SlideShare a Scribd company logo
Remarks on Local Volatility.




Ilya Gikhman
6077 Ivy Woods Ct
Mason OH 45040
Ph. (513)-573-9348
Email: iljogik@yahoo.com


Abstract.

In this short notice some comments on local volatility are provided.



        The Black–Scholes (BS) model of the options pricing has advised a ‘fair’ price
that interpreted as the PV of the ‘neutralized’ pay off value at maturity. In BS equation
(BSE) the real stock return µ is replaced by the risk-free rate of return r. These
parameters are assumed to be constants though the setting admits that µ, r, and volatility
σ could be known deterministic functions on time t.
        If the market option prices are given one could calculate volatility of the
underlying. This calculation leads to a notion known as implied volatility. If the model
and calculation are perfect, this implied volatility value would be the same for the options
with different strike prices and maturities. In reality the calculations show that this is not
the case.
Implied Black–Scholes volatilities highlight a strong dependence on maturity T and the
strike price K. The dependence of the implied volatility on K and T is known as “smile”
effect. The way how to solve the smile problem was presented in [1-3]. We briefly recall
following [1] the main steps of this derivation.
        The risk- neutral stock price in the BS model is assumed to be written in the form

                             d Sr ( t )
                                        = r ( t ) dt + σ ( t ) dw ( t )                    (*)
                              Sr ( t )

Here w ( t ) is Wiener process on original probability space { Ω , F , P }. Denote
C ( T , K ) the BS European call option price at the date t given
S r ( t ) = x. Parameters T and K are maturity date and strike price correspondingly. In
order to develop a solution of the smile problem it was assumed that




                                                                                            1

                 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1270153
d Sr ( t )
                                      = r ( t ) dt + σ ( t , S r ( t )) dw ( t )
                            Sr ( t )
Let φ T ( x ) denote the probability density of the solution of the equation (1). We put for
simplicity r = 0. Then

                               d Sr ( t )
                                          = σ ( t , S r ( t )) dw ( t )                   (1)
                                Sr ( t )

Then

                            C ( T , K ) = ∫ ( x - K ) + φ T ( x ) dx                      (2)

Twice differentiation in (2) respect to K leads to the equality

                                            ∂ 2 C( T , K )
                            φT(K) =                                                       (3)
                                                ∂K 2

We pay attention only to martingale diffusions x ( t )

                               d x = b( x, t ) d W                                        (4)

Here diffusion coefficient b ( t , x ) ≥ δ 2 > 0 is unknown function. The Fokker-Planck
( Kolmogorov’s first ) equation for the density f ( t , x ) is

                              ∂2             ∂f
                                 2
                                   (b2 f ) =                                              (5)
                              ∂x             ∂t
         ∂2C
As f =       we obtain, after changing the order of derivatives:
         ∂x2

                            ∂2             ∂ 2 ∂C
                                (b2 f ) =
                           ∂ x2           ∂ x2 ∂ t

                       ∂C
Assuming that lim         = 0 and integrating twice in x leads to the equation
                x→+∞   ∂t

                            1 2 ∂2C    ∂C
                              b    2
                                     =                                                    (6)
                            2   ∂x     ∂t

Solving this equation for b we have




                                                                                               2

                Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1270153
∂ C ( x,t )
                                              2
                                                    ∂t
                              b ( x,t ) =       2
                                                                                            (7)
                                               ∂ C ( x,t )
                                                  ∂ x2

Compare (1) and (4) we see that

                             xσ(x,t) = b(x,t)                                               (8)

Reminding that ( x , t ) is actually ( K , T ) we rewrite (5) as

                                      1 2 ∂2C    ∂C
                                        b    2
                                               =                                            (9)
                                      2   ∂K     ∂T

This equation has the same ‘flavor’ as the classical BSE but distinct from it by
independent variables involved.

Comments.

        I. First we remind that the underlying density is a function of the several
variables. That is φ T ( x ) = φ ( t , y ; T , x ) where the variables y, x ∈ ( 0 , + ∞ ) are
associated with the coordinate points for security price S (*) at dates t and T . The BS’s
call option price is introduced above and is also the multivariable function C ( T , K ) =
= C ( t , y ; T , K ). The equality (3) we present in the form

                                                   ∂ 2 C ( t , y ;T , K )
                          φ(t,y;T,K) =
                                                           ∂K 2

Here in the left hand side of the density φ its value is calculated at the point in which the
pricing variable x = K though variables x > 0 and K> 0 have different meaning.
        The Fokker-Planck equation for the x-diffusion defined in (4) we rewrite in
following form

                    ∂2                                          ∂ f ( t , y; T , x )
                       2
                         [ b 2 ( T , x ) f ( t , y ; T , x )] =                            (5′)
                    ∂x                                                   ∂t

If we wish to apply in (5′) the substitution

                                                  ∂ 2 C( t , y;T, K )
                           f(t,y;T,K) =                                                   (10)
                                                        ∂K 2




                                                                                                3

                 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1270153
in which parameter K is considered as a parameter taking values from ( 0 , + ∞ ) we need
to exchange the independent variable x on K that is the strike price coordinate. This
transformation leads us to equality

    ∂2               ∂ 2 C( t , y; T , K )    ∂    ∂ 2 C( t , y; T , K )
        [ b2(T , K )                       ]=    [                       ]                (5′′)
   ∂ x2                      ∂K 2             ∂t           ∂K 2

This equation shows that the substitution (10) does not replace x-diffusion by K-diffusion
having the same finite distributions as it was done above. From general point of view it is
difficult to expect that one could translate the diffusion (1) taking place in the ( x, t )-
coordinate space into ( K, T )-diffusion implied by (9) with the help of (2).
On the other hand if we define the ( K, T )-diffusion implied by (9) explicitly then there
is no path wise connection this diffusion with ( x, t )-diffusion.
                        ∂2C
The substitution f =           in (5) is correct only if f = φ T and the second derivatives in
                         ∂x2
x here is actually the second derivatives in K.
         II. The assumption (1) could not be applied to the stock market. Indeed, in this
case equation (1) is nonlinear and rate of return on 1, 2 or more stocks does not equal.
Indeed sum of two equations (1) does not lead to the same type of equation with doubled
initial condition. That means if an investor hold 2 the same stocks and one stock bring a
dollar profit over a day then 2 stocks do not bring 2 dollars. The linearity of the stock
prices is an axiom of the stock market and could not be violated at least in standard
situations.

Very Last remark. It also might be make sense to highlight BS pricing approach itself.
The BS pricing is a theoretical approach that using mathematics attempts to construct a
logical concept of the option price. If we logically assume that a stock has an expected
return µ and volatility σ then BS price for a particular initial stock value x for given K
and T will be the same regardless of µ. Thus for the same BS-premium one can get at
maturity the right to buy a junk or a good stocks. This interpretation of the notion ‘price’
applied for the option contradicts the common sense.
Note that another definition introduced in [4] does not present such confusion.

Here we add a new remark to Local Volatility Concept.
The solution C ( T , K ) = C ( t , x ; T , K ) , T > t of the problem (9) and satisfies
initial condition

                   C ( t , y ; t , K ) = max ( y – K , 0 )                                (11)

Thus, C ( t , x ; T , K ) is a solution of the Cauchy problem (9), (11) and it has “ the same
‘flavor’ as the classical Black–Scholes Equation. One distinction of the ( T , K )-Cauchy
problem from its ( t , x ) counterpart is that the independent variables are different. We
can change the direction of time by introducing new time variable. Denote fixed initial




                                                                                               4
moment as t = t 0 and let T ∈ [ t 0 , T* ]. Introduce new variable t = T* – T + t 0 .
                      ∂         ∂
Bearing in mind that       = −      the equation (9) can be rewritten as
                     ∂T        ∂t

                        ~               ~
                       ∂C   1 2       ∂2C
                          +   b (t,K)      =               0                                 (9′)
                       ∂t   2         ∂K 2

       ~              ~
Here C ( t , K ) = C ( T* , y ; t , K ) = C ( t – T* + T , y ; T* – t + t 0 , K ). The
initial condition (11) given at t = t 0 corresponds to the terminal condition at t = T*
for the solution (9′)
                 ~
                 C ( T* , y ; T* , K ) = max ( y – K , 0 )                                  (11′)

Cauchy problem (9′) , (11′) is similar to classical Black–Scholes Equation and the only
difference is the diffusion coefficient in (9′).
        Recall that the risk neutral stock price in the BS model is assumed to be written in
the form

                       dS r ( t )
                                  = r(t)dt + σ(t)dw(t)                                        (*)
                       S r (t)

where w ( t ) is a Wiener process on original probability space { , F , P }. In smile
problem we arrive at the equation (1) and let us replace the variable K by S. Recall that
equations (*) and (1) are interpreted in the integral form and they have the same initial
value S ( t 0 ) = x. Assume that initial value of In formula (4) it was used a Wiener
process W ( t ) that can be differed from the Wiener process w ( t ) used in (*). Note that
as far as we deal with strong solutions, i.e. the coefficients of the SDEs are assumed to be
Lipchitz continuous functions the Wiener process in (1) , (4) could be chosen the same.
For technical simplicity we put r = 0.
Statement 1. Equalities (*) and (1) take place when and only when if
σ ( t ) = b ( t , S ( t )) and therefore σ ( t , S ( t )) actually does not a random function and
it is independ on S.
Indeed, subtraction (1) from (1) leads to the equality
t

∫
0
    [ σ ( t ) – b ( t , S ( t )) ] S ( t ) d w ( t ) = 0

Raising into second power and taking expectation leads us to equality
t

∫
0
    E [ σ ( t ) – b ( t , S ( t )) ] 2 S 2 ( t ) d t = 0

Bearing in mind that S 2 ( t ) > 0 it follows that b ( t , S ( t )) = σ ( t ), where σ ( t ) is
a nonrandom function . The case r ≠ 0 can be studied analogously.
Hence, the smile underlying which corresponds to the (9′), (11′) either equal to the
original security (*) or is a different unobservable diffusion process.


                                                                                               5
References.


1. Dupire, B., “Pricing and Hedging with Smiles” , Research paper, 1993, p.9.
2. Dupire, B., “Pricing with a Smile”. Risk Magazine, 7, 1994, p.8-20.
3. Derman, E., and Kani,I., Riding on a smile, Risk, 7 (1994), p.32—33.
4. Gikhman, I., 2003, On Black-Scholes Equation ICFAI J.of Applied Finance, v.10,
   No.4, April 2004, p.47-74 ( http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=500303).




                                                                                             6

More Related Content

PDF
Supplement to local voatility
PPT
Analysis Of Algorithms Ii
ZIP
Desktop
PDF
The Probability that a Matrix of Integers Is Diagonalizable
DOC
Chapter 4 (maths 3)
PDF
Coincidence points for mappings under generalized contraction
PDF
[Vvedensky d.] group_theory,_problems_and_solution(book_fi.org)
PDF
Instantons and Chern-Simons Terms in AdS4/CFT3
Supplement to local voatility
Analysis Of Algorithms Ii
Desktop
The Probability that a Matrix of Integers Is Diagonalizable
Chapter 4 (maths 3)
Coincidence points for mappings under generalized contraction
[Vvedensky d.] group_theory,_problems_and_solution(book_fi.org)
Instantons and Chern-Simons Terms in AdS4/CFT3

What's hot (20)

PDF
Asymptotic Growth of Functions
PDF
Perspectives on the wild McKay correspondence
DOC
Chapter 5 (maths 3)
PDF
The wild McKay correspondence
PDF
Moment Closure Based Parameter Inference of Stochastic Kinetic Models
PDF
Prime numbers boundary
PDF
Thesis 6
PDF
SOME THOUGHTS ON DIVERGENT SERIES
PDF
Timoteo carletti stefano marmi
DOC
some thoughts on divergent series
PDF
Computing F-blowups
PDF
Northcott1957 (1)
PDF
A Note on Latent LSTM Allocation
PDF
Equivariance
PDF
Generalization of Tensor Factorization and Applications
PDF
A common fixed point of integral type contraction in generalized metric spacess
PDF
tensor-decomposition
PDF
11.0001www.iiste.org call for paper.differential approach to cardioid distrib...
PDF
1.differential approach to cardioid distribution -1-6
PDF
Imc2017 day2-solutions
Asymptotic Growth of Functions
Perspectives on the wild McKay correspondence
Chapter 5 (maths 3)
The wild McKay correspondence
Moment Closure Based Parameter Inference of Stochastic Kinetic Models
Prime numbers boundary
Thesis 6
SOME THOUGHTS ON DIVERGENT SERIES
Timoteo carletti stefano marmi
some thoughts on divergent series
Computing F-blowups
Northcott1957 (1)
A Note on Latent LSTM Allocation
Equivariance
Generalization of Tensor Factorization and Applications
A common fixed point of integral type contraction in generalized metric spacess
tensor-decomposition
11.0001www.iiste.org call for paper.differential approach to cardioid distrib...
1.differential approach to cardioid distribution -1-6
Imc2017 day2-solutions
Ad

Viewers also liked (9)

PDF
American option
PDF
Black Scholes pricing consept
PDF
Stochastic Schrödinger equations
PPT
Talk at Quantopian.com quant finance meetup.
PDF
Stochastic calculus
PDF
Martingales Stopping Time Processes
PPTX
Trading For A Living
PPTX
Local and Stochastic volatility
PPTX
Trade The News
American option
Black Scholes pricing consept
Stochastic Schrödinger equations
Talk at Quantopian.com quant finance meetup.
Stochastic calculus
Martingales Stopping Time Processes
Trading For A Living
Local and Stochastic volatility
Trade The News
Ad

Similar to Local Volatility 1 (20)

PDF
Euler lagrange equation
PDF
Research Inventy : International Journal of Engineering and Science
PDF
Fourier series
PDF
Comparison Theorems for SDEs
PDF
Lesson 28: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus
PDF
Lesson 28: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus
PDF
Lesson 26: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus (slides)
PDF
Lesson 26: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus (slides)
PDF
Lesson 26: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus (slides)
PDF
System dynamics 3rd edition palm solutions manual
DOCX
1 d wave equation
ZIP
Desktop
PDF
On the Stick and Rope Problem - Draft 1
PDF
Engr 213 midterm 1a sol 2009
PDF
Engr 213 midterm 1b sol 2010
PDF
Lattices and codes
PDF
Lesson24 Implicit Differentiation Slides
PDF
Lesson 24: Implicit Differentiation
PDF
SOLVING BVPs OF SINGULARLY PERTURBED DISCRETE SYSTEMS
Euler lagrange equation
Research Inventy : International Journal of Engineering and Science
Fourier series
Comparison Theorems for SDEs
Lesson 28: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus
Lesson 28: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus
Lesson 26: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus (slides)
Lesson 26: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus (slides)
Lesson 26: The Fundamental Theorem of Calculus (slides)
System dynamics 3rd edition palm solutions manual
1 d wave equation
Desktop
On the Stick and Rope Problem - Draft 1
Engr 213 midterm 1a sol 2009
Engr 213 midterm 1b sol 2010
Lattices and codes
Lesson24 Implicit Differentiation Slides
Lesson 24: Implicit Differentiation
SOLVING BVPs OF SINGULARLY PERTURBED DISCRETE SYSTEMS

More from Ilya Gikhman (20)

PDF
Options pricing and hedging
PDF
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
PDF
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
PDF
equity, implied, and local volatilities
PDF
My pricing of american options
PDF
A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.
PDF
BS concept of the Dynamic Hedging
PDF
Remark on variance swaps pricing new
PDF
Bond Pricing and CVA
DOCX
Alternative option pricing and cva
PDF
Critical thoughts about modern option pricing
DOCX
портфель English
DOCX
ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ
PDF
Basic of pricing 2
PDF
Basic pricing
PDF
Option local and volatility 2 25 2014
PDF
Cambridge
PDF
Market risk and liquidity of the risky bonds
PDF
Cross currency swap
DOCX
Fixed rates modeling
Options pricing and hedging
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
CRITICAL POINT ON STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY OPTION PRICING.
equity, implied, and local volatilities
My pricing of american options
A short remark on Feller’s square root condition.
BS concept of the Dynamic Hedging
Remark on variance swaps pricing new
Bond Pricing and CVA
Alternative option pricing and cva
Critical thoughts about modern option pricing
портфель English
ЗАМЕЧАНИЕ К ПОСТРОЕНИЮ НЕ ИМЕЮЩЕГО РИСКА ПОРТФЕЛЯ
Basic of pricing 2
Basic pricing
Option local and volatility 2 25 2014
Cambridge
Market risk and liquidity of the risky bonds
Cross currency swap
Fixed rates modeling

Recently uploaded (20)

PPT
Fundamentals of Financial Management Chapter 3
PPT
KPMG FA Benefits Report_FINAL_Jan 27_2010.ppt
PDF
Pitch Deck.pdf .pdf all about finance in
PDF
DTC TRADIND CLUB MAKE YOUR TRADING BETTER
PPTX
ML Credit Scoring of Thin-File Borrowers
PDF
USS pension Report and Accounts 2025.pdf
PPTX
INDIAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM (Financial institutions, Financial Markets & Services)
PDF
The Role of Islamic Faith, Ethics, Culture, and values in promoting fairness ...
PPTX
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
PDF
The Right Social Media Strategy Can Transform Your Business
PDF
THE EFFECT OF FOREIGN AID ON ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ETHIOPIA
PPTX
Group Presentation Development Econ and Envi..pptx
PPTX
Lesson Environment and Economic Growth.pptx
PPTX
lesson in englishhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhh
PDF
GVCParticipation_Automation_Climate_India
PDF
3a The Dynamic Implications of Sequence Risk on a Distribution Portfolio JFP ...
PDF
4a Probability-of-Failure-Based Decision Rules to Manage Sequence Risk in Ret...
PDF
Financial discipline for educational purpose
PDF
Buy Verified Stripe Accounts for Sale - Secure and.pdf
PPTX
Grp C.ppt presentation.pptx for Economics
Fundamentals of Financial Management Chapter 3
KPMG FA Benefits Report_FINAL_Jan 27_2010.ppt
Pitch Deck.pdf .pdf all about finance in
DTC TRADIND CLUB MAKE YOUR TRADING BETTER
ML Credit Scoring of Thin-File Borrowers
USS pension Report and Accounts 2025.pdf
INDIAN FINANCIAL SYSTEM (Financial institutions, Financial Markets & Services)
The Role of Islamic Faith, Ethics, Culture, and values in promoting fairness ...
2. RBI.pptx202029291023i38039013i92292992
The Right Social Media Strategy Can Transform Your Business
THE EFFECT OF FOREIGN AID ON ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ETHIOPIA
Group Presentation Development Econ and Envi..pptx
Lesson Environment and Economic Growth.pptx
lesson in englishhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhhh
GVCParticipation_Automation_Climate_India
3a The Dynamic Implications of Sequence Risk on a Distribution Portfolio JFP ...
4a Probability-of-Failure-Based Decision Rules to Manage Sequence Risk in Ret...
Financial discipline for educational purpose
Buy Verified Stripe Accounts for Sale - Secure and.pdf
Grp C.ppt presentation.pptx for Economics

Local Volatility 1

  • 1. Remarks on Local Volatility. Ilya Gikhman 6077 Ivy Woods Ct Mason OH 45040 Ph. (513)-573-9348 Email: iljogik@yahoo.com Abstract. In this short notice some comments on local volatility are provided. The Black–Scholes (BS) model of the options pricing has advised a ‘fair’ price that interpreted as the PV of the ‘neutralized’ pay off value at maturity. In BS equation (BSE) the real stock return µ is replaced by the risk-free rate of return r. These parameters are assumed to be constants though the setting admits that µ, r, and volatility σ could be known deterministic functions on time t. If the market option prices are given one could calculate volatility of the underlying. This calculation leads to a notion known as implied volatility. If the model and calculation are perfect, this implied volatility value would be the same for the options with different strike prices and maturities. In reality the calculations show that this is not the case. Implied Black–Scholes volatilities highlight a strong dependence on maturity T and the strike price K. The dependence of the implied volatility on K and T is known as “smile” effect. The way how to solve the smile problem was presented in [1-3]. We briefly recall following [1] the main steps of this derivation. The risk- neutral stock price in the BS model is assumed to be written in the form d Sr ( t ) = r ( t ) dt + σ ( t ) dw ( t ) (*) Sr ( t ) Here w ( t ) is Wiener process on original probability space { Ω , F , P }. Denote C ( T , K ) the BS European call option price at the date t given S r ( t ) = x. Parameters T and K are maturity date and strike price correspondingly. In order to develop a solution of the smile problem it was assumed that 1 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1270153
  • 2. d Sr ( t ) = r ( t ) dt + σ ( t , S r ( t )) dw ( t ) Sr ( t ) Let φ T ( x ) denote the probability density of the solution of the equation (1). We put for simplicity r = 0. Then d Sr ( t ) = σ ( t , S r ( t )) dw ( t ) (1) Sr ( t ) Then C ( T , K ) = ∫ ( x - K ) + φ T ( x ) dx (2) Twice differentiation in (2) respect to K leads to the equality ∂ 2 C( T , K ) φT(K) = (3) ∂K 2 We pay attention only to martingale diffusions x ( t ) d x = b( x, t ) d W (4) Here diffusion coefficient b ( t , x ) ≥ δ 2 > 0 is unknown function. The Fokker-Planck ( Kolmogorov’s first ) equation for the density f ( t , x ) is ∂2 ∂f 2 (b2 f ) = (5) ∂x ∂t ∂2C As f = we obtain, after changing the order of derivatives: ∂x2 ∂2 ∂ 2 ∂C (b2 f ) = ∂ x2 ∂ x2 ∂ t ∂C Assuming that lim = 0 and integrating twice in x leads to the equation x→+∞ ∂t 1 2 ∂2C ∂C b 2 = (6) 2 ∂x ∂t Solving this equation for b we have 2 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1270153
  • 3. ∂ C ( x,t ) 2 ∂t b ( x,t ) = 2 (7) ∂ C ( x,t ) ∂ x2 Compare (1) and (4) we see that xσ(x,t) = b(x,t) (8) Reminding that ( x , t ) is actually ( K , T ) we rewrite (5) as 1 2 ∂2C ∂C b 2 = (9) 2 ∂K ∂T This equation has the same ‘flavor’ as the classical BSE but distinct from it by independent variables involved. Comments. I. First we remind that the underlying density is a function of the several variables. That is φ T ( x ) = φ ( t , y ; T , x ) where the variables y, x ∈ ( 0 , + ∞ ) are associated with the coordinate points for security price S (*) at dates t and T . The BS’s call option price is introduced above and is also the multivariable function C ( T , K ) = = C ( t , y ; T , K ). The equality (3) we present in the form ∂ 2 C ( t , y ;T , K ) φ(t,y;T,K) = ∂K 2 Here in the left hand side of the density φ its value is calculated at the point in which the pricing variable x = K though variables x > 0 and K> 0 have different meaning. The Fokker-Planck equation for the x-diffusion defined in (4) we rewrite in following form ∂2 ∂ f ( t , y; T , x ) 2 [ b 2 ( T , x ) f ( t , y ; T , x )] = (5′) ∂x ∂t If we wish to apply in (5′) the substitution ∂ 2 C( t , y;T, K ) f(t,y;T,K) = (10) ∂K 2 3 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1270153
  • 4. in which parameter K is considered as a parameter taking values from ( 0 , + ∞ ) we need to exchange the independent variable x on K that is the strike price coordinate. This transformation leads us to equality ∂2 ∂ 2 C( t , y; T , K ) ∂ ∂ 2 C( t , y; T , K ) [ b2(T , K ) ]= [ ] (5′′) ∂ x2 ∂K 2 ∂t ∂K 2 This equation shows that the substitution (10) does not replace x-diffusion by K-diffusion having the same finite distributions as it was done above. From general point of view it is difficult to expect that one could translate the diffusion (1) taking place in the ( x, t )- coordinate space into ( K, T )-diffusion implied by (9) with the help of (2). On the other hand if we define the ( K, T )-diffusion implied by (9) explicitly then there is no path wise connection this diffusion with ( x, t )-diffusion. ∂2C The substitution f = in (5) is correct only if f = φ T and the second derivatives in ∂x2 x here is actually the second derivatives in K. II. The assumption (1) could not be applied to the stock market. Indeed, in this case equation (1) is nonlinear and rate of return on 1, 2 or more stocks does not equal. Indeed sum of two equations (1) does not lead to the same type of equation with doubled initial condition. That means if an investor hold 2 the same stocks and one stock bring a dollar profit over a day then 2 stocks do not bring 2 dollars. The linearity of the stock prices is an axiom of the stock market and could not be violated at least in standard situations. Very Last remark. It also might be make sense to highlight BS pricing approach itself. The BS pricing is a theoretical approach that using mathematics attempts to construct a logical concept of the option price. If we logically assume that a stock has an expected return µ and volatility σ then BS price for a particular initial stock value x for given K and T will be the same regardless of µ. Thus for the same BS-premium one can get at maturity the right to buy a junk or a good stocks. This interpretation of the notion ‘price’ applied for the option contradicts the common sense. Note that another definition introduced in [4] does not present such confusion. Here we add a new remark to Local Volatility Concept. The solution C ( T , K ) = C ( t , x ; T , K ) , T > t of the problem (9) and satisfies initial condition C ( t , y ; t , K ) = max ( y – K , 0 ) (11) Thus, C ( t , x ; T , K ) is a solution of the Cauchy problem (9), (11) and it has “ the same ‘flavor’ as the classical Black–Scholes Equation. One distinction of the ( T , K )-Cauchy problem from its ( t , x ) counterpart is that the independent variables are different. We can change the direction of time by introducing new time variable. Denote fixed initial 4
  • 5. moment as t = t 0 and let T ∈ [ t 0 , T* ]. Introduce new variable t = T* – T + t 0 . ∂ ∂ Bearing in mind that = − the equation (9) can be rewritten as ∂T ∂t ~ ~ ∂C 1 2 ∂2C + b (t,K) = 0 (9′) ∂t 2 ∂K 2 ~ ~ Here C ( t , K ) = C ( T* , y ; t , K ) = C ( t – T* + T , y ; T* – t + t 0 , K ). The initial condition (11) given at t = t 0 corresponds to the terminal condition at t = T* for the solution (9′) ~ C ( T* , y ; T* , K ) = max ( y – K , 0 ) (11′) Cauchy problem (9′) , (11′) is similar to classical Black–Scholes Equation and the only difference is the diffusion coefficient in (9′). Recall that the risk neutral stock price in the BS model is assumed to be written in the form dS r ( t ) = r(t)dt + σ(t)dw(t) (*) S r (t) where w ( t ) is a Wiener process on original probability space { , F , P }. In smile problem we arrive at the equation (1) and let us replace the variable K by S. Recall that equations (*) and (1) are interpreted in the integral form and they have the same initial value S ( t 0 ) = x. Assume that initial value of In formula (4) it was used a Wiener process W ( t ) that can be differed from the Wiener process w ( t ) used in (*). Note that as far as we deal with strong solutions, i.e. the coefficients of the SDEs are assumed to be Lipchitz continuous functions the Wiener process in (1) , (4) could be chosen the same. For technical simplicity we put r = 0. Statement 1. Equalities (*) and (1) take place when and only when if σ ( t ) = b ( t , S ( t )) and therefore σ ( t , S ( t )) actually does not a random function and it is independ on S. Indeed, subtraction (1) from (1) leads to the equality t ∫ 0 [ σ ( t ) – b ( t , S ( t )) ] S ( t ) d w ( t ) = 0 Raising into second power and taking expectation leads us to equality t ∫ 0 E [ σ ( t ) – b ( t , S ( t )) ] 2 S 2 ( t ) d t = 0 Bearing in mind that S 2 ( t ) > 0 it follows that b ( t , S ( t )) = σ ( t ), where σ ( t ) is a nonrandom function . The case r ≠ 0 can be studied analogously. Hence, the smile underlying which corresponds to the (9′), (11′) either equal to the original security (*) or is a different unobservable diffusion process. 5
  • 6. References. 1. Dupire, B., “Pricing and Hedging with Smiles” , Research paper, 1993, p.9. 2. Dupire, B., “Pricing with a Smile”. Risk Magazine, 7, 1994, p.8-20. 3. Derman, E., and Kani,I., Riding on a smile, Risk, 7 (1994), p.32—33. 4. Gikhman, I., 2003, On Black-Scholes Equation ICFAI J.of Applied Finance, v.10, No.4, April 2004, p.47-74 ( http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=500303). 6