SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Skills matching challenge
Skills matching challenge
The skill matching
challenge
Analysing skill mismatch
and policy implications




Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, 2010
A great deal of additional information on the European Union
is available on the Internet.

It can be accessed through the Europa server (http://europa.eu).

Cataloguing data can be found at the end of this publication.

Luxembourg:
Publications Office of the European Union, 2010

ISBN 978-92-896-0485-7

© European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training, 2010
All rights reserved.

Designed by Fotone - Greece
Printed in the European Union
The European Centre for the Development
    of Vocational Training (Cedefop) is the European Union’s
         reference centre for vocational education and training.
          We provide information on and analyses of vocational
education and training systems, policies, research and practice.
                              Cedefop was established in 1975
                       by Council Regulation (EEC) No 337/75.



            Europe 123, 570 01 Thessaloniki (Pylea), GREECE
                PO Box 22427, 551 02 Thessaloniki, GREECE
                   Tel. +30 2310490111, Fax +30 2310490020
                              E-mail: info@cedefop.europa.eu
                                    www.cedefop.europa.eu



                                     Aviana Bulgarelli, Director
                            Christian Lettmayr, Deputy Director
                    Peter Kreiml, Chair of the Governing Board
Skills matching challenge
Foreword

Cedefop analyses of skill needs and supply provide a core input to debates on
future developments in European labour markets. Policy-makers increasingly
recognise the added value of anticipating skill trends to support evidence-
based policy-making.
   At the time of writing this report, Europe is battling a major recession.
Matching skills and jobs is gaining importance with rising unemployment
and increasing difficulties for people entering the labour market to find
jobs matching their potential. At the same time, structural trends challenge
Europe’s ability to provide the skills that its economies need to grow and
prosper. The European population is ageing rapidly, leading to a large
outflow of experienced workers in the coming decades while those nearing
retirement will need to adapt to the new skills that many jobs require. The
dynamics of today’s labour markets not only create new jobs while others
shrink or disappear, but also contribute to changing skill requirements in
many existing jobs.
   The analysis of skill mismatch is, therefore, a crucial pillar of Cedefop
work on skills. Assessing mismatch and its effects involves much more
than straightforward comparisons between skill needs and skill supply.
Skill mismatch is a complex phenomenon affecting citizens, enterprises,
economies and societies. It refers not only to skill gaps and shortages, but
also to skills exceeding job requirements.
   The prominence of skill mismatch as a core challenge on many policy
agendas, such as the new skills of jobs initiative, inspired Cedefop to explore
and analyse skill mismatch systematically. After setting the priorities for
future work on skill mismatch research in 2008 (Cedefop, 2009), this report
is the first in a series bridging the worlds of research and practice, aiming
to provide insights that enable evidence-based policy-making. The report
gives a broad overview of skill mismatch and the factors that contribute; it
analyses economic and social costs and discusses why mismatch should
be a concern for national and European policy-makers. As cross-country
information on skill mismatch is limited, the report also discusses how skill
mismatch can be better approached and measured in surveys to give more
detailed and sound analyses in the coming years.
2    The skill matching challenge




       I believe this report serves a clear need by structuring the currently scattered
    information on skill mismatch. Organising research findings to answer seven
    important questions, the report is a direct input to evidence-based policy-
    making. I am convinced this publication will add to the understanding of
    skill mismatch in Europe and help national and European policy-makers to
    make choices to aid matching skills and jobs in Europe.


    Aviana Bulgarelli
    Director of Cedefop
Acknowledgements   3




                            Acknowledgements

This report is the result of a team effort with contributions from those working
on Cedefop’s skill mismatch research. In particular, Jasper van Loo, who
supervised and edited the publication, Manfred Tessaring and Pascaline
Descy. This report was prepared under contract number 2008-FWC11/
AO/RPA/PDE-GUTCH-JVLOO/VETBenefits-skillmismatch/007/08 Lot 7.
It is largely based on the contributions of Nigel O’Leary and Peter Sloane
(Welmerc, School of Business and Economics, Swansea University), Seamus
McGuinness and Philip O’Connell (ESRI – Economic and Social Research
Institute, Dublin) and Kostas Mavromaras (NILS – National Institute of
Labour Studies, Flinders University, Adelaide, Australia). Thanks also go to
Alena Zukersteinova and Torsten Dunkel from Cedefop for their valuable
comments and suggestions.
Table of contents

Foreword	                                                                1
Acknowledgements	                                                        3
Executive summary	                                                       6

1.	   Why be concerned about skill mismatch?	                            9
	     1.1. Framing the issue and policy background	                      9
	     1.2. Glossary of terms	                                           12
	     1.3.	Aim and format of this report	                               14

2.	 What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe?	                    16
	 2.1.	Vertical mismatch and impact on wages	                           16
	 2.2.	Horizontal mismatch and impact on wages	                         21
	 2.3.	What is the likely duration of skill mismatches?	                22
		     2.3.1. Individual overeducation and overskilling	                22
		     2.3.2. Overeducation and overskilling at firm level	             23
		     2.3.3. Undereducation and underskilling in individuals/firms	    24
		     2.3.4. Skill shortages	                                          24
		     2.3.5. Skill gaps	                                               25
		     2.3.6. Skills obsolescence	                                      25

3.	   What causes skill mismatch?	                                      27
	     3.1.	Causes of overeducation	                                     27
	     3.2.	Underlying causes of skill shortages	                        32
	     3.3.	Causes of skills obsolescence	                               32
	     3.4.	Mismatch and individual characteristics	                     34

4.	 What are the links between the different types
	 of skill mismatch?	                                                   36
	 4.1.	Skill shortages, skill gaps, undereducation and underskilling	   36
	 4.2.	What is the relationship between overeducation,
		     overskilling and skill shortages?	                               40
	 4.3.	Combinations and durations of mismatch	                          43
Table of contents   5




5.	   Business cycle impact on skill mismatch	                              46
	     5.1.	Skill mismatch and business cycles	                              46
	     5.2.	The impact of the economic crisis	                               47
	     5.3.	Evidence from Australia	                                         50

6.	 The implications of skill mismatch	                                     51
	 6.1.	Skill mismatch and productivity	                                     51
		      6.1.1. Overeducation and productivity	                              52
		      6.1.2. Skill shortages and productivity	                            53
		      6.1.3. Skill gaps and productivity	                                 53
	 6.2.	Skill mismatch and job satisfaction	                                 54
	 6.3.	Possible positive impacts of skill mismatch	                         55
	 6.4.	Skill mismatch costs for society	                                    56

7.	   Appropriate skill mismatch measuring	                                 59
	     7.1.	Measuring overeducation and overskilling	                        59
	     7.2.	Focusing on overskilling	                                        62
	     7.3.	Measuring skills obsolescence	                                   64

8.	   Skill mismatch data needed in Europe	                                 65
	     8.1.	Improving data on skill mismatch in Europe	                      65
	     8.2.	What information should be collected and how?	                   66
	     8.3.	The way forward	                                                 68

Annex: comprehensive schemata for skill mismatch
		     questions in surveys	                                                69
References	                                                                 72

List of tables
1.	 Glossary of terms	                                                      13
2.	 Reported incidence of overeducation	                                    18
3.	 Types and causes of skills obsolescence	                                33
4.	 Combination of mismatch for firms	                                      43
5.	Data sets containing questions to individual employees on skill
    mismatch	                                                               60

Boxes
1.	 Theoretical approaches to overeducation	                                29
2.	 The Beveridge curve	                                                    39
Executive summary

With global competition increasing, demographic change unfolding and
rapid technological change intensifying, skill mismatch has come to the
forefront of Europe’s policy debate. Skill mismatch refers not only to skill
shortages or gaps, but also to qualifications, knowledge and skills exceeding
job requirements. Shortages in some sectors may occur simultaneously
with overeducation in others. When skill mismatch takes time to resolve
it imposes real costs on individuals, enterprises and societies. Given the
relevance of matching skills and jobs and how information on mismatch is
scattered, this report synthesises evidence and provides new insights to
promote comprehensive policies that prevent and address skill mismatch
and its consequences. An overview of the meaning and characteristics of
different types of skill mismatch, such as overeducation and overqualification,
are provided in the glossary of terms in Section 1.2.
    Skill mismatch is a widespread phenomenon in Europe, with overeducation
incidence averaging around 30 % and a substantial share of the population
undereducated. Whether skill mismatch is stable or increasing over time
differs between countries. The overeducated suffer a wage penalty, but
earn more than their matched colleagues, while the reverse applies to the
undereducated. Mismatch between the type of skills someone has and
the type of skills required is also prominent and has a negative impact on
earnings. There is, however, some disagreement on the extent to which
mismatch is a temporary or a long-term phenomenon, but both overeducation
and overskilling may persist over long periods. The overeducated may be
trapped in low-level jobs while the undereducated or underskilled are paid
more than those with the same level of education in matching jobs and,
therefore, have no incentive to move. The duration of skill shortages will
be a function of their level and complexity, while the duration of skill gaps
is linked to retraining. Skills obsolescence can occur over a relatively short
number of years compared to a working lifetime, which means that lifelong
learning is essential for successful careers.
    To understand the causes of mismatch, one needs to look at its various
forms. A core reason explaining overeducation is the asymmetry of labour-
market information. Better-informed individuals are better prepared to avoid
overeducation than less-informed ones. Part of what is described in the
Executive summary   7




literature as ‘overeducation’ reflects the differences in individual abilities and
of skills within particular education categories. Light can be cast on this issue
by considering the job satisfaction of workers in this state or the extent to
which their skills are used. Several factors are responsible for skill shortages,
such as insufficient training, education and training systems responding
slowly to market changes, skill-biased technological progress and business
cycles. Skill shortages also emerge when people accept a low-skilled job
while continuing to search for a better match, for instance when options
are limited for personal or family reasons. Skills obsolescence, which is a
process rather than a state, occurs when skills depreciate due to ageing or
lack of use at work; or when economic developments change the skills that
firms need. Mismatch is more relevant for specific groups, such as young
people entering the labour market, older workers, females, ethnic minorities
and the disabled. Certain racial minorities suffer from mismatch to a greater
degree than the majority population. Whether women suffer more than men
is less clear. Older workers are likely to suffer most from skills obsolescence
but little evidence links skills obsolescence to long-term problems.
    What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch?
Overeducation and overskilling are expected to be negatively related to
labour shortages. Whenever they coexist it is probably because skills or
education are of the wrong type or because the two phenomena refer to
different occupations in the same enterprise, industry or economy. It seems
there is no strong correlation between the occurrence of skill shortages
and skill gaps, but the latter may be closely linked to underskilling. Various
types of mismatch can be present at the same time in firms but probably
not simultaneously within specific occupations.
    Different phases of the business cycle result in different imbalances
between labour demand and supply. These imbalances have profound
implications on how skill mismatch arises and how it influences the economy.
Studying the dynamics of skills creation and destruction is at the heart of
understanding mismatch driven by the business cycle. Currently, there is
insufficient empirical evidence to address the complex policy issues involved.
In the present downturn, the following policy issues need to be addressed
urgently: the role of training; the role of obsolescence; and how they may
affect different parts of the economy, in particular vulnerable groups of
people and vulnerable industries, such as those under intense international
competition.
    Mismatched individuals may suffer from lower wages and are less satisfied
with their jobs than if they were properly matched; employers may suffer from
8    The skill matching challenge




    lower productivity; and the economy may suffer from a loss of output. This is
    true for overeducation, overskilling and skill shortages. Both skill shortages
    and skill gaps might lead to a loss of competitiveness; this is supported by
    empirical evidence. Similar arguments apply to over/undereducation and
    over/underskilling; this is confirmed by studies of US firms. However, if
    skilled workers are hired anticipating future manpower requirements this
    could have a positive effect for firms and be favourable for society through
    increased innovation.
       How to measure skill mismatch is a core concern. Three alternative
    methods have been used: systematic job evaluation (objective measure),
    worker self-assessment (subjective measure) and empirical method (where
    data sets do not contain a direct question on the phenomenon). Each method
    has weaknesses. The report argues that over and underskilling may be
    superior measures to over and undereducation, especially if we are concerned
    with potential welfare losses. Skills obsolescence can be measured in several
    ways, but little consensus exists on which method is the most appropriate,
    while few data sets contain questions that can be used to assess skills
    obsolescence.
       Good data are probably the most crucial prerequisite to supporting
    timely, effective and evidence-based skill mismatch policies. The current
    shortcomings of data sets may take years to remedy. Ideally, new matched
    employer-employee panel data, with information on labour demand and
    supply, should be developed. Collecting these data is very expensive and
    several years of data are needed for full research potential. Individual or
    household data can be used instead, but with a comprehensive coverage of
    the various elements of mismatch, which is not currently the case. Remedying
    existing data sets is cheaper than developing new ones. An alternative cost-
    effective method for collecting Europe-wide data on mismatch could be a new
    module containing questions on mismatch, possibly introduced in several
    existing European large panel surveys at regular but infrequent intervals
    (such as once every three years). We support the view that alternative
    means of data collection should also be considered for issues that may be
    too detailed to be informed through conventional interviews.
CHAPTER 1

  Why be concerned about skill
  mismatch?

Skill mismatch should be of concern to all citizens, but especially to policy-
makers, employers’ associations and trade unions. Because of skill-
biased technological change, its incidence will increase over time, though
overeducation could have some positive effects. As Europe’s population
is ageing rapidly, skills obsolescence is also likely to grow in importance.
Matching skills and jobs is, therefore, crucial for Europe.
   It is unrealistic to assume that labour markets can work without temporary
imbalances but skill mismatch that takes time to resolve or is even permanent
implies real economic and social losses. Aiming to provide insights supporting
evidence-based policy-making, this report considers all types of skill
mismatch and their interrelationships, recognising that their measurement
and interpretation is not always straightforward. The report focuses on
seven research questions, on some of which relatively little is known. In this
chapter, we examine why policy-makers and other stakeholders should be
concerned about skill mismatch. Subsequently, we provide a glossary of
terms and elaborate the aim and the set-up of this report.


1.1.   Framing the issue and policy background
Skill mismatch has come to the forefront of the policy debate in Europe,
with global competition increasing, demographic change progressing and
rapid technological change intensifying (European Commission, 2008a).
Skill problems might arise, with shortages in some sectors combined with
the problem of overeducation in others. Skilled people frequently working
in elementary jobs is a pervasive international phenomenon. The challenge
facing Europe is to provide businesses with the right skills to encourage
innovation and growth, to address unemployment and to ensure that the
potential of Europe’s citizens is fully utilised.
   As the European Commission Communication on new skills for new jobs
(European Commission, 2008) observes, skill matching should be improved
to confront rising unemployment. It is also suggested that the composition of
skills emerging from both European Union universities and training systems
needs to be better adapted to innovation-driven economies. Further, skill-
10    The skill matching challenge




     biased technological change results in a need for education upgrading as
     demand for more highly-educated workers increases at the expense of
     the less educated (1). The recent Cedefop report on Future skill needs in
     Europe (Cedefop, 2008) notes that out of a net employment increase of
     over 13 million jobs between 2006 and 2015 almost 12.5 million will be at
     the highest qualification level (ISCED 5 and 6).
         Skill mismatch is a crucial policy issue, not only for policy-makers but
     also for social partners including employers associations and trade unions.
     Reducing skill mismatch is likely to generate social benefits with higher
     job satisfaction for employees and possibly reduced stress from work,
     increasing health and wellbeing. At macro level, skill shortages and skill
     gaps can potentially lead to a loss of competitiveness as wage rates are
     bid up and productivity lowered within industries where skill problems exist.
     Productivity may also suffer if firms are forced to place lower-skilled workers
     in skilled positions and/or if where a skills shortage exists, workers use their
     position to alter their employment terms and conditions in a way that harms
     productivity.
         As the European Commission Communication on new skills for new
     jobs (European Commission (2008b) states, skills upgrading is important
     for Europe’s future growth potential and for employment equity, given the
     vulnerability of those lacking skills. It goes on to state that, due to imperfect
     information and structural rigidities, the lack of appropriate skills harms
     competitiveness, particularly for small enterprises. The communication
     suggests that skills upgrading is the most relevant solution to current and
     anticipated imbalances in the labour market.
         Skill-biased technological and organisational change has not only increased
     the demand for highly-skilled manpower but has also been encouraged itself
     by the availability of such manpower. An increasing pace of technological
     change is likely, however, to result in growing skill shortages and skill gaps
     if appropriate education and training is not provided. At the same time the
     routine tasks of the middle-skilled may be eliminated by new technologies
     (hollowing out).
         Mismatches are usually explained by a combination of information
     asymmetry between employers and employees, incomplete information
     in the labour market, differences between people, and transactions costs.


     (1)  or a recent theory paper on the implications of on-the-job search in a matching model, which traces
         F
         out the effects on the composition of jobs, unemployment, wages and labour-market reactions to
         shifts in the supply of and demand for skills, see Dolado et al. (2009).
CHAPTER 1
                                                     Why be concerned about skill mismatch?   11




Therefore, tackling mismatch by providing labour-market information and
efficient job placement services should be a priority for policy-makers. This
holds for both vertical and horizontal mismatch.
   Vertical mismatch, which is commonly referred to as overeducation,
occurs when an individual is hired for a job advertised as requiring a lower
level of education than the individual possesses, or alternatively, when an
individual is employed in a job which requires a lower level of education.
When overeducation is partly a consequence of lower ability at a given
education level or choice of employment by the individual concerned, this
does not, in itself, imply a particular role for policy. If overeducation is merely
a temporary phenomenon, policy-makers should not be too concerned but,
for many employees, overeducation lasts a long time. Yet, if employers hire
the overeducated, anticipating a future need, their action may have positive
rather than negative repercussions.
   Along these lines, for Schlotter (2008), overeducation can be a desirable
feature of education and training systems and, following Sloane (2003), low-
skilled workers may compensate for their lack of skill/ability by additional
education to gain employment which they might otherwise not obtain.
However, overskilling has negative effects on the wages earned by individuals
experiencing it and on their job satisfaction. Greater care in job matching
may, therefore, not only improve the welfare of overskilled employees, but
also have positive effects on productivity and the growth in the economy.
Finally, skills obsolescence is likely to grow in significance as the pace
of economic and technological change intensifies and the labour force is
ageing. Here there is a need for policies which encourage employers to
retain older workers, as it is much more difficult to find new employment
as workers age.
   Graduates sometimes face horizontal skill mismatch, when not the level,
but the type of education or skills are inappropriate for the job. Those with
specific degrees do better than those with more general degrees (arts and
humanities). This suggests that better information should be provided for
potential students to address and prevent mismatches of this type.
   A particular policy issue is whether genuine mismatch requires action from
education providers or employers. For skill mismatch, whether horizontal
or vertical, Weststar (2009) suggests that attention should be shifted away
from education reform towards considering the impact of workplace and
job design. This could be best achieved by giving workers greater task
discretion on both social and technical control. The former includes taking
part in decision-making, while the latter includes the ability to plan certain
12    The skill matching challenge




     aspects of the work and elements of choice in the way work is performed.
     Training needs of mismatched workers should also be considered.
        Data on skill mismatch in Europe shows that it is pervasive, but evidence
     is scattered and there is much confusion about what is meant by different
     aspects of skill mismatch. Poor understanding of skill mismatch implies poor
     understanding of interactions between types of skill imbalances, thereby
     preventing coordinated actions. Addressing skill mismatch problems is
     especially relevant for vulnerable groups on the labour market, such as
     migrants, older workers and young people transiting from school to work.



     1.2. Glossary                   of terms
     Literature is not always clear on what is precisely meant by different types
     of skill mismatch. For example, it is often not straightforward to assess
     whether mismatch refers to qualitative or quantitative aspects and what is
     meant by occupational or education levels in a context where the notion of
     levels is blurring in many workplaces. Despite this, it is useful to have some
     initial understanding of various types of mismatch before examining more
     detailed issues. Therefore, Table 1 presents a glossary of terms. Although
     the definitions are based on a loose interpretation of literature and sometimes
     combine qualitative and quantitative dimensions of mismatch, they allow
     better understanding of different types and dimensions of mismatch. As an
     example, overeducation is defined in terms of years and overqualification
     in terms of credentials. While these terms are used interchangeably in
     literature and not all questions in various surveys allow a clear distinction
     between the two, they are not equivalent. In fact, Brynin and Longhi (2009),
     using data from the e-Living project showed that, while a qualification higher
     than required mostly generates a wage premium, time spent in education
     does not. The latter may involve repeating a year of study and reflects
     variations in ability, motivation or institutional arrangements which differ
     between countries.
CHAPTER 1
                                                                                         Why be concerned about skill mismatch?               13




Table 1. Glossary of terms
         

Overeducation        A situation in which an individual has more education than the current job requires (measured in years).

Undereducation       A situation in which an individual has less education than the current job requires (measured in years).

Overqualification    A situation in which an individual has a higher qualification than the current job requires.

Underqualification   A situation in which an individual has a lower qualification than the current job requires.

Overskilling         A situation in which an individual is not able to fully utilise his or her skills and abilities in the current job.

Underskilling        A
                     	 situation in which an individual lacks the skills and abilities necessary to perform on the current job to
                     acceptable standards.

Credentialism        A situation in which the level of education required to obtain the job exceeds the level of education
                     required to perform the job adequately. It relies upon a belief of the employer that the possession of
                     certificates and diplomas implies higher productivity on the part of the individual.

Real                 A situation in which an individual possesses more education than the current job requires and also in
overeducation        which current skills and abilities are underutilised.

Formal               A situation in which an individual possesses more education than the current job requires, but in which
overeducation        current skills and abilities are fully utilised.

Genuine              A situation in which an individual has more education than the current job requires and this state has a
overeducation        negative effect on the level of job satisfaction.

Apparent             A situation in which an individual has more education than the current job requires, but this does not
overeducation        adversely affect the level of job satisfaction.

Skill shortage       A situation in which the demand for a particular type of skill exceeds the supply of available people with that skill.

Skill surplus        A situation in which the supply of available people with a particular skill exceeds the demand for it.

Skill gap            A situation in which the level of skills of the currently employed is less than that required to perform the
                     job adequately or the type of skill does not match the requirements of the job.

Economic skills      A situation in which skills previously utilised in a job are no longer required or have diminished in
obsolescence	        importance.

Physical             Physical or mental skills and abilities deteriorate due to atrophy or wear and tear.
(technical)
obsolescence
Vertical mismatch    A situation in which the level of education or skills is less or more than the required level of education or skills.

Horizontal           A situation in which the level of education or skills matches job requirements, but the type of education or
mismatch             skills is inappropriate for the current job.

Subjective meas-     The mismatch estimate is obtained by self assessment in employee responses to a questionnaire.
ures of mismatch
Objective            The mismatch estimate is obtained by evaluating job requirements.
measures of
mismatch
The empirical        T
                     	 he mismatch estimate is derived from differences in the actual education of an individual within an
mismatch method      occupation relative to the mean or modal level of education of all people employed in that occupation
                     (where there are no direct data on mismatch obtained from either of the above methods).
Crowding out/        When better qualified workers are hired to do jobs that less qualified workers could also do, they are crowding
bumping down         out the less qualified workers from what would be their traditional employment possibilities for that level of
                     skill. Bumping down refers to the fact that this process works from the top to the bottom and pushes the less
                     qualified workers to even lower level jobs. At the extreme some lower level workers may lose employment
                     altogether when crowding out occurs.
14    The skill matching challenge




     1.3. Aim         and format of this report
     Of all types of skill mismatch, the concept of overeducation has received
     most attention in literature. This concept was first introduced in 1976 by
     Richard Freeman in The overeducated American, an influential book based
     on US experience (Freeman, 1976). Since then literature on overeducation
     has grown substantially and points to the 30-40 % of the working population
     falling into this category and suffering from a substantial wage penalty
     compared to properly-matched workers. In most countries a smaller, though
     often substantial, number of workers are mismatched in the sense of being
     undereducated for their job. Interpretation of these phenomena is, however,
     far from straightforward. First, measurement issues arise from the diversity of
     information sources, such as the subjective responses to questions directed
     at employees, ‘objective’ estimates of the education requirements of jobs
     obtained by job analysis, or estimates derived by the empirical method
     from the spread of education qualifications within occupations. Second, the
     relationship between occupations and their education requirements may
     be imprecise. Thus, some jobs may merely specify a minimal education
     requirement, while education requirements may be rising over time as jobs
     become more complex.
        In recent years, a more limited strand of literature, encouraged by new
     data on the issue, has focused on both overskilling and underskilling (e.g.
     Allen and van der Velden, 2001; Green and McIntosh, 2007). This has raised
     questions about the relationship between overeducation and overskilling.
     There is also much older literature on skill shortages, i.e. insufficient numbers
     of suitably-qualified applicants to fill available posts, and the associated
     concept of skill gaps, i.e. when management judges that existing employees
     lack appropriate skills to maximise their contribution to output. Further, there
     is distinctive, but more limited, literature on the related question of skills
     obsolescence.
        Although there has been a lot of attention on different types of skill
     mismatch, little attempt has been made to synthesise and integrate these
     disparate strands in literature. By drawing together consistently the various
     strands of research literature on skill mismatch and by synthesising empirical
     evidence, this study provides new insights to promote comprehensive policies
     to prevent and address skill mismatch and its consequences.
CHAPTER 1
                                                 Why be concerned about skill mismatch?   15




   While conducting a literature survey, this study also reviews concepts,
theories and empirical evidence on skill mismatch. To analyse and evaluate
skill mismatch in a broad and comprehensive way, it focuses on the following
research questions:
	 (a) what do we know about skill mismatch in Europe?
	 (b) what causes skill mismatch?
	 (c) what are the links between the different types of skill mismatch?
	 (d) what impact do business cycles have on skill mismatch?
	 (e) what are the implications of skill mismatch?
	 (f) what is the most appropriate method of measuring skill mismatch?
	 (g)  hat types of data are needed to assess and analyse skill mismatch
       w
       in Europe?
   As some of these questions have been relatively neglected in literature,
any conclusions drawn must be tentative.
CHAPTER 2

  What do we know about skill
  mismatch in Europe?

This chapter examines the pervasiveness of skill mismatch in Europe.
Ideally, we would wish to know the extent of various types of mismatch and
trends over time but, as comprehensive data on skill mismatch is limited,
we focus instead on discussing the incidence of vertical and horizontal skill
mismatch and their impact on wages. Though incidence varies substantially
across countries, overeducation is found to be substantial across Europe
with significant negative effects on earnings. The incidence of overskilling
is lower, but higher for men than for women and increases with the level
of education. In several countries, where evidence is available, horizontal
mismatch is also substantial and impacts on earnings in a similar way. In
Section 2.3, we review evidence on the duration and persistence of mismatch.
The available information supports the hypothesis that much of it persists
over the medium to the long term and may differ by level of education.
Evidence on skills obsolescence suggests that many individuals, particularly
the more educated in high-tech industries, may require substantial lifelong
learning to remain productive.


2.1.   Vertical mismatch and impact on wages
One of the most recent surveys (McGuinness, 2006), summarised in Table 2,
in line with Groot and Maassen van den Brink’s (2000) meta analysis, found
that subjective measures of overeducation yield higher mean figures (29 %)
than objective measures (22 %). This suggests that employees do not have, as
some have argued, a clear tendency to exaggerate their own qualifications. The
lowest incidence is recorded in the Netherlands and the highest in the US. For
McGuinness (2006) it is reasonable to conclude that overeducation has remained
relatively stable over time, although it is not always the case. Green and Zhu
(2008) reported that in the UK overeducation increased for men from 21.7 % in
1992 to 33.2 % in 2006, while for women the comparable figures were 23.8 %
and 32.1 %. However, they also split the overeducated into two groups – ‘real’
and ‘formal’ according to whether or not it is accompanied by underutilisation
of skill. Real overqualification has been steady or rising only slowly.
CHAPTER 2
                                              What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe?   17




   Gottschalk and Hansen (2003) classified occupations in the US as graduate
and non-graduate on a different basis: whether 90 % or more of workers
in that occupation were graduates or, failing that, there was a significant
graduate pay premium of 10 % or more in that occupation. They found that
the probability of a graduate being employed in a non-graduate job actually
fell between 1983 and 1996, a result ‘which stands in stark contrast to those
in previous studies’ (Gottschalk and Hansen, p. 450). Similar findings have
been obtained by Cardoso (2007) for Portugal and by Grazier et al. (2008)
for the UK. It is clear, therefore, that conventional data on the incidence of
overeducation should be treated with caution.
   Ignoring the above distinctions about the precise nature of overeducation,
Sicherman (1991) suggested that there were two stylised facts in relation to
the effect of mismatch on pay. First, there is a pay penalty for overeducation,
but the overeducated earn more than their matched colleagues. Second,
the undereducated suffer a pay penalty relative to their matched colleagues
but earn more than if they were properly matched. Later studies tend to
confirm these results. Groot and Maassen van der Brink (2000) in their
meta analysis summarised 25 studies as producing unweighted average
rates of return of 5.6 % for attained years of education, 7.8 % for required
years of education, 3 % for years of overeducation and -1.5 % for years of
undereducation.
   There is, however, little or no information on how employers differentiate
the pay of their employees in this way. Is it, for instance, based on some
form of assessment of performance? There is evidence that wage benefits
of overeducation decline with additional labour-market experience. This
is consistent with ‘sheepskin effects’, whereby initial pay is determined by
certification, but eventually workers are sorted into their most appropriate jobs
on the basis of performance, so that qualifications become less significant
over time.
   Chevalier (2003) found a pay penalty of 26 % for genuinely overeducated
graduates, but only 7 % for those who were only apparently so. The wage
penalties for overeducation appear to be greater than for overskilling, but
this may reflect a failure to correct for unobserved differences between
individuals in most studies. Wage effects may also vary by level of education or
occupation. Mavromaras et al. (2009d) found that there were wage penalties
associated with overskilling in both Australia and the UK, but these were
larger for men than for women and increased with education level.
18    The skill matching challenge




     Table 2.  eported incidence of overeducation
              R

     Name of study         Year      Definition employed                    Country        Data collection Incidence of
                                                                                                           overeducation (%)

     Groot and Maassen     2000      Meta-analysis                                                         26.2 (a)
     van den Brink

     Galasi                2008      Subjective job requirements            25 Countries   2004-06         33.00

     Groot                 1996      Objective standard deviation-based     UK             1991            11.00
                                     measure
     Alpin                 1998      (1)  bjective occupational
                                         O                                                 1995            27.00
                                         dictionary-based measure
                                                                            UK
                                     (2)  bjective standard deviation
                                         O                                                 1995            37.70
                                         modal measure
     Sloane et al.         1999      Subjective – job requirements          UK             1986-87         30.63

     Green et al.          1999      (1) Subjective                         UK             1995            27.40
                                     (2) Subjective                         UK             1997            32.00

     Dolton and Vignoles   2000      Self assessment – subjective job       UK             1986            30.00
                                     requirement
                                     (1) Subjective – satisfaction          UK             1996            40.40 (a)
                                                                                           1996            40.70 (a)
     Battu et al.          2000      (2)  bjective occupational
                                         O                                  UK             1996            21.75 (a)
                                         dictionary-based measure                          1996            22.15 (a)

                                     (3) Subjective – degree requirements   UK             1996            33.65
                                                                                           1996            38.00 (a)
     Dolton and Siles      2003      Subjective – not clear which one       UK             1998            22.00
                                     they used

                                     (1)  bjective occupational
                                         O                                  UK             1996            17.00 (a)
                                         dictionary-based measure

     Chevalier             2003      (2) Subjective – job requirement       UK             1996            32.40 (a)

                                     (3) Subjective – satisfaction          UK             1996            16.20 (a)

     Green and Zhu         2008      Subjective job requirements            UK             1992            26.40
                                                                                           1997            26.50
                                                                                           2001            32.50
                                                                                           2006            37.30
     Grazier et al.        2008      Occupational classification            UK             1994            40.00
                                                                                           2004            30.00
     Hannan et al.         1998      Objective standard deviation           Ireland        1992            20.00

     McGuinness            2003a     Subjective – job requirements          Northern       2000            20.00
                                                                            Ireland
     McGuinness            2003b     Subjective – job requirements          Northern       1999            24.00
                                                                            Ireland
CHAPTER 2
                                                                 What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe?   19




Name of study        Year   Definition employed                  Country       Data collection Incidence of
                                                                                               overeducation (%)

Hartog and           1988   Subjective – required education      Netherlands   1982            16.00
Oosterbeek                  objective                                          1960            7.00
                                                                               1971            13.60
                                                                               1977            25.70
Groot                1993   Objective standard deviation-based   Netherlands   1983            16.10
                            measure
Groot and Maassen    2000   (1)  bjective standard deviation-
                                O                                Netherlands   1994            11.85 (a)
van den Brink                   based measure
                            (2)  bjective occupational
                                O                                Netherlands   1994            15.90 (a)
                                dictionary-based measure
                            (3) Subjective                       Netherlands   1994            11.15 (a)

Allen and van der    2001   Subjective – required education      Netherlands   1998            14.00
Velden
Dekker et al.        2002   Objective occupational dictionary-   Netherlands   1992            30.60
                            based measure
                            (1)  bjective standard deviation
                                O                                Portugal      1991            9.40
                                mean measure
                            (2)  bjective standard deviation
                                O                                Portugal      1991            25.50
Kiker et al.         1997       modal measure
                            (3)  bjective occupational
                                O                                Portugal      1991            33.10
                                dictionary-based measure

                                                                               1986            5.00
Cardoso              2007   Occupational classification          Portugal
                                                                               1999            1.00
Alba-Ramirez         1993   Subjective – job requirements        Spain         1985            17.00
Bauer                2002   Objective standard deviation-based   Germany       1984-98         11.50 (a)
                            measure
Büchel and van Ham   2002   Subjective – job requirements        Germany       1998            15.80 (a)
Patrinos             1997   Objective standard deviation-based   Greece        1977            16.00
                            measure
Duncan and Hoffman   1981   Subjective – job requirements        US            1976            42.00
Burris               1983   Objective occupational dictionary-   US            1977            21.70
                            based measure

                                                                               1969            35.00
Rumberger            1987   (1) Subjective – job requirements    US            1973            27.00
                                                                               1977            32.00
                            (2)  bjective occupational
                                O                                US            1973            57.00
                                dictionary-based measure

Verdugo and          1989   Objective standard deviation-based   US            1980            10.90 (b)
Verdugo                     measure
20    The skill matching challenge




     Name of study          Year     Definition employed                   Country        Data collection Incidence of
                                                                                                          overeducation (%)

     Sicherman              1991     Subjective – job requirements         US             1976 and 1978   40.80

                                     (1) Subjective – required education   US             1969            35.00
                                                                                          1973            27.00

     Tsang et al.           1991                                                          1977            32.00
                                     (2)  bjective occupational
                                         O                                 US             1973            57.00
                                         dictionary-based measure
                                     (1)  bjective standard deviation-
                                         O                                 US             1985            13.00
                                         based measure
     Cohn and Khan          1995     (2)  ubjective measure – Sicherman
                                         S                                 US             1985            33.00
                                         definition

     Robst                  1995     Subjective – required education       US             1976, 1978      44.68
                                                                                          and 1985

     Hersch                 1995     Subjective – job requirements         US             1991            21.00
                                     (1) Subjective – job requirements     US             1985            50.00 (a)

     McGoldrick             1996     (2)  bjective occupational
                                         O                                 US             1985            30.80 (a)
     and Robst                           dictionary-based measure
                                     (3)  bjective standard deviation-
                                         O                                 US             1985            12.55 (a)
                                         based measure

     Daly et al.            2000     Subjective – required education       US             1976            37.75 (a)
                                                                           US             1985            32.65 (a)
                                                                           Germany        1984            17.50 (a)
     Gottschalk and         2003     Occupational classification           US             1983            9.00
     Hansen
                                                                                          1996            5.00
     Vahey                  2000     Subjective – required education       Canada         1982            31.00 (a)
                                                                                          1986            35.00 (a)
     Cohn and Ng            2000     Objective modal measure               Hong Kong
                                                                                          1991            34.00 (a)

     (a) Average, (b) Males only                                                    Source: Adapted from McGuinness (2006).



        There are also differences between countries. Galasi (2008) used the
     European Social Survey to analyse the effects of education mismatch across
     25 countries. Overall, 33 % of workers were found to be overeducated, but this
     ranged from 15 % in the Netherlands to 79 % in Estonia; these data suggest
     a higher proportion of undereducated, with a mean of 59 %. Otherwise most
     of the empirical regularities found in earlier literature seem to hold.
CHAPTER 2
                                               What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe?   21




2.2.   Horizontal mismatch and impact on wages
We must also consider horizontal mismatch. Robst (2008) suggested the
following four hypotheses in relation to this type of mismatch:
hypothesis 1: the wage effects of overeducation are larger when workers
                 
                 are also mismatched the basis of type of degree and level of
                 occupational requirements;
hypothesis 2: among workers mismatched on the basis of level and type of
                 
                 education, the wage effect depends on the transferability of
                 skills between type of degree and occupation;
hypothesis 3: individuals who face discrimination (such as coloured people,
                 
                 the disabled and single women) or who have lower ability are
                 more likely to be mismatched due to demand-related reasons.
                 Supply-related mismatches are more likely among married
                 men and women than among single men and women;
hypothesis 4: the wage effects of mismatch are likely to be larger when
                 
                 workers have accepted a job due to demand-side reasons
                 (i.e. genuine mismatch) compared to supply-side reasons
                 (i.e. apparent mismatch).
    Robst finds that overeducated men, whose work and field of study are related,
earn 2.4 % less than well matched men. However, if the job is only somewhat
related the penalty rises to 7.1 % and to 21.6 % if it is completely unrelated. For
women the corresponding figures are 3.6 %, 5.3 % and 19.1 %. The income
penalty for horizontal mismatches appears to exceed that for vertical mismatches.
Further, while most workers report supply-side reasons as the main reason
for being in a particular job, it also appears that wage effects are large where
workers are mismatched for demand-side reasons. A Swedish study (Nordin et
al., 2008) found that being horizontally mismatched was associated with 38 %
lower income for men and 26 % for women. An Irish study (Kelly et al., 2008)
found, in contrast, a much smaller pay penalty of around 5 % for those who
were mismatched by field, though this varied by field of study. In this case the
vertical mismatch penalty (14.4 %) exceeded the horizontal.
22    The skill matching challenge




     2.3. What
              is the likely duration of skill
           mismatches?
     The extent to which a particular form of mismatch persists over time
     determines the costs to the individual, firm or economy. While evidence on
     persistence of overeducation is rich, it is limited to insights based on cross-
     sectional data. Meaningful tests for mismatch persistence require longitudinal
     data on individuals and jobs over a longer period of time. Evidence on the
     persistence of other forms of mismatch is scarce, but some conclusions
     can be drawn.


     2.3.1. Individual overeducation and overskilling
     There has been considerable debate on whether individual overeducation
     will persist over time. Sicherman (1991) found a positive and significant
     relationship between job mobility and overeducation which was taken as
     evidence of non-persistence. However, later research produced more mixed
     results.
        Some studies have reported evidence of higher rates of job mobility (e.g.,
     Alba-Ramirez, 1993; Sloane et al. 1999; Alba-Ramirez and Blázquez, 2003),
     higher rates of promotion within firms (Hersch, 1995; Dekker et al. 2002;
     Alba-Ramirez and Blázquez 2003; Groeneveld and Hartog, 2004), or greater
     levels of quit intention (Hersch, 1995; Robst, 1995) among the overeducated.
     Sloane et al. (1999) also reported that, while overeducated workers were
     more likely to have short job tenure with their current employer, they were
     also more likely to experience involuntary job separations and to exit from
     employment into unemployment. Further, for McGuinness and Wooden (2007)
     increased job mobility cannot be taken as evidence of falling overeducation
     given that workers are most likely to move from one overeducated job to
     another. The most convincing evidence to support the view that overeducation
     can be a long lasting phenomenon comes from studies of graduate labour
     markets, but these studies are typically based on cross-sectional data or short
     time-series. Dolton and Vignoles (2000) found that 38 % of a large sample
     of UK graduates in 1980 was overeducated in their first job; six years later
     this proportion still stood at 30 %. Similarly, McGuinness (2003c) reported
     that among a sample of graduates in Northern Ireland, 31 % indicated that
     a university degree was not a requirement for their first job, and after two to
     four years this proportion was still at 24 %. Finally, Frenette (2004) reported
     on longitudinal data for Canadian graduates, which showed little evidence
CHAPTER 2
                                                    What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe?   23




of any decline in the incidence of overeducation over a three-year window
(between two and five years after graduation).
   Research on overskilling persistence is much more limited as panel data
on overskilling in Europe are lacking. McGuinness and Wooden (2007)
examined durations using the first four waves of the household income
and labour dynamics for Australia (HILDA) panel. The study concludes that
overskilling tends to be a non-transitory phenomenon with less than 25 %
of employees who were severely overskilled in wave 1 likely to be matched
three years later. The study also found that, as for overeducation, increased
job mobility cannot be evidence of reduced overskilling. Mavromaras et al.
(2009b) using HILDA found that overskilling varies by education level: it is
rare among university graduates, but highly persistent; it is low but significant
among school leavers from general education; and none at all is found
among vocational education and training graduates.
   Graduate studies focusing on overeducation and overskilling are typically
based on short time-series. This hampers the ability to examine whether
overeducation in the early stages of a career are reversible later on, when
people acquire more training or experience. Also, these studies only provide
a partial picture of mismatch persistence, as they focus on the transition
from school to work. Far less attention is on transition from unemployment
to work, mainly because suitable data is lacking, but also due to insufficient
analysis of the incentives and preferences, decisive factors in people’s
education and occupation choices. Many research questions remain open,
but we can tentatively conclude that overeducation and overskilling are
non-transitory phenomena.


2.3.2. Overeducation and overskilling at firm level
Although overeducation and overskilling can be a long lasting phenomenon for
individuals, it does not mean firms retain overeducated or overskilled workers
for long periods. High rates of voluntary and involuntary separations among
the overeducated and overskilled (2) suggest that their average job tenure
is likely to be some fraction of their total mismatch duration. However, the
fact that the overeducated earn a premium relative to matched colleagues,
coupled with the finding that the probability of involuntary separation tends
to be much lower than the probability of voluntary separation (3), suggests
that employers hiring overeducated and overskilled workers have some

(2) Sloane et al., 1999; McGuinness, 2003; McGuinness and Wooden, 2007.
(3) McGuinness and Wooden, 2007.
24    The skill matching challenge




     productivity advantage. This is confirmed by Jones et al. (2009) using
     British workplace employment relations survey (WERS) data to demonstrate
     higher productivity in firms employing overeducated workers. However,
     the consistent finding that the overeducated and overskilled have lower
     job satisfaction (4) also indicates that retaining such workers may not be
     in the firm’s long-term interest. Therefore, the extent to which firms retain
     overskilled or overeducated workers will depend on the magnitude of any
     short-term benefit relative to the long-term cost. From an economy point of
     view, demand for skills and educated labour rising over time should reduce
     the incidence of overskilling and overeducation, provided that the surplus
     are in areas of demand within the economy and that workers are mobile.

     2.3.3. Undereducation and underskilling in individuals/firms
     Generally, the undereducated have no incentive to become matched, as
     they earn a premium relative to matched colleagues with similar education
     levels (5). Little research exists to date for the underskilled, so for now we
     will assume that their situation reflects that of the undereducated.
        Accepting that earnings reflect workers’ marginal products, the finding
     that the undereducated are paid less than matched individuals in the same
     job who are matched (6) suggests that firms employing undereducated
     workers may have some productivity penalty. The extent to which a firm will
     continue to hire undereducated workers will vary according to the underlying
     causes of the undereducation itself. If undereducation relates to an inability
     to hire suitably qualified workers, i.e. a skill shortage, then the duration of
     undereducation within the firm will be highly correlated with the persistence
     of the skill shortage within the economy generally.

     2.3.4. Skill shortages
     Duration of skill shortages depends on the level at which the problem is
     assessed. For firms, the shortage will persist as long as the vacancy remains
     unfilled or until the firm adopts an alternative strategy for dealing with the
     problem. Duration will be longer the more complex and skilled the unfilled
     vacancy so duration should vary across occupations and sectors. For the
     economy more generally, duration of skill shortages will depend on the time
     elapsing before it is communicated through the market mechanism and the
     period required to induce and train individuals in the specific skill area.

     (4) Battu et al., 1999; Fleming and Kler, 2007.
     (5) Kiker et al., 1997; Sloane et al., 1999.
     (6) Kiker et al., 1997.
CHAPTER 2
                                              What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe?   25




2.3.5. Skill gaps
Given that skill gaps relate to the firms’ current employees and that they are
specific to the firm’s requirements, dealing with skill gaps largely remains the
responsibility of firms. Generally, skill gaps can only be eradicated through
firm-sponsored training or by providing individuals with relevant incentives
to participate in upskilling. Duration depends on the period necessary to
retrain individuals in the relevant skill areas, as for skill shortages, and on
costs involved. Given the difficulties and costs associated with equipping
workers with basic and advanced skills, durations are likely to be shorter for
skill gaps related to intermediate skills. However, when skill gaps arise as a
result of firms adopting a second best strategy in the face of skill shortage,
duration will again be related to the duration of skill shortage.

2.3.6.  Skills obsolescence
Here we are interested in how long on average it takes for a worker’s skill
to become obsolete. In an early study, Bosworth (1978) noted that little was
known about the obsolescence of technical knowledge. However, using a
restrictive definition – the time when a particular technology was no longer
embodied in goods currently being sold – he was able to use patent renewal
data to measure obsolescence. Evidence pointed to annual rates of decay
of well over 10 % in the post-war period. Neuman and Weiss (1995) showed
that obsolescence was more evident in high-tech than low-tech industries
and greater for more educated workers. Allen and van der Velden (2007),
using a Dutch survey, reported that 30 % of skills in their sample had become
obsolete with a half-life for competences in the range of 10 to 15 years.
This implies that many individuals would have to renew their competences
regularly over their career, giving justification for lifelong learning.
    In the 1970s several studies examined the rate of obsolescence among
engineers. Notably, Kaufman (1974; 1975) pointed out that the introduction
of computer technology was critical and ironically threatened most those
introducing it: engineers, computer scientists and other technical professionals.
He defined obsolescence as ‘the degree to which organisational professionals
lack the up-to-date knowledge of skills necessary to maintain effective
performance in either their current or future work roles’ (Kaufman, 1974
p. 23). He developed an open systems approach (Kaufman, 1989) to
analyse obsolescence, based on extensive questionnaires sent to technical
professionals in a single organisation. The approach considered four elements:
environmental change (e.g. rapid changes in technology); organisational
climate (determined largely by managerial policies and practices); the nature
26    The skill matching challenge




     of work (in terms of job assignments); and individual characteristics such as
     the cognitive and personality factors related to keeping up-to-date. The last of
     these is important in determining how individuals cope with rapid technological
     change (Trimmer et al., 1998; Pazy, 1998; 2006). The US National Academy
     of Sciences concluded in 1985 that engineers could work productively
     over a longer period if they had access to effective continuing education
     regardless of the state of the business cycle. This required interdisciplinary
     approaches and non-technical skills that are not imparted by the formal
     training of engineers.
CHAPTER 3

  What causes skill mismatch?

This chapter analyses the causes of different types of skill mismatch. Based
on evidence, we discuss the causes of overeducation, skill shortages and
skills obsolescence, and reflect on the role of individual characteristics.
Overeducation can result from the asymmetric nature of the supply of
labour-market information. However, literature has devoted little attention to
explaining overeducation by considering the decision processes of firms and
individuals. A key issue is whether perceived mismatches represent labour
market sorting on the basis of the lower ability of the individuals concerned; it
is perhaps necessary to disaggregate overeducation according to the level of
job satisfaction or use of skills of overeducated workers. Insufficient training,
markets reacting slowly to changes, skill-biased technological progress and
business cycles are core factors explaining skill shortages. When skills
depreciate due to ageing or when economic developments change the skills
that firms need, this process is referred to as skills obsolescence. Young
people entering the labour market, older workers, females, ethnic minorities
and the disabled are disproportionately affected by skill mismatch.


3.1. Causes       of overeducation
Education type and level may influence the likelihood of mismatch on entering
employment. As Stigler (1961) observed, the higher the level of education
the better defined the set of jobs a worker can obtain and the better the
information individuals have about the nature of the labour market. Further,
individuals in narrower fields of study (such as law or medicine) are likely
to have a better defined set of job alternatives than those in more broadly
defined ones (such as arts and humanities). Thus, Kucel and Byrne (2008)
suggested that those from broader educational backgrounds are likely to
be less well informed about labour-market opportunities. Using the 2003-05
British labour force survey, which contains information on type of degree
and the nature of the job finding process, they found that graduates in hard
disciplines are significantly less likely to apply for a job through a private
employment agency, by relying on an advertisement or by a method other
28    The skill matching challenge




     than through personal contacts relative to those from broader educational
     backgrounds. Thus, overeducation can result from the asymmetric nature
     of the supply of labour-market information.
        Büchel (in Cedefop; Büchel, 2001) advocated regarding overqualification as
     a result of a decision-making process by both employers and employees. For
     employees, the choice between unemployment and work, or different types
     of jobs, precedes overeducation. Employer decisions may involve dealing
     with problems in recruiting workers with the right skills. Very few studies have
     focused on the decision-making processes of both firms and individuals to
     explain the occurrence and persistence of overeducation. Research on the
     role of employers in hiring mismatched workers is also rare, although this is
     a possible strategy for fluctuating demand for skilled employees and rising
     demand for skilled manpower. Sloane et al. (1996) also pointed out that
     undereducated workers compensated for lack of qualifications by having
     more experience, tenure and training (the substitutability hypothesis), so one
     cannot necessarily infer that mismatch is wasteful. In their matching model
     for UK graduates, Battu et al. (1999) included variables capturing the nature
     of the job (e.g. occupations, sector of work and size of firm). Unsurprisingly,
     higher occupations increase the likelihood of matching, with individuals in the
     education sector and private practice more likely to be matched and size of
     firm being positively and strongly related to the probability of a match.
        A key issue is to what extent perceived mismatches represent labour-
     market sorting on the basis of varying quality of labour within education
     levels. This is particularly so as the number of graduates has increased
     substantially in many countries. If less able individuals have entered the
     pool of graduates, quality may have fallen over time which may increase
     the incidence of overeducation. For example, Battu et al. (1999) controlled
     for the degree class and institution type in the UK, finding that the class of
     degree has a significant effect on graduate earnings, with a first class degree
     having a 8-13 % premium over a lower-second class one, and graduates
     from more established universities earning 8-11 % more than graduates from
     former polytechnics, holding constant a measure of overeducation. Dolton
     and Vignoles (2000) and Green and Zhu (2008) also found that those with
     better degree classifications and those from more established universities
     are less likely to be overeducated.
        There may also be cohort effects if individuals qualify for entry into
     the labour market in periods when there is an excess supply of qualified
     applicants. This will happen because it takes some time for workers to accept
     a lower-skilled job and then continue searching for a more complex one
CHAPTER 3
                                                                            What causes skill mismatch?   29




which pays more (Gautier, 2000). This may be reinforced when the individual
faces short-term constraints on the search process through personal, family,
location or other reasons. As Dolton and Silles (2003) also suggested, the
process of finding a suitable job may take some time, so we would expect
in this case, and in contrast to what was stated earlier, that overeducation
is a temporary phenomenon. Most studies of skill mismatch, however,
focus on the state of mismatch rather than on the process of becoming
mismatched; available data does not allow for analyses that follow the same
individuals in their employment careers, which makes a valid assessment
of persistence difficult.
   Most data sets do not contain the data necessary to correct for individual
heterogeneity. One exception is the British national child development study.
Using this data set, Green et al. (1999) found that individuals who scored
higher on a maths test administered at age 16 were significantly less likely to
be overeducated later in their working lives, and this effect was substantial.
Their analysis of the International adult literacy survey (IALS) also suggested
that individuals who lacked good quantitative skills were more likely to be
overeducated. Büchel and Pollmann-Schult (2001) found that in Germany
a poor grade in the school leaving certificate had a strong effect on the
later risk of overeducation for graduates with a vocational degree and after
controlling for selectivity effects.
Box 1. Theoretical approaches to overeducation
       

  There is no generally-accepted theory of overeducation (McGuinness, 2006), but it is possible
  to consider how the phenomenon relates to various models of the labour market as illustrated
  in the table below. The standard Becker/Mincer human capital model suggests in its simplest
  form that wages are determined by endowments of human capital and particularly years of
  education and experience. There is no role for demand side factors, where more years of
  education imply higher earnings, and no distinction is made between actual and required
  years of education. Thus, any year of education is just as valuable as another. In contrast, in the
  Thurow job competition model, marginal productivity resides in the job rather than the worker,
  and in the extreme, education simply serves to place the individual at the front of the queue
  for jobs, as it signals that the employer will be required to invest less in training. Hence, the
  return on overeducation is zero, as all workers in a given job are paid the same. In contrast,
  the Sattinger job assignment model (Sattinger, 1993) considers both supply and demand to be
  important determinants of wages, as there is an allocation problem in assigning heterogeneous
  workers to heterogeneous jobs. At any time it is unlikely that there will be a perfect match and
  overeducation can be a persistent problem. Earnings will be a function of both worker and job
  characteristics and this model can encompass the human capital and job competition models
  in a more general equation which is sometimes referred to as the Duncan and Hoffman model
  (1981) or in other cases as the ORU model.
30   The skill matching challenge




      log Wt= β0 + β1qr+ β2qs β3qu+ε
      In this model, actual educational qualifications (q) of individuals are decomposed into the
      required or normally accepted level (qr), surplus or more than required qs), and deficit or less
      than required (qu), qualifications in relation to those necessary to do the job. The human capital
      specification implies that β1=β2=β3 and the job competition model that β2=β3=0. Tests of
      these models, using an F test on the residual sum of squares, tend to suggest that generally
      the job assignment model outperforms the other two. The theory of career mobility associated
      with Sicherman and Galor (1990) suggests that individuals may be prepared to accept jobs
      with low returns on education provided that this is accompanied by a higher probability of
      promotion. In this context overeducation is a purely temporary phenomenon and additional
      returns on education will be obtained later. Finally, Frank’s theory of differential overqualification
      (1978) is based on the proposition that, for married couples, the search for a pair of jobs will be
      constrained geographically and only infrequently will the best job offer for both spouses occur in
      the same location. If the husband’s job choice dominates because of the wife’s responsibilities
      for children, married women will face the greater constraints, whether as tied stayers or tied
      movers and we expect married women to experience greater overeducation than either married
      men or single men or women.

      Theory             Main proponent(s)      Main determinants of wage      Predictions of
                                                                               overeducation (overskiling)
      Human              Becker (1964),         Supply (personal               Return on years of
      capital            Mincer (1974)          characteristics)               overeducation = return
      model                                                                    on years of required
                                                                               education
      Job                Thurow (1975)          Demand (job queues)            Return on overeducation
      competition                                                              is zero
      model
      Assignment         Sattinger (1993)       Supply and demand              Return on years of
      model                                                                    overeducation  return
                                                                               on required education
      Career             Sicherman and Galor Training costs are general        • n the short-run
                                                                                 i
      mobility           (1990)              and paid for by the                 return on years of
      theory                                 individual                          overeducation  return
                                                                                 on required education
                                                                               • n the long-run
                                                                                 i
                                                                                 return on years of
                                                                                 overeducation  return
                                                                                 on years of required
                                                                                 education
      Theory of          Frank (1978)           Gender and family status       Return on years of
      differential                                                             overeducation  return
      overqualifi-                                                             on required education
      cation
CHAPTER 3
                                                                 What causes skill mismatch?   31




   Where data sets lack the appropriate variables, indirect methods are
necessary. Thus, Chevalier (2003) distinguished between apparently and
genuinely overeducated graduates in the UK based on their answers to
questions on job satisfaction. Graduates in graduate jobs are defined as
‘matched’, whatever their level of satisfaction. Those satisfied but in non-
appropriate (or non-traditional graduate) jobs are described as ‘apparently
overeducated’ and those in non-graduate jobs and dissatisfied as ‘genuinely
overeducated’. A similar approach was adopted by Allen and van der Velden
(2001), who used a 1991 Dutch data set which allowed job levels to vary
for given education qualifications. They distinguished between a formal
education mismatch and a skill mismatch based on two key questions:
whether the current job offered sufficient scope to use acquired knowledge
and skills (utilisation); and whether they would perform better in their current
job if additional knowledge and skills had been acquired (skill deficit). While
about 15 % of their sample experienced underutilisation, a much higher
proportion experienced skills deficits and the latter was only weakly related
to education mismatches.
   These results cast doubt on one of the key assumptions of assignment
theory, namely that education mismatches imply skill mismatches. One
interpretation is that overeducation in part masks unmeasured ability
differences and is, therefore, spurious. Taking these results together, it
seems clear that a substantial part of what is described in literature as
overeducation merely reflects the heterogeneity of individual abilities and
of skills within particular education categories. Far from implying inefficient
allocation of labour, this suggests that the labour market is functioning
effectively in allocating workers to jobs which match their skills and abilities
(Sloane, 2003).
   Brunello et al. (2007) argued that employment protection legislation might
increase the extent of skill mismatch by making it harder for individuals
to obtain their first job and more difficult for firms to reduce staff because
of restrictions on firing. Using the European Community household panel
1994-2001 they found a positive association between skill mismatch and
employment protection legislation. Their regression analysis for the five
largest countries suggests that men are more likely to be mismatched than
women (7), that overqualification increases with years of education (apart from
Germany), and declines with increased labour experience, which, in contrast
to evidence cited earlier, suggests that overqualification is a temporary


(7)  his is in contrast to other findings reported elsewhere.
    T
32    The skill matching challenge




     phenomenon. There are also important differences between countries, with
     the suggestion that for Germany and the UK some workers may choose to
     become overqualified to avoid unemployment. Adopting a fourfold classification
     of mismatch in terms of combinations of overeducation, overskilling and
     matching, it appears that skill mismatch rather than overqualification causes
     pay penalties.


     3.2.	 Underlying                causes of skill shortages
     Skill shortages can be caused by underinvestment in training. The idea of
     market underprovision of skills can be traced back to Pigou in 1912 (cited
     by Haskel and Holt, 1999) who argued that the additional transferable skills
     associated with training will raise the probability that a worker will be poached,
     thus reducing the likelihood that training will take place. Individuals may
     underinvest due to perceived high training costs, coupled with uncertain
     returns (Booth and Snower, 1996). Information gaps or inadequately structured
     education provision may also lead to incorrect investments on the part of
     students, while insufficient labour-market mobility can also lead to imbalances
     (Neugart and Schomann, 2002).
         Institutional factors may also prevent the labour market from clearing; for
     instance, centralised wage bargaining systems may be unable to consider
     sectoral or regionally-based changes in demand. A sluggish supply-side
     may also contribute to the problem. For instance, Haskel and Martin (2001)
     argued that skill shortages in the UK have arisen primarily as a consequence
     of education supply failing to keep pace with skill-biased technical progress.
     Finally, the incidence of skill shortages will vary according to the economy’s
     position in the business cycle. Specifically, skill shortages tend to have a
     strong negative correlation with the claimant count (Frogner, 2002). Hogarth
     and Wilson (2001) go so far as to suggest that skill shortages are actually a
     significant driver of the business cycle itself, placing a productivity constraint on
     the economy which in turn leads to a downturn in activity. Further, the factors
     listed above may also act as drivers for undereducation and underskilling.


     3.3.	 Causes               of skills obsolescence
     Skills obsolescence, which may lead to skill gaps, is a process rather than a
     state. De Grip and van Loo (2007) distinguished between physical (technical)
     and economic skills obsolescence as outlined in Table 3. Technical skills
CHAPTER 3
                                                                                What causes skill mismatch?   33




obsolescence results from depreciation of manual skills or physical strength
through ageing, while economic obsolescence occurs as a result of changes
in production technology which alter the optimal input mix for firms. If there
are new skill requirements as a result of changes in production, this may
have a major impact on job specific skills. If employment declines across
an industry or occupation, this is referred to as sectoral skills obsolescence.
If firm reorganisation or closures occur more job losses may result in firm
specific skills obsolescence. Physical (technical) obsolescence and job loss
combined may result in organisational knowledge loss. Thijssen (2005) has
identified a third type of skills obsolescence: perspectivistic obsolescence.
This refers to outdated views and beliefs on work and the work environment.
Skills obsolescence can manifest itself through unemployment, crowding out
to lower-skilled jobs, lower wages or through problems in performing the job
properly. As workers become more educated and skill biased technological
change remains important, while at the same time the workforce is ageing,
skills obsolescence is likely to become even more significant.

Table 3. Types and causes of skills obsolescence
         

Types                                Forms of human capital depreciation

Physical (technical) obsolescence
Wear and tear                        •  eterioration of mental and physical capacities through
                                       d
                                       ageing, illness or injury
                                     • decreasing capacity to learn and adapt to new situations
Atrophy                              Insufficient use of skills as a result of overeducation, increased
                                     specialisation or unemployment
Economic skills obsolescence
Job specific skills                  New skill requirements due to changes in production
obsolescence
Sectoral skills obsolescence         Employment declines either by industry or occupation
Firm-specific skills                 Voluntary or involuntary quits resulting from firm reorganisation
obsolescence                         or closure
Organisational knowledge loss
                                     Combining wear and tear of skills of individual workers or
                                     quitting by workers with firm specific skills
Perspectivistic obsolescence
                                     Outdated views or beliefs concerning the nature of work and
                                     the work environment
Source: Adapted from de Grip et al., 2007.
34    The skill matching challenge




        Weinberg (2007) showed that skills obsolescence arises in two ways.
     First, the diffusion of new technology may increase the obsolescence of
     existing skills. Second, experienced workers who have accumulated greater
     stocks of skills relevant to the old technology lose more human capital when
     switching to new tasks. Contrary to expectations, skills obsolescence occurs
     not only in strongly field-specific and technical fields of study, but also in
     more generic and non-technical fields (Allen and van der Velden, 2007).
     The traditional vintage human capital model emphasises the imperfect
     transferability of human capital across technologies, implying that younger
     workers will be the primary adopters of new technology. New technologies
     may also complement existing skills and there is some evidence that this
     applies in particular to more educated men with substantial (30-40 years)
     experience.


     3.4.	 Mismatch                  and individual characteristics
     Are there particular personal characteristics which make certain individuals
     more prone to mismatch than others? Particular groups may be more subject
     to discrimination in the labour market – young workers, older workers,
     females, ethnic minorities and the disabled – and this feature may also
     manifest itself in labour-market mismatch.
        Young workers are likely to be particularly prone to skill mismatch as new
     entrants into the labour market, and the finding that overeducation is linked
     to a lack of work experience supports this hypothesis. One Dutch study by
     Dekker et al. (2002), for example, found that the proportion of overeducated
     decreased from 41.7 % for the 15-19 age group, to 27 % for the 30-44 age
     group and 18 % for the 49-64 age group. Many other studies report similar
     results. Older workers may suffer from mismatch as a consequence of skills
     obsolescence, which is more likely in industries subject to rapid technological
     change or in decline through shifting patterns of demand.
        In an early US study, Frank (1978) examined the link between gender and
     overqualification. He suggested that, in a dual earner household, there would
     be greater constraints on married women than married men on account of
     child-rearing causing intermittent labour-force participation on the part of
     the wife. Married women would tend to be tied stayers or tied movers, thus
     limiting their ability to obtain optimal matches in the labour market. However,
CHAPTER 3
                                                            What causes skill mismatch?   35




McGoldrick and Robst (1996), who attempted to test whether married women
in small local labour markets were more prone to overqualification than those
in larger labour markets, could find no evidence to support this proposition.
Büchel and Battu (2003) extended this analysis using German data by
making allowance for commuting distances between home and work and
found that longer commuting distances tended to reduce the likelihood of
overqualification, though not differentially between men and women.
    An alternative reason why one might expect gender differences in mismatch
is the presence of fixed costs of employment together with higher quit rates
for women than men. This may lead employers to require higher ability from
women relative to men when hiring for particular jobs. Thus, van Ours and
Ridder (1995) found that women in their Dutch data set required almost
six months more work experience than men to be hired for the same job,
implying that they were overqualified in this sense. Yet, overall there is
mixed evidence of skill mismatch being a more serious problem for women
than for men across countries, with counter examples. Why there are such
differences between countries seems to be an important issue for further
research.
    Studies of skill mismatch across ethnic minorities are limited in number.
Battu and Sloane (2004) used the Fourth national survey of ethnic minorities
1993/94 to investigate whether overeducation was greater for ethnic minorities
in Britain than for the white majority using a modal measure of required
education across 60 occupations. They found that overeducation was higher
for non-whites than for whites, while undereducation was lower for non-
whites, but within the non-white population the African Asian group was
more likely to be overeducated than Indians. The consequences of labour-
market mismatch in terms of the wage penalty were more severe than for
the indigenous white population. Lindley (2009) examined the extent of
overeducation among UK immigrants using labour force survey data for
1993-2003, again estimating over- and undereducation in terms of deviations
from the mode. The results were largely consistent with those of Battu and
Sloane (2004), though in this case Indian immigrants were more likely to
be overeducated compared to indigenous whites.
    Studies of labour-market mismatch among the disabled are notable by their
absence, and often a disabled dummy is not even included in the estimating
equation. Where it is, there is sometimes a significant effect on the probability
of overeducation. This is clearly an area for future research.
CHAPTER 4

  What are the links between
  the different types of skill
  mismatch?

This chapter analyses to what extent, how and why different types of skill
mismatch occur simultaneously. First, we look at skill shortages, skill gaps,
undereducation and underskilling. We then examine whether overeducation,
overskilling and skill shortages can occur simultaneously. In the third part of
the chapter we focus on the duration of particular combinations of mismatch.
There does not appear to be a strong correlation between the occurrence
of skill shortages and skill gaps, but the latter may be closely linked to
underskilling. Both overeducation and overskilling may be a consequence
of excess labour supply, which can be illustrated by the Beveridge curve.
Skills obsolescence is different from the above as it is a process rather than
a state. Levels of skill are important as it is open to a skilled worker to obtain
an unskilled job, while it is not normally open to an unskilled worker to obtain
a skilled job. This is reflected in the concept of skill bumping (or crowding
out). Various types of mismatch can be present at the same time in individual
firms but not often in the same occupations. Ideally we require matched
employer-employee data sets to cast light on all these phenomena.


4.1. Skill
        shortages, skill gaps, undereducation
     and underskilling
Skills related problems can arise because of skill shortages or skill gaps.
   Skill shortages refer to a skills related labour-market shortage, i.e.
where there are not enough individuals with the required skills within the
economy to fill existing vacancies. This is the most simplistic definition to
skill shortages. However, measurement issues are clearly important (e.g.
Green et al., 1998) and some recent attempts have been made to move
towards a more refined system of definition that incorporates training lead
times. For example, Richardson (2006) proposed the following system for
defining skill shortages:
	 (a) evel 1 shortage: there is a shortage of individuals with the relevant
       l
       technical skills who are not already using them and it takes a long
       training time to develop these skills;
CHAPTER 4
                                     What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch?   37




	 (b) evel 2 shortage: there are few people who have sufficient skills and are not
       l
       already using them, but such skills can be developed relatively quickly.
   Skill gaps occur when skill levels in the workforce are below those desired
by employers or when job requirements do not match precisely the content
of the knowledge and abilities of individuals.
   The 2001 UK employer skills survey (UKESS) concluded that skill
shortages were more commonly associated with skilled occupations with
more substantial education and training requirements. In terms of skill
gaps, the UKESS study found that these were more strongly related to poor
human resource management practices such as lack of staff training and
poor labour retention. Therefore, it is not at all evident that skills gaps and
skill shortages are necessarily strongly correlated.
   Each of these concepts points to the difficulties employers are faced with
in attracting sufficient labour of the right quality. Skill shortages are not easy
to measure, but indicate that the demand for labour exceeds the (available)
supply at the given market wage. However, if employers are not willing to pay
the market wage to attract additional labour, this should not be considered
a labour shortage. In a classic paper Arrow and Capron (1959) focused
on the possibility that lags in decision-making could result in a dynamic
shortage. Such lags may occur through the time taken to recognise that
there is a need to raise salaries, in obtaining approval for the increase and
in putting the new pay policy into action. The reaction speed of an employer
will be influenced by institutional arrangements such as the presence of
long-term labour contracts and partly by the speed with which information
about salaries, vacancies and the availability of workers becomes generally
available throughout the market.
   Wage adjustments are, however, only one possible means of adjustment
and non-wage adjustments appear to be more common in the short-term.
Common examples are reducing output, adjusting inventories, increasing
overtime, using more vigorous recruitment methods or reducing hiring
standards. It is in the last of these circumstances that skill gaps may arise
in the sense that employees hired under such circumstances are less likely
to possess the skills necessary to complete tasks with maximum efficiency.
Skill gaps seem to equate with underskilling and it is difficult to differentiate
between the two, apart from the fact that skill gaps may reflect the views of
the employer and underskilling the views of the employee. In both cases
the remedy seems to lie with the provision of additional training.
   In one study of Northern Ireland, Bennett and McGuinness (2009) found
that 58 % of employers in the IT and engineering sectors adjusted to the
38    The skill matching challenge




     problem of skill shortages by training and upskilling their existing staff,
     and 47 % chose to recruit staff from other backgrounds and train them up.
     Under such circumstances workers may find themselves undereducated
     in relation to existing workers in the occupation to which they have been
     upgraded. Though individuals in this category may lack formal qualifications,
     they may have previous experience of the type of work, so that they will not
     necessarily be underskilled.
        All the above scenarios imply that demand exceeds supply. Where supply
     exceeds demand, a reverse scenario will apply. If there has been a rapid
     increase in the numbers graduating with certain qualifications skill surpluses
     may arise, resulting in the downgrading of some individuals who find it more
     difficult to obtain a job matching their qualifications. This crowding out may
     result in skill bumping in which workers with lower qualifications are also
     subject to downgrading or lose their jobs altogether. Both overeducation and
     overskilling may result in these circumstances. If overeducation is caused
     by too many qualified workers chasing too few jobs we would expect a high
     rate of unemployment among those workers with lower qualifications who
     have to compete with more educated workers, as well as a low vacancy rate.
     Overeducation can also result from institutional regulations, if unemployed
     persons are required by employment officers to accept lower-skilled jobs than
     those for which they are qualified to avoid losing unemployment benefits,
     as occurs under workfare policies.
        Underskilling may arise as a result of skills obsolescence, which occurs
     when skills become less valuable in the production process. This particularly
     applies to older workers. While they may be retrained in new production
     techniques, such as computer technology, this may be uneconomic because
     of the shorter pay-back period compared to that of younger workers. A
     further problem is that a mismatch between the level of education and/or
     skills and the job lack of use of capabilities may lead to a decline in workers
     cognitive abilities (the ‘use it or lose it’ phenomenon as described by de
     Grip et al., 2008).
        Suitable employee-employer linked data are undoubtedly required (see
     Chapter 8) if we are to understand fully and quantify the relationships
     that exist between skill mismatches for the firm and skill mismatches for
     individuals. However, in the absence of such data, it is possible to develop
     some reasonable and ultimately testable hypotheses based on existing
     knowledge. First, evidence suggests that little overlap between skill shortages
     and skill gaps exists. For instance, data from the 2001 UK employer skills
     survey revealed that less than 1 % of establishments experienced both skill
CHAPTER 4
                                              What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch?   39




shortages and skill gaps. Such a weak occurrence supports the view that firms
experiencing skill gaps have little difficulty in recruiting staff, suggesting that
skill gaps tend to be more heavily associated with skill deficiencies, while skill
shortages are more commonly associated with higher level functions (8).



Box 2. The Beveridge curve
       

  Both cases of supply exceeding demand and demand exceeding supply can be portrayed on the
  Beveridge curve (see below) which relates unemployment to unfilled vacancies. This assumes
  that there is labour-market equilibrium when the number of unemployed (U) equals the number of
  unfilled vacancies (V). When U does not equal V there is an imbalance at the level of the economy,
  region, industry, occupation or individual firm. However, this pays no attention to the quality of
  employed labour relative to the quality of filled jobs. Those in employment may be under- or
  overutilised as reflected in levels of education qualifications, skills or abilities.
      Vacancies




                                               B


                                                                                UV2
                                    A




                                                                                UV1


                  0
                                    Unemployment




(8)  askel and Martin (2001) showed that skill shortages are greater in the high-tech sectors of the
    H
    economy.
40    The skill matching challenge




            Both A and B represent points of equilibrium but, in the latter case, vacancies equal
       unemployment with a higher level of both vacancies and unemployment, representing increased
       structural unemployment. In this sense there is a greater degree of mismatch either because
       labour is immobile or it is equipped with insufficient or the wrong sort of skills.
            When an economy is subjected to shocks, such as rapid technological change, skill mismatch
       will occur if workers cannot readily learn new skills or are unwilling to accept jobs that do not
       utilise their existing skills, and employers are unable or unwilling to redesign jobs so that they
       can be performed by people with a different set of qualifications from those originally intended.
       Geographic mismatch may arise if neither workers nor jobs are fully mobile because of the
       costs of mobility. Other considerations are on the employer-side, whether minimum hiring
       standards can be met by applicants or wage offers are acceptable to them. This suggests that
       labour market dynamics are likely to play an important role. In a recent study Ochsen (2009)
       estimated the Beveridge curve for nine countries, eight of them European, over the period
       1960-99. He found that mismatch is not generally lower in those countries considered to have
       more flexible labour markets, though it has decreased in some countries in which the labour
       market has become more flexible.



        Frogner (2002) reported on evidence from an occupational disaggregation
     of the UK employer skills survey data that tends to verify this view (9). However,
     this is not to say that skill gaps cannot occur among highly qualified staff.
     For instance, McGuinness and Bonner (2002) and Bennett and McGuinness
     (2009) uncovered skill gaps in soft skill areas such as business awareness
     and communication among IT and engineering professionals.


     4.2. What
                is the relationship between
           overeducation, overskilling and skill
           shortages?
     It is important to determine whether overeducation results from supply-side
     or demand-side reasons. The former may include accepting jobs for their
     amenities, location advantages or family reasons. The latter may include a
     lack of jobs with appropriate education requirements or discrimination on
     the grounds of gender, race, disability or other group characteristics.


     (9)  rofessional, associate professional and skilled trades were found to account for 56% of all skill
         P
         shortage vacancies despite accounting for only 34% of all jobs. With respect to skill gaps, according
         to the 2001 UK employer skills survey, firms employing sales/service staff, personal service staff
         or workers in elementary occupations, were most likely to report skill gaps.
CHAPTER 4
                                     What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch?   41




    If, when advertising a vacancy, an employer requires a higher level of
education than is necessary to perform the job, it is referred to as credentialism.
This is a term widely used in sociological literature to describe a situation
in which employers require diplomas or certificates for jobs to screen and
identify personal traits that are desirable in the workplace. It is assumed
that people with higher level diplomas or certificates are inherently more
productive. This may also be justified on the grounds that more educated
individuals learn faster or change the nature of the job in such a way that
their productivity eventually becomes higher than that of less educated
workers. Credentialism is more likely to occur when there are skill surpluses.
Employers hiring workers with lower education than required is likely to be
exceptional and reflects skill shortages.
    We would expect a negative relationship between overeducation and/
or overskilling and labour shortages. Since shortages are an increasing
function of excess labour demand over labour supply, it becomes necessary
for employers to make maximum use of existing labour and we would expect
it to be easier for previously overeducated or overskilled employees to find
better matches. Where skill shortages and/or overeducation/overskilling
coexist this is symptomatic of individuals possessing the wrong skills or type
of education or preferring their current ‘mismatch’ because of compensating
job differences.
    Few studies have examined the relationship between these variables
over time because most data sets containing appropriate questions tend
to be single cross-sections and only panel data extending over reasonably
long-time periods can consider changes in employment status. We would
expect a continuing shortage of, say, engineers to be reflected in reduced
rates of overeducation and overskilling among engineering graduates. In
contrast, a surplus of engineers resulting from a sudden increase in the
supply of engineering graduates would be expected to lead to a bumping
down phenomenon in which non-graduate engineers are crowded out of
higher engineering jobs. Skott (2006) has noted an asymmetry between the
options facing high- and low-skill workers. It is open to high-skill workers who
are unable to obtain high-skill jobs to accept low-skill jobs for which they are
overeducated. An equivalent option is not open to low-skill workers since
they are not qualified for high-skill jobs. This could give rise to a decline in
both the relative employment and the relative wage of low-skilled workers
when faced with a transfer of high-skill workers into low-skill jobs. Skott
observed that this occurred between the early 1970s and the mid-1990s
in the UK and the US. Any tendency of employers to keep skilled labour in
42    The skill matching challenge




     the recession because they fear it will be difficult to recruit skilled labour in
     the recovery phase will tend to weaken the above tendency.
         The idea that, as the proportion of the labour force with qualifications
     increases, some of the educated may be forced into lower-prestige jobs
     (generating overeducation) has been examined by Battu and Sloane (2000).
     If the less educated are bumped down this implies that the mean level of
     education will rise across all occupations and some of the uneducated may
     be forced into unemployment. This, in turn, implies that wage differentials
     overall will widen, thus offsetting any tendency for the wage differential of
     the educated to fall relative to the wage for uneducated workers with an
     increase in the supply of qualifications.
         Using data from the social change and economic life initiative and the
     British household panel survey, both of which use the Hope-Goldthorpe scale
     to measure occupational prestige, Battu and Sloane (2000) found evidence
     of skill bumping for Britain between 1986, 1991 and 1995, but this declines
     as one moves down the occupational hierarchy and does not extend to the
     lowest education qualification categories (10). In a similar study for Belgium,
     Nicaise (2000) found evidence of bumping down for men, but not for women
     (11). However, if crowding out is important we would expect to find that it is
     concentrated in recessionary periods when skilled workers find it more difficult
     to obtain jobs at their own level. Further, it if is a temporary phenomenon
     only new workers are likely to be subject to it, as existing employees may
     have job protection. Using Dutch data for the period 1992 to 1995, Gautier
     (2000) found relatively little evidence of crowding out, but where it does
     happen it seems to be a temporary phenomenon and to be driven either
     by short-term variations in the supply of high skilled workers or by shocks
     to the relative productivity of high skill jobs. Asplund and Lilja (2000, for
     evidence of bumping down in Finland) found that the deep recession in
     the early 1990s led to a substantial decline in the employment of the least
     educated and this boosted the upgrading of occupational skills, consistent
     with bumping down. It remains true, however, that there are relatively few
     studies which have attempted to assess the extent of crowding out and skill
     bumping across countries and over time.

     (10)  he Hope-Goldthorpe scale has 36 categories ranked by ‘social desirability’ of male occupations.
          T
          The categories are assumed to provide a high degree of differentiation in terms of both occupational
          function and employment status. It is important to highlight that this class schema was devised for men,
          but the scores are commonly used for both men and women (Goldthorpe and Hope, 1974).
     (11) t is suggested that women may be more driven by family considerations than are men. Thus,
          I
          non-employment of women is more frequently determined by supply-side constraints than is the
          case for men and this tends to offset the bumping down effects on wages.
CHAPTER 4
                                            What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch?   43




4.3. Combinations                  and durations of mismatch
Some general predictions can be developed about the likely relationships
between worker and firm mismatches. Following Cedefop (Cedefop, Descy
and Tessaring, 2001) under and overeducation (or more strictly under and
overqualification) occurs when qualifications of workers do not compare
with job entry requirements; over and underskilling occur when job content
does not compare with workers’ skills and competences. We wish to draw
out potential interrelationships between measures of skill shortages at
individual and firm levels. Table 4 summarises some potential connections
for firms.




Table 4. Combination of mismatch for firms

                 Skill shortages                            Skill gaps

Overeducation    Overeducation and skill shortages          There is a potential correlation as the
                 are not likely to occur together           overeducated may still not possess
                 within occupations within firms.           the correct mix of skills required by
                 But they can coexist across                the firm. However, overeducation will
                 occupations within firms.                  not be correlated with basic skill gaps.

Overskilling     Overskilling and skill shortages           These can coexist within occupations
                 are not likely to occur together           within firms but only in different
                 within occupations within firms.           dimensions whereby the skills surplus
                 But they can coexist across                to the individual are not the skills
                 occupations within firms.                  demanded by the employer.

Undereducation Undereducation and skill                     Within firms and occupations, while
               shortages will exist within                  we do not expect both to coexist in
               occupations within firms if firms            basic occupations with low entry
               are reacting to skill shortages by           requirements it is possible for them to
               upskilling existing staff.                   coexist as the education requirement
                                                            of the occupation rises.

Underskilling    Underskilling and skill shortages          We might expect some correlation
                 will exist within occupations              within occupations and within firms
                 within firms if firms are reacting         if both the worker and the employer
                 to skill shortages by upskilling           recognise they are deficient in the
                 existing staff and some deficits           required skills.
                 remain.
44    The skill matching challenge




        In terms of overeducation and skill shortages, the occupations within
     which the firm employs overeducated workers will not correspond with the
     occupations where skill shortages are being experienced. However, this is
     not to say that the firm cannot simultaneously experience overeducation
     and skill shortages in different occupations. Nevertheless, there is nothing
     to suggest a strong correlation is probable at firm level. At macroeconomic
     level, a high incidence of both overeducation and skill shortage would provide
     a strong indication that the composition of education supply is poorly aligned
     with labour demand. Turning to skill gaps, it is possible that overeducated
     workers within the firm may also be those identified as possessing skill gaps:
     the overeducation may be indicative of the fact that such workers possess
     the incorrect mix of skills required by the firm. However, the consistent
     finding that the overeducated earn more than matched individuals doing the
     same job would tend to suggest the overeducated do not have skill gaps.
     Further, the overeducated, by nature of their education attainment, will not
     tend to be deficient in basic competences, where skill gaps are most likely
     to occur, leading us to the general conclusion that overeducation and skill
     gaps are also likely to be poorly correlated at firm level.
        Overskilling arguably represents a much more direct measure of individual
     underutilisation than overeducation. Nevertheless, the relationship between
     overskilling and skill shortages remains unchanged from that outlined for
     overeducation. While both phenomena may occur across occupations within
     firms they will not tend to be highly correlated within occupations. Once again,
     at economy level, a high incidence of both overskilling and skill shortages
     suggests that some rebalancing of post-compulsory education and training
     supply would benefit both workers and firms. Overskilling and skill gaps
     can, however, occur both within occupations and within firms, but only in
     different dimensions, whereby the skills that are surplus to the individual
     are not the skill areas in which the firm is experiencing a shortfall. Unlike
     overeducation, where the relationship between skill gaps can be discounted,
     no study has yet demonstrated that the overskilled earn a premium relative
     to matched workers carrying out the same job, leaving open the possibility
     that the overskilled may, nonetheless, lack essential skills.
        Evidence suggests that many employers attempt to overcome the problem
     of skill shortages by upskilling their workers to fill vacancies. It may well be
     that reallocated workers do not possess the credentials required to fill the
     post; therefore, some correlation between undereducation and skill shortages
     might be expected. However, evidence from firm-level surveys suggests that
     skill shortages relate to a lack of individuals with the necessary skills and
CHAPTER 4
                                     What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch?   45




experience, as opposed to qualifications, and so the within-firm correlation
is likely to be weak. In terms of skill gaps, if the deficiencies relate to basic
skills then undereducation is unlikely, given that entry requirements to the
occupations in question will be relatively low. However, the likelihood of
correlation will be higher the greater the entry requirement of the positions
where skill gaps are being reported.
    Finally for underskilling, we might expect a relatively strong relationship
between this phenomenon and skill shortages in instances where firms
seek to relieve the problem of unfilled vacancies by training and reallocating
existing staff. Specifically, if upskilling deficiencies remain in terms of the
individual worker’s ability to carry out the job in question, then upskilling
will result in skill gaps. So, there are circumstances where we might expect
strong correlation between underskilling, skill shortages and skill gaps at
firm level.
    Table 4 neglects skills obsolescence, which is different in nature as it is
strongly related to technical change, to rapid changes in work organisation
and to shortcomings in higher education in particular. It is only weakly
related to current skill shortages and not at all to the prospects for future skill
acquisition (Allen and van der Velden, 2007). In fact, skills obsolescence
should be considered a process rather than a state.
CHAPTER 5

  Business cycle impact on skill
  mismatch

This chapter considers the impact of business cycles on the occurrence
of skill mismatch. It is difficult to assess what impacts the economic crisis
Europe is facing at the time of writing will have on skill mismatch. Little is
known about the relationship between skill mismatch and the business cycle
because of the lack of extensive panel data, but there are reasons to believe
that such a relationship exists. Some general assessments are possible:
there is also evidence that skill mismatch is a persistent phenomenon in
difficult times and that overskilled workers who change their jobs do not
always improve their position.



5.1.   Skill mismatch and business cycles
Few, if any, studies have examined the relationship between various dimensions
of skill mismatch and the business cycle because most data sets which
contain appropriate questions tend to be single cross-sections. To understand
what happens over the business cycle requires panel data extending over a
sufficiently long period to pick up the various stages of the cycle.
   By their very nature, business cycles result in a continual change in the
balance between labour demand and supply. Change happens in relation to
the match between the stock of job vacancies and the skills of the unemployed,
and to the flow of jobs and skills into and out of the labour market through
job destruction, job creation, training and skills obsolescence. The impact of
business cycles varies by sector and occupation. Volatility in cyclical excess
product demand or supply is likely to influence labour-market outcomes in
terms of more or less under- and overeducation and under- and overskilling.
In the first instance, business cycles will impact on skill mismatches through
changing the level and composition of the demand for skills and the returns
on the way in which these skills are matched in the workplace (reduced in
a downturn, increased in an upturn). It is also likely that the response of the
labour market itself could influence the duration and depth of a business
cycle, especially through the ability of the market to preserve existing skills
and offer training in new ones.
CHAPTER 5
                                                     Business cycle impact on skill mismatch   47




    Training is crucial in this context. The way the costs of training end up
being split between the worker, the employer and possibly the State could
be influenced by the business cycle. It could also influence the resulting
skills composition and ability of the labour market to match jobs and workers
during a recession and the recovery that follows. The distinction between
(firm or sector) specific and more general training and education matters
because of the financial incentives they imply regarding who covers the
cost of training. Firm/sector specific skills are not transferable to other firms/
sectors. It follows that firms have a stronger incentive to contribute to the
cost of generating specific skills rather than general skills, as the former
cannot be poached as easily.
    Recent research by Mavromaras et al. (2009d; 2009c) using UK and
Australian data suggested that skill mismatches are less prevalent and
their negative consequences are less severe where education is more
specific to the needs of the employer (i.e. a higher proportion of ‘specific’
versus ‘general human capital’). However, this finding was based on data
that included only years in which the economy was doing well. The recent
downturn indicates that, what can be an advantage during a buoyant economy,
can also become a problem during a downturn, because workers with
more (sector, occupation) specific skills are less flexible in shifting to new
jobs if and when their own sector/occupation is adversely affected by the
downturn. In a recession, the best skills for a displaced worker are general
ones, as they allow broader search in sectors that may have been less
affected by the downturn. For example, highly specialised vehicle industry
workers may suffer a larger drop in pay during the current recession than
less specialised but equally well qualified service industry workers. There
is little research in this area and generating evidence using conventional
large survey data sets will not be feasible for some time: the data at hand in
2009 just touches on the starting phase of the current downturn and so all
data series refer to very different general economic conditions. Further, the
data from previous recessions may not be as useful because considerable
institutional changes have taken place in the last two to three decades in
most Western economies.



5.2.   The impact of the economic crisis
Despite the lack of relevant research and appropriate data, some developments
are easy to forecast for the recent downturn. The (re-)training effort will have
48    The skill matching challenge




     to be intensified before the upturn has even started because of its lagged
     effects. If we wait until an upturn is clearly visible, we will experience a slower
     recovery handicapped by skill shortages. However, there is a natural reduction
     in the willingness of employers to pay for training during a recession. A
     prime reason for this is that employers contribute to the cost of training and
     recessionary pressures have a negative effect on such investment. There
     is also a natural increase in the willingness of individuals, especially the
     unemployed and new labour-market entrants, to purchase more education
     and training as this may be the only way to obtain a new job.
        Further, there is a considerable reduction in the social opportunity cost of
     the State paying for the worker training during the current recession, which
     will be the stronger the deeper the recession proves to be. This applies in
     particular to displaced workers, but also to young labour-market entrants.
     There may be problems, however, with these hypotheses. First, the displaced
     workers will probably be the least productive ones and their training may not
     be the most cost-effective intervention (12). Although equity arguments may
     shift the balance in favour of training the less able displaced workers, as
     may the presence of a strong unemployment support and welfare net, such
     considerations may not reduce the level of skill mismatch when the upturn
     occurs. Second, it is not clear where and how training should be provided.
     A mix of classroom and workplace training seems appropriate, as is a mix
     of specific and general training. However, there is little research to guide
     specific choices and the danger is always present in subsidising skills and
     sectors that have little economic future but a strong lobbying presence in
     the current industrial scene.
        Skill shortages are also related to both the business cycle and the extent
     of skill mismatches. In the upturn, skill shortages will lead to increases in
     undereducation and underskilling as labour with appropriate education and
     skill is in short supply. Conversely, in the downturn new entrants to the labour
     market may experience difficulties in locating jobs with the appropriate levels
     of education and skill.
        There is some suggestion from skills shortage literature that some
     shortages persist over most stages of the business cycle in some skilled
     occupations: what varies is their extent over different stages of the business
     cycle. Such shortages are also often evident in industries and occupations
     with modest employment growth or even employment decline. Shortages


     (12)  he same will not apply to young labour-market entrants, where long-term adverse consequences
          T
          will influence a much wider segment of ability distribution.
CHAPTER 5
                                                   Business cycle impact on skill mismatch   49




can coexist with relatively high overall unemployment or in the occupation
under analysis. One reason is that, in cyclical downturns, employers often
reduce training places and apprenticeships, which can affect the number or
trained workers for many years to come, including the upturn years when
demand for skills may have fully recovered. Further, qualified workers who
lose their job during downturns often do not return to the same industry or
occupation. This can result from demand or supply changes in industry
restructuring, making some of the older skills obsolete, or individual workers
having experienced long-term unemployment/non-participation during the
downturn, with adverse effects on their ability to work when the upturn
occurs. In these situations undereducation and underskilling may also exist
regardless of the stage of the business cycle, and it can play a role in the
intensity of downturns and the speed at which an upturn in product demand
can be translated into a wider economic upturn. The role of mature industries
and mature workforce (sometimes the two go together) may intensify the
effect of mismatches and may indicate the need to train younger workers
and retrain older workers.
   There may also be cohort effects in how graduates are matched with jobs
related to the business cycle. If graduates enter the labour market in a period
of recession they may be more likely to experience overeducation; the effect
of this may persist over the longer term. Further, taking the employment
of an overeducated graduate (presumably to a non-graduate job) as an
example, this employment is likely to cause bumping down as a side effect,
displacing a non-graduate worker who may be less qualified generally, but
perfectly well qualified for the (non-graduate) job the overqualified graduate
obtained. It is well established in literature that increasing unemployment
in the less qualified part of the labour market may cause severe scarring
effects. The longer the lead time needed for training any specific type of
graduate, the more likely it is that cyclical volatility may have detrimental
scarring effects. Similar phenomena may be observed where there may be
sudden sharp increases in the number of graduates even if the economy is
not in recession, as absorption is more difficult. This is again accentuated
where there are long training lead times.
   Some of the more general literature on the nature of dynamic labour-
market adjustment is relevant. Although worker quits are often associated
with both wage gains and higher job satisfaction, many workers quit again
within one or two years. There are two rival explanations. First, Burdett
(1978) assumed that job quality in a new job is perfectly observable ex
ante, so that repeated quit behaviour results from workers using new
50    The skill matching challenge




     jobs as a stepping stone to even better jobs. Second, Jovanovic (1979)
     assumed the complete absence of such information, so that repeated job
     moves result from disappointment over job quality. Gielen (2008) observed
     that an appropriate test is whether any improvement in job satisfaction is
     permanent. The British household panel survey shows that the stepping
     stone model can explain up to 80 % of repeated job behaviour and 20 %
     learning about job quality. Using Finnish data, Bockerman and Ilmakunnas
     (2009) suggested that heterogeneity of workplaces and wage compression
     hinder creating sufficiently compensating wage differentials, so that adverse
     working conditions encourage workers to quit. The implication is that, at any
     time, labour markets will be in disequilibrium.



     5.3. Evidence                   from Australia
     In one of the few attempts to measure the dynamics of overskilling,
     McGuinness and Wooden (2007) used the first four waves of the household
     income and labour dynamics for Australia (HILDA) data set. The results
     suggest that, while the overskilled express a desire to quit in order to obtain
     a job which offers a better match, they are not confident of their ability to
     achieve this. Further, though they have a higher propensity to be mobile
     than matched workers, some of this higher mobility is due to involuntary
     separations; even where job separations are voluntary, most job moves do
     not result in improved skill matches. Also, many overskilled workers move into
     unemployment or inactivity. This adds to evidence that policy should focus
     on skill mismatch rather than education mismatch. Using the first six waves
     of HILDA, Mavromaras et al. (2009b) examined the extent of persistence
     defined as the ability of the state to perpetuate among the overskilled. The
     strongest persistence was found for those with higher education. Lower
     persistence, but still strong and statistically significant, was found for those
     with up to year 12 schooling. There is no trace of overskilling persistence for
     those with vocational education and training, indicating that mismatches are
     much easier not only to avoid but also to correct for those with vocational
     training. A caveat for this, and many other contemporary findings, is that
     they have been derived from data drawn exclusively from Australia in an
     economic upturn. It is not clear that these findings can be generalised and
     extrapolated to study today’s recession climate in Europe without careful
     consideration. Despite this caveat, evidence suggests that, at least for some
     groups, overskilling is not a purely temporary phenomenon.
CHAPTER 6

  The implications of skill
  mismatch

This chapter discusses the implications of skill mismatch. The next section
examines the impact of mismatch in terms of productivity and discusses
overeducation, skills shortages and skills gaps. The following section reviews
the impact of skill mismatch on job satisfaction. We then turn to possible
positive impacts of overeducation or overskilling for employers and end by
reflecting on the overall costs of mismatch for society. Skill shortages have
a significant impact on productivity, GDP growth and earnings, though less
is known about the effects of skill gaps or skills obsolescence. We know that
overeducation reduces job satisfaction for individual workers while, for firms,
hiring overeducated workers can be a deliberate strategy to benefit from
extra skills in the long term, despite negative impacts in the short term.


6.1.   Skill mismatch and productivity
We might expect that both skills shortage and skills gap can lead to a loss
of competitiveness as wage rates are bid up and productivity lowered within
industries where skill problems exist. Productivity may also be harmed as
firms may be forced to place lower-skilled workers in skilled positions and/
or, if in an area with skills shortage, workers use their position to alter their
terms and conditions inefficiently from a productivity perspective.
   Finegold and Soskice (1988), and Haskel and Holt (1999), take the analysis
a step further by describing a scenario whereby skills shortage can lead to
low-skill equilibrium within the economy. They described a situation where
firms react to skills shortage by investing in technologies that complement the
low-skilled element of the workforce, resulting in an economy characterised
by low wages and a low demand for high-skilled labour. As a consequence of
the low demand for high wage/high-skilled workers within the labour market,
individuals will no longer invest in their own human capital, thus perpetuating
the low-skill equilibrium position. Tether et al. (2005) argued that once a low-
skill equilibrium has become established, there are no obvious policy levers
for correcting the situation. However, despite some extensive discussion
of the theoretical concept in literature, there is little actual evidence linking
skills shortage with the emergence of a low-skill equilibrium.
52    The skill matching challenge




     6.1.1. Overeducation and productivity
     While the wage effects of overeducation, overskilling, undereducation and
     underskilling are well known (Hartog, 2000; Sloane, 2003; McGuinness,
     2006; Mavromaras et al., 2009a; 2009d) their implications for firm productivity
     are less clear cut. In imperfect labour markets, firms may obtain a rent from
     the services of their employees, which means that the link between the
     wage and productivity is imprecise. There may also be differences between
     short-term and long-term effects, since overeducation is known to reduce
     job satisfaction, which in turn may negatively influence performance, both
     directly and indirectly, through its effects on absence and quit rates. Tsang
     and Levin (1985) suggested that overeducated workers often exhibit counter-
     productive behaviour in the workplace, but this might also be influenced by
     their lower ability, health problems or a different attitude towards work.
         The effects of overeducation on productivity can be measured in two ways.
     If wages equal marginal productivity, the finding that overeducated workers
     receive a wage premium over matched colleagues, though less than matched
     workers with the same education as themselves, suggests that such work-
     ers are somewhat more productive than matched colleagues. An alternative
     and preferable approach, given the presence of imperfect labour markets, is
     to measure productivity directly through analysis of output per head in indi-
     vidual companies or industries. The expectation is that, since overeducation
     reduces job satisfaction, there will also be a negative effect on productivity,
     through higher shirking, absence and quit rates. As Hartog (2000) observed,
     this leaves a puzzle since, along this line of reasoning, overeducation should
     reduce wages rather than increase them as the wage evidence suggests.
         If workers are genuinely mismatched, in the sense that they are not fully
     utilising their education qualifications or skills in their current jobs, reallocating
     labour appropriately should increase productivity and GDP/GNP at macro
     level. However, as Borghans and de Grip (2000) pointed out, to assess this
     properly we require better understanding of the skills that people currently
     possess and the precise ways in which they utilise these skills.
         Unfortunately, much less is known about this than about the allocation
     of different types of workers in the labour market. Also, what is known is
     largely confined to single case studies. In one of the few direct attempts to
     measure the effect of overeducation on productivity, Tsang (1987), applying
     a Cobb-Douglas production function approach and using data on companies
     within the US Bell Corporation, found evidence of negative productivity
     impact. Unfortunately, Tsang’s (1987) study is the only attempt to measure
     productivity effects using company data.
CHAPTER 6
                                                         The implications of skill mismatch   53




6.1.2. Skill shortages and productivity
Skill shortages are important for their impact on productivity, GDP/GNP
growth and earnings. Frogner (2002) cited descriptive evidence from the
2001 European social survey to support this in terms of the productivity
impact, although evidence on earnings was more limited. A study by the
National Institute of Economic and Social Research (Mason and Wilson,
2003) reported that relative to German plants, output per worker in British
firms was over 60 % lower, with the authors arguing that this productivity gap
was a consequence of lower-skill levels. Further, Haskel and Martin (1996)
suggested that skill shortages reduced annual productivity growth in the UK
by 0.4 percentage points over the period 1983-99. On productivity corollaries,
Nickell and Nicolitsas (1997) estimated that a permanent 10 % rise in firms
reporting skill shortages lowers investment proportionately, and RD by a
temporary 4 %. Evidence from more specific sectoral studies include that
of Bennett and McGuinness (2009), who reported that, after controlling for
the influence of selection bias, output per worker was lower in high-tech
firms experiencing both hard-to-fill and unfilled vacancies. Finally, Forth and
Mason (2004) found among UK firms that a quantity shortfall in the number
of graduate engineers and scientists led to lower output per worker.
   But not all empirical evidence points in the same direction. For instance,
McGuinness and Bonner (2002) and McGuinness and Doyle (2003; 2005)
found no evidence that unfilled vacancies substantially lowered the productivity
of Northern Ireland IT and construction firms. Further, for Forth and Mason
(2004) skill shortages arising as a result of the poor quality of applicants
had no productivity impact.


6.1.3. Skill gaps and productivity
While the productivity effects of skill shortages in firms have been relatively
well researched, much less is known about the productivity effects of skill gaps.
Nevertheless, some studies tested the impact of skill gaps on productivity-
related variables (McGuinness and Bennett, 2006; McGuinness and Bonner,
2002), but no significant relationships were found. Some descriptive evidence
suggests, however, that firm performance across a range of indicators
is severely constrained as a consequence of such gaps (e.g. Hogarth
and Wilson, 2001). A series of Northern Ireland sectoral studies (NIERC,
2000; 2001; 2002; Erini, 2005) reported descriptive evidence that skill gaps
substantially hampered firm performance on several fronts. Further, the UK
national employment survey (2003) also found that over a fifth of employers
reporting skill gaps delayed introducing new products, while a third stated
54    The skill matching challenge




     that skill gaps represented a barrier to implementing new work practices
     (Tether et al., 2005).
        Further, de Grip et al. (2008) found, using a Dutch data set, that job
     worker mismatch induces cognitive decline (use it or lose it) with respect to
     immediate and delayed recall abilities, cognitive flexibility and verbal fluency.
     This adds to the relevance of preventing overeducation and also provides a
     reason why overeducation should have a negative effect on earnings.
        For skills obsolescence, contrary to expectations, Allen and van der
     Velden (2001) could find little evidence of long-term problems and no effect
     at all on current wage levels. This may be a result of informal on-the-job
     training or the fact that job loss is an important outcome for workers with
     obsolete skills.


     6.2. Skill        mismatch and job satisfaction
     The overeducated and/or overskilled earn less than if properly matched, but
     more than properly matched colleagues. There is, therefore, an incentive
     to move to a job reflecting better their education and skills. In contrast, the
     undereducated or underskilled earns more than if properly matched, but less
     than properly matched colleagues. As in this case there is no incentive to
     move to a job reflecting better education and skills we expect the mismatch
     to last longer than in the previous case. This should be reflected in lower
     job satisfaction for the overeducated/overskilled and higher job satisfaction
     for the undereducated/underskilled.
        There is limited, but increasing, literature on the effects of skill mismatch on
     job satisfaction. For the US, Tsang and Levin (1985) were the first explicitly
     to model this relationship. They suggested that overeducation may result in
     reduced work effort, increased production cost and lower productivity. Tsang
     (1987) found evidence for this in the Bell Telephone company and Tsang et al.
     (1991) confirmed this, using a broader cross-industry data set. Hersch (1991,
     1995) found similar results for Oregon manufacturing and warehouse firms.
     For Britain, Battu et al. (1999) found that job satisfaction among graduates
     was significantly adversely affected by mismatch in non-graduate jobs. Yet,
     though Belfield and Harris (2002) found a similar relationship, using the same
     data set, this did not appear to be associated with education quality, which
     might be expected to raise job satisfaction through increasing the job-offer rate.
     In contrast, Büchel (2002) found no significant difference in job satisfaction
     between overeducated and adequately educated workers in Germany.
CHAPTER 6
                                                                          The implications of skill mismatch   55




   Allen and van der Velden (2001) differentiated between education and skill
mismatches and found that there was only a significant negative relationship
between mismatch and job satisfaction for skill mismatch. Similarly for Britain,
Green and Zhu (2008) found that overqualification is not a problem for job
satisfaction in itself if it is not accompanied by skill mismatch. For Spain,
Badillo-Amador and Vila (2008) also found that skill mismatches are a better
predictor of job satisfaction than education mismatches, which are not only
related to differences between individuals but also influenced by workers’
previous perceptions, suggesting that a dynamic structure is appropriate
for analysing job satisfaction.
   The above studies neglect the possibility that an overlap exists between
observed and unobserved characteristics which determine both overeducation
and job satisfaction. For this reason one Australian study (Fleming and Kler,
2007) used a different statistical technique and considers various facets of
job satisfaction rather than just overall satisfaction. It was found that the
impact of overeducation on job satisfaction is positively biased for three of
the six facets of job satisfaction considered when using a traditional statistical
technique. However, even with the improved estimation, the significant
negative relationship between overeducation and job satisfaction remains.
Similar results for facets of job satisfaction using Australian data were found
by Linsley (2005) and Kler (2006) (13), the latter finding that overeducated
graduates are more satisfied with job security than matched graduates. Finally
Mavromaras et al. (2009d) used the panel element of the household income
and labour dynamics for Australia and distinguish between overskilling and
overeducation, finding that it is only overskilling on its own or jointly with
overeducation which has a negative effect on job satisfaction. This parallels
the findings in relation to the effect of mismatch on wages.


6.3. Possible             positive impacts of skill mismatch
Employers will hire overeducated or overskilled workers if they believe that
such workers are more productive and the extra productivity is not outweighed
by the higher wages required to attract such workers. They will also use the
undereducated and underskilled if the lower wage costs of such workers
compensate for lower productivity.


(13)  he facets considered by Linsley are satisfaction with work and with level of responsibility; in the
     T
     case of Kler they are satisfaction with pay, job security, hours, work and flexibility.
56    The skill matching challenge




        Dupuy and de Grip (2002) suggested that overeducation is related to
     the hiring policy of large firms. By hiring overeducated workers when the
     supply of highly educated workers exceeds demand for their services,
     large firms increase their opportunities to substitute high-skill for low-skill
     workers in times when high-skill workers are in short supply. High elasticity
     of substitution between high-skill and low-skill workers in large firms explain
     their higher rates of labour productivity. Further, this also encourages skill
     biased technological change (Acemoglu, 2002). However, to determine
     precisely the relative efficiency of using the overeducated instead of matched
     workers is difficult. As Jochmann and Pohlmeier (2003) pointed out, the
     traditional Mincer human capital earnings function approach may reflect
     decreasing returns on schooling or the non-random selection of individuals
     into overeducation status. Using the 1998 wave of the German socioeconomic
     panel they presented Bayesian estimates of treatment effects to overcome
     these problems and found, contrary to earlier studies which neglect selectivity
     issues, no evidence of overeducation depressing earnings.
        Jones et al. (2009) included an overskilling variable, using the British
     workplace employment relations survey 2004 (which is a matched employer-
     employee data set), in equations explaining five measures of performance.
     He found that the variable is positive and significant in at least some of the
     equations. This may explain why employers hire overskilled workers and
     pay them more, but the effect is likely to be short-term as such workers are
     more likely to quit. For Germany Büchel (2002), using the German socio-
     economic panel, found that overeducated workers in low-skill jobs (where
     most of the overeducated are found) tend to be more productive than their
     matched colleagues, which he also took to explain employer motivation in
     hiring the overeducated. Clearly, however, more studies among firms are
     required to understand better this phenomenon and to examine its short-
     term versus long-term implications.


     6.4.   Skill mismatch costs for society
     The economy will lose the output that could have been generated by real-
     locating genuinely mismatched workers to higher productivity jobs. There is
     no loss of output implied, however, for apparently mismatched workers (as
     defined in Chevalier, 2003) as their current jobs reflect their actual levels of
     ability or skills. Further, whether overeducation imposes real costs is challenged
     by some researchers who view overeducation or overskilling as an inherent
CHAPTER 6
                                                         The implications of skill mismatch   57




phenomenon of market economies, as education and training systems cannot
adapt instantly to labour-market needs. Others have argued that the notion
of overeducation is not valid, as people are able to shape their own jobs or
employers may tailor jobs to the skills of workers (Halaby, 1994).
   It is reasonable to conclude that skill shortages are likely to prove costly
to the economy by restricting productivity growth in key sectors. Accepting
that, for many reasons, the market will fail to clear and skill shortages persist,
another question arises on the extent to which the wage mechanism is
sufficient to provide an effective signal of changing labour-market conditions.
Evidence is mixed. Finegold and Soskice (1988) found that individuals in
Britain are less likely than in other countries to increase training in reaction
to a rise in labour price. However, Connolly (1996), using data from the
national child development study, suggested that the demand for training is
responsive to changes in price. Nevertheless, the principal problem arises
from the often substantial training time-lag associated with producing skilled
labour, implying that the market signal usually occurs too late to aid a timely
market response. Further, the price mechanism itself may be a poor indicator
of labour-market shortage, given that increasing wages is one of a range of
strategies adopted by firms to tackle the problem of skill shortages (Bennett
and McGuinness, 2009). Frogner (2002) confirms this, reporting that less
than half of firms, claiming to experience skill shortages in the 2001 European
social survey, indicated a willingness to raise the wage.
   Thus, job mismatch may be associated with social costs, which can be
defined as private costs plus negative externalities. Alternatively, social
benefits may be higher than private benefits if it were not for mismatch.
For instance, at macroeconomic level national output, and hence welfare,
is potentially lower than if workers and firms were fully matched in the
economy. The loss will be a function of the number of workers who are
mismatched and the difference in productivity if they were reallocated. Such
a loss is likely to be greater for skill mismatch than education mismatch,
given the fact that the latter is not likely to incorporate lower ability effects.
In addition, tax revenues may be wasted on equipping individuals with non-
productive education, suggesting less than optimal allocation of resources
by governments. However, education may also enable certain individuals
to gain employment who otherwise may find it difficult to do so.
   Most studies that have examined the relationship between mismatch and
job satisfaction have found a significant negative relationship (for British
graduates see e.g. Battu et al., 1999). This would represent a social cost.
However, recent work using the household income and labour dynamics in
58    The skill matching challenge




     Australia panel suggests that such a negative relationship only applies to
     overskilling, not to overeducation, and that it is not uniform across all employed
     individuals. This needs to be examined in relation to other countries.
        Finally, there may be a link between labour-market mismatch and
     discrimination, which makes certain groups more susceptible to mismatch.
     Battu and Sloane (2004) and Lindley (2009) have, for example, found that
     relative to whites, individuals from some ethnic groups are significantly more
     likely to be overeducated, suggesting that they find it harder to locate optimal
     matches. In addition, migrants may be faced with lower recognition of their
     qualifications, if obtained in country of origin, than is warranted on economic
     grounds. For gender, differences in mismatch appear not to be marked in
     many countries. However, Johansson and Katz (2007) found that, in Sweden,
     women were more likely to be overeducated and men more likely to be
     undereducated. It is also possible that gender-based differences in subject
     choice may further exacerbate the problem through increased horizontal
     mismatch. Again in Sweden, Nordin et al. (2008) found that there were clear
     gender gaps in the share of mismatched jobs in certain disciplines. Men were
     more likely to be mismatched in female-dominated occupations and females
     more so in male-dominated occupations. The gender gap in income declines
     from 12 % to 2 % when type of degree is included in their analysis, implying
     that men are more likely to use education to select into well-paid fields than
     are women. Last, for older workers we have to consider the problem of skills
     obsolescence and the possibility of a subsequent mismatch arising from
     structural factors. A particular problem arises from the fact that there is a
     relatively short payback period in relation to any investment in retraining and
     several studies suggest that retraining older workers may be uneconomic
     for this reason. However, if there is substantial skills obsolescence there
     may be no alternative to retraining older workers. As employers are less
     likely to hire older workers than they are to continue to employ them, this
     emphasises the need for measures to encourage employers to retain older
     workers rather than to dismiss them.
        Rising levels of education may also affect pay dispersion. Increasing
     dispersion in the returns on graduate education in the UK has been detected
     by Green and Zhu (2008) over the period 1994 to 2006, when the numbers
     of graduating increased sharply. While the benefits of graduate education
     improved at the top end of the distribution for both men and women, at the
     bottom end they sharply decreased. This means that the financial risks
     associated with investment in higher education have increased, since
     individuals cannot be certain where they will end up in terms of the overall
     earnings distribution. This could result in insufficient supply of individuals
     coming forward to meet the needs of the economy.
CHAPTER 7

  Appropriate skill mismatch
  measuring

Consistent with the considerable attention to overeducation in literature, we
begin by giving an overview of data sets that include items on overeducation
or overskilling. Five European and two UK data sets extending beyond 2000
contain relevant questions, but only the household income and labour dynamics
for Australia data set is a panel. We discuss three alternative measures:
the objective method, the subjective method and the empirical method
can be used to measure overeducation and reflect on their weaknesses.
Subsequently, we explain why overskilling offers a better picture of skill
surpluses. Few data sets, however, contain questions on it. In the final
section we argue that skills obsolescence can be measured in different
ways, but that there is little consensus on what is the most appropriate way
of measuring; few data sets contain questions that can be used to assess
skills obsolescence.


7.1. Measuring         overeducation and overskilling
In Table 5 we list the main recent cross-country data sets which contain relevant
questions on overeducation and overskilling, plus several single-country
data sets which contain questions on overskilling and have advantages.
We focus on the concept of overeducation and overskilling, where the main
measurement issues seem to lie. Three alternative measures have been
used to measure overeducation:
   (a)  ystematic job evaluation, used to determine the precise level of
       s
       qualifications required to perform a particular job. It is referred to as
       an ‘objective’ measure, but fails to allow more than one education
       level to be appropriate for particular occupations, particularly if they
       are broadly defined. It also fails to allow for the possibility that the
       appropriate education level may change over time;
   (b)  orker self-assessment, referred to as a ‘subjective’ measure, depends
       w
       on the precise question asked, such as ‘how much education is required
       to obtain a job like yours?’ or ‘what level of education is required to
       perform this job?’. When firms specify a level of education higher than
60    The skill matching challenge




           necessary to perform a job, it suggests the use of credentialism and
           may well result in overskilling or skill underutilisation;
       (c)  ost data sets do not contain a direct question on overeducation,
           m
           in which case reliance has to be placed on the empirical method.
           Conventionally, mismatching occurs when the level of education
           is more than one standard deviation above or below the mean for
           education within an occupation. This cannot be directly compared
           with the above two measures as it ignores minor differences between
           actual and mean education.
       Several studies have sought to assess the correlation between different mea-
     sures of mismatch. McGoldrick and Robst (1996) showed that the incidence of
     male overeducation varied from 50 % under the objective measure to 30 %


     Table 5.  ata sets containing questions to individual employees on
              D
              skill mismatch

     Data set                 Type                    Dates                   Questions
     European                 Panel                   1994-2001               overskilling
     Community                                                                (three questions)
     household panel
     European social          Cross-section over 30   Biennial 2002/03,       over- and
     survey                   countries               2004/05, 2006/07,       undereducation
                                                      2008/09
     European working Cross-section	                  1996, 2000, 2005	       over- and underskilling
     conditions survey
     Flexible                 Mail questionnaire, nine 2005                   overskilling,
     professional in the      countries (graduates                            underskilling,
     knowledge society        only)                                           horizontal mismatch,
     (REFLEX)                                                                 overeducation and
                                                                              undereducation
     EU e-living project      Household survey six    2001 and 2002           over- and
                              countries                                       underqualification
     Workplace                Matched employer-       2004                    over- and underskilling
     employment               employee data
     relations survey
     UK skills survey         Cross-section           1992, 1997, 2001, 2006 over- and
                                                                             underqualification
                                                                             overskilling
     Household income         Panel                   2001                    overskilling
     and labour
     dynamics in
     Australia (HILDA)
CHAPTER 7
                                                     Appropriate skill mismatch measuring   61




under the subjective measure and 16 % under the empirical method. Battu et
al. (2000) found that the various measures tended to identify different people
as being overeducated with correlations under two subjective measures being
around 0.2 to 0.3. Verhaest and Omey (2006) considered the reliability of five
different measures of overeducation on the basis of encompassing tests. They
concluded that objective job evaluation and subjective data on the level of
education required to do the job should always be preferred over the empirical
method or to subjective measures of the education level required to get the
job. Allen et al. (2006) suggested that analysis of the wage consequences
of education mismatch needed to be complemented by including the effects
of job-worker skill mismatches, expecting that the wage effects of educa-
tion mismatches would be absorbed by the skill mismatch measure. In fact,
there is little correlation between the two. Green and McIntosh (2007) found
a correlation between overeducation and overskilling of 0.2. Further, when
an overskilling variable is included in a wage equation already containing an
overeducation variable, the coefficient on overeducation only falls from -0.164
to -0.144, a statistically insignificant difference.
    An obvious problem with measures for overeducation is that they treat dif-
ferent degrees of overeducation in the same way. A graduate in a job for which
only a higher school leaving certificate is required is treated as a graduate in
a menial job, while the policy implications of the two cases might be different.
It is less likely this occurs under the empirical method, but using the standard
deviation criterion is purely arbitrary. Further, there is another ambiguity ac-
cording to whether the mean or the mode is used as the standard. In many,
though not all countries, the incidence of overeducation is higher than that
of undereducation, so the mode, rather than the mean, would appear to be
the appropriate yardstick. Where the number of workers in an occupation is
limited or the dispersion of actual qualifications wide, any measure of central
location is likely to be unreliable. Thus, De Oliveira et al. (2000) suggested
generally limiting the analysis to cases where the modal number of years of
education is shared by at least 60 % of the workers in that occupation.
    The measures discussed above are examples of vertical mismatch but
none deal with the case of horizontal mismatch, where the level of education
is appropriate but the type is not. For example, some degree fields focus on
occupation-specific skills that may not easily transfer to other occupations,
while others focus on more general human capital (e.g. arts). But, perhaps, the
biggest problem of overeducation as a measure of mismatch is the frequent
omission of any measure of ability in empirical work on the phenomenon,
so that we simply do not know whether overeducated workers are in this
state simply for low ability given the level of education.
62    The skill matching challenge




     7.2. Focusing                   on overskilling
     Such reasoning suggests that overskilling might be regarded as a superior
     measure of mismatch, particularly where the question makes direct references
     to ability. The Australian HILDA panel asks respondents whether they use
     many of their skills and abilities in their current job, with a response of 1
     corresponding to strongly disagree and 7 to strongly agree. This, however,
     requires a cut-off point for being overskilled and does not allow clear
     delineation of the underskilled (14). In contrast, the question in the British
     workplace employment relations survey 2004 simply asks individuals how
     well the skills they personally have match the skills they need to do their
     present job. Here, however, there is a five point scale with respondents
     answering that their own skills are much higher, a bit higher, about the same,
     a bit lower or much lower than needed. This enables a clear distinction to be
     made between those severely overskilled or underskilled or only moderately
     so. Neither of these data sets contains a direct question on overeducation,
     though one can be derived using the empirical method.
         The European Community household panel, which ran for eight years
     between 1994 and 2001, also contains questions on overskilling. In 2001
     respondents were asked whether they had formal training or education
     that had given them the skills needed for the present type of work and how
     much this training and education had contributed to their present work. A
     further question asked whether the respondents felt that they had the skills
     or qualifications to do a more demanding job than they now have. Brunello
     et al. (2007) have examined these questions for five countries using both
     probit and multinomial analysis, and Badillo-Amador and Vila (2008) have
     done so for Spain. The latter use the modal procedure to estimate education
     mismatch using years of education. They defined the overskilled as those
     answering positively to the first and third questions and the underskilled
     as answering negatively. Those who answer yes to first question and no
     to the third are defined as adequately skilled; those who answer no to the
     first question and yes to the third are, debatably, defined as wrongly skilled.
     These questions are also not ideal as they refer to education as well as
     skills; it is impossible to disentangle the two.
         The European working conditions survey conducted in 1996, 2000 and
     2005 contains relevant questions on skill mismatch. In 2005 respondents


     (14)  he same will not apply to young labour-market entrants, where long-term adverse consequences
          T
          will influence a much wider segment of ability distribution.
CHAPTER 7
                                                     Appropriate skill mismatch measuring   63




were asked which of the following alternative would best describe their skills
in their own work:
   (a) I need further training to cope well with my duties (underskilled);
   (b) my duties correspond well with my present skills (matched);
   (c)  have the skills to cope with more demanding duties (possibly
        I
        overskilled).
   The 2005 survey was not analysed in relation to these questions.
   The REFLEX graduate survey 2005 contains data on graduates in nine
European countries and has the advantage of asking separate questions on
skill and education mismatches. Skill mismatches are identified from workers’
responses on a scale from 1 (not at all) to 5 (to a very large extent) to the
questions: to what extent does your current work demand more knowledge
and skills than you can actually offer; and to what extent are your knowledge
and skills utilised in your current work? For overeducation the equivalent
question is ‘what type of education do you feel is most appropriate for the
current work?’. This can be compared directly with reported education
levels.
   The European social survey 2002/03-2008/09 has information on 25
countries and contains two questions relevant to education matching: first ‘if
someone was applying nowadays for the job you do now, would they need
any education or vocational schooling beyond compulsory education?’;
and ‘about how may years of education and vocational schooling beyond
compulsory education would they need?’ The 2001/02 e-Living project
contains questions on both qualifications and years of education but for a
more restricted range of countries.
   It is necessary to consider all possible combinations of skill mismatch.
Ignoring undereducation and underskilling, which are less common
phenomena, there are four possible matching combinations:
   (a) matched education and matched skills;
   (b) overeducation, but skill matching;
   (c) matched education, but overskilling;
   (d) overeducation and overskilling.
   The first case is more likely where there are specific qualifications, as in
law or medicine or skilled craft apprenticeships. The second is more likely
when the individual is at the lower end of the ability distribution for a given
qualification, so that he or she is unable to obtain a job which matches
that level of qualification. However, the job obtained may make full use of
that person’s skills or abilities. Alternatively, this combination may result
through choice, if the job has non-pecuniary benefits which offset the lower
64    The skill matching challenge




     wage offered. The third case might occur when employers raise the level of
     education required for the job, as they realise that the supply of individuals with
     a particular level of education is now higher than it was. If the requirements
     of the job have not changed this amounts to grade inflation. The final case
     may be more likely for married women returning to work after childbirth or who
     are constrained by a job move on the part of the husband (tied movers). The
     constraints on job search make it more difficult to find jobs commensurate
     with their qualifications and abilities.
        In the context of the above four measures, recent work by Mavromaras
     et al. (2009d), using the HILDA panel, indicates the need to run separate
     equations for each of the four groups. Only those subject to overskilling, either
     on its own or jointly with overeducation, suffer from lower job satisfaction,
     and for men when controlling for unobserved individual heterogeneity there is
     no clear wage penalty for overeducation. This is not the case for overskilled
     men. This emphasises the need for data sets which have separate questions
     on overeducation and overskilling, which are panel in nature and ideally
     which enable one to identify horizontal and vertical mismatches.


     7.3. Measuring                  skills obsolescence
     Finally, we should consider measuring skills obsolescence, which is far from
     straightforward. In principle it can be measured:
        (a) objectively, by testing the deterioration of workers’ skills over time;
        (b) hrough subjective methods such as asking workers (or employers)
            t
            whether they face skills obsolescence;
        (c)  y the individual measurement of productivity (e.g. tests of workers’
            b
            skills deterioration or levels of wages);
        (d)  y the rate of innovation which should indicate the speed of
            b
            obsolescence.
        Survey data questions include Blechinger and Pfeiffer (2000) ‘how much
     of the occupational knowledge and skills that you acquired during your
     apprenticeship can you still apply in your current work?’ and Van Loo et al.
     (2001) ‘have your qualifications depreciated due to changes in your current
     job?’ and ‘what is the extent to which your qualifications are suited to your
     current job?’. Relatively few data sets include such questions.
CHAPTER 8

  Skill mismatch data needed in
  Europe

Given the problems that current data sources pose, this final chapter considers
data needed to analyse skill mismatch comprehensively in Europe. We
would learn most from a new matched employer-employee panel containing
appropriate questions but this would be very expensive. We suggest to add
to panel data sets several questions in the form of modules, to be asked
once every two or three years; to use several European panel surveys to
allow comparative analyses; to consider alternative methods for information
collection of a more detailed, but also revealing nature.


8.1. Improving        data on skill mismatch in Europe
One of the current problems in analysing mismatch in Europe is the absence
of appropriate questions in regular series such as labour force surveys and
household panels. A panel with enough observations to observe changes
in mismatch over the business cycle would be ideal and, if a matched
employer/employee panel, this would enable control for unobserved individual
heterogeneity both in relation to personal characteristics of individuals and
establishments.
   While this would provide substantial gains in understanding the mismatch
problem, developing a new data set would be very costly. To collect this new
information cost-effectively would demand funding and support for adding
a set of pertinent labour-market mismatch questions to several existing
large data sets. This can be difficult because most data sets are already
overburdened and interviewee fatigue is a serious problem but it would be a
lot cheaper than starting a new data set. Given the rather long-term nature
of training and education, yearly collection of the relevant information may
not be essential.
   The cost-effectiveness of the data collection could be improved by dis-
pensing with annual information and starting a special module, collected
once every two or three years, as part of several existing, long-running data
sets across Europe. The questions asked should preferably be the same
in all data sets. Where we judge that there may be a requirement for some
66    The skill matching challenge




     additional questions for purposes of equivalisation, these should be asked
     as necessary. Appropriate momentum could be assured by starting with
     collection in years 1, 3, 5 and then moving to a longer three-year interval,
     8, 11, etc. The information collected in this way can be almost as useful
     as that collected annually and will be supported by the annual information
     as well. Where specific detailed information cannot be obtained through
     conventional survey interview methods, alternative methods, such as quali-
     tative analysis and discrete choice experiments, should be considered as
     complements that could enhance our understanding obtained from large
     survey data sets.


     8.2. What
                         information should be collected and
           how?
     For new information useful within a wider survey context, separate ques-
     tions should be asked in relation to skill shortages, skill gaps, over- and
     undereducation, over- and underskilling, and skills obsolescence. Some of
     the information could be obtained from employers, some from employees
     and some from both to check for consistency (15). This would be much
     cheaper and would provide real gains in identifying links between these
     different concepts.
        Only the employer has the relevant information on skill shortages and
     should be asked whether there are any occupations they are unable, or have
     difficulty, to fill. This could be supplemented by questions on the duration
     of vacancies and the wage competitiveness of the employer. Further,
     employers could be asked what they perceive to be the reasons for the skill
     shortages. For skill gaps, employers should be asked to cite cases where
     existing employees do not have the required qualifications, experience and/
     or specialised skills to meet the firm’s skill needs for an occupation. This
     needs to be supplemented by questions on training provision and why this
     has not solved the problem or has not taken place. In case of a matched
     data set, employees could be asked the same question on underskilling to
     check for consistency in responses from the two parties.
        Questions on over- and undereducation should ideally focus on both
     qualifications and time spent on being educated. Further they should focus


     (15)  major project including a study and network of European labour-market analysts using firm panel
          A
          data and linked employer-employee data was launched in 2008 and is due to report this year.
CHAPTER 8
                                                        Skill mismatch data needed in Europe   67




on the education level required to do the job rather than to obtain the job,
though the latter could be asked as a supplementary question. Objective
and subjective approaches are to be preferred to the empirical method.
Information on the objective approach could be obtained from the employer,
while the subjective approach requires questions addressed to the employee.
If both are asked in a matched panel, the responses could be checked
for consistency. In particular, employers need to be asked why they hire
overeducated workers and how they differentiate their pay from that of
properly matched colleagues. Similarly, employees need to be asked why
they accepted a job for which they were overeducated. Any panel element
could be used to ascertain time trends. Questions also need to be asked
on horizontal and vertical mismatch.
    Questions on over- and underskilling seem to be more informative than
those on over- and undereducation and seem to be less contaminated by
unobserved individual heterogeneity. It is necessary to ensure that any
scale used for employees to rank the extent to which they use their skills
and abilities allows the underskilled and the overskilled to be classified
clearly. It is important to include ‘ability’ and ‘skill’ in the question. Questions
on the extent and type of training should be included to establish whether
or not the provision of training diminishes the extent of overskilling and
underskilling.
    Skills obsolescence is often hard to measure using currently available data
sets. Questions on skills obsolescence should allow differentiation between
economic and technological change explanations. The latter will be illustrated
by reductions in overall employment and relative employment by occupation,
on which the employer is more likely to have information, while the former is
more related to the individual. This needs to be linked to age and the provision
of retraining. Using a panel, workers can be asked at different times to rate
the extent to which their skills are suitable for their current job; the reduction
in the score will then indicate the degree of obsolescence. Induction time
(the time the respondent expects a new recruit to learn how to do the job)
has been found to be a strong determinant of skills obsolescence, and so
it is useful to have a question on this in any survey.
    An important but overlooked aspect is the role of past training on present
overeducation and overskilling levels. It should not be assumed that the
provision of education and training always reflects accurately the preferences
of the trainees. Little is known, in the economic context of mismatches,
of the role that education providers may play in generating mismatches.
How provision is funded and organised, as well as how it tries to address
68    The skill matching challenge




     the demand by trainees and their future employers, is as important as it is
     inadequately researched. For example, the space at the borders between
     vocational and university level can be riddled with problems related to
     entrenched education positions. Key aspects are curriculum design and
     permeability between VET and general education. Such problems appear
     in different guises in many countries and their presence can distort the
     efficient provision of education in a fast changing economy. The collection
     of information on the type of provision and how this meets the needs of
     trainees and the industry should become standard in related data sets.


     8.3. The         way forward
     What is the way forward? First, comprehensiveness of relevant questions on
     skill mismatch in surveys (see Annex) should be ensured to understand the
     relationship between different forms of mismatch. For example, do vertical and
     horizontal mismatches tend to have a positive, negative or no relationship?
     Does skills obsolescence tend to intensify the problem of labour shortages?
     Only if individual data sets contain a comprehensive list of questions are we
     likely to be in a position to answer such questions. Then it will be necessary
     to establish which European panel data sets can be used to include these
     questions alongside their wider survey questions.
ANNEX

  Comprehensive schemata for
  skill mismatch questions in
  surveys

1. Qualifications (employee questions)
	 (a)  ow long did it take you to obtain the highest qualification you currently
      H
      hold?
	 (b) Was it obtained on a part-time or full-time basis?
	 (c) What is the normal time taken to obtain this qualification?
	 (d) From which institution did you obtain this qualification?
	 (e)  as the qualification classified and if so what classification did you
      W
      obtain?
	 (f) s a particular qualification required to obtain the job you currently
      I
      hold?
	 (g) If so, what is it?
	 (h)  as the level of required qualification changed since you obtained
      H
      this job?
	 (i)  hat level of qualification do you consider to be necessary to perform
      W
      the job adequately?
	 (j)  hat field of study do you consider to be most appropriate for this
      W
      work?
			 • exclusively own field;
			 • own or related field;
			 • a completely different field;
			 • no particular field.
	 (k)  as your employer offered you training to enable you to perform your
      H
      current job better or to perform another job?

2.	Skills and abilities (employee question)
	 (a)  ow well do the skills and abilities you have match the skills needed
       H
       to do your current job?
		 My own skills are:
			 • much higher;
			 • a bit higher;
			 • about the same;
			 • a bit lower;
			 • much lower than needed.
70    The skill matching challenge




     3. Skill shortages and skill gaps (employer questions)
     	 (a) re there any occupations that you are unable to fill or have difficulty
           A
           in filling?
     		 • please name them
     	 (b) On average how long does it take before a vacancy is filled?
     	 (c)  ow do your wage rates for these shortage occupations compare with
           H
           those of your main competitors in the labour market?
     		 • above average;
     		 • average;
     		 • below average.
     	 (d) What are the main reasons for these labour shortages?
     		 • lack of qualified applicants;
     		 • the job is unattractive;
     		 • location;
     		 • other, please specify.
     	 (e)  re there any occupations in which existing employees do not have the
           A
           required qualification, experience and/or specialised skills to perform
           the job to acceptable or most efficient levels?
     		 • please name them
     	 (f) What are the main reasons for these skill deficiencies?
     		 • skill shortages;
     		 • changing job requirements;
     		 • labour turnover;
     		 • other, please specify.
     	 (g) Which skills are inadequate?
     		 • technical/ICT;
     		 • numeracy;
     		 • literacy/communication skills;
     		 • problem solving;
     		 • teamwork;
     		 • other, please specify.
     	 (h) Why does the company not provide off-the-job training to remedy this?
           
     		 • costs;
     		 • time constraints;
     		 • no suitable training available;
     		 • other, please specify.
Comprehensive schemata for skill mismatch questions in surveys   71




4. Skills obsolescence (employee questions)
	 (a) Are there any skills you once possessed no longer required in your
      
      current job?
		 • if so, please name them
	 (b) Are there new skills which have emerged in your current job that you
      
      do not possess?
		 • if so, please name them
	 (c)  o you consider that your ability to perform your current job has
      D
      diminished over time?
	 (d)  ow long does it take a new employee to become fully proficient in
       H
       the job?
	 (e) Has this duration increased over time?
	 (f)  o you think that you will be able to continue in your present job until
       D
       the normal age of retirement?
	 (g) Has training been provided by your employer to update your skills?
	 (h) If so, when and how often has this been provided?
References

Acemoglu, D. (2002). Technical change, inequality and the Labour Market.
       Journal of Economic Literature, XL, 7-72.
Alba-Ramirez, A. (1993). Mismatch in the Spanish labor market. Journal of
       Human Resources, Vol. 28, No 2, p. 259-278.
Alba-Ramirez, A.; Blázquez, M. (2003). Types of job match, overeducation
       and labour mobility in Spain. In Büchel, F. et al. Overeducation in
       Europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 65-92.
Allen, J. et al. (2006). Wage effects of job-worker mismatches: heterogeneous
       skills or institutional effects. Maastricht: ROA – Research Centre for
       Education and the Labour Market.
Allen, J.; van der Velden, R. (2001). Educational mismatches versus skill
       mismatches: effects on wages, job satisfaction, and on-the-job search.
       Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 53, No 3, p. 434-452.
Allen, J.; van der Velden, R. (2007). When do skills become obsolete, and
       when does it matter? In De Grip, A. et al. (eds). The economics of
       skills obsolescence, p. 27-50.
Alpin, C. et al. (1998). Over and undereducation in the UK graduate labour
       market. Studies in Higher Education, Vol. 1, p. 17-34.
Arrow, K.J.; Capron, W.M. (1959). Dynamic shortages and price rises: the engi-
       neer-scientist case. Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 73, p. 292-308.
Asplund, R.; Lilja, R. (2000). Has the Finnish labour market bumped
       the least educated? In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The over-
       educated worker: the economics of skill utilisation. Cheltenham:
       Edward Elgar, p. 57-76.
Badillo-Amador, L.; Vila, L.E. (2008). Education and skill mismatches:
       wage and job satisfaction consequences. Cartagena: Polytechnic
       University of Cartagena.
Battu, H. et al. (1999). Overeducation among graduates: a cohort view.
       Education Economics, Vol. 17, No 1, p. 21-38.
Battu, H. et al. (2000). How well can we measure graduate overeducation
       and its effects? National Institute Economic Review, No 171, January
       2000, p. 82-93.
References   73




Battu, H.; Sloane, P.J. (2000). Overeducation and crowding out in Britain.
       In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The overeducated worker.
       Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 157-174.
Battu, H.; Sloane, P.J. (2004) Over-education and ethnic minorities in
       Britain. Manchester School, Vol. 72, No 4, p. 535-559.
Bauer, T. (2002). Educational mismatch and wages: a panel analysis.
       Economics of Education Review, Vol. 21, p. 221-229.
Becker, G. (1964). Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis with
       special reference to education. Irvington, NY: Columbia University
       Press.
Belfield, C.R.; Harris, R.D.F.(2002). How well do theories of job matching
       explain variations in job satisfaction across education levels?
       Evidence for UK graduates. Applied Economics, Vol. 34, p. 535-
       548.
Bennett, J.; McGuinness, S. (2009). Assessing the impact of skill shortages
       on the productivity performance of high-tech firms in Northern
       Ireland. Applied Economics, Vol. 41, No 6, p. 727-737.
Blechinger, D.; Pfeiffer, F. (2000). Technological change and skill
       obsolescence: the case of German apprenticeship training. In
       Heijke, H.; Musken, J. (eds). Education and training in a knowledge-
       based economy. London: MacMillan, p. 243-276.
Bockerman, P.; Ilmakunnas, P. (2009). Job disamenities, job satisfaction,
       quit intentions and actual separations; putting the pieces together.
       Industrial Relations, Vol. 48, No 1, p. 73-96.
Booth, A.; Snower, D. (1996). Acquiring skills: market failures, their
       symptoms and policy responses. Cambridge: University Press.
Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (2000). The debate in economics about skill
       utilisation. In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The overeducated
       worker. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 3-26.
Bosworth, D.L. (1978). The rate of obsolescence of technical knowledge: a
       note. Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. XXVI, No 3, p. 273-279.
Brunello, G. et al. (2007) (eds). Education and training in Europe. Oxford:
       Oxford University Press.
Brynin, M.; Longhi, S. (2009). Overqualification: major or minor mismatch?
       Economics of Education Review, Vol. 28, p. 114-121.
Büchel, F. (2002). The effects of overeducation on productivity in Germany:
       the firm’s viewpoint. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 21, p.
       263-275.
74    The skill matching challenge




     Büchel, F.; Battu, H. (2003). The theory of differential overqualification:
            does it work? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 50, No 1,
            p. 1-16.
     Büchel, F.; Pollmann-Schult, M. (2001). Overeducation and skill endow-
            ments: the role of school achievement and vocational training qual-
            ity. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labour (Discussion paper,
            No 337).
     Büchel, F.; van Ham, M. (2002). Overeducation, regional labour markets
            and spatial flexibility. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labor
            (IZA Discussion papers, No 424).
     Burdett, K. (1978). A theory of employee job search and quit rates. American
            Economic Review, Vol. 68, No 1, p. 212-220.
     Burris, V. (1983). The social and political consequence of overeducation.
            American Sociological Review, Vol. 48, No 4, p. 454-469.
     Cardoso, A. (2007). Jobs for young university graduates. Economics
            Letters, 94, 271-277.
     Cedefop (2008). Future skill needs in Europe: medium term forecast:
            synthesis report. Luxembourg: Publications Office.
     Cedefop (2009). Skill mismatch: identifying priorities for future research.
            Luxembourg: Publications Office (Working paper, No 3).
     Cedefop; Büchel, F. (2001). Overqualification: reasons, measurement
            issues and typological affinity to unemployment. In Cedefop; Descy,
            P.; Tessaring, M. Training in Europe: second report on vocational
            training research in Europe 2000: background report volume 2.
            Luxembourg: Publications Office.
     Cedefop; Descy, P.; Tessaring, M. (2001). Training and learning for
            competence: second report on vocational training research in
            Europe: synthesis report. Luxembourg: Publications Office (Cedefop
            Reference series).
     Chevalier, A. (2003). Measuring over-education. Economica, Vol. 70, No 3,
            p. 509-531.
     Cohn, E.; Khan, P. (1995). The wage effects of overschooling revisited.
            Labour Economics, Vol. 2, Issue 1, p. 67-76.
     Cohn, E.; Ng, C.Y. (2000). Incidence and wage effects of underschooling
            and overschooling in Hong Kong. Economics of Education Review,
            Vol. 19, p. 159-168.
     Connolly, S. (1996). Does training choice depend on prospective returns?
            East Anglia: Economics Research Centre (ERC Working paper,
            9604).
References   75




Daly, A. et al. (1985). Productivity, machinery and skills in a sample of British
       and German manufacturing plants. National Institute Economic
       Review, Vol. 111, No 1, p. 48-61.
Daly, M. et al. (2000). Premiums and penalties for surplus and deficit
       education: evidence from the United States and Germany. Economics
       of Education Review, Vol. 19, p. 169-178.
De Grip, A. et al. (2008). Job-worker mismatch and cognitive decline.
       Oxford Economic Papers, No 60, p. 237-253.
De Grip, A.; van Loo, J. (2007). The economics of skills obsolescence:
       a review. In de Grip, A. et al. (eds). The economics of skills
       obsolescence: theoretical innovations and empirical applications.
       Bingley: Emerald, p. 1-26 (Research in Labor Economics, Vol. 21).
De Oliveira, M. (2000). The role of human capital and technological change
       in overeducation. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19, p. 199-
       206.
Dekker, R. et al. (2002). The effects of training and overeducation on
       career mobility in a segmented labour market. International Journal
       of Manpower, Vol. 23, No 2, p. 106-125.
Dolado, J.J. et al. (2009). On-the-job search in a matching model with
       heterogenous jobs and workers. Economic Journal, No 119, p. 200-
       228.
Dolton, P.; Siles, M. (2003). The determinants and consequences of
       overeducation. In Büchel, F. et al. (eds). Overeducation in Europe.
       Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 189-217.
Dolton, P.; Vignoles, A. (2000). The incidence and effects of overeducation
       in the UK graduate labour market. Economics of Education Review,
       Vol. 19, No 2, p. 179-198.
Duncan, J.; Hoffman, S. (1981). The incidence and wage effects of overe-
       ducation. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 1, No 1, 7p. 5-86.
Dupuy, A.; de Grip, A. (2002). Do large firms have more opportunities to
       substitute between skill categories than small firms? Aarhus: Centre
       for Labour Market and Social Research (Working paper 02-01).
Erini, J. (2005). An examination of the Northern Ireland labour market for
       construction skills. Belfast: DEL – Department for Employment and
       Learning.
European Commission (2008a). The Bordeaux communiqué on enhanced
       European cooperation in vocational education and training.
       Communiqué of the European Ministers for Vocational Education
       and Training, the European social partners and the European
76    The skill matching challenge




            Commission, meeting in Bordeaux on 26 November 2008 to review
            the priorities and strategies of the Copenhagen process. Brussels:
            European Commission.
     European Commission (2008b). Communication from the Commission to
            the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and
            Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions: new skills for
            new jobs; anticipating and matching labour market and skills needs.
            Luxembourg: Publications Office (COM(2008) 868 final).
     Finegold, D.; Soskice, D. (1988). The failure of training in Britain: analysis
            and prescription. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 4, No 3,
            p. 21-52.
     Fleming, C.M.; Kler, P. (2007). I’m too clever for this job: a bivariate probit
            analysis on overeducation and job satisfaction in Australia. Applied
            Economics, i-First, p. 1-16.
     Forth, J.; Mason, G. (2004). The impact of high-level skill shortages on
            firm-level performance: evidence from the UK technical graduate
            labour market. London: NIESR – National Institute of Economic and
            Social Research (Discussion paper, 235).
     Frank, R.H. (1978). Why women earn less: the theory and estimation of
            differential overqualification. American Economic Review, Vol. 68,
            No 3, p. 360-373.
     Freeman, R.B. (1976). The overeducated American. New York: Academic
            Press.
     Frenette, M. (2004). The overqualified Canadian graduate: the role of the
            academic program in the incidence, persistence, and economic re-
            turns to overqualification. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 23,
            No 1, p. 29-45.
     Frogner, M.L. (2002). Skill shortages. Labour Market Trends, January
            2002, p. 17-27.
     Galasi, P. (2008). The effect of educational mismatch on wages for 25
            countries. Budapest: Corvinus University (Working papers on the
            Labour Market, BWP – 2008/8).
     Gautier, P. (2000). Do more high skilled workers occupy simple jobs during
            bad times? In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The overeducated
            worker. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 203-230.
     Gielen, A.C. (2008). Repeated job quits: stepping stones or learning about
            quantity. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labour (Discussion
            paper, No 3838).
References   77




Goldthorpe, J.H.; Hope, K. (1974). Social grading of occupations: a new
      approach and scale. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Gottschalk, P.; Hansen, M. (2003). Is the proportion of college workers in
      non-college jobs increasing? Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 21,
      p. 449-471.
Grazier, S. et al. (2008). Graduate employment in the UK: an application of
      the Gottschalk-Hansen model. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of
      Labour (Discussion paper, No 3618).
Green, F. et al. (1998). The meaning and determinants of skills shortages.
      Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 60, No 2, p. 165-87.
Green, F. et al. (1999). Overeducation and skills: clarifying the concepts.
      London: Centre for Economic Performance.
Green, F.; McIntosh, S. (2007). Is there a genuine under-utilisation of skills
      amongst the over-qualified? Applied Economics, Vol. 39, p. 427-439.
Green, F.; Zhu, Y. (2008). Overqualification, job dissatisfaction, and
      increasing dispersion in the returns to graduate education. Kent:
      University of Kent, Department of Economics (Discussion papers
      KDPE 08/03).
Groeneveld, S.; Hartog, J. (2004). Overeducation, wages and promotions
      within the firm. Labour Economics, Vol. 11, No 6, p. 701-714.
Groot, W. (1993). Overeducation and the returns to enterprise related
      schooling. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 17, No 4, p. 299-
      309.
Groot, W. (1996). The incidence and returns to overeducation in the UK.
      Applied Economics Vol. 28, p. 1345-1350.
Groot, W.; Maassen van den Brink, H. (2000). Overeducation in the labor
      market: a meta analysis. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19,
      Issue 2, p. 149-158.
Halaby, C.N. (1994). Overeducation and skill mismatch. Sociology of
      Education, Vol. 67, p. 47-59.
Hannan, D.F. et al. (1998). Trading qualifications for jobs: overeducation
      and the Irish youth labour market. Dublin: ESRI.
Hartog, J. (2000). Overeducation and earnings: where are we, where should
      we go? Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19, No 2, p. 131-148.
Hartog, J.; Oosterbeek, H. (1988). Education, allocation and earnings in
      the Netherlands: overschooling? Economics of Education Review,
      Vol. 7, No 2, p. 185-194.
78    The skill matching challenge




     Haskel, J.; Holt, R. (1999). Anticipating future skill needs: can it be done?
             Does it need to be done? Sudbury: DfEE (Skills task force research
             group, Research paper 1).
     Haskel, J.; Martin, C. (2001). Technology, wages and skill shortages: evi-
             dence from UK micro data. Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 53, No 4,
             p. 642-658.
     Haskel, J.; Martin, C. (1996). Skill shortages, productivity growth and
             wage inflation. In Booth, A.; Snower, D. (eds). Acquiring skills:
             market failures: their symptoms and policy responses. Cambridge:
             University Press, p. 147-174.
     Hersch, J. (1991). Education and job match. Review of Economics and
             Statistics, No 79, p. 140-144.
     Hersch, J. (1995). Optimal mismatch and promotions. Economic Inquiry,
             No 33, p. 611-624.
     Hogarth, T.; Wilson, R. (2001). Skills matter: a synthesis of research on the
             extent, causes and implications of skills deficiencies. Nottingham:
             Department for Education and Skills (DFES report SMSI).
     Jochman, M.; Pohlmeier, W. (2003). The causal effect of overqualification
             on earnings: evidence from a Bayesian approach. In Büchel, F. et al.
             Overeducation in Europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 93-108.
     Johansson, M.; Katz, K. (2007). Wage differences between women and
             men in Sweden: the impact of skill mismatch. Uppsala: IFAU –
             Institute for Labour Market Policy Evaluation (Working paper 2007-
             13).
     Jones, M.K. et al. (2009). Training, job satisfaction and workplace
             performance in Britain: evidence from WERS 2004. Labour, Vol. 23,
             No s1, p. 139-175.
     Jovanovic, B. (1979). Job matching and the theory of turnover. Journal of
             Political Economy, No 87, p. 972-990.
     Kaufman, H.G. (1974). Obsolescence and professional career development.
             New York: Amacom.
     Kaufman, H.G. (1975) (ed.). Career management: a guide to combating
             obsolescence. New York: IEEE Press/Wiley Interscience.
     Kaufman, H.G. (1989). Obsolescence of technical professionals: a measure
             and a model. Applied Psychology: an International Review, Vol. 38,
             No 1, p. 73-85.
     Kelly, E. et al. (2008). The economic returns to field of study and competencies
             among higher education graduates in Ireland. Dublin: ESRI – European
             Studies Research Institute (Working paper, No 242).
References   79




Kiker, B. et al. (1997). Overeducation and undereducation: evidence for
       Portugal. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 16, p. 111-125.
Kler, P. (2006). The impact of overeducation on job satisfaction among
       tertiary educated Australians. St. Lucia: University of Queensland
       (LERG – Labour Economics Research Group, Discussion paper,
       No 10).
Kucel, A.; Byrne, D. (2008). Are overeducated people insiders or outsiders?
       A case of job search methods and overeducation in the UK. Dublin:
       ESRI – European Studies Research Insitute (Working paper, No
       258).
Lindley, J. (2009). The over-education of UK immigrants and minority
       ethnic groups: evidence from the labour force survey. Economics of
       Education Review, No 28, p. 80-89.
Linsley, I. (2005). Overeducation in the Australian labour market: its
       incidence and effects. Victoria: University of Melbourne, Department
       of Economics Research Group (Discussion paper, No 939).
Mason, G.; Wilson, R. (2003). Employer skill survey: new analysis and
       lessons learned. London: NIESR – National Institute of Economic
       and Social Research.
Mavromaras, K. et al. (2009a). Assessing the incidence and wage effects
       of over-skilling in the Australian labour market. Economic Record,
       Vol. 85, No 268, p. 60-72.
Mavromaras, K. et al. (2009b). Overskilling dynamics and education
       pathways. Melbourne: Institute of Applied Economic and Social
       Research (Working paper, No 22/09).
Mavromaras, K. et al. (2009c). The incidence and wage effects of
       overskilling among employed VET graduates. Monograph prepared
       for the National Centre for Vocational Education Research, Adelaide,
       Australia.
Mavromaras, K. et al. (2009d). The problem of overskilling in Australia and
       Britain. Manchester School (forthcoming).
McGoldrick, K.M.; Robst, J. (1996). Gender differences in overeducation: a
       test of the theory of differential overqualification. American Economic
       Review, No 86, p. 280-284.
McGuinness, S. (2003a). Graduate overeducation as a sheepskin effect:
       evidence from Northern Ireland. Applied Economics, Vol. 35, No 5,
       p. 597-608.
McGuinness, S. (2003b). University quality and labour market outcomes.
       Applied Economics Vol. 35, Issue 18, p. 1943-1955.
80    The skill matching challenge




     McGuinness, S. (2006). Overeducation in the labour market. Journal of
            Economic Surveys, Vol. 20, No 3, p. 387-418.
     McGuinness, S.; Bennett, J. (2006). Examining the link between skill
            shortages, training composition and productivity levels in the
            Northern Ireland construction industry, International Journal of
            Human Resource Management, Vol. 17, No 2, p. 265-279.
     McGuinness, S.; Bonner, K. (2002). Employer characteristics and practices
            as drivers of unfilled IT vacancies. Service Industries Journal, Vol. 22,
            No 4, p. 137-153.
     McGuinness, S.; Doyle, J. (2003). Three years on: reassessing the Northern
            Ireland labour market for IT skills. Belfast: DEL – Department for
            Employment and Learning.
     McGuinness, S.; Doyle, J. (2005). An examination of the Northern Ireland
            labour market for construction skills. Belfast: DEL – Department for
            Employment and Learning.
     McGuinness, S.; Wooden, M. (2007). Overskilling, job insecurity and career
            mobility: evidence from Australia. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study
            of Labour (Discussion paper, 2938).
     Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, experience and earnings. New York: Columbia
            University Press.
     Neugart, M.; Schomann, K. (2002). Employment outlooks: why forecast
            the labour market and for whom? Berlin: WZB – Social Science
            Research Center Berlin (Discussion paper FS I 02-206).
     Neuman, S.; Weiss, A. (1995). On the effects of schooling vintage on
            experience – earnings profiles: theory and evidence. European
            Economic Review, Vol. 39, No 5, p. 943-955.
     Nicaise, I. (2000) The effect of bumping down on wages: an empirical
            test. In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The overeducated worker.
            Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 175-190.
     Nickell, S.; Nicolitsas, D. (1997). Human capital, investment and
            innovation: what are the connections? London: Centre for Economic
            Performance (Discussion paper, No 20).
     NIERC (2000) – Northern Ireland Economic Research Centre. A study of
            the Northern Ireland labour market for IT skills. Belfast: DHFETE
            – Department of Higher and Further Education Training and
            Employment.
     NIERC (2001) – Northern Ireland Economic Research Centre. A study of
            labour market conditions in the Northern Ireland electronics industry.
            Belfast: DEL – Department for Employment and Learning.
References   81




NIERC (2002) – Northern Ireland Economic Research Centre. A study of
       the Northern Ireland labour market for mechanical engineering skills.
       Belfast: DEL – Department for Employment and Learning.
Nordin, M. et al. (2008). Education-occupation mismatch: is there an income
       penalty? Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labour (Discussion
       paper, No 3806).
Ochsen, C. (2009). On the measurement of mismatch. Applied Economics
       Letters, No 16, p. 405-409.
Pazy, A. (1998). Concept and career-stage differentiation in obsolescence re-
       search. Journal of Organisational Behaviour, Vol. 17, No 1, p. 59-78.
Pazy, A. (2006). The threat of professional obsolescence: how do
       professionals at different career stages experience it and cope with
       it? Human Resource Management, Vol. 29, No 3, p. 251-269.
Pigou, A.C. (1912). Wealth and welfare. London: Macmillan.
Richardson, S. (2006). What is a skill shortage? Adelaide: National Institute
       of Labour Studies.
Robst, J. (1995). Career mobility, job match, and overeducation. Eastern
       Economic Journal, Vol. 21, No 4, p. 539-550.
Robst, J. (2008). Overeducation and college major: expanding the defini-
       tion of mismatch between schooling and jobs. Manchester School,
       Vol. 76, No 4, p. 349-368.
Rumberger, R. (1987). The impact of surplus education on productivity and
       earnings. Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 22, No 1, p. 24-50.
Sattinger, M. (1993). Assignment models of the distribution of earnings.
       Journal of Economic Literature, No 31, p. 831-880.
Schlotter, M. (2008). Origins and consequences of changes in labour/
       market skill needs. Analytical report for the European Commission.
       Munich: EENEE – European Expert Network on Economics of
       Education.
Sicherman, N. (1991). Overeducation in the labour market. Journal of
       Labor Economics, Vol. 9, No 2, p. 101-122.
Sicherman, N.; Galor, O. (1990). A theory of career mobility. Journal of
       Political Economy, Vol. 98, No 1, p. 169-192.
Skott, P. (2006). Wage inequality and over-education in a model with
       efficiency wages. Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 39, No 1,
       p. 94-123.
Sloane, P.J. (2003). Much ado about nothing? What does the overeducation
       literature really tell us? In Büchel, F. et al. (eds). Overeducation in
       Europe: current issues in theory and policy. Cheltenham: Edward
82    The skill matching challenge




            Elgar, p. 11-48.
     Sloane, P.J. et al. (1996). Overeducation and the formal education/
            experience and training trade-off. Applied Economics Letters, No 3,
            p. 511-515.
     Sloane, P.J. et al. (1999). Overeducation, undereducation and the British
            labour market. Applied Economics, No 31, p. 1437-1453.
     Stigler, G.J. (1961). The economics of information. Journal of Political
            Economy, No 69, p. 213-225.
     Tether, B. et al. (2005). A literature review on skills and innovation: how
            does successful innovation impact on the demand for skills and how
            do skills drive innovation? Manchester: ESRC – Centre for Research
            on Innovation and Competition.
     Thijssen, J.G.L. (2005). Niet meer up-to-date: de betekenis van (perspec-
            tivische) obsoletie nader verkend [No longer up-to-date: the mean-
            ing of (perspectivistic) obsolescence]. BBV-Bulletin, Vol. 12, No 1,
            p. 4-10.
     Thurow, L.C. (1975). Generating inequality. New York: Basic Books.
     Trimmer, K.J. et al. (1998). An evaluation of factors affecting professional
            obsolescence of information technology professionals. Proceedings
            of the 31st annual Hawaii international conference on system
            sciences. New York: IEEE, p. 406-415.
     Tsang, M.C. (1987). The impact of the underutilisation of education on
            productivity: a case study of the US Bell companies. Economics of
            Education Review, Vol. 6, No 3, p. 239-254.
     Tsang, M.C. et al. (1991). The impact of surplus schooling on worker
            productivity. Industrial Relations, Vol. 30, No 2, p. 209-228.
     Tsang, M.C.; Levin, H.M. (1985). The economics of overeducation.
            Economics of Education Review, Vol. 4, No 2, p. 93-104.
     Vahey, S. (2000) The great Canadian training robbery: evidence on the
            returns to educational mismatch. Economics of Education Review,
            Vol. 19, p. 219-227.
     Van Loo, J. et al. (2001). Skills obsolescence: causes and cures.
            International Journal of Manpower, Vol. 22, No 1/2, p. 121-137.
     Van Ours, J.C.; Ridder, G. (1995). Job matching and job competition:
            are lower educated workers at the back of job queues? European
            Economic Review, Vol. 39, No 9, p. 1717-1731.
     Verdugo, R.; Verdugo, N. (1989). The impact of surplus schooling on
            earnings. Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 24, No 4, p. 629-643.
     Verhaest, D.; Omey, E. (2006). Discriminating between alternative
References   83




     measures of overeducation. Applied Economics, Vol. 38, p. 2113-
     2120.
Weinberg, B.A. (2007). New technologies, skills obsolescence, and skill
     complementarity. In De Grip A. et al. (eds). The economics of skills
     obsolescence: theoretical innovations and empirical applications.
     Bingley: Emerald, p. 101-118 (Research in Labor Economics series,
     Vol. 21).
Weststar, J. (2009). Worker control as a facilitator in the match between
     education and jobs. British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 47,
     No 4, p. 723-740.
Skills matching challenge
The skill matching
challenge
Analysing skill mismatch
and policy implications


Luxembourg:
Publications Office of the European Union

2010 - 83 pp. - 17 x 24 cm
ISBN 978-92-896-0485-7
Cat. No: TI-31-10-301-EN-C
Free of charge - On request from Cedefop

No of publication: 3056 EN
Skills matching challenge
Skills matching challenge

More Related Content

PPTX
Skills Labour Mismatch
PPTX
Education Mismatch
PPTX
Keeping cars on the road
PDF
IRJET- TVET- Industry Linkage and Collaboration in Ethiopia: A Necessity ...
PPTX
Comsat kasumov pm
PDF
[Challenge:Future] Revalorisation of technical education and woking continuou...
PPT
Project individual employment paths
PDF
Journal of business initial document
Skills Labour Mismatch
Education Mismatch
Keeping cars on the road
IRJET- TVET- Industry Linkage and Collaboration in Ethiopia: A Necessity ...
Comsat kasumov pm
[Challenge:Future] Revalorisation of technical education and woking continuou...
Project individual employment paths
Journal of business initial document

What's hot (20)

PDF
Relationship between technical and vocational acquired skills and skills requ...
PPTX
Technical and Vocational Education and Training, 10th Global RCE Conference
PPTX
[Challenge:Future] Creating Human Capital
PPTX
TVET & Socio-Economic Development in Bangladesh Steps Challenges & Ways Forward
PPTX
Promoting skills for the future world of work
PDF
1883 file egelmaroc
DOC
CE-voc(guide)
PDF
giz2014-berufsbildung-beschaeftigung-kirgisistan-en
PDF
11.higher institution students’ access to information and communications tech...
DOC
Concept Note on SIS Nationwide Network (20082103)F
PDF
Industrial Attachment challenges: Lessons drawn from Gweru Polytechnic Colleg...
PDF
An appraisal of technical skills possessed by technical college auto mechanic...
PDF
Stemm disciplines in Entrepreneurship - Jordan
PDF
World Manufacturing Forum (WMF) Report 2019
PDF
financing-tvet-prc-en
PDF
ACostE Article July2015
PDF
Are graduates from the public authority for applied education and training in...
Relationship between technical and vocational acquired skills and skills requ...
Technical and Vocational Education and Training, 10th Global RCE Conference
[Challenge:Future] Creating Human Capital
TVET & Socio-Economic Development in Bangladesh Steps Challenges & Ways Forward
Promoting skills for the future world of work
1883 file egelmaroc
CE-voc(guide)
giz2014-berufsbildung-beschaeftigung-kirgisistan-en
11.higher institution students’ access to information and communications tech...
Concept Note on SIS Nationwide Network (20082103)F
Industrial Attachment challenges: Lessons drawn from Gweru Polytechnic Colleg...
An appraisal of technical skills possessed by technical college auto mechanic...
Stemm disciplines in Entrepreneurship - Jordan
World Manufacturing Forum (WMF) Report 2019
financing-tvet-prc-en
ACostE Article July2015
Are graduates from the public authority for applied education and training in...
Ad

Viewers also liked (20)

PDF
What the Current Labor Says about Job Skill Mismatch
PDF
New General Education Curriculum (NGEC)
PPT
Volt Employee Retention Presentation
PPTX
Causal link between Education, Poverty and Terrorism
PPTX
Guidance and counseling in the k 12 program
PPTX
Student unrest & indiscipline
PPTX
Career guidance
PPTX
Motivational choosing a career
PPTX
What is an Energetic Mismatch?
PPTX
GENERAL EDUCATION CURRICULUM
PPTX
Curriculum Approaches (Systems-managerial and Intellectual-academic Approach)
PDF
CHEd Memorandum Order No. 20 s2013 - General Education Curriculum
PPT
Employment and Unemployment
PPTX
Peer pressure presentation
PPTX
Employment and unemployment
PPTX
Guidance & Counseling for High School in the Philippines
PPTX
Unemployement
PPT
Student Project: Peer Pressure
PPT
Curriculum approaches
What the Current Labor Says about Job Skill Mismatch
New General Education Curriculum (NGEC)
Volt Employee Retention Presentation
Causal link between Education, Poverty and Terrorism
Guidance and counseling in the k 12 program
Student unrest & indiscipline
Career guidance
Motivational choosing a career
What is an Energetic Mismatch?
GENERAL EDUCATION CURRICULUM
Curriculum Approaches (Systems-managerial and Intellectual-academic Approach)
CHEd Memorandum Order No. 20 s2013 - General Education Curriculum
Employment and Unemployment
Peer pressure presentation
Employment and unemployment
Guidance & Counseling for High School in the Philippines
Unemployement
Student Project: Peer Pressure
Curriculum approaches
Ad

Similar to Skills matching challenge (20)

PDF
The Skill Matching Challenge - CEDEFOP
PDF
The skill mismatch challenge - CEDEFOP
PDF
Matching Skills to support career development
PPT
Tackling the skills mismatch through education and training
PPTX
An International Perspective: The Importance of Skills and Vocational Education
PDF
Skills supply and demand in Europe up to 2020
PDF
Defining Skills and Quantifying Skill Shortages: A Critical Assessment
PDF
New Skills For New Jobs
PPTX
Early Career Challenges of Educators review
PPTX
The OECD Skills Strategy: Better skills, better jobs, better lives - Joanne ...
PPTX
Skills January 2010
PDF
Paul MacFlynn, A low skills equilibrium in Northern Ireland
PDF
Eurokid builds up his future
PPT
reResearch and Understanding the need for evidenceResearch and Understanding ...
PDF
Skills forecast and skill mismatch in the EU
PPTX
Nordic PIAAC network 2013-2014 PIAAC data analyses in Estonia and links to s...
PPTX
Skills May 2013
PPT
Producing skills: challenges and current trends
The Skill Matching Challenge - CEDEFOP
The skill mismatch challenge - CEDEFOP
Matching Skills to support career development
Tackling the skills mismatch through education and training
An International Perspective: The Importance of Skills and Vocational Education
Skills supply and demand in Europe up to 2020
Defining Skills and Quantifying Skill Shortages: A Critical Assessment
New Skills For New Jobs
Early Career Challenges of Educators review
The OECD Skills Strategy: Better skills, better jobs, better lives - Joanne ...
Skills January 2010
Paul MacFlynn, A low skills equilibrium in Northern Ireland
Eurokid builds up his future
reResearch and Understanding the need for evidenceResearch and Understanding ...
Skills forecast and skill mismatch in the EU
Nordic PIAAC network 2013-2014 PIAAC data analyses in Estonia and links to s...
Skills May 2013
Producing skills: challenges and current trends

More from paulyeboah (19)

DOCX
Drs 255 project management skills
DOCX
Drs 255 skills in job matching and placement
PDF
Vocational training skills
PDF
Skills assessment
PDF
Glossary of terminologies for vocational evaluation
DOCX
Drs 255 skills in vocational assessment
DOCX
Drs 255 skills in vocational assessment
PDF
What does it mean to be enterprising
PDF
Uploads 178 entrepreneurship education-can business meet the challange
DOCX
ACCESSING FINANCIAL RESORCES
PDF
Participation & decision making
PDF
Manual human rights-disability-eng07
PDF
Magic+potion handout empowerment
PDF
Ilo working out of poverty
PDF
Ghana shared growth & development agenda
PDF
Ethical issues in resource allocation
PDF
A guide on how the common fund can be used for pw ds handouts
PDF
Resource allocation and empowerment practices
PDF
Drs 255 disability and livelihood notes on empowerment, etc
Drs 255 project management skills
Drs 255 skills in job matching and placement
Vocational training skills
Skills assessment
Glossary of terminologies for vocational evaluation
Drs 255 skills in vocational assessment
Drs 255 skills in vocational assessment
What does it mean to be enterprising
Uploads 178 entrepreneurship education-can business meet the challange
ACCESSING FINANCIAL RESORCES
Participation & decision making
Manual human rights-disability-eng07
Magic+potion handout empowerment
Ilo working out of poverty
Ghana shared growth & development agenda
Ethical issues in resource allocation
A guide on how the common fund can be used for pw ds handouts
Resource allocation and empowerment practices
Drs 255 disability and livelihood notes on empowerment, etc

Skills matching challenge

  • 3. The skill matching challenge Analysing skill mismatch and policy implications Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, 2010
  • 4. A great deal of additional information on the European Union is available on the Internet. It can be accessed through the Europa server (http://europa.eu). Cataloguing data can be found at the end of this publication. Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, 2010 ISBN 978-92-896-0485-7 © European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training, 2010 All rights reserved. Designed by Fotone - Greece Printed in the European Union
  • 5. The European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training (Cedefop) is the European Union’s reference centre for vocational education and training. We provide information on and analyses of vocational education and training systems, policies, research and practice. Cedefop was established in 1975 by Council Regulation (EEC) No 337/75. Europe 123, 570 01 Thessaloniki (Pylea), GREECE PO Box 22427, 551 02 Thessaloniki, GREECE Tel. +30 2310490111, Fax +30 2310490020 E-mail: info@cedefop.europa.eu www.cedefop.europa.eu Aviana Bulgarelli, Director Christian Lettmayr, Deputy Director Peter Kreiml, Chair of the Governing Board
  • 7. Foreword Cedefop analyses of skill needs and supply provide a core input to debates on future developments in European labour markets. Policy-makers increasingly recognise the added value of anticipating skill trends to support evidence- based policy-making. At the time of writing this report, Europe is battling a major recession. Matching skills and jobs is gaining importance with rising unemployment and increasing difficulties for people entering the labour market to find jobs matching their potential. At the same time, structural trends challenge Europe’s ability to provide the skills that its economies need to grow and prosper. The European population is ageing rapidly, leading to a large outflow of experienced workers in the coming decades while those nearing retirement will need to adapt to the new skills that many jobs require. The dynamics of today’s labour markets not only create new jobs while others shrink or disappear, but also contribute to changing skill requirements in many existing jobs. The analysis of skill mismatch is, therefore, a crucial pillar of Cedefop work on skills. Assessing mismatch and its effects involves much more than straightforward comparisons between skill needs and skill supply. Skill mismatch is a complex phenomenon affecting citizens, enterprises, economies and societies. It refers not only to skill gaps and shortages, but also to skills exceeding job requirements. The prominence of skill mismatch as a core challenge on many policy agendas, such as the new skills of jobs initiative, inspired Cedefop to explore and analyse skill mismatch systematically. After setting the priorities for future work on skill mismatch research in 2008 (Cedefop, 2009), this report is the first in a series bridging the worlds of research and practice, aiming to provide insights that enable evidence-based policy-making. The report gives a broad overview of skill mismatch and the factors that contribute; it analyses economic and social costs and discusses why mismatch should be a concern for national and European policy-makers. As cross-country information on skill mismatch is limited, the report also discusses how skill mismatch can be better approached and measured in surveys to give more detailed and sound analyses in the coming years.
  • 8. 2 The skill matching challenge I believe this report serves a clear need by structuring the currently scattered information on skill mismatch. Organising research findings to answer seven important questions, the report is a direct input to evidence-based policy- making. I am convinced this publication will add to the understanding of skill mismatch in Europe and help national and European policy-makers to make choices to aid matching skills and jobs in Europe. Aviana Bulgarelli Director of Cedefop
  • 9. Acknowledgements 3 Acknowledgements This report is the result of a team effort with contributions from those working on Cedefop’s skill mismatch research. In particular, Jasper van Loo, who supervised and edited the publication, Manfred Tessaring and Pascaline Descy. This report was prepared under contract number 2008-FWC11/ AO/RPA/PDE-GUTCH-JVLOO/VETBenefits-skillmismatch/007/08 Lot 7. It is largely based on the contributions of Nigel O’Leary and Peter Sloane (Welmerc, School of Business and Economics, Swansea University), Seamus McGuinness and Philip O’Connell (ESRI – Economic and Social Research Institute, Dublin) and Kostas Mavromaras (NILS – National Institute of Labour Studies, Flinders University, Adelaide, Australia). Thanks also go to Alena Zukersteinova and Torsten Dunkel from Cedefop for their valuable comments and suggestions.
  • 10. Table of contents Foreword 1 Acknowledgements 3 Executive summary 6 1. Why be concerned about skill mismatch? 9 1.1. Framing the issue and policy background 9 1.2. Glossary of terms 12 1.3. Aim and format of this report 14 2. What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe? 16 2.1. Vertical mismatch and impact on wages 16 2.2. Horizontal mismatch and impact on wages 21 2.3. What is the likely duration of skill mismatches? 22 2.3.1. Individual overeducation and overskilling 22 2.3.2. Overeducation and overskilling at firm level 23 2.3.3. Undereducation and underskilling in individuals/firms 24 2.3.4. Skill shortages 24 2.3.5. Skill gaps 25 2.3.6. Skills obsolescence 25 3. What causes skill mismatch? 27 3.1. Causes of overeducation 27 3.2. Underlying causes of skill shortages 32 3.3. Causes of skills obsolescence 32 3.4. Mismatch and individual characteristics 34 4. What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch? 36 4.1. Skill shortages, skill gaps, undereducation and underskilling 36 4.2. What is the relationship between overeducation, overskilling and skill shortages? 40 4.3. Combinations and durations of mismatch 43
  • 11. Table of contents 5 5. Business cycle impact on skill mismatch 46 5.1. Skill mismatch and business cycles 46 5.2. The impact of the economic crisis 47 5.3. Evidence from Australia 50 6. The implications of skill mismatch 51 6.1. Skill mismatch and productivity 51 6.1.1. Overeducation and productivity 52 6.1.2. Skill shortages and productivity 53 6.1.3. Skill gaps and productivity 53 6.2. Skill mismatch and job satisfaction 54 6.3. Possible positive impacts of skill mismatch 55 6.4. Skill mismatch costs for society 56 7. Appropriate skill mismatch measuring 59 7.1. Measuring overeducation and overskilling 59 7.2. Focusing on overskilling 62 7.3. Measuring skills obsolescence 64 8. Skill mismatch data needed in Europe 65 8.1. Improving data on skill mismatch in Europe 65 8.2. What information should be collected and how? 66 8.3. The way forward 68 Annex: comprehensive schemata for skill mismatch questions in surveys 69 References 72 List of tables 1. Glossary of terms 13 2. Reported incidence of overeducation 18 3. Types and causes of skills obsolescence 33 4. Combination of mismatch for firms 43 5. Data sets containing questions to individual employees on skill mismatch 60 Boxes 1. Theoretical approaches to overeducation 29 2. The Beveridge curve 39
  • 12. Executive summary With global competition increasing, demographic change unfolding and rapid technological change intensifying, skill mismatch has come to the forefront of Europe’s policy debate. Skill mismatch refers not only to skill shortages or gaps, but also to qualifications, knowledge and skills exceeding job requirements. Shortages in some sectors may occur simultaneously with overeducation in others. When skill mismatch takes time to resolve it imposes real costs on individuals, enterprises and societies. Given the relevance of matching skills and jobs and how information on mismatch is scattered, this report synthesises evidence and provides new insights to promote comprehensive policies that prevent and address skill mismatch and its consequences. An overview of the meaning and characteristics of different types of skill mismatch, such as overeducation and overqualification, are provided in the glossary of terms in Section 1.2. Skill mismatch is a widespread phenomenon in Europe, with overeducation incidence averaging around 30 % and a substantial share of the population undereducated. Whether skill mismatch is stable or increasing over time differs between countries. The overeducated suffer a wage penalty, but earn more than their matched colleagues, while the reverse applies to the undereducated. Mismatch between the type of skills someone has and the type of skills required is also prominent and has a negative impact on earnings. There is, however, some disagreement on the extent to which mismatch is a temporary or a long-term phenomenon, but both overeducation and overskilling may persist over long periods. The overeducated may be trapped in low-level jobs while the undereducated or underskilled are paid more than those with the same level of education in matching jobs and, therefore, have no incentive to move. The duration of skill shortages will be a function of their level and complexity, while the duration of skill gaps is linked to retraining. Skills obsolescence can occur over a relatively short number of years compared to a working lifetime, which means that lifelong learning is essential for successful careers. To understand the causes of mismatch, one needs to look at its various forms. A core reason explaining overeducation is the asymmetry of labour- market information. Better-informed individuals are better prepared to avoid overeducation than less-informed ones. Part of what is described in the
  • 13. Executive summary 7 literature as ‘overeducation’ reflects the differences in individual abilities and of skills within particular education categories. Light can be cast on this issue by considering the job satisfaction of workers in this state or the extent to which their skills are used. Several factors are responsible for skill shortages, such as insufficient training, education and training systems responding slowly to market changes, skill-biased technological progress and business cycles. Skill shortages also emerge when people accept a low-skilled job while continuing to search for a better match, for instance when options are limited for personal or family reasons. Skills obsolescence, which is a process rather than a state, occurs when skills depreciate due to ageing or lack of use at work; or when economic developments change the skills that firms need. Mismatch is more relevant for specific groups, such as young people entering the labour market, older workers, females, ethnic minorities and the disabled. Certain racial minorities suffer from mismatch to a greater degree than the majority population. Whether women suffer more than men is less clear. Older workers are likely to suffer most from skills obsolescence but little evidence links skills obsolescence to long-term problems. What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch? Overeducation and overskilling are expected to be negatively related to labour shortages. Whenever they coexist it is probably because skills or education are of the wrong type or because the two phenomena refer to different occupations in the same enterprise, industry or economy. It seems there is no strong correlation between the occurrence of skill shortages and skill gaps, but the latter may be closely linked to underskilling. Various types of mismatch can be present at the same time in firms but probably not simultaneously within specific occupations. Different phases of the business cycle result in different imbalances between labour demand and supply. These imbalances have profound implications on how skill mismatch arises and how it influences the economy. Studying the dynamics of skills creation and destruction is at the heart of understanding mismatch driven by the business cycle. Currently, there is insufficient empirical evidence to address the complex policy issues involved. In the present downturn, the following policy issues need to be addressed urgently: the role of training; the role of obsolescence; and how they may affect different parts of the economy, in particular vulnerable groups of people and vulnerable industries, such as those under intense international competition. Mismatched individuals may suffer from lower wages and are less satisfied with their jobs than if they were properly matched; employers may suffer from
  • 14. 8 The skill matching challenge lower productivity; and the economy may suffer from a loss of output. This is true for overeducation, overskilling and skill shortages. Both skill shortages and skill gaps might lead to a loss of competitiveness; this is supported by empirical evidence. Similar arguments apply to over/undereducation and over/underskilling; this is confirmed by studies of US firms. However, if skilled workers are hired anticipating future manpower requirements this could have a positive effect for firms and be favourable for society through increased innovation. How to measure skill mismatch is a core concern. Three alternative methods have been used: systematic job evaluation (objective measure), worker self-assessment (subjective measure) and empirical method (where data sets do not contain a direct question on the phenomenon). Each method has weaknesses. The report argues that over and underskilling may be superior measures to over and undereducation, especially if we are concerned with potential welfare losses. Skills obsolescence can be measured in several ways, but little consensus exists on which method is the most appropriate, while few data sets contain questions that can be used to assess skills obsolescence. Good data are probably the most crucial prerequisite to supporting timely, effective and evidence-based skill mismatch policies. The current shortcomings of data sets may take years to remedy. Ideally, new matched employer-employee panel data, with information on labour demand and supply, should be developed. Collecting these data is very expensive and several years of data are needed for full research potential. Individual or household data can be used instead, but with a comprehensive coverage of the various elements of mismatch, which is not currently the case. Remedying existing data sets is cheaper than developing new ones. An alternative cost- effective method for collecting Europe-wide data on mismatch could be a new module containing questions on mismatch, possibly introduced in several existing European large panel surveys at regular but infrequent intervals (such as once every three years). We support the view that alternative means of data collection should also be considered for issues that may be too detailed to be informed through conventional interviews.
  • 15. CHAPTER 1 Why be concerned about skill mismatch? Skill mismatch should be of concern to all citizens, but especially to policy- makers, employers’ associations and trade unions. Because of skill- biased technological change, its incidence will increase over time, though overeducation could have some positive effects. As Europe’s population is ageing rapidly, skills obsolescence is also likely to grow in importance. Matching skills and jobs is, therefore, crucial for Europe. It is unrealistic to assume that labour markets can work without temporary imbalances but skill mismatch that takes time to resolve or is even permanent implies real economic and social losses. Aiming to provide insights supporting evidence-based policy-making, this report considers all types of skill mismatch and their interrelationships, recognising that their measurement and interpretation is not always straightforward. The report focuses on seven research questions, on some of which relatively little is known. In this chapter, we examine why policy-makers and other stakeholders should be concerned about skill mismatch. Subsequently, we provide a glossary of terms and elaborate the aim and the set-up of this report. 1.1. Framing the issue and policy background Skill mismatch has come to the forefront of the policy debate in Europe, with global competition increasing, demographic change progressing and rapid technological change intensifying (European Commission, 2008a). Skill problems might arise, with shortages in some sectors combined with the problem of overeducation in others. Skilled people frequently working in elementary jobs is a pervasive international phenomenon. The challenge facing Europe is to provide businesses with the right skills to encourage innovation and growth, to address unemployment and to ensure that the potential of Europe’s citizens is fully utilised. As the European Commission Communication on new skills for new jobs (European Commission, 2008) observes, skill matching should be improved to confront rising unemployment. It is also suggested that the composition of skills emerging from both European Union universities and training systems needs to be better adapted to innovation-driven economies. Further, skill-
  • 16. 10 The skill matching challenge biased technological change results in a need for education upgrading as demand for more highly-educated workers increases at the expense of the less educated (1). The recent Cedefop report on Future skill needs in Europe (Cedefop, 2008) notes that out of a net employment increase of over 13 million jobs between 2006 and 2015 almost 12.5 million will be at the highest qualification level (ISCED 5 and 6). Skill mismatch is a crucial policy issue, not only for policy-makers but also for social partners including employers associations and trade unions. Reducing skill mismatch is likely to generate social benefits with higher job satisfaction for employees and possibly reduced stress from work, increasing health and wellbeing. At macro level, skill shortages and skill gaps can potentially lead to a loss of competitiveness as wage rates are bid up and productivity lowered within industries where skill problems exist. Productivity may also suffer if firms are forced to place lower-skilled workers in skilled positions and/or if where a skills shortage exists, workers use their position to alter their employment terms and conditions in a way that harms productivity. As the European Commission Communication on new skills for new jobs (European Commission (2008b) states, skills upgrading is important for Europe’s future growth potential and for employment equity, given the vulnerability of those lacking skills. It goes on to state that, due to imperfect information and structural rigidities, the lack of appropriate skills harms competitiveness, particularly for small enterprises. The communication suggests that skills upgrading is the most relevant solution to current and anticipated imbalances in the labour market. Skill-biased technological and organisational change has not only increased the demand for highly-skilled manpower but has also been encouraged itself by the availability of such manpower. An increasing pace of technological change is likely, however, to result in growing skill shortages and skill gaps if appropriate education and training is not provided. At the same time the routine tasks of the middle-skilled may be eliminated by new technologies (hollowing out). Mismatches are usually explained by a combination of information asymmetry between employers and employees, incomplete information in the labour market, differences between people, and transactions costs. (1) or a recent theory paper on the implications of on-the-job search in a matching model, which traces F out the effects on the composition of jobs, unemployment, wages and labour-market reactions to shifts in the supply of and demand for skills, see Dolado et al. (2009).
  • 17. CHAPTER 1 Why be concerned about skill mismatch? 11 Therefore, tackling mismatch by providing labour-market information and efficient job placement services should be a priority for policy-makers. This holds for both vertical and horizontal mismatch. Vertical mismatch, which is commonly referred to as overeducation, occurs when an individual is hired for a job advertised as requiring a lower level of education than the individual possesses, or alternatively, when an individual is employed in a job which requires a lower level of education. When overeducation is partly a consequence of lower ability at a given education level or choice of employment by the individual concerned, this does not, in itself, imply a particular role for policy. If overeducation is merely a temporary phenomenon, policy-makers should not be too concerned but, for many employees, overeducation lasts a long time. Yet, if employers hire the overeducated, anticipating a future need, their action may have positive rather than negative repercussions. Along these lines, for Schlotter (2008), overeducation can be a desirable feature of education and training systems and, following Sloane (2003), low- skilled workers may compensate for their lack of skill/ability by additional education to gain employment which they might otherwise not obtain. However, overskilling has negative effects on the wages earned by individuals experiencing it and on their job satisfaction. Greater care in job matching may, therefore, not only improve the welfare of overskilled employees, but also have positive effects on productivity and the growth in the economy. Finally, skills obsolescence is likely to grow in significance as the pace of economic and technological change intensifies and the labour force is ageing. Here there is a need for policies which encourage employers to retain older workers, as it is much more difficult to find new employment as workers age. Graduates sometimes face horizontal skill mismatch, when not the level, but the type of education or skills are inappropriate for the job. Those with specific degrees do better than those with more general degrees (arts and humanities). This suggests that better information should be provided for potential students to address and prevent mismatches of this type. A particular policy issue is whether genuine mismatch requires action from education providers or employers. For skill mismatch, whether horizontal or vertical, Weststar (2009) suggests that attention should be shifted away from education reform towards considering the impact of workplace and job design. This could be best achieved by giving workers greater task discretion on both social and technical control. The former includes taking part in decision-making, while the latter includes the ability to plan certain
  • 18. 12 The skill matching challenge aspects of the work and elements of choice in the way work is performed. Training needs of mismatched workers should also be considered. Data on skill mismatch in Europe shows that it is pervasive, but evidence is scattered and there is much confusion about what is meant by different aspects of skill mismatch. Poor understanding of skill mismatch implies poor understanding of interactions between types of skill imbalances, thereby preventing coordinated actions. Addressing skill mismatch problems is especially relevant for vulnerable groups on the labour market, such as migrants, older workers and young people transiting from school to work. 1.2. Glossary of terms Literature is not always clear on what is precisely meant by different types of skill mismatch. For example, it is often not straightforward to assess whether mismatch refers to qualitative or quantitative aspects and what is meant by occupational or education levels in a context where the notion of levels is blurring in many workplaces. Despite this, it is useful to have some initial understanding of various types of mismatch before examining more detailed issues. Therefore, Table 1 presents a glossary of terms. Although the definitions are based on a loose interpretation of literature and sometimes combine qualitative and quantitative dimensions of mismatch, they allow better understanding of different types and dimensions of mismatch. As an example, overeducation is defined in terms of years and overqualification in terms of credentials. While these terms are used interchangeably in literature and not all questions in various surveys allow a clear distinction between the two, they are not equivalent. In fact, Brynin and Longhi (2009), using data from the e-Living project showed that, while a qualification higher than required mostly generates a wage premium, time spent in education does not. The latter may involve repeating a year of study and reflects variations in ability, motivation or institutional arrangements which differ between countries.
  • 19. CHAPTER 1 Why be concerned about skill mismatch? 13 Table 1. Glossary of terms Overeducation A situation in which an individual has more education than the current job requires (measured in years). Undereducation A situation in which an individual has less education than the current job requires (measured in years). Overqualification A situation in which an individual has a higher qualification than the current job requires. Underqualification A situation in which an individual has a lower qualification than the current job requires. Overskilling A situation in which an individual is not able to fully utilise his or her skills and abilities in the current job. Underskilling A situation in which an individual lacks the skills and abilities necessary to perform on the current job to acceptable standards. Credentialism A situation in which the level of education required to obtain the job exceeds the level of education required to perform the job adequately. It relies upon a belief of the employer that the possession of certificates and diplomas implies higher productivity on the part of the individual. Real A situation in which an individual possesses more education than the current job requires and also in overeducation which current skills and abilities are underutilised. Formal A situation in which an individual possesses more education than the current job requires, but in which overeducation current skills and abilities are fully utilised. Genuine A situation in which an individual has more education than the current job requires and this state has a overeducation negative effect on the level of job satisfaction. Apparent A situation in which an individual has more education than the current job requires, but this does not overeducation adversely affect the level of job satisfaction. Skill shortage A situation in which the demand for a particular type of skill exceeds the supply of available people with that skill. Skill surplus A situation in which the supply of available people with a particular skill exceeds the demand for it. Skill gap A situation in which the level of skills of the currently employed is less than that required to perform the job adequately or the type of skill does not match the requirements of the job. Economic skills A situation in which skills previously utilised in a job are no longer required or have diminished in obsolescence importance. Physical Physical or mental skills and abilities deteriorate due to atrophy or wear and tear. (technical) obsolescence Vertical mismatch A situation in which the level of education or skills is less or more than the required level of education or skills. Horizontal A situation in which the level of education or skills matches job requirements, but the type of education or mismatch skills is inappropriate for the current job. Subjective meas- The mismatch estimate is obtained by self assessment in employee responses to a questionnaire. ures of mismatch Objective The mismatch estimate is obtained by evaluating job requirements. measures of mismatch The empirical T he mismatch estimate is derived from differences in the actual education of an individual within an mismatch method occupation relative to the mean or modal level of education of all people employed in that occupation (where there are no direct data on mismatch obtained from either of the above methods). Crowding out/ When better qualified workers are hired to do jobs that less qualified workers could also do, they are crowding bumping down out the less qualified workers from what would be their traditional employment possibilities for that level of skill. Bumping down refers to the fact that this process works from the top to the bottom and pushes the less qualified workers to even lower level jobs. At the extreme some lower level workers may lose employment altogether when crowding out occurs.
  • 20. 14 The skill matching challenge 1.3. Aim and format of this report Of all types of skill mismatch, the concept of overeducation has received most attention in literature. This concept was first introduced in 1976 by Richard Freeman in The overeducated American, an influential book based on US experience (Freeman, 1976). Since then literature on overeducation has grown substantially and points to the 30-40 % of the working population falling into this category and suffering from a substantial wage penalty compared to properly-matched workers. In most countries a smaller, though often substantial, number of workers are mismatched in the sense of being undereducated for their job. Interpretation of these phenomena is, however, far from straightforward. First, measurement issues arise from the diversity of information sources, such as the subjective responses to questions directed at employees, ‘objective’ estimates of the education requirements of jobs obtained by job analysis, or estimates derived by the empirical method from the spread of education qualifications within occupations. Second, the relationship between occupations and their education requirements may be imprecise. Thus, some jobs may merely specify a minimal education requirement, while education requirements may be rising over time as jobs become more complex. In recent years, a more limited strand of literature, encouraged by new data on the issue, has focused on both overskilling and underskilling (e.g. Allen and van der Velden, 2001; Green and McIntosh, 2007). This has raised questions about the relationship between overeducation and overskilling. There is also much older literature on skill shortages, i.e. insufficient numbers of suitably-qualified applicants to fill available posts, and the associated concept of skill gaps, i.e. when management judges that existing employees lack appropriate skills to maximise their contribution to output. Further, there is distinctive, but more limited, literature on the related question of skills obsolescence. Although there has been a lot of attention on different types of skill mismatch, little attempt has been made to synthesise and integrate these disparate strands in literature. By drawing together consistently the various strands of research literature on skill mismatch and by synthesising empirical evidence, this study provides new insights to promote comprehensive policies to prevent and address skill mismatch and its consequences.
  • 21. CHAPTER 1 Why be concerned about skill mismatch? 15 While conducting a literature survey, this study also reviews concepts, theories and empirical evidence on skill mismatch. To analyse and evaluate skill mismatch in a broad and comprehensive way, it focuses on the following research questions: (a) what do we know about skill mismatch in Europe? (b) what causes skill mismatch? (c) what are the links between the different types of skill mismatch? (d) what impact do business cycles have on skill mismatch? (e) what are the implications of skill mismatch? (f) what is the most appropriate method of measuring skill mismatch? (g) hat types of data are needed to assess and analyse skill mismatch w in Europe? As some of these questions have been relatively neglected in literature, any conclusions drawn must be tentative.
  • 22. CHAPTER 2 What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe? This chapter examines the pervasiveness of skill mismatch in Europe. Ideally, we would wish to know the extent of various types of mismatch and trends over time but, as comprehensive data on skill mismatch is limited, we focus instead on discussing the incidence of vertical and horizontal skill mismatch and their impact on wages. Though incidence varies substantially across countries, overeducation is found to be substantial across Europe with significant negative effects on earnings. The incidence of overskilling is lower, but higher for men than for women and increases with the level of education. In several countries, where evidence is available, horizontal mismatch is also substantial and impacts on earnings in a similar way. In Section 2.3, we review evidence on the duration and persistence of mismatch. The available information supports the hypothesis that much of it persists over the medium to the long term and may differ by level of education. Evidence on skills obsolescence suggests that many individuals, particularly the more educated in high-tech industries, may require substantial lifelong learning to remain productive. 2.1. Vertical mismatch and impact on wages One of the most recent surveys (McGuinness, 2006), summarised in Table 2, in line with Groot and Maassen van den Brink’s (2000) meta analysis, found that subjective measures of overeducation yield higher mean figures (29 %) than objective measures (22 %). This suggests that employees do not have, as some have argued, a clear tendency to exaggerate their own qualifications. The lowest incidence is recorded in the Netherlands and the highest in the US. For McGuinness (2006) it is reasonable to conclude that overeducation has remained relatively stable over time, although it is not always the case. Green and Zhu (2008) reported that in the UK overeducation increased for men from 21.7 % in 1992 to 33.2 % in 2006, while for women the comparable figures were 23.8 % and 32.1 %. However, they also split the overeducated into two groups – ‘real’ and ‘formal’ according to whether or not it is accompanied by underutilisation of skill. Real overqualification has been steady or rising only slowly.
  • 23. CHAPTER 2 What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe? 17 Gottschalk and Hansen (2003) classified occupations in the US as graduate and non-graduate on a different basis: whether 90 % or more of workers in that occupation were graduates or, failing that, there was a significant graduate pay premium of 10 % or more in that occupation. They found that the probability of a graduate being employed in a non-graduate job actually fell between 1983 and 1996, a result ‘which stands in stark contrast to those in previous studies’ (Gottschalk and Hansen, p. 450). Similar findings have been obtained by Cardoso (2007) for Portugal and by Grazier et al. (2008) for the UK. It is clear, therefore, that conventional data on the incidence of overeducation should be treated with caution. Ignoring the above distinctions about the precise nature of overeducation, Sicherman (1991) suggested that there were two stylised facts in relation to the effect of mismatch on pay. First, there is a pay penalty for overeducation, but the overeducated earn more than their matched colleagues. Second, the undereducated suffer a pay penalty relative to their matched colleagues but earn more than if they were properly matched. Later studies tend to confirm these results. Groot and Maassen van der Brink (2000) in their meta analysis summarised 25 studies as producing unweighted average rates of return of 5.6 % for attained years of education, 7.8 % for required years of education, 3 % for years of overeducation and -1.5 % for years of undereducation. There is, however, little or no information on how employers differentiate the pay of their employees in this way. Is it, for instance, based on some form of assessment of performance? There is evidence that wage benefits of overeducation decline with additional labour-market experience. This is consistent with ‘sheepskin effects’, whereby initial pay is determined by certification, but eventually workers are sorted into their most appropriate jobs on the basis of performance, so that qualifications become less significant over time. Chevalier (2003) found a pay penalty of 26 % for genuinely overeducated graduates, but only 7 % for those who were only apparently so. The wage penalties for overeducation appear to be greater than for overskilling, but this may reflect a failure to correct for unobserved differences between individuals in most studies. Wage effects may also vary by level of education or occupation. Mavromaras et al. (2009d) found that there were wage penalties associated with overskilling in both Australia and the UK, but these were larger for men than for women and increased with education level.
  • 24. 18 The skill matching challenge Table 2. eported incidence of overeducation R Name of study Year Definition employed Country Data collection Incidence of overeducation (%) Groot and Maassen 2000 Meta-analysis 26.2 (a) van den Brink Galasi 2008 Subjective job requirements 25 Countries 2004-06 33.00 Groot 1996 Objective standard deviation-based UK 1991 11.00 measure Alpin 1998 (1) bjective occupational O 1995 27.00 dictionary-based measure UK (2) bjective standard deviation O 1995 37.70 modal measure Sloane et al. 1999 Subjective – job requirements UK 1986-87 30.63 Green et al. 1999 (1) Subjective UK 1995 27.40 (2) Subjective UK 1997 32.00 Dolton and Vignoles 2000 Self assessment – subjective job UK 1986 30.00 requirement (1) Subjective – satisfaction UK 1996 40.40 (a) 1996 40.70 (a) Battu et al. 2000 (2) bjective occupational O UK 1996 21.75 (a) dictionary-based measure 1996 22.15 (a) (3) Subjective – degree requirements UK 1996 33.65 1996 38.00 (a) Dolton and Siles 2003 Subjective – not clear which one UK 1998 22.00 they used (1) bjective occupational O UK 1996 17.00 (a) dictionary-based measure Chevalier 2003 (2) Subjective – job requirement UK 1996 32.40 (a) (3) Subjective – satisfaction UK 1996 16.20 (a) Green and Zhu 2008 Subjective job requirements UK 1992 26.40 1997 26.50 2001 32.50 2006 37.30 Grazier et al. 2008 Occupational classification UK 1994 40.00 2004 30.00 Hannan et al. 1998 Objective standard deviation Ireland 1992 20.00 McGuinness 2003a Subjective – job requirements Northern 2000 20.00 Ireland McGuinness 2003b Subjective – job requirements Northern 1999 24.00 Ireland
  • 25. CHAPTER 2 What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe? 19 Name of study Year Definition employed Country Data collection Incidence of overeducation (%) Hartog and 1988 Subjective – required education Netherlands 1982 16.00 Oosterbeek objective 1960 7.00 1971 13.60 1977 25.70 Groot 1993 Objective standard deviation-based Netherlands 1983 16.10 measure Groot and Maassen 2000 (1) bjective standard deviation- O Netherlands 1994 11.85 (a) van den Brink based measure (2) bjective occupational O Netherlands 1994 15.90 (a) dictionary-based measure (3) Subjective Netherlands 1994 11.15 (a) Allen and van der 2001 Subjective – required education Netherlands 1998 14.00 Velden Dekker et al. 2002 Objective occupational dictionary- Netherlands 1992 30.60 based measure (1) bjective standard deviation O Portugal 1991 9.40 mean measure (2) bjective standard deviation O Portugal 1991 25.50 Kiker et al. 1997 modal measure (3) bjective occupational O Portugal 1991 33.10 dictionary-based measure 1986 5.00 Cardoso 2007 Occupational classification Portugal 1999 1.00 Alba-Ramirez 1993 Subjective – job requirements Spain 1985 17.00 Bauer 2002 Objective standard deviation-based Germany 1984-98 11.50 (a) measure Büchel and van Ham 2002 Subjective – job requirements Germany 1998 15.80 (a) Patrinos 1997 Objective standard deviation-based Greece 1977 16.00 measure Duncan and Hoffman 1981 Subjective – job requirements US 1976 42.00 Burris 1983 Objective occupational dictionary- US 1977 21.70 based measure 1969 35.00 Rumberger 1987 (1) Subjective – job requirements US 1973 27.00 1977 32.00 (2) bjective occupational O US 1973 57.00 dictionary-based measure Verdugo and 1989 Objective standard deviation-based US 1980 10.90 (b) Verdugo measure
  • 26. 20 The skill matching challenge Name of study Year Definition employed Country Data collection Incidence of overeducation (%) Sicherman 1991 Subjective – job requirements US 1976 and 1978 40.80 (1) Subjective – required education US 1969 35.00 1973 27.00 Tsang et al. 1991 1977 32.00 (2) bjective occupational O US 1973 57.00 dictionary-based measure (1) bjective standard deviation- O US 1985 13.00 based measure Cohn and Khan 1995 (2) ubjective measure – Sicherman S US 1985 33.00 definition Robst 1995 Subjective – required education US 1976, 1978 44.68 and 1985 Hersch 1995 Subjective – job requirements US 1991 21.00 (1) Subjective – job requirements US 1985 50.00 (a) McGoldrick 1996 (2) bjective occupational O US 1985 30.80 (a) and Robst dictionary-based measure (3) bjective standard deviation- O US 1985 12.55 (a) based measure Daly et al. 2000 Subjective – required education US 1976 37.75 (a) US 1985 32.65 (a) Germany 1984 17.50 (a) Gottschalk and 2003 Occupational classification US 1983 9.00 Hansen 1996 5.00 Vahey 2000 Subjective – required education Canada 1982 31.00 (a) 1986 35.00 (a) Cohn and Ng 2000 Objective modal measure Hong Kong 1991 34.00 (a) (a) Average, (b) Males only Source: Adapted from McGuinness (2006). There are also differences between countries. Galasi (2008) used the European Social Survey to analyse the effects of education mismatch across 25 countries. Overall, 33 % of workers were found to be overeducated, but this ranged from 15 % in the Netherlands to 79 % in Estonia; these data suggest a higher proportion of undereducated, with a mean of 59 %. Otherwise most of the empirical regularities found in earlier literature seem to hold.
  • 27. CHAPTER 2 What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe? 21 2.2. Horizontal mismatch and impact on wages We must also consider horizontal mismatch. Robst (2008) suggested the following four hypotheses in relation to this type of mismatch: hypothesis 1: the wage effects of overeducation are larger when workers are also mismatched the basis of type of degree and level of occupational requirements; hypothesis 2: among workers mismatched on the basis of level and type of education, the wage effect depends on the transferability of skills between type of degree and occupation; hypothesis 3: individuals who face discrimination (such as coloured people, the disabled and single women) or who have lower ability are more likely to be mismatched due to demand-related reasons. Supply-related mismatches are more likely among married men and women than among single men and women; hypothesis 4: the wage effects of mismatch are likely to be larger when workers have accepted a job due to demand-side reasons (i.e. genuine mismatch) compared to supply-side reasons (i.e. apparent mismatch). Robst finds that overeducated men, whose work and field of study are related, earn 2.4 % less than well matched men. However, if the job is only somewhat related the penalty rises to 7.1 % and to 21.6 % if it is completely unrelated. For women the corresponding figures are 3.6 %, 5.3 % and 19.1 %. The income penalty for horizontal mismatches appears to exceed that for vertical mismatches. Further, while most workers report supply-side reasons as the main reason for being in a particular job, it also appears that wage effects are large where workers are mismatched for demand-side reasons. A Swedish study (Nordin et al., 2008) found that being horizontally mismatched was associated with 38 % lower income for men and 26 % for women. An Irish study (Kelly et al., 2008) found, in contrast, a much smaller pay penalty of around 5 % for those who were mismatched by field, though this varied by field of study. In this case the vertical mismatch penalty (14.4 %) exceeded the horizontal.
  • 28. 22 The skill matching challenge 2.3. What is the likely duration of skill mismatches? The extent to which a particular form of mismatch persists over time determines the costs to the individual, firm or economy. While evidence on persistence of overeducation is rich, it is limited to insights based on cross- sectional data. Meaningful tests for mismatch persistence require longitudinal data on individuals and jobs over a longer period of time. Evidence on the persistence of other forms of mismatch is scarce, but some conclusions can be drawn. 2.3.1. Individual overeducation and overskilling There has been considerable debate on whether individual overeducation will persist over time. Sicherman (1991) found a positive and significant relationship between job mobility and overeducation which was taken as evidence of non-persistence. However, later research produced more mixed results. Some studies have reported evidence of higher rates of job mobility (e.g., Alba-Ramirez, 1993; Sloane et al. 1999; Alba-Ramirez and Blázquez, 2003), higher rates of promotion within firms (Hersch, 1995; Dekker et al. 2002; Alba-Ramirez and Blázquez 2003; Groeneveld and Hartog, 2004), or greater levels of quit intention (Hersch, 1995; Robst, 1995) among the overeducated. Sloane et al. (1999) also reported that, while overeducated workers were more likely to have short job tenure with their current employer, they were also more likely to experience involuntary job separations and to exit from employment into unemployment. Further, for McGuinness and Wooden (2007) increased job mobility cannot be taken as evidence of falling overeducation given that workers are most likely to move from one overeducated job to another. The most convincing evidence to support the view that overeducation can be a long lasting phenomenon comes from studies of graduate labour markets, but these studies are typically based on cross-sectional data or short time-series. Dolton and Vignoles (2000) found that 38 % of a large sample of UK graduates in 1980 was overeducated in their first job; six years later this proportion still stood at 30 %. Similarly, McGuinness (2003c) reported that among a sample of graduates in Northern Ireland, 31 % indicated that a university degree was not a requirement for their first job, and after two to four years this proportion was still at 24 %. Finally, Frenette (2004) reported on longitudinal data for Canadian graduates, which showed little evidence
  • 29. CHAPTER 2 What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe? 23 of any decline in the incidence of overeducation over a three-year window (between two and five years after graduation). Research on overskilling persistence is much more limited as panel data on overskilling in Europe are lacking. McGuinness and Wooden (2007) examined durations using the first four waves of the household income and labour dynamics for Australia (HILDA) panel. The study concludes that overskilling tends to be a non-transitory phenomenon with less than 25 % of employees who were severely overskilled in wave 1 likely to be matched three years later. The study also found that, as for overeducation, increased job mobility cannot be evidence of reduced overskilling. Mavromaras et al. (2009b) using HILDA found that overskilling varies by education level: it is rare among university graduates, but highly persistent; it is low but significant among school leavers from general education; and none at all is found among vocational education and training graduates. Graduate studies focusing on overeducation and overskilling are typically based on short time-series. This hampers the ability to examine whether overeducation in the early stages of a career are reversible later on, when people acquire more training or experience. Also, these studies only provide a partial picture of mismatch persistence, as they focus on the transition from school to work. Far less attention is on transition from unemployment to work, mainly because suitable data is lacking, but also due to insufficient analysis of the incentives and preferences, decisive factors in people’s education and occupation choices. Many research questions remain open, but we can tentatively conclude that overeducation and overskilling are non-transitory phenomena. 2.3.2. Overeducation and overskilling at firm level Although overeducation and overskilling can be a long lasting phenomenon for individuals, it does not mean firms retain overeducated or overskilled workers for long periods. High rates of voluntary and involuntary separations among the overeducated and overskilled (2) suggest that their average job tenure is likely to be some fraction of their total mismatch duration. However, the fact that the overeducated earn a premium relative to matched colleagues, coupled with the finding that the probability of involuntary separation tends to be much lower than the probability of voluntary separation (3), suggests that employers hiring overeducated and overskilled workers have some (2) Sloane et al., 1999; McGuinness, 2003; McGuinness and Wooden, 2007. (3) McGuinness and Wooden, 2007.
  • 30. 24 The skill matching challenge productivity advantage. This is confirmed by Jones et al. (2009) using British workplace employment relations survey (WERS) data to demonstrate higher productivity in firms employing overeducated workers. However, the consistent finding that the overeducated and overskilled have lower job satisfaction (4) also indicates that retaining such workers may not be in the firm’s long-term interest. Therefore, the extent to which firms retain overskilled or overeducated workers will depend on the magnitude of any short-term benefit relative to the long-term cost. From an economy point of view, demand for skills and educated labour rising over time should reduce the incidence of overskilling and overeducation, provided that the surplus are in areas of demand within the economy and that workers are mobile. 2.3.3. Undereducation and underskilling in individuals/firms Generally, the undereducated have no incentive to become matched, as they earn a premium relative to matched colleagues with similar education levels (5). Little research exists to date for the underskilled, so for now we will assume that their situation reflects that of the undereducated. Accepting that earnings reflect workers’ marginal products, the finding that the undereducated are paid less than matched individuals in the same job who are matched (6) suggests that firms employing undereducated workers may have some productivity penalty. The extent to which a firm will continue to hire undereducated workers will vary according to the underlying causes of the undereducation itself. If undereducation relates to an inability to hire suitably qualified workers, i.e. a skill shortage, then the duration of undereducation within the firm will be highly correlated with the persistence of the skill shortage within the economy generally. 2.3.4. Skill shortages Duration of skill shortages depends on the level at which the problem is assessed. For firms, the shortage will persist as long as the vacancy remains unfilled or until the firm adopts an alternative strategy for dealing with the problem. Duration will be longer the more complex and skilled the unfilled vacancy so duration should vary across occupations and sectors. For the economy more generally, duration of skill shortages will depend on the time elapsing before it is communicated through the market mechanism and the period required to induce and train individuals in the specific skill area. (4) Battu et al., 1999; Fleming and Kler, 2007. (5) Kiker et al., 1997; Sloane et al., 1999. (6) Kiker et al., 1997.
  • 31. CHAPTER 2 What do we know about skill mismatch in Europe? 25 2.3.5. Skill gaps Given that skill gaps relate to the firms’ current employees and that they are specific to the firm’s requirements, dealing with skill gaps largely remains the responsibility of firms. Generally, skill gaps can only be eradicated through firm-sponsored training or by providing individuals with relevant incentives to participate in upskilling. Duration depends on the period necessary to retrain individuals in the relevant skill areas, as for skill shortages, and on costs involved. Given the difficulties and costs associated with equipping workers with basic and advanced skills, durations are likely to be shorter for skill gaps related to intermediate skills. However, when skill gaps arise as a result of firms adopting a second best strategy in the face of skill shortage, duration will again be related to the duration of skill shortage. 2.3.6. Skills obsolescence Here we are interested in how long on average it takes for a worker’s skill to become obsolete. In an early study, Bosworth (1978) noted that little was known about the obsolescence of technical knowledge. However, using a restrictive definition – the time when a particular technology was no longer embodied in goods currently being sold – he was able to use patent renewal data to measure obsolescence. Evidence pointed to annual rates of decay of well over 10 % in the post-war period. Neuman and Weiss (1995) showed that obsolescence was more evident in high-tech than low-tech industries and greater for more educated workers. Allen and van der Velden (2007), using a Dutch survey, reported that 30 % of skills in their sample had become obsolete with a half-life for competences in the range of 10 to 15 years. This implies that many individuals would have to renew their competences regularly over their career, giving justification for lifelong learning. In the 1970s several studies examined the rate of obsolescence among engineers. Notably, Kaufman (1974; 1975) pointed out that the introduction of computer technology was critical and ironically threatened most those introducing it: engineers, computer scientists and other technical professionals. He defined obsolescence as ‘the degree to which organisational professionals lack the up-to-date knowledge of skills necessary to maintain effective performance in either their current or future work roles’ (Kaufman, 1974 p. 23). He developed an open systems approach (Kaufman, 1989) to analyse obsolescence, based on extensive questionnaires sent to technical professionals in a single organisation. The approach considered four elements: environmental change (e.g. rapid changes in technology); organisational climate (determined largely by managerial policies and practices); the nature
  • 32. 26 The skill matching challenge of work (in terms of job assignments); and individual characteristics such as the cognitive and personality factors related to keeping up-to-date. The last of these is important in determining how individuals cope with rapid technological change (Trimmer et al., 1998; Pazy, 1998; 2006). The US National Academy of Sciences concluded in 1985 that engineers could work productively over a longer period if they had access to effective continuing education regardless of the state of the business cycle. This required interdisciplinary approaches and non-technical skills that are not imparted by the formal training of engineers.
  • 33. CHAPTER 3 What causes skill mismatch? This chapter analyses the causes of different types of skill mismatch. Based on evidence, we discuss the causes of overeducation, skill shortages and skills obsolescence, and reflect on the role of individual characteristics. Overeducation can result from the asymmetric nature of the supply of labour-market information. However, literature has devoted little attention to explaining overeducation by considering the decision processes of firms and individuals. A key issue is whether perceived mismatches represent labour market sorting on the basis of the lower ability of the individuals concerned; it is perhaps necessary to disaggregate overeducation according to the level of job satisfaction or use of skills of overeducated workers. Insufficient training, markets reacting slowly to changes, skill-biased technological progress and business cycles are core factors explaining skill shortages. When skills depreciate due to ageing or when economic developments change the skills that firms need, this process is referred to as skills obsolescence. Young people entering the labour market, older workers, females, ethnic minorities and the disabled are disproportionately affected by skill mismatch. 3.1. Causes of overeducation Education type and level may influence the likelihood of mismatch on entering employment. As Stigler (1961) observed, the higher the level of education the better defined the set of jobs a worker can obtain and the better the information individuals have about the nature of the labour market. Further, individuals in narrower fields of study (such as law or medicine) are likely to have a better defined set of job alternatives than those in more broadly defined ones (such as arts and humanities). Thus, Kucel and Byrne (2008) suggested that those from broader educational backgrounds are likely to be less well informed about labour-market opportunities. Using the 2003-05 British labour force survey, which contains information on type of degree and the nature of the job finding process, they found that graduates in hard disciplines are significantly less likely to apply for a job through a private employment agency, by relying on an advertisement or by a method other
  • 34. 28 The skill matching challenge than through personal contacts relative to those from broader educational backgrounds. Thus, overeducation can result from the asymmetric nature of the supply of labour-market information. Büchel (in Cedefop; Büchel, 2001) advocated regarding overqualification as a result of a decision-making process by both employers and employees. For employees, the choice between unemployment and work, or different types of jobs, precedes overeducation. Employer decisions may involve dealing with problems in recruiting workers with the right skills. Very few studies have focused on the decision-making processes of both firms and individuals to explain the occurrence and persistence of overeducation. Research on the role of employers in hiring mismatched workers is also rare, although this is a possible strategy for fluctuating demand for skilled employees and rising demand for skilled manpower. Sloane et al. (1996) also pointed out that undereducated workers compensated for lack of qualifications by having more experience, tenure and training (the substitutability hypothesis), so one cannot necessarily infer that mismatch is wasteful. In their matching model for UK graduates, Battu et al. (1999) included variables capturing the nature of the job (e.g. occupations, sector of work and size of firm). Unsurprisingly, higher occupations increase the likelihood of matching, with individuals in the education sector and private practice more likely to be matched and size of firm being positively and strongly related to the probability of a match. A key issue is to what extent perceived mismatches represent labour- market sorting on the basis of varying quality of labour within education levels. This is particularly so as the number of graduates has increased substantially in many countries. If less able individuals have entered the pool of graduates, quality may have fallen over time which may increase the incidence of overeducation. For example, Battu et al. (1999) controlled for the degree class and institution type in the UK, finding that the class of degree has a significant effect on graduate earnings, with a first class degree having a 8-13 % premium over a lower-second class one, and graduates from more established universities earning 8-11 % more than graduates from former polytechnics, holding constant a measure of overeducation. Dolton and Vignoles (2000) and Green and Zhu (2008) also found that those with better degree classifications and those from more established universities are less likely to be overeducated. There may also be cohort effects if individuals qualify for entry into the labour market in periods when there is an excess supply of qualified applicants. This will happen because it takes some time for workers to accept a lower-skilled job and then continue searching for a more complex one
  • 35. CHAPTER 3 What causes skill mismatch? 29 which pays more (Gautier, 2000). This may be reinforced when the individual faces short-term constraints on the search process through personal, family, location or other reasons. As Dolton and Silles (2003) also suggested, the process of finding a suitable job may take some time, so we would expect in this case, and in contrast to what was stated earlier, that overeducation is a temporary phenomenon. Most studies of skill mismatch, however, focus on the state of mismatch rather than on the process of becoming mismatched; available data does not allow for analyses that follow the same individuals in their employment careers, which makes a valid assessment of persistence difficult. Most data sets do not contain the data necessary to correct for individual heterogeneity. One exception is the British national child development study. Using this data set, Green et al. (1999) found that individuals who scored higher on a maths test administered at age 16 were significantly less likely to be overeducated later in their working lives, and this effect was substantial. Their analysis of the International adult literacy survey (IALS) also suggested that individuals who lacked good quantitative skills were more likely to be overeducated. Büchel and Pollmann-Schult (2001) found that in Germany a poor grade in the school leaving certificate had a strong effect on the later risk of overeducation for graduates with a vocational degree and after controlling for selectivity effects. Box 1. Theoretical approaches to overeducation There is no generally-accepted theory of overeducation (McGuinness, 2006), but it is possible to consider how the phenomenon relates to various models of the labour market as illustrated in the table below. The standard Becker/Mincer human capital model suggests in its simplest form that wages are determined by endowments of human capital and particularly years of education and experience. There is no role for demand side factors, where more years of education imply higher earnings, and no distinction is made between actual and required years of education. Thus, any year of education is just as valuable as another. In contrast, in the Thurow job competition model, marginal productivity resides in the job rather than the worker, and in the extreme, education simply serves to place the individual at the front of the queue for jobs, as it signals that the employer will be required to invest less in training. Hence, the return on overeducation is zero, as all workers in a given job are paid the same. In contrast, the Sattinger job assignment model (Sattinger, 1993) considers both supply and demand to be important determinants of wages, as there is an allocation problem in assigning heterogeneous workers to heterogeneous jobs. At any time it is unlikely that there will be a perfect match and overeducation can be a persistent problem. Earnings will be a function of both worker and job characteristics and this model can encompass the human capital and job competition models in a more general equation which is sometimes referred to as the Duncan and Hoffman model (1981) or in other cases as the ORU model.
  • 36. 30 The skill matching challenge log Wt= β0 + β1qr+ β2qs β3qu+ε In this model, actual educational qualifications (q) of individuals are decomposed into the required or normally accepted level (qr), surplus or more than required qs), and deficit or less than required (qu), qualifications in relation to those necessary to do the job. The human capital specification implies that β1=β2=β3 and the job competition model that β2=β3=0. Tests of these models, using an F test on the residual sum of squares, tend to suggest that generally the job assignment model outperforms the other two. The theory of career mobility associated with Sicherman and Galor (1990) suggests that individuals may be prepared to accept jobs with low returns on education provided that this is accompanied by a higher probability of promotion. In this context overeducation is a purely temporary phenomenon and additional returns on education will be obtained later. Finally, Frank’s theory of differential overqualification (1978) is based on the proposition that, for married couples, the search for a pair of jobs will be constrained geographically and only infrequently will the best job offer for both spouses occur in the same location. If the husband’s job choice dominates because of the wife’s responsibilities for children, married women will face the greater constraints, whether as tied stayers or tied movers and we expect married women to experience greater overeducation than either married men or single men or women. Theory Main proponent(s) Main determinants of wage Predictions of overeducation (overskiling) Human Becker (1964), Supply (personal Return on years of capital Mincer (1974) characteristics) overeducation = return model on years of required education Job Thurow (1975) Demand (job queues) Return on overeducation competition is zero model Assignment Sattinger (1993) Supply and demand Return on years of model overeducation return on required education Career Sicherman and Galor Training costs are general • n the short-run i mobility (1990) and paid for by the return on years of theory individual overeducation return on required education • n the long-run i return on years of overeducation return on years of required education Theory of Frank (1978) Gender and family status Return on years of differential overeducation return overqualifi- on required education cation
  • 37. CHAPTER 3 What causes skill mismatch? 31 Where data sets lack the appropriate variables, indirect methods are necessary. Thus, Chevalier (2003) distinguished between apparently and genuinely overeducated graduates in the UK based on their answers to questions on job satisfaction. Graduates in graduate jobs are defined as ‘matched’, whatever their level of satisfaction. Those satisfied but in non- appropriate (or non-traditional graduate) jobs are described as ‘apparently overeducated’ and those in non-graduate jobs and dissatisfied as ‘genuinely overeducated’. A similar approach was adopted by Allen and van der Velden (2001), who used a 1991 Dutch data set which allowed job levels to vary for given education qualifications. They distinguished between a formal education mismatch and a skill mismatch based on two key questions: whether the current job offered sufficient scope to use acquired knowledge and skills (utilisation); and whether they would perform better in their current job if additional knowledge and skills had been acquired (skill deficit). While about 15 % of their sample experienced underutilisation, a much higher proportion experienced skills deficits and the latter was only weakly related to education mismatches. These results cast doubt on one of the key assumptions of assignment theory, namely that education mismatches imply skill mismatches. One interpretation is that overeducation in part masks unmeasured ability differences and is, therefore, spurious. Taking these results together, it seems clear that a substantial part of what is described in literature as overeducation merely reflects the heterogeneity of individual abilities and of skills within particular education categories. Far from implying inefficient allocation of labour, this suggests that the labour market is functioning effectively in allocating workers to jobs which match their skills and abilities (Sloane, 2003). Brunello et al. (2007) argued that employment protection legislation might increase the extent of skill mismatch by making it harder for individuals to obtain their first job and more difficult for firms to reduce staff because of restrictions on firing. Using the European Community household panel 1994-2001 they found a positive association between skill mismatch and employment protection legislation. Their regression analysis for the five largest countries suggests that men are more likely to be mismatched than women (7), that overqualification increases with years of education (apart from Germany), and declines with increased labour experience, which, in contrast to evidence cited earlier, suggests that overqualification is a temporary (7) his is in contrast to other findings reported elsewhere. T
  • 38. 32 The skill matching challenge phenomenon. There are also important differences between countries, with the suggestion that for Germany and the UK some workers may choose to become overqualified to avoid unemployment. Adopting a fourfold classification of mismatch in terms of combinations of overeducation, overskilling and matching, it appears that skill mismatch rather than overqualification causes pay penalties. 3.2. Underlying causes of skill shortages Skill shortages can be caused by underinvestment in training. The idea of market underprovision of skills can be traced back to Pigou in 1912 (cited by Haskel and Holt, 1999) who argued that the additional transferable skills associated with training will raise the probability that a worker will be poached, thus reducing the likelihood that training will take place. Individuals may underinvest due to perceived high training costs, coupled with uncertain returns (Booth and Snower, 1996). Information gaps or inadequately structured education provision may also lead to incorrect investments on the part of students, while insufficient labour-market mobility can also lead to imbalances (Neugart and Schomann, 2002). Institutional factors may also prevent the labour market from clearing; for instance, centralised wage bargaining systems may be unable to consider sectoral or regionally-based changes in demand. A sluggish supply-side may also contribute to the problem. For instance, Haskel and Martin (2001) argued that skill shortages in the UK have arisen primarily as a consequence of education supply failing to keep pace with skill-biased technical progress. Finally, the incidence of skill shortages will vary according to the economy’s position in the business cycle. Specifically, skill shortages tend to have a strong negative correlation with the claimant count (Frogner, 2002). Hogarth and Wilson (2001) go so far as to suggest that skill shortages are actually a significant driver of the business cycle itself, placing a productivity constraint on the economy which in turn leads to a downturn in activity. Further, the factors listed above may also act as drivers for undereducation and underskilling. 3.3. Causes of skills obsolescence Skills obsolescence, which may lead to skill gaps, is a process rather than a state. De Grip and van Loo (2007) distinguished between physical (technical) and economic skills obsolescence as outlined in Table 3. Technical skills
  • 39. CHAPTER 3 What causes skill mismatch? 33 obsolescence results from depreciation of manual skills or physical strength through ageing, while economic obsolescence occurs as a result of changes in production technology which alter the optimal input mix for firms. If there are new skill requirements as a result of changes in production, this may have a major impact on job specific skills. If employment declines across an industry or occupation, this is referred to as sectoral skills obsolescence. If firm reorganisation or closures occur more job losses may result in firm specific skills obsolescence. Physical (technical) obsolescence and job loss combined may result in organisational knowledge loss. Thijssen (2005) has identified a third type of skills obsolescence: perspectivistic obsolescence. This refers to outdated views and beliefs on work and the work environment. Skills obsolescence can manifest itself through unemployment, crowding out to lower-skilled jobs, lower wages or through problems in performing the job properly. As workers become more educated and skill biased technological change remains important, while at the same time the workforce is ageing, skills obsolescence is likely to become even more significant. Table 3. Types and causes of skills obsolescence Types Forms of human capital depreciation Physical (technical) obsolescence Wear and tear • eterioration of mental and physical capacities through d ageing, illness or injury • decreasing capacity to learn and adapt to new situations Atrophy Insufficient use of skills as a result of overeducation, increased specialisation or unemployment Economic skills obsolescence Job specific skills New skill requirements due to changes in production obsolescence Sectoral skills obsolescence Employment declines either by industry or occupation Firm-specific skills Voluntary or involuntary quits resulting from firm reorganisation obsolescence or closure Organisational knowledge loss Combining wear and tear of skills of individual workers or quitting by workers with firm specific skills Perspectivistic obsolescence Outdated views or beliefs concerning the nature of work and the work environment Source: Adapted from de Grip et al., 2007.
  • 40. 34 The skill matching challenge Weinberg (2007) showed that skills obsolescence arises in two ways. First, the diffusion of new technology may increase the obsolescence of existing skills. Second, experienced workers who have accumulated greater stocks of skills relevant to the old technology lose more human capital when switching to new tasks. Contrary to expectations, skills obsolescence occurs not only in strongly field-specific and technical fields of study, but also in more generic and non-technical fields (Allen and van der Velden, 2007). The traditional vintage human capital model emphasises the imperfect transferability of human capital across technologies, implying that younger workers will be the primary adopters of new technology. New technologies may also complement existing skills and there is some evidence that this applies in particular to more educated men with substantial (30-40 years) experience. 3.4. Mismatch and individual characteristics Are there particular personal characteristics which make certain individuals more prone to mismatch than others? Particular groups may be more subject to discrimination in the labour market – young workers, older workers, females, ethnic minorities and the disabled – and this feature may also manifest itself in labour-market mismatch. Young workers are likely to be particularly prone to skill mismatch as new entrants into the labour market, and the finding that overeducation is linked to a lack of work experience supports this hypothesis. One Dutch study by Dekker et al. (2002), for example, found that the proportion of overeducated decreased from 41.7 % for the 15-19 age group, to 27 % for the 30-44 age group and 18 % for the 49-64 age group. Many other studies report similar results. Older workers may suffer from mismatch as a consequence of skills obsolescence, which is more likely in industries subject to rapid technological change or in decline through shifting patterns of demand. In an early US study, Frank (1978) examined the link between gender and overqualification. He suggested that, in a dual earner household, there would be greater constraints on married women than married men on account of child-rearing causing intermittent labour-force participation on the part of the wife. Married women would tend to be tied stayers or tied movers, thus limiting their ability to obtain optimal matches in the labour market. However,
  • 41. CHAPTER 3 What causes skill mismatch? 35 McGoldrick and Robst (1996), who attempted to test whether married women in small local labour markets were more prone to overqualification than those in larger labour markets, could find no evidence to support this proposition. Büchel and Battu (2003) extended this analysis using German data by making allowance for commuting distances between home and work and found that longer commuting distances tended to reduce the likelihood of overqualification, though not differentially between men and women. An alternative reason why one might expect gender differences in mismatch is the presence of fixed costs of employment together with higher quit rates for women than men. This may lead employers to require higher ability from women relative to men when hiring for particular jobs. Thus, van Ours and Ridder (1995) found that women in their Dutch data set required almost six months more work experience than men to be hired for the same job, implying that they were overqualified in this sense. Yet, overall there is mixed evidence of skill mismatch being a more serious problem for women than for men across countries, with counter examples. Why there are such differences between countries seems to be an important issue for further research. Studies of skill mismatch across ethnic minorities are limited in number. Battu and Sloane (2004) used the Fourth national survey of ethnic minorities 1993/94 to investigate whether overeducation was greater for ethnic minorities in Britain than for the white majority using a modal measure of required education across 60 occupations. They found that overeducation was higher for non-whites than for whites, while undereducation was lower for non- whites, but within the non-white population the African Asian group was more likely to be overeducated than Indians. The consequences of labour- market mismatch in terms of the wage penalty were more severe than for the indigenous white population. Lindley (2009) examined the extent of overeducation among UK immigrants using labour force survey data for 1993-2003, again estimating over- and undereducation in terms of deviations from the mode. The results were largely consistent with those of Battu and Sloane (2004), though in this case Indian immigrants were more likely to be overeducated compared to indigenous whites. Studies of labour-market mismatch among the disabled are notable by their absence, and often a disabled dummy is not even included in the estimating equation. Where it is, there is sometimes a significant effect on the probability of overeducation. This is clearly an area for future research.
  • 42. CHAPTER 4 What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch? This chapter analyses to what extent, how and why different types of skill mismatch occur simultaneously. First, we look at skill shortages, skill gaps, undereducation and underskilling. We then examine whether overeducation, overskilling and skill shortages can occur simultaneously. In the third part of the chapter we focus on the duration of particular combinations of mismatch. There does not appear to be a strong correlation between the occurrence of skill shortages and skill gaps, but the latter may be closely linked to underskilling. Both overeducation and overskilling may be a consequence of excess labour supply, which can be illustrated by the Beveridge curve. Skills obsolescence is different from the above as it is a process rather than a state. Levels of skill are important as it is open to a skilled worker to obtain an unskilled job, while it is not normally open to an unskilled worker to obtain a skilled job. This is reflected in the concept of skill bumping (or crowding out). Various types of mismatch can be present at the same time in individual firms but not often in the same occupations. Ideally we require matched employer-employee data sets to cast light on all these phenomena. 4.1. Skill shortages, skill gaps, undereducation and underskilling Skills related problems can arise because of skill shortages or skill gaps. Skill shortages refer to a skills related labour-market shortage, i.e. where there are not enough individuals with the required skills within the economy to fill existing vacancies. This is the most simplistic definition to skill shortages. However, measurement issues are clearly important (e.g. Green et al., 1998) and some recent attempts have been made to move towards a more refined system of definition that incorporates training lead times. For example, Richardson (2006) proposed the following system for defining skill shortages: (a) evel 1 shortage: there is a shortage of individuals with the relevant l technical skills who are not already using them and it takes a long training time to develop these skills;
  • 43. CHAPTER 4 What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch? 37 (b) evel 2 shortage: there are few people who have sufficient skills and are not l already using them, but such skills can be developed relatively quickly. Skill gaps occur when skill levels in the workforce are below those desired by employers or when job requirements do not match precisely the content of the knowledge and abilities of individuals. The 2001 UK employer skills survey (UKESS) concluded that skill shortages were more commonly associated with skilled occupations with more substantial education and training requirements. In terms of skill gaps, the UKESS study found that these were more strongly related to poor human resource management practices such as lack of staff training and poor labour retention. Therefore, it is not at all evident that skills gaps and skill shortages are necessarily strongly correlated. Each of these concepts points to the difficulties employers are faced with in attracting sufficient labour of the right quality. Skill shortages are not easy to measure, but indicate that the demand for labour exceeds the (available) supply at the given market wage. However, if employers are not willing to pay the market wage to attract additional labour, this should not be considered a labour shortage. In a classic paper Arrow and Capron (1959) focused on the possibility that lags in decision-making could result in a dynamic shortage. Such lags may occur through the time taken to recognise that there is a need to raise salaries, in obtaining approval for the increase and in putting the new pay policy into action. The reaction speed of an employer will be influenced by institutional arrangements such as the presence of long-term labour contracts and partly by the speed with which information about salaries, vacancies and the availability of workers becomes generally available throughout the market. Wage adjustments are, however, only one possible means of adjustment and non-wage adjustments appear to be more common in the short-term. Common examples are reducing output, adjusting inventories, increasing overtime, using more vigorous recruitment methods or reducing hiring standards. It is in the last of these circumstances that skill gaps may arise in the sense that employees hired under such circumstances are less likely to possess the skills necessary to complete tasks with maximum efficiency. Skill gaps seem to equate with underskilling and it is difficult to differentiate between the two, apart from the fact that skill gaps may reflect the views of the employer and underskilling the views of the employee. In both cases the remedy seems to lie with the provision of additional training. In one study of Northern Ireland, Bennett and McGuinness (2009) found that 58 % of employers in the IT and engineering sectors adjusted to the
  • 44. 38 The skill matching challenge problem of skill shortages by training and upskilling their existing staff, and 47 % chose to recruit staff from other backgrounds and train them up. Under such circumstances workers may find themselves undereducated in relation to existing workers in the occupation to which they have been upgraded. Though individuals in this category may lack formal qualifications, they may have previous experience of the type of work, so that they will not necessarily be underskilled. All the above scenarios imply that demand exceeds supply. Where supply exceeds demand, a reverse scenario will apply. If there has been a rapid increase in the numbers graduating with certain qualifications skill surpluses may arise, resulting in the downgrading of some individuals who find it more difficult to obtain a job matching their qualifications. This crowding out may result in skill bumping in which workers with lower qualifications are also subject to downgrading or lose their jobs altogether. Both overeducation and overskilling may result in these circumstances. If overeducation is caused by too many qualified workers chasing too few jobs we would expect a high rate of unemployment among those workers with lower qualifications who have to compete with more educated workers, as well as a low vacancy rate. Overeducation can also result from institutional regulations, if unemployed persons are required by employment officers to accept lower-skilled jobs than those for which they are qualified to avoid losing unemployment benefits, as occurs under workfare policies. Underskilling may arise as a result of skills obsolescence, which occurs when skills become less valuable in the production process. This particularly applies to older workers. While they may be retrained in new production techniques, such as computer technology, this may be uneconomic because of the shorter pay-back period compared to that of younger workers. A further problem is that a mismatch between the level of education and/or skills and the job lack of use of capabilities may lead to a decline in workers cognitive abilities (the ‘use it or lose it’ phenomenon as described by de Grip et al., 2008). Suitable employee-employer linked data are undoubtedly required (see Chapter 8) if we are to understand fully and quantify the relationships that exist between skill mismatches for the firm and skill mismatches for individuals. However, in the absence of such data, it is possible to develop some reasonable and ultimately testable hypotheses based on existing knowledge. First, evidence suggests that little overlap between skill shortages and skill gaps exists. For instance, data from the 2001 UK employer skills survey revealed that less than 1 % of establishments experienced both skill
  • 45. CHAPTER 4 What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch? 39 shortages and skill gaps. Such a weak occurrence supports the view that firms experiencing skill gaps have little difficulty in recruiting staff, suggesting that skill gaps tend to be more heavily associated with skill deficiencies, while skill shortages are more commonly associated with higher level functions (8). Box 2. The Beveridge curve Both cases of supply exceeding demand and demand exceeding supply can be portrayed on the Beveridge curve (see below) which relates unemployment to unfilled vacancies. This assumes that there is labour-market equilibrium when the number of unemployed (U) equals the number of unfilled vacancies (V). When U does not equal V there is an imbalance at the level of the economy, region, industry, occupation or individual firm. However, this pays no attention to the quality of employed labour relative to the quality of filled jobs. Those in employment may be under- or overutilised as reflected in levels of education qualifications, skills or abilities. Vacancies B UV2 A UV1 0 Unemployment (8) askel and Martin (2001) showed that skill shortages are greater in the high-tech sectors of the H economy.
  • 46. 40 The skill matching challenge Both A and B represent points of equilibrium but, in the latter case, vacancies equal unemployment with a higher level of both vacancies and unemployment, representing increased structural unemployment. In this sense there is a greater degree of mismatch either because labour is immobile or it is equipped with insufficient or the wrong sort of skills. When an economy is subjected to shocks, such as rapid technological change, skill mismatch will occur if workers cannot readily learn new skills or are unwilling to accept jobs that do not utilise their existing skills, and employers are unable or unwilling to redesign jobs so that they can be performed by people with a different set of qualifications from those originally intended. Geographic mismatch may arise if neither workers nor jobs are fully mobile because of the costs of mobility. Other considerations are on the employer-side, whether minimum hiring standards can be met by applicants or wage offers are acceptable to them. This suggests that labour market dynamics are likely to play an important role. In a recent study Ochsen (2009) estimated the Beveridge curve for nine countries, eight of them European, over the period 1960-99. He found that mismatch is not generally lower in those countries considered to have more flexible labour markets, though it has decreased in some countries in which the labour market has become more flexible. Frogner (2002) reported on evidence from an occupational disaggregation of the UK employer skills survey data that tends to verify this view (9). However, this is not to say that skill gaps cannot occur among highly qualified staff. For instance, McGuinness and Bonner (2002) and Bennett and McGuinness (2009) uncovered skill gaps in soft skill areas such as business awareness and communication among IT and engineering professionals. 4.2. What is the relationship between overeducation, overskilling and skill shortages? It is important to determine whether overeducation results from supply-side or demand-side reasons. The former may include accepting jobs for their amenities, location advantages or family reasons. The latter may include a lack of jobs with appropriate education requirements or discrimination on the grounds of gender, race, disability or other group characteristics. (9) rofessional, associate professional and skilled trades were found to account for 56% of all skill P shortage vacancies despite accounting for only 34% of all jobs. With respect to skill gaps, according to the 2001 UK employer skills survey, firms employing sales/service staff, personal service staff or workers in elementary occupations, were most likely to report skill gaps.
  • 47. CHAPTER 4 What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch? 41 If, when advertising a vacancy, an employer requires a higher level of education than is necessary to perform the job, it is referred to as credentialism. This is a term widely used in sociological literature to describe a situation in which employers require diplomas or certificates for jobs to screen and identify personal traits that are desirable in the workplace. It is assumed that people with higher level diplomas or certificates are inherently more productive. This may also be justified on the grounds that more educated individuals learn faster or change the nature of the job in such a way that their productivity eventually becomes higher than that of less educated workers. Credentialism is more likely to occur when there are skill surpluses. Employers hiring workers with lower education than required is likely to be exceptional and reflects skill shortages. We would expect a negative relationship between overeducation and/ or overskilling and labour shortages. Since shortages are an increasing function of excess labour demand over labour supply, it becomes necessary for employers to make maximum use of existing labour and we would expect it to be easier for previously overeducated or overskilled employees to find better matches. Where skill shortages and/or overeducation/overskilling coexist this is symptomatic of individuals possessing the wrong skills or type of education or preferring their current ‘mismatch’ because of compensating job differences. Few studies have examined the relationship between these variables over time because most data sets containing appropriate questions tend to be single cross-sections and only panel data extending over reasonably long-time periods can consider changes in employment status. We would expect a continuing shortage of, say, engineers to be reflected in reduced rates of overeducation and overskilling among engineering graduates. In contrast, a surplus of engineers resulting from a sudden increase in the supply of engineering graduates would be expected to lead to a bumping down phenomenon in which non-graduate engineers are crowded out of higher engineering jobs. Skott (2006) has noted an asymmetry between the options facing high- and low-skill workers. It is open to high-skill workers who are unable to obtain high-skill jobs to accept low-skill jobs for which they are overeducated. An equivalent option is not open to low-skill workers since they are not qualified for high-skill jobs. This could give rise to a decline in both the relative employment and the relative wage of low-skilled workers when faced with a transfer of high-skill workers into low-skill jobs. Skott observed that this occurred between the early 1970s and the mid-1990s in the UK and the US. Any tendency of employers to keep skilled labour in
  • 48. 42 The skill matching challenge the recession because they fear it will be difficult to recruit skilled labour in the recovery phase will tend to weaken the above tendency. The idea that, as the proportion of the labour force with qualifications increases, some of the educated may be forced into lower-prestige jobs (generating overeducation) has been examined by Battu and Sloane (2000). If the less educated are bumped down this implies that the mean level of education will rise across all occupations and some of the uneducated may be forced into unemployment. This, in turn, implies that wage differentials overall will widen, thus offsetting any tendency for the wage differential of the educated to fall relative to the wage for uneducated workers with an increase in the supply of qualifications. Using data from the social change and economic life initiative and the British household panel survey, both of which use the Hope-Goldthorpe scale to measure occupational prestige, Battu and Sloane (2000) found evidence of skill bumping for Britain between 1986, 1991 and 1995, but this declines as one moves down the occupational hierarchy and does not extend to the lowest education qualification categories (10). In a similar study for Belgium, Nicaise (2000) found evidence of bumping down for men, but not for women (11). However, if crowding out is important we would expect to find that it is concentrated in recessionary periods when skilled workers find it more difficult to obtain jobs at their own level. Further, it if is a temporary phenomenon only new workers are likely to be subject to it, as existing employees may have job protection. Using Dutch data for the period 1992 to 1995, Gautier (2000) found relatively little evidence of crowding out, but where it does happen it seems to be a temporary phenomenon and to be driven either by short-term variations in the supply of high skilled workers or by shocks to the relative productivity of high skill jobs. Asplund and Lilja (2000, for evidence of bumping down in Finland) found that the deep recession in the early 1990s led to a substantial decline in the employment of the least educated and this boosted the upgrading of occupational skills, consistent with bumping down. It remains true, however, that there are relatively few studies which have attempted to assess the extent of crowding out and skill bumping across countries and over time. (10) he Hope-Goldthorpe scale has 36 categories ranked by ‘social desirability’ of male occupations. T The categories are assumed to provide a high degree of differentiation in terms of both occupational function and employment status. It is important to highlight that this class schema was devised for men, but the scores are commonly used for both men and women (Goldthorpe and Hope, 1974). (11) t is suggested that women may be more driven by family considerations than are men. Thus, I non-employment of women is more frequently determined by supply-side constraints than is the case for men and this tends to offset the bumping down effects on wages.
  • 49. CHAPTER 4 What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch? 43 4.3. Combinations and durations of mismatch Some general predictions can be developed about the likely relationships between worker and firm mismatches. Following Cedefop (Cedefop, Descy and Tessaring, 2001) under and overeducation (or more strictly under and overqualification) occurs when qualifications of workers do not compare with job entry requirements; over and underskilling occur when job content does not compare with workers’ skills and competences. We wish to draw out potential interrelationships between measures of skill shortages at individual and firm levels. Table 4 summarises some potential connections for firms. Table 4. Combination of mismatch for firms Skill shortages Skill gaps Overeducation Overeducation and skill shortages There is a potential correlation as the are not likely to occur together overeducated may still not possess within occupations within firms. the correct mix of skills required by But they can coexist across the firm. However, overeducation will occupations within firms. not be correlated with basic skill gaps. Overskilling Overskilling and skill shortages These can coexist within occupations are not likely to occur together within firms but only in different within occupations within firms. dimensions whereby the skills surplus But they can coexist across to the individual are not the skills occupations within firms. demanded by the employer. Undereducation Undereducation and skill Within firms and occupations, while shortages will exist within we do not expect both to coexist in occupations within firms if firms basic occupations with low entry are reacting to skill shortages by requirements it is possible for them to upskilling existing staff. coexist as the education requirement of the occupation rises. Underskilling Underskilling and skill shortages We might expect some correlation will exist within occupations within occupations and within firms within firms if firms are reacting if both the worker and the employer to skill shortages by upskilling recognise they are deficient in the existing staff and some deficits required skills. remain.
  • 50. 44 The skill matching challenge In terms of overeducation and skill shortages, the occupations within which the firm employs overeducated workers will not correspond with the occupations where skill shortages are being experienced. However, this is not to say that the firm cannot simultaneously experience overeducation and skill shortages in different occupations. Nevertheless, there is nothing to suggest a strong correlation is probable at firm level. At macroeconomic level, a high incidence of both overeducation and skill shortage would provide a strong indication that the composition of education supply is poorly aligned with labour demand. Turning to skill gaps, it is possible that overeducated workers within the firm may also be those identified as possessing skill gaps: the overeducation may be indicative of the fact that such workers possess the incorrect mix of skills required by the firm. However, the consistent finding that the overeducated earn more than matched individuals doing the same job would tend to suggest the overeducated do not have skill gaps. Further, the overeducated, by nature of their education attainment, will not tend to be deficient in basic competences, where skill gaps are most likely to occur, leading us to the general conclusion that overeducation and skill gaps are also likely to be poorly correlated at firm level. Overskilling arguably represents a much more direct measure of individual underutilisation than overeducation. Nevertheless, the relationship between overskilling and skill shortages remains unchanged from that outlined for overeducation. While both phenomena may occur across occupations within firms they will not tend to be highly correlated within occupations. Once again, at economy level, a high incidence of both overskilling and skill shortages suggests that some rebalancing of post-compulsory education and training supply would benefit both workers and firms. Overskilling and skill gaps can, however, occur both within occupations and within firms, but only in different dimensions, whereby the skills that are surplus to the individual are not the skill areas in which the firm is experiencing a shortfall. Unlike overeducation, where the relationship between skill gaps can be discounted, no study has yet demonstrated that the overskilled earn a premium relative to matched workers carrying out the same job, leaving open the possibility that the overskilled may, nonetheless, lack essential skills. Evidence suggests that many employers attempt to overcome the problem of skill shortages by upskilling their workers to fill vacancies. It may well be that reallocated workers do not possess the credentials required to fill the post; therefore, some correlation between undereducation and skill shortages might be expected. However, evidence from firm-level surveys suggests that skill shortages relate to a lack of individuals with the necessary skills and
  • 51. CHAPTER 4 What are the links between the different types of skill mismatch? 45 experience, as opposed to qualifications, and so the within-firm correlation is likely to be weak. In terms of skill gaps, if the deficiencies relate to basic skills then undereducation is unlikely, given that entry requirements to the occupations in question will be relatively low. However, the likelihood of correlation will be higher the greater the entry requirement of the positions where skill gaps are being reported. Finally for underskilling, we might expect a relatively strong relationship between this phenomenon and skill shortages in instances where firms seek to relieve the problem of unfilled vacancies by training and reallocating existing staff. Specifically, if upskilling deficiencies remain in terms of the individual worker’s ability to carry out the job in question, then upskilling will result in skill gaps. So, there are circumstances where we might expect strong correlation between underskilling, skill shortages and skill gaps at firm level. Table 4 neglects skills obsolescence, which is different in nature as it is strongly related to technical change, to rapid changes in work organisation and to shortcomings in higher education in particular. It is only weakly related to current skill shortages and not at all to the prospects for future skill acquisition (Allen and van der Velden, 2007). In fact, skills obsolescence should be considered a process rather than a state.
  • 52. CHAPTER 5 Business cycle impact on skill mismatch This chapter considers the impact of business cycles on the occurrence of skill mismatch. It is difficult to assess what impacts the economic crisis Europe is facing at the time of writing will have on skill mismatch. Little is known about the relationship between skill mismatch and the business cycle because of the lack of extensive panel data, but there are reasons to believe that such a relationship exists. Some general assessments are possible: there is also evidence that skill mismatch is a persistent phenomenon in difficult times and that overskilled workers who change their jobs do not always improve their position. 5.1. Skill mismatch and business cycles Few, if any, studies have examined the relationship between various dimensions of skill mismatch and the business cycle because most data sets which contain appropriate questions tend to be single cross-sections. To understand what happens over the business cycle requires panel data extending over a sufficiently long period to pick up the various stages of the cycle. By their very nature, business cycles result in a continual change in the balance between labour demand and supply. Change happens in relation to the match between the stock of job vacancies and the skills of the unemployed, and to the flow of jobs and skills into and out of the labour market through job destruction, job creation, training and skills obsolescence. The impact of business cycles varies by sector and occupation. Volatility in cyclical excess product demand or supply is likely to influence labour-market outcomes in terms of more or less under- and overeducation and under- and overskilling. In the first instance, business cycles will impact on skill mismatches through changing the level and composition of the demand for skills and the returns on the way in which these skills are matched in the workplace (reduced in a downturn, increased in an upturn). It is also likely that the response of the labour market itself could influence the duration and depth of a business cycle, especially through the ability of the market to preserve existing skills and offer training in new ones.
  • 53. CHAPTER 5 Business cycle impact on skill mismatch 47 Training is crucial in this context. The way the costs of training end up being split between the worker, the employer and possibly the State could be influenced by the business cycle. It could also influence the resulting skills composition and ability of the labour market to match jobs and workers during a recession and the recovery that follows. The distinction between (firm or sector) specific and more general training and education matters because of the financial incentives they imply regarding who covers the cost of training. Firm/sector specific skills are not transferable to other firms/ sectors. It follows that firms have a stronger incentive to contribute to the cost of generating specific skills rather than general skills, as the former cannot be poached as easily. Recent research by Mavromaras et al. (2009d; 2009c) using UK and Australian data suggested that skill mismatches are less prevalent and their negative consequences are less severe where education is more specific to the needs of the employer (i.e. a higher proportion of ‘specific’ versus ‘general human capital’). However, this finding was based on data that included only years in which the economy was doing well. The recent downturn indicates that, what can be an advantage during a buoyant economy, can also become a problem during a downturn, because workers with more (sector, occupation) specific skills are less flexible in shifting to new jobs if and when their own sector/occupation is adversely affected by the downturn. In a recession, the best skills for a displaced worker are general ones, as they allow broader search in sectors that may have been less affected by the downturn. For example, highly specialised vehicle industry workers may suffer a larger drop in pay during the current recession than less specialised but equally well qualified service industry workers. There is little research in this area and generating evidence using conventional large survey data sets will not be feasible for some time: the data at hand in 2009 just touches on the starting phase of the current downturn and so all data series refer to very different general economic conditions. Further, the data from previous recessions may not be as useful because considerable institutional changes have taken place in the last two to three decades in most Western economies. 5.2. The impact of the economic crisis Despite the lack of relevant research and appropriate data, some developments are easy to forecast for the recent downturn. The (re-)training effort will have
  • 54. 48 The skill matching challenge to be intensified before the upturn has even started because of its lagged effects. If we wait until an upturn is clearly visible, we will experience a slower recovery handicapped by skill shortages. However, there is a natural reduction in the willingness of employers to pay for training during a recession. A prime reason for this is that employers contribute to the cost of training and recessionary pressures have a negative effect on such investment. There is also a natural increase in the willingness of individuals, especially the unemployed and new labour-market entrants, to purchase more education and training as this may be the only way to obtain a new job. Further, there is a considerable reduction in the social opportunity cost of the State paying for the worker training during the current recession, which will be the stronger the deeper the recession proves to be. This applies in particular to displaced workers, but also to young labour-market entrants. There may be problems, however, with these hypotheses. First, the displaced workers will probably be the least productive ones and their training may not be the most cost-effective intervention (12). Although equity arguments may shift the balance in favour of training the less able displaced workers, as may the presence of a strong unemployment support and welfare net, such considerations may not reduce the level of skill mismatch when the upturn occurs. Second, it is not clear where and how training should be provided. A mix of classroom and workplace training seems appropriate, as is a mix of specific and general training. However, there is little research to guide specific choices and the danger is always present in subsidising skills and sectors that have little economic future but a strong lobbying presence in the current industrial scene. Skill shortages are also related to both the business cycle and the extent of skill mismatches. In the upturn, skill shortages will lead to increases in undereducation and underskilling as labour with appropriate education and skill is in short supply. Conversely, in the downturn new entrants to the labour market may experience difficulties in locating jobs with the appropriate levels of education and skill. There is some suggestion from skills shortage literature that some shortages persist over most stages of the business cycle in some skilled occupations: what varies is their extent over different stages of the business cycle. Such shortages are also often evident in industries and occupations with modest employment growth or even employment decline. Shortages (12) he same will not apply to young labour-market entrants, where long-term adverse consequences T will influence a much wider segment of ability distribution.
  • 55. CHAPTER 5 Business cycle impact on skill mismatch 49 can coexist with relatively high overall unemployment or in the occupation under analysis. One reason is that, in cyclical downturns, employers often reduce training places and apprenticeships, which can affect the number or trained workers for many years to come, including the upturn years when demand for skills may have fully recovered. Further, qualified workers who lose their job during downturns often do not return to the same industry or occupation. This can result from demand or supply changes in industry restructuring, making some of the older skills obsolete, or individual workers having experienced long-term unemployment/non-participation during the downturn, with adverse effects on their ability to work when the upturn occurs. In these situations undereducation and underskilling may also exist regardless of the stage of the business cycle, and it can play a role in the intensity of downturns and the speed at which an upturn in product demand can be translated into a wider economic upturn. The role of mature industries and mature workforce (sometimes the two go together) may intensify the effect of mismatches and may indicate the need to train younger workers and retrain older workers. There may also be cohort effects in how graduates are matched with jobs related to the business cycle. If graduates enter the labour market in a period of recession they may be more likely to experience overeducation; the effect of this may persist over the longer term. Further, taking the employment of an overeducated graduate (presumably to a non-graduate job) as an example, this employment is likely to cause bumping down as a side effect, displacing a non-graduate worker who may be less qualified generally, but perfectly well qualified for the (non-graduate) job the overqualified graduate obtained. It is well established in literature that increasing unemployment in the less qualified part of the labour market may cause severe scarring effects. The longer the lead time needed for training any specific type of graduate, the more likely it is that cyclical volatility may have detrimental scarring effects. Similar phenomena may be observed where there may be sudden sharp increases in the number of graduates even if the economy is not in recession, as absorption is more difficult. This is again accentuated where there are long training lead times. Some of the more general literature on the nature of dynamic labour- market adjustment is relevant. Although worker quits are often associated with both wage gains and higher job satisfaction, many workers quit again within one or two years. There are two rival explanations. First, Burdett (1978) assumed that job quality in a new job is perfectly observable ex ante, so that repeated quit behaviour results from workers using new
  • 56. 50 The skill matching challenge jobs as a stepping stone to even better jobs. Second, Jovanovic (1979) assumed the complete absence of such information, so that repeated job moves result from disappointment over job quality. Gielen (2008) observed that an appropriate test is whether any improvement in job satisfaction is permanent. The British household panel survey shows that the stepping stone model can explain up to 80 % of repeated job behaviour and 20 % learning about job quality. Using Finnish data, Bockerman and Ilmakunnas (2009) suggested that heterogeneity of workplaces and wage compression hinder creating sufficiently compensating wage differentials, so that adverse working conditions encourage workers to quit. The implication is that, at any time, labour markets will be in disequilibrium. 5.3. Evidence from Australia In one of the few attempts to measure the dynamics of overskilling, McGuinness and Wooden (2007) used the first four waves of the household income and labour dynamics for Australia (HILDA) data set. The results suggest that, while the overskilled express a desire to quit in order to obtain a job which offers a better match, they are not confident of their ability to achieve this. Further, though they have a higher propensity to be mobile than matched workers, some of this higher mobility is due to involuntary separations; even where job separations are voluntary, most job moves do not result in improved skill matches. Also, many overskilled workers move into unemployment or inactivity. This adds to evidence that policy should focus on skill mismatch rather than education mismatch. Using the first six waves of HILDA, Mavromaras et al. (2009b) examined the extent of persistence defined as the ability of the state to perpetuate among the overskilled. The strongest persistence was found for those with higher education. Lower persistence, but still strong and statistically significant, was found for those with up to year 12 schooling. There is no trace of overskilling persistence for those with vocational education and training, indicating that mismatches are much easier not only to avoid but also to correct for those with vocational training. A caveat for this, and many other contemporary findings, is that they have been derived from data drawn exclusively from Australia in an economic upturn. It is not clear that these findings can be generalised and extrapolated to study today’s recession climate in Europe without careful consideration. Despite this caveat, evidence suggests that, at least for some groups, overskilling is not a purely temporary phenomenon.
  • 57. CHAPTER 6 The implications of skill mismatch This chapter discusses the implications of skill mismatch. The next section examines the impact of mismatch in terms of productivity and discusses overeducation, skills shortages and skills gaps. The following section reviews the impact of skill mismatch on job satisfaction. We then turn to possible positive impacts of overeducation or overskilling for employers and end by reflecting on the overall costs of mismatch for society. Skill shortages have a significant impact on productivity, GDP growth and earnings, though less is known about the effects of skill gaps or skills obsolescence. We know that overeducation reduces job satisfaction for individual workers while, for firms, hiring overeducated workers can be a deliberate strategy to benefit from extra skills in the long term, despite negative impacts in the short term. 6.1. Skill mismatch and productivity We might expect that both skills shortage and skills gap can lead to a loss of competitiveness as wage rates are bid up and productivity lowered within industries where skill problems exist. Productivity may also be harmed as firms may be forced to place lower-skilled workers in skilled positions and/ or, if in an area with skills shortage, workers use their position to alter their terms and conditions inefficiently from a productivity perspective. Finegold and Soskice (1988), and Haskel and Holt (1999), take the analysis a step further by describing a scenario whereby skills shortage can lead to low-skill equilibrium within the economy. They described a situation where firms react to skills shortage by investing in technologies that complement the low-skilled element of the workforce, resulting in an economy characterised by low wages and a low demand for high-skilled labour. As a consequence of the low demand for high wage/high-skilled workers within the labour market, individuals will no longer invest in their own human capital, thus perpetuating the low-skill equilibrium position. Tether et al. (2005) argued that once a low- skill equilibrium has become established, there are no obvious policy levers for correcting the situation. However, despite some extensive discussion of the theoretical concept in literature, there is little actual evidence linking skills shortage with the emergence of a low-skill equilibrium.
  • 58. 52 The skill matching challenge 6.1.1. Overeducation and productivity While the wage effects of overeducation, overskilling, undereducation and underskilling are well known (Hartog, 2000; Sloane, 2003; McGuinness, 2006; Mavromaras et al., 2009a; 2009d) their implications for firm productivity are less clear cut. In imperfect labour markets, firms may obtain a rent from the services of their employees, which means that the link between the wage and productivity is imprecise. There may also be differences between short-term and long-term effects, since overeducation is known to reduce job satisfaction, which in turn may negatively influence performance, both directly and indirectly, through its effects on absence and quit rates. Tsang and Levin (1985) suggested that overeducated workers often exhibit counter- productive behaviour in the workplace, but this might also be influenced by their lower ability, health problems or a different attitude towards work. The effects of overeducation on productivity can be measured in two ways. If wages equal marginal productivity, the finding that overeducated workers receive a wage premium over matched colleagues, though less than matched workers with the same education as themselves, suggests that such work- ers are somewhat more productive than matched colleagues. An alternative and preferable approach, given the presence of imperfect labour markets, is to measure productivity directly through analysis of output per head in indi- vidual companies or industries. The expectation is that, since overeducation reduces job satisfaction, there will also be a negative effect on productivity, through higher shirking, absence and quit rates. As Hartog (2000) observed, this leaves a puzzle since, along this line of reasoning, overeducation should reduce wages rather than increase them as the wage evidence suggests. If workers are genuinely mismatched, in the sense that they are not fully utilising their education qualifications or skills in their current jobs, reallocating labour appropriately should increase productivity and GDP/GNP at macro level. However, as Borghans and de Grip (2000) pointed out, to assess this properly we require better understanding of the skills that people currently possess and the precise ways in which they utilise these skills. Unfortunately, much less is known about this than about the allocation of different types of workers in the labour market. Also, what is known is largely confined to single case studies. In one of the few direct attempts to measure the effect of overeducation on productivity, Tsang (1987), applying a Cobb-Douglas production function approach and using data on companies within the US Bell Corporation, found evidence of negative productivity impact. Unfortunately, Tsang’s (1987) study is the only attempt to measure productivity effects using company data.
  • 59. CHAPTER 6 The implications of skill mismatch 53 6.1.2. Skill shortages and productivity Skill shortages are important for their impact on productivity, GDP/GNP growth and earnings. Frogner (2002) cited descriptive evidence from the 2001 European social survey to support this in terms of the productivity impact, although evidence on earnings was more limited. A study by the National Institute of Economic and Social Research (Mason and Wilson, 2003) reported that relative to German plants, output per worker in British firms was over 60 % lower, with the authors arguing that this productivity gap was a consequence of lower-skill levels. Further, Haskel and Martin (1996) suggested that skill shortages reduced annual productivity growth in the UK by 0.4 percentage points over the period 1983-99. On productivity corollaries, Nickell and Nicolitsas (1997) estimated that a permanent 10 % rise in firms reporting skill shortages lowers investment proportionately, and RD by a temporary 4 %. Evidence from more specific sectoral studies include that of Bennett and McGuinness (2009), who reported that, after controlling for the influence of selection bias, output per worker was lower in high-tech firms experiencing both hard-to-fill and unfilled vacancies. Finally, Forth and Mason (2004) found among UK firms that a quantity shortfall in the number of graduate engineers and scientists led to lower output per worker. But not all empirical evidence points in the same direction. For instance, McGuinness and Bonner (2002) and McGuinness and Doyle (2003; 2005) found no evidence that unfilled vacancies substantially lowered the productivity of Northern Ireland IT and construction firms. Further, for Forth and Mason (2004) skill shortages arising as a result of the poor quality of applicants had no productivity impact. 6.1.3. Skill gaps and productivity While the productivity effects of skill shortages in firms have been relatively well researched, much less is known about the productivity effects of skill gaps. Nevertheless, some studies tested the impact of skill gaps on productivity- related variables (McGuinness and Bennett, 2006; McGuinness and Bonner, 2002), but no significant relationships were found. Some descriptive evidence suggests, however, that firm performance across a range of indicators is severely constrained as a consequence of such gaps (e.g. Hogarth and Wilson, 2001). A series of Northern Ireland sectoral studies (NIERC, 2000; 2001; 2002; Erini, 2005) reported descriptive evidence that skill gaps substantially hampered firm performance on several fronts. Further, the UK national employment survey (2003) also found that over a fifth of employers reporting skill gaps delayed introducing new products, while a third stated
  • 60. 54 The skill matching challenge that skill gaps represented a barrier to implementing new work practices (Tether et al., 2005). Further, de Grip et al. (2008) found, using a Dutch data set, that job worker mismatch induces cognitive decline (use it or lose it) with respect to immediate and delayed recall abilities, cognitive flexibility and verbal fluency. This adds to the relevance of preventing overeducation and also provides a reason why overeducation should have a negative effect on earnings. For skills obsolescence, contrary to expectations, Allen and van der Velden (2001) could find little evidence of long-term problems and no effect at all on current wage levels. This may be a result of informal on-the-job training or the fact that job loss is an important outcome for workers with obsolete skills. 6.2. Skill mismatch and job satisfaction The overeducated and/or overskilled earn less than if properly matched, but more than properly matched colleagues. There is, therefore, an incentive to move to a job reflecting better their education and skills. In contrast, the undereducated or underskilled earns more than if properly matched, but less than properly matched colleagues. As in this case there is no incentive to move to a job reflecting better education and skills we expect the mismatch to last longer than in the previous case. This should be reflected in lower job satisfaction for the overeducated/overskilled and higher job satisfaction for the undereducated/underskilled. There is limited, but increasing, literature on the effects of skill mismatch on job satisfaction. For the US, Tsang and Levin (1985) were the first explicitly to model this relationship. They suggested that overeducation may result in reduced work effort, increased production cost and lower productivity. Tsang (1987) found evidence for this in the Bell Telephone company and Tsang et al. (1991) confirmed this, using a broader cross-industry data set. Hersch (1991, 1995) found similar results for Oregon manufacturing and warehouse firms. For Britain, Battu et al. (1999) found that job satisfaction among graduates was significantly adversely affected by mismatch in non-graduate jobs. Yet, though Belfield and Harris (2002) found a similar relationship, using the same data set, this did not appear to be associated with education quality, which might be expected to raise job satisfaction through increasing the job-offer rate. In contrast, Büchel (2002) found no significant difference in job satisfaction between overeducated and adequately educated workers in Germany.
  • 61. CHAPTER 6 The implications of skill mismatch 55 Allen and van der Velden (2001) differentiated between education and skill mismatches and found that there was only a significant negative relationship between mismatch and job satisfaction for skill mismatch. Similarly for Britain, Green and Zhu (2008) found that overqualification is not a problem for job satisfaction in itself if it is not accompanied by skill mismatch. For Spain, Badillo-Amador and Vila (2008) also found that skill mismatches are a better predictor of job satisfaction than education mismatches, which are not only related to differences between individuals but also influenced by workers’ previous perceptions, suggesting that a dynamic structure is appropriate for analysing job satisfaction. The above studies neglect the possibility that an overlap exists between observed and unobserved characteristics which determine both overeducation and job satisfaction. For this reason one Australian study (Fleming and Kler, 2007) used a different statistical technique and considers various facets of job satisfaction rather than just overall satisfaction. It was found that the impact of overeducation on job satisfaction is positively biased for three of the six facets of job satisfaction considered when using a traditional statistical technique. However, even with the improved estimation, the significant negative relationship between overeducation and job satisfaction remains. Similar results for facets of job satisfaction using Australian data were found by Linsley (2005) and Kler (2006) (13), the latter finding that overeducated graduates are more satisfied with job security than matched graduates. Finally Mavromaras et al. (2009d) used the panel element of the household income and labour dynamics for Australia and distinguish between overskilling and overeducation, finding that it is only overskilling on its own or jointly with overeducation which has a negative effect on job satisfaction. This parallels the findings in relation to the effect of mismatch on wages. 6.3. Possible positive impacts of skill mismatch Employers will hire overeducated or overskilled workers if they believe that such workers are more productive and the extra productivity is not outweighed by the higher wages required to attract such workers. They will also use the undereducated and underskilled if the lower wage costs of such workers compensate for lower productivity. (13) he facets considered by Linsley are satisfaction with work and with level of responsibility; in the T case of Kler they are satisfaction with pay, job security, hours, work and flexibility.
  • 62. 56 The skill matching challenge Dupuy and de Grip (2002) suggested that overeducation is related to the hiring policy of large firms. By hiring overeducated workers when the supply of highly educated workers exceeds demand for their services, large firms increase their opportunities to substitute high-skill for low-skill workers in times when high-skill workers are in short supply. High elasticity of substitution between high-skill and low-skill workers in large firms explain their higher rates of labour productivity. Further, this also encourages skill biased technological change (Acemoglu, 2002). However, to determine precisely the relative efficiency of using the overeducated instead of matched workers is difficult. As Jochmann and Pohlmeier (2003) pointed out, the traditional Mincer human capital earnings function approach may reflect decreasing returns on schooling or the non-random selection of individuals into overeducation status. Using the 1998 wave of the German socioeconomic panel they presented Bayesian estimates of treatment effects to overcome these problems and found, contrary to earlier studies which neglect selectivity issues, no evidence of overeducation depressing earnings. Jones et al. (2009) included an overskilling variable, using the British workplace employment relations survey 2004 (which is a matched employer- employee data set), in equations explaining five measures of performance. He found that the variable is positive and significant in at least some of the equations. This may explain why employers hire overskilled workers and pay them more, but the effect is likely to be short-term as such workers are more likely to quit. For Germany Büchel (2002), using the German socio- economic panel, found that overeducated workers in low-skill jobs (where most of the overeducated are found) tend to be more productive than their matched colleagues, which he also took to explain employer motivation in hiring the overeducated. Clearly, however, more studies among firms are required to understand better this phenomenon and to examine its short- term versus long-term implications. 6.4. Skill mismatch costs for society The economy will lose the output that could have been generated by real- locating genuinely mismatched workers to higher productivity jobs. There is no loss of output implied, however, for apparently mismatched workers (as defined in Chevalier, 2003) as their current jobs reflect their actual levels of ability or skills. Further, whether overeducation imposes real costs is challenged by some researchers who view overeducation or overskilling as an inherent
  • 63. CHAPTER 6 The implications of skill mismatch 57 phenomenon of market economies, as education and training systems cannot adapt instantly to labour-market needs. Others have argued that the notion of overeducation is not valid, as people are able to shape their own jobs or employers may tailor jobs to the skills of workers (Halaby, 1994). It is reasonable to conclude that skill shortages are likely to prove costly to the economy by restricting productivity growth in key sectors. Accepting that, for many reasons, the market will fail to clear and skill shortages persist, another question arises on the extent to which the wage mechanism is sufficient to provide an effective signal of changing labour-market conditions. Evidence is mixed. Finegold and Soskice (1988) found that individuals in Britain are less likely than in other countries to increase training in reaction to a rise in labour price. However, Connolly (1996), using data from the national child development study, suggested that the demand for training is responsive to changes in price. Nevertheless, the principal problem arises from the often substantial training time-lag associated with producing skilled labour, implying that the market signal usually occurs too late to aid a timely market response. Further, the price mechanism itself may be a poor indicator of labour-market shortage, given that increasing wages is one of a range of strategies adopted by firms to tackle the problem of skill shortages (Bennett and McGuinness, 2009). Frogner (2002) confirms this, reporting that less than half of firms, claiming to experience skill shortages in the 2001 European social survey, indicated a willingness to raise the wage. Thus, job mismatch may be associated with social costs, which can be defined as private costs plus negative externalities. Alternatively, social benefits may be higher than private benefits if it were not for mismatch. For instance, at macroeconomic level national output, and hence welfare, is potentially lower than if workers and firms were fully matched in the economy. The loss will be a function of the number of workers who are mismatched and the difference in productivity if they were reallocated. Such a loss is likely to be greater for skill mismatch than education mismatch, given the fact that the latter is not likely to incorporate lower ability effects. In addition, tax revenues may be wasted on equipping individuals with non- productive education, suggesting less than optimal allocation of resources by governments. However, education may also enable certain individuals to gain employment who otherwise may find it difficult to do so. Most studies that have examined the relationship between mismatch and job satisfaction have found a significant negative relationship (for British graduates see e.g. Battu et al., 1999). This would represent a social cost. However, recent work using the household income and labour dynamics in
  • 64. 58 The skill matching challenge Australia panel suggests that such a negative relationship only applies to overskilling, not to overeducation, and that it is not uniform across all employed individuals. This needs to be examined in relation to other countries. Finally, there may be a link between labour-market mismatch and discrimination, which makes certain groups more susceptible to mismatch. Battu and Sloane (2004) and Lindley (2009) have, for example, found that relative to whites, individuals from some ethnic groups are significantly more likely to be overeducated, suggesting that they find it harder to locate optimal matches. In addition, migrants may be faced with lower recognition of their qualifications, if obtained in country of origin, than is warranted on economic grounds. For gender, differences in mismatch appear not to be marked in many countries. However, Johansson and Katz (2007) found that, in Sweden, women were more likely to be overeducated and men more likely to be undereducated. It is also possible that gender-based differences in subject choice may further exacerbate the problem through increased horizontal mismatch. Again in Sweden, Nordin et al. (2008) found that there were clear gender gaps in the share of mismatched jobs in certain disciplines. Men were more likely to be mismatched in female-dominated occupations and females more so in male-dominated occupations. The gender gap in income declines from 12 % to 2 % when type of degree is included in their analysis, implying that men are more likely to use education to select into well-paid fields than are women. Last, for older workers we have to consider the problem of skills obsolescence and the possibility of a subsequent mismatch arising from structural factors. A particular problem arises from the fact that there is a relatively short payback period in relation to any investment in retraining and several studies suggest that retraining older workers may be uneconomic for this reason. However, if there is substantial skills obsolescence there may be no alternative to retraining older workers. As employers are less likely to hire older workers than they are to continue to employ them, this emphasises the need for measures to encourage employers to retain older workers rather than to dismiss them. Rising levels of education may also affect pay dispersion. Increasing dispersion in the returns on graduate education in the UK has been detected by Green and Zhu (2008) over the period 1994 to 2006, when the numbers of graduating increased sharply. While the benefits of graduate education improved at the top end of the distribution for both men and women, at the bottom end they sharply decreased. This means that the financial risks associated with investment in higher education have increased, since individuals cannot be certain where they will end up in terms of the overall earnings distribution. This could result in insufficient supply of individuals coming forward to meet the needs of the economy.
  • 65. CHAPTER 7 Appropriate skill mismatch measuring Consistent with the considerable attention to overeducation in literature, we begin by giving an overview of data sets that include items on overeducation or overskilling. Five European and two UK data sets extending beyond 2000 contain relevant questions, but only the household income and labour dynamics for Australia data set is a panel. We discuss three alternative measures: the objective method, the subjective method and the empirical method can be used to measure overeducation and reflect on their weaknesses. Subsequently, we explain why overskilling offers a better picture of skill surpluses. Few data sets, however, contain questions on it. In the final section we argue that skills obsolescence can be measured in different ways, but that there is little consensus on what is the most appropriate way of measuring; few data sets contain questions that can be used to assess skills obsolescence. 7.1. Measuring overeducation and overskilling In Table 5 we list the main recent cross-country data sets which contain relevant questions on overeducation and overskilling, plus several single-country data sets which contain questions on overskilling and have advantages. We focus on the concept of overeducation and overskilling, where the main measurement issues seem to lie. Three alternative measures have been used to measure overeducation: (a) ystematic job evaluation, used to determine the precise level of s qualifications required to perform a particular job. It is referred to as an ‘objective’ measure, but fails to allow more than one education level to be appropriate for particular occupations, particularly if they are broadly defined. It also fails to allow for the possibility that the appropriate education level may change over time; (b) orker self-assessment, referred to as a ‘subjective’ measure, depends w on the precise question asked, such as ‘how much education is required to obtain a job like yours?’ or ‘what level of education is required to perform this job?’. When firms specify a level of education higher than
  • 66. 60 The skill matching challenge necessary to perform a job, it suggests the use of credentialism and may well result in overskilling or skill underutilisation; (c) ost data sets do not contain a direct question on overeducation, m in which case reliance has to be placed on the empirical method. Conventionally, mismatching occurs when the level of education is more than one standard deviation above or below the mean for education within an occupation. This cannot be directly compared with the above two measures as it ignores minor differences between actual and mean education. Several studies have sought to assess the correlation between different mea- sures of mismatch. McGoldrick and Robst (1996) showed that the incidence of male overeducation varied from 50 % under the objective measure to 30 % Table 5. ata sets containing questions to individual employees on D skill mismatch Data set Type Dates Questions European Panel 1994-2001 overskilling Community (three questions) household panel European social Cross-section over 30 Biennial 2002/03, over- and survey countries 2004/05, 2006/07, undereducation 2008/09 European working Cross-section 1996, 2000, 2005 over- and underskilling conditions survey Flexible Mail questionnaire, nine 2005 overskilling, professional in the countries (graduates underskilling, knowledge society only) horizontal mismatch, (REFLEX) overeducation and undereducation EU e-living project Household survey six 2001 and 2002 over- and countries underqualification Workplace Matched employer- 2004 over- and underskilling employment employee data relations survey UK skills survey Cross-section 1992, 1997, 2001, 2006 over- and underqualification overskilling Household income Panel 2001 overskilling and labour dynamics in Australia (HILDA)
  • 67. CHAPTER 7 Appropriate skill mismatch measuring 61 under the subjective measure and 16 % under the empirical method. Battu et al. (2000) found that the various measures tended to identify different people as being overeducated with correlations under two subjective measures being around 0.2 to 0.3. Verhaest and Omey (2006) considered the reliability of five different measures of overeducation on the basis of encompassing tests. They concluded that objective job evaluation and subjective data on the level of education required to do the job should always be preferred over the empirical method or to subjective measures of the education level required to get the job. Allen et al. (2006) suggested that analysis of the wage consequences of education mismatch needed to be complemented by including the effects of job-worker skill mismatches, expecting that the wage effects of educa- tion mismatches would be absorbed by the skill mismatch measure. In fact, there is little correlation between the two. Green and McIntosh (2007) found a correlation between overeducation and overskilling of 0.2. Further, when an overskilling variable is included in a wage equation already containing an overeducation variable, the coefficient on overeducation only falls from -0.164 to -0.144, a statistically insignificant difference. An obvious problem with measures for overeducation is that they treat dif- ferent degrees of overeducation in the same way. A graduate in a job for which only a higher school leaving certificate is required is treated as a graduate in a menial job, while the policy implications of the two cases might be different. It is less likely this occurs under the empirical method, but using the standard deviation criterion is purely arbitrary. Further, there is another ambiguity ac- cording to whether the mean or the mode is used as the standard. In many, though not all countries, the incidence of overeducation is higher than that of undereducation, so the mode, rather than the mean, would appear to be the appropriate yardstick. Where the number of workers in an occupation is limited or the dispersion of actual qualifications wide, any measure of central location is likely to be unreliable. Thus, De Oliveira et al. (2000) suggested generally limiting the analysis to cases where the modal number of years of education is shared by at least 60 % of the workers in that occupation. The measures discussed above are examples of vertical mismatch but none deal with the case of horizontal mismatch, where the level of education is appropriate but the type is not. For example, some degree fields focus on occupation-specific skills that may not easily transfer to other occupations, while others focus on more general human capital (e.g. arts). But, perhaps, the biggest problem of overeducation as a measure of mismatch is the frequent omission of any measure of ability in empirical work on the phenomenon, so that we simply do not know whether overeducated workers are in this state simply for low ability given the level of education.
  • 68. 62 The skill matching challenge 7.2. Focusing on overskilling Such reasoning suggests that overskilling might be regarded as a superior measure of mismatch, particularly where the question makes direct references to ability. The Australian HILDA panel asks respondents whether they use many of their skills and abilities in their current job, with a response of 1 corresponding to strongly disagree and 7 to strongly agree. This, however, requires a cut-off point for being overskilled and does not allow clear delineation of the underskilled (14). In contrast, the question in the British workplace employment relations survey 2004 simply asks individuals how well the skills they personally have match the skills they need to do their present job. Here, however, there is a five point scale with respondents answering that their own skills are much higher, a bit higher, about the same, a bit lower or much lower than needed. This enables a clear distinction to be made between those severely overskilled or underskilled or only moderately so. Neither of these data sets contains a direct question on overeducation, though one can be derived using the empirical method. The European Community household panel, which ran for eight years between 1994 and 2001, also contains questions on overskilling. In 2001 respondents were asked whether they had formal training or education that had given them the skills needed for the present type of work and how much this training and education had contributed to their present work. A further question asked whether the respondents felt that they had the skills or qualifications to do a more demanding job than they now have. Brunello et al. (2007) have examined these questions for five countries using both probit and multinomial analysis, and Badillo-Amador and Vila (2008) have done so for Spain. The latter use the modal procedure to estimate education mismatch using years of education. They defined the overskilled as those answering positively to the first and third questions and the underskilled as answering negatively. Those who answer yes to first question and no to the third are defined as adequately skilled; those who answer no to the first question and yes to the third are, debatably, defined as wrongly skilled. These questions are also not ideal as they refer to education as well as skills; it is impossible to disentangle the two. The European working conditions survey conducted in 1996, 2000 and 2005 contains relevant questions on skill mismatch. In 2005 respondents (14) he same will not apply to young labour-market entrants, where long-term adverse consequences T will influence a much wider segment of ability distribution.
  • 69. CHAPTER 7 Appropriate skill mismatch measuring 63 were asked which of the following alternative would best describe their skills in their own work: (a) I need further training to cope well with my duties (underskilled); (b) my duties correspond well with my present skills (matched); (c) have the skills to cope with more demanding duties (possibly I overskilled). The 2005 survey was not analysed in relation to these questions. The REFLEX graduate survey 2005 contains data on graduates in nine European countries and has the advantage of asking separate questions on skill and education mismatches. Skill mismatches are identified from workers’ responses on a scale from 1 (not at all) to 5 (to a very large extent) to the questions: to what extent does your current work demand more knowledge and skills than you can actually offer; and to what extent are your knowledge and skills utilised in your current work? For overeducation the equivalent question is ‘what type of education do you feel is most appropriate for the current work?’. This can be compared directly with reported education levels. The European social survey 2002/03-2008/09 has information on 25 countries and contains two questions relevant to education matching: first ‘if someone was applying nowadays for the job you do now, would they need any education or vocational schooling beyond compulsory education?’; and ‘about how may years of education and vocational schooling beyond compulsory education would they need?’ The 2001/02 e-Living project contains questions on both qualifications and years of education but for a more restricted range of countries. It is necessary to consider all possible combinations of skill mismatch. Ignoring undereducation and underskilling, which are less common phenomena, there are four possible matching combinations: (a) matched education and matched skills; (b) overeducation, but skill matching; (c) matched education, but overskilling; (d) overeducation and overskilling. The first case is more likely where there are specific qualifications, as in law or medicine or skilled craft apprenticeships. The second is more likely when the individual is at the lower end of the ability distribution for a given qualification, so that he or she is unable to obtain a job which matches that level of qualification. However, the job obtained may make full use of that person’s skills or abilities. Alternatively, this combination may result through choice, if the job has non-pecuniary benefits which offset the lower
  • 70. 64 The skill matching challenge wage offered. The third case might occur when employers raise the level of education required for the job, as they realise that the supply of individuals with a particular level of education is now higher than it was. If the requirements of the job have not changed this amounts to grade inflation. The final case may be more likely for married women returning to work after childbirth or who are constrained by a job move on the part of the husband (tied movers). The constraints on job search make it more difficult to find jobs commensurate with their qualifications and abilities. In the context of the above four measures, recent work by Mavromaras et al. (2009d), using the HILDA panel, indicates the need to run separate equations for each of the four groups. Only those subject to overskilling, either on its own or jointly with overeducation, suffer from lower job satisfaction, and for men when controlling for unobserved individual heterogeneity there is no clear wage penalty for overeducation. This is not the case for overskilled men. This emphasises the need for data sets which have separate questions on overeducation and overskilling, which are panel in nature and ideally which enable one to identify horizontal and vertical mismatches. 7.3. Measuring skills obsolescence Finally, we should consider measuring skills obsolescence, which is far from straightforward. In principle it can be measured: (a) objectively, by testing the deterioration of workers’ skills over time; (b) hrough subjective methods such as asking workers (or employers) t whether they face skills obsolescence; (c) y the individual measurement of productivity (e.g. tests of workers’ b skills deterioration or levels of wages); (d) y the rate of innovation which should indicate the speed of b obsolescence. Survey data questions include Blechinger and Pfeiffer (2000) ‘how much of the occupational knowledge and skills that you acquired during your apprenticeship can you still apply in your current work?’ and Van Loo et al. (2001) ‘have your qualifications depreciated due to changes in your current job?’ and ‘what is the extent to which your qualifications are suited to your current job?’. Relatively few data sets include such questions.
  • 71. CHAPTER 8 Skill mismatch data needed in Europe Given the problems that current data sources pose, this final chapter considers data needed to analyse skill mismatch comprehensively in Europe. We would learn most from a new matched employer-employee panel containing appropriate questions but this would be very expensive. We suggest to add to panel data sets several questions in the form of modules, to be asked once every two or three years; to use several European panel surveys to allow comparative analyses; to consider alternative methods for information collection of a more detailed, but also revealing nature. 8.1. Improving data on skill mismatch in Europe One of the current problems in analysing mismatch in Europe is the absence of appropriate questions in regular series such as labour force surveys and household panels. A panel with enough observations to observe changes in mismatch over the business cycle would be ideal and, if a matched employer/employee panel, this would enable control for unobserved individual heterogeneity both in relation to personal characteristics of individuals and establishments. While this would provide substantial gains in understanding the mismatch problem, developing a new data set would be very costly. To collect this new information cost-effectively would demand funding and support for adding a set of pertinent labour-market mismatch questions to several existing large data sets. This can be difficult because most data sets are already overburdened and interviewee fatigue is a serious problem but it would be a lot cheaper than starting a new data set. Given the rather long-term nature of training and education, yearly collection of the relevant information may not be essential. The cost-effectiveness of the data collection could be improved by dis- pensing with annual information and starting a special module, collected once every two or three years, as part of several existing, long-running data sets across Europe. The questions asked should preferably be the same in all data sets. Where we judge that there may be a requirement for some
  • 72. 66 The skill matching challenge additional questions for purposes of equivalisation, these should be asked as necessary. Appropriate momentum could be assured by starting with collection in years 1, 3, 5 and then moving to a longer three-year interval, 8, 11, etc. The information collected in this way can be almost as useful as that collected annually and will be supported by the annual information as well. Where specific detailed information cannot be obtained through conventional survey interview methods, alternative methods, such as quali- tative analysis and discrete choice experiments, should be considered as complements that could enhance our understanding obtained from large survey data sets. 8.2. What information should be collected and how? For new information useful within a wider survey context, separate ques- tions should be asked in relation to skill shortages, skill gaps, over- and undereducation, over- and underskilling, and skills obsolescence. Some of the information could be obtained from employers, some from employees and some from both to check for consistency (15). This would be much cheaper and would provide real gains in identifying links between these different concepts. Only the employer has the relevant information on skill shortages and should be asked whether there are any occupations they are unable, or have difficulty, to fill. This could be supplemented by questions on the duration of vacancies and the wage competitiveness of the employer. Further, employers could be asked what they perceive to be the reasons for the skill shortages. For skill gaps, employers should be asked to cite cases where existing employees do not have the required qualifications, experience and/ or specialised skills to meet the firm’s skill needs for an occupation. This needs to be supplemented by questions on training provision and why this has not solved the problem or has not taken place. In case of a matched data set, employees could be asked the same question on underskilling to check for consistency in responses from the two parties. Questions on over- and undereducation should ideally focus on both qualifications and time spent on being educated. Further they should focus (15) major project including a study and network of European labour-market analysts using firm panel A data and linked employer-employee data was launched in 2008 and is due to report this year.
  • 73. CHAPTER 8 Skill mismatch data needed in Europe 67 on the education level required to do the job rather than to obtain the job, though the latter could be asked as a supplementary question. Objective and subjective approaches are to be preferred to the empirical method. Information on the objective approach could be obtained from the employer, while the subjective approach requires questions addressed to the employee. If both are asked in a matched panel, the responses could be checked for consistency. In particular, employers need to be asked why they hire overeducated workers and how they differentiate their pay from that of properly matched colleagues. Similarly, employees need to be asked why they accepted a job for which they were overeducated. Any panel element could be used to ascertain time trends. Questions also need to be asked on horizontal and vertical mismatch. Questions on over- and underskilling seem to be more informative than those on over- and undereducation and seem to be less contaminated by unobserved individual heterogeneity. It is necessary to ensure that any scale used for employees to rank the extent to which they use their skills and abilities allows the underskilled and the overskilled to be classified clearly. It is important to include ‘ability’ and ‘skill’ in the question. Questions on the extent and type of training should be included to establish whether or not the provision of training diminishes the extent of overskilling and underskilling. Skills obsolescence is often hard to measure using currently available data sets. Questions on skills obsolescence should allow differentiation between economic and technological change explanations. The latter will be illustrated by reductions in overall employment and relative employment by occupation, on which the employer is more likely to have information, while the former is more related to the individual. This needs to be linked to age and the provision of retraining. Using a panel, workers can be asked at different times to rate the extent to which their skills are suitable for their current job; the reduction in the score will then indicate the degree of obsolescence. Induction time (the time the respondent expects a new recruit to learn how to do the job) has been found to be a strong determinant of skills obsolescence, and so it is useful to have a question on this in any survey. An important but overlooked aspect is the role of past training on present overeducation and overskilling levels. It should not be assumed that the provision of education and training always reflects accurately the preferences of the trainees. Little is known, in the economic context of mismatches, of the role that education providers may play in generating mismatches. How provision is funded and organised, as well as how it tries to address
  • 74. 68 The skill matching challenge the demand by trainees and their future employers, is as important as it is inadequately researched. For example, the space at the borders between vocational and university level can be riddled with problems related to entrenched education positions. Key aspects are curriculum design and permeability between VET and general education. Such problems appear in different guises in many countries and their presence can distort the efficient provision of education in a fast changing economy. The collection of information on the type of provision and how this meets the needs of trainees and the industry should become standard in related data sets. 8.3. The way forward What is the way forward? First, comprehensiveness of relevant questions on skill mismatch in surveys (see Annex) should be ensured to understand the relationship between different forms of mismatch. For example, do vertical and horizontal mismatches tend to have a positive, negative or no relationship? Does skills obsolescence tend to intensify the problem of labour shortages? Only if individual data sets contain a comprehensive list of questions are we likely to be in a position to answer such questions. Then it will be necessary to establish which European panel data sets can be used to include these questions alongside their wider survey questions.
  • 75. ANNEX Comprehensive schemata for skill mismatch questions in surveys 1. Qualifications (employee questions) (a) ow long did it take you to obtain the highest qualification you currently H hold? (b) Was it obtained on a part-time or full-time basis? (c) What is the normal time taken to obtain this qualification? (d) From which institution did you obtain this qualification? (e) as the qualification classified and if so what classification did you W obtain? (f) s a particular qualification required to obtain the job you currently I hold? (g) If so, what is it? (h) as the level of required qualification changed since you obtained H this job? (i) hat level of qualification do you consider to be necessary to perform W the job adequately? (j) hat field of study do you consider to be most appropriate for this W work? • exclusively own field; • own or related field; • a completely different field; • no particular field. (k) as your employer offered you training to enable you to perform your H current job better or to perform another job? 2. Skills and abilities (employee question) (a) ow well do the skills and abilities you have match the skills needed H to do your current job? My own skills are: • much higher; • a bit higher; • about the same; • a bit lower; • much lower than needed.
  • 76. 70 The skill matching challenge 3. Skill shortages and skill gaps (employer questions) (a) re there any occupations that you are unable to fill or have difficulty A in filling? • please name them (b) On average how long does it take before a vacancy is filled? (c) ow do your wage rates for these shortage occupations compare with H those of your main competitors in the labour market? • above average; • average; • below average. (d) What are the main reasons for these labour shortages? • lack of qualified applicants; • the job is unattractive; • location; • other, please specify. (e) re there any occupations in which existing employees do not have the A required qualification, experience and/or specialised skills to perform the job to acceptable or most efficient levels? • please name them (f) What are the main reasons for these skill deficiencies? • skill shortages; • changing job requirements; • labour turnover; • other, please specify. (g) Which skills are inadequate? • technical/ICT; • numeracy; • literacy/communication skills; • problem solving; • teamwork; • other, please specify. (h) Why does the company not provide off-the-job training to remedy this? • costs; • time constraints; • no suitable training available; • other, please specify.
  • 77. Comprehensive schemata for skill mismatch questions in surveys 71 4. Skills obsolescence (employee questions) (a) Are there any skills you once possessed no longer required in your current job? • if so, please name them (b) Are there new skills which have emerged in your current job that you do not possess? • if so, please name them (c) o you consider that your ability to perform your current job has D diminished over time? (d) ow long does it take a new employee to become fully proficient in H the job? (e) Has this duration increased over time? (f) o you think that you will be able to continue in your present job until D the normal age of retirement? (g) Has training been provided by your employer to update your skills? (h) If so, when and how often has this been provided?
  • 78. References Acemoglu, D. (2002). Technical change, inequality and the Labour Market. Journal of Economic Literature, XL, 7-72. Alba-Ramirez, A. (1993). Mismatch in the Spanish labor market. Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 28, No 2, p. 259-278. Alba-Ramirez, A.; Blázquez, M. (2003). Types of job match, overeducation and labour mobility in Spain. In Büchel, F. et al. Overeducation in Europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 65-92. Allen, J. et al. (2006). Wage effects of job-worker mismatches: heterogeneous skills or institutional effects. Maastricht: ROA – Research Centre for Education and the Labour Market. Allen, J.; van der Velden, R. (2001). Educational mismatches versus skill mismatches: effects on wages, job satisfaction, and on-the-job search. Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 53, No 3, p. 434-452. Allen, J.; van der Velden, R. (2007). When do skills become obsolete, and when does it matter? In De Grip, A. et al. (eds). The economics of skills obsolescence, p. 27-50. Alpin, C. et al. (1998). Over and undereducation in the UK graduate labour market. Studies in Higher Education, Vol. 1, p. 17-34. Arrow, K.J.; Capron, W.M. (1959). Dynamic shortages and price rises: the engi- neer-scientist case. Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 73, p. 292-308. Asplund, R.; Lilja, R. (2000). Has the Finnish labour market bumped the least educated? In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The over- educated worker: the economics of skill utilisation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 57-76. Badillo-Amador, L.; Vila, L.E. (2008). Education and skill mismatches: wage and job satisfaction consequences. Cartagena: Polytechnic University of Cartagena. Battu, H. et al. (1999). Overeducation among graduates: a cohort view. Education Economics, Vol. 17, No 1, p. 21-38. Battu, H. et al. (2000). How well can we measure graduate overeducation and its effects? National Institute Economic Review, No 171, January 2000, p. 82-93.
  • 79. References 73 Battu, H.; Sloane, P.J. (2000). Overeducation and crowding out in Britain. In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The overeducated worker. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 157-174. Battu, H.; Sloane, P.J. (2004) Over-education and ethnic minorities in Britain. Manchester School, Vol. 72, No 4, p. 535-559. Bauer, T. (2002). Educational mismatch and wages: a panel analysis. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 21, p. 221-229. Becker, G. (1964). Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education. Irvington, NY: Columbia University Press. Belfield, C.R.; Harris, R.D.F.(2002). How well do theories of job matching explain variations in job satisfaction across education levels? Evidence for UK graduates. Applied Economics, Vol. 34, p. 535- 548. Bennett, J.; McGuinness, S. (2009). Assessing the impact of skill shortages on the productivity performance of high-tech firms in Northern Ireland. Applied Economics, Vol. 41, No 6, p. 727-737. Blechinger, D.; Pfeiffer, F. (2000). Technological change and skill obsolescence: the case of German apprenticeship training. In Heijke, H.; Musken, J. (eds). Education and training in a knowledge- based economy. London: MacMillan, p. 243-276. Bockerman, P.; Ilmakunnas, P. (2009). Job disamenities, job satisfaction, quit intentions and actual separations; putting the pieces together. Industrial Relations, Vol. 48, No 1, p. 73-96. Booth, A.; Snower, D. (1996). Acquiring skills: market failures, their symptoms and policy responses. Cambridge: University Press. Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (2000). The debate in economics about skill utilisation. In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The overeducated worker. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 3-26. Bosworth, D.L. (1978). The rate of obsolescence of technical knowledge: a note. Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. XXVI, No 3, p. 273-279. Brunello, G. et al. (2007) (eds). Education and training in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Brynin, M.; Longhi, S. (2009). Overqualification: major or minor mismatch? Economics of Education Review, Vol. 28, p. 114-121. Büchel, F. (2002). The effects of overeducation on productivity in Germany: the firm’s viewpoint. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 21, p. 263-275.
  • 80. 74 The skill matching challenge Büchel, F.; Battu, H. (2003). The theory of differential overqualification: does it work? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 50, No 1, p. 1-16. Büchel, F.; Pollmann-Schult, M. (2001). Overeducation and skill endow- ments: the role of school achievement and vocational training qual- ity. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labour (Discussion paper, No 337). Büchel, F.; van Ham, M. (2002). Overeducation, regional labour markets and spatial flexibility. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA Discussion papers, No 424). Burdett, K. (1978). A theory of employee job search and quit rates. American Economic Review, Vol. 68, No 1, p. 212-220. Burris, V. (1983). The social and political consequence of overeducation. American Sociological Review, Vol. 48, No 4, p. 454-469. Cardoso, A. (2007). Jobs for young university graduates. Economics Letters, 94, 271-277. Cedefop (2008). Future skill needs in Europe: medium term forecast: synthesis report. Luxembourg: Publications Office. Cedefop (2009). Skill mismatch: identifying priorities for future research. Luxembourg: Publications Office (Working paper, No 3). Cedefop; Büchel, F. (2001). Overqualification: reasons, measurement issues and typological affinity to unemployment. In Cedefop; Descy, P.; Tessaring, M. Training in Europe: second report on vocational training research in Europe 2000: background report volume 2. Luxembourg: Publications Office. Cedefop; Descy, P.; Tessaring, M. (2001). Training and learning for competence: second report on vocational training research in Europe: synthesis report. Luxembourg: Publications Office (Cedefop Reference series). Chevalier, A. (2003). Measuring over-education. Economica, Vol. 70, No 3, p. 509-531. Cohn, E.; Khan, P. (1995). The wage effects of overschooling revisited. Labour Economics, Vol. 2, Issue 1, p. 67-76. Cohn, E.; Ng, C.Y. (2000). Incidence and wage effects of underschooling and overschooling in Hong Kong. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19, p. 159-168. Connolly, S. (1996). Does training choice depend on prospective returns? East Anglia: Economics Research Centre (ERC Working paper, 9604).
  • 81. References 75 Daly, A. et al. (1985). Productivity, machinery and skills in a sample of British and German manufacturing plants. National Institute Economic Review, Vol. 111, No 1, p. 48-61. Daly, M. et al. (2000). Premiums and penalties for surplus and deficit education: evidence from the United States and Germany. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19, p. 169-178. De Grip, A. et al. (2008). Job-worker mismatch and cognitive decline. Oxford Economic Papers, No 60, p. 237-253. De Grip, A.; van Loo, J. (2007). The economics of skills obsolescence: a review. In de Grip, A. et al. (eds). The economics of skills obsolescence: theoretical innovations and empirical applications. Bingley: Emerald, p. 1-26 (Research in Labor Economics, Vol. 21). De Oliveira, M. (2000). The role of human capital and technological change in overeducation. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19, p. 199- 206. Dekker, R. et al. (2002). The effects of training and overeducation on career mobility in a segmented labour market. International Journal of Manpower, Vol. 23, No 2, p. 106-125. Dolado, J.J. et al. (2009). On-the-job search in a matching model with heterogenous jobs and workers. Economic Journal, No 119, p. 200- 228. Dolton, P.; Siles, M. (2003). The determinants and consequences of overeducation. In Büchel, F. et al. (eds). Overeducation in Europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 189-217. Dolton, P.; Vignoles, A. (2000). The incidence and effects of overeducation in the UK graduate labour market. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19, No 2, p. 179-198. Duncan, J.; Hoffman, S. (1981). The incidence and wage effects of overe- ducation. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 1, No 1, 7p. 5-86. Dupuy, A.; de Grip, A. (2002). Do large firms have more opportunities to substitute between skill categories than small firms? Aarhus: Centre for Labour Market and Social Research (Working paper 02-01). Erini, J. (2005). An examination of the Northern Ireland labour market for construction skills. Belfast: DEL – Department for Employment and Learning. European Commission (2008a). The Bordeaux communiqué on enhanced European cooperation in vocational education and training. Communiqué of the European Ministers for Vocational Education and Training, the European social partners and the European
  • 82. 76 The skill matching challenge Commission, meeting in Bordeaux on 26 November 2008 to review the priorities and strategies of the Copenhagen process. Brussels: European Commission. European Commission (2008b). Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions: new skills for new jobs; anticipating and matching labour market and skills needs. Luxembourg: Publications Office (COM(2008) 868 final). Finegold, D.; Soskice, D. (1988). The failure of training in Britain: analysis and prescription. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 4, No 3, p. 21-52. Fleming, C.M.; Kler, P. (2007). I’m too clever for this job: a bivariate probit analysis on overeducation and job satisfaction in Australia. Applied Economics, i-First, p. 1-16. Forth, J.; Mason, G. (2004). The impact of high-level skill shortages on firm-level performance: evidence from the UK technical graduate labour market. London: NIESR – National Institute of Economic and Social Research (Discussion paper, 235). Frank, R.H. (1978). Why women earn less: the theory and estimation of differential overqualification. American Economic Review, Vol. 68, No 3, p. 360-373. Freeman, R.B. (1976). The overeducated American. New York: Academic Press. Frenette, M. (2004). The overqualified Canadian graduate: the role of the academic program in the incidence, persistence, and economic re- turns to overqualification. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 23, No 1, p. 29-45. Frogner, M.L. (2002). Skill shortages. Labour Market Trends, January 2002, p. 17-27. Galasi, P. (2008). The effect of educational mismatch on wages for 25 countries. Budapest: Corvinus University (Working papers on the Labour Market, BWP – 2008/8). Gautier, P. (2000). Do more high skilled workers occupy simple jobs during bad times? In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The overeducated worker. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 203-230. Gielen, A.C. (2008). Repeated job quits: stepping stones or learning about quantity. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labour (Discussion paper, No 3838).
  • 83. References 77 Goldthorpe, J.H.; Hope, K. (1974). Social grading of occupations: a new approach and scale. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Gottschalk, P.; Hansen, M. (2003). Is the proportion of college workers in non-college jobs increasing? Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 21, p. 449-471. Grazier, S. et al. (2008). Graduate employment in the UK: an application of the Gottschalk-Hansen model. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labour (Discussion paper, No 3618). Green, F. et al. (1998). The meaning and determinants of skills shortages. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 60, No 2, p. 165-87. Green, F. et al. (1999). Overeducation and skills: clarifying the concepts. London: Centre for Economic Performance. Green, F.; McIntosh, S. (2007). Is there a genuine under-utilisation of skills amongst the over-qualified? Applied Economics, Vol. 39, p. 427-439. Green, F.; Zhu, Y. (2008). Overqualification, job dissatisfaction, and increasing dispersion in the returns to graduate education. Kent: University of Kent, Department of Economics (Discussion papers KDPE 08/03). Groeneveld, S.; Hartog, J. (2004). Overeducation, wages and promotions within the firm. Labour Economics, Vol. 11, No 6, p. 701-714. Groot, W. (1993). Overeducation and the returns to enterprise related schooling. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 17, No 4, p. 299- 309. Groot, W. (1996). The incidence and returns to overeducation in the UK. Applied Economics Vol. 28, p. 1345-1350. Groot, W.; Maassen van den Brink, H. (2000). Overeducation in the labor market: a meta analysis. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19, Issue 2, p. 149-158. Halaby, C.N. (1994). Overeducation and skill mismatch. Sociology of Education, Vol. 67, p. 47-59. Hannan, D.F. et al. (1998). Trading qualifications for jobs: overeducation and the Irish youth labour market. Dublin: ESRI. Hartog, J. (2000). Overeducation and earnings: where are we, where should we go? Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19, No 2, p. 131-148. Hartog, J.; Oosterbeek, H. (1988). Education, allocation and earnings in the Netherlands: overschooling? Economics of Education Review, Vol. 7, No 2, p. 185-194.
  • 84. 78 The skill matching challenge Haskel, J.; Holt, R. (1999). Anticipating future skill needs: can it be done? Does it need to be done? Sudbury: DfEE (Skills task force research group, Research paper 1). Haskel, J.; Martin, C. (2001). Technology, wages and skill shortages: evi- dence from UK micro data. Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 53, No 4, p. 642-658. Haskel, J.; Martin, C. (1996). Skill shortages, productivity growth and wage inflation. In Booth, A.; Snower, D. (eds). Acquiring skills: market failures: their symptoms and policy responses. Cambridge: University Press, p. 147-174. Hersch, J. (1991). Education and job match. Review of Economics and Statistics, No 79, p. 140-144. Hersch, J. (1995). Optimal mismatch and promotions. Economic Inquiry, No 33, p. 611-624. Hogarth, T.; Wilson, R. (2001). Skills matter: a synthesis of research on the extent, causes and implications of skills deficiencies. Nottingham: Department for Education and Skills (DFES report SMSI). Jochman, M.; Pohlmeier, W. (2003). The causal effect of overqualification on earnings: evidence from a Bayesian approach. In Büchel, F. et al. Overeducation in Europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 93-108. Johansson, M.; Katz, K. (2007). Wage differences between women and men in Sweden: the impact of skill mismatch. Uppsala: IFAU – Institute for Labour Market Policy Evaluation (Working paper 2007- 13). Jones, M.K. et al. (2009). Training, job satisfaction and workplace performance in Britain: evidence from WERS 2004. Labour, Vol. 23, No s1, p. 139-175. Jovanovic, B. (1979). Job matching and the theory of turnover. Journal of Political Economy, No 87, p. 972-990. Kaufman, H.G. (1974). Obsolescence and professional career development. New York: Amacom. Kaufman, H.G. (1975) (ed.). Career management: a guide to combating obsolescence. New York: IEEE Press/Wiley Interscience. Kaufman, H.G. (1989). Obsolescence of technical professionals: a measure and a model. Applied Psychology: an International Review, Vol. 38, No 1, p. 73-85. Kelly, E. et al. (2008). The economic returns to field of study and competencies among higher education graduates in Ireland. Dublin: ESRI – European Studies Research Institute (Working paper, No 242).
  • 85. References 79 Kiker, B. et al. (1997). Overeducation and undereducation: evidence for Portugal. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 16, p. 111-125. Kler, P. (2006). The impact of overeducation on job satisfaction among tertiary educated Australians. St. Lucia: University of Queensland (LERG – Labour Economics Research Group, Discussion paper, No 10). Kucel, A.; Byrne, D. (2008). Are overeducated people insiders or outsiders? A case of job search methods and overeducation in the UK. Dublin: ESRI – European Studies Research Insitute (Working paper, No 258). Lindley, J. (2009). The over-education of UK immigrants and minority ethnic groups: evidence from the labour force survey. Economics of Education Review, No 28, p. 80-89. Linsley, I. (2005). Overeducation in the Australian labour market: its incidence and effects. Victoria: University of Melbourne, Department of Economics Research Group (Discussion paper, No 939). Mason, G.; Wilson, R. (2003). Employer skill survey: new analysis and lessons learned. London: NIESR – National Institute of Economic and Social Research. Mavromaras, K. et al. (2009a). Assessing the incidence and wage effects of over-skilling in the Australian labour market. Economic Record, Vol. 85, No 268, p. 60-72. Mavromaras, K. et al. (2009b). Overskilling dynamics and education pathways. Melbourne: Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research (Working paper, No 22/09). Mavromaras, K. et al. (2009c). The incidence and wage effects of overskilling among employed VET graduates. Monograph prepared for the National Centre for Vocational Education Research, Adelaide, Australia. Mavromaras, K. et al. (2009d). The problem of overskilling in Australia and Britain. Manchester School (forthcoming). McGoldrick, K.M.; Robst, J. (1996). Gender differences in overeducation: a test of the theory of differential overqualification. American Economic Review, No 86, p. 280-284. McGuinness, S. (2003a). Graduate overeducation as a sheepskin effect: evidence from Northern Ireland. Applied Economics, Vol. 35, No 5, p. 597-608. McGuinness, S. (2003b). University quality and labour market outcomes. Applied Economics Vol. 35, Issue 18, p. 1943-1955.
  • 86. 80 The skill matching challenge McGuinness, S. (2006). Overeducation in the labour market. Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 20, No 3, p. 387-418. McGuinness, S.; Bennett, J. (2006). Examining the link between skill shortages, training composition and productivity levels in the Northern Ireland construction industry, International Journal of Human Resource Management, Vol. 17, No 2, p. 265-279. McGuinness, S.; Bonner, K. (2002). Employer characteristics and practices as drivers of unfilled IT vacancies. Service Industries Journal, Vol. 22, No 4, p. 137-153. McGuinness, S.; Doyle, J. (2003). Three years on: reassessing the Northern Ireland labour market for IT skills. Belfast: DEL – Department for Employment and Learning. McGuinness, S.; Doyle, J. (2005). An examination of the Northern Ireland labour market for construction skills. Belfast: DEL – Department for Employment and Learning. McGuinness, S.; Wooden, M. (2007). Overskilling, job insecurity and career mobility: evidence from Australia. Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labour (Discussion paper, 2938). Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, experience and earnings. New York: Columbia University Press. Neugart, M.; Schomann, K. (2002). Employment outlooks: why forecast the labour market and for whom? Berlin: WZB – Social Science Research Center Berlin (Discussion paper FS I 02-206). Neuman, S.; Weiss, A. (1995). On the effects of schooling vintage on experience – earnings profiles: theory and evidence. European Economic Review, Vol. 39, No 5, p. 943-955. Nicaise, I. (2000) The effect of bumping down on wages: an empirical test. In Borghans, L.; de Grip, A. (eds). The overeducated worker. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, p. 175-190. Nickell, S.; Nicolitsas, D. (1997). Human capital, investment and innovation: what are the connections? London: Centre for Economic Performance (Discussion paper, No 20). NIERC (2000) – Northern Ireland Economic Research Centre. A study of the Northern Ireland labour market for IT skills. Belfast: DHFETE – Department of Higher and Further Education Training and Employment. NIERC (2001) – Northern Ireland Economic Research Centre. A study of labour market conditions in the Northern Ireland electronics industry. Belfast: DEL – Department for Employment and Learning.
  • 87. References 81 NIERC (2002) – Northern Ireland Economic Research Centre. A study of the Northern Ireland labour market for mechanical engineering skills. Belfast: DEL – Department for Employment and Learning. Nordin, M. et al. (2008). Education-occupation mismatch: is there an income penalty? Bonn: IZA – Institute for the Study of Labour (Discussion paper, No 3806). Ochsen, C. (2009). On the measurement of mismatch. Applied Economics Letters, No 16, p. 405-409. Pazy, A. (1998). Concept and career-stage differentiation in obsolescence re- search. Journal of Organisational Behaviour, Vol. 17, No 1, p. 59-78. Pazy, A. (2006). The threat of professional obsolescence: how do professionals at different career stages experience it and cope with it? Human Resource Management, Vol. 29, No 3, p. 251-269. Pigou, A.C. (1912). Wealth and welfare. London: Macmillan. Richardson, S. (2006). What is a skill shortage? Adelaide: National Institute of Labour Studies. Robst, J. (1995). Career mobility, job match, and overeducation. Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 21, No 4, p. 539-550. Robst, J. (2008). Overeducation and college major: expanding the defini- tion of mismatch between schooling and jobs. Manchester School, Vol. 76, No 4, p. 349-368. Rumberger, R. (1987). The impact of surplus education on productivity and earnings. Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 22, No 1, p. 24-50. Sattinger, M. (1993). Assignment models of the distribution of earnings. Journal of Economic Literature, No 31, p. 831-880. Schlotter, M. (2008). Origins and consequences of changes in labour/ market skill needs. Analytical report for the European Commission. Munich: EENEE – European Expert Network on Economics of Education. Sicherman, N. (1991). Overeducation in the labour market. Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 9, No 2, p. 101-122. Sicherman, N.; Galor, O. (1990). A theory of career mobility. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No 1, p. 169-192. Skott, P. (2006). Wage inequality and over-education in a model with efficiency wages. Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 39, No 1, p. 94-123. Sloane, P.J. (2003). Much ado about nothing? What does the overeducation literature really tell us? In Büchel, F. et al. (eds). Overeducation in Europe: current issues in theory and policy. Cheltenham: Edward
  • 88. 82 The skill matching challenge Elgar, p. 11-48. Sloane, P.J. et al. (1996). Overeducation and the formal education/ experience and training trade-off. Applied Economics Letters, No 3, p. 511-515. Sloane, P.J. et al. (1999). Overeducation, undereducation and the British labour market. Applied Economics, No 31, p. 1437-1453. Stigler, G.J. (1961). The economics of information. Journal of Political Economy, No 69, p. 213-225. Tether, B. et al. (2005). A literature review on skills and innovation: how does successful innovation impact on the demand for skills and how do skills drive innovation? Manchester: ESRC – Centre for Research on Innovation and Competition. Thijssen, J.G.L. (2005). Niet meer up-to-date: de betekenis van (perspec- tivische) obsoletie nader verkend [No longer up-to-date: the mean- ing of (perspectivistic) obsolescence]. BBV-Bulletin, Vol. 12, No 1, p. 4-10. Thurow, L.C. (1975). Generating inequality. New York: Basic Books. Trimmer, K.J. et al. (1998). An evaluation of factors affecting professional obsolescence of information technology professionals. Proceedings of the 31st annual Hawaii international conference on system sciences. New York: IEEE, p. 406-415. Tsang, M.C. (1987). The impact of the underutilisation of education on productivity: a case study of the US Bell companies. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 6, No 3, p. 239-254. Tsang, M.C. et al. (1991). The impact of surplus schooling on worker productivity. Industrial Relations, Vol. 30, No 2, p. 209-228. Tsang, M.C.; Levin, H.M. (1985). The economics of overeducation. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 4, No 2, p. 93-104. Vahey, S. (2000) The great Canadian training robbery: evidence on the returns to educational mismatch. Economics of Education Review, Vol. 19, p. 219-227. Van Loo, J. et al. (2001). Skills obsolescence: causes and cures. International Journal of Manpower, Vol. 22, No 1/2, p. 121-137. Van Ours, J.C.; Ridder, G. (1995). Job matching and job competition: are lower educated workers at the back of job queues? European Economic Review, Vol. 39, No 9, p. 1717-1731. Verdugo, R.; Verdugo, N. (1989). The impact of surplus schooling on earnings. Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 24, No 4, p. 629-643. Verhaest, D.; Omey, E. (2006). Discriminating between alternative
  • 89. References 83 measures of overeducation. Applied Economics, Vol. 38, p. 2113- 2120. Weinberg, B.A. (2007). New technologies, skills obsolescence, and skill complementarity. In De Grip A. et al. (eds). The economics of skills obsolescence: theoretical innovations and empirical applications. Bingley: Emerald, p. 101-118 (Research in Labor Economics series, Vol. 21). Weststar, J. (2009). Worker control as a facilitator in the match between education and jobs. British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 47, No 4, p. 723-740.
  • 91. The skill matching challenge Analysing skill mismatch and policy implications Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union 2010 - 83 pp. - 17 x 24 cm ISBN 978-92-896-0485-7 Cat. No: TI-31-10-301-EN-C Free of charge - On request from Cedefop No of publication: 3056 EN