor Dominant insider ownership Dominant outsider ownership Supervisory board composition 1997 1998 1999 1997 1998 1999 1997 1998 1999 1997 1998 1999 Only outsiders 19 12 12 54 41 46 17 10 10 54 37 37 Dominance of outsiders 16 29 29 23 50 38 16 29 27 21 49 40 Mixed composition 11 6 2 13 – 3 13 5 1 9 2 4 Dominance of insiders 28 25 21 5 9 10 28 26 22 9 8 13 Only insiders 26 28 36 5 – 3 26 30 40 7 4 6 Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 36. 36 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward Table 46. The body that appoints the executive board, by ownership structure type (%) The executive board is appointed by: Dominant owner group shareholders' meeting supervisory board ily from legal requirements, but rather from the needs of the agents involved in the functioning of the companies. When we look at the evolution of supervisory board composition from the point of view of the occupations of their members (e.g., the increasing percentage of members with specialist and non-managerial positions), we see evi-dence of increasing representation of stakeholders on this body, which is consistent with the above-mentioned conti-nental model. While the external investor does not risk loss of control over the board (an overwhelming majority of incumbent and newly appointed supervisory board presi-dents are outsiders), naming a person from the company to the supervisory board contributes to ease tensions or con-flicts between employees and the owners and to create at least an illusion of employee representation. Presumably this is also due to the owners' realization that insiders have better access to certain information about what is going on in the firm than those observing it from outside. Executive Board The executive board can be appointed in different ways, depending on stipulations of the company's charter. In 1999, in 69 percent of the companies under review, the executive board was appointed and dismissed not directly by the owners, but by the supervisory board (in 1998 this was the case in 60 percent of the companies). Appointment of the executive board by the supervisory board is most frequent in the companies not dominated by any particular group of owners, and secondly in companies with a strate-gic outside investor. The opposite pole is made up of firms characterized by "insider" ownership structures, where the executive board is relatively most frequently appointed directly by the owners (Table 46). Interestingly, superviso-ry boards appointed executive boards more often in 1999 than in 1998, especially in the groups of companies where earlier they had performed this function most infrequently. Research shows that the boards' behavior depends largely on what positions their members occupied previ-ously, in particular on the nature of their involvement in the governance system of the transformed state-owned enter-prise. From this point of view, the majority of companies in our sample constitute examples of the reproduction of managerial elites47: as many as 79 percent of the current executive board members worked at the given firm before its privatization, and 74 percent occupied managerial posi-tions. The membership of the executive boards is dominated by former state enterprise managers (former state enter-prise directors and deputy directors together make up 55 percent). Those coming to the companies' executive boards from outside are primarily managers and owners from the private sector – private businessmen or managers of private firms (together 14 percent). On the other hand, there are very few former managers of other state-owned enterprises or persons previously occupying non-manager-ial positions. Table 47 adds the ownership dimension to this analysis. There are few surprises here: the reproduction of elites is more frequently halted in firms in which over 50 percent of the shares are in the hands of outsiders than in the "insider" firms, especially those in which the majority of shares belong to non-managerial employees. Certain exceptions to this rule are firms with ownership dominance of the managerial staff, among which we see a surprising percent-age (14 percent) of private businessmen from other firms. 6.2. The Decision-Making Process The role of supervisory boards The main factor defining the place and role of the super-visory board in the governance system of the companies in question is the range of powers with which it is vested and which are exercised by it in practice. Polish law sets the general framework in the Commercial Code, which pro-vides only for the following basic, minimum range of the supervisory board's responsibilities: – review of the company's balance sheet and profit and loss statement; – review of reports of the executive board; CASE Reports No. 47 47 On the reproduction versus replacement of elites see Wasilewski and Wnuk-Lipinski (1995), 669 Total Dominance of strategic outsider 25 75 100 Dominance of other outsiders 36 64 100 Dominance of managers 35 65 100 Dominance of non-managerial employees 40 60 100 Lack of dominant group 17 83 100 TOTAL 31 69 100 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 37. 37 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 47. Former posts of executive board members, by the companies' ownership structures (percent) – review of the executive board's proposals regarding the distribution of profits and coverage of losses; – reporting the results of the above reviews at the share-holders' meeting; – suspending, for important reasons, the executive board or individual members of the board in the perfor-mance of their functions; – delegating supervisory board members to temporary performance of functions of the suspended executive board members; – when necessary, taking steps towards supplementing the membership of the executive board. The Commercial Code allows for widening the range of the supervisory board's responsibilities through appro-priate provisions of the company's charter. In all the com-panies under review, the formal powers of the executive board were extended in comparison with the minimum provided for by Polish law. The extensions mostly regard approval of decisions made by other statutory bodies of the company, more rarely to making "own" binding deci-sions. Directions in which the rights of the supervisory boards have been extended can be divided into six cate-gories: 1. Decisions on broadly understood organizational mat-ters (found in 99 percent of the companies where supervisory boards had been created): appointing executive board members, setting the company's wage scale, monitoring the execution of resolutions made by the executive board or shareholders' meet-ing. 2. Decisions on financial matters (84 percent): approval of profit distribution, giving consent to contracting large financial liabilities. 3. Decisions on economic and production-related mat-ters, i.e. the company's development and production plans, quality control, etc. (74 percent). 4. Disposing of the firm's capital and the firm itself as a corporate entity, i.e. decisions on changes in the shareholders' agreement and the company's line of activity, size of the company's capital, operations on shares, change in the ownership structure, etc. (88 percent). 5. Giving consent to changes in the company's assets: acquisition or sale of real estate, putting assets to lease, investment purchases, etc. (73 percent). 6. Powers conventionally defined as "social": monitoring compliance with occupational safety regulations and safeguarding the interests of employees (21 percent of the companies). The supervisory boards did not use all the powers they were given, at least during 1998–1999. The use of these powers depends not only on the character of the board, but also on the company's need for such actions. For example, it can be assumed that all supervisory boards are active in reviewing financial documents, statements, etc., while, as a rule, their participation in appointing and dis-missing the executive board, approving large transactions, etc., occurs much more rarely, simply because these actions are much less frequent. Table 48 shows which powers were actually exercised by the supervisory boards in 1998–1999. Only 9 percent of the boards under review confined their activity to the min- CASE Reports No. 47 Dominant ownership categories Former positions of executive board members TOTAL outsiders managers non-managerial employees without dominant group Worked at the firm before privatization 79 68 81 96 86 Of which, in the position of: Director 26 25 24 31 29 Deputy director, chief accountant 29 25 34 41 27 Other managerial post 19 16 19 20 23 Non-managerial post 5 2 4 4 7 Did not work at the firm before privatization, but: 21 32 19 4 14 In managerial position in a state-owned enterprise 2 5 – 2 – In managerial position in a private firm 8 17 4 2 4 As employee of a public institution 1 – 1 – 2 As employee of a consulting firm 1 2 – – – As private businessman 6 5 14 – 4 Other positions 2 3 – – 4 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 38. 38 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward imum outlined by the Commercial Code. The most fre-quently used additional powers were those of an organiza-tional nature (81 percent of the supervisory boards under review), followed by powers to dispose of the capital and the firm (62 percent), economic and production-related powers (60 percent), control over the firm's assets (49 per-cent), and powers in the financial sphere (44 percent). The list ends with supervisory boards that have made use of the powers defined as social (14 percent). This table points to certain trends. Confinement of activities to the statutory minimum of responsibilities is most frequent in supervisory boards that are composed exclusively of insiders, and in companies with ownership dominance of the managerial staff. The supervisory boards' powers in the organizational sphere are most frequently exercised where the board's composition is mixed, in loss-making companies, and in companies without a dominant owners' group. Financial powers are exercised most fre-quently in the companies in which more than 50 percent of the shares belong to the managerial staff and in loss-making companies. Economic and production-related powers are most characteristic of supervisory boards in loss-making companies and companies with a strategic investor. Dispos-ing of the capital and the firm is most typical of supervisory boards in firms without any dominant owner category, boards with mixed membership and boards of loss-making companies. Exercise of the right of control over the assets and of powers in the social sphere is most frequently observed in companies with employee ownership domi-nance and in loss-makers. To sum up, we can say that extension of the supervi-sory boards' activities is observed most frequently in com-panies in economic distress. Interrelationships between the ownership structure and the extension of the supervi-sory boards' powers are of a more complex nature. The most striking relationships seem to be the following: lack of any dominant owners' group is linked to extension of the supervisory boards' activities to the organizational sphere and to the control over the capital and the firm; dominance of employee ownership is linked to the board's "social" activity and control over the firm's assets, and dominance of the managerial staff in the ownership struc-ture is, in general, not accompanied by any extension of the supervisory board's powers, except to the area of finance. Thus, different configurations of the insider-dom-inated ownership structure go hand in hand with different patterns of extension of the supervisory board's range of powers. Lack of dominance of any group is often accom-panied by the assumption of other organs' and services' functions by the supervisory boards; dominance of employee ownership dictates special attention to matters that are important for the employees, i.e. to social prob-lems, and dominance of the managerial staff in the ownership structure tends to be accompanied by limita- CASE Reports No. 47 Table 48. Percentage of supervisory boards exercising given powers in 1998–1999 Kind of powers Characteristics of firm Only those provided for in the Commer-cial Code Organiza-tional Financial Economic and produc-tion-related Disposing over the capital and the firm Control over the assets Social Total 9 81 44 60 62 49 14 Dominating ownership group Outsiders 8 85 40 66 64 57 8 Managers 14 72 62 59 62 38 17 Non- anageriaml employees 5 75 45 65 50 60 25 Lack of predominant group – 95 29 62 86 38 14 Presence of strategic investor Is not present 7 81 47 58 65 45 14 Is present 8 84 37 76 66 61 13 Type of supervisory board composition Only outsiders 7 86 54 75 57 61 11 Predominance of outsiders 9 84 43 64 59 36 7 Dominance of insiders 4 89 52 63 63 48 11 Only insiders 13 70 38 45 68 55 23 Profit criterion There is no profit 11 89 48 78 70 63 30 There is profit 9 79 43 56 60 46 10 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 39. 39 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Table 49. Average influence of different actors on decision making processes in the company, in the opinion of company presidents (1 – the weakest influence, 5 – the strongest influence) tion of the supervisory board's powers to certain strictly defined areas. The hierarchy of decision-makers The strong, stable ownership position of the executive board members and the inertia in the composition of executive boards constitute evidence of continuity of the governance structures in the periods before and after pri-vatization. We would therefore expect that in most cases it is the executive board that has the greatest influence on decision making processes, not only in day-to-day manage-ment matters but also with respect to strategic problems. This was verified in company presidents' responses to questions concerning the relative role of various groups in decision-making processes. The important role of company presidents is stressed more frequently than average in companies with owner-ship dominance of non-strategic outsiders and managerial staff; whereas that of the executive board as a whole is more frequently stressed in firms with dominance of employee ownership. The biggest shareholders have strongest influence in the "outsider" and manager-con-trolled companies, and the weakest where there are few such shareholders; i.e., in firms with dominant employee ownership. The general assembly of shareholders, in turn, is relatively strongest where the ownership dominance of managers, employees, or non-strategic outsiders has evolved. The influence of the supervisory board is at its strongest where there is ownership dominance of external investors, and weakest in the manager-owned companies. Trade unions are also at their weakest in the latter group and strongest in strategic outsider-controlled firms and in companies with dominance of non-managerial employee ownership. The role of non-managerial employees is per-ceived as relatively strongest (but still at the lower end of hierarchy) in companies controlled by non-managerial employees and weakest in firms with strategic outsider investors (Table 49). The owners most frequently act as decision makers where ownership is concentrated in the hands of a strate-gic outside investor. The role of owners in decision-making also grows in loss-making companies (at the expense of the powers of the executive and supervisory boards). The small role of owners is striking. Only 10 percent of company presidents mentioned them among the decision makers at all, and a mere 3 percent named them as the sole center of strategic decision-making. Accordingly, the per-ception of the relative importance of the general assembly of shareholders is often very low too. Almost half (45 per-cent) of the company presidents, when asked directly, described the role of this body as purely formal. There is no doubt that among company presidents there is a certain skewing in the perception of the power distribution within the companies. They perceive this question from the standpoint of their own position, tasks and responsibilities. Since the executive board's basic task is keeping the com-pany in operation, for them, the most important people are those who are directly involved in carrying out this task. CASE Reports No. 47 Dominating ownership group category Agent strategic outsiders other outsiders managers non-managerial employees without dominant category Total Executive board president 4.50 4.73 4.63 4.52 4.45 4.57 Executive board as a whole 4.42 4.54 4.58 4.68 4.40 4.52 Supervisory board 3.58 3.71 3.22 3.42 3.38 3.54 General assembly of 3.42 3.87 3.88 3.86 3.05 3.62 shareholders The biggest shareholders 4.00 4.00 4.00 3.05 3.50 3.80 Trade unions 2.38 2.00 1.80 2.17 2.09 2.07 Non-managerial employees 2.17 2.40 2.27 2.70 2.29 2.32 Source: own calculations using Database 2.
  • 40. 40 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward The ownership structure of Polish employee-leased companies, especially immediately after privatization, was characterized by large holdings of dispersed insider owners. Subsequently, the shares of non-managerial employees gradually decline, while those of outsiders grow. Concentra-tion of shares in the hands of managers can be seen from the very moment of privatization. Later, however, managerial holdings stabilize and even decrease somewhat in favor of outsiders. The sample of employee-leased companies is gradually becoming more and more heterogeneous. We observe three chief directions of ownership structure changes: – perpetuation of a dispersed shareholding structure, with dominance of insiders (an approximation of an egalitarian, worker cooperative ownership struc-ture); – consolidation of ownership in the hands of insider elites; – concentration of ownership in the hands of outside investors. In general, however, change is incremental. Radical changes in the ownership structure are rare, and owner-ship structure seems to be fairly inert. It would, never-theless, be wrong to conclude that significant change is not possible when it is in the interests of the incumbents, as new strategic investors had appeared in about 10 per-cent of the sample by 1998. (It is, however, worth noting that there is a negative relationship between the size of top management's share and the appearance of strategic investors; it appears that once managers have decisive control over the ownership structure of a company, they are reluctant to relinquish it.) A number of factors which influence the direction and the dynamics of ownership changes, among others sector affiliation, company size, initial ownership structure, etc., but the most important is the economic condition of the company, which, when it is poor, favors concentration and "outsiderization" of ownership (as well as changes in corpo-rate governance). Management ownership on the average appears in relatively small companies, while strategic investors appear in companies whose average employment is above the sample average. This is probably due to the fact that, given low levels of personal savings at the beginning of the transformation, it was more difficult for an individual or small group of individuals to buy a large block of shares in a large company than in a small firm. Post-privatization ownership transformations were achieved not only by trade in existing shares but also by issues of new ones. Nineteen firms had carried out new share issues by mid-1997. Most frequently, new share issues serve to promote concentration of shares (espe-cially in the hands of management and strategic investors). Access to credit and company size seem to be the most significant determinants of investment spending. Very surprisingly, the presence of strategic investors seems to be unrelated to investment spending. Many firms in the sample refrain from making dividend pay-ments, but there is no indication that this leads to increased investment and may simply be a result of ab-uses by management. There is some evidence that con-centration of shares in the hands of management is posi-tively related to investment, while the evidence concern-ing the relationship between the share of non-managerial employees and investment is ambiguous. There appears to be no relationship between ownership structure and marketing activity or expansion into new markets (the former is most strongly related to company size, and the latter to the branch in which the company is operating). However, companies with strategic investors do much better than others in the area of ISO quality certification. There is (very) slight evidence that the extent of non-managerial employees' share in the ownership of the firm had a negative effect on economic performance in the early 1990s. In particular, there is a case – albeit a weak one – to be made for the claim that companies whose employees constitute the dominant owners follow a poli-cy favoring consumption (wages, dividends and the like) over investment and development. However, the situa-tion in the companies is likely to be differentiated, with the character of relationships between ownership struc-ture and economic decision-making dependent on many CASE Reports No. 47 7. Conclusions
  • 41. 48 We must remember that each firm in fact constitutes a complex social organism, and the number of groupings and factions is probably propor-tional to the number of employees. For a clear and comprehensive picture of the decision-making process in such firms, we probably need an indepth sociological analysis which would reveal the differences among such groups as current and former employees, new and old employees, white-collar and blue-collar employees, employees of various departments and divisions, etc. 41 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... factors which we were unable to analyze here48. An example of such differences is found in the opinion encountered by one of the authors of this paper in case studies of Polish employee-owned companies, according to which the most consumption-oriented attitudes are exhibited by former employees. One of the company presidents expressing this opinion about former emp-loyees also said that he regretted the fact that new employees were unable to acquire shares in the company, since such employees (young, well-educated persons hired in the 1990s) are often the most valuable in the firm49. From this point of view, it is possible that emp-loyee- owned companies in Poland could gain certain advantages from the creation of trust funds which would hold employee shares on behalf of the employees, issuing shares to new employees and purchasing them from those that leave the company. Such a mechanism might resemble, for example, the Employee Stock Ownership Plans of the United States50. Turning to issues of corporate governance, we conclude with a brief look at executive boards and supervisory boards. The membership of the executive boards is dominated by persons who had managed the companies before priva-tization, when they were still state enterprises. The repro-duction of elites is more frequently halted in firms in which over 50 percent of the shares are in the hands of outsiders than in the "insider" firms, especially those in which the majority of shares belong to non-managerial employees. When viewed over a longer period of time, the evolu-tion of the composition of the supervisory boards has not been unidirectional. Contrary to what one might expect in view of the process of ownership "outsiderization", the position of insiders measured by numerical dominance in the composition of different boards was markedly strength-ened in 1998–1999. in companies belonging to the employ-ees, institutional control is increasingly concentration of in the hands of insiders, while in the "outsider" companies their employees are more and more often allowed to par-ticipate in the organs of corporate governance. Moreover, when we look at the evolution of supervisory board com-position from the point of view of the occupations of their members (e.g., the increasing percentage of members with specialist and non-managerial positions), we see evidence of increasing representation of stakeholders on this body. At the same time, polarization into purely "insider" and purely "outsider" boards was accentuated. The supervisory boards did not use all the powers they were given, at least during 1998–1999. The use of these powers depends not only on the character of the board, but also on the company's need for such actions. For example, it can be assumed that all supervisory boards are active in reviewing financial documents, statements, etc., while, as a rule, their participation in appointing and dismissing the executive board, approving large transactions, etc., occurs much more rarely, simply because these actions are much less frequent. Extension of the supervisory boards' activities is observed most frequently in companies in economic dis-tress. Interrelationships between the ownership structure and the extension of the supervisory boards' powers are of a more complex nature. The most striking relationships seem to be the following: lack of any dominant owners' group is linked to extension of the supervisory boards' activ-ities to the organizational sphere and to the control over the capital and the firm; dominance of employee ownership is linked to the board's "social" activity and control over the firm's assets, and dominance of the managerial staff in the ownership structure is, in general, not accompanied by any extension of the supervisory board's powers, except to the area of finance. Thus, different configurations of the insider-dominated ownership structure go hand in hand with dif-ferent patterns of extension of the supervisory board's range of powers. Lack of dominance of any group is often accompanied by the assumption of other organs' and ser-vices' functions by the supervisory boards; dominance of employee ownership dictates special attention to matters that are important for the employees, i.e. to social prob-lems, and dominance of the managerial staff in the owner-ship structure tends to be accompanied by limitation of the supervisory board's powers to certain strictly defined areas. Generally speaking, the small role of owners in the deci-sion- making process is striking. The owners most frequent-ly act as decision makers where ownership is concentrated in the hands of a strategic outside investor. The role of own-ers in decision-making also grows in loss-making companies (at the expense of the powers of the executive and super-visory boards). 49 See Woodward (1999). 50 For more on the subject of ESOPs, see Blasi (1988). CASE Reports No. 47
  • 42. 42 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward Appendix Definitions of variables and correlations Definitions of variables L employment (end of year) P.C. CH percentage change in employment between the end of the year prior to privatization and the end of 1996 MAN percentage of the company's shares held by members of the Executive Board (at time of privatization, and in mid-1997, 1998, and 1999) SI percentage of the company's shares held by the strategic investor (at time of privatization, and in mid- 1997, 1998, and 1999) WOR percentage of the company's shares held by non-managerial employees (at time of privatization, and in mid-1997, 1998, and 1999; in section 5, in mid-1992, 1993, and 1994) GRMAN difference between percentage of the company's shares held by Executive Board members in mid- 1997 and at time of privatization GRSI difference between percentage of the company's shares held by strategic investor in mid-1997 and at time of privatization GRWORdifference between percentage of the company's shares held by non-managerial employees in mid- 1997 and at time of privatization TRCONdummy indicating whether neither Executive Board members nor a strategic investor had a share of more than 20% at time of privatization and one or both of these types of owners had over 20% in mid-1997 TRSI dummy indicating whether strategic investor had a share of less than 20% at time of privatization and over 20% in mid-1997 TRM dummy indicating whether Executive Board mem-bers had a share of less than 20% at time of privati-zation and over 20% in mid-1997 BIG percentage of the company's shares held by the single largest shareholder (in mid-1997, 1998, and 1999) OWN percentage of the work force that holds shares (at time of privatization, and in mid-1997, 1998, and 1999; in section 5, in mid-1992, 1993, and 1994) UNI percentage of the work force that belongs to a trade union (at time of privatization, and in mid-1997, 1998, and 1999; in section 5, in mid-1992, 1993, and 1994) DIV two variables: absolute value of the dividend payment in PLN, or dummy variable for payment of dividend (1: dividend was paid; 0: dividend was not paid) DIVS ratio of dividend to the face value of one share DIVP ratio of dividend to net profit LEA dummy for whether the lease had been paid off (mid- 1999) NMKT number of positive responses to question whether new markets had been found (range: 0 to 3) MK DUM dummy for whether the firm has a marketing divi-sion MK EMPemployment in the marketing division Dummies for the degree of equality of shareholding: EQ1 at least one shareholder holds at least 10 percent of all shares (high concentration) EQ2 at least one person holds 5–10 percent of all shares (medium concentration) EQ3 at least one person holds 1–5 percent of all shares (relative equality) Dummies for the population of the city or town in which the company is located: POP1 less than 20,000 POP2 21,000–50,000 POP3 51,000–200,000 POP4 201,000–500,000 POP5 over 500,000 Dummies concerning new issues: NEW a new share issue was held CLO the new share issue was a closed (i.e., not public) subscription Dummies for market share of the firm: MON the company is a monopolist OLI the company is an oligopolist COM the company operates in a competitive market Investment variables: INV annual investment spending (1996) PC value of current investment projects, per employee (total from 1992 through 1996, and 1998) INCR dummy for whether investment was financed by obtainment of credit Variables used only in Section 5: K = value of fixed assets, in millions of pre-1995 zlotys (as of June 199351, end of 1993, end of 1994) YEAR = dummy for year of production (1992=0, 1993=1, 1994=2) AMORT= amortization of fixed assets at the time of privati-zation (as a proxy for the firm's age) 51 End-of-year fixed assets data for 1992 were unfortunately not available. Given the choice between using fixed assets for the ti me of privatization (in 1990 or 1991) and in June 1993 as an approximation for the 1992 capital stock, the latter measure seemed much better, given that a great deal of property was frequently sold or leased by the companies within the initial period following privatization. CASE Reports No. 47
  • 43. 43 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... Bibliography Blasi, Joseph R. (1988), Employee Ownership: Revolution or Ripoff? Grand Rapids, Michigan. Brada, J.C. Singh, I. (1995), Industrial Transformation and Labor Productivity in Central and Eastern Europe. IN: Quaisser, W. Woodward, R. and B³aszczyk, B. (eds.) Privati-zation in Poland and East Germany: A Comparison. Munich, Osteuropa-Institut. Central Statistical Office (G³ówny Urz¹d Statystyczny). (1995), Prywatyzacja przedsiêbiorstw pañstwowych wg. stanu na 31.12.1994 r. (Privatization of state enterprises as of 31 December, 1994). Warsaw. Central Statistical Office (G³ówny Urz¹d Centralny). (1999) Prywatyzacja przedsiêbiorstw pañstwowych w 1998 r. (Privatization of state enterprises as of 31 December, 1994). Warsaw. Conte, M.A. Svejnar, J. (1988) Productivity Effects of Worker Participation in Management, Profit-Sharing, Work-er Ownership of Assets and Unionization in U.S. Firms. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 6. Estrin, S. Jones, D.C. and Svejnar, J. (1987) The Produc-tivity Effects of Worker Participation: Producer Coopera-tives in Western Economies. Journal of Comparative Econom-ics, 11 March. Eyeing up the risk (1995) Business Central Europe, 3 (25) October. Frydman, R. and Rapaczynski, A. (1994) Privatization in Eastern Europe: Is the State Withering Away? Budapest, CEU Press. Gardawski, J. (1995) Trends in the Ownership and Authority Structure of Employee-Owned Companies. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Management Employee Buy-Outs in Poland, Warsaw, ISP PAN. Gardawski, J. (1996) Toward Management-Employee Ownership. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Polish Employee-Owned Com-panies in 1995, Warsaw, ISP PAN. Gardawski, J. (2000) Forming of Owner Groups in Pri-vatized Enterprises. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Ten Years of Direct Pri-vatization, Warsaw, ISP PAN. Grosfeld, I. Nivet, J.F. (1998) Insider Power and Wage Set-ting in Transition: Evidence from a Panel of Large Polish Firms, 1988–1994. Paper prepared for the European Economic Association Congress, 2–5 September, Berlin. Jarosz, M. ed. (1994) Employee-Owned Companies in Poland. Warsaw, ISP PAN. Jarosz, M. ed. (1995) Management Employee Buy-outs in Poland. Warsaw, ISP PAN. Jarosz, M. ed. (1996) Polish Employee-Owned Companies in 1995. Warsaw, ISP PAN. CASE Reports No. 47 Jarosz, M. ed. (1999) Direct Privatization. Investors. Man-agers. Employees. Warsaw, ISP PAN. Jarosz, M. ed. (2000) Ten Years of Direct Privatization. Warsaw, ISP PAN. Jones, D.C. (1993) The Productivity Effects of Employee Ownership Within Command Economies: Evidence from Poland. Managerial and Decision Economics, 14. Kierunki prywatyzacji maj¹tku pañstwowego w 1995r. (Directions of privatization of state property in 1995). Dzien-nik Ustaw 1995 nr 27, poz. 142. Kozarzewski, P. (1999) Elity kierownicze spó³ek pracow-niczych: w³asnooeæ – zarz¹dzanie – oewiadomooeæ (Elites of Employee-Owned Companies: Ownership – Management – Mentality). Warsaw, ISP PAN. Kozarzewski, P. (2000a) Authority Structures in the Companies. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Ten Years of Direct Privatiza-tion. Warsaw, ISP PAN. Kozarzewski, P. (2000b) Owner Control. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Ten Years of Direct Privatization. Warsaw, ISP PAN. Kozarzewski, P. Krajewski, S. and Majak, R. (2000) Own-ership Transformations in 1990–1998 in the Light of Law and Statistical Data. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Ten Years of Direct Privati-zation. Warsaw, ISP PAN. Krajewski, S. (1998) Efekty ekonomiczne prywatyzacji bezpooeredniej (Economic effects of Direct Privatization). IN: Jarosz, M.ed. Prywatyzacja bezpooerednia: Inwestorzy, Mened¿erowie, Pracownicy (Direct Privatization. Investors. Managers. Employees), Warsaw, ISP PAN. Krajewski, S. (2000) Economic effects of direct privati-zation. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Ten Years of Direct Privatization, Warsaw, ISP PAN. Ministry of Ownership Transformation (Ministerstwo Przekszta³ceñ W³asnooeciowych – Departament Delegatur i Analiz Prywatyzacji) (1995) Informacja o procesie prywatyza-cji przedsiêbiorstw pañstwowych – do dnia 31.12.1994 r. (Information on the process of privatization of state enterpris-es through 31 December, 1994), 21 January, Warsaw. Pietrewicz, J. (1995) Direction of Transformation of Employee-Owned Companies. IN: Jarosz, M. ed. Manage-ment Employee Buy-outs in Poland,Warsaw, ISP PAN. Supreme Control Chamber (Najwy¿sza Izba Kontroli – Zespó³ Przekszta³ceñ W³asnooeciowych). (1993) Informacja o wynikach kontroli prywatyzacji przedsiêbiorstw pañstwowych w drodze likwidacji przez oddanie przedsiêbiorstwa lub jego czêoe-ci do odp³atnego korzystania (Results of investigation of privati-zation of state enterprises by the method of enterprise liquida-tion and asset leasing). December, Warsaw. Szomburg, J. D¹browski, J.M. and Kamiñski, T. (1994) Monitoring przedsiêbiorstw sprywatyzowanych (Review of pri-vatized enterprises). Gdañsk Institute for Market Economics, Gdañsk.
  • 44. 44 P. Kozarzewski, R. Woodward CASE Reports No. 47 Uchwa³a Sejmu Rzeczypospolitej Polskiej z dnia 12 lutego 1993 r. w sprawie podstawowych kierunków prywatyzacji w 1993 r. (Resolution dated 12 February, 1993, of the Polish par-liament concerning the directions of privatization in 1993). Monitor Polski 1993 nr 9, poz. 64. Wasilewski, J. Wnuk-Lipinski, E. (1995) Winding Road from the Communist to the Post-Solidarity Elite. Theory and Society, No. 24. Woodward, R. (1998) Various Forms of Employee Par-ticipation in Polish Employee-Owned Companies. IN: Jones, D.C. and others. eds. Advances in the Economic Analy-sis of Participatory and Labor-Managed Firms, 6, London, JAI Press Inc. Woodward, R. (1999) Employee Involvement in Emp-loyee- Owned Companies in Poland. Unpublished doctoral dis-sertation, University of £ódŸ. Zarz¹dzenie Ministra Finansów z dnia 7 maja 1991 r. (Instruction of the Minister of Finance, 7 May, 1991). Monitor Polski 1991 nr 18, poz. 123. Zarz¹dzenie Ministra Finansów z dnia 13 maja 1993 r. (Instruction of the Minister of Finance, 13 May, 1993). Moni-tor Polski 1993 nr 26, poz. 274. Zellner, A. Kmenta, J. and Dreze, J. (1966) Specification and Estimation of Cobb-Douglas Production Function Mod-els. Econometrica, October.
  • 45. 45 Secondary Privatization in Poland (Part 1) ... 26 M. D¹browski: Macroeconomic and Fiscal Challenges Facing Central European Countries during the EU Accession Process 27 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ B. B³aszczyk i A. Cylwika: Charakterystyka wybranych sektorów infrastrukturalnych i wra¿liwych w gospodarce polskiej oraz mo¿liwooeci ich prywatyzacji 28 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ B. Liberdy: Determinanty oszczêdzania w Polsce 29 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ J.Kochanowicza: Ekonomia polityczna konsolidacji reform 30 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ B. B³aszczyk, E. Balcerowicz: Uwarunkowania wzrostu sektora prywatnego w Polsce 32 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ A. Wojtyny: Alternatywne strategie dezinflacji 33 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ A. Wojtyny: Wspieranie wzrostu gospodarczego poprzez konsolidacjê reform 34 J. Pankow, L. Dimitrov, P. Kozarzewski: Effects of Privatization of Industrial Enterprises in Bulgaria. Report on Empirical Research 35 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ S. Golinowskiej: Edukacja i rynek pracy 36 S. Golinowska, P. Kurowski (eds.): Rational Pension Supevision, First Experiences of Central and Eastern European States in Comparison with other Countries 37 J. Pañków (ed.): Fiscal Effects from Privatization: Case of Bulgaria and Poland 38 G. Ganev, M. Jarociñski, R. Lubenova, P. WoŸniak: Credibility of the Exchange Rate Policy in Transition Countries 39 M. D¹browski (ed.): The Episodes of Currency Crises in Latin American and Asian Economies 40 M. D¹browski (ed.): The Episodes of Currency Crises in the European Transition Economies 41 M. D¹browski (ed.): Currency Crises in Emerging Markets – Selected Comparative Studies 42 Praca zbiorowa pod redakcj¹ J. Cukrowskiego: Renta emisyjna jako Ÿród³o finansowania bud¿etu pañstwa 43 P. Bujak, M. Jarmu¿ek, S. Kordel, W. Nawrot, J. OEmietaniak: OEredniookresowa projekcja dzia³alnooeci inwestycyjnej Otwartych Funduszy Emerytalnych na regulowanym rynku gie³dowym akcji 44 E. Balcerowicz, A. Bratkowski: Restructuring and Development of the Banking Sector in Poland. Lessons to be Learnt by Less Advanced Transition Countries ^ 45 E. Kocenda: Secondary Privatization in the Czech Republic: Changes in Ownership and Enterprise Performance in Voucher- Privatized Firms 46 M. Simoneti, A. Böhm, M. Rems, M. Rojec, J.P. Damijan, B. Majcen: Secondary Privatization in Slovenia: Evolution of Ownership Structure and Company Performance Following Mass Privatization