SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Perturbation Methods

                                    Jesús Fernández-Villaverde

                                       University of Pennsylvania


                                           July 10, 2011




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods     July 10, 2011   1 / 91
Introduction


Introduction

       Remember that we want to solve a functional equation of the form:

                                                H (d ) = 0

       for an unknown decision rule d.

       Perturbation solves the problem by specifying:

                                                       n
                                    d n (x, θ ) =     ∑ θ i (x   x0 )i
                                                      i =0


       We use implicit-function theorems to …nd coe¢ cients θ i ’s.

       Inherently local approximation. However, often good global properties.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods           July 10, 2011   2 / 91
Introduction


Motivation
       Many complicated mathematical problems have:

          1   either a particular case

          2   or a related problem.


       that is easy to solve.

       Often, we can use the solution of the simpler problem as a building
       block of the general solution.

       Very successful in physics.

       Sometimes perturbation is known as asymptotic methods.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)        Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   3 / 91
Introduction


The World Simplest Perturbation
                    p
       What is          26?

       Without your Iphone calculator, it is a boring arithmetic calculation.

       But note that:
              p       q                 p
                 26 = 25 (1 + 0.04) = 5   1.04                      5 1.02 = 5.1

       Exact solution is 5.099.
                                              p
       We have solved a much simpler problem ( 25) and added a small
       coe¢ cient to it.

       More in general
                                             q                   p
                                    p
                                        y=       x 2 (1 + ε ) = x 1 + ε

       where x is an integer and ε the perturbation parameter.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)            Perturbation Methods          July 10, 2011   4 / 91
Introduction


Applications to Economics

       Judd and Guu (1993) showed how to apply it to economic problems.


       Recently, perturbation methods have been gaining much popularity.


       In particular, second- and third-order approximations are easy to
       compute and notably improve accuracy.


       A …rst-order perturbation theory and linearization deliver the same
       output.


       Hence, we can use much of what we already know about linearization.

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)      Perturbation Methods     July 10, 2011   5 / 91
Introduction


Regular versus Singular Perturbations

       Regular perturbation: a small change in the problem induces a small
       change in the solution.


       Singular perturbation: a small change in the problem induces a large
       change in the solution.


       Example: excess demand function.


       Most problems in economics involve regular perturbations.


       Sometimes, however, we can have singularities. Example: introducing
       a new asset in an incomplete markets model.

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)      Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   6 / 91
Introduction


References
       General:
          1   A First Look at Perturbation Theory by James G. Simmonds and
              James E. Mann Jr.
          2   Advanced Mathematical Methods for Scientists and Engineers:
              Asymptotic Methods and Perturbation Theory by Carl M. Bender,
              Steven A. Orszag.

       Economics:
          1   Perturbation Methods for General Dynamic Stochastic Models” by
              Hehui Jin and Kenneth Judd.
          2   Perturbation Methods with Nonlinear Changes of Variables” by
              Kenneth Judd.
          3   A gentle introduction: “Solving Dynamic General Equilibrium Models
              Using a Second-Order Approximation to the Policy Function” by
              Martín Uribe and Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)      Perturbation Methods        July 10, 2011   7 / 91
A Baby Example


A Baby Example: A Basic RBC

Model:
                                                      ∞
                                      max E0      ∑ βt log ct
                                                  t =0


                       s.t. ct + kt +1 = e zt ktα + (1            δ) kt , 8 t > 0
                                zt = ρzt   1   + σεt , εt         N (0, 1)

Equilibrium conditions:
                             1            1
                                = βEt          1 + αe zt +1 ktα+1 δ
                                                                1
                             ct         ct + 1
                                ct + kt +1 = e zt ktα + (1 δ) kt
                                        zt = ρzt          1   + σεt


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods                     July 10, 2011   8 / 91
A Baby Example


Computing a Solution
       The previous problem does not have a known “paper and pencil”
       solution except when (unrealistically) δ = 1.
       Then, income and substitution e¤ect from a technology shock cancel
       each other (labor constant and consumption is a …xed fraction of
       income).
       Equilibrium conditions with δ = 1:
                                                                1
                                        1          αe zt +1 ktα+1
                                            = βEt
                                        ct             ct + 1
                                          ct + kt +1 = e zt ktα
                                          zt = ρzt       1   + σεt
       By “guess and verify”:
                                        ct = ( 1        αβ) e zt ktα
                                           kt +1 = αβe zt ktα
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods         July 10, 2011   9 / 91
A Baby Example


Another Way to Solve the Problem

       Now let us suppose that you missed the lecture when “guess and
       verify” was explained.

       You need to compute the RBC.

       What you are searching for? A decision rule for consumption:


                                            ct = c (kt , zt )

       and another one for capital:

                                           kt +1 = k (kt , zt )

       Note that our d is just the stack of c (kt , zt ) and k (kt , zt ).
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods       July 10, 2011   10 / 91
A Baby Example


Equilibrium Conditions

       We substitute in the equilibrium conditions the budget constraint and
       the law of motion for technology.


       And we write the decision rules explicitly as function of the states.


       Then:

                                1                αe ρzt +σεt +1 k (kt , zt )α 1
                                         = βEt
                            c (kt , zt )       c (k (kt , zt ) , ρzt + σεt +1 )
                                    c (kt , zt ) + k (kt , zt ) = e zt ktα

       System of functional equations.


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods               July 10, 2011   11 / 91
A Baby Example


Main Idea


       Transform the problem rewriting it in terms of a small perturbation
       parameter.


       Solve the new problem for a particular choice of the perturbation
       parameter.


       This step is usually ambiguous since there are di¤erent ways to do so.


       Use the previous solution to approximate the solution of original the
       problem.



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   12 / 91
A Baby Example


A Perturbation Approach

       Hence, we want to transform the problem.


       Which perturbation parameter? Standard deviation σ.


       Why σ? Discrete versus continuous time.


       Set σ = 0 )deterministic model, zt = 0 and e zt = 1.


       We know how to solve the deterministic steady state.


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   13 / 91
A Baby Example


A Parametrized Decision Rule


       We search for decision rule:

                                           ct = c (kt , zt ; σ)

       and
                                         kt +1 = k (kt , zt ; σ)



       Note new parameter σ.


       We are building a local approximation around σ = 0.



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods     July 10, 2011   14 / 91
A Baby Example


Taylor’ Theorem
      s


       Equilibrium conditions:


                                                                                      !
                             1                  αe ρzt +σεt +1 k (kt , zt ; σ)α 1
               Et                          β                                              =0
                       c (kt , zt ; σ)       c (k (kt , zt ; σ) , ρzt + σεt +1 ; σ)
                               c (kt , zt ; σ) + k (kt , zt ; σ)   e zt ktα = 0

       We will take derivatives with respect to kt , zt , and σ.


       Apply Taylor’ theorem to build solution around deterministic steady
                    s
       state. How?


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)           Perturbation Methods                  July 10, 2011   15 / 91
A Baby Example


Asymptotic Expansion I



         ct     = c (kt , zt ; σ)jk ,0,0 = c (k, 0; 0)
                  +ck (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) + cz (k, 0; 0) zt + cσ (k, 0; 0) σ
                    1                                1
                  + ckk (k, 0; 0) (kt k )2 + ckz (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) zt
                    2                                2
                    1                                 1
                  + ck σ (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) σ + czk (k, 0; 0) zt (kt k )
                    2                                 2
                    1                    2  1
                  + czz (k, 0; 0) zt + cz σ (k, 0; 0) zt σ
                    2                       2
                    1                                 1
                  + cσk (k, 0; 0) σ (kt k ) + cσz (k, 0; 0) σzt
                    2                                 2
                    1                    2
                  + cσ2 (k, 0; 0) σ + ...
                    2

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods    July 10, 2011   16 / 91
A Baby Example


Asymptotic Expansion II



       kt +1 =          k (kt , zt ; σ)jk ,0,0 = k (k, 0; 0)
                        +kk (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) + kz (k, 0; 0) zt + kσ (k, 0; 0) σ
                         1                          1
                        + kkk (k, 0; 0) (kt k )2 + kkz (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) zt
                         2                          2
                         1                           1
                        + kk σ (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) σ + kzk (k, 0; 0) zt (kt k )
                         2                           2
                         1                2  1
                        + kzz (k, 0; 0) zt + kz σ (k, 0; 0) zt σ
                         2                   2
                         1                           1
                        + kσk (k, 0; 0) σ (kt k ) + kσz (k, 0; 0) σzt
                         2                           2
                         1                2
                        + kσ2 (k, 0; 0) σ + ...
                         2

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods        July 10, 2011   17 / 91
A Baby Example


Comment on Notation

       From now on, to save on notation, I will write
                             "                                                   #
                                     1           αe ρzt +σεt +1 k (k ,zt ;σ)α 1
                                              β c (k (kt ,zt ;σ),ρztt+σεt +1 ;σ)                      0
        F (kt , zt ; σ) = Et   c (kt ,zt ;σ )                                      =
                               c (kt , zt ; σ) + k (kt , zt ; σ) e zt ktα                             0


       Note that:

                             F (kt , zt ; σ) = H (ct , ct +1 , kt , kt +1 , zt ; σ)
          = H (c (kt , zt ; σ) , c (k (kt , zt ; σ) , zt +1 ; σ) , kt , k (kt , zt ; σ) , zt ; σ)

       I will use Hi to represent the partial derivative of H with respect to
       the i component and drop the evaluation at the steady state of the
       functions when we do not need it.

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)           Perturbation Methods                      July 10, 2011       18 / 91
A Baby Example


Zeroth-Order Approximation

       First, we evaluate σ = 0:

                                                 F (kt , 0; 0) = 0

       Steady state:
                                                   1    αk α          1
                                                     =β
                                                   c      c
       or
                                                                      1
                                                   1 = αβk α
       Then:                                                          α                1
                                    c = c (k, 0; 0) = (αβ) 1              α   (αβ) 1       α

                                                                              1
                                         k = k (k, 0; 0) = (αβ) 1                 α




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods                            July 10, 2011   19 / 91
A Baby Example


First-Order Approximation


       We take derivatives of F (kt , zt ; σ) around k, 0, and 0.


       With respect to kt :
                                            Fk (k, 0; 0) = 0


       With respect to zt :
                                            Fz (k, 0; 0) = 0


       With respect to σ:
                                            Fσ (k, 0; 0) = 0


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods      July 10, 2011   20 / 91
A Baby Example


Solving the System I

       Remember that:

                                              F (kt , zt ; σ)
       = H (c (kt , zt ; σ) , c (k (kt , zt ; σ) , zt +1 ; σ) , kt , k (kt , zt ; σ) , zt ; σ) = 0

       Because F (kt , zt ; σ) must be equal to zero for any possible values of
       kt , zt , and σ, the derivatives of any order of F must also be zero.


       Then:

                       Fk (k, 0; 0) = H1 ck + H2 ck kk + H3 + H4 kk = 0
                Fz (k, 0; 0) = H1 cz + H2 (ck kz + ck ρ) + H4 kz + H5 = 0
                 Fσ (k, 0; 0) = H1 cσ + H2 (ck kσ + cσ ) + H4 kσ + H6 = 0


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods                 July 10, 2011   21 / 91
A Baby Example


Solving the System II
       A quadratic system:
                       Fk (k, 0; 0) = H1 ck + H2 ck kk + H3 + H4 kk = 0
                Fz (k, 0; 0) = H1 cz + H2 (ck kz + ck ρ) + H4 kz + H5 = 0
       of 4 equations on 4 unknowns: ck , cz , kk , and kz .
       Procedures to solve quadratic systems:
          1   Blanchard and Kahn (1980).
          2   Uhlig (1999).
          3   Sims (2000).
          4   Klein (2000).

       All of them equivalent.
       Why quadratic? Stable and unstable manifold.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods     July 10, 2011   22 / 91
A Baby Example


Solving the System III
       Also, note that:
                 Fσ (k, 0; 0) = H1 cσ + H2 (ck kσ + cσ ) + H4 kσ + H6 = 0
       is a linear, and homogeneous system in cσ and kσ .
       Hence:
                                              cσ = kσ = 0

       This means the system is certainty equivalent.
       Interpretation)no precautionary behavior.
       Di¤erence between risk-aversion and precautionary behavior. Leland
       (1968), Kimball (1990).
       Risk-aversion depends on the second derivative (concave utility).
       Precautionary behavior depends on the third derivative (convex
       marginal utility).
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   23 / 91
A Baby Example


Comparison with LQ and Linearization
       After Kydland and Prescott (1982) a popular method to solve
       economic models has been to …nd a LQ approximation of the
       objective function of the agents.

       Close relative: linearization of equilibrium conditions.

       When properly implemented linearization, LQ, and …rst-order
       perturbation are equivalent.

       Advantages of perturbation:

          1   Theorems.

          2   Higher-order terms.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods    July 10, 2011   24 / 91
A Baby Example


Some Further Comments



       Note how we have used a version of the implicit-function theorem.


       Important tool in economics.


       Also, we are using the Taylor theorem to approximate the policy
       function.


       Alternatives?




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   25 / 91
A Baby Example


Second-Order Approximation
       We take second-order derivatives of F (kt , zt ; σ) around k, 0, and 0:

                                         Fkk (k, 0; 0) = 0
                                         Fkz (k, 0; 0) = 0
                                         Fk σ (k, 0; 0) = 0
                                         Fzz (k, 0; 0) = 0
                                         Fz σ (k, 0; 0) = 0
                                         Fσσ (k, 0; 0) = 0
       Remember Young’ theorem!
                      s
       We substitute the coe¢ cients that we already know.
       A linear system of 12 equations on 12 unknowns. Why linear?
       Cross-terms kσ and zσ are zero.
       Conjecture on all the terms with odd powers of σ.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   26 / 91
A Baby Example


Correction for Risk


       We have a term in σ2 .


       Captures precautionary behavior.


       We do not have certainty equivalence any more!


       Important advantage of second-order approximation.


       Changes ergodic distribution of states.



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   27 / 91
A Baby Example


Higher-Order Terms

       We can continue the iteration for as long as we want.


       Great advantage of procedure: it is recursive!


       Often, a few iterations will be enough.


       The level of accuracy depends on the goal of the exercise:


          1   Welfare analysis: Kim and Kim (2001).

          2   Empirical strategies: Fernández-Villaverde, Rubio-Ramírez, and Santos
              (2006).

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)         Perturbation Methods      July 10, 2011   28 / 91
A Numerical Example


A Numerical Example

                            Parameter           β           α          ρ      σ
                              Value            0.99        0.33       0.95   0.01

       Steady State: c = 0.388069                         k = 0.1883
       First-order terms:
                         ck (k, 0; 0) = 0.680101                kk (k, 0; 0) = 0.33
                         cz (k, 0; 0) = 0.388069                kz (k, 0; 0) = 0.1883
       Second-order terms:
                     ckk (k, 0; 0) = 2.41990                   kkk (k, 0; 0) = 1.1742
                     ckz (k, 0; 0) = 0.680099                  kkz (k, 0; 0) = 0.33
                     czz (k, 0; 0) = 0.388064                  kzz (k, 0; 0) = 0.1883
                     cσ2 (k, 0; 0) ' 0                         kσ2 (k, 0; 0) ' 0
       cσ (k, 0; 0) = kσ (k, 0; 0) = ck σ (k, 0; 0) = kk σ (k, 0; 0) =
       cz σ (k, 0; 0) = kz σ (k, 0; 0) = 0.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods                 July 10, 2011   29 / 91
A Numerical Example


Comparison



                                          ct = 0.6733e zt kt0.33
                  ct ' 0.388069 + 0.680101 (kt k ) + 0.388069zt
                2.41990                                  0.388064 2
                        (kt k )2 + 0.680099 (kt k ) zt +         zt
                   2                                         2
and:

                                        kt +1 = 0.3267e zt kt0.33
                        kt +1 ' 0.1883 + 0.33 (kt                     k ) + 0.1883zt
                      1.1742                                                    0.1883 2
                              (kt k )2 + 0.33 (kt                      k ) zt +       zt
                         2                                                         2


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods                   July 10, 2011   30 / 91
A Numerical Example




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   31 / 91
A Numerical Example


A Computer

       In practice you do all this approximations with a computer:


          1   First-, second-, and third-order: Matlab and Dynare.

          2   Higher-order: Mathematica, Dynare++, Fortran code by Jinn and
              Judd.


       Burden: analytical derivatives.


       Why are numerical derivatives a bad idea?


       Alternatives: automatic di¤erentiation?

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   32 / 91
A Numerical Example


Local Properties of the Solution
       Perturbation is a local method.
       It approximates the solution around the deterministic steady state of
       the problem.
       It is valid within a radius of convergence.
       What is the radius of convergence of a power series around x? An
       r 2 R∞ such that 8x 0 , jx 0 z j < r , the power series of x 0 will
              +
       converge.

A Remarkable Result from Complex Analysis
The radius of convergence is always equal to the distance from the center
to the nearest point where the policy function has a (non-removable)
singularity. If no such point exists then the radius of convergence is in…nite.

       Singularity here refers to poles, fractional powers, and other branch
       powers or discontinuities of the functional or its derivatives.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   33 / 91
A Numerical Example


Remarks



       Intuition of the theorem: holomorphic functions are analytic.


       Distance is in the complex plane.


       Often, we can check numerically that perturbations have good non
       local behavior.


       However: problem with boundaries.




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   34 / 91
A Numerical Example


Non Local Accuracy Test
       Proposed by Judd (1992) and Judd and Guu (1997).


       Given the Euler equation:
                                   1                       αe zt +1 k i (kt , zt )α 1
                               i (k , z )
                                          = Et
                              c t t                        c i (k i (kt , zt ), zt +1 )
       we can de…ne:
                                                                      αe zt +1 k i (kt , zt )α 1
                  EE i (kt , zt )        1     c i (kt , zt ) Et
                                                                      c i (k i (kt , zt ), zt +1 )


       Units of reporting.


       Interpretation.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods                       July 10, 2011   35 / 91
A Numerical Example




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   36 / 91
The General Case


The General Case

       Most of previous argument can be easily generalized.


       The set of equilibrium conditions of many DSGE models can be
       written as (note recursive notation)

                                          Et H(y , y 0 , x, x 0 ) = 0,

       where yt is a ny             1 vector of controls and xt is a nx     1 vector of
       states.


       De…ne n = nx + ny .


       Then H maps R ny               R ny       R nx     R nx into R n .
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)            Perturbation Methods           July 10, 2011   37 / 91
The General Case


Partitioning the State Vector



       The state vector xt can be partitioned as x = [x1 ; x2 ]t .


       x1 is a (nx          n )     1 vector of endogenous state variables.


       x2 is a n          1 vector of exogenous state variables.


       Why do we want to partition the state vector?




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)           Perturbation Methods        July 10, 2011   38 / 91
The General Case


Exogenous Stochastic Process

                                        0
                                       x2 = Λx2 + ση              0

       Process with 3 parts:
          1   The deterministic component Λx2 :
                  1   Λ is a n     n matrix, with all eigenvalues with modulus less than one.
                  2   More general: x2 = Γ(x2 ) + ση 0 , where Γ is a non-linear function
                                       0
                      satisfying that all eigenvalues of its …rst derivative evaluated at the
                      non-stochastic steady state lie within the unit circle.
          2   The scaled innovation η          0   where:
                  1   η is a known n       n matrix.
                  2     is a n   1 i.i.d innovation with bounded support, zero mean, and
                      variance/covariance matrix I .
          3   The perturbation parameter σ.
       We can accommodate very general structures of x2 through changes
       in the de…nition of the state space: i.e. stochastic volatility.
       Note we do not impose Gaussianity.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods             July 10, 2011   39 / 91
The General Case


The Perturbation Parameter


       The scalar σ            0 is the perturbation parameter.


       If we set σ = 0 we have a deterministic model.


       Important: there is only ONE perturbation parameter. The matrix η
       takes account of relative sizes of di¤erent shocks.


       Why bounded support? Samuelson (1970) and Jin and Judd (2002).



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   40 / 91
The General Case


Solution of the Model


       The solution to the model is of the form:

                                                y = g (x; σ)
                                            0                     0
                                          x = h(x; σ) + ση

       where g maps R nx            R + into R ny and h maps R nx      R + into R nx .


       The matrix η is of order nx                n and is given by:

                                                          ∅
                                                η=
                                                          η



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods          July 10, 2011   41 / 91
The General Case


Perturbation


       We wish to …nd a perturbation approximation of the functions g and
       h around the non-stochastic steady state, xt = x and σ = 0.
                                                      ¯


       We de…ne the non-stochastic steady state as vectors (x, y ) such that:
                                                            ¯ ¯

                                           H(y , y , x, x ) = 0.
                                             ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯



       Note that y = g (x; 0) and x = h(x; 0). This is because, if σ = 0,
                 ¯      ¯         ¯     ¯
       then Et H = H.



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods    July 10, 2011   42 / 91
The General Case


Plugging-in the Proposed Solution
       Substituting the proposed solution, we de…ne:


       F (x; σ)         Et H(g (x; σ), g (h(x; σ) + ησ 0 , σ), x, h(x; σ) + ησ 0 ) = 0


       Since F (x; σ) = 0 for any values of x and σ, the derivatives of any
       order of F must also be equal to zero.

       Formally:

                                    Fx k σj (x; σ) = 0        8x, σ, j, k,


       where Fx k σj (x, σ) denotes the derivative of F with respect to x taken
       k times and with respect to σ taken j times.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods              July 10, 2011   43 / 91
The General Case


First-Order Approximation
       We look for approximations to g and h around (x, σ) = (x, 0):
                                                              ¯
                     g (x; σ) = g (x; 0) + gx (x; 0)(x
                                   ¯           ¯                  x ) + gσ (x; 0)σ
                                                                  ¯         ¯
                     h(x; σ) = h(x; 0) + hx (x; 0)(x
                                 ¯           ¯                    x ) + hσ (x; 0)σ
                                                                  ¯         ¯
       As explained earlier,
                                                g (x; 0) = y
                                                   ¯       ¯
       and
                                                h(x; 0) = x.
                                                  ¯       ¯
       The four unknown coe¢ cients of the …rst-order approximation to g
       and h are found by using:
                                               Fx (x; 0) = 0
                                                   ¯
       and
                                               Fσ (x; 0) = 0
                                                   ¯
       Before doing so, I need to introduce the tensor notation.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods             July 10, 2011   44 / 91
The General Case


Tensors
       General trick from physics.
       An nth -rank tensor in a m-dimensional space is an operator that has n
       indices and mn components and obeys certain transformation rules.
       [Hy ]iα is the (i, α) element of the derivative of H with respect to y :
          1   The derivative of H with respect to y is an n                       ny matrix.
          2   Thus, [Hy ]iα is the element of this matrix located at the intersection of
              the i-th row and α-th column.
                                                   n                ∂ H i ∂g α ∂h β
              Thus, [Hy ]iα [gx ]α [hx ]j = ∑α=1 ∑nx 1
                                         β    y
                                                                    ∂y α ∂x β ∂x j .
          3
                                 β                β=

       [Hy 0 y 0 ]iαγ :
          1   Hy 0 y 0 is a three dimensional array with n rows, ny columns, and ny
              pages.
          2   Then [Hy 0 y 0 ]iαγ denotes the element of Hy 0 y 0 located at the
              intersection of row i, column α and page γ.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)            Perturbation Methods                        July 10, 2011   45 / 91
The General Case


Solving the System I

       gx and hx can be found as the solution to the system:

       [Fx (x; 0)]ij = [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hx ]j + [Hy ]iα [gx ]jα + [Hx 0 ]iβ [hx ]j + [Hx ]ij =
                                                       β                         β
            ¯                         β
                  i = 1, . . . , n; j, β = 1, . . . , nx ; α = 1, . . . , ny

       Note that the derivatives of H evaluated at (y , y 0 , x, x 0 ) = (y , y , x, x )
                                                                          ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯
       are known.


       Then, we have a system of n nx quadratic equations in the n                        nx
       unknowns given by the elements of gx and hx .


       We can solve with a standard quadratic matrix equation solver.


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods           July 10, 2011   46 / 91
The General Case


 Solving the System II
         gσ and hσ are identi…ed as the solution to the following n equations:
                                                    [Fσ (x; 0)]i =
                                                         ¯
                  Et f[Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hσ ] β + [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [η ]φ [ 0 ]φ + [Hy 0 ]iα [gσ ]α
                                                                         β
                                     β                          β

                           +[Hy ]iα [gσ ]α + [Hx 0 ]iβ [hσ ] β + [Hx 0 ]iβ [η ]φ [ 0 ]φ g
                                                                                    β


              i = 1, . . . , n;       α = 1, . . . , ny ;     β = 1, . . . , nx ;       φ = 1, . . . , n .
         Then:
[Fσ (x; 0)]i = [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hσ ] β + [Hy 0 ]iα [gσ ]α + [Hy ]iα [gσ ]α + [fx 0 ]iβ [hσ ] β = 0;
     ¯                        β
              i = 1, . . . , n;       α = 1, . . . , ny ;     β = 1, . . . , nx ;       φ = 1, . . . , n .
         Certainty equivalence: this equation is linear and homogeneous in gσ
         and hσ . Thus, if a unique solution exists, it must satisfy:
                                                      hσ 6 = 0
                                                      gσ = 0
  Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)             Perturbation Methods                       July 10, 2011     47 / 91
The General Case


Second-Order Approximation I


The second-order approximations to g around (x; σ) = (x; 0) is
                                                      ¯

       [g (x; σ)]i       = [g (x; 0)]i + [gx (x; 0)]ia [(x x )]a + [gσ (x; 0)]i [σ]
                                ¯              ¯           ¯            ¯
                              1
                           + [gxx (x; 0)]iab [(x x )]a [(x x )]b
                                      ¯               ¯         ¯
                              2
                              1
                           + [gx σ (x; 0)]ia [(x x )]a [σ]
                                      ¯             ¯
                              2
                              1
                           + [gσx (x; 0)]ia [(x x )]a [σ]
                                      ¯             ¯
                              2
                              1
                           + [gσσ (x; 0)]i [σ][σ]
                                      ¯
                              2
where i = 1, . . . , ny , a, b = 1, . . . , nx , and j = 1, . . . , nx .



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods            July 10, 2011   48 / 91
The General Case


Second-Order Approximation II


The second-order approximations to h around (x; σ) = (x; 0) is
                                                      ¯

       [h(x; σ)]j        = [h(x; 0)]j + [hx (x; 0)]ja [(x x )]a + [hσ (x; 0)]j [σ]
                              ¯               ¯            ¯           ¯
                             1
                           + [hxx (x; 0)]jab [(x x )]a [(x x )]b
                                     ¯               ¯         ¯
                             2
                             1
                           + [hx σ (x; 0)]ja [(x x )]a [σ]
                                     ¯             ¯
                             2
                             1
                           + [hσx (x; 0)]ja [(x x )]a [σ]
                                     ¯             ¯
                             2
                             1
                           + [hσσ (x; 0)]j [σ][σ],
                                     ¯
                             2
where i = 1, . . . , ny , a, b = 1, . . . , nx , and j = 1, . . . , nx .



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods            July 10, 2011   49 / 91
The General Case


Second-Order Approximation III



       The unknowns of these expansions are [gxx ]iab , [gx σ ]ia , [gσx ]ia , [gσσ ]i ,
       [hxx ]jab , [hx σ ]ja , [hσx ]ja , [hσσ ]j .


       These coe¢ cients can be identi…ed by taking the derivative of F (x; σ)
       with respect to x and σ twice and evaluating them at (x; σ) = (x; 0).
                                                                         ¯


       By the arguments provided earlier, these derivatives must be zero.




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods          July 10, 2011   50 / 91
The General Case


Solving the System I
We use Fxx (x; 0) to identify gxx (x; 0) and hxx (x; 0):
            ¯                      ¯              ¯

                                           [Fxx (x; 0)]ijk =
                                                 ¯
 [Hy 0 y 0 ]iαγ [gx ]γ [hx ]k + [Hy 0 y ]iαγ [gx ]k + [Hy 0 x 0 ]iαδ [hx ]k + [Hy 0 x ]iαk [gx ]α [hx ]j
                            δ                     γ                       δ                                    β
                     δ                                                                          β

                      +[Hy 0 ]iα [gxx ]α [hx ]k [hx ]j + [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hxx ]jk
                                              δ         β                       β
                                       βδ                               β

  + [Hyy 0 ]iαγ [gx ]γ [hx ]k + [Hyy ]iαγ [gx ]k + [Hyx 0 ]iαδ [hx ]k + [Hyx ]iαk [gx ]jα
                     δ
                            δ                  γ                    δ


                                           +[Hy ]iα [gxx ]jk
                                                          α


+ [Hx 0 y 0 ]iβγ [gx ]γ [hx ]k + [Hx 0 y ]iβγ [gx ]k + [Hx 0 x 0 ]iβδ [hx ]k + [Hx 0 x ]iβk [hx ]j
                             δ                     γ                       δ                            β
                      δ

                                           +[Hx 0 ]iβ [hxx ]jk
                                                               β


     +[Hxy 0 ]ij γ [gx ]γ [hx ]k + [Hxy ]ij γ [gx ]k + [Hxx 0 ]ij δ [hx ]k + [Hxx ]ijk = 0;
                        δ
                               δ                   γ                     δ

                  i = 1, . . . n,     j, k, β, δ = 1, . . . nx ;   α, γ = 1, . . . ny .

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)           Perturbation Methods                     July 10, 2011   51 / 91
The General Case


Solving the System II



       We know the derivatives of H.


       We also know the …rst derivatives of g and h evaluated at
       (y , y 0 , x, x 0 ) = (y , y , x, x ).
                              ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯


       Hence, the above expression represents a system of n nx nx linear
       equations in then n nx nx unknowns elements of gxx and hxx .




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   52 / 91
The General Case


Solving the System III
Similarly, gσσ and hσσ can be obtained by solving:

[Fσσ (x; 0)]i
      ¯             = [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hσσ ] β
                                     β

                           +[Hy 0 y 0 ]iαγ [gx ]γ [η ]δ [gx ]α [η ]φ [I ]ξ
                                                                           β   φ
                                                δ     ξ      β

                           +[Hy 0 x 0 ]iαδ [η ]δ [gx ]α [η ]φ [I ]ξ
                                                              β      φ
                                               ξ      β

                           +[Hy 0 ]iα [gxx ]α [η ]δ [η ]φ [I ]ξ + [Hy 0 ]iα [gσσ ]α
                                                           β       φ
                                            βδ    ξ

                           +[Hy ]iα [gσσ ]α + [Hx 0 ]iβ [hσσ ] β
                           +[Hx 0 y 0 ]iβγ [gx ]γ [η ]δ [η ]φ [I ]ξ
                                                               β       φ
                                                δ     ξ

                    +[Hx 0 x 0 ]iβδ [η ]δ [η ]φ [I ]ξ = 0;
                                                     β    φ
                                        ξ
                i = 1, . . . , n; α, γ = 1, . . . , ny ; β, δ = 1, . . . , nx ; φ, ξ = 1, . . . , n

a system of n linear equations in the n unknowns given by the elements of
gσσ and hσσ .
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)             Perturbation Methods                    July 10, 2011   53 / 91
The General Case


Cross Derivatives
       The cross derivatives gx σ and hx σ are zero when evaluated at (x, 0).
                                                                       ¯
       Why? Write the system Fσx (x; 0) = 0 taking into account that all
                                     ¯
       terms containing either gσ or hσ are zero at (x, 0).
                                                      ¯
       Then:
                   [Fσx (x; 0)]ij = [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hσx ]j + [Hy 0 ]iα [gσx ]α [hx ]jγ +
                                                                β
                         ¯                         β                           γ

                                    [Hy ]iα [gσx ]jα + [Hx 0 ]iβ [hσx ]j = 0;
                                                                        β


                      i = 1, . . . n;     α = 1, . . . , ny ;       β, γ, j = 1, . . . , nx .
       a system of n nx equations in the n nx unknowns given by the
       elements of gσx and hσx .
       The system is homogeneous in the unknowns.
       Thus, if a unique solution exists, it is given by:
                                                   gσx    = 0
                                                   hσx    = 0
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)            Perturbation Methods                      July 10, 2011   54 / 91
The General Case


Structure of the Solution

       The perturbation solution of the model satis…es:

                                                 gσ (x; 0) = 0
                                                     ¯
                                                 hσ (x; 0) = 0
                                                     ¯
                                               gx σ (x; 0) = 0
                                                     ¯
                                               hx σ (x; 0) = 0
                                                     ¯

       Standard deviation only appears in:
          1   A constant term given by 1 gσσ σ2 for the control vector yt .
                                       2
          2   The …rst nx                         1
                                    n elements of 2 hσσ σ2 .

       Correction for risk.
       Quadratic terms in endogenous state vector x1 .
       Those terms capture non-linear behavior.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)             Perturbation Methods     July 10, 2011   55 / 91
The General Case


Higher-Order Approximations

       We can iterate this procedure as many times as we want.


       We can obtain n-th order approximations.


       Problems:


          1   Existence of higher order derivatives (Santos, 1992).

          2   Numerical instabilities.

          3   Computational costs.


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)          Perturbation Methods       July 10, 2011   56 / 91
Change of Variables




Erik Eady
It is not the process of linearization that limits insight.
It is the nature of the state that we choose to linearize about.




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)             Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   57 / 91
Change of Variables


Change of Variables


       We approximated our solution in levels.


       We could have done it in logs.


       Why stop there? Why not in powers of the state variables?


       Judd (2002) has provided methods for changes of variables.


       We apply and extend ideas to the stochastic neoclassical growth
       model.


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)             Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   58 / 91
Change of Variables


A General Transformation


       We look at solutions of the form:


                                               µ                       ζ
                                     cµ      c0     = a kζ            k0 + bz

                                    k 0γ
                                               γ                       ζ
                                            k0      = c kζ            k0 + dz

       Note that:


          1   If γ, ζ, and µ are 1, we get the linear representation.

          2   As γ, ζ and µ tend to zero, we get the loglinear approximation.


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods             July 10, 2011   59 / 91
Change of Variables


Theory
       The …rst-order solution can be written as
                                    f (x ) ' f (a ) + (x             a ) f 0 (a )


       Expand g (y ) = h (f (X (y ))) around b = Y (a), where X (y ) is the
       inverse of Y (x ).


       Then:
                   g (y ) = h (f (X (y ))) = g (b ) + gα (b ) (Y α (x )                 bα )
       where gα = hA fi A Xα comes from the application of the chain rule.
                           i



       From this expression it is easy to see that if we have computed the
       values of fi A , then it is straightforward to …nd gα .
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)             Perturbation Methods                  July 10, 2011   60 / 91
Change of Variables


Coe¢ cients Relation


       Remember that the linear solution is:

                                    k0      k0    = a1 ( k            k0 ) + b1 z
                                     (l      l0 ) = c1 (k             k0 ) + d1 z

       Then we show that:


                                           γ ζ                          γ 1
                              a3 = γ k0
                                   ζ             a1           b3 = γk0      b1
                                      µ µ 1 1 ζ                         µ 1
                              c3 =    ζ l0 k0 c1              d3 =    µl0 d1




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)              Perturbation Methods                 July 10, 2011   61 / 91
Change of Variables


Finding the Parameters



       Minimize over a grid the Euler Error.


       Some optimal results

                                Euler Equation Errors
                       γ        ζ           µ         SEE
                       1        1          1          0.0856279
                       0.986534 0.991673 2.47856 0.0279944




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)             Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   62 / 91
Change of Variables


Sensitivity Analysis

       Di¤erent parameter values.


       Most interesting …nding is when we change σ:

                             Optimal Parameters for di¤erent σ’s
                             σ      γ        ζ          µ
                             0.014 0.98140 0.98766 2.47753
                             0.028 1.04804 1.05265 1.73209
                             0.056 1.23753 1.22394 0.77869



       A …rst-order approximation corrects for changes in variance!


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)             Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   63 / 91
Change of Variables




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)             Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   64 / 91
Change of Variables


A Quasi-Optimal Approximation
       Sensitivity analysis reveals that for di¤erent parametrizations

                                                            γ'ζ

       This suggests the quasi-optimal approximation:

                                    k 0γ
                                                γ                             γ
                                            k0       = a3 k γ                k0 + b3 z
                                                µ                             γ
                                      lµ     l0      = c3 k γ                k0 + d3 z
                   b
       If we de…ne k = k γ                 k0 and b = l µ
                                            γ
                                                  l
                                                                         µ
                                                                         l0 we get:
                                                b        b
                                                k 0 = a3 k + b3 z
                                                 b = c3 k + d3 z
                                                 l       b

       Linear system:
          1   Use for analytical study.
          2   Use for estimation with a Kalman Filter.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)                 Perturbation Methods                   July 10, 2011   65 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Perturbing the Value Function
       We worked with the equilibrium conditions of the model.

       Sometimes we may want to perform a perturbation on the value
       function formulation of the problem.

       Possible reasons:

          1   Gain insight.

          2   Di¢ culty in using equilibrium conditions.

          3   Evaluate welfare.

          4   Initial guess for VFI.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   66 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Basic Problem

       Imagine that we have:
                                             "                                               #
                                                                1 γ
                                                            c
                  V (kt , zt ) = max (1                  β) t  + βEt V (kt +1 , zt +1 )
                                        ct                 1 γ
                                    s.t. ct + kt +1 = e zt ktθ + (1         δ) kt
                                     zt = λzt        1   + σεt , εt     N (0, 1)

       Write it as:
                                             "                                                      #
                                                                1 γ
                                                            c
              V (kt , zt ; χ) = max (1                   β) t  + βEt V (kt +1 , zt +1 ; χ)
                                        ct                 1 γ
                                    s.t. ct + kt +1 = e zt ktθ + (1         δ) kt
                                    zt = λzt        1   + χσεt , εt     N (0, 1)

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)                Perturbation Methods               July 10, 2011       67 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Alternative


       Another way to write the value function is:


                                                  V (kt , zt ; χ) =
                       "                                               1 γ
                                                                                        #
                max
                                             (1 β ) c t γ +
                                                    1
                  ct       βEt V e zt ktθ + (1 δ) kt ct , λzt + χσεt +1 ; χ

       This form makes the dependences in the next period states explicit.


       The solution of this problem is value function V (kt , zt ; χ) and a
       policy function for consumption c (kt , zt ; χ).



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods         July 10, 2011   68 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Expanding the Value Function
The second-order Taylor approximation of the value function around the
deterministic steady state (kss , 0; 0) is:
                                              V (kt , zt ; χ) '
                 Vss + V1,ss (kt kss ) + V2,ss zt + V3,ss χ
      1                     1                       1
    + V11,ss (kt kss )2 + V12,ss (kt kss ) zt + V13,ss (kt                          kss ) χ
      2                     2                       2
              1                       1            1
            + V21,ss zt (kt kss ) + V22,ss zt2 + V23,ss zt χ
              2                       2            2
               1                     1              1
            + V31,ss χ (kt kss ) + V32,ss χzt + V33,ss χ2
               2                     2              2
where
                          Vss       = V (kss , 0; 0)
                         Vi ,ss     = Vi (kss , 0; 0) for i = f1, 2, 3g
                        Vij ,ss     = Vij (kss , 0; 0) for i, j = f1, 2, 3g
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods          July 10, 2011   69 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Expanding the Value Function

       By certainty equivalence, we will show below that:

                                        V3,ss = V13,ss = V23,ss = 0


       Taking advantage of the equality of cross-derivatives, and setting
       χ = 1, which is just a normalization:

                     V (kt , zt ; 1) ' Vss + V1,ss (kt kss ) + V2,ss zt
                                         1                     1
                                       + V11,ss (kt kss )2 + V22,ss ztt 2
                                         2                     2
                                                              1
                                       +V12,ss (kt kss ) z + V33,ss
                                                              2
       Note that V33,ss 6= 0, a di¤erence from the standard linear-quadratic
       approximation to the utility functions.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   70 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Expanding the Consumption Function

       The policy function for consumption can be expanded as:

                ct = c (kt , zt ; χ) ' css + c1,ss (kt                 kss ) + c2,ss zt + c3,ss χ

       where:

                                            c1,ss     = c1 (kss , 0; 0)
                                            c2,ss     = c2 (kss , 0; 0)
                                            c3,ss     = c3 (kss , 0; 0)

       Since the …rst derivatives of the consumption function only depend on
       the …rst and second derivatives of the value function, we must have
       c3,ss = 0 (precautionary consumption depends on the third derivative
       of the value function, Kimball, 1990).

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                   July 10, 2011   71 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Linear Components of the Value Function

       To …nd the linear approximation to the value function, we take
       derivatives of the value function with respect to controls (ct ), states
       (kt , zt ), and the perturbation parameter χ.


       Notation:


          1   Vi ,t : derivative of the value function with respect to its i-th argument,
              evaluated in (kt , zt ; χ) .

          2   Vi ,ss : derivative evaluated in the steady state, (kss , 0; 0).

          3   We follow the same notation for higher-order (cross-) derivatives.


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods        July 10, 2011   72 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Derivatives
       Derivative with respect to ct :
                                                        γ
                                      (1      β ) ct         βEt V1,t +1 = 0
       Derivative with respect to kt :

                               V1,t = βEt V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ            1
                                                                           +1   δ

       Derivative with respect to zt :
                                     h                          i
                        V2,t = βEt V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V2,t +1 λ

       Derivative with respect to χ:
                                    V3,t = βEt [V2,t +1 σεt +1 + V3,t +1 ]
       In the last three derivatives, we apply the envelope theorem to
       eliminate the derivatives of consumption with respect to kt , zt , and χ.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                July 10, 2011   73 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


System of Equations I

Now, we have the system:

                                    ct + kt +1 = e zt ktθ + (1           δ) kt
                                                         1 γ
                                                        ct
                V (kt , zt ; χ) = (1            β)          + βEt V (kt +1 , zt +1 ; χ)
                                                        1 γ
                                                    γ
                                    (1     β ) ct           βEt V1,t +1 = 0
                            V1,t = βEt V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ
                                        h                            i
                             V2,t = βEt V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V2,t +1 λ
                              V3,t = βEt [V2,t +1 σεt +1 + V3,t +1 ]
                                           zt = λzt         1   + χσεt



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods               July 10, 2011   74 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


System of Equations II
If we set χ = 0 and compute the steady state, we get a system of six
equations on six unknowns, css , kss , Vss , V1,ss , V2,ss , and V3,ss :
                                                           θ
                                             css + δkss = kss
                                                             1 γ
                                                            css
                                     Vss = (1          β)         + βVss
                                                            1 γ
                                       (1     β) css γ       βV1,ss = 0
                                    V1,ss = βV1,ss θkss 1 + 1 δ
                                                      θ

                                              h                    i
                                                      θ
                                     V2,ss = β V1,ss kss + V2,ss λ
                                               V3,ss = βV3,ss
       From the last equation: V3,ss = 0.
                                           1 γ
       From the second equation: Vss = css γ .
                                          1
                                                            1 β   γ
       From the third equation: V1,ss =                      β css .
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods       July 10, 2011   75 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


System of Equations III
       After cancelling redundant terms:
                                                               θ
                                                 css + δkss = kss
                                         1 = β θkss 1 + 1 δ
                                                   θ

                                                h                    i
                                                        θ
                                       V2,ss = β V1,ss kss + V2,ss λ

       Then:
                                                                        1
                                              1             1          θ 1
                                        kss =                    1+δ
                                              θ             β
                                                      θ
                                               css = kss δkss
                                                     1 β θ γ
                                            V2,ss =      k c
                                                    1 βλ ss ss
       V1,ss > 0 and V2,ss > 0, as predicted by theory.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods         July 10, 2011   76 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Quadratic Components of the Value Function
From the previous derivations, we have:
                                                            γ
                          (1        β) c (kt , zt ; χ)             βEt V1,t +1 = 0
                            V1,t = βEt V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ
                                        h                            i
                             V2,t = βEt V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V2,t +1 λ
                                V3,t = βEt [V2,t +1 σεt +1 + V3,t +1 ]
where:
                       kt +1 = e zt ktθ + (1                    δ) kt   c (kt , zt ; χ)
                           zt       = λzt       1   + χσεt , εt         N (0, 1)
       We take derivatives of each of the four equations w.t.r. kt , zt , and χ.
       We take advantage of the equality of cross derivatives.
       The envelope theorem does not hold anymore (we are taking
       derivatives of the derivatives of the value function).
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                      July 10, 2011   77 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


First Equation I
We have:
                                                             γ
                          (1        β) c (kt , zt ; χ)               βEt V1,t +1 = 0

       Derivative with respect to kt :
                                                                              γ 1
                                         (1      β) γc (kt , zt ; χ)                c1,t
                                    h                                                      i
                           βEt V11,t +1 e zt θktθ                1
                                                                     +1       δ     c1,t       =0

       In steady state:
                                                                     h                                             i
                                                     1                                         1
              βV11,ss        (1         β) γcss γ                              θ
                                                            c1,ss = β V11,ss θkss                  +1         δ

       or
                                                                 V11,ss
                                    c1,ss =                                         γ 1
                                               βV11,ss           (1      β) γcss
       where we have used that 1 = β θkss
                                       θ                             1   +1       δ .
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                               July 10, 2011       78 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


First Equation II


       Derivative with respect to zt :
                                                                          γ 1
                                         (1      β) γc (kt , zt ; χ)            c2,t
                           βEt V11,t +1 e zt ktθ                  c2,t + V12,t +1 λ = 0

       In steady state:

                                                            1
                 βV11,ss            (1   β) γcss γ              c2,ss = β V11,ss ktθ + V12,ss λ

       or
                                                   β                             θ
                  c2,ss =                                          γ 1
                                                                         V11,ss kss + V12,ss λ
                              βV11,ss         (1       β) γcss



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                   July 10, 2011   79 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


First Equation III


       Derivative with respect to χ:
                                                                            γ 1
                                        (1       β) γc (kt , zt ; χ)              c3,t
                        βEt ( V11,t +1 c3,t + V12,t +1 σεt +1 + V13,t +1 ) = 0

       In steady state:
                                                                       1
                             βV11,ss         (1       β) γcss γ            c3,ss = βV13,ss

       or
                                                                 β
                            c3,ss =                                                  V13,ss
                                                                               γ 1
                                           βV11,ss          (1       β) γcss



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                      July 10, 2011   80 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Second Equation I
We have:
                            V1,t = βEt V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ               1
                                                                           +1      δ

       Derivative with respect to kt :
                   "                                                                                                  #
                      V11,t +1 θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ                            c1,t       θe zt ktθ     1
                                                                                                          +1    δ
       V11,t = βEt
                                                                                            2
                                       +V1,t +1 θ (θ                        1) e zt ktθ

       In steady state:

                                                 1                                            θ       2
                   V11,ss = V11,ss                         c1,ss   + βV1,ss θ (θ          1) kss
                                                 β
       or
                                                         β                             θ    2
                             V11,ss =                1
                                                                 V1,ss θ (θ        1) kss
                                            1        β   + c1,ss

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                            July 10, 2011   81 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Second Equation II


       Derivative with respect to zt :
                     2                                                                                          3
                           V11,t +1 e zt ktθ c2,t θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ
        V12,t = βEt  4                                                                                          5
                        +V12,t +1 λ θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ + V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ                                   1


       In steady state:

                                     θ                                                               1
                    V12,ss = V11,ss kss                    c2,ss + V12,ss λ + βV1,ss θktθ

       or                                       h                                                    i
                                        1                   θ                               θ    1
                     V12,ss =                       V11,ss kss             c2,ss + βV1,ss θkss
                                    1       λ



Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)                   Perturbation Methods                    July 10, 2011       82 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Second Equation III

       Derivative with respect to χ:

                    V13,t = βEt [ V11,t +1 c3,t + V12,t +1 σεt +1 + V13,t +1 ]

       In steady state,

                              V13,ss       = β [ V11,ss c3,ss + V13,ss ] )
                                                β
                              V13,ss       =      V11,ss c3,ss
                                             β 1

       but since we know that:
                                                                 β
                            c3,ss =                                                  V13,ss
                                                                               γ 1
                                           βV11,ss          (1       β) γcss

       the two equations can only hold simultaneously if V13,ss = c3,ss = 0.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                      July 10, 2011   83 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Third Equation I
We have                                h                             i
                             V2,t = βEt V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V2,t +1 λ

       Derivative with respect to zt :

                                 V11,t +1 e zt ktθ c2,t e zt ktθ + V12,t +1 λe zt ktθ
       V22,t = βEt
                              +V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V21,t +1 λ e zt ktθ c2,t + V22,t +1 λ2

       In steady state:

                                    V11,ss ktθ c2,ss kss + V12,ss λkss + V1,ss kss
                                                       θ            θ           θ
          V22,t      = β                                                                    )
                                          +V21,ss λ kss c2,ss + V22,ss λ2
                                                     θ

                              β               V11,ss ktθ c2,ss kss + 2V12,ss λkss
                                                                θ              θ
         V22,ss      =
                            1 βλ2                   +V1,ss kss V12,ss λc2,ss
                                                            θ


       where we have used V12,ss = V21,ss .
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods        July 10, 2011   84 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Third Equation II




       Derivative with respect to χ:

                                    V11,t +1 e zt ktθ c3,t + V12,t +1 e zt ktθ σεt +1 + V13,t +1 e zt ktθ
       V23,t = βEt
                                           V21,t +1 λc3,t + V22,t +1 λσεt +1 + V23,t +1 λ

       In steady state:
                                                      V23,ss = 0




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                   July 10, 2011   85 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Fourth Equation


We have
                              V3,t = βEt [V2,t +1 σεt +1 + V3,t +1 ] .

       Derivative with respect to χ:

                                    V21,t +1 c3,t σεt +1 + V22,t +1 σ2 ε2+1 + V23,t +1 σεt +1
                                                                        t
        V33,t = βEt
                                           V31,t +1 c3,t + V32,t +1 σεt +1 + V33,t +1

In steady state:
                                                                β
                                         V33,ss =                       V22,ss
                                                            1       β




Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods             July 10, 2011   86 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


System I

                                                            V11,ss
                               c1,ss =                                       γ 1
                                            βV11,ss         (1     β) γcss
                                             β                                 θ
              c2,ss =                                        γ 1
                                                                       V11,ss kss + V12,ss λ
                          βV11,ss         (1     β) γcss
                                                 β
                         V11,ss =              1
                                                      1) kss 2
                                                          θ
                                                         V1,ss θ (θ
                            1                  β + c1,ss
                          1 h                                    i
               V12,ss =       V11,ss kss c2,ss + βV1,ss θkss 1
                                      θ                        θ
                        1 λ
                        β     V11,ss ktθ c2,ss kss + 2V12,ss λkss
                                                    θ            θ
            V22,ss =
                      1 βλ2          +V1,ss kss V12,ss λc2,ss
                                             θ

                                      β
                            V33,ss =       σ2 V22,ss
                                     1 β
plus c3,ss = V13,ss = V23,ss = 0.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                    July 10, 2011   87 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


System II


       This is a system of nonlinear equations.


       However, it has a recursive structure.


       By substituting variables that we already know, we can …nd V11,ss .


       Then, using this results and by plugging c2,ss , we have a system of
       two equations, on two unknowns, V12,ss and V22,ss .


       Once the system is solved, we can …nd c1,ss , c2,ss , and V33,ss directly.


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   88 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


The Welfare Cost of the Business Cycle

       An advantage of performing the perturbation on the value function is
       that we have evaluation of welfare readily available.


       Note that at the deterministic steady state, we have:

                                                             1
                                       V (kss , 0; χ) ' Vss + V33,ss
                                                             2
       Hence 1 V33,ss is a measure of the welfare cost of the business cycle.
             2


       This quantity is not necessarily negative: it may be positive. For
       example, in an RBC with leisure choice (Cho and Cooley, 2000).


Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods   July 10, 2011   89 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


Our Example

                                             1 γ
                                          css
       We know that Vss =                 1 γ.
       We can compute the decrease in consumption τ that will make the
       household indi¤erent between consuming (1 τ ) css units per period
       with certainty or ct units with uncertainty.
       Thus:
                                     1 γ
                                    css  1                                 (css (1    τ ))1   γ
                                        + V33,ss                     =                            )
                                    1 γ 2                                        1    γ
                                                                                  1
                        (1       τ )1    γ        1
                                               1 css         γ
                                                                     = (1       γ) V33,ss
                                                                                  2
       or                                                                             1
                                                                 1       γ1          1 γ
                                     τ=1               1+            1
                                                                            V
                                                                         γ 2 33,ss
                                                                 css

Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)                  Perturbation Methods                       July 10, 2011   90 / 91
Perturbing the Value Function


A Numerical Example
       We pick standard parameter values by setting
                     β = 0.99, γ = 2, δ = 0.0294, θ = 0.3, and λ = 0.95.
       We get:
             V (kt , zt ; 1) '              0.54000 + 0.00295 (kt               kss ) + 0.11684zt
                                                                          2
                                            0.00007 (kt           kss )       0.00985zt2
                                            0.97508σ2            0.00225 (kt       kss ) zt
             c (kt , zt ; χ) ' 1.85193 + 0.04220 (kt                          kss ) + 0.74318zt
       DYNARE produces the same policy function by linearizing the
       equilibrium conditions of the problem.
       The welfare cost of the business cycle (in consumption terms) is
       8.8475e-005, lower than in Lucas (1987) because of the smoothing
       possibilities allowed by capital.
       Use as an initial guess for VFI.
Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN)               Perturbation Methods                    July 10, 2011   91 / 91

More Related Content

PDF
Chapter 3 projection
PDF
Chapter 5 heterogeneous
PDF
Chapter 1 nonlinear
PDF
Chapter 4 likelihood
PDF
Lecture on solving1
PDF
Optimalpolicyhandout
PDF
Nber slides11 lecture2
PDF
Lesson 15: Exponential Growth and Decay
Chapter 3 projection
Chapter 5 heterogeneous
Chapter 1 nonlinear
Chapter 4 likelihood
Lecture on solving1
Optimalpolicyhandout
Nber slides11 lecture2
Lesson 15: Exponential Growth and Decay

What's hot (20)

PDF
Parameter Uncertainty and Learning in Dynamic Financial Decisions
PDF
Lesson 14: Derivatives of Logarithmic and Exponential Functions
PDF
Estimation of Static Discrete Choice Models Using Market Level Data
PDF
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysis
PDF
Lesson 13: Related Rates Problems
PDF
Rouviere
PDF
04 structured prediction and energy minimization part 1
PDF
On estimating the integrated co volatility using
PDF
Chapter2: Likelihood-based approach
PDF
Savage-Dickey paradox
PPTX
Discrete Probability Distributions
PDF
Propensity albert
PDF
Lesson 1: Functions
PDF
Saddlepoint approximations, likelihood asymptotics, and approximate condition...
PDF
Label propagation - Semisupervised Learning with Applications to NLP
PDF
Generalization of Tensor Factorization and Applications
PDF
ABC and empirical likelihood
PDF
State Space Model
PDF
Lesage
PDF
1 - Linear Regression
Parameter Uncertainty and Learning in Dynamic Financial Decisions
Lesson 14: Derivatives of Logarithmic and Exponential Functions
Estimation of Static Discrete Choice Models Using Market Level Data
The Black-Litterman model in the light of Bayesian portfolio analysis
Lesson 13: Related Rates Problems
Rouviere
04 structured prediction and energy minimization part 1
On estimating the integrated co volatility using
Chapter2: Likelihood-based approach
Savage-Dickey paradox
Discrete Probability Distributions
Propensity albert
Lesson 1: Functions
Saddlepoint approximations, likelihood asymptotics, and approximate condition...
Label propagation - Semisupervised Learning with Applications to NLP
Generalization of Tensor Factorization and Applications
ABC and empirical likelihood
State Space Model
Lesage
1 - Linear Regression
Ad

Viewers also liked (8)

PDF
Lecture on nk [compatibility mode]
PDF
Csvfrictions
PDF
Dynare exercise
PDF
Econometrics of High-Dimensional Sparse Models
PDF
Applications: Prediction
PDF
Nuts and bolts
PDF
High-Dimensional Methods: Examples for Inference on Structural Effects
PDF
Big Data Analysis
Lecture on nk [compatibility mode]
Csvfrictions
Dynare exercise
Econometrics of High-Dimensional Sparse Models
Applications: Prediction
Nuts and bolts
High-Dimensional Methods: Examples for Inference on Structural Effects
Big Data Analysis
Ad

Similar to Chapter 2 pertubation (20)

PDF
Mit18 330 s12_chapter5
PDF
Program on Mathematical and Statistical Methods for Climate and the Earth Sys...
PDF
ContractorBeamer
PDF
quan2009.pdf
PDF
ICCF_2022_talk.pdf
PDF
On probability distributions
PDF
SAS Homework Help
PDF
Can we estimate a constant?
PDF
CMA-ES with local meta-models
PDF
Modeling Heterogeneity by Structural Varying Coefficients Models in Presence of...
PDF
Linear regression
PDF
MCQMC 2020 talk: Importance Sampling for a Robust and Efficient Multilevel Mo...
PDF
100 things I know
PDF
Monte Carlo Methods 2017 July Talk in Montreal
PDF
Fundamentals of Momentum, Heat and Mass Transfer | 6th Edition UnsteadyModel...
PDF
NONLINEAR DIFFERENCE EQUATIONS WITH SMALL PARAMETERS OF MULTIPLE SCALES
PDF
Chapter 1_Sets. Operation sets, Principle of inclusion and exclusion etc.
PDF
6. bounds test for cointegration within ardl or vecm
PDF
Bath_IMI_Summer_Project
Mit18 330 s12_chapter5
Program on Mathematical and Statistical Methods for Climate and the Earth Sys...
ContractorBeamer
quan2009.pdf
ICCF_2022_talk.pdf
On probability distributions
SAS Homework Help
Can we estimate a constant?
CMA-ES with local meta-models
Modeling Heterogeneity by Structural Varying Coefficients Models in Presence of...
Linear regression
MCQMC 2020 talk: Importance Sampling for a Robust and Efficient Multilevel Mo...
100 things I know
Monte Carlo Methods 2017 July Talk in Montreal
Fundamentals of Momentum, Heat and Mass Transfer | 6th Edition UnsteadyModel...
NONLINEAR DIFFERENCE EQUATIONS WITH SMALL PARAMETERS OF MULTIPLE SCALES
Chapter 1_Sets. Operation sets, Principle of inclusion and exclusion etc.
6. bounds test for cointegration within ardl or vecm
Bath_IMI_Summer_Project

More from NBER (20)

PDF
FISCAL STIMULUS IN ECONOMIC UNIONS: WHAT ROLE FOR STATES
PDF
Business in the United States Who Owns it and How Much Tax They Pay
PDF
Redistribution through Minimum Wage Regulation: An Analysis of Program Linkag...
PDF
The Distributional E ffects of U.S. Clean Energy Tax Credits
PDF
An Experimental Evaluation of Strategies to Increase Property Tax Compliance:...
PDF
Nbe rtopicsandrecomvlecture1
PDF
Nbe rcausalpredictionv111 lecture2
PPTX
Recommenders, Topics, and Text
PPTX
Machine Learning and Causal Inference
PDF
Introduction to Supervised ML Concepts and Algorithms
PDF
Jackson nber-slides2014 lecture3
PDF
Jackson nber-slides2014 lecture1
PDF
Acemoglu lecture2
PDF
Acemoglu lecture4
PPTX
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Joshua Gans
PPTX
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Claudia Goldin
PPT
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - James Poterba
PPTX
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Scott Stern
PDF
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Glenn Ellison
PDF
L3 1b
FISCAL STIMULUS IN ECONOMIC UNIONS: WHAT ROLE FOR STATES
Business in the United States Who Owns it and How Much Tax They Pay
Redistribution through Minimum Wage Regulation: An Analysis of Program Linkag...
The Distributional E ffects of U.S. Clean Energy Tax Credits
An Experimental Evaluation of Strategies to Increase Property Tax Compliance:...
Nbe rtopicsandrecomvlecture1
Nbe rcausalpredictionv111 lecture2
Recommenders, Topics, and Text
Machine Learning and Causal Inference
Introduction to Supervised ML Concepts and Algorithms
Jackson nber-slides2014 lecture3
Jackson nber-slides2014 lecture1
Acemoglu lecture2
Acemoglu lecture4
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Joshua Gans
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Claudia Goldin
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - James Poterba
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Scott Stern
The NBER Working Paper Series at 20,000 - Glenn Ellison
L3 1b

Recently uploaded (20)

PPTX
Group 1 Presentation -Planning and Decision Making .pptx
PDF
Blue Purple Modern Animated Computer Science Presentation.pdf.pdf
PPTX
Machine Learning_overview_presentation.pptx
PDF
Video forgery: An extensive analysis of inter-and intra-frame manipulation al...
PDF
August Patch Tuesday
PPTX
Digital-Transformation-Roadmap-for-Companies.pptx
PDF
Per capita expenditure prediction using model stacking based on satellite ima...
PDF
Assigned Numbers - 2025 - Bluetooth® Document
PPTX
TLE Review Electricity (Electricity).pptx
PDF
Building Integrated photovoltaic BIPV_UPV.pdf
PPTX
cloud_computing_Infrastucture_as_cloud_p
PPTX
Programs and apps: productivity, graphics, security and other tools
PDF
Network Security Unit 5.pdf for BCA BBA.
PDF
Univ-Connecticut-ChatGPT-Presentaion.pdf
PDF
Unlocking AI with Model Context Protocol (MCP)
PDF
7 ChatGPT Prompts to Help You Define Your Ideal Customer Profile.pdf
PPTX
1. Introduction to Computer Programming.pptx
PPTX
OMC Textile Division Presentation 2021.pptx
PDF
Agricultural_Statistics_at_a_Glance_2022_0.pdf
PDF
Machine learning based COVID-19 study performance prediction
Group 1 Presentation -Planning and Decision Making .pptx
Blue Purple Modern Animated Computer Science Presentation.pdf.pdf
Machine Learning_overview_presentation.pptx
Video forgery: An extensive analysis of inter-and intra-frame manipulation al...
August Patch Tuesday
Digital-Transformation-Roadmap-for-Companies.pptx
Per capita expenditure prediction using model stacking based on satellite ima...
Assigned Numbers - 2025 - Bluetooth® Document
TLE Review Electricity (Electricity).pptx
Building Integrated photovoltaic BIPV_UPV.pdf
cloud_computing_Infrastucture_as_cloud_p
Programs and apps: productivity, graphics, security and other tools
Network Security Unit 5.pdf for BCA BBA.
Univ-Connecticut-ChatGPT-Presentaion.pdf
Unlocking AI with Model Context Protocol (MCP)
7 ChatGPT Prompts to Help You Define Your Ideal Customer Profile.pdf
1. Introduction to Computer Programming.pptx
OMC Textile Division Presentation 2021.pptx
Agricultural_Statistics_at_a_Glance_2022_0.pdf
Machine learning based COVID-19 study performance prediction

Chapter 2 pertubation

  • 1. Perturbation Methods Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania July 10, 2011 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 1 / 91
  • 2. Introduction Introduction Remember that we want to solve a functional equation of the form: H (d ) = 0 for an unknown decision rule d. Perturbation solves the problem by specifying: n d n (x, θ ) = ∑ θ i (x x0 )i i =0 We use implicit-function theorems to …nd coe¢ cients θ i ’s. Inherently local approximation. However, often good global properties. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 2 / 91
  • 3. Introduction Motivation Many complicated mathematical problems have: 1 either a particular case 2 or a related problem. that is easy to solve. Often, we can use the solution of the simpler problem as a building block of the general solution. Very successful in physics. Sometimes perturbation is known as asymptotic methods. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 3 / 91
  • 4. Introduction The World Simplest Perturbation p What is 26? Without your Iphone calculator, it is a boring arithmetic calculation. But note that: p q p 26 = 25 (1 + 0.04) = 5 1.04 5 1.02 = 5.1 Exact solution is 5.099. p We have solved a much simpler problem ( 25) and added a small coe¢ cient to it. More in general q p p y= x 2 (1 + ε ) = x 1 + ε where x is an integer and ε the perturbation parameter. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 4 / 91
  • 5. Introduction Applications to Economics Judd and Guu (1993) showed how to apply it to economic problems. Recently, perturbation methods have been gaining much popularity. In particular, second- and third-order approximations are easy to compute and notably improve accuracy. A …rst-order perturbation theory and linearization deliver the same output. Hence, we can use much of what we already know about linearization. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 5 / 91
  • 6. Introduction Regular versus Singular Perturbations Regular perturbation: a small change in the problem induces a small change in the solution. Singular perturbation: a small change in the problem induces a large change in the solution. Example: excess demand function. Most problems in economics involve regular perturbations. Sometimes, however, we can have singularities. Example: introducing a new asset in an incomplete markets model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 6 / 91
  • 7. Introduction References General: 1 A First Look at Perturbation Theory by James G. Simmonds and James E. Mann Jr. 2 Advanced Mathematical Methods for Scientists and Engineers: Asymptotic Methods and Perturbation Theory by Carl M. Bender, Steven A. Orszag. Economics: 1 Perturbation Methods for General Dynamic Stochastic Models” by Hehui Jin and Kenneth Judd. 2 Perturbation Methods with Nonlinear Changes of Variables” by Kenneth Judd. 3 A gentle introduction: “Solving Dynamic General Equilibrium Models Using a Second-Order Approximation to the Policy Function” by Martín Uribe and Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 7 / 91
  • 8. A Baby Example A Baby Example: A Basic RBC Model: ∞ max E0 ∑ βt log ct t =0 s.t. ct + kt +1 = e zt ktα + (1 δ) kt , 8 t > 0 zt = ρzt 1 + σεt , εt N (0, 1) Equilibrium conditions: 1 1 = βEt 1 + αe zt +1 ktα+1 δ 1 ct ct + 1 ct + kt +1 = e zt ktα + (1 δ) kt zt = ρzt 1 + σεt Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 8 / 91
  • 9. A Baby Example Computing a Solution The previous problem does not have a known “paper and pencil” solution except when (unrealistically) δ = 1. Then, income and substitution e¤ect from a technology shock cancel each other (labor constant and consumption is a …xed fraction of income). Equilibrium conditions with δ = 1: 1 1 αe zt +1 ktα+1 = βEt ct ct + 1 ct + kt +1 = e zt ktα zt = ρzt 1 + σεt By “guess and verify”: ct = ( 1 αβ) e zt ktα kt +1 = αβe zt ktα Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 9 / 91
  • 10. A Baby Example Another Way to Solve the Problem Now let us suppose that you missed the lecture when “guess and verify” was explained. You need to compute the RBC. What you are searching for? A decision rule for consumption: ct = c (kt , zt ) and another one for capital: kt +1 = k (kt , zt ) Note that our d is just the stack of c (kt , zt ) and k (kt , zt ). Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 10 / 91
  • 11. A Baby Example Equilibrium Conditions We substitute in the equilibrium conditions the budget constraint and the law of motion for technology. And we write the decision rules explicitly as function of the states. Then: 1 αe ρzt +σεt +1 k (kt , zt )α 1 = βEt c (kt , zt ) c (k (kt , zt ) , ρzt + σεt +1 ) c (kt , zt ) + k (kt , zt ) = e zt ktα System of functional equations. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 11 / 91
  • 12. A Baby Example Main Idea Transform the problem rewriting it in terms of a small perturbation parameter. Solve the new problem for a particular choice of the perturbation parameter. This step is usually ambiguous since there are di¤erent ways to do so. Use the previous solution to approximate the solution of original the problem. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 12 / 91
  • 13. A Baby Example A Perturbation Approach Hence, we want to transform the problem. Which perturbation parameter? Standard deviation σ. Why σ? Discrete versus continuous time. Set σ = 0 )deterministic model, zt = 0 and e zt = 1. We know how to solve the deterministic steady state. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 13 / 91
  • 14. A Baby Example A Parametrized Decision Rule We search for decision rule: ct = c (kt , zt ; σ) and kt +1 = k (kt , zt ; σ) Note new parameter σ. We are building a local approximation around σ = 0. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 14 / 91
  • 15. A Baby Example Taylor’ Theorem s Equilibrium conditions: ! 1 αe ρzt +σεt +1 k (kt , zt ; σ)α 1 Et β =0 c (kt , zt ; σ) c (k (kt , zt ; σ) , ρzt + σεt +1 ; σ) c (kt , zt ; σ) + k (kt , zt ; σ) e zt ktα = 0 We will take derivatives with respect to kt , zt , and σ. Apply Taylor’ theorem to build solution around deterministic steady s state. How? Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 15 / 91
  • 16. A Baby Example Asymptotic Expansion I ct = c (kt , zt ; σ)jk ,0,0 = c (k, 0; 0) +ck (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) + cz (k, 0; 0) zt + cσ (k, 0; 0) σ 1 1 + ckk (k, 0; 0) (kt k )2 + ckz (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) zt 2 2 1 1 + ck σ (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) σ + czk (k, 0; 0) zt (kt k ) 2 2 1 2 1 + czz (k, 0; 0) zt + cz σ (k, 0; 0) zt σ 2 2 1 1 + cσk (k, 0; 0) σ (kt k ) + cσz (k, 0; 0) σzt 2 2 1 2 + cσ2 (k, 0; 0) σ + ... 2 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 16 / 91
  • 17. A Baby Example Asymptotic Expansion II kt +1 = k (kt , zt ; σ)jk ,0,0 = k (k, 0; 0) +kk (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) + kz (k, 0; 0) zt + kσ (k, 0; 0) σ 1 1 + kkk (k, 0; 0) (kt k )2 + kkz (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) zt 2 2 1 1 + kk σ (k, 0; 0) (kt k ) σ + kzk (k, 0; 0) zt (kt k ) 2 2 1 2 1 + kzz (k, 0; 0) zt + kz σ (k, 0; 0) zt σ 2 2 1 1 + kσk (k, 0; 0) σ (kt k ) + kσz (k, 0; 0) σzt 2 2 1 2 + kσ2 (k, 0; 0) σ + ... 2 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 17 / 91
  • 18. A Baby Example Comment on Notation From now on, to save on notation, I will write " # 1 αe ρzt +σεt +1 k (k ,zt ;σ)α 1 β c (k (kt ,zt ;σ),ρztt+σεt +1 ;σ) 0 F (kt , zt ; σ) = Et c (kt ,zt ;σ ) = c (kt , zt ; σ) + k (kt , zt ; σ) e zt ktα 0 Note that: F (kt , zt ; σ) = H (ct , ct +1 , kt , kt +1 , zt ; σ) = H (c (kt , zt ; σ) , c (k (kt , zt ; σ) , zt +1 ; σ) , kt , k (kt , zt ; σ) , zt ; σ) I will use Hi to represent the partial derivative of H with respect to the i component and drop the evaluation at the steady state of the functions when we do not need it. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 18 / 91
  • 19. A Baby Example Zeroth-Order Approximation First, we evaluate σ = 0: F (kt , 0; 0) = 0 Steady state: 1 αk α 1 =β c c or 1 1 = αβk α Then: α 1 c = c (k, 0; 0) = (αβ) 1 α (αβ) 1 α 1 k = k (k, 0; 0) = (αβ) 1 α Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 19 / 91
  • 20. A Baby Example First-Order Approximation We take derivatives of F (kt , zt ; σ) around k, 0, and 0. With respect to kt : Fk (k, 0; 0) = 0 With respect to zt : Fz (k, 0; 0) = 0 With respect to σ: Fσ (k, 0; 0) = 0 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 20 / 91
  • 21. A Baby Example Solving the System I Remember that: F (kt , zt ; σ) = H (c (kt , zt ; σ) , c (k (kt , zt ; σ) , zt +1 ; σ) , kt , k (kt , zt ; σ) , zt ; σ) = 0 Because F (kt , zt ; σ) must be equal to zero for any possible values of kt , zt , and σ, the derivatives of any order of F must also be zero. Then: Fk (k, 0; 0) = H1 ck + H2 ck kk + H3 + H4 kk = 0 Fz (k, 0; 0) = H1 cz + H2 (ck kz + ck ρ) + H4 kz + H5 = 0 Fσ (k, 0; 0) = H1 cσ + H2 (ck kσ + cσ ) + H4 kσ + H6 = 0 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 21 / 91
  • 22. A Baby Example Solving the System II A quadratic system: Fk (k, 0; 0) = H1 ck + H2 ck kk + H3 + H4 kk = 0 Fz (k, 0; 0) = H1 cz + H2 (ck kz + ck ρ) + H4 kz + H5 = 0 of 4 equations on 4 unknowns: ck , cz , kk , and kz . Procedures to solve quadratic systems: 1 Blanchard and Kahn (1980). 2 Uhlig (1999). 3 Sims (2000). 4 Klein (2000). All of them equivalent. Why quadratic? Stable and unstable manifold. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 22 / 91
  • 23. A Baby Example Solving the System III Also, note that: Fσ (k, 0; 0) = H1 cσ + H2 (ck kσ + cσ ) + H4 kσ + H6 = 0 is a linear, and homogeneous system in cσ and kσ . Hence: cσ = kσ = 0 This means the system is certainty equivalent. Interpretation)no precautionary behavior. Di¤erence between risk-aversion and precautionary behavior. Leland (1968), Kimball (1990). Risk-aversion depends on the second derivative (concave utility). Precautionary behavior depends on the third derivative (convex marginal utility). Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 23 / 91
  • 24. A Baby Example Comparison with LQ and Linearization After Kydland and Prescott (1982) a popular method to solve economic models has been to …nd a LQ approximation of the objective function of the agents. Close relative: linearization of equilibrium conditions. When properly implemented linearization, LQ, and …rst-order perturbation are equivalent. Advantages of perturbation: 1 Theorems. 2 Higher-order terms. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 24 / 91
  • 25. A Baby Example Some Further Comments Note how we have used a version of the implicit-function theorem. Important tool in economics. Also, we are using the Taylor theorem to approximate the policy function. Alternatives? Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 25 / 91
  • 26. A Baby Example Second-Order Approximation We take second-order derivatives of F (kt , zt ; σ) around k, 0, and 0: Fkk (k, 0; 0) = 0 Fkz (k, 0; 0) = 0 Fk σ (k, 0; 0) = 0 Fzz (k, 0; 0) = 0 Fz σ (k, 0; 0) = 0 Fσσ (k, 0; 0) = 0 Remember Young’ theorem! s We substitute the coe¢ cients that we already know. A linear system of 12 equations on 12 unknowns. Why linear? Cross-terms kσ and zσ are zero. Conjecture on all the terms with odd powers of σ. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 26 / 91
  • 27. A Baby Example Correction for Risk We have a term in σ2 . Captures precautionary behavior. We do not have certainty equivalence any more! Important advantage of second-order approximation. Changes ergodic distribution of states. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 27 / 91
  • 28. A Baby Example Higher-Order Terms We can continue the iteration for as long as we want. Great advantage of procedure: it is recursive! Often, a few iterations will be enough. The level of accuracy depends on the goal of the exercise: 1 Welfare analysis: Kim and Kim (2001). 2 Empirical strategies: Fernández-Villaverde, Rubio-Ramírez, and Santos (2006). Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 28 / 91
  • 29. A Numerical Example A Numerical Example Parameter β α ρ σ Value 0.99 0.33 0.95 0.01 Steady State: c = 0.388069 k = 0.1883 First-order terms: ck (k, 0; 0) = 0.680101 kk (k, 0; 0) = 0.33 cz (k, 0; 0) = 0.388069 kz (k, 0; 0) = 0.1883 Second-order terms: ckk (k, 0; 0) = 2.41990 kkk (k, 0; 0) = 1.1742 ckz (k, 0; 0) = 0.680099 kkz (k, 0; 0) = 0.33 czz (k, 0; 0) = 0.388064 kzz (k, 0; 0) = 0.1883 cσ2 (k, 0; 0) ' 0 kσ2 (k, 0; 0) ' 0 cσ (k, 0; 0) = kσ (k, 0; 0) = ck σ (k, 0; 0) = kk σ (k, 0; 0) = cz σ (k, 0; 0) = kz σ (k, 0; 0) = 0. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 29 / 91
  • 30. A Numerical Example Comparison ct = 0.6733e zt kt0.33 ct ' 0.388069 + 0.680101 (kt k ) + 0.388069zt 2.41990 0.388064 2 (kt k )2 + 0.680099 (kt k ) zt + zt 2 2 and: kt +1 = 0.3267e zt kt0.33 kt +1 ' 0.1883 + 0.33 (kt k ) + 0.1883zt 1.1742 0.1883 2 (kt k )2 + 0.33 (kt k ) zt + zt 2 2 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 30 / 91
  • 31. A Numerical Example Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 31 / 91
  • 32. A Numerical Example A Computer In practice you do all this approximations with a computer: 1 First-, second-, and third-order: Matlab and Dynare. 2 Higher-order: Mathematica, Dynare++, Fortran code by Jinn and Judd. Burden: analytical derivatives. Why are numerical derivatives a bad idea? Alternatives: automatic di¤erentiation? Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 32 / 91
  • 33. A Numerical Example Local Properties of the Solution Perturbation is a local method. It approximates the solution around the deterministic steady state of the problem. It is valid within a radius of convergence. What is the radius of convergence of a power series around x? An r 2 R∞ such that 8x 0 , jx 0 z j < r , the power series of x 0 will + converge. A Remarkable Result from Complex Analysis The radius of convergence is always equal to the distance from the center to the nearest point where the policy function has a (non-removable) singularity. If no such point exists then the radius of convergence is in…nite. Singularity here refers to poles, fractional powers, and other branch powers or discontinuities of the functional or its derivatives. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 33 / 91
  • 34. A Numerical Example Remarks Intuition of the theorem: holomorphic functions are analytic. Distance is in the complex plane. Often, we can check numerically that perturbations have good non local behavior. However: problem with boundaries. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 34 / 91
  • 35. A Numerical Example Non Local Accuracy Test Proposed by Judd (1992) and Judd and Guu (1997). Given the Euler equation: 1 αe zt +1 k i (kt , zt )α 1 i (k , z ) = Et c t t c i (k i (kt , zt ), zt +1 ) we can de…ne: αe zt +1 k i (kt , zt )α 1 EE i (kt , zt ) 1 c i (kt , zt ) Et c i (k i (kt , zt ), zt +1 ) Units of reporting. Interpretation. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 35 / 91
  • 36. A Numerical Example Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 36 / 91
  • 37. The General Case The General Case Most of previous argument can be easily generalized. The set of equilibrium conditions of many DSGE models can be written as (note recursive notation) Et H(y , y 0 , x, x 0 ) = 0, where yt is a ny 1 vector of controls and xt is a nx 1 vector of states. De…ne n = nx + ny . Then H maps R ny R ny R nx R nx into R n . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 37 / 91
  • 38. The General Case Partitioning the State Vector The state vector xt can be partitioned as x = [x1 ; x2 ]t . x1 is a (nx n ) 1 vector of endogenous state variables. x2 is a n 1 vector of exogenous state variables. Why do we want to partition the state vector? Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 38 / 91
  • 39. The General Case Exogenous Stochastic Process 0 x2 = Λx2 + ση 0 Process with 3 parts: 1 The deterministic component Λx2 : 1 Λ is a n n matrix, with all eigenvalues with modulus less than one. 2 More general: x2 = Γ(x2 ) + ση 0 , where Γ is a non-linear function 0 satisfying that all eigenvalues of its …rst derivative evaluated at the non-stochastic steady state lie within the unit circle. 2 The scaled innovation η 0 where: 1 η is a known n n matrix. 2 is a n 1 i.i.d innovation with bounded support, zero mean, and variance/covariance matrix I . 3 The perturbation parameter σ. We can accommodate very general structures of x2 through changes in the de…nition of the state space: i.e. stochastic volatility. Note we do not impose Gaussianity. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 39 / 91
  • 40. The General Case The Perturbation Parameter The scalar σ 0 is the perturbation parameter. If we set σ = 0 we have a deterministic model. Important: there is only ONE perturbation parameter. The matrix η takes account of relative sizes of di¤erent shocks. Why bounded support? Samuelson (1970) and Jin and Judd (2002). Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 40 / 91
  • 41. The General Case Solution of the Model The solution to the model is of the form: y = g (x; σ) 0 0 x = h(x; σ) + ση where g maps R nx R + into R ny and h maps R nx R + into R nx . The matrix η is of order nx n and is given by: ∅ η= η Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 41 / 91
  • 42. The General Case Perturbation We wish to …nd a perturbation approximation of the functions g and h around the non-stochastic steady state, xt = x and σ = 0. ¯ We de…ne the non-stochastic steady state as vectors (x, y ) such that: ¯ ¯ H(y , y , x, x ) = 0. ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯ Note that y = g (x; 0) and x = h(x; 0). This is because, if σ = 0, ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯ then Et H = H. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 42 / 91
  • 43. The General Case Plugging-in the Proposed Solution Substituting the proposed solution, we de…ne: F (x; σ) Et H(g (x; σ), g (h(x; σ) + ησ 0 , σ), x, h(x; σ) + ησ 0 ) = 0 Since F (x; σ) = 0 for any values of x and σ, the derivatives of any order of F must also be equal to zero. Formally: Fx k σj (x; σ) = 0 8x, σ, j, k, where Fx k σj (x, σ) denotes the derivative of F with respect to x taken k times and with respect to σ taken j times. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 43 / 91
  • 44. The General Case First-Order Approximation We look for approximations to g and h around (x, σ) = (x, 0): ¯ g (x; σ) = g (x; 0) + gx (x; 0)(x ¯ ¯ x ) + gσ (x; 0)σ ¯ ¯ h(x; σ) = h(x; 0) + hx (x; 0)(x ¯ ¯ x ) + hσ (x; 0)σ ¯ ¯ As explained earlier, g (x; 0) = y ¯ ¯ and h(x; 0) = x. ¯ ¯ The four unknown coe¢ cients of the …rst-order approximation to g and h are found by using: Fx (x; 0) = 0 ¯ and Fσ (x; 0) = 0 ¯ Before doing so, I need to introduce the tensor notation. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 44 / 91
  • 45. The General Case Tensors General trick from physics. An nth -rank tensor in a m-dimensional space is an operator that has n indices and mn components and obeys certain transformation rules. [Hy ]iα is the (i, α) element of the derivative of H with respect to y : 1 The derivative of H with respect to y is an n ny matrix. 2 Thus, [Hy ]iα is the element of this matrix located at the intersection of the i-th row and α-th column. n ∂ H i ∂g α ∂h β Thus, [Hy ]iα [gx ]α [hx ]j = ∑α=1 ∑nx 1 β y ∂y α ∂x β ∂x j . 3 β β= [Hy 0 y 0 ]iαγ : 1 Hy 0 y 0 is a three dimensional array with n rows, ny columns, and ny pages. 2 Then [Hy 0 y 0 ]iαγ denotes the element of Hy 0 y 0 located at the intersection of row i, column α and page γ. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 45 / 91
  • 46. The General Case Solving the System I gx and hx can be found as the solution to the system: [Fx (x; 0)]ij = [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hx ]j + [Hy ]iα [gx ]jα + [Hx 0 ]iβ [hx ]j + [Hx ]ij = β β ¯ β i = 1, . . . , n; j, β = 1, . . . , nx ; α = 1, . . . , ny Note that the derivatives of H evaluated at (y , y 0 , x, x 0 ) = (y , y , x, x ) ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯ are known. Then, we have a system of n nx quadratic equations in the n nx unknowns given by the elements of gx and hx . We can solve with a standard quadratic matrix equation solver. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 46 / 91
  • 47. The General Case Solving the System II gσ and hσ are identi…ed as the solution to the following n equations: [Fσ (x; 0)]i = ¯ Et f[Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hσ ] β + [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [η ]φ [ 0 ]φ + [Hy 0 ]iα [gσ ]α β β β +[Hy ]iα [gσ ]α + [Hx 0 ]iβ [hσ ] β + [Hx 0 ]iβ [η ]φ [ 0 ]φ g β i = 1, . . . , n; α = 1, . . . , ny ; β = 1, . . . , nx ; φ = 1, . . . , n . Then: [Fσ (x; 0)]i = [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hσ ] β + [Hy 0 ]iα [gσ ]α + [Hy ]iα [gσ ]α + [fx 0 ]iβ [hσ ] β = 0; ¯ β i = 1, . . . , n; α = 1, . . . , ny ; β = 1, . . . , nx ; φ = 1, . . . , n . Certainty equivalence: this equation is linear and homogeneous in gσ and hσ . Thus, if a unique solution exists, it must satisfy: hσ 6 = 0 gσ = 0 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 47 / 91
  • 48. The General Case Second-Order Approximation I The second-order approximations to g around (x; σ) = (x; 0) is ¯ [g (x; σ)]i = [g (x; 0)]i + [gx (x; 0)]ia [(x x )]a + [gσ (x; 0)]i [σ] ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯ 1 + [gxx (x; 0)]iab [(x x )]a [(x x )]b ¯ ¯ ¯ 2 1 + [gx σ (x; 0)]ia [(x x )]a [σ] ¯ ¯ 2 1 + [gσx (x; 0)]ia [(x x )]a [σ] ¯ ¯ 2 1 + [gσσ (x; 0)]i [σ][σ] ¯ 2 where i = 1, . . . , ny , a, b = 1, . . . , nx , and j = 1, . . . , nx . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 48 / 91
  • 49. The General Case Second-Order Approximation II The second-order approximations to h around (x; σ) = (x; 0) is ¯ [h(x; σ)]j = [h(x; 0)]j + [hx (x; 0)]ja [(x x )]a + [hσ (x; 0)]j [σ] ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯ 1 + [hxx (x; 0)]jab [(x x )]a [(x x )]b ¯ ¯ ¯ 2 1 + [hx σ (x; 0)]ja [(x x )]a [σ] ¯ ¯ 2 1 + [hσx (x; 0)]ja [(x x )]a [σ] ¯ ¯ 2 1 + [hσσ (x; 0)]j [σ][σ], ¯ 2 where i = 1, . . . , ny , a, b = 1, . . . , nx , and j = 1, . . . , nx . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 49 / 91
  • 50. The General Case Second-Order Approximation III The unknowns of these expansions are [gxx ]iab , [gx σ ]ia , [gσx ]ia , [gσσ ]i , [hxx ]jab , [hx σ ]ja , [hσx ]ja , [hσσ ]j . These coe¢ cients can be identi…ed by taking the derivative of F (x; σ) with respect to x and σ twice and evaluating them at (x; σ) = (x; 0). ¯ By the arguments provided earlier, these derivatives must be zero. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 50 / 91
  • 51. The General Case Solving the System I We use Fxx (x; 0) to identify gxx (x; 0) and hxx (x; 0): ¯ ¯ ¯ [Fxx (x; 0)]ijk = ¯ [Hy 0 y 0 ]iαγ [gx ]γ [hx ]k + [Hy 0 y ]iαγ [gx ]k + [Hy 0 x 0 ]iαδ [hx ]k + [Hy 0 x ]iαk [gx ]α [hx ]j δ γ δ β δ β +[Hy 0 ]iα [gxx ]α [hx ]k [hx ]j + [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hxx ]jk δ β β βδ β + [Hyy 0 ]iαγ [gx ]γ [hx ]k + [Hyy ]iαγ [gx ]k + [Hyx 0 ]iαδ [hx ]k + [Hyx ]iαk [gx ]jα δ δ γ δ +[Hy ]iα [gxx ]jk α + [Hx 0 y 0 ]iβγ [gx ]γ [hx ]k + [Hx 0 y ]iβγ [gx ]k + [Hx 0 x 0 ]iβδ [hx ]k + [Hx 0 x ]iβk [hx ]j δ γ δ β δ +[Hx 0 ]iβ [hxx ]jk β +[Hxy 0 ]ij γ [gx ]γ [hx ]k + [Hxy ]ij γ [gx ]k + [Hxx 0 ]ij δ [hx ]k + [Hxx ]ijk = 0; δ δ γ δ i = 1, . . . n, j, k, β, δ = 1, . . . nx ; α, γ = 1, . . . ny . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 51 / 91
  • 52. The General Case Solving the System II We know the derivatives of H. We also know the …rst derivatives of g and h evaluated at (y , y 0 , x, x 0 ) = (y , y , x, x ). ¯ ¯ ¯ ¯ Hence, the above expression represents a system of n nx nx linear equations in then n nx nx unknowns elements of gxx and hxx . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 52 / 91
  • 53. The General Case Solving the System III Similarly, gσσ and hσσ can be obtained by solving: [Fσσ (x; 0)]i ¯ = [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hσσ ] β β +[Hy 0 y 0 ]iαγ [gx ]γ [η ]δ [gx ]α [η ]φ [I ]ξ β φ δ ξ β +[Hy 0 x 0 ]iαδ [η ]δ [gx ]α [η ]φ [I ]ξ β φ ξ β +[Hy 0 ]iα [gxx ]α [η ]δ [η ]φ [I ]ξ + [Hy 0 ]iα [gσσ ]α β φ βδ ξ +[Hy ]iα [gσσ ]α + [Hx 0 ]iβ [hσσ ] β +[Hx 0 y 0 ]iβγ [gx ]γ [η ]δ [η ]φ [I ]ξ β φ δ ξ +[Hx 0 x 0 ]iβδ [η ]δ [η ]φ [I ]ξ = 0; β φ ξ i = 1, . . . , n; α, γ = 1, . . . , ny ; β, δ = 1, . . . , nx ; φ, ξ = 1, . . . , n a system of n linear equations in the n unknowns given by the elements of gσσ and hσσ . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 53 / 91
  • 54. The General Case Cross Derivatives The cross derivatives gx σ and hx σ are zero when evaluated at (x, 0). ¯ Why? Write the system Fσx (x; 0) = 0 taking into account that all ¯ terms containing either gσ or hσ are zero at (x, 0). ¯ Then: [Fσx (x; 0)]ij = [Hy 0 ]iα [gx ]α [hσx ]j + [Hy 0 ]iα [gσx ]α [hx ]jγ + β ¯ β γ [Hy ]iα [gσx ]jα + [Hx 0 ]iβ [hσx ]j = 0; β i = 1, . . . n; α = 1, . . . , ny ; β, γ, j = 1, . . . , nx . a system of n nx equations in the n nx unknowns given by the elements of gσx and hσx . The system is homogeneous in the unknowns. Thus, if a unique solution exists, it is given by: gσx = 0 hσx = 0 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 54 / 91
  • 55. The General Case Structure of the Solution The perturbation solution of the model satis…es: gσ (x; 0) = 0 ¯ hσ (x; 0) = 0 ¯ gx σ (x; 0) = 0 ¯ hx σ (x; 0) = 0 ¯ Standard deviation only appears in: 1 A constant term given by 1 gσσ σ2 for the control vector yt . 2 2 The …rst nx 1 n elements of 2 hσσ σ2 . Correction for risk. Quadratic terms in endogenous state vector x1 . Those terms capture non-linear behavior. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 55 / 91
  • 56. The General Case Higher-Order Approximations We can iterate this procedure as many times as we want. We can obtain n-th order approximations. Problems: 1 Existence of higher order derivatives (Santos, 1992). 2 Numerical instabilities. 3 Computational costs. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 56 / 91
  • 57. Change of Variables Erik Eady It is not the process of linearization that limits insight. It is the nature of the state that we choose to linearize about. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 57 / 91
  • 58. Change of Variables Change of Variables We approximated our solution in levels. We could have done it in logs. Why stop there? Why not in powers of the state variables? Judd (2002) has provided methods for changes of variables. We apply and extend ideas to the stochastic neoclassical growth model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 58 / 91
  • 59. Change of Variables A General Transformation We look at solutions of the form: µ ζ cµ c0 = a kζ k0 + bz k 0γ γ ζ k0 = c kζ k0 + dz Note that: 1 If γ, ζ, and µ are 1, we get the linear representation. 2 As γ, ζ and µ tend to zero, we get the loglinear approximation. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 59 / 91
  • 60. Change of Variables Theory The …rst-order solution can be written as f (x ) ' f (a ) + (x a ) f 0 (a ) Expand g (y ) = h (f (X (y ))) around b = Y (a), where X (y ) is the inverse of Y (x ). Then: g (y ) = h (f (X (y ))) = g (b ) + gα (b ) (Y α (x ) bα ) where gα = hA fi A Xα comes from the application of the chain rule. i From this expression it is easy to see that if we have computed the values of fi A , then it is straightforward to …nd gα . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 60 / 91
  • 61. Change of Variables Coe¢ cients Relation Remember that the linear solution is: k0 k0 = a1 ( k k0 ) + b1 z (l l0 ) = c1 (k k0 ) + d1 z Then we show that: γ ζ γ 1 a3 = γ k0 ζ a1 b3 = γk0 b1 µ µ 1 1 ζ µ 1 c3 = ζ l0 k0 c1 d3 = µl0 d1 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 61 / 91
  • 62. Change of Variables Finding the Parameters Minimize over a grid the Euler Error. Some optimal results Euler Equation Errors γ ζ µ SEE 1 1 1 0.0856279 0.986534 0.991673 2.47856 0.0279944 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 62 / 91
  • 63. Change of Variables Sensitivity Analysis Di¤erent parameter values. Most interesting …nding is when we change σ: Optimal Parameters for di¤erent σ’s σ γ ζ µ 0.014 0.98140 0.98766 2.47753 0.028 1.04804 1.05265 1.73209 0.056 1.23753 1.22394 0.77869 A …rst-order approximation corrects for changes in variance! Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 63 / 91
  • 64. Change of Variables Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 64 / 91
  • 65. Change of Variables A Quasi-Optimal Approximation Sensitivity analysis reveals that for di¤erent parametrizations γ'ζ This suggests the quasi-optimal approximation: k 0γ γ γ k0 = a3 k γ k0 + b3 z µ γ lµ l0 = c3 k γ k0 + d3 z b If we de…ne k = k γ k0 and b = l µ γ l µ l0 we get: b b k 0 = a3 k + b3 z b = c3 k + d3 z l b Linear system: 1 Use for analytical study. 2 Use for estimation with a Kalman Filter. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 65 / 91
  • 66. Perturbing the Value Function Perturbing the Value Function We worked with the equilibrium conditions of the model. Sometimes we may want to perform a perturbation on the value function formulation of the problem. Possible reasons: 1 Gain insight. 2 Di¢ culty in using equilibrium conditions. 3 Evaluate welfare. 4 Initial guess for VFI. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 66 / 91
  • 67. Perturbing the Value Function Basic Problem Imagine that we have: " # 1 γ c V (kt , zt ) = max (1 β) t + βEt V (kt +1 , zt +1 ) ct 1 γ s.t. ct + kt +1 = e zt ktθ + (1 δ) kt zt = λzt 1 + σεt , εt N (0, 1) Write it as: " # 1 γ c V (kt , zt ; χ) = max (1 β) t + βEt V (kt +1 , zt +1 ; χ) ct 1 γ s.t. ct + kt +1 = e zt ktθ + (1 δ) kt zt = λzt 1 + χσεt , εt N (0, 1) Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 67 / 91
  • 68. Perturbing the Value Function Alternative Another way to write the value function is: V (kt , zt ; χ) = " 1 γ # max (1 β ) c t γ + 1 ct βEt V e zt ktθ + (1 δ) kt ct , λzt + χσεt +1 ; χ This form makes the dependences in the next period states explicit. The solution of this problem is value function V (kt , zt ; χ) and a policy function for consumption c (kt , zt ; χ). Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 68 / 91
  • 69. Perturbing the Value Function Expanding the Value Function The second-order Taylor approximation of the value function around the deterministic steady state (kss , 0; 0) is: V (kt , zt ; χ) ' Vss + V1,ss (kt kss ) + V2,ss zt + V3,ss χ 1 1 1 + V11,ss (kt kss )2 + V12,ss (kt kss ) zt + V13,ss (kt kss ) χ 2 2 2 1 1 1 + V21,ss zt (kt kss ) + V22,ss zt2 + V23,ss zt χ 2 2 2 1 1 1 + V31,ss χ (kt kss ) + V32,ss χzt + V33,ss χ2 2 2 2 where Vss = V (kss , 0; 0) Vi ,ss = Vi (kss , 0; 0) for i = f1, 2, 3g Vij ,ss = Vij (kss , 0; 0) for i, j = f1, 2, 3g Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 69 / 91
  • 70. Perturbing the Value Function Expanding the Value Function By certainty equivalence, we will show below that: V3,ss = V13,ss = V23,ss = 0 Taking advantage of the equality of cross-derivatives, and setting χ = 1, which is just a normalization: V (kt , zt ; 1) ' Vss + V1,ss (kt kss ) + V2,ss zt 1 1 + V11,ss (kt kss )2 + V22,ss ztt 2 2 2 1 +V12,ss (kt kss ) z + V33,ss 2 Note that V33,ss 6= 0, a di¤erence from the standard linear-quadratic approximation to the utility functions. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 70 / 91
  • 71. Perturbing the Value Function Expanding the Consumption Function The policy function for consumption can be expanded as: ct = c (kt , zt ; χ) ' css + c1,ss (kt kss ) + c2,ss zt + c3,ss χ where: c1,ss = c1 (kss , 0; 0) c2,ss = c2 (kss , 0; 0) c3,ss = c3 (kss , 0; 0) Since the …rst derivatives of the consumption function only depend on the …rst and second derivatives of the value function, we must have c3,ss = 0 (precautionary consumption depends on the third derivative of the value function, Kimball, 1990). Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 71 / 91
  • 72. Perturbing the Value Function Linear Components of the Value Function To …nd the linear approximation to the value function, we take derivatives of the value function with respect to controls (ct ), states (kt , zt ), and the perturbation parameter χ. Notation: 1 Vi ,t : derivative of the value function with respect to its i-th argument, evaluated in (kt , zt ; χ) . 2 Vi ,ss : derivative evaluated in the steady state, (kss , 0; 0). 3 We follow the same notation for higher-order (cross-) derivatives. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 72 / 91
  • 73. Perturbing the Value Function Derivatives Derivative with respect to ct : γ (1 β ) ct βEt V1,t +1 = 0 Derivative with respect to kt : V1,t = βEt V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ 1 +1 δ Derivative with respect to zt : h i V2,t = βEt V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V2,t +1 λ Derivative with respect to χ: V3,t = βEt [V2,t +1 σεt +1 + V3,t +1 ] In the last three derivatives, we apply the envelope theorem to eliminate the derivatives of consumption with respect to kt , zt , and χ. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 73 / 91
  • 74. Perturbing the Value Function System of Equations I Now, we have the system: ct + kt +1 = e zt ktθ + (1 δ) kt 1 γ ct V (kt , zt ; χ) = (1 β) + βEt V (kt +1 , zt +1 ; χ) 1 γ γ (1 β ) ct βEt V1,t +1 = 0 V1,t = βEt V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ h i V2,t = βEt V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V2,t +1 λ V3,t = βEt [V2,t +1 σεt +1 + V3,t +1 ] zt = λzt 1 + χσεt Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 74 / 91
  • 75. Perturbing the Value Function System of Equations II If we set χ = 0 and compute the steady state, we get a system of six equations on six unknowns, css , kss , Vss , V1,ss , V2,ss , and V3,ss : θ css + δkss = kss 1 γ css Vss = (1 β) + βVss 1 γ (1 β) css γ βV1,ss = 0 V1,ss = βV1,ss θkss 1 + 1 δ θ h i θ V2,ss = β V1,ss kss + V2,ss λ V3,ss = βV3,ss From the last equation: V3,ss = 0. 1 γ From the second equation: Vss = css γ . 1 1 β γ From the third equation: V1,ss = β css . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 75 / 91
  • 76. Perturbing the Value Function System of Equations III After cancelling redundant terms: θ css + δkss = kss 1 = β θkss 1 + 1 δ θ h i θ V2,ss = β V1,ss kss + V2,ss λ Then: 1 1 1 θ 1 kss = 1+δ θ β θ css = kss δkss 1 β θ γ V2,ss = k c 1 βλ ss ss V1,ss > 0 and V2,ss > 0, as predicted by theory. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 76 / 91
  • 77. Perturbing the Value Function Quadratic Components of the Value Function From the previous derivations, we have: γ (1 β) c (kt , zt ; χ) βEt V1,t +1 = 0 V1,t = βEt V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ h i V2,t = βEt V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V2,t +1 λ V3,t = βEt [V2,t +1 σεt +1 + V3,t +1 ] where: kt +1 = e zt ktθ + (1 δ) kt c (kt , zt ; χ) zt = λzt 1 + χσεt , εt N (0, 1) We take derivatives of each of the four equations w.t.r. kt , zt , and χ. We take advantage of the equality of cross derivatives. The envelope theorem does not hold anymore (we are taking derivatives of the derivatives of the value function). Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 77 / 91
  • 78. Perturbing the Value Function First Equation I We have: γ (1 β) c (kt , zt ; χ) βEt V1,t +1 = 0 Derivative with respect to kt : γ 1 (1 β) γc (kt , zt ; χ) c1,t h i βEt V11,t +1 e zt θktθ 1 +1 δ c1,t =0 In steady state: h i 1 1 βV11,ss (1 β) γcss γ θ c1,ss = β V11,ss θkss +1 δ or V11,ss c1,ss = γ 1 βV11,ss (1 β) γcss where we have used that 1 = β θkss θ 1 +1 δ . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 78 / 91
  • 79. Perturbing the Value Function First Equation II Derivative with respect to zt : γ 1 (1 β) γc (kt , zt ; χ) c2,t βEt V11,t +1 e zt ktθ c2,t + V12,t +1 λ = 0 In steady state: 1 βV11,ss (1 β) γcss γ c2,ss = β V11,ss ktθ + V12,ss λ or β θ c2,ss = γ 1 V11,ss kss + V12,ss λ βV11,ss (1 β) γcss Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 79 / 91
  • 80. Perturbing the Value Function First Equation III Derivative with respect to χ: γ 1 (1 β) γc (kt , zt ; χ) c3,t βEt ( V11,t +1 c3,t + V12,t +1 σεt +1 + V13,t +1 ) = 0 In steady state: 1 βV11,ss (1 β) γcss γ c3,ss = βV13,ss or β c3,ss = V13,ss γ 1 βV11,ss (1 β) γcss Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 80 / 91
  • 81. Perturbing the Value Function Second Equation I We have: V1,t = βEt V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ 1 +1 δ Derivative with respect to kt : " # V11,t +1 θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ c1,t θe zt ktθ 1 +1 δ V11,t = βEt 2 +V1,t +1 θ (θ 1) e zt ktθ In steady state: 1 θ 2 V11,ss = V11,ss c1,ss + βV1,ss θ (θ 1) kss β or β θ 2 V11,ss = 1 V1,ss θ (θ 1) kss 1 β + c1,ss Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 81 / 91
  • 82. Perturbing the Value Function Second Equation II Derivative with respect to zt : 2 3 V11,t +1 e zt ktθ c2,t θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ V12,t = βEt 4 5 +V12,t +1 λ θe zt ktθ 1 + 1 δ + V1,t +1 θe zt ktθ 1 In steady state: θ 1 V12,ss = V11,ss kss c2,ss + V12,ss λ + βV1,ss θktθ or h i 1 θ θ 1 V12,ss = V11,ss kss c2,ss + βV1,ss θkss 1 λ Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 82 / 91
  • 83. Perturbing the Value Function Second Equation III Derivative with respect to χ: V13,t = βEt [ V11,t +1 c3,t + V12,t +1 σεt +1 + V13,t +1 ] In steady state, V13,ss = β [ V11,ss c3,ss + V13,ss ] ) β V13,ss = V11,ss c3,ss β 1 but since we know that: β c3,ss = V13,ss γ 1 βV11,ss (1 β) γcss the two equations can only hold simultaneously if V13,ss = c3,ss = 0. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 83 / 91
  • 84. Perturbing the Value Function Third Equation I We have h i V2,t = βEt V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V2,t +1 λ Derivative with respect to zt : V11,t +1 e zt ktθ c2,t e zt ktθ + V12,t +1 λe zt ktθ V22,t = βEt +V1,t +1 e zt ktθ + V21,t +1 λ e zt ktθ c2,t + V22,t +1 λ2 In steady state: V11,ss ktθ c2,ss kss + V12,ss λkss + V1,ss kss θ θ θ V22,t = β ) +V21,ss λ kss c2,ss + V22,ss λ2 θ β V11,ss ktθ c2,ss kss + 2V12,ss λkss θ θ V22,ss = 1 βλ2 +V1,ss kss V12,ss λc2,ss θ where we have used V12,ss = V21,ss . Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 84 / 91
  • 85. Perturbing the Value Function Third Equation II Derivative with respect to χ: V11,t +1 e zt ktθ c3,t + V12,t +1 e zt ktθ σεt +1 + V13,t +1 e zt ktθ V23,t = βEt V21,t +1 λc3,t + V22,t +1 λσεt +1 + V23,t +1 λ In steady state: V23,ss = 0 Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 85 / 91
  • 86. Perturbing the Value Function Fourth Equation We have V3,t = βEt [V2,t +1 σεt +1 + V3,t +1 ] . Derivative with respect to χ: V21,t +1 c3,t σεt +1 + V22,t +1 σ2 ε2+1 + V23,t +1 σεt +1 t V33,t = βEt V31,t +1 c3,t + V32,t +1 σεt +1 + V33,t +1 In steady state: β V33,ss = V22,ss 1 β Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 86 / 91
  • 87. Perturbing the Value Function System I V11,ss c1,ss = γ 1 βV11,ss (1 β) γcss β θ c2,ss = γ 1 V11,ss kss + V12,ss λ βV11,ss (1 β) γcss β V11,ss = 1 1) kss 2 θ V1,ss θ (θ 1 β + c1,ss 1 h i V12,ss = V11,ss kss c2,ss + βV1,ss θkss 1 θ θ 1 λ β V11,ss ktθ c2,ss kss + 2V12,ss λkss θ θ V22,ss = 1 βλ2 +V1,ss kss V12,ss λc2,ss θ β V33,ss = σ2 V22,ss 1 β plus c3,ss = V13,ss = V23,ss = 0. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 87 / 91
  • 88. Perturbing the Value Function System II This is a system of nonlinear equations. However, it has a recursive structure. By substituting variables that we already know, we can …nd V11,ss . Then, using this results and by plugging c2,ss , we have a system of two equations, on two unknowns, V12,ss and V22,ss . Once the system is solved, we can …nd c1,ss , c2,ss , and V33,ss directly. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 88 / 91
  • 89. Perturbing the Value Function The Welfare Cost of the Business Cycle An advantage of performing the perturbation on the value function is that we have evaluation of welfare readily available. Note that at the deterministic steady state, we have: 1 V (kss , 0; χ) ' Vss + V33,ss 2 Hence 1 V33,ss is a measure of the welfare cost of the business cycle. 2 This quantity is not necessarily negative: it may be positive. For example, in an RBC with leisure choice (Cho and Cooley, 2000). Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 89 / 91
  • 90. Perturbing the Value Function Our Example 1 γ css We know that Vss = 1 γ. We can compute the decrease in consumption τ that will make the household indi¤erent between consuming (1 τ ) css units per period with certainty or ct units with uncertainty. Thus: 1 γ css 1 (css (1 τ ))1 γ + V33,ss = ) 1 γ 2 1 γ 1 (1 τ )1 γ 1 1 css γ = (1 γ) V33,ss 2 or 1 1 γ1 1 γ τ=1 1+ 1 V γ 2 33,ss css Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 90 / 91
  • 91. Perturbing the Value Function A Numerical Example We pick standard parameter values by setting β = 0.99, γ = 2, δ = 0.0294, θ = 0.3, and λ = 0.95. We get: V (kt , zt ; 1) ' 0.54000 + 0.00295 (kt kss ) + 0.11684zt 2 0.00007 (kt kss ) 0.00985zt2 0.97508σ2 0.00225 (kt kss ) zt c (kt , zt ; χ) ' 1.85193 + 0.04220 (kt kss ) + 0.74318zt DYNARE produces the same policy function by linearizing the equilibrium conditions of the problem. The welfare cost of the business cycle (in consumption terms) is 8.8475e-005, lower than in Lucas (1987) because of the smoothing possibilities allowed by capital. Use as an initial guess for VFI. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde (PENN) Perturbation Methods July 10, 2011 91 / 91