SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Behaviour, and
         communication

                          4th
                             August 2012
            Oliver Payne, founder, The Hunting Dynasty
Author of ‘Inspiring Sustainable Behaviour: 19 ways to ask for change’
                    oliver@thehuntingdynasty.com

                            |   How, do you change behaviour?
What is common to us all?




          |   How do you change behaviour?
|   How do you change behaviour?
dark v roads




 |   How do you change behaviour?
|   How do you change behaviour?
|   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                           (quasi-stationary
Context                    equilibria)
(situational influences)                                  Construal
                                                          (subjective influence)




                            |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                           (quasi-stationary
Context                    equilibria)
(situational influences)                                  Construal
                                                          (subjective influence)




                            |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                                    (quasi-stationary
     Context                        equilibria)
     (situational influences)                                      Construal
                                                                   (subjective influence)
Decision-making is
relative to what
you can have, not
absolutely about
what you want.

Your decision is affected by
what’s on offer – to the point
where the addition or subtraction
of things you don’t want still
affects your decision.




                                     |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                                         (quasi-stationary
     Context                             equilibria)
     (situational influences)                                           Construal
                                                                        (subjective influence)
Decision-making is                  Shared
relative to what                    understanding
you can have, not                   about expectations
absolutely about                    of behaviour within
what you want.                      a group.
                                    We tend to conform to
                                    expectations even though we
Your decision is affected by        like to think of ourselves as
what’s on offer – to the point      making personal and
where the addition or subtraction   principled decisions.
of things you don’t want still
affects your decision.              (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . . .
                                    Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc)




                                          |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                                        (quasi-stationary
     Context                            equilibria)
     (situational influences)                                           Construal
                                                                        (subjective influence)
Decision-making is                  Shared
relative to what                    understanding         Where you think
you can have, not                   about expectationsabout something
absolutely about                    of behaviour withinrelative to yourself
what you want.                      a group.              affects what you
                                    We tend to conform to
                                                          think about it
                                    expectations even though we
Your decision is affected by        like to think of ourselves as      The closer – or more proximal –
what’s on offer – to the point      making personal and                events are the more we think
where the addition or subtraction   principled decisions.              about ‘actions’; the further away
of things you don’t want still                                         – or distal – events are the more
affects your decision.              (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . we think ‘in theory’
                                                                       ..
                                    Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc)       - Here/not here
                                                                       - Me/not me
                                                                       - Now/not now
                                                                       - Clear/Unclear
                                          |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                                    (quasi-stationary
     Context                        equilibria)
     (situational influences)                                      Construal
                                                                   (subjective influence)
Decision-making is
relative to what
you can have, not
absolutely about
what you want.

Your decision is affected by
what’s on offer – to the point
where the addition or subtraction
of things you don’t want still
affects your decision.




                                     |   How do you change behaviour?
Context




Rolls Royce were having
  problems selling cars in their
  regular showrooms.




                               |   How do you change behaviour?
Context



                                         So they sold them at Yacht fairs,
Rolls Royce were having                    where the items on sale go for
  problems selling cars in their           a few million rather than a few
  regular showrooms.                       hundred thousand.




                               |   How do you change behaviour?
Context



                                         So they sold them at Yacht fairs,
Rolls Royce were having                    where the items on sale go for
  problems selling cars in their           a few million rather than a few
  regular showrooms.                       hundred thousand.



                                           (I've saved £8m not
                                             buying that yacht…
                                             what's £350k for a
                                             lovely car?!)


                               |   How do you change behaviour?
Context



Huber & Puto beer
choice experiement
‘Market boundaries and product
choice’ 1983




        |   How do you change behaviour?
$1.80              $2.60
                                      Context




30%                  70%




   |   How do you change behaviour?
$1.80              $2.60
$1.60                                         Context




        30%                  70%




           |   How do you change behaviour?
$1.80              $2.60
$1.60                                         Context




0%
        50%                  50%




           |   How do you change behaviour?
$1.80              $2.60
                                      Context




30%                  70%




   |   How do you change behaviour?
$1.80              $2.60              $3.40
                                              Context




30%                  70%




   |   How do you change behaviour?
$1.80              $2.60              $3.40
                                              Context




                                      10%
0%                   90%




   |   How do you change behaviour?
$1.80               $2.60              $3.40
$1.60                                                      Context



        Huber & Puto beer
        choice experiement
        ‘Market boundaries and product
        choice’ 1983

0%                                                 10%
             30%                  70%




          Who are we?


                |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                                    (quasi-stationary
     Context                        equilibria)
     (situational influences)                                      Construal
                                                                   (subjective influence)
Decision-making is
relative to what
you can have, not
absolutely about
what you want.

Your decision is affected by
what’s on offer – to the point
where the addition or subtraction
of things you don’t want still
affects your decision.




                                     |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                                (quasi-stationary
Context                         equilibria)
(situational influences)                                       Construal
                                                               (subjective influence)
                           Shared
                           understanding
                           about expectations
                           of behaviour within
                           a group.
                           We tend to conform to
                           expectations even though we
                           like to think of ourselves as
                           making personal and
                           principled decisions.

                           (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . . .
                           Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc)




                                 |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms




In Australia, tax-payers
   were informed that
   normal practice was
   honesty in tax returns




   HEADS, YOU DIE: Bad decisions, choice architecture, and how to mitigate predictable irrationality | Jack Fuller | Per Capita research



                                                            |   How do you change behaviour?behaviour?
                                                                           create sustainable
Norms


          The discrepancy between the average behaviour of
            people and the perceived behaviour of the average
            person can be pretty wide.




                                 Deductions plunged by 47%
                                        (675,000,000 Aus$ extra revenue)

HEADS, YOU DIE: Bad decisions, choice architecture, and how to mitigate predictable irrationality | Jack Fuller | Per Capita research



                                                         |   How do you change behaviour?behaviour?
                                                                        create sustainable
Norms




Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20



                                   |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms




People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park.


 Many past visitors have                                                                  Please don’t remove the
removed petrified wood                                                                  petrified wood from the Park,
from the Park, changing                               [nothing]                                in order to preserve
     the natural state                                                                         the natural state
  of the Petrified Forest                                                                   of the Petrified Forest

Signs were tested to stop the theft: Some more successful than others…




               Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20



                                                  |    How do you change behaviour?
Norms




People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park.


 Many past visitors have                                                                  Please don’t remove the
removed petrified wood                                                                  petrified wood from the Park,
from the Park, changing                               [nothing]                                in order to preserve
     the natural state                                                                         the natural state
  of the Petrified Forest                                                                   of the Petrified Forest

       8% theft




               Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20



                                                  |    How do you change behaviour?
Norms




People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park.


 Many past visitors have                                                                  Please don’t remove the
removed petrified wood                                                                  petrified wood from the Park,
from the Park, changing                               [nothing]                                in order to preserve
     the natural state                                                                         the natural state
  of the Petrified Forest                                                                   of the Petrified Forest

       8% theft                                    3% theft




               Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20



                                                  |    How do you change behaviour?
Norms




People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park.


 Many past visitors have                                                                  Please don’t remove the
removed petrified wood                                                                  petrified wood from the Park,
from the Park, changing                               [nothing]                                in order to preserve
     the natural state                                                                         the natural state
  of the Petrified Forest                                                                   of the Petrified Forest

       8% theft                                    3% theft                                           1.7% theft




               Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20



                                                  |    How do you change behaviour?
Norms




People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park.


 Many past visitors have                                                                  Please don’t remove the
removed petrified wood                                                                  petrified wood from the Park,
from the Park, changing                               [nothing]                                in order to preserve
     the natural state                                                                         the natural state
  of the Petrified Forest                                                                   of the Petrified Forest

       8% theft                                    3% theft                                           1.7% theft
      “…a message that focuses recipients on the injunctive norm will
       be superior to messages that focus recipients on the descriptive
                            norm.” (Cialdini et al., 2003)
               Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20



                                                  |    How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                                (quasi-stationary
Context                         equilibria)
(situational influences)                                       Construal
                                                               (subjective influence)
                           Shared
                           understanding
                           about expectations
                           of behaviour within
                           a group.
                           We tend to conform to
                           expectations even though we
                           like to think of ourselves as
                           making personal and
                           principled decisions.

                           (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . . .
                           Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc)




                                 |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                           (quasi-stationary
Context                    equilibria)
(situational influences)                                  Construal
                                                          (subjective influence)

                                                          Where you think
                                                          about something
                                                          relative to yourself
                                                          affects what you
                                                          think about it
                                                          The closer – or more proximal –
                                                          events are the more we think
                                                          about ‘actions’; the further away
                                                          – or distal – events are the more
                                                          we think ‘in theory’
                                                          - Here/not here
                                                          - Me/not me
                                                          - Now/not now
                                                          - Clear/Unclear
                            |   How do you change behaviour?
US hybrid sales 2000 –’ 06                                              Temporal
                                                                       discounting
(3,000 to 250,000)



                                                                  1

              1
          Sales tax incentive: $1k



                $1,000                                     $2,000
                Kick-back                                  Kick-back




                               |   How do you change behaviour?
US hybrid sales 2000 –’ 06                                                Temporal
(3,000 to 250,000)                                                       discounting




                                                                  1

              1
          Sales tax incentive: $1k



                $1,000                                     $2,000
                Sales tax discount                         Income tax rebate




                               |   How do you change behaviour?
US hybrid sales 2000 –’ 06                                                Temporal
(3,000 to 250,000)                                                       discounting




                                                                  1

              1
          Sales tax incentive: $1k



                $1,000                                     $2,000
                Sales tax discount                         Income tax rebate

                     Now                                          Not now

                               |   How do you change behaviour?
US hybrid sales 2000 –’ 06                                                   Temporal
                                                                            discounting
(3,000 to 250,000)
              7       6
        5
    3                4                                               1
        2
              1

                  $1,000                                      $2,000
                  Sales tax discount                          Income tax rebate

                      Now                                            Not now
              The tendency for people to have excessively stronger
              preferences for immediate gains relative to future gains.

                                  |   How do you change behaviour?
Norms
                                        (quasi-stationary
     Context                            equilibria)
     (situational influences)                                           Construal
                                                                        (subjective influence)
Decision-making is                  Shared
relative to what                    understanding         Where you think
you can have, not                   about expectationsabout something
absolutely about                    of behaviour withinrelative to yourself
what you want.                      a group.              affects what you
                                    We tend to conform to
                                                          think about it
                                    expectations even though we
Your decision is affected by        like to think of ourselves as      The closer – or more proximal –
what’s on offer – to the point      making personal and                events are the more we think
where the addition or subtraction   principled decisions.              about ‘actions’; the further away
of things you don’t want still                                         – or distal – events are the more
affects your decision.              (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . we think ‘in theory’
                                                                       ..
                                    Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc)       - Here/not here
                                                                       - Me/not me
                                                                       - Now/not now
                                                                       - Clear/Unclear
                                          |   How do you change behaviour?
“Just as no building lacks an
  architecture, so no choice
       lacks a context.”
      Dr. Robert Cialdini, ex-Regents' Professor of Psychology and
      Marketing Arizona State University




                       |   How do you change behaviour?
Thank you




  |   How do you change behaviour?

More Related Content

PDF
Ft pt mba_eibe_2011-12_9-systems_thinking_scenario_planning
PDF
Fish@noon a4 poster 04 feb 2013
PPT
Sustainability Edinburgh Personas introduction & workshop
PDF
E design affordance theory-mental models
PPTX
Diversity Management For Serious Players Flash
PPTX
behavioural communication
PPTX
Behavioural Communcation For Personal and Professional Development by Munish
Ft pt mba_eibe_2011-12_9-systems_thinking_scenario_planning
Fish@noon a4 poster 04 feb 2013
Sustainability Edinburgh Personas introduction & workshop
E design affordance theory-mental models
Diversity Management For Serious Players Flash
behavioural communication
Behavioural Communcation For Personal and Professional Development by Munish

Viewers also liked (20)

PPTX
Communication behaviour
PPT
Interpersonal communication
PPT
Interpersonal Communication
PPTX
Behavioural change communication 1
PPT
Self disclosure
PPT
Building rapport
PPT
Building Rapport
PPTX
Interpesonal communication ppt
PPTX
Communication and interpersonal relationships ppt
DOCX
Behavior_Change_Communication_manual_-experimental_1_
PPT
Rapport - Main Aspects
PPTX
Self disclosure
PPT
Interpersonal communication
PPTX
Building rapport
PPTX
Building Rapport in Business
PPT
Models of interpersonal communications
PPTX
Building Successful Rapport
PPTX
Organizational beahviour till personality
PPT
Individual differences and work behaviour
PPT
Chapter 5: Intrapersonal Communication
Communication behaviour
Interpersonal communication
Interpersonal Communication
Behavioural change communication 1
Self disclosure
Building rapport
Building Rapport
Interpesonal communication ppt
Communication and interpersonal relationships ppt
Behavior_Change_Communication_manual_-experimental_1_
Rapport - Main Aspects
Self disclosure
Interpersonal communication
Building rapport
Building Rapport in Business
Models of interpersonal communications
Building Successful Rapport
Organizational beahviour till personality
Individual differences and work behaviour
Chapter 5: Intrapersonal Communication
Ad

Similar to Behaviour, and communication (12)

PPTX
Perception
PPT
Bim bangalore ob
PPT
B'lore ob1
PPTX
change the perception
PDF
Driving healthy habits through behavioral product design (short) pdf
PDF
Hearts, Minds, Will, Body, World, Tribe A Framework for Considering Consumer ...
PDF
Conclusion - Decision/action model for soccer - Boyd's snowmobiles - Analysis...
PPTX
ThinkBehaviour: 8 practical tips
PPTX
Perception
PDF
National Graduate Development Programme Keynote & Workshop
PPTX
GENN001 Fall2013 Session #3 seven habits
PPTX
Attitude
Perception
Bim bangalore ob
B'lore ob1
change the perception
Driving healthy habits through behavioral product design (short) pdf
Hearts, Minds, Will, Body, World, Tribe A Framework for Considering Consumer ...
Conclusion - Decision/action model for soccer - Boyd's snowmobiles - Analysis...
ThinkBehaviour: 8 practical tips
Perception
National Graduate Development Programme Keynote & Workshop
GENN001 Fall2013 Session #3 seven habits
Attitude
Ad

More from The Hunting Dynasty (10)

PPT
Dana Center/Sci. Museum 'Hot Heads' evening speaking and workshop
PPT
Wscc behaviour change capacity building workshop
PPT
Short: Using Behavioural Economics to sell carbon-reducing products & initiat...
PPTX
Green Unplugged
PPT
Creating Sustainable Behaviour, for Forum for the Future Master's scholars an...
PPTX
How do you create sustainable behaviour? Part II
PPTX
How do you create sustainable behaviour? Part III
PPTX
How do you create sustainable behaviour? Part I
PPT
Creating Sustainable Behaviour
PPT
Effective Communication And The Elevator Pitch Hunting Dynasty
Dana Center/Sci. Museum 'Hot Heads' evening speaking and workshop
Wscc behaviour change capacity building workshop
Short: Using Behavioural Economics to sell carbon-reducing products & initiat...
Green Unplugged
Creating Sustainable Behaviour, for Forum for the Future Master's scholars an...
How do you create sustainable behaviour? Part II
How do you create sustainable behaviour? Part III
How do you create sustainable behaviour? Part I
Creating Sustainable Behaviour
Effective Communication And The Elevator Pitch Hunting Dynasty

Recently uploaded (20)

PDF
Nante Industrial Plug Factory: Engineering Quality for Modern Power Applications
PPTX
chapter 2 entrepreneurship full lecture ppt
PDF
Satish NS: Fostering Innovation and Sustainability: Haier India’s Customer-Ce...
PDF
Daniels 2024 Inclusive, Sustainable Development
DOCX
Handbook of Entrepreneurship- Chapter 5: Identifying business opportunity.docx
PDF
Kishore Vora - Best CFO in India to watch in 2025.pdf
PPTX
Slide gioi thieu VietinBank Quy 2 - 2025
PDF
ICv2 White Paper - Gen Con Trade Day 2025
PPTX
2 - Self & Personality 587689213yiuedhwejbmansbeakjrk
PDF
TyAnn Osborn: A Visionary Leader Shaping Corporate Workforce Dynamics
PDF
Susan Semmelmann: Enriching the Lives of others through her Talents and Bless...
DOCX
Center Enamel Powering Innovation and Resilience in the Italian Chemical Indu...
PDF
income tax laws notes important pakistan
DOCX
Center Enamel A Strategic Partner for the Modernization of Georgia's Chemical...
PPTX
interschool scomp.pptxzdkjhdjvdjvdjdhjhieij
PPTX
svnfcksanfskjcsnvvjknsnvsdscnsncxasxa saccacxsax
PPTX
TRAINNING, DEVELOPMENT AND APPRAISAL.pptx
PDF
Charisse Litchman: A Maverick Making Neurological Care More Accessible
PPT
Lecture 3344;;,,(,(((((((((((((((((((((((
PDF
PMB 401-Identification-of-Potential-Biotechnological-Products.pdf
Nante Industrial Plug Factory: Engineering Quality for Modern Power Applications
chapter 2 entrepreneurship full lecture ppt
Satish NS: Fostering Innovation and Sustainability: Haier India’s Customer-Ce...
Daniels 2024 Inclusive, Sustainable Development
Handbook of Entrepreneurship- Chapter 5: Identifying business opportunity.docx
Kishore Vora - Best CFO in India to watch in 2025.pdf
Slide gioi thieu VietinBank Quy 2 - 2025
ICv2 White Paper - Gen Con Trade Day 2025
2 - Self & Personality 587689213yiuedhwejbmansbeakjrk
TyAnn Osborn: A Visionary Leader Shaping Corporate Workforce Dynamics
Susan Semmelmann: Enriching the Lives of others through her Talents and Bless...
Center Enamel Powering Innovation and Resilience in the Italian Chemical Indu...
income tax laws notes important pakistan
Center Enamel A Strategic Partner for the Modernization of Georgia's Chemical...
interschool scomp.pptxzdkjhdjvdjvdjdhjhieij
svnfcksanfskjcsnvvjknsnvsdscnsncxasxa saccacxsax
TRAINNING, DEVELOPMENT AND APPRAISAL.pptx
Charisse Litchman: A Maverick Making Neurological Care More Accessible
Lecture 3344;;,,(,(((((((((((((((((((((((
PMB 401-Identification-of-Potential-Biotechnological-Products.pdf

Behaviour, and communication

  • 1. Behaviour, and communication 4th August 2012 Oliver Payne, founder, The Hunting Dynasty Author of ‘Inspiring Sustainable Behaviour: 19 ways to ask for change’ oliver@thehuntingdynasty.com | How, do you change behaviour?
  • 2. What is common to us all? | How do you change behaviour?
  • 3. | How do you change behaviour?
  • 4. dark v roads | How do you change behaviour?
  • 5. | How do you change behaviour?
  • 6. | How do you change behaviour?
  • 7. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) | How do you change behaviour?
  • 8. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) | How do you change behaviour?
  • 9. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) Decision-making is relative to what you can have, not absolutely about what you want. Your decision is affected by what’s on offer – to the point where the addition or subtraction of things you don’t want still affects your decision. | How do you change behaviour?
  • 10. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) Decision-making is Shared relative to what understanding you can have, not about expectations absolutely about of behaviour within what you want. a group. We tend to conform to expectations even though we Your decision is affected by like to think of ourselves as what’s on offer – to the point making personal and where the addition or subtraction principled decisions. of things you don’t want still affects your decision. (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . . . Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc) | How do you change behaviour?
  • 11. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) Decision-making is Shared relative to what understanding Where you think you can have, not about expectationsabout something absolutely about of behaviour withinrelative to yourself what you want. a group. affects what you We tend to conform to think about it expectations even though we Your decision is affected by like to think of ourselves as The closer – or more proximal – what’s on offer – to the point making personal and events are the more we think where the addition or subtraction principled decisions. about ‘actions’; the further away of things you don’t want still – or distal – events are the more affects your decision. (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . we think ‘in theory’ .. Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc) - Here/not here - Me/not me - Now/not now - Clear/Unclear | How do you change behaviour?
  • 12. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) Decision-making is relative to what you can have, not absolutely about what you want. Your decision is affected by what’s on offer – to the point where the addition or subtraction of things you don’t want still affects your decision. | How do you change behaviour?
  • 13. Context Rolls Royce were having problems selling cars in their regular showrooms. | How do you change behaviour?
  • 14. Context So they sold them at Yacht fairs, Rolls Royce were having where the items on sale go for problems selling cars in their a few million rather than a few regular showrooms. hundred thousand. | How do you change behaviour?
  • 15. Context So they sold them at Yacht fairs, Rolls Royce were having where the items on sale go for problems selling cars in their a few million rather than a few regular showrooms. hundred thousand. (I've saved £8m not buying that yacht… what's £350k for a lovely car?!) | How do you change behaviour?
  • 16. Context Huber & Puto beer choice experiement ‘Market boundaries and product choice’ 1983 | How do you change behaviour?
  • 17. $1.80 $2.60 Context 30% 70% | How do you change behaviour?
  • 18. $1.80 $2.60 $1.60 Context 30% 70% | How do you change behaviour?
  • 19. $1.80 $2.60 $1.60 Context 0% 50% 50% | How do you change behaviour?
  • 20. $1.80 $2.60 Context 30% 70% | How do you change behaviour?
  • 21. $1.80 $2.60 $3.40 Context 30% 70% | How do you change behaviour?
  • 22. $1.80 $2.60 $3.40 Context 10% 0% 90% | How do you change behaviour?
  • 23. $1.80 $2.60 $3.40 $1.60 Context Huber & Puto beer choice experiement ‘Market boundaries and product choice’ 1983 0% 10% 30% 70% Who are we? | How do you change behaviour?
  • 24. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) Decision-making is relative to what you can have, not absolutely about what you want. Your decision is affected by what’s on offer – to the point where the addition or subtraction of things you don’t want still affects your decision. | How do you change behaviour?
  • 25. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) Shared understanding about expectations of behaviour within a group. We tend to conform to expectations even though we like to think of ourselves as making personal and principled decisions. (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . . . Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc) | How do you change behaviour?
  • 26. Norms In Australia, tax-payers were informed that normal practice was honesty in tax returns HEADS, YOU DIE: Bad decisions, choice architecture, and how to mitigate predictable irrationality | Jack Fuller | Per Capita research | How do you change behaviour?behaviour? create sustainable
  • 27. Norms The discrepancy between the average behaviour of people and the perceived behaviour of the average person can be pretty wide. Deductions plunged by 47% (675,000,000 Aus$ extra revenue) HEADS, YOU DIE: Bad decisions, choice architecture, and how to mitigate predictable irrationality | Jack Fuller | Per Capita research | How do you change behaviour?behaviour? create sustainable
  • 28. Norms Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20 | How do you change behaviour?
  • 29. Norms People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park. Many past visitors have Please don’t remove the removed petrified wood petrified wood from the Park, from the Park, changing [nothing] in order to preserve the natural state the natural state of the Petrified Forest of the Petrified Forest Signs were tested to stop the theft: Some more successful than others… Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20 | How do you change behaviour?
  • 30. Norms People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park. Many past visitors have Please don’t remove the removed petrified wood petrified wood from the Park, from the Park, changing [nothing] in order to preserve the natural state the natural state of the Petrified Forest of the Petrified Forest 8% theft Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20 | How do you change behaviour?
  • 31. Norms People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park. Many past visitors have Please don’t remove the removed petrified wood petrified wood from the Park, from the Park, changing [nothing] in order to preserve the natural state the natural state of the Petrified Forest of the Petrified Forest 8% theft 3% theft Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20 | How do you change behaviour?
  • 32. Norms People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park. Many past visitors have Please don’t remove the removed petrified wood petrified wood from the Park, from the Park, changing [nothing] in order to preserve the natural state the natural state of the Petrified Forest of the Petrified Forest 8% theft 3% theft 1.7% theft Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20 | How do you change behaviour?
  • 33. Norms People steal bits of wood from Arizona’s Petrified Forest National Park. Many past visitors have Please don’t remove the removed petrified wood petrified wood from the Park, from the Park, changing [nothing] in order to preserve the natural state the natural state of the Petrified Forest of the Petrified Forest 8% theft 3% theft 1.7% theft “…a message that focuses recipients on the injunctive norm will be superior to messages that focus recipients on the descriptive norm.” (Cialdini et al., 2003) Yes! 50 secrets from the science of persuasion | Goldstein, Martin, Cialdini | 2007 | pp20 | How do you change behaviour?
  • 34. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) Shared understanding about expectations of behaviour within a group. We tend to conform to expectations even though we like to think of ourselves as making personal and principled decisions. (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . . . Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc) | How do you change behaviour?
  • 35. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) Where you think about something relative to yourself affects what you think about it The closer – or more proximal – events are the more we think about ‘actions’; the further away – or distal – events are the more we think ‘in theory’ - Here/not here - Me/not me - Now/not now - Clear/Unclear | How do you change behaviour?
  • 36. US hybrid sales 2000 –’ 06 Temporal discounting (3,000 to 250,000) 1 1 Sales tax incentive: $1k $1,000 $2,000 Kick-back Kick-back | How do you change behaviour?
  • 37. US hybrid sales 2000 –’ 06 Temporal (3,000 to 250,000) discounting 1 1 Sales tax incentive: $1k $1,000 $2,000 Sales tax discount Income tax rebate | How do you change behaviour?
  • 38. US hybrid sales 2000 –’ 06 Temporal (3,000 to 250,000) discounting 1 1 Sales tax incentive: $1k $1,000 $2,000 Sales tax discount Income tax rebate Now Not now | How do you change behaviour?
  • 39. US hybrid sales 2000 –’ 06 Temporal discounting (3,000 to 250,000) 7 6 5 3 4 1 2 1 $1,000 $2,000 Sales tax discount Income tax rebate Now Not now The tendency for people to have excessively stronger preferences for immediate gains relative to future gains. | How do you change behaviour?
  • 40. Norms (quasi-stationary Context equilibria) (situational influences) Construal (subjective influence) Decision-making is Shared relative to what understanding Where you think you can have, not about expectationsabout something absolutely about of behaviour withinrelative to yourself what you want. a group. affects what you We tend to conform to think about it expectations even though we Your decision is affected by like to think of ourselves as The closer – or more proximal – what’s on offer – to the point making personal and events are the more we think where the addition or subtraction principled decisions. about ‘actions’; the further away of things you don’t want still – or distal – events are the more affects your decision. (Social, Injunctive, Descriptive . we think ‘in theory’ .. Provincial, Proscr/Pre, etc) - Here/not here - Me/not me - Now/not now - Clear/Unclear | How do you change behaviour?
  • 41. “Just as no building lacks an architecture, so no choice lacks a context.” Dr. Robert Cialdini, ex-Regents' Professor of Psychology and Marketing Arizona State University | How do you change behaviour?
  • 42. Thank you | How do you change behaviour?

Editor's Notes

  • #4: Anthropologically speaking, we’ve developed lots of rules of thumb and schematic about the world around us in order to reduce the           burned of cognitive load for day-to-day tasks liberating us to focus on advantage and survival. However, the last few hundred years of              development have placed us in a world we no longer recognise:             We jump a mile at snakes [show snake], but are ambivalent about electricity cable [show cable (ref: Pinker)]
  • #5: Deal with hits developed lots of rules of thumb (and they are in system 1 – we get the answers for ‘free’ so we can think about protecting ourselves from lions, tigers, and strange monks lurking in the woods) [shot from In The Name Of The Rose]
  • #6: There are so many decisions to make in life, those that are made for us a often welcomed. “ Defaults work best when decision makers are too indifferent, confused, or conflicted to consider their options. That principle is particularly relevant in a world that’s increasingly awash with choices https://www.mckinseyquarterly.com/A_marketers_guide_to_behavioral_economics_2536
  • #7: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #8: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #9: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #10: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #11: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #12: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #13: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #17: Huber and Puto recruited over one hundred respondents and gave them a simple hypothetical choice: would you buy a beer that’s $1.80 with a quality ‘score’ of 50/100, or a beer that’s $2.60 with a quality ‘score’ of 70/100? Pay more, get better. Simple.   The choice saw 30% choosing the $1.80 beer, and 70% wanting the quality beer. (They obviously like the posh stuff.)   But here come the additions.   A low-quality ‘decoy’ at $1.60 with a 30/100 quality was added. No one chose it – not one. But it changed the desire for the original beers: With 0% wanting the $1.60 decoy, instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a near 50/50% split. How odd. Rational actors in a rational world would not have changed their minds based on the addition of an unwanted outlier, and most choice models don’t allow for this.   Does it work at the other end of the price spectrum? They tried a high-quality decoy at $3.40 with a quality of 75/100, and 10% chose it. Obviously (or so it seems), there were a few people for whom the original highest-price $2.60 choice was not high-quality enough. But the rest of the choice shift was phenomenal.   With the addition of the $3.40 decoy (which 10% plumped for), absolutely no one wanted the original $1.80 beer – despite 30% originally preferring it – leaving 90% climbing up to the $2.60 option. So instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a 0/90% split.   The addition of options twisted the original choice: the decoy effect is powerful.
  • #18: Huber and Puto recruited over one hundred respondents and gave them a simple hypothetical choice: would you buy a beer that’s $1.80 with a quality ‘score’ of 50/100, or a beer that’s $2.60 with a quality ‘score’ of 70/100? Pay more, get better. Simple.   The choice saw 30% choosing the $1.80 beer, and 70% wanting the quality beer. (They obviously like the posh stuff.)   But here come the additions.   A low-quality ‘decoy’ at $1.60 with a 30/100 quality was added. No one chose it – not one. But it changed the desire for the original beers: With 0% wanting the $1.60 decoy, instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a near 50/50% split. How odd. Rational actors in a rational world would not have changed their minds based on the addition of an unwanted outlier, and most choice models don’t allow for this.   Does it work at the other end of the price spectrum? They tried a high-quality decoy at $3.40 with a quality of 75/100, and 10% chose it. Obviously (or so it seems), there were a few people for whom the original highest-price $2.60 choice was not high-quality enough. But the rest of the choice shift was phenomenal.   With the addition of the $3.40 decoy (which 10% plumped for), absolutely no one wanted the original $1.80 beer – despite 30% originally preferring it – leaving 90% climbing up to the $2.60 option. So instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a 0/90% split.   The addition of options twisted the original choice: the decoy effect is powerful.
  • #19: Huber and Puto recruited over one hundred respondents and gave them a simple hypothetical choice: would you buy a beer that’s $1.80 with a quality ‘score’ of 50/100, or a beer that’s $2.60 with a quality ‘score’ of 70/100? Pay more, get better. Simple.   The choice saw 30% choosing the $1.80 beer, and 70% wanting the quality beer. (They obviously like the posh stuff.)   But here come the additions.   A low-quality ‘decoy’ at $1.60 with a 30/100 quality was added. No one chose it – not one. But it changed the desire for the original beers: With 0% wanting the $1.60 decoy, instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a near 50/50% split. How odd. Rational actors in a rational world would not have changed their minds based on the addition of an unwanted outlier, and most choice models don’t allow for this.   Does it work at the other end of the price spectrum? They tried a high-quality decoy at $3.40 with a quality of 75/100, and 10% chose it. Obviously (or so it seems), there were a few people for whom the original highest-price $2.60 choice was not high-quality enough. But the rest of the choice shift was phenomenal.   With the addition of the $3.40 decoy (which 10% plumped for), absolutely no one wanted the original $1.80 beer – despite 30% originally preferring it – leaving 90% climbing up to the $2.60 option. So instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a 0/90% split.   The addition of options twisted the original choice: the decoy effect is powerful.
  • #20: Huber and Puto recruited over one hundred respondents and gave them a simple hypothetical choice: would you buy a beer that’s $1.80 with a quality ‘score’ of 50/100, or a beer that’s $2.60 with a quality ‘score’ of 70/100? Pay more, get better. Simple.   The choice saw 30% choosing the $1.80 beer, and 70% wanting the quality beer. (They obviously like the posh stuff.)   But here come the additions.   A low-quality ‘decoy’ at $1.60 with a 30/100 quality was added. No one chose it – not one. But it changed the desire for the original beers: With 0% wanting the $1.60 decoy, instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a near 50/50% split. How odd. Rational actors in a rational world would not have changed their minds based on the addition of an unwanted outlier, and most choice models don’t allow for this.   Does it work at the other end of the price spectrum? They tried a high-quality decoy at $3.40 with a quality of 75/100, and 10% chose it. Obviously (or so it seems), there were a few people for whom the original highest-price $2.60 choice was not high-quality enough. But the rest of the choice shift was phenomenal.   With the addition of the $3.40 decoy (which 10% plumped for), absolutely no one wanted the original $1.80 beer – despite 30% originally preferring it – leaving 90% climbing up to the $2.60 option. So instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a 0/90% split.   The addition of options twisted the original choice: the decoy effect is powerful.
  • #21: Huber and Puto recruited over one hundred respondents and gave them a simple hypothetical choice: would you buy a beer that’s $1.80 with a quality ‘score’ of 50/100, or a beer that’s $2.60 with a quality ‘score’ of 70/100? Pay more, get better. Simple.   The choice saw 30% choosing the $1.80 beer, and 70% wanting the quality beer. (They obviously like the posh stuff.)   But here come the additions.   A low-quality ‘decoy’ at $1.60 with a 30/100 quality was added. No one chose it – not one. But it changed the desire for the original beers: With 0% wanting the $1.60 decoy, instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a near 50/50% split. How odd. Rational actors in a rational world would not have changed their minds based on the addition of an unwanted outlier, and most choice models don’t allow for this.   Does it work at the other end of the price spectrum? They tried a high-quality decoy at $3.40 with a quality of 75/100, and 10% chose it. Obviously (or so it seems), there were a few people for whom the original highest-price $2.60 choice was not high-quality enough. But the rest of the choice shift was phenomenal.   With the addition of the $3.40 decoy (which 10% plumped for), absolutely no one wanted the original $1.80 beer – despite 30% originally preferring it – leaving 90% climbing up to the $2.60 option. So instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a 0/90% split.   The addition of options twisted the original choice: the decoy effect is powerful.
  • #22: Huber and Puto recruited over one hundred respondents and gave them a simple hypothetical choice: would you buy a beer that’s $1.80 with a quality ‘score’ of 50/100, or a beer that’s $2.60 with a quality ‘score’ of 70/100? Pay more, get better. Simple.   The choice saw 30% choosing the $1.80 beer, and 70% wanting the quality beer. (They obviously like the posh stuff.)   But here come the additions.   A low-quality ‘decoy’ at $1.60 with a 30/100 quality was added. No one chose it – not one. But it changed the desire for the original beers: With 0% wanting the $1.60 decoy, instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a near 50/50% split. How odd. Rational actors in a rational world would not have changed their minds based on the addition of an unwanted outlier, and most choice models don’t allow for this.   Does it work at the other end of the price spectrum? They tried a high-quality decoy at $3.40 with a quality of 75/100, and 10% chose it. Obviously (or so it seems), there were a few people for whom the original highest-price $2.60 choice was not high-quality enough. But the rest of the choice shift was phenomenal.   With the addition of the $3.40 decoy (which 10% plumped for), absolutely no one wanted the original $1.80 beer – despite 30% originally preferring it – leaving 90% climbing up to the $2.60 option. So instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a 0/90% split.   The addition of options twisted the original choice: the decoy effect is powerful.
  • #23: Huber and Puto recruited over one hundred respondents and gave them a simple hypothetical choice: would you buy a beer that’s $1.80 with a quality ‘score’ of 50/100, or a beer that’s $2.60 with a quality ‘score’ of 70/100? Pay more, get better. Simple.   The choice saw 30% choosing the $1.80 beer, and 70% wanting the quality beer. (They obviously like the posh stuff.)   But here come the additions.   A low-quality ‘decoy’ at $1.60 with a 30/100 quality was added. No one chose it – not one. But it changed the desire for the original beers: With 0% wanting the $1.60 decoy, instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a near 50/50% split. How odd. Rational actors in a rational world would not have changed their minds based on the addition of an unwanted outlier, and most choice models don’t allow for this.   Does it work at the other end of the price spectrum? They tried a high-quality decoy at $3.40 with a quality of 75/100, and 10% chose it. Obviously (or so it seems), there were a few people for whom the original highest-price $2.60 choice was not high-quality enough. But the rest of the choice shift was phenomenal.   With the addition of the $3.40 decoy (which 10% plumped for), absolutely no one wanted the original $1.80 beer – despite 30% originally preferring it – leaving 90% climbing up to the $2.60 option. So instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a 0/90% split.   The addition of options twisted the original choice: the decoy effect is powerful.
  • #24: Huber and Puto recruited over one hundred respondents and gave them a simple hypothetical choice: would you buy a beer that’s $1.80 with a quality ‘score’ of 50/100, or a beer that’s $2.60 with a quality ‘score’ of 70/100? Pay more, get better. Simple.   The choice saw 30% choosing the $1.80 beer, and 70% wanting the quality beer. (They obviously like the posh stuff.)   But here come the additions.   A low-quality ‘decoy’ at $1.60 with a 30/100 quality was added. No one chose it – not one. But it changed the desire for the original beers: With 0% wanting the $1.60 decoy, instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a near 50/50% split. How odd. Rational actors in a rational world would not have changed their minds based on the addition of an unwanted outlier, and most choice models don’t allow for this.   Does it work at the other end of the price spectrum? They tried a high-quality decoy at $3.40 with a quality of 75/100, and 10% chose it. Obviously (or so it seems), there were a few people for whom the original highest-price $2.60 choice was not high-quality enough. But the rest of the choice shift was phenomenal.   With the addition of the $3.40 decoy (which 10% plumped for), absolutely no one wanted the original $1.80 beer – despite 30% originally preferring it – leaving 90% climbing up to the $2.60 option. So instead of a 30/70% split for the original beers it now shifted to a 0/90% split.   The addition of options twisted the original choice: the decoy effect is powerful.
  • #25: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #26: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #35: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #36: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.
  • #37: We know that decisions about brands – the decisions we aim to influence – are complex. They involve not only direct utility (a car that will take you from A to B) and opportunity cost (what else could the same money buy?), but also status (what does this car say about me?), concern with the needs of others (who else will use the car, and for what purposes? And what would this car say about them?), social concerns (should I drive less or get a hybrid?), fashion (who does buy yellow cars?), and many other issues and concerns. NOTES: Gas prices aren’t the only reason for more hybrid sales http://nudges.wordpress.com/gas-prices-arent-the-only-reason-for-more-hybrid-sales/ http://www.thehuntingdynasty.com/2010/01/death-and-taxes-why-your-decisions-kill-you-and-cost-you-money/ Gas prices aren’t the only reason for more hybrid sales | Nudge blog
  • #38: We know that decisions about brands – the decisions we aim to influence – are complex. They involve not only direct utility (a car that will take you from A to B) and opportunity cost (what else could the same money buy?), but also status (what does this car say about me?), concern with the needs of others (who else will use the car, and for what purposes? And what would this car say about them?), social concerns (should I drive less or get a hybrid?), fashion (who does buy yellow cars?), and many other issues and concerns. NOTES: Gas prices aren’t the only reason for more hybrid sales http://nudges.wordpress.com/gas-prices-arent-the-only-reason-for-more-hybrid-sales/ http://www.thehuntingdynasty.com/2010/01/death-and-taxes-why-your-decisions-kill-you-and-cost-you-money/ Gas prices aren’t the only reason for more hybrid sales | Nudge blog
  • #39: We know that decisions about brands – the decisions we aim to influence – are complex. They involve not only direct utility (a car that will take you from A to B) and opportunity cost (what else could the same money buy?), but also status (what does this car say about me?), concern with the needs of others (who else will use the car, and for what purposes? And what would this car say about them?), social concerns (should I drive less or get a hybrid?), fashion (who does buy yellow cars?), and many other issues and concerns. NOTES: Gas prices aren’t the only reason for more hybrid sales http://nudges.wordpress.com/gas-prices-arent-the-only-reason-for-more-hybrid-sales/ http://www.thehuntingdynasty.com/2010/01/death-and-taxes-why-your-decisions-kill-you-and-cost-you-money/ Gas prices aren’t the only reason for more hybrid sales | Nudge blog
  • #40: ” In Israel – one of the first countries to sign a zero-emissions agreement with the Renault-Nissan Alliance – the government cut the purchase tax for new vehicles from 80% to 10% for all-electric vehicles.” We know that decisions about brands – the decisions we aim to influence – are complex. They involve not only direct utility (a car that will take you from A to B) and opportunity cost (what else could the same money buy?), but also status (what does this car say about me?), concern with the needs of others (who else will use the car, and for what purposes? And what would this car say about them?), social concerns (should I drive less or get a hybrid?), fashion (who does buy yellow cars?), and many other issues and concerns. NOTES: Gas prices aren’t the only reason for more hybrid sales http://nudges.wordpress.com/gas-prices-arent-the-only-reason-for-more-hybrid-sales/ http://www.thehuntingdynasty.com/2010/01/death-and-taxes-why-your-decisions-kill-you-and-cost-you-money/
  • #41: It’s quite a broad term. In fact, almost all the other effects described here can ‘frame’ a choice, and in so doing create different outcomes. In that sense, ‘framing’ tells us that what is said is less significant than how it’s said. In broad terms ‘choice architecture’ concerns itself with how people gather information, when they choose, and how absolute values are crowded out by other influences. The broad groups of effects are framing biases (e.g. the ‘availability’ heuristic, and ‘ anchoring effects’), where the grouping of choices influences final choice, and ordering effects (e.g. the ‘primacy’ effect and the ‘recency effect’), where relative order in the group creates bias. The whole area of Behavioural Economics dedicated to choice architecture is perhaps one of the richest seams for our industry, and the one which we believe we should make into a special subject for priority investigation of its potential applications. ■ We are all choice architects because there is no neutral way to present a choice. Presenting something first on a list can bias its choice (the ‘primacy’ effect), as can presenting it last (the ‘recency’ effect). This phenomenon is well known to the market research industry, who try to eliminate its affect by rotating stimulus. People tend to choose relative to what is available rather than to any absolute standard (this is known as the ‘availability’ heuristic). The way we frame choice is therefore fundamental to the decisions that we make. ■ We are all familiar with the experience of choosing the second-cheapest wine on the wine list. We are also familiar with never choosing the most expensive item on the menu. However, having one very expensive item on the menu can increase the average value of dishes ordered, even if the most expensive choice is rarely chosen.